Skip to main content

Full text of "Dictionary of political economy"

See other formats


3Ju»im0  (Ear^lu^  (B^rWrr]^ 


Digitized  by  the  Internet  Archive 

in  2007  with  funding  from 

IVIicrosoft  Corporation 


http://www.archive.org/details/dictionaryofpoli01palguoft 


DICTIONAEY  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY 


i 


MACMILLAN  AND  CO.,  Limited 

LONDON  •  BOMBAY  •  CALCUTTA  ^ 
MELBOURNE 

THE  MACMILLAN    COMPANY 

NEW  YORK  •  BOSTON  •  CHICAGO 
DALLAS  •  SAN  FRANCISCO 

THE  MACMILLAN  CO.   OF  CANADA,  Ltd 

TORONTO 


^5^; 


^^ 


'"^^ — A 


NOV       7   1940 


DICTIONAKY 


OF 


POLITICAL    ECONOMY 


EDITED  BY 

Sir  ROBERT  HARRY  INGLIS  PALGRAVE,  RR.S. 


Omnia  mutantur  :  nihil  interit. 


VOL.   I. 

A— E 


MACMILLAN   AND    CO.,   LIMITED 

ST.    MARTIN'S    STREET,    LONDON 

1915 


Ore  trahit  quodcumque  potest  atque  addit  acervo. 


COPYRIGHT 

Printed  xZ()i, 

Reprinted  pages  1-256   with  Corrections,  1901,  1909 

Reprinted  with  Corrections  19 15 


TO   THE   DEAR   MEMORY   OF 


Sir  JFrancis  ^^algrafae,  It.Jg.,  anti  lElijaietl),  ILatig  ^algrabe 


HIS   PARENTS,    TEACHERS,    FRIENDS 

THIS   WORK   IS   DEDICATED   BY 
R.    H.    INGLIS    PALGRAVE 


INTEODUCTION   TO  VOLUME   I. 

The  complete  preface  to  a  book  naturally  cannot  be  written  till  the  work  itself  is 
finished ;  but  with  the  first  volume  some  remarks  by  way  of  introduction  will  be 
useful,  to  explain  the  object  for  which  this  work  has  been  written,  and  the  method 
on  which  it  is  arranged. 

The  primary  object  of  the  Dictionary  of  Political  Economy  is  to  provide  the 
student  with  such  assistance  as  may  enable  him  to  understand  the  position  of 
economic  thought  at  the  present  time,  and  to  pursue  such  branches  of  inquiry  as 
may  be  necessary  for  that  end. 

The  table  of  the  contents  of  the  work  shows  how  large  is  the  range  of 
investigation  which  the  student  must  follow  at  the  present  time. 

During  recent  years  the  course  of  economic  study  has  extended  so  widely 
that  it  was  obviously  impossible  to  restrict  the  work  to  the  old  and  formerly  well- 
recognised  boundaries.  The  development  of  the  historical  school  has  opened  out 
new  and  fertile  fields,  while  the  wants  of  those  who  follow  the  mathematical  method 
of  study  have  also  to  be  considered.  These  two  main  lines  of  treatment  are  here 
but  mentioned  as  examples.  They  are  far  from  exhausting  the  countless  ramifi- 
cations of  inquiry  now  rightly  thought  necessary  for  the  complete  investigation  of 
a  study  bounded  only  by  the  requirements  of  human  life  in  every  social  relation. 

In  making  the  selection  necessitated  by  the  limits  of  space,  the  requirements 
of  different  classes  of  students  have  throughout  been  borne  in  mind.  On  the 
one  side  purely  business  matters,  such  as  banking,  the  foreign  exchanges,  and  the 
operations  of  the  mint  come  in ;  on  the  other,  subjects  of  a  philosophical  character 
have  been  dealt  with,  such  as  questions  of  ethics  and  methods  of  definition, 
analysis,  and  reasoning ; — and  the  ways  in  which  diagrams  and  mathematical  pro- 
cesses may  lend  assistance  to  economic  inquiry  have  also  been  discussed.  Again, 
those  interested  in  historical  studies  require  an  explanation  of  words  found  in 
early  works,  and  those  derived  from  classical  and  mediaeval  times ;  also  of  legal 
phrases,  now  archaic,  together  with  the  modern  correlative  terms,  for  only  thus 
can  it  be  understood  how  ancient  usage  has  influenced  present  habit.  Life  in  the 
present  day,  even  in  the  most  modern  settlements  in  the  United  States,  in  our 
British  colonies,  in  the  new  countries  coming  into  existence  in  different  parts 
of  the  world,  is  influenced  largely  by  the  past.     The  stream  of  existence,  if  the 


vi  INTKODUCTION 


simile  may  be  permitted,  reaches  us  deeply  coloured  by  the  soil  of  the  fields 
through  which  it  has  flowed,  by  the  varied  strata  of  the  cliffs — some  of  them 
undermined  by  it — that  have  bounded  its  long  and  devious  course. 

Considerations  of  space  have  necessarily  confined  the  scope  of  the  work  mainly 
to  the  developments  of  economic  study  in  England,  the  United  States,  and  our 
English-speaking  colonies — and,  in  regard  to  these,  an  endeavour  has  been  made 
to  present  under  all  the  subjects  treated  an  account  of  the  best  and  most  recent 
authorities ;  whilst  the  opinions  held  in  other  countries  have  also,  as  far  as  the 
required  limits  allowed,  been  considered  and  mentioned. 

The  biographies  introduced  have  been  selected  with  the  same  end.  They 
show  what  has  actually  been  written  in  former  times,  and  hence  will  enable  the 
reader  to  trace  the  progress  of  economic  thought.  Much  attention  has  been 
given  to  the  less-known  writers.  It  is  difficult  for  the  student  under  ordinary 
circumstances  to  trace  out  when  such  authors  lived,  the  surroundings  which 
influenced  their  lives,  and  the  opinions  they  held.  While  the  oversights  in  science 
are  sometimes  as  remarkable  as  the  discoveries,  these  earlier  labourers  have  not 
unfrequently  been  the  precursors  of  other  and  better-known  men,  and  have  some- 
times anticipated  opinions  that  have  held  sway  for  long  periods  after  them. 

The  different  economic  schools  in  the  principal  countries  of  the  world  are 
also  described.  Thus  this  volume  contains  notices  of  the  American,  Austrian, 
Dutch  and  English  schools,  and  the  French,  German,  Italian,  and  Spanish  schools 
will  follow  in  due  course. 

A  work  extending  over  so  wide  a  range  of  subjects  is,  necessarily,  the  pro- 
duction of  many  minds,  of  writers  whose  pursuits,  occupations,  and  studies  are 
very  diverse  and  varied.  I  desire  to  record  my  warm  thanks  to  the  contri- 
butors to  the  book,  which  is,  I  think,  in  itself  an  almost  unique  example  of 
economic  co-operation.  Where  all  have  assisted  so  heartily,  it  is  less  easy  to 
select  individual  names ;  but  I  wish  to  be  allowed  to  express  my  special  thanks 
to  Professor  Dunbar,  Dr.  Keynes,  Professor  Marshall,  Professor  Montague,  Pro- 
fessor Nicholson,  Signor  M.  Pantaleoni,  Mr.  L.  R.  Phelps,  Mr.  L.  L.  Price,  Mr.  R 
Schuster,  Professor  H.  Sidgwick,  and  General  Walker  for  valuable  assistance  in 
different  directions,  and  particularly  to  Dr.  Bonar,  Professor  Edgeworth,  Mr. 
Henry  Higgs,  and  Mr,  H.  R.  Tedder,  who  have  kindly  helped  in  the  more 
arduous  labour  of  the  preparation  of  the  work  for  the  press. 

This  is  but  an  act  of  justice,  that  readers  may  know  to  whom  they  are  specially 

indebted. 

R.  H.  INGLIS  PALGRAVE 

Belton,  near  Great  Yarmouth, 

Christmas  189S. 

(Henstead  Hall,  Wrentham,  Suffolk, 

Midsummer  1914.) 


TABLE   OF   CONTENTS 


The  nunibers  immediatdy  following  the  headings  of  the  Articles  are  those  of  tlie  pages  on  which 
the  Articles  will  he  found.     Biographies  in  small  capitals. 


Abatemeat  or  Rebate,  1 

Abbot,  C,  Lord  Colchester,  1 

Abeille,  L.  p.,  1 

Abolitionist,  1 

About,  E.,  2 

Abrasion,  2 

Abroad  {see  Jurisdiction),  3 

Absentee,  3 

Abstinence,  4 

Abstract  of  Title,  5 

Abstract  Political  Economy,  5 

Abundance,  5 

'V.cceptance,  6 

Acceptilation,  6 

Acceptor,  6 

Accessio,  6 

Accession,  Deed  of  {see  Bank- 
ruptcy, Scotch),  6 

Accommodation  Bill,  6 

Account,  6 

Account  Duty  {see  Death  Duties), 
7 

Accounts,  Merchants'  {see  Pre- 
scription, Scotch),  7 

Accretion,  7 

Accrue,  7 

Accumulation,  7 

ACHBNWALL,  G.,  7 
ACKERSDYK,  J.,  8 

Acknowledgment,  8 

AcLAND,  Rev.  J.,  8 

Acquittance,  8 

Act  of  Bankruptcy  {see  Bank- 
ruptcy, Scotch),  8 

Actor  Seqiiitur  Forum  Rei  {see 
Jurisdiction),  8 

Actuary,  8 

Actus,  9 

Adams,  C.  F.,  9 

Addison,  J.,  9 

Ademption  of  Legacy,  9 

Adjustment,  Average,  9 

Administration,  10 

Administration,  Letters  of,  14 

Administrator,  15 

Adulteration,  15 

Ad  Valorem  Duty,  16 
[       Advances,  16 

Adventurers,  Merchants,  16 

Advice,  18 

African  Companies,  Early,  18 

African  Companies,  Recent,  19 


I 


Agazzini,  M.,  20 

Agency,  Law  of,  21 

Agents  of  Production,  21 

Agio,  22 

Agiotage  or  Agio,  22 

Agnati  (Adnati),  22 

Agricultural  Community,  22 

Agricultural  Gangs  {see  Gangs),  26 

Agricultural  Holdings  Acts,  26 

Agricultural  Systems,  27 

Agriculture  in  England,  27 

AicKiN,  Rev.  J.,  30 

Aid,  Auxilium,  30 

Aid ,  Rate  in  {see  Local  Taxation),  3  0 

Aides,  Cour  des,  30 

AiKiN,  J.,  30 

AlSLABIE,  J.,  30 

Alba  Firma,  30 

Alcavala,  30 

Alcock,  Rev.  T.,  31 

Aleatory,  31 

Ale-taster,  31 

Algarotti,  F.,  31 

Alienl  Juris,  31 

Aliens,  31 

Alison,  Sir  A.,  32 

Alison,  W.  P.,  32 

Allmend  {see  Agricultural  Com- 
munity), 32 

Allonge,  32 

Allotment,  32 

Allowance,  Tare,  33 

Allowance  System,  33 

Alloy,  34 

Alod,  Alodial  Land,  35 

Alternative  Standard,  35 

Althusitjs,  J.,  36 

Altruism,  37 

Amana  Society,  The,  37 

Amercements,  37 

American  School  of  Political 
Economy,  37 

Amortisation,  88 

Amsterdam,  Bank  of  {see  Banks, 
Early  European),  38 

Analytical  Method,  38 

Anarchism,  38 

Anatocismus,  39 

Anderson,  A.,  39 

Anderson,  J,,  39 

Anderson,  J.  (No.  2),  40 

Angarie,  Droit  d',  40 


Angel,  40 

Anna,  40 

Annates,  40 

Annealing,  40 

Annual  Rent,  Scotch,  40 

Annuity,  40 

Ansell,  C,  42 

Antedate,  42 

Antichresis,  42 

Anti- Corn-Law  League,  42 

Anti-Rent  Agitations,  42 

Antoninus,  St.,  43 

A  Posteriori  reasoning,  43 

Appanage,  43 

Appleton,  N.,  43 

Applied  Economics,  44 

Apportionment  (No.  1),  44 

Apportionment  (No.  2),  44 

Appraisers,  45 

Appreciation  of  Standard,  45 

Apprenticeship,  45 

Apprenticeship,  Statute  of,  46 

Appropriation,  47 

Approved  Bill,  47 

A  Priori  reasoning,  47 

Aquinas,  St.  Thomas,  48 

Arable      Land,     Conversion     to 

Pasture  in  Great  Britain,  49 
Arbitrage  (Stock  Ex.),  50 
Arbitrage  (General  Business),  50 
Arbitrage  (Exchange),  50 
Arbitration   between    Employers 

and  Employed,  51 
Arbitration,  Scotch,  52 
Arbuthnot,  J.,  52 
Arbuthnot,    J.,     of     Mitcham, 

52 
Arco,  G.  G.,  DEI  CoNTi  d'Arco,  52 
Argenson,  R.  L.  de  Voter  db 

Paulmy,  Marquis  de,  52 
Argentarii,  52 
Aristocracy,  52 
Aristotle,  53 
Arithmetic,  Political,  55 
Arithmetic,     Political,      History 

of,  56 
Arithmetical  Ratio,  67 
Aries  or  An-hes,  57 
Armed  Neutrality,  57 
Armstrong,  C,  57 
Arnd,  K.,  68 
Arnould,  a.  M.,  68 


VIU 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


Arrangement  with  Creditors  {see 
Bankruptcy),  58 

Arrangement,  Deed  of,  58 

Arrears,  58 

Arrest,  68 

Arrestment  (Scots  Law),  58 

Arrestment  Jurisdictionis  Fun- 
dan  dse  causa  {see  Jurisdiction, 
Scotch),  58 

Arbivabene,  G.,  Count,  58 

Art  of  Political  Economy,  58 

Art^l,  59 

Articles  of  Apprenticeship,  59 

Articles  of  Association,  59 

Articles  of  Roup  (Scotch),  60 

Artisan,  60 

Arts  and  Crafts  {see  Corporations 
of  Arts  and  Trades),  60 

As,  60 

ASGILL,  J,,  60 

ASHBURTON,  A.  B.,  60 

Ashley,  J.,  60 

Assay,  60 

Assessed  Taxes,  61 

Assessment,  61 

Assets,  62 

Assiento  Treaty,  62 

Assignat.  62 

AssignatioL-  (Scots  Law  Term),  64 

Assignee,  64 

Assigment,  64 

Assignment,  Deed  of,  64 

Assignor,  64 

Assize  of  Bread  and  Beer,  64 

Assize  of  Weights  and  Measures, 

64 
Assumption,  Deed  of  (Scots  Law 

Term),  65 
Assurance  {see  Insurance),  65 
Assythment  (Scots  Law),  65 
Ateliers  Nationaux,  66 
Atkinson,  W.,  66 
Attachment,  6Q 
Attestation,  67 
Attorney,  Power  of,  67 
Attornment,  67 
Attwood,  T.,  67 
Attwood,   T.,   and  Birmingham 

School,  67 
Aubaine,  Droit  d',  68 
Auckland,  W.  E.,  Lord,  68 
Auction,  68 
AuDiFFBET,  C.  L.  Gr.,  Marquis  d', 

68 

AUDIQANNE,  A.,  69 

Audit,  69 

Audit  (Scots  Law),  71 

Audit  Office,  71 

Auditor  of  Court  of  Session,  72 

Augmentations,  Court  of,  72 

AUGUSTINIS,  M.  DE,  72 

Aulnager,  72 

Auncel,  or  Handsal  Weight,  73 

Austrian  School  of  Economists, 
73 

Authorities,  Economic  {see  Politi- 
cal Economy,  Authorities  on), 
73 


Autumnal  Drain,  73 

AUXIBON,  C.  F.  J.  d',  74 

Average,  74 

Average  (Maritime),  74 

Award,  75 

AzuNi,  D.  A.,. 75 

Babbagb,  C,  75 

Babeuf,  F.  N.,  77 

Back-Bond  (Scots  law  term),  78 

Backwardation,  78 

Bacon,  F.  (Viscount  St.  Albans), 

78 
Badger,  78 
Bagehot,  W.,  79 
Bailee,  82 
Bailey,  S.,  82 
Bailey,  S.,  on  Value,  82 
Baily,  F.,  83 
Baines,  E.,  83 
Bainbs,  SirE.,  83 
Baines,  T.,  84 
Bairn's  part  of  Gear  {see  Legitim), 

84 
Bakounin,  M.,  84 
Balance  of  Trade,  84 
Balance    of    Trade,    History  of 

the  Theory,  85 
Balance  Sheet,  88 
Balance  Sheet  (2nd  Statement), 

88 
Balbi,  a.,  89 
Baldwin,  L.,  90 
Balsamo,  p.,  90 
Bamford,  S.,  90 
Ban,  90 
Banalites,  90 
Banco,  90 
Bandini,  S.  a.,  91 
Banfield,  T.  C,  91 
Banking,  91 — 

Bank  of  England,  92 
Banks,  England  and  Wales,  93 
do.     Scotland,  95 
do.     Ireland,  96 
do.     India  and  Colonies,  97 
Bank  of  France,  97 
French  banks,  98 
Bank  of  Germany,  98 
German  banks,  99 
Chartered  Banks  in  Scotland, 

100 
Banks  in  Canada,  100 
Banks,  National,  United  States, 

America,  102 
Early  European  Banks — 
Amsterdam,  104 
Genoa,  104 
Hamburgh,  105 
Middleburgh,  106 
Rotterdam,  106 
Sweden,  104 
Venice,  103 
Land  Banks,  106 

do.     Germany,  106 
Popular  Banks,  Germany,  109 

do.     Italy,  109 
Savings  Banks,  110 


Bank  Note,  111 

Bank  Note,  Laws  in  different 

Countries,  112 
Bank  Note,   United  States  ol 
America,  113 

Bankruptcy  in  Scotland,  114 

Bankruptcy  Law  and  Administra- 
tion (England),  116 

Banvin,  droit  de,  118 

Barbary  Co.  {see  Turkey  Co.),  119 

Babbon,  N.,  119 

Baring,  Sir  F.,  Bart,,  121 

Babnabd,  Sir  J.,  121 

Barrator,  121 

Babbington,  Bishop  S.,  121 

Barter,  121 

Barter  and  Exchange,  122 

Barton,  J.,  122 

BASTLA.T,  F.,  123 

Bastiat  as  a  Theorist,  124 

Batbie,  a.  p.,  124 

Bate's  Case,  or  the  Case  of  Im- 
positions, 126 

Baudeau,  N.,  Abb6,  126 

Baudi,  C.  di  v.,  126 

Baumstabk,  R,  125 

Baxter,  R.  D.,  126 

Bazaar,  126 

Bazard,  Saint- a.,  127 

Bear,  127 

Bearer  (Securities),  127 

Beccaria,  C.  B.  (Marquis),  127 

Becheb,  J.  J.,  128 

Beckmann,  J.,  128 

Bede  (Manor),  128 

Beeke,  Rev.  H.,  129 

Beldam,  129 

Bell,  W.,  129 

Bellebs,  J.,  129 

Bellitti,  G.,  129 

Belloni,  G.,  129 

Benefice  (1),  130 

Benefice  (2),  130 

Beneficium     Cedendarum     Acti- 
onum  (Scots  law  Term),  130 

Beneficium  Competentiae,  130 

Beneficium  Divisionis  (Scots  law), 
130 

Beneficium  Excussionis,  130 

Beneficium  Inventarii,  130 

Benevolences,  130 

Bbntham,  J.,  131 

Bequest,  Powe^  of,  133 

Bebkeley,  G.,  Bishop  of  Cloyne, 
134 

Berlin   Decrees  {see  Continental 
System),  135 

Bernabd,  Sir  T.,  135 

Bebnhaedi,  T.  von,  135 

Bbsold,  C,  135 

Betterment,  136 

Bettemess,  138 

Bezants,  139 

bla.nchini,  l.,  139 

Biblia,  F.,  139 

BiDDLE,  N.,  139 

BiEL,  G.,  140 

BiGBLOw,  E.  B.,  LL.D.,  140 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


BUI  Broking,  140 

Bill  of  Exchange,  142 

Bill  of  Exchange,  Law  of,  143 

Bill  of  Lading,  145 

Bill  of  Sale,  145 

Billon,  146 

Bi-Metallism,  146 

Birth-rate,  150 

BiUNDi,  G.,  151 

Black,  D.,  151 

Black  Death,  The,  151 

Blackleg,  153 

Blairie,  Droit  de,  153 

Blakb,  W.,  153 

Blanc,  J.  J.  L.,  153 

Bland  Act,  154 

Blank  Credit,  155 

Blank  Endorsement,  155 

Blank  Transfer,  155 

Blanqui,  J.  A.,  155 

Blench  (Scots  law  term),  155 

Blockade,  156 

Board,  156 

Board  of  Agriculture  (1793),  156 

Board  of  Agriculture  and   Fish' 

eries,  157 
Board  of  Trade,  158 
Boarding-out  System,  159 
BoccHi,  K,  160 
BocKH,  A.,  160 
Bocland,  160 
BODIN,  J.,  160 

Body  Corporate,  Covi)oration,  161 
BCECLER,  J.  H.,  161 
BOILEAU  (or  BOYLEAU),   E.,  161 
BOISGUILLEBERT,  P.,  162 
BOLLES,  J.  A.,  162 
BOLLMAN,  J.  E.,  M.D.,  162 
Bon,  162 
Bona  fide,  162 
Bona  notabilia,  163 
Bona  vacantia,  163 
Bonce  RF,  P.  F.,  163 
Bond,  163 
Bond  of  Caution  (Scots  Law  Term, 

— see  Caution),  163 
Bond    of    Corroboration    (Scots 

law),  163 
Bond  and  Disposition  in  Security, 

163 
Bond  of  Belief  (Scots  law  term), 

163 
Bonded  Warehouses,  163 
Bonnet,  V.,  164 
Bonorum  Possessio,  164 
Bonus,  164 

Book  account  credit,  164 
Book-keeping,  164 

Do.     Logismography,  165 
Book  of  Rates,  167 
Boom,  168 
Booty,  168 
BORNITZ,  J.,  168 
Borough,  168 
Borough  English,  168 
BOSANQUET,  C,  168 
BOSBLLINI,  C,  169 
Boston  Port  Bill,  169 


BoTERO,  G.,  169 
Bottomry,  Loan  on,  169 

BOULAINVILLIERS,  H.  DE,  170 

Bounties,  171 

Bounties,  Abstract  Theory  of,  172 

Bounties  on  Sugar,  173 

Bourgeois,  174 

Bourse,  174 

Bourse  du  Travail,  174 

BowEN,  F.,  175 

BoxHORN,  M.  Z.,  175 

Boycotting,  175 

Bradlaugh,  C,  175 

Brands  and  other  Certificates  of 
Quality,  Government,  175 

Brassage,  176 

Brassey,  T.,  176 

Bray,  C,  176 

Bray,  J.  F.,  177 

Breach  of  Trust  (Scots  criminal 
law  term),  177 

Breach  of  Trust,  177 

Breck,  S.,  177 

Brehon  law,  178 

Brevi  Manu  Traditio,  178 

Brewster,  Sir  F,,  178 

Briganti,  F.,  179 

Bright,  J.,  179 

Brindley,  J.,  179 

Briscoe,  J.,  179 

Brissot  de  Warville,  J. p.,  179 

Broqgla,  a.,  180 

Broker,  General,  180 

Broker,  Stock,  181 

Brokerage,  181 

Brougham,  H,,  Lord,  181 

Brown,  J.,  181 

Brydges,  Sir  E.,  181 

Bubble  Act,  182 

Bubbles,  History  of,  182 

Buchanan,  D.,  183 

BucHEZ,  P.  J.  B.,  184 

Buckle,  T.  H.,  184 

Budget,  The,  185 

Building  Societies,  188 

BuLAU,  F.  von,  190 

Bull,  190 

Bull  of  Borgia,  190 

Bullion,  191 

Bullion  Committee,  Report  of, 
191 

Buonarroti,  P.,  192 

BuQUOY,  G.  F.,  Count,  192 

Bureau  of  Labour,  192 

Bureau  of  Labour  in  U.S.,  193 

Bureaucracy,  193 

Buret,  A.  E.,  194 

Burgh,  194 

Burgher  {see  Citizen),  194 

buridan,  j.,  194 

Burke,  E.,  194 

burlamaqui,  j.  j.,  195 

Burton,  J.  Hill  {see  Hill  Bur- 
ton, J.),  195 

BuscH,  J.  G.,  195 

BtJscHiNQ,  A.  F.J  196 

Butel-Dumont,  G.  M.,  196 

Butlerage,  196 


Buying  in,  196 
By-law,  Byelaw,  196 
By-product,  197 

By-products,  Theory  of  Value  o5 
197 

Caret,  E.,  197 

Cable  Transfer,  199 

Cadastral  Survey,  199 

Cadet,  F.,  200 

Cagnazzi,  L.  S.,  200 

Cairnes,  J.  E.,  201 

Caisse,  203 

Call,  203 

Calonne,  C.  a.  de,  204 

Calvin,  J.,  204 

Cambage,  Droit  de,  206 

Cambist   {see  Exchange  Broker)^ 

206 
Cambon,  p.  J.,  206 
Cambreleng,  C.  C,  207 
Canieralistic  Science,  207 
Camerarius,  J,,  208 
Campanella,  T.,  208 
Campomanes,  p.  R.,  208 
Canals,  208 
Canard,  N.  F.,  209 
Cancel,  Cancellation,  209 
Cancrin,  G.,  210 
Candareen,  210 
Canning,  G.,  210 
Canon  Law,  211 
Cantalupo,  D.,  214 
Cantillon,  p.,  214 
Cantillon,  R.,  214 
Capello,  p.  a.,  217 
Capitainerie,  217 
Capital,  217— 

History  of  the  Word,  221 

Legal  ruling  that  Capital  need 
not  be  replaced  from  Profits, 
221 

Rarely  permanent,  222 
Capitation  (in  France),  223 
Capitation  Taxes,  223 
Caraccioli,  D.,  224. 
Carafa,  D.,  224 
Carbonari,  225 
Cardozo,  I.  N.,  225 
Carey,  H.  C,  225 
Carey.  M.,  227 
Carli,  G.  R.,  227 
Carlyle,  T.,  227 
Carolus  (English),  228 
Carolus  Dollar,  228 
Carrier,  Common,  228 
Carrying  Over,  228 
Carrying  Trade,  228 
Cartel,  229 
Cartograra,  229 
Carucage,  229 
Gary,  J.,  230 

Casaregis,  J.  L.  M.  DE,  230 
Case   of  Need  {see  BiU  of  Ex- 

change),  230 
Cash,  Money,  230 
Cash  (or  Li),  230 
Cash  Account,  231 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


Cash  Credit,  231 

Cash,  Sale  for,  231 

Cashier,  231 

Caste,  231 

Casuel,  233 

Casus,  233 

Catallactics,  233 

Catasto,  233 

Cattanbo,  C,  234 

Cattle  Plague  Orders,  234 

Caution  (Scots  Law  Term),  234 

Caution,  234 

Caveat,  234 

Caveat  Emptor,  234 

Cavour,  Count  C.  B.  Di,  234 

Caylet,  E.,  237 

Cedula,  237 

Cens,  237 

Census,  238 

Census,  United  States,  243 

Cent,  Centesimo,  or  Centavo,  250 

Cent,  Dutch,  250 

Centesimi,  Centimes,  Centimos. 
250 

Centralisation,  250 

Certainty,  251 

Certificate,  Share,  251 

Cbsare,  C.  de,  252 

Cess,  252 

Cessio  Bonorum  {see  Bankruptcy, 
Scotch),  252 

Cessionary  (Scots  law  terra),  252 

Ceva,  G.,  252 

Chadwick,  Sir  E.,  252 

Chaffer,  254 

Chalmers,  G.,  254 

Chalmers,  T.,  255 

Chamberlayne,  E.,  256 

Chamberlen,  H.,  257 

Chambers  of  Agriculture,  257 

Chambers  of  Commerce,  258 

Chambre  Ardente,  260 

Chamillart,  M.  de,  260 

Champart,  260 

Champion  and  Severalty,  260 

Change,  Abbreviation  for  Ex- 
change, 261 

Change  (Agents  de),  261 

Chapman,  262 

Charging  Order,  262 

Charitable  Foundations,  262 

Charitable  Institutions,  264 

Charity,  265 

Charity  Organisation,  266 

Charity,  State,  268 

Charter,  271 

Charter  Party,  271 

Chartism,  271 

The  Points  of  the  Charter, 

272 

Chastbllux,  F.  J.,  Marquis  de, 
273 

Chattel  or  Chattel  Personal,  273 

Checks  on  Population,  273 

Cheques,  Law  of,  273 

Chbrbulibz,  a.  E.,  274 

Chevage,  274 

Chevalier,  M.,  276 


Chickebinq,  J.,  M.D.,  277 

Chief  Kent   {see  Eent   Charge), 

277 
Child,  Sir  J.,  277 
Childrens'  Labour  (Factory  Acts), 

277 
Chiminage,  '279 
Chitti,  L.,  279 
Chorogram,  279 
Choses  in  Action,  279 
Choses  in  Possession,  279 
Chrematistic  (or  Money-making), 

279 
Christian  Socialism,  280 
Christianity  and  Economics — 

Church,  the  Mediaeval,  Econ- 
omic Influence  of,  280 

Koman     Catholic     School     of 
Economics,  283 

Influence  of  Protestant  Thought 
on   Economic    Opinion  and 
Practice,  285 
Chronogram  and  Hexogram,  287 
Church  Seed,  287 
Cibrario,  G.  A.  L.,  Count,  287 
Cinque  Ports,  287 
Ciompi,  288 

Circulating  Medium,  288 
Citation  {see  Jurisdiction,  Scotch), 

288 
Citation,  288 
Cite  Ouvriere,  288 
Citizen,  289 
City- 
Ancient,  290 

Mediaeval,  292 

Modern,  295 
City   of  London,    Companies   of 

{see  Companies,  City  of  Lon- 
don), 297 
Civil  Law,  297 
Civil  List,  300 
Civilisation,  302 
Clarkson,  T.,  303 
Classical  Economists,  303 
Classification,  303 
Clay,  H.,  304 
Clayton,  D.,  305 
Clearing  System — 

Clearing  Houses,  305 

London      Bankers'      Clearing 
House,  306 

Provincial    Clearing     Houses, 
307 

Foreign  Clearing  Houses,  307 

Statistics,  309 

Other  Classes  of  Clearings,  310 

Stock  Exchange  Clearing,  310 

Beetroot  Sugar  Association,  310 

London  Produce  Clearing,  311 

Railway  Clearing,  311 

Cotton  Clearing,  311 
Clement,  A.,  312 
Clement,  P.,  312 
Clement,  S.,  312 
Clergy,  Benefit  of,  313 
Client,  313 
Client,  Stockbroker's,  313 


Clipfe  Leslie  {see  Leslie,  T.  E. 

C),  313 
Clipped  Money,  313 
Cloff  or  Clough,  313 
Coalitions    {see    Trade   Unions), 

313 
Coasting  Trade,  313 
Cobbett,  W.,  314 
COBDEN,  R,  316 
Cochut,  p.  a.,  317 
Code  Napoleon,  317 
Codicil,  318 

Coinage,  The  Right  of,  318 
Coinage,    Decimal    {see  Deoimal 

System),  318 
Coke,  R.,  318 
Colbert,  J.  B.,  319 
Collateral  Security  {see  Caution), 

320 
Collation   {see  Succession,   Scot- 
land), 320 
Collect,  320 
Collective  Goods,  320 
Collectivism,  320 
Collegium,  320 
Colonies — 

Colonies,  description  of,  321 

Colonial  Policy,  322 

Colonial  Lands,  323 

Public     Debts     of     Colonies 
324 

Trade  and  the  Flag,  324 

Methods  of  Government,  326 

Currency  in  British  Colonies, 
326 

Denominational    Currency  in, 
328 

Government  of,  by  Companies, 
329 

Systems  of  Colonisation,  333 
Colquhoun,  Patrick,  334 
COLTON,  Rev.  Calvin,  335 
CoLWELL,  Stephen,  335 
Combination — 

Production,  335 

Distribution,  336 

Production  and   Distribution, 
336 

Distribution  and  Consumption, 

336 
Combination  Laws,  336 
Comfort,  Standard  of,  337 
Commandite,  Society  en,  338 
Commerce,  338 
Commerce  British  (History  of), 

341 
Commercial  Instrument,  346 
Commercial  Law,  346 
Commercial  Routes  (History  of), 

347 
Commercial  Science,  351 
Commercial  System,  351 
Commercial  Treaties,  354 
Commissary  {see  Succession,  Scot- 
land), 355 
Commission  Agent,  355 
Commissions  of  Enquiry,  355 
Commissions,  Judicial,  356 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


Commissioner  {see  Factor),  357 
Commissioners    of    Sequestrated 
Estate  {see  Bankruptcy,  Scot- 
land), 357 
Committee  (Lunacy),  357 
Committee  of  Inspection,  357 
Commodatum,  357 
Commodity,  357 
Common  Assurance,  358 
Common  Employment,   Doctrine 

of,  358 
Common  Good  (Scotland),  358 
Commons,  358 
Commonty  (Scotch),  360 
Commune,  360 

Commune  of  Paris  (1871),  361 
Communication,  Means  of,  361 
Communio,  362 
Communism,  362 
Compagnonnages,  367 
Companies — 

Companies,  English  and  Scotch 

Law,  368 
Increase  of,  369 
Influence  on  Business,  370 
Companies,  City  of  London,  371 
Companies,  Staple,  373 
Companies,  Trading  (see  Foreign 
Trade,  Regulation  of),  375 
Compensation,  375 
Competition  and  Custom,  376 
Competition      and      Eegulation, 

378 
Complementary  Goods,  380 
Composition    {see    Bankruptcy), 

880 
Compound  Interest,  380 
Compromise  (Scots  law),  380 
Comptes,  Chambre  des,  380 
Compulsory  Pilotage,  380 
Compulsory  Preference,  381 
Compulsory  Taking  of  Land,  381 

COMTE,  AUQUSTE,   381 

CoMTE,  Aug.  ,  and  English  Politi- 
cal Economy,  382 
COMTB,  Chas.,  383 
Concession,  384 
Conciliation,  Boards  of,  384 
Concourse  (Scots  Law),  385 
Concurrence  (Scotland),  385 
CoNDiLLAC,  E.  B.  de,  385 
Conditioning,  385 
CONDORCET,  M.  C,  Marquis  de, 
386 

CONDUITT,  J.,  387 

Confident  Person  {see  Bankruptcy, 

Scotland),  387 
Confirmation  of  Executor  (Scots 

Law),  387 
Conflict  of  Laws  (Foreign),  387  ; 

(Domestic),  387 
Confusio,  387 
Conjunctur,  387 
Conquest,  388 
CONRINQ,  H.,  388 
Conscription,  388 
Conseils  de  Prud'hommes,  389 
Consideration,  389 


Consignee,  389 

Consolidated  Fund,  389 

Consolidatio,  390 

Consols,  390 

Conspiracy,  Common-Law  Doc- 
trine of,  390 

Constitutum  debiti,  391 

Constitutum  possessorium,  391 

Consul,  391 

Consular  Reports,  391 

Consumables  {see  Consumptibles), 
392 

Consumers'  Goods  (or  Consump- 
tion Goods),  392 

Consumers'  Rent,  392 

Consuniptibles.  A  term  em- 
ployed by  the  Schoolmen,  393 

Consumptibles  (Modern  Economic 
Term),  393 

Consumption,  393 

Consumption,  Taxes  on,  395 

Continuation  or  Contango,  396 

Continental  System,  396 

Contraband,  398 

Contract,  399 

Contract,  Law  of,  401 

Contract  Note,  402 

Contractors,  402 

Contractus  Trinus  {see  Eck, 
Johann),  402 

Contribution,  Contributory  {see 
Company),  402 

Convention  of  Royal  Burghs  of 
Scotland,  403 

Conventional  Tariff",  403 

Conventional  Value,  404 

Conversion  of  British  National 
Debt,  404 

Conversion,  Colonial  and  Foreign 
Stocks,  405 

Conversion  of  Aralile  Land  into 
Pasture  in  England,  406 

Convertibility  of  Bank  Notes,  407 

Conveyance,  408 

Coolie  System,  408 

Cooper,  T.  (1759-1840),  408 

Cooper,  T.  (1805-1892),  408 

Co-operation,  409 

Co-operative  Associations,  409 

Co-operative  Farming,  413 

Co-operative  Workshops,  415 

Co  -  operation.  Partial  (Oldham 
Cotton  Spinning  Companies), 
417 

Co-operation,  Social  Aspects  of, 
418 

Coparceners,  420 

Copernicus,  Nicolaus,  420 

COPLESTON,  E.  (Bishop  of  Llan- 
daff),  420 

Copper  Money  (England),  421 

Copper  Money  (Sweden),  421 

Copyhold,  422 

Copyright,  422 

Literary  Copyright,  422 
Dramatic  Copyright,  422 
Works  of  Art;  422 
Designs,  422 


Copyright  in  Foreign  Countries, 

422 
International  Copyright,  422 
Basis  of  Copyright,  423 

coquelin,  c,  423 

Corbet,  T.,  423 

corbetta,  e.,  423 

Corn  Laws,  423 

Corn  Rents,  426 

Corn  Returns,  426 

Cornage,  426 

Corner  on  Stock  Exchange,  427 

CORNIANI,  G.,  427 

Corporation,  Municipal,  427 

Corporation,  Aggregate,  428 

Corporation,  Sole,  428 

Corporations  of  Arts  and  Trades — 
England,  428 
France,  430 
Germany,  431 

CORTI,  A.,  432 

CORVAIA,  Baron,  432 

Corvee,  432 

CoRVETTO,  L,-E.,  Comte  de,  433 

Coshery,  434 

Cost  (Comparative  and  Relative), 
434 

Cost,  in  the  Sense  of  Price,  434 

Cost  Book,  434 

Cost  of  Collection  of  Taxes,  435 

Cost  of  Labour  (see  Cost  of  Pro- 
duction), 437 

Cost  of  Production,  437 

Cost,  Relative  {see  Cost,  Compara- 
tive), 439 

Cottiers,  439 

Cotton  Famine  (1861-65),  439 

Cotton  Lists,  441 

Cotton,  Sir  R  B.,  441 

Coulisse,  441 

Council      Bills     (India    Council 
Drawings),  442 

Countervailing  Duty,  443 

County  Borough,  443 

County  Council,  443 

County  Rate,  444 

Coupon,  444 

CouRCY,  A.  de,  444 

CouRNOT,  A.  A.,  445 

Court,  P.  de  la,  447 

Court  Rolls,   Manorial  Accounts 
and  Extents,  447 

Courten,  Sir  W.,  1572-1636  {see 
Interlopers),  448 

Courtier,    Broker    {see    Change, 
Agents  de),  448 

Courts  of  Law  (England),  448 

Courts  (Ireland),  449 

Courts  (Scotland),  449 

Coverture,  450 

COWELL,  J.  W.,  450 

Cowrie,  450 

CoxE,  T.,  450 

Cradocke,  F.,  451 

Craft  Guilds  {see  Corporations  of 
Arts  and  Trades),  451 

Craig,  John,  451 

Credit,  451 


^u 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


Credit,  Influence  on  Prices,  452 
Credit  Foncier  of  France,  454 
Credit,  Letter  of,  455 
Criminal  Prosecution,  455 
Crises,  Commercial  and  Financial, 

455 
Crises  (1857-1866-1890),  462 
Crises,  Periodicity  of,  466 
Crombib,  a.,  467 
Crome,  a.  F.  W.,  467 
Cross  Drawing,  468 
Crossed  Cheque,  468 
Crown  Debts,  468 
Crown,  English  (Gold  Coin),  468  ; 

Silver  Coin,  468 
Crown  (Scandinavian),  468 
Crown  Lands,  469 
Crumpe,  S.,  469 
Crusade,  469 

Crusades,  Economic  Effects  of,  469 
Culpa,  470 

CULPEPER,  Sir  T.  (the  elder),  470 
CuLPBPEB,  Sir  T.  (the  younger), 

470 
Culture,  Large  and  Small,  470 
Cum  Dividend,  472 
Curator  Bonis,  472 
Currency,  472 
Currency  Doctrine  or   Principle, 

472 
Curves,  473 
CusTODi,  P.,  474 
Custodia,  474 

Custom,  Customs  Duties,  474 
Custom,  Habit,  476 

Dairb,  K,  477 

Dalbiac,  General  Sir  J.  C,  478 

Dalrymplb,  Sir  J, ,  478 

Damages,  478 

Damages,  Measure  of,  479 

Dameth,  H.,  479 

Damnum  Emergens,  479 

Damnum  Fatale  (Scot),  480 

Danegeld,  480 

Dangeul,  Marquis  de  Plum  art, 

480 
Darg,  481 
Daric,  481 

Darien  Company,  481 
Darwinism,  481 
Date  of  Drawing,  482 
Davach,  482 
Davanzati,  B,,  482 
Davbnant,  C,  483 
Davies,  David,  D.D.,  484 
Davila,  el  Padre  Bautista,  485 
Davila  y  Lugo,  Don  Francisco, 

485 
Day,  Day  Work,  and  Diet,  485 
Days  of  Grace,  485 
Dead  Freight,  486 
Deadly,  Warrandice  against  All 

(Scot.),  486 
Dead  Eent,  486 
Dead's  Part  (Scot.),  486 
Deadweight  Annuity,  486 
Dealer  (Stock  Exchange),  486 


Dearness,  Artificial,  487 
Dearth  (see  Famine),  490 
Death  Duties,  490 
Death-rate — 

Analysis,  Definition  of  Subject, 
493 

Death -rate   as   Factor  in   in- 
crease of  Population,  493 

Causes  of  variation  in  Death- 
rate,  494 

Death-rate,  as  indicating   Na- 
tional Prosperity,  497 

In  relation  to  Insurance,  497 
Debasement  of  Coin,  History  of 

the,  498 
Debenture,  501 
Debenture  Stock,  502 
Debit,  503 

Debitum  Fundi  (Scot.),  503 
Debouches  Theorie  des,  503 
Db  BROUCKiiRB,  C,  503 
Debt- 
Debt,  503 

Imprisonment  for,  504 

Debtor  and  Creditor,  Law  of, 
505 

Debtor's  Summons,  506 
Debts,  Public,  506 
Debt,  Public,  Statement  of,  509 
Debts,      Public,     Local,     Great 

Britain  and  Ireland,  509 
De    Cardenas    di    Maqueda, 

D.  R.,  513 
Decentralisation,  513 
Decimal  System  (Coinage,  Weights 

and  Measures),  514 
Decime,  518 
Decimes,  518 
Decker,  Sir  M.,  518 
Declaration  of  Paris,  520 
Declaration  of  War,  521 
Declared  and  Real  Values,  521 
Decreasing  Returns  {see  Diminish- 
ing Returns),  522 
Decree   of    Registration   (Scot.), 

522 
Deductive  Method,  523 
Deed  (Scot.),  526 
Deed  of  Arrangement,  527 
Deed  Poll,  529 
Defalcation,  529 
Defence,  529 
Defence,  Cost  of,  529 
Deferred  Payments,  532 
Deferred  Stock,  532 
Deficiency  Advances,  533 
Deficiency  Bills,  533 
Deficit,  533 
Definitions,  534 
Defoe,  D.,  535 
Degree  of  Utility,  536 
Db  la  Court  {see  Court,  Pieter 

de  la),  537 
De  LajonchIcre,  537 
De  la  Mare,  N.,  537 
Del  Credere,  537 
Delegation,  537 
Delfico,  M.,  537 


Delictum,  538 

Delivery  (of  Bills  of  Exchange), 

538 
Delivery  (of  Deeds, — see  Deed), 

538 
Delivery  (of  Chattels),  538 
Delivery,  Good,  539 
De  Luca,  G.  B.,  539 
Demand,  539 
Demand  Curves,  542 
Demand  Schedules  {see  Demand), 

544 
Demesne,  544 
De  Metz-Noblat,  A.,  544 
Demise,  544 
Demography,  544 
Demoivre,  a.,  545 
Demology  {see  Demography),  546 
Demonetisation,  546 
Demonstrative  Legacy,  546 
Demurrage,  546 
Denarius,  546 
Denarius  Dei,  547 
Denier  (Coin),  547 

Denier  (Tax),  547 

Denier     (as    denoting    Price), 
547 
Deniers  de  Calais,  547 
Denizen,  548 
Denny,  W.,  548 
Denominational     Currency     {see 

Colonial  Currency),  548 
Denominations   of   Bank    Notes, 

548 
Denominator,  Common,  549 
Deodand,  549 
Deparcieux,  a.,  549 
De  Parieu  {see  Parieu,  Esquirol 

de),  550 
Department,  550 
Department  (France),  551 
Depopulation  (Term),  551 
Depopulation  (in  Relation  to  Eco 

nomic  History),  551 
Depopulation  (Causes),  552 
Deposit  (Sales  of  Land),  559 
Deposit  (Deposits,  Banking),  559 
Deposition,  560 
Depositum,  560 
Dep6ts  et  Consignations  (Caisse 

des),  560 
Depreciation,  561 
Depreciation  of  Monetary  Stand- 
ard, 562 
Depression,  Agricultural,  563 
Depression  of  Trade,  565 
Deputy,  568 
Db  Quincby,  T.,  568 
Derelict,  570 
Derelictio,  570 
De  Sanctis,  M.  A.,  570 
Descent  of  Property,  570 
Designs,  Copyright  in,  571- 
Desmarets,  N.,  571 
Destutt  db  Tracy,  A.  L.   C, 
572 

Destutt  de  Tracy  and  Ricardo, 
572 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


xiii 


Detraction,  Droit  de,  572 

Development,  572 

De  Vio,  F.  T.,  573 

Devise,  573 

Dew,  T.  K.,  573 

Diagrams,  574 

Dialogus  de  Scaccario,  576 

Dica,  576 

Dickinson,  J.,  576 

Dickson,  Kbv.  A.,  577 

BiDEROT,  D.,  in  his  relation  to 
Economics,  577 

DiETERici,  K.  F.  W.,  579 

Differential  Duties  {see  Discrim- 
inating Duties),  579 

DiflBculty  of  Attainment,  579 

DiflFusion  Theory  of  Taxation,  582 

DiGGES,  Sir  D.,  582 

Diligence  (Scot. ),  582 

Diligentia,  582 

Dime,  582 

Dime  Roy  ale,  583 

Dimensions  of  Economic  Quan- 
tities, 583 

Diminishing  Returns,  585 

Diminishing  Utility  (see  Utility), 
586 

Dinar  (Ancient),  586 

Dinar  (Modern),  586 

DiODATi,  D.,  586 

DiODATi,  L.,  586 

Direct  Taxation,  586 

Directors,  Legal  Duty  of,  587 

DiROM,  Major  A, ,  587 

Disabilities  of  Aliens,  587 

Disabilities  of  Infants,  587 

Disabilities  of  Lunatics  and 
Drunkards,  588 

Disabilities  of  Married  Women, 
588 

Discharge  (Scot.),  588 

Discharge  in  Bankruptcy,  589 

Disclaimer,  589 

Discommodity,  589 

Discount,  589 

Discount,  French  Stock  Exchange, 
590 

Discount  (London  Stock  Ex- 
change), 590 

Discount  Houses  {see  Bill  Brok- 
ing), 591 

Discoveries,  Geographical  (Influ- 
ence on  Trade  of),  591 

Discoveries  of  Precious  Metals 
{see  Gold — Silver,  Discoveries 
of),  591 

Discovery  in  Actions,  591 

Discriminating  or  Differential 
Duties,  591 

Discussion  (Scot.),  592 

Dishonour  of  a  Bill,  592 

Disposition  (Scot.),  592 

Distance  in  Time  as  an  Element 
of  Value,  592 

Distress,  594 

Distress  (Legal  Term),  594 

Distribution  (or  in  full  The  Dis 
tribution  of  Wealth),  595 


Distribution,  Ethics  of,  596 
Distribution,  Law  of,  599 
Distribution  (uses  of  the  Term), 

602 
Distribution,  Cost  of  {see  Produc- 
tion and  Distribution),  603 
Distribution,  Statutes  of,  603 
Distribution     of     the     Precious 

Metals,  603 
Distributive  Justice,  606 
Distringas,  606 
Disutility    {see     Discommodity), 

606 
D'lVERNOis,  Sir  F.  {see  Ivernois, 

Sir  F.  de),  606 
Dividend  (on  Stock  and  Shares), 

606 
Dividend  (Mediaeval),  607 
Dividend  (in  Bankruptcy),  607 
Dividend  Warraut,  607 
Divisibility  of  Money.     Divisions 

of  Money,  608 
Division  of  Labour,  608 
Dizain,  611 
DOBBS,  A.,  611 
Dock,  611 

Development    of    the    Modern 
Dock  System,  611 

London  Docks,  611 

Provincial  Dock  Development, 
613 

Dock  Warrants,  615 

Etfect    of    Economic    Changes 
upon  Docks,  615 

List  of  Mercantile  Docks  in  the 
United  Kingdom,  616 

Competition     in     relation     to 
Docks,  621 

Incidence    of    Dock    Charges, 
621 

Dock  Finance,  621 

Dock  Ownership,  621 

Public  Ownership,  621 

(1)  Management,  621 

(2)  Public  Convenience, 

621 

(3)  Finance,  621 
Dock  Labour,  622 
Dock  Warrant,  623 
Docquet,  623 
Doctrinaire,  623 

Doctrine  of  Population — Malthus 

{see    Malthus,     Rev.    T.     R.  ; 

Population),  624 
Dogma,  624 
Doitkin,  625 
Dole  Fish,  625 
Doles,  625 
Dollar,  626 

History  of,  626 

Of  Accounts,  627 

Hard  (Stock  Exchange  use  of 
word),  627 

Hard  (Spanish),  627 

United  States,  627 

Trade  (United  States),  627 

Maria  Theresa    or    Levantiner 
Thaler,  628 


Mexican,  or  Peso,  628 

South  and  Central  American 
Republics,  and  British  Hon- 
duras, 628 

Spanish     {see    Hard    Dollar), 
628 
Dolus,  628 
Domaine,  628 

DOMBASLES,  A.  M.  de,  628 
Domesday  Book,  629 
Domestic    System    of    Industry, 

630 
Domicil  or  Domicile,  631 
Domicile  (Scotland),  632 
Domiciled  Bill,  632 
Dominium,  632 
Domus  Conversomm  {see  Jews  in 

England),  632 
Donatio  Mortis  Causa,  632 
Donation  (Scotland),  632 
DoNATO,  N.,  632 
Don  Gratuit,  632 
DoRiA,  P.  M.,  633 
Dormant  (or  Sleeping)   Partner, 

633 
Dormer,  D.  J.,  633 
Dos,  633 

Doses  (of  Capital),  633 
Douane  (Fr.  Customs),  633 
Double  Entry  {see  Book-keeping). 

634 

DOUBl.EDAT,  T.,  634 

Double-Florin,  634 

Double    Standard    {see    Bimetal- 
lism ;  Standard  of  Value),  634 

Doubloon,  History  of,  634 

Doubloon,  635 

Douglass,  W.,  635 

Dove,  P,  E.,  635 

Dower,  636 

Drachma,  637 

Drafts  on  Demand  {see  Cheques; 
Law  of),  637 

Dragonetti,  G.,  637 

Dragonetti,  L.,  637 

Drain  of  Bullion,  637 

Drake,  J.,  639 

Drajner's  Letters,  639 

Drawbacks,  640 

Drawer  of  a  Bill  of  Exchange,  640 

Drawing,  640 

Drengage,  641 

Drinks,    Taxes    on   {see    Taxes), 
641 

Drofland,  or  Dryfland,  641 

Droit,     Annuel    {see    Paulette), 
641 

Droits  of  Admiralty,  641 

Droits  d'Aubaine  {see  Aubaine), 
641 

Droz,  J.,  641 

Drummond,  H.,  641 

Drunkards,    Legislation   respect- 
ing, 642 

Dry  Exchange  {CamMum  siccum), 
643 

Dry  Rent  {Rent  sec.),  643 

DUBOS,  Abb^  J.  B.,  648 


xiv 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


Ducat,  History  of,  643 
Ducat  (Modern),  644 
DuoHATEL,  Comte  T.,  644 
DucPETiAUX,  E.,  645 
Due   [gerihta,  rectitudo,  rectum). 

645 
Due  Date   (Bill    of    Exchange) 

648 
DUFAU,  F.  P.,  648 
Ddhamel  du  Monceau,  H.  L. 

648 
DuMOULm  {see  Molinaeus),  648 
DONCAN,  H.,  D.D.,  648 
Duncan,  John,  650 
Duncan,  Jonathan,  650 
Dundas,  H.,  650 
Dunning,  E.,  650 
Dunoyer,  C,  650 
Duodecimal  System,  651 
DupiN,  Baron  C,  651 
DupiN,  Claude,  652 
DUPONT    (Du    Pont),    P.    S.    de 

Nemours,  652 
Dupont-Whitb,  C,  653 
DuPRE  DE  Saint-Maur,  N.  F. 

654 
DUPUIT,  A.  J.  E.,  654 
Duquesnot,  a.  C,  655 
Duration  of  Life  (as  an  element 

of  well-being),  655 
DussARD,  H.,  655 
Dutch  Auction  {see  Auction),  655 
Dutch    School     of    Economists, 

656 
DuTENS,  J.  M.,  660 
DuTOT,  660 
Duty,    Customs    {see    Customs) 

660 
Duty,  Export  {see  Exports,  Duties 

on),  660 
Duty,  Import  {see  Imports,  Duties 

on),  660 
Duty,   Legacy,   Probate,  Succes- 
sion {see  Death  Duties),  660 
Du     Vernet     {see     Paris     Du 

Vemey),  660 

DUVILLARD      DE      DURAND,     E. 

660 
Dwellings,  Industrial,  660 
Dwellings,    Model,    of    Working 

Classes  in  France,  664 
Dwellings    (Regulation    by    the 

State  in  England),  665 

Eagle,  667 
Earnest  Money,  667 
Earnings  and  Interest  Fund,  667 
Earnings  of  Management,  667 
Easement,  668 
EasterUngs,  668 
East  India  Company,  669 
Eastland  Company,  672 
Eaton,  D.  L,  673 
Ebaudy  db  Fresne,  673 
Eok,  J.,  673 
Economic  Freedom,  674 
Economic     Goods     {see    Goods, 
Economic),  674 


Economic  Hannony,  674  | 

Economic  History,  675 
Economic  Law,  676 
Economic  Man,  676 
Economics  {see  Political  Economy), 

677 
Economic  Science  and  Economics, 

677 
Economistes,  679 
Ecu,  679 

Eden,  Sir  F.  M.,  679 
Edgeworth,  M.,  680 
Edmonds,  T.  K,  681 
Education,  Economic  Aspects  of, 

681 
Edwards,  B.,  681 
Edwards,  G.,  M.D.,  682 
Effects,  682 
Effectual  Demand   {see  Demand 

Effectual),  682 
Efficiency  of  Labour,  682 
Efficiency  of  Money,  685 
Egoism,  685 
Egron,  a.  C,  687 
Eight-Piece,  687 
Eight  Hours  Movement,  687 
Einert,  C,  690 
ElSDELL,  J.  S.,  690 
Eiselen,  J.  F.  G.,  690 
Eject,  Ejectment,  Ejection,  690 
Elasticity,  691 

Elasticity  of    Demand   {see    De- 
.  mand),  691 
Elder,  W.,  691 
Election,  691 
Elegit  (Writ  of),  692 
Elevator,  692 
Elibank,  p.  M.,  692 
Eliot,  F.  P.,  692 
Elizabethan  Legislation  {see  Legis- 
lation), 693 
Elking,  H.,  693 
Elliott,  E.,  693 
Ellis,  W.  (1758),  693 
Ellis,  W.  (1800-81),  693 
Ellman,  J.,  694 
^lus,  694 
Emancipation,  694 
Embargo,  695 
Embezzlement,  696 
Emblements,  696 
Emerson,   Gouverneur,  M.D., 

696 
Emigration,    its    Effect    on    the 

Country  of  Origin,  696 
Eminent  Domain,  702 
Emmery  db  Sept  Fontaines,  H. 

C,  703 
Empanel,  703 
Emphyteusis,  703 
Empiricism,  703  - 
Employers  and  Employed,  704 
Employers'  Liability  Act,  706 
Employing  Class,  707 
Employment,  707 
Employment    of     Women     and 

Children    in    Agriculture    {see 

Female  Labour),  708 


Employments  {see  Occupations), 

708 
Emption,  708 
Emptio-Venditio,  708 
Emulation,  Effects  of,  on  Society, 

708 
Encabezamiento,  709 
Enclosures,  709 
Encomienda,  712 
Encroachment  {see  Trespass),  712 
Encyclical,    Papal,    on     Labour 

(1891),  712 
Endorsement    {see    Bill    of    Ex- 
change), 713 
Endowments,  713 
Enemy  Goods,  714 
Enfaced  Paper  or  Rupee  Paper,  715 
Enfacement,  715 
Enfantin,  p.,  715 
Enfranchisement,  716 
Enfranchisement   of   Land  from 

Copyhold  and  similar  Tenures, 

History  of,  717 
English  Early  Economic  History, 

719 
English      School      of     Political 

Economy,  before  Adam  Smith, 

730 
English      School      of     Political 

Economy,  Modern  Economics, 
"  733 
Engrossing  {see  Forestallers  and 

Regrators),  737 
Enregistrement,  737 
Ensenada,  Z.,  Marquis,  737 
Entail,  Law  of,  738 
Entail  (Scotland),  740 
Entrep&ts,  741 
Entrepreneur,  741 
Entry,  Bill  of,  742 
Entry,  Right  of,  742 
Enumerated  Commodities,  743 
!^phemerides,  743 
Bpices,  747 

Equalisation  of  International  De- 
mand, 747 
Equality,  748 
Equation  of  Supply  and  Demand 

{see  Demand),  749 
Equilibrium,  749 
Equitable  Assets,  749 
Equitable  Estate,  749 
Equitable  Execution,  749 
Equitable  Mortgage,  749 
Equitable  Waste,  750 
Equity,  750 

Equity  of  Redemption,  751 
Equity  to  a  Settlement,  751 
Error  Excepted,  751 
Error,  Law  of,  751 
Escheat  (historical),  753 
Escheat  (modern  law),  754 
Escudo,  754 
Escusado,  754 

Essart,  Exart,  or  Assart,  754 
Estate,  754 
Estate  Duty  {see  Death  Duties) 

755 


TABLE  OF  CONTENTS 


EsTCouRT,  T.,  755 

ESTERNO,  P.,  755 

Estimo,  755 

Estoppel,  756 

Estovers,  756 

Etats  Generaux,  The,  or  States 

General  of  France,  756 
Ethel  {see  Alod),  756 
Evans,  D.  M.  ,  756 
Evans,  T.,  757 
Evelyn,  J.  (1620-1706),  757 
Evelyn,  J.  (1830),  757 
Everett,  A.  H.,  757 
Everett,  G.,  757 
Evolution  {see  Development),  758 
Eviction,  758 
Ex.  All,  758 
Examples,  758 
Excambion,  758 
Exchange,  758 
Exchange,  Value  in,  759 
Exchange,  Value  in.     History  of 

Growth  of  Theory,  762 
Exchange,    Usury    {see    Usury), 

767 
Exchange,  as  Bourse,  767 
Exchange,  Stock,  768 


Exchange,  Stock,  Provincial,  in 
Great  Britain  and  Ireland,  770 

Exchange,  Foreign,  770 

Exchange,  Foreign,  practical  work- 
ing of,  772 

Exchange  between  Holland  aud 
Dutch  India,  773 

Exchange  between  Great  Britain 
and  British  India,  776 

Exchange,  Internal,  777 

Exchange  of  Notes,  778 

Exchange  Broker,  778 

Exchanger,  Royal,  778 

Exchequer,  Early  History  of,  779 

Exchequer,  Present  Constitution 
of,  781 

Exchequer  (Scotland),  784 

Exchequer  Bill,  784 

Exchequer  Bill,  History  of,  784 

Exchequer  Bond,  785 

Exchequer  Bond,  History  of,  785 

Exchequer,  Closing  of  the,  786 

Excise,  The,  786 

Excise  Scheme  of  Sir  R.  Walpole, 
788 

Ex.  Dividend,  789 

Ex.  Drawing,  789 


Execution,  789 

Executor,  789 

Executry  (Scottish),  790 

Exercitor  (Scottish),  790 

Exhereditatio,  790 

Ex.  New,  790 

Expectation  of  Life,  790 

Expeditation,  790 

Expenditure  or  Spending,  790 

Expenses  of  Production  {see  Pro« 
ductiou),  790 

Experience,  790 

Experimental  Methods  in  Econo- 
mics, 791 

Expert,  792 

Expertise  (French),  793 

Exploit,  793 

Exports  and  Imports  {see  Imports 
and  Exports),  794 

Exports,  Duties  on,  794 

Expropriation,  797 

Extensive  Cultivation  {see  Inten- 
sive), 798 

Extents  {see  Court  Rolls,  Manorial 
Accounts,  and  Extents),  798 

Extraneus,  798 

Eyton,  R.  W.,  798 


The  great  art  therefore  of  political  oeconomy  is,  first  to  adapt  the  different 
operations  of  it  to  the  spirit,  manners,  habits,  and  customs  of  the  people  ; 
and  afterwards  to  model  these  circumstances  so,  as  to  be  able  to  introduce  a 
set  of  new  and  more  useful  institutions. 

The  principal  object  of  this  science  is  to  secure  a  certain  fund  of  subsist- 
ence for  all  the  inhabitants,  to  obviate  every  circumstance  which  may  render 
it  precarious  ;  to  provide  everything  necessary  for  supplying  the  wants  of 
the  society,  and  to  employ  the  inhabitants  (supposing  them  to  be  free  men) 
in  such  a  manner  as  naturally  to  create  reciprocal  relations  and  dependencies 
between  them,  so  as  to  make  their  several  interests  lead  them  to  supply  one 
another  with  their  reciprocal  wants. — Sir  James  Steuart,  Iiiquiry  into  the 
Principles  of  Political  (Economy. 


The  more  extended  our  research  becomes,  the  more  we  find  that  know- 
ledge is  a  thing  of  slow  progression,  that  the  very  notions  which  appear  to 
ourselves  new  have  arisen,  though  perhaps  in  a  very  indirect  manner,  from 
successive  modifications  of  traditional  opinions.  Each  word  we  utter,  each 
thought  we  think,  has  in  it  the  vestiges,  is  in  itself  the  impress,  of  antecedent 
words  and  thoughts. — Sir  W.  R.  Grove,  Correlation  of  Physical  Forces. 


DICTIONAEY  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY 


ABATEMENT— ABOLITIONIST 


ABATEMENT  or  Rebate.  A  deduction, 
drawback,  or  decrease  made.  A  proportionate 
reduction  of  a  payment  allowed  for  special 
reasons — e.g.  for  prompt  payment.  E.  s. 

ABBOT,  Charles,  afterwards  Lord  Colchester 
(bom  1757,  died  1829),  entered  parliament  in 
1795,  and  became  chairman  of  Pitt's  finance 
committee  1797.  He  carried  in  1800  a  bill  for 
charging  public  paymasters  with  the  payment 
of  interest  on  sums  in  hand.  He  was  also  the 
Initiator  of  the  commission  of  inquiry  into  the 
public  records  in  the  same  year.  But  perhaps 
his  chief  title  to  fame  is  his  introduction,  in 
1800,  of  the  motion  for  a  complete  census  of 
Great  Britain.  In  spite  of  some  opposition  tlie 
Population  Act,  as  it  was  called,  was  duly  passed, 
and  its  provisions  carried  into  force  in  the  next 
year  (see  Census).  As  speaker  (elected  1802) 
he  gave  his  casting  vote  against  Lord  ]\IelviUe 
in  1805.  On  his  retirement  from  the  House  of 
Commons  in  1817  he  was  made  a  peer,  and 
received  a  pension  of  £i000  a  year.  He  d&- 
vx)ted  his  later  years  to  foreign  travel,  and  to 
the  improvement  of  roads  in  the  Scottish  high- 
lands. J.  B. 

ABEILLE,  Louis  Paul  (born  1719,  died 
1807),  became  secretary  of  the  Agiicultural 
Society  of  Brittany,  established  through 
Gournay's  influence  in  1757.  He  was  an 
ardent  physiocrat,  and  argued  (1763)  for  free 
trade  in  corn,  along  with  Quesnay,  Morellet, 
and  the  elder  Mirabeau.  Writing  later  on  the 
same  subject  (1768)  he  fell  into  the  fallacy  that 
high  corn  prices  make  high  wages.  Dupont 
speaks  of  his  style  as  "cold  and  heavy"  but 

clear."  He  wrote  occasionally  in  the  Journal 
d' Agriculture  of  Paris,  when  Dupont  became 
■its  editor  in  1765  ;  but  he  seems  never  to  have 
'been  on  very  good  tei-ms  Avith  that  economist. 
I  When  he  was  chosen  inspector-general  of  manu- 
factures (1768)  his  ardour  seems  to  have  cooled 
down,  and  he  is  not  to  be  reckoned  among  the 
few  who  upheld  the  physiocratic  cause  after 
Tuegot's  death  in  1781.  His  writings  include 
(besides  the  Corps  d' Observations  of  the  Breton 
Agricultm-al  Society)  the  following  : — 


Lettre  d'un  negociant  sur  la  nature  du  commerce 
des  Grains,  Paris,  1763. — Rejiexions  sur  la  police 
des  Grains  en  Angleterre  et  en  France,  Paris, 
1764. — Effets  d'un  privilege  exclusif  sur  les  droits 
de  propriete,  Paris,  1764. — Principes  sur  la  liberty 
du  commerce  des  Grains,  Paris,  1768. — Fails  qui 
ont  influx  sur  la  cherti  des  Grains  en  France  et  en 
Angleterre,  Paris,  1768. — Mimoire  presents  par 
la  SociHS  Roycde  d' Agriculture  sur  V usage  des 
domaines  congeables,  Paris,  1791. — Memoire  en 
faveur  d'Argant,  the  inventor  of  the  "  Argand  " 
lamp,  Geneva,  1785. — Memoire  d  consulter  {on  the 
subject  of  the  French  Fast  India  Company),  Paris, 
1768. — [See  Schelle's  Dupont  de  Nemours  et  V6cole 
Physiocratique  [\^%^) passim,  Daire's  Physiocrates, 
1846  {e.g.  p.  38).]  j.  b. 

ABOLITIONIST.  A  term  applied  specially 
to  the  social  reformers  headed  by  Thomas 
Clarkson,  who  advocated  and  carried  the  aboli- 
tion of  the  slave-trade  in  the  British  dominions  ; 
and  applied  generally  to  all  who  have  aimed  at 
abolishing  either  the  trade  in  slaves  or  the 
institution  of  Slavery,  whether  in  the  British 
dominions  or  elsewhere. 

The  causes  which  contributed  to  abolition  in 
the  first  sense  are  arranged  by  Clarkson  (q.v.), 
the  historian  of  the  movement,  in  four  divisions, 
quaintly  illusti'ated  by  four  confluent  streams 
(History  of  the  A  bolition  of  Slave-  Trade,  1 8  0  8,  p. 
259).  The  four  classes  of  abolitionists  may  be 
summarily  described  as  (1)  miscellaneous,  mostly 
literary  (Pope,  Thomson,  etc.)  ;  (2)  Quakers  in 
England ;  (3)  Quakers  in  America ;  (4)  Clarkson 
himself,  with  his  fellow- workers.  In  1787  the 
first  committee  for  the  abolition  of  this  trade  was 
formed  by  Clarkson  and  his  associates.  At  first 
their  efforts  were  devoted  to  the  abolition  only  of 
the  trade  in  slaves,  as  theabolitionof  slavery  itself 
seemed  hopeless.  In  1 789  Wilberforce  introduced 
a  measure  into  parliament,  founded  upon  Clark- 
son's  materials,  but  it  was  not  till  1807  that 
the  bill  for  the  abolition  of  the  slave-trade 
passed  the  House  of  Commons,  and  not  till 
1883  that  British  colonial  slavery  was  abolished 
by  act  of  parliament.  The  abolition  of  slavery 
in  the  British  dominions  gave  prominence  to 
two  points  of  economic  interest — the  inefiiciency 


VOL.  L 


^ 


ABOUT— ABRASION 


of  slave  labour,  and  the  right  to  compensation 
in  case  of  expropriation,  even  when  the  kind  of 
property  has  received  the  most  severe  public 
moral  condemnation. 

The  movement  towards  liberty,  initiated  by 
England,  has  been  continued  by  most  of  the 
continental  nations  at  varying  rates  down  to 
the  present  time.  Denmark,  indeed,  has  the 
honour  of  anticipating  the  action  of  England. 
In  1792  it  was  ordered  that  slave-trade  should 
cease  in  Danish  dominions  after  1802.  In  the 
United  States  the  movement  in  favour  of  aboli- 
tion is  coeval  with  the  union.  Before  the  end 
of  last  century,  or  early  in  the  beginning  of  the 
present  one,  slavery  was  abolished  in  many  of 
the  original  states.  The  admission  of  new  states 
has  more  than  once  raised  the  question,  within 
what  limits  should  slavery  be  tolerated  ?  Thus, 
on  the  admission  of  Missouri,  the  boundaries 
within  which  slavery  was  permitted  or  pro- 
hibited were  carefully  defined  by  the  "Mis- 
souri compromise"  (1820).  That  arrangement 
was  at  a  later  period  (in  the  case  of  Dred  Scott, 
1856-57)  interpreted  unfavourably  to  the  cause 
of  abolition.  The  indignation  of  abolitionists 
was  roused  by  the  cruel  administration  of  the 
fugitive  slave  law  and  other  iniquities.  Slavery 
was  a  cause,  and  abolition  a  result,  of  the  Civil 
War  1861-65. 

The  economic  questions  connected  with 
American  slavery  have  been  well  treated  by 
Cairnes  in  his  work  on  the  Slave  Power  (see 
Slavery).  See  also,  with  reference  to  America, 
H.  Greeley,  The  American  Conflict,  1865. 
Clarkson  published  in  1808  a  History  of  the 
Abolition  of  the  Slave-Trade  (2  vols.) 

J.  S.  N. 

ABOUT,  Edmond  (member  of  the  Acadimie 
Frangaise),  born  at  Dieuze  (Lorraine),  1828, 
died  at  Paris,  1885.  It  was  especially  as  a 
novelist  that  About  made  his  reputation,  and 
it  is  to  be  regretted  that  politics,  after  1871, 
reduced  this  inimitable  romance  writer,  who 
had  produced  such  works  as  the  Hoi  des  Mon- 
tagnes  and  the  Mariages  de  Paris,  to  the  posi- 
tion of  a  mere  editor  of  a  journal  (the  XIX. 
Si^cle).  The  works  which  should  be  noticed  in 
this  place  were  written  between  the  purely 
literary  period  and  the  more  militant  period  of 
About's  animated  life.  In  Maitre  Pierre  (1858) 
and  the  Lettres  d'un  bon  jeune  homvfie  (I860) 
About,  as  a  passionate  admirer  of  the  wonders 
of  human  industry,  and  the  conscientious  de- 
fender of  the  principles  of  laissez  faire  laissez 
passer,  still  writes  as  a  novelist  and  a  story- 
teller. But  genuine  didactic  works  followed. 
We  may  cite  le  Progrhs  (1864)  and  VA  B  C  du 
travailleur  (1868),  l' Assurance  (1865)  and  le 
Capital  pour  tous  (1869).  In  these  last-named 
works  the  author  limits  himself  to  setting  forth 
the  principles  which  others  had  formulated 
before  him,  while  he  denounces  certain  errors  of 
interpretation.    Though  About  may  be  described 


as  only  a  populariser,  he  yet  deserves  con- 
sideration from  the  students  of  economic  science, 
to  which,  for  ten  years,  he  devoted  all  the 
resources  of  his  humour,  imagination,  and  in- 
comparable style.  A.  DE  F. 

ABRASION.  The  abrasion  or  loss  by  wear 
and  tear  of  the  coins  in  use  is  an  important 
factor  in  the  cost  of  a  metallic  circulation.  This 
differs  between  one  country  and  another  accord- 
ing to  the  hardness  of  the  coin  which  results 
from  the  description  of  Alloy  employed,  to  the 
surface  of  the  coin  exposed  to  wear  in  propor- 
tion to  its  bulk,  to  the  greater  or  less  employ- 
ment of  coin  in  circulation.  At  the  present 
time  the  wear  of  the  principal  gold  coin  of  the 
British  empire  (Sovereign)  is  very  consider- 
able. The  investigation  set  on  foot  by  Jevons 
in  1868  shows  that  the  sovereign  in  ordinary 
use  loses  on  an  average  '043  of  a  grain  annu- 
ally. In  other  words,  the  wear  and  tear  of  an 
English  sovereign  appears  to  be  at  the  rate 
o^  loEUoo  parts,  or  something  less  than  one- 
tenth  of  a  penny  per  annum  (J.  B.  Martin, 
"Media  of  Exchange,"  Journal  of  Statistical 
Society,  1884,  p.  489).  The  standard  weight  is 
123-274  grains,  and  the  lowest  weight  of  legal 
currency  122-5  grains,  so  that  the  sovereign  loses 
the  '774  grains,  which  reduces  it  below  legal 
tender,  on  an  average  in  about  1 5  •  7  years.  In  the 
case  of  the  Half-Sovereign,  the  difference  be- 
tween standard  weight  and  the  lowest  current 
weight  is  -512  grains ;  and  as  the  yearly  loss  of  the 
half-sovereign  averages  -069  grains,  these  coins 
are  reduced  below  legal  tender  weight  generally 
in  the  short  period  of  seven  and  a  half  years. 
The  wear  of  the  English  coinage  cannot,  how- 
ever, be  taken  as  the  criterion  of  the  wear  of 
all  coinages  everywhere,  as  varying  rapidity  of 
circulation,  use  of  small  paper  representatives 
of  money,  etc.,  cause  great  differences  between 
one  country  and  another.  The  estimates  of  the 
actual  amount  differ  very  greatly  from  each 
other  ;  one  made  by  Jacob,  which  includes  the 
wear  both  of  gold  and  silver  coins,  is  of  "one 
part  in  three  hundred  and  sixty  annually" 
(Jacob  on  the  Precious  Metals,  vol.  ii.  p.  186). 

[For  detailed  information  see  An  Historical  In- 
quiry into  the  Production  and  Consumption  of  the 
Precious  Metals,^ .  Jacob,  London,  1831  (2  vols.) 
— •'  Paper  on  the  Condition  of  the  Gold  Coinage  of 
the  United  Kingdom,"  W.  S.  Jevons,  Journal  of  the 
Statistical  Society  of  London,  reprinted  with  much 
similar  information  in  Jevons's  Investigations  in 
Currency  and  Finance. — See  also  paper  by  John 
B.  Martin,  "  Our  Gold  Coinage,"  Journal  of  the 
Institute  of  Bankers,  June  1882. — Paper  by  R.  H. 
Inglis  Palgrave,  "  The  Deficiency  in  Weight  of  our 
Gold  Coinage,  with  a  Proposal  for  its  Reform," 
March  1883  ;  "  The  Gold  Coinage,"  December  1884 
(both  in  Journal,  Institute  of  Bankers). — Reports 
of  Deputy  Master  of  Mint,  particularly  those  for 
1883, 1884, 1885,  trnd^  passim, — and  Evidence  and 
Reports  Royal  Commission  on  Recent  Changes  in 
the  Relative  Values  of  the  Precious  Metals,  which 


ABROAD— ABSENTEE 


3 


includes  a  translation  of  A.  Soetbeer's  Materials 
for  the  Illustration  and  Criticism  of  the  Economic 
Relations  of  the  Precious  Metals,  and  of  the  Cur- 
rency Question. — Evidence  and  Reports  Royal 
Commission  on  Depression  of  Trade  and  Industry, 
1886.] 

ABROAD.     See  Jurisdiction. 

ABSENTEE.  An  absentee  may  be  variously 
defined  (1)  as  a  landed  i)roprietor  who  resides 
away  from  his  estate,  or  (2)  from  his  country  ; 
or  more  generally  (3)  any  unproductive  con- 
sumer who  lives  out  of  the  country  from  which 
he  derives  his  income. 

Examples  of  these  species  are  (1)  a  seigneur 
under  the  an/;ien  regime  living  in  Paris  at  a 
distance  from  his  estates  ;  (2)  an  Irish  landlord 
resident  abroad  ;  (3)  an  Anglo-Indian  ex-official 
resident  in  England  and  drawing  a  pension 
from  India.  In  writing  briefly  on  the  evils  of 
absenteeism  it  is  difficult  to  use  general  terms 
appropriate  to  all  the  definitions  ;  but  considera- 
tions primarily  relating  to  some  one  definition 
may  easily  be  adapted  to  another  by  the  reader. 

It  is  useful  to  consider  separately  the  effects 
of  the  absentee  proprietor's  consumption  upon 
the  wealth  of  his  countrymen  ;  and  the  moral, 
as  well  as  economical  effects  of  other  circum- 
stances. 

I.  The  more  abstract  question  turns  upon 
the  fact  that  the  income  of  an  absentee  is  mostly 
remitted  by  means  of  exports.  "The  tribute, 
subsidy,  or  remittance  is  always  in  goods 
.  .  .  unless  the  country  possesses  mines  of  the 
precious  metals "  (Mill).  So  far  as  the  pro- 
prietor, if  resident  at  home,  would  consume 
foreign  produce,  his  absence,  not  increasing  ex- 
ports, does  not  affect  local  industry.  So  far  as 
the  proprietor's  absence  causes  manufactures  to 
be  exported,  his  countrymen  are  not  prejudiced. 
For  they  may  have  as  profitable  employment 
in  manufacturing  those  exports  as,  if  the  pro- 
prietor had  resided  at  home,  they  would  have 
had  in  supplying  manufactured  commodities  or 
services  for  his  use.  But  if  the  proprietor  by 
his  absence  causes  raw  materials  to  be  exported, 
while  if  present  he  would  have  used  native 
manufactures  and  services,  his  absence  tends 
to  deprive  his  countrymen  of  employment,  to 
diminish  their  prosperity,  and  perhaps  their 
numbers.  This  reasoning  is  based  on  Senior's 
Lectures  on  the  Rate  of  Wages  (Lecture  II.), 
and  Political  Economy  (pp.  155-161).  Senior's 
position  is  in  a  just  mean  between  two  extremes, 
— the  popular  fallacy  and  the  paradox  of 
M  'CuLLOOH.  On  the  one  hand  it  is  asserted  that 
between  the  payment  of  a  debt  to  an  absentee 
and  a  resident  there  is  the  same  difference  as 
between  the  payment  and  non-payment  of  a 
tribute  to  a  foreign  country.  On  the  other 
hand  it  is  denied  that  there  is  any  difference 
at  all.  The  grosser  form  of  the  vulgar  error, 
the  conception  that  the  income  of  the  absentee 
is  drawn  from  the  tributary  country  in  specie, 


is  exemplified  in  Thomas  Prior's  List  of  Absen- 
tees {1^2^).  M'CuUoch's  arguments  are  stated 
in  the  essay  on  "Absenteeism"  in  his  Treatises, 
and  Essays  on  Money,  etc.,  and  in  the  evidence 
given  by  him  before  some  of  the  parliamentary 
commissions  which  are  referred  to  below.  Asked 
"Do  you  see  any  difference  between  raw  pro- 
duce and  manufactured  goods,"  M'Culloch  re- 
plies, "  I  do  not  think  it  makes  any  difference  " 
(compare  Treatises  and  Essays,  p.  232).  He 
appeals  to  observation,  and  finds  that  the  tenants 
of  absentee  landlords  are  "subjected  to  less 
fleecing  and  extortion  than  those  of  residents." 

J.  S.  Mill  attributes  to  absenteeism  a  tendency 
to  lower  the  level  of  prices  in  the  country  from 
which  the  absentee  draws  an  income  ;  with  the 
consequence  that  the  inhabitants  of  that  country 
obtain  their  imports  at  an  increased  cost  of 
effort  and  sacrifice  (Unsettled  Questions,  essay  i. 
p.  43).  Mill's  meaning  may  be  made  clearer 
by  a  study  of  the  rest  of  the  essay  which  has 
been  cited,  and  of  the  parallel  passage  in  his 
Political  Economy  (bk.  v.  ch.  iv.  §  6),  where 
he  argues  that  an  inequality  between  exports 
and  imports  results  in  an  "efflux  of  money" 
from  one  country  to  another. 

Upon  less  distinct  grounds  Quesnay  connects 
absenteeism  with  a  development  of  trade  and 
industry  in  an  unhealthy  direction  ((Euvres,  ed. 
Oncken,  p.  189).  Among  recondite  considera- 
tions which  may  bear  on  the  subject  should 
be  mentioned  Cantillon's  theory  concern- 
ing the  effect  of  the  consumption  of  the  rich  on 
the  gi-owth  of  population  (Essai,  pt.  i.  ch.  xv.) 

II.  Other  economical  advantages  lost  by  ab- 
senteeism are  those  which  spring  from  the 
interest  which  a  resident  is  apt  to  take  in  the 
things  and  persons  about  him.  Thus  he  may 
be  prompted  to  invest  capital  in  local  improve- 
ments, or  to  act  as  an  employer  of  workmen. 
"It  is  not  the  simple  amount  of  the  rental 
being  remitted  to  another  country,"  says  Arthur 
Young,  * '  but  the  damp  on  all  sorts  of  improve- 
ments." d'Argenson  in  his  Considerations  sur 
le  gouvernement  ancien  et  present  de  la  France 
(1765,  p.  183),  attributes  gi-eat  importance  to 
the  master's  eye. 

The  good  feeling  which  is  apt  to  grow  up 
between  a  resident  landlord  and  his  tenantry 
has  material  as  well  as  moral  results,  which 
are  generally  beneficial.  The  absentee  is  less 
likely  to  take  account  of  circumstances  (e.g. 
tenant's  improvements),  which  render  rack- 
renting  unjust.  He  is  less  likely  to  make 
allowance  for  calamities  which  render  punctual 
payment  difficult.  "  Miseries  of  which  he  can 
see  nothing,  and  probably  hear  as  little  of,  can 
make  no  impression,"  A.  Young.  He  is  glad 
to  get  rid  of  responsibility  by  dealing  with  a 
"  middleman,"  or  intermediate  tenant — an 
additional  wheel  in  the  machinery  of  exaction, 
calculated  to  grind  relentlessly  those  placed 
underneath  it.      Without  the  softening  influence 


ABSENTEE— ABSTINENCE 


of  personal  communication  between  the  owner 
and  the  cultivator  of  the  soil,  the  "  cash  nexus  " 
is  liable  to  be  strained  beyond  the  limit  of 
human  patience,  and  to  burst  violently.  There 
can  be  little  doubt  but  that  absenteeism  has 
been  one  potent  cause  of  the  misery  and  dis- 
turbances in  Ireland.  The  same  cause  has 
produced  like  effects  in  cases  widely  different 
in  other  respects.  The  cruellest  oppressors  of 
the  French  peasantry  before  the  Revolution 
were  the  fermiers,  who  purchased  for  an  annual 
sum  the  right  to  collect  the  dues  of  absentee 
seigneurs.  The  violence  of  the  Granger 
Railway  legislation  in  the  western  states  of 
America  is  attributed  to  the  fact  that  the 
shareholders  damnified  were  absentee  proprie- 
tors (Seligman,  Journal  of  Political  Science, 
1888). 

There  are  also  the  moral  advantages  due  to 
the  influence  and  example  of  a  cultivated  upper 
class.  The  extent  of  this  benefit  will  vary 
according  to  the  character  of  the  proprietors 
and  the  people.  In  some  cases  it  may  be,  as 
Adam  Smith  says,  that  "the  inhabitants  of  a 
large  village,  after  having  made  considerable 
progress  in  manufactures,  have  become  idle  in 
consequence  of  a  great  lord  having  taken  up 
his  residence  in  their  neighbourhood."  The  op- 
posite view,  presented  by  Miss  Edgewoeth  in 
her  Absentee,  may  be  true  in  other  states  of 
civilisation.  Perhaps  the  safest  generalisation 
is  that'  made  by  Senior  that  "in  general  the 
presence  of  men  of  large  fortune  is  morally 
detrimental,  and  that  of  men  of  moderate 
fortime  morally  beneficial,  to  their  immediate 
neighbourhood. " 

[The  references  cited  below  are  to  be  added  to 
those  which  have  been  already  made.  They  fall 
under  two  heads  :  {a)  the  unfortunately  large  class 
relating  specially  to  Ireland,  and  (6)  Miscellaneous, 
(a)  The  Act  3  Richard  II.  and  28  Henry  VIII., 
inflicting  on  absentees  forfeiture  of  two-thirds  of 
the  yearly  profits  from  their  lands.  These  and 
other  acts  relatiug  to  absentees  are  cited  in  Tracts 
and  Treatises  Illustrative  of .  .  .  Ireland  (reprinted 
by  Thorn),  1840.  The  index  to  this  work,  under  the 
heading  "Absentees"  gives  some  other  useful  refer- 
ences. Swift,  Seventh  Drapier's  Letter  (vol.  viL 
p.  40,  ed.  Walter  Scott). —Thomas  Prior,  List  of 
Absentees,  1727  (cited  above),  and  continuations  in 
subsequent  years. — Lecky,  History  of  England  in 
18th  Century,  vol.  ii.  2d  ed.  ch.  vii.  p.  237  et  seq. ; 
Id.,  vol.  iv.  ch.  xvi.  p.  Bl7 etseq. — Arthur  Young, 
Tour  in  Ireland,  1780,  ii.  p.  59  (a  terrific  "general 
picture"  of  the  evils  of  absenteeism). — Edward 
Wakefield,  Account  of  Ireland,  1812  (passages  re- 
ferred to  in  index). —  Westminster  Review  1827. 
— John  Wiggin's  (a  land  agent)  Letter  to  .  .  . 
Absentee  Landlords,  1822  (anonymous  at  first), 
(recommends  absentee  landlord  to  employ  a  con- 
fidential friend  to  visit  the  estate  occasionally).  — 
Minutes  of  evidence  taken  before  the  select  com- 
mittee of  the  House  of  Lords  .  . .  Ireland,  Parlia- 
mentary Papers,  1825,  ix. — Minutes  of  evidence 
taken  before  the  Select  Committee  of  the  House  of 


Commons  .  .  .  Ireland,  Parliamentary  Papers, 
1825,  viii. — Quarterly  Journal,  March  1826. — 
London  Magazine,  April  1826.  —  Westminstei 
Review,  January  1829. — De  Beaumont,  L'Irlande, 
1829. — Bicheno,  Ireland  and  its  Economy,  1830, 
ch.  viii.  (sensible  remarks  on  the  paradox  of  "  the 
economists"). — Select  committee  on  state  of  the 
poor inlrelund,  Parliaynentary Papers,1830,vu. — 
Debate  in  the  House  of  Commons,  1833,  Hansard, 
xix.  p.  583  (cp.  xvi.  p.  727). —  Westminster  Review, 
October  1833. — Von  Raumer  (a  writer  quoted  with 
approbation  by  Mill),  England  in  1835,  letter  Ixii. 
(very  forcible).  —  Westminster  Review,  October 
1835. — G.  Cornewall  Lewis,  Disturbances  in  Ire- 
land, 1836,  p.  451. — Report  of  the  Devon  Com- 
mission, Parliamentary  Papers,  1845,  xix.-xxii. 
(Answers  referred  to  under  the  head  of  Estate 
Management  nearly,  but  not  quite,  unanimous  that 
the  estates  of  absentees  are  badly  managed. )  Digest 
of  the  same  (ch.  xxiv.,  on  estate  management). — 
Dublin  University  Magazine,  1850. — Lavergne, 
Economic  ruraledeVAngleterre,  1858,  pp.  378,383 
(referring  to  M'Cdlloch's  paradox  says,  "En  ce  qui 
concerne  ITrlande  la  question  me  parait  tranch^e 
par  les  faits"). — Caienes,  Political  Essays,  1873 
(Fragments  on  Ireland),  p.  168. 

(6)  Montchretibn.  Traict6  de  Vcekonomie  poli- 
tique, .  .  .  1615,  edited  by  T.  FunckrBreutano, 
Paris,  1881,  p.  41  (early  appearance  of  absenteeism 
in  France). — AUam  Smith,  bk.  v.  ch.  ii.  (Tax  on  ab- 
sentees)— A.  TocQUEViLLB  (Clerel  de),  VAncien 
Rigime,  1857,  ch.  xii.  (Absenteisme  de  coeur  of 
the  small  resident  proprietors). — H.  Taine,  Ancien 
Regime,  1876,  liv.  i.  ch.  iii.  pp.  52-77  ;  and 
numerous  authorities  there  cited.  —  H.  Carey, 
Ledures  on  Wages  ...  1835,  p.  46  (criticises 
Senior's  theory). — E.  Levasseur,  La  PopvIMion 
Frangaise,  1889,  ch.  xi.  p.  237. — Hadley,  Rail- 
way Transportation,  1886,  p.  133  (absentee  share- 
holders), and  p.  21). — Journal  des  Economistes, 
1885,  November  and  December,  summarising  the 
results  of  the  recent  Italian  Commission. — Brod- 
rick,  English  Land  and  Landlords  (passages 
referred  to  in  index  under  heading  "  Absentee  "). 
Reference  in  Lavergne,  Economic  rurale  de  la 
France  (medium  properties,  as  in  England,  lead 
to  absenteeism  less  than  large  properties).  ] 

ABSTINENCE.  This  weU-chosen  expression 
of  Senior's,  to  use  J.  S.  Mill's  well-known 
description,  has  been  unfortunate  in  giving  rise 
to  much  controversy.  It  was  intended  to  refer  to 
that  element  in  profits  which  might  be  considered 
as  the  "  natural "  reward  of  the  capitalist  for  ab- 
staining from  immediate  consumption.  It  was 
thus  closely  connected  with  the  effective  desire 
of  accumulation  and  the  theory  of  a  "minimum 
rate  of  profits."  It  has  also  been  much  used  in 
the  establishment  of  economic  harmonies  in  the 
style  of  Bastiat  with  the  view  of  showing  that 
"natural"  economic  laws  are  in  fundamental 
accord  with  "common -sense"  morality.  As 
might  have  been  expected  from  the  ambiguity 
of  the  terms  "natural"  and  "common -sense," 
and  from  the  vagueness  of  the  conception  ab- 
stinence itself,  this  economic  harmony  has  been 
severely   criticised   in   the   first  place  by  the 


ABSTRACT  OF  TITLE— ABUNDANCE 


f 


Socialists  (e.g.  Lassalle  in  Schulze-Delitsch, 
Karl  Marx  in  Das  Capital).  It  was  easy  to  point 
out  that  the  virtue  of  abstinence  could  in  many- 
cases  be  reduced  merely  to  desire  for  money  as 
such  and  to  a  positive  reluctance  to  spend. 
This  criticism  does  not,  however,  seem  capable 
of  general  extension.  More  recently  another 
line  of  criticism  has  been  developed  and  atten- 
tion has  been  drawn  to  the  positive  effort 
required  to  convert  wealth  into  capital  for  use 
in  production  corresponding  in  the  main  to  the 
management  or  superintendence  required  after 
the  capital  has  been  formed  (compare  Bagehot, 
Economic  Studies,  and  Schonberg's  Handbuch, 
art.  "Capital").     (See  Capital.)       j.  s.  n. 

ABSTRACT  OF  TITLE.  An  epitome  of  the 
evidence  of  ownership  showing  the  soundness 
of  one's  right  to  an  estate.  In  the  absence  of 
any  agi-eement  to  the  contrary  the  purchaser 
of  a  freehold  estate  is  entitled  to  have  such 
evidence  for  a  period  of  forty  years,  but  in  the 
case  of  advowsons  the  period  is  one  hundred 
years.  The  abstract  is  sufficient  if  it  shows 
that  the  vendor  is  either  himself  competent  to 
convey  or  can  otherwise  procure  to  be  vested  in 
the  piu"chaser  the  legal  and  equitable  estates  free 
from  incumbrances.  [Dart's  Vendors  and  Pur- 
chasers, London,  1888.]  j.  e.  c.  m. 

ABSTRACT  POLITICAL  ECONOMY. 
Political  economy  is  sometimes  described  as  a 
wholly  abstract  science,  dealing  with  an  unreal 
and  imaginary  subject,  that  is  to  say,  not  with 
the  entire  real  man  as  we  know  him  in  fact, 
but  with  a  simpler  being  who  is  supposed  to 
be  engrossed  with  one  desire  only,  namely,  the 
desire  of  wealth.  Thus,  according  to  the 
doctrine  laid  down  by  J.  S.  Mill  in  his  Un- 
settled Questions  of  Political  Economy  ^  the  science 
makes  entire  abstraction  of  every  human 
passion  and  motive,  other  than  the  pursuit  of 
wealth,  and  the  perpetually  antagonising  prin- 
ciples to  that  pursuit,  namely,  aversion  to 
labour,  and  desire  of  the  present  enjoyment  of 
costly  indulgences.  In  other  words,  the 
economist  is  described  as  always  working  on  the 
hypothesis  that  the  acquisition  of  wealth  is  the 
sole  end  and  aim  of  human  action.  In  opposi- 
tion to  this  view  is  that  of  the  so-called  "  realis- 
tic "  school,  some  of  whom  practically  deny  the 
utility  of  any  abstract  or  hypothetical  treatment 
of  political  economy  at  all.  It  is  maintained 
by  CoMTE  and  others  that  any  attempt  to  separ- 
ate economic  science  from  social  philosophy  in 
general  must  necessarily  end  in  failure.  The 
truth  seems  to  lie  between  these  two  extreme 
doctrines  ;  and  it  may  be  pointed  out  that 
writers  who,  like  Mill  and  Bagehot,  describe 
political  economy  as  in  its  complete  form  a  purely 
abstract  science,  nevertheless  do  not  treat  it  as 
such  in  their  own  writings.  It  is  true  that  they  - 
employ  an  abstract  method  in  many  of  their 
reasonings,  but  it  is  also  true  that,  taking  their 
doctrines  as  a  whole,  they  do  not  hold  themselves 


aloof  from  the  concrete  realities  of  actual  life  to 
anything  like  the  extent  that  their  description  of 
the  science  would  lead  one  to  anticipate.  They 
begin  with  abstractions,  but  do  not  end  with 
them  ;  and  herein  is  the  true  method  of  the 
science  roughly  set  forth.  We  ought  accordingly 
to  recognise  two  stages  in  economic  doctrine, 
which  may  be  called  the  abstract  and  the  con- 
crete stage  respectively.  It  may  not  be  possible 
to  draw  a  hard  and  fast  line  between  the  two, 
but  this  does  not  destroy  the  value  of  the  dis- 
tinction. Abstract  political  economy  concerns 
itself  entirely  with  certain  broad  general  prin- 
ciples, irrespective  of  particular  economic  con- 
ditions ;  or,  as  Jevons  puts  it,  with  "those 
general  laws  which  are  so  simple  in  nature,  and 
so  deeply  grounded  in  the  constitution  of  man 
and  the  outer  world,  that  they  remain  the  same 
throughout  all  those  ages  which  are  within 
our  consideration "  {Fortnightly  Review,  Nov. 
1876,  p.  625).  It  may  thus  be  of  universal 
validity,  but  this  is  after  aU  only  in  virtue  of  its 
hypothetical  character.  It  may  remain  remote 
from  the  actual  concrete  facts.  Concrete  political 
economy  comes  in,  therefore,  as  a  supplement. 
It  takes  account  of  special  conditions  that  the 
pure  theory  avowedly  neglects,  and  especially 
concerns  itself  with  the  qualifications  and  limita- 
tions, with  which  the  abstract  doctrines  need  to 
be  interpreted.  It  puts  forth  no  claim  to  uni- 
versality, but  is  content  if  it  can  interpret  and 
explain  the  actual  economic  phenomena,  charac- 
teristic of  a  given  period  or  a  given  state  of 
society. 

[Compare  Mill,  Unsettled  Questions  of  Political 
Economy,  Essay  v.  ; — Bagehot,  Economic  Studies, 
Essays  i.  ii.  ; — Jevons,  The  Future  of  Political 
Economy  ; — Fortnightly  Review,  Nov,  1876  ; — 
Keynes,  Scope  and  Method  of  Political  Economy, 
eh.  iv.,  note  A.]  j.  n.  k. 

ABUNDANCE.  In  economical,  as  in  popular, 
discussions,  abundance  is  usually  the  correla- 
tive of  scarcity  and  the  synonym  of  plenty. 
If  there  is  a  distinction  plenty  is  taken  to 
mean  a  sufficient,  and  abundance  a  more  than 
sufficient,  provision  for  wants.  Abundance 
taken  absolutely,  in  the  sense  of  an  overflowing 
plenty,  of  all  and  every  sort  of  goods  is  cer- 
tainly one  ultimate  aim  of  economic  effort ;  and 
Bastiat  in  the  cause  of  free  trade  has  done 
good  service  by  his  assertion  and  illustration  of 
this  axiom.  As  an  overflowing  plenty  it  implies 
the  possibility  of  leisure  ;  it  is  a  provision 
secured  without  cost  of  labour.  Though  this 
is  an  unrealisable  ideal,  the  economical  progress 
of  any  society  may  nevertheless  be  measured  by 
its  approximation  to  it.  In  the  introduction 
to  the  Wealth  of  Nations  "  the  abundance  or 
scantiness  of  the  annual  supply  of  the  necessaries 
and  conveniences  of  life  "  is  made  synonymous 
with  wealth  and  poverty.  In  ordinary  language, 
however,  abundance  does  not,  like  wealth  or 
riches,  suggest  a  contrast  of  more  fortunate  with 


6 


ACCEPTANCE  —ACCOUNT 


less  fortunate  men,  but  rather  a  relation  of  the 
wants  of  individual  men  to  their  means  of  satis- 
faction, without  any  idea  of  contrast  with  their 
neighbours. 

Taken  in  a  narrower  sense,  abundance,  not 
of  all  and  sundry,  but  of  particular  classes 'of 
goods,  is  less  clearly  a  benefit  than  general 
abundance.  To  the  seller,  abundance  (which 
lowers  the  value  of  his  wares)  is  an  evil.  The 
paradox  of  Quesnay  and  other  physiocrats, 
"Disette  et  cherte  est  misere ;  abondance  et 
cherts  est  opulence  "  {e.g.  Daire's  Fhysiocrates, 
p.  98,  cf.  391  ft.),  meant,  for  example,  that 
the  agriculturist  could  only  prosper  if  he  had 
a  good  market  for  his  crops  as  well  as  a  large 
harvest  of  them.  It  is  bad  policy,  they  said, 
to  create  an  abundance  of  necessaries  in  prefer- 
ence to  an  abundance  of  other  goods,  damaging 
one  class  of  producers  in  order  to  benefit  the 
rest.  So  it  is  a  fact  of  common  experience 
that  abundance,  when  confined  to  one  kind  of 
goods,  means  an  "over-production"  or  "glut" 
of  them.  The  remedy  (as  Say  pointed  out)  is 
not  to  decrease  the  abundance  of  the  one  kind  but 
to  increase  the  abundance  of  the  others,  and  so 
bring  the  community  nearer  its  ideal  of  general 
abundance  (see  also  Glut  ;  Over-production  ; 
Physiocrats  ;  J.  B.  Say  ;  Value  ;  and 
Wealth).  j.  b. 

ACCEPTANCE.  In  relation  to  contracts 
generally,  the  term  "acceptance"  means  the 
signification  of  assent  by  one  person  to  a  pro- 
posal made  by  another. 

In  relation  to  contracts  of  sale  the  term  has 
two  significations  which  must  be  distinguished. 
There  is  an  acceptance  in  performance  of  the 
contract  when  the  buyer  intimates  to  the  seller 
that  he  has  accepted  the  goods,  or  when  he 
does  any  act  in  relation  to  them  inconsistent 
with  the  ownership  of  the  seller ;  but  for  the 
purposes  of  the  17th  section  of  the  Statute  of 
Frauds,  it  is  sufficient  if  he  does  any  act  which 
recognises  a  pre-existing  contract  of  sale,  even 
though  he  may  not  be  precluded  from  after- 
wards rejecting  the  goods  (see  Sale). 

In  relation  to  bills  of  exchange  the  term 
primarily  means  the  acceptance  by  the  drawee 
of  a  bill  of  exchange  duly  written  thereon  and 
signed  ;  but  as  the  main  object  of  the  drawer  of 
a  bill  is  to  get  it  accepted,  the  term  "accept- 
ance" is  frequently  used  to  denote  the  bill 
itself,  and  is  then  synonymous  with  "bill  of 
exchange  "  (see  Bill  of  Exchange). 

M.  D.  c. 

ACCEPTILATION  (Scots  and  civil  law). 
Extinction  of  a  debt  by  discharge  granted 
gratuitously  or  for  trifling  payment.        A.  D. 

ACCEPTOR.  The  person  on  whom  a  bill  of 
exchange  is  drawn,  namely,  the  drawee,  becomes 
the  acceptor  by  signifying  his  assent  to  the 
document  in  writing  (see  Bill  of  Exchange). 
The  validity  of  an  acceptance  sometimes  turns 
on  very  intricate  points  of  law. 


For  details  on  this,  see  The  Practice  of  Bank- 
ing, by  John  Hutchison,  especially  vols.  i.  and  iii. 

ACCESSIO.  A  term  of  Roman  law  used 
to  express  the  acquisition  of  property  by  an 
addition  to  former  property,  due  to  an  acci- 
dental circumstance.  If,  for  instance,  a  plot 
of  land  on  the  bank  of  a  river  was  increased  by 
the  gradual  deposit  of  earth  on  the  bank,  the 
property  in  the  new  piece  of  land  was  said  to 
be  acquired  by  "accessio."  e.  s. 

ACCESSION,  Deed  of.  See  Bankruptcy 
in  Scotland. 

ACCOMMODATION  BILL.  An  accommo- 
dation bill  may  be  described  as  a  bill  given 
without  receipt  of  value,  in  order  that  the 
person  to  whom  it  is  given  may  raise  money 
and  obtain  credit  by  means  of  it.  Ordinarily, 
the  person  who  lends  his  name  accepts  a  biU 
drawn  on  him  by  the  person  he  wishes  to 
accommodate,  but  sometimes  a  bill  is  drawn, 
accepted,  and  indorsed  by  different  persons,  in 
order  to  accommodate  some  person  who  is  not 
a  party  to  the  bill  at  aU.  Perhaps  the  strict 
legal  definition  of  an  accommodation  bill  would 
be  a  bill  whereon  the  principal  debtpr,  accord- 
ing to  the  terms  of  the  instrument,  is  in  sub- 
stance a  mere  surety  for  some  other  person, 
whether  that  person  be  a  party  to  the  bill  or 
not.  When  an  accommodation  bill  gets  into 
the  hands  of  a  holder  for  value  he  may  enforce 
payment  of  it  precisely  in  the  same  way  as  if 
the  bill  had  been  given  for  value.  When,  how- 
ever, an  accommodation  bill  is  dishonoured, 
some  special  considerations  come  into  play.  In 
the  first  place  a  drawer  or  indorser  for  whose 
accommodation  the  bill  was  accepted  cannot  set 
up  as  a  defence  either  absence  of  notice  of  dis- 
honour or  informality  in  presentment  for  pay- 
ment, for  he  was  the  party  primarily  liable  to 
meet  the  bill.  Secondly,  if  the  bill  be  held  by 
a  person  who  knows  the  real  relationship  of  the 
parties,  the  ordinary  rule  of  the  law  of  principal 
and  surety  then  attaches,  and  a  discharge  of. 
or  binding  agreement  to  give  time  to,  the  prin- 
cipal debtor  may  discharge  the  surety.  Fot 
instance,  suppose  the  holder  of  a  bill  knows 
that  it  was  accepted  to  accommodate  the  drawer. 
If  it  is  dishonoured,  he  may  sue  either  the  ac- 
ceptor or  the  drawer,  or  both  ;  but  if,  for  some 
fresh  consideration,  he  agrees  with  the  drawer 
not  to  press  him  for  (say)  three  months,  he 
thereby  discharges  the  acceptor.  So  if  a  joint 
and  several  note  is  made  by  three  persons,  two 
of  whom  sign  to  accommodate  the  third,  and 
the  holder  accepts  a  non-statutory  composition 
from  such  third  person,  the  two  co-makers  who 
signed  to  accommodate  him  would  ordinarily 
be  discharged.  m.  d.  c. 

ACCOUNT.  On  the  stock  exchange  there 
are  settlements,  bi-monthly  in  general  securi- 
ties, and  monthly  in  British  consols  and  India 
Government  sterling  stocks.  The  account  begins 
after  one  settlement  and  ends  at  the  date  of  the 


ACCOUNT  DUTY— ACHENWALL 


next.  Transactions  are  said  to  be  "for  the 
account,"  and  prices  are  quoted  for  the  account, 
to  distinguish  these  transactions  from  bargains 
done  "for  cash,"  meaning  for  ready  money. 
Practically,  all  the  speculation  that  goes  on  in 
the  stock  exchange  is  done  by  buying  or  selling 
"for  the  account"  (see  Carrying  Over; 
Backwardation).  a.  e. 

ACCOUNT  DUTY.     See  Death  Duties. 

ACCOUNTS,  Merchants'.  See  Prescrip- 
tion, Scotch. 

ACCRETION  (Scots  law  term).  Referring 
back  an  after- acquired  title  so  as  to  complete  a 
right  originally  defective  or  imperfect,    a.  d. 

ACCRUE.  To  arise  or  spring  as  a  natural 
growth  or  result.  Accrued  interest  is  the  in- 
terest due  for  the  period  which,  at  a  given 
moment,  has  elapsed  since  the  last  payment  of 
interest,  as  for  the  time  being  it  increases  the 
principal  debt.  The  word  is  not  always  free 
from  ambiguity  ;  if,  for  instance,  property  ac- 
cruing after  a  certain  date  is  spoken  of,  it  is  not 
quite  clear  whether  property  in  which  a  future 
interest  was  acquired  before  the  period  named, 
but  which  only  came  into  possession  afterwards, 
is  included.  E.  s. 

ACCUMULATION.  Without  entering  into 
the  difficulties  involved  in  the  definitions  of 
Capital  ;  Wealth  {q.v.),  and  simply  assuming 
that  accumulation  refers  to  wealth  set  aside  from 
present  consumption  for  future  uses,  the  rate  of 
accumulation  in  any  country  at  any  time  is  held 
to  depend  upon  two  groups  of  causes:  (I.) 
causes  affecting  the  fund  from  which  savings 
can  be  made  ;  (II.)  causes  which  induce  people 
to  save  rather  than  to  consume  their  wealth. 

Under  the  first  group  of  causes  may  be  enu- 
merated— (1)  natural  resources,  e.g.  minerals, 
climate,  harbours,  rivers,  etc.  ;  (2)  efficiency  of 
labour  and  capital,  including  industrial  skill 
and  organisation  (see  Efficiency  of  Labour)  ; 
(3)  the  amount  taken  by  government  for  public 
purposes  either  directly  by  taxation  or  indirectly 
by  exacting  services,  as  in  conscription  for  mili- 
tary purposes.  The  indirect  effects  and  methods 
of  expending  it  must  always  be  taken  into 
account  (see  Taxation)  ;  (4)  foreign  trade, 
under  which  we  must  take  into  account  the 
various  elements  of  international  indebtedness 
(see  Foreign  Exchanges),  e.g.  earnings  for 
freight  and  returns  on  foreign  investments ; 
(5)  credit,  which  indirectly  and  directly  saves 
both  labour  and  capital.  Division  of  labour  in 
the  modem  sense  would  hardly  be  possible 
without  credit,  and  it  is  largely  owing  to  credit 
that  saving  in  the  economic  sense  has  taken  the 
place  of  hoarding  (see  Credit)  ;  (6)  means  of 
communication,  e.g.  roads,  canals,  and  railways, 
play  an  important  part  in  the  production  of 
wealth,  for  the  act  of  production  is  not  complete 
till  the  commodity  is  in  the  hands  of  the  con- 
sumer. To  summarise  in  a  sentence,  the  amount 
of  the  fund  from  which  savings  can  be  made 


depends  upon  the  efficiency  of  the  three  great 
agents  of  production — natural  agents,  labour, 
and  capital,  as  compared  with  the  total  expenses 
of  all  kinds,  both  of  individuals  and  govern- 
ments, which  are  necessary  to  preserve  what  is 
called  the  Stationary  State  {q.v.) 

Secondly  we  must  consider  the  motives  which 
induce  people  to  save  rather  than  to  consume 
this  real  net  produce.  The  following  are  held 
to  be  the  most  important  factors :  (1)  security 
that  what  is  saved  will  be  preserved  to  or  en- 
joyed by  the  owner.  Even  slaves,  out  of  their 
small  peculium  have  been  known  to  save  if  they 
were  sure  of  their  savings.  Security,  as  Mill 
points  out,  must  be  given  not  only  by  the 
government  but  against  the  government  (com- 
pare Turkey  at  present  or  the  old  Roman  pro- 
vinces). Security  of  life  owing  to  climatic  or 
other  natural  causes  may  also  be  mentioned  ; 
(2)  effective  desire  of  accumulation  ;  this  con- 
sists really  of  a  group  of  motives.  It  may  be 
weak  from  intellectual  deficiency,  mere  want 
of  power  to  look  forward  (compare  American 
Indians  and  Chinese),  or  from  moral  deficiency, 
no  interest  in  others,  no  sufficient  care  to  avoid 
pauperism  in  old  age,  or  to  provide  for  a  family, 
etc.  ;  (3)  desire  to  rise  in  the  social  scale — the 
importance  attached  to  the  mere  possession  of 
wealth  apart  from  its  uses — a  point  too  often 
overlooked  ;  (4)  facilities  for  investment ;  this 
is  specially  illustrated  by  the  case  of  labourers 
and  savings  facilitated  by  growth  of  savings 
banks,  building  societies,  etc. ,  and  by  insurance 
companies  for  all  classes  ;  (5)  the  difference  of 
the  classes  among  which  the  national  wealth 
is  distributed,  as  certain  classes  tend  to  save 
more  than  others  (compare  France  before  and 
after  the  Revolution,  the  waste  of  the  aristocracy 
and  the  saving  of  the  peasants)  ;  (6)  the  rate  of 
interest,  which  operates  in  two  ways.  If  the 
return  is  high  there  is  a  greater  inducement  to 
invest,  though  Adam  Smith,  in  speaking  of  the 
high  profits  of  the  monopoly  of  the  colonial 
trade,  thinks  it  tends  to  promote  extravagance. 
If  the  return  is  low,  however,  there  is  need  to 
save  more  to  make  a  certain  provision  against 
old  age,  sickness,  etc. 

[The  subject  of  accumulation  is  treated  at  length 
in  all  the  principal  text-books.  Special  attention, 
however,  may  be  called  to  the  criticism  by  Jones 
{Political  Economy,  edited  by  Whewell)  of 
previous  writers,  and  to  the  practical  example  in 
Sir  R.  Giflfen's  paper  entitled  "  Recent  Accumula- 
tion of  Capital,"  Essays  in  Finance,  1878,  and  by 
the  same  author  The  Growth  of  Capital,  1889 
(see  Capital).  ]  J.  s.  n. 

ACHENWALL,  Gottfried,  economist  and 
statistician,  born  in  1719  at  Elbing  in  West 
Prussia,  died  in  1772  at  Gottingen,  where  he 
was  a  professor  in  the  university.  He  was 
author  of  StaatsHicgheit  nach  ihren  ersten 
Grundsdtzen,  1761,  a  work  in  which,  as  Roscher 
remarks,  description  greatly  preponderates  ever 


ACKERSDYK— ACTUARY 


criticism.  He  belongs  to  the  same  school  as 
Jttsti,  namely,  that  of  the  moderate  mercantil- 
ists. It  is  in  the  history  of  statistics  more  than 
in  connection  with  economics  that  he  holds  a 
really  high  place  ;  the  Germans  indeed  some- 
times call  him  the  Father  of  Statistics,  strangely 
ignoring  the  claims  of  Petty  and  other  earlier 
writers.  The  work  by  which  he  is  known  in 
this  department  is  his  Staatsverfassung  der 
heutigen  vornehrristen  Europdischen  Reiche,  1752. 
There  is  prefixed  to  this  treatise  an  introduc- 
tion on  statistics  in  general,  in  which  he  seeks 
to  determine  accurately  the  province  of  the 
study,  and  to  distinguish  it  clearly  from  other 
kindred  branches  of  research.  In  the  body  of 
the  work  he  gives  a  view  of  the  constitutions 
of  the  several  states  of  Europe,  and  describes 
the  condition  of  their  agriculture,  manufactures, 
and  commerce,  often  supplying  numerical  details 
in  relation  to  these  subjects.  He  seems  to  have 
been  the  first  to  use  the  German  word  Statistik  ; 
the  Latin  adjective  Statisticus  is  found  in  the 
title  of  a  book  by  a  German  publicist,  known  as 
Helenus  Politanus  (Microscopium  Statisticum, 
qico  status  imperii  Romano- Germanici  repraesen- 
tatur)  published  in  1672  (Roscher,  Gesch.  der 
Nat.  Oek.  in  Deutschland,  p.  466).       J.  K.  i. 

ACKERSDYK,  John,  born  at  Bois-le-duc, 
20th  Oct.  ]  790,  studied  law  at  Utrecht,  and 
graduated  there  in  1810.  He  died  1861.  First 
a  lawyer,  afterwards  a  judge,  he  was  appointed 
in  1825  a  professor  at  the  University  of  Liege, 
and  in  1830,  after  the  Belgian  revolution,  a 
professor  at  Utrecht.  Here  from  1849  till  1860 
he  taught  economics. 

During  his  long  and  frequent  travels  Ackers- 
dyk  collected  a  vast  mass  of  information  which 
he  availed  himself  of  to  enrich  his  lectures. 
His  writings  are  not  very  numerous,  being 
principally  short  essays  in  periodicals.  The 
following  are  specially  deserving  of  notice : 
Bedenkingen  over  de  Korenwetten  (Remarks  on 
the  Corn  Laws),  1835  ; — Nederlands  financien — 
Nationale  Schuld  (Financial  condition  of 
Holland — National  debt),  1843  ; — Nederlands 
Muntweze7i  (The  Dutch  Currency),  1845  ; — Over 
helastingen  en  Bezuinigingen  (On  Taxes  and 
Savings),  1849.  A.  f.  v.  l. 

ACKNOWLEDGMENT.  The  formal  ad- 
mission of  some  fact — e.g.  acknowledgement  of 
indebtedness.  The  "acknowledgement  of  an 
account "  in  commercial  language  is  equivalent 
to  the  "account  stated"  of  legal  language,  which 
is  an  admission  by  one  party  who  is  in  account 
with  another  that  there  is  a  balance  due  from 
him.  Such  an  admission  in  our  law  imports  a 
promise  to  pay  upon  request.  "Acknowledge- 
ment of  married  women  "  is  the  technical  ex- 
pression for  the  particular  method  which  must  be 
adopted  whenever  a  married  woman  alienates  real 
property  which  is  not  included  in  her  separate 
estate.  The  deed  conveying  the  property  must 
be  acknowledged  by  the  woman  on  being  exa- 


mined by  a  judge  or  commissioner  apart  from 
her  husband.  As  the  sphere  of  the  separate 
estate  has  been  considerably  enlarged  by  the 
Married  Women's  Property  Acts,  the  oppor- 
tunities for  adopting  this  procedure  are  less 
frequent.  E.  s. 

ACLAND,  Rev.  John,  born  in  1699,  was 
the  second  son  of  John  Acland,  M.P.,  of  Woodly, 
Yorkshire.  He  graduated  M.A.  at  Oxford 
(Exeter  Coll.)  in  1725,  was  instituted  vicar  of 
Broad  Clyst,  Devonshire,  in  1753,  and  was  led 
by  the  failure  of  friendly  society  legislation  in 
that  county  to  publish — A  Plan  for  rendering 
the  Poor  independent  on  Public  Contribution 
founded  on  the  basis  of  Friendly  Societies  com- 
monly  called  Clubs,  to  which  is  added  a  letter 
from  Dr.  Price,  Exeter,  1786,  8vo.  Acland's 
proposal  was  that  Parliament  should  establish 
throughout  England  a  general  club  for  the  poor 
in  sickness,  old  age,  or  when  out  of  work  ;  to 
this  every  adult  wage-earner  should  contribute 
as  well  as  the  general  community  (see  Insur- 
ance, Articles  on).  This  plan  was  criticised  in 
a  pamphlet  (1788)  by  the  Rev.  John  Howlett 
(q.v.)  An  abstract  of  it  may  be  seen  in  Eden's 
State  of  the  Poor,  i.  373-380.  Acland  also 
wrote  An  AnMoer  to  a  Pamphlet  published  by 
K  King,  in  which  he  attempts  to  Prove  the  Public 
Utility  of  the  National  Debt,  and  a  True  Statement 
of  the  Real  Cause  of  the  present  high  price  of  Pro- 
visions, 1796,  8vo  (a  tractate  on  the  evils  of 
the  National  Debt).  h.  r.  t. 

ACQUITTANCE.  (1)  Release,  discharge. 
(2)  A  receipt  in  full,  which  bars  a  further  de- 
mand. E.  s. 

ACT  OF  BANKRUPTCY.  For  Scotch 
equivalent  (Notour  bankruptcy)  see  Bank- 
ruptcy IN  Scotland.  a.  d. 

ACTOR  SEQUITUR  FORUM  REI.  See 
Jurisdiction. 

ACTUARY.  The  officer  of  a  life  insurance 
company  wbose  duty  it  is  to  advise  upon  all 
questions  relating  to  their  tariffs,  rates  of 
premium,  and  periodical  valuations  of  assets 
and  liabilities,  in  which  the  calculations  are 
based  upon  mathematical  science,  the  laws 
of  probability,  and  the  statistics  of  death 
and  of  survivorship,  in  combination  with  all 
the  scientific  formulae  connected  with  interest 
of  money  and  with  commercial  finance.  In 
this  sense  the  designation  defines  a  distinct 
class  of  professional  men,  and,  as  such,  it  has 
long  been  used  in  the  legislative  enactments 
relating  to  life  assurances  and  annuities,  and  to 
friendly  societies.  In  the  year  1884  the 
united  members  of  this  profession  received  a 
charter  of  incorporation  from  the  crown,  em- 
powering the  existing  members  of  two  societies 
theretofore  known  as  the  Actuaries  Club  and  the 
Institute  of  Actuaries  to  combine  under  specified 
regulations,  by  the  title  of  that  institute,  and 
the  present  and  future  members  to  allix  the 


ACTUS— ADJUSTMENT,  AVEKAGE 


denoting  letters  of  F.I.  A.  to  their  names.  The 
Jom-nal  of  the  Institute  of  Actuaries  is  pub- 
lished quarterly,  and  its  twenty-eighth  volume 
has  already  been  reached.  The  earlier  volumes 
bore  the  title  of  The  Assurance  Magazine.  Its 
contents  may  with  confidence  be  recommended 
to  students,  as  embracing  papers  of  the  highest 
importance  in  connection  with  the  doctrine, 
history,  and  practice  of  life  assurance,  and  vital 
and  other  statistics  bearing  thereon  and  upon 
annuities,  marine  and  fire  insurance.  The 
designation  of  actuary  has  also  been  long 
applied  to  certain  oflBcers  invested  with  duties, 
more  or  less  like  the  above,  in  savings  banks 
and  in  government  offices  such  as  those  of  the 
commissioners  for  the  reduction  of  the  national 
debt,  the  war  office,  etc.  It  has  also  been 
applied  in  the  last  two  centuries  to  the  clerk  to 
the  convocation  of  clergy,  but  the  name  is  in 
this  case  derived  from  his  being  the  recording 
officer  of  the  acts  arising  but  of  the  deliberations 
of  that  ancient  body,  in  the  same  way  that  the 
"actuar,"  a  functionary  of  the  courts  of  justice 
in  Germany,  has  to  record  and  to  see  to  the 
promulgation  of  their  decrees.  An  account  of 
the  designation  of  actuaries  in  the  case  of  public 
officers  of  other  kinds  in  ancient  Greece  and 
Rome,  may  be  read  in  Sir  George  Cornwall 
Lewis's  Methods  of  reasoning  in  matters  of 
Politics  (see  Insurance).  f.  h. 

ACTUS.  An  expression  of  Roman  law  used 
to  indicate  the  right  of  an  adjoining  owner  to 
drive  cattle  and  take  carts  over  his  neighbour's 
land.  E.  s. 

ADAMS,  Charles  Francis,  born  in  Boston 
1807  ;  died  1886  ;  was  a  lawyer  and  diplomat- 
ist, and  during  the  civil  war  minister  to 
England.  In  the  period  1835-40  he  gave 
considerable  attention  to  the  subject  of  cur- 
rency, and  diff'ered  from  the  Whig  party's  posi- 
tion. Adams  wrote,  in  1837,  Reflections  upon 
the  present  state  of  the  currency  in  the  United 
States,  Boston,  pp.  34,  also  Further  reflections 
upon  the  state  of  the  currency  in  the  United 
States,  Boston,  pp.  41.  He  asserted  that  the 
financial  disturbance  of  1837  was  due  to  over- 
banking,  and  not  to  over-trading  ^^-ith  foreign 
countries,  and  that  it  would  be  impossible  to 
secure  a  uniform  currency  until  it  was  taken  in 
hand  by  the  national  government.  Adams  was 
opposed  to  the  sub-treasury  system,  and  favoured 
a  national  bank.  He  must  not  be  confounded 
with  his  son,  Charles  Francis  Adams  the 
younger,  the  well-known  writer  on  the  railway 
question.  d.  r.  d. 

ADDISON,  Joseph,  born  1672,  died  1719. 
Addison's  brilliant  literary  career  has  drawn 
away  general  attention  from  his  official  position 
in  the  government  of  his  time,  and  his  occupa- 
tion as  one  of  the  lords  commissioners  of  trade 
(see  Board  of  Trade).  His  remarks  (No.  69 
of  the  Spectator)  on  the  importance  of  the  traffic 
of  the  merchant  in  reference  to  the   general 


prosperity  of  the  country  may  still  be  read  with 
interest  as  embodying  those  facts  on  which  the 
principles  of  free  trade  rest. 

ADEMPTION  OF  LEGACY  occurs  where  a 
legacy  does  not  take  effect  owing  to  some  act  on 
the  part  of  a  testator  not  affecting  the  validity 
of  the  will ;  (1)  Where  the  testator  alienates 
the  subject  matter  during  his  lifetime  the  legacy 
fails  ;  (2)  Where  a  parent  or  a  person  in  loco 
parentis  gives  a  legacy  to  a  child,  and  after- 
wards advances  to  such  child  a  portion  on 
marriage,  or  on  preferment  in  life,  if  the  por- 
tion be  equal  to  or  greater  than  the  legacy,  it 
operates  as  a  total  ademption  of  such  legacy  ;  if 
of  lesser  amount  it  adeems  the  legacy  p^-o  tanto. 

[See  Williams  on  Executors,  1879,  pp.  1327- 
1345.]  J.  E.  c.  M. 

ADJUSTMENT,  Average.  A  Rhodian  law 
provided  that  if,  in  order  to  save  a  vessel,  a 
portion  of  the  cargo  was  thrown  overboard,  the 
owners  of  the  rest  of  the  cargo  should  contri- 
bute to  the  loss.  This  principle  has  been 
followed  by  modern  nations,  and  in  the  Eng- 
lish law  it  has  been  expressed  in  the  following 
terms  : — "All  loss  which  arises  in  consequence 
of  extraordinary  sacrifices  made  or  expenses 
incurred  for  the  preservation  of  the  ship  and 
cargo  comes  within  general  average,  and  must 
be  borne  proportionally  by  all  who  are  inter- 
ested "  {hoyf^'DiL^ow  General  Average,  4th  ed., 
London,  1888,  p.  21).  The  calculation  of  the 
losses  incurred  and  the  adjustment  of  the 
amount  to  be  contributed  by  the  ship,  the 
cargo,  and  the  freight  respectively,  is  ellected 
by  a  class  of  arbitrators  called  **  average 
adjusters,"  whose  duty  it  is  to  give  their 
decision  in  accordance  with  legal  principles. 
In  computing  the  amount  to  be  made  good  the 
following  are  the  chief  rules.  (1)  Disburse- 
ments are  estimated  at  the  amount  expended 
plus  the  costs  of  raising  funds.  (2)  Cargo 
sacrificed  is  valued  at  such  a  sum  as  would 
place  the  owner  in  the  same  position  at  the 
time  and  place  of  adjustment  as  if  not  his 
goods  but  those  of  some  other  person  had  been 
sacrificed.  (3)  Ship's  materials  sacrificed  are 
valued  at  the  cost  of  repair,  less  a  deduction  of 
one-third  in  respect  of  the  advantage  derived 
by  the  owner  from  the  fresh  repairs. 

To  the  amount  of  loss  so  ascertained  contri- 
bution has  to  be  made  (1)  by  the  ship  in  pro- 
portion to  its  actual  value  to  the  owner  at  the 
time  of  adjustment ;  (2)  by  the  cargo  in  pro- 
portion to  its  net  market  value  at  the  date  of 
delivery  or  at  the  time  and  place  of  adjustment, 
deducting  the  expenses  the  merchant  incurs  in 
case  of  delivery  ;  (3)  by  the  freight  less  the 
expense  of  earning  it  which  would  have  been 
saved  had  the  ship  been  lost  (see  Average, 
Maritime). 

[^The  Law  of  General  Average,  English  and 
Foreign,  by  Richard  Lowndes,  4th  ed.,  London, 
1888.]  J.  B.  c.  M. 


10 


ADMINISTRATION 


ADMINISTRATION.  The  term  adminis- 
tration is  not  easy  to  define.  It  is  oftenest 
used  to  describe  the  executive  business  of  the 
state.  The  functions  of  the  state  are  usually 
classified  as  legislative,  judicial,  and  executive, 
and  this  classification,  while  open  to  many 
objections,  is  as  good  as  any  other  that  has 
been  suggested.  If  we  adoi)t  it  and  take 
administration  as  equivalent  to  the  execu- 
tive function,  administration  will  practically 
comprehend  all  the  activities  of  the  state  with 
two  important  exceptions,  the  function  of 
making  laws — the  legislative  function — and  the 
function  of  interpreting  laws — the  judicial 
function.  Administration  in  this  sense  includes 
an  immense  number  of  subordinate  functions, 
which  demand  separate  treatment.  In  a  general 
view  of  administration  it  is  only  necessary  to 
discuss  the  following  topics  :  (I)  The  sphere  of 
administration  as  defined  (a)  by  theoretical 
writers,  (b)  in  concrete  historical  instances.  (II) 
The  organisation  of  administration.  (Ill)  The 
relation  of  the  administrative  organisation  to 
(a)  the  sovereign  person  or  body  of  persons,  (&) 
the  individual  citizen.  (IV)  The  economic 
aspects  of  administration. 

I.  Sphere  of  Administration  (a)  as  defined 
by  theoretical  writers.  The  innumerable 
theories  on  this  subject  may  be  reduced 
to  three  types,  the  laissez-faire  type,  the 
socialist  type,  and  the  empirical  type.  The 
Laissez-Faire  theory  may  be  stated  thus : 
Individual  liberty  is  the  one  indispensable  con- 
dition of  goodness  and  happiness.  Constraint 
is  put  upon  the  individual  by  any  and  every 
action  of  the  state.  The  action  of  the  state 
is  therefore  an  evil  to  be  reduced  within  the 
narrowest  limits.  The  state,  therefore,  should 
undertake  only  those  functions  which  cannot 
possibly  be  discharged  by  private  persons, 
singly  or  associated.  Therefore  administration 
should  be  restricted  to  protecting  the  individual 
from  interference,  either  by  lawbreakers  at 
home  or  by  enemies  from  abroad.  The  only 
useful  departments  of  administration  are  the 
army,  navy,  and  police.  The  socialist  theory 
may  be  stated  thus — The  co-operation  of  all 
for  the  good  of  all  is  the  one  indispensable  con- 
dition of  goodness  and  happiness.  This  co- 
operation can  be  effected  by  the  state  and  by 
the  state  alone.  The  action  of  the  state  is 
therefore  a  blessing  to  be  extended  as  much  as 
possible.  Every  human  being  should  be  an 
official  either  in  training,  on  service,  or  pen- 
sioned off".  Administration  should  be  co- 
extensive with  social  life,  and  there  should  be 
as  many  administrative  departments  as  there 
are  branches  of  industry. 

The  empirical  theory  may  be  stated  thus — 
Individual  liberty  and  compulsory  co-operation 
are  not  ends  in  themselves,  but  only  means  to 
human  well-being.  Some  wants  of  society  can 
be  provided  for  only  by  individuals,  other  Avants 


only  by  the  state  ;  but  there  are  many  other 
wants  of  society  respecting  the  satisfaction  of 
which  no  general  rule  can  be  laid  down. 
Experience  must  in  each  case  decide  what  the 
state  should  and  what  it  should  not  attempt. 
Different  maxims  will  apply  to  different  cases. 
What  should  be  done  by  administration  in  any 
country  will  depend  on  the  circumstances  of 
that  country.  This  theory  being  elastic,  its 
professors  differ  greatly  among  themselves, 
some  inclining  to  laissez-faire  and  some  to 
socialism. 

(b)  The  sphere  of  administration,  as  seen  in 
concrete  historical  instances,  has  varied  widely, 
although  it  has  never  corresponded  to  the  re- 
quirements of  extreme  socialism  or  extreme 
laissez-faire.  So  long  as  society  remains  a 
collection  of  self-governing  families,  the  sphere 
of  administration,  like  that  of  legislation,  is 
restricted.  So  long  as  population  continues 
sparse,  wealth  restricted,  and  wants  few,  there 
is  little  work  for  administration.  There  is 
hardly  a  circumstance  in  the  condition  of  a 
people  which  does  not  contribute  to  determine 
the  sphere  of  administrative  action. 

II.  The  Organisation  of  Administration. — 
Administrative  organisation  takes  innumer- 
able forms.  But  the  character  of  an  adminis- 
trative system  depends  mainly  on  the  question 
whether  it  is  carried  on  by  paid  officials  (in 
which  case  it  is  popularly  called  a  bureau- 
cracy), or  whether  it  is  carried  on  by  unpaid 
citizens  (in  which  case  it  is  popularly  called 
self-government).  With  this  distinction  is 
connected  the  distinction  between  a  centralised 
and  a  localised  administration.  A  central- 
ised administration  must,  necessarily,  be  con- 
ducted by  paid  officials,  since  private  persons 
cannot  regularly  travel  long  distances  to  take 
part  in  administrative  work,  most  of  which  lies 
outside  their  knowledge  or  interest.  A  localised 
administration  might  be  whoUy  conducted  by 
paid  officials  of  the  local  authority.  But  in 
practice  it  is  usually  in  great  measure  conducted 
by  private  persons,  who  make  up  for  the  want 
of  professional  skill  by  the  knowledge  of  their 
own  wants,  and  give  their  unpaid  service 
because  they  obtain  an  indirect  return  in 
power,  consideration,  and  the  satisfaction  of 
managing  their  own  affairs. 

BuKEAUCEACY  and  self-government  must  not, 
however,  be  regarded  as  mutually  exclusive 
systems  of  administration.  In  all  civilised 
states  they  supplement  one  another,  although 
their  relative  importance  is  hardly  ever  in  two 
instances  the  same.  It  is  a  mistake  to  suppose 
that  there  is  no  self-government  in  Prussia,  in 
France,  or  even  in  Russia.  It  is  a  mistake  to 
suppose  that  bureaucracy  does  not  play  a  great 
part  in  England.  In  fact  the  administration 
of  a  civilised  state  is  so  serious  a  task  as  to 
demand  all  the  power  of  bureaucracy  and  self- 
government  combined.     The  paid  official   has, 


ADMINISTRATION 


11 


or  should  have,  the  advantage  in  professional 
knowledge,  professional  skill,  professional  disci- 
pline, whilst  the  unpaid  citizen  has,  or  should 
have,  the  advantage  in  familiarity  with  local 
requirements,  in  local  patriotism,  and  in  free- 
dom from  technical  prejudice  and  routine.  An 
ideal  system  would  make  the  unpaid  citizen  do  as 
much  work  for  the  public  as  could  be  got  out  of 
him,  and  ensure  his  doing  it  properly  by  provid- 
ing  official  information,  supervision,  and  audit. 
A  certain  independence  is  necessary  to  make 
unpaid  work  attractive  to  able  and  honest  men. 
On  the  other  hand  some  duties  can  never  be 
efficiently  discharged  by  unpaid  officers,  because 
they  need  a  special  training  and  a  sjjecial  skill. 

Administrative  organisation  admits  of  in- 
numerable variations  in  detail.  A  certain  simi- 
larity may  nevertheless  be  noted  in  the  adminis- 
trative systems  of  states  which  are  similar  in 
extent  and  civilisation.  In  very  small  states 
the  administrative  system  must  necessarily  have 
rather  a  municipal  than  an  imperial  character. 
Thus  in  the  states  of  ancient  Greece  and  of 
ancient  and  mediseval  Italy,  we  find  admini- 
strative organisations  suited  to  the  wants  of  a 
single  town  (see  City — Ancient,  Medieval). 
When  the  state  expanded  beyond  these  dimen- 
sions a  municipal  had  to  be  transformed  into 
an  imperial  administration.  The  most  striking 
instance  of  this  process  is  afforded  by  the 
history  of  Rome.  But  in  very  large  states  the 
imperial  and  the  municipal  organisations  are 
distinct  from  the  first.  The  central  administra- 
tion is  from  the  first  contrasted  with  the  local 
administration.  Both,  however,  are  servants 
and  representatives  of  the  state.  Both  exist  in 
order  to  carry  out  its  laws.  Their  separation 
is  due  to  the  necessities  of  public  business.  It 
is  qualified  by  the  superior  power  of  the  central 
as  compared  with  that  of  the  local  authority, 
and  of  the  sovereign  as  compared  Avith  both. 
Yet  it  is  so  important  that  each  must  be  con- 
sidered by  itself. 

Central  Administration  in  modern  Europe 
has  had  its  root  in  the  power  of  the  monarch 
and  has  grown  with  the  growth  of  that  power. 
Thus  in  France  the  development  of  the  central 
administration  is  almost  co-extensive  with  the 
political  history  of  the  nation.  In  England, 
before  the  Conquest,  there  was  hardly  anything 
which  could  be  called  a  central  administration, 
although  the  local  administration  was  tolerably 
•complete.     After  the  Conquest  the  nucleus  of 

strong  administration  was  created  by  the 
Norman  kings,  who  had  to  maintain  their 
authority  at  once  against  a  recently  conquered 
people  and  a  lawless  feudal  nobility.  By  the 
Domesday  survey  the  central  government  was, 
for  the  first  time,  informed  of  the  population 
and  resources  of  the  kingdom.  The  taxes  were, 
much  augmented  and  the  exchequer  was  organ- 
ised for  the  business  of  collection  and  manage- 
ment.    The  circuits  of  the  itinerant  justices,  at 


first  designed  as  much  for  financial  as  for 
judicial  business,  began  under  Henry  I.  and 
were  systematised  by  Henry  11.  By  means 
of  these  circuits  the  central  administrative 
authority  was  placed  in  direct  contact  with  the 
local  administrative  authorities.  Great  works 
of  architecture  were  executed  at  the  royal 
expense.  Mercenary  armies  were  frequently 
employed.  But  the  administration  as  yet  con- 
cerned itself  with  a  few  comparatively  simple 
matters.  It  was  still  indissolubly  blended  with 
the  economy  of  the  king's  household.  Through- 
out the  Middle  Ages  public  health,  public  com- 
munications, and  police  in  so  far  as  provided 
for,  were  in  the  hands  of  the  local  authorities. 
The  local  authorities  enforced  the  many  regula- 
tions respecting  agriculture,  manufactures,  and 
trade,  which  were  enacted  either  by  themselves 
or  by  parliament.  Education  and  the  Relief 
of  the  poor  were  for  the  most  part  left  to  the  care 
of  the  church.  From  the  accession  of  the  house 
of  Tudor  down  to  our  own  time  the  strength 
and  activity  of  the  central  administration  have 
constantly  grown,  but  so  gradually  and  irregu- 
larly that  a  summary  account  of  the  change  is 
almost  impossible.  The  following  are  the  chief 
points  which  call  for  attention.  During  the 
16  th  century  the  central  administration  is  in 
the  hands  of  the  monarch  and  his  privy 
council,  whose  power  is  seen  rather  in  particular 
arbitrary  acts  than  in  a  minute  official  inter- 
ference with  ordinary  life.  By  the  political 
revolution  of  the  17th  century  a  prime  minister 
depending  on  the  House  of  Commons  and  a 
cabinet  are  substituted  for  the  king  and  privy 
council  as  heads  of  the  administration.  The 
distinction  between  the  Civil  List  {q.v.)  and 
the  rest  of  the  public  expenditure  prc])ares  the 
way  for  the  ultimate  total  separation  between 
the  royal  household  and  the  central  adminis- 
tration. At  the  same  time  the  establishment, 
first  of  a  regular  navy,  then  of  a  regular  army, 
and  the  growth  of  commerce  and  of  colonies, 
involves  the  creation  of  new  administrative 
departments.  But  every  addition  was  made 
piecemeal,  so  that  the  central  administration 
in  the  last  century  presented  a  scene  of  extra- 
ordinary confusion.  In  the  19th  century, 
especially  since  the  passing  of  the  Reform  Act 
of  1832,  the  central  administration  has  been 
almost  completely  transformed.  At  the  acces- 
sion of  William  lY.  the  civil  list  was  so  arranged 
as  to  complete  the  separation  between  the 
personal  income  of  the  monarch  and  the  other 
public  charges.  The  Poor  Law  Amendment 
Act  of  1834  established  the  poor  law  board, 
since  developed  into  the  local  government 
board,  a  body  which  supervises  and  controls 
the  great  majority  of  local  authorities.  The 
modem  legislation  on  public  health,  beginning 
with  the  act  of  1848  and  consolidated  by  the 
Public  Health  Act,  1875,  is  also  enforced  by 
the  local  government  board.     The  Committee 


12 


ADMINISTRATION 


of  Council  of  Education,  established  in  1839, 
became  in  virtue  of  the  Education  Act  of  1870 
an  education  department  controlling  the  public 
elementary  education  of  England.  The  military 
and  naval  departments  have  undergone,  and  are 
still  undergoing,  various  modifications. 

Local  Administration. — The  character  of  a 
system  of  local  administration  depends  chiefly 
upon  (a)  the  mode  in  which  the  country  is 
distributed  into  administrative  areas  ;  (&)  the 
constitution  of  the  administrative  authorities  ; 
(c)  the  functions  entrusted  to  them  ;  and  (d) 
their  relation  to  the  central  administrative 
authority,  (a)  In  modern  states  it  has  gener- 
ally been  found  advisable  to  divide  the  territory 
into  at  least  three  species  of  administrative  areas, 
the  smallest  being  the  Township,  Parish,  or 
Commune,  the  intermediate  being  the  hundred 
or  Union  or  arrondissement,  and  the  largest,  the 
County,  province,  or  Department.  The  whole 
territory  is  thus  divided  into  three  systems  of 
areas.  But  certain  parts  of  the  territory, 
especially  towns  and  cities,  differ  so  much  from 
the  rest  in  requirements  and  resources  that  they 
are  usually  constituted  into  special  administra- 
tive areas.  The  space  covered  by  these  areas 
may  or  may  not  be  withdrawn  from  the  general 
subdivision.  Thus  many  of  the  larger  English 
cities  and  towns  possess  all  the  attributes  of 
counties,  but  they  are  distributed  into  parishes. 

Again,  the  larger  areas  may  be  formed  by 
grouping  the  smaller  areas,  or  they  may  have 
no  reference  to  them.  Thus  in  England  the 
union  area  has  always  been  made  up  by  grouping 
a  number  of  poor-law  parishes ;  but  these 
parishes  may  be  in  more  than  one  county,  so 
that  the  boundaries  of  the  union  often  intersect 
those  of  the  county.  Again,  the  union  area 
and  the  area  of  a  municipal  borough  may  coin- 
cide, but  generally  they  have  been  traced  with- 
out reference  to  each  other,  and  a  municipal 
area  may  contain  fragments  of  two  or  three 
poor-law  areas.  Besides  these,  many  other 
administrative  areas  have  been  created  at  differ- 
ent times  and  have  not  been  harmonised  with 
one  another.  This  confusion  of  areas  is,  how- 
ever, almost  confined  to  England,  and  is  being 
gradually  mitigated.  In  England  and  elsewhere 
different  methods  of  division  have  prevailed  in 
different  periods.  The  county  has  always 
remained  the  largest  administrative  area  ;  but 
the  Hundred  has  almost  disappeared,  whilst  the 
Poor  Law  union  is  quite  modern  ;  and  in  the 
lowest  range  the  township  has  in  many  instances 
been  succeeded  by  the  Manor,  and  this  again 
by  the  parish,  civil  or  ecclesiastical. 

(&)  The  constitution  of  the  local  authority 
in  each  area  admits  of  much  variety,  but  is 
generally  reducible  to  one  of  four  types  ;  an 
assembly  of  all  householders  in  the  area,  an 
assembly  of  elected  representatives,  a  compara- 
tively small  ruling  body  recruited  either  by 
co-optation  or  by  the  selection  of  the  supreme 


government,  and  a  staff  of  officials  paid  by, 
and  immediately  controlled  by,  that  government. 
Thus  the  Anglo-Saxon  township  and  the  town- 
ship of  New  England  had  as  their  authority  the 
assembly  of  householders,  and  the  same  type  of 
authority  appears  modified  by  feudal  influence 
in  the  courts  of  the  mediaeval  manor,  and 
modified  by  ecclesiastical  influence  in  the 
general  vestry  of  the  modern  parish.  Some- 
thing similar  is  seen  in  the  village  council  of 
eastern  Europe  and  of  Asia.  But  this  type  of 
authority  is  suitable  only  to  the  smallest  area. 
The  second  type  of  authority,  the  elective 
assembly,  is  seen  in  the  English  select  vestry, 
board  of  guardians,  and  modern  municipal  and 
county  councils,  and  generally  in  the  urban 
communities  of  the  civilised  world.  Unlike 
the  popular  assembly,  it  is  compatible  with  an 
extensive  area  and  with  multifarious  adminis- 
trative duties,  and  as  it  harmonises  with  demo- 
cratic sentiment,  it  is  coming  into  more  general 
employment.  The  third  type  of  authority,  the 
exclusive  body,  was  seen  in  many  English 
municipal  corporations  before  the  act  of  1835, 
and  in  the  English  county  authorities  before  the 
act  of  1888.  Some  of  the  municipal  bodies  of 
this  class  renewed  themselves  by  co-optation. 
The  Quarter  Sessions  were  recruited  by  the 
appointment  of  the  crown  from  a  list  presented 
by  the  lord-lieutenant,  and  composed  of 
persons  having  a  certain  property  qualification. 
The  fourth  type  of  authority,  the  staflf  of 
government  officials,  is  almost  unknown  in 
England  and  is  not  common  anywhere.  But  in 
many  countries  the  head  of  the  administrative 
body,  and  the  possessor  of  all  real  administra- 
tive power,  the  prefect  or  mayor,  is  a  govern- 
ment official,  and  his  elective  colleagues  exist 
chiefly  in  order  to  disguise  the  fact  that  there 
is  no  real  self-government. 

(c)  As  regards  the  functions  of  the  local 
authority,  these  have  undergone  many  changes. 
In  England  they  originally  comprised,  besides 
certain  legislative  and  judicial  duties,  the  duty 
of  maintaining  a  police,  the  duty  of  keeping  up 
public  communications,  the  duty  of  taking 
certain  precautions  for  the  public  health  by 
removal  of  nuisances,  etc.,  and  the  duty  of 
enforcing  a  multitude  of  regulations  as  to 
weights  and  measures,  the  quality  of  goods 
offered  for  sale,  especially  provisions,  and  other 
matters  connected  with  manufactures  and  com- 
merce. A  series  of  statutes  culminating  in  the 
poor  law  of  Elizabeth  passed  in  1601  added 
the  function  of  relieving  the  poor,  formerly  left 
to  ecclesiastical  or  to  private  charity.  The 
duty  of  providing  for  the  public  health,  which 
had  been  little  more  than  nominal,  has  become 
in  our  time  a  great  branch  of  local  administra- 
tion. The  duty  of  providing  for  elementary 
education  is  still  more  recent.  Besides  these 
functions  local  authorities  have  acquired,  under 
a  number  of  general  or  special  acts,  power  to 


ADMINISTRATION 


13 


provide  almost  everything  which  can  minister 
to  the  health,  decency,  comfort,  or  amusement 
of  a  dense  population — gas  and  water  works, 
markets,  museums,  galleries  of  art,  libraries, 
parks,  gardens,  baths,  lodging-houses,  and 
burial  grounds. 

(d)  Relation  to  the  central  authority.  This 
relation  differs  widely  not  only  in  different 
states  but  in  the  same  state  at  different  times, 
or  with  respect  to  different  classes  of  local 
authority.  Thus  in  England  the  control  of  the 
central  authority  has  usually  been  less  strict 
than  in  France.  In  England  tliere  was  hardly 
any  effective  control  of  local  administrative 
bodies  by  a  central  authority,  until  the  Poor 
Law  Amendment  Act  of  1834.  The  poor  law 
commission  first,  and  afterwards  the  local 
government  board,  have  exercised  over  the 
union  authorities  a  pretty  complete  control.  It 
has  been  said  that  the  only  question  with  respect 
to  which  a  board  of  guardians  has  any  real 
discretion  is  that  of  granting  or  refusing  applica- 
tions for  relief.  The  municipal  corporations  on 
the  other  hand,  especially  those  of  the  largest 
boroughs,  have  retained  a  real  independence. 

The  central  administrative  authority  may 
influence  the  local  administration  in  one  or 
more  of  the  following  ways  :  (a)  By  collecting, 
preserving,  and  circulating  statistical  and  other 
information  useful  for  administrative  purposes  ; 
(6)  by  enacting  rules  to  guide  the  local 
authority  ;  (c)  by  periodical  inspection  or 
constant  supervision  to  ensure  the  observance 
of  these  rules  ;  {d)  by  periodical  audit  of  the 
accounts  of  the  local  authority.  The  means  of 
enforcing  this  control  are  various.  The  extreme 
penalty  for  disobedience  is  the  dissolution  of  the 
offending  local  authority.  In  England  a  board 
of  guardians  may  be  dissolved  by  order  of  the 
local  government  board,  but  a  municipal  cor- 
poration cannot  be  dissolved  by  any  merely 
administrative  authority.  A  lighter  penalty  is 
the  withliolding  either  altogether  or  in  part  of 
grants  of  money,  ordinarily  made  by  the  central 
to  the  local  authority.  Thus  a  school  board  in 
England  obtains  the  government  grant  only  in 
so  far  as  the  education  given  by  it  satisfies  the 
education  department. 

III.  Relation  of  the  Administrative  Organisa- 
tion to  (a)  the  sovereign  person  or  body  of 
persons ;  (6)  the  individual  citizen.  The 
sovereign  in  each  state  will  necessarily  control 
the  administration,  but  this  will  be  effected  in 
diflferent  ways.  Under  the  older  form  of  con- 
stitutional monarchy  the  monarch  made  laws 
by  the  advice  of  his  parliament  and  carried  on 
the  administration  by  the  help  of  his  council. 
The  ministers  were  his  ministers,  and  through 
them  he  controlled  every  branch  of  the  adminis- 
tration. At  the  same  time  he  depended  on  his. 
parliament  for  the  necessary  funds,  and  his 
ministers  were  liable  to  parliamentary  impeach- 
ment.    Under  the  later  form  of  constitutional 


monarchy,  the  prime  minister  takes  the  place 
of  the  king  and  the  cabinet  takes  the  place  of 
the  privy  council.  The  prime  minister  and 
cabinet  owe  their  power  to  the  support  of  the 
majority  in  the  more  popular  house  of  the 
legislature.  Thus  that  house  which  is  virtually 
sovereign  has  a  direct  control  over  the  adminis- 
tration. Most  modern  republics  are  organised 
on  the  model  of  constitutional  monarch3\  In 
the  United  States  the  president  is  perliaps  more 
influential  in  the  administration  than  was 
formerly  the  king  of  England.  The  ministers 
are  his  niinisters  and  do  not  even  sit  in  congress. 
In  France  the  president  takes  tlic  place  of  a 
modern  king  of  England,  the  prime  minister  is 
the  real  ruler  of  the  state,  and  he  and  liis  cabinet 
hold  oflSce  at  the  pleasure  of  the  majority  in  the 
chamber  of  deputies.  In  despotic  monarchies 
the  monarch  has  sole  control  of  the  administra- 
tion, unchecked  either  by  a  power  of  withholding 
supplies  or  by  a  power  of  impeachment  residing 
in  a  representative  body. 

The  relation  of  the  administrative  system 
to  the  individual  citizen  differs  in  different 
countries  according  to  the  nature  of  the  authority 
empowered  to  decide  upon  tlieir  respective  rights 
and  duties.  In  many  des2)otic  states  of  a  rude 
type  administrative  and  judicial  functions  are 
united  in  the  hands  of  tlie  monarch  and  the 
provincial  governors.  Under  this  system  there 
can  be  little  protection  for  the  individual  citizen. 
In  the  despotic  states  of  civilised  Europe  the 
administrative  and  judicial  organisations  were 
usually  kept  distinct,  but  acts  done  in  the 
course  of  administration  were  })laced  under  a 
special  law  administered  by  special  tribunals, 
and  in  many  cases  action  could  not  be  taken 
before  these  tribunals  witliout  the  previous  sanc- 
tion of  the  government.  In  Fi-ance  this  system 
survived  many  revolutions  and  has  but  recently 
been  modified.  It  is  also  found  more  or  less 
developed  in  many  other  continental  states. 
In  England  a  special  administrative  law  and 
special  administrative  tribunals  are  unknown. 
Every  branch  of  the  public  service  has  its  own 
regulations  and  discipline,  but  these  affect  only 
its  members.  Every  administrative  autliority 
stands  in  the  position  of  a  private  person  em- 
powered by  law  to  discharge  certain  special 
functions.  Acts  done  in  the  course  of  admini- 
stration are  on  the  footing  of  all  other  acts. 
If  a  policeman  uses  excessive  violence  in  taking 
a  prisoner  to  the  police  station,  or  if  a  collector 
of  taxes  exceeds  his  lawful  powers,  redress  is 
afforded  by  the  ordinary  courts  of  justice  apply- 
ing the  same  laws  and  observing  the  same 
procedure  as  in  any  other  case  of  assault  or  of 
extortion.  So  too  the  rights  and  duties  of  any 
government  department  or  local  authority  are 
determined  like  those  of  any  private  individual. 

IV.  Economic  Aspects  of  Administration. — 
These  are  numerous  and  complicated.  In  the 
first  place  administration  includes  the  business 


14 


ADMINISTRATION— ADMINISTRATION,  LETTERS  OF 


of  raising  the  public  Revenue.  It  thus  in- 
cludes the  whole  of  public  finance.  In  this  light 
thequestions  as  to  the  safe  limits  of  Taxation,  as 
to  the  best  kinds  of  taxes,  as  to  the  most  economi- 
cal methods  of  levying  them,  as  to  the  least 
harmful  ways  of  raising  and  the  least  oppresgive 
modes  of  liquidating  public  loans,  are  all 
administrative  questions,  although  they  are  so 
extensive  that  they  cannot  be  treated  in  this 
article.  In  the  second  place  administration 
includes  the  business  of  spending  the  public 
revenue.  That  business  suggests  the  inquiry 
as  to  the  proper  functions  of  the  state.  What 
should  the  state  attempt  to  do  itself?  what 
should  it  attempt  to  regulate  ?  what  should  it 
leave  entirely  out  of  view?  These  questions 
raise  other  than  economical  issues  ;  but  they 
raise  economical  issues  too.  Thus  experience 
shows  that  in  countries  where  capital  and 
knowledge  are  rare  many  of  the  requisites  of 
production  such  as  Railways,  Canals,  aque- 
ducts, Docks,  drainage,  and  irrigation  works,  can 
be  provided  only  by  administrative  efifort.  By 
providing  these  the  state  does  not  lessen  indi- 
vidual energy  or  narrow  its  field  of  action. 
On  the  contrary,  by  facilitating  production 
these  administrative  undertakings  have  often 
strengthened  the  spirit  of  individual  enterprise 
and  accumulation,  A  notable  illustration  of 
the  service  which  may  thus  be  rendered  by  an 
efiicient  administration  is  seen  in  the  growing 
prosperity  of  British  India.  In  a  later  stage 
of  economic  development  more  can  be  done  by 
private  effort  and  less  needs  to  be  done  by 
administration.  But  the  growing  complexity 
of  life  and  industry,  the  gathering  of  multitudes 
into  large  cities,  the  concentration  of  industries 
in  huge  factories,  the  production  of  the  neces- 
saries of  life,  not  by  domestic  labour,  but  by 
scientific  processes  on  a  vast  scale,  the  new 
combinations  of  labour  and  of  capital,  the 
increased  attention  given  to  health,  the  more 
exacting  demand  for  enjoyment,  and  education, 
the  dissolution  of  old  customs  and  beliefs, 
all  these  changes  bring  with  them  difficulties 
which  compel  interference  here  and  interference 
there  and  a  vast  process  of  administrative  regu- 
lation. No  general  rule  can  be  laid  down 
respecting  the  effect  of  such  regulation  ;  the 
eftect  can  be  known  in  each  case  only  by  experi- 
ence. All  that  can  be  said  is  that  before 
regulating  any  branch  of  industry  the  fullest 
information  possible  should  be  procured,  and 
that  all  new  regulation  should  be  tentative. 
In  the  third  place  we  have  to  consider  the 
economic  effect  of  efficiency  or  inefficiency  in 
administration  irrespective  of  its  objects.  The 
industry,  the  integrity,  and  the  intelligence  of 
the  administration  are  great  economic  forces. 
Compare  the  administrative  staff  in  Turkey 
with  the  administrative  staff  in  Prussia  and 
consider  their  influence  on  the  economic  con- 
dition of  their  respective   countries.      If  the 


administrator  is  an  official,  his  efficiency  will 
depend  greatly  upon  the  spirit,  education,  and 
traditions  of  the  service  of  which  he  is  a  mem- 
ber ;  if  he  is  a  private  citizen,  his  efficiency  will 
depend  greatly  upon  the  spirit,  education,  and 
traditions  of  the  class  from  which  he  comes. 
In  the  fourth  place  the  magnitude  of  the  ad- 
ministrative staff  is  a  circumstance  of  economic 
importance.  An  overgrown  civil  service  means  a 
great  number  of  idlers  and  a  waste  of  productive 
power,  especially  power  of  mind.  It  also  means 
a  heavier  taxation  of  the  productive  classes  (see 
Bureaucracy  ;  Civil  List  ;  Government). 

[For  a  general  view  of  the  modern  state  and  its 
organs,  see  Bluntschli,  Theory  of  the  State ;  for 
the  history  of  the  English  administrative  system 
consult  Stubbs's  and  Gneist's  Constitutional  His- 
tories of  England  ;  for  its  present  state  consult 
the  volumes  on  Central  Government,  Local  Oovem- 
inent,  The  National  Income  and  Expenditure,  The 
State  in  Relation  to  Labour,  and  The  State  in  Rela- 
tion to  Trade  in  the  English  Citizen  Series,  and 
the  statutes  and  other  authorities  to  which  they 
refer.]  F,  c.  m. 

ADMINISTRATION,  Letters  of.  When 
a  person  dies  intestate  his  real  estate  passes 
immediately  to  his  heir,  i.e.  to  the  person 
designated  by  law  as  entitled  to  its  enjoyment. 
His  persona?  estate,  however,  has  to  be  ad- 
ministered for  the  benefit  of  (1)  his  creditors 
(2)  of  the  next  of  kin  entitled  to  enjoy  the 
surplus  after  payment  of  his  debts.  The  ad- 
ministrator is  a  person  who  takes  out  letters  of 
administration,  i.e.  procures  himself  to  be 
nominated  by  the  Probate  Division  of  the 
High  Court  to  the  administration  of  the  estate. 
Letters  of  administration  are  granted  usually 
to  some  of  the  next  of  kin  ;  failing  them,  to  a 
creditor,  and,  if  there  be  no  creditor,  to  any 
person  whom  the  Court  thinks  suitable.  Once 
appointed,  the  administrator  very  closely  re- 
sembles an  executor  appointed  by  will.  Like 
the  executor  the  administrator,  as  such,  has  no 
beneficial  interest  in  the  estate,  and  no  liability 
for  anything  beyond  the  assets  which  he  receives. 
He  is  bound  to  realise  the  personal  estate  of  the 
intestate  to  pay  the  funeral  expenses  and  debts, 
and  to  distribute  the  balance,  if  any,  among 
the  persons  entitled  under  the  Statutes  of  Dis- 
tribution (22  &  23  Car.  II.  c.  10,  and  acts 
explaining  or  amending).  He  may  himself 
happen  to  be  one  of  these  persons. 

It  may  happen  that  although  the  deceased 
has  made  a  will  he  has  named  no  Executor,  or 
that  the  executor  named  refuses  to  act,  or  be- 
comes incapable,  or  dies  before  the  testator. 
In  any  of  these  cases  an  administrator  must  be 
appointed,  and  his  administration  is  said  to  be 
"cum  testamento  annexe,"  since  it  is  his  duty 
to  give  effect  to  the  provisions  of  the  will. 
Should  the  sole  executor  or  the  administrator 
be  an  infant,  his  guardian  will  obtain  letters  of 
administration  "durante  minori  aetate,"  thai 
is,  until  the  infant  attains  his  majority. 


ADMINISTRATOR— AD   VALOREM  DUTY 


15 


Should  the  administrator  die  before  he  has 
fully  administered  the  estate,  a  new  adminis- 
trator must  be  appointed.  For  the  office  of 
administrator  does  not  pass  like  the  office  of 
executor  to  the  personal  representatives  of  the 
person  who  held  it.  The  new  administrator 
has  administration  "de  bonis  non  adminis- 
tratis"  (often  termed  "  de  bonis  non")  i.e.  of 
goods  not  administered  by  his  predecessor. 

What  would  be  the  best  law  of  intestate 
succession  is  a  question  which  has  been  much 
discussed,  and  involves  complicated  economical 
considerations.  But,  whatever  the  nature  of 
that  law,  the  office  of  administrator  of  the 
estate  of  the  intestate  appears  equally  necessary. 

[See  Williams's  Personal  Property.]    F.  c.  M. 

ADMINISTRATOR.  The  personal  repre- 
sentative of  a  deceased  intestate  or  of  a  testator 
whose  will  does  not  appoint  any  executors,  or 
whose  executors  are  unable  or  unwilling  to  act. 
The  nearest  relative  who  is  willing  to  act  is 
appointed  administrator,  and  in  default  of 
relatives  administration  may  be  granted  to  a 
creditor.  The  instrument  certifying  the  gi-ant 
is  called  "letters  of  administration."  The 
personal  estate  of  the  intestate  or  testator 
(and  since  1882  such  real  estate  as  was  held  by 
him  in  a  fiduciary  capacity)  becomes  vested  in 
the  administrator,  who  has  to  pay  all  debts 
chargeable  to  the  estate,  and  to  distribute  the 
residue  according  to  law,  viz.  in  case  of  intestacy 
in  accordance  with  the  Statutes  of  Distribution 
and  the  modifying  enactments  (22  &  23  Car. 
II.  c.  10  ;  1  Jac.  II.  c.  17),  and,  where  there 
is  a  valid  will  in  accordance  with  the  directions 
contained  in  the  same.  In  the  latter  case  the 
grant  is  made  "with  the  will  annexed  "  (cum 
testamento  annexo).  e.  s. 

ADULTERATION.  The  alteration  of  an 
article  into  something  inferior,  but  not  readily 
distinguishable  in  appearance,  by  the  addition  of 
cheaper  materials.  Legislation  has  endeavoured 
to  provide,  in  many  instances,  but  not  always 
successfully,  that  the  articles  thus  deteriorated 
should  be  marked  out  so  distinctly  that  the 
unwary  may  be  always  able  to  escape  the  pit- 
fall. Against  this  endeavour  the  maxims  of 
Caveat  Emptor  and,  with  less  ground,  of 
Laissez  Faire,  are  sometimes  invoked.  Occa- 
sionally even  the  spirit  of  class  opposition  (as 
when  legislation  against  adulteration  is  promoted 
by  producers  whose  interests  are  individually 
aflfected)  is  called  up  to  hinder  the  prevention 
of  the  sale  of  something  which,  though  con- 
fessedly not  what  it  professes  to  be,  is  claimed 
to  be  a  cheaper  and  as  useful  an  article  as  that 
for  which  it  is  substituted.  Professor  Marshall 
observed  {Inaugural  Address,  Co-operative  Con- 
gress, Ipswich,  1889),  in  speaking  of  adulteration, 
"That  term  is  often  used  so  as  to  include  open 
and  undisguised  changes  in  the  character  of 
goods  to  suit  the  wants  and  the  tastes  of  con- 
sumers.    But  you  seem  to  me  to  have  a  clear 


duty :  it  is  to  explain  to  consumers  what 
things  are  cheap  and  what  things  only  appear 
to  be  cheap  ;  to  give  them  for  their  money 
as  high  class  goods  as  you  can  affi)rd,  and  as 
much  truthful  information  about  them  as  you 


AD  VALOREM  DUTY.  A  duty  levied  on 
a  commodity  in  proportion  to  the  value,  in 
contrast  to  a  specific  charge  on  the  quantity. 
At  first  sight  this  form  of  taxation  appears  the 
more  equitable  one.  In  practice,  however, 
customs  duties  ad  valorem  have  been  found  to 
work  out  with  great  inequality,  and  also  to  be 
inconvenient  to  levy  for  various  reasons,  among 
which  are  the  following :  (1)  the  difficulty  of 
ascertaining  correctly  the  values  of  the  goods 
charged  with  the  duty;  (2)  the  opening  to  fraud  ; 
(3)  the  delay  and  hindrances  caused  to  importers 
and  others.  In  theory  it  might  be  supposed 
that  ad  valorem  taxes  on  all  commodities  would 
not  affect  their  relative  values,  but  it  has  been 
maintained  that,  owing  to  the  different  propor- 
tions in  which  fixed  and  circulating  capitals  enter 
into  their  cost  of  production,  this  would  not  be 
so.  Thus  J.  S.  Mill  remarks  {Principles  of  Pol. 
Econ.  bk.  v.  ch.  iv.  §  1)  that  in  case  of  an  ad 
valorem  duty  on  all  commodities  exactly  in 
proportion  to  their  value  there  would  be  a 
disturbance  of  values  owing  to  .  .  .  "  the 
different  durability  of  the  capital  employed  in 
different  occupations."  An  ad  valorem  duty 
was  levied  at  an  early  date  in  this  country. 
There  existed  temp.  Edward  I.  an  ad  valorem 
duty  of  3d.  upon  every  lihrate  or  twenty  solidi 
of  lead  and  tin  {Customs  Revenue  of  England, 
Hubert  Hall,  vol.  i.  p.  66).  At  the  present 
date  ad  valorem  duties,  as  such,  are  practically 
unknown  to  the  British  fiscal  system ;  the 
wine  duties  levied  differently  on  different  classes 
of  wine  approach  them  (see  Taxation). 

CouRNO'j'  arrives  by  mathematical  reasoning 
at  the  conclusion  that  the  effect  of  an  ad 
valorem  tax  of  so  much  per  cent  will  be  the 
increase  of  the  expenses  of  production  (includ- 
ing transmission  into  the  consumer's  hands)  by 
a  larger  percentage.  Let  n  be  that  fraction  of 
the  value  which  constitutes  the  tax.  Then  the 
effect  is  as  if  the  expenses  of  production  had 
been  increased  in  the  ratio  \-n:l.  Whence 
it  follows  that,  other  things  being  equal,  a  tax 
will  be  heavier  as  the  expense  of  production  is 
greater,  that  is  "as  in  the  price  of  the  com- 
modity a  smaller  part  represents  the  profit "  of 
the  seller.  The  theorem  is  true  both  in  a 
rigime  of  monopoly  and  of  competition. 

[See  James  Mill,  Elements  of  Pol.  Econ.  —J.  S. 
mil,  Principles  of  Pol.  Econ.— J.  R.  M'Culloch, 
Principles  of  Pol.  Econ.,  Taxation  and  the  Fund- 
ing Systevi,  p.  ii.  ch.  iii. — S.  Buxton,  Finance 
and  Politics,  an  Historical  Study,  1786-1885. — 
Paul  Leroy-Beaulieu,  Traiti  de  la  Science  des 
Finances,  vol.  i.  ed.  1877,  p.  566. — Dictionnaire 
des  Finances,  1889,  vol.  i.,  "Droits  ad  valorem." 


16 


ADVANCES— ADVENTURERS,  MERCHANTS 


Recherches  sur  les  prindpes  Malh^iatiques  de 
la  Theorie  des  Richesses,  arts.  41  and  53.  The 
passages  referred  to  contain  some  other  abstract 
theorems  relating  to  an  ad  valorem  tax.] 

ADVANCES.  In  the  writings  of  the  French 
Physiocrats  "advances"  are  an  outlay  of  wealth 
with  a  view  to  some  future  return,  as  opposed 
to  an  outlay  for  immediate  consumption.  This 
notion  was  wide  enough  to  include  the  advances 
of  food  made  by  a  parent  to  his  infant  child 
(Daire,  Fhysiocrates,  ed.  1846,  p.  391),  and 
might  include  the  means  of  preparing  a  feast 
or  making  a  toy.  But  more  commonly  the 
word  was  used  almost  as  we  now  use  "capital." 
"The  weapons  made  by  the  first  hunter  were 
a  great  augmentation  of  his  capital  or  his 
advances"  (Daire,  ib.)  The  physiocrats  dis- 
tinguished three  sorts  of  advances  in  agricul- 
ture : — (1)  Tlie  ground  expenses  or  avances 
fondhres  which  are  laid  out  once  for  all,  e.g, 
on  clearing,  draining,  etc.  ;  (2)  The  original 
advances  or  avances  pr'imitives,  needing  occa- 
sional repair  or  renewal,  e.g.  on  ploughs,  carts, 
oxen,  and  manure  ;  (3)  the  annual  expenses, 
or  dApenses  annuelles,  which  need  regular  and 
continual  renewal,  e.g.  wages  of  labourers  and 
food  of  cattle  (Daire,  ih.,  p.  3'44).  Turgot 
applies  similar  distinctions  even  to  manufac- 
ture {Form,  et  Distrib.  des  Rich.  §  52  seq.) 
The  distinction  drawn  by  Adam  Smith  between 
fixed  and  circulating  capital  rests  not  on  this 
difference  of  durability  but  on  the  retention  or 
non-retention  of  the  capital  in  the  hands  of 
the  investor.  Ricardo  adopts  the  criterion  of 
durability  while  preserving  the  twofold  instead 
of  the  physiocratic  threefold  division.  Later 
economists  have  followed  Ricardo,  though  most 
of  them  admit  with  him  that  such  a  distinc- 
tion, being  one  of  mere  degree,  cannot  be 
closely  pressed.  The  "advances  necessary  to 
produce  a  commodity  "  are  sometimes  described 
as  synonymous  with  the  capital  necessary  to 
produce  it  {e.g.  Malthus,  Pol.  JScon.,  1st  ed., 
p.  293)  ;  and  sometimes  we  hear  of  the  "ad- 
vance of  capital"  (Senior,  Fol.  Econ.,  p.  194)  ; 
but  it  is  specially  in  relation  to  wages  and  the 
wages  fund  that  the  word  "advances"  has 
been  most  frequently  employed  (see  Capital  ; 
W.  N.  Senior  ;  Wages  Fund).  The  financial 
sense  of  the  word  (e.g.  advances  to  government 
by  the  bank)  calls  for  no  special  consideration 
here.  j.  b. 

ADVENTURERS,  Merchants.  English 
companies  for  the  conduct  and  extension  of  foreign 
commerce  have  been  of  two  diflferent  kinds — (1) 
Regulated,  and  (2)  Joint -stock  companies. 
"  When  they  do  not  trade  upon  a  joint  stock," 
says  Adam  Smith  (bk.  v.  ch.  i.),  "but  are 
obliged  to  admit  any  person,  properly  qualified, 
upon  paying  a  certain  fine  and  agi^eeing  to 
submit  to  the  regulations  of  tlie  company,  each 
member  trading  upon  his  own  stock  and  at  his 
own  risk,  they  are  called  regulated  companies. 


When  they  trade  upon  a  joint  stock,  each 
member  sharing  in  the  common  profit  and  loss 
in  proportion  to  his  share  in  the  stock,  they 
are  called  joint-stock  companies."  The  oldest 
and  most  celebrated  of  the  former  class  was  the 
company  of  Merchants  Adventurers.  To  under- 
stand its  history,  we  must  advert  to  the  system 
of  the  Staple,  established  temp.  Henry  III. 
Certain  places  on  the  continent  were  fixed  by 
royal  authority  as  the  sole  marts  for  English 
wares,  where  goods  were  to  be  "  collected,  tried, 
and  assessed."  During  the  13th  and  14th 
centuries  the  five  great  exports  of  England  were 
wool,  woolfells,  leather,  tin,  and  lead,  the  first 
by  far  the  most  important.  Bruges  in  Flanders 
was  most  commonly  the  seat  of  the  Staple,  but 
the  English  kings  frequently  transferred  it  to 
other  continental  towns,  as,  for  example,  to 
Bergen,  Dort,  and  Calais,  usually  for  political 
rather  than  commercial  reasons.  When  the 
English  cloth  manufacture  began  to  assume 
importance,  the  company  of  Merchants  Adven- 
turers came  into  existence,  and  from  the  first 
it  was  most  closely,  though  not  exclusively, 
associated  with  the  export  of  cloth.  "Wheeler, 
secretary  of  the  company,  says  of  it  {Treatise  oj 
Commerce,  1^01) :  "It  consisteth  of  a  great 
number  of  wealthy  and  well  experimented 
merchants,  dwelling  in  diverse  great  cities, 
maritime  towns,  and  other  parts  of  the  realm, 
to  wit,  London,  York,  Norwich,  Exeter,  Ipswich, 
Newcastle,  Hull,  etc.  These  men,  of  old  time,  • 
linked  and  bound  themselves  together  in 
company  for  the  exercise  of  merchandise  and 
seafare,  trading  in  cloth,  kersie,  and  all  other, 
as  well  English  as  foreign,  commodities  vend- 
ible abroad."  The  origin  of  the  company  is 
obscure,  and  the  date  of  its  incorporation  cannot 
be  determined  with  certainty.  But  privileges 
were  granted  to  it  in  the  14th  century  by  the 
Count  of  Flanders  for  trading  in  his  dominions, 
and  Edward  III.  fixed  Bruges  as  the  place  to 
which  its  commodities  should  be  carried.  In 
1407  Henry  IV.  gave  its  members  the  right  of 
appointing  their  own  governor.  About  the 
middle  of  the  15  th  century  they  came  into 
conflict  with  the  Merchants  of  the  Staple.  The 
latter  alleged  that  the  Merchants  Adventurers 
had  no  right  to  exact  the  regular  contribution  to 
their  society  from  all  persons  exporting  cloth  to 
the  Low  Countries.  The  quarrel  came  to  a  head 
temp.  Henry  VII.,  who  favoured  the  claims  of 
the  Merchants  Adventurers,  because  they  had 
given  him  valuable  help  during  his  diplomatic 
differences  with  Margaret  of  Burgundy  arising 
out  of  the  assistance  she  gave  to  Perkin  War- 
beck.  They  had  prevented  distress  and  dis- 
content among  the  artisans  by  "taking  up  the 
commodities  of  the  kingdom,  though  they  lay 
dead  upon  their  hands  for  want  of  vent"  (Bacon, 
Hist,  of  Henry  VII.)  The  amount  which  the 
company  could  exact  for  membership  was  limited 
by  act  of  parliament,  but  its  right  to  control 


ADVENTURERS,  MERCHANTS 


17 


the  cloth -trade  to  the  Netherlands  was  recog- 
nised. It  received,  in  1501,  a  charter  author- 
ising its  members  to  elect  a  president  and 
twenty-four  assessors,  to  make  their  own  decrees 
for  the  management  of  the  trade,  and  to  punish 
transgressors.  The  Star  Chamber,  in  1505,  de- 
cided that  the  merchants  of  either  of  the  con- 
tending companies  who  wished  to  share  in  the 
trade  of  the  other  must  pay  the  ordinary  contri- 
bution. From  tliis  time  the  extension  of  English 
commerce  was  principally  the  work  of  the  Mer- 
chants Adventurers.  Henry  VH.  had  obtained 
from  the  government  of  the  Netherlands  in  1496 
a  treaty  known  as  the  Intercuhsus  Magnus, 
which  secured  mutual  freedom  of  trade ;  the  mer- 
chants of  both  countries  were  allowed  proper 
houses  for  residence  and  for  the  storing  of  their 
merchandise.  The  English  traders  were  also 
permitted  (1499)  to  sell  their  woollen  cloths  in 
other  towns  of  the  Netherlands  besides  Bruges 
and  Antwerp.  The  further  right  to  sell  by  retail 
was  afterwards  obtained  by  pressure  exercised 
on  the  Archduke  Philip,  when  driven  by  a  storm 
on  the  coast  of  England  in  1506  ;  but  this  con- 
cession was  strongly  protested  against  by  the 
Flemings,  who  called  the  agreement  the  Inter- 
cuRsus  JMalus,  and  it  was  before  long  revoked. 
Antwerp  had  drawn  away  from  Bruges  the 
greater  part  of  the  English  trade  by  offering 
special  advantages,  and  though  the  return  of 
the  Merchants  Adventurers  to  Bruges  had  been 
agitated  from  time  to  time,  it  now  soon  ceased 
to  be  thought  of,  and  Antwerp  became  the 
great  market  for  English  cloth.  About  the 
same  time  (1516),  the  Xing  of  Portugal  removed 
to  Antwerp  the  staple  for  oriental  wares,  and 
the  Portuguese  merchants  thenceforth  purchased 
there  the  English  cloth  which  they  sold  in  the 
eastern  countries  and  in  Brazil. 

The  second  great  struggle  of  the  Merchants 
Adventurers  was  with  the  Hanseatic  traders  in 
England.  In  the  14th  century  the  Hanseatio 
League  {q.v.)  had  been  a  great  power,  but 
towards  the  end  of  the  15th  it  began  to  decline. 
It  had  established  itself  {temp.  Henry  III.) 
strongly  in  England.  Its  merchants  assisted 
the  English  kings  financially  and  were  there- 
fore favoured.  Having  first  settled  in  some 
of  the  towns  on  the  east  coast,  they  finally 
concentrated  themselves  in  the  Steelyard  at 
London,  where  they  had  an  establishment 
imposing  by  its  magnitude  and  strong  defences. 
A  rigorous  discipline  was  maintained  amongst  the 
Easterlings,  as  they  were  called,  the  jealous 
hostility  of  the  city  population  requiring  them 
to  be  perpetually  on  their  guard.  The  Merchants 
Adventurers,  when  they  had  successfully  asserted 
their  claims  against  their  English  rivals,  were 
eager  to  get  into  their  hands  the  whole  export 
trade,  at  least  that  in  woollen  cloth.  They 
were  jealous  of  the  comparative  immunity  from 
customs  enjoyed  by  the  cloths  exported  through 
the  Hanse  traders.  The  treaty  of  Utrecht, 
VOL.  I. 


1474,  had  provided  that  Englishmen  should 
possess  the  same  privileges  in  Hanseatic  towns 
abroad  as  the  Germans  did  in  England.  But 
the  English  merchants  complained  that  this 
reciprocity  was  not  accorded  to  them.  Efforts 
were  made  in  consequence  by  Henry  VII.  to 
obtain  such  compacts  with  Denmark,  and  such 
a  footing  in  Livonia,  as  would  to  some  extent 
make  English  traders  independent  of  the  Hanse. 
But  political  motives  led  the  king  to  recede 
from  the  attitude  thus  taken  up,  and  to  con- 
firm to  the  Hanseatic  traders  the  privileges  they 
enjoyed  in  London.  Henry  VIII.  also,  unwill- 
ing to  provoke  the  enmity  of  the  League,  con- 
tinued to  protect  the  rights  of  the  ' '  ^Merchants 
of  the  Steelyard." 

Meantime  the  Merchants  Adventurers  had 
been  pushing  with  great  energy  their  trade 
with  the  Low  Countries.  "Wolsey,  dissatisfied 
with  the  treatment  of  English  traders  in  the 
Netherlands,  sought  to  remove  the  staple  for 
cloth  to  Calais,  and  Thomas  Cromwell  wished 
to  establish  it  in  England.  But  both  these 
projects  failed.  The  latter  proposal  was  revived 
in  the  reign  of  Elizabeth,  and  was  strongly 
advocated  by  Cecil ;  but  the  Merchants  Adven- 
turers preferred  to  continue  trading  to  Antwerp, 
probably  because  the  new  arrangement  would 
have  necessitated  the  granting  to  foreigners  in 
England  an  equality  with  the  native  traders. 
The  Duke  of  Alva,  when  sent  to  the  Netherlands 
by  Philip  II.,  seized  the  property  of  the  English 
merchants  at  Antwerp,  and  they  in  consequence 
withdrew  in  1578  to  Hamburg,  where  special 
inducements  were  offered  them.  Antwerp, 
as  a  commercial  centre,  was  ruined  by  the 
civil  war ;  many  of  the  Netherland  merchants 
also  removed  to  England,  and  a  great  number 
of  artisans  did  the  same,  thus  introducing 
branches  of  the  cloth  manufacture  which  had 
not  previously  been  practised  there.  Already 
in  1552  the  English  merchants  had  obtained 
from  the  Privy  Council  a  decree  abolishing  the 
privileges  of  the  Steelyard,  and  reducing  the 
Hanse  traders  in  England  to  the  position  of 
other  foreigners.  Their  privileges  were,  how- 
ever, partially  restored  under  Mary,  and  in  the 
early  part  of  Elizabeth's  reign  ;  but,  failing  to 
recover  their  old  position,  they  procured  the 
expulsion  from  Hamburg  of  the  English  mer- 
chants who  had  been  invited  thither.  After 
various  measures  of  retaliation  on  both  sides, 
the  English  were,  in  1597,  expelled  from  all  the 
dominions  of  the  Empire.  Elizabeth  forthwith 
directed  the  civic  authorities  of  London  to  close 
the  Steelyard,  and  ordered  the  German  merchants 
to  leave  England,  thus  bringing  to  an  end  the 
history  of  the  Hanseatic  league  in  this  country. 

After  this  period,  we  find  the  **  foreign 
residence  or  comptoir  "  of  the  Merchants  Adven- 
turers fixed  successively  at  Groningen,  Delft, 
and  Dort.  In  1649  they  are  invited  to  return 
to  Bruges,  but  decline  to  do  so.     They  are  then 


18 


ADVENTURERS,  MERCHANTS— AFRICAN  COMPANIES,  EARLY 


finally  established  at  Hamburg,  and  come  to 
be  commonly  known  as  the  Hamburg  Company. 

The  general  model  of  the  Merchants  Adven- 
turers' Association  was  followed  in  the  regu- 
lated companies  which  are  the  great  feature  of 
English  commerce  from  the  middle  of  the  16th 
century.  1  o  encourage  the  trade  with  Rlissia 
opened  by  Chancellor,  Queen  Mary  incorporated 
the  Muscovy  Company,  and  English  factors 
settled  at  Novgorod  ;  the  charter  of  the  com- 
pany gave  it  the  exclusive  right  of  trading  to 
Russia.  Th  e  Eastland  or  Baltic  Company  was 
incorporated  1579,  the  Tuekey  Company  1581, 
the  Mauritania  Company  1585,  and  the  Guinea 
Company  1588.     (See  Companies,  Staple.) 

Mercantile  companies,  with  special  powers 
entrusted  to  them  by  the  government  for  the 
protection  of  trade,  may,  Adam  Smith  remarks, 
"have  been  useful  for  the  first  introduction  of 
some  branches  of  commerce,  by  making  at  their 
own  expense  an  experiment  which  the  state 
might  not  think  it  prudent  to  make."  And 
the  trade  of  England  was  certainly  in  its  early 
stages  greatly  furthered  by  the  action  of  the 
Merchants  Adventurers.  The  abuse  to  which 
such  corporations  are  liable  is  the  restriction  of 
the  greater  part  of  the  trade  to  the  directors 
of  the  company  and  their  particular  friends, 
and  the  enforcement  of  burdensome  regulations 
with  a  view  to  that  end.  The  Merchants 
Adventurers  were  not  always  free  from  this  evil ; 
but  by  the  interference  of  parliament,  as  we 
have  seen,  the  terms  of  admission  were  reduced, 
and,  Anderson  tells  us,  from  the  middle  of 
the  17th  century  no  complaint  was  made 
against  them.  Smith  admits  that  the  Russia 
and  Eastland  Companies  were  not,  in  his  time, 
oppressive.  The  Turkey  trade,  he  says,  not- 
withstanding recent  legislation  to  open  the 
corresponding  company  fully,  was  still  con- 
sidered by  many  people  as  very  far  from  being 
altogether  free.  He  does  not  believe  the 
Afkican  Company,  though  accused  of  "re- 
straining the  trade,  and  establishing  some  sort 
of  improper  monopoly,"  really  open  to  that 
charge.  But  he  censures  it  on  the  ground 
that  it  did  not  fulfil  its  duty  of  properly  main- 
taining forts  and  garrisons.  And,  where  such 
maintenance  is  necessary  from  the  trade  being 
with  barbarous  or  semi-civilised  communities, 
he  holds  that  regulated  companies  are  less 
likely  to  attend  to  it  than  joint-stock  com- 
panies, first,  because  the  directors  of  the  former 
have  no  interest  in  the  prosperity  of  the 
general  trade  of  their  company,  and  may  even 
be  gainers  by  its  limitation ;  and,  secondly, 
because  they  have  no  adequate  fund  at  their 
disposal,  the  company  possessing  no  common 
stock,  and  being  dependent  for  their  outlay  on 
the  casual  revenue  from  admission  fines  and 
corporation  dues.  While  Smith  appears  scarcely 
to  allow  the  regulated  companies  due  credit  for 
the   part   which   most   competent    authorities 


assign  them  in  the  extension  of  English  com- 
merce, it  is,  doubtless,  true  that,  when  he 
wrote,  the  services  which  such  corporations  were 
fitted  to  render  were  substantially  exhausted, 
and,  as  he  says,  the  highest  eulogy  that  could 
be  bestowed  on  them  was  that  of  being  merely 


[J.  Wheeler,  Treatise  of  Commerce,  1601. — A. 
Anderson,  Historical  and  Chronological  Deduc- 
tion of  the  Origin  of  Commerce,  1764. — G.  Schanz, 
Englische  llandelspolitik  gegen  Ende  des  Mittd- 
alters,  1881. — W.  Cunningham,  Growth  of  English 
Industry  and  Covimerce,  1890. — In  the  present 
article  we  are  much  indebted  to  Foreign  Comm^ce 
of  England  under  the  Tudors  (Stanhope  Essay 
for  1883,  by  John  Bruce  Williamson),  an  excellent 
abstract  of  Schanz,  with  information  from  other 
sources.]  J.  k.  i. 

ADVICE.  Primarily,  an  order  given  by 
one  person  to  another  to  perform  some  act  of 
business,  such  as  the  payment  of  a  bill  of 
exchange,  for  him — ^used  also  in  the  sense  of 
giving  information  on  business  matters  more 
generally. 

AFRICAN  COMPANIES,  Early.  The  cir- 
cumstances of  trade  with  Africa,  or  rather  with 
Africa  excluding  the  Mediterranean  coast,  were 
of  such  a  nature  as  to  favour  particularly  the 
formation  and  maintenance  of  privileged  trading 
companies.  The  trade  was  sufficiently  danger- 
ous to  suggest  the  need  of  special  privileges, 
and  not  sufficiently  profitable  to  permit  of  being 
carried  on  without  them.  England,  however, 
was  not  the  first  country  to  enter  into  trading 
relations  with  the  west  coast  of  Africa.  Por- 
tugal held  that  position,  and  practically  en- 
joyed a  monopoly  till  1536.  In  that  year  we 
hear  of  English  adventurers  and  of  their  success. 
Benin  on  the  Guinea  coast  was  the  attraction  of 
the  traders.  The  venture  was  probably  repeated 
more  than  once  ;  without  leading  immediately 
to  the  formation  of  a  company.  That  result, 
however,  soon  ensued,  and  the  first  charter  was 
granted,  the  precursor  of  many  others. 

(1)  1588  ;  Elizabeth  granted  to  certain  mer- 
chants of  Devonshire,  Exeter,  and  London  a 
charter  giving  exclusive  trading  privileges  for 
ten  years  to  the  rivers  of  Senegal,  Gambia,  and 
the  neighbouring  district.  This  company,  called 
The  Guinea  Company,  was  in  reality  the  fore- 
runner of  the  African  companies,  among  which 
it  may  itself  be  numbered.  They  were  all 
companies  formed  to  trade  with  the  west  coast. 
Under  the  auspices  of  this  company  several 
voyages  were  made,  the  chief  goods  brought 
back  being  pepper,  ivory,  palm  oil,  cotton  cloth. 
It  seems  to  have  been  very  unsuccessful,  owing 
in  part  to  the  action  of  "interlopers  "  or  inde- 
pendent traders. 

(2)  1618  ;  a  new  exclusive  charter  to  Sir 
Robert  Rich  and  other  Londoners.  It  too  was 
unsuccessful,  first  through  the  action  of  private 
traders  and  secondly  owing  to  the  very  small 
profit  gained  by  those  engaged  in  this  trade 


AFRICAN  COMPANIES,  EARLY— AFRICAN  COMPANIES,  RECENT       19 


before  the  development  of  the  slave  trade 
between  the  west  coast  and  the  English  planta- 
tions in  America. 

(3)  1631  ;  a  new  company  was  formed,  the 
charter  gi-anted  to  Sir  Richard  Young,  Sir 
Kenelm  Digby,  and  others  for  thirty-one  years, 
the  limits  assigned  extending  from  Cape  Blanco 
to  the  Cape  of  Good  Hope.  Similar  causes  to 
those  before  enumerated  appear  to  have  led  to 
its  dissolution. 

(4)  1662  ;  a  fourth  company  formed  this  time 
with  the  definite  object  of  conveying  3000  slaves 
a  year  to  the  American  settlements.  Its 
development  was  interfered  with  by  wars  with 
the  Dutch,  and  it  gave  way  to — 

(5)  1672  ;  i)xQ  Royal  African  Company,  which 
really  bought  out  the  rights  of  the  proprietors 
of  the  foregoing.  These,  like  other  trading 
companies  of  the  time,  were  based  on  grants  of 
exclusive  privileges  to  certain  persons  made  by 
royal  charter.  As  such  they  were  doomed  by 
the  act  passed  after  the  Revolution  of  1688, 
whereby  all  exclusive  privileges  except  those 
authorised  or  granted  by  parliament  were  with- 
drawn. The  African  trade  was  thus  thrown 
open  though  it  must  be  remembered  that  the 
company  was  not  destroyed.  Its  exclusive 
rights  were  taken  away  ;  but  (1698)  some  part 
of  these  rights  were  restored  by  statute  (9  &  10 
Will.  III.)  in  regard  of  the  settlements  and  forts 
which  had  to  be  supported.  Traders  other  than 
those  belonging  to  the  company  were  burdened 
with  differential  duties.  From  this  time  onwards 
disputes  continually  arose  as  to  the  expediency  of 
restriction.  But  despite  the  attention  devoted 
to  the  trade,  it  continued  to  be  most  unprofit- 
able. At  one  time  its  stock  dropped  to  4^, 
and  though  it  rose  above  this  low  figure  it 
seems  never  to  have  approached  par  except  at 
the  time  of  the  South  Sea  Bubrle.  In  conse- 
quence of  the  low  credit  it  stood  in,  and  of  the 
increased  liabilities  incurred  by  the  company,  it 
was  resolved  to  transfer  its  property  to  a  new 
company  composed  of  the  proprietors  of  the  old 
company  and  its  creditors,  and — 

(6)  1750  ;  a  new  African  company  was  estab- 
lished. It  was  of  course  without  exclusive 
rights.  In  1752  the  property  of  the  former 
company  was  finally  transferred  to  its  hands. 

[Anderson,  History  of  Commerce. — Macpherson, 
Annals  of  Comvierce. — Rymer,  Foedera. — Lans- 
down  MSS.  in  Brit.  Mus.]  e.  c.  k.  g. 

(7)  1791 ;  the  Sierra  LeoTie  Company  may  be 
classed  with  the  early  African  companies  in  the 
sense  that  the  acts  of  parliament  establishing 
and  determining  it  both  precede  the  act  de- 
termining the  old  African  companies. 

The  Sierra  Leone  Company  originated  in  the 
philanthropic  schemes  of  certain  gentlemen  who 
(1787)  formed  themselves  into  a  committee  and 
raised  a  fund  for  assisting  destitute  blacks, 
most  of  whom  had  been  the  victims  of  the 
slave  trade,   to  settle  in   Sierra  Leone.     The 


project  very  quickly  took  the  form  of  a  regular 
company,  and  in  1791  an  act  was  passed 
incorporating  the  Sierra  Leone  Company.  In 
1800  letters  patent  were  issued  definitely 
granting  the  peninsula  of  Sierra  Leone,  so  far 
as  was  in  the  power  of  the  crown,  to  the 
company.  But  the  French  war  very  adversely 
aff"ected  the  fortunes  of  the  company,  and  heavy 
subsidies  were  granted  from  imperial  funds  to 
sustain  it,  so  that  in  1807  an  act  was  passed 
providing  for  the  extinction  in  seven  years' 
time  of  the  Sierra  Leone  Company  and  its 
rights  over  the  colony.  In  1809  a  charter 
was  granted  to  the  company  providing  for  the 
"  Colony  of  Sierra  Leone,"  and  after  the  powers 
given  to  the  company  had  expired,  this  charter 
was  (in  1821)  regranted  direct  to  the  colonists, 
who  were  then  placed  directly  under  the  crown 
of  Great  Britain.  c.  a.  h. 

AFRICAN  COMPANIES,  Recent.  It  would 
appear  from  a  review  of  historical  facts  that 
in  periods  when  a  number  of  difi"erent  civilised 
nations  have  been  actively  competing  for  the 
possession  or  settlement  of  an  unallotted  region, 
the  favourite  method  of  occupation  has  been  the 
quasi-national  company.  The  recent  allotment  of 
a  great  portion  of  the  African  continent  amongst 
chartered  companies  is  on  a  par  with  the  early 
settlementof  North  America  and  the  "West  Indies. 

Putting  aside  the  Congo  Free  State,  which 
in  some  respects  is  analogous  to  a  chartered 
company,  we  have  in  order  of  time  the  Eoyal 
Niger  Company  (chartered  as  the  National 
African  Company  in  1886)  dominating  the 
basin  of  the  river  Niger  on  the  west,  the  Im- 
perial British  East  African  Company  (1888) 
on  the  Somali  coast  to  the  east,  and  the  British 
South  African  Company  (1889)  between  the 
Zambesi  and  the  British  colonies  to  the  south. 
All  these  are  British  companies,  and  all  hold 
a  royal  charter.  A  German  South- West  African 
Company  has  been  at  work  for  some  years 
with  indilierent  success,  and  does  not  seem  to 
enjoy  any  privileged  position.  The  German 
East  African  Company,  which  is  chartered,  was 
formed  in  1888  by  a  coalition  of  the  private 
Commandite  Company  and  Karl  Peters  and 
Co.,  to  compete  with  the  British  company  in 
the  Somali  and  Zanzibar  districts. 

An  amalgamation  of  powerful  houses  in 
West  Africa  is  at  this  time  moving  to  obtain 
a  charter  as  the  Oil  Rivers  Company.  The 
African  Lakes  Company  is  unchartered  and  is 
likely  to  become  merged  with  the  British  South 
African  Company.  The  Congo  Company  is  an 
ordinary  one,  with  its  seat  of  operations  in  the 
Congo  Free  State.  The  **  United  African 
Company"  of  1879  was  the  parent  of  the 
^^ National  African  Company,"  now  the  Royal 
Niger  Company  ;  it  successfully  competed  with 
'and  eventually  absorbed  two  French  companies 
which  received  considerable  support  from  their 
government. 


20 


AFRICAN  COMPANIES,  RECENT— AGAZZINI 


The  new  Britisli  companies  differ  from  the  last 
of  the  old  ones — the  Sierra  Leone  Company 
(see  African  Companies,  early) — in  being 
avowedly  commercial.  As  explained  in  the 
article  on  Colonies,  Government  by  Companies 
{c[.v.) — they  are  similar  in  conception  ^  and 
aim  to  the  old  Royal  African  and  Guinea 
Companies.  Governments,  however  strong, 
have  usually  shrunk  from  the  responsibility  of 
administering  a  large  unknown  tract  of  terri- 
tory, but  have  been  willing  to  encourage  the 
hazards  aad  adopt  the  successes  of  a  company. 
In  the  first  blush  of  African  development 
Bechuanaland  was  annexed  as  a  protectorate 
under  the  immediate  care  of  the  British  crown, 
but  this  policy  was  too  severely  criticised  by 
the  timid  to  encourage  its  repetition  in  dealing 
with  African  territories.  When  the  movement 
went  on  and  in  various  parts  of  Africa  a  number 
of  ordinary  commercial  companies  had  secured 
valuable  concessions  or  established  the  nucleus 
of  a  trade,  their  present  security  and  the  future 
establishment  of  a  colonial  dependency  was 
assured  by  their  consolidation  into  large  asso- 
ciations under  boards  of  directors  of  recognised 
substance,  with  wide  powers  over  considerable 
extents  of  territory,  and  enjoying  the  prestige 
of  a  royal  charter. 

The  charters  of  the  existing  companies  are 
all  very  similar.  That  of  the  South  African 
Company  has  a  special  colouring,  in  that  two  or 
three  of  its  provisions  (Glauses  10,  17,  18) 
appear  to  contemplate  the  future  transfer  of  its 
powers  to  a  crown  colony ;  for  instance  it 
may  make  "  ordinances  "  subject  to  confirmation 
by  the  secretary  of  state.  All  through  the 
charters  modern  caution  and  modern  philan- 
thropy are  conspicuous.  The  control  of  the 
orown  through  one  of  the  secretaries  of  state 
is  secured  at  every  point,  especially  as  regards 
any  foreign  relations.  In  the  case  of  the  Royal 
Niger  and  Imperial  British  East  African  Com- 
panies this  control  is  exercised  through  the 
foreign  office  ;  in  the  case  of  the  British  South 
African  Company  through  the  colonial  office. 
The  difference  of  the  controlling  department 
was  determined  solely  by  the  fact  that  in  the 
case  of  the  first  two  companies  their  immediate 
contact  was  with  foreign  states,  in  that  of  the 
British  South  African  Company  it  was  with 
British  colonies  and  protectorates.  The  stipu- 
lations in  respect  of  the  slave  trade  and  liquor 
traffic  with  the  natives  are  the  offspring  of  a 
humanitarian  age.  Subject  to  these  limitations 
the  companies  have  wide  powers,  not  only  of 
carrying  on  commerce  and  industries  on  their 
own  account,  but  of  granting  concessions  and 
powers  to  individuals  for  every  sort  of  under- 
taking. They  have  all  the  attributes  of  large 
joint-stock  companies  with  some  of  those  of 
independent  states.  But  they  cannot  enjoy  or 
create  any  monopoly  of  trade. 

The  Imperial  British  East  African  Company 


has  at  present  (1892)  less  individuality  than  the 
others  ;  part  of  its  sphere  is  within  the  territory 
of  the  sultan  of  Zanzibar  and  there  it  is  bound 
to  use  the  sultan's  flag  and  conform  to  the 
sultan's  trade  restrictions.  Herein  the  diff"erent 
genius  of  the  British  and  German  companies  (see 
Colonies,  Government  by  Companies)  was  well 
illustrated.  Both  had  their  sphere  of  operations 
in  the  territory  of  the  sultan  ;  the  British 
company,  as  just  mentioned,  was  carefully  kept 
by.  the  British  government  subservient  to  their 
ally  ;  the  German  company  everywhere  hoisted 
the  German  flag  and  displayed  its  nationality  ; 
it  was,  in  fact,  the  German  government  working 
through  the  company  for  paramount  influence. 

The  sphere  of  influence  dominated  by  Germany 
through  its  East  African  Company  lies  between 
those  of  the  Imperial  British  East  African 
Company  and  the  British  South  African  Com- 
pany, stretching  from  the  east  coast  inland  to 
Lake  Tanganyika  and  the  Congo  Free  State. 
It  thus  covers  some  of  the  richest  country  in 
the  Continent,  the  objectof  considerable  jealousy 
to  English  traders. 

The  commercial  success  of  the  Royal  Niger 
Company  has,  on  the  whole,  been  considerable  ; 
that  of  the  South  African  Company  is  described 
in  its  AnnuM  Reports. 

[The  charters  of  the  three  companies  are  to  be 
found  in  the  London  Gazette  of  13th  July  1886 
(Niger),— 7th  Sept.  1888  (East  African),— 20th 
Dec.  1889  (South  African), — and  an  account  of  the 
first  and  last  in  the  Colonial  Office  List  for  1890. 
The  Royal  Niger  Company  and  British  South 
African  Companyhsiwe  printed  interesting  accounts 
of  their  development  for  private  circulation.  For 
history  since  1892  see  Annual  Reports  of  the  British 
South  African  Company, — of  the  Administrator  of 
East  Africa, — and  on  Northern  and  Southern 
Nigeria  ;  also  Precis  of  Information  concerning 
the  British  East  Africa  Protectorate.']     c.  a.  H. 

AGAZZINI,  MiCHELE  (an  Italian  economist 
of  the  commencement  of  the  19th  century), 
published  a  system  of  political  economy  not 
destitute  of  original  ideas,  or,  at  least,  of  an 
original  manner  of  presenting  old  ones.  He 
had  a  clear  idea  of  what  was  later  called  by 
Senior  and  Carey  the  cost  of  reproduction,  and 
makes  it  the  centre  of  his  theory  of  value. 
Every  producer,  according  to  Agazzini,  obtains 
for  his  produce  a  price  determined  by  the  cost 
(in  labour  and  abstinence)  which  the  consumer 
saves ;  this  same  law  holds  good  for  the  price 
of  commodities,  of  labour,  and  of  capital.  The 
law  of  supply  and  demand  (he  says)  regulates 
current  prices,  and  the  cost  of  reproduction 
normal  value.  All  this  is,  however,  explained 
in  a  language  totally  lacking  technical  pre- 
cision. His  most  important  work  was  first 
written  and  published  by  him  in  French  under 
the  title : 

La  science  de  Viconomie  politique,  ou  principes 
de  la  formation,  du  progris  et  de  la  decadence  de 
la  richesse,  et  a2)plication  de  ces  principes  d  Vad- 


AGENCY,  LAW  OF— AGENTS  OF  PRODUCTION 


21 


f 


ministration,  1822.  Paris  et  Londres,  Bossange 
pere.  It  was  published  at  Venice  in  Italian  in 
1827.  Later,  in  1834,  Agazzini  published  a  criti- 
cal essay  on  Smith,  Say,  and  Malthus,  in  which 
only  the  history  of  the  doctrines  concerning  value 
are  noteworthy.  He  is  particularly  successful  in 
the  correct  exposition  of  the  doctrines  of  the 
mediseval  canonists.  Sconvenevolezza  delle  teoriche 
del  valore  insegnate  da  Smith,  dai  professori 
Malthus  e  Say  e  dagli  scrittori  piU  celebri  di  pvh- 
blica  economia,  Milano,  Fontana,  1834.        M.  p. 

AGENCY,  Law  of.  An  agent  is  a  person 
authorised  by  another  (called  the  principal)  to 
act  on  his  behalf.  An  agent  authorised  to  act 
for  a  special  purpose  only  is  called  a  particular 
agent ;  if  there  is  a  general  authority  to  act 
within  a  given  sphere,  the  agent  is  called  a 
general  agent.  A  partnership  is  an  instance  of 
general  agency  in  the  widest  sense,  each  partner 
being,  as  a  rule,  considered  the  agent  of  his  co- 
partners for  all  purposes  coming  within  the 
scope  of  the  partnership  business.  An  agent 
may  not,  according  to  Englisli  law,  derive  any 
concealed  profit  from  his  agency,  and  he  may 
not,  as  a  general  rule,  delegate  his  authority  to 
another  person.  An  agent  may  in  his  dealings 
with  third  parties  act  as  principal,  or  he  may 
state  the  fact  of  the  agency  without  disclosing 
the  name  of  the  principal,  or  he  may  deal  on 
behalf  of  a  named  principal.  The  rules  of  law 
concerning  the  liabilities  and  mutual  relations 
of  the  various  parties  in  all  these  cases  are  too 
complicated  to  be  stated  here,  and  the  general 
rules  are  often  modified  by  the  customs  of 
particular  localities  or  particular  trades.  The 
authority  of  an  agent  acting  on  belialf  of  a 
corporate  body  cannot  extend  beyond  the  limits 
imposed  upon  the  sphere  of  action  of  the  cor- 
poration either  by  Act  of  Parliament,  or  by  the 
charter  of  incorporation  or  by  the  memorandum 
of  association  (see  Ultra  Vires).  e.  s. 

AGENTS  OF  PRODUCTION.  The  causes 
or  requisites  of  production,  often  called  "  agents 
of  production,"  may  be  divided  into  two 
classes :  human  action  and  external  nature ; 
commonly  distinguished  as  "labour,"  and 
**  natural  agents."  The  first  category  comprises 
mental  as  well  as  muscular  exertion ;  the  second, 
force  as  well  as  matter.  To  the  second  factor  is 
sometimes  applied  the  term  land  :  in  a  technical 
sense,  denoting  not  only  the  "brute  earth," 
but  also  all  other  physical  elements  with  their 
properties.  But  this  term  is  more  frequently 
employed  in  another  classification,  according  to 
which  the  agents  of  production  are  divided  into 
three  classes — land,  labour,  and  capital.  Of 
the  two  classifications  which  have  been  stated 
the  former  appears  the  more  fundamental  and 
philosophical.  That  "all  production  is  the 
result  of  two  and  only  two  elementary  agents 
of  production,  nature  and  labour,"  is  particularly 
well  argued  by  Bohm-Bawerk  in  his  Kapital 
und  Kapitalzins,  pt.  ii.  p.  83.  "There  is  no 
room  for  a  third  elementery  aource,"  he  main- 


tains. This  view  is  countenanced  by  high 
authorities,  of  whom  some  are  cited  below. 
Even  J.  S.  MiLL,whois  disposed  to  make  capital 
nearly  as  important  as  the  other  members  of 
the  tripartite  division,  yet  admits  that '  *  labour 
and  natural  agents"  are  "the  primary  and 
universal  requisites  of  production  "  {Pol.  Econ., 
bk.  i.  ch.  iv.  §  1).  Prof.  Marshall,  dividing  the 
subject  more  closely,  thinks  "it  is  perhaps  best 
to  say  that  there  are  three  factors  of  production, 
land,  labour,  and  the  sacrifice  involved  in 
waiting  "  {Principles  of  Economics,  p.  614,  note). 
For  fui'ther  remarks  on  the  third  species  of 
agent  see  Capital. 

In  the  case  where  both  labour  and  natural 
agents  are  required,  the  most  frequent  and 
important  case,  the  question  may  be  raised 
whether  nature  or  man  contributes  more  to  the 
result.  According  to  Quesnay  {Maximes, 
Edn.  Oncken,  p.  331)  land  is  the  sole  source  of 
riches.  According  to  Adam  Smi'J'H,  in  manu- 
factures "nature  does  nothing,  man  does  all" 
{Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  ii.  ch.  v.)  The  better 
view  appears  to  be  that  the  division  of  industries 
into  those  in  which  labour  does  most  and 
those  in  which  nature  does  most  is  not  signi- 
ficant. It  is  like  attempting  "  to  decide  which 
half  of  a  pair  of  scissors  has  most  to  do  in  the 
act  of  cutting"  (Mill,  Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  i.  ch.  i. 
§3). 

Agents  of  production  may  be  subdivided  into 
those  which  are  limited,  and  those  which 
are  practically  unlimited.  This  distinction 
applies  principally  to  natural  agents.  For 
labour  may  in  general  be  regarded  as  an 
article  of  which  the  supply  is  limited.  The 
ownership  or  use  of  those  agents  of  production 
which  are  limited  and  capable  of  being  appro- 
priated acquires  a  value  in  exchange.  Hence 
rent  of  land  and  wages  of  labour  take  their 
origin. 

To  account  for  the  difierence  in  the  rents 
paid  for  different  lands,  it  has  been  usual,  after 
RiCARDO,  to  arrange  the  lands  in  a  sort  of  scale 
of  fertility :  No.  1,  No.  2,  and  so  on.  Upon 
this  classification  it  is  to  be  remarked  that 
productivity,  the  real  basis  of  the  differences  in 
question,  does  not  vary  according  to  any  one 
attribute,  such  as  the  indestructible  powers  of 
the  soil,  or  proximity  to  the  centres  of  industry  ; 
but  upon  a  number  of  attributes  (compare  B. 
'Pbiue.,  Practical  Pol.  Econ.,  chapter  on  "Rent"). 
Moreover  a  scale  in  which  lands,  or  other 
natural  agents,  were  arranged  according  to  their 
productive  power,  would  hold  good  only  so 
long  as  the  other  factor  of  production,  human 
action,  might  remain  constant.  A  light  sandy 
soil  may  be  more  productive  than  a  heavy  clay, 
so  long  as  the  doses  of  labour  ap^jlied  to  each 
are  small.  But  the  order  of  fertility  may  be 
reversed  when  the  cultivation  is  higher.  As 
Prof.  Sidgwick  remarks  "  these  material  advan- 
tages" [afforded  by  natural  agents]  "donotremain 


AGIO— AGRICULTUKAL  COMMUNITY 


the  same  in  all  stages  of  industrial  development : 
but  vary  with  the  varying  amounts  of  labour 
applied,  and  the  varying  eflaciency  of  instru- 
ments and  processes  "  {Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  i.  eh.  iv. 
§  3).  Compare  Prof.  Marshall,  Principles  of 
Economics,  bk.  iv.  eh.  iii.  §  4. 

A  similar  difficulty  attends  the  attempt  to 
arrange  the  other  agent  of  production,  human 
labour,  in  a  scale  of  excellence  ;  whereby  to 
determine  what  has  been  called  Rent  of  Ability 
{q.v.).  Prof.  Macvane  has  noticed  this  difficulty 
in  an  article  on  "Business  Profits"  in  the 
Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics  (Harvard)  for 
Oct.  1887.  Prof.  Walker,  in  a  reply  to  Prof. 
Macvane  in  the  same  journal,  April  1888, 
admits  and  very  happily  illustrates  the  difficulty 
(p.  227). 

[On  this  subject  as  many  references  might  be 
given  as  there  are  treatises  on  political  economy. 
The  twofold  classification  above  indicated  is 
illustrated  by  the  following  : — Hobbes,  Leviathan, 
beginning  of  ch.  xxiv.  ("The  plenty  of  matter" 
consists  of  "those  commodities  which  from  the 
two  breasts  of  our  common  mother,  land  and  sea, 
God  usually  either  freely  giveth,  or  for  labour 
selleth  to  mankind  "). — Petty,  Treatises  on  Taxes 
(3d  ed.  1685),  ch.  viii.  p.  57  (labour  the  father, 
land  the  mother,  of  wealth). — Berkeley,  Querist, 
Query  4.  ("  Whether  the  four  elements  and  man's 
labour  therein  be  not  the  true  source  of  wealth.") 
— Cantillon,  Essay,  pt.  i.  ch.  i.  (land  the  matter 
and  labour  the  form  of  riches). — Courcelle-Seneuil 
Traiti  theoriqtie,  bk.  i.  ch.  iii. — Hearn,  Plutology, 
ch.  ii.]  F.  y.e. 

AGIO.  An  Italian  word,  the  original  mean- 
ing of  which  is  "ease,  convenience."  It  was 
introduced  into  general  mercantile  language  to 
express  the  additional  sum  payable  by  a  person 
who  wished  to  exchange  one  kind  of  money 
against  another  kind,  the  kind  taken  in  ex- 
change being  in  greater  demand  than  the  kind 
given  in  exchange ;  the  person  effecting  the 
exchange  paid  the  premium  for  his  convenience. 
The  expression  when  now  used  is  employed  in 
countries  where  a  premium  is  payable  on  me- 
tallic money,  and  where  paper  money  with  a 
forced  currency  is  the  regular  medium  of  ex- 
change. E.  s. 

AGIOTAGE,  OR  AGIO,  was  a  term  first  used 
in  Venetian  finance  to  denote  the  difference  in 
exchange  between  depreciated  currency  and 
metal  of  full  value.  Such  depreciated  currency 
formerly  consisted  mainly  of  debased  or  worn 
coins,  but  more  recently  paper  money,  whether 
bank  notes  or  government  notes,  have  afforded 
illustrations  under  this  head.  The  banks  estab- 
lished at  Venice,  Hamburg,  Genoa,  Amsterdam 
and  elsewhere,  were  bound  by  law  to  receive 
deposits  and  make  payments  according  to  cer- 
tain standards,  and  the  premiums  charged  upon 
such  money  as  compared  with  the  general  cir- 
culation represented  the  agio  payable  to  the 
banks  in  question.  These  banks  were  used 
in  making    international    payments    for    the 


reason  that  their  standard  was  a  fixed,  not 
a  varying  quantity,  and  served  greatly  to  in- 
troduce the  system  of  economising  coinage  by 
exchanging  bills  and  promises  to  pay  instead  of 
actual  metal.     See  Banks,  early  European. 

AGNATI  (Adgnati).  The  members  of  a 
Roman  family  having  a  common  legitimate  male 
ancestor  in  the  male  line,  either  natiu-ally  or 
by  fiction  of  law  (adoption  or  marriage  with  in 
manum  conventio).  Cognati,  on  the  other  hand, 
are  relatives  in  the  modern  sense.  e.  s. 

AGRICULTURAL  COMMUNITY.  In  giving 
an  account  of  agricultural  communities  it  seems 
best  to  follow  the  plan  adopted  by  Mr.  Seehohm 
in  his  standard  work  on  the  English  Villagp. 
Community,  and  to  proceed  from  known  and 
undisputed  facts,  open  to  present  observation, 
back  through  historical  evidence  which  step 
by  step  decreases  in  authority  and  increases  in 
difficulty  of  interpretation  until  we  anive  at 
the  tribal  organisations,  clans,  and  kindred 
settlements  of  prehistoric  times ;  that  is  to 
say,  the  comparative  method  may  be  first 
applied  to  existing  communities,  and  to  the 
traces  and  survivals  of  the  past,  and  then  an 
explanation  may  be  attempted  by  the  historical 
method. 

Communities  in  which  land  is  practically 
owned  and  cultivated  in  a  collective  manner, 
according  to  customary  rules  of  great  antiquity, 
and  in  which  the  rights  and  powers  of  any 
individual  are  strictly  limited,  still  exist  over 
large  areas  and  among  vast  populations.  In 
Central  Asia  the  tribes  of  pastoral  nomads  are 
made  up  of  groups,  each  under  the  authority 
of  the  head  of  a  family,  and  nothing  is  the 
subject  of  separate  ownership  except  clothes 
and  weapons  (Le  Play,  Ouvriers  Europeens). 
When  a  group  becomes  too  large  a  division  is 
made  by  the  head  in  a  manner  suggestive  of 
the  division  made  between  Abraham  and  Lot. 

More  interest,  however,  attaches  to  the  com- 
munities which  have  a  settled  system  of  agri- 
culture in  a  fixed  area.  The  most  important 
at  present  is  the  Russian  Mir,  which  may  be 
described  as  ''the  aggregation  of  inhabitants 
of  a  village  possessing  in  common  the  land 
attached  to  it. "  Each  male  inhabitant  of  full 
age  is  entitled  to  an  equal  share  of  the  land. 
The  period  of  distribution  at  present  varies  in 
different  districts,  nine  years  being  the  average, 
and  the  limits  from  three  to  fifteen.  The 
arrangements  for  the  partition  are  decided  by 
the  peasants  under  the  presidency  of  the 
stavosta  (headman  or  mayor).  All  the  arable 
land  is  divided  into  three  concentric  zones 
which  extend  round  the  village,  and  these 
zones  are  again  divided  into  three  fields  to 
admit  of  the  three-field  system  of  cultivation. 
These  fields  again  are  divided  into  long  narrow 
strips,  in  length  from  one  to  four  furlongs,  and 
in  breadth  from  one  to  two  rods.  The  division 
of  the  parcels  is  arranged  so  that  every  man  hofc 


AGRICULTURAL  COMMUNITY 


23 


at  least  one  parcel  in  each  of  the  great  fields. 
The  bundle  of  parcels  is  arranged  before  the 
lots  are  drawn.  As  a  rule  there  is  not  much 
difference  in  the  fertility  of  the  land,  but  in 
some  cases  the  measuring  rods  are  of  different 
lengths  according  to  the  fertility.  Formerly  a 
certain  amount  of  forest,  pasture,  and  meadow 
was  attached  to  each  village,  the  inhabitants 
paying  a  kind  of  labour  rent,  but  by  the  Act 
of  Emancipation  of  1861  this  part  of  the  land 
was  made  over  to  the  lord.  The  cultivation  is 
carried  on  in  a  strictly  routine  manner,  the 
time  of  sowing,  reaping,  etc.,  being  fixed  by 
the  village  assembly,  and  there  being  no 
division  between  the  parcels  of  land,  and  no 
separate  approach.  The  dwelling-house,  izha, 
with  its  enclosed  garden  ground,  is,  however, 
private  property,  although  even  in  this  case 
the  owner  cannot  sell  it  to  a  stranger  without 
the  consent  of  the  mir^  which  has  always  the 
right  of  pre-emption.  Before  the  abolition  of 
serfdom  the  lord  of  the  manor  (to  give  the 
nearest  English  equivalent)  granted  about  half 
the  arable  land  to  the  Serfs,  and  cultivated  the 
remainder  with  their  forced  labour  of  about 
three  days  a  week.  On  the  emancipation  a 
rent  (redeemable — the  money  being  in  many 
cases  advanced  by  government)  was  fixed,  and 
a  minimum  amount  of  land  assigned  to  each 
serf.  Power  was  given  to  the  mirs  by  a  two- 
thirds  majority  to  abandon  the  system  of  collec- 
tivism in  favour  of  individual  ownership,  but  on 
the  whole  the  mir  has  been  rather  strengthened, 
and  is  taken  by  the  government  as  the  basis  of 
taxation.  From  the  economic  standpoint  the 
most  striking  objections  to  the  mir,  which  also 
seem  to  render  its  long  continuance  imder 
modern  conditions  doubtful,  are  (1)  the  natural 
growth  of  population  under  the  system  of  equal 
division.  Hitherto  this  increase  has  been  slow, 
owing  partly  to  the  large  mortality  of  the 
children,  and  partly  to  the  women  being  much 
older  than  their  husbands,  and  to  the  preval- 
ence of  immorality.  But  the  infant  mortality 
might  readily  be  lessened,  and  the  system  of 
unequal  marriages,  which  rests  on  the  conveni- 
ence of  the  head  of  the  family  in  obtaining 
women-servants  by  the  marriage  of  his  boys, 
seems  to  be  falling  into  disfavour.  (2)  The 
second  objection  lies  in  the  constraint  placed 
upon  individual  enterprise  by  the  compulsory 
cultivation  according  to  fixed  methods,  in  the 
impossibility  of  highly  extensive  cultivation 
with  the  periodic  divisions  of  the  land,  and  the 
absence  of  enclosures,  and  in  causes  similar  to 
those  which  in  England  in  the  15  th  century 
secured  the  victory  of  several  (enclosed,  indivi- 
dual) over  champion  (non-enclosed,  common) 
cultivation  (compare  E.  deLAVELEYE,  Primitive 
Property,  ch.  iii.  "Economic  Results  of  the 
Russian  Mir  "). 

Next  to  Russia,  India  is  the  most  important 
example  of  the  present  existence  of  village  com- 


munities, although  in  the  manner  described  by 
Sir  H.  Maine  {Village  Communities,  Lect.  IV.) 
their  primitive  simplicity  and  essential  features 
were  sacrificed  for  a  time  at  least  to  alien 
English  and  Mohammedan  law,  the  Zemindar 
or  official  collector  of  customary  taxes  having 
been  converted  into  a  kind  of  manorial  pro- 
prietor. In  recent  years,  however,  the  tendency 
has  been  to  protect  these  communities,  and  over 
large  districts  to  regard  them  as  the  agricul- 
tural and  fiscal  unit.  The  general  features — 
allowance  being  made  for  differences  in  climate — 
are  not  unlike  those  of  the  Russian  mir  and  the 
early  Teutonic  settlements  described  below. 
There  is  the  division  into  strips,  and  the  cul- 
tivation according  to  minute  customary  rules  of 
the  arable  portion,  and  there  is  a  certain  por- 
tion of  waste  enjoyed  as  pasture  by  the  different 
members.  The  village  consists  of  households, 
each  under  a  despotic  head,  the  family  life 
being  characterised  by  extraordinary  secrecy 
and  isolation.  In  many  communities  the 
customs  are  declared  and  interi)reted  not  by 
a  council  of  elders  but  by  the  headman  alone, 
his  office  being  sometimes  hereditary  and  some- 
times nominally  elective.  The  various  trades 
or  crafts  necessary  to  a  self-supjiorting  village 
are  also  often  hereditary,  e.g.  the  blacksmith, 
the  harness  maker,  etc. 

In  Java  a  system  prevails  closely  analogous 
to  that  of  India.  The  village  is  jointly  re- 
sponsible for  the  payment  of  taxes,  and  there  is 
common  use  of  the  waste.  The  rice  fields  are 
periodically  divided  amongst  the  village  families 
and  the  houses  and  gardens  are  private  property. 
Irrigation  is  conducted  according  to  communal 
rules  and  plans  (cp.  De  Laveleye,  Primitive  Pro- 
perty, ch.  iv.)  The  Allmends  of  Switzerland 
furnish  another  example  of  common  cultivation. 
These  are  lands  belonging  to  the  communes,  the 
right  of  use,  however,  being  hereditary  in  certain 
families  only,  and  most  residents  even  of  long 
standing  and  although  having  political  rights, 
are  excluded.  The  Allmend  furnishes  wood 
for  fire  and  building,  pasture  for  cattle  on  the 
alp,  and  a  certain  portion  bf  arable  land.  In 
some  cases  there  is  still  periodical  division  of 
the  land,  in  others  the  land  is  let  and  the  pro- 
ceeds devoted  to  the  expenses  of  the  commune. 

In  Scotland,  in  the  crofting  parishes,  we  find 
as  a  rule  that  the  tenants  have  a  certain  amount 
of  hill  ground  on  which  they  have  the  right  to 
pasture  so  many  sheep  or  cattle,  the  number 
varying  in  difi'erent  cases  according  to  the 
holding.  As  soon  as  the  crops  are  gathered  the 
ground  is  thrown  open  in  the  same  way.  There 
are,  however,  no  periodical  divisions,  and  the 
village  had  no  rights  not  derived  from  the  feudal 
proprietor  until  the  recent  legislation  giving 
effect  to  presumed  custom  established  fixity 
of  tenure  at  a  "  fair  rent,"  and  made  provisions 
for  consolidating  holdings. 

In  England  there  still  survive  a  number  of 


24 


AGRICULTUEAL  COMMUNITY 


Commons  and  Lammas-Lands  in  which  certain 
members  of  a  village  have  definite  rights,  and 
there  are  abundant  traces  of  the  old  agricultural 
communities.  In  most  of  the  countries  of 
Europe  where  private  property  has  become  the 
rule  there  are  also  survivals  which  point  to  the 
wide  prevalence  of  customary  cultivation  in 
common.  On  the  historical  development  and 
gi-adual  decay  of  the  village  community,  the 
reader  should  consult  Mr.  Seebohm's  remark- 
able work,  which,  on  its  broad  outlines  has 
been  mainly  followed  in  the  rest  of  this  article. 
Although  nominally  this  work  is  confined  to 
England,  the  search  for  a  rational  explanation 
led  the  writer  to  make  a  wide  survey  of  many 
other  countries  at  different  times.  Before  Mr. 
Seebohm's  work  appeared  many  writers  had  called 
attention  to  the  wide  prevalence  of  common 
cultivation  in  England  in  recent  times.  A 
passage  is  quoted  by  Sir  Henry  Maine  (  Village 
Communities,  p.  90)  from  Marshall's  Treatise 
on  Landed  Property  (1804),  in  which  the  writer 
from  personal  observation  of  "provincial  prac- 
tice" attempts  to  construct  a  picture  of  the 
ancient  agricultural  state  of  England.  He 
notices  the  division  of  the  arable  land  into  three 
great  unenclosed  fields  adapted  for  the  regular 
triennial  succession  of  fallow,  wheat  (or  rye),  and 
spring  crops  (oats,  beans,  peas,  etc.)  He  de- 
scribes also  the  division  of  these  fields  into  strips 
and  the  mode  in  which  the  meadows  and  the 
waste  were  used.  He  gives  also  statistics  on 
the  extent  to  which  in  his  day  these  open  and 
common  fields  existed,  which  have  been  sum- 
marised by  E.  Nasse,  The  Common  Field  System 
for  England  in  the  Middle  Ages.  Mr.  Seebohm 
points  out  (p.  14)  that  taking  the  whole 
of  England  with  roughly  speaking  its  10,000 
parishes,  nearly  4000  Enclosure  Acts  were 
passed  between  1760  and  1844,  the  object  of 
these  acts  being  expressly  to  get  rid  of  the  old 
common  unenclosed  fields.  But  in  spite  of  the 
Enclosure  Acts  the  old  system  has  left  many 
indelible  traces  on  the  surface  of  the  land  itself 
and  the  nature  of  the  holdings  in  the  size 
and  shape  of  the  fields  (compare  also  Canon 
Taylor's  paper  in  Domesday  Studies  on  "  Domes- 
day Survivals  ").  The  open  fields  were  nominally 
divided  into  long  acre  strips  a  furlong  (i.e.  a 
furrow-long)  in  length  and  four  rods  in  width. 
Originally  these  strips  were  separated  by  green 
balks  of  unploughed  turf,  and  these  balks  can 
still  be  traced.  A  bundle  of  these  long  acre 
strips  a  furlong  in  width  made  a  "  shot "  (Anglo- 
Saxon)  "quarentena"  (Latin)  "furlong"  (old 
English),  and  these  furlongs  were  divided  by 
broader  balks  generally  overgrown  with  bushes. 
The  roads  by  which  access  was  obtained  to  the 
strips  usually  lay  along  the  side  of  the  furlong 
and  at  the  end  of  the  strips,  and  these  roads, 
often  at  right  angles  to  one  another,  still 
survive.  There  are  further  traces  on  the  land 
itself  of  the  old  "head -lands"  (Scotch  head- 


rig),  the  "linches,"  "butts,"  "gored  acres" 
and  pieces  of  "no  man's  land  "  (Seebohm,  p.  6). 
Canon  Taylor  in  the  paper  cited  above  gives 
some  very  remarkable  examples  of  the  eff"ects  of 
the  same  method  of  ploughing  in  these  open 
fields  having  been  practised  for  many  generations. 

But  not  only  on  the  surface  of  the  land,  but 
in  the  present  distribution  of  the  fields  and 
"closes"  constituting  a  farm,  the  effect  of  its 
common  open  fields  may  be  traced.  Taking 
any  manor  as  a  centre  we  find  the  farms  of  which 
it  is  composed  not  consisting  only  of  solid  blocks 
(as  in  the  newly-settled  land  of  the  United 
States),  but  of  a  number  of  little  fields  scattered 
about  in  the  most  "admired  disorder,"  and  at 
a  considerable  distance  from  one  another.  Of 
the  present  inconvenience  and  want  of  economy 
involved  in  the  an-angement  of  farming  land 
there  can  be  no  doubt  from  the  modern  agricul- 
tural standpoint,  and  if  a  tabula  rasa  could 
be  made  of  the  land  such  a  wasteful  method 
of  distribution  would  never  be  adopted.  The 
inference  is  plain  that  this  irregukr  straggling 
scattered  ownership  and  occupation  of  the  land 
must  be  a  survival  from  a  past  custom  of  which 
the  inner  meaning  has  been  lost.  The  great  merit 
of  Mr.  Seebohm's  work  is  that  he  provides  a  key 
for  the  explanation  of  this  peculiarity,  and 
whatever  modifications  may  be  found  necessary 
with  further  research  this  explanation  is  cer- 
tainly at  any  rate  a  most  valuable  working  hypo- 
thesis. Evidence  of  the  full  existence  of  the 
open-field  system  is  easily  perceived  as  far  back 
as  the  16th,  15th,  and  14th  centuries.  We 
have  the  literary  remains  of  the  great  agricul- 
tural controversy,  in  the  two  former  centuries, 
on  "champion"  and  "several"  already  alluded 
to,  and  for  the  14th  century  we  have  the  graphic 
touches  of  Piers  Plowman  in  describing  his  "  fair 
felde  "  full  of  all  sorts  of  folk.  Then  through 
a  series  of  documents  such  as  the  Winslow  Manor 
Rolls  (reign  of  Edward  III.),  the  Hundred  Rolls 
(Edward  I.),  the  records  of  various  abbeys,  the 
Boldon  Book  (1183  a.d.),  we  are  taken  back  to 
the  gi-eat  Domesday  Survey  (1086  a.d.)  So 
far  the  result  of  the  evidence  is  certainly  to 
show  that  the  further  we  go  back  the  more 
clearly  do  we  discover  the  wide  prevalence  of 
the  open-field  system  and  cultivation  in  common. 
Up  to  the  time  of  Domesday  at  any  rate,  Mr. 
Seebohm  may  be  admitted  to  have  proved  his  case, 
and  it  will  be  convenient  in  this  short  summary 
at  this  point  to  abandon  the  retrogressive  chrono- 
logical method  and  to  notice  the  principal 
features  of  the  system  at  the  time  of  the  Con- 
quest and  the  processes  and  causes  of  its  decay. 

At  the  completion  of  the  Conquest  there  were 
certainly  manors  everywhere,  some  belonging  to 
the  king,  others  to  great  barons  and  prelates, 
and  others  to  the  mesne  tenants  of  these  greater 
lords  (cp.  Madox,  Exchequer).  Some  lords  held 
many  manors  and  were  represented  by  a  steward 
or  Reeve  (villicus).     The  typical  Manor  was  a 


AGKICULTURAL  COMMUNITY 


25 


manorial  lord's  estate  with  a  village  or  town- 
ship upon  it  under  his  jurisdiction  and  held  in 
the  peculiar  system  of  serfdom  known  as  villen- 
age. 

Passing  now  to  the  internal  economic  con- 
stitution of  one  of  these  manors  and  leaving  the 
legal  difficulties  on  one  side,  we  observe  that 
the  arable  land  was  divided  into  the  lord's 
demesne  and  the  land  in  villenage.  The  whole 
of  the  arable  land  was  in  three  great  open  fields, 
and  the  demesne  land  was  interspersed  with 
the  villein's  land.  For  the  present  purpose 
the  liberi  homines  may  be  omitted,  and  we  may 
observe  that  there  were  three  classes  of  tenants 
in  villenage,  namely  villani  (proper),  cotarii  or 
bordarii  (cottagers),  and  servi  (slaves).  The 
chief  interest  attaches  to  the  villeins.  The 
typical  villeiij  holding  was  a  virgate  or  yard- 
land,  and  a  Virgate  normally  consists  of  thirty 
acres,  namely  ten  of  the  long-acre  strips  in 
each  of  the  three  great  open  fields.  It  has 
been  calculated  (Seebohm,  p.  102)  that  about 
5,000,000  acres  were  under  the  plough  in 
the  counties  named  in  the  survey,  about  half 
being  held  by  the  villeins. 

The  normal  virgate  was  an  indivisible  bundle 
of  strips  of  land  passing  with  the  homestead 
by  regrant  from  the  lord  to  a  single  successor. 
There  were  also  rights  to  certain  use  of  meadow 
and  waste.  The  virgates  with  their  homesteads 
were  sometimes  called  for  generations  by  the 
family  name  of  the  holder.  The  central  idea 
of  the  system  was  to  keep  up  the  services  ol 
various  kinds  due  to  the  lord  of  the  manor,  and 
the  virgate  was  a  typical  family  holding.  The 
services  consisted  of  so  much  Week  Work,  gener- 
ally three  days,  an  uncertain  quantity  of  boon- 
work  {adprecem.,  precarious)  at  the  will  of  the  lord, 
and  certain  payments,  occasionally  of  money  but 
more  frequently  in  kind.  There  were  also  re- 
strictions upon  the  personal  freedom  of  the 
villeins,  e.g.  the  lord's  licence  must  be  obtained 
on  the  marriage  of  a  daughter,  or  the  sale  of 
an  ox,  etc.,  and  no  one  could  leave  the  land 
without  the  lord's  assent. 

The  normal  outfit  of  the  Villein  was  a  pair 
of  oxen,  and  the  ploughing  was  usually  done  with 
a  team  of  eight  oxen.  Thus  even  so  far  as  the 
beasts  were  concerned  the  co-operation  of  at 
least  four  villeins  was  required.  We  find  also 
that  certain  craftsmen  held  their  virgates  in 
virtue  of  their  services  to  the  village,  and  the 
principal  wants  of  the  community  were  satisfied 
by  its  OAvn  labour.  Everywhere  and  in  every- 
thing custom  was  in  force  limiting  the  nature 
and  amount  of  the  services  and  prescribing  the 
times  and  methods  of  cultivation.  The  princi- 
pal diff"erences  between  the  English  village  com- 
munity at  the  Conquest  and  at  the  time  of  the 
Black  Death  (1349  a.d.)  are  to  be  found  in  the 
gradual  break-up  of  these  overpowering  customs 
and  the  increasing  scope  given  to  individual 
enterprise   and   variety.      The   nature   of  the 


movement  is  shown  by  the  increasing  irregu- 
larity of  the  holdings  and  the  departure  from 
the  normal  type,  by  the  progressive  limitation 
of  the  services  demanded  and  above  all  by  the 
substitution  of  money  payments  for  these  services 
and  payments  in  kind.  This  commutation  in 
the  mode  of  rendering  tribute  to  the  landowner 
was  the  most  potent  cause  of  economic  progress 
in  the  mediaeval  period.  By  the  time  of  tlie 
Black  Death  the  option  at  any  rate  of  money 
payments  had  become  usual.  The  landowner 
found  his  advantage  in  the  greater  efiiciency  of 
hired  labour,  and  the  villein  had  the  power  of 
benefiting  himself  by  exceptional  industry. 

For  a  long  time,  however,  the  customary 
methods  of  cultivation  prevailed,  and,  as  pointed 
out  above,  the  open  fields  remained  down  to 
the  close  of  last  century.  The  principal  point 
to  observe  is  that  starting  with  the  Conquest, 
economic  and  agricultui'al  improvement  has 
been  closely  connected  with  the  disintegration 
of  Village  Communities.  The  nature  of  this 
movement  is,  however,  often  overlooked,  because 
a  comparison  is  made  at  different  times  between 
different  parts  of  the  social  scale,  the  modern 
farm  labourer  being  compared  to  the  villein 
with  the  virgate,  to  the  apparent,  disadvantage 
of  the  former  in  spite  of  serfdom.  But  the 
true  counterpart  of  the  modern  labourer  was 
the  mediaeval  slave,  and  the  villein  corresponds 
to  the  modern  small  farmer  or  landowner. 

When  we  go  back  beyond  the  Conquest  we 
find  strong  evidence  of  the  prevalence  in  the 
eastern  districts  of  Britain  of  these  village  com- 
munities in  serfdom  under  manorial  lords, 
though  the  points  of  similarity  are  at  first  dis- 
guised by  the  difference  of  language.  There 
seems,  however,  little  doubt  that,  whatever 
may  have  happened  at  the  time  of  the  Saxon 
invasion  and  in  the  dark  period  which  followed 
after  the  departure  of  the  Romans,  as  soon  as 
the  Saxons  were  settled  they  developed  (or 
adapted)  the  essential  economic  features  of  the 
manor  (compare  the  Laws  of  Ine  quoted  by 
Mr.  Seebohm,  p.  142).  It  is  at  this  point  that 
the  principal  controversy  arises.  The  older 
view  generally  associated  with  the  name  of  Von 
Maurer  was  that  the  Saxons  imported  into  this 
island  the  fully-developed  ^Iark  System.  The 
members  of  the  mark  were  freemen,  and  in 
their  assemblies  decided  on  points  of  interest 
to  the  community.  The  arable  land  was  divided, 
and  the  portions  of  meadow  were  allotted  by 
popular  vote.  According  to  this  vieAV  the 
village  community  in  historical  Saxon  times 
had  degenerated  from  this  original  type,  the 
overlordship  of  a  single  individual  having 
taken  the  place  of  the  free  assembly  of  equals. 
Against  this  view,  however,  Mr.  Seebohm  has 
made  out  a  very  strong  case.  His  principal 
points  are  that  the  Saxons  in  their  own  homes 
do  not  appear  to  have  cultivated  land  on  the 
Three-field  System  ;  that  as  soon  as  historical 


26      AGRICULTURAL  COMMUNITY— AGRICULTURAL   HOLDINGS  ACTS 


evidence  is  available  we  find  the  closest  ana- 
logies between  the  agricultural  systems  in  Saxon- 
England  and  that  in  the  Romano -Teutonic 
portion  of  southern  Germany  ;  that  there  is  no 
sufficient  time  allowed  for  the  full  development 
independently  of  the  manorial  from  the  mark 
system,  and  that  there  is  no  reason  to  suppose 
that  the  Saxons  exterminated  the  inhabitants 
and  treated  the  land  as  if  it  were  virgin  forest. 
The  conclusion  is  that  to  a  great  extent  the 
Saxons  simply  adopted  the  system  which  they 
found  already  established  by  the  Romans  during 
their  four  centuries  of  occupation.  This  opinion 
is  supported  by  the  close  analogy  between  the 
conditions  of  tenure  of  the  Romano-British 
eolonus  and  the  later  villani  (Seebohm,  p.  267). 
Thus  the  Roman  villa  is  made  to  contribute 
some  of  the  most  important  elements  of  the 
late  English  village.  But  now  the  question 
arises : — Whence  were  the  elements  of  the 
Roman  system  in  Britain  derived  ?  Did  the 
Romans  themselves  import  their  own  agricul- 
tural customs  and  impose  them  upon  the  in- 
habitants, or  did  they  adapt  what  they  found 
to  their  own  uses?  It  is  known  from  other 
sources  that  the  most  usual  course  of  the  Romans 
in  their  policy  of  parcere  suhjedis  was  to 
amalgamate  as  far  as  possible  foreign  customs 
with  their  own.  It  is  known  also  from  his- 
torical evidence  that  before  the  Roman  invasion 
in  many  parts  of  Britain  there  was  a  settled 
system  of  agriculture,  notably  in  the  south- 
east, and  it  would  be  in  accordance  with  their 
usual  practice  for  the  Romans  to  take  what 
they  found  as  the  basis  of  their  own  methods 
of  cultivation  and  extracting  revenue  from 
the  people.  We  are  thus  thrown  still  further 
back,  in  order  to  discover  the  elements  of 
this  system  which  existed  in  Britain  before 
the  Roman  invasion,  and  in  the  search  we 
discover,  following  the  lines  of  Mr.  Seebohm's 
investigation,  that  through  the  whole  period 
from  pre-Roman  to  modern  times  there  were  two 
parallel  systems  of  rural  economy  the  essential 
features  of  which  were  preserved  in  spite  of 
the  Roman,  English,  and  Norman  invasions — 
namely  the  village  community  in  the  east  and 
the  tribal  community  in  the  west  of  the  island. 
Neither  system  was  introduced  into  Britain 
during  a  historical  period  of  more  than  2000 
years.  The  village  community  of  the  east  was 
connected  with  a  settled  system  of  agriculture  ; 
the  equality  and  uniformity  of  the  holdings 
were  signs  of  serfdom,  and  this  serfdom  again 
had  itself  arisen  from  a  lower  stage  of  slavery. 
The  mark  Math  its  equal  freemen,  so  far  as  this 
part  of  Britain  is  concerned,  is  thus  an  unten- 
able hypothesis.  We  have  equality  and  com- 
munity, it  is  true,  but  they  are  based  not  on 
freedom  but  on  organised  serfdom.  On  the 
other  hand  the  Tribal  System  which  prevailed 
in  the  west  of  Britain  (especially  Scotland  and 
Wales)  and  also  in  Ireland  was  connected  with 


an  earlier  stage  of  economic  development  mainly 
of  a  pastoral  kind.  The  tribal  community  was 
bound  together  by  the  strong  ties  of  blood - 
relationship  between  free  tribesmen.  This  free 
equality  involved  an  equal  division  amongst  the 
tribesmen  according  to  various  tribal  rules, 
and  this  custom  of  sub-division  has  survived  to 
our  own  day  in  the  "Rundale"  or  "run-rig" 
system  of  the  west  of  Scotland  and  Ireland.  In 
this  brief  summary  many  interesting  points  have 
been  omitted  and  many  certainly  require  further 
investigation.  The  origin  of  the  size  and  shape 
of  the  long -acre  strips,  the  original  object  of 
the  irregular  scattering,  and  the  way  in  which 
the  system  became  solidified  in  such  an  incon- 
venient form  for  modern  requirements,  can  only 
be  alluded  to.  Perhaps  the  most  remarkable 
general  result  is  that  co-operation  which  we  are 
accustomed  to  regard  as  a  purely  modern  pro- 
duct is  very  ancient,  but  whether  this  co-opera- 
tion arose,  unlike  most  other  ancient  institutions, 
purely  from  rational  elements  and  from  motives 
of  economy  and  convenience,  has  not  yet  been 
the  subject  of  sufficient  investigation.  Certainly 
hitherto  the  principal  danger  in  re-constructing 
primitive  societies  has  been  to  import  too  readily 
modem  ide^s  and  not  to  allow  sufficiently  for 
what  we  should  now  call  irrational  elements. 

[Besides  the  works  referred  to  above  the  reader 
may  consult  for  the  history  of  English  villenage, 
Six  Centuries  of  English  Work  and  Wages,  b> 
Prof.  Thorold  Rogers ;  and  for  other  matters 
Coote's  Romans  in  Britain. — Skene's  Celtic  Scot- 
land ;  various  works  and  papers  by  Professors 
Hannsen  and  Meitzen  and  Lamprecht  on  the  open- 
field  system  in  Germany ;  also  the  volumes  en- 
titled Domesday  Studies.  —  G.  L.  Gomme,  The 
Village  Community  with  special  reference  to  thi 
origin  and  form  of  its  survivals  in  Great  Britain. 
London,  1890.]  J.  s.  N. 

AGRICULTURAL  GANGS.     See  Gangs. 

AGRICULTURAL  HOLDINGS  ACTS.  An 
Agricultural  Holdings  Act  for  England  and 
Wales  was  passed  in  1875,  but,  not  being 
compulsory,  remained  inoperative,  and  was  re- 
pealed by  the  act  of  1883,  which  is  now  in 
force,  and  applies  to  agricultural  and  pastoral 
holdings,  to  market  gardens,  and  to  holdings 
let  to  tenants  in  connection  with  any  employ- 
ments. The  principal  provisions  of  this  act 
come  under  five  heads :  (a)  Compensation  for 
improvements,  (b)  fixtures,  (c)  distress,  (d) 
notice  to  terminate  yearly  tenancy,  (e)  resump- 
tion of  holding  by  landlord  for  the  purposes  of 
carrying  out  improvements. 

(a)  At  common  law  an  outgoing  tenant  is 
not  entitled  to  compensation  for  improve- 
ments, except  under  a  local  custom.  It  is  now 
provided  that  every  tenant  on  quitting  his 
holding  shall  be  entitled  to  compensation  for 
the  improvements  made  at  his  own  expense 
during  his  tenancy.  The  act  enumerates  three 
classes  of  improvements.  As  regards  the  first 
class    (comprising   the   erection   of    buildings, 


AGRICULTUKAL  SYSTEMS— AGRICULTURE  IN  ENGLAND 


27 


laying  down  of  permanent  pasture,  making  of 
gardens,  etc.),  compensation  cannot  be  claimed 
unless  the  landlord  has  given  his  consent  to  the 
improvement.  As  regards  the  second  (drainage), 
notice  must  be  given  to  the  landlord,  who  has  the 
option  of  executing  the  improvement  at  his  own 
cost,  charging  5  per  cent  interest.  The  im- 
provements comprised  in  the  third  class  (boning, 
chalking,  liming,  application  of  artificial 
manm'e,  etc.)  may  be  executed  without  the 
landlord's  consent  and  without  notice  to  hini. 
The  sum  payable  for  compensation  is  to  re- 
present the  value  of  the  improvements  to  an 
incoming  tenant.  Any  contract  made  by  a 
tenant,  by  vii'tue  of  which  he  is  deprived  of 
his  rights  to  compensation,  is  void. 

(b)  At  common  law  fixtures  on  agricultural 
holdings  belong  to  the  landlord.  The  act  now 
provides  that  engines,  machines,  fences,  or 
buildings,  which  the  tenant  affixes  or  erects 
without  being  obliged  to  do  so,  may  be  re- 
moved by  an  outgoing  tenant,  unless  the  land- 
lord (to  whom  notice  must  be  given)  elects  to 
purchase  them  at  a  price  representing  their 
fair  value  to  an  incoming  tenant. 

(c)  In  ordinary  cases  the  landlord  may  dis- 
train for  six  years'  arrears  of  rent,  but  in  the 
case  of  holdings  coming  under  the  act  the  right 
to  distrain  is  now  limited  to  one  year's  rent. 
Some  partial  and  total  exemptions  from  dis- 
traint are  also  created  by  the  act.  Live-stock 
taken  in  to  be  fed  at  a  fair  price  payable  by  the 
owner  cannot  be  distrained,  if  other  sufficient 
distress  be  found,  and  cannot  in  any  case  be 
distrained  for  a  sum  exceeding  the  amount 
remaining  due  from  the  owner  for  the  cost  of 
feeding.  Hired  machinery,  and  live-stock  be- 
longing to  another  person  which  is  on  the 
premises  merely  for  breeding  pm-poses,  are  not 
to  be  distrained  at  all. 

(d)  The  usual  tenancy  from  year  to  year  can 
be  terminated  at  the  end  of  each  year  by  a 
six- monthly  notice,  but  in  the  case  of  a  holding 
coming  under  the  act,  one  year's  notice  is  now 
required  in  the  absence  of  any  special  arrange- 
ment. 

(e)  The  act  allows  a  landlord  in  the  case  of  a 
tenancy  from  year  to  year  to  give  notice  to 
terminate  the  tenancy,  as  to  part  only,  if  the 
land  be  wanted  for  labourers'  cottages,  or 
gardens,  for  allotments,  for  the  planting  of 
trees,  for  mines,  quarries,  or  sand-pits,  or  for 
making  watercourses  or  reservoirs,  roads,  rail- 
ways, etc.  The  tenant  may,  however,  within 
twenty -eight  days  after  receiving  the  notice, 
inform  the  landlord  that  he  accepts  it  as  a 
notice  to  quit  the  entire  holding. 

See  also  Appendix,  sub  voce.  An  act  applying 
to  Scotland  was  passed  in  1883  ;  it  contains 
provisions  as  to  compensation,  fixtures,  notice,  and 
some  matters  peculiar  to  Scots  law.  As  regards 
Ireland,  see  Irish  Land  Laws.  e.  s. 

AGRICULTURAL  SYSTEMS.  Adam  Smith 


uses  this  term  in  the  title  of  ch.  ix.  of  bk.  iv. 

of  the  Wealth  of  Nations,  as  equivalent  to 
"those  systems  of  political  economy  which 
represent  the  produce  of  land  as  either  the  sole 
or  the  principal  source  of  the  revenue  and  wealth 
of  every  country."  The  last  part  of  the  chapter 
deals  with  the  policy  of  favouring  agriculture 
rather  than  manufactures  and  commerce 
adopted  by  China  and  ancient  Egypt,  Hindo- 
stan,  Greece,  and  Rome.  This  policy  Adam 
Smith  treats  as  an  agricultural  system,  presum- 
ably because  he  thought  it  to  have  been  inspired 
by  a  belief  that  the  produce  of  land  is  the 
"principal"  source  of  wealth.  But  the  chief 
object  of  the  chapter  is  to  explain  and  criticise 
the  system  of  the  French  "economists"  or 
physiocrats,  in  which  the  produce  of  land  is 
represented  as  the  "sole"  som-ce  of  wealth. 
For  an  account  of  this  system  see  Physiocrats. 

Prof.  Oncken  maintains  in  the  Introduction  to 
his  Quesnay,  that  Adam  Smith  has  done  less  than 
justice  to  the  "sect  "  of  the  "  economists." 

AGRICULTURE  IN  ENGLAND.  The 
agriculture  of  the  Romans  in  England,  familiar 
Vv^ith  writers  like  Columella,  and  supplying  the 
needs  of  an  advanced  civilisation,  was  superior 
to  that  of  their  barbarous  predecessors  or  suc- 
cessors. During  the  Roman  occupation  the 
land  which  was  owned  by  individuals  was  tilled 
in  one  of  three  ways :  (1)  by  slave  labour 
directed  by  a  steward  (villicus)  ;  (2)  by  tenants 
at  produce  rents  (partiarii  or  mdayers)  ;  (3) 
by  free  farmers  at  money  rents  {liberi  coloni). 
[See  Dickson's  Husbandry  of  the  Ancients,  Coote's 
Jiomans  in  Britain,  Daubeny's  Lectures  on 
Homan  Husbandly.']  It  is  probable  that  among 
the  Romans,  the  Celts,  and  the  Anglo-Saxons, 
common  tillage  was  practised  (on  the  question 
whether  the  Anglo-Saxon  comimmities  ever,  in 
this  country,  owned  the  land  they  cultivated, 
see  Commons).  In  one  essential  point  the 
farming  of  the  Celtic  people  who  preceded  the 
Romans  differed  from  that  of  the  Teutonic 
settlers  by  whom  they  were  succeeded.  Among 
the  Celts  fresh  tracts  of  grass-land  were  succes- 
sively taken  in  by  the  co- partners,  tilled  for 
corn,  and  then  thrown  back  into  pasture.  To 
this  primitive  form  of  nomadic  farming  the 
name  of  "  wild- field-grass  husbandry  "  has  been 
given  (cp.  Nasse  on  Village  Community,  and 
Marshall's  Agriculture  of  the  Western  Counties). 
In  the  common  fields  of  the  Anglo-Saxon  com- 
munities, on  the  contrary,  pasturage  and  tillage 
were  permanently  separated  ;  gi^ass-land  always 
remained  pasture  ;  it  was  never  broken  up  for 
tillage.  This  permanent  separation  of  grass- 
land from  tillage  appears  a  retrogi-ession  in 
farming  practice.  It  is  the  application  to 
England  of  a  system  which  Avas  better  adapted 
to  the  drier  climate  of  the  country  whence  the 
Saxon  immigrants  came.  Among  the  early 
Saxons  the  soil  had  been  tilled  by  Village  Com- 
munities.    The  land  held  by  the  association 


28 


AGRICULTURE  IN  ENGLAND 


was  divided  into  two  main  divisions  :  (1)  round 
the  homesteads  lay  permanent  enclosures  held 
as  private  property  (cp.  Tacitus,  suam  quisque 
domum  spatio  cirmmdat) ;  (2)  beyond  the  village 
lay  the  common  lands  of  the  association.  This 
latter  portion  consisted  of  {a)  arable  fields,  some- 
times two,  generally  three,  and  in  later  times 
four,  in  number  ;  {h)  meadowland  for  hay  ;  (c) 
rough  wild  pasture  for  live  stock.  Of  the  three 
arable  fields  one  was  cultivated  each  year  for 
wheat  or  rye,  another  for  oats,  barley,  peas,  and 
beans,  and  the  third  lay  fallow.  Thus  each 
field  every  third  year  was  fallow.  Both  the 
meadow  and  arable  lands  were  cut  into  strips 
and  annually  allotted  to  the  use  of  individuals 
from  putting  up  for  hay  or  from  seed-time. 
Each  partner  held  scattered  intermixed  parcels 
in  each  of  the  arable  fields,  so  as  to  equalise 
the  quality  of  the  land,  and  to  give  each  a  share 
in  the  diff'erent  crops  cultivated.  The  farming 
was  regulated  by  a  system  of  "field  constraint," 
or  later  by  the  Reeve  of  the  manorial  lord. 
After  the  crops  were  cleared,  separate  use  ter- 
minated and  common  rights  recommenced,  the 
cattle  and  sheep  of  the  community  wandering 
over  the  fields  before  the  common  herdsman  or 
shepherd  (for  a  detailed  account  of  the  system 
see  Seebohm's  The  English  Village  Community). 
Oo-tillage  remained  a  feature  of  English  farming 
after  the  Norman  Conquest.  Up  to  the  close 
of  the  18th  century  half  the  soil  of  England  was 
thus  cultivated,  and,  in  1879,  600  acres  at 
Stogoursey  near  Bridgwater  were  farmed  on  this 
system  (for  the  theories  respecting  the  changes 
effected  at  the  Conquest,  see  Commons).  By 
the  close  of  the  11th  century,  the  immediate 
lordship  of  the  soil  was  vested  in  lords  of 
manors,  subject  to  regulated  rights  of  user  en- 
joyed by  the  co-operative  farmers.  The  manorial 
estate  was  divided  into  three  parts,  the  Demesne, 
the  tenemental  land  of  the  associated  farmers, 
and  the  lord's  wastes,  over  which  the  live  stock 
of  the  tenants  grazed.  The  soil  was  tilled  by 
serfs,  by  freemen,  and  by  semi-servile  tenants, 
who  paid  for  their  land  by  military  or  agricul- 
tural services.  Out  of  these  grades  in  the  rural 
population  sprang  the  freeholder,  the  copyholder, 
and  the  free  wage-earning  labourer.  The  most 
striking  features  in  mediaeval  farming  were  the 
violent  alternations  from  perpetual  cropping  to 
barrenness,  from  indolence  to  intense  labour, 
from  famine  to  feasting.  Scarcely  anything  was 
grown  for  markets  ;  nearly  all  the  produce  was 
consumed  at  home  by  the  producers.  Arable 
land  exceeded  grass-land.  No  manure  was  em- 
ployed ;  horses  were  scarcely  ever  used  ;  oxen 
were  more  economical ;  their  food,  harness,  and 
shoes  were  cheaper  ;  when  dead  they  were  meat 
for  man.  The  crops  were  wheat,  oats,  barley, 
rye,  beans,  peas,  flax,  and  hemp.  Rye  was  the 
chief  grain  crop.  Roots,  artificial  grasses,  and 
potatoes  were  unknown.  There  was  little  or  no 
winter  keep  for  live  stock  ;  consequently  cattle 


were  killed  at  Michaelmas,  after  having  been 
well  nourished  by  the  aftermath  of  the  meadows, 
or  the  stubble  and  haulm  of  the  arable  land, 
and  salted  for  winter  provision.  Wheaten  bread 
was  a  luxury  of  the  richest.  The  monks  were 
the  only  pioneers  of  good  farming.  In  the 
change  from  mediaeval  to  modern  farming  two 
great  epochs  must  be  noted — (A)  the  Tudor 
period  ;  (B)  the  latter  part  of  the  18th  century. 
(A)  The  Black  Death,  1348-49-61,  is  said  to 
have  destroyed  half  the  population  of  the  country 
(see  Hecker's  Epidemics  of  the  Middle  Ages; 
Rogers's  Hist,  of  Prices,  vol.  i.  ;  Jessop,  Coming 
of  the  Friars,  and  other  Essays).  The  mortality 
resulting  raised  the  rate  of  wages  50  per  cent. 
The  attempts  of  manorial  lords  to  fix  rates  of 
wages  by  statute  (25  Ed.  III.)  or  to  resume 
personal  services,  caused  the  Peasants'  Revolt 
of  1 381.  This  proves  that  by  1350  the  relations 
of  occupiers  and  owners  had  settled  down  into 
more  modern  conditions,  that  tenant-farmers, 
copyholders,  and  free  wage-earning  labourers 
had  replaced  the  serfs  and  villeins,  that  leases 
had  become  common,  that  the  customary  ser- 
vices of  the  peasantry  were  first  rendered  certain 
and  then  commuted  for  money  rents  or  money 
wages  (see  Denton's  England  in  the  Fourteenth 
Century,  and  Ashley's  Econmnic  History).  The 
effects  of  the  Black  Death  were  social  rather 
than  agricultural,  and  as  such  will  be  noted 
elsewhere.  With  the  close  of  the  "Wars  of  the 
Roses  and  the  commencement  of  the  15th  cen- 
tury, begins  the  era  of  farming  for  profit  which 
characterises  the  Tudor  period.  Feudalism  was 
extinct ;  commerce  progressed  ;  the  wool  trade 
flourished  ;  landlords  required  money,  not  re. 
tainers.  Two  great  changes  were  introduced  : 
(1)  individual  for  common  occupation  ;  (2)  the 
conversion  of  arable  land  into  pasture.  (1) 
Lords  of  manors  withdrew  from  the  agrarian 
associations  and  enclosed  their  demesnes  and 
wastes  ;  common-field  farmers  were  encouraged 
to  extinguish  their  reciprocal  common  rights, 
and  exchange  solid  tenements  for  their  scattered 
strips.  (2)  Arable  land  was  converted  into 
pasture,  farms  were  consolidated,  farm-buildings 
destroyed,  and  England  became  a  sheep-produc- 
ing country.  The  increase  of  enclosures  and 
decrease  of  tillage,  combined  with  the  dissolu- 
tion of  the  monasteries  and  the  absorption  of 
church  lands  into  the  estates  of  adjoining  land- 
lords, inflicted  serious  losses  on  thousands  of 
cottagers,  common-field  farmers,  and  labourers, 
and  produced  the  widespread  social  discontent 
of  the  Tudor  period.  It  is  the  first  step  in  the 
separation  of  the  peasantry  from  their  interest 
in  land  and  the  extinction  of  the  Yeomen  class. 
Towards  the  end  of  the  reign  of  Elizabeth  the 
balance  of  social  relations  began  to  recover  its 
equilibrium.  The  17  th  century  was  a  period 
of  theoretical  progress,  practically  interrupted 
by  civil  disturbances.  The  improvement  ia 
shown  in  (1)  the  rise  of  agricultural  literature. 


AGRICULTURE  IN  ENGLAND 


29 


beginning  with  Fitzhekbert  and  Tusser  ;  (2) 
the  introduction  of  new  crops — hops  (Reginald 
Scot's  A  Per  file  Platform,  of  a  Hoppe-Garden, 
1574),  potatoes  (J.  Foster's  English  Happiness, 
1664),  turnips  (Sir  R.  Weston's  Discourse  of 
Rushandry,  1650),  artificial  grasses  (Hartlib's 
Legade,  1652)  ;  (3)  improved  methods  of  culti- 
vation— Gabriel  Plattes  advocated  drill-sowing  ; 
Vaughan  (TFater  Workes,  1610)  urged  irriga- 
tion ;  Blith  {Tlie  English  Improver,  1649)  studied 
drainage  as  a  science  ;  (4)  increased  attention 
to  live  stock — (Mascall's  QovemtneTit  of  Cattell, 
1605)  ;  (5)  removal  of  feudal  abuses  (stat.  12 
Car.  XL) ;  (6)  increased  enclosui-es  (Joshua 
Lee's  Eutaxia  toit  Agrou,  1656). 

(B)  The  work  of  the  18th  century  may  be 
summed  up  in  the  practical  application,  diffusion, 
and  extension  of  these  improvements  through 
the  work  of  men  like  TuU,  Townshend,  Bake- 
well,  Arthur  Young,  and  Coke  of  Holkham. 
lull  was  a  man  of  scientific  turn,  who  invented 
several  improvements  in  implements  and  was 
the  exponent  of  drill -husbandry.  "Turnip" 
Townshend  introduced  into  Norfolk  turnips  and 
artificial  grasses.  The  alternations  of  these 
crops  with  cereals  enabled  farmers  to  observe 
what,  in  the  absence  of  chemical  manures,  was 
the  golden  rule  of  not  taking  two  coin-crops  in 
euccession,  largely  diminished  the  area  of  fallows, 
assisted  them  to  carry  more  live  stock  and  feed 
it  in  the  winter,  increased  their  command  of 
manure,  and  consolidated  the  light  sandy  soils 
of  the  eastern  counties.  Bakewell  was  the 
founder  of  the  grazier's  art.  He  was  the  first 
scientific  breeder  of  sheep  and  cattle  ;  and  the 
methods  ho  adopted  with  his  Leicester  sheep 
and  Leicester  longhorns  were  applied  through- 
out the  country  by  other  breeders  to  other 
breeds.  As  population  advanced,  sheep  and 
cattle  were  valued  more  for  their  carcases  than 
for  their  fleece  or  their  powers  of  draught.  So 
long  as  the  common -field  system  prevailed, 
Townshend's  or  Bakewell's  improvements  were 
impossible.  England,  excluded  from  foreign 
markets  by  wars  and  commercial  policy,  was 
compelled  to  supply  the  needs  of  vast  manu- 
facturing centres  from  her  native  resources. 
The  common- field  system,  only  adapted  to  meet 
the  wants  of  producers,  was  obsolete.  Arthur 
Young  was  the  theoretical.  Coke  of  Holkham 
the  practical,  exponent  of  the  new  system  of 
large  farms  and  capitalist  farmers.  Landlords 
put  themselves  at  the  head  of  the  movement, 
expended  money  in  buildings,  gi-anted  long 
leases.  New  roads  and  canals  opened  out  new 
means  of  communication.  Agricultural  societies 
and  shows  were  multiplied ;  surveys  of  the 
country  were  made  by  Young,  Marshall,  and 
the  Board  of  Agriculture,  which  was  constituted 
in  1793  (see  Board  of  Agriculture).  Be- 
tween 1760  and  1820  more  than  6,000,000 
acres  of  land  were  enclosed.  The  change  pro- 
duced a  new  agricultural  and  social  crisis  more 


severe  than  that  of  the  Tudor  period.  Tha 
century  closed  with  the  miseries  which  resulted 
from  enclosures,  consolidation  of  holdings,  and 
the  reduction  of  thousands  of  small  farmers  to 
the  ranks  of  wage-dependent  labourers.  The 
result  of  the  crisis  was  to  consolidate  large 
estates,  extinguish  the  yeomanry  and  tlie  peasant 
proprietary,  and  to  sever  the  connection  of  the 
labourer  from  the  soil.  The  subsequent 
history  of  agriculture  may  be  summed  up  in 
the  application  of  science  to  practice  under  the 
conditions  of  land-tenure,  with  which  we  aro 
now  familiar.  Vast  capital  has  been  cx})ended 
on  farm -buildings  and  drainage  ;  machinery 
and  steam  have  lessened  the  cost  of  production  ; 
the  farmer's  resources  of  crops,  winter  food, 
manures,  and  implements  are  indefinitely  in- 
creased ;  new  means  of  transport  have  opened 
new  markets  in  every  direction  ;  mechanics, 
capitalists,  arcliitects,  geologists,  chemists, 
physiologists,  botanists,  statisticians,  are  now 
enlisted  on  the  side  of  the  farmer.  Smith  of 
Deanston  (1834)  and  Josiah  Parkes  (1843) 
applied  their  i)ractical  and  scientific  knowledge 
to  drainage  ;  Reed's  cylindrical  pipes  (1843), 
Scrogg's  machine  (1843)  for  their  construction, 
and  the  facilities  provided  by  pailiament  for 
raising  loans  for  land  improvement  (1846) 
enabled  landloids  to  profit  by  improved  science 
and  new  appliances.  New  manures  were  dis- 
covered. Nitrate  of  soda  (1835),  Lawes's 
superphosphates  of  bone  dust  (1843),  Henslow's 
superphosphates  from  coprolites  (1843),  Odam's 
ammoniacal  manures  (1851),  revolutionised  the 
old  rules  of  cropping.  Inventions  in  agricul- 
tural implements  of  every  description  were 
rapidly  produced.  New  crops  such  as  swedes, 
field  cabbages,  kohl-rabi,  mangel-wurzel,  etc., 
were  introduced.  More  live  stock  is  kept,  and 
it  is  better  bred,  better  fed,  and  more  rapidly 
brought  to  maturity.  Intelligence  is  more 
widely  diffused  both  among  landlords  and 
farmers.  Agricultural  statistics  supply  new 
and  valuable  information  and  record  the  results 
of  striking  experiments.  The  constitution  of 
the  Royal  Agricultural  Society  in  1838,  in  place 
of  the  old  Board  of  Agi-iculture  wliicli  ex])ired 
in  1819,  marked  the  return  of  prosperity  after 
the  disastrous  interval  from  1795  to  1835. 
Many  legislative  improvements  were  effected, 
such  as  the  new  Poor  Laws,  the  Commutation 
of  Tithes,  the  General  Enclosures  Act,  the  En- 
franchisement of  Copyholds,  the  Settled  Land 
Acts,  the  Agricultural  Holdings  Acts. 
Recently  also  (1889)  the  Board  of  Agricul- 
ture {q.  V. )  has  been  re-established.  But  in  the 
last  fifteen  years  agriculture  has  ceased  to  pro- 
gress, even  if  it  has  not  retrograded,  owing  to  the 
agricultural  depression,  1873-89  (Depression, 
Agricultural  ;  Depression  of  Trade). 

[Besides  the  books  mentioned  in  the  text  the 
student  is  referred  to  the  following  works  :  (1) 
Professor  Rogers's  Agriculture  and  Prices ;  (2) 


30 


AICKIN— ALCAVALA 


Professor  Kogers's  Six  Centuries  of  Work  and 
Wages,  both  which  contain  an  immense  amount 
of  valuable  information  ;  (3)  Prothero's  Pioneers 
and  Progress  of  English  Farming,  which  is  in- 
tended to  meet  the  want  of  a  short  history  of 
agricultural  progress,  especially  in  the  18th  and 
19th  centuries  ;  (4)  and  the  following  origitial 
authorities— Arthur  Young's  Tours  of  the  English 
Counties  (Southern,  1768, 1  vol.),  Northern  (1770, 
4  vols.),  Eastern  (1771,  4  vols.),— and  Tour  in  Ire- 
land (1776-79);— Marshall'siitwaZ  (Economy  of  the 
English  Counties  and  Scotland  (1787-98, 14  vols.) ; 
—Reports  of  the  Board  of  Agriculture,  1793-1815  ; 
— Reports  of  the  Royal  Com^missionson  Agriculture, 
1820,  '21,  '22,  '33,'  36,  '37,  and '79-81  ;— Pusey's 
Parliamentary  Committee  on  Agricultural  Customs, 
1848  ;— Sir  James  Caird's  letters  to  the  Times  as 
ri?n«s commissioner  in  1850-51 ; — Landed  Interest, 
4th  ed.,  1880  ;  and  the  letters  of  the  commissioner 
of  the  Morning  Chronicle  in  1850  ; — the  Parlia- 
mentary Inquiry  into  Land  Improvements,  1873 ; — 
Report  of  the  Central  Chamber  of  Agriculture  on 
Agricultural  Customs,  1874; — and  the  Agricul- 
tural Returns  annually  published  since  1864.] 

R.  E.  P. 

AICKIN,  Rev.  Joseph,  author  of  Mysteries 
of  the  Counterfeiting  of  the  Coin  of  the  Nation 
.  .  .  (London,  1696).  As  a  method  of  "pre- 
venting the  said  abuse  for  ever,"  it  is  proposed 
that  a  licence  should  be  required  for  all  occu- 
pations ill  which  the  materials  or  implements 
employed  in  counterfeiting  coin  are  made,  sold, 
or  used.  F.  Y.  E. 

AID,  AuxiLiUM.  A  tax,  which  might  be  as- 
sessed, while  the  feudal  system  prevailed,  on  the 
knight's  fee  on  three  occasions :  (1)  when  the 
king  made  his  eldest  son  a  knight ;  (2)  when 
the  king  gave  his  eldest  daughter  in  marriage  ; 
(3)  if  the  king  were  made  captive,  to  ransom 
his  person  (Dowell,  History  of  Taxation  in 
England,  vol.  i.  p.  21).  Used  also  in  same 
sense  as  Subsidy  (q.v.) 

AID,  Rate  in.     See  Local  Taxation. 

AIDES,  CouR  DES.  The  aides,  or  indirect 
taxes  on  commodities,  were  first  imposed  in 
France  by  the  States-general  in  1355.  Instead 
of  entrusting  their  administration  to  the  existing 
financial  court,  the  chambre  des  comptes  (see 
CoMPTES,  Chambre  des),  a  new  body  was 
created  called  the  cour  des  aides.  Before  long 
its  functions  became  almost  solely  judicial,  the 
decision  of  disputes  arising  about  the  Gabelle 
on  salt  and  other  indirect  taxes.  Its  jurisdiction 
was  curtailed  by  the  usurpations  of  the  conseil 
du  roy,  and  was  frequently  disputed  by  the 
rival  chambre  des  comptes.  It  continued  to 
exist  as  one  of  five  cours  souveraines  till  it  was 
swept  away  with  the  other  institutions  of  mon- 
archical France  by  the  Revolution. 

[Gasquet,  Precis  des  Institutions  politiques  et 
sociales  de  Vancienne  France.]  r.  l. 

AIKIN,  John,  M.D.  (1747-1822)  brother  of 
Mrs.  Barbauld  and  author  of  General  Biography, 
Works  of  th^  British  Poets,  etc.,  editor  of  Bods- 
ley's  Annual  Register  (1811-15),  the  Athenmum, 


etc.,  published  in  1795  his  Description  of  the 
Country  from  30  to  40  miles  round  Manchester, 
giving  details  of  commerce,  manufactures,  popu- 
lation, in  addition  to  physical  features,  history, 
and  biography  of  leading  men — a  work  still 
valuable  for  the  history  of  the  Industrial 
Revolution  {q.v.)  j.  b. 

AISLABIE,  John,  bom  December  1670,  sat 
as  M.P.  for  Ripon  1695-1702,  then  for  North- 
allerton, and  for  Ripon  again  from  1705  to  his  ex- 
pulsion. He  was  chancellor  of  the  exchequer  in 
the  Sunderland  ministry  in  1718,  and  supported 
the  South  Sea  scheme  for  paying  off  the  national 
debt.  When  the  bubble  broke  in  1720,  a  secret 
Committee  investigated  his  connection  with  the 
company  and  he  was  expelled  the  House  of 
Commons.     He  died  in  1742.     He  wrote  : 

Speech  upon  his  Defence  in  the  Hou^e  of  Lords 
against  the  Bill  for  raising  Money  upon  the  Estates 
of  the  South  Sea  Directors,  London,  1721,  4to  (three 
editions  ;  also  in  Dutch). — Second  Speech,  London, 
1721,  4to. — Memorial  of  the  Contractants  tenth 
Mr.  Aislabie  in  a  Letter  to  Lixiniv^  Stolo,  London, 
1721,  8vo.  H.  R.  T. 

ALBA  FIRMA.  The  term  applied  to  rents 
reserved  by  the  crown  in  silver,  or  white  money, 
as  opposed  to  rents  reserved  and  payable  in 
kind.     2  Coke's  Institutes,  19.         j.  e.  o.  m. 

ALCAVALA.  A  tax  formerly  charged  in 
Spain  and  its  colonies  on  all  sales  of  property. 
The  name,  of  Moorish  origin,  had  existed  from 
very  early  timeS  ;  we  possess  documents  of  the 
12th  and  13th  centuries  in  which  it  occurs  ; 
but  it  appears  to  have  been  then  applied  to  a 
species  of  seigniorial  due,  or,  perhaps,  sometimes 
to  a  tax  levied  to  meet  a  special  emergency  and 
confined  to  certain  places.  Alfonso  XL,  1342, 
imposed  it  on  the  whole  of  Castile  and  Leon, 
his  object  being  to  procure  money  for  the  war 
with  the  Moors.  At  first  only  temporary,  the 
cortes  of  Burgos,  1377,  granted  it  to  Henry  II. 
without  limitation  of  time.  It  was  a  duty, 
originally  of  10,  afterwards  of  14  per  cent  on 
the  selling  price  of  every  sort  of  property, 
whether  movable  or  immovable,  chargeable  as 
often  as  the  property  was  sold.  In  Adam 
Smith's  time  it  had  been  reduced  to  6  per  cent. 
It  continued  to  exist  down  to  the  invasion  of 
Spain  by  Napoleon,  except  in  Catalonia  and 
Arragon,  those  provinces  having  purchased  ex- 
emption from  Philip  V.  It  violated  the  fourth 
of  Smith's  canons  of  taxation,  taking  and  keep- 
ing out  of  the  pockets  of  the  people  more  than 
it  brought  into  the  treasury  of  the  state.  It 
was,  besides,  a  great  annoyance  to  manufac- 
turers, merchants,  and  shopkeepers  who,  for 
the  purpose  of  its  collection,  were  subjected  to 
the  continual  surveillance  of  the  tax-gatherers. 
Ustariz  attributes  to  it  the  ruin  of  the  manu- 
factures of  Spain  ;  he  might,  says  Smith,  have 
imputed  to  it  also  the  decline  of  agriculture,  aa 
it  was  imposed  not  only  on  manufactures,  but 
on  the  rude  produce  of  the  land. 


ALCOCK— ALIENS 


31 


[Colmeiro,  Historia  de  la  Econoviia  Poliiica  en 
Esjpafla,  vol.  ii.  p.  550 ;  Smith,  Wealth  of  Nations, 
bk.  V.  ch.  ii.]  j.  k.  i. 

ALCOCK,  Rev.  Thomas,  was  born  in  1709, 
and  died  in  1 798.  He  graduated  M.  A.  at  Oxford 
(Brasenose  Coll.)  in  1741.  He  was  presented  to 
the  vicarage  of  Runcorn  in  Cheshire,  and  printed 
some  small  pieces,  besides  the  following  ably 
written  pamphlets : — Observations  on  the  Defects  of 
the  Poor  Laws,  and  on  the  causes  and  consequences 
of  the  great  increase  and  burden  of  tJie  Poor, 
London,  1752,  8vo  (an  attack  upon  compulsory 
provision). — Remarks  on  two  Bills  for  the  Better 
Maintenance  of  the  Poor,  London,  1752,  8vo. — 
Observations  on  that  part  of  a  late  Act  of  Parlia- 
ment which  lays  an  Additional  Duty  on  Cyder 
and  Perry,  Plymouth,  1764,  8vo.  (The  duty 
of  4s.  per  hhd.  on  cider  imposed  in  1763  was 
repealed  in  1766.)  h.  r.  t. 

ALEATORY  (derived  from  the  Latin  alea,  a 
die)  means  uncertain,  risky.  The  more  uncer- 
tain any  prospective  advantage  appears,  the 
less  ceteris  paribus  will  be  given  for  the  chance 
of  obtaining  it.  In  other  words  a  greater  risk 
must  be  compensated  by  a  prospect  of  greater 
gain,  the  purchase -money  being  the  same. 
Thus  £100  stock  bearing  a  fixed  interest,  say 
£3  per  cent,  will  fetch  a  lower  price  the  less 
safe  the  security  is.  A  person  investing  a 
certain  sum  of  money,  say  £100,  will  expect  a 
higher  interest  according  as  the  investment  is 
more  speculative.  It  must  not  be  supposed 
that  the  diminution  of  value  due  to  uncertainty 
admits  of  being  determined  by  any  actuarial 
calculation  of  probabilities.  For  the  deprecia- 
tion depends  not  so  much  on  the  real  imcer- 
tainty  as  on  the  purchasers'  estimate  of  the 
risk.  On  the  one  hand,  as  Prof.  Sidgwick 
points  out  {Principles  of  Political  Economy,  bk. 
ii.  ch.  vi.  §  2),  "ignorant,  rash,  and  credulous 
persons  investing  in  novel  undertakings  are 
believed  to  get,  on  the  average,  considerably 
less  interest  than  if  they  had  lent  their  capital 
on  perfectly  good  security."  On  the  other 
hand  "there  may  be  and  often  is  something  to 
be  allowed  as  a  charge  on  account  of  uncer- 
tainty"  .  .  .  considered  as  "  an  evil  in  itself." 
...  A  railway  stock  that  is  certain  to  pay  4  per 
cent  will  sell  for  a  higher  price  than  one  which 
is  equally  likely  to  pay  1  or  7  per  cent,  or  any 
intermediate  amount "  (Prof.  Marshall,  Principles 
of  Economics,  bk.  vi.  ch.  vi.  §  5).  Similar  prin- 
ciples apply  to  the  influence  of  risk  upon  the 
remuneration  of  different  occupations.  Adam 
Smith's  remarks  upon  the  "natural  confidence 
which  every  man  has  more  or  less  not  only  in 
his  own  abilities,  but  in  his  own  good  fortune  " 
( Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  i.  ch.  x.),  do  not  require 
to  be  quoted.  Prof.  Marshall  thinks  that  "in 
the  large  majority  of  cases  the  influence  of  risk  is 
in  the  opposite  direction  "  {loc.  cit.),  tending  to'_ 
increase  the  remuneration  by  an  amount  greater 
than  the  insurance  against  risk. 


For  a  fuller  discussion  see  Peobability  and 
Risk  as  an  Element  of  Cost  of  Production. 

F.  Y.  E. 

ALE-TASTER.  This  was  the  title  of  an 
officer  formerly  appointed  under  the  Assize  of 
Bread  and  ale  (1267)  to  inspect  the  quality  and 
regulate  the  sale  of  those  commodities  in  every 
borough  and  manor.  In  some  parts  of  England 
the  ofiice  still  survives,  but  its  functions  have 
become  purely  formal.  r.  l. 

ALGAROTTI,  Francis,  born  at  Venice 
1712,  died  at  Pisa  1764.  He  was  learned  and 
very  witty,  and  owes  his  reputation  to  his  liter- 
ary merits  and  his  long  personal  intercourse  and 
friendship  with  Frederick  II.  of  Prussia,  who 
ordered  a  monument  to  be  erected  at  Pisa  to 
his  memory  with  the  epitaph  : 

Algarotto  .  OviDii .  Aemulo 

NeWTONI  .  DiSCIPULO 

Fridericus  .  Magnus 

He  was  a  great  admirer  of  English  science, 
English  literature,  and  English  political  institu- 
tions. As  an  economist  he  -wrote  but  little — 
An  Essay  on  Commerce  and  a  short  pamphlet 
on  the  advantages  of  developing  Africa  com- 
mercially rather  than  Asia  or  America,  This 
little  tract  contained  an  idea  which  -was  utilised 
thirty  years  later  by  the  African  Company, 
directed  by  Sir  Joseph  Banks,  at  whose  expense 
the  famous  traveller  Mungo  Park  undertook  his 
expedition.  m.  p. 

ALIENI  JURIS.  Persons  are  alieni  juris 
if  they  are  not  fully  capable  of  binding  them- 
selves by  contract  or  to  alienate  property,  alien- 
able in  itself,  e.g.  infants  and  man-ied  women. 
They  are  opposed  to  persons  sui  juris,      e.  s. 

ALIENS.  The  subjects  or  citizens  of  a 
foreign  state.  The  disabilities  of  aliens  have 
in  England  been  almost  entirely  removed.  Up 
to  the  year  1870,  aliens  were  unable  to  acquire 
any  land  either  by  descent  or  purchase,  and 
even  natural-born  subjects  could  not  make  a 
title  to  land  by  descent  from  alien  ancestors. 
The  only  disqualification  which  still  remains, 
as  regards  the  ownership  of  property,  arises 
from  the  rule  of  law  that  no  alien  may  be 
owner  or  part  OAvner  of  a  British  ship. 

An  alien  etumy,  though  he  can  make  a  valid 
contract  in  England,  has,  during  tlie  continu- 
ance of  the  war,  no  right  to  enforce  it  by  action, 
and  if  the  war  lasts  long  enough  his  claim  may 
thus  be  barred  by  the  Statute  of  Limitation. 
An  alien  cannot  be  a  member  of  cither  house  of 
parliament,  and  has  no  parliamentary  vote  ;  on 
the  other  hand  he  has  the  privilege  of  serving 
on  juries  if  he  has  resided  in  England  or  Wales 
for  upwards  of  ten  years.  An  alien  involved 
in  civil  or  criminal  litigation  in  England  was 
up  to  the  year  1870  entitled  to  a  jury  "de 
medietate  linguse" — i.e.  a  jury  one  half  of 
which  was  composed  of  foreign  subjects. 

An  alien  may  become  a  British  subject  by 
naturalisation,   either  by  special  act  of  parlia- 


ALISON— ALLOTMENT 


ment  or  by  a  certificate  of  the  Secretary  of 
State.  The  law  as  to  Naturalisation  is  at 
present  regulated  by  the  acts  of  1870  and  1872, 
the  effect  of  which  is  to  confer  on  naturalised 
foreigners  all  the  rights  and  privileges  of  a 
British-bom  subject.  A  candidate  for  natural- 
isation must  have  resided  in  the  United  King- 
dom or  served  under  the  crown  for  at  least  five 
years,  and  must  declare  his  intention  to  estab- 
lish his  permanent  residence  in  the  United 
Kingdom  or  to  take  service  under  the  crown. 
He  must  also  swear  the  oath  of  allegiance. 

E.  S. 

ALISON,  Sir  Archibald,  first  baronet,  son 
of  Kev.  A.  Alison  (bom  1792,  died  1867),  was 
educated  at  Edinburgh  University.  A  paper 
written  by  him  in  reply  to  Malthus  determined 
his  profession  as  a  lawyer.  Alison  was  called  to 
the  Scottish  bar  December  1814,  and  appointed 
advocate-depute  in  1822.  He  travelled  on  the 
Continent,  wrote  much  in  Blackwood,  was  made 
Sheriff  of  Lanarkshire  in  1834,  and  published 
his  voluminous  History  of  Europe  (1789-1852), 
full  of  economical  reflections,  some  biographies, 
an  autobiography,  and  other  works.  The  Act 
restricting  the  paper  currency,  the  Eeform  of 
1832,  and  the  abolition  of  the  com  laws  were  his 
special  abominations.  Few,  if  any,  writers  have 
insisted  with  more  vehemence  on  the  advan- 
tages of  an  increased  production  of  the  precious 
metals  than  Alison  {History  of  Europe,  ch.  1. 
§§  33-40,  1851-52).  It  was  to  the  decrease 
in  the  supply  of  gold  and  silver  and  to  the 
shrinkage  in  the  circulatory  medium  thus 
caused,  that  he  ascribes  the  decline  and  fall  of 
the  Roman  Empire.  Hence  it  was  natural  that 
Alison  should  entirely  approve  of  the  Suspension 
of  Specie  Payments  in  this  country  carried  out 
in  1797,  and  the  substitution  of  a  paper 
currency  during  the  severe  struggle  of  the 
early  years  of  this  century  (see  "Walker,  Money, 
pp.  81-83,  349,  350,  New  York,  1883).  He 
wrote : 

The  Principles  of  Population  and  their  Connec- 
tion with  Human  Happiness,  Edinburgh,  1840,  2 
vols.  8vo  (dull  and  wordy  ;  the  relations  between 
population  and  subsistence  are  elaborately  set 
forth). — Free  Trade  and  Protection,  being  a  Tract 
on  the  Necessity  of  Agricultural  Protection,  Edin- 
burgh, 1844,  8vo. — England  in  1815  and  1845, 
or  a  Sufficient  and  Contracted  Currency,  Edin- 
burgh, 1845  (4th  ed.  IM1).—Free  Trade  and  a 
Fettered  Currency,  Edinburgh,  1847, 8vo. — Essays, 
Edinburgh,  1850,  3  vols.  8vo  (many  economical). 

H.  R.  T. 

ALISON,  William  Pultenet,  M.D.,  pro- 
fessor of  the  practice  of  medicine  in  Edinburgh, 
brother  of  the  historian,  is  best  known  by  his 
Observations  on  the  Management  of  the  Poor  in 
Scotland,  1840  (see  Carlyle's  Past  and  Present), 
and  his  Remarks  on  the  Report  of  the  Commis- 
sioners on  the  Poor  Laws  of  Scotland,  1844. 
He  gives  extracts  from  the  evidence,  drawing 
special  attention  to  the  unemployed.     In  opposi- 


tion to  T.  Chalmers,  and  indeed  to  the  Report 
itself,  he  pleads  for  an  extension  of  legal  relief. 
He  wrote  a  dissertation  on  the  Reclamation  of 
Waste  Lands  (1850),  in  which  he  suggests  this 
as  a  proper  field  of  employment  for  convicts 
and  paupers.  J.  b. 

ALLMEND.  See  Agricultural  Com- 
munity. 

ALLONGE.  A  slip  of  paper  fastened  to  a 
bill  of  exchange  to  receive  indorsements  for 
which  there  is  not  space  on  the  bill  itself ;  "as 
a  protection  against  fraud,  and  in  compliance 
with  the  provisions  of  some  of  the  foreign  codes, 
the  first  of  the  indorsements  in  connection  with 
it  is  sometimes  so  made  that  it  begins  on  the 
biU  and  ends  on  the  allonge.  There  is  no  legal 
limit  to  the  number  of  indorsements." 

[Hutchison,  The  Practice  of  Banking,  vol.  i.  p. 
188.] 

ALLOTMENT.  A  small  portion  of  land 
cultivated  by  a  labourer  or  artisan  in  his  leisure 
hours.  There  is  ample  evidence  to  show  that 
previous  to  the  Tudor  period  the  labourer 
and  the  artisan  had  usually  a  piece  of  ground 
attached  to  their  homes.  A  series  of  economic 
changes  and  the  policy  of  the  land  system  gradu- 
ally resulted  in  the  separation  of  the  labourers 
from  the  soil  (see  Cliffe  Leslie's  Land  Systems 
of  Ireland,  England,  and  the  Continent,  London, 
1871  ;  Nasse's  Land  Community  of  the  Middle 
Ages,  London,  1871  ;  Rogers'  Six  Centuries  of 
Work  and  Wages,  London,  1884).  An  attempt 
to  check  this  movement  was  made  by  the  31 
Eliz.  c.  7,  which  prohibited  the  building  of  any 
cottage  without  an  allotment  of  four  acres.  The 
inclosure  acts  of  the  18th  century  deprived 
many  labourers  of  their  land,  though  the  ad- 
vantages of  allotments  were  recognised,  in  1795, 
by  a  select  committee  of  the  House  of  Commons. 
The  Select  Vestry  Act,  1819,  empowered  the 
churchwardens  and  overseers  of  a  parish  to  let 
land  to  industrious  inhabitants  and  the  1  & 
2  Wm.  IV.  c.  42  ;  1  &  2  WHl.  IV.  c.  59  ;  and 
2  "Will.  IV.  c.  42  contained  similar  provisions. 
The  Allotments  Committee  of  the  House  of  Com- 
mons in  1843  recognised  the  importance  of 
allotments,  but  the  "Women's  and  Children's 
employment  committee  of  1868  reported  that 
but  sparing  use  had  been  made  of  the  facilities 
granted  by  the  legislature.  The  total  number 
of  separate  detached  allotments  under  one  acre 
existing  in  1890  was  455,005.  The  number 
of  other  small  holdings  up  to  50  acres  was 
409,422  (see  Return  of  Allotments  and  Small 
Holdings,  1890,  c.  6144). 

In  1887  an  act  (50  &  51  Vict.  c.  48)  was 
passed  which  empowers  a  sanitary  authority  on 
the  petition  of  six  ratepayers  to  purchase  land 
for  allotments  not  exceeding  one  acre  each.  If 
the  land  cannot  be  obtained  by  agreement,  the 
county  council  may  authorise  its  being  taken 
compulsorily,  the  price  being  determined  by  arbi- 
tration.   All  the  conditions  of  tenancy  are  to  be 


i 


ALLOWANCE,  TARE— ALLOWANCE  SYSTEM 


33 


fixed  by  the  local  authority,  but  no  buildings 
save  those  mentioned  in  the  act  can  be  erected 
on  the  land.  On  the  economic  advantage  of 
allotments  see  in  addition  to  the  authorities 
above  quoted,  Report  of  the  Poor  Law  Commis- 
sioners, 1834  ;  English  Land  and  English  Land- 
l(yrds,  by  G.  C.  Brodrick  (London,  1881).  As  to 
Bmall  holdings,  see  Report  of  Select  Committee 
H.  ofC,  1890. 

[J.  S.  Mill  objects.  Principles  of  Political  Econ- 
omy, bk.  ii,  ch.  xii.  §  4,  to  the  allotment  system. 
For  account  of  the  law  previous  to  1886,  see  The 
Law  of  Allotments,  by  T.  H.  Hall  (Loudon,  1886).] 

J.  E.  C.  M. 

ALLOWANCE  (Tare,  or  difference  between 
Gross  and  Net).  A  commercial  term  signify- 
ing the  deduction  made  from  the  gross  weight 
of  the  goods,  either  to  represent  the  weight  of 
the  package  or  refuse,  or  a  particular  deduction 
established  by  custom  of  certain  trades,  districts, 
or  countries.  2\ire  has  been  more  especially 
described  as  the  allowance  for  the  weight  of  the 
box  or  package,  or  the  cart  or  waggon  in  which 
the  goods  are  conveyed  ;  and  tret  as  an  allow- 
ance for  waste,  but  the  former  is  the  word  more 
generally  in  use  ;  and  gross  weight  and  net 
weight,  live  weight  and  dead  weight,  and 
allowance  in  converting  from  one  to  the  other, 
are  busiuess  terms  commonly  understood.  One 
instance  of  allowance  will  sulfice.  The  coal 
merchant  receives  from  the  colliery  21  cwts.  of 
coal  from  the  pit  for  every  ton  purchased  by 
him,  while  he  sells  to  the  cousumer  but  20 
cwts.  The  difference  is  the  allowance,  or  tare, 
to  cover  waste  in  transhijjment,  cartage,  and 
screening.  In  many  other  industries  similar 
allowances  are  made. 

ALLOWANCE  SYSTEM.  The  allowance 
system  was  a  conspicuous  feature  in  the  adminis- 
tration of  the  poor  law  at  the  very  end  of  the 
last  and  beginning  of  the  present  century.  It 
was  a  form  of  out-door  relief  (see  Poor  Law), 
and  may  be  defined  as  relief  given  to  those  em- 
ployed by  individuals  at  the  average  wages  of  a 
district.  It  was  thus,  in  effect,  an  attempt  on 
the  part  of  the  state  to  regulate  wages,  and  its 
history  gives  an  illustration  of  the  results  which 
political  economy  leads  us  to  expect  from  such 
interference.  It  is  not  too  much  to  say  that  in 
the  brief  space  of  forty  years,  the  allowance  sys- 
tem sent  large  areas  of  land  out  of  cultivation, 
forced  capital  into  less  profitable  employments, 
and  caused  a  demoralisation  from  which  the 
labourers  in  some  rural  districts  have  not  yet 
recovered.  The  very  class  which  it  was  designed 
to  benefit  has  suffered  most  from  its  action. 

It  originated  with  the  administrative  author- 
ity, viz.  the  justices  of  the  peace.  These  derived 
or  assumed  their  powers  under  5  Eliz.  c.  4, 
which  authorised  them  to  fix  wages,  taken  in 
connection  with  3  &  4  W.  and  M.  c.  11,  and  9 
Geo.  I.  c.  7,  which  empowered  them  to  order 
and  direct  relief.     The  system  in  practice  dates 

VOL.  1. 


from  6th  May  1795,  when  the  Berkshire  justices 
resolved  to  make  up  by  relief  from  the  rates 
the  difference  between  actual  wages  and  what, 
in  their  judgment,  was  a  minimum  or  "fair" 
rate  for  the  county.  In  fixing  this  last,  the 
price  of  bread  and  the  size  of  the  family  were 
to  be  taken  into  account,  e.g.  when  bread  was 
at  Is.  8d.  the  gallon,  a  single  man  was  to 
receive  in  all  4s.  6d.,  a  man  and  wife  6s.  8d.,  man, 
wife  and  five  children  17s.  6d.  This  resolu- 
tion is  often  called  the  **  Speenhamland  Act," 
from  the  place  of  meeting  of  the  justices,  and 
the  scale  drawn  up  for  Berkshire  was  used  as  a 
model  by  most  of  the  southern  counties.  It 
may  be  doubted  how  far  such  action  was  even 
legal,  as,  by  9  Geo.  I.  c.  7,  relief  had  been 
prohibited  to  those  who  refused  to  accept  it  in 
a  workhouse  ;  but  it  was  supported  by  public 
opinion,  and  confirmed  in  principle  the  next 
year  by  36  Geo.  III.  c.  23,  which  repealed  the 
prohibitory  clauses  of  9  Geo.  I.  c.  7,  and 
empowered  justices  to  order  relief  to  any  indus- 
trious poor  person  at  his  own  house  or  home. 

The  effects  of  the  system  were  soon  seen. 
Within  forty  years  of  the  passing  of  36  Geo. 
III.  c.  23  it  seemed  probable  that  rents  Avould 
cease  altogether  to  be  paid,  and  in  one  parish, 
Cholesbury,  Bucks,  the  rates  had  actually 
swallowed  up  the  rental.  Where  the  leasehold 
system  threw  the  burden  temporarily  on  the 
occupier,  no  solvent  tenants  were  forthcoming 
owing  to  uncertainty  as  to  the  amount  which 
they  might  be  called  upon  to  pay,  for  in  some 
cases  the  rates  increased  threefold  in  twenty 
years.  In  several  counties  (e.g.  Kent,  Cambridge- 
shire, Leicestershire)  rent  was  gradually  but 
surely  disappearing. 

It  might  seem,  at  first  sight,  as  if  profits 
would.be  raised  by  a  system  which  forced  non- 
employers  to  contribute  to  the  wages  of  labour. 
But  in  agriculture  any  such  advantage  was 
more  than  counterbalanced  by  an  increase  in 
the  cost  of  labour,  due  to  its  diminished  eflSci- 
ency.  The  motive  to  industry  being  removed 
whsn  the  reward  of  the  labourer  no  longer 
depended  on  his  exertions,  industry  itself  dis- 
appeared. In  manufactures,  on  the  other  hand, 
where  piece-work  was  generally  adopted,  a  closer 
supervision  exercised,  and  a  larger  proportion 
of  non-employers  liable  to  the  poor-rate,  the 
system  increased  profits  largely. 

Both  in  agi'iculture  and  in  manufactures  the 
wages  of  labour  were  lowered,  partly  by  the 
great  diminution  of  efficiency,  partly  by  the 
increase  of  population  which  was  stimulated 
under  a  system  which  placed  the  married  man 
with  a  family  in  a  better  position  than  the  single 
man,  and  the  mother  of  illegitimate  children 
than  the  honest  woman,  partly,  again,  because 
employers  were  deterred  from  employing  non- 
paupers  by  the  consideration  that  they  were 
thus  reducing  their  neighbours'  labour  bill. 
More  important  still  was  the  moral  effect  of  the 


34 


ALLOY 


system  upon  the  labourers.  Industry  and 
prudential  foresight  were  extinguished  when 
the  possession  of  property  was  a  bar  to  employ- 
ment, and  the  position  of  the  thriftless  was 
made  an  object  of  envy  to  the  careful :  parental 
responsibility,  filial  obligation  and  affection  ^ere 
discouraged  ;  drunkenness,  vice,  and  crime  grew 
apace  ;  and  the  deterioration  of  a  large  part  of 
the  labouring  population  in  the  districts  in 
which  the  system  was  adopted  became  matter 
of  common  knowledge.  Had  it  continued  in 
force  but  a  few  years  longer  the  whole  social 
fabric  must  have  crumbled  away.  The  rela- 
tions between  employer  and  employed  were 
embittered  to  an  extent  which  showed  itself  in 
constant  riots  ;  in  the  southern  counties  the 
labourers  established  a  reign  of  terror.  Mean- 
while the  production  of  wealth  fell  off  as  the 
rates  rose,  population  grew  apace,  and  civilisa- 
tion went  backwards. 

Allowances  in  aid  of  wages  were  gradually 
abolished  as  regards  men,  by  the  orders  of  the 
poor-law  board  restricting  or  prohibiting  out- 
door relief  to  the  able-bodied.  It  may,  how- 
ever, be  questioned  whether  the  same  results 
are  not  now  produced  in  the  case  of  women  by 
a  loose  administration  of  the  law. 

[For  a  full  account  of  the  allowance  system,  see 
Poor- Law  Commissioners'  First  Eeport,  1834 
(reprinted  by  order  of  House  of  Commons,  1885). 
— Nicholls,  Hist,  of  the  English  Poor  Law. — 
Eden's  State  of  the  Poor. — Fowle,  The  Poor  Law 
(Macmillan  ;  English  Citizen  Series).]      L.  r.  p. 

[The  following  statement,  taken  from  the  obitu- 
ary notice  of  the  Rev.  Henry  Playsted  Jeston, 
late  perpetual  curate  of  Cholesbury,  Bucks,  in  the 
Guardian  newspaper  of  3d  July  1889,  gives  a  vivid 
picture  of  the  effects  of  the  allowance  system  under 
the  old  poor  laws. 

"In  1830  the  parish  (Cholesbury),  under  the 
old  poor  law,  was  on  the  verge  of  bankruptcy.  In 
1831,  out  of  98  who  had  a  settlement  in  the  parish 
(the  total  population  being  then  127,  and  in  1881 
being  99),  there  were  no  less  than  64  in  receipt  of 
relief,  and  the  poor-rates  alone  exceeded  24s.  in 
the  pound.  As  the  result,  the  glebe,  as  well  as 
all  the  land  in  the  parish  save  some  sixteen  acres, 
was  thrown  out  of  cultivation,  and  the  parish  had 
to  exist  for  some  time  by  means  of  rates  in  aid 
levied  on  other  parishes  in  the  hundred.  This 
state  of  affairs,  together  with  a  series  of  letters 
which  Mr.  Jeston  wrote  to  the  Times,  and  his 
evidence  before  the  poor-law  commission,  had  a 
considerable  share  in  bringing  on  the  present  poor 
law.  Before  his  death  Mr.  Jeston  saw  his  parish- 
ioners in  a  fairly  prosperous  condition,  not  one  of 
them  being  in  receipt  of  relief  from  the  rates."] 

ALLOY.  With  regard  to  the  derivation  of 
the  word  "aUoy  "  it  may  be  sufficient  to  point 
out  that  the  old  French  alei  was  retained  in 
the  Norman  as  alai  or  allai,  whence  our  word 
"allay."  Through  the  erroneous  fancy  that 
the  French  aloi  was  equivalent  to  d  loi  (to  law), 
the  word  meaning  originally  simple  ''combina- 
tion union"  came  to  be  used  specially  of  the 


mixing  baser  metal  with  gold  and  silver  in 
coin  so  as  to  bring  it  to  the  recognised  standard, 
and  hence  of  the  standard  itself.  The  French 
word  comes  from  alleium  or  alaium,  the  ori- 
ginal being  probably  adligo  (allego),  to  bind  to. 

The  meaning  of  the  word  alloy  in  mint  lan- 
guage is  different  from  that  ordinarily  accepted 
in  scientific  phraseology,  as  it  is  applied  to  the 
base  metal  added  to  a  more  precious  one,  and 
not  to  the  mass — which  may  be  either  molten 
or  solidified — of  the  mixed  metals. 

The  reasons  for  the  use  of  alloys  for  the 
coinage  in  preference  to  pure  metals  are  some- 
what complex,  and  many  conditions  have  to  be 
taken  into  consideration  in  choosing  the  base 
metal  to  be  added  to  the  precious  metal.  The 
resulting  alloy  must  be  of  good  colour,  must  be 
ductile,  and  must  not  exhibit  any  traces  of 
brittleness.  In  the  case  of  gold,  silver  forms 
a  very  ductile  alloy,  but  then  it  sensibly  lowers 
the  colour  of  the  gold.  Copper,  on  the  other 
hand,  heightens  the  tint  and  has  the  advantage 
of  yielding  a  durable  as  well  as  ductile  alloy. 
A  triple  alloy  of  gold,  silver,  and  copper  may 
be  made  of  delicate  tints,  but  a  triple  alloy  is 
difficult  to  assay,  and  it  is  undesirable  to  com- 
plicate the^  accounts  of  a  mint  by  the  use  of 
two  precious  metals  and  a  base  one  in  the  same 
alloy,  therefore  a  single  base  metal — copper — 
is  almost  universally  used. 

It  has  long  been  known  that  the  union  of 
two  or  more  metals  produces  a  result  which 
often  differs  more  in  physical  properties  from 
either  of  its  constituents  than  these  do  from 
each  other.  Copper  and  tin,  for  instance, 
yield  alloys  of  a  wide  range  of  properties  and 
there  is  hardly  any  fact  more  remarkable  in 
the  whole  range  of  metallurgy  than  the  enor- 
mous influence  exerted  on  a  large  mass  of  metal 
by  a  small  quantity  of  another  metal  as 
metalloid. 

The  properties  which  are  found  the  most 
desirable  to  be  secured  are: — (1)  ductility; 
(2)  durability  ;  (3)  uniformity  of  composition. 

The  alloys  actually  used  for  coinage  at  the 
present  time  are  not  numerous,  but  looking 
back  over  the  numismatic  history  of  the  world, 
endless  combinations  of  the  precious  and  base 
metals  will  be  found  to  have  been  used.  Pure 
gold  and  silver  have  been  used,  either  singly  or 
alloyed  with  each  other,  or  alloyed  with  copper, 
the  latter  metal  in  turn  being  sometimes  em- 
ployed with  only  infinitesimal  additions  of 
precious  metal. 

In  the  case  of  both  the  gold  and  silver 
currency  of  this  country  the  adjustment  of  the 
relative  proportions  of  the  precious  and  the 
base  metals  was  undoubtedly  guided  by  the 
particular  systems  of  weights  used.  To  take 
the  silver  coinage  first,  the  fineness  of  alloys 
of  this  metal  has  from  very  early  times  been 
computed  by  divisions  of  the  troy  Poitnd, 
which   weight   is   still    retained    in   weighing 


ALOD— ALTERNATIVE  STANDARD 


35 


gold  and  silver.  The  computation  of  the 
standard  fineness  for  alloys  of  gold  is  based 
on  the  singular  ''carat"  system  of  weights, 
the  origin  of  which  is  popularly  believed  to 
have  been  derived  from  the  weight  of  an 
oriental  plant  seed.  It  appears  more  probable, 
however,  that  it  came  from  the  ^^  Keralion,"  a 
small  Greek  weight  (see  also  Peiuot). 

The  standard  ef  fineness  of  the  alloy  used  at 
the  present  time  for  tlie  British  gold  coinage  is 
22  carats,  or  91 6 '66  i)arts  in  1000  of  pure 
gold  ;  that  for  the  silver  coinage  is  925  parts 
pure  silver. 

The  accompanying  table  shows  the  variations 
in  the  standard  of  fineness  from  the  reign  of 


Henry  III.  to  the  present  time.  The  coins  in 
circulation  in  France  from  the  beginning  of 
the  17th  to  the  end  of  the  18th  century  varied 
in  fineness  from  900  to  982,  when,  however,  the 
decimal  system  of  weights  and  measures  was 
fairly  established,  coins  were  issued  in  con- 
formity with  it.  The  law  of  the  28th  Ther- 
midor,  an.  iii.  (1796),  enacted  that  the 
standard  fineness  of  the  silver  coins  should  be 
900,  and  eight  years  later  a  law  prescribed  the 
coinage  of  gold  pieces  of  twenty  francs,  the 
standard  of  wliich  was  also  900.  A  subse- 
quent law  lowered  the  standard  fineness  of 
silver  coins  to  835.  By  the  Monetary  Con- 
vention  of   1865    concluded   between   France, 


1250  7275            7325            13 

75            1425            14 

75            1525 

7550 

1600 

1650 

^7000 
Z  925 

> 

Z 
Ul 

EOWARD.I. 
EDWARD.II 

Q 
cr,  < 

RICHARD.il 
HENRY.IV. 
HENRY.V. 

ii 

> 

1 

h 

> 
d 

1 

rTi 

7550  MARY 

ELIZABETH 
1584 
1601 
JAME8.I. 

CHARLE8.1 

IS 

t 

._.!.... 

— 

99 

"  916-66 

958-3 

I 

..__ 

^ 

... 

is50 
111 

CO 

3  700 
O 

o 

Ul 

cc 

'^   550 

u. 
O 

CO 

H 

t  ann 

1 

833-3'^y  \ 

i 

500  s  !j 

2™" 

250 

333-3^-  j 

1 

250                    1                    1 

Belgium,  Italy,  and  Switzerland  these  stand- 
ards of  fineness  were  adhered  to,  and  several 
other  countries  have  adopted  the  same  mone- 
tary system.  In  Germany  the  standard  fine- 
ness of  both  gold  and  silver  has  been  fixed  at 
900,  and  the  same  standard  has  been  adopted 
in  the  United  States  for  both  metals. 

It  will  be  evident,  from  the  table  as  Avell  as 
fi'om  the  foregoing  remarks,  that  the  two  really 
important  alloys  used  for  the  coinage  of  gold 
have  respectively  the  standard  fineness  of 
916-6  and  900,  Avhile  the  standard  900  is 
now  more  widely  used  than  any  other,  Eng- 
land alone  employing  925,  which  still  maintains 
the  connection  Avith  Saxon  coins.  c.  r-a. 

ALOD,  Alodial  Land.  When  the  German 
tribes  overran  Europe  in  the  5th  century, 
they  distributed  among  themselves  the  con- 
quered lands.  In  England,  owing  to  the  dis- 
placement of  the  conquered  population,  this 
distribution  was  probably  more  complete  than 
elsewhere.  Each  toAvnship  or  village  received 
an  allotment  of  land,  the  surplus  being  the 
Folkland,  or  property  of  the  tribe.  Within 
the  village  a  further  distribution  took  place 
among  the  free  heads  of  households,  each  of 


whom  had  a  homestead  as  private  property, 
while  the  arable  and  pasture  land  remained  for 
some  time  in  common  occupation,  being  annually 
distributed  for  the  harvest,  whether  of  hay  or 
corn.  Land  which  was  held  in  se]»arate  owner- 
ship was  called  ethel  or  alod.  The  derivation 
of  the  latter  word  is  disputed,  but  it  is  probably 
connected  with  lot,  and  thus  expresses  the 
original  method  of  distribution.  In  the  11th 
century  we  find  the  term  applied  in  England  to 
all  land  held  independently,  without  rent  or 
sei-vice  to  a  superior.  It  thus  included  both 
the  original  cfJirl,  and  also  Bocland,  or  private 
estates  carved  out  of  the  folkland  for  the  benefit 
of  individuals.  After  the  Norman  Conquest 
alodial  land  ceased  to  exist,  owing  to  the  general 
introduction  of  feudal  or  conditional  tenure. 

[See  Stubbs,  Constitxdional  History,  vol.  i.  ch. 
V. — Kemble,  Saxons  in  England. — Freeman,  Nor- 
man Conquest,  vol.  i.]  R.  L. 

ALTERNATIVE  STANDARD.  It  has 
been  urged  by  monometallists  that  a  Standard 
OF  Value  formed  of  two  metals  is  not  really 
a  double,  but  only  an  alternative  standard, 
debtors,  where  payment  is  permitted  in  either 
metal,    naturally  electing  to   use  the  cheaper 


36 


ALTERNATIVE  STANDARD— ALTHUSIUS 


in  discharge  of  their  obligations.  Jevons 
says  on  this  subject,  referring  to  the  countries 
included  in  the  Latin  union— "When  silver 
is  lower  in  price  than  5s.  Q^^d.  per  ouiice, 
silver  becomes  the  standard  ;  when  silver  rises 
above  this  price,  gold  takes  its  place  as  the 
real  measure  of  value.  So  far  the  English 
economists  are  no  doubt  correct ;  but,  in  the 
first  place,  it  does  not  follow  that  the  prices 
of  commodities  follow  the  extreme  fluctuations 
of  value  of  both  metals,  as  many  writers 
have  inconsiderately  declared.  Prices  only 
depend  upon  the  course  of  the  metal  which 
happens  to  have  sunk  in  value  below  the  legal 
ratio  of  15^  to  1.  ...  At  any  moment  the 
standard  of  value  is  doubtless  one  metal  or 
the  other,  and  not  both  ;  yet  the  fact  that 
there  is  an  alternation  tends  to  make  each  vary 
much  less  than  it  would  otherwise  do.  It 
cannot  prevent  both  metals  from  falling  or 
rising  in  value  compared  with  other  commodi- 
ties, but  it  can  throw  variations  of  supply  and 
demand  over  a  larger  area,  instead  of  leaving 
each  metal  to  be  affected  merely  by  its  own 
accidents."  3foney,  by  Prof.  W.  S.  Jevons,  pp. 
137-140. 

It  is  alleged,  on  the  other  side.  (1)  That  the 
currency  may  indeed  alternate,  in  greater  or 
less  degree,  under  the  influence  of  a  difference 
of  ratio  in  another  bimetallic  country ;  but 
that  this  does  not  affect  the  standard,  nor  the 
public  right  under  a  bimetallic  law  to  have 
either  metal  coined  at  the  legal  ratio,  and  to 
pay  one's  debts  in  either  at  one's  own  choice. 

(2)  That,  as  to  internal  action,  no  one  has  yet 
shown  how  the  debtor  can  obtain  one  metal  at 
a  "cheaper"  rate  than  the  other,  inasmuch  as 
it  is  inconceivable  that  the  seller,  who  can  get 
silver  coined  into  a  fixed  number  of  francs  or 
shillings  at  the  mint,  would  be  content  to  take 
a  smaller  number  from  any  one  else. 

(3)  That,  as  to  external  action,  though  it  were 
true,  which  bimetallists  maintain  it  never  was, 
that  either  metal  was  wholly  absent  from  the 
circulation,  yet  the  effect  of  the  law  on  mono- 
metallic countries  would,  and  always  did  re- 
main intact,  the  open  mint,  and  the  right  of 
sending  either  metal  to  be  coined  into  the 
current  money  of  the  bimetallic  state,  making 
it  impossible  that  the  metal  so  sent  could 
materially  fall  in  price  in  the  monometallic 
state  remitting  it ;  because  such  remittance 
must  always  be  realisable  at  the  rate  of  ex- 
change current  between  the  two  states  ;  and 
that  accordingly  the  price  (of  silver,  for  example) 
in  the  English  market,  neither  did  nor  could 
fall  below  6s.  O^fd.,  except  so  far  as  it  might  be 
modified  by  the  current  rate  of  exchange. 

(4)  That,  consequently,  a  par  of  exchange  was 
established  and  maintained  between  all  silver- 
and  gold-using  countries.  (See  Bimetallism  ; 
Guinea,  Rating  of  ;  Standard  of  Value). 
These  are  the  contentions  on  both  sides. 


[The  difficulties  experienced  in  keeping  two 
metals  in  circulation  are  described  in  Sir  I.  New- 
ton's three  reports  "  Representations  on  the  Sub- 
ject of  Money,"  1711-1712, 1717.  Private  reprint 
of  Tracts  on  Money,  collected  by  J.  R.  M'Culloch 
(London,  1856),  pp.  269-279.  The  two  principal 
of  these  reports  are  also  reprinted  in  Report  and 
Proceedings  International  Monetary  Conference, 
1878  (Washington,  1879),  pp.  317-321.— Also 
Investigations  on  Currency  and  Finance,  Prof. 
W.  S.  Jevons.] 

ALTHUSIUS,  Johannes  (1557-1638),  a 
German  writer,  born  at  Diedenshausen  (Witgen- 
stein-Berleburg).  He  is  said  to  have  studied  at 
Geneva  under  the  influence  of  Calvinistic 
teachers.  In  1586  he  became  professor  of  law 
and  ethics  at  Herborn  (Nassau),  and  in  1604 
syndic  of  the  free  town  of  Emden.  This  honour 
was  conferred  upon  him  on  account  of  his 
treatise  on  politics  ;  in  his  new  position  he 
struggled  successfully  against  the  pretensions 
of  the  nobility  and  the  count  of  Eastern  Fries- 
land.  He  died  at  Emden  in  1638.  His 
Politica  is  the  first  systematic  treatise  on  that 
subject  written  in  Germany  ;  he  regards  politics 
as  the  art  of  constituting  social  life — "  symbiotic 
art."  The  fipundation  of  the  organisation  of 
"social  life"  is  an  express  or  tacit  contract 
between  associated  men.  As  all  rights  there- 
fore proceed  from  the  people,  they  have  the 
right  of  resistance  against  usurpations  of 
authority.  "  Even  if  the  people  would  like  to 
do  so,  they  could  not  transfer  or  alienate  the 
sovereign  power  to  any  one  else,  just  as  no  one 
can  give  to  another  the  physical  life  he  himself 
has."  In  consequence  of  these  opinions  Althus- 
ius  has  been  ranked  among  the  "monarcho- 
machic  school"  (George  Buchanan,  1579, 
Languet,  1579  ;  Boucher,  1591  ;  G.  Rossaeus, 
1590  ;  Hotomannus,  1573  ;  Mariana,  1599  ; 
Althusius,  and  John  Milton,  1651),  and  was 
assailed  by  H .  Arn isaeus, De  autoritate  principum, 
1611  ;  Grotius,  De  jure  belli  ac  pacts,  1625, 
I.  ch.  iii.  §  8  ;  Conring,  De  auctorihus  politicis, 
and  Boecler,  Institutiones  polit.,  Argentor, 
1674,  II.  ch.  i.  p.  102.  Though  forgotten  in 
the  latter  half  of  the  17th  century,  this  work 
seems  to  have  had  considerable  influence  upon 
the  formation  of  the  political  ideas  of  Rousseau 
(compare  Gierke,  p.  201).  The  social  and 
economical  ideas  contained  in  it  are  remarkable, 
it  analyses  the  historic  forms  of  political  associa- 
tions in  the  order  of  formation,  and  distinguishes 
between  associations  for  the  realisation  of  private 
common  interests  ("  peculiare  commune  "),  both 
natural  (the  family)  and  civil  (corporations), 
and  associations  for  public  interests  (the 
"politeuma")  both  particular  (parish,  town, 
province)  and  universal  (the  state).  In  the 
latter  resides  the  supreme  power,  controlled, 
however,  by  ephori,  and  exercised  by  supreme 
"magistratus,"  whose  creation  is  effected  by  a 
contract ;  and  the  different  forms  of  government 


ALTRUISM— AMERICAN  SCHOOL  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY 


37 


are  only  as  many  species  of  supreme  magistrates, 
be  they  monarchical  or  polyarchical. 

The  views  held  by  Althusius  on  economic 
policy  and  in  respect  of  which  he  follows  Botero, 
are  contained  in  the  32d  chapter  {De  administra- 
tione  mediomm  ad  vitce  socialis  commoditates 
necessariorum).  Trade  enriches,  as  is  shown  by 
the  example  of  Venice  and  Genoa,  the  sovereign 
and  the  people.  Tlierefore  the  sovereign  must 
procure  a  steady  supply  of  all  things  needed  for 
the  public  weal,  secure  the  public  from  enhance- 
ment of  prices,  prevent  the  importation  of 
dangerous  or  immoral  commodities,  and  the  ex- 
portation of  provisions.  The  establishment  of 
staples  and  the  maintenance  of  Gild  regulations 
are  recommended  by  Althusius,  but  monopolies 
should  only  be  allowed  in  case  private  means  are 
not  suflBcient  or  security  is  wanting.  Among 
monopolies  he  reckons  combinations  of  artisans. 
His  definition  of  monopolies  has  been  quoted  by 
Edw.  MissELDEN,  Free  Trade,  or,  the  Meanes  to 
make  Trade  florish,  1622,  ch.  iii.  p.  59. 

Politica  methodice  Digesta,  Herbomae,  1603, 
2d  ed.,  Groningae,  1610  ;  3d  ed.,  Arnheim,  1617  ; 
8th  and  last  ed.,  Herbomae,  1654.  His  other 
works  are  :  Jurisprudentia  Bomana,  Herbomae, 
1588  ;  Dicceologicce  lihri  tres  totum  et  univer- 
sum  jus,  quo  utimur,  methodice  complectentes,  Her- 
bomae, 1617  ;  Fraucofurti,  1618.— See  Otto  Gierke, 
Johannes  Althiisiics  und  die  Entwicklung  der 
naturrechtlichen  Staatstheorien,  Breslau,  1880, 
and  Friedrich  Althaus,  Theodor  Althaus,  ein 
Lebensbild,  Bonn,  1888.  8.  b. 

ALTRUISM.  Altruism  is  an  ethical  term 
which  is  often  used  in  economic  discussions  on 
Socialism,  Laissez  -  Faire,  the  functions  of 
government,  and  generally  questions  of  distribu- 
tion. Altruism  is  the  opposite  of  indi\adualism 
or  egoism,  and  embraces  those  moral  motives 
which  induce  a  man  to  regard  the  interests  of 
others.  Most  English  economists  have  ^v^itten 
with  the  "regulative  idea"  that  self-interest 
should  at  least  provisionally  and  hypothetically 
be  regarded  as  the  mainspring  of  economic 
activity.  In  recent  times,  however,  the  tend- 
ency, especially  under  German  influences,  has 
been  to  give  more  weight  to  altruistic  impulses. 

[Compare  Dr.  Sidgwick's  Principles  of  Political 
Economy,  bk.  iii.  ch.  ii. — and  Prof.  Marshall, 
Principles  of  Economics,  bk.  i.  ch.  vi.]      j.  s.  N. 

AMANA  SOCIETY,  The,  a  communistic 
society  and  religious  sect  ( JVahre  Inspirations 
Gemeinden),  consisting  of  Germans,  established 
at  Amana,  Iowa  Co.,  Iowa,  U.S.A.  More  than 
a  century  after  its  foundation  in  Germany  the 
sect,  in  1843,  emigrated  to  Ebenezer  near 
Buffalo,  and  there  adopted  communism.  The 
society  thus  formed  eventually  removed  to 
Amana,  where  it  still  (1890)  exists  (see  Com- 
munism). E.  c. 

AMERCEMENTS.  The  mediaeval  history 
of  pecuniary  penalties  possesses  an  economical  as 
well  as  a  legal  interest.  Even  in  the  royal 
courts  of  justice  the  decision  of  criminal  or 


civil  causes  was  not  the  sole  object  aimed  at. 
For  it  was  also  the  duty  of  the  court  to  assess 
and  account  for  tlie  various  fines  and  amerce- 
ments found  to  be  leviable  in  the  course  of  the 
sitting.  These  payments  form  a  regular  portion 
of  the  issues  of  the  County,  and  are  duly  ac- 
counted for  by  the  sheriff  at  the  exchequer. 
Their  amount  was  limited  by  the  clause  of  the 
Great  Charter  declaring  that  no  free  man  shall 
be  amerced  except  according  to  the  measure  of 
his  offence,  and  protecting  from  seizure  the 
freeman's  house  and  household  goods  and  the 
villein's  wainage.  The  local  seigneurial  juris- 
dictions imitated  the  royal  courts  in  making  a 
free  use  of  pecuniary  penalties,  but  there  is 
reason  to  believe  that  the  amercements  in- 
flicted by  them  were  of  a  far  more  extortionate 
character.  The  clause  in  Magna  Charta  gave 
little  or  no  protection  to  the  Villein,  and  the 
Steward  or  Rkevk  who  presided  in  these  local 
courts,  naturally  found  their  chief  interest  in 
raising  as  much  money  as  possible  by  way  of 
"profits  of  the  court,"  a  regular  item  in 
manorial  accounts.  A  glance  through  Prof. 
Maitland's  Select  Pleas  in  Manoi'ial  Courts 
brings  out  the  fact  that  the  regular  punishment 
for  manorial  offences,  such  as  bad  ploughing,  or 
not  coming  to  wash  the  lord's  sheep,  was  an 
amercement,  amounting  in  some  cases  to  a 
tax  of  6s.  8d.  on  the  township.  Besides  this,  fines 
were  levied  for  breaking  the  Assize  of  Beer, 
for  trespassing  on  the  lord's  wood,  for  fighting, 
and  for  a  large  number  of  other  reasons.  The 
amount  of  these  must  frequently  have  been 
burdensome.  The  oppressive  reeve  is  expressly 
reproved  in  the  Ayenhit  oflnwyt  (written  1340)  ; 
in  his  Parsons  Tale  Chaucer  devotes  a  long 
passage  to  the  blame  of  extortionate  amerce- 
ments ;  and  the  same  tone  can  be  noticed  in 
Piers  Ploughman,  passus  ix.  (C.  text)  and  in 
Wyclif  s  writings. 

{Select  Pleas  in  Manorial  Courts,  vol.  i.,  edited 
for  the  Selden  Society  by  F.  W.  Maitland,  1889. 
— Chaucer's  Canterbury  Pilgrims  ;  The  Parson's 
Tale,  1386.  The  Vision  of  Piers  Ploughman,  text 
C.  passus  ix.  1393,  Early  English  Text  Society. 
—  Unpublished  English  Works  of  Wyclif,  Early 
English  Text  Society,  1880.]  c.  g.  c. 

AMERICAN  SCHOOL  OF  POLITICAL 
ECONOMY.  Stiictly  speaking,  an  American 
school  of  political  economy  has  not  yet  arisen, 
but  two  movements  are  sometimes  referred 
to  under  that  title :  (1)  In  the  strong  pro- 
tective agitation  which  began  in  the  United 
States  about  1820,  the  name  "American  system" 
was  applied  to  the  general  policy  of  developing 
the  resources  of  the  country  by  high  import 
duties  on  the  one  hand,  and  by  extensive  in- 
ternal improvements  on  the  other.  But  the 
phrase  obviously  points  to  an  episode  in  political 
history  rather  than  to  a  movement  in  political 
economy.  The  best  advocacy  of  this  American 
system  is  to  be  found  in  the  speech  of  Henry 


38 


AMOETISATION— ANARCHISM 


Clay  on  the  tariff,  made  in  1824,  easily  to  be 
found  in  the  various  editions  of  his  writings. 
(2)  With  more  propriety,  the  term  American 
school  may  be  applied  to  the  doctrines  of  Henry 

C.  Carey  (g.-y.)  and  his  followers.  The  rejection 
of  the  Ricardian  doctrine  of  rent  and  of  Ihe 
Malthusian  theory,  the  general  optimism,  the 
reference  of  value  in  all  instances  to  cost  of  pro- 
duction, the  advocacy  of  protection,  are  easily 
seen  to  be  connected  with  the  conditions  of  a 
new  country  possessed  of  abundant  fertile  land, 
rapidly  increasing  in  population  and  wealth, 
confronted  as  yet  by  few  of  the  difficulties  that 
beset  older  communities,  constantly  varying  and 
develo])ing  its  industries  as  time  passes  on. 
Carey's  doctrines  in  this  sense  are  American ; 
and  are  the  most  distinctively  national  contribu- 
tion which  the  United  States  has  yet  made  to 
economic  literature.     Among  his  followers  are  : 

Erasmus Peshine  Smith,  A  Manualof  Political  Economy, 
Philadelphia,  1852,  and  later  editions.— William  Elder, 
Questions  ofthf.  Day,  Philadelphia,  1871.— Robert  Ellis 
Thompson,  Social  Science  and  National  Economy,  Phila- 
delphia, 1875,  and  later  editions ;  Protection  to  Home 
Industry,  New  York,  1886.— W.  D.  Kelley,  Speeches, 
Letters,  and  Addresses,  Philadelphia,  1872.         f.  w.  t. 

Among  otlier  writers  of  great  ability  space  only  allows 
Tis  to  name,  C.  F.  Adams,  J.  Davidson,  C.  P.  Dunbar, 
F.  A.  Walker.  D.  A.  Wells,  H.  C.  Adams,  J.  B.  Clark, 

D.  R  Dewey,  R.  T.  Ely,  C.  Gross,  A.  T.  Hadley,  J.  W. 
Jenks,  S.  N.  Patten,  B.  R.  A.  Seligman,  and  F.  W. 
Taussig. 

AMORTISATION,  or  Amortization.  The 
financial  signification  of  amortisation  is  the 
redemption,  reimbursement,  liquidation,  or  re- 
payment of  debt  generally,  and  the  term  is 
often  applied  in  connection  with  the  sinking 
funds  of  mortgages  and  debentures.  Thus,  in 
the  recent  rearrangement  of  the  Venezuelan  debt 
we  read,  "  the  surplus  applicable,  after  covering 
the  interest,  to  amortisation  shall  be  applied 
half-yearly,"  etc.,  and  in  the  instance  of  one  of 
the  Buenos  Ayres  loans — "  the  government  have 
the  power  to  at  any  period  increase  the  amount 
of  the  amortisation."  But  the  word  is  much 
more  often  used  in  French  finance.  Thus  M. 
Waddington  wrote  to  Messrs.  Rothschild  on 
28th  October  1878,  "nous  declinons  toute  re- 
sponsabilite  relativement  au  paiement  del'interet 
et  de  I'araortissement  de  I'emprunt  prqjete." 
The  French  expressions  "fonds  d'amortisse- 
ment"  (sinking  funds)  and  "caisse  d'amortisse- 
meut "  (sinking  fund  office)  are  in  common  use. 
But  here,  in  the  sense  of  the  amortisation  of 
loans,  the  operation  can  be  treated  more  in  de- 
tail under  the  head  of  Sinking  Fund   (q.v.) 

In  law  amortisation  signifies  the  transfer  of 
lands  to  a  corporation,  Gild,  or  charitable  body 
in  perpetuity,  or  in  other  words,  an  alienation 
in  mortmain.  The  laws  in  force  restricting 
such  amortisation  of  property  in  perpetuity  are 
recounted  under  Mortmain  (q.v.) 

AMSTERDAM,  Bank  of.  See  Banks, 
Early  European. 

ANALYTICAL  METHOD.     We  employ  an 


analytical  method  in  science  when  we  commence 
with  particular  facts,  and,  by  analysing  them, 
discover  the  laws  in  operation,  thus  working  up 
to  general  principles  ;  we  employ  a  Synthetic 
Method  when  we  commence  with  general  prin- 
ciples, known  or  assumed,  and  combine  them 
so  as  to  obtain  conclusions  that  serve  to  explain 
particular  facts.  In  the  one  case,  we  proceed 
from  the  individual  to  the  universal ;  in  the 
other,  from  the  universal  to  the  individual. 
In  political  economy  one  of  the  main  contro- 
versies as  to  method  turns  on  this  distinction. 
It  is  maintained,  on  the  one  hand,  that  our 
starting-point  should  be  the  analysis  of  complex 
industrial  phenomena  ;  it  is  affirmed,  on  the 
other  hand,  that  the  science  should  be  con- 
structed by  deductive  reasoning  from  elementary 
laws  of  human  nature. 

In  reality  the  contrast  here  indicated  is  far 
too  sharply  drawn.  A  true  economic  science 
can  be  built  up  only  by  a  method  of  combined 
analysis  and  synthesis.  The  former  without  the 
latter  would  yield  merely  empirical  results  of 
uncertain  validity,  and  disconnected  with  one 
another.  The  latter  without  the  former  would 
yield  results  always  hypothetical,  and  sometimes 
entirely  renfote  from  the  actual  facts  of  the 
economic  world.  Hence  the  synthetical  method 
is  required  to  rationalise  and  systematise  con- 
clusions gained  by  the  method  of  analysis,  and 
the  analytical  method  is  in  its  turn  required  to 
guide  and  give  reality  to  the  synthetical.  It 
may  be  said  that  upon  this  point,  thus  broadly 
stated,  economists  are,  generally  speaking,  com- 
ing to  agreement.  At  the  same  time,  some  differ- 
ence of  opinion  is  always  likely  to  remain  in 
regard  to  the  relative  importance  of  the  two 
methods  in  economic  science,  and  the  extent  to 
which,  at  different  stages  of  inquiry,  each  should 
in  its  turn  be  subordinated  to  the  other.  In 
the  last  resort,  some  latitude  must  be  left  to 
the  natural  intellectual  bias  of  the  individual 
investigator.  For  further  discussion  of  this 
question,  see  Deductive  Method  ;  Inductive 
Method.  j.  n.  k. 

ANARCHISM  is  the  theory  held  by  a  party 
which  denies  the  justice  and  expediency  of  both 
government  and  property,  and  tries  to  over- 
throw these  institutions  by  violence.  At  the 
peace  congress  of  Geneva  in  1867,  Michael 
Bakounin  (q.v.),  a  Russian  exile,  advocated  the 
abolition  of  centralised  states,  and  the  substitu- 
tion of  voluntary  federations  of  independent 
communes.  He  urged  the  next  congress,  held 
at  Berne  under  the  presidency  of  Victor  Hugo  in 
1868,  to  declare  in  favour  of  socialism,  and  join 
the  International  (q.v.)  Failing  to  convince 
the  assembly,  he  formed  his  supporters  into  a 
'*  Social  Democratic  Alliance,"  the  aim  of  which 
was  to  make  land  and  capital  the  collective 
property  of  society,  and  secure  that  they  should 
be  used  only  by  agricultural  and  manufacturing 
associations.     All  existing  states  were  to  "  dis- 


ANARCHISM— ANDERSON 


39 


appear  in  the  universal  union  of  free  associations." 
The  Alliance  desired  to  be  recognised  as  part  of 
the  International,  but  its  claim  was  rejected, 
whereupon  it  dissolved  after  six  months'  ex- 
istence, during  which  it  had  been  active  in 
Spain  and  Italy,  and  its  sections  joined  the 
International  separately.  At  the  beginning  of 
1869  the  groups  of  the  International  in  French- 
speaking  Switzerland  organised  themselves  as 
the  **  Romance  Federation."  This  speedily  split 
into  two  sections,  one  of  which,  under  James 
Guillaume,  a  disciple  of  Bakounin,  became  the 
"Federation  of  the  Jura."  Bakounin,  Guil- 
laume, and  shortly  afterwards  the  whole  Fed- 
eration, were  expelled  from  the  International. 
The  Federation  did  not  acquiesce  in  its  expul- 
sion, but  held  meetings  in  1873,  1874,  1876, 
and  1877,  which  professed  to  be  the  sixth, 
seventh,  eighth,  and  ninth  general  meetings  of 
the  International.  To  its  influence  Prince 
Kropotkin,  in  1882,  ascribed  the  greater  part 
of  the  gi'owth  of  anarchist  opinions  in  France 
and  elsewhere.  As  early  as  at  the  meeting  of 
1873,  Brousse  said  incidentally  "anarchy  is 
your  progi-amme,"  but  it  was  not  till  five  or 
six  years  afterwards  that  the  "anarchists" 
became  definitely  known  by  that  name,  and 
ceased  to  rank  as  collectivists  (see  Collectiv- 
ism). In  August  1882,  a  meeting  held  at 
Geneva  for  the  express  purpose  of  making  clear 
"the  separation  of  the  anarchist  party  from  all 
political  parties,"  issued  a  manifesto  which 
declared  the  enmity  of  "  anarchists,  that  is  men 
without  chiefs,"  to  all  who  have,  or  wish  to 
get  power — to  the  lando%vner,  the  capitalist 
employer,  the  state,  "abstractions  of  authority," 
such  as  God  and  the  Devil,  and  "the  law, 
always  made  for  the  oppression  of  the  weak  by 
the  strong."  "We  declare  ourselves  allies  of 
every  man,  group,  or  society  which  denies  the 
law  by  a  revolutionary  act.  We  reject  all 
legal  methods.  .  .  We  spurn  the  suffrage 
called  universal.  .  .  We  wish  to  remain  our 
own  masters.  .  .  Nevertheless  we  know  that 
individual  liberty  cannot  exist  without  associa- 
tion with  other  free  comrades.  .  .  .  Every 
social  product  is  a  result  of  collective  work  to 
which  all  are  equally  entitled.  We  are  there- 
fore communists  ;  wo  recognise  that  without 
the  destruction  of  family,  communal,  provincial, 
and  national  boundaries,  the  work  will  always 
have  to  be  done  over  again. "  The  idea  of  making 
the  commune  the  basis  of  a  social  reorganisation 
was  a  mere  Russian  importation  (see  ]\Iir),  which 
never  obtained  any  hold  on  western  minds,  and 
may  have  been  discredited  by  the  failure  of  the 
Commune  of  Paris  (q.v.)  to  establish  its  inde- 
pendence. The  "free  association,"  which  has 
taken  the  place  of  the  commune,  has  acquired 
no  definite  shape.  Anarchists  are  content  to 
believe  that  every  one  would  behave  properly 
if  governments  with  their  forcible  methods 
were  abolished.      They  are  not  satisfied  with 


watching  or  even  with  accelerating  the  gradual 
elimination  of  force  which  marks  the  progress 
of  civilisation,  but  insist  on  the  immediate 
extinction  of  force  by  force. 

Bakounin  died  in  1876  ;  the  chief  agitators 
who  have  carried  on  his  work  are  Prince 
Kropotkin,  Elisee  Reclus,  and  Emile  Gautier  in 
Switzerland  and  France,  and  Most,  editor  of 
the  Freiheit  newspaper  among  Germans,  first  in 
England,  and  afterwards  in  America  (see  Com- 
munism ;  Socialism  ;  Nihilism  ;  Proudhon). 

[J.  Garin,  L'Anarchie  et  les  Anarchistes,  1885. 
— E.  de  Laveleye,  Le  Socialisme  Contemporain,  3™* 
ed.  1885,  ch.  ix.  x. — Elisee  Reclus,  "Anarchy" 
in  the  Contemporary  Review,  May  1884  (xlv.  pp. 
627-641,  especially  635,  636).— John  Rae,  Con- 
temporary Socialism,  1884. — Prince  Kropotkin, 
"  The  Scientific  Bases  of  Anarchy,"  in  the  Niiie- 
teenth  Century,  February  1887  (xxi.  pp.  238-252, 
especially  242). — "The  Coming  Anarchy,"  Ihid., 
August  1887  (xxii.  pp.  149-164).— R.  T.  Ely, 
Recent  American  Socialism  [Johns  Hopkins  Uni- 
versity Studies,  3d  Series,  No.  4),  April  1885. — 
Wm.  Godwin's  PoliticalJustice,  1793,  is  to  a  great 
extent  an  antici})ation  of  the  anarchist  theory.] 
(See  also  Socialism  in  App.)  e.  c. 

ANATOCISJNIUS.  A  term  employed  in  the 
technical  language  of  the  civil  law  for  compound 
interest.  The  Roman  law  did  not  allow  com- 
pound interest  and  even  prevented  a  creditor 
from  claiming  an  accumulation  of  simple  interest 
in  so  far  as  it  exceeded  the  amount  of  the 
principal.  E.  s. 

ANDERSON,  Adam,  bora  in  Scotland  about 
1692,  was  for  forty  years  a  clerk  in  the  South 
Sea  House.  He  died  at  Clerkenwell,  10th  Janu- 
ary 1765.      His  only  work  was — 

An  Historical  and  Chronological  Deduction  of 
the  Origin  of  Commerce  from  the  Earliest  A  ccounts 
to  the  Present  Time,  London,  1764,  2  vols,  folio 
(a  monument  of  industry  in  the  form  of  annals, 
treating  specially  of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland). 
A  new  edition,  carefully  revised  and  coJitinued  (by 
Wm.  Combe),  London,  1787-89,  4  vols.  4to. 
Anderson's  text  from  1492  to  1760,  was  incorpor- 
ated by  David  Macpherson  in  his  Annals  of 
Commerce,  London,  1805,  4  vols.  4to.      H.  R.  T. 

ANDERSON,  James,  LL.D.,  born  at  Hermis- 
ton,  near  Edinburgh,  1739,  died  at  West  Ham, 
Essex,  15th  October  1808.  A  practical  farmer, 
employed  by  Pitt  to  survey  the  fisheries,  Scot- 
tish rural  economy  owes  much  to  him.  Dr. 
Anderson  first  propounded  the  theory  of 
"rent,"  afterwards  rehandled  by  Malthus 
and  RiCARDO.  In  his  works,  e.g.  in  his  Obser- 
vations on  the  National  Industry  of  Scotland 
(vol.  ii.  pp.  208-9,  published  1779,  but  written 
1775),  he  says  that  rent  is  a  premium  for  the 
cultivation  of  the  richer  soils,  reducing  the 
profits  of  the  cultivators  to  an  equality  with 
those  of  the  cultivators  of  the  poorer. 

He  edited  The  Bee,  Edinburgh,  1790-94, 18  vols. 
8vo  ; — Recreations  in  Agriculture,  Natural  His' 
t&ry,  etc.,  1799-1802,  6  vols.  8vo,  and  wrote  among 


40 


ANDERSON— ANNUITY 


other  things  : — Inquiry  into  the  Nature  of  the  Corn 
Laws,  vnth  a  View  to  the  new  Corn  Bill  proposed 
for  Scotland,  Edinburgh,  1777,  8vo  (the  earliest 
explanation  of  the  theory  of  rent  usually  called 
after  Ricardo  ;  see  also  his  Recreations,  v.  401-28). 
— Inquiry  into  the  Causes  that  have  hitherto  Re- 
tarded the  Advancement  of  Agriculture  in  Eurbpe, 
Edinburgh,  1779,  Svo. — Account  of  the  Present 
State  of  the  Hebrides  and  Western  Coasts  of  Scot- 
land, Edinburgh,  1785,  8vo. — Essays  Relating  to 
Agriculture  and  Rural  Affairs,  5th  ed.,  London, 
1800,  3  vols.  8vo. — Investigation  of  the  Circum- 
stances that  have  led  to  the  Present  Scarcity  of 
Grain  in  Britain,  London,  1801,  Svo  (friendly  to 
protection).  H.  R.  T. 


ANDERSON,  James  (No.  2). 
such  as  Observations  on  the  National  Industry 
of  Scotland  (vol.  ii.  pp.  208-209,  published 
1779,  but  written  1775)  show  clearly  that 
Anderson  had  a  more  correct  view  of  the  theory 
of  rent  than  his  greater  contemporary  and 
compatriot,  A.  Smith.  Rent,  he  says,  is  a 
premium  for  the  cultivation  of  the  richer 
soils,  reducing  the  profits  of  the  cultivators  to 
an  equality  with  those  of  the  cultivators  of  the 
poorer.  j.  b. 

ANGARIE,  Droit  d'  {ayyapeia,  see  St. 
Matthew  v.  41).  Angarie  means  in  interna- 
tional law  the  actual  impressment  of  foreign 
(even  neutral)  vessels,  as  distinguished  from 
embargo,  which  is  mere  exclusion  from  the 
ports.  The  right  was  exercised  by  the  Prus- 
sians in  the  war  of  1870-71,  when  they  sank 
six  English  ships  in  the  Seine.  j.  b. 

ANGEL.  English  gold  coin  (Edward  IV.  to 
Charles  I.)  of  the  following  weights,  fineness, 
and  value — 


Value  in 

A  ■ 

Fine- 

gold 916-6, 

Reign. 

Year. 

Rating. 

bO 

fine  at 

1 

ness. 

£3  :  17  :  lOJ 

1     an  oz.      1 

grains. 

Edward  IV. 

1466 

6s.  8d. 

85-25 

994-8 

153. 

Henry  VIII. 

1527 

7s.  6d. 

80 

14s.  Id, 

>i 

1543 

8s. 

" 

916-6 

12s.  ll|d. 

Edward  VI. 

1551 

j^ 

" 

994-8 

14s.  Id. 

Mary 

1553 

lOs. 

Elizabeth 

1601 

79 

13s'' lid. 

James  I. 

1605 

„ 

71 

12s.  6d. 

„ 

1606 

,, 

65-5 

lis.  6^d, 

t. 

1610 

lis. 

1619 

,, 

64-25 

lls."3|d. 

Charles  I. 

1627 

lOs. 

" 

>> 

F.  E.  A. 

ANNA  (British  India).  One  sixteenth  of 
a  rupee.  Silver  coins:  4  and  2  annas,  916 '6 
fine  ;  weight  45  and  22^  grains  ;  value  6|d. 
and  S^d.,  or  "59  fr.  and  -30  fr.  respectively. 

F.  E.  A. 

ANNATES.  This  was  the  first  year's 
revenue  of  a  bishopric  or  benefice  which  was 
paid  to  the  pope  in  all  countries  which  acknow- 
ledged his  spiritual  headship.  It  is  probable 
that  the  practice  was  not  introduced  into  Eng- 


land until  after  1213,  when  John  did  homage 
to  the  papacy.  This  and  other  papal  exactions 
were  very  unpopular  in  England,  and  the  clergy 
themselves  petitioned  for  the  abolition  of  an- 
nates, when  Henry  VIII.  quarrelled  with  the 
pope  about  his  divorce.  A  bill  for  this  purpose 
was  passed  by  parliament  in  1532,  but  Henry 
postponed  his  consent,  hoping  to  use  it  as  a 
means  of  influencing  the  Roman  court.  In 
1534,  however,  the  Annates  Act  became  law. 
Besides  prohibiting  the  payment  to  Rome,  this 
Act  also  laid  down  the  regulations  for  the  choice 
of  bishops  which  are  still  observed.  To  the 
great  disappointment  of  the  clergy,  the  annates, 
instead  of  being  abolished,  were  transferred  to 
the  crown.  Mary  surrendered  them,  but  they 
were  restored  to  the  crown  under  Elizabeth. 
Ultimately  Anne  gave  them  back  to  the  church, 
in  order  to  subsidise  small  livings,  and  the  fund 
still  exists  under  the  name  of  Queen  Anne's 
bounty. 

[Perry,  History  of  the  English  Church,  1887, 
vol.  ii.]  R.  L. 

ANNEALING.  Most  metals  and  alloys,  when 
submitted  to  the  operations  of  rolling  or  wire 
drawing,  lose  their  malleability  or  power  of 
being  extended.  This  may  be  restored  by  cm- 
n^aling,  which  consists  in  raising  the  metal  to 
a  high  temperature,  usually  above  redness,  and 
allowing  it  to  cool  slowly.  With  some  metals 
it  is  immaterial  whether  the  cooling  from  the 
high  temperature  takes  place  rapidly  or  slowly. 
Thus  certain  alloys  of  copper  and  tin  are  ren- 
dered most  malleable  by  rapid  cooling  and  the 
same  observation  applies  to  alloys  of  iron  and 
manganese  which  contain  more  than  8  per  cent 
of  manganese.  In  the  preparation  of  steel  for 
industrial  use  annealing  is  of  great  importance, 
and  the  particular  temperature  suitable  to  each 
variety  of  steel  has  to  be  determined  with  great 
accuracy.  The  density  of  rolled  metals  is  gener- 
ally diminished  slightly  by  annealing.  The  pro- 
cess is  of  importance  in  the  coinage  of  the 
precious  metals  (see  Alloy).  c.  r-a. 

ANNUAL  RENT  (Scotch).  Nearly  equiva- 
lent to  rent  charge. 

ANNUITY.  The  simplest  way  in  which  an 
annuity  can  be  defined  from  an  economic  point 
of  view  is  to  regard  it  as  p  payment  in  one  in- 
stalment, or  in  any  number  of  instalments, 
composed  (1)  of  the  sinking  fund  to  redeem  or 
restore  the  principal  or  purchase  money  of  the 
annuity  by  an  investment  increasing  at  interest 
in  geometrical  progression ;  and  (2)  of  the  interest 
on  the  principal  or  purchase  money  and  its  un- 
redeemed balances  throughout  the  term  of  the 
annuity,  such  interest  decreasing  in  geometrical 
progression  until  the  sinking  fund  replaces  the 
whole  of  the  principal  or  purchase  money. 
Thus,  if  an  annuity  of  £100  for  one  year  be 
bought  to  pay  3  per  cent  interest,  it  is  worth 
£97*0874  purchase  money,  and  the  annuity 
itself  is  made  up  : — 


ANNUITY 


41 


(1)  Of  the  present  value  at  3  per  cent 

interest  of  the  sum  of  £100,  due 
at  the  end  of  one  year,  or  of  a 
sinking  fund  of       .         .         . 

(2)  Of  the  interest  at  3  per  cent  for 

one  year  on  the  £97-0874  pur- 
chase money   .... 


£97-0874 


2-9126 


Total  annuity 


.  £100-0000 


The  value  of  each  instalment  for  any  term  of 
years  for  which  an  annuity  is  gi-anted,  may  be 
similarly  calculated  ;  thus,  the  value  at  3  per 
cent  interest  of  an  annuity  of  £100  per  annum 
to  endure  in  perpetuity  or  for  an  infinite  number 
of  years,  may  be  stated  in  the  same  manner  as 
made  up : — 

(1)  Of  the  present  valueof  £3333-3333 

(or  of  the  purchase  money  at  3 
per  cent  of  a  perpetual  annuity 
of  £100)  redeemable  at  the  end 
of  an  infinite  number  of  years     £000-0000 

(2)  Of  the  annual  interest  at  3  per 

cent    upon    the    £3333-3333 

purchase  money       .         .         .      100-0000 


Total  annuity 


.  £100-0000 


In  any  scheme  of  taxation  which  deducts  a 
percentage,  or  so  much  in  the  pound,  upon  the 
whole  or  gross  amount  of  an  annuity,  without 
distinguishing  between  what  part  of  it  is  sink- 
ing fund  and  what  part  interest,  the  result  is 
that  the  fiscal  burden  infringes  on  property  as 
well  as  on  income,  although  in  ordinary  language 
this  common   mode  of  procedure  is  called   an 
income-tax.      If  it  were  so  purely  and  truly,  it 
would,  in  the  first  of  the  above  examples,  make 
a  deduction  for  tax,  not  upon  the  whole  £100 
of  annuity,  but  upon  £2-9126  only,  so  that  the 
exaction  is  more  than   thirty-three   times   too 
great.     In  the  second  example  the  tax  is  rightly 
levied  upon  the  whole  £100  of  annuity,  as  there 
is  no  possible  existence  of  a  sinking  fund  where 
the  term  the  annuity  has  to  run  is  infinite.     It 
follows  that  the  shorter  such  term  is  the  greater 
is  the  inequity  of  assessment,  and  the  longer 
the  term  the  less  its  inequity.     So  much  has 
this  been  felt  by  those  who  purchase  annuities 
or  rent  charges  by  way  of  equated   payments 
continuing  for  a  given  number  of  years,  that  it 
is  not  uncommon  for  purchasers  of  such  annui- 
ties, or  lenders  of  money  on  their  security,  to 
contract  themselves  out  of  the  incidence  of  the 
Income  tax  on  that  part  of  the  annual  payment 
which  represents  Sinking  Fund.     This  is  done 
by  the  annuity  or  mortgage-deed  containing  a 
schedule  setting  forth  in  separate  columns  what 
is  sinking  fund  and  what  is  interest.     Thus, 
for  example,  in  an  annuity  of  £100  gi-anted  for 
two  years  and  calculated  to  pay  the  purchaser 
3  per  cent,  the  value  or  purchase  money  of  this 
18,*  by  calculation,  £191*3470.     The  schedule 
runs  thus : 


Col.  1. 
Year. 

Col.  2. 

Repayment 

of  Piuehase 

Money. 

Interest  on 
Yearly  Balance      g; 
of  Purchase         '^ 
Money. 

Col.  4. 

'H 

1  .          .          . 

2  .         .          . 

Total  payments 

£94-2596 
97-0874 

£5-7404 
2-91-26 

£100- 
100- 

£191-3470 

£8-6530 

£200- 

By  this  means  income-tax  becomes  assessable 
in  the  two  years  upon  £8-6530  instead  of  upon 
£200. 

The  same  methods  of  analysis  of  an  annuity 
ceasing  at  the  death  of  a  single  lite  or  of  the 
survivor  of  any  number  of  lives,  could  be  applied 
so  as  to  distinguish  between  capital  and  income, 
and  the  sinking  fund  and  interest  admit  of 
being  similarly  separated  and  defined  from  the 
initial  year  or  age  at  which  the  life-annuity 
commences  to  its  ultimate  or  terminal  year, 
which,  in  such  cases,  is  tlie  oldest  age  to  which 
it  is  possible  tlie  life  or  lives  can  attain,  accord- 
ing to  the  particular  table  of  mortality  on  which 
the  annuity  is  based  or  valued. 

From  what  has  been  above  stated  several  im- 
portant economic  conclusions  follow — (1)  that 
wlien  a  state  borrows  money  by  grant  or  sale 
of  Terminable  Annuities  ceasing  at  the  ex- 
piration of  a  certain  number  of  years,  long  or 
sliort,  and  its  fiscal  system  at  the  same  time 
includes  the  imposition  of  what  is  called  an 
income-tax,  such  a  tax  falls  upon  the  whole  of 
the  capital  out  of  which  the  annuity  is  consti- 
tuted, and  the  tax  becomes  one  on  property  as 
well  as  on  income  ;  (2)  that  although  the  system 
of  borrowing  on  terminable  as  compared  with 
that  of  borrowing  on  perpetual  annuities  has 
been  frequently  extolled  as  the  more  provident 
and  beneficial  of  the  two  arrangements,  it  is 
really  subject  to  much  qualification,  as  it  involves 
in  every  instance  an  obligatory  sinking  fund, 
which  cannot  be  suspended,  for  the  repayment 
of  principal.  This  must  continue  for  the  whole 
of  the  term  of  years  the  annuities  have  to  run, 
during  which  the  borrower  (and  few  modern 
states  fail  to  be  in  that  position  over  many 
years)  is  hampered  with  the  prejudicial  condition 
of  having  to  borrow  to  pay  debts,  a  course 
generally  antagonistic  to  the  principles  of  sound 
finance  ;  (3)  that  as  in  these  terminable  annui- 
ties the  state  as  borrower  repays  portions  of 
principal  combined  with  every  payment  of  in- 
terest, the  state  creditor,  small  as  well  as  great, 
is,  in  his  turn,  compelled  to  reinvest,  periodi- 
cally and  with  undeviating  regularity,  fractions 
of  the  principal  returned  to  him,  unless  he  be 
content  to  see  his  capital  destroyed.  This 
liecessity  of  re-investment  is  a  troublesome,  and 
sometimes  a  difficult,  task,  and  has  a  tendency 


42 


ANSELL— ANTI-RENT  AGITATIONS 


towards  improvidence  on  the  lender's  part,  as 
it  exposes  him  to  the  temptation  of  omitting  to 
save  the  means  by  which  he  may  restore  his 
capital ;  (4)  the  knowledge  of  these  circum- 
stances and  the  unfair  incidence  of  the  income- 
tax  on  terminable  annuities  combine  in  render- 
ing it  impossible,  as  a  general  rule,  for  large 
state  loans  to  be  contracted  at  as  low  a  rate  of 
interest  in  terminable  annuities  as  in  perpetual 
annuities.  The  market  price  of  the  Ibrmer  as 
compared  with  the  latter  has  in  almost  every 
known  instance  revealed  a  lower  public  estima- 
tion of  the  terminable  annuity,  and  it  has 
shown  that  as  the  repayment  of  the  principal 
augments  in  geometrical  proportion  with  each 
instalment,  the  depression  of  the  security  grows 
greater  and  greater  as  the  annuity  approaches 
nearer  and  nearer  to  its  terminal  period.  Out 
of  the  total  sum  of  about  585  millions  sterling 
raised  by  loans  in  England  in  1792-1816,  not 
more  than  1^  per  cent  can  be  estimated  to  have 
been  obtained  through  the  employment,  as  an 
adjunct  to  other  financial  methods,  of  the  ter- 
minable annuity  system.  The  remaining  98| 
per  cent  of  what  in  those  days  was  a  huge 
mountain  of  fresh  indebtedness,  was  raised  by 
perpetual  annuities.  The  terminable,  or  long 
annuities  as  they  were  called,  mostly  granted 
for  sixty  years,  were  only  floated  on  terms  of 
market  valuation  imposing  a  differential  and 
higher  rate  of  interest  on  the  borrower  of  at 
least  1  per  cent  as  compared  with  the  terms  for 
perpetual  annuities.  The  writer  of  the  present 
article  was  associated  with  the  late  Mr.  New- 
MAECH,  in  1854-55,  in  the  investigations  that 
served  as  the  basis  of  the  elaborate  essay  by 
that  economist  On  the  loans  raised  by  Mr. 
Pitt  during  the  first  French  War,  1793-1801, 
with  some  statements  in  defence  of  the  methods 
of  funding  employed.  London  :  Effingham 
Wilson,  1855  {vide  pp.  29-31).  This  essay 
has  now  become  extremely  scarce.  A  short 
paragraph  may  be  quoted  from  it  as  giving  the 
pith  of  a  very  laborious  inquiry.  "  Upon  mere 
financial  gi-ounds  a  public  loan  contracted  in 
terminable  annuities  is,  perhaps  for  the  state, 
the  form  of  borrowing  the  most  desirable,  for  at 
the  lapse  of  the  term  the  annual  burden  of  the 
debt  ceases.  But  connected  with  the  plan  of 
terminable  annuities  there  are  other  considera- 
tions of  a  higher  and  more  general  nature  than 
those  of  mere  finance  ;  and  when  the  whole 
question  has  to  be  discussed  it  will  appear, 
that  while  terminable  annuities  maybe  employed 
with  advantage  as  one  of  several  forms  of  fund- 
ing, it  would  be  exceedingly  unwise  to  resort  to 
them  as  the  sole  or  even  as  the  principal 
method."  See  Terminable  Annuities  ; 
National  Debt.  f.  h. 

ANSELL,  Chakles,  F.R.S.,  born  1794,  died 
1881.  He  entered  the  Atlas  Fire  and  Life  As- 
surance Company  in  1808,  became  actuary  of 
the  life  branch  in  1823,  and  held  the  office 


down  to  1864.  He  applied  himself  much  to 
the  actuarial  problems  connected  with  friendly 
societies,  and  wrote — 

A  Treatise  on  Friendly  Societies  in  which  the 
Doctrine  of  the  Interest  of  Money  artd  the  Doctrine 
of  Probability  are  applied,  London,  1835,  8vo 
(published  by  the  Society  for  the  Diffusion  of  Use- 
ful Knowledge  ;  one  of  the  first  attempts  to  treat 
the  subject  scientifically).  H.  R.  T. 

ANTEDATE.  To  date  a  document  from  a 
point  of  time  earlier  than  the  actual  date  of 
execution.  If  this  is  done  with  the  intention 
of  defrauding  a  third  party,  the  parties  to  the 
document  are  liable  to  be  prosecuted  for  forgery. 

E.  s. 

ANTICHRESIS.  A  contract  of  Roman 
law  by  which  a  mortgagee  acquired  the  right  to 
take  the  profits  of  the  mortgaged  property  in 
the  place  of  interest  on  the  mortgage  debt. 
Such  contracts  were  not  allowed,  if  they  were 
made  with  the  intention  of  evading  the  Roman 
usury  laws.  e.  s. 

ANTI-CORN-LAW  LEAGUE.  It  cannot 
be  doubted  that  the  irritation  caused  by  the 
agitation  for  the  factory  acts,  which  applied  to 
children  only  in  the  manufacturing  districts,  and 
not  to  tho^e  in  the  agricultural  part  of  the 
country,  supplied  a  great  stimulus  to  the  agita- 
tion against  the  corn  laws.  The  formation  of 
an  association  under  the  name  of  the  Anti-Com- 
Law  League  was  the  inevitable  consequence,  and 
apart  from  an  active  canvass  all  over  the  country, 
the  association  at  last  started  a  newspaper  of 
great  force  and  ability  under  the  name  of  the 
League,  complete  copies  of  which  are  now  very 
uncommon. 

The  success  of  the  League  was  in  great  degree 
assisted  by  the  potato  plague  and  the  very  scanty 
harvest  of  1845.  Sir  R.  Peel,  then  in  power, 
took  the  step  of  opening  the  ports,  an  expedient 
which  the  executive  had  frequently  adopted 
during  the  scarcities  of  the  18th  century. 
It  was  impossible  to  reverse  this  policy,  and 
the  repeal  of  the  corn  laws  became  inevitable 
in  the  next  session  of  parliament.  It  is  re- 
markable that  a  parliament  certainly  summoned 
to  defend  and  maintain  the  laws,  should  have 
been  the  instrument  of  extirpating  them,  but 
the  situation  could  not  be  trifled  with,  and 
Peel,  as  the  introducer,  said  that  his  action 
averted  the  troubles  of  1848  from  the  United 
Kingdom. 

As  soon  as  the  act  repealing  the  com  laws 
had  received  the  royal  assent,  the  leaders  of 
the  League  at  once  broke  up  their  organisation 
and  extinguished  the  machinery  which  they  had 
driven  at  high  pressure.  This  policy  was 
exceedingly  conciliatory,  and  greatly  assisted  in 
obviating  any  reaction.  j.  t.  r. 

ANTI-RENT  AGITATIONS.  The  phrase 
has  been  used  by  English  writers  with  special 
reference  to  the  movement  countenanced  by 
O'Connell   in    1843,   and  a  similar  movement 


ANTONINUS— APPLEtON 


43 


countenanced  by  some  of  the  Irish  leaders  in 
1881,  among  the  Irish  tenants.  In  both  cases 
the  threat  to  pay  no  rent  was  a  temporary 
expedient  to  enforce  an  article  of  popular 
policy.  The  advocates  of  the  nationalisation 
of  the  land  cannot  be  said  to  conduct  an  anti- 
rent  agitation,  for  they  do  not  aim  at  the  re- 
moval of  rent,  but  at  a  change  of  landlords. 
In  the  United  States  the  name  ' '  anti-renters  " 
was  given  to  the  farmers  of  New  York  State, 
holding  their  lands  on  long  leases,  who  de- 
manded the  removal  of  quit  rents  and  gi-ound 
rents  (1839-46).  The  movement  led  to  riot 
and  bloodshed  ;  and  was  at  the  time  only 
partially  successful,  though  now  the  system  of 
land-tenure  which  occasioned  it  has  all  but 
wholly  disappeared. 

See  E.  P.  Cheyuey,  The  Anti-rent  Agitation  of 
the  State  of  New  Fork,  Philadelphia,  1887.    J.  B. 

ANTONINUS,  St.,  archbishop  of  Florence, 
was  born  1389  and  died  1459.  Following 
Aquinas  (q.v.),  Antoninus  defines  what  transac- 
tions are  to  be  condemned  as  usury ;  and  remarks 
on  the  difficulty  of  determining  the  fair  price 
JusTUM  Pretium  of  an  article  on  sale.  See 
his  Summa  Theologica  in  quatuor  partem  clistri- 
buta,  2d  Part,  Title  II.  ch.  6,  7.  f.  y.  e. 

A  POSTERIORI  reasoning  is  reasoning  that 
is  directly  based  on  observation  and  inductive 
generalisation.  It  follows,  therefore,  and  does 
not  precede  experience  of  the  specific  class  of 
phenomena  to  which  the  conclusion  relates. 
The  kind  of  reasoning  with  which  it  is  con- 
trasted is  called  A  Pmoiii  (q.v.) 

It  is  held  by  the  majority  of  English 
economists  that  in  political  economy  the  purely 
a  posteriori  method  is  inefficacious  for  arriv- 
ing at  any  considerable  body  of  valuable 
truth.  The  opposite  view  is  maintained  by 
the  HisTOEicAL  School  of  Economists. 
Without  entering  here  upon  the  controversy 
between  these  schools,  it  may  be  pointed  out 

(1)  that  the  a  posteriori  method  is,  in  certain 
cases,  employed  even  by  those  who  for  the  most 
part  reject  its  aid  in  economic  reasoning  ;  and 

(2)  that   when  entire  reliance   is   not   placed 
'Upon  it,   it  may  still  be  used  to  supplement 

reasoning  of  a  different  type.  As  an  illustra- 
tion of  a  posteriori  reasoning  in  economics, 
reference  may  be  made  to  Mill's  treatment  of 
[the  subject  of  peasant  proprietorship  in  the 
[second  book  of  his  Principles  of  Political 
\Economy.  A  considerable  mass  of  evidence  is 
[cited  as  to  the  working  of  this  system  in  those 
I  countries  in  which  its  operation  can  be  observed 
Ion  a  large  scale  ;  and  the  force  of  Mill's  argu- 
iment  as  to  the  influence  of  peasant  properties 
>in  stimulating  industry,  training  intelligence, 
iand  promoting  forethought  and  self-control, 
[depends  more  upon  the  generalisations  that  the 
tabove  evidence  seems  to  justify,  than  upon 
[direct  deductions  from  general  principles  of 
Inhuman  nature. 


A  posteriori  reasoning  is  also  described  as 
analytical,  and  as  inductive.  For  further  discus- 
sion, see  Analytical  ;  Deductive  :  Induo 
TiVE  ;  Synthetic  Method.  j.  n.  k. 

APPANAGE  (French  apanage,  from  Pro- 
ven9al  verb  apanar,  to  give  bread),  the  provision 
made  by  French  kings  and  barons  for  daughters 
and  younger  sons  (puis-nes),  as  distinguished 
from  the  eldest  son  (aind  =  aisn6,  avant-n6). 
The  ap})anage  of  royal  princes  consisted  in  some 
cases  of  lands  so  extensive  and  wealthy  {e.g. 
Normandy  or  Burgundy)  that  the  possessors 
were  dangerous  rivals  to  the  monarch  himself, 
especially  as  the  salic  law  increased  their  pro- 
spects of  ultimate  succession  to  the  throne  ; 
hence  the  attempts  {e.g.  of  Charles  V.  in  14th 
century)  to  limit  the  appanage  of  sons  to  a 
specified  money  revenue  from  land.  As  early  as 
Philip  Augustus  (13th  century),  the  daughters' 
do^vries  were  paid  in  that  form.  From  St. 
Louis  downwards  (13th  century),  the  kings  tried 
to  secure  the  reversion  of  the  appanage  to  the 
crown  on  failure  of  male  heirs  ;  and  the  crown 
lands  ceased  in  point  of  fact  to  be  rediWded. 
Appanages  were  abolished  by  the  constituent 
assembly  in  1790,  and  the  burden  put  on  the 
civil  list ;  revived  by  Napoleon  and  the  Bour- 
bons, they  disappeared  definitively  in  the  re- 
volution of  July  1830. 

The  corresponding  provision  in  England  is 
an  annual  income  voted  by  parliament  out  of 
the  imperial  taxes  {e.g.  in  1889  for  the  Queen's 
grandchildren).  A  similar  course  is  followed 
in  Italy.  In  many  German  states  the  a])panage 
is  often  a  mere  rent-charge  on  crown-lands.  Tlie 
German  lawyers  of  last  century  confined  the 
term  apanagium  to  the  provision  in  money,  and 
used  paragium  for  provision  in  lands  (see  Civil 
List).  j.  b. 

APPLETON,  Nathan,  merchant  and  cotton 
manufacturer  ;  born  in  New  Hampshire  1779  ; 
died  in  Massachusetts  1861.  He  was  one  of  the 
three  founders  of  the  gi'eat  manufacturing  town 
of  Lowell ;  served  a  number  of  years  in  congi-ess, 
where  he  was  a  champion  of  Whig  principles. 
His  best  known  pamphlet  is  Pemarks  on  cur- 
rency and  banking,  Boston,  1841,  pp.  48  (3d 
ed.  1857,  pp.  63).  He  favoured  a  national  bank 
as  a  fiscal  agent  of  the  treasury,  but  denied  its 
necessity  to  regulate  the  currency,  equalise  the 
exchanges,  or  supply  a  uniform  paper  medium. 
He  also  ^vrote  An  examination  of  the  hanking 
system  of  Massachusetts  in  reference  to  the  renei'ial 
of  the  hank  charters,  Boston,  1831,  pp.  48. 
Appleton  objected  to  state  banks  with  small 
capitals  :  the  bank  should  have  a  paid-up  capital 
exceeding  its  issues  ;  and  the  tax  should  be 
upon  the  circulation  instead  of  upon  the  capital. 
He  persistently  advocated  high  tarifl"  duties  by 
speeches  in  congress  ;  of  these  the  one  of  30th 
May  1832  is  the  most  valuable,  in  which  he  criti- 
cised at  length  the  theory  that  a  tax  on  imports 
is  a  tax  on  exports.     In  an  article  on  Labour 


44 


APPLIED  ECONOMICS— APPORTIONMENT 


in  Europe  and  America  compared,  Hunt's  Maga- 
zine, 1844,  pp.  16,  he  denied  that  the  theory 
of  wages  as  stated  by  English  economists  applied 
to  American  labour,  owing  to  the  cheapness  of 
land.  A  list  of  his  writings  is  found  in  Robert 
C.  Winthrop's  Memoir  of  Nathan  Appleton, 
Boston,  1861,  pp.  64. 

Among  them  may  be  mentioned,  What  is  a 
Revenue  Standard  ?  and  a  Review  of  Secretary 
Walkers  Report,  1846. — Introduction  of  the 
Power-Loom  and  Origin  of  Lowell,  1858. 

D.  R.  D. 

APPLIED  ECONOMICS.  The  term  applied 
economics  or  applied  political  economy  has 
been  used  in  at  least  three  different  senses : 
(a)  To  designate  the  application  of  economic 
science  to  the  solution  of  practical  questions  ; 
in  this  sense  equivalent  to  what  is  also  called 
the  Art  of  Political  Economy,  {h)  To 
designate  the  application  of  economic  science 
to  the  interpretation  and  explanation  of  par- 
ticular economic  phenomena,  (c)  To  mark  off 
the  more  concrete  and  specialised  portions  of 
economic  science  from  those  more  abstract 
doctrines,  which  are  held  to  pervade  all 
economic  reasoning.  The  term  is  used  in  this 
last  sense  by  Jevons  when  he  remarks  that 
"  currency,  banking,  the  relations  of  labour  and 
capital,  those  of  landlord  and  tenant,  pauper- 
ism, taxation,  and  finance,  are  some  of  the 
principal  portions  of  applied  political  economy, 
all  involving  the  same  ultimate  laws,  manifested 
in  most  different  circumstances."  {Fortnightly 
Review,  Nov.  1876,  p.  626.)  J.  N.  k. 

APPORTIONMENT  (No.  1).  The  distribu- 
tion of  one  subject  in  proportion  to  another  pre- 
viously distributed.  Though  Rents  form  the 
chief  subject  matter  of  apportionment,  the  term 
is  also  applied  to  the  division  of  covenants  and 
conditions.  As  regards  rents  a  distinction  has 
to  be  drawn  between  rent  services  and  rent 
charges.  A  rent  service  may  be  apportioned 
by  (1)  act  of  God  ;  (2)  operation  of  law  ;'(3) 
act  of  parties.  (1)  Where  a  portion  of  land 
demised  is  surrounded  or  covered  by  the  sea, 
this  being  the  act  of  God,  the  rent  is  appor- 
tioned so  that  the  tenant  pays  rent  in  respect 
of  the  uncovered  land  only.  (2)  At  common 
law  there  could  be  no  apportionment  of  rent 
in  respect  of  time,  the  contract  for  payment 
being  regarded  as  "  entire,"  or  incapable 
of  division.  Hence  a  successor  in  interest 
succeeding  before  a  periodical  payment  became 
due  took  the  whole,  and  the  representatives 
of  his  predecessor  took  nothing.  This  was 
remedied  by  the  11  Geo.  II.  c.  19,  §  15 ; 
4  &  5  Will.  IV.  c.  22  ;  and  33  &  34  Vict. 
c.  35.  The  effect  of  these  statutes  is  that 
all  rents,  annuities,  dividends,  and  other 
periodical  payments  in  the  nature  of  income 
are  like  interest  on  money  lent,  to  be  re- 
garded as  accruing  from  day  to  day,  and  to 
be  apportionable  in  respect  of  time. 


(3)  Where  a  part  of  a  reversion  was  granted 
away,  an  apportioned  part  of  the  rent  passed 
with  it  as  incident  thereto.  By  the  22  &  23 
Vict.  c.  35,  §  3,  where  a  reversion  is  severed 
into  parts,  and  the  rent  is  "legally  appor- 
tioned," the  assignee  of  each  part  becomes 
entitled,  as  regards  his  part,  to  the  benefit  of 
all  conditions  for  securing  the  payment  of  rent 
attached  to  the  original  undivided  rent,  and 
the  10th  section  of  the  Conveyancing  Act,  1881, 
extends  this  principle,  and  renders  aU  con- 
ditions and  provisos  apportionable. 

As  regards  rent  charges,  the  general  rule  was 
that  they  could  not  be  apportioned,  and  hence 
if  the  owner  of  a  rent  charge  purchased  any 
portion  of  the  land  out  of  which  it  issued,  the 
whole  rent  charge  became  extinct.  This  was 
remedied  by  the  10th  section  of  the  22  &  23 
Vict.  c.  35,  which  provided  that  the  release 
from  a  rent  charge  of  a  part  of  the  land  charged, 
should  only  bar  the  right  to  recover  any  part 
of  the  rent  charge  out  of  the  land  released. 

[The  Law  of  Rents,  by  W.  A.  Copinger  and  J. 
E.  C.  Munro,  London,  1886.]  .    J.E.C.  M. 

APPORTIONMENT  (No.  2).  Apportionment 
may  be  further  explained  as  the  distribution  of 
benefits  or  burdens  connected  with  property 
among  several  persons  becoming  successively  or 
simultaneously  owners  of  the  property  to  which 
they  refer.  With  regard  to  successive  owners, 
rent  and  other  periodical  payments  were  for- 
merly not  apportionable.  If  land  was  leased 
for  the  life  of  the  tenant-for-life  only,  the  sub- 
tenant was  not  liable  to  pay  any  rent  for  the 
period  between  the  last  payment  and  the  death 
of  the  tenant-for-life.  If  the  lease  extended 
beyond  the  life  of  the  tenant-for-life,  and  if 
the  person  entitled  to  the  rent  for  life  died 
on  the  day  before  the  rent  became  due,  his 
representatives  could  not  claim  any  part  of  the 
rent,  and  the  whole  of  it  went  to  the  person 
next  entitled  to  the  income  of  the  land  ;  the 
same  thing  happened  with  respect  to  dividends 
on  stock,  or  annuities  to  which  a  person  was 
entitled  for  life.  Successive  acts  of  parliament, 
beginning  with  one  passed  in  the  reign  of 
George  II.,  have  gradually  removed  these 
anomalies,  and  now  the  Apportionment  Act  of 
1870  provides  that  all  rents,  dividends,  and 
periodical  payments  in  the  nature  of  income, 
shall  be  considered  as  accruing  from  day  to  day, 
and  shall  be  apportionable  in  respect  of  time 
accordingly.  Apportionment  of  benefits  or 
burdens  between  persons  becoming  simul- 
taneously owners  of  property  was  formerly  not 
possible  in  many  cases.  Rent -charges,  for 
instance,  were  not  apportionable,  and  if  the 
owner  of  a  Rent-Charge  purchased  part  of  the 
land  subject  to  it  (which  naturally  had  the 
ettect  of  releasing  that  part  from  the  rent- 
charge)  the  whole  property  became  discharged  ' 
in  the  same  way  the  benefits  of  conditions  of 
re-entry  and  other   conditions  in  leases  could 


APPRAISERS— APPRENTICESHIP 


46 


not  be  apportioned  ;  if  land  subject  to  a  lease 
was  sold  in  part  or  sold  in  several  lots,  the 
benefit  of  such  conditions  lapsed  entirely. 
Ordinary  rent  was  always  apportionable  be- 
tween persons  becoming  simultaneously  the 
o\vners  of  the  property  with  respect  to  which  it 
was  payable,  and  modern  acts  (among  wliich 
the  Property  Law  Amendment  Act  of  1859,  and 
the  Conveyancing  Act  of  1881,  are  the  most 
important)  liave  provided  for  the  apportionment 
of  rent-charges,  and  of  the  benefit  of  conditions 
in  leases  among  simultaneous  owners  of  land 
subject  to  a  rent- charge  or  a  lease.  Under  the 
Tithe  Commutation  Act  of  1836,  the  rent- 
charge  in  lieu  of  tithes  may  be  specially  ap- 
portioned, so  as  to  throw  the  amount  attribut- 
able to  the  tithes  of  an  entire  estate  upon  some 
particular  persons  in  exoneration  of  the  residue. 

E.  s. 

APPRAISERS.  Sworn  and  licensed  valuers 
of  poinded  goods  (goods  on  which  execution  is 
levied)  in  Scotland.  The  business  of  appraisers 
(valuers)  in  England  is  usually  conjoined  with 
that  of  the  auctioneer. 

APPRECIATION  OF  STANDARD.  The 
alterations  in  purchasing  power  of  the  standard 
of  value  are,  when  the  period  over  which  tlie 
investigation  extends  is  only  a  short  one, 
among  the  most  difficult  questions  into  which 
the  economist  has  to  inquii-e.  Remote  events 
stand  out  in  this  respect  more  clearly.  The 
great,  and  up  to  the  present  time  permanent, 
depreciation  occasioned  by  the  enormous  finds  of 
the  precious  metals  in  South  America  wliich 
followed  the  discovery  of  that  continent  by 
Columbus,  is  now  matter  of  history,  as  is  also 
the  further  change  in  the  same  direction  occa- 
sioned by  the  development  of  new  mines  in 
California  and  Australia,  commencing  ratlier  less 
than  fifty  years  ago.  During  a  comparatively 
recent  period,  however,  now  extending  over  ten 
or  fifteen  years,  the  balance  appears  to  have 
turned  the  other  way,  and  an  appreciation  of 
gold,  to  a  considerable  extent,  to  have  taken 
place.  It  was  pointed  out  by  Giffen,  Essays  in 
Finance,  2d  series,  p.  19,  that  average  prices, 
1885,  stood  "about  5  per  cent  less  than  the 
average  of  1845-60,"  and  by  Palgrave,  Appen- 
dix B,  Third  Report  of  Royal  Covimission  on 
Depression  of  Trade  and  Industry,  pp.  329,  330, 
that,  as  compared  with  1865-69,  prices  in  1885 
showed  a  drop  of  more  than  20  per  cent.  The 
VaHation  of  Prices  and  the  Value  of  the  Cur- 
rency since  1782-1S65,  a  paper  by  Jevons, 
Journal  of  the  Statistical  Society  of  Lon- 
don for  June  1865,  reprinted  in  his  volume 
Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finance,  shows 
the  oscillations  of  prices  very^  clearly.  Periods 
of  transition  in  matters  of  this  description  are, 
as  Chevalier  remarks  {De  la  Baisse  Pro- 
bable de  V  Or),  painful  to  pass  through.  It  is  here, 
however,  the  fact  of  a  recent  appreciation 
which  it  is  desirable  to  note,  not  the  causes 


which  have  led  to  it,  or  the  results  which  have 
followed  it.  Though  the  tendency  of  the 
standard  of  value  appears,  so  far  as  history  ex- 
tends, to  have  been  generally  towards  deprecia- 
tion, and  not  towards  appreciation,  so  recent 
and  marked  an  instance  of  appreciation  deserves 
record  (see  also  Depreciation  of  Monetary 
Standard,  Sj andard  of  Yalue). 

[For  history,  Jacob,  On  the  Precious  Metals 
London,  1831. — Jevons,  Investigations  in  Currency 
and  Finance,  London,  1884. — Giffen,  Essays  in 
Finance,  2d  series,  London,  1886. — Palgrave, 
Appendix  B,  Third  Report,  Roijal  Commission  on 
Depression  of  Trade  and  Industry,  1886.] 

APPRENTICESHIP.  A  system  by  which 
those  intended  to  follow  a  particular  occupation 
engage  to  serve  and  work  under  a  master  for 
a  certain  period,  and  the  master  engages  to 
teach  them  during  that  period  the  industry  or 
branch  of  industry  in  which  he  is  occupied. 
This  system  was  once  very  common,  if  not 
universal  ;  and  with  few,  if  any,  exceptions, 
every  workman  was  compelled  to  serve  a  master 
for  seven  years  before  he  ciould  practise  a  handi- 
craft on  his  own  account.  A  large  number  of 
tlie  rules  and  regulations  of  the  mediaeval  craft 
guilds  (see  Gilds)  dealt  with  the  conditions 
of  apprenticeship  ;  and  a  solemn  ceremonial 
was  observed  when  a  boy  was  bound  over  to 
be  an  apprentice,  and  when,  the  period  of  his 
service  being  ended,  he  became  a  full  member 
of  the  guild.  These  rules  and  regulations, 
which  obtained  the  binding  authority  of  uniform 
custom,  were  embodied  in  law  by  the  statute 
of  apprenticeship  (5  Eliz.  c.  4)  by  which  it 
was  "enacted  that  no  person  should  for  the 
future  exercise  any  trade,  craft,  or  mystery  at 
that  time  exercised  in  England  unless  he  had 
previously  served  to  it  an  apprenticeship  of  seven 
years  at  least."  The  system,  however,  was  open 
to  abuse  ;  and  Adam  Smith  (  Wealth  of  Nations, 
bk.  i.  ch.  x.  part  ii.),  protested  against  the  way 
in  which  the  trade  corporations  employed  it, 
to  maintain  a  monopoly  of  their  exclusive 
privileges.  But  gradually  it  came  to  be  held 
that  industries  which  had  arisen  since  the 
passing  of  the  statute,  or  which  were  not 
carried  on  in  market  towns,  were  exempt  from 
its  limitations;  and  in  the  development  of 
factory  industry  at  the  close  of  the  last  and 
the  commencement  of  the  present  century, 
manufacturers  exhibited  a  wholesale  disregard 
of  the  restrictions  of  apprenticeship.  The  efforts 
of  the  early  trades  unions  (see  Trade  Unions) 
were  directed  in  many  cases  towards  securing 
the  observance  of  the  Elizabethan  Legisla- 
tion. Prosecutions  were  instituted  against  the 
masters  with  successful  results.  But  the  opera- 
tion of  this  statute  was  suspended  by  parliament 
-  for  the  cloth  trade  during  successive  years  from 
1803  to  1809,  and  in  the  last  year  it  was  alto- 
gether rescinded  for  that  trade,  and  in  181 4  for  all 
trades.     The  custom,  however,  of  apprenticeship 


46 


APPRENTICESHIP,  STATUTE  OF 


continued  to  prevail ;  and  it  still  forms  part, 
in  theory  at  least,  of  the  policy  of  some  trades 
unions  to  attempt,  by  positive  regulation  or 
otherwise,  to  restrict  the  number  of  apprentices, 
and  to  insist  on  the  production  of  evidence  of 
having  served  a  regular  apprenticeship  before  a 
man  is  admitted  to  the  membership  of  the 
union.  But  despite  of  these  efforts  the  system 
appears,  with  the  growing  subdivision  of  labour, 
to  be  falling  into  disuse,  in  many  trades,  at  any 
rate  in  its  strict  form.  Some  wi'iters  have 
urged,  although  others  have  maintained  that 
this  is  impracticable,  that  technical  education 
should  be  generally  introduced  as  a  substitute 
for  apprenticeship. 

[For  the  regulations  of  the  old  craft  guilds  on 
the  matter  cp.  Brentano  on  Gilds  and  Howell's 
Conflicts  of  Capital  and  Labour,  eh.  i.  pt.  iv.  For 
the  efforts  of  early  trades  unions  cp.  the  same  book, 
oh.  ii. ,  and  Arnold  Toynbee's  Industrial  Revolu- 
tion :  Lecture  on  Industry  and  Democracy,  pp. 
178,  etc.  For  the  present  attitude  of  workmen  cp. 
Howell,  ch.  v.  gmdMaxshalV  a  Economics  of  Indv^stry, 
bk.  iii.  ch.  v.  §§  3  and  9.  A  list  of  recent  German 
works  on  Apprenticeships  is  given  by  Prof.  Stieda 
in  an  article  in  Jahrbiicher  fur  Nat.  Oek.  u.  Stat. 
21st  June  1890  ("Das  gewerbliche  Lehrlings- 
wesen  ").]  l.  l.  p. 

APPRENTICESHIP,  Statute  of  (5  Eliz. 
c.  4).  This  statute  is  of  considerable  import- 
ance in  the  history  of  English  labour.  Its 
general  drift  was  not  new.  Many  of  its  pro- 
visions had  been  previously  enacted.  The 
preamble  points  out  the  failure  of  former  statutes 
"partly  through  the  imperfection  and  con- 
trariety" in  the  laws  themselves,  and  "chiefly 
for  that  the  wages  and  allowances  .  .  .  are  too 
small,  and  not  answerable  to  this  time  (1562) 
respecting  the  advancement  of  prices  of  all 
things. ' '  The  legislature  proposed  therefore  '  *  to 
digest  and  reduce  into  one  sole  law  "  the  sub- 
stance of  the  old  statutes,  in  the  hope  that  the 
new  law  (duly  executed)  would  **  banish  idle- 
ness, encourage  husbandry,  and  yield  unto  the 
hired  person,  both  in  the  time  of  scarcity  and 
in  the  time  of  plenty,  a  convenient  proportion 
of  wages."  Former  statutes,  thirty-four  in 
number  since  Edward  III.,  were  repealed  so  far 
as  they  concerned  the  hiring,  keeping,  wages, 
etc.  of  servants,  labourers,  artificers,  and  appren- 
tices. According  to  the  new  statute  certain 
persons  were  confined  to  the  craft  in  which 
they  were  brought  up,  and  all  persons 
not  otherwise  employed,  nor  possessing  a 
certain  amount  of  property,  were  compelled  to 
serve  in  husbandry.  The  latter  clause  was 
supplemented  with  a  law  of  settlement,  which 
however  was  relaxed  in  time  of  harvest.  The 
regulations  with  regard  to  apprenticeship  were 
important.  The  term  of  apprenticeship  was 
to  be  seven  years.  Except  in  the  case  of 
smiths,  wheelwrights,  plaisterers,  bricklayers, 
etc.,  certain  property  qualifications  were 
necessary   for    apprenticeship,    and    the    craft 


could  be  carried  on  only  by  those  who  had 
served  their  time.  Every  person  with  three 
apprentices  must  keep  one  journeyman.  No 
one  could  be  apprenticed  over  the  age  of  twenty- 
one.  Penalties  of  imprisonment  were  imposed 
on  those  who  refused  to  be  apprenticed.  The 
act  was  administered  by  the  justices  of  the 
peace,  or  other  magistrates  specified  in  the  act. 
They  were  empowered  to  fix  the  rate  of  wages 
in  their  districts,  etc.  at  the  Easter  Quarter 
Sessions,  and  to  enforce  this  rate  by  fine  and 
imprisonment.  They  were  also  to  arbitrate  in 
disputes  between  masters  and  apprentices.  The 
hours  of  labour  were  to  be  from  5  a.m.  till 
6  or  8  P.M.  in  the  summer,  and  from  daylight 
to  dusk  in  the  winter,  not  more  than  two  and 
a  half  hours  being  allowed  for  meals.  There 
were  numerous  other  provisions  of  a  less  import* 
ant  character.  By  39  Eliz.  e.  12  the  act  was 
extended  to  weavers.  It  was  continued  by  43 
Eliz.  c.  9,  and  1  Jac.  c.  6,  the  latter  of  which 
extended  the  power  of  the  justices  and  town 
magistrates  to  fix  limits  to  the  wages  of  all 
labourers  and  workmen  whatever.  As  Prof. 
Rogers  points  out  {Agriculture  and  Prices,  vol.  v. 
p.  821)  the  law  was  "  effectually  supplemented  " 
by  14  Car.  ,11.  c.  12,  3  W.  and  M.  c.  11,  8  & 
9  Will.  III.  c.  30,  9  Will.  III.  c.  11,  and  11 
Will.  III.  c.  13. 

It  is  not  easy  to  form  a  just  estimate  of  the 
effects  of  Elizabeth's  legislation.  The  materials 
are  scanty,  and  contemporary  evidence  of  the 
working  of  the  statute  difficult  to  obtain. 
A.  Smith  ( Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  i.  ch.  x. 
pt.  ii. )  criticised  the  apprenticeship  clauses  in 
terms  which  were  certainly  justified  at  the 
end  of  the  18th  century.  Brentano  (Bnglish 
Gilds,  §  5)  has  taken  a  more  favourable  view 
of  the  statute,  and  has  produced  evidence  to 
prove  that  modem  trade  unions  originated  in 
the  non-observance  of  its  provisions.  Bren- 
tano's  criticism,  however,  is  open  to  much 
adverse  comment.  Prof.  Thorold  Rogers 
attributed  much  of  the  misery  of  the  working 
classes  in  succeeding  generations  to  the  opera- 
tion of  this  statute.  He  described  it  (  Work  and 
Wages,  p.  353,  cp.  also  Agriculture  and  Prices, 
vol.  V.  ch.  xxiii.,  xxviii.)  as  "the  third  in  the  set 
of  causes  from  which  pauperism  was  the  inevit- 
able effect."  He  justly  remarks  that  the  statute 
"seems  to  favour  traders  and  artisans  at  the 
expense  of  labourers  in  husbandry,  by  limiting 
the  number  of  the  former  and  making  tlie  latter 
the  residuum  of  all  non-apprenticed  labour." 
It  may  be  doubted,  however,  whether  at 
present  it  is  possible  to  form  an  accurate 
judgment  with  regard  to  the  working  of  the 
statute.  Comparatively  few  wages  assessments 
have  yet  been  discovered.  In  1793,  Ruggles 
could  refer  to  only  one.  Sir  F.  Eden  increased 
the  number  to  eight,  and  Thorold  Rogers  to 
eleven.  Four  more  are  printed  in  Hamilton's 
Quarter    Sessions   from    Mimbeth    to    Anne, 


APPROPRIATION— A  PRIORI 


47 


pp.  12,  163,  249,  and  273,  and  two  in  the 
Belvoir  Papers  (one  of  them,  9th  April  1621, 
in  full).  The  act  was  no  doubt  a  great  hard- 
ship where  it  was  rigorously  enforced,  especially 
amongst  the  agricultural  labourers.  Three  Devon- 
shire assessments  covering  a  period  of  119  years 
(vide  Hamilton)  indicate  a  very  slow  increase, 
except  in  the  case  of  indoor  servants,  while  in 
Bucks  the  rate  of  wages  for  farm  labourers  in 
the  reign  of  Anne  was  no  gi-eater  than  that 
fixed  in  Devonshire  in  the  reign  of  Elizabetli. 
It  may,  however,  be  doubted  if  the  act  was  on 
the  whole  effectual.  Prof.  Rogers's  statistics 
show  that  the  wages  received  by  the  labourers 
in  the  main  exceeded  the  rate  fixed  by  the 
justices,  i.e.  the  employers  were  more  merciful 
than  the  Quarter  Sessions,  or  (more  probably) 
wages  fluctuated  in  spite  of  the  statutes.  The 
statute  continued  in  force,  without  substantial 
modification,  until  1825,  when  it  was  repealed  ; 
but  it  had  been  practically  a  dead  letter  for 
many  years. 

[Adam  Smith,  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  i.  eh.  x. — 
Eden's  State  of  the  Poor,  Loudon,  1797. — Bren- 
tano's  English  Gilds,  §  5. — Thorold  Rogers's 
Work  and  Wages. — Thorold  Rogers's  History  of 
Agriculture  and  Prices,  vols.  iv.  v.  vl. — Thorold 
Rogers's  Economic  Interpretation  of  History. — 
Hamilton's  Quarter  Sessions  from  Elizabeth  to 
Anne. — MSS.  of  the  Duke  of  Rutland  preserved  at 
Belvoir  Castle  vol.  i.  (Historical  MSS.  Commission).] 

W.  A.  S.  H. 

APPROPRIATION.  The  appropriation  of 
the  instruments  of  production  by  individuals 
either  singly  or  in  gi'oups,  is  of  great  antiquity. 
Food  and  other  forms  of  movables  seem  to 
have  been  appropriated  prior  to  land,  and 
though  we  cannot  imagine  a  time  when  private 
property  was  unknown,  there  is  strong  evidence 
to  show  that  in  primitive  times  the  important 
forms  of  property  were  regarded  as  belonging  to 
the  group  and  not  the  individual.  The  Irish 
early  feudal  system  was,  for  instance,  based  on 
the  loan  of  cattle  by  the  chief  to  his  adherents, 
the  land  belonging  to  the  whole  tribe.  The 
accumulation  of  movable  property  would  begin, 
when  once  a  separate  household  was  acquired  by  a 
family,  since  a  house  would  involve  the  necessity 
of  some  movable  articles.  When  in  course  of 
time  the  relative  importance  of  land  and  mov- 
ables altered,  land  was  appropriated  by  groups 
of  men  united  by  a  real  or  supposed  blood  relation- 
ship. From  this  collective  form  of  ownership 
private  property  in  land  was  slowly  evolved  (see 
Property. — Maine's  Early  History  of  Institu- 
tions, London,  1875  ; — Maine's  Village  Com- 
munities, London,  1871  ; — Laveleye's  Primitive 
Property,  London,  1878). 

The  title  of  modern  states  to  the  territories 
appropriated  by  them  is  based  either  on  con- 
quest or  on  discovery  and  occupation,  confirmed 
by  lapse  of  time  (Wheaton's  Int.  Law,  ed.  Boyd, 
London,  1880,  c.  iv.)     It  is  now  admitted  that 


the  high  seas,  i.e.  the  seas  more  than  3  miles 
distant  from  low  water  mark,  cannot  be  appro- 
priated either  by  a  state  or  an  individual  (lb. 
p.  251)  though  the  fish  in  such  seas  may  be 
taken  by  capture.  As  regards  the  seas  within 
3  miles  of  the  coast,  some  writers  allow  a  state 
jurisdiction  only,  whilst  others  assign  to  it  pro- 
perty over  such  seas  (see  the  various  views  in 
Hall's  Int.  Law,  Oxlbrd,  1890).  From  the 
maxim  cuius  est  solum  eius  est  usque  ad  ccelura 
et  ad  infe7-os,  it  follows  that  not  only  mines  but 
even  air  may  be  appropriated.  Under  English 
law  the  owner  of  land  as  such  is  entitled  to  all 
the  light  and  air  that  fall  per})endicularly  on 
his  land.  By  lapse  of  time,  i.e.  twenty  years, 
he  may  also  acquire  a  riglit  to  the  reception  of 
light  and  air  in  a  lateral  direction,  and  that  either 
for  domestic  or  tratle  purposes  (Gale  on  Ease- 
ments, London,  1888). 

The  extent  to  which  appropriation  of  natural 
agents  is  to  be  permitted  is  a  matter  for  state 
regulation  (see  Occupation  ;  Possession  ;  Pro- 
perty). J.  E.  C.  M. 

APPROVED  BILL.  A  bill  of  exchange  to 
which  no  reasonable  objection  can  be  made. 

A  PRIORI  reasoning  is  reasoning  that  starts 
from  general  principles,  and  not  from  an  induc- 
tive examination  of  particular  instances.  What 
constitutes  the  basis  of  the  argument  is  thus  prior 
to  observation  or  experience  of  the  specific  class 
of  phenomena  to  which  the  conclusion  relates. 

KicARDo's  ordinary  method  of  reasoning  is 
a  priori.  Thus,  in  order  to  show  that  a  tax  on 
raw  produce  falls  on  the  consumer,  he  takes  for 
granted  the  general  principles  that  profits  tend 
to  equality,  and  that  the  {)rice  of  raw  produce  is 
determined  by  its  cost  of  production  on  land  that 
yields  no  rent.  Then,  taking  the  case  of  produce 
raised  on  the  margin  of  cultivation,  he  argues  as 
follows  :  "A  rise  of  price  is  the  only  means  by 
which  the  cultivator  could  pay  the  tax,  and 
continue  to  derive  the  usual  and  general  profits 
from  this  employment  of  his  capital.  He  could 
not  deduct  the  tax  from  his  rent,  and  oblige  his 
landlord  to  [»ay  it,  for  he  pays  no  rent.  He 
would  not  deduct  it  from  his  profits,  for  there  is 
no  reason  why  he  should  continue  in  an  employ- 
ment which  yields  small  profits,  when  all  other 
employments  are  yielding  greater.  There  can 
then  be  no  question,  but  that  he  will  have  the 
power  of  raising  the  price  of  raw  produce  by  a 
sum  equal  to  the  tax.  A  tax  on  raw  produce 
would  not  be  paid  by  the  landlord  ;  it  would  not 
be  paid  by  the  farmer  ;  but  it  would  be  paid,  in 
an  increased  price,  by  the  consumer  "  (Principles 
of  Political  EconoTny  and  Taxation,  ch.  ix.)  It 
will  be  seen  that  this  argument  does  not  pre- 
suppose any  examination  of  instances  in  which 
taxes  on  raw  produce  have  actually  been  imposed, 
or  of  the  consequences  observed  to  result  there- 
from. According  to  the  school  of  Ricardo  the 
right  method  of  economic  reasoning  in  general 
is  of  the  above  character  ;  it  is  a  priori.     The 


48 


AQUINAS 


same  view  is  expressed  in  Senior's  dictum  that 
"political  economy  depends  more  on  reasoning 
than  on  observation." 

A  priori  reasoning  is  also  described  as  syn- 
thetical, and  as  deductive,  the  terms  used  in  anti- 
thesis being  A  Posteriori  {q.v.),  analytical, 
inductive.  For  further  discussion  see  Analyti- 
cal ;  Deductive  ;  Inductive  ;  Synthetic 
Method.  •  J.  n.  k. 

AQUmAS,  St.  Thomas  {h.  1225,  d.  1274), 
the  gi-eatest  of  the  schoolmen,  is  of  the  utmost 
importance  in  the  history  of  economic  thought, 
in  that  he  sums  up  the  teaching  of  the  mediaeval 
church,  and  at  the  same  time  furnishes  the 
point  of  departure  for  all  subsequent  reasoning 
down  to  the  Kenaissanee.  He  would  seem, 
indeed,  to  have  had  no  special  interest  in  the 
economic  side  of  life  ;  he  was  led  to  handle  it 
partly  because  his  Summa  Theologica  was  in- 
tended to  be  encyclopaedic,  partly  because  the 
growth  of  industry  and  trade,  and  the  tendency 
to  apply  to  them  the  maxims  of  the  Civil  Law 
{q.v.),  rendered  necessary  a  restatement  of 
Christian  principles.  Politics  and  economics 
were  not  yet  separated  from  theology  ;  accord- 
ingly the  utterances  of  Aquinas  on  political 
economy  are  to  be  found  not  in  any  one  place, 
but  scattered  up  and  down  his  great  treatise 
and  his  minor  writings.  It  will,  however,  be 
convenient  to  group  them  under  three  heads — 
(i.)  fundamental  questions  of  social  organisa- 
tion ;  (ii.)  the  ethics  of  business ;  (iii.)  the 
theory  of  taxation. 

(i.)  The  early  Christian  Fathers  had  used 
language  which  might  seem  to  deny  the  justice 
of  private  property  ;  the  canon  law  had  ex- 
pressly included  community  of  goods  among  its 
examples  of  natural  law,  and  had  even  incor- 
porated a  passage  ascribed  to  Clement  of  Rome 
(bishop  of  Rome  in  the  latter  part  of  the  1st 
century),  wherein  it  was  laid  down  that  the  use 
of  all  that  is  in  the  world  ought  to  be  common 
to  all  men.  Aquinas,  with  strong  common  sense, 
set  himself  to  justify  individual  ownership  with- 
out directly  taking  up  a  position  of  antagonism 
to  those  earlier  ideals.  In  the  first  place,  he 
explained  away  the  significance  of  the  generally 
accepted  phrase  as  to  natural  law,  by  drawing  a 
distinction  between  what  was  natural  absolutely, 
and  what  was  natural  by  way  of  consequence. 
In  the  former  sense,  it  was  true,  there  was  no 
reason  why  a  field  should  belong  to  one  man 
rather  than  to  another  ;  but  in  the  latter  sense 
such  ownership  might  properly  be  called  natural, 
considering  how  necessary  it  was  that  the  land 
should  be  cultivated  and  that  its  fruits  should 
be  enjoyed  in  peace.  Moreover,  argued  Aquinas, 
the  phrase  did  not  mean  that  natural  law  for- 
bade private  property,  but  only  that  it  did  not 
introduce  it ;  its  introduction  was  due  to  positive 
law,  the  invention  of  human  wisdom.  In  the 
second  place,  he  fell  back  on  the  teaching  of 
Aristotle — whose  Politics  he  was  the  first  of  the 


schoolmen  to  incorporate  with  mediaeval  thought 
— and  pointed  out  the  beneficial  results  of  private 
property  ;  and  in  Aristotle's  maxim  that  pro- 
perty should  be  owned  separately  but  used  for 
the  common  good,  he  found  a  distinction  which 
seemed  to  harmonise  with  the  meaning  of  the 
Fathers. 

But  if  the  absence  of  private  property  was 
not  suitable  for  society  generally,  might  it  not 
be  a  duty  incumbent  on  such  Christians  as 
sought  perfection  in  the  religious  life  to  divest 
themselves  of  their  wealth  ?  St.  Francis  had 
taken  poverty  for  his  bride  ;  there  was  a  strong 
party  among  the  Franciscans  who  opposed  even 
the  corporate  holding  of  property  ;  and  the 
question  of  apostolic  poverty  was  already  be- 
ginning to  tear  the  church  asunder.  Accord- 
ingly Aquinas  devotes  to  this  topic  a  more  than 
usually  long  section.  Poverty,  he  lays  down, 
is  not  an  end  in  itself,  but  a  means — a  means 
towards  following  Christ.  Riches,  therefore, 
aire  wrong  only  so  far  as  they  are  hindrances  in 
the  way  of  this  object.  And  if  external  goods 
are  possessed  only  in  such  moderate  quantities 
as  are  necessary  for  men's  due  maintenance, 
they  need  not  distract  the  soul.  If  they  are 
the  common  property  of  a  religious  body,  the 
care  of  them  may  even  be  regarded  as  a  work 
of  charity.  But  in  this  case  the  degree  in  which 
material  goods  are  desirable,  will  depend  on  the 
character  of  each  particular  organisation. 

The  duty  of  almsgiving  had  been  closely 
associated  in  the  teaching  of  the  Fathers  with 
their  views  as  to  property  ;  and  it  had  been  in- 
culcated without  much  regard  to  possible  limit- 
ations. Here  again  Aquinas  endeavoured  to 
state  traditional  principles  in  a  more  prudent 
form.  The  giving  of  alms  was,  of  course,  with 
him  also,  a  matter  of  divine  command,  and  not 
merely  a  counsel  of  perfection.  But  it  was  to 
be  guided  by  right  reason,  according  to  which 
men  were  not  bound,  unless  in  exceptional 
cases,  to  give  more  than  their  superfluity  ;  and 
superfluity  was  defined  as  that  which  remained 
after  providing  for  a  man's  due  maintenance, 
and  that  of  those  dependent  on  him,  in  the  rank 
of  life  to  which  they  belonged. 

In  what  to  Aristotle  was  the  other  great 
fundamental  question,  viz.  Slavery,  Aquinas 
was  clearly  but  little  interested,  doubtless  owing 
to  the  changed  conditions  of  society.  He  no- 
where discusses  at  any  length  the  justice  of 
personal  servitude,  and  his  occasional  arguments 
on  the  subject  seem  purely  academic.  He  would 
appear  to  have  accepted  Aristotle's  view  of  the 
expediency  of  slavery  ;  but  he  differed  from  him 
in  believing  that  by  nature  (in  the  "absolute" 
sense  of  the  term)  all  men  were  equal  ;  and  he 
followed  some  of  the  Fathers  in  holding  that 
slavery  was  among  the  consequences  of  the  fall 
of  Adam. 

(ii.)  Of  wider  practical  importance  was  his 
teaching   as    to   the    ethics    of    business.     Hf 


AQUINAS— ARABLE  LAND,  CONVERSION  TO  PASTURE 


49 


contributed    but    little    to    the    development 
of  church    doctrine   in    this    regard  ;    but   he 
gave    it    a    systematic    shape   which    greatly 
strengthened  its  hold  upon  men's  minds.      In 
laying  down  that,  in  buying  and  selling,  no- 
thing but  a  Just  Price  {q.v.)  should  ever  be  de- 
manded or  paid,  Aquinas  was  quite  conscious 
that  he  was  enunciating  a  principle  in  direct 
opposition   to  that  of  the  civil  law  ;   and  he 
met  the  difficulty  by  urging  that  human  law 
was  necessarily  limited,  and  that  it  could  not, 
like  divine  law,  prohibit  all  that  was  opposed 
to  virtue.     As  to  trade,  he  agreed  with  Aristotle 
that  it  was  base  (see  Aristotle),  and  with  the 
Fathers  that  it  was  sinful,  if  carried  on  for  the 
sake  of  gain  ;  but  it  was  not  sinful  when  the 
merchant  sought  only  a  moderate  reward  for  his 
exertions,  and  spent  it  in  the  maintenance  of 
his  family  or  the  relief  of  the  poor  ;  still  less 
when  it  was  carried  on  for  the  public  good,  that 
a  country  might  not  be  without  the  necessaries 
of  life  (see  Fathers).     Concerning  usury  he 
repeated    the    arguments   of    his    predecessors 
Alexander  of  Hales  and  Albert  the  Great,  laying 
particular   stress    on    the    distinction    between 
Fungibles  and  Consumptibles  (q.v.):   with 
the  loan   of  a  consumptible,   such   as  money, 
passed  the  right  to  make  use  of  it,  so  that  to 
demand  the  return  of  the  money  and  a  payment 
for  its  use  was  to  make  a  double  charge  for  one 
thing.     He  allows,  however,  that  a  compensa- 
tion  may  justly  be   received  for   a  Damnum 
Emergens  (q.v.),  i.e.  the  loss  arising  from  the 
non-restoration  of  a  loan  at  the  appointed  time, 
though  not  for  a  Lucrum  Cessans  (q.v.)     But 
he  makes  two  dangerous  concessions  when  he 
allows  that  a  man   may,   without  sin,  borrow 
from  one  who  is  already  a  usurer,  if  it  is  for 
some  good  object ;  and  that  a  man  may,  without 
sin,  entrust  his  money  to  a  usurer,  if  the  purpose 
is  not  gain,  but  the  safe  keeping  of  the  money, 
(iii.)  The  treatise  De  Begimine  Principum,  the 
most  popular  manual  of  statecraft  in  the  later 
Middle  Ages,  is,  unfortunately,  from  the  hand  of 
Aquinas  only  as  far  as  the  middle  of  the  second 
chapter  of  the  second  book  (see  Ptolemy  or 
Lucca).     But  there  is  extant  almost  interesting 
letter  of  his  in  reply  to  certain  questions  of  the 
Duchess  of  Brabant ;  among  others  as  to  the 
justice  of  Taxation.    Aquinas  replies  that  as 
princes  are  established  by  God,  not  that  they 
may  seek  their  own  gain,  but  the  common  utility 
of  the  people,  they  should,  as  a  general  rule, 
content  themselves  with  the  revenues  of  their 
demesne  lands.     But  when  these  will  not  suffice 
for  the  defence  of  the  country  or  to  meet  other 
emergencies,  then  it  is  just  that  subjects  should 
be  called  upon  to  give  their  aid.     This  position 
is  identical  with  the  demand,  which  appears  so 
often  in  the  constitutional  struggles  of  the  14th 
century  in  England,  that  the  king  should  "  live 
of  his  own." 

[There  is  no  adequate  account  of  the  economic 
VOL.  I. 


teaching  of  Aquinas,  which  indeed  may  be  best 
collected  from  Aquinas  himself.  See  the  Suiiima 
Theologica,  as  to  private  property,  Secunda  Secundae, 
Quaestio  77,  Articulus  3  ;  Q.  66,  Art.  1,  2  ;  as 
to  voluntary  poverty,  Q.  188,  Aft.  7  ;  as  to  alms, 
Q.  32,  Art.  5,  6  ;  as  to  slavery,  Pars  Prima,  Q. 
96,  Art.  3  ;  Prima  Secuudse,  Q.  94,  Art.  5  ;  as 
to  price,  Secunda  Secundse,  Q.  77  ;  as  to  usury, 
Q.  78  ;  as  to  taxation,  De  Regiviine  Jitdceorum 
among  the  Opuscula.  The  best  brief  account  will 
be  found  in  C.  Jourdain,  La  Philosophie  de  S. 
Thomas  d'Aqtdn,  1858.  See  also  W.  J,  Ashley, 
Economic  History,  vol.  i.  pt.  i.,  1888  ; — P.  Janet, 
Histoire  de  la  Science  Politique,  3d  ed.,  1887  ; — 
H.  Contzen,  Geschichte  der  Volksidrthsthaftlichen 
Literatur  im  Mittelalter,  2d  ed.,  1872; — J.  J. 
Baumann,  Die  Staatslehre  des  h.  Thovias,  1873 
(little  more  than  a  series  of  extracts  in  German). 
For  its  relation  to  the  teaching  of  the  church  in 
general,  W.  Endemauu,  Studien  in  der  Rovianisch- 
Kanonistischen  Wirthschafts  ic.  Rechts-lehre,  vol. 
i.,  1874  ;  vol.  ii.,  1883  ;  and  the  brief  (^'eschichte 
des  Kirchlichen  Zinsverbotes  of  F.  X.  Funk,  1876.] 

w.  J.  A. 

ARABLE  LAND,  Conversion  to  Pasture 
IN  Great  Britain.  Naturally  and  histori- 
cally Great  Britain  is  a  grass-gi'owing  pastoral 
country.  Nature,  by  the  moist  climate,  sug- 
gests a  preponderance  of  permanent  grass-land  ; 
history  proves  that,  before  the  Napoleonic  wars 
and  the  pressure  of  scarcity  and  corn  laws, 
this  preponderance  in  fact  existed.  But,  at  the 
beginning  of  the  19th  century,  vast  areas  of 
poor  soils,  of  downs,  heaths,  sheep-walks,  and 
rabbit-warrens,  were  ploughed  uj)  under  the 
temptation  of  high  prices.  These  tracts  cannot 
now  be  tilled  with  prolit,  nor  can  many  of  them 
be  restored  to  pasture  so  as  to  benefit  the 
present  generation.  Within  recent  years,  the 
heavy  fall  in  the  price  of  cereals  has  led  to  the 
reconversion  of  arable  land  to  pasture,  and  the 
consequent  diminution  of  the  corn -growing 
area.  The  increase  of  permanent  pasture  has 
been  greatest  in  grain -gi-owing  districts,  which 
are,  by  climate  and  by  soil,  least  adapted  for 
pasture,  and  the  economic  loss  is  consequently 
gi-eater.  In  1872  the  total  acreage  of  per- 
manent pasture  was  12^  million  acres  ;  in 
1877  it  was  13,575,606"  acres  ;  in  1887  it 
was  15,671,395  acres;  since  1904  it  has  been 
over  17  million  acres.  Bearing  in  mind  the 
fact  that  the  increase  has  been  greatest  in  corn- 
growing  districts,  it  is  improbable  that  the 
reconverted  pastures  are  really  permanent,  or 
that  they  represent  more  than  a  temporary  loss 
of  capital.  The  immediate  results  of  the 
change  are :  (1)  a  considerable  reduction  in  the 
farmer's  labour  bill.  Assuming  that  farmers 
save  £1  an  acre  by  the  change,  more  than  two 
millions  are  annually  withdrawn  from  the  wages 
of  the  agi-icultural  population.  Half  the  popu- 
,  lation  only  is  required  when  dairying  replaces 
-tillage,  and  less  than  half  where  neat  stock  are 
kept  The  full  results  of  the  displacement  of 
1  labour  cannot  be  gauged,  partly  because  the 


60 


ARBITRAGE 


area  over  which  it  extends  is  wide,  partly 
because  agricultural  labourers,  especially  the 
older  generation,  remain  at  their  homes,  though 
employment  may  be  precarious,  in  preference  to 
seeking  permanent  work  elsewhere.  The  census 
returns  for  1911,  compared  with  those  for  1671, 
show  a  decrease  in  the  number  of  agricultural 
labourers  of  about  410,000.  Part  of  this 
decrease  must  be  attributed  to  the  develop- 
ment of  agricultural  machinery.  (2)  A  con- 
siderable loss  in  the  producing  power  of  the 
country  is,  for  a  time  at  least,  the  second 
result  of  the  conversion.  Under  favourable 
circumstances  of  soil  and  climate,  it  takes  ten 
years  before  a  profitable  permanent  pasture  can 
be  obtained.  Under  unfavourable  conditions, 
the  period  may  be  doubled  or  even  trebled. 
The  expense  of  converting  arable  land  to  pasture 
is  greatest  where  the  return  is  least,  and  longest 
postponed.  Thus  in  the  moist  climate  of  the 
west,  permanent  pasture  may  be  secured  by 
allowing  arable  land  to  fall  down  to  grass.  In 
the  eastern  counties,  "tumble-down"  land  can 
scarcely  ever  become  profitable  pasture.  Great 
care,  liberal  management,  abundance  of  manure, 
are  necessary.  If  these  are  neglected,  especially 
in  the  third  and  fourth  years  from  the  sowing, 
the  soil  will  become  bare  as  the  desert.  On 
reconverted  pasture,  the  value  of  the  additional 
sheep,  cattle,  pigs,  hay,  and  milk  will  for 
many  years — and  the  gi-eater  the  necessary 
outlay  of  capital  the  longer  the  profits  are 
postponed — fall  below  the  value,  even  at  present 
prices,  of  the  corn  and  straw  they  replace. 

[The  practical  side  of  the  question  is  treated  in 
all  books  on  agriculture.  But  see  especially  the 
article  by  Mr.  Faunce  de  Laune  of  Sharsted,  Sitting- 
bourne,  in  the  Journal  of  the  Royal  Agricultural 
Society,  pt.  i.  1882,  and  Permanent  and  Tem- 
porary Pasture,  by  Martin  J.  Sutton.]    b.  e.  p. 

ARBITRAGE  (Stock  Exchange).  On  the 
stock  exchange  arbitrage  dealings  are  those 
which  are  done  by  houses  in  London,  for  in- 
stance, to  cover  other  transactions  which  may 
be  done  in  Paris  or  Berlin  or  New  York  or  in 
other  distant  places.  The  method  pursued  is 
often  something  like  this  :  The  arbitrage  dealer 
learns  by  telegram  from  some  distant  place  that 
his  colleagues  stationed  there  have  bought  or 
sold  certain  securities  at  advantageous  prices. 
His  business  then  is  to  sell  or  buy  in  London  if 
possible  at  a  better  price  for  the  same  securities. 
For  example,  A.  sells  Egyptian  Unified  bonds  in 
Paris  at  a  price  corresponding  to  80  here.  B., 
an  arbitrage  dealer  in  London,  thereupon  en- 
deavours to  buy  the  same  amount  here  at  79|, 
leaving  a  profit  of  |-  per  cent  to  be  divided  be- 
tween the  two  firms.  Or  C.  buys  in  New  York 
Erie  Railroad  shares  at  29^,  and  seeks  to  im- 
prove his  bargain  by  instructing  D.,  his  colleague 
in  arbitrage  business,  to  sell  the  same  number  of 
shares  at  30  here  if  possible.  The  nicest  atten- 
tion to  the  rate  of  exchange,   cost  of  transit, 


insurance,  loss  of  interest,  etc.,  must  be  given 
to  these  transactions.  Arbitrage  is  also  con- 
ducted, under  the  title  of  "  shunting, "  between 
London  and  Liverpool,  or  Manchester,  or  Glas- 
gow, as  the  case  may  be,  the  favourite  opera- 
tions between  these  markets  being  English 
railway  stocks,  which  are  dealt  in  indifferently 
in  each.  a.  e. 

ARBITRAGE  (General  Business).  An 
expression  used  in  general  business  language  for 
international  dealings  in  stock  exchange  securi- 
ties, bullion,  specie,  bills  of  exchange,  etc.  If 
the  price  of  a  security  is  higher  in  one  place  than 
in  another,  it  is  said  that  there  is  a  margin  be- 
tween the  two  places  in  the  particular  security, 
and  arbitrage  dealers,  whenever  they  discover 
such  a  margin,  take  advantage  of  it  by  effecting 
purchases  in  the  cheaper,  and  sales  in  the  dearer 
market.  As  one  of  the  two  operations  must 
precede  the  other,  the  margin  may  disappear  be- 
fore the  transaction  is  completed  ;  but  this  is  not 
the  only  element  of  uncertainty.  The  original 
arbitrage  transaction  always  involves  a  covering 
transaction  to  re-imburse  the  buyer  for  his  out- 
lay. The  re-imbursement  can  be  effected  either 
by  a  reversed  buying  and  selling  of  some  other 
security,  or  by  the  remittance  of  bills  of  ex- 
change  from  the  seller  to  the  buyer,  or  by  the 
issuing  of  a  draft  on  the  seller  by  the  buyer, 
The  first  operation  may  not  always  be  possible 
without  loss,  and  the  second  and  third  may  be 
disturbed  by  an  unfavourable  fluctuation  in  the 
rate  of  exchange.  The  original  margin  ought 
to  be  wide  enough  to  cover  all  these  risks  as 
well  as  the  outlay  for  carriage,  insurance,  bill 
stamps,  security  stamps,  brokerage,  etc.  In 
some  cases  it  may  be  advisable,  instead  of  for- 
warding the  securities,  to  continue  the  bargains 
on  each  side  until  the  margin  is  reversed,  and 
then  to  close  the  transaction  by  buying  in  the 
place  where  the  first  sale  took  place  and  by  sell- 
ing in  the  place  where  the  first  purchase  took 
place.  In  this  way  all  the  forwarding  expenses 
and  stamps  are  saved  on  both  transactions,  but 
there  must,  of  course,  be  a  reasonable  prospect 
of  such  a  reversal  in  the  margin  within  a 
measurable  time,  and  there  must  be  no  un- 
favourable difference  between  the  rates  of  con- 
tinuation in  the  two  places  (for  this  see  Con- 
tinuation OR  Contango).  As  whenever  there 
is  a  margin  in  any  secuiity  all  arbitrage  dealers 
buy  in  the  one  place  and  sell  in  the  other,  the 
price  in  the  cheaper  place  necessarily  rises  almost 
immediately,  and  in  the  same  way  the  price  in 
the  dearer  place  falls,  and  as,  moreover,  for  vari- 
ous reasons,  which  it  would  not  be  possible  to 
explain  in  a  short  space,  arbitrage  operations 
are  frequently  effected  with  a  very  slight,  or  even 
without,  margin,  the  natural  effect  of  arbitrage 
business  is  to  maintain  the  prices  of  securities 
in  all  places  on  the  same  level.  e.  s. 

ARBITRAGE  (Exchange).      The  difference    j 
in  the  rates  of  exchange  {i.e.  the  prices  payable  M 


ARBITRATION  BETWEEN  EMPLOYERS  AND  EMPLOYED 


51 


for  bills  of  exchange  on  foreign  countries)  in 
different  places  occasions  the  so-called  "arbi- 
trage transactions  in  exchange."  If,  for  in- 
stance, bills  on  demand  on  Berlin  can  be  bought 
in  London  at  20*40,  and  bills  on  London  can 
be  bought  in  Berlin  at  20  "So,  it  will  be  profit- 
able for  a  Berlin  banker  to  buy  the  latter  and 
to  obtain  in  exchange  bills  on  Berlin.  For 
every  £1000  on  London  which  he  buys  he  has 
in  that  case  to  pay  20,350  marks,  while  the 
same  £1000  in  London  will  enable  him  to 
purchase  20,400  marks  on  Berlin  ;  he  therefore 
receives  50  marks  more  than  he  spent,  from 
which  sum,  however,  the  expenses  for  postage, 
bill  stamps,  brokerage,  etc.,  must  be  deducted. 
In  the  case  of  long  bills,  allowance  must  also  be 
made  for  the  rates  of  discount  on  both  sides. 
These  transactions  become  more  complicated  if 
a  bill  on  a  third  place  is  remitted  from  one  of 
the  two  places — if,  for  instance,  the  Berlin 
banker,  instead  of  obtaining  a  bill  on  Berlin  in 
London  in  exchange  for  the  bill  on  London 
remitted  by  him,  instructs  his  correspondent  to 
send  a  bill  on  St.  Petersburg  ;  in  such  a  case 
there  is  more  risk  of  loss  involved,  as,  before 
the  St.  Petersburg  bill  is  received  in  Berlin 
and  negotiated  there  the  exchange  m.ay  vary 
to  the  disadvantage  of  the  transaction.  The 
competition  of  arbitrage  dealers  naturally  re- 
duces the  margins  of  profit,  and  thus  the  rates 
of  exchange  in  all  important  centres  nearly 
correspond  with  each  other.  [See  H.  Deutsch, 
Arbitrage,  Effingham  Wilson,  1910.]  E.  s. 

ARBITRATION  BETWEEN  EMPLOYERS 
AND  EMPLOYED.  A  system  of  adjusting 
industrial  disputes.  It  should  not  be  identified 
with  conciliation  (see  Conciliation,  Boakds 
of),  although  a  hard  and  fast  line  of  distinc- 
tion cannot  be  drawn.  Arbitration  may,  perhaps, 
be  said  to  be  adapted  to  a  more  advanced  stage 
of  a  dispute,  and  to  be  more  compulsory  in 
character.  If  the  representatives  of  employers 
and  employed  at  a  board  of  conciliation  cannot 
arrive  at  a  mutual  agreement,  they  may  refer — 
and  definite  provision  is  generally  made  for  such 
ultimate  reference — to  an  arbitrator.  Arbitra- 
tion may  also  be  found  possible  where  there  is 
no  board  of  conciliation  established,  and  has 
sometimes  paved  the  way  for  the  institution  of 
such  a  board.  The  details  of  arbitration  are 
subject  to  great  variation.  The  arbitrator  may 
be  an  outsider,  or  he  may  be  himself  a  member 
of  the  trade  in  which  he  is  called  upon  to  arbi- 
trate. The  advantage  of  the  former  alternative 
is  the  avoidance  of  suspicions  of  bias  which  may 
naturally  arise  in  the  latter  case  ;  but  one  disad- 
vantage is  the  necessity  of  acquainting  the  arbitra- 
tor with  the  meaning  of  those  technical  terms 
which  would  be  familiar  to  a  member  of  the 
*  trade.  In  some  cases  the  attempt  is  made  to 
javoid  these  diflBculties  by  the  appointment  on  ' 
either  side  of  an  arbitrator  who  is  a  member  of 
'the  trade,  and  by  the  selection,  in  addition,  of  a 


single  umpire  who  is  an  outsider  invested  with 
the  power  of  final  decision  should  the  arbitrators 
disagree.  The  questions  referred  to  an  arbitrator 
may  also  be  various,  but,  in  the  generality  of 
cases,  they  are  concerned  with  the  regulation  of 
wages.  The  procedure  pursued,  again,  is  subject 
to  variation,  but  is  usually  of  the  following 
nature.  The  arbitrator  holds  a  court,  as  it  is 
termed,  on  a  fixed  day.  Some  time  before  he 
is  furnished  with  statements  from  both  the 
contending  parties,  setting  forth  their  rival 
claims  and  the  arguments  on  which  they  are 
based.  On  the  day  Avhen  the  court  sits  repre- 
sentatives of  both  sides  attend  and  state  their 
case,  sometimes  by  means  of  printed  or  AVTitten 
documents,  sometimes  supplementing  these  by, 
or  substituting  for  them,  oral  pleadings.  The 
arbitrator  asks  for  any  additional  evidence  he 
may  consider  necessary,  and  makes  his  award 
either  at  once  or  at  a  subsequent  date.  The 
diflSculties  connected  with  industrial  arbitration 
may  be  summarised  under  three  heads.  The 
award  may  be  disregarded,  and  to  avoid  this 
some  A\Titers  have  urged  that  a  legal  character 
should  be  given  to  courts  of  arbitration,  and  a 
legal  sanction  to  the  awards  of  arbitrators. 
Others  have  contended  that  this  would  tend  to 
impart  too  elaborate  and  technical  a  character 
to  the  proceedings,  and  that  it  is  not  in  harmony 
with  English  traditions  or  inclinations.  They 
liave  also  pointed  to  the  fact  that  there  is  already 
]n-ovision  in  the  statute  book  for  legalised  ar- 
bitration, e.g.  (1)  a  series  of  acts  passed  in  the 
18th  century,  providing  for  the  settlement  of 
disputes  in  particular  trades,  and  consolidated 
in  5  Geo.  lY.  c.  96  ;  (2)  Lord  St.  Leonard's 
Act  of  1867  (30  &  31  Yict.  c.  105),  providing 
for  the  establishment  of  councils  of  conciliation 
after  the  model  of  the  French  conseils  de  prud- 
'hommes  (see  Conseils  de  Prud'hommes)  ;  and 
(3)  Mr.  Itlundella's  Arbitration  Act  of  1872  (35 
&  36  Yict.  c.  46),  and  that  this  legislation  has 
hitherto  proved  inoperative.  And  therefore, 
they  contend,  the  only  satisfactory  means  of 
avoiding  the  difficulty  is  to  secure  thorough 
representation  of  the  contending  parties  by 
means  of  Tiiade  Unions  and  Masters'  Asso- 
ciations (which  see).  The  second  difiiculty 
connected  with  arbitration  is  the  element  of 
contentiousness  naturally  attaching  to  the  pro- 
ceedings, which  are,  however,  often,  if  not 
generally,  conducted  with  remarkable  courtesy. 
The  third  and  last,  and  perhaps  tlie  crucial,  difii- 
culty is  that  of  securing  accurate  data  for  the 
arbitrator,  and  of  determining  the  principle  on 
which  his  award  should  be  based — whether,  that 
is,  decisions  as  to  changes  in  wages  should  rest  on 
changes  in  the  prices  of  the  articles  produced  by 
the  wage  earners,  or  on  changes  in  the  ccst  of 
the  raw  material  (see  Competition  ;  Engineer- 
ing Trades  Industrial  Treaty,  App.) 

[For  an  account  of  these  difficulties  see  Price's 
Industrial  Peace,    ch.    iii.,   where   a  history  \b 


52 


ARBITRATION— ARISTOCRACY 


given  of  the  board  of  conciliation  and  arbitration 
m  the  manufactured  iron  trade  of  the  north  of 
England,  and  Professor  Marshall's  preface  to  the 
same  work. — Consult  also  Jevons's  The  State  in 
Relation  to  Labour^  ch.  vii. — Marshall's  Economics 
of  Industry,  bk.  iii.  ch.  viii. — Howell's  Con- 
flicts of  Capital  and  Labour,  ch.  xi.  part  ii.* ; — 
and  for  the  difficulty  of  determining  the  principle 
on  which  the  award  should  be  based,  Sidgwick's 
Principles  of  Political  Economy,  2d  ed. ,  bk.  ii. 
ch.  X.  §  5,  and  bk.  iii.  ch.  vii.  §  7,  and  Price's 
Paper  on  Sliding  Scales  and  Economic  Theory 
{British  Association  Report,  1889,  pp.  523-35) — 
Crompton's  Industrial  Conciliation  contains  a 
good  account  of  experiments  in  arbitration  and 
conciliation,  but  is  now  out  of  print.]       L.  L.  P. 

ARBITRATION",  Scotch.  The  principal 
distinctive  features  are  :  (1)  the  arbiter's  award 
("decreet-arbitral")  can  only  be  set  aside  by 
an  action  of  reduction  on  the  ground  of  bribery, 
corruption,  or  falsehood  ;  (2)  the  arbiter  lias 
implied  power  to  give  costs  ;  (3)  the  decree  is 
attested  and  executed  in  the  form  of  a  regular 
deed  ;  it  is  transcribed  in  the  public  registers, 
and  gives  warrant  for  execution  issuing  against 
either  party.  a.  d. 

ARBUTHNOT,  John,  M.D.,  born  1667  ; 
died  27th  February  1734-35  ;  he  was  appointed 
physician  to  Queen  Anne  ;  founded  the  Scrib- 
lerus  Club  with  Swift,  Pope,  Gay,  and  ParneU  ; 
wrote  some  witty  political  satires,  a  few  pro- 
fessional papers,  and  the  following  important 
work. 

Tables  of  the  Grecian,  Roman,  and  Jewish 
Measures,  Weights,  and  Coins  reduced  to  the 
English  Standard,  London  [1705],  8vo,  reprinted 
as  Tables  of  Ancient  Coins,  Weights,  and 
Measures,  Explained  and  Exemplified  [published 
by  his  son  Charles],  London,  1 727,  4to. — Second 
Edition,  with  Appendix,  containing  Observations, 
by  B.  Langwith,  D.D.,  London,  1764,  4to  (Latin 
translation  by  D.  Konig,  Lugd.  Bat.,  1764,  4to). 

ARBUTHNOT,  John,  of  Mitcham  (Surrey), 
towards  the  end  of  18th  century,  whose  abilities 
as  a  farmer  have  been  acknowledged  by  Arthur 
Young  {On  the  Husbandry  of  three  celebrated 
British  Farmers,  1811,  pp.  17-28),  refutes,  in 
An  Inquiry  into  the  Connection  between  the 
present  Price  of  Provisions,  and  the  Size  of  Farms, 
etc.,  By  a  Farmer,  1773,  the  views  of  authors 
ascribing  the  high  price  of  provisions  to  large 
farms,  asserts  that  the  proportion  of  land  which 
is  in  some  degree  governed  by  its  value  should 
be  equal  to  a  given  capital  (p.  35),  and  ascribes 
the  deamess  to  failures  of  crops,  luxury  in  the 
mode  of  living,  and  the  increase  of  post-horses. 
The  remedy  consisting  in  the  extension  and 
improvement  of  agriculture,  he  recommends 
enclosures.  Then  '*make  the  trade  free  .  .  . 
let  corn  flow  like  water,  and  it  will  find  its 
level "  (p.  88).  Even  the  bounty  on  its  exporta- 
tion is  needless.  The  effects  of  importation 
from  America  are  not  dangerous,  "for  there 
labour  is  dear."     He  laments   only  that  the 


development  of  large  farms  was  accompanied 
by  "  the  loss  of  our  yeomanry,  that  set  of  men 
who  really  kept  up  the  independence  of  this 
nation  ;  and  sorry  I  am  to  see  their  lands  now 
in  the  hands  of  monopolising  lords,  tenanted 
out  to  small  farmers,  who  hold  their  leases  on 
such  conditions  as  to  be  little  better  than 
vassals  ready  to  attend  a  summons  on  every 
mischievous  occasion,"  p.  139  (see  Yeomen). 

This  work  has  been  translated  into  French  by 
Freville,  1775,  as  the  second  volume  of  his 
Arithmitiqu^ politiqiie  de  A.  Young. — See  M'Cul- 
loch.  The  Literature  of  Political  Economy,  pp. 
193,  194.— K.  Marx,  Capital,  vol.  ii.  pp.  746 
note  2,  751  note  1.  s.  b. 

ARCO,  Gherardo  Giambattista  dei  Conti 
d'Arco,  born  at  Arco  in  the  Tyrol  1739,  died 
at  Goito  1791,  was  a  great  personal  friend  of 
CoNDiLLAC.  As  an  economist  he  was  a  man  of 
sound  common  sense,  possessing  no  brilliant 
talent.  His  writings,  consisting  mostly  of  prize 
essays  written  for  academies,  have  been  collected 
by  CusTODi  in  his  Economisti  classici  Italiani, 
1804,  Milano.  His  principal  essays  are  dated 
as  follows : 

On  the  Politicaland  Economical  Harmonybetu^een 
Tovmsand  Country,  1771  (Mantua  Academy).  — On 
Com  Stores,  1,775  (Mantua  Academy). — On  the  In- 
fluence Commerce  exerts  over  Talents  and  Habits, 
published  in  1782  (written  in  1777  for  the  Aca- 
demy of  Marseilles). — On  the  Influence  the  Spirit 
of  Commerce  exerts  on  the  Domestic  Economy  of  the 
People  and  on  the  prosperity  of  States,  1778  (pub- 
lished in  Cremona). — Reply  to  the  Question  whether 
Agriculture  or  Industry  is  to  be  preferred  in  a  fer- 
tile Country,  1780  (Mantua  Academy). — On  the 
Liberty  of  Transit  Commerce,  1784  (published  in 
Mantua).  M.  p. 

ARGENSON,  R6n^  Louis  de  Voyer  de 
Paulmy,  Marquis  d',  born  1694,  died  1757  ; 
was  the  eldest  son  of  the  "Garde  des  sceaux" 
of  the  same  name,  under  the  Regency.  He  is 
better  known  by  his  celebrated  mot  "Pas  trop 
gouvemer," — lineal  ancestor  in  the  spirit  of  the 
"  laissez-faire,  laissez-passer  "  of  Gournay, — 
than  by  his  works,  now  little  read.  His  Con- 
siderations sur  le  gouvernement  ancien  et  present 
de  la  France  (published  1764,  but  written  more 
than  thirty  years  previously),  in  which  he  treats 
of  democracy  in  a  state  governed  by  a  monarch, 
deserves,  however,  to  be  reprinted.  He  was  one 
of  the  most  active  members  of  the  Club  de 
V Entresol  (Place  Vendome),  which  was  founded 
in  1724,  and  closed  in  1731  by  order  of  Cardinal 
de  Fleury.  A.  c.  f. 

ARGENTARII.  The  bankers  of  ancient 
Rome.  There  were  some  special  rules  regarding 
their  transactions.  An  action  of  a  special 
kind  could,  for  instance,  be  brought  against  an 
argentarius  who  had  engaged  to  answer  for  the 
debt  of  another.  The  argentarii  had  special 
privileges  as  regards  the  right  of  set-ofF.  E.  s. 

ARISTOCRACY.  Aristocracy  meant  to  the 
Greeks  "government  by  those  who  are  best," 


ARISTOCRACY— ARISTOTLE 


53 


in  other  words  not  government  by  one  indi- 
vidual (monarchy),  or  by  the  majority  (demo- 
cracy), but  by  a  select  class,  who  are  privileged 
because  of  some  real  or  alleged  superiority  to 
the  rest.  Government  by  a  class,  if  it  possessed 
no  such  superiority,  was  not  aristocracy  but  olig- 
archy (government  of  the  few).  Such  are  in  the 
main  the  distinctions  of  Aeistotle  {Politics). 
Aristocracy,  however,  has  come  to  mean  in  our 
own  day  simply  that  class  in  society  which  is, 
or  claims  to  be,  superior  to  the  rest,  with  or 
without  any  special  power  in  the  government. 
Historically,  therefore,  there  have  been  as  many 
forms  of  aristocracy  as  there  are  forms  of  excel- 
lence amongst  men.  There  were  aristocracies 
built  on  a  superiority  of  race  and  birth,  aristo- 
cracies of  culture  (such  as  a  caste  of  priests)  ; 
aristocracies  of  age  and  experience  (senatus, 
yepovaia) ;  military  aristocracies,  territorial 
aristocracies  (of  proprietors  of  land),  and  finally 
aristocracies  of  wealth  (equites,  merchant  princes). 
It  is  of  the  last  that  Cicero  recorded  his  opinion  : 
"Nee  ulla  deformior  species  est  ciWtatis  quam 
ilia  in  qua  opulentissimi  optimi  putantur  "  {Rep. 
I.  34).  The  popular  notion  of  aristocracy 
changes  with  the  popular  standard  of  excellence  ; 
and  the  changes  have  clearly  been,  on  the  whole, 
for  the  benefit  of  civilisation.  Between  the 
actual  equality  of  men  in  barbarous  societies,  and 
the  endeavour  after  equality  in  the  most  civil- 
ised, there  are  intervening  stages  where  society 
is  necessarily  composed  of  privileged  and  un- 
privileged classes.  The  relative  justification  of 
slavery,  for  example,  lies  in  the  sparing  of  the 
conquered,  the  training  of  them  to  habits  of 
industry,  and  the  securing  to  their  masters  of 
the  leisure  for  the  acquisition  of  science  and 
culture.  But  if  these  were  the  conditions  of 
the  beginning  of  progress,  they  are  not  neces- 
sarily the  conditions  of  its  continuance. 

In  the  same  way  an  aristocracy  of  birth  has 
been  the  means  of  reducing  a  people  to  military 
and  political  discipline,  as  in  the  Roman 
republic  and  mediaeval  Europe.  The  republic 
of  Venice  grew  strong  and  wealthy  under  a 
governing  council  filled  entirely  by  sons  of 
office-holders.  But  the  lessons  once  learnt,  the 
teachers  are  dismissed.  In  Venice,  e.g.^  the 
(closing  of  the  Lihro  d'oro  in  1309  was  the  suicide 
I  of  the  governing  class.  In  modern  times  the 
two  types  of  most  importance  in  economical 
band  social  development  have  been  the  territorial 

id  the  commercial  aristocracies.  The  aristo- 
Jidracy  of  feudalism  became  territorial  when  the 

award  of  victory  was  the  grant  of  lands.  Land 
JWas  in  those  times  "the  means  not  of  subsist- 
merely,  but  of  power  and  protection." 
Juch  customs  as  Primogeniture  and  Entail 

reserved  the  estate  to  the  lord's  family ;  to  divide 

le  land  would  have  been  to  lessen  the  power. 
Jut  by  thus  endeavouring  to  maintain  their 
)wn  power,  the  lords  were  giving  security  of 

erson  to  their  dependants,  and  to  their  country 


a  continuity  and  stability  of  institutions  which 
every  country  in  Europe  needed  above  every- 
thing in  those  times.  In  addition  they  intro- 
duced a  rale  of  conduct  {noblesse  oblige)  which 
had  in  many  ways  a  real  superiority  to  that 
of  common  folk.  Nevertheless  the  growth  of 
absolute  monarchies,  of  towns,  guilds,  and  com- 
merce, not  only  made  the  feudal  institutions 
unnecessary  as  guarantees  of  stability,  but  re- 
vealed the  fact  that  they  might  be  hindrances 
to  progress.  Economical  causes  worked,  among 
others,  to  free  the  dependants  and  to  raise  up 
formidable  rivals  to  the  power  of  the  nobles. 
Politically  their  exclusive  privileges  may  be 
said  to  have  lasted  in  France  till  the  Revolu- 
tion of  1789.  In  England  territorial  nobles 
tempered  the  hostility  of  the  merchant  princes 
by  admitting  many  of  the  latter  from  time  to 
time  within  their  ranks  ;  and  they  thus  saved 
their  privileges  for  another  half  century.  The 
aristocracy  of  wealth,  which  at  first  rivalled 
and  then  conquered  the  aristocracy  of  birth  in 
England,  will  no  doubt  give  place  in  its  turn 
to  a  successor  when  its  work  is  done.  It  is  of 
a  nature  to  invite  the  odium  of  those  who  are 
excluded  from  it,  in  proportion  as  fortunes  seem 
to  be  due  to  chance  and  speculation  more  than 
to  industry  and  talent.  The  recognition  of  its 
superiority  is  often  the  confession  of  weakness 
in  presence  of  strength  rather  than  reverence 
before  admitted  excellence.  The  latter  feeling 
is  not  only  consistent  with  modern  democracy, 
but  is  an  imperative  condition  of  its  health. 
Democracy  claims  a  fair  field  for  the  exercise 
of  all  the  powers  of  men,  and  anything  like  a 
hereditary  caste  of  privileged  persons  would 
never  be  willingly  created,  and  is  very  re- 
luctantly maintained  by  it.  But  it  recognises 
an  inequality  of  ability,  an  aristocracy  of  genius, 
and  an  aristocracy  of  labour.  The  difierences 
in  talent  between  individuals,  and  the  eft'ect 
of  heredity  in  intensifying  them,  will  remain 
a  constant  factor  of  economical  and  social 
development  (see  also  Equality  ;  Feudalism  ; 
Heredity  ;  Inheritance,  Estate  of). 

[Bluntschli,  Staatslehre,  II.  x.  and  VI.  xix. 
(1875). — Stahl,  Philosophie  des  Rechts,  vol.  ii.  p. 
103,  Der  Add  (1878).— Ad.  Smith,  Wealth  of 
Nations,  bk.  iii. — G.  C.  Lewis,  Use  and  Abuse  oj 
Political  Terms,  §  8  (1832). — Montesquieu,  Esprit 
des  Lois,  II.  iii..  III.  iv.]  J.  b. 

ARISTOTLE.  By  (Economic  {oUovoficKT}) 
Aristotle  meant  the  practical  science,  or  art, 
of  household  management — practical  wisdom 
{(f>f)6v7j<ns)  applied  to  the  household  {Eth.  Nic. 
VI.  8  §  3),  the  household  {otKta)  including  the 
three  relations  of  husband  and  wife,  father  and 
child,  master  and  slave,  and  obviously  requiring 
property  for  its  maintenance  {Pol.  I.  2).  The 
two  disconnected  books  called  The  (Economics, 
which  have  come  down  to  us  among  Aristotle's 
writings,  are  certainly  not  his,  but  works  of  the 
Peripatetic  school,  the  first  being  earlier  and  of 


54 


ARISTOTLE 


more  value  than  the  second  (Zeller,  Phil,  der 
Grieehen,  Ed.  3,  Theil  II.,  Abtheil.  11.  p.  944). 
The  first  book  of  the  Politics  constitutes  his  own 
contribution  to  the  subject  (cp.  PoL  I.  3,  §  1  ; 
and  III.  6,  §  3),  and  is,  indeed,  summarised 
under  the  title  of  we  pi  rod  oiKovofiiKov,  i.e.  Con- 
cerning the  (Economist,  in  the  epitome  by  Areius 
Didymus  (?)  preserved  in  Stobseus  {Bel.  II.  c.  6). 

XprjfxaTLa-TiKTi,  the  science  or  art  of  wealth,  is, 
he  tells  us,  by  some  considered  identical  with 
household  management,  by  some  regarded  as 
the  most  important  part  of  it  (Pol.  I.  3,  §  3). 
He  treats  of  it  in  chaps.  8-1 1 ;  and  in  these  chap- 
ters, taken  along  with  JEth.  Nic.  V.  5,  §§  6-16,  we 
have  what  would  now  be  called  the  "political 
economy  "  of  Aristotle.  Both  households  and 
states  require  means  for  their  support.  Wealth 
(ttXoOtos)  is,  therefore,  defined  as  *'a  quantity 
of  instruments  for  the  household  or  state  "  (Pol. 
I.  8,  §  15).  This  definition  Mill  {Pol.  Econ. 
"  Preliminary  Remarks")  would  consider  "philo- 
sophically correct,"  though  like  other  English 
economists  he  prefers  to  define  wealth  in  terms 
of  Exchange.  In  Eth.  Nic.  IV.  1,  §  2,  Aristotle 
defines,  or  rather  describes,  property  (XpiJ/^ara) 
as  "everything  whose  value  is  measured  by 
money  ; "  but  the  more  scientific  definition  of 
the  Politics  serves  him  as  a  basis  for  his  opinion 
about  the  true  relation  of  xPVf^o.ri.aTiK'^  to 
oLKovofiLKrj  and  ttoKltlkt}  (as  we  should  say  "of 
economics  to  politics").  A  science  of  instru- 
ments or  means  is  obviously  subordinate  to  a 
science  of  ends. 

Aristotle  uses  xpij/^ctrio-Ti/cj?  in  the  widest  sense 
as  equivalent  to  kttjtlkti,  the  art  of  acquisition 
in  general ;  but  in  a  narrower  sense  it  is  limited 
to  the  art  of  acquiring  that  wealth  which  is 
only  rendered  possible  by  exchange  and,  on  any 
considerable  scale,  by  Money.  The  kinds  of 
acquisition  are  distinguished  as  "natural"  and 
"unnatural,"  the  latter  arising  through  the 
introduction  of  exchange.  "Natural"  wealth 
is  to  the  household  just  what  nature's  provision 
of  food  is  to  animals,  e.g.  mother's  milk  to  the 
young,  or  its  ordinary  food  to  the  graminivorous 
or  carnivorous  animal.  And  so  hunting,  either 
of  wild  animals  for  their  flesh  or  skins  (fishing 
would  fall  under  the  same  head),  or  of  slaves  to 
serve  as  "living  tools,"  is  named  among  the 
"natural"  modes  of  acquisition.  The  "nom- 
adic '  life  of  those  who  rear  sheep  and  cattle, 
agriculture  (including  tlie  cultivation  of  fruit- 
trees),  the  keeping  of  bees  (important  when 
sugar  was  little  known),  and  the  rearing  of 
fowls  and  fish  —  all  these  are  considered 
"  natural "  ways  of  supporting  life.  Intermedi- 
ate between  these  and  the  "  unnatural "  class, 
Aristotle  places  wood-cutting  and  mining  :  the 
man  who  grows  corn  is  in  immediate  contact 
with  nature,  but  the  man  who  makes  the  spade, 
or  plough,  or  procures  the  materials  for  it,  is 
a  step  removed  from  nature — such,  at  least, 
seems   to  bo  his  line  of  thought.     Exchange 


{pLera^XriTiK'n),  as  already  said,  introduces  the 
"unnatural"  kind  of  acquisition.  Aristotle 
distinguishes,  as  Adam  Smith  did  again  long 
afterwards,  between  the  Value  possessed  by  any- 
thing in  v^e  and  its  value  in  exchange  {Pol.  I. 
9,  §  2).  If  a  shoe  be  worn,  that  is  according  to 
nature  ;  if  it  be  used  to  purchase  other  com- 
modities, that  is  not  "natural,"  though  still  a 
use  of  the  shoe  qud  shoe  ;  for  the  person  who 
takes  it  in  exchange  takes  it  because  it  is  a  shoe. 
Exchange  only  comes  to  be  needed  when  wo 
pass  outside  the  limits  of  the  household.  In 
early  stages  of  society,  "as  among  many  bar- 
barians still,"  it  took  place  by  simple  Barter 
{Pol.  I.  9,  §  5).  The  introduction  of  money 
{vbiuffimY  makes  no  difterence  in  the  character  of 
exchange  {Eth.  Nic.  V.  5,  §  16),  but  facilitates  it 
enormously  by  supplying  a  measure  of  value 
{irdvTa  TToiet  (TvpLfierpa,  "it  makes  all  things 
commensurable,"  Eth.  Nic.  V.  5,  §  15)  and  a 
convenient  medium  of  exchange.  Money  is 
defined  as  "a  conventional  exchangeable  repre- 
sentative of  demand"  {vTrdWay/ma  ttjs  xP^^°-^ 
Kard  (Twd-fiK-qv,  Eth.  Nic.  V.  6,  §  11.  Gold  and 
Silver  serve  this  purpose  best ;  being  useful 
themselves,  they  are  at  the  same  time  easily 
carried  about  {Pol.  I.  9,  §  8),  and,  although  liable 
to  change  in  value,  they  do  so  less  than  other 
commodities  {Eth.  Nic.  V.  5,  §  14).  At  first 
they  were  always  weighed,  afterwards  a  stamp  was 
imposed  {Pol.  I.  9,  §  8).  This  brings  out  the 
conventional  character  of  Currency,  so  that  a 
change  in  the  currency  will  make  the  old  coins 
useless  {Eth.  Nic.  V.  5,  §  11).  About  money 
there  are  two  opposite  errors :  (1)  that  wealth 
consists  in  a  quantity  of  money  {Pol.  I.  9,  §  10)  ; 
(2)  that  it  is  something  utterly  valueless — (here 
he  doubtless  alludes  to  Cynic  theories,  such  as 
are  maintained  in  the  pseudo- Platonic  Eryxias). 
The  "unnatural"  kind  of  xPW°-'^'-'^''''-i^'0  ^^' 
eludes  (1)  Trade  {efiiropla,  commerce,  and  Kain}- 
Xi/c?7,  retail  trade),  diff"erent  forms  of  which  are 
ship-owning,  the  carrying-trade,  shopkeeping  ; 
(2)  Money-lending  (T0K:i(rAi6  J,  ^jSoXocrrart/c^),  which 
is  even  more  unnatural,  for  it  is  a  perversion 
even  of  the  natural  use  of  money  to  make  money 
breed  money,  instead  of  simply  facilitating  ex- 
change ;  (3)  Labour  for  wages  {jxiadapvla) ; 
for  while,  in  Aristotle's  view,  there  are  slaves 
by  nature,  the  hired  labourer,  whether  skilled 
or  unskilled,  is  something  contrary  to  nature — 

1  A  remarkable  proof  of  the  force  with  which  this 
conception  has  been  impressed  on  modern  thought  is 
found  in  the  reference  made  by  Mirabeau  to  Aristotle  at 
the  session  of  the  National  Assembly,  12th  December 
1790  (see  Dana  Horton,  Report  on  International  Monetary 
Conference,  Paris,  1S78,  p.  29  (art.  Bi-metallism). 

The  same  influence  is  also  exemplified  in  the  statement 
made  by  recent  bi-metallists,  "  that  the  greater  part  of 
the  value  of  vi/j,i(r/^x,  (money)  is  given  it  by  v6f/.6;  (law), 
to  which  it,  as  Aristotle  says,  both  etymologically  and 
actually  owes  its  origin"  (see  letter  to  the  Times  of 
Chrysargyros,  26th  May  1881),  and  in  the  remarks  of 
H.  Cernuschi,  "  Money  is  instituted  by  law  :  nomos,  law  ; 
nomisma,  money"  in  his  work,  Bi-metallism  at  \b\  a 
necessity  nf  the  Continent,  for  the  United  States,  for  Eng- 
land, by  H.  Cernuschi,  London,  P.  S.  King,  1881. 


( 


ARISTOTLE— ARITHMETIC,  POLITICAL 


56 


something  for  which  he  can  find  no  proper  place 
in  his  political  ideal.  Regarding  wealth  as  an 
instrument  to  life,  and  therefore  as  a  means  and 
not  as  an  end,  Aristotle  rejects  the  money- 
making  life  as  one  that  no  rational  man  would 
choose  (Elh.  Nic.  I.  5,  §  8,  6  S^  xPW^ti-<^ttis 
[sc.  ^tos],  j8^ai6s  rts  eo-rij',  "The  money-making 
life  is"  either  "unnatural"  or  rather  "chosen 
only  under  compulsion,"  "  as  a  mere  necessary  " 
— a  passage  of  which  the  mistranslation,  "The 
money-maker  is  a  violent  person,"  determined 
the  position  of  the  usurers  in  Dante's  Inferno, 
canto  xi.)  But  is  Aristotle  quite  consistent  in 
holding,  as  he  does,  that  the  city  state  is  "  prior 
by  nature,"  and  so  higher  in  type,  than  the 
village  community  or  patriarchal  family,  and 
yet  condemning  as  unnatural  all  the  more 
complex  economic  conditions  of  city  civilisation  ? 
His  economic  views  are  really  dependent  on  the 
ethical  principle  that  conduct  (Trpa^is),  and  not 
the  production  of  commodities  {Troirjcns),  is  the 
end  for  man.  This  and  the  prejudices  of  a  slave- 
holding  society  prevented  him,  perhaps,  from 
sufficiently  understanding  the  economic  struc- 
ture even  of  the  very  society  in  which  he  was 
living. 

To  return  to  the  original  question,  his  answer 
is  that  only  the  natural  kind  of  xp77/AaTio-Ti/c'J7  is 
a  part  of  household  management.  The  other 
kind  is  subordinate  or  subservient  (v-n-qpeTLKri, 
Pol.  I.  10,  §  3)  ;  and,  because  concerned  with 
mere  means  and  instruments  of  living,  both 
kinds  are  to  be  pursued  only  to  a  limited  degi-ee. 
Thus  those  are  wTong  who  identify  household 
management  with  amassing  wealth,  and  states- 
manship with  finance. 

While  thus  laying  the  foundations  of  a  special 
science  of  wealth,  Aristotle  never  treats  the 
subject  apart  from  ethical  and  political  con- 
siderations. In  Eth.  Nic.  V.  5,  he  seems  to 
consider  that  the  value  of  commodities  is,  in 
some  way,  determined  by  the  value  of  the  pro- 
ducers. Fair  exchange  is  reciprocal  action 
regulated  by  proportion  (t6  avTiireirovebs  Kar 
avaXoylav),  e.g.  as  the  farmer  to  the  shoemaker, 
so  must  be  the  quantity  of  shoes  that  the  farmer 
receives  to  the  quantity  of  corn  that  the  shoe- 
maker receives.  Money,  as  already  said,  makes 
commensurability  and  so  equalisation  possible 
between  such  incommensurable  quantities.  AVe 
may  perhaps  make  his  idea  intelligible  to  our- 
selves by  thinking  of  the  amounts  to  be  given 
in  exchange  as  in  the  inverse  ratio  to  the  value 
of  an  hour's  labour  of  each  producer. 

Aristotle  was  fully  alive  to  the  close  relation 
between  social  or  political  institutions  and  econ- 
omic conditions.  In  Pol.  I.  8,  he  points  out 
that,  just  as  the  food  of  animals  determines  their 
habits  as  gregarious  or  solitary,  etc.,  so  are  men's 
lives  different  in  the  pastoral,  the  hunting  and 
fishing,  and  the  agricultural  stage  (or  in  various 
combinations  of  these).  The  pastoral  is  here 
placed  first,  not  as  Deiug  the  nideati  but  as 


that  which  leaves  most  leisure.  And  so  in  Pol, 
YI.  (  =  VII.  in  the  changed  order  of  St.  Hilaire, 
etc.)  4,  when  grouping  the  different  types  "of 
democracy  according  to  economic  conditions,  he 
considers  a  pastoral  democracy  less  stable  than 
an  agricultural,  because  there  is  more  leisure  for 
political  interests  ;  while,  again,  an  industrial 
population,  living  in  a  city,  develops  the  most 
extreme  form  of  democracy. 

Colonies  are  referred  to  as  a  remedy  for  over- 
population (VI.  5,  §  9).  The  nature  of  a  Mono- 
poly (with  the  use  of  this  term)  is  illustrated 
in  I.  11.  In  criticising  Plato's  Communism 
Aristotle  uses  the  argument,  often  repeated 
since,  that  "the  magic  of  property"  is  needed 
to  ensure  due  care  of  anything.  Not  abolition 
of  all  private  property,  but  e(jualisation  of  pro- 
perty among  the  free  citizens,  along  with  the 
maintenance  of  a  nearly  equal  population,  con- 
stitutes his  own  ideal  state  on  its  economic 
side  {Pol.  VII.  =  IV.  in  order  of  St.  Hilaire,  etc.) 

Most  of  Aristotle's  economic  discoveries  may 
be  said  to  have  lain  dormant,  and  to  have  re- 
quired rediscovery  in  modern  times.  His 
influence,  however,  was  directly  exercised  as 
one  of  the  factors  in  the  mediaival  abhorrence 
of  usury  (cp.  Ashley,  English  Economic  History, 
I.  pp.  145,  152.     See  Canon  Law  ;  Usury). 

[Newman,  The  Politics  of  Aristotle  (Oxf.  1887), 
i.  pp.  125-138;  ii.  pp.  165-208.— Jowett,  The 
Politics  of  Aristotle  (Oxf.  1885),  vol.  ii.  pp.  24-37, 
especially  p.  35,  where  will  be  found  a  convenient 
table  of  the  various  divisions  of  ktt^tlkt},  which  we 
are  permitted  to  reproduce  here  in  English  : — 

The  art  of  acquisition  {kttjtlkti  :  but  xpT/Marto-rt/c?] 
is  sometimes  used  in  this  wide  sense). 

1.  Hunting  (a)  of  wild  beasts  {b)  of  those 
who  are  "  by  nature  slaves." 

2.  xp77/iaTt(rTi/c'?7  (c.  9,  §  1),  the  science  or 

art  of  wealth. 

(1)  Natural,  including 

{a)  keeping  of  cattle,  flocks,  etc. 

(b)  agriculture  (including  cultivation  of 
fruit  trees). 

(c)  bee-keeping. 
{d)  keeping  of  fish. 
{e)  keeping  of  birds. 

(2)  Intermediate, 
(a)  wood-cutting. 
(6)  mining. 

(3)  Unnatural  ( =  fxera^XTjTLK-^,  exchange). 
(a)  trade  (commerce  and  retail  trade). 

1st,  ship-owning. 

2d,  carrying-trade. 

3d,  shopkeeping. 
{b)  money-lending  (usury). 
(c)  labour  for  hire. 

1st,  of  the  skilled  artisan. 

2d,  of  the  unskilled.]         D.  G.  R. 

ARITHMETIC,  Political.  Economic  in- 
quiry was  sometimes  styled  thus  during  the 
early  development  of  the  study  of  economics, 
the  best  known  example  being  found  in  the 
works  of  Sir  William  Petty,  who,  writing  in 
the  latter  half  of  the  17  th  century,  speaks  of 


66 


ARITHMETIC,  POLITICAL 


the  mode  in  which  he  conducted  his  economic 
investigations — a  mode  which  later  inquirers 
have  scarcely  been  able  to  improve  on — thus  : 
' '  The  Method  I  take  to  do  this,  is  not  yet  very 
usual ;  for  instead  of  using  only  comparative 
and  superlative  Words,  and  intellectual  Argi\- 
ments,  I  have  taken  the  Course  (as  a  Specimen 
of  the  Political  Arithmetick  I  have  long  aimed 
at)  to  express  myself  in  Terms  of  Number, 
Weight,  or  Measure  ;  to  use  only  Arguments  of 
Sense,  and  to  consider  only  such  Causes,  as 
have  visible  Foundations  in  Nature  ;  leaving 
those  that  depend  upon  the  mutable  Minds, 
Opinions,  Appetites,  and  Passions  of  particular 
Men,  to  the  Consideration  of  others :  Really 
professing  myself  as  unable  to  speak  satis- 
factorily upon  those  Grounds  (if  they  may  be 
called  Grounds,)  as  to  foretell  the  Cast  of  a 
Dye  ;  to  play  well  at  Tennis,  Billiards,  or  Bowls 
(without  long  Practice,)  by  Virtue  of  the  most 
elaborate  Conceptions  that  have  ever  been 
written  De  Projedilihus  et  Missilihus,  or  of  the 
Angles  of  Incidence  and  Reflection  "  (p.  98). 

Several  Essays  in  Political  Arithmetick,  by  Sir 
William  Petty,  London  (Fourth  edition),  1755. 

ARITHMETIC,  Political.  History  of. 
The  name  of  this  mother  science,  both  of 
statistics  and  of  political  economy  in  England 
can  be  traced  to  Sir  William  Petty's  Discourse 
made  before  the  Royal  Society  the  S  6th  of  November 
1674,  Concerning  the  use  of  duplicate  proportions 
in  sundry  important  particulars,  London,  1674 
(the  Epistle  Dedicatory  to  His  Grace  William, 
Lord  Duke  of  Newcastle).  * '  There  is, "  he  says, 
"a. political  arithmetic  and  a  geometrical  justice 
to  be  yet  further  cultivated  in  the  world  ;  the 
errors  and  defects  whereof  neither  wit,  rhetoric, 
nor  interest  can  more  than  palliate,  never  cure. 
For  falsity,  disproportion,  and  inconsistence 
cannot  be  rectified  by  any  sermocinations, 
though  made  all  of  figurate  and  measured 
periods,  pronounced  in  tune  and  cadence, 
through  the  most  advantageous  organs  ;  much 
less  by  grandisonous  or  euphonical  nonsence 
farded  with  formality ;  no  more  than  vicious 
wines  can  be  remedied  with  brandy  and  honey, 
or  ill  cookery  with  enormous  proportions  of 
spice  and  sugar :  Nam  Pes  nolunt  maU  ad- 
ministrari."  Besides  the  founder  of  this  new 
science  other  eminent  British  writers  laboured 
on  the  subject  of  "political  arithmetic,"  desir- 
ing to  supply  by  its  means  solid  arguments  in 
favour  of  the  economical  superiority  of  the 
nation.  They  extended  the  field  of  investiga- 
tion to  the  extent  and  productiveness  of  land 
and  population,  considering  them  to  be  the 
real  sources  of  national  riches.  These  com- 
putations could  be  no  more  than  estimates  of 
complex  facts  of  political  interest,  starting  from 
the  most  typical  and  calculable  instances. 
Though  Adam  Smith  confesses  not  to  have 
great  faith  in  political  arithmetic  (Wealth  of 
Nations,  bk.  iv.   ch.  v.),  its  conclusions  have 


often  been  affirmed  by  later  investigations  and 
its  methods  followed  by  modern  statists. 

This  method  is  exemplified  by  the  Natural 
and  Political  Observations  mentioned  in  a  follow- 
ing Index  and  made  upon  the  Bills  of  Mortality, 
By  John  Graunt,  citizen  of  London,  With  Pefer- 
ence  to  the  Government,  Religion,  Trade,  Growth^ 
Ayer,  Diseases,  and  the  several  changes  of  the 
said  City.  London,  1662.  By  an  ingenious 
analysis  of  the  bills  of  mortality  (after  1603), 
Graunt  constructed  a  rude  statistical  statement 
of  births,  deaths,  and  disease,  the  very  begin- 
nings of  vital  statistics. 

Sir  W.  Petty  used  political  arithmetic  to  in- 
quire into  the  wealth  of  the  nation,  taking  some- 
times the  annual  consumption,  sometimes  the 
poll  and  other  taxes  as  basis.  His  followers 
were  Gregory  King  (1696),  whose  name  is  con- 
nected with  the  laws  of  prices  ;  Ch.  Davenant 
(1656-1714),  Erasmus  Philips  (1725),  A. 
HooKE  (1750),  Mitchell  (1767),  Pulteney 
(1779),  Arthur  Young  in  the  second  part  of  his 
Political  Arithmetick  (1779),  the  first  being  a 
treatise  on  agricultural  politics  (1774),  and 
G.  Chalmers  (1783,  1812).  Decaying  since 
Davenant,  this  branch  of  political  arithmetic 
reached  its  end  with  the  inquiries  founded  upon 
the  new  income  tax  [introduced  in  1843]  ;  H. 
Beeke  (1800)  ;  W.  Playfair  (1801,  author  of 
a  Breviary  showing  on  a  principle  entirely  new 
the  resources  of  every  state  and  kingdom  in 
Europe),  London,  1801,  and  P.  Colquhoun 
(1815),  still  professing  the  old  method. 

In  France  Vauban,  Dixme  Roy  ale  (1707), 
and  later  on  Quesnay  and  Mirabeau  (1760), 
Lavoisier  (1791),  and  Lagrange  (1796)  tried 
to  calculate  the  production  and  consumption 
and  revenue  of  their  nation,  relying  on  the 
doctrines  known  under  the  title  of  Agricul- 
tural Systems  (q.v.) 

To  the  inquiries  into  the  number  of  popu- 
lation and  its  increase,  about  which  numerous 
controversies  had  taken  place  (Hume  v.  Wal- 
lace, Temple  v.  Bell,  Hewlett  v.  Price,  and 
at  last  Mai  thus  v.  Godwin),  the  census  of  1801 
put  an  end.  The  inquiries  on  the  movement 
of  population  were  continued  and  developed  in 
the  most  remarkable  manner  by  E.  Halley,  An 
Estimate  of  the  Degrees  of  Mortality,  1693. 
He  gave  the  first  exact  account  of  the  chances  of 
life  and  hints  as  to  its  application  to  insurances 
and  annuities  on  lives.  His  followers  in  Eng- 
land were  Derham  (1713),  Demoivre  (1725), 
Shout  (1750),  Simpson  (1742),  Hodgson 
(1747),  Brakenridge  (1755),  Price  (1771), 
Heysham  (1797)  ;— see  C.  Walford,  The  Inmr- 
ance  Cyclopaedia,  vol.  i.,  Annuities  on  Lives  and 
Bills  of  Mortality.  This  branch  of  political 
arithmetic,  concerning  insurance  calculations, 
has  survived  the  others  and  is  sometimes  still 
called  by  its  old  name. 

Following  this  line  of  inquiry,  W.  Kersseboom 
(1777)  in  Holland,  A.  Deparcieux  (1746)  in 


ARITHMETICAL  RATIO  OR  PROGRESSION— ARMSTRONG 


57 


France,  Wargentin  (1764-1767)  in  Sweden,  in- 
quired into  the  average  probabilities  of  life. 
The  most  systematic  of  this  series  of  writers  is 
John  Peter  SiJssMiLCH  {Gottliche  Ordnung,  1741, 
4th  ed.,  1775).  Taking  the  regularity  of  the 
phenomena  of  mortality  and  conjugal  fertility,  as 
well  as  that  of  the  rarest  events  of  life  for  a 
proof  of  divine  interference,  his  work  became  the 
forerunner  of  Malthus's  theory  of  population 
as  well  as  of  Quetelet's  moral  statistics. 

It  is  besides  worth  notice  that  modern 
Demography  {q.v.)  comprehends  nearly  the 
same  domain  of  statistical  inquiry  which  was 
originally  cultivated  by  political  arithmetic  ;  it 
deals  with  the  numerical  apprehension  of  facts 
"concerning  trade  and  government,  others 
concerning  the  air,  countries,  seasons,  fruitful- 
ness,  health,  diseases,  longevity,  and  the  pro- 
portions between  the  sex,  of  ages  of  mankind  " 
(John  Graunt,  Natural  and  Political  Observa- 
tions, 1662.     The  Epistle  Dedicatory). 

[See  Davenant,  Of  the  use  of  Political  Arith- 
metic (1698);  Works,  vol.  i.  p.  128.— Melon, 
Essai  politique  sur  le  commerce,  2d.  ed.  1736, 
ch.  xxiv. — Egerton  Brydges,  Censura  Literaria, 
1805,  vol,  1.  pp.  59-79. — Ingram,  History  of 
Political  Economy,  p,  51. — John,  Geschichte  der 
Statistik,  pp.  155-273. — Meitzen,  Geschichte, 
Theorie,  und  Technik  der  Statistik,  pp.  15-181. — 
J.  B.  Say,  Cours  complet,  part  ix.  ch.  ill. — 
M'Culloch,  Literature  of  Political  P2conomy,  pp. 
211,  258,  271.— R.  Giffen,  The  Growth  of  Capital, 
1890. — Gabaglio,  Storia  e  teoria  generate  delta 
statistica,  1880, — H.  Westergaard,  Die  Grundziige 
der  Theorie  der  Statistik,  1890,  pp.  253-270,— 
Farr,  Vital  Statistics,  1885.]  s.  b. 

ARITHMETICAL  RATIO  OR  PROGRES- 
SION. Three  or  more  quantities  are  in  arith- 
metical progression  when  they  increase  or 
decrease  by  a  common  difference,  e.g.  1,  4,  7,  10, 
where  the  common  difference  is  3  ;  2,  2^,  3,  3^, 
where  it  is  \  ;  and  25,  21,  17,  13,  where  it  is  4. 
Malthus  introduced  the  term  into  political 
economy  in  comparing  the  possible  increase 
of  food  with  that  of  population.  He  thought 
that  after  a  country  was  as  fully  peopled  as 
Great  Britain  was  in  1798,  the  addition  which 
could  be  made  in  the  course  of  any  given 
period,  such  as  twenty-five  years,  to  the  normal 
annual  production  of  food  would  actually  de- 
crease as  the  annual  production  of  food  grew 
larger.  But  for  the  purpose  of  argument  he 
was  willing  to  suppose  that  instead  of  decreas- 
ing, the  possible  periodical  addition  might 
remain  the  same.  Under  this  supposition,  if 
the  annual  production  of  food  were  always 
increased  as  much  as  possible,  it  would  be 
represented  at  the  end  of  successive  equal 
intervals  of  time  by  quantities  in  arithmetical 
progression,  or,  as  Malthus  put  it,  the  pro- 
duction of  food  would  increase  in  an  arithmetical' 
ratio.  Population,  on  the  other  hand,  Malthus 
described  as  having  the  capacity  and  tendency 
to  increase  in  a  Geometkical  Ratio  {q.v.) 


[Todhunter's  A  Igebra.  —  Malthus,  Essay  on  the 
Principle  of  Population,  bk.  1.  ch.  i.,  and  "Popu- 
lation" in  the  E7icyclopcedia  Britannica,  4th  ed., 
Supplement  1824.]  e.  c. 

ARLES  OR  ARRHES.  Earnest- money- 
money  paid  on  initiation  of  a  bargain  to  secure 
its  fulfilment. 

ARMED  NEUTRALITY.  The  right  of 
neutral  states  to  trade  with  belligerents  was  one 
of  the  most  important  questions  in  the  18th 
century.  According  to  the  policy  of  the  Mer- 
cantile System  every  power  tried  to  monopolise 
the  trade  with  its  own  Colonies.  But  in  time 
of  war  such  a  monopoly  was  often  rendered  im- 
possible, and  a  belligerent  found  it  necessary  to 
relax  its  restrictions  in  order  to  receive  colonial 
produce  in  neutral  ships.  England,  in  its  fre- 
quent wars  with  France,  endeavoured  to  pre- 
vent this  jiractice,  and  acted  upon  the  old- 
established  principle  that  "the  goods  of  an 
enemy  found  on  a  neutral  ship  are  liable  to 
seizure."  The  maritime  ascendency  of  England 
enabled  it  to  exercise  its  right  of  search  with  an 
efficiency  that  was  resented  by  the  neutral 
powers,  especially  as  ports  were  often  declared 
to  be  blockaded  when  there  was  no  sufficient 
force  to  close  them.  In  1780,  when  France  and 
Spain  were  supporting  the  American  colonies  of 
Great  Britain  against  the  mother  country,  the 
northern  states,  headed  by  Russia,  concluded 
the  Armed  Neutrality  to  protect  their  interests. 
The  chief  principles  which  they  laid  down  were, 
that  neutral  vessels  may  carry  all  goods  of 
belligerents  which  are  not  contraband  of  war, 
and  that  a  Blockade  need  not  be  respected  un- 
less there  are  a  sufficient  number  of  ships  to 
enforce  it.  This  league  was  extremely  advan- 
tageous to  the  enemies  of  England,  because  it 
protected  them  from  the  complete  interruption 
of  their  commerce  which  England  was  endeav- 
ouring to  bring  about.  It  was  only  gradually 
broken  up  by  treaties  between  England  and  the 
various  powers  (see  Search,  Right  of). 

In  1800,  during  the 'war  with  revolutionary 
France,  the  northern  states  concluded  a  second 
Anned  Neutrality  on  the  same  lines  as  the 
league  of  1780.  England  still  refused  to  ac- 
cept the  principles  thus  laid  down,  but  this 
time  she  was  able  to  act  with  more  energy  than 
on  the  previous  occasion.  Copenhagen  was 
bombarded  and  the  Danish  fleet  seized.  In 
1801  the  death  of  the  Czar  Paul  broke  up  the 
Armed  Neutrality,  and  a  convention  at  St. 
Petersburg  fixed  limits  to  the  light  of  search 
and  agreed  that  a  blockade  must  be  efficient  to 
be  respected.  But  the  gi-eat  questions  at  issue 
remained  unsettled,  and  to  this  day  the  extent 
to  which  a  belligerent  is  entitled  to  damage  the 
trade  of  its  enemy  is  a  subject  of  discussion. 

[Wheaton,  International  Law. — Lecky,  History 
of  England  in  the  ISth  Century. — Alison,  History 
of  Europe.]  R.  l. 

ARMSTRONG,  Clement  (an  English  writer 


58 


ARND— ART  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY 


about  1530)  complains  of  the  speculations  in 
wool  of  merchant  staplers,  who  drive  by  importa- 
tions of  foreign  commodities  the  money  out  of 
the  realm  and  destroy  husbandry  by  converting 
the  cornfields  into  sheepwalks.  He  proposes 
to  erect  a  staple  of  woollen  cloth  in  London,  4;o 
restore  tillage,  and  to  set  people  to  work,  for 
"  the  hoU  welth  of  the  body  of  the  realme  risith 
out  of  the  labours  and  workes  of  the  common 
peple "  (p.  61).  Sermons  and  Dedaracions 
agaynst  Popish  Cdremonies,  reprinted  in  Drei 
volksvdrtschaftliche  Denkschriften  aus  der  Zeit 
Heinrichs  VIII.  von  England.  Zum  ersten  Male 
herausgegeben  von  Reinhold  Pauli,  23,  Bd.  Ab- 
handlungen  der  K.  Gesellsch.  der  Wissenschaften 
zu  Gdttiugen,  1878. — G.  Schanz,  Englische  Han- 
delspolUik  gegen  Ende  des  Mittelalters,  Bd.  i.  pp. 
83,  475. — Cunningham,  The  Growth  of  English 
Industry  and  Commercey  1890,  p.  292  n.       s.  b. 

ARND,  Karl  (a  German  economist),  bom  at 
Fulda,  1788,  was  an  architect  in  Hesse,  and 
died,  1877,  at  Hanau.  He  was  a  warm 
advocate  of  Free  Trade  and  of  one  Single  Tax 
on  rent.  He  opposed  Ricardo's  theories  and 
his  German  followers,  as  well  as  Fr.  List's 
protectionist  views. 

Dieneicere  Guterlehre,  1821. — Die  naturgem&sse 
Volksvnrtschaft,  1845. — Die  Volkswirtschaft,  he- 
griindet  auf  und  andelhare  Naturgesetze,  1863. — 
Die  Befreiung  der  Bodenrente  und  die  Emancipa- 
tion des  Bauernstandes,  1865. — Adam  Smith's  des 
jungemPrufung  der  heutigen  volksvnrtschaftlichen 
Systeme,  1867 ;  see  Roscher,  Oeschichie  der  Na- 
tionaZokonomik  in  Deutschland,  p.  500 ;  and 
Handworterbuch  der  Staatswissenschaften,  heraus- 
gegeben von  Conrad,  Lexis  und  Loening,  1890, 
vol.  i.  p.  931.  s.  B. 

ARNOULD,  Ambroise-Marie  (1750-1812) 
a  French  economist,  was  director  of  the  board 
of  commerce  under  the  revolution.  His  works 
contain  valuable  information  upon  the  theory  of 
trade,  the  state  of  the  Balance  of  Trade  in 
Europe  during  the  18th  century,  French  finances, 
etc.  He  advocated  the  division  of  France  into 
departments  according  to  their  homogeneous 
economical  nature  ;  and  appealed  to  all  mari- 
time nations  to  confederate  against  the  menac- 
ing power  of  England. 

De  la  Balance  du  Commerce^  2  vols.,  1791. — 
Repartition  de  la  contribution  fonci^re,  1791. — 
Systeme  maritime  et  politique  des  Europeens  pen- 
dant le  18e.  siecle,  1797. — Histoire  generate  des 
finances  dp.  la  France^  1806.  s.  B. 

ARRANGEMENT  WITH  CREDITORS. 
See  Bankruptcy,  Law  and  Administration. 

ARRANGEMENT,  Deed  of.  An  instru- 
ment embodying  an  agreement  between  a 
debtor  and  the  general  body  of  his  creditors  for 
the  purpose  of  modifying  the  debtor's  obliga- 
tions without  resorting  to  bankruptcy  proceed- 
ings. Some  additional  security  is  frequently 
given  in  such  cases,  but  the  fact  of  the  other 
creditors  foregoing  part  of  their  claims,  and 
thus  making  the  debtor's  position  an  easier  one,  is 


considered  to  be  a  valid  consideration  for  the  in- 
dulgence granted  by  any  individual  creditor.  An 
arrangement  of  this  nature  is,  of  course,  binding 
on  those  creditors  only  who  expressly  assent  to  it. 
The  Deed  of  Arrangement  Act  1887  (50  &  51 
Vict.  c.  57),  provides  that  a  deed  of  arrange- 
ment is  void  unless  registered  within  a  given 
time  and  stamped  with  an  ad  valorem  stamp. 
The  register  is  open  to  the  public.  The  act  de- 
fines a  deed  of  arrangement  so  as  to  include  (a) 
any  assignment  of  property  ;  (6)  any  agreement 
for  a  composition ;  (c)  any  deed  of  inspectorship ; 
(c?)  any  letter  of  licence  to  carry  on  business  with 
a  view  to  the  payment  of  debts  ;  (e)  any  agree- 
ment for  the  carrying  on  or  winding  up  a  business 
for  the  benefit  of  creditors.  e.  s. 

ARREARS.  Sums  remaining  unpaid  after 
they  are  due  ;  for  example — interest  in  arrear  ; 
arrears  of  dividend  ;  instalments  in  arrear ; 
arrears  of  wages,  of  rent,  etc.  ;  contracts  in 
arrear,  etc.  Such  arrears  often  involve  penalties 
(see  Contract,  Lavv^  of  ;  Wages). 

ARREST.  A  process  of  the  Admiralty 
Division  of  the  High  Court  by  which  the 
removal  of  a  ship  or  cargo  pending  an  action 
referring  to  the  same  is  prevented.  Certain 
actions  in  that  Division  (called  actions  inrem.^ 
are  not  broug'ht  against  a  personal  defendant, 
but  against  a  ship  or  a  cargo  against  which  the 
claim  is  directed.  The  owner  may,  on  giving 
security,  prevent  the  arrest  by  the  entry  of  a 
caveat  (s.v.  Caveat)  or,  after  the  arrest  haa 
been  effected,  obtain  a  release.  e.  s. 

ARRESTMENT  (Scots  law).  Attachment 
of  debt  either  before  or  after  judgment. 

ARRESTMENT  JURISDICTIONIS  FUN- 
DAND^  CAUSA.    See  Jurisdiction,  Scotch. 

ARRIVABENE,  Giovanni,  Count,  born  in 
1787  in  Mantua,  died  June  1881.  Condemned 
to  death  for  political  conspiracy  in  1824,  he  fled 
abroad.  In  1847  he  was  a  promoter  of  the 
economical  congress  of  Brussels.  His  high 
position  amongst  political  men,  and  in  cultivated 
society,  gave  him  a  standing  as  an  economist 
which  he  otherwise  would  not  have  held.  He 
was  a  friend  of  N.  W.  Senior  and  translated 
some  of  his  best  writings.  Arrivabene's  writ- 
ings were  collected  in  1870  under  the  title, 
Scritti  morali  ed  economici,  Firenze.  A  part  of 
his  life  has  been  told  by  himself  in  Un  epoca 
delta  mia  vita,  Memorie,  Torino,  1860.  The 
book  which  first  established  his  credit  was 
WTitten  by  him  in  London,  Di  varie  society  e 
istituzioni  di  heneficenza  in  Londra,  1828, 
Lugano.  m.  p. 

ART  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY.  By  the 
majority  of  English  economists  for  the  last  half 
century  political  economy  has  been  held  to  be  in 
itself  a  positive  science,  concerned  exclusively 
with  the  investigation  of  uniformities,  and  not 
directly  formulating  a  single  practical  rule  of 
action.  While  the  knowledge  it  affords  may  be 
turned  to  practical  account  by  tlie  legislator  or 


ARTEL— AKTICLES  OF  ASSOCIATION 


59 


the  social  reformer,  it  is  described  as  in  it- 
self standing  neutral  between  competing  social 
schrmes.  In  other  words,  a  sharp  line  of  distinc- 
tion is  drawn  between  economic  science,  and  tlie 
application  of  economic  science  to  practice.  A 
very  different  view  is  taken  by  the  majority  of 
continental  economists,  who,  generally  speaking, 
make  little  attempt  to  separate  theoretical  and 
practical  problems.  Adequately  to  treat  these 
problems  apart  from  one  another  is  even  main- 
tained to  be  an  impossibility,  and  hence  it  is 
denied  that  political  economy  can  properly  be 
regarded  as  a  purely  positive  science.  Its  prim- 
ary function,  according  to  this  view,  is  to  direct 
conduct  to  given  ends  rather  than  merely  to  in- 
vestigate facts  qf  a  given  kind. 

It  has  been  further  maintained  that  English 
economists  are  themselves  inconsistent,  and 
that,  professing  to  construct  a  pure  science  of 
economics,  they  do  in  fact  build  up  an  economic 
art.  It  is  pointed  out,  for  instance,  that 
nearly  the  whole  of  the  last  book  of  Mill's 
political  economy  is  concerned  with  the  discus- 
sion of  practical  questions.  It  would  not  be 
difficult  to  explain  away  tliis  apparent  incon- 
sistency, so  far  as  our  leading  economists  arc 
themselves  concerned  ;  but  at  the  same  time  it 
cannot  be  maintained  that  the  distinction 
which  they  profess  to  draw  between  political 
economy  and  its  applications  has  ever  been 
clearly  gi-asped  beyond  what  may  be  called  the 
inner  circle  of  their  disciples.  One  consequence 
of  this  has  been  grave  misconception  as  to  the 
true  meaning  of  many  of  the  laws  which  they 
have  formulated.  They  have  often  been  under- 
stood to  prescribe  what  ought  to  be,  when  their 
sole  intention  has  been  to  determine  what  is. 
Partly  to  correct  this  error,  and  partly  for 
other  reasons,  it  has  been  proposed  explicitly 
to  recognise  the  twofold  aspect  of  economic 
inquiry  by  dethiitely  formulating  an  economic 
art  as  well  as  an  economic  science. 

[See,  in  particular,  Sidgwick,  Principles  of  Pol- 
itical Economy,  1887,  p.  395.  The  art  is 
described  by  Dr.  Sidgwick  as  consisting  mainly 
of  the  theory  of  what  ought  to  be  done  by 
government  to  improve  production  or  distribu- 
tion, and  to  provide  for  governmental  expenditure. 
A  similar  division  of  economic  doctrine  was 
indicated  by  Senior,  Political  Economy,  Intro- 
duction, p.  2  et  seq.,  ed.  1854,  and  the  distinction 
is  also  put  clearly  by  Professor  Cossa.  The  latter 
writer  describes  the  art  of  political  economy  as 
studying  economic  phenomena  with  the  immediate 
aim  of  providing  safe  rules  for  administration,  or 
of  directing  economic  institutions,  so  that  they 
may  conduce  to  the  general  welfare.  Compare, 
further,  Keynes'  Scope  and  Method  of  Political 
Economy,  ch.  ii.,  note  B.]  j.  N.  K. 

ARTEL  (Russian  for  "gang,")  is  used 
specially  of  the  Russian  associations  of  inde- 
pendent workmen  undertaking  a  job  in  concert 
and  dividing  its  gains  equally.  This  primitive 
form  of  artd  is  still  to  be  found  (e.g.  among  the 


fishermen  of  Archangel).  But  the  peasants,  at 
least  in  the  less  fertile  districts,  find  greater 
security  in  working  for  a  contractor  ;  and  the 
"gangs"  so  Avorking  have  no  co-operative 
feature,  except  occasionally  the  common  pur- 
chase of  ])rovisions.  In  towns  the  arid  is  often 
simply  a  trade  guild  with  mutual  responsibility ; 
thus  that  of  bank  porters  is  jointly  responsible 
for  its  several  members.  Since  the  Emancipa- 
tion, 1861,  various  local  councils  throughout 
Russia  have  tried  to  establish  associations  for 
production,  with  scant  success.  The  workmen's 
own  attempts  have  been  more  fortunate,  es- 
pecially in  popular  banks.  But  the  new 
co-operative  societies  will  not  be  a  mere  re- 
vival of  the  old  artel.  The  industrial  village 
of  Struve  &  Co.,  engineers  (founded  1885), 
is  on  the  model  of  Pullman  City,  U.S.  The 
communism  of  the  sect  called  Douchobornians 
differs  both  from  true  co-operation  and  from  the 
old  art^l  (see  Banks,  Popular  ;  Co-operation). 

[Les  A  rteles  et  le  Moiivement  Co-operatif  en  Russie, 
W.  Longuinine,  (Paris,  1886). — Russia,  Mackenzie 
Wallace,  ch.  vi.  (1877). — Proprietcl  Capitalista, 
Loria  (1889),  vol.  ii.  pp.  iSQ-7.— Political  Science 
Quarterly  (New  York),  I\Iarch  1887, — Rabbeno,  Le 
Societd  Co-operative,  Part  I.  (Milan,  1889).  See 
too  the  article  by  \V.  Stieda  in  the  Jahrbiicher  fUr 
Nationalok.  und  Statist  (Neue  Folge),  vi.  pp.  192- 
230.  The  Russian  authorities  include  IsajefT, 
Kalachoff,  Nemirotf,  Vreden,  Scherbina,  and  Novo- 
selsky.]  j.  B. 

ARTICLES  OF  APPRENTICESHIP.  Writ- 
ten agreements  by  which  the  master  })romises 
to  instruct,  and  the  ap})rentice  promises  to 
learn  and  serve.  The  master  frequently  receives 
a  premium,  which  must  be  set  forth  as  the 
consideration  of  the  agreement  for  the  purpose 
of  ascertaining  the  stamp  duty.  Seven  years 
were  formerly  the  minimum  period  of  ap- 
prenticeship, but  there  is  now  no  fixed  period. 
The  master  is  entitled  to  all  the  apprentice's 
earnings  and  has  certain  other  rights  under  the 
contract  notwithstanding  the  apprentice's  in- 
fancy, but  he  cannot  bring  an  action  to  enforce 
the  covenants  of  an  infant  apprentice,  and  the 
apprentice  may  disaffirm  the  contract  on  attain- 
ing the  age  of  twenty -one.  The  master's 
bankruptcy  determines  the  contract.  Disputes 
between  masters  and  apprentices  to  the  business 
of  a  workman  may  be  brought  before  the  justices, 
who  may  make  an  order  directing  the  apprentice 
to  perform  his  duties  under  the  apprenticeship, 
or  may  rescind  the  instrument  of  Apprentice- 
ship (q.v.)  (38  &  39  Vict.  c.  90,  §§  5-7).    e.  s. 

ARTICLES  OF  ASSOCIATION  contain  the 
regulations  concerning  the  constitution  and 
management  of  joint-stock  companies  registered 
under  the  Companies  Acts.  The  first  schedule 
of  the  Companies  Act  1862,  Table  A,  contains 
a  set  of  regulations  which  may  be  adopted 
wholly  or  in  part,  and  which  in  the  case  of  a 
company  limited  by  shares  are  deemed  to  be 
adopted  by  the  company,  if  the  memorandum 


60 


ARTICLES  OF  ROUP— ASSAY 


of  association  is  not  on  registration  accompanied 
by  articles,  or  in  so  far  as  the  articles  do  not 
expressly  exclude  or  modify  them.  In  the 
case  of  a  company  limited  by  guarantee,  or  of 
an  unlimited  company,  articles  of  association 
must  always  accompany  the  memorandum. 
While  the  Memorandum  of  Association  can- 
not be  varied  even  by  the  unanimous  decision 
of  aU  the  shareholders  unless  such  variation  is 
confirmed  by  the  court  under  the  provisions  of 
the  act  of  1890  (except  with  regard  to  the 
amount  and  division  of  the  capital),  articles  of 
association  may  be  varied  by  special  resolution 
and  the  company  cannot  deprive  itself  of  its 
power  to  alter  them.  In  a  conflict  between  the 
articles  and  the  memorandum  the  former  must 
give  way.  Articles  of  association  generally  con- 
tain most  of  the  following  heads  :  (1)  Prelimin- 
ary (definitions,  commencement  of  business,  allot- 
ment of  shares,  etc.),  (2)  Certificates,  (3)  Calls, 
(4)  Transfer  and  Transmission  of  Shares  and 
Stock,  (5)  Share  Warrants,  (6)  Forfeiture  and 
Lien,  (7)  Conversion  of  Shares  into  Stock,  (8) 
Increase  of  Capital,  (9)  Reduction  of  Capital, 
Consolidation  and  Sub-division  of  Shares,  (10) 
Surrender  of  Shares,  (11)  Borrowing  Powers, 
(12)  General  Meetings,  (13)  Votes  of  Members, 
(14)  Directors  (qualification,  etc.),  (15)  Proceed- 
ings and  Powers  of  Directors,  (16)  Officers,  (17) 
Dividends,  (18)  Accounts  and  Audit,  (19) 
Notice,  (20)  Arbitration,  (21)  Winding  up  (see 
Joint-Stock  Companies,  etc.  ;  see  Partner- 
ship ;  Limited  Partnerships  Act,  1907,  App.) 

E.  S. 

ARTICLES  OF  ROUP  (Scotch).  Conditions 
of  sale  by  auction. 

ARTISAN.  An  artisan  is  a  person  employed 
in  the  industrial  arts,  formerly  distinguished 
from  other  labourers  by  the  fact  that  he  works 
for  himself.  This,  however,  is  only  true  of  a 
few  remaining  village  artisans,  such  as  the 
blacksmith  and  the  carpenter.  The  early 
English  artisans  were  few  in  number.  They 
supplied  labour  only,  their  employers  finding 
materials.  In  course  of  time  they  became 
organised  in  guilds,  at  least  in  the  towns  (see 
Gild).  The  15th  century  saw  the  rise  of  the 
capitalist  artisan,  but  the  invention  of  machinery 
paved  the  way  for  the  modern  forms  of  industry 
under  which  production  is  carried  on  by  associated 
labour  working  under  capitalists.  The  artisan 
is  now  usually  a  workman  employed  by  others, 
though  in  some  districts  and  in  some  villages 
a  few  of  the  old  capitalist  artisans  still  remain. 

[Six  Centuries  of  Work  and  Wages,  by  J.  E. 
T.  Rogers,  Loudon,  1884. — Labour  in  Europe  and 
America,  by  Edward  Young,  Washington,  1870. — 
Conflicts  of  Capital  and  Labour,  by  George 
Howell,  London,  1878  (see  Labour,  Skilled).] 

J.  E.  c.  M. 

ARTS  AND  CRAFTS.  See  Corporations 
OF  Arts  and  Trades. 

AS.     A  Roman  coin,  of  an  alloy  of  copper 


and  tin  called  aes,  of  different  weights  and  com 
position  at  diff'erent  times.  Originally  1  lb., 
reduced  to  2  oz.  after  the  first  Punic  War,   to 

1  oz.  during  the  second  Punic  War,  and  finally, 
by  the  Papirian  Law,  to  \  oz.  Design  :  a  sheep, 
(jjecus,  hence  the  word  pecuniary),  an  ox,  or  a 

sow.  F.  E.  A. 

ASGILL,  John,  born  at  Hanley  Castle, 
Worcestershire,  1659,  called  to  the  English  bar 
1692,  expelled  from  the  Irish  House  of  Commons 
1703,  and  from  the  British  Parliament  1707, 
for  an  eccentric  pamphlet  contending  that  man 
could  be  translated  to  heaven  without  dying. 
He  left  this  world  in  the  ordinary  way,  1738. 
He  wrote  the  following  economic  works. 

Several  Assertions  proved  in  order  to  create 
another  Species  of  Money  than  Gold  and  Silver, 
London,  1696,  8vo  (based  on  the  theory  "  rnan 
deals  in  nothing  but  earth  ; "  a  contemporary 
pamphlet  asserts  that  it  is  plagiarised  from  J. 
Briscoe's  {q.v.)  Discourse  on  the  Late  Funds,  1694, 
4to). — Essay  on  a  Registry  for  Titles  of  Land, 
London,  1698,  12mo  (4th  ed.,  1758).—^  Collec- 
tion of  Tracts,  London,  1715,  8  parts,  8vo. — Ab- 
stract of  the  PvJblick  Funds  Granted  and  Continued 
to  the  Crown  since  1  W.  <h  M.,  London,  1715,  4to 
(reprinted  in  Somers's  Tracts,  1815,  xiii.  pp.  730- 
742).  »  H.  r.  t. 

ASHBURTON,  Alexander  Baring,  first 
lord,  second  son  of  Sir  Francis  Baring,  was  born 
1774.  He  visited  America  on  business  connected 
with  his  father's  firm,  the  head  of  which  he  be- 
came in  1810  ;  he  was  president  of  the  Board  of 
T  RADE  in  1 8  3  4 ,  and  raised  to  the  peerage  in  1 8  3  5 . 
He  concluded  the  boundary  treaty  between  the 
United  States  and  England  at  Washington  in 
1842,  and  died  1848.     He  wrote  — 

Inquiry  into  the  Causes  and  Consequences  of  the 
Orders  in  Council  and  an  Examination  of  the  Con- 
duct of  Great  Britain  towards  the  neutral  Commerce 
of  America,  London,  1808,  8vo  (two  editions  ;  op- 
poses restrictions  on  commerce). — The  Financial 
and  Commercial  Crisis  Considered,  London,  1847, 
8vo  (three  editions  ;  to  show  how  mischievous  at 
that  date  was  the  Bank  Charter  Act  of  1844). 

H.  R.  T. 

ASHLEY,  John,  member  of  council  in  Bar- 
badoes,  died  at  Blackheath,  Kent,  1751.  He 
wrote — 

The  Sugar  Trade,  with  the  Incumbrances  thereon 
laid  open,  London,  1734,  8vo. — Some  Observations 
on  a  direct  Importation  of  Sugar  from  the  British 
Islands,  London,  1735,  4to. — Memoirs  and  Con- 
siderations concerning  the  Trade  and  Revenues  of 
the  British  Colo7iies  in  America,  Loudon,  1740-43, 

2  parts,  8vo.  H.  R.  T. 

ASSAY.  The  assay  methods  for  Silver  and 
Gold  are  analogous,  in  so  far  that  both  are  puri- 
fied by  the  action  of  a  solvent,  but  the  base 
metals  are  removed  from  silver  by  fused 
litharge,  while  in  its  turn  silver  is  parted 
from  gold  by  nitric  acid. 

If  the  silver  has  been  associated  only  with 
readily  oxidisable  metals,  especially  copper,  as 
is    usually   the    case  when    silver    coins    are 


ASSAY— ASSESSMENT 


61 


assayed,  it  then  only  becomes  a  question  of 
providing  the  amount  of  lead  necessary  to 
furnish,  by  oxidation,  sufficient  litharge  to 
dissolve  the  oxides  and  carry  them  away.  If, 
however,  the  silver  is  associated  witli  gold,  the 
latter  metal  resists  oxidation,  and  will  remain 
on  the  cupel  with  the  silver.  The  cupellation 
stage  must  then  be  supplemented  by  a 
"parting"  operation,  that  is,  the  silver  must 
be  dissolved  away  by  some  solvent  that  will 
leave  the  gold  untouched,  and  for  this  purpose 
nitric  acid  is  universally  employed.  If  the 
silver  contains  but  a  minute  particle  of  gold, 
the  presence  of  the  latter  will  be  indicated  by 
a  few  specks  of  bro\vn  powder  left  at  the 
bottom  of  the  vessel  in  which  the  silver  is 
dissolved  ;  if,  however,  the  silver  contains 
about  one  thu'd  of  its  mass  of  gold,  and  has 
been  extended  into  a  strip,  the  gold  will 
remain,  after  the  action  of  the  acid,  as  a  co- 
herent band  retaining  the  original  form  of  the 
strip  but  much  reduced  in  volume.  There  is 
this  difference  between  the  assay  of  gold  and 
silver.  In  the  case  of  the  cupellation  assay  of 
silver,  the  button  of  metal  has  only  to  be 
removed  from  the  cupel,  and  when  the  adhering 
bone  ash  has  been  removed  with  a  brush,  it 
passes  direct  to  the  balance.  The  process 
would  also  be  sufficient  for  gold,  if  it  contained 
no  other  precious  metal ;  when,  however,  the 
problem  is  to  ascertain  by  assay  how  much 
gold  is  contained  in  an  alloy,  which  may 
contain  silver  or  platinum  and  other  metals  of 
similar  properties,  then  care  must  be  taken 
that  the  amount  of  gold  believed  to  be  jn-esent 
in  the  alloy  does  not  exceed  the  third  part  of 
the  mass,  as  a  larger  proportion  of  gold  would 
protect  the  alloy  from  the  solvent  action  of  the 
acid,  and  the  gi-eater  the  amount  of  gold,  the 
less  perfect  would  be  the  attack  of  the  acid. 
The  first  stage  of  assaying  a  gold  alloy,  say  a 
sovereign,  is  to  melt  it  with  such  an  amount 
of  silver  as  shall  yield  a  button  containing 
rather  less  than  one  third  of  its  weight  of  gold. 
For  the  sake  of  convenience  and  for  the  inci- 
dental advantage  that  the  solvent  action  of 
fused  litharge  removes  copper  and  other 
impurities,  the  first  stage  of  the  assay  of  gold 
is  conducted  on  a  cupel,  the  object  to  be 
attained  being  mainly  to  secure  a  button  of 
gold  and  silver  in  a  convenient  form  for  sub- 
mitting to  the  subsequent  operations.  The 
alloying  stage  would,  however,  be  just  as 
effective  if  it  were  conducted  in  a  small  non- 
porous  receptacle,  such  as  a  small  crucible  of 
glazed  porcelain. 

The  subsequent  operations  are,  flattening  the 
button,  annealing  it,  rolling  it  into  a  strip,  and 
annealing  it  a  second  time.  It  is  then  coiled 
into  a  spiral,  or  cornet,  and  treated  by  two 
successive  portions  of  nitric  acid  in  order  to 
remove  the  silver ;  after  this  the  spiral  of 
spongy  gold,  which  retains  the  original   form 


given  to  the  silver -gold  alloy,  is  heated  to 
redness,  when  it  becomes  bright,  and  is  some- 
times so  coherent  that  it  may  be  unrolled 
without  fracture.  The  cornet  is  then  weighed 
on  a  delicate  balance,  and  its  weight,  compared 
with  that  of  the  portion  of  metal  taken  for 
assay,  affords  a  means  for  readily  calculating 
the  proportion  of  precious  metal  present  in  the 
mass  assayed  (see  Alloy  ;  Periot).     c.  r-a. 

ASSESSED  TAXES.  A  group  of  taxes  "  on 
houses,  carriages,  men-servants,  saddle  and 
carriage  horses,  and  race  horses  "  (Dowell,  His- 
tory of  Taxation,  2d  ed.  vol.  ii.  p.  189).  These 
were  placed  imder  better  supervision  by  W. 
Pitt,  1785,  and  were  intended  to  be  taxes  on 
"  luxuries. "  Hair  powder  and  armorial  bearings 
were  afterwards  added.  The  sporting  and  dog 
duties,  though  not  included  among  assessed 
taxes,  may  be  considered  as  of  an  analogous 
nature.  Some  of  these  taxes,  as  those  on  horses 
and  hair  powder,  have  been  remitted,  but  the 
principle  of  taxing  luxuries  has  been  main- 
tained, though  not  unfrequently  modified,  in 
our  fiscal  system  (see  Taxation,  Taxes,  etc.) 

[Dowell,  History  of  Taxation  and  Taxes  in 
England,  4  vols.,  1888,  2d  ed.] 

ASSESSMENT.  The  official  valuation  of 
income  or  property  for  the  purposes  of  taxation. 
The  word  is  sometimes  used  in  another  sense, 
viz.  the  amount  of  a  tax  a  particular  person  has 
to  pay.  It  was  also  applied  to  certain  taxes 
on  lands  and  goods  levied  during  the  common- 
wealth, and  which  Dowell  (History  of  Taxation, 
London,  1888,  iii.  p.  72)  says  formed  the  link 
between  the  Subsidy  of  the  Tudor  and  earlier 
Stuarts  and  the  Property  Tax  of  William  III. 
Where  a  tax  has  to  be  levied  on  property  or  on 
income,  the  amount  of  such  property  or  income 
must  be  ascertained,  and  this  is  by  no  means  an 
easy  task.  Even  then  the  principles  of  taxation 
may  require  certain  allowances  to  be  deducted 
before  the  taxable  property  is  ascertained.  In 
some  cases  the  assessors  are  officials,  in  other 
cases  they  are  elected  directly  or  indirectly  by 
those  who  pay  the  tax. 

1.  Imperial  Taxation. — In  the  case  of  im- 
perial taxes,  assessment  is  required  for  the 
Land  Tax,  the  inhabited  house  duty,  the  income 
tax,  and  the  Death  Duties.  The  amount  of 
the  land  tax  payable  by  each  parish  is  fixed  by 
statute,  and  each  parish  raises  its  quota  by  a 
rate  on  the  yearly  value  of  all  lands  and  heredita- 
ments. The  gi-eat  increase  in  the  value  of  land 
in  many  parishes  has  gi'eatly  diminished  the 
rate  per  £  necessary  to  raise  the  quota  in  such 
parishes  (Bourdin's  Land  Tax,  by  S.  Bunbury, 
London,  1885).  Inhabited  houses  are  assessed 
to  the  inliabited  house  duty  at  the  yearly  rent 
they  are  worth.  Where  the  occupier  is  also 
the  owner,  some  difficulty  often  exists  in  fixing 
the  yearly  value.  Perhaps  the  soundest  prin- 
ciple would  be  to  take  a  certain  interest,  so  much 
per  cent,  on  the  selling  value  as  the  estimated 


62 


ASSESSMENT— ASSIGNAT 


rental  (see  Inhabited  House  Duty).  As  re- 
gards income  tax,  income  from  landed  property 
including  houses,  is  assessed  at  its  rent  or  annual 
value,  but  speaking  generally  with  respect  to 
profits  for  occupation  of  land  the  assessment 
is  one-half  the  rent  in  England,  and  one-third 
in  Scotland  and  Ireland,  subject  to  rectification 
if  che  profits  are  less.  No  deduction  is  allowed 
on  account  of  repairs.  Returns  are  made  by 
the  occupiers,  and  on  such  returns  the  assess- 
ment is  made.  Income  derived  from  public 
funds  or  from  public  offices  is  assessed  at  the 
amount  received,  and  the  tax  is  deducted 
where  possible  before  the  income  is  paid. 
Income  derived  from  professions,  trades,  and 
other  occupations  is  assessed  upon  the  average 
profits  of  the  preceding  three  years,  other 
forms  of  income  are  assessed  at  the  amount 
actually  received.  Incomes  under  £160  are  ex- 
empt, and  the  following  abatements  are  allowed 
on  incomes  : — 

Over  £160  but  below  £400,  abatement  of  £160 

„       400    „       ,,        500,  ,,  ,,     150 

500    „       „         600,  ,,  ,,     120 

„       600    „       „        700,  „  „       70 

Allowance  for  children  may  be  claimed  on  in- 
comes under  £500.  £10  to  be  free  of  tax  in 
respect  of  each  child  under  16  years  of  age.  In- 
comes over  £3000  pay  a  super- tax  charged  on 
the  amount  over  £2500,  imposed  1914. 

2.  Local  Taxation. — Taxes  required  for  local 
purposes,  such  as  the  poor  rate,  the  county  rate, 
the  borough  rate,  are  levied  upon  the  full  rate- 
able value,  with  certain  exceptions  that  are 
based  on  no  definite  principle.  The  assessment 
for  the  lighting  and  watching  rate  is  three  times 
greater  on  buildings  than  upon  land,  certain 
lands  are  assessed  to  the  general  district  rate  at 
one-fourth  the  rateable  value,  whilst  owners  of 
small  tenements,  if  they  compound  for  the 
rates,  are  assessed  at  one-half  the  rateable  value. 
The  rateable  value  for  the  poor  rate  which  is 
conclusive  for  the  majority  of  rates,  is  defined 
by  the  6  &  7  Will.  IV.  c.  96,  as  "the  net 
annual  value  of  the  several  hereditaments  rated 
thereto  ;  that  is  to  say,  of  the  rent  at  which  the 
same  might  reasonably  be  expected  to  let  from 
year  to  year  free  of  all  usual  tenants'  rates  and 
taxes  and  tithe  commutation  rent-charge,  if  any, 
and  deducting  therefrom  the  probable  average 
annual  cost  of  repairs,  insurances,  and  other 
expenses,  if  any,  necessary  to  maintain  them  in 
a  state  to  command  such  rent."  The  pro- 
visions of  6  &  7  Will.  IV.  c.  96,  do  not, 
however,  apply  to  the  metropolis.  In  the 
metropolis  the  gross  value  is  taken  as  the  basis 
of  the  assessment  for  the  purpose  of  ascertain- 
ing the  rateable  value,  and  deductions  are  made 
which  vary  according  to  the  nature  of  the 
tenement,  a  maximum  percentage  being  fixed 
for  the  deduction  in  each  case.  Land  occupied 
by  the  crown  for  public  purposes,  property  un- 


occupied or  not  capable  of  yielding  any  rent, 
and  personal  property,  are  not  rateable.  (As 
to  the  taxation  of  ground  rents,  see  Ground 
Rents.)  The  basis  of  the  county  rate  is  ascer- 
tained in  a  similar  way,  but  the  assessors  are 
not  bound  to  follow  the  poor-rate  assessment 
(see  County  Rate).  By  the  bill  introduced  by 
]\Ir.  Goschen  in  the  House  of  Commons  on  the 
3d  April  1871  it  was  proposed  to  render  "every 
hereditament,  corporeal  or  incorporeal,"  with 
the  exception  of  rent-charges,  liable  to  be  rated 
to  all  local  taxes  (see  Local  Taxation,  by  G.  J. 
Goschen,  London,  1872  ;  and  the  Report  of  the 
Select  Committee  of  the  House  of  Commons  on 
Local  Taxation,  1871). 

[On  assessment  for  local  taxation  see  Local  Govern- 
ment and  Local  Taxation,  by  R.  S.  Wright  and  H. 
Hobhouse  (London,  1884), — Law  of  Rating,  by 
E.  J.  Castle  (London,  1%%^).— Handbook  for 
Council  Authorities,  by  A,  Pulling  (London,  1889). 
( For  assessment  for  general  average,  see  Adj  ustment, 
Average;  Average,  Maritime.)]      j.  e.  c.  m. 

ASSETS  (Lat.  ad  satis;  French  assez)-,  liter- 
ally, sufficient.  Originally  the  use  of  the  word 
was  confined  to  property  which  an  executor  or 
lieir  could  apply  for  the  discharge  of  the  debts 
and  legacies  due  from  the  estate  of  a  deceased 
person.  Those  obligations  could  only  be  en- 
forced in  so  far  as  the  property  available  for 
that  purpose  was  suflicient.  The  applicat'on 
of  the  expression  was  afterwards  extended  to 
the  property  which  could  be  applied  for  distri- 
bution among  the  creditors  of  an  insolvent 
debtor,  and  in  course  of  time  acquired  the  still 
wider  meaning  of  any  person's  property  in  so 
far  as  it  could  be  used  for  the  discharge  of  his 
liabilities.  The  assets  remaining  after  the  dis- 
charge of  liabilities  are  a  person's  actual  capital. 

ASSIENTO  TREATY.  This  treaty  requires 
mention,  owing  to  the  connection  between  it 
and  the  development  of  slavery  in  North 
America.  In  1713  Spain  by  agreement 
(Assiento)  conceded  to  France  the  privilege  of 
carrying  negro  slaves  to  the  Spanish  colonies. 
France,  by  the  treaty  of  Utrecht,  surrendered 
this  privilege  which,  by  the  treaty  de  1' Assiento, 
was  granted  to  England  for  thirty-three  years 
from  the  1st  May  1713.  England  engaged  to 
furnish  4800  slaves  annually,  and  in  return 
was  entitled  to  send  two  phips  every  year  with 
negroes  to  America.  The  South  Si-:a  Company 
obtained  the  benefit  of  this  monopoly.  At  the 
outbreak  of  the  war  with  Spain,  the  Assiento 
was  suspended,  but  it  was  renewed  in  1725  and 
again  in  1748, 

[The  leading  clauses  are  set  out  in  Hosack's  Law 
of  Nations,  London,  1882,  p,  355,  and  are  taken 
from  Actes  et  Memoires  de  la  Paix  d' Utrecht. 
See  also  Histoire  des  Traites  de  Paix,  par  F.  Schoell, 
p.  214  (Brussels,  1837),]  J,  e,  c,  m. 

ASSIGNAT  (from  Lat.,  Assignatus).  The 
Paper  Money  issued  by  the  French  republic  in 
1789-94,  in  consequence  of  the  scarcity  of  coin, 
was  termed  assignats  because  it  was  secured 


ASSIGNAT 


63 


not  upon  coin,  but  upon  crown  and  church  pro- 
perty, in  the  purchase  of  which  these  notes  were 
receivable  at  par.  Each  note  was  of  100  francs 
(£4),  and  notes  returned  to  the  state  in  pay- 
ment of  purchase  money  were  to  be  cancelled. 
The  first  issue  of  400,000,000  francs  carried 
interest  at  a  daily  rate  (as  exchequer  bills  did 
here  prior  to  1862),  but  were  inconvertible  ex- 
cept in  payment  for  property  publicly  assigned 
for  the  purpose.  A  second  issue  of  800,000,000 
francs  carried  no  interest,  and  further  issues 
effected  rapidly  brought  the  total  up  to 
3,750,000,000  francs,  or  £150,000,000,  nomi- 
nal. At  that  time,  in  August  1793,  the  de- 
preciation of  the  assignat  had  become  so  great, 
it  being  quite  impossible  for  the  country  pro- 
perly to  absorb  this  vast  amount  of  paper,  that 
the  100  francs  nominal  ranked  for  less  than  20 
francs  coin.  Then  recourse  was  had  to  pro- 
tective legislation.  First,  May  1793,  a  decree 
was  issued  that  farmers  must  declare  the  quantity 
of  corn  in  their  possession,  and  sell  it  in  recog- 
nised markets,  no  one  being  permitted  to  pur- 
chase more  than  suflBcient  for  one  month's  con- 
sumption. Then  maximum  prices  were  decreed, 
and  as  such  laws  could  not  rehabilitate  the 
assiguats,  a  forced  loan  of  1,000,000,000  francs, 
and  the  forced  prepayment  of  taxes,  were  applied 
to  the  reduction  of  this  paper  currency.  lii 
this  way  the  total  was  brought  down  to  about 
2,500,000,000  francs.  But  the  wants  of  the 
government  were  so  pressing  that  but  a  few 
months  had  elapsed  before  these  notes  had  been 
reissued,  and  a  far  larger  amount  followed. 
In  June  1794  the  assiguats  in  circulation  reached 
the  vast  total  of  6,536,000,000  francs,  or 
£261,440,000,  nominal.  The  result  of  legisla- 
tion then  was  that  the  land  remained  untilled 
and  all  business  was  paralysed.  At  this  time 
the  100  francs  assignat  was  not  worth  1  franc, 
and  though,  after  the  fall  of  Robespierre,  the 
maximum  laws  were  relaxed,  the  value  of  the 
assiguats  did  not  recover.  The  government  and 
the  entire  country  had  been  reduced  to  a  state  of 
pauperism,  and  when,  in  October  1795,  the  Direc- 
tory had  been  established,  the  total  issue  reached 
22,000,000,000  francs,  or £880,000,000,  nomi- 
nal. Yet  in  two  months  another  15,000,000,000 
francs  were  issued,  and  the  depreciation  was  such 
that  the  paper  became  entirely  valueless.  Then 
followed  the  conversion  of  the  assignats  into 
mandats  (or  warrants)  at  the  thirtieth  part  of 
their  face  value,  and  these  in  their  turn  were 
returned  to  the  state  in  1796  at  about  the  seven- 
tieth part  of  the  value  of  coin.  Thiers'  History 
of  the  French  Revolution  gives  a  vivid  description 
of  this  eventful  period,  and  of  the  disastrous 
effects  of  these  issues  of  inconvertible  paper. 

In  Russia  in  the  early  part  of  the  present 
century  an  issue  of  paper  was  made  similar  in . 
form  to  the  assignats  in  France  and  became 
greatly  depreciated.  These  notes  were  subse- 
auently  to  a  large  extent  withdrawn. 


Professor  F.  A.  Walker  has  in  his  work  on 
Money  (ch.  xvi.),  described  the  development  of 
the  paper  issue,  and  the  fruitless  opposition  of 
Necker.  It  was  assumed  that  the  republic 
could  do  safely  what  had  been  (1719-21)  dis- 
astrous under  the  monarchy.  "Paper  money," 
it  was  argued  before  the  assembly,  * '  paper  money 
under  a  despotism  is  dangerous,  it  favours  cor- 
ruption ;  but  in  a  nation  constitutionally 
governed,  which  takes  care  of  its  own  notes, 
which  determines  their  number  and  their  use, 
that  danger  no  longer  exists. "  A  desire  to  com- 
mit the  thrifty  middle  class  of  France  to  the 
principles  and  measures  of  the  Revolution  for 
political  purposes  largely  actuated  the  assembly. 
This  was  avowed  by  Mirabeau,  ' '  Partout  ou  se 
placera  un  assignat -monnaie,  1^  silrement  re- 
posera  avec  lui  uu  vosu  secret  pour  le  credit  des 
assignats,  un  desir  de  leur  solidite  .  .  .  par- 
tout  ou  se  trouvera  un  porteur  d'assignats, 
vous  compterez  un  defenseur  necessaire  de 
vos  mesures,  un  creancier  iuteresse  a  vos 
succes."  These  notes,  the  Comte  de  JSriRABEAU 
continued  to  declare,  could  never  be  issued  in 
excess.  "They  represent,"  he  said,  "real 
property,  the  most  secure  of  all  possessions, 
the  soil  on  which  we  tread."  Again,  "There 
cannot  be  a  greater  error  than  the  fear  so 
generally  prevalent  as  to  the  over-issue  of 
assignats.  .  .  .  Re-absorbed  progressively  in  the 
purchase  of  the  national  domains,  this  paper 
money  can  never  become  redundant." 

The  following  table  of  the  depreciation  of 
the  assignats,  derived  from  M.  Bresson  {Hist. 
Financikre  de  la  France),  shows  how  entirely 
Mirabeau's  anticipations  were  falsified  by  events. 

24  livres  in  coin  were  worth  in  assignats — 


April  1, 

1795 

.    238 

Oct.  1,  1795 

1205 

May   „ 

)) 

.    299 

Nov.,,     „       . 

2588 

June  ,, 

)) 

.     439 

Dec.  ,,     ,, 

3575 

July  „ 

)  t 

.    808 

Jau.  ,,  1796 

4658 

Aug.  ,, 

.    807 

Feb.  „     „       . 

5337 

Sept.  „ 

.  1101 

At  the  last, 

"an  as 

signat  professir 

ig  to  b 

worth  100  francs  Avas  commonly  exchanged  for 
5  sous  6  deniers,  in  other  words,  a  paper^note 
professing  to  lie  worth  £4  sterling  passed 
current  for  less  than  3d.  in  money "  (Twiss, 
Progress  of  Political  Economy,  p.  263). 
M.  Joseph  Gakxier  gives  {Traiti  de  Finances, 
p.  408),  the  following  statement  from  a  work  of 
M.  Ramel,  former  minister  of  finance.  The 
figures  represent  millions  of  francs. 

Assignats  crees  par  I'assemblee  constituante  (lois 
des  21st  Dec.  1789, 1 7th  Avril 
1790,  19th  Juin  1790)  1,800 

,,  ,,      par  I'assemblee  legislative       900 

,,  ,,      directement  par  la  Con- 

vention       .  .  7,278 

, ,  , ,     par  les  Comites  au  torises 

.,  .,      par  le  Directoire 


33,603 


43,681 


64 


ASSIGNATION— ASSIZE  OF  WEIGHTS  AND  MEASURES 


M.  Bresson  gives  a  total  differing  by  only  two 
or  three  millions  from  the  above  (see  Money,  by 
Francis  A.  Walker,  pp.  336-347,  for  further 
details).     See  Chamberlen,  H.  ;  Law,  J. 

ASSIGNATION  (Scots  law  term).  Assign- 
ment. 

ASSIGNEE.  One  to  whom  a  right  or  pro- 
perty is  transferred.  The  terra  "assignee  in 
bankruptcy"  is  not  used  under  the  present 
bankruptcy  law,  but  there  is  an  "official  as- 
signee "  on  the  London  stock  exchange  on  whom 
certain  duties  devolve  in  the  case  of  the  in- 
solvency of  a  member. 

ASSIGNMENT.  The  transfer  of  a  right  or 
property.  In  strict  legal  phraseology  the  word 
is  used  with  reference  to  personal  property  only. 
It  is  correct  to  speak  of  the  assignment  of  a 
lease,  but  the  term  could  not  be  applied  to  the 
transfer  of  freehold  property. 

ASSIGNMENT,  Deed  of.  This  expression, 
though  it  might  be  used  for  every  deed  assign- 
ing property,  is  more  specially  applied  to  in- 
strum^ts  by  which  a  debtor's  property  is  con- 
veyed or  assigned  to  a  trustee  for  the  benefit  of 
his  creditors  generally.  An  assignment  of  this 
nature  is  considered  an  act  of  bankruptcy 
(Bankruptcy  Act  1883,  §  4  {a)).  e.  s. 

ASSIGNOR.  One  who  transfers  a  right  or 
property. 

ASSIZE  OF  BREAD  AND  BEER.  In  the 
collection  of  ancient  acts  of  parliament,  two  are 
always  cited  as  of  indefinite  antiquity,  neither 
reign  nor  date  in  which  they  were  first  enacted 
or  promulgated  being  given,  or  indeed  discover- 
able. These  are  the  statute  on  weights  and 
measures,  and  the  assize  of  bread  and  beer.  It 
is  highly  probable  that  these  statutes  are 
declaratory  of  very  ancient  custom,  and  were 
necessarily  reduced  to  a  form  because  they 
each  represent  rules  exhibited  in  figures.  They 
are  constantly  copied  in  those  legal  handy 
books  which  lawyers  possessed  and  referred  to, 
and  of  which  some  still  survive,  dating  occa- 
sionally from  the  13th  century.  It  was  at 
first  the  duty  of  the  local  court  (that  of  the 
Manor),  to  enforce  the  assize,  and  the  records 
of  those  courts  contain  frequent  entries  of  fines 
levied  on  those  offenders  who  had  broken  the 
assize. 

The  assize  of  bread  and  beer  is  drawn  up  in 
the  form  of  a  sliding  scale,  the  price  of  the 
unit  (in  bread,  the  weight  of  the  unit)  varying 
vnth.  the  price  of  grain  by  the  quarter,  wheat 
and  malt  as  the  case  may  be,  information  as  to 
the  price  having  been  easily  procurable  from 
market  rates.  The  scale  of  prices  goes  beyond 
recorded  experience  of  cheapness  or  dearness,  at 
least  as  far  as  the  writer  has  registered  prices. 
The  assize  was  therefore  a  regulation  by  ancient 
custom  or  law  of  the  rate  at  which  baker  and 
brewer  ^should  be  remunerated  for  the  service 
which  their  labour  did  to  society.  The  uni- 
formity of  this  practice  was  the  justification  for 


other  and  subsequent  statutes  regulating  the 
price  of  labour,  statutes  which  were  enacted  and 
re-enacted  from  1349  till  1824,  at  which  lattei 
date  the  labour  statutes  were  repealed  en  masse. 
After  the  discipline  of  the  manor  court  had 
become  obsolete,  the  assize  of  bread  and  beer 
was  enforced  in  quarter  sessions  uncertainly, 
but  by  the  corporations  of  towns  regularly  into 
the  last  quarter  of  the  18th  century,  the 
archives  of  these  corporations  constantly  sup- 
plying evidence  of  wheat  and  malt  prices.  The 
assize  of  bread  and  beer  proves  indirectly  that 
the  traditional  food  of  the  English  was  wheaten 
bread,  and  their  drink  barley  beer,  for  the 
assize  was  a  law  which  was  operative  all  over 
England  from  the  Scottish  border  to  the 
Channel.  It  is  to  be  observed  that,  except  on 
very  rare  occasions,  the  legislature  or  the 
government  did  not  aff'ect  to  fix  the  price  of 
the  materials,  wheat  and  malt,  as  foreign 
governments,  especially  that  of  France,  habitu- 
ally did.  The  regulation,  too,  was  avowedly 
in  the  interest  of  consumers,  for  the  rolls  of 
parliament  and  the  statute  -  book  supply 
abundant  evidence  of  the  anxiety  with  which 
the  government  foresaw  and  provided  against 
artificial  dearness.  Later  experience  has  in- 
ferred that  tteir  remedies  were  nugatory,  ot 
even  mischievous,  but  there  can  be  no  doubt  as 
to  their  motives.  In  brief,  the  assize  of  bread 
and  beer  had  the  same  object  with  the  laws 
directed  against  Badgers  ;  Forestallers  and 
Regrators,  viz.  the  protection  of  the  consumer. 

J.  E.  T.  B, 

ASSIZE  OF  WEIGHTS  AND  MEASURES. 
Besides  the  assize  of  bread  and  beer,  weights  and 
measures,  and  the  articles  themselves  which  were 
thus  computed,  were  subject  to  similar  legisla- 
tion. Thus  innkeepers,  licensed  victuallers, 
vintners,  butchers,  and  others  were  subject  to 
regulations  of  the  same  class.  The  "  inholders  " 
were  to  use  measures  "a  small  quantity  bigger 
than  the  standard"  to  allow  for  the  "working 
and  ascending  of  the  Yest  and  Froth,"  and,  with 
the  "Cooks  and  Victuallers,"  were  "forbidden 
to  bake,  seeth,  or  roast,  any  Fish  or  Flesh  twice, 
or  sell  and  utter  unto  the  subjects  any  manner 
of  corruptible  Victuals,  which  may  be  to  the 
hurt  and  the  infection  of  Man's  body  " — their 
"excessive  price"  was  guarded  against,  and  a 
scale  appointed  at  which  horses  were  to  be  re- 
ceived "to  Livery  at  Hay  and  Litter  by  Day 
and  Night."  If  the  price  of  hay  was  31s.  6d. 
a  load,  the  calculation  was  as  follows  : — 

"  Then  if  the  Botel  of  Hay  shall  weigh  three 
Pounds  for  a  halfpenny,  which  is  six  Pound  for 
one  penny,  and  so  18  Pounds  of  Hay  for 
three  pence,  the  which  1 8  Pounds  of  Hay,  with 
reasonable  Provender  at  every  watering,  will 
suffice  one  Horse  Day  and  Night."  The  rate  for 
litter  being  fixed  in  proportion,  it  was  considered 
that  the  "Inh older"  would  have  "sufficient 
gain."    The  rates  were  to  vary  according  as  the 


I 


ASSUMPTION— ATELIERS  NATIONAUX 


65 


price  of  the  "Load  of  Hay  shall  yearly  increase 
and  diminish."  The  rules  for  the  butchers  were 
more  particular.  These  were  "most  carefully 
looked  into  and  provided  for  by  good  and 
ancient  Orders  and  Laws  of  this  Realm,  and  also 
by  Advice  of  the  learned  and  skilful  Physicians 
of  the  same  ;" — the  Butchers  were  to  take  the 
utmost  care  that  the  meat  was  to  be  wholesome, 
they  were  not  to  "kill  and  sell  any  Bull  or 
Bulls  unbaiten."  The  weight  also  was  to  be 
exact  and  true.  They  were  not  to  "sell  their 
Flesh,  with  any  Beam  or  Balance  inclining 
more  unto  one  end  than  to  the  other  "  ;  "  Musty 
and  Corrupted  Meat "  was  also  strictly  guarded 
against.  Similar  regulations  were  also  extended 
to  other  articles.  "The  Assize  of  Fuel,  to  be 
observed  in  the  City  of  London,  Westminster, 
and  the  suburbs  of  the  same,"  fixed  the  size  and 
weight  of  the  sack  of  charcoal,  the  billet,  and  the 
faggot,  requiring  each  "Faggot-band  to  contain 
in  length  three  foot,  and  the  Band  of  every  such 
Faggot  to  be  14  inches  about,  besides  the  knot." 
Among  the  punishments  for  these  offences  was 
the  pillory,  the  fraudulent  butcher  to  be  exposed 
there,  and  "  his  corrupt  flesh  to  be  burnt  openly 
before  his  place  in  the  Market-place, "  the  fraudu- 
lent seller  of  fuel  with  a  "Billet,  Faggot,  or 
Sack  of  Coals  bound  to  some  part  of  his  body." 
Besides  articles  of  this  class,  building  materials 
were  subject  to  similar  regulations  ;  the  dimen- 
sions of  lath,  timber,  and  tiles  were  strictly  laid 
down,  and  directions  even  given  as  to  the 
manner  in  which  the  earth  of  which  the  tiles 
were  made  was  to  be  worked.  These  regula- 
tions, together  with  those  which  regulated  the 
assize  of  bread  and  beer,  may  be  found  described 
in  The  Assize  of  Bread  and  other  Assizes  of 
Weights  and  Measures,  to  which  the  name  of 
John  Powel,  clerk  of  the  market,  originally 
of  the  king's  (James  I.)  household,  is  attached. 
Reference  is  made  in  this  to  the  order  in  council 
31st  January  1604,  in  which  the  whole  question 
was  reconsidered.  The  edition  from  which  the 
quotations  made  above  are  made  contains 
references  to  the  early  acts  of  parliament,  etc., 
and  is  dated  1714.  It  is  interesting  as  giving 
incidentally  a  vivid  picture  of  "state  regula- 
tion "  in  early  ages. 

[An account  of  the  assize  of  bread,  meat,  and  other 
necessaries  in  Germany  is  given  by  Rohrscheide  in 
\Jah/rbucher  f»ir  NationaLokonomik,  October  1888.] 

ASSUMPTION,  Deed  of  (Scots  law  term). 
[Deed  of  appointment  of  new  trustees. 

ASSURANCE.     See  Insurance. 

ASSYTHMENT  (Scots  law).  Damages  suable 
at  common  law  by  wife,  family,  or  relatives  of 
person  killed,  from  person  culpable,  though  not 
convicted  and  punished,  the  assythment  being 
both  a  consolation  and  an  indemnification  for 
pecuniary  damage.  a.  d. 

ATELIERS  NATIONAUX,  government 
workshops,  tried  in  France  1848,  with  the  object 
of  aff'ording  relief,  in  the  form  of  wages,  to  the 
VOL.  I. 


unemployed.  The  name  is  inexactly  given  to 
(1)  the  old  ateliers  de  charity,  which  gave  em- 
ployment and  a  small  wage,  often  in  kind,  to 
destitute  workmen ;  (2)  Louis  Blanc's  pro- 
posed ateliers  sociaux  or  state  -  supported  co- 
operative productive  societies. 

On  the  25th  February  1848,  the  day  after 
the  abdication  of  Louis  Philippe,  the  provisional 
government,  under  urgent  popular  pressure, 
published  a  decree  undertaking  to  guarantee  a 
livelihood  to  every  one  who  would  work,  and 
therefore  to  find  labour  for  any  citizen.  Three 
days  later  public  works  were  proclaimed  to  begin 
from  1st  March  ;  every  one  in  want  of  employ- 
ment was  invited  to  apply  to  his  mayor,  who 
would  immediately  direct  him  to  the  national 
workshops.  So  precipitate  was  this  step  that 
no  workshops  could  be  found,  nor  any  works 
except  some  ti'ifling  road  repairs  and  navvies' 
jobs.  To  gain  admittance  to  the  "workshops  " 
a  man  procured  from  his  landlord  a  certificate 
of  six  months'  residence  in  Paris,  had  this 
visaed  by  the  local  police,  and  exchanged  it  at 
the  mairie  for  an  admission  ticket.  The  pay 
was  two  francs  a  day.  When  the  number  em- 
ployed reached  6000  no  work  could  be  found 
for  more.  After  vainly  applying  at  each  dis- 
trict, and  having  their  admission  tickets  en- 
dorsed accordingly,  men  were  paid  1^  frs. 
daily.  Two  central  bureaux  were  o])cned  to 
avoid  the  inconvenience  of  visiting  each  district. 
When  the  lack  of  work  became  notorious,  men 
in  regular  work  attended  these  bureaux,  and 
drew  1^  frs.  without  quitting  their  own 
employment.  Unscnipulous  men  obtained 
certificates  from  two  landlords,  and  drew  double 
pay.  Moreover  the  "inactive"  men  formed 
angi-y  crowds  around  the  bureaux,  endangering 
public  order  and  alarming  the  government. 

At  this  stage  (3d  March),  a  young  chemist, 
M.  Emile  Thomas,  suggested  that  the  men 
should  be  brigaded  so  as  to  assure  regularity, 
centralise  relief,  and  prevent  double  inscriptions, 
while  a  free  registry  should  facilitate  their  em- 
ployment by  private  persons.  His  plan  was 
approved,  and  he  was  appointed  director  (6th 
March).  He  embodied  ten  men  in  a  squad, 
five  squads  in  a  brigade,  four  brigades  in  a 
lieutenancy,  and  four  lieutenancies  in  a  com- 
pany. Each  division  was  under  an  ofiicer 
eventually  elected  by  his  subordinates.  A 
company,  therefore,  numbered  900  men.  A 
chefde  service  commanded  three  companies,  a  chef 
d'arrondissement  a  district.  The  daily  pay  was  : 
cadets,  d^ves  is  the  original  word,  5  frs.  ;  these 
were  students  chosen  by  Emile  Thomas  from  his 
old  school  the  Ucole  Centrale  des  Arts  et  Mitiers, 
where  they  were  training  for  civil  engineers, 
etc.  ;  lieutenants,  4  frs.  ;  brigadiers,  3  frs.  ; 
heads  of  squads,  2^  frs.  (active),  1|-  frs. 
(inactive)  ;  men,  2  frs.  (active),  1  fr.  (inactive). 

By  dint  of  tact  and  energy,  M.  Thomas 
maintained  order.     This  was  all  he  had  under- 


66 


ATELIEKS  NATIONAUX— ATTACHMENT 


taken  to  do.  He  could  not  procure  work. 
The  government,  glad  to  be  momentarily  rid 
of  peril,  turned  a  deaf  ear  to  his  appeals.  He 
set  some  of  the  men  to  make  shoes  and  clothes 
for  others,  but  such  small  expedients  availed 
little.  His  numbers  steadily  swelled,  being : 
21st  March,  30,000  ;  16th  April,  66,000  ;  iSth 
May,  100,000  ;  25th  May,  over  115,000.  The 
needy  and  criminal  classes  flowed  in  from  all 
parts  of  France,  and  even  from  Belgium,  and 
easily  obtained  false  certificates  of  domicile. 
Ministers  and  influential  men  constantly  pushed 
their  friends  and  supporters  into  appointments 
as  officers.  600  actors,  artists,  and  clerks 
claimed  in  one  day  the  right  to  employment. 
The  expenses  grew  rapidly,  but  the  government 
had  political  aims  in  view.  At  one  time  it 
counted  on  the  ateliers  for  support  at  the  polls  ; 
at  another  a  minister  spoke  of  using  the  men 
in  the  streets  in  case  of  a  rising  ;  yet  again  it 
was  hinted  that  collapse  would  be  useful  in 
damaging  the  party  of  Louis  Blanc,  whose 
principles  of  V organisation  du  travail  and  le 
droit  au  travail,  were  supposed  to  be  bound  up 
with  the  experiment  (see  Blanc,  Louis).  The 
jealousy  of  the  official  engineers  still  starved 
the  ateliers  of  work.  So  futile  were  the  tasks 
set  the  men  that  one  of  them  sarcastically  pre- 
dicted they  would  be  set  to  bottle  off"  the  Seine  ! 
After  the  elections,  the  government  became  alive 
to  the  expense  and  political  danger  of  the  growing 
agglomeration.  The  director  was  ordered  (23d 
May)  to  dismiss  immediately  all  bachelors 
under  twenty-five  who  would  not  enlist  in  the 
army,  all  men  who  could  not  prove  six  months' 
residence  in  Paris,  and  all  who  refused  offers  of 
private  employment  in  their  own  trade.  Day 
work  was  to  give  way  to  task  work  ;  and  men 
were  to  be  liable  to  be  drafted  into  the  provinces. 
M.  Thomas  protested  that  this  ordinance  was 
harsh,  dangerous,  and  contrary  to  the  previous 
decree  of  the  whole  government  (25th  February, 
supra).  It  was  withdrawn  for  a  time.  But  on 
the  20  th  June  (M.  Thomas  having,  meanwhile, 
been  superseded)  it  was  approved  by  the  national 
assembly,  and  published.  The  workmen  re- 
volted at  once  throughout  Paris.  The  ateliers 
were  dissolved,  and  the  rising  was  suppressed 
by  troops  after  three  days'  fighting  (23d  to 
25th  June),  during  which  10,000  men  were 
killed  and  12,000  captured. 

The  ateliers  were  evidently  not  fairly  tried. 
But  they  are  open  to  fatal  political  and  econo- 
mic objection.  A  heterogeneous  crowd  of  social 
failures  employed  in  indefinite  numbers  by  a 
party  majority  must  seriously  endanger  political 
morality.  Louis  Blanc  would  have  each  man 
engaged  at  his  own  trade.  Obviously,  however, 
this  replaces  private  enterprise  by  pure  socialism. 
'i&i'L'L{Dissertations,i\.  384)  contends  that  the 
right  to  labour  depends  upon  the  same  principle 
as  the  poor  law  of  Elizabeth.  But  is  the  state 
fitted  to  discharge  the  correlative  duty  of  em- 


ployment? Taxing  and  trading  are  widely 
different  functions.  Fawcett  (Manual,  p.  586) 
considers  that  government  might  possibly, 
though  rarely,  be  justified  in  giving  employment 
during  occasional  depression. 

[Consult  Histoire  des  Ateliers  Nationaux,  par 
l^mile  Thomas,  Paris,  1848  ;  well  condensed  in 
the  Quarterly  Review  for  June  1850  (vol.  Ixxxvii. 
No.  173). — Rapport  de  la  Commission  d'EnquUe 
sur  V Insurrection  du  23  juin,  et  surles  ivenements 
du  15  mai  1848,  Paris,  1848. — Histoire  de  la 
R^olution  de  1848,  par  L.  A.  Garnier-Pages, 
Paris,  1861-72. — 2848  Historical  Revelations, 
Louis  Blanc,  London,  1858.]  h.  h. 

ATKINSON,  William,  bom  towards  com- 
mencement of  19th  century,  was  a  Fellow  of 
the  Statistical  Society,  from  which  he  retired  in 
1844.  One  of  the  early  assailants  of  the  classical 
school,  he  lays  great  stress  on  its  inability  to 
agree  upon  questions  of  population,  of  the 
preference  of  home  over  foreign  trade,  and  its 
want  of  moral  and  religious  principle.  Though 
his  own  arguments  in  favour  of  protection  are 
founded  upon  a  rather  abstruse  "law  of  pro- 
portions," they  have  been  welcomed  by  Ameri- 
can economists.  His  last  work  gives  curious 
details  upon  the  influence  of  the  orthodox 
school  on  coijamercial  politics  in  England. 

The  Principle  of  Protecting  Home  Trade  or  the 
Principle  of  Free  Trade  Refuted,  ISSS.— The  State 
of  the  Science  of  Political  JEconomy  investigated, 
1838. — Principles  of  Political  Economy,  1840 
(reprinted  1843,  New  York,  with  an  introduc- 
tion by  Horace  Greeley). — Principles  of  Social 
and  Political  Economy,  vol.  i.  (and  last)  1858 
(see  Classical  Economists).  s.  b. 

ATTACHMENT.  1.  The  legal  seizure  of  a 
debtor's  property.  In  the  Rules  of  the  Supreme 
Court  the  term  is  used  for  the  process  by  which 
a  judgment  creditor  tries  to  secure  for  himself 
the  judgment  debtor's  money  claim  against  a 
third  party  (called  the  Garnishee).  The  Court 
may,  on  satisfactory  proof  that  the  judgment 
remains  unsatisfied,  and  that  the  garnishee 
(who  must  be  within  the  jurisdiction)  is  in- 
debted to  the  judgment  debtor,  order  the  gar- 
nishee to  pay  the  applicant  to  the  extent  of  his 
claim.  A  peculiar  process  (called  foreign  attach- 
ment), by  which  any  part  of  a  debtor's  property 
may  be  seized  before  judgment,  is  available  for 
creditors  whose  claims  have  arisen  within  the 
city  of  London,  through  the  instrumentality  of 
the  Lord  Mayor's  Court. 

2.  A  writ  of  attachment  against  a  disobedient 
party  is  used  in  the  supreme  court  for  the  en- 
forcement of — (1)  judgments  for  the  recovery 
of  any  property  other  than  land  or  money  ;  (2) 
judgments  for  payment  of  money  into  court  if 
the  liability  is  within  the  exceptions  of  the 
Debtor's  Act ;  (3)  judgments  or  orders  against 
corporations  wilfully  disobeyed  by  the  directors 
or  officers  ;  (4)  orders  to  answer  interrogatories, 
or  for  discovery  or  inspection  of  documents,  and 
in  several  other  cases.     The  disobedient  partly 


ATTESTATION— ATTWOOD 


67 


is  imprisoned  until  his  discharge  is  ordered  by 
the  court.  e.  s. 

ATTESTATION.  The  verification  of  a  docu- 
ment by  the  signature  of  a  witness  or  witnesses 
who  were  present  at  the  time  of  its  execution. 

ATTORNEY,  Power  of.  A  document 
generally  authorising  an  agent  to  act  for  his 
principal. 

ATTORNMENT.  An  acknowledgment  of 
tenancy  by  the  tenant  to  a  landlord.  The 
purchase  of  land  subject  to  leases  was  formerly 
incomplete  tOl  the  lessees  had  attorned  to  the 
purchaser  ;  but  this  was  rendered  unnecessary 
by  the  statute  4  &  5  Anne,  c.  3.  It  was 
formerly  usual  to  insert  attornment  clauses  into 
mortgage  deeds,  so  as  to  create  a  tenancy  be- 
tween the  mortgagor  and  the  mortgagee,  and  to 
give  the  latter  a  landlord's  preferential  rights. 
A  clause  of  this  nature  would  now  mostly  be 
futile  unless  the  forms  requii'ed  by  the  Bills  of 
Sale  Acts  of  1878  and  1882  are  complied  with  ; 
and  as  it  exposes  the  mortgagee  to  certain 
special  liabilities,  it  is  considered  more  prudent 
for  mortgagees  to  omit  it.  e.  s. 

ATTWOOD,  Thomas  (born  1783,  died  1856), 
belonged  to  a  Birmingham  firm  of  bankers 
during  the  first  half  of  this  century.  The 
Birmingham  Currency  School,  to  which  he  be- 
longed, were,  as  mentioned  by  J.  S.  Mill  {Prin- 
dples  of  Political  Economy,  bk.  iii.  ch.  xiii.  §  5). 
strong  supporters  of  inconvertible  currency, 
Thomas  Attwood  wrote  the  following  pamphlets : 

Letter  to  JV.  Van  sit  tart  on  the  Creation  of 
Money  and  on  its  Action  upon  National  Prosperity, 
Birmingham,  1817,  8vo. — Observations  on  Cur- 
rency, Population,  and  Pauperism,  Birmingham, 
1818,  8vo. — Exposition  of  the  Cause  and  Remedy 
of  the  Agricultural  Distress,  Hertford,  1828,  8vo. 
Evidence  of  Thomas  Attwood  before  the  Select 
Comniittee  on  the  Depressed  State  of  Agriculture, 
1821,  Parliamentary  Papers,  viii.  pt.  ii. — Scotch 
Banker,  1828,  embodying  six  articles  on  banking 
and  currency  contributed  by  Thomas  Attwood  to 
The  Globe  (reviewed  by  Cobbett  in  his  Political 
Register,  for  24th  May  1828,  and  noticed  by  the 
Quarterly  Review,  No.  78). — Letters  of  Thomas 
Attwood  to  the  Times  [and  comments  of  the  Times 
thereon,  Oct.-Dec.  1843.]  h.  r.  t. 

ATTWOOD,  Thomas,  and  the  Birmikg- 
;  ham  School.  Thomas  Attwood  is  a  signal  ex- 
[ample  of  good  sense  and  general  intelligence 
foverborne  by  a  futile  monetary  theory.  He  was 
[the  leader  of  the  "Birmingham  School,"  who 

Ivocated  high  prices  maintained  by  inflation 

[of  the  currency.      Attwood  and  his  followers 

mght  a  lesson  needed  by  some  of  their  con- 

jmporaries  when  they  insisted  on  the  hardship 

^inflicted  on  debtors  by  a  fall  in  general  prices,  or 

rise  in  the  value  of  the  monetary  standard.    But 

"le  extent  of  the  evil  was  greatly  exaggerated  when 

'the  Resumption  of  Specie  Payments  in  1819 

was  made  responsible  for  almost  every  trouble 

which  subsequently  befell  the  kingdom — the 

agricultural  distress  in  England,  the  turbulence 


of  O'Connell  in  Ireland,  or  the  "  Rebecca  "  riota 
in  "Wales.  The  argument  directed  against  the 
resumption  deserves  particular  attention.  It 
was  held  that  the  depreciation  of  paper  with 
respect  to  gold  just  before  the  resumption  was 
much  less  than  the  appreciation  of  gold  with 
respect  to  things  in  general  which  followed  the 
resumption.  ' '  That  measure  (which  it  was  said 
would  only  eff"ect  a  charge  to  the  extent  of  3 
per  cent)  had  imposed  an  additional  burthen  of 
25,  30,  or  40  per  cent  on  every  man  in  the 
community  in  all  cases  of  deed,  mortgage,  settle- 
ment, or  contract."  Prof.  Walker  appears 
inclined  to  ascribe  some  weight  to  this  argu- 
ment (Money,  p.  388  ;  Money,  Trade,  and 
Industry,  p.  282). 

Thomas  Attwood's  advocacy  of  monetary 
reform  derived  strength  from  his  political  in- 
fluence. He  was  the  founder  of  the  "  Political 
Union"  at  Birmingham,  and  took  an  active 
part  in  the  agitation  for  parliamentary  reform. 
It  was  believed  that  Attwood  desired  political 
reform  principally  as  a  means  whereby  to  obtain 
a  rectilication  of  the  currency.  To  that  end 
he  moved  in  the  reformed  parliament  for  a 
select  committee  to  inquire  into  the  causes  of 
the  general  distress.  This  motion,  like  others 
which  emanated  from  the  Birmingham  School, 
was  lost. 

Thomas  Attwood  was  greatly  assisted  in  this 
monetary  crusade  by  his  brother  Mathias  (born 
1779,  died  1851).  Mathias's  speech  on  the 
currency,  11th  June  1822,  is  placed  by  Alison 
with  Huskisson's  speech  on  the  other  side,  as 
"containing  all  that  ever  has,  or  ever  can  be, 
said  on  the  subject."  In  1830  Mathias  pro- 
posed a  double  standard  of  silver  and  gold  ;  at 
the  rate  of  15^///^  lbs.  of  silver  to  1  lb.  of  gold 
(Hansard,  1830,  vol.  xxv.  pp.  102-145 ;  Alison, 
History  of  Europe,  1815-52,  vol.  iv.  ch.  xxii.  § 
32).  Mathias,  unlike  his  brother,  was  a  Tory. 
He  was  a  successful  banker,  co-founder  of  the 
National  Provincial  Bank  of  Ireland,  the 
Imperial  Continental  Gas,  and  other  companies. 
So  little  is  business  power  alone  a  guarantee  of 
sound  economical  theory. 

There  is  an  appreciative  account  of  Thomas 
Attwood  and  the  Birmingham  School  in  a 
series  of  letters  which  were  addressed  to  the 
Midland  Counties  Herald  in  1843  by  two  Bir- 
mingham men  (T.  B.  Wright  and  J.  Harlow) 
signing  themselves  Gemini,  and  were  repub- 
lished in  1844  in  the  form  of  a  book  under 
that  title.  The  title  Gemini  was  ajipropriate 
according  to  Sir  Robert  Peel,  for  "the  efforts 
of  no  single  writer  are  equal  to  the  production 
of  so  much  nonsense "  (Speech  on  the  Bank 
Charter,  1844).  According  to  this  par  nobile 
"the  political  economy  of  Mr.  Attwood  has  this 
one  great  distinguishing  feature,  that  it  releases 
the  nation  from  the  thraldom  of  the  heart- 
chilling  doctrine  of  Malthus.  The  world  ia 
capable  of  multiplying  its  production   to  an 


68 


AUBAINE— AUCTION 


almost  unlimited  extent ;  the  governments  of 
the  world  would  have  only  to  provide  for  the 
proper  distribution  of  the  productions,  and  the 
wants  of  all  people  will  be  supplied."  Such 
are  the  beneficent  results  of  "accommodating 
our  coinage  to  man,  and  not  man  to  our  coin- 
age "  {Gemini,  Letter  24).  The  cardinal  tehets 
of  the  "Birmingham  economists"  are  com- 
pendiously stated  at  page  104,  and  again  at  page 
285  of  Gemini. 

There  is  in  the  library  of  the  British  Museum 
a  life  of  Thomas  Attwood  by  his  grandson,  0. 
M.  Wakefield,  "printed  for  private  circula- 
tion ; "  which  throws  much  light  on  the  his- 
tory of  the  Birmingham  School.  Mr.  Wake- 
field does  not  profess  to  interpret  his  grand- 
father's views  on  currency. 

J.  S,  Mill  devotes  a  paragraph  to  the  refuta- 
tion of  Attwood's  theory  of  currency  {Pol.  Econ. , 
bk.  iii.  ch.  xiii.  §  4).  F.  Y.  B. 

ATJBAINE,  Droit  d'.  Under  the  French  rule 
of  law,  known  as  the  droit  d'aubaine  or  right  of 
alienage,  the  whole  property  of  an  alien  dying 
in  France  without  leaving  children  born  in  that 
country  escheated  to  the  crown.  The  royal 
right  was  not  universally  exacted,  and  at  a  very 
early  period  special  exceptions  were  introduced 
in  favour  of  certain  classes.  Thus  Louis  XI. 
exempted  merchants  of  Brabant,  Flanders, 
Holland,  and  Zealand  from  the  operation  of  the 
law,  and  a  similar  privilege  was  extended  by 
Henri  II.  to  merchants  of  the  Hanse  towns, 
and  from  Scotland.  Henri  IV.  and  Louis 
XIV.,  in  their  desire  to  promote  the  settlement 
of  skilled  artisans  in  France,  exempted  at  a 
later  date  various  classes  of  workmen,  and  the 
latter  king  extended  the  exception  to  include 
aliens  serving  five  years  in  the  navy  and  then 
settling  in  France.  The  towns  of  Lyons,  Tou- 
louse, Bourdeaux,  and  some  other  ports  in  Pro- 
vence and  Guienne  were  also  free  from  the 
operation  of  the  rule. 

Originally  one  of  the  rights  possessed  by  the 
feudal  lord,  the  droit  d'aubaine  or  similar 
institutions,  existed  in  most  countries  where  the 
form  of  society  was  feudal ;  and  the  alien's 
power  of  bequest  was  restrained  in  the  same 
manner  in  Tuscany,  the  two  Sicilies,  Spain, 
Germany,  Prussia,  Holland,  Denmark,  and 
other  countries.  Even  in  England  the  power 
of  the  crown  over  the  goods  of  aliens  was 
formerly  considerable,  though  no  strictly  similar 
rule  of  law  seems  to  have  existed  in  this 
country.  Treaties  for  the  mutual  abrogation  of 
the  right  did  something  to  modify  the  applica- 
tion of  the  law.  But  its  complete  abrogation 
is  due  primarily  to  the  policy  of  Necker,  who 
was  controller-general  of  finance  at  the  time 
when  the  decree  of  the  6th  August  1790  abol- 
ished the  droit  d'aubaine  and  the  droit  de  de- 
traction in  France.  In  his  work  De  V adminis- 
tration des  Finances  he  had  already  pointed  out 
that  owing  to  the  expenses  of  collection  the 


annual  not  produce  of  the  right  did  not  amount 
to  more  than  40,000  ecus.  The  droit  d'aubaine 
in  its  original  form  was  never  re-established  in 
France.  But  with  the  droit  de  detraction,  which 
enabled  the  state  to  confiscate  part  of  the  prop- 
erty bequeathed  by  aliens,  it  reappeared  in  the 
Code  Civile  in  a  modified  form.  Under  the 
provisions  of  sections  726  and  912  no  alien 
could  possess  in  France  a  larger  power  of  suc- 
cession or  bequest  than  a  Frenchman  would 
possess  in  the  alien's  country.  But  even  this 
relic  of  the  old  feudal  right  was  abolished  by 
the  law  of  the  14th  July  1819. 

[Diderot  et  D'Alembert,  EncyclopSdie,  1772.— r 
Dictionnaire  general  de  la  Politique,  par  Maurice 
Block,  1873. — Les  Codes  annotSes  de  Sirey,  Edition 
enti^rement  refondue,  par  P.  Gilbert,  1847. — De 
V administration  des  Finances  de  la  France,  par 
M.  Necker,  1784.]  c.  g.  c. 

AUCKLAND,  William  Eden,  first  lord,  the 
third  son  of  Sir  Robert  Eden,  born  3d  April  1744, 
M.P.  for  Woodstock  1774,  was  one  of  the  five 
commissioners  sent  to  America  in  1 7 7 8.  As  chief 
secretary,  1780-82,  he  established  the  National 
Bank  of  Ireland,  and  was  sent  by  Pitt  to 
Versailles,  1785,  to  negotiate  the  commercial  ■ 
treaty  with  France,  signed  1786.  He  was  raised 
to  the  English  peerage  1793,  and  died  28th 
May  1814.     Among  his  writings  are — 

Fovnr  Letters  to  the  Earl  of  Carlisle,  London, 
1779,  8vo  (on  public  debts,  credit,  revenue  laws, 
etc.;  3d  ed.,  1780,  with  a  fifth  letter  on  popula- 
tion).— Short  Vindication  of  the  French  Treaty. 
London,  1787,  8vo. — Substance  of  a  Speech  in  the 
House  of  Peers  on  the  Third  Reading  of  the  Bill 
for  granting  certain  Duties  upon  Income,  London, 
1799,  8vo  (three  editions).  h.  e.  t. 

AUCTION,  Ordinary  (Lat.  aicctio,  an  in- 
crease— because  each  bid  is  an  increase  on  the 
preceding  one).  A  public  sale  in  which  succes- 
sive bidders  increase  the  price  until  one  offers  a 
price  which  no  others  are  prepared  to  exceed. 
The  auctioneer  is  recognised  by  law  as  the  agent 
both  of  the  vendor  and  purchaser  ;  he  is  bound 
to  take  out  a  licence  to  the  amount  of  £10 
annually  ;  he  is  bound  to  give  due  public  notice 
of  the  sale  ;  to  provide  a  properly  attested  cata- 
logue ;  and,  as  a  rule,  the  conditions  of  sale  are 
printed  on  the  catalogue.  The  auctioneer  is  for- 
bidden to  buy  on  his  own  account ;  and  his  sign 
of  office  is  a  hammer,  the  fall  of  which  repre- 
sents that  the  sale  has  been  eff'ected.  It  is  a 
common  practice  for  the  actual  vendor  of  the 
property  put  up  to  auction  to  bid  until  what  he 
regards  as  a  sufficient  price  for  his  goods  has  been 
attained,  or  he  may  place  a  "reserve  price  "  upon 
them.  Until  the  hammer  falls  the  bidder  may 
retract  his  bid,  but  when  the  hammer  falls  the 
contract  is  notified  and  there  is  no  appeal  upon 
either  side.  The  auctioneer  makes  a  charge  for 
his  services,  which  ^i  paid  by  the  vendor.  At 
one  time  a  duty  was  payable  to  the  government 
upon  the  value  of  all  auction  sales,  and  in 
1830  a  revenue  of  £234,854  was  derived  from 


AUDIFFRET— AUDIT 


69 


£6,326,481  worth  goods  sold.  But  this  duty 
has  now  been  relinquished  by  the  state.  The 
conditions  of  sale  usually  contain  a  statement 
in  effect  that  "any  error  or  mis-statement  shall 
not  vitiate  the  sale,  but  that  an  allowance  shall 
be  made  for  it  in  the  purchase  money,"  but  this 
is  only  held  to  guard  against  unintentional 
errors,  not  designedly  misleading  statements. 
Many  descriptions  of  merchandise,  such  as 
wool,  tallow,  hides  and  leather,  timber,  hemp, 
wine,  etc.,  are  sold  by  periodical  auctions,  at 
which  buyers  from  all  parts  can  conveniently 
attend  and  have  a  good  selection  to  purchase 
from.  At  the  five  series  of  colonial  wool  sales 
in  London,  wool  is  annually  disposed  of  to  the 
value  of  £20,000,000  and  more,  and  many 
others  of  these  auction  sales  are  most  valuable 
in  their  results  and  in  the  worth  of  the  goods 
disposed  of.  In  1830  the  auctioneers'  licences 
issued  in  the  United  Kingdom  numbered  3043  ; 
in  1913  the  number  issued  in  England  and 
Wales  was  6160,  Scotland  695,  Ireland  861. 
The  business  oi auctioneer  is  often  combined  with 
that  oi  appraiser  and  house-agent,  and  in  1913 
these  businesses  together  paid  £87,332  to  the 
inland  revenue.  The  sales  of  real  property  at 
the  London  Auction  Mart,  in  the  Country 
and  Suburbs,  and  by  Private  Contract  as 
stated  by  the  Estate  Exchange  Auction  JNlart, 
London,  were  in  1913,  £8,574,111  ;  1912, 
£9,089,543;  1911,  £8,397,794. 

A  Dutch  Auction  is  a  public  sale  in  which 

the  vendor  continues  to  lower  his  prices  until  a 

bidder  is  found,  or  until  in  his  own  interest  he 

[can  lower  them  no  more.     Dutch  auction  some- 

[times  enables  a  better  price  for  the  goods  sold 

'  to  be  obtained  than  ordinary  auction. 

[As  to  effect  on  price  by  employing  English  or 
(Dutch  mode  of  sale  by  auction,  see  W.  T.  Thokn- 
[nON  on  Labour,  p.  47,  et  stq.,  ed.  1869.] 

AUDIFEKET,  Ch.  L.  G.,  Marquis  d',  bom  at 

[Paris  1787,  died  April  1878.    He  entered,  when 

quite  young,  the  financial  department  of 

16  government,  through  all  the  grades  of  which 

16  was  destined  to  pass  with  great  rapidity. 

^Originally  placed,  1805,  as  a  book-keeper  in  the 

^"Caisse  des  depots  et  consignations,"  he  be- 

ime,  1808,  a  clerk  in  the  public  treasury,  and 

appointed,   1815,  director  of  the  office  of 

16    "comptabilite    generals     des     finances." 

I6n,  in  1829,  he  passed,  from  being  director 

the  finances  to  the  presidency  of  the  "cour 

comptes."     He  prepared  in  1830  the  Rap- 

au  roi,  which   appeared  in  March  under 

16  signature  of  the  Comte  de  Chabrol ;   was 

)pointed  a  "Pair  de  France"  in  1837,  and  in 

drew  up    the    famous  Reglement   de    la 

nptabilit^  jmblique,  a  subject  of  which  he  was 

uknowledged  a  passed  master.     In  1839  Audif- 

published  the  Examen  des  revenus  publics, 

vol.  in  8vo)  ;  in  1840  the  first  edition  of  the 

hme financier  de  la  France  (2  vols,  in  8vo),  in 

1841,  Le  Budget  (1  vol.  in  8vo)  ;  in  1843  the 


Liberation  de  lapropri6t6  ou  refornie  de  Vadinin- 
istration  des  impots  directs  et  des  hypotlUques 
(8vo,  pamphlet),  and  in  1848  ia  crise  financiere 
de  1848  (8vo,  pamphlet).  He  entered  the 
senate  in  1852,  having  published,  1851,  an 
8vo  pamphlet  entitled  R&forme  de  Vadminis- 
tration  financiere  des  hypothhques.  An  imperial 
decree,  24th  April  1853,  appointed  him  to  the 
Academic  des  sciences  morales  et  politiques.  In 
1854  he  published  a  second  edition  of  his  prin- 
cipal work  :  Le  SystSme  financier  de  la  France  (5 
vols,  in  8vo)  ;  of  this  a  3rd  ed.,  also  in  5  vols., 
appeared  in  1863-64.  In  these  were  embodied 
all  his  writings  on  administrative  questions  or 
others.  To  these  five  volumes  were  added  a 
sixth  in  1870,  containing  parliamentary  reports, 
eloges,  etc.,  and  in  1876  a  final  one,  under  the 
title  of  Souvenirs  de  ma  carriere,  an  auto- 
biogi-aphy  in  which  he  shows  himself  to  be  a 
persistent  partisan  of  the  monarchy,  without 
regard'  to  the  occupant  of  the  throne.    A.  c.  f. 

AUDIGANNE,  Amand,  born  at  Antwerp 
1814,  died  at  Paris  1875.  He  was  for  many  years 
employed  at  the  Minist^re  de  V agi-iculture  et  du 
commerce  ;  and  wrote,  commencing  1846,  many 
articles  in  the  Revue  des  deux  mondes,  on  agri- 
culture, trade,  banking,  railways,  and  par- 
ticularly on  the  condition  of  the  working 
classes,  which  had  been  the  object  of  many 
conscientious  inquiries  on  his  part.  Originally 
a  declared  Protectionist  he  became  Liberal  as 
time  went  on.  In  1 850  he  published  the  Ouvriers 
en  famille  in  the  form  of  conversations  (Paris, 
in  32mo,  frequently  reprinted),  then,  Les popula- 
tions ouvrieres  et  les  industries  de  la  France 
(2  vols.  1854,  in  18mo,  which  has  gone  to  a  second 
edition),  L'industrie  contemporaine  (1  vol.  in 
8vo,  1856),  Les  ouvriers  d'd  present  et  la 
nouvelle  iconmnie  du  travail  (1  vol.  in  Svo, 
1865),  L" economic  de  la  paix  et  la  richesse  des 
pcuples  (1  vol.  in  8vo,  1866),  La  lutte  in- 
dustricllc  des  pcuples  (1  vol.  in  Svo,  1867)  ; 
then  Les  chemins  de  fer  aujourd'hui  et  dans 
cent  ans  chez  tous  les  pcuples  (2  vols,  in  8vo, 
1858-1862).  This  last  is  an  economic  and 
financial  history  of  railways,  principally  in 
France,  containing  judicious  remarks  on  the 
future  of  this  great  industry,  some  of  which 
have  been  realised.  A.  c.  f. 

AUDIT.  An  audit  is  the  examination  of  an 
account,  or  books  of  account,  for  the  purpose  of 
ascertaining  their  correctness.  The  word  shows 
that  such  an  examination  originally  consisted 
of  the  hearing  of  explanations  from  the  person 
rendering  the  account,  such  as  would  be  fitting 
from  an  agent  when  submitting  his  account  to 
his  principal.  The  term  is  now  generally  used 
in  connection  with  the  examination  of  accounts 
of  public  bodies  or  companies  by  persons  ap- 
pointed for  the  purpose,  and  accounts  or  books 
are  considered  as  audited  or  proved  if  supported 
by  such  written  evidence  with  regard  to  the 
transactions  recorded  as  may,  in  the  opinion  oi 


70 


AUDIT 


the  auditor,  be  considered  sufficient  to  establish 
the  correctness  of  the  individual  entries  and  the 
truth  of  the  accounts.  It  has  long  been  the 
habit  of  those  responsible  for  the  accounts  of 
charitable  institutions  or  publicly  subscribed 
funds,  to  obtain  and  publish  a  certificate  of  one 
or  more  independent  persons,  to  the  effect  that 
the  accounts  have  been  examined  and  found 
correct.  Joint-stock  companies  also  from  an 
early  period  have  employed  the  services  of 
auditors,  and  the  law  which  has  grown  up  with 
regard  to  the  management  of  these  companies 
contains  various  regulations  with  reference  to 
the  audit  of  their  accounts.  The  Companies 
Clauses  Consolidation  Act  1845  (8  Vict.  c.  16) 
provides  that,  except  where  by  special  act 
auditors  shall  be  directed  to  be  appointed  other- 
wise than  by  the  company,  two  auditors,  each 
holding  at  least  one  share  in  the  undertaking, 
shall  be  elected  by  the  company  in  general 
meeting,  and  that  it  shall  be  their  duty  to 
receive  from  the  directors  the  periodical  accounts 
and  balance  sheet,  to  examine  the  same,  and 
confirm  or  report  upon  the  accounts  to  be  read 
at  the  ordinary  meeting.  The  Companies  Act 
1862  (25  &  26  Vict.  c.  89)  and  the  great 
extension  of  joint-stock  enterprise  under  limited 
liability  which  followed,  led  to  greater  attention 
being  paid  to  the  subject  of  audit.  In  the  first 
schedule  appended  to  that  act.  Table  A,  regula- 
tions for  management  are  prescribed  for  such 
companies  as  may  not  have  articles  of  association 
of  their  own  framed  to  suit  their  individual 
requirements,  and  these  include  provisions  with 
regard  to  the  appointment  and  duties  of  auditors. 
The  audit  of  the  accounts  of  railway  companies 
was  the  subject  of  special  legislation  in  1867, 
the  attention  of  parliament  having  been  drawn 
to  the  imperfect  and  erroneous  accounts  issued 
by  some  companies.  The  Railway  Companies 
Act  of  that  year  (30  &  31  Vict.  c.  127,  §  30) 
prescribes : — 

' '  No  dividend  shall  be  declared  by  a  company 
until  the  auditors  have  certified  that  the  half- 
yearly  accounts  proposed  to  be  issued  contain  a 
full  and  true  statement  of  the  financial  condition 
of  the  company,  and  that  the  dividend  proposed 
to  be  declared  on  any  shares  is  bona  fide  due  there- 
on after  charging  the  revenue  of  the  half  year  with 
all  expenses  which  ought  to  be  paid  thereout  in 
the  judgment  of  the  auditors." 

The  Regulation  of  Railways  Act  1868  (31  & 
32  Vict.  c.  119,  §  12)  repeals  the  regulation  of 
the  Companies  Clauses  Consolidation  Act  1845 
as  to  auditors  being  necessarily  interested  as 
shareholders. 

The   parliamentary   accounts   of  the  public 
expenditure  of  the  United  Kingdom — that  is, 
of  all  moneys  expended  for  the  public  service  by 
he  various  departments  of  the   State  out  of 
erial  public  moneys — are  rendered  to  and 
ted  by  the  comptroller  and  auditor-general, 
r  the  Exchequer  and  Audit  Departments  Act 


1866  (29  &  30  Vict.  c.  39).  This  act,  which 
abolished  the  former  offices  of  comptroller- 
general  of  the  exchequer  and  of  commissioners 
of  audit,  defines  the  functions  of  the  comptroller 
and  auditor-general  generally  in  regard  to  the 
examination  of  the  public  accounts  ;  and  in 
particular  requires  him,  on  behalf  of  the  House 
of  Commons,  to  examine  and  report  on  the 
"appropriation  accounts"  of  money  gi-anted  by 
parliament  upon  the  annual  estimates  for  the 
naval,  military,  and  various  civil  services. 
These  last-named  annual  accounts,  and  the 
reports  of  the  controller  and  auditor-general 
thereon,  are  presented  to  the  House  of  Commons 
at  the  commencement  of  the  session  immedi- 
ately following  their  preparation,  and  are  re- 
viewed by  a  committee  of  the  House,  called  the 
' '  Public  Accounts  Committee,  "who  take  evidence 
from  the  departments  concerned,  and  from  the 
Treasury,  on  any  points  to  which  attention  is 
drawn  by  the  comptroller  and  auditor-general, 
and  report  their  conclusions  and  recommenda- 
tions to  the  House. 

The  procedure  to  be  observed  in  an  audit, 
and  the  extent  to  which  an  audit  can  be  carried, 
depend  largely  on  the  character  of  the  trans- 
actions of  which  the  accounts  which  are  the 
subject  of  the  audit  are  the  record.  The  audit 
of  the  cash  account  of  a  charity  would  naturally 
include  the  vouching  of  the  payments  by  the 
written  acknowledgments  of  the  persons  to 
whom  the  cash  is  paid,  and  of  the  receipts  by 
the  counterfoils  of  the  printed  forms  filled  up  at 
the  time  of  acknowledgment,  or,  if  there  be 
such,  by  the  published  list  of  subscriptions  and 
donations.  The  auditor  might  obtain  evidence 
to  satisfy  him  that  aU  the  moneys  that  should 
have  been  received  had  been  brought  into  the 
account,  that  the  payments  were  correctly  made 
and  proper  in  their  character,  and  that  the 
balance  of  funds  in  hand  at  the  date  of  closing 
the  account  duly  existed.  This  should  be 
proved  by  the  bank  pass-book  supported  by  a 
certificate  from  the  bankers.  The  audit  in  such 
a  case  might  be  thorough  and  complete. 

The  audit  of  a  bank,  on  the  other  hand,  can- 
not be  carried  much  further  than  the  examina- 
tion of  the  accuracy  of  the  balance-sheet  as 
representing  the  financial  position  of  the  com- 
pany at  the  date  of  the  account.  It  would  be 
impossible  for  the  auditor,  even  if  evidence  were 
procurable,  to  prove  the  innumerable  entries 
recording  the  transactions  of  the  bank  and  re- 
sulting in  the  profit  taken  credit  for,  and  his 
work  necessarily  consists  mainly  of  an  examina- 
tion to  ascertain  that  the  assets  and  liabilities 
of  the  bank  are  correctly  described  in  the  balance- 
sheet,  that  the  assets  are  taken  at  no  more  than 
their  actual  value,  due  reserves  being  made  for 
any  depreciation  in  the  value  of  securities  or 
for  probable  loss  or  bad  debts,  and  that  all  the 
liabilities  are  brought  into  the  account.  The 
securities  representing   investments   should  be 


AUDIT— AUDIT  OFFICE 


71 


examined  at  the  date  to  which  the  accounts  are 
made  up ;  the  stocks  which  are  registered  without 
the  issue  of  a  certificate,  such  as  consols,  bank 
stock,  and  most  colonial  stocks,  being  proved 
by  a  special  letter  from  the  Bank  of  England  or 
other  registering  office,  certifying  the  holding. 

With  railways,  the  abstracts  of  traffic  from 
which  the  revenue  is  derived,  are  in  all  large 
companies  submitted  to  the  examination  of  a 
distinct  department  of  the  railway  called  the 
"audit  department"  which  is  wholly  inde- 
pendent of  the  issue  of  tickets  or  the  receipt  of 
cash,  and  the  shareholders'  auditor  can  but  ac- 
cept the  totals  arrived  at  by  that  department  as 
the  gi'oss  earnings  of  the  company.  It  is  his 
duty  to  see  that  these  are  duly  entered  and 
accounted  for,  to  examine  into  the  correctness 
of  the  records  of  the  company's  expenditure, 
and  more  especially  to  satisfy  himself  that  the 
allocation  of  this  expenditure  as  between  capital 
and  revenue  is  a  fair  one. 

It  is  not  considered  the  duty  of  an  auditor 
to  express  any  opinion  as  to  the  policy  of  a 
board  of  directors,  or  to  object  to  any  outlay 
which  the  board,  under  parliamentary  authority, 
or  under  the  general  powers  entrusted  to  direc- 
tors, may  think  fit  to  incur  ;  but  should  any 
expenditure  take  place  of  an  unusual  character, 
or  which,  in  the  auditor's  opinion,  the  directors 
are  not  autliorised  to  make,  or  should  the  ac- 
counts be  drawn  up  on  what  appears  to  him  to 
be  an  erroneous  basis,  it  is  incumbent  on  him, 
if  his  views  are  not  adopted  by  the  board  and 
the  accounts  amended  accordingly,  to  see  that 
the  facts  are  laid  before  the  shareholders. 

The  duties  of  auditing  now  form  a  very  im- 
portant portion  of  the  business  undertaken  by 
chartered  accountants.  The  variety  and  in- 
tricacy of  present  systems  of  account  keeping 
make  it  difficult  for  persons,  without  special 
training  and  experience,  to  discover  error  and, 
it  may  be,  fraud,  on  the  part  of  those  who  draw 
them  up,  and  it  has  become  the  practice  of  com- 
panies and  other  piiblic  bodies  to  appoint  profes- 
sional men  for  this  purpose.  As  an  instance  of 
this  tendency  the  statutes  made  for  the  uni- 
versities of  Oxford  and  Cambridge  by  the  com- 
missioners acting  in  pursuance  of  the  Universities 
of  Oxford  and  Cambridge  Act  1877,  provide  for 
the  audit  of  the  accounts  both  of  the  universities 
and  of  all  the  colleges,  either  by  professional 
accountants  carrying  on  business  in  London  or 
"Westminster,  or  by  persons  conversant  with 
accounts  approved  by  the  permanent  secretary 
to  Her  Majesty's  Treasury.  It  is  also  an 
increasing  practice  with  private  banks  and 
commercial  firms  to  have  the  accuracy  of  their 
books  and  annual  balance-sheets  tested  by 
professional  accountants.  The  rapidity  of 
modern  commercial  transactions  leads  to  the- 
finance  of  business  offices  being  entrusted  more' 
and  more  to  salaried  assistants,  and,  as  a  check 
on  these,  to  the  employment  of  independent 


persons  to  supervise  the  work  periodically. 
The  methods  adopted  by  the  professional 
accountant  and  his  trained  clerks  in  the  ex- 
amination of  books,  constitute  a  more  complete, 
systematic,  and  independent  audit  than  can  be 
easily  undertaken  by  a  partner  in  the  business, 
however  conversant  he  may  be  with  the  work. 
An  audit  of  this  kind  secures,  as  far  as  possible, 
accurate  bookkeeping,  the  detection  of  fraud, 
correct  and  intelligible  balance-sheets,  and  the 
proper  distribution  of  profits  or  losses,  and  acts 
in  not  a  few  cases  as  a  deterrent  from  crime 
by  practically  destroying  the  probabilities  that 
\vrong-doing  will  escape  detection.  Such  firms 
and  companies  also  who  seek  to  attract  business 
by  exhibiting  the  sound  condition  of  their 
finances,  and  with  that  object  publish  their 
balance-sheets,  find  it  necessary  to  have  their 
accounts  confirmed  by  independent  professional 
men,  on  whom  a  very  large  share  of  responsi- 
bility properly  rests  for  the  accuracy  of  the 
figures  which  they  certify. 

[Auditors,  their  Duties  and  Responsibilities,  F. 
W.  Pixley,  London,  5th  ed.  1889.]  KW. 

AUDIT  (Scots  law).     Taxation. 

AUDIT  OFFICE.  The  department  of  the 
state,  officially  designated  the  Exchequer  and 
audit  department,  which  is  entrusted  with  the 
audit  and  control  of  the  public  accounts. 

The  necessity  of  making  provision  for  an 
efficient  audit  of  the  receipt  and  expenditure  of 
public  moneys  has  long  been  recognised,  the 
office  of  auditor  of  the  exchequer,  the  most 
ancient  of  all  offices  of  control,  having  been 
established  as  far  back  as  the  year  1314.  Many 
of  the  great  departments  of  the  state  were  at 
the  outset  subject  to  separate  and  independent 
audit  arrangements,  but  in  the  year  1785  a 
special  office  for  auditing  the  public  accounts 
was  created,  and  the  first  step  of  importance 
taken  towards  the  concentration  of  this  function 
in  the  hands  of  a  single  authority.  In  1867 
this  object  may  be  said  to  have  been  definitely 
attained  by  the  amalgamation  of  the  offices  of 
the  comptroller -general  of  the  exchequer  and 
of  the  commissioners  for  auditing  the  public 
accounts,  a  single  department  being  then  estab- 
lished for  the  dual  purpose  of  controlling  the 
receipts  into  and  issues  from  the  exchequer,  and 
of  examining  the  accoimts  of  receipt  and  ex- 
penditure. 

The  responsible  heads  of  this  department  are 
the  comptroller  and  auditor- general  and  the 
assistant  comptroller  and  auditor,  both  of  whom 
are  appointed  by  the  croAvn  and  hold  their 
offices  during  good  behaviour,  being  immovable 
except  on  an  address  from  both  houses  of  par- 
liament. 

The  comptroller  and  auditor -general  is  re- 
quired to  examine,  on  behalf  of  the  House  of 
Commons,  the  accounts  of  all  moneys  voted  in 
supply,  or  which  are  a  charge  on  the  consoli- 


72 


AUDITOR  OF  THE  COURT  OF  SESSION— AULNAGER 


dated  fund,  and  for  this  purpose  full  powers  of 
access  to  public  accounts  are  given  him.  He  is 
required  to  report  the  result  of  his  examination 
annually,  and  if  the  treasury  fail  to  present  his 
reports  to  the  House  of  Commons,  he  must  do 
so  himself.  In  addition  to  this  duty  tijchnicarlly 
described  as  the  "appropriation  audit,"  the 
comptroller  and  auditor  -  general  must,  if  the 
treasury  so  direct,  examine  and  audit  any  other 
public  accounts  submitted  to  him  for  the  purpose, 
but  in  respect  to  this  portion  of  his  functions, 
the  comptroller  and  auditor-general  must  accept 
the  decision  of  the  treasury  on  any  question 
which  he  may  raise,  his  direct  responsibility  to 
the  House  of  Commons  being  limited  to  the 
appropriation  audit  above  referred  to.  In  con- 
nection with  the  exchequer  branch  of  his  depart- 
ment, the  comptroller  and  auditor -general  is 
required  from  time  to  time,  upon  the  requisi- 
tions of  the  treasury,  to  grant  credits  upon  the 
exchequer  for  consolidated  fund  and  supply 
services,  if  he  is  satisfied  that  they  are  not  in 
excess  of  the  sums  granted  by  the  various  acts 
of  parliament,  and  all  warrants  for  the  prepara- 
tion and  issue  of  exchequer  bills  and  bonds  and 
treasury  bills  are  countersigned  by  him. 

Recently,  the  opinion  has  been  very  generally 
expressed  that  the  manufacturing,  shipbuilding, 
and  other  like  accounts  of  the  army  and  navy 
should  be  subjected  to  a  more  rigorous  inde- 
pendent scrutiny  than  has  hitherto  been  the 
case.  Effect  has  been  given  to  this  opinion  in 
the  Army  and  Navy  Audit  Act,  1889  (52  and 
63  Vict.  c.  31),  which  imposes  upon  the 
comptroller  and  auditor -general  the  duty  of 
examining  accounts  showing  the  distribution 
and  cost  of  labour  employed  and  the  value  of 
stores  expended  in  the  several  government  dock- 
yards, ordnance  factories,  and  other  manufactur- 
ing establishments  of  the  army  and  navy. 

For  the  year  1913-14,  over  200  persons  were 
employed  by  the  department,  the  cost,  mainly 
for  salaries,  amounting  to  £68,265. 

The  duties  of  the  audit  office  are  set  forth  in 
detail  in  the  act  29  and  30  Vict.  c.  39,  and 
the  annual  reports  of  the  comptroller  and 
auditor -general  issued  with  the  appropriation 
accounts  for  the  army,  navy,  and  civil  services 
respectively  may  also  be  consulted,      t.  h.  e. 

AUDITOR  OF  THE  COURT  OF  SESSION. 
Taxing-master. 

AUGMENTATIONS,  Court  of.  This  was 
created  in  1536  to  collect  and  administer  the 
property  of  the  dissolved  monasteries.  It  con- 
sisted of  a  chancellor-treasurer,  an  attorney, 
ten  auditors,  and  seventeen  receivers.  A  vast 
amount  of  wealth  passed  through  the  hands  of 
this  body  during  the  next  few  years.  In  1545 
the  property  of  colleges,  chantries,  hospitals, 
and  guilds  was  also  confiscated  to  the  king,  and 
its  administration  entrusted  to  the  court  of 
augmentations.  But  this  enormous  property 
was   soon   dissipated   by  the   extravagance   of 


Henry  VIII.  and  of  the  council  under  Edward 
VI.,  and  with  its  dispersal  the  functions  of  the 
court  came  to  an  end. 

[Perry,  History  of  the  English  Church,  1887, 
vol.  ii.]  R.  L. 

AUGUSTINIS,  Matteo  de  (a  Neapolitan, 
living  in  the  first  half  of  19th  century),  the 
author  of  two  elementary  treatises  of  political 
economy  ;  both  are  summaries  of  the  leading 
doctrines  of  his  time,  mixed  with  criticisms 
from  a  moral  and  political  point  of  view.  He 
is  of  opinion  that  Free  Trade  ought  somewhat 
to  be  restricted  for  moral  and  social  considera- 
tions, and  considers  A.  Smith's  doctrines  as 
leading  sometimes  to  anarchy  of  both  personal 
interest  and  human  passions  ;  nevertheless  he 
thinks  that  liberty  ought  to  be  the  rule,  and 
government  interference  the  exception.  De 
Augustinis  represents  a  singular  intermixture 
of  doctrines  taken  from  J.  B.  Say,  Dunoyer, 
Senior,  and  other  liberal  economists,  and  of 
doctrines  taken  from  Sismondi  and  Romagnosi 
favourable  to  state  interference.  He  is  an 
eclectic  writer,  somewhat  like  Florez-Estrada. 
In  the  theory  of  value  he  tries  to  reconcile  the 
doctrines  based  on  the  cost  of  production  with 
those  based  oa  the  principle  of  utility  ;  but  he 
does  this  in  an  infantine  manner.  This  author, 
like  Cagnazzi  and  many  other  second  -  rate 
economists,  would  have  been  totally  forgotten 
by  this  time  if  the  modern  historical  school 
and  the  Socialists  op  the  Chair  had  not 
picked  up  and  collected  every  trace  of  opposi- 
tion which  in  course  of  time  had  manifested 
itself  against  the  so-caUed  English  school,  and 
if  they  had  not  given  a  renewed  importance 
to  the  intermixture  of  moral,  or  political,  or 
social  questions,  with  economic  topics.  De 
Augustinis's  Istituzioni  di  EcoTwmia  Saddle 
appeared  in  1837,  Naples  (tipografia  Porcelli), 
and  his  Elementi  di  Eeonomia  Sociale  in  1843. 
His  best  work  is  a  critical  essay  on  Pellegrino 
Rossi's  lectures  on  political  economy :  Studii 
critici  sopra  it  corso  di  Eeonomia  pol.  di  P.  Rossi, 
Napoli,  1844.  He  examines  in  it  one  by  one  the 
thirty-six  lectures  of  Rossi,  making  not  seldom 
acute  remarks  in  favour  or  against  doctrines  of 
Rossi.  This  work  was  originally  published  in 
a  series  of  articles  in  a  weekly  review  called 
Libcifero,  and  now  forms  a  volume  of  176  pages 
of  small  print  in  8vo. 

As  statistician  he  is  known  by  a  series  of 
letters  on  the  economical  condition  of  Naples  : 
Delia  condizione  economica  del  Regno  di  Napoli, 
Lettere,  Napoli,  1833,  Manzi.  m.  p. 

AULNAGER.  Under  Richard  I.  it  was 
ordered  that  "woollen  cloths,  wherever  they 
are  made,  shall  be  of  the  same  width,  to  wit, 
of  two  ells  within  the  lists,  and  of  the  same 
goodness  in  the  middle  and  sides."  This  rule 
was  again  asserted  in  Magna  Charta,  art.  35, 
and  under  Edward  I.  an  official,  called  aulnager, 
was  appointed  to  enforce  it.     It  was  his  duty 


AUNCEL— AUTUMNAL  DRAIN 


73 


to  affix  a  stamp  to  all  cloth  as  evidence  that  it 
was  of  the  necessary  size  and  quality.  When 
the  arbitrary  regulations  of  Richard  I.  were 
abandoned  in  the  14th  century,  the  aulnager's 
stamp  -was  still  used  to  certify  the  difference 
between  any  piece  of  cloth  and  the  old  require- 
ments. The  office  continued  to  exist  until  the 
reign  of  William  III.,  but  it  had  ceased  to 
be  of  much  importance  in  securing  customers 
against  fraud  and  imposition. 

[Ashley,  Economic  History,  i.  p.  180.]     R.  L. 
AUNCEL,  or  HANDSAL  weight,  a  kind  of 
balance  used  in  weighing  wool.     Forbidden  by 
25  Ed.  in. 

[Smith's  Memoirs  of  Wool,  1747,  vol.  i.  p. 
38.]  J.  B. 

AUSTRIAN  SCHOOL  OF  ECONOMISTS, 
The.  Among  German -speaking  nations  the 
predominant  school  of  economists  has  been, 
since  the  middle  of  the  century,  the  historical, 
which  seeks  to  reconstruct  economics  by  the 
aid  of  history  and  sociology.  Since  1871 
its  supremacy  has  been  threatened  in  Austria 
(if  not  in  Germany)  by  a  group  of  writers  who 
have  returned  to  the  deductive  method.  From 
their  agreement  in  method  and  leading  doc- 
trines, as  well  as  from  their  virtual  collabora- 
tion with  each  other,  these  writers  are  justly 
regarded  as  a  distinct  school,  which  may  (from 
the  nationality  of  the  chief  members)  be  called 
the  "Austrian"  school  of  economists.  Their 
method  is,  like  Ricardo's,  deductive  ;  and,  like 
RiCARDO,  they  treat  the  doctrine  of  value  as 
the  cardinal  point  in  economic  theory.  Their 
results,  however,  differ  considerably  from  the 
Ricardian.  Like  Jevons,  they  find  the  key  to 
the  problem  of  value  in  the  notion  of  final 
utility.  Unlike  Jevons,  they  regard  economics 
as  having  nearer  affinity  \vith  psychology  than 
with  mathematics,  and  they  are  sparing  in  the 
Use  of  mathematical  illustration.  They  have 
thus  made  the  doctrine  of  Final  Utility  {q.v.) 
intelligible  to  a  wider  circle  ;  and  have  influ- 
enced economists  outside  of  their  school  (for 
example,  M,  Block  in  France,  Professor  Cossa 
in  Italy,  and  Professors  J.  B.  Clark,  E.  B. 
Andrews,  and  S.  Patten  in  America).  It  was 
stated  in  reply  to  enquiries  in  1914  that  they 
have  practically  ceased  to  exist  as  a  separate 
School.     The  chief  authors  and  works  are  : 

Carl  Menger,  Grundsdtze  der  Volksxvirthschafts- 
lehre,  Vienna,  1871  ;  Methode  der  Sozial-vnssen- 

\8chaften,  Vienna,  1883  ;  Irrth'dvier  des  Hislorismus 
in  der  deutschen  Nationalokonomie,  Vienna,  1884. 

; — Friedr.  v.  Wieser,  Ursprung  und  Hauptgesetze 

\des    vnrthschaftlichen    Werthes,    Vienna,    1884 ; 

^Ber  Naturliche  Werth,  Vienna,  1889.— Em il  Sax, 
Wesen  und  Aufgaben  der  Nationalokonomik, 
Vienna,  1884  ;  Qrundlegung  der  theoretischen 
Staatswirthschaft^Yienna,  1887. — Eugen  v.  Bohm- 
Bawerk,  Rechte  und  VerhoLltnisse  vom  Stand- 
punkte  der  volkswirlhsch.  Griiterlehre,  Innsbruck, 
1881  ;  Kapital  und  Kapital-zins,  vol.  i.,  Inns- 
bruck, 1884  ;  vol.  ii.,  Innsbruck,  1889.— Robert 


Zuckerkandl,  Theorie  des  Preises,  Leipzig,  1889. 
— E.  von  Philippovich,  Avfgcd>e  und  Methode  der 
politischen  Oekonomie,  Freibiu-g,  1886. — Robert 
Meyer,  Principien  der  gerechten  Besteuerung, 
Vienna,  1884;  Das  Wesen  des  Einkoynmens,  1887. 
— Victor  Mataja,  Der  Unternehmergewinn,Yienna,, 
1884  ;  Das  Recht  des  Schadenersatzes,  Vienna, 
1888. — Johann  v.  Komorzynski,  Werth  in  der 
isolirten  Wirthschaft,  Vienna,  1889.  — Dr.E.  Seidlei 
in  Jahrb.  fur  JVat.  Oek.  und  Statist.,  March  1890 
applies  the  theory  of  value  to  doctrine  of  legal 
punishments  ;  he  gives  a  full  bibliography. — Ugo 
Mazzola,  Finanza  pubblica  (Rome,  189U). — C.  A. 
Conigliani,  Effetti  Economici  delle  Imposte  (Milan, 
1890). — For  a  criticism  from  a  Ricaidiau  point  of 
view,  see  A.  Loria  in  the  Nuova  A7itoloyia,  April 
1890. — Compare  H.  Dietzel  in  Conrad's  Jahrb. 
fiir  Nat.  Oek.  und  Statist.,  June  1890. —  See  also 
Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics  (Harvard),  Octo- 
ber 1888  and  April  1889.  Cf.  articles  below  on 
Value  ;  Historical  Method,  etc.  j.  b. 

AUTHORITIES,  Economic.  See  Political 
Economy,  Authorities  on. 

AUTUMNAL  DRAIN.  A  movement  of  coin 
in  the  autumn  throughout  the  country,  taking 
its  origin  from  the  season,  which  stimulates 
employment  in  agi'iculture,  and  sets  great  part 
of  the  population  free  for  an  autumnal  holiday. 

Statement  showing  autumnal  movements  of  gold 
and  silver  coin  held  by  Bank  of  England  for 
1881-1900 — beginning  of  September  to  about 
the  middle  of  November  (OOO's  omitted),  thus 
£1772  reads  £1,772,000. 


Year. 

S 
p 

Gold  Coin. 

Silve 

rCoin. 

i 

•2  " 

■1% 

I  fi-oin  or 
IlomeCir- 

II  balance. 

0) 

«3 

%a^ 

.s^ 

•2^ 

>  5  - 

-o 

o 

y 

Hi 

3 
& 

£ 

Q 

£ 

£ 

£ 

£ 

£ 

£ 

£ 

£ 

18S1 

1772 

811 

430 

788 

8801 

60 

1882 

417 

838 

610 

880 

2745 

.. 

19 

1883 

413 

795 

ISO 

873 

2261 

92 

1884 

1460 

765 

270 

935 

3430 

67 

1885 

754 

660 

1110 

252 

2776 

13 

1886 

259 

.. 

717 

330 

391 

1179 

28 

1887 

353 

575 

25 

383 

630 

57 

1888 

.. 

2513 

445 

420 

689 

4067 

141 

1889 

,. 

2431 

612 

300 

., 

640 

3983 

414 

1890 

,, 

2009 

616 

480 

1215 

4320 

174 

1891 

1471 

478 

320 

288 

2559 

•• 

77 

1892 

1856 

533 

235 

720 

3344 

153 

1893 

65 

SOO 

440 

724 

451 

145 

.. 

1894 

74 

584 

300 

730 

1540 

40 

1895 

3329 

964 

178 

1213 

5684 

104 

1896 

1453 

539 

108 

_^ 

348 

2448 

27 

1897 

928 

685 

SOO 

.. 

137 

2050 

.. 

4 

1898 

.. 

773 

829 

345 

,^ 

1523 

3470 

.. 

131 

1899 

4905, 

515 

357 

,_ 

1149 

6926! 

132 

1900 

1052'  926  1 

330  163 

2145  1 

■• 

49 

A  corresponding  influx  occurs  in  May  and  June 
of  2  to  3  millions.     (See  also  suh  voce  in  App.) 

The  effect  of  this  autumnal  pressure  was 
described,  1857,  by  the  late  Mr.  William  Lang- 
ton  to  the  Statistical  Society  of  Manchester 
(Transactions,  Session  1857-58),  and  the  investi- 


74 


AUXIEON— AVERAGE,  MARITIME 


gation  was  carried  on,  with  his  accustomed  in- 
genuity and  research,  by  Prof.  W.  S.  Jevons, 
1866  {Statistical  Society  of  London  Journal,  vol. 
xxix.)  The  pressure  appears  to  be  enhanced 
somewhat  by  the  requirements  of  the  Bank 
Act  of  1844,  in  consequence  of  the  movements  in 
the  Scotch  and  Irish  issues.  On  average,  for  the 
years  1846-1900,  the  rate  of  discount  charged 
by  the  Bank  of  England  was  higher  during  the 
autumn  months,  and  particularly  in  November, 
in  connection  with  this  movement.  A  some- 
what similar  influence  is  traceable  in  the  re- 
turns of  the  banks  of  France  and  Germany. 

[Jevons,  Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finance, 
London,  1884. — R.  H.  Inglis  Palgrave,  Bank  Rate 
in  England,  France,  and  Germany,  1844--'?8, 
London,  1880.— See  also  R.  H.  Inglis  Palgrave, 
Evidence  before  Select  Committee  of  House  of  Com- 
mons, Banks  of  Zssue,  1875. — Notes  on  Banking, 
R.  H.  Inglis  Palgrave,  London,  1873.] 

AUXIRON",  Claude  FRAN901S  Joseph  d' 
(b.  1728,  d.  1778),  an  engineer  and  physio- 
cratic  economist;  was  author  of  the  anonymously 
published — 

Principes  de  tout  Gouvernement,  ou  Examen  des 
causes  de  la  faihlesse  ou  de  la  splendeur  de  tout 
Stat  consider^  en  lui-mime  et  indipendamment  des 
■moeurs,  1766.  r.  y.  e. 

AVERAGE.  In  the  most  familiar  applica- 
tion of  the  term  the  average  of  a  given  set  of 
quantities  denotes  their  sum  divided  by  their 
number,  their  arithmetic  mean.  More  gener- 
ally an  average  may  be  defined  as  an  intermedi- 
ate value  derived  from  a  given  set  of  quantities 
by  a  process  such  that,  if  all  the  quantities 
were  equal,  the  derivative  quantity  would  coin- 
side  with  the  given  ones.  For  example,  if  a, 
6,  c,  etc.,  are  given  quantities  in  numlDer  w, 

then  the  expression 


J'- 


i-fC^ 


etc. 


average.  Of  the  forms  included  under  this  de- 
finition the  number  is  infinite.  The  following 
four  appear  to  be  most  important :  (1)  the 
arithmetic  mean  above  defined  ; — (2)  the  geo- 
metric mean,  formed  by  multiplying  n  quantities 
together  and  extracting  the  wth  root ; — (3)  the 
median,  which  is  such  that,  if  the  given  quan- 
tities be  arranged  in  the  order  of  their  magnitude, 
there  shall  be  as  many  of  them  above  as  below 
the  median  ; — (4)  the  mean  value  distinguished 
by  Fechner  as  ''dichteste  werth,"  and  by  De 
Venn  as  the  "maximum  ordinate  average," 
which  is  such  that  in  its  neighbourhood  the 
given  quantities  cluster  most  densely. — Varieties 
of  these  species  arise  when,  instead  of  allowing 
to  each  of  the  given  quantities  an  equal  part  in 
forming  the  average,  we  assign  more  importance 
to  some  of  the  data  than  to  others. 

In  choosing  among  these  different  species  and 
varieties,  attention  must  be  paid  to  two  rather 
subtle  distinctions.  First,  in  taking  an  average 
we  may  have  in  view  some  special  purpose  as  dis- 
tinguished from  the  general  objects  of  art  and 


science.  Suppose,  for  instance,  our  object  in 
finding  the  average  variation  of  prices  is  to 
ascertain  how  much  the  monetary  value  of  a 
specified  set  of  articles,  say  the  necessaries  of  a 
labouring  man,  has  varied.  This  specific  ob- 
ject is  evidently  correlated  with  a  qualified  or 
veighted  arithmetic  mean.  But,  if  the  average 
stature  for  each  of  several  districts  were  required, 
in  order  to  investigate  whether  there  is  any  con- 
nection between  height  and  food  (or  other 
attribute),  there  is  no  longer  the  same  presump- 
tion in  favour  of  the  arithmetic  mean.  Possibly 
the  third  or  fourth  species  of  average  might  be 
better.  Again,  the  average  may  or  may  not  be 
designed  to  represent  something  outside  and 
behind  the  given  numbers.  Thus  in  taking 
the  average  of  several  independent  estimates  of 
the  number  of  coins  in  a  country,  our  quoesitv/m 
is  an  objective  thing,  the  real  amount  of  coin. 
Less  substantive,  but  still  extraneous  to  the 
given  statistics,  is  a  species  of  qucesitum  more 
common  in  social  science,  which  may  be  de- 
scribed as  that  mean  value  towards  which  tends 
the  average  of  the  cmnplete  series,  of  which  the 
given  statistics  are  only  samples.  Thus,  in 
taking  the  average  of  a  given  set  of  price-varia- 
tions, we  may  aim  at  ascertaining,  as  far  as 
possible,  what  would  be  the  mean  variation  of 
prices,  if  we  could  complete  the  whole  series  of 
statistics  out  of  which  we  have  only  selections. 

The  general  result  of  these  considerations  is, 
on  the  one  hand,  in  many  cases  to  add  some 
reasons  in  favour  of  the  arithmetic  mean  be- 
sides the  obvious  grounds  of  familiarity  and 
convenience,  and,  on  the  other  hand,  in  certain 
cases  to  show  that  one  of  the  other  species  of 
average  is  preferable  (see  Adjustment,  Aver- 
age ;  Average,  Maritime). 

[Bertillon,  "  Moyemie,"  Dictionnaire  Encyclo- 
p9dique  des  Sciences  Medicates.  —  Edgeworth, 
"Observations  and  Statistics,"  Transactions  oj 
the  Cambridge  Philosophical  Society,  1885. — 
"The  Choice  of  Means,"  London  Philosophical 
Magazine,  1887. — "  Some  New  Methods  of  Measur- 
ing Variation  of  Prices,"  Journal  of  the  Royal 
Statistical  Society,  1888. — Galton  and  Macalister, 
"Law  of  the  Geometric  Mean,"  Proceedings  oj 
the  Royal  Society,  1879, — Lexis,  Massenerschevn- 
ungen. — Messedaglia,  "  Calcul  des  Valeurs  Moyen- 
nes,"  Annates  de  Demographic  Internationale, 
1880  (translated  from  Archivio  di  Statistica). — 
Venn,  Logic  of  Chance,  3d  ed.,  chaps,  xviii.  and 
xix.  See  also  the  older  authorities,  Laplace, 
QuETELET,  and  others,  referred  to  by  the  above  - 
named  writers.]  r.  T.  E. 

AVERAGE  (Maritime),  is  the  custom  that 
all  parties  concerned  in  the  adventuie  of  a 
vessel  at  sea  are  liable  in  equitable  proportion 
to  contribute  their  shares  of  losses  (particularly 
those  arising  from  "jettison"  or  the  throwing 
overboard  of  cargo  to  lighten  the  vessel)  and  of 
expenses,  when  such  losses  and  expenses  are 
incurred  for  the  common  good  by  one  or  more 
of  the  adventurers.     Although  this  custom  is 


AVERAGE,  MARITIME— BABBAGE 


75 


not  expressly  set  forth  in  the  most  ancient  sea- 
laws,  owing  perhaps  to  the  then  infrequency  of 
joint-stock  adventures  at  sea,  it  came  at  length 
to  be  so  fully  and  clearly  adopted  in  the  laws  of 
Rhodes  as  to  commend  itself  in  its  integrity  to 
the  founders  of  the  Roman  civil  law,  and  after- 
wards, with  occasional  modifications  of  no  very 
great  importance,  by  all  commercial  countries, 
from  the  date  of  the  Pandects  down  to  the 
present  time.  The  chapter  of  the  digest  De 
Lege  Rhodia  de  Jadu  (xiv.  2)  gives  full  details. 
The  following  is  the  illustrative  example  it 
contains  :  "  Wherefore,  if  two  men  should  each 
of  them  own  a  hundred  parts  in  the  cargo,  and 
Oaius,  the  owner  of  the  goods  thrown  overboard, 
shall  own  two  hundred,  Caius,  on  a  loss  of  the 
cargo,  should  receive  fifty  from  each  of  them  : 
losing  his  other  hundred  by  shipwreck,  because 
he  had  just  as  large  a  share  in  the  wares  lost 
as  they  together  had  in  the  wares  preserved. 
Hence,  as  the  share  of  Caius,  which  represented 
two  hundred,  was  in  excess  of  the  share  of  each 
of  them  which  represented  one  hundred  each, 
in  the  same  proportion  after  the  disaster,  the 
share  of  Caius,  representing  one  hundred,  will 
be  in  excess  of  the  share  of  each  representing 
fifty,  just  as  both  before  and  after  the  disaster 
the  share  of  Caius  exceeded  by  a  half  the  share 
of  each  of  the  others.  On  the  other  hand,  if 
Caius  should  throw  overboard  wares  to  the 
value  of  fifty,  but  each  of  the  other  men  shall 
have  kept  his  own,  estimated  at  one  hundred 
each,  Caius  shall  suft'er  a  loss  of  ten,  but  these 
other  two  shall  contribute  double  each,  namely 
twenty  ;  so  that  just  as  his  fifty  answered  to 
the  one  hundred  of  each  of  his  })artiiers,  in  like 
manner  his  forty  may  answer  to  the  eighty 
apiece  that  each  of  them  retains." 

It  would  certainly  have  conduced  to  clearness 
if  this  example   had   set  out  that   the  total 


cargo  was  made  up  of  400  parts,  and  that  the 
loss  of  Caius's  goods,  200  parts,  entailed  an 
average  contribution  of  one-half  on  each  of  the 
adventurers'  shares.  Similarly,  in  the  second 
case,  the  total  value  of  the  cargo  was  250, 
and  the  loss  of  Caius's  goods,  worth  fifty,  en- 
tailed an  average  contribution  of  one-fifth  on 
each  of  their  shares  in  tha  total  value,    f.  h. 

AWARD.  The  decision  of  the  arbitrators  or 
of  the  umpire  to  whom  parties,  wishing  to  avoid 
recurrence  to  a  legal  tribunal,  have  referred 
their  dispute.  A  submission  to  arbitration  may 
be  made  a  rule  of  court  on  the  application  of 
either  party,  and  if  this  has  been  done,  the  award 
may  be  enforced  with  the  court's  assistance  ; 
otherwise  the  only  means  of  compelling  the 
party,  against  whom  the  award  has  been  given, 
to  satisfy  its  directions,  is  to  bring  an  action 
and  to  obtain  judgment  on  the  basis  of  the 
award  (see  Arbitration).  e.  s. 

AZUNI,  DoMENico  Alberto,  born  at 
Sassari  (Sardinia)  in  1760,  died  1827  at 
Cagliari  in  Sardinia.  A  famous  commercial 
lawyer  and  president  of  the  Court  of  Appeal  of 
Genoa,  he  became  a  member  of  the  French  corps 
legislatif,  and  was  appointed  by  Napoleon  I. 
one  of  the  members  of  the  commission  which 
drew  up  the  Code  de  Commerce.  He  was  the 
principal  author  of  the  Livre  dcuxUme  du 
Commerce  maritiine.  Maritime  commerce,  is 
also  the  subject  of  his  principal  works  which.are 
^vritten  in  French,  or  in  French  and  Italian. 

Sistema  universale  dei  priiicipii  del  diritto 
marittimo  deW  Jiiirojja  ;  the  French  edition  has 
the  title  Droit  maritime  de  V Europe  ; — Essai 
sur  Vhistoire  geographique,  politique  et  morale  de 
la  Sardaigne  ; — Suit' origine  delta  bussola;  Dizion- 
ario  di  giurisprudenza  mercantile; — Memoires 
pour  servir  d  Vhistoire  des  viarins  navigateurs  de 
Marseille.  M.  p. 


BABBAGE,  Charles,  born  near  Teign- 
mouth  1792,  studied  at  Trinity  College,  Cam- 
bridge, gi-aduating  (without  honours)  1814. 
In  1816  he  was  made  fellow  of  the  Royal 
Society.  He  was  also  an  active  member  of  the 
Astronomical  Society.  Feeling  the  defects  of 
the  Royal  Society  as  then  organised,  he  helped 
to  found  the  British  Association  (1831),  the 
statistical  section  of  which  (1833)  was  due  to 
him,  as  well  as  the  Statistical  Society  (1834). 
Between  1822  and  1843  his  time  and  money 
were  almost  wholly  devoted  to  the  building  of 
his  two  great  calculating  engines,  one  of  which 
(partially  complete)  is  preserved  in  the  South 
Kensington  Museum.  In  1828  he  was  chosen 
Lucasian  professor  of  mathematics  at  Cambridge. 
He  wrote  not  only  on  mathematical  subjects, 
but  on  geology,  the  diving  bell,  lighthouses, 
metal-planing,  life  insurance,  infant  mortality, 
taxation,  and  last  (but  to  economists  not  least), 
on  machinery   and   manufactures.       His    last 


public  efforts  were  to  repress  the  barrel-organ, 
an  unhappy  application  of  mechanical  invention 
to  the  fine  arts.  He  gave  the  world  a  retro- 
spect of  his  own  career  in  Passages  from  the 
Life  of  a  Philosopher  (1864).  He  died  in  1871. 
Though  Babbage  himself  has  done  compara- 
tively little  for  economic  theory,  he  has  certainly 
aided  it  indirectly,  by  his  full  and  faithful  de- 
scriptions of  some  of  the  most  characteristic 
phenomena  of  modern  industry.  If  he  is  con- 
tent to  take  most  of  his  economical  doctrines 
at  second  hand,  he  at  least  holds  them  intelli- 
gently, and  states  them  with  a  vigour  of  his 
own,  dwelling  chiefly  on  the  aspect  which 
strikes  him  most.  Political  economy,  he  says, 
proceeds  on  the  assumption  of  certain  principles 
which  are  no  more  than  general,-  not  com- 
pelling universal  obedience  like  the  principles 
of  mathematical  science,  but  no  less  than 
general,  being  much  more  frequently  obeyed  than 
violated.      Such    is,    e.g.,    the    principle    that 


76 


BABBAGE 


men  are  governed  by  their  imagined  interest, 
and  that  each  individual  is  the  best  judge 
of  this  for  himself.  The  proper  method  of 
economic  (as  of  other)  inquiries  is  "to  divide 
the  subject  into  as  many  different  questions  g,s 
it  "A^ill  admit  of,  and  then  to  examine  each 
separately,  or  in  other  words,  to  suppose  that 
each  single  cause  successively  varies,  whilst  all 
the  others  remain  constant."  It  is  hopeless 
for  those  who  cannot  master  the  separate 
questions  in  their  simplicity  to  make  a  success- 
ful investigation  of  their  united  action  (Bx- 
position  of  1851,  pp.  1-4).  Babbage  has  a  clear 
view  of  the  distinction  between  economics  and  the 
exact  sciences,  and,  though  a  mathematician  and 
a  contemporary  of  Cournot,  Whewell,  and 
Tozer,  he  makes  no  attempt  to  treat  political  econ- 
omy by  mathematical  methods.  He  lays  down 
with  great  clearness  the  distinction  of  fine  arts 
from  industrial  arts,  a  technical  distinction  that 
involves  an  economical  one.  He  makes  it  plain 
that  economical  inquiries  must  deal  mainly  with 
industrial  arts.  In  the  fine  arts,  "each  example 
is  an  individual,  the  production  of  individual 
taste,  and  executed  by  individual  hands,"  and 
therefore  costly.  In  the  industrial,  "each  ex- 
ample is  but  one  of  a  multitude  generated  ac- 
cording to  the  same  law,  by  tools  or  machines, 
and  moved  with  unerring  precision  by  the 
application  of  physical  force,"  and  therefore 
cheap  {Exposition  of  1851,  pp.  48,  49).  The 
social  and  economical  effects  of  cheapness  are 
brought  out  by  Babbage  with  useful  reiteration 
in  support  of  free  trade,  and  more  especially  in 
connection  with  the  invention  and  application 
of  tools  and  machinery.  In  fact,  his  chief  direct 
contribution  to  theoretical  economics  has  been 
his  clear  analysis  of  the  Division  of  Labour 
(g-.-u.),  and  of  the  economical  function  of  Ma- 
chinery in  the  modern  industrial  system.  In 
regard  to  division  of  labour,  the  merits  of  his 
discussion  of  the  subject  are  generally  admit- 
ted. He  pointed  out  that  the  advantages 
mentioned  by  Adam  Smith  in  the  Wealth 
of  Nations  (bk.  i.  ch.  i.),  would  not  explain 
the  cheapness  of  manufactured  articles,  un- 
less, to  that  author's  list  we  add  the  following 
{Economy  of  Machinery  and  Manufactures,  ch. 
xviii.  p.  1 3  7).  "  That  the  master  manufacturer, 
by  dividing  the  work  into  different  processes, 
each  requiring  different  degrees  of  skill  and 
force,  can  purchase  exactly  that  precise  quantity 
of  both  which  is  necessary  for  each  process, — 
whereas,  if  the  whole  work  were  executed  by 
one  workman,  that  person  must  possess  suffi- 
cient skill  to  perform  the  most  difficult,  and 
sufficient  strength  to  execute  the  most  laborious, 
of  the  operations  into  which  the  art  is  divided. " 
In  other  words,  advantage  must  be  taken  of 
the  several  individual  capabilities  of  the  work- 
men, intellectual  and  physical,  and  the  work 
must  be  so  organised  that  workmen  be  only 
called  upon  to  do  that  which  they  can  do  best 


of  all.  In  the  statement  of  this  principle  he 
has,  as  he  allows,  been  anticipated  by  Gioja,  the 
Italian  economist  {Nuovo  Prospetto  delle  Scienze 
Economiche,  vol.  i.  ch.  iv.,  Milan,  1815)  ;  but 
he  was  led  to  it  independently  by  his  own 
observation  of  the  actual  working  of  English 
and  foreign  factories.  Without  this  organis- 
ation of  labour  (he  says),  full  advantage  cannot 
be  taken  of  tools  and  machines,  however 
ingenious.  The  nature  of  machinery,  as  dis- 
tinguished from  mere  tools,  is  thus  described : 
"When  each  process  has  been  reduced  to  the 
use  of  some  simple  tool,  the  union  of  all  these 
tools,  actuated  by  one  moving  power,  constitutes 
a  machine  "  {Economy  of  Machinery  and  Manu- 
factures, p.  136  ;  cp.  Marx,  Kapital  I.  xiii.  389 
note).  The  examples  show  that  Babbage  con- 
ceived, as  Marx  has  done  after  him,  that  so 
long  as  the  moving  power  is  simply  the  human 
muscles,  we  have  to  do,  not  with  a  machine, 
but  only  with  a  tool.  It  is  on  subjects  like 
these,  at  once  of  technical  and  of  economical 
importance,  that  Babbage  is  at  his  best.  In 
his  views  on  taxation  and  currency,  he  accepts 
substantially  the  ordinary  doctrines  of  the  domi- 
nant school  of  economists.  His  criticisms  of 
the  defects  in^the  exhibition  of  1851  remind 
us  in  many  places  of  Cobden's  views  {e.g.  in 
England,  Ireland,  and  America)  on  the  blessings 
of  cheap  goods  and  large  advertising.  But  in  his 
Economy  of  Machinery  and  Manufactures  (1832), 
Babbage  not  only  showed  the  range  and  accuracy 
of  his  own  personal  observation  and  inquiry,  but 
displayed  a  better  comprehension  of  the  econ- 
omical bearings  of  the  factory  system  of  produc- 
tion than  any  previous  economical  writer.  The 
book  is  a  storehouse  of  illustrations  from  actual 
business ;  the  writer  never  draws  on  his 
imagination  for  an  example  when  his  memory 
and  his  note -book  will  serve  him.  On  the 
other  hand,  his  book  is  not  like  Beokmann's 
History  of  Inventions,  a  mere  collection  and 
narrative  of  facts,  without  an  interpretation  of 
them  by  economical  principles,  nor  is  it,  like 
Ure's  Philosophy  of  Manufactures,  a  mere  eulogy 
of  the  factory  system  of  his  own  day.  Though 
he  lays,  perhaps,  undue  stress  on  the  capitalist, 
and  his  gains  by  the  economy  of  materials  and 
labour,  he  sees  the  need  of  improved  industrial 
arrangements  for  the  workmen,  co-operative 
stores,  and  industrial  profit-sharing,  and  is  in 
favour  of  the  abolition  of  the  truck  system,  and 
all  unfair  restrictions  on  workmen's  liberty  of 
combination  {Economy  of  Machinery  and  Manu- 
factures, ch.  xxi.  p.  177,  ch.  xxviii.  p.  253). 
He  is  no  blind  worshipper  of  Mammon  ;  and 
he  sneers  at  the  vulgar  notion  that  no  calling 
is  respectable  which  does  not  produce  wealth. 
It  is  in  the  public  interest  rather  than  their 
own  that  he  wishes  scientific  men  to  have  a 
larger  material  reward  than  niggardly  govern 
ments  were  then  granting  {Exposition  of  1851. 
p.  147,  etc.) 


B  ABBAGE— B  ABEUF 


77 


He  Mo-ote  with  feeling  on  this  last  subject 
because  he  was  himself  above  everything  an 
inventor.  This  is  not  the  place  tp  discuss  the 
merits  of  his  calculating  engines,  or  the  justice 
of  his  complaints  against  the  successive  govern- 
ments witli  which  he  contended  in  his  twenty 
years'  endeavour  to  build  his  engines  (see 
Appendix  to  Exposition  of  1851).  But  we  may 
note  that  his  design  in  the  invention  of  them 
was  simply  to  convert  into  physical  mechanism 
what  had  already  become  a  mechanical  process 
psychologically  (Mach.  and  Maniif.,  ch.  xix. 
p.  157),  and  this  is  one  of  the  brightest  aspects 
of  the  work  of  a  modern  inventor.  In  the  ab- 
stract, Babbage  was  far  from  magnifying  an 
inventor's  office.  '*The  man  who  aspires  to 
fortune  or  fame  by  new  discoveries  must,"  he 
sa,ys  (Mack,  and 3Ianvf. ,  ch.  xxv.  p.  212),  "be 
content  to  examine  with  care  the  knowledge  of 
his  contemporaries,  or  to  exhaust  his  etibrts  in 
inventing  again  what  he  will  most  probably  find 
has  been  better  executed  before  ;  the  power  of 
making  new  mechanical  combinations  is  a  pos- 
session common  to  a  multitude  of  minds,  and 
by  no  means  requires  talents  of  a  high  order." 
It  results,  he  believes,  from  the  principle  of  the 
division  of  labour,  which  should  be  applied  not 
only  to  industrial,  but  to  mental  labour,  and 
has  a  great  career  still  before  it  in  the  latter 
field.  Under  happier  auspices,  Babbage  would 
no  doubt  have  led  the  way  in  person  still  further 
than  he  did,  in  the  directions  thus  indicated. 

Those  of  l)is  works  which  are  directly  and 
indirectly  of  most  economical  importauce  are  the 
following : — On  the  Economy  of  Machinei-y  and 
Mamtfacturcs,  1 832,  third  edition,1833. — Thoughts 
on  the  Principles  of  2\ixation  with  reference  to  a 
Property  Tax  and  its  Exceptions  [exemptions  from 
it],  1848  ;  second  edition,  1851  ;  third  edition, 
1852.  An  Italian  translation  of  the  first  edition, 
with  notes,  was  published  in  1851  at  Turin. — Ob- 
servations on  the  Decline  of  Science  in  England, 
1830  [largely  an  attack  on  the  Royal  Society]. — 
A  Comparative  View  of  the  different  Institutions 
for  the  Assurance  of  Life,  1826.—  Essay  on  the 
General  Principiles  which  regulate  the  Application 
of  Machinery  (from  Encyclop.  Metropolitana, 
1829).—"  Letter  to  T.  P.  Courtenay  on  the  Pro- 
portion of  Births  of  the  two  sexes  amongst  Legiti- 
mate and  Illegitimate  Children "  (Brewster's 
Edinr.  Journal  of  Science,  vol.  ii.  p.  85,  1829). — 
"On  the  Principles  of  Tools  for  Turning  and  Plan- 
ing Metals  "  (In  Holtzapffel's  Turning  and  Mechani- 
cal Manipulation,  vol.  ii.  1846). — The  Exposition 
of  1851,  or  Views  of  the  Industry,  the  Science,  and 
the  Government  of  England,  1851. — Statistics  of 
•  the  Clearing  House,  reprinted  from  Transactions 
of  the  Statistical  Society,  1856. — Passages  from 
"  the  Life  of  a  Philosopher,  1864.  J.  B. 

BABEUF,  Franqois  Noel,  called  Caius 
Gracchus,  born  at  Saint  Quentin  1764,  died  at 
VendOme,  24th  February  1797.  Left  to  his  own 
resources  at  the  age  of  sixteen,  his  youth  was. 
stormy,  and  his  whole  life  wild  and  irregular. 
From  the  commencement  of  the  Revolution  he 


wrote  in  the  journal  Le  correspondant  Picard, 
articles  so  violent  in  tone  that  he  was  brought 
to  trial.  His  acquittal,  14th  July  1790,  did 
little  to  calm  him.  Appointed  administrator 
of  the  Departement  of  the  Somme,  he  soon 
had  to  be  dismissed  from  tliat  office.  This 
was  the  time  at  which  he  took  the  name  of 
Caius  Gracchus,  posing  as  a  Tribun  du  peuple. 
He  gave  the  same  name  to  a  journal,  which  he 
had  previously  carried  on  under  the  sub-title  of 
Defenseur  de  la  liberte  de  la  prcsse.  All  this 
took  place  shortly  after  the  fall  of  Robespierre 
from  power.  This  for  a  time  had  his  approval ; 
but  he  soon  returned  to  his  earlier  views  and 
appealed  to  those  violent  2>assions  which,  as  a 
demagogue,  he  knew  how  to  rouse.  He  gathered 
round  him,  under  the  name  of  the  Secte  des 
Egaux,  all  the  old  Montagnards  who  were  dis- 
satisfied with  the  regime  of  the  Thermidorians. 
The  object  of  this  sect,  which  drew  its  inspira- 
tion from  some  of  the  sentimental  ideas  of  J.  J. 
Rousseau,  was  to  destroy  inequality  o  f  condition, 
with  the  object  of  attaining  the  general  good. 
Sylvain  Marechal,  author  of  a  Dicfionnaire  des 
AtMes,  BuoNAimori,  who  claimed  to  be  descended 
from  Michael  Angelo,  with  Amand  and  Anto- 
nelle,  who  did  not,  it  is  true,  remain  associated 
long,  and  some  others,  formed  the  stall  wliich 
recognised  Babeuf  as  tlieir  chief.  AVorking  with 
feverish  activity,  they  gathered  round  them  a 
considerable  number  of  adherents.  The  place 
where  their  club  met  was  the  Pantheon.  At 
first  orderly,  their  meetings  became  tumultuous 
and  threatening  and  were  ]u-olonged  far  into 
the  night.  Attending  armed,  they  prepared  to 
resist  by  force  the  dissolution  of  tlic  club  wliieli 
the  authorities  had  determined  on.  General 
Bonaparte,  acting  with  nmch  tact,  contrived  to 
close  the  meetings  of  the  club,  but  the  members 
formed  tliemselves  forthwith  into  a  secret  society, 
and  gradually,  by  winning  over  soldiers  and 
police,  .  became  a  formidable  body,  numbering 
nearly  17,000  able-bodied  and  armed  men,  with- 
out including  the  Faubourgs  Saint-Antoine  and 
Saint-Marceau,  which  Avere  at  their  back.  Ad- 
dressing themselves  to  the  masses,  tliey  pub- 
lished a  manifesto  written  by  Sylvain  Marechal 
in  his  most  inflammatory  style — "AVe  desire," 
said  they,  ' '  real  equality  or  death.  This  is 
what  we  want.  And  we  will  have  real  e(piality, 
no  matter  what  it  costs.  Woe  to  those  wlio 
come  between  us  and  our  wishes.  Woe  to  him 
who  resists  a  desire  so  resolutely  insisted  on. 
.  .  .  If  it  is  needful,  let  all  civilisation  perish, 
]irovided  that  we  obtain  real  equality.  .  .  . 
The  common  good,  or  the  community  of  goods. 
No  further  private  property  in  land  ;  the  land 
belongs  to  no  private  person.  We  claim, 
we  require  the  enjoyment  of  the  fruits  of  the 
land  for  all ;  the  fruits  belong  to  the  whole 
world,"  etc. 

Instructions  in  great  detail  as  to  the  methods 
of  raising  insurrectionary  movements  were  added. 


78 


BACK-BOND— BADGER 


"  Those  who  hinder  us  shall  be  exterminated  ; 
.  .  .  shall  all  alike  be  put  to  death :  Those 
who  oppose  us  or  gather  forces  against  us  ; 
strangers,  of  whatever  nation  they  may  be,  who 
are  found  in  the  streets  ;  all  the  presidents, 
secretaries,  and  officers  of  the  royalist  (sic)  con- 
spiracy of  Vendemiaire,  who  may  also  dare  to 
show  themselves."  If  the  lives  of  men  were 
to  be  treated  thus,  one  may  guess  what  fate 
was  reserved  for  their  property.  But,  after 
massacres  and  spoliations,  what  was  to  come  of 
it  all  ?  The  public  authorities  were  to  organise 
employment ;  there  was  to  be  only  one  source 
of  employment,  the  state,  with  subdivisions 
devised  to  meet  the  wants,  somewhat  rudimen- 
tary, of  the  community.  Every  one  was  to 
have  a  right  to  lodging,  clothes,  washing,  warm- 
ing, and  lighting,  to  food,  mediocre  maisfrugale, 
to  medical  attendance.  This  is  much  what 
Louis  Blano,  who  appears  to  have  sought  his 
inspiration  among  the  decrees  of  the  Ripuhlique 
des  Egaux,  enunciated  in  more  methodical  and 
sober  language.  "  Every  one  is  to  work  as  he  is 
able,  and  to  consume  according  to  his  wants." 

The  secret  was  well  kept ;  it  was  only  a  few 
hours  before  the  moment  fixed  for  the  explosion 
of  the  conspiracy  (May  1796)  that  a  captain, 
named  Grisel,  revealed  it  to  the  directory. 
Decisive  steps  were  taken  at  once  ;  a  vigorous 
watch  was  kept,  while  the  public  authorities 
seized  the  leaders  and  their  papers. 

Babeuf  and  Darthe,  condemned  to  death  the 
23d  of  February  1797,  stabbed  themselves  before 
the  tribunal.  Life  still  lingering  on,  they  were 
guillotined  the  next  day.  Buonarroti  and 
Sylvain  Marechal,  condemned  to  exile  (deporta- 
tion), died,  the  first  in  1837,  the  second  in  1803. 

It  may  be  added  that  Babeuf  seems  to  have 
had  rather  a  disordered  brain  than  an  absolutely 
criminal  disposition.  He  died  with  courage, 
leaving  his  wife  a  written  paper  declaring  his 
conviction  that  he  had  always  been  a  "perfectly 
virtuous  man." 

See  Blano,  J.  J.  L. ;  Brissot  de  Warville  ; 
Communism  ;  Proudhon.  a.  c.  f. 

BACK- BOND  (Scots  law  term).  A  declara- 
tion by  one  apparently  an  absolute  owner  that 
he  is  only  a  trustee  or  mortgagee. 

BACKWARDATION.  When  a  seUer  of 
stock  "for  the  account"  (v.  Account)  on  the 
stock  exchange  finds  that  he  has  not  previously 
obtained  the  stock  which  he  sold,  he  asks  the 
dealer  to  whom  he  sold  to  allow  him  to  prolong 
his  bargain  until  the  next  settlement.  If  the 
security  in  question  be  unusually  scarce,  the 
buyer  finds  himself  in  a  position  to  charge  the 
seller  for  the  accommodation,  and  the  rate  or  fine 
which  he  imposes  upon  the  person  unable  to 
deliver  his  stock  or  shares,  according  to  the  con- 
tract, is  called  a  Backwardation.  This  fine,  being 
paid  again  and  again  from  settlement  to  settle- 
ment, at  varying  and  sometimes  very  high  rates, 
is  the  main  source  of  profit  in  a  Corner  (q.v.) 


in  stocks  and  shares.  The  unlucky  seller  in 
blank,  being  unable  either  to  deliver  or  borrow 
stock  in  satisfaction  of  the  contract,  is  occasion- 
ally at  the  mercy  of  the  buyer.  The  stocks  of 
certain  railways  have,  on  some  occasions,  been 
made  so  scarce  by  such  operations  that  specula- 
tive sellers  have  had  to  pay  whatever  "back- 
wardation" the  successful  speculative  buyers 
have  been  pleased  to  impose.  a.  b. 

BACON,  Francis  (Viscount  St.  Albans). 
Born  1560-61,  died  1626.  At  the  time  when 
Bacon  lived,  economic  questions  had  not  taken 
any  separate  place  among  the  studies  to  which 
a  statesman  gave  special  attention  ;  but  Bacon's 
mind,  ingenious,  fertile  in  resource,  keen  in 
research  as  it  was,  did  not  neglect  the  examina- 
tion of  those  questions  of  policy  which  require 
economic  treatment.  Mr.  Spedding  (Bacon's 
Works,  ed.  Spedding,  vol.  iii.  p.  515)  considers 
that  Bacon  was  "little  before  his  age  in  his 
views  with  regard  to  usury,  trade,  etc."  (See 
Essay  xxxiv.,  "  Of  Riches ").  By  the  time, 
however,  when  the  essay  on  "  Plantations  "  was 
written,  Colonies,  as  Mr.  Reynolds  observes, 
had  been  successfully  founded.  Bacon's  remark, 
"Let  there  be  freedom  from  custom  tiU  the 
plantation  be  of  strength,  and  not  only  freedom 
from  custom,  hut  freedom  to  carry  their  com- 
modities where  they  may  make  their  best  of 
them,  except  there  be  some  special  cause  of 
caution,"  and  those  on  the  treatment  and 
government  of  colonies  generally,  show  perhaps 
his  best  judgments  on  these  matters.  Most  of 
Bacon's  writings  deal  with  other  subjects,  but 
the  reference  to  colonial  possessions  in  his 
speech  when  lord  chancellor  on  the  election  of 
Serjeant  Richardson  as  Speaker  (1620),  describ- 
ing this  country's  portion  "in  the  New  World, 
by  the  plantation  of  Virginia  and  the  Summer 
Islands.  .  .  .  Sometimes  a  grain  of  mustard 
seed  proves  a  great  tree,  who  can  tell  ?"  (Bacon's 
Works,  ed.  Spedding,  vol.  xiv.  p.  175),  may 
also  be  quoted  in  this  connection.  The  essay 
"Of  the  true  greatness  of  Kingdoms  and  Estates," 
and  the  history  of  Henry  VII.,  though  these 
deal  principally  with  politics,  show  that  Bacon 
had  taken  the  study  of  these  branches  of  econo- 
mics also  "among  his  portion." 

The  editions  of  Bacon's  Works  are  many.  That 
edited  by  Spedding,  Ellis,  etc.  (14  vols.,  London, 
1857-74),  and  those  of  the  Essays  (London, 
1881)  and  the  Advancement  of  Learning  by  W. 
Aldis  Wright,  and  of  the  Essays  by  S.  H.  Rey- 
nolds (both  these  Clarendon  Press),  may  be  speci- 
ally mentioned.  Mr.  Reynolds  remarks,  and 
truly,  that  in  Bacon's  "views  about  trade  he 
takes  the  mercantile  theory  as  his  guide." 

BADGER.  This  name  was  formerly  used  to 
signify  a  small  trader  buying  corn  or  victuals 
(fish,  butter,  or  cheese,  specially  mentioned)  in 
one  place  in  order  to  sell  them  in  another.  The 
Act  5  &  6  Edw.  VI.  c.  14,  §  7  exempts  these 
men  from  the  penalties  enacted  against  Fore- 


BADGER— BAGEHOT 


79 


STALLERS  AND  Regrators  {q.v.),  but  requires 
them  to  be  licensed  by  three  justices  of  the 
peace  of  the  county  where  they  dwell.  A  subse- 
quent act,  5  Eliz.  c.  12,  declares  that  the  result 
of  this  legislation  was  that  many  persons  ' '  seek- 
ing only  to  live  easily  and  to  leave  their  honest 
labour"  have  taken  up  this  trade,  and  enacts 
that  licensees  are  to  be  householders  having 
dwelt  in  the  county  for  three  years,  and  that 
the  justices  may  require  a  badger  to  enter  into 
recognisances  not  to  forestall  or  engross.  The 
rules  as  to  licensing  are  made  more  stringent, 
and  penalties  assigned  for  a  breach  of  them. 
The  word  is  now  obsolete  excei)t  in  certain 
dialects.  It  was  used  to  denote  the  foreman  of 
a  Gang  of  agricultural  labourers  (Kebbel's  Agri- 
cultural Labourer,  1870,  p.  3). 

[Tomlins'  Law  Dictionary,  1835. — Dr.  Murray's 
New  English  Dictionary,  s.v.  1884.]        C.  G.  c. 

BAGEHOT,  Walter.  Born  at  Langport, 
Somersetshire,  1826,  died  at  Langport,  1877. 
Bagehot  was  son  of  the  managing  partner  of 
Stuckey's  Bank  who  sent  him  to  be  educated 
at  University  College,  London.  After  taking 
successively  his  B.A.  and  M.A.  degrees  at 
London  University,  with  the  higliest  honours, 
in  1846  and  1848,  he  read  law,  and  was 
called  to  the  Bar  ;  but,  after  a  visit  to  Paris, 
where  he  was  living  at  the  time  of  the  coup 
d'4tat,  in  1851,  he  decided  to  enter  his 
father's  bank.  His  stay  in  Paris  gave  occa- 
sion to  a  series  of  very  brilliant  letters  on  the 
political  condition  of  France  under  the  prince 
president  (as  Louis  Napoleon  was  at  that  time 
entitled),  which  were  published  in  the  Inquirer 
newspaper.  They  were  in  effect  an  apology  for 
the  coup  cCitat.  After  Bagehot's  death  they 
were  republished  in  an  appendix  to  the  Studies 
on  Literature.  These  letters  gave  the  first 
evidence  of  the  rise  of  a  new  critic  of  higli 
genius,  a  critic  who  will  take  his  place  far 
above  Lord  Jeffrey,  and  Lord  Brougham,  and 
Sydney  Smith — though  in  mere  humour  Bage- 
hot, humorous  as  he  was,  would  hardly  com- 
pare with  the  last  -  mentioned — in  relation 
both  to  political  literature  and  belles-lettres. 
Indeed,  in  belles  -  lettres  Bagehot  will  take 
rank  with  Matthew  Arnold  as  one  of  the  two 
most  lucid  as  well  as  most  discerning  critics  of 
that  time.  The  essays  which  Bagehot  con- 
tributed, first  to  the  Prospective  Review  and 
then  to  the  National  Review,  between  1853  and 
1864,  were  not  merely  among  the  most  brilliant, 
but  among  the  most  remarkable  for  wide  in- 
tellectual survey  and  a  detached  literary  judg- 
ment of  any  published  in  England  during  those 
years.  In  style  they  were  remarkable  equally 
for  their  gaiety,  for  the  delicacy  of  their  appre- 
hensiveness,  for  the  savoir  faire  of  a  man  of  the 
world,  and  for  the  impartiality  of  their  personal 
estimates.  It  is  difficult  to  say  whether  he. 
wrote  best  on  a  theologian  like  Bishop  Butler, 
on  a  sensitive  poet  like  Hartley  Coleridge,  on  a 


novelist  like  Sir  Walter  Scott,  or  on  a  great 
historian  and  essayist  like  Macaulay.  Bagehot's 
style  was  buoyant,  bright,  and  often  eloquent, 
but  there  was  always  a  certain  dash  of  mockery 
in  his  eloquence,  and  a  large  infusion  of  serious- 
ness in  his  mockery.  In  1858  he  married  the 
eldest  daughter  of  James  Wilson,  editor  of  the 
Economist,  and  two  years  afterwards  succeeded 
his  father-in-law  in  the  editorship  of  that  paper, 
retaining  the  post  till  his  death  in  1877.  He 
was  universally  regarded  as  one  of  the  best 
financiers  of  his  day,  and  was  consulted  by 
successive  chancellors  of  the  exchequer  on  all 
critical  occasions. 

The  special  service  which  Bagehot  sought  to 
render  to  economics  may  be  roughly  described 
as  the  reconciliation  of  it  with  history.  He 
was  not  himself  able  to  perfect  this  work  ;  but 
he  has  stated  the  needs  of  the  case  clearly,  and 
has  pointed  the  way  to  a  solution  of  its  diffi- 
culties. ' '  The  great  want  of  our  present 
political  economy  "  (he  says  in  the  preface  to 
Universal  Money,  1869)  "is  that  some  one 
should  do  for  it  what  Sir  Henry  Maine  has 
done  so  well  for  ancient  law.  We  want  some 
one  to  connect  our  theoretical  account  of  the 
origin  of  things  with  the  real  origin."  Simple 
definitions  come  first  in  the  text-books ;  but, 
as  in  physics,  the  actual  commencements 
in  history  and  experience  have  been  much 
harder  and  odder.  Banks,  for  example,  are 
now  part  of  a  refined  mechanism  of  credit,  but 
they  were  first  invented  to  supply  a  verified 
and  trustworthy  money  for  traders  {Universal 
Money,  p.  xv.  seq.) 

No  economical  writer  shows  clearer  conscious- 
ness of  the  enormous  difference  between  the 
present  conditions  of  European  commerce  and 
the  conditions  of  life  and  industry  among  our 
rude  forefathers  ;  or,  at  the  present  day,  among 
barbarous  nations.  He  had  always  the  twofold 
object  before  him — to  perfect  the  abstract 
theory  of  political  economy  as  applicable  to  the 
former,  and  to  bring  home  to  himself  and  his 
readers  the  existence  of  the  latter.  An  abstract 
Deductive  Method  seemed  to  him  indispens- 
able from  the  very  complexity  of  the  subject  ; 
but  it  was  to  be  applied  only  to  the  study  of  the 
peculiarly  modern  "large  commerce,"  which  he 
loved  to  contrast  with  the  simple  industry  of 
primitive  men.  Epigram,  however,  even  more 
than  antithesis,  was  his  strength,  if  sometimes 
his  snare.  He  was  never  at  a  loss  for  words, 
and  he  had  a  "gay  wisdom,"  absent  from 
economical  writing  since  Perronet  Thompson. 
He  can  hardly  be  taken  quite  seriously  when 
he  complains  that  Montesquieu,  Hume,  and 
Adam  Smith  would  have  written  more  pro- 
foundly if  the  public  for  whom  they  wrote  had 
not  been  so  intolerant  of  dulness  {Econ.  Stud. 
p.  131). 

Political  economy,  as  he  understands  it,  is 
not  "a  questionable  thing  of  unlimited  extent, 


80 


BAGEHOT 


but  a  most  certain  and  useful  thing  of  limited 
extent"  {Econ.  Stud.  p.  21).  It  is  "a  conveni- 
ent series  of  deductions  from  assumed  axioms 
which  are  never  quite  true,  which  in  many 
times  and  in  many  countries  would  be  utterly 
untrue,  but  which  are  sufficiently  near  to  ijie 
principal  conditions  of  the  modern  world  to 
make  it  useful  to  consider  them  by  themselves  " 
{Econ.  Stud.  p.  157).  Bagehot  considers  himself 
the  last  man  ofthe  ante-Mill  period  (ibid.  p.  215) ; 
he  thinks  that  J.  S.  Mill  "widened  the  old 
political  economy  either  too  much  or  not 
enough  "  (pp.  19,  20).  If  he  meant  to  carry  on 
what  Adam  Smith  and  Ricardo  had  begun,  and 
to  give  a  theory  of  modern  large  commerce  only, 
he  has  given  us  too  much  ;  if  he  meant  to  give 
a  theory  applying  to  all  societies,  "advanced"  or 
not,  he  has  given  us  too  little.  Bagehot  had 
almost  unbounded  admiration  for  Ricardo,  with 
whom,  as  at  once  business  man  and  abstract 
thinker,  he  had  many  points  of  affinity.  "  The 
true  founder  of  abstract  political  economy  is 
Ricardo  "  (p.  151).  Adam  Smith  discovered  the 
country  but  Ricardo  made  the  first  map  (p.  18). 
Ricardo,  it  is  true,  dealt  in  abstractions  without 
knowing  them  to  be  abstractions,  and  fancied 
them  the  real  things  (p.  157).  But  it  is  by  the 
method  of  Ricardo  that  Bagehot  would  build 
up  the  science.  Two  rival  methods  he  mentions 
only  to  reject.  The  first  is  the  "All  Case 
Method,"  recommended  by  some  theorists  of 
the  historical  school,  who  tell  us  that  before 
we  begin  to  reason  we  must  have  "a  complete 
experience."  We  might  as  well  (says  Bagehot) 
demand  a  complete  record  of  human  conversa- 
tion as  demand  a  complete  record  of  commercial 
facts  (Econ.  Stiid.  pp.  11-14).  The  second 
rival  method  is  the  "Single  Case  Method,"  the 
advocates  of  which  recommend  that  each  group 
of  facts,  e.g.  a  commercial  panic,  be  analysed 
separately  on  the  merits,  without  any  prelim- 
inary theory.  But  you  might  as  well  (says 
Bagehot)  attempt  to  explain  the  bursting  of  a 
boiler  without  knowing  the  theory  of  steam. 
On  the  other  hand  the  mathematical  method 
(ibid.  p.  15)  of  Professor  Jevons  and  Professor 
Walras  is  too  abstract  for  him  (pp.  15,  16);  he 
hints  that  it  explains  obscurum  per  obscuriits- 
(p.  77).  He  thinks  (with  the  later  rather  than  the 
earlier  economists)  that  definitions  must  (very 
much,  it  may  be  added,  as  in  Law)  adapt  them- 
selves to  the  subject  matter  (p.  49). 

His  own  definitions  of  wealth — (p.  81)  and 
cajntal  (pp.  49,  50)  for  example  are  on  the  whole 
on  the  old  lines.  Incidentally,  in  dealing  witli 
"  Adam  Smith  and  our  modern  political  eco- 
nomy, "  he  gives  us  his  idea  of  what  a  treatise  on 
political  economy  should  contain.  It  should  (he 
says)  answer  four  questions — (1)  What  is  the 
cause  which  makes  one  thing  exchange  for  more 
or  less  of  other  things  ?  (2)  What  are  the  laws 
under  which  that  cause  acts  in  producing  these 
things  (the  laws,   namely,   of  population  and 


capital)  ?  (3)  If  these  things  are  produced  b^ 
the  co-operation  of  many  people,  what  settles 
the  share  of  each  of  those  people  in  those  things 
or  in  their  proceeds  (the  laws,  namely,  of 
distribution)  ?  (4)  If  this  co-operation  costs 
something,  who  is  to  pay  that  cost,  and  how  is 
the  payment  to  be  levied  (the  theory  of  taxa- 
tion) ?    (Econ.  Stud.  pp.  99,  100.) 

In  considering  his  own  answers  to  these 
questions  we  have  to  make  some  allowance  for 
the  incomplete  state  of  much  of  his  published 
writings.  He  had  begun  in  the  Fortnightly 
Review,  1876,  a  series  of  essays  ("The  Postulates 
of  Political  Economy")  which  were  to  have 
developed  into  three  distinct  volumes  on  politi- 
cal economy  (see  prefatory  note  to  Economic 
Studies).  The  first  was  apparently  to  include 
the  abstract  theory  and  the  complementary 
comparison  with  primitive  life,  the  second  a 
criticism  of  the  works  of  previous  economists, 
and  the  third  a  biographical  sketch  of  them. 
Though  he  never  carried  out  the  whole  plan,  he 
has  left  us  specimens  of  his  work  in  all  its 
three  sections.  The  biographies  include  '  *  Adam 
Smith  as  a  Person,"  which  is  in  his  best  manner. 
The  criticism  of  previous  economical  work  is 
acute  ;  but,  in  the  case  where  it  is  most  elabor- 
ate (Demand  and  Supply,  and  Cost  of  Produo- 
,tion),  it  results  (as  he  himself  says  of  Adam 
Smith's  reasonings)  not  in  the  "establishment 
of  coherent  truths,"  but  in  "a  rough  outline  of 
sensible  thoughts"  (Econ.  Stud.  p.  119).  His 
criticism  (p.  138  seq. )  of  the  theory  of  population 
is  hardly  consistent  with  his  own  general 
account  of  economical  laws  (e.g.  p.  76).  Like  his 
father-in-law  he  was  perhaps  stronger  in 
presenting  the  axiomata  media  than  the  first 
'principles  (Literary  Stud. -p]).  374,  375).  He  was 
one  of  the  first  economists  in  England  to 
recognise  the  importance  of  the  idea  of  develop- 
ment (which  to  him  meant  Darwinism)  for 
social  and  economic  theories  ;  yet  in  most  cases 
he  is  more  careful  to  dwell  on  the  contrast 
between  the  old  and  the  new  than  to  show  how 
the  one  passed  into  the  other  or  how  the  pheno- 
mena of  the  one  shed  light  on  the  phenomena 
of  the  other.  In  one  case.  Barter,  where  he 
has  done  the  last  very  skilfully,  his  own  re- 
sults might  have  suggested  to  him  the  possi- 
bility of  an  abstract  economical  theory,  even  of 
exchange,  by  no  means  confined,  as  he  has 
confined  it,  to  the  facts  ofthe  "great  commerce  " 
(Econ.  Stud.  p.  102).  His  conception  of  the 
process  of  mediating  between  the  two  extreme 
stages  of  culture,  or  in  other  words,  passing 
from  the  " pre-economic "  to  the  "economic 
age,"  is  given  in  outline  in  his  Physics  and 
Politics,  in  which  book  (as  even  in  the  "  Letters 
on  the  Coup  d'Etat,"  and  the  pamphlet  on 
"  Parliamentary  Reform  ")  he  shows  the  bent  of 
his  mind  in  his  preference  for  economical  illus- 
trations, and  his  special  note  of  the  economical 
aspects  of  the  subject  in  hand.     Towards  the 


BAGEHOT 


81 


working  classes  and  Trade  Unions  he  was 
never  hostile  ;  but  he  was  not  demonstratively 
sympathetic.  His  sympathies  lay  with  the 
capitalist-employers  ; — the  people  who  "spend 
their  minds  on  little  else  than  on  thinking 
whether  other  people  will  pay  their  debts " 
{Econ.  Stud.  p.  45)  have  seldom  found  a  more 
brilliant  spokesman.  The  book  by  which 
he  will  always  be  best  known  to  economical 
students  is  undoubtedly  Lombard  Street,  a 
History  of  the  Money  Market.  No  more  vivid 
picture  of  "what  they  do  in  the  City," — no 
more  j^erfect  description  of  a  "Single  Case," 
was  ever  given  ;  tlie  author  is  "in  the  secret," 
and  can  vouch  for  the  facts  at  first  hand.  The 
wonderful  clearness  of  Bagehot's  power  of  state- 
ment, his  exact  knowledge  of  the  subject 
treated  on,  together  with  his  ffl-ra  grasp  of 
economic  theory  have  caused  this  volume  to 
exert  an  influence  which  few  books  on  a  subject 
naturally  so  dry  have  possessed.  The  first 
sentence  gives  the  key-note,  "  I  venture  to  call 
this  Essay  '  Lombard  Street, '  and  not  the 
*  Money  Market, '  or  any  sucli  phrase,  because 
I  wish  to  deal,  and  to  show  that  I  mean  to 
deal,  with  concrete  realities."  The  promise  of 
this  opening  is  abundantly  ful Idled.  The 
character  of  thought  in  the  "  City,"  the  cease- 
less movement  of  men  and  business,  the 
reasons  which  led  to  our  money  market  being 
arranged  and  worked  as  it  is,  the  relative  posi- 
tion of  the  Bank  of  England  to  the  other 
banks,  the  results  of  Government  interference 
with  banking,  are  all  treated  with  the  vividness 
of  one  who  felt  every  vibration  of  these  varied 
currents  in  every  fibre  of  his  own  life.  The 
reform  Bagehot  recommended  in  the  govern- 
ment of  the  Bank  of  England  has  not  yet  been 
carried  out,  but  a  proposal  so  original  as  the 
appointment  of  a  permanent  head  to  an  institu- 
tion which,  since  its  formation,  some  two 
centuries  since,  has  always  been  managed  on 
the  principle  that  tlie  head  should  never  be 
permanent,  could  hardly  be  expected  to  win 
acceptance  on  its  first  suggestion.  Events  since 
Bagehot  wrote  have  shown  more  distinctly 
even  than  in  his  time  the  prudence  contained 
in  a  proposal  apparently  so  revolutionary. 
"  liOmbard  Street,"  perhaps  more  than  any 
otner  of  Bagehot's  works,  shows  how  gi'eatly 
Economic  Science  gains  when  those  who  are 
"conversant  with  its  abstractions"  are  in  "true 
contact  with  "  the  facts  with  which  it  deals. 
On  the  advantage  the  knowledge  hence  arising 
gives  the  economist,  Bagehot  not  only  wrote 
but  constantly  spoke  during  his  life,  with  a 
vigour  and  an  insistence  which  those  who  knew 
him  will  continually  remember,  and  which 
those  who  read  him  will  be  able  in  some 
measure  to  appreciate.  The  papers  on  the 
"Depreciation  of  Silver"  and  on  "A  Universal 
Money  "  were  also  on  a  congenial  subject.  In 
the  latter  he  advocates!  the  farthing  plan,  or 

VOL.  T. 


the  reckoning  of  1000  farthings  instead  of  960 
to  the  English  sovereign,  thus  making  the 
sovereign  equal  to  five  dollars  and  the  half- 
penny equal  to  the  cent.  This,  he  thought, 
would  at  least  provide  the  Anglo-Saxon  races 
with  a  comnion  money  of  account. 

In  the  volume  on  the  Depreciation  of  Silver, 
Bagehot  discusses  the  position  of  England, 
France,  India,  and  the  United  States,  in  view 
of  the  falling  gold  price  of  silver  in  1876. 

The  cause  of  the  fall,  in  his  opinion,  was  not 
an  actually  increased  supply  of  silver  but  the 
apprehension  of  an  increased  supply,  together 
with  the  inconstant  proceedings  of  the  German 
and  French  governments  (pp.  51,  52),  He  lays 
stress  on  the  fact  that  Indian  prices  have  not 
risen  in  response  to  the  fall  (p.  54,  etc.)  Yet 
he  refuses  all  remedies  but  laissez-faire  ;  we 
must  simply  give  silver  a  free  course,  and  in 
the  end  the  prices  will  rise  in  India,  and  the 
previous  condition  of  trade  and  finance  there 
will  be  restored  (Depreciation,  pp.  40,  55,  etc.) 
Changes  in  currency  should  never  be  introduced 
except  when  trade  is  in  its  normal  condition 
(p.  113).  In  regard  to  Bi-Metalltsm  he  deals 
far  too  hastily  with  tlie  arguments  which  tell 
in  its  favour  as  an  abstract  theory  ;  he  scouts 
it  both  as  an  abstract  theory  and  as  a  practical 
measure  {Depreciation,  pp.  11,  12,  13,  37,  110 
scq.  to  118).  So  in  the  papers  on  "Universal 
Coinage"  he  says  bluntly:  "The  French  coinage 
is  based  on  a  double  standard,  which  is  absurd  " 
(p.  23),  "  The  French  is  a  symmetrical  embodi- 
ment of  imperfect  principles  ;  the  English,  a 
confused  embodiment  of  the  best  principles " 
(p.  27).  From  his  attitude  to  these  and  not  a 
few  other  questions,  Bagehot  might  be  faii-ly 
set  down  as  one  of  the  last  economists  of  the 
ante-Jevons  period. 

Perhaps  the  most  complete  of  Bagehot's 
works  was  the  study  of  The  English  Constitution, 
which  has  been  used  as  a  text-book  both  at 
Oxford  and  in  several  of  the  universities  of  the 
United  States,  and  translated  into  Gennan, 
French,  and  Italian.  He  preferred  very  much 
the  English  constitution,  with  that  complete 
fusion  of  the  legislative  and  administrative 
powers  which  was  effected  by  the  relation  of 
the  cabinet  to  the  House  of  Commons,  to  the 
American  constitution  with  its  careful  separa- 
tion of  legislative  and  administrative  powers, 
an  arrangement  which,  in  his  opinion,  resulted 
in  making  the  people  indifferent  as  to  their 
choice  of  representatives  who  vere  so  carefully 
restrained  from  exerting  any  dominant  influence 
over  the  actual  executive.  Bagehot  attached 
great  importance  to  what  he  called  the  orna- 
mental parts  of  the  constitution,  namely  the 
throne  and  the  House  of  Lords.  Not  that  he 
regarded  them  as  essential  elements  in  the 
action  of  the  state,  but  that  he  thought  that 
without  them  the  people  of  the  United  Kingdom 
would  be  far  more  restless,  far  more  unwilling 


82 


BAILEE— BAILEY 


to  submit  to  political  guidance,  far  more  dis- 
posed to  interfere  mischievously  in  arrange- 
ments which  they  do  not  really  understand. 
The  "ornamental  parts"  of  the  constitution 
contributed,  in  his  opinion,  greatly  to  the 
safety  of  the  whole,  as  they  disposed  the 
English  people  to  defer  to  the  opinions  of  the 
prosperous  and  wealthy  classes,  and  to  be  on 
their  guard  against  violent  and  needy  adven- 
turers. The  whole  discussion  of  the  theory  of 
the  cabinet,  as  a  constituent  element  in  political 
philosophy,  is  of  the  highest  value. 

["Letters  on  the  Coup  d'Etat  of  1851, "written to 
the  Inquirer  (Unitarian  organ),  1852,  and  reprinted 
in  vol.  i.  of  Literary  Studies. — Parliamentary 
Reform  (review  of  Newmarch  on  Electoral  Sta- 
tistics) reprinted,  with  additions,  from  National 
Review  (Chapman  and  Hall,  1858). — History  of 
the  Unref&rmed  Parliament  (also  from  National 
Review). — Estimates  of  some  Englishmen  and 
Scotchmen,  1858,  written  for  the  Prospective 
Review  and  National  Review  and  in  great  part 
reprinted  in  Literary  Studies  and  Biographical 
Studies. — Many  Articles  in  the  Economist,  1860 
to  1877. — Physics  and  Politics,  or  Thoughts  on 
the  Application  of  tlie  Principles  of  Natural  Selec- 
tion and  Inheritance  to  Political  Society,  1872 
(Internat.  Sclent.  Series).  (In  the  German  transla- 
tion (1874)  this  figures  as  Ur sprung  der  Nationen). 
— Lombard  Street,  a  Description  of  the  Money 
Market,  1773.  New  Ed.  (Smith,  Elder  &  Co.), 
1910. — Various  Articles  in  the  Fortnightly  Review, 
e.g.  "Postulates  of  Political  Economy,"  Feb. 
and  May  1876.  See  Economic  Studies.  —  The 
English  Constitution,  1867  (enlarged,  2d  ed,, 
1872 ).  — IntemationaZ  Coinage.  A  Practical  Plan 
for  Assimilating  the  English  and  American  Money 
as  a  Step  towards  a  Universal  Money  (reprinted 
from  the  Econmnist),  1869,  2d  ed.  1889.— On  the 
Depreciation  of  Silver  (from  the  Economist,  1876), 
1877. — Literary  Studies  (with  a  biography  of  the 
author),  ed.  by  R.  H.  Hutton,  2  vols.,  1879.— 
Economic  Studies,  1880. — Biographical  Studies, 
1881.  New  Editions  (Longmans)  1905-7.  See 
also  Political  Economy  in  England,  by  L.  L. 
Price,  London,  1891,  ch.  vi.,  on  Walter  Bagehot's 
position  as  an  economist.] 

BAILEE.  A  person  to  whom  the  goods  of 
another  are  entrusted,  either  for  custody  or  for 
other  purposes.  The  most  conspicuous  class  of 
bailees  consists  of  the  so-called  common  carriers 
of  goods,  viz.  railway  companies,  steamship 
owners,  and  others  whose  business  it  is  to  carry 
goods  from  one  place  to  another.  They  are 
subjected  to  a  particularly  stringent  liability  for 
the  safety  of  the  goods,  but  as  a  general  rule 
bailees  are  liable  for  those  losses  only  which 
occur  in  consequence  of  their  negligence.  A 
bailee  who  takes  goods  into  his  custody  with- 
out being  rewarded  for  doing  so  is  called  a 
gratuitous  bailee. 

BAILEY,  Samuel,  was  born  in  1791,  the  son 
of  a  Sheffield  merchant,  was  elected  a  town 
trustee  in  1828,  and  became  known  as  the 
"  Hallamshire  Bentham."  Failing  to  be  elected 
as  M.  P. ,  he  applied  himself  to  local  affairs,  and 


left,  when  he  died,  18th  January  1870,  over 
£80,000  to  Sheffield.  Besides  some  political 
pieces,  he  wrote — 

A  Critical  Dissertation  on  tJie  Natwre,  Measures, 
and  Causes  of  Value,  London,  1825,  8vo  (a  re- 
markable little  volume,  pointing  out  the  incon- 
sistencies of  RiCARDO,  J.  S.  Mill,  and  De  Quincet 
in  their  theories  of  value). — Letter  to  a  Political 
Economist,  London,  1826,  8vo  (reply  to  a  notice 
of  the  previous  work  in  the  Westminster  Review). — 
Money  and  its  Vicissitudes  in  Value  as  they  affect 
National  Industry,  London,  1837,  8vo. — Defence 
of  Joint- Stock  Banks  and  Country  Issues,  London, 
1840,  Svo.  H.  B.  T. 

BAILEY,  Samuel,  on  Value.  Bailey's 
"dissertation"  on  the  theory  of  value  requires 
separate  notice.  Known  in  metaphysics  by  his 
attack  on  Berkeley's  theory  of  vision,  Bailey 
plays  a  similar  part  in  economics,  objecting 
to  subtleties  sanctioned  by  authority.  Defin- 
ing value  as  nothing  positive  or  intrinsic,  but 
merely  the  relation  in  which  two  objects  stand  to 
each  other  as  exchangeable  commodities,  Bailey 
controverts  through  several  chapters  Ricardo's 
theory  of  real  value  and  its  corollaries.  Bailey 
refuses  to  admit  the  antithesis  of  real  and 
nominal  value  {Critical  Dissertation,  ch.  ii.), 
the  possibilfty  of  comparing  the  value  of  com- 
modities at  different  periods  (ch.  v.),  the 
Ricardian  formula  that  the  value  of  A  in 
relation  to  B  "depends  on  the  comparative 
quantities  of  labour  necessary  for  the  pro- 
duction of  it  and  B,  and  not  on  the  greater  or 
less  compensation  which  is  paid  for  that  labour  " 
{ih.),  the  distinction  between  value  and  riches 
(ch.  ix.),  and  any  measure  of  value  of  the  sort 
desiderated  by  Malthus  (ch.  vii.  et  passim). 
Malthus,  severely  criticising  the  Critical  Dis- 
sertation (Definitions,  ch.  viii.),  contends  that 
the  writer,  by  his  too  narrow  definition  of 
value  as  relating  to  some  definite  thing,  has 
missed  the  essential  idea  of  value  in  relation 
to  things  in  general.  Upon  Bailey's  principles, 
"we  must  on  no  account  say  that  butter  has 
been  rising  during  the  last  month."  The  con- 
troversy is  now  of  some  practical  importance, 
as  it  has  a  bearing  upon  recent  proposals  for 
determining  the  variation  in  the  value  of 
money  (in  relation  to  things  in  general)  by  a 
Tabulae  Standard  or  Index  Number  (g.v.) 
in  particular  that  standard  which  is  based  on 
wages.  Of  more  purely  historical  interest  are 
other  observations,  new  perhaps  when  made 
(1825).  Criticising  Ricardo,  Bailey  disen- 
tangles different  senses  of  profits  (ch.  iv.) 
He  classifies  valuables  much  as  J.  S.  Mill 
(Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.)  ;  and  remarking  on 
the  class  of  commodity  which  "  admits  of  hemg 
increased  by  industry  and  competition,  but 
only  at  a  greater  cost,"  observes — "The  extra- 
ordinaiy  profit  out  of  which  rent  arises  is 
analogous  to  the  extraordinary  remuneration, 
which  an  artisan  of  more  than  common  dex- 
terity obtains  beyond  the  wages  given  to  work 


BAILY— BAINES 


83 


men  of  ordinary  skill"  (cli.  xi.  p.  197).  He 
complains  that  the  Rieardians  "attempt  to 
give  the  science  an  air  of  simplicity  which  it 
does  not  possess."  "Why  persist  in  calling 
quantity  of  labour  the  sole  determining  principle 
of  value"  {ib.  p.  217)  ;  instead  of  "the  more 
accurate  proposition  that  it  is  the  principle 
cause"  (p.  232).  "What  should  we  think  of 
an  assertion  that  coats  are  to  each  other  in  value 
as  the  quantities  of  cloth  contained  in  them  " 
— with  the  addition  "  that  due  allowances  must 
be  made  for  the  different  qualities  of  the 
cloth?"  (p.  211).  De  Quincey  (q.v.)  in  his 
Logic  of  Political  EcoTwmy  has  replied  to  Bailey 
(see  Rent).  f.  y.  e. 

BAILY,  Francis,  was  born  at  Newbury  in 
[Berkshire,  28th  April  1774,  and  went  on  the 
jondon  Stock  Exchange,  1799.  He  helped  to 
[found  the  Royal  Astronomical  Society,  and 
stu'ed  from  business  in  1825  in  order  to  devote 
[himself  entirely  to  astronomy.  His  revision  of 
[star  catalogues  ranks  him  among  the  greatest  of 
modern  benefactors  to  that  science.  He  died 
80th  August  1844.  Among  other  books  he 
wrote — 

The  Doctrine  of  Interest  and  Annuities,  London, 
1808,  4to. — The  Doctrine  of  Life  Annuities  and 
Assurances,  London,  1810,  large  8vo ;  again  in 
1813,  2  vols.  8vo,  with  Appendix,  new  edition, 
[enlarged,  by  H.  Filipowski,  Liverpool,  1864, 
8vo  (the  best  work  on  the  subject  when  first 
[published,  and  still  useful  ;  French  translation  by 
[A.  de  Courcy,  1836,  8vo). — Account  of  the  several 
\I/ife  Assurance  Companies  in  London,  2d  ed., 
[London,  1811,  8vo  (reprinted  from  the  foregoing). — 
[TaJbUsfor  the  Purchasing  and  Reneioing  of  Leases, 
[London,  1802,  3d  ed.,  1812,  8vo.  H.  r.  t. 

BAINES,   Edward,   1774-1848,  descended 

[jfrom  a  family  of  Yorkshire  yeomen,  and  a't  first 

[apprenticed  to  the  printing  trade,  became  (1801) 

litor  and   proprietor   of  the  Leeds  Mcrcnry, 

rhich   became  under  him   the  leading  Whig 

iper  in  Yorkshire.     Cobbett  {Manchester  Lee- 

res,  1832),  calls  him  "the  gi-eat  oracle  of  the 

forth."    He  was  a  zealous  social  reformer.     In 

[1834  he  succeeded  Macaulay  as  one  of  the  two 

[members  for  Leeds,  retiring  in  1841.     He  wrote 

rief  histories  and  gazetteers  of  the  counties  of 

[York  and  Lancaster  ;   his  chief  work  being  a 

^standard  History  of  the  County  Palatini,  and 

>^Duchy  of  Lancaster  (Fisher,  Son,  and  Jackson, 

London,  1836).     He  was  also  the  author  (aided 

very  largely  by  his  son  Edward)  of  a  History  of 

the  Wars  of  the  French  Revolution  (2  vols.  4 to, 

1817),  which  was  expanded  after  the  close  of 

the  reign,  by  the  addition  of  two  volumes,  into 

a  History  of  the  Reign  of  George  III.  (London, 

1823).     He  visited  Owen  at  New  Lanark  in 

1819  with  Oastler  and  Cawood,  and  helped  to 

institute  at  Leeds  a  home  colony  on  Owen's 

model.     See  Life  of  Edward  Bain^s,  by  his  son 

Edward  Baines,  London,  1851.  J.  b. 

BAINES,  Sir  Edward,  (1800-1890),  second 
son   of  the   preceding,  is   best  known  by  his 


History  of  the  Cotton  Manufacture  (1835), 
which  was  originally  written  for  his  father's 
history  of  Lancashire,  but  expanded  and  separ- 
ately published  on  the  suggestion  of  M  'Culloch 
{Edinburgh  Review,  No.  117).  He  wrote  in 
1826  a  letter  To  the  U')iemployed  Workmen  oj 
Yoi'kshire  and  Lancashire  on  the  Present  Distress, 
and  on  Machinery,  published  fiist  in  the  Leeds 
Mercury,  and  afterwards,  by  order  of  the  magis- 
trates, very  largely  circulated  as  a  ti'act  through 
the  manufacturing  districts,  and  which  was  held 
to  have  had  the  happy  effect  of  settling  the 
minds  of  many  whose  opinions  had  been  waver- 
ing. In  the  year  1843  he  published  Tline 
Letters  to  the  Right  Hon.  Lord  John  Russell, 
entitled  "Reasons  in  favour  of  Free  Trade  in 
Corn,  and  against  a  Fixed  Duty."  In  the  same 
year  he  vrrote  Two  Letters  to  Si)-  Robert  Peel  on 
Die  Social,  Edu^cational,  and  Religious  State  of  the 
Manufactu/riiig  Districts  (1843) — a  criticism  of 
the  school  clauses  in  Sir  James  Graham's  Fac- 
tory Educational  Bill,  from  the  point  of  view  of 
a  Nonconformist,  and  as  being  too  unreservedly 
in  the  interest  of  the  employers.  He  succeeds 
in  showing  that  the  charges  of  depravity  and 
ignorance  made  against  the  manufacturing  dis- 
tricts of  the  north  were  largely  exaggerated,  and 
could  in  any  case  have  been  brought  with  equal 
justice  against  the  agi'icultural  districts  of 
south  England.  In  1846  he  wrote  a  series  of 
twelve  Letters  to  the  Right  Hon.  Lord  John 
Russell  on  the  subject  of  the  resolutions  which 
resulted  in  the  system  of  grants  under  the  com- 
mittee of  the  privy  council  on  education,  bearing 
on  the  analogy  between  "government  protec- 
tion to  industry  and  government  protection  to 
mind," — sifting  the  statistical  evidences  on  which 
the  proposals  were  based,  both  as  to  the  actual 
position  at  home  and  the  comparison  vnih.  the 
conditions  of  the  people.  The  results  of  various 
state  systems  of  education  on  the  Continent  of 
Europe  and  in  the  United  States.  These  and 
other  letters  were  collected  into  a  volume  and 
published  by  a  company  in  London  for  ' '  cheap 
circulation"  (1847).  Again  in  1871,  as  chair- 
man of  the  educational  department  of  the 
Social  Science  Association,  at  its  annual  meeting 
in  Leeds,  he  delivered  an  address,  subsequently 
published  in  London,  On  the  Position  and  Pros- 
pects of  National  Education.  In  1823  the  first 
mechanics'  institution  in  England  was  estab- 
lished ;  and  in  1837,  on  the  formation  of  the 
Yorkshire  Union  of  Mechanics'  Institutes, 
Baines  was  elected  president,  and  for  more  than 
fifty  years,  in  his  annual  addresses  from  the 
chair,  he  reviewed  the  position  of  scientific  and 
technical  education  in  this  country  (see  Annual 
Reports  of  the  Yorkshire  Union  of  Mechanics* 
Institutes).  In  1858,  as  president  of  the 
'section  of  economic  science  and  statistics  at  the 
annual  meeting  of  the  British  Association  for 
the  Advancement  of  Science,  at  Leeds,  his 
address  wa.s  "  On  the  Woollen  Manufacture  of 


84 


BAINES— BALANCE  OF  TRADE 


England,  with  Special  Reference  to  the  Leeds 
Clothing  District,"  and  it  was  published  both 
in  the  report  of  the  British  Association  and  in 
the  Journal  of  the  Statistical  Society  of  Londo-n, 
March  1859.  He  represented  Leeds  as  a 
Liberal  in  the  House  of  Commons  from  1859-74, 
he  took  a  leading  part  in  modifying  the  pro- 
posals for  taking  the  Census  for  1861,  and 
notably  against  a  census  of  religious  opinions. 
He  brought  in  a  Borough  Franchise  Bill  in 
1861,  and  on  moving  the  second  reading  (lOtb. 
April),  he  traced  the  progress  of  the  country, 
and  notably  of  the  working  classes  since  1831, 
in  education,  in  providence,  in  temperance,  and 
in  morality ;  illustrating  these,  too,  by  the 
growth  and  the  improved  character  of  our 
periodical  literatm-e.  The  speech  was  said  by 
Mr.  Gladstone  to  have  added  a  new  chapter  to 
the  social  history  of  the  country.  It  was  pub- 
lished in  London  under  the  title  of  Progress  and 
Reform,  1831  and  1861. 

BAINES,  Thomas,  younger  brother  of  Sir 
E.  Baines  (1806-1881),  wrote  on  the  History  of 
the  Town  and  Commerce  of  Liverpool  (1852),  On 
the  Agricultural  Hesources  of  Great  Britain, 
Ireland,  and  the  Colonies,  1847,  and  on  the 
Present  State  of  the  Affairs  of  the  River  Plate, 
1845.  J.  B. 

BAIRN'S  PART  OF  GEAR.     See  Legitim. 

BAKOUNIN,  Michael  (1814-1876),  the 
founder  of  anarchism,  began  life  as  a  Russian 
artillery  officer.  Stationed  in  Poland,  he  con- 
ceived a  disgust  at  the  repressive  measures  he 
saw  in  force  there,  resigned  his  commission, 
and  devoted  himself  to  the  study  of  philosophy 
at  Moscow.  He  went  to  Germany  about  1846, 
and  became  a  Hegelian.  In  1847  he  was  at 
Paris,  and  made  the  acquaintance  of  Proudhon. 
Expelled  from  France,  he  returned  to  Germany 
and  took  a  prominent  part  in  the  Dresden  in- 
surrection of  1849,  for  which  he  was  condemned 
to  imprisonment  for  life.  He  was  handed  over 
to  the  Russian  authorities,  aud  confined  in  the 
prison  of  SS.  Peter  and  Paul  at  St.  Petersburg 
for  eight  years.  Then,  in  1857,  he  was  exiled 
to  Siberia,  whence  he  soon  managed  to  escape 
to  Japan.  After  passing  through  America  and 
England  he  established  himself  in  Switzerland. 
His  subsequent  history  will  be  found  under 
Anarchism  (q.v.)  He  died  at  Berne  2d  July 
1876. 

[6.  de  Laveleye,  Le  Socialisme  Contemporain, 
3me  M.  1885,  pp.  227-239.]  E.  C. 

BALANCE  OF  TRADE.  "It  often  happens, " 
says  Mill,  referring  to  the  supposed  mercan- 
tilist views  on  money,  "  that  the  universal  belief 
of  one  age  of  mankind"  "becomes  to  a  subse- 
quent age  so  palpable  an  absurdity  that  the  only 
difiiculty  then  is  to  imagine  how  such  a  thing 
can  ever  have  aj^peaied  credible."  It  is  gener- 
ally found,  however,  on  investigation  that  the 
"palpable  absurdity  "  formed  but  a  minor  part 
of  a  system  the  rest  of  which  is  forgotten,  but 


which,  as  a  whole,  was,  in  the  historical  condi- 
tions  of  the  case,  not  unreasonable.  This  ia 
true  especially  of  the  doctrine  or  policy  of  a 
"favourable  balance  of  trade."  From  the 
modern  ])oint  of  view  we  take  it  as  axiomatic 
that,  apart  from  other  international  obligations 
such  as  tributes  and  the  like,  exports  must  over 
a  term  of  years  pay  for  imports.  No  nation, 
it  is  held,  can  go  on  receiving  from  other  nations 
quantities  of  real  wealth,  actual  consumable 
commodities,  without  giving  something  in  re- 
turn. But  the  store  of  precious  metals,  and 
even  the  power  of  incmTing  debt,  or  of  paying 
by  previous  commutations,  would  soon  be  ex- 
hausted with  a  constantly  adverse  balance,  and 
accordingly  produce  must  pay  for  produce,  tak- 
ing the  term  in  its  most  general  sense  (cp.  H. 
Sidgwick,  bk.  i.),  so  as  to  include  services 
freights,  etc.  It  is  further  argued  that  if  a 
nation  were  to  attempt  to  import  more  than  its 
normal  exports  could  pay  for  there  must  soon 
be  a  drain  on  its  money,  and  then  directly  or  in- 
directly, by  the  Quantity  Theory  (see  Money), 
prices  would  fall.  This  fall  would  stimulate 
exports  and  place  a  check  on  imports  until  the 
balance  was  again  restored.  Under  a  system  of 
approximately  perfect  competition  it  follows 
from  the  very  nature  of  money  that  all  Ex- 
change is  ultimately  Barter,  and  that  the  flow 
of  the  precious  metals  from  country  to  country  is 
an  effect  and  not  a  cause  of  the  direction  and  ex 
tent  of  its  foreign  trade.  A  nation  will  always 
obtain  under  such  a  system  enough  of  the 
precious  metals  to  keep  its  prices  at  such  a  level 
that  its  exports  will  just  pay  for  its  imports  ; 
in  other  words,  that  the  balance  of  trade  will,  if 
time  is  allowed  for  adjustment,  be  even.  Ac- 
cordii!gly  nothing  can  seem  more  absurd,  so  far 
as  trade  is  concerned,  than  for  a  government  to 
attempt  to  get  a  permanent  and  constant  excess 
of  Exports  over  Imports  in  order  that  a  balance 
may  be  due  on  the  precious  metals.  For  by  a 
converse  train  of  reasoning  the  eflfect  of  such  an 
influx  would  soon  be  a  rise  in  prices  and  a  check 
on  exports  and  a  stimulus  to  imports  until  the 
natural  rate  of  exchange  was  restored.  Thus 
from  the  modern  point  of  view  the  policy  of 
attempting  to  obtain  a  favourable  balance  (or 
excess  of  exports)  in  order  to  obtain  money 
seems  not  only  palpably  absurd,  but  on  analysis 
quite  impossible. 

Yet  in  its  origin  this  peculiar  importance 
attached  to  the  Precious  Metals  was  by  no 
means  an  absurdity,  and  the  regulations  intended 
to  increase  the  amount  of  money  in  the  country 
to  a  great  extent  achieved  their  object.  In  the 
Middle  Ages  we  find  the  germ  of  the  balance  of 
trade  system  in  what  was  very  hai)pily  styled 
by  Jones  the  balance  of  bargain  system  (Jones 
Political  Economy,  edit,  by  Whewell).  [Com- 
pare Mercantile  System  ;  Commercial  Sys- 
tem]. According  to  this  primitive  method  the 
state,  through  its  officials,  attempted  on  every 


BALANCE  OF  TEADE 


8fi 


bargain  to  obtain  a  balance  in  money  (of  silver 
or  later  on  of  gold).  Thus,  with  certain  material 
imports  a  certain  amount  of  money  must  be 
brought  in  ;  the  foreign  merchant  who  came 
to  the  country  to  sell  was  obliged  to  "  employ  " 
the  money  he  obtained  in  the  purchase  of  English 
wares  ;  the  organisation  of  the  Staple  was  used 
to  the  same  end,  and,  in  short,  all  kinds  of  devices 
by  way  of  prohibition  and  encouragement  were 
adopted  so  as  to  obtain  a  favourable  balance  in 
money.  There  can  be  little  doubt  (compare 
Schanz,  Englische  Handels  -  Politik  gegen  Ende 
des  Mittclalters,  etc.;  Jacob's  History  of  the 
Precious  Metals  ;  Jones,  op.  cit. )  that  this  policy 
was  at  any  rate  partially  successful,  and  that 
the  country  obtained  more  money  than  it  other- 
wise would  have  done.  But  not  only  was  this 
policy,  to  some  extent  at  least,  practicable,  but 
under  the  historical  conditions  it  appears  to 
have  been  justidable.  In  the  Middle  Ages 
Credit  was  almost  unknown,  and  the  rudiment- 
ary forms  which  appeared  were  strangled  by 
the  wide-reaching  laws  and  adverse  public 
opinion  on  interest.  As  a  consequence  thei-e 
was  often  a  real  dearth  of  the  precious  metals, 
in  a  sense  that  to  us  is  almost  unintelligible. 
At  the  same  time  also  it  must  be  observed  the 
whole  economic  progress  of  tlie  mcdireval  period 
was  bound  up  with  the  commutation  of  services 
and  payments  in  kind  into  money  payments 
(compare  T.  Roger>;  on  Scutage  in  Six 
[Centuries  of  English  Work  and  Wages).  Thus 
lany  scarcity  of  money  was  a  real  evil  involving 
[very  real  burdens,  and  it  was  good  policy  to 
)btain  a  favourable  balance  because  money  was 
peculiarly  important  part  of  the  fixed  capital 
Eof  the  nation.  In  process  of  time  the  balance 
[of  bargain  system  gave  place  to  the  balance  of 
le,  and  nations  took  the  place  of  individuals 
[(see  Commekcial  System).  Adam  Smith  had 
difficulty  in  showing  that  before  his  time 
lis  system  had  become  antiquated  and  useless 
luse  the  natural  course  of  trade  gave  a 
ifficiency  of  money,  and  the  accumulation  of 
rtreasure  was  not  desirable  (even  if  possible)  for 
Irfiirthering  foreign  policy.  Money,  in  fact,  had 
idy  lost  its  peculiar  importance,  and  it  was 
3y  to  show  at  any  rate  that  if  a  favoural)le 
lance  was  desired,  one  country  must  be  com- 
with  the  rest  of  the  commercial  world, 
id  that  the  best  policy  was  to  buy  in  the 
leapest  and  sell  in  the  dearest  markets,  inde- 
rpendently  of  the  particular  balance  with  indi- 
vidual countries. 

Reverting  to  the  modem  position,  it  must  be 
noticed  that  exports  and  imports  form  only  a 
part  (though  with  this  country  the  most  con- 
siderable part)  of  the  international  indebtedness 
(for  a  complete  enumeration  of  items  see 
Goschen's  Foreign  Exchanges,  ch.  iv.)  There 
must  also  be  taken  into  account  "invisible" 
exports,  such  as  freights,  commissions,  loans, 
expenses  of  government  or  individuals  abroad, 


tributes,  interest,  etc.  It  must  be  noted  also 
that  so  far  as  the  influx  or  efflux  of  the  precious 
metals  is  concerned,  it  is  not  the  permanent  in- 
debtedness but  the  need  of  payment  at  a  par- 
ticular time  which  is  of  importance.  Thus  the 
balance  of  indebtedness  may  for  the  time  being 
be  in  favour  of  a  country  that  is  hopelessly  in- 
solvent (compare  Commerce). 

In  conclusion  it  may  be  observed  that  even 
under  modern  conditions  sometimes  it  is  of  real 
importance  to  the  nation  as  a  whole  to  have  a 
favourable  balance,  or  at  least  to  be  able  to 
brave  an  unfavourable  one,  in  other  words,  to 
check  a  drain  of  gold.  In  normal  conditions 
the  existence  of  a  favourable  balance  (or  a  state 
of  indebtedness  in  Avliich  money  is  due  to  the 
country)  would  simply  mean  that  importers  of 
foreign  goods  can  obtain  exporters'  bills  at  a 
cheaper  rate  than  usual  owing  to  their  relative 
abundance,  so  that  favourable  is  construed  re- 
latively to  importers,  the  same  state  of  things 
being  adverse  to  exporters,  and  practically  in- 
difl'erent  to  the  nation  at  large.  But  at  certain 
times  a  foreign  drain  becomes  sufficiently  serious 
to  threaten  the  stability  of  the  banking  system 
of  the  country,  and  in  technical  language  the 
"exchanges  must  be  corrected."  Tliis  can 
only  be  done,  as  a  rule,  either  by  effectively 
raising  the  rate  of  discount  or  l)y  affecting  the 
trade  balance  through  checking  imports  and 
increasing  exports  (see  Exchakges,  Foreign  ; 
Drain  of  Bullion).  Apart  from  this  occasional 
effect  of  an  adverse  balance  from  the  banking 
point  of  view,  the  principal  point  to  observe  is 
the  rightful  interpretation  of  the  causes  of  a 
certain  purely  trade  balance.  Thus  for  many 
years  the  imports  into  England  of  commodities 
liave  exceeded  the  exports,  whilst  with  India 
the  converse  is  the  case.  The  explanation  is 
to  be  found  in  the  other  elements  of  interna- 
tional indebtedness.  It  is  a  gi-eat  error  to  argue 
at  once  that  because  there  is  an  excess  of  imports 
the  nation  is  practically  living  on  its  capital, 
for  the  other  items  in  the  account,  especially 
interest  on  foreign  investments  and  paymenth 
of  freights,  must  be  considered  (see  Sir  K.  Giffen, 
essay  on  "The  Use  of  Import  and  Export  Sta- 
tistics "  in  Essays  on  Finance). 

[For  the  historical  treatment  of  the  question 
compare  Schanz,  op.  cit.,  and  Adam  Smith's 
Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  iv. — List,  National  System 
of  Political  Economy.  The  theory  is  given  in  all 
the  text-books,  but  special  attention  may  be  called 
to  Prof.  Bastable's  International  Trade.] 

J.  S.  N. 

BALANCE  OF  TRADE  (History  of  the 
Theory). — The  views  of  the  earliest  popular 
economists  of  England  on  the  best  manner  of 
enriching  the  nation  agree  with  the  measures 
-taken  by  the  legislature  and  with  the  balance- 
of-bargain  system,  as  enforced  by  the  statutes 
of  employment.  "The  holl  welthe  of  the 
reame  is  for  all  om'  riche  commodites  to  gete 


86 


BALANCE  OF  TRADE 


owt  of  all  other  reamys  therfore  redy  money  ; 
and  after  the  money  is  brought  in  to  the  holl 
reame,  so  shall  all  peple  in  the  reams  be  made 
riche  therwith."  (Clement  Armstrong,  A 
treatise  concerninye  the  Staple  and  the  Com- 
modities of  this  Realme,  1530,  ed.  Pauli,  'pp. 
32,  61). 

But  when  the  English  merchants  had  broken 
down  the  power  of  foreign  Companies  and  had 
formed  companies  of  their  own,  they  sought 
after  a  rule  by  which  to  ascertain  what  advan- 
tages the  regulation  of  commerce  afforded  to 
the  nation  taken  as  a  whole.  Even  during  the 
prevalence  of  the  balance-of-bargain  system,  a 
rough  rule  for  the  policy  on  which  the  coinage 
should  be  based  had  been  given  by  an  officer  of 
the  mint,  Richard  Aylesbury,  who  thought 
that  "provided  the  merchandise  exported  from 
England  was  properly  regulated,  that  is,  if  no 
more  of  foreign  commodities  were  allowed  to  be 
imported  than  the  value  of  the  native  com- 
modities which  should  be  taken  out,  the 
money  in  England  would  remain,  and  gi-eat 
plenty  would  come  from  beyond  the  seas." 
Rolls  of  Parliament,  vol.  iii.  p.  126  ;  in  Rud- 
ing,  Annals  of  the  Coinage,  vol.  i.  p.  241, 
These  views,  put  forward  in  1381  by  Richard 
Aylesbury,  contrary  to  the  then  prevalent 
opinion  (Cunningham,  Growth  of  English  In- 
dustry and  Commerce,  Early  ami  Middle  Ages, 
1890,  p.  354),  were  formulated  anew  and  with 
success  by  the  anonymous  author  of  "  A  Dis- 
course of  the  City  of  London."  He  shows  that 
the  increase  of  prices,  which  followed  the  influx 
of  the  precious  metals  from  the  West  Indies 
had  induced  the  gentry  to  ' '  play  the  fermours, 
grasiars,  brewers,  or  such  like."  This  mercan- 
tile spirit  must  be  guided  by  the  experience  of 
the  merchant's  daily  practice.  England  being 
in  need  of  foreign  commodities,  and  having  no 
mines  of  its  own,  "it  foUoweth  necessarily, 
that  if  we  follow  the  councel  of  that  good  old 
Husband  Marcus  Cato,  saying,  '  oportei  patrem 
familias  vendacem  esse,  non  emacem '  and  do 
Carrie  more  commodities  in  value  over  the  seas, 
then  wee  bring  hether  from  thence  :  that  then 
the  Realme  shall  receive  that  Overplus  in 
Money  "  {A  JDiscoiirse  of  the  Names  and  First 
Causes  of  the  Institution  of  Cities,  and  peopled 
Towns  ;  and  of  the  Commodities  that  do  grow  by 
the  same ;  and  namely  of  the  City  of  London, 
etc.  (about  1578),  in  Stow's  Survey  of  London, 
1598,  p.  450).  William  Stafford  accepted 
these  principles,  adding,  that  the  imported  com- 
modities should  be  "most  apte  to  be  either 
carried  for  or  kepte  in  store,"  and  he  praised  the 
bailiff  of  Carmarthen,  who  had  forbidden  a  ship 
freighted  with  oranges  to  sell  them  (^A  Compendi- 
ous and  Brief  Examination,  ed.  1581.  New 
Shakspere  Soc.  Ed.,  pp.  50,  54,  57).  This  rule 
of  commercial  politics  has  been  accepted  by 
John  Wheeler  (A  Treatise  of  Commei'ce,  1601, 
pp.  7, 8)  and  by  Gerrard  de  Malynes,  who  seems 


to  have  suggested  the  name  of  balance,  say- 
ing that  the  prince  should  not  suffer  "  an  over- 
balancing of  forreine  commodities  with  his  home 
commodities,  or  in  buying  more  then  he  selleth." 
A  Treatise  of  the  Canker  of  England's  Common- 
wealth, 1601,  p.  2.  The  underbalance  of  trade 
and  the  consequent  scarcity  of  money  he 
ascribed  to  the  "undervaluation  of  our  Money 
in  Exchange,"  effected  by  the  practices  of  the 
bankers.  His  erroneous  ideas  and  those  of 
Thomas  Milles  concerning  "  merchandising  ex- 
change" {The  Customer's  Replie,  1604)  were 
attacked  by  Edward  Misselden,  who  hoped  to 
remedy  this  undervaluation  of  the  coin  by 
"raising"  it  {Free  Trade  or  the  meanes  to 
make  Trade  florish,  1622,  pp.  103-105),  similar 
views  being  expressed  in  the  parliament  {Pari. 
Hist.  i.  1195)  ;  he  calls,  however,  the  balance 
of  trade  "an  excellent  and  politique  invention, 
to  shew  us  the  difference  of  waight  in  the  com- 
merce of  one  kingdome  with  another  in  the 
scale  of  commerce  "  {The  Circle  of  Commerce,  or 
the  Balance  of  Trade,  in  defence  of  Free  Trade, 
by  E.  M.,  1623,  pp.  116,  117).  He  considers 
poverty  and  prodigality  as  the  causes  of  the 
present  underbalance,  the  Dutch  at  once  grow- 
ing rich  by , manufactures  and  restraining  the 
home  consumption  (pp.  132-135).  These 
opinions  were  generally  accepted  even  by  Fras 
Bacon  {Letter  of  Advice  to  George  Villiers,  1616 
Letters  and  Life,  ed.  S})edding,  vol.  vi.  pp, 
22-49,  and  History  of  Henry  VII.  Works,  vol 
vi.  p.  223),  and  King  James  L  {Pari.  Hist 
vol.  i.  p.  1179).  As  stress  was  laid  upon  the 
profit  of  exportation  of  manufactures,  the  use- 
lessness  of  the  prohibitions  of  the  exportation 
of  money  and  bullion  became  more  and  more 
evident.  Commercial  states  like  Tuscany  and 
Holland,  allowing  its  free  exportation,  grew  rich, 
while  those  forbidding  it,  like  Spain,  became 
impoverished.  This  point  was  clearly  elucidated 
by  Lewes  Roberts,  The  Treasure  of  Traffike, 
1641,  p.  77,  and  the  whole  doctrine,  including 
the  views  on  exchange  as  a  symptom,  not  as  an 
agent  of  trade,  as  Malynes  had  maintained, 
was  most  systematically  explained  by  Thomas 
MuN  in  his  posthumous  treatise  England's 
Treasure  by  Forraigne  Trade ;  or  the  Balance 
of  our  Forraigne  Trade  is  the  Rule  of  our 
Treasure,  1664,  who  in  his  Discourse  of  Trade 
(new  ed.  1621)  had  still  advocated  the  statutes 
of  employment.  To  him  therefore  the  honour 
of  its  invention  has  often  been  ascribed.  The 
obstacles  to  trade  were  for  the  most  part  caused 
by  fiscal  motives,  and  the  Commonwealth  sought 
to  stimulate  the  exportation  of  English  com- 
modities by  the  Act  of  Navigation.  The  balance 
of  trade  was  thought  to  be  advantageous :  by 
fetching  the  commodities  from  the  immediate 
places  of  their  production  and  by  sending  them 
to  their  best  market,  where  they  yield  the 
greatest  price,  but  above  all  by  the  cheapness 
of  the  exported  manufactures  and  the  reductior. 


BALANCE  OF  TEADE 


87 


of  the  price  of  labour  {The  Advocate :  or  a 
Narrative  of  the  State  and  Condition  of  Things 
between  the  English  and  Dutch  Nation,  eel. 
1651.)  This  programme  was  supported  by  the 
gi-eatest  economists  of  the  end  of  the  17th 
century  like  Petty,  Temple,  Locke,  having  all 
the  tendency  to  overwhelm  the  Dutch  power, 
Another  body  of  practical  men  inquired  into 
the  advantage  of  some  special  trades,  among 
which  the  French  and  East  India  trade  was 
found  ruinous,  as  absorbing  money  and  bullion, 
and  giving  in  its  stead  but  wines  or  spices. 
To  these  at  a  later  date  acceded  the  fear  of 
Irish  competition  in  the  matter  of  wool.  This 
pessimistic  series  of  writers  begins  with  S. 
Fortrey's  England's  Interest  and  Improvement, 
1663  ;  i\\Q  ax\t\iOV  oi Britannia  Lanrjuens,  1680, 
and  J.  PoLLEXFEN,  England  and  East  India  In- 
consistent in  Their  Mannfa/Aures,  1697,  were  its 
foremost  champions.  The  commercial  treaty 
with  France  in  1713  was  a  new  matter  of 
complaint.  In  the  British  Merchant,  all  the 
arguments  against  the  underbalance  are  restated 
by  Sir  Theodore  Janssen  in  his  General  Maxims 
in  Trade,  1713,  and  by  Joshua  Gee,  who  after- 
wards put  forward  his  views  in  The  Trade  and 
Navigation  of  Great  Britain  consider  d,  1729. 
"His  writings,"  says  Hume,  "struck  the  nation 
with  an  universal  panic,  when  they  saw  it 
plainly  demonstrated  that  the  balance  was 
against  them  for  so  considerable  a  sum  as  must 
leave  them  without  a  single  shilling  in  five  or  six 
years."  Nevertheless,  the  creed  of  the  balance 
of  trade  was  shared  not  only  by  Cantillon  and 
Sir  J.  Steuart,  bk.  ii.  ch.  xv.,  but  even  by  free- 
traders like  Thomas  Gordon,  The  Nature  and 
Weight  of  the  Taxes  of  the  Nation^  1722,  Van- 
derlint.  Money  answers  All  Things,  1734,  and 
the  author  of  An  Essay  on  the  Causes  of  the 
Decline  of  Foreign  Trade,  1743. 

For  some  time,  however,  the  belief  in  the  doc- 
trine had  been  shaken,  partly  by  traders  whose 
interest  it  was  to  refute  its  postulates,  partly  by 
the  in^possibility  of  giving  the  exact  statistical 
statement  of  the  balance,  partly  by  the  doubts 
raised  by  superior  thinkers.  One  of  the  first, 
it  seems,  was  the  author  of  Free  Forts,  the  Nature 
and  Necessltie  of  them  Stated,  B.  W.,  1652. 
"All  consultations  whatsoever  about  trade,  if 
free  ports  bee  not  opened  and  this  wholesale  or 
general  trade  bee  not  incouraged,  do  still  but 
terminate  in  som  advice  or  other  about  regulat- 
ing our  consumption  ;  and  have  no  other  good 
at  farthest,  but  jireventional,  that  our  Ballance 
of  Import  exceed  not  our  Export :  which  to 
confine  ourselves  to  alone,  is,  on  the  other  side 
a  cours  to  short,  as  it  will  neither  serv  to  rais 
the  Strength  of  this  Nation  in  shipping,  or  to 
Govern  the  Exchange  abroad  "  (p.  8).  But  the 
first  thorough  refutation  was  given  by  Nicholas 
Barbon  in  1690  and  1696  (see  Barbon),  and 
his  influence  is  to  be  traced  in  the  writings  ojf 
Sir  Dudley  North   {Discourses  of  Trade,   ed. 


1691),  who  calls,  evidently  in  reference  to  it, 
the  balance  of  trade  one  of  the  current  "poli- 
tick conceits  in  trade  ;  most  of  which  Time  and 
better  Judgment  hath  disbanded."  The  in- 
crease of  manufactures  had  in  opposition  to  the 
former  opinion  that  "trade  was  the  source  of 
national  riches  "  made  way  to  the  doctrine  that 
the  employment  of  population  and  labour  was 
the  primitive  enriching  power.  "Land  and 
labour,"  says  therefore  John  Bellers,  "are  the 
foundations  of  riches,  and  tlie  fewer  Idle  Hands 
we  have  the  faster  we  inciease  in  value  ;  and 
spending  less  than  we  raise  is  a  much  greater 
certainty  of  gi-owing  Rich  than  any  computa- 
tions  that  can  be  made  from  our  Exportation 
and  Importation  "  {Essays  about  the  Foor,  1699, 
p.  12).  These  views,  though  far  more  mingled 
with  mercantilist  beliefs,  were  U]»held  by  the 
author  of  The  Advantages  of  the  East  India  Trade 
to  Eigland  consider'd  (1701  and  1720),  who 
pointed  out,  that  the  only  rule  of  foreign 
trade  should  be  "to  get  a  greater  for  a  less 
value,"  and  by  De  Foe,  who  while  refuting  the 
authors  of  the  British  Merchant,  declared  him- 
self to  be  "a  profess'd  opposer  of  all  fortuitous 
calculations,  making  estimates  by  guess  work  of 
the  Quantities  and  Value  of  any  Trade  or  Export- 
ation" {A  Flan  of  the  English  Commerce,  1728 
(2nd  ed.  1737,  p.  232).  This  confession  and  the 
doubts  raised  by  Bishop  Berkeley  in  his  Querist 
(1735),  Queries  555,  556,  whether  the  rule  of  the 
balance  of  trade  held  always  true,  and  whether  it 
admitted  not  of  exceptions,  were  indeed  nothing 
new.  For  even  Davenant,  originally  much  de- 
voted to  these  estimates  {Of  the  use  of  Fqlitical 
Arithmetic,  1698,  Works,  vol.  i.  pp.  146-148), 
declared  himself  afterwards  convinced  that  they 
were  inaccurate  for  many  important  trades  {A 
Report  to  the  Commissioners,  1712,  Works,  vol. 
V.  p.  382).  Sir  Josiah  Child  also  stated,  as 
Berkeley  did,  that  by  means  of  smuggling,  and 
furthermore  in  the  case  of  countries  whose 
income  was  consumed  by  absentees,  like  Ireland, 
exports  could  exceed  imports  without  enriching 
the  peoj)le  {A  new  Discourse  of  Trade,  1690, 
ch.  ix.)  The  doubts  which  all  these  ex- 
pressions of  opinion  fostered,  paved  the  way 
for  the  overthrow  of  the  system.  This  was 
accelerated  by  the  flourishing  state  of  English 
trade,  which  continued  to  prosper  through  the 
18th  century  notwithstanding  all  the  predic- 
tions of  evil  expressed  by  the  balance- of- trade 
theorists. 

The  successful  onslaught  on  the  system  made 
by  Hume  in  his  Essays  (1752)  is  now  a  matter 
of  history.  In  these  he  restated  Barbon's 
assertion  that  an  equivalent  must  be  paid  in 
an  export  for  every  import  received.  Hume's 
refutation  of  the  balance-of-trade  theory  had  a 
considerable  influence  on  the  free  trade  doctrines 
of  the  Physiocrats  and  also  upon  Adam  Smith. 
The  latter,  like  Barbon,  controverted  the  theory 
on  this  subject  which  was  laid  down  by  Mun 


88 


BALANCE  OF  TRADE— BALANCE-SHEET 


and  by  Locke.  Adam  Smith  also,  in  the 
preference  he  gave  to  the  home  trade,  and  in 
his  opposition  to  the  mercantilist  views,  shows 
an  inclination  to  incredulity  in  relation  to  the 
theory  of  foreign  trade.  The  manner  in  which 
Adam  Smith  thus  placed  himself  in  opposition 
to  the  commonly-accepted  opinions  of  his  time 
explains  the  fact  that  his  criticism  of  the  theory 
of  foreign  trade  obtained,  when  it  first  appeared, 
comparatively  few  adherents.  Even  Pitt, 
while  proving  the  success  of  his  policy  by  the 
growth  of  exports,  said,  when  the  authority  of 
Adam  Smith  was  quoted  against  him,  that  he 
considered  "that  great  author,  though  always 
ingenious,  sometimes  injudicious  "  {Pari.  Hist. 
xxxiii.  562-3).  The  questioning,  however,  as  to 
the  complete  applicability  of  the  theory  gradu- 
ally extended  as  the  18th  century  waned. 
Afiter  the  successful  peace  of  Paris  in  1763 
the  fear  of  a  drain  of  specie  began  to  spread 
in  consequence  of  the  growth  of  indebtedness 
to  foreigners  ;  and  though  the  balance  of  trade 
seemed  favourable,  new  doubts  were  expressed 
whether  the  values  stated  of  the  goods  exported 
were  accurate  {The  Present  State  of  the  Nation, 
1769  ;  by  W.  Knox,  secretary  to  George 
Grenville,  pp.  65-67).  The  observations  of 
Burke  on  this  occasion,  though  professedly 
designed  to  prove  the  balance  to  be  favourable, 
are  very  acute.  Though  not  allowing  the 
statement  as  to  the  certificated  goods  for  re- 
exportation to  admit  of  error,  he  concedes  the 
possibility  for  free  goods,  exported  without 
drawback  and  bounty  ;  he  remembers  that  the 
costs  of  freight  and  the  profits  of  the  merchant 
are  not  taken  into  account,  that  in  the  balance 
of  the  Irish  and  West  India  trades  import  and 
export  both  refer  to  one  nation,  and  he  ridi- 
cules those  who  held  that  the  foreign  imports 
were  a  loss  without  even  considering  that  part 
of  it  which  enters  into  production.  {Observa- 
tions on  a  late  State  of  the  Nation,  1769,  pp. 
34-38.  Also  his  Letters  on  a  Megicide  Peace, 
1796,  Works,  vol.  iv.  p.  554).  The  refutation 
of  the  original  theory  of  the  balance  of  trade  is 
justly  ascribed  to  Adam  Smith,  and  his  pre- 
decessors in  England,  of  whose  principal  works 
some  notice  has  been  given  here.  The  work  of 
Adam  Smith  was  completed  by  Ricardo  in  his 
theory  of  international  trade  (see  International 
Trade  ;  Burke  ;  Adam  Smith  ;  Rioardo) 
which  has  hitherto  been  the  special  domain  of 
English  economics. 

[See  Buckle's  History  of  Civilisation  in  England, 
vol.  i.  pp.  210-212. — J.  Janschull,  English  Free 
Trade  (Russian)  1  part,  Moscow  1876. — E.  von 
Heyking,  Zur  Geschichte  der  Handelshilanztheorie, 
Berlin,  1882.— W.  Cunningham,  The  Growth  of 
English  Industry  and  Commerce,  1885,  p.  362. — 
C.  F.  Bastable,  The  Theory  of  International  Trade, 
Dublin,  1887,  p.  164.— G.  Schanz,  Englische 
Handelspolitik,  1881.]  s.  B. 

BALANCE-SHEET.     The  simplest  form  of 


balance-sheet  which  a  trader  can  require  is  the 
following : — 


BALANCE-SHEET  of 

.    19 

Assets. 

Liabilities. 

Debtors    on    open 

account       .        .    £4500 
Stock  in  Trade       .      8250 
Balance  at  Bankers      1250 
Other  Property      .      6000 

Creditors  on  open 

account        .        .    £2750 
Acceptances   .        .      1250 
Other  Liabilities    .      7000 
Surplus  or  Capital        9000 

£20,000 

£20,000 

How  much  may  depend,  not  only  on  the 
amount,  but  on  the  character  of  the  various 
"assets"  and  "liabilities,"  is  explained  with 
great  clearness  in  the  Country  Banker  by  Mr. 
George  Rae,  Letter  III.  on  the  "Testimony  of 
a  Balance-Sheet."  Mr.  Rae  remarks  on  this : 
"A  man's  duly-certified  balance-sheet  is  the 
one  reliable  voucher  of  his  actual  position  ;  all 
other  information  that  we  can  gain  respecting 
him  must  be  more  or  less  at  second  hand  and 
imperfect,  and  it  may  be  delusive.  But  there 
is  no  mistaking  the  figures  of  an  honest  balance- 
sheet." 

Mr.  Rae  writes  especially  from  a  banker's 
point  of  view,  as  a  man  in  the  habit  of  advanc- 
ing money,  sometimes  in  large  sums,  to  traders, 
but  the  knowledge  of  what  a  man's  own  business 
position  may  be  is  often  obscured  even  to  him- 
self by  careless  and  slovenly  book-keeping,  and 
the  habit  of  preparing  an  "honest"  balance- 
sheet  is  essential  to  soundness  of  trade. 

BALANCE-SHEET.  (2nd  statement.)  A 
balance-sheet  is  a  statement  exhibiting  the  assets 
and  liabilities  of  a  concern,  the  capital  invested 
in  it,  and  the  balance  of  profit  and  loss,  or  of 
income  and  expenditure,  accrued  to  date  of  the 
account.  If  books  of  account  are  kept  on  a 
proper  Double  Entry  System  the  debit  and  credit 
balances  of  the  ledger  will  form  respectively  the 
credit  (right  hand)  and  debit  (left  hand)  sides 
of  the  balance-sheet,  and  will  agi-ee  in  total. 
The  capital  of  the  concern  will  appear  on  the 
left-hand  side,  representing,  subject  to  any 
balance  of  profit  or  loss,  the  excess  of  assets  over 
liabilities.  If  the  liabilities  exceed  the  assets  a 
balance  of  loss,  which  will  more  than  absorb  any 
capital,  will  appear  on  the  right-hand  side. 

The  term  balance-sheet  is  sometimes  errone- 
ously applied  to  what  are  really  statements  of 
receipts  and  payments,  as  in  the  case  of  the 
accounts  of  charitable  institutions  ;  these  last 
naturally  and  usefully  take  the  form  of  a  state- 
ment of  income  and  expenditure  for  a  period. 
No  account  covering  a  period  of  time,  and  not 
exhibiting  the  position  of  matters  at  a  particular 
date,  can  properly  be  termed  a  balance-sheet. 

A  form  of  balance-sheet  appended  to  the 
First  Schedule  of  the  Joint  Stock  Companies' 
Act  of  1862  is  a  suitable  one  for  such  companies 
as  have  not  special  2)rovisions  with  regard  to 
the  form  of  their  accounts  laid  down  in  their 
articles  of  association.  This  form  of  account  ia 
as  follows : — 


J 


BALANCE-SHEET— BALBI 


89 


Dr. 

B  A  T.  A.NCE-SHEET  of  the 

Co.  made 

up 

to                     19     . 

Cr. 

Capital  and  Liabilities. 

Property  and  Assets.                              i 

I.  Capital. 

Showing : 

£s.d.\£s.d. 

III.     Prop- 

Showing : 

£s.d. 

£s.d. 

1. 

The  Number  of  shares 

erty    held 

7. 

Immovable   Property, 

2. 

The  Amount  paid  per 
Share 

by  the  Com- 
pany. 

disling  uishing — 
(a)  Freehold  Land 

S. 

If   any    Arrears    of 
Calls,  the  Nature  of 
the  Arrear,  and  the 
Names    of   the    De- 
faulters   . 

8. 

(b)  „         Build' 
ings  . 

(c)  Leasehold      „ 
Movable        Property, 

distinguishing — 

4. 

The    Particulars    of 
any  forfeited  Sliares 

{d)  Stock  in  Trade 
(e)  Plant 

11.      Debts 

Shoicing : 

The  Cost  to  be  stated 

AND     Lia- 

5. 

The  Amount  of  Loans 

with      Deductions 

bilities  of 

on  Mortgages  or  De- 

for    Deterioration 

i 

the     Com- 

benture Bonds  . 

in  Value  as  churyed\ 

1 
1 

pany. 

6. 

The  Amount  of  Debts 

to  the  Reserve  Fundi 

owing   by    the    Cuvi- 

or  Profit  and  Loss 

pany,      distinguish- 

IV.    Debts 

Shoicing  : 

ing — 

owing       to 

9. 

Debts  considered  good 

! 

(a)  Debts  for  which 

the      Com- 

for which   the  Com- 

A cceptances 

pany. 

pany   hold   Bills   or 

have  been  given 

other  Securities 

(b)  Debts  to  Trades- 

10. 

Debts  considered  good 

men  for   sup- 

for which   the   Com- 

plies of  Stock  in 

pany  hold  no  Sectirity 

Trade  or  other 

11. 

Debts    considered 

Articles  . 

doubtful  and  bad 

(c)  Debts   for    Law 

Any  Debt  due  from 

Expenses 

a  Director  or  other 

(d)  Debts    for    In- 

Officer of  the  Com- 

terest  on  Deben- 

pany to  be  separ- 

tures or  other 

ately  stated  . 

Loans 
{e)  Unclaimed  Divi- 
dends 

V.  Cash  AND 

Shotmng  : 

Invest- 

12. 

The  Nature  of  Invest- 

(/) Debts     not     en- 

ments. 

ment  and  Rate  of  In- 
terest 
The  Avwunt  of  Cash, 

umerated  above 

13. 

VI.        Re- 

Showing: 

where  lodged,  aoul  if 

serve 

The  Amount  set  aside 

hearing  Interest 

Fund. 

from  Profits  to  meet 
Contingencies  . 

VII.  Profit 

Shoioing  : 

AND  Loss. 

The   disposable    Bal- 
ance for  Payment  of 
Dividend,  tfcc.    . 

Contin- 

Claims   against    the 

gent    Lia- 

Company not  acknow- 

bilities. 

ledged  as  Debts 
Monies  for  which  the 
Company  is   contin- 

gently liable     . 

BALBI,  Adriano  (an  Italian  Economist  of 
the  firat  half  of  the  1 9th  century).  Author  of 
Saggio  di  una  statistica  d' Italia,  published  at 
Vienna  in  1833.  He  was  also  the  author  of 
the  following  works  : — 

Bilancia  politica  del  gloho  o  quadro  geografico- 


statistico  delta  terra,  Padova,  Zambeivari,  coi  tipi 
delta  Minerva  1833. — L'impero  russo  paragonato 
alle  principali  nazioni  del  mondo  (in  .French), 
Paris,  1829. — La  monorchia  francese  covfrontata 
coi  principali  Stati  del  mondo  (in  French),  Paris, 
1828. — Quadro  politico-statistico  dell  Europa,  net 
1820  (in  French),  Lisbon,  1820. — Saggio  statistico 


90 


BALDWIN— BANCO 


sul  Regno  di  Portogallo,  paragonato  agli  altri 
Stati  di  Europa  (in  French),  Paris,  1822,  2  vols, 
in  8vo, — Ragionamenti  di  statistica  e  geograjm 
patria,  Milano,  Civelli,  1845,  in  8vo. — Scritti 
geografici,  statistici  e  vari,  pubblicati  da  diversi 
giornali  d'  Italia,  di  Francia  e  di  Germania,  rac- 
colti  e  ordinati  per  la  prima  volta,  Torino,  1841-'42, 
5  vols,  in  8vo.  M.  p. 

BALDWIN,  LoAMMi,  born  in  Massachusetts 
1780  ;  an  eminent  civil  engineer  ;  died  1838. 
In  his  Thoughts  on  the  study  of  political  economy 
as  connected  with  the  population,  industry,  and 
paper  currency  of  the  United  States  (Cambridge, 
Mass.,  1809,  pp.  75)  Baldwin  advocated,  as 
a  remedy  for  the  evils  of  the  irregular  currency 
of  the  time,  that  the  state  banks  be  consoli- 
dated, and  that  the  capital  of  the  United  States 
Bank  be  extended.  He  favoured  internal  im- 
provements in  his  country,  and  displayed  more 
than  ordinary  appreciation  of  the  use  of  statis- 
tics ;  he  also  advised  that  the  United  States 
census  of  1810  should  include  a  record  of  births, 
deaths,  and  marriages.  D.  R.  D. 

BALSAMO,  Paolo,  born  at  Termini  (Sicily) 
in  1763,  died  at  Palermo  in  1816.  He  was  a 
priest  who  travelled  for  several  years  in  Italy, 
France,  and  England.  In  England  he  became 
a  friend  of  Arthur  Young,  from  whom  he  learnt 
a  great  deal.  Arthur  Young  published  some  of 
the  writings  of  Balsamo  in  his  Annals  of  Agri- 
culture ;  Broussonnet  translated  some  into 
French  and  enriched  others  with  commentaries. 
When  Balsamo  returned  from  England  he  be- 
came professor  of  political  economy  in  the 
university  of  Palermo,  and  his  teaching  is  clearly 
based  upon  Young's  doctrines  ;  he  divides  his 
course  into  political,  theoretical,  and  prac- 
tical agriculture,  considers  agriculture  as  pre- 
eminent, opposes  state  regulation  of  prices  and 
every  other  form  of  state  interference  with 
production  and  commerce,  and  declares  state 
help  for  the  poor  a  calamity.  His  lectures 
exerted  a  great  and  salutary  influence  on  his 
countrymen,  although  it  was  some  time  before 
he  triumphed  over  their  prejudices.  His  lec- 
tures were  not  only  technical,  viz.  concerning 
methods  of  agriculture,  but  also  political,  as  he 
insisted  strongly  on  the  necessity  of  giving  the 
proprietor  of  the  soil  absolute  certainty  of  pos- 
session and  personal  security,  and  of  putting 
down  brigandage  and  robbery.  As  to  the 
technical  part  of  his  lectures,  Balsamo  recast 
it  in  conformity  with  the  new  doctrines  of 
chemistry  which  were  being  discovered  in  his 
days.  Having  received  an  abbey  from  the 
viceroy  Caramanico,  he  entered  parliament  as 
one  of  the  clergy,  and  succeeded  in  passing  a 
plan  of  radical  reform  in  the  system  of  taxa- 
tion. The  basis  of  revenue  consisted  of  rents 
from  properties  of  the  crown,  and  of  an  intricate 
list  of  taxes  called  donations,  which  parliament 
had  granted,  and  which  weighed  very  differently 
on  the  different  classes,  and  had  each  a  separate 
machinery  for  collection.     Balsamo  succeeded 


in  substituting  for  all  these  taxes  a  proportional 
income-tax.  He  was  rewarded  by  the  govern- 
ment with  a  very  rich  abbey.  A  part  of  his 
writings  is  perhaps  lost ;  a  part  was  published 
in  1802  at  Palermo,  under  the  title  Memorie 
economiche  ed  agrarie  riguardanti  il  regno  di 
Sicilia  ;  another  part  was  published  after  his 
death  in  a  review  called  Effemeridi  scientiflche 
e  letterarie  per  la  Sicilia,  Nos.  8,  10,  11,  18, 
24,  32.  In  1804  he  published  a  pamphlet  on 
diseases  of  sheep,  and  in  1816  his  Principii  di 
Agricoltura  e  di  vegetazione  per  gli  agricoltori 
di  Sicilia.  Noteworthy  is  also  his  journal  of 
a  voyage  through  Sicily,  published  1809,  fall 
of  statistical  information.  In  1845  two 
volumes  of  economical  writings  were  published 
at  Palermo  (tipogr.  Muratori),  under  the  title, 
Memorie  inedite  di  puhlica  economia  ed  agri- 
coltura. M.  p. 

BAMFORD,  Samuel  (1788-1872),  son  of 
a  weaver  at  Middleton,  Lancashire,  after  being 
a  warehouseman  in  Manchester,  and  then  a 
sailor  in  the  coasting  trade,  finally  settled  down 
as  a  weaver  at  Middleton.  His  book,  Passages 
in  the  Life  of  a  Radical,  2  vols.  1841,  is  a  valu- 
able authority  for  the  history  of  the  condition  of 
the  working^  classes,  and  their  political  move- 
ments in  the  years  succeeding  Waterloo.  He 
was  all  his  life  a  strong  radical  reformer ;  and 
was  more  than  once  imprisoned  for  his  part  in 
political  movements  ;  but  his  maxim  was  al- 
ways "hold  fast  by  the  laws,"  and  he  braved 
the  loss  of  popularity  by  a  remonstrance  with 
the  Chartists  (To  the  Hand -loom  Weavers  of 
Lancashire,  and  the  persons  styled  Chartists, 
1839).  His  poems,  especially  those  in  Lanca- 
shire dialect,  had  a  wide  circulation.        J.  b. 

BAN.  Roumanian  coin  equal  to  1  centime 
(100  bans  =  l  leu).  f.  e.  a. 

BANALITES.  The  name  given  to  the  ex- 
clusive right  of  the  lord  in  France  to  erect  a 
mill,  bakehouse,  or  wine  press,  and  to  compel 
his  tenants  or  serfs  to  make  use  of  them.  As 
he  had  a  monopoly,  he  could  make  what  charge 
he  pleased.  The  only  provinces  exempt  from 
hanalit6s  were  Flanders,  Artois,  and  Hainault. 
These  petty  oppressions  were  a  great  source  of 
discontent  in  the  agricultural  districts  of  France. 
This  right,  with  so  many  others,  was  abolished 
in  the  famous  session  of  the  national  assembly  on 
4th  August  1789. 

[De  Tocqueville,  France  before  the  Revolution, 
note  Ixxvii.]  R.  L. 

BANCO.  The  addition  of  this  word  to  the 
name  of  a  coin  implies  that  the  coin  designated 
is  an  imaginary  one  representing  only  bullion  of 
a  certain  weight.  Before  the  introduction  of 
the  present  German  monetary  system  all  large 
payments  in  Hamburg  were  efiected  by  trans- 
fers at  the  principal  bank,  the  unit  of  which 
was  the  mark-banco,  a  coin  which  did  not  exist, 
but  which  was  supposed  to  be  containing  silver 
of  a   certain  weight   and  fineness,    and  wortt 


BANDINI— BANKING 


91 


Is.  6d.  The  aggregate  deposits  were  held  by 
the  Bank  of  Hambukg  in  bullion  or  foreign 
coins.  A  similar  system  of  transfers  was  for- 
merly used  in  Amsterdam,  and  existed  to  a  cer- 
tain degree  in  the  practice  of  the  mediaeval 
deposit  banks  in  Italy.  It  is  not  used  any- 
where at  present. 

BANDINI,  Salustio  Antonio,  born  1677, 
at  Siena,  brought  up  as  a  soldier,  preferred  retir- 
ing into  the  country  and  giving  himself  up  to 
agriculture.  In  1705  he  took  holy  orders,  and 
became  an  archdeacon  in  1723.  He  was  pre- 
sident of  the  Physiocratical  Academy,  a  society 
intended  to  promote  natural  sciences  rather 
than  literature. 

In  1737  he  wrote  his  famous  essay  on  the 
Sienese  marshes,  Discorso  Econoniico,  offered  in 
manuscript  to  the  grand-duke  Francis  in  1739  ; 
but  not  printed  till  1775  {Prima  edizione  di 
Firenze  per  Gaetano  Camhiagi  stampator  gran- 
ducale),  fifteen  years  after  Baudini's  death 
(1760).  Asecond  edition  was  issued  by  Custodi, 
Scrittoi'i  classici  italiani  di  ec.  polit.,  Milano, 
1803,  Parte  modcrna,  Tomo  I.  Bandini's 
essay  contains  the  following  leading  principles 
of  political  economy.  (1)  "  Human  natm-e  gives 
its  best  when  it  can  act  unfettered  ;  conse- 
quently, the  fewer  and  simpler  the  laws  the 
better." — (2)  As  a  corollary  from  the  preceding 
principle,  "abolition  of  all  vexatious  taxes  and 
reduction  of  state  officials  to  a  mininmm." — (3) 
Abolition  of  laws  regulating  prices  ;  "if  proprie- 
tors and  peasants  grow  rich  through  high  prices 
of  agiicultural  produce,  so  much  the  better  for 
the  consumers,  because  more  produce  will  be 
produced  for  them." — (4)  "The  want  of  com- 
mercial and  industrial  liberty  causes  famines." 
— (5)  "Laws  against  monopolies  (natural)  and 
3omers  are  based  on  prejudices." — (6)  Rapid- 
ity and  facility  of  exchange,  not  abundance  of 
money,  are  the  causes  of  wealth. — (7)  A  single 
tax  is  easier  and  cheaper  for  all  parties  con- 
cerned than  a  great  many  ;  it  ought  to  be  im- 
posed on  land  and  farmed  out. 

The  Sienese  marshes,  which  Bandini  hoped  to 
reclaim  by  the  adoption  of  these  maxims,  con- 
stitute the  lower  part  of  the  province  of  Siena 
and  about  two-fifths  of  the  whole  of  Tuscany. 
His  maxims,  neglected  by  Francis,  inspired  the 
policy  of  the  grand-duke  Peter  Leopold  of  Tus- 
cany, but  the  Maremma  benefited  by  it  only 
after  the  granduke  had  charged  the  mathema- 
tician Leonardo  Ximenes  to  investigate  the  hy- 
drostatical  problems  of  the  case,  and  received  a 
favourable  report  upon  Bandini's  suggestions. 

[Delia  fisica  riduzione  della  Maremvia  Senese 
di  L.  Ximenes,  Firenze,  1769,  nella  stamperia  di 
Fr.  Moucke,  in  4°.  And,  reply  to  a  critic  in  1775, 
Esame  dell'  esame  d'un  libro  sopra  la  Mar&mma 
Senese,  Firenze,  1775,  G.  Carabiagi.]  m.  p. 

BANFIELD,  Thomas  C.  (first  half  19th 
century).  The  most  important  of  Banfield's 
writings    is     the    Organisation    of   Industry. 


Having  lived  some  years  in  Germany,  he  was 
led  to  study  the  works  of  continental  econo- 
mists, then  little  known  in  England,  and  his 
book  oAves  special  debt  to  Hermann  and  Rossi. 
By  the  Organisation  of  Industry  he  means  a 
graduated  scale  of  industries,  corresponding  to 
a  graduated  scale  of  human  wants,  and  depend- 
ing on  the  axiom  that  the  satisfaction  of  a 
primary  want  at  once  gives  rise  to  a  secondary ; 
e.g.  "in  proportion  as  food  gi'ows  abundant, 
the  other  wants  rise  in  importance,  and  a  con- 
stantly expanding  series  of  desires  is  awakened, 
which  are  classified  according  to  their  different 
grades  of  pressure  "  (Lecture  III.  p.  60).  The 
cheapening  of  the  means  of  satisfying  the  more 
urgent  wants  creates  savings,  which  are  necessarily 
spent  in  satisfying  the  second — an  argument 
for  free  trade.  His  criticisms  of  other  econo- 
mists {e.g.  RiCAiiDo)  are  not  always  convincing, 
and  his  own  definitions  are  not  always  precise. 
But  his  remarks  on  commercial  history  and  on 
the  economical  features  of  his  own  time  are 
often  acute  and  suggestive. 

Professor  Jevons,  in  his  Political  Economy 
(1871),  has  pointed  out  some  passages  where 
13anfield  has,  in  some  degree,  anticipated  the 
main  theorems  of  that  work. 

Six  Letters  to  Sir  Robert  Peel  on  the  Dangerous 
Tendency  of  the  Theory  of  Rent  advocated  by 
Ricardo,  1843. — Four  Lectures  on  the  Orga7iiHL- 
tion  of  Lndustry,  delivered  at  Cambridge,  1844, 
])ublished  1845.  Translated  into  French,  by 
jfiniile  Thomas,  1851.  —  Tlie  Progress  of  tlie 
Prussian  Nation,  since  1805  (from  Dieterici), 
Journal  of  Statistical  Society,  1848.— Tlie  Sta- 
tistical Companion  for  1848,  1850,  etc.  (T.  C. 
Baufleld  and  C.  R.  Weld).  —  The  Lndustry  oj 
tlie  Rhine  in  Knight's  Weekly  Volumes,  1846, 
1848.— .4  Letter  to  W.  Brown,  M.P.,  on  his 
system  of  Decimal  Coinage,  1855. — Articles  in  the 
Mining  Journal.  J.  B. 

BANKING 

Bank  of  England,  p.  92  ;  Banks  :  England  and  Wales,  p. 
93  ;  Scotland,  p.  95  ;  Ireland,  p.  96  ;  India  and  Colonies, 
p.  97  ;  Bank  of  France,  p.  97  ;  Banks :  France,  p.  98  ; 
Bank  of  Germany,  p.  98 ;  Banlcs :  Germany,  p.  99  ; 
Chartered  Banks  in  Scotland,  p.  100  ;  Banks  in  Canada, 
p.  100  ;  United  States  National  Banks,  p.  102 ;  Early 
European  Banks  —Amsterdam,  p.  104  ;  Genoa,  p.  104  ; 
Hamburg,  p.  105  ;  Middelbnrg,  p.  lOG ;  Rotterdam, 
p.  106  ;  Sweden,  p.  104  ;  Venice,  p.  103  ;  Land  Banks, 
p.  106;  Do.,  Germany,  p.  106;  Popular  Banks,  Ger- 
many, p.  109;  Do.,  Italy,  p.  109;  Savings  Banks,  p. 
110  ;  Bank  Notes,  p.  Ill  ;  Laws  in  different  Countries, 
p.  112  ;  National  Banks  U.S.,  p.  113. 

BANKS,  United  Kingdom.  The  business 
of  banking,  generally  speaking,  consists  in 
taking  money  on  deposit,  and  also,  in  issuing 
notes  and  drafts,  by  which  the  transfer  of 
loanable  capital  is  facilitated.  The  funds 
thus  obtained,  together  with  those  supplied 
by  the  capitals  of  the  banks  themselves,  are 
employed  in  making  advances,  in  the  discount 
of  bills,  and  in  investments  in  first-class  securi- 
ties, such  as  the  public  funds  ;  some  part  being 
kept  in  cash  to  meet  current  requirements.     The 


92 


BANKS,   UNITED  KINGDOM 


proportion  to  he  employed  in  these  methods  de- 
pends on  the  circumstances  of  each  individual 
bank.  No  absolute  rule  can  be  laid  down. 
The  judgment  of  the  banker  is  shown  in  the  use 
he  makes  of  the  capital  intrusted  to  him.  In 
a  general  way  the  maintenance  of  a  reserve  6f 
resources  immediately  available,  to  the  extent 
of  a  third  of  the  liabilities,  may  be  regarded  as 
adequate.  The  assistance  which  a  judiciously 
worked  system  of  banking  gives  to  the  economic 
development  of  a  country  is  enormous  ;  it  en- 
ables capital  to  be  transferred  from  those  persons 
by  whom,  and  from  those  places  where  it  is  not 
required  lor  active  use  to  those  requiring  it. 
Both  sides,  the  borrower  and  the  lender,  gain 
from  the  operation.  The  one  obtains  some 
interest  for  his  money  when  placed  on  deposit — 
the  spare  cash  which  he  does  not  need  for  im- 
mediate use.  The  other  obtains  the  aid  of  an 
instrument  of  credit  which  enables  him  to  carry 
on  his  business,  and  which  would  otherwise  be 
out  of  his  reach.  The  following  observations 
apply  to  tlie  principal  countries  in  which 
methods  of  banking  exist. 

Bank  of  England.  The  Bank  of  England 
was  foimded  in  1694  by  act  of  parliament  (Ways 
and  Means  Bill)  of  1694,  5  William  and  Mary 
c.  20.  It  afforded  an  immediate  and  powerful 
support  to  the  government,  and  also  to  the 
inland  trade  of  the  country.  By  its  original 
constitution  it  was  authorised  to  deal  in  bullion 
and  bills,  to  issue  notes,  and  to  make  advances 
on  merchandise.  At  that  period,  and  for  a  long 
time  afterwards,  the  issue  of  notes  formed  a  very 
large  part  of  the  business  of  banking.  To  trace 
the  development  of  the  Bank  of  England  in 
detail  here  would  extend  beyond  the  limits  to 
which  these  remarks  must  be  confined.  The 
Bank  has  rendered  very  important  services  to 
the  government  in  times  of  war  and  difficulty, 
and  also  to  the  trade  and  commerce  of  the 
country. 

The  charter  under  which  it  was  founded  was 
periodically  renewed  till  it  was  superseded  in 
many  respects  by  the  Bank  Act  of  1844.  In 
the  interval  between  its  foundation  and  that 
date  the  most  important  event  which  befell  the 
bank  was  the  suspension  of  specie  payments  1797- 
1821  (see  Bullion  Committee,  Report  of). 
A.t  the  present  time  the  Bank  of  England  forms 
the  centi'e  of  banking  operations  in  the  United 
Kingdom.  Three  principal  reasons  have  led  to 
its  holding  this  position.  These  are,  that  it  is 
the  issuer  of  the  only  note  circulation  which  is 
legal  tender,  that  it  is  the  banker  of  the  govern- 
ment, and  also  of  the  other  bankers  of  the 
country.  Owing  to  the  last-named  circum- 
stance the  reserve  of  the  Bank  of  England  is, 
practically,  at  the  present  time,  the  only  un- 
used money  in  the  country  available  for  any 
sudden  demand,  either  of  a  domestic  or  a 
foreign  character.  The  position  which  a  bank 
so  circumstanced  holds  is  unique  ;  and  hence, 


though  less  distinctly  now  than  in  former  years, 
the  bank  rate  of  discount  is  regarded  as  the 
authoritative  guide  to  the  current  rate  of  dis- 
count. That  it  is  less  distinctly  a  guide  now  than 
formerly  is  due  to  the  fact  that  modern  arrange- 
ments have  placed  enormous  sums,  as  deposits, 
in  the  hands  of  other  banks  ;  still  the  pre- 
eminence of  the  Bank  of  England  is  generally 
recognised,  and  in  any  time  of  difficulty  or 
distrust  its  actions  are  watched  with  the  most 
sedulous  anxiety,  and  it  is  not  too  much  to 
say  that  at  such  times  the  fate  of  the  com- 
mercial prosperity  of  the  community  lies  in  its 
hands. 

The  constitution  of  the  governing  body  of 
this  powerful  institution  is  very  simple.  The 
court  of  directors  numbers  twenty-six.  This 
includes  the  governor  and  deputy-governor  and 
twenty -four  directors,  chosen  from  the  old- 
established  firms  in  the  city.  Custom  has  ex- 
cluded English  bankers  from  this  body,  but 
members  of  the  powerful  firms  employed  in 
negotiating  foreign  loans  and  in  foreign  bill- 
broking  are  considered  eligible.  The  directors 
are  practically  self-elected.  The  respect  due  to 
the  high  position  they  hold  has  been  well  main- 
tained by  the  high  standard  of  character  observed. 
The  Bank  of  England,  acting  as  agent  of  the 
government,  naturally  becomes  the  holder  of  the 
bullion  reserve  of  the  country,  as  by  law  the 
bank  is  bound  to  receive  all  gold  bullion  offered 
to  it  of  standard  value,  at  the  price  of  £3  : 1 7  :  9 
an  ounce,  retaining  the  practical  difference  of 
l^d.  between  this  sum,  and  £3  :  17  :  IO5  the  mint 
price  (see  Mint),  as  a  remuneration  for  its  trouble. 
Importers  may,  if  they  prefer,  take  the  Bullion 
direct  to  the  mint  and  receive  new  coin  at  the 
rate  of  £3  :  17  :  10^  an  ounce  for  it  themselves. 
But  the  trouble  of  doing  so,  and  the  delay  which 
always  ensues,  causes  the  bullion  to  be  brought 
to  the  bank  by  preference.  Here  it  makes  its 
way  to  the  issue  department  and  forms  the 
basis  of  the  note  circulation  of  the  bank  for  the 
amount  beyond  that  allowed  to  be  issued  on 
securities.  For  the  connection  between  the 
bank  note  circulation  and  the  other  operations 
of  the  bank  (see  Bank  Note).  As  a  bank  the 
Bank  of  England  receives  large  amounts  of 
deposits,  on  which  it  allows  no  interest  what- 
ever. Suggestions  have  often  been  made  that  it 
should  do  this,  but,  were  the  bank  to  compete 
with  the  other  banks  in  this  manner,  it  is  hardly 
likely  that  the  other  banks  would  continue  to 
keep  the  large  balances  they  do  with  it.  These 
balances  are  always  large.  No  statement 
respecting  them  has,  however,  been  published 
since  1877,  but  at  times  they  have  exceeded 
the  reserve.  The  balances  of  the  London 
bankers  are  held  with  the  bank  in  connection 
with  the  clearing  house  transfers  (see  Clearing 
House).  As  a  discounter  of  commercial  paper 
the  business  of  the  bank  is  largely  exceeded  at 
present  by  other  financial  institutions,  but  it  is 


BANKS,  UNITED  KINGDOM 


93 


still  the  ultimate  resort  of  al]  who  want  to  borrow 
and  find  other  banks  clo%d  to  them. 

The  average  minimuni  rate  of  discount  of  the 
Banks  of  England,  France,  and  Germany  for 
1844-1912,  was—     ■ 


Year. 

Sank  of 

Bank  of 

Bank  of 

^  f  England. 

France. 

Prussia. 

• 

Per  cent. 

Per  cent. 

Per  cent. 

£  s.    d. 

£  s.    d. 

£  s.    d. 

1844 

2  10    0 

4     0    0 

4    0    0 

1845 

2  13     8 

4    0    0 

4    7     0 

1846 

3     6     6 

4     0    0 

4   14     0 

1847 

5     3     6 

4  19     0 

4  17     0 

184S 

3  14     5 

4    0     0 

4  13     0 

1S49 

2  18     7 

4     0    0 

4     1     0 

1S50 

2  10     1 

4     0    0 

4     0     0 

]S51 

3     0    0 

4    0    0 

4     0     0 

1852 

2     3     0 

3     3    0 

4     0     0 

*-           1853 

3  13  10 

3     5     0 

4     5     0 

1854 

5     2     3 

4     6     0 

4     7     0 

1855 

4  17  10 

4     9     0 

4     2     0 

1856 

6     1     2 

5  10    0 

4  19     0 

1857 

6  13     3 

6    3     0 

5  15     0 

1858 

3     4     7 

3  14     0 

4  10    0 

1859 

2  14     7 

3     9     0 

4     4     0 

1860 

4     3     7 

3  13     0 

4     0     0 

1861 

5     5     4 

5  10     0 

4     0     0 

1862 

2  10     7 

3  16     0 

4     0    0 

1863 

4     8     2 

4  13     0 

4     2    0 

1864 

7     8     0 

6  K)     0 

5     C     0 

1865 

4  15     4 

3   11     4 

4  19     0 

1866 

6  19     0 

3  14     0 

6     4     0 

1867 

2  10    9 

2  14     0 

4     0     0 

1868 

2     1  11 

2  10     0 

4     0    0 

1869 

3     4     2 

2  10     0 

4     2     0 

1870 

3     2     0 

4     0     0 

4   17     0 

1871 

2  17     8 

5  14     0 

4     3     0 

1872 

4     2     0 

5     3     0 

4     6     0 

1873 

4  15  10 

5     3     0 

5     1     0 

1874 

3   13  10 

4     6     0 

4    7    0 

1875 

3     4     8 

4     0    0 

4  14    0 

1876 

2  12     1 

3     8    0 

4    3     Ol 

1877 

2  18     0 

2     5     3 

4     8     0 

1S78 

3  15     8 

2     4     2 

4     6     9 

1879 

2  10     4 

2  11    10 

3  14    3 

1880 

2  15     4 

2  k;  10 

4     4  10 

1881 

3  10     0 

3   17     6 

4     S     6 

1882 

4     2     S 

3  15     4 

4  10     3 

1883 

3  11     4 

3     1     5 

4     1     0 

1884 

2  19     1 

3     0     0 

4     0     0 

1885 

2  17     7 

3     0    0 

4     2     5 

1886 

3     1     0 

3     0    0 

3     5     8 

1887 

3     7     0 

3     0    0 

3     8     4 

1888 

3     5  11 

3     1  11 

3     6     6 

1889 

3  10  11 

3     18 

3  13     7 

1890 

4  10    5 

3     0    0 

4  10    5 

1891 

3     5     2 

3     0     0 

3  15     4 

1892 

2  10    7 

2  13  11 

3     4     1 

1893 

3     1     0 

2  10    0 

4     1     5 

1894 

2     2    3 

2  lU    0 

3     2     6 

1895 

2    0     0 

2     2    0 

3     2     7 

1896 

2     9     8 

2     0     0 

3  13     3 

1897 

2  12     8 

2     0    0 

3  16     3 

1898 

3     4  10 

2     4    0 

4     5     1 

1899 

3  15    0 

3     15 

5     0     5 

1900 

8  19    3 

3     4     8 

5     6     6 

1901 

8  14    4 

3     0     0 

4     1  11 

1902 

3     6     7 

3     0    0 

3    6    6 

1903 

3  15     0 

3     0     0 

3  16     9 

1904 

3     6     1 

3    0     0 

4     4     7 

1905 

3    0     1 

3    0     0 

3  16     3 

1906 

4     5     3 

3    0     0 

5     2  11 

1907 

4  18     5 

3    9    3 

6     0     7 

1908 

3     0     4 

3     10 

4  15     6 

1900 

3     ')     3 

3    0    0 

3  18     5 

1910 

3  14     5 

8    0    0 

4     6  11 

1911 

3     9     4 

3     2    9 

4     7  11 

1912 

3  15     6 

3    7    5 

4  18  10 

Average  from  \ 
1844-1912      / 

3  12     9 

3  11    2 

I 

4    7    2" 

The  ten  yearly  averages  are  as  follows 


Years. 

Bank  of 

Bank  of 

Imperial 
Bank  of 

England. 

Prance. 

Germany. 

£  s.    d. 

£  s.    d. 

£  s.    d. 

1S44-1S53 

3    3    4 

3  IS     S 

4    6    4 

1854-1863 

4  10     2 

4  10     4 

4    7  11 

1864-1873 

4     3     8 

4     3     3 

4  13  10 

1874-1SS3 

3     5     5 

3     4     8 

4     5     9 

1884-1893 

3     4  10 

2  18     9 

3  14     9 

1894-1903 

3     1  11 

2  12     2 

3  19     2 

1904-1912 

3  12     2 

3     2     3 

4  12     5 

1  Since  1876  the  Imperial  Bank  of  Germany. 


It  appears  hence  that  the  London  money 
market  has,  on  the  average  of  sixty-nine  years, 
been  cheaper  than  that  of  Berlin.  Throughout, 
with  a  few  exceptions,  especially  for  the  last 
fifty  years,  the  value  of  money  in  England  has, 
on  average,  been  dearer  than  in  France. 

England  and  Wales.  The  origin  of  banking 
in  Germany  may  be  traced  even  further  back 
than  the  habit  of  depositing  money  with  the 
London  goldsmiths,  which  was  in  full  vigour  by 
the  end  of  the  17th  century.  Banking  in  the 
I)rovinces  was  at  the  outset  more  dependent  on 
the  issue  of  notes  than  that  of  the  metropolis, 
which  naturally  resulted  from  the  difference  of 
its  field  lor  operations.  The  history  of  the 
bank  of  Dundee  may  be  taken  as  an  illustration, 
for  in  this  the  habits  of  Scotch  arid  of  English 
provincial  banks  may  be  regarded  as  a  good  deal 
similar  (see  Banks  in  Scotland).  The  early 
employment  of  credit  in  this  manner  led  to 
results  which  govern,  or  at  least  largely  influ- 
ence, the  banking  system  of  this  country  to  the 
present  day.  The  value  ascribed  to  the  power 
of  issuing  notes  led  to  the  act  of  1708,  Avhich 
restricted  the  number  of  partners  in  banks  of 
issue,  and  vu'tually  in  all  banks,  to  a  number 
not  exceeding  six  during  the  continuance  of  the 
Bank  of  England.  This  restriction  lasted  till 
the  year  1826,  when  the  establishment  of  joint- 
stock  banks  of  issue  was  permitted  ;  it  was 
further  modified  by  the  act  of  1862,  which 
allowed  private  partnerships,  not  being  banks 
of  issue,  to  have  ten  members.  The  Act  of 
1833,  however,  prohibits  any  English  joint- 
stock  bank  of  issue  from  jjossessing  a  banking 
oflSce  in  London.  The  act  of  1844  restricts 
the  privileges  of  issuing  notes  to  those  banks 
whether  private  or  joint  stock,  which  possessed 
the  privilege  at  that  date.  The  main  object 
of  the  early  legislation  was  to  secure  a  mono- 
poly of  issue  to  the  Bank  of  England.  In- 
cidentally it  has  served  to  prevent  English 
banking  from  taking  its  proper  develojmient. 
In  this  the  act  of  1844,  the  latest  of  Sir  Robert 
Peel's  acts  dealing  with  monetary  questions, 
has  also  assisted.  His  object  in  this  was  to 
cause  the  note  issue  of  the  country  to  centralise 
on  the  Bank  of  England,  and  to  provide  that, 
with  the  exception  of  the  notes  allowed  to  be 
issued  against  securities,  an  equivalent  value 
in  the  precious  metals  should  be  held  against 


94 


BANKS,  UNITED  KINGDOM 


the  amount  in  circulation  in  the  case  of  the 
notes  issued  by  that  bank  (see  Bank  Note). 
Through  the  restrictions  imposed  on  dealing 
with  the  power  of  issuing  notes  by  this  act, 
the  existence  of  a  considerable  number  of  com- 
paratively small  banks  of  issue  was  continued 
in  England  long  after  the  time  when,  judging 
by  the  analogy  of  events  in  Scotland  and  Ire- 
land, coalition  into  larger  concerns  would  have 
been  desirable.  It  is  not  necessary  to  refer 
here  to  the  detail  of  our  banking  system.  It 
may  be  sufficient  to  remark  that  in  hardly  any 
other  country  are  the  positions  and  circum- 
stances of  individual  banks  so  widely  different 
from  each  other  as  in  our  own.  It  is  to  be 
regretted  that  the  attention  of  the  legislature 
in  England  has  been  directed  mainly  to  the 
note  issue,  with  a  view  to  centralise  it,  and 
that  so  little  has  been  given  to  other  points  of 
more  importance  to  the  wellbeing  of  the  bank- 
ing system.  Some  provincial  banks,  both 
private  and  joint  stock,  possess  the  privilege  of 
issuing  their  own  notes,  but  this  power  can  only 
be  exercised  by  those  who  possessed  it  before 
the  year  1844.  Very  few  banks  in  England 
and  Wales  issue  tlieir  own  notes  now.  The 
act  of  1844  fixed  the  maximum  circulation  of 
the  country  banks  in  England  and  Wales  at 

£5,153,417  (207)  private  banks, 
reduced  by  amalgamation  subsequently  to  205, 
and 

£3,478,230  (72)  joint-stock  banks, 
but  of  this  amount 

£4,818,802  (197)  private  banks, 
3,307,643  (67)  joint-stock  banks, 
have  since  lapsed  from  various  causes,  volun- 
tary and  other,  so  that  the  limit  of  the  pro- 
vincial issues  now  (1913)  stands  at 
£334,615  (8)  private  banks, 
170,587(5)  j  oint-stock  banks. 

The  banking  business  of  England  and  Wales 
is  now  carried  on  by  about  19  private  and 
44  joint- stock  banks.  The  different  banks 
vary  much  in  size  and  importance.  By  the  side 
of  very  large  banks,  wielding  immense  amounts 
of  capital  and  deposits,  very  small  concerns, 
possessing  proportionally  small  resources,  may 
be  found  carrying  on  business  to  advantage, 
and  competing  successfully  with  their  more 
powerful  rivals.  One  result,  and  it  is  a  very 
peculiar  one,  of  the  manner  in  which  our  bank- 
ing system  has  developed  itself,  employing  the 
Bank  of  England  as  the  pivot  of  its  transac- 
tions, is  that  no  bank  in  the  country  keeps  any 
large  stock  of  the  precious  metals  in  reserve — 
more,  in  fact,  than  habit  has  shown  to  be  ade- 
quate for  daily  requirements,  except  the  Bank 
of  England.  By  this  method  economy  in  use 
of  metallic  money  has  been  greatly  promoted, 
with  corresponding  advantages  to  the  com- 
munity. The  necessary  drawback  to  this  is 
that  in  times  either  of  panic  or  of  foreign  de- 


V 


mands  for  bullion,  t'he  strain  on  our  banking 
system  becomes  ex^emely  sharp,  and  the 
troubles  of  the  time 'greatly  intensified  (see 
Drain  of  Bullion  and  Crisis).  -  The  reserve 
of  the  Bank  of  England  a^j^ears  to- those  outside 
the  business  to  be  "idle  mcAigy,"  but  no  portion 
of  our  monetary  resources  reatiiv  has  so  import- 
ant a  part  to  play,  or  is  so  entir^V  **  employed  " 
as  the  bankers'  balances,  which  flg^ft^'linit^at 
reserve,  and  sometimes  exceed  it '  in ,  amoum;.* ' 
Through  the  agency  of  our  system  ''English 
capital  runs  as  surely  and  instantly  where  it  is 
most  wanted,  and  where  there  is  most  to. be 
made  of  it,  as  water  runs  to  find  its  level." 
The  ramification  of  our  banking  system  to  every 
small  town  and  village  enables  our  monetary' 
resources  to  be  economised  to  the  utmost,  thus 
persons  requiring  advances,  whose  position  jus- 
tifies their  being  made  to  them,  are  enabled 
to  obtain  the  advantages  which  the  use  of 
capital  will  afford,  both  in  remote  places  and 
in  our  larger  commercial  and  industrial  centres. 
The  extension  of  banking  throughout  the  pro- 
vinces of  late  years  has  been  very  marked. 
The  total  number  of  offices  of  banks  in  England 
and  Wales  which  was  1927  in  1876,  in  1913 
reached  a  total  of  6973.  The  deposits  in  the 
banks  of  England  and  Wales  are  estimated  at 
the  same  date  as  about  £958,000,000.  The 
aggregate  number  of  banking  offices  in  the 
country  generally  was  nearly  9116  at  the  same 
date,  while  the  deposits  in  the  banks  of  the 
United  Kingdom,  which  were  estimated  as 
being  from  £470,000,000  to  £480,000,000 
in  1879,  were  estimated  in  the  Bankers' 
Magazine  as  being  about  £1,065,760,000  in 
1913,  exclusive  of  the  deposits  held  by 
the  Bank  of  England,  which  were  about 
£34,000,000  in  1879  and  £62,500,000  in  1913. 
The  publication  of  accounts  is  still  not  uni- 
versal though  far  more  general  than  formerly. 
Official  statistics  of  the  aggregate  do  not  exist. 
No  doubt  in  some  cases  undue  credit  has  been 
given  to  those  who  have  not  been  deserving 
of  it,  with  disastrous  results  (see  Crisis).  In 
some,  but  fortunately  much  rarer  instances,  the 
fraudulent  have  been  assisted,  or  the  banks 
themselves  been  ruined,  by  bad  trading.  But 
on  the  whole  these  results  have  but  seldom 
occurred,  and  the  prosperity  of  the  country  has 
probably  been  promoted  fully  as  much  by  the 
banking  system  it  has  possessed  as  by  any 
modern  adaptation  of  physical  science  to  the 
comforts  and  conveniences  of  life. 

Some  banks  in  the  provinces  allow  interest 
at  a  low  rate  on  the  daily  balances  of  their 
customers  in  their  hands  ;  but  the  more  general 
rule  is  to  make  an  allowance  of  interest  only  on 
sums  placed  specially  on  deposit.  This  interest 
usually  varies  according  to  the  "London"  rate 
for  the  time  being  ;  but  some  banks  allow  a 
fixed  and  uniform  rate.  The  practice  varies  io 
different  localities. 


BANKS.   UNITED  KINGDOM 


96 


Scotland.  Considered  historically,  the  dis- 
tinctive pecnliirities  of  Ivanking  in  wScotland 
arose  froin  the  fact  that,  unlike  their  neigh- 
bours in  EugLiud,  the  .people  were  allowed  by 
the  legislature  al  solute  freedom  to  create  what- 
ever system  of  ba  iiking  they  fouinl  best  suited 
to  their  wants.  Thereupon,  before  the  days  of 
railways  and  steamboats,  every  district  of  the 
country,  however  remote,  apj^ears  to  have  de- 
veloped its  banker  by  a  process,  as  it  were,  of 
"natural  selection."  He  was  the  trusted  cus- 
todian of  the  savings  of  the  thrifty.  He  was, 
on  the  whole,  the  discreet  and  sagacious  sup- 
porter of  the  enterprising  trader  and  adventurous 
man  of  commerce.  His  promises  to  pay  gold 
on  demand  were  readily  accepted  within  his  dis- 
trict as  a  convenient  medium  of  exchange. 
There  was  no  state  bank,  no  corporation  with 
exclusive  privileges.  In  this  way,  from  the 
end  of  the  I7th  century,  there  grew  up  through- 
out the  country  substantial  private  copartneries 
conducting  the  business  of  banking  and  serving 
the  important  purpose  of  promoting  industry 
and  thrift.  At  this  time  the  currency  doctor 
had  not  yet  appeared,  and  the  subtle  suggestion 
had  not  yet  been  made  that  a  one -pound 
note,  convertible  into  gold  on  demand,  might 
be  of  less  value  than  the  coin  it  represented 
and  for  which  it  could  at  any  moment  be  ex- 
changed. 

The  range,  however,  of  banking  credit  enjoyed 
by  these  substantial  copartneries  was  naturally 
limited  to  the  districts  in  which  they  were 
known,  and  when  facilities  of  communication 
and  of  transit  were  increased  and  the  scale  of 
commercial  transactions  became  enlarged,  it 
became  obvious  that  banking  institutions  of 
more  commanding  importance  and  more  widely 
recognised  stability  were  required  to  take  the 
place  of  the  old  local  private  banks.  The  three 
old  banks  in  EdinlDurgh — the  Bank  of  Scotland, 
Royal  Bank  of  Scotland,  and  British  Linen 
Company — had  not  yet  seriously  set  themselves 
to  serve  the  country  districts.  A  new  chapter 
was  accordingly  opened  early  in  the  1 9th  century 
when  joint-stock  banks  were  formed,  having 
their  headquarters  in  Edinburgh,  Glasgow,  and 
some  of  the  other  more  important  towns,  with 
numerous  branches  throughout  the  provinces. 
This  proved  to  be  the  knell  of  the  private 
banks,  for  by  degrees  these  ancient  institutions, 
being  free  to  transfer  themselves  in  their  in- 
tegrity, were  merged  in  the  more  powerful  joint- 
stock  banks,  and  the  system  of  banking  as  a 
whole  became  adapted  to  the  enlarged  opera- 
tions of  commerce. 

The  movement  thus  described  involved, 
among  other  consequences,  a  reduction  in  the 
number  of  banks  in  Scotland.  In  1819  there 
were  36  ;  in  1844,  24  ;  in  1873,  11  ;  in  191:? 
there  were  8.  All  possess  the  power  of  circula- 
tion, the  limit  to  each  of  authorised  note  issue 
is  as  follows  : — 


Name  of  Bank. 

Amonnt  of 
authorised 
Circulation. 

1  Bank  of  Scotland       .... 

2  Royal  Bank  of  Scotland     . 

3  British  LineTi  Company     . 

4  Commercial  Bank  of  Scotland,  Ltd. 

5  National  Bank  of  Scotland,  Ltd.       . 
,     6  Union  Bank  of  Scotland,  Ltd. 

7  North   of  Scotland   and   Town  and 

County  Bank,  Ltd. 

8  Clydesdale  Banking  Company,  Ltd. 

Total     . 

£396,852 
216,451 
438,024 
374,880 
297,024 
454,346 

224,452 
274,321 

i;2,076,350 

The  average  circulation  of  these  banks, 
allowed  by  the  Acts  of  1844-45  to  exceed  the 
authoiiised  limit  (see  Bank  Note),  was,  col- 
lectively, £7,784,185  in  1913,  their  deposits 
about  £127,000,000. 

The  development  of  banking  in  Scotland 
was  gi-catly  assisted  by  the  provisions  of  the 
law,  which  placed  no  limit  on  the  number  of 
partners,  and  allowed  security  to  be  taken  on 
land,  all  being  registered,  as  well  as  on  other 
descriptions  of  a  debtor's  property,  with  great 
facility.  The  private  fortune  of  every  partner 
was  also  liable  for  all  the  debts  of  the  bank 
except  in  the  case  of  the  Bank  of  Scotland  and 
the  two  chartered  banks.  The  effect  of  this  last 
provision  has  been  restricted  by  the  application 
of  the  limited  liability  acts,  but  the  sy.stem  of 
banking  thus  established,  assisted  by  the  power 
of  circulating  small  notes,  has  extended  itself 
over  Scotland  with  great  completeness.  Hardly 
any  village  is  without  the  advantage  of  banking 
facilities,  provided  by  numerous  branch  offices. 
The  early  history  of  the  Bank  of  Dundee  may 
be  taken  as  typical  of  the  growth  of  Scotch 
banking.  Originally  instituted,  1764,  as  a  bank 
of  issue,  it  was  not  till  1792  that  deposits  were 
received  by  it,  and  these  were  for  some  time 
hardly  equal  in  amount  to  the  note  circulation. 
A  similar  system  was  no  doubt  the  origin  of 
banking  in  the  United  Kingdom  generally. 
Though  the  branch  offices  of  the  Scotch  banks 
are  numerous,  the  banks  themselves,  as  stated 
above,  are  few  in  number.  Amalgamation  for 
the  most  part,  failure  in  some  conspicuous  and 
terrible  instances,  account  for  the  diminution. 
The  credit  of  the  remaining  banks  has  never 
been  shaken.  The  deposits,  21  millions  in 
1826,  were  30  millions  in  1851.  Since  that 
date  the  gi'owth  has  been  most  rapid.  Includ- 
ing capital,  the  resources  Avere  63  millions  in 
1866,  92  in  1872,  and  nearly  158  millions 
in  1913.  The  old  practice  of  the  banks  in 
Scotland  of  making  advances  on  Cash  Credit 
{q.'o.),  that  is  on  the  personal  security  of  two 
bondsmen,  tended  to  develop  the  energies  of 
the  country  facilitated  by  the  thriftiness  of  the 
people.  The  system  of  note  circulation  in 
Scotland  (see  Bank  Note)  has  been  of  great 
assistance  to  the  banks  in  many  ways,  and  has 
provided  the  banks  with  "till  money  "free  of 


96 


BANKS,  UJ^JTED  KINGDOM 


cost.  Through  its  existence  the  early  prosperity 
of  the  banking  system  of  the  country  was 
developed  and  fostered  ;  it  has  caused  great 
economy  in  the  use  of  specie,  and  also  it  has 
facilitated  book-keeping  by  removing  the  necess- 
ity for  the  use  of  small  cheques  in  many  direc* 
tions.  The  vast  network  of  branch  offices,  the 
working  of  which,  as  previously  mentioned,  is 
facilitated  by  the  use  of  small  notes,  is  also  of 
great  service  to  the  business.  In  those  districts 
which  are  poor,  and  where  deposits  are  scanty, 
the  advances  of  capital  required  for  the  develop- 
ment of  business  are  easily  provided  from  the 
resources  which  the  wealthier  districts  supply. 
The  small  number  of  banks  in  Scotland,  however, 
is  sometimes  made  the  subject  of  complaints. 
The  habits  of  the  people,  which  lead  them  to 
prefer  notes  to  specie  in  their  daily  transactions, 
coupled  with  the  other  advantages  which  the 
possession  of  a  note  circulation  gives,  have 
practically  restricted  banking  in  Scotland  to 
banks  of  issue,  and  as  no  addition  to  the  number 
of  issuing  banks  has  been  possible  since  Peel's 
acts  of  1844-45,  the  existing  banks  have  such 
a  hold  of  the  field  that  no  increase  has  been 
made  since  that  time.  The  rates  of  discount 
for  advances,  and  those  for  the  allowance  of 
interest  on  deposit  are  settled  by  agreement 
among  the  banks  ;  hence  they  are  practically 
uniform  over  the  whole  of  the  country.  While 
complaints  as  to  the  monopoly  of  the  existing 
banks  are  thus  heard  from  time  to  time,  it  does 
not  appear  probable  either  that  the  rates  of 
interest  charged,  or  allowed,  would  differ  much, 
if  at  all,  from  those  which  have  been  the  rule 
in  Scotland  under  existing  circumstances,  if  the 
freest  competition  were  established.  Nor  is  it 
at  aU  likely  that  any  one  to  whom  an  advance 
may  safely  be  made  is  prevented  from  obtaining 
such  an  advance  through  the  limitation  of  the 
number  of  the  banks.  Hence  the  public  may 
not  gain  wherever  such  competition  is  started  ; 
on  the  other  hand  competition,  in  the  direction 
of  making  advances  on  insufficient  security,  or 
to  those  who  employ  them  in  rash  speculation, 
is  one  of  the  most  disastrous  things  which  can 
happen. 

Two  bank  failures  in  Scotland  during  recent 
years  have  been  on  a  scale  so  large  as  to  deserve 
special  notice.  The  aggregate  loss  of  the  share- 
holders of  the  Western  Bank  of  Scotland,  failed 
1857,  was  upwards  of  £2,800,000.  The  failure 
of  the  City  of  Glasgow  Bank  in  1878  involved 
its  shareholders  in  a  loss  of  about  £6,000,000. 
In  neither  case  were  the  general  public  losers 
(see  Banks,  Chaeterkd  ;  Cash  Credit). 

Banking  in  Ireland  has  been  conducted 
generally  on  the  same  principles  as  in  Scotland, 
and  hence  requires  no  detailed  notice.  One 
point,  however,  to  the  great  credit  of  the  Irish 
ijanks,  deserves  commemoration,  namely,  that  at 
the  present  time  of  writing  (1913)  every  bank 
of  issue  in  Ireland  which  was  in  existence  in  1844 


is  still  carrying  oil  business.  The  stability 
which  this  indicates  has. not  occurred  in  either 
England  or  Scotland.  'The.  exceptions  to  the 
general  prosperity  wei?e  the  stoppage  of  the 
Tipperary  Joint-Stock  Bank  (1856),  and  of  the 
Munster  Bank  (18.86),-  since  replaced  by  the 
Munster  and  Leinster  Bank,  Limited.  This 
general  soundness  of  recent  banking  in  Ireland 
may  well  be  contrasted  with  its  laxity,  fre- 
quently involving  consequent  failure,  at  an 
earlier  date.  At  the  commencement  of  this 
century,  Ireland  was  overspread  with  a  number 
of  small  and  principally  very  ill-managed  banks, 
each  carrying  on  its  affairs  within  a  narrow 
circle,  and  in  a  most  irregular  and  unsound 
manner.  The  appendix  to  a  parliamentary 
report  (Report  of  the  House  of  Commons 
Committee  on  circulating  Paper,  Specie,  and 
Current  Coin  in  Ireland,  1804)  contains  a  list  of 
the  names  of  fifty  firms,  all  believed  to  be 
engaged  in  the  business  at  that  time.  Others 
who  issued  notes  for  small  amounts  from  3^d.  to 
6s.  each,  who  had  really  no  pretensions  to  be 
called  bankers  at  all,  undertook  similar  re- 
sponsibilities. By  the  year  1820,  however, 
only  six  of  the  banks  were  left,  the  numbers 
having  been  reduced  principally  by  failures. 
The  over-issue  of  notes  had  led  to  great  distress. 
The  want  of  confidence  resulting  from  the  fre- 
quent failures  was  general,  and  even  the  notes 
of  the  Bank  of  Ireland  were  for  a  time  un- 
negotiable.  The  act  of  1820  which  permitted 
the  establishment  of  joint-stock  banks,  gradu- 
ally led  to  the  sounder  state  of  affairs  mentioned 
above,  but  it  was  not  till  the  amending  acts  of 
1824-25  allowed  persons  resident  in  any  part 
of  Great  Britain  or  Ireland  to  become  share- 
holders in  these  banks  that  their  success  be- 
came established,  as  the  previous  exclusion  of 
English  and  Scotch  capitalists  had  greatly  re- 
tarded their  welfare  (see  History  of  Banking  in 
Ireland  by  Mr.  Dillon).  The  experience  of 
Ireland  in  banking  matters  has  been  very 
chequered,  the  injury  caused  by  the  earlier  and 
unsound  banks  having  been  very  considerable, 
while  the  assistance  given  in  recent  times  by 
the  existing  banks  to  the  general  prosperity, 
has  been  equally  marked.  It  only  remains  to 
mention  the  Bank  of  Ireland.  This  bank  was 
originally  projected  1695,  but  the  plan  was  not 
carried  Qut  then  ;  it  was  also  rejected  by  the 
Irish  House  of  Commons  1721,  and  it  was  more 
than  half  a  century  afterwards,  1783,  that  the 
bank  was  established.  It  has  been  prudently 
and  successfully  conducted  to  the  present  date. 
The  Suspension  of  Cash  Payments,  1797, 
extended  to  Ireland,  and  a  very  considerable 
expansion  of  the  note  circulation — over-issue  it 
might  more  properly  be  termed — followed. 
This,  however,  was  soon  reduced  after  the  re- 
turn to  cash  payments. 

Considerable  privileges  were  granted  to  the 
Bank  of  Ireland — after  1820  no  bank  with  more 


BANKS,  FRANCE 


9> 


than  six  partners  was  allowed  to  issue  notes 
within  a  radius  of  fifty  (Irish)  miles  from 
Dublin.  After  1845  this  restriction  was  re- 
moved, and  the  arrangements  as  to  the  circula- 
tion of  notes  practically  assimilated  to  those  in 
force  in  Scotland  (see  Bank  Note).  There  are 
nine  banks  in  Ireland,  of  tliese  six  possess  the 
power  of  circulation. 


Name  of  Bank. 

Amount  of 
authorised 
Circulation. 

1  Bank  of  Ireland 

2  Provincial  Bank  of  Irel.ind 
8  Belfast  Bankin.i;  Company 

4  Northern  Banking  Company      , 

5  Ulster  Bank 

6  The  National  Bank     .... 

Total      . 

£3,738,428 
927,667 
281,611 
243,44U 
811,079 
852,269 

£0,354,494 

The  average  circulation  of  these  banks, 
allowed  by  the  Acts  of  1844-45  to  exceed  the 
authorised  limit  (see  Bank  Note),  was,  col- 
lectively, £8,074,000  in  1913.  The  Hibernian 
Bank,  Limited,  the  Munster  and  Leinster, 
Limited,  the  Royal  Bank  of  Ireland,  Limited, 
have  no  issues.  The  total  resources  of  the  nine 
banks  were  nearly  £91,000,000  in  1913. 

India  and  the  British  Colonies.  British 
India,  our  colonies  generally,  and  the  Australian 
colonies  in  particular,  possess  well -developed 
banking  systems.  These  do  not,  however, 
possess  features  calling  for  special  notice  from 
an  economic  ])oint  of  view,  except  that  with 
other  very  similar  associations  these  Colonial 
banks,  whose  deposits  collectively  were,  in 
1913,  about  £797,000,000,  have  been,  to  a 
large  extent,  the  conduit  pipes  through  which 
British  capital  has  been  ditfused  thi-oughout 
the  colonies.  Their  rapid  development  may 
be  cited  as  one  of  the  advantages  hence 
resulting. 

France.  The  Bank  of  France,  the  most  im- 
portant banking  institution  in  the  country,  was 
founded  in  1800  as  a  private  company,  and 
received  the  basis  of  its  permanent  constitution, 
which  made  it  practically  a  state  bank,  through 
the  law  of  24  Germinal  An.  xi.  of  the  First 
Republic  (14th  April  1803).  The  law  of  22d 
April  1806  reconstituted  the  bank,  which  is  now 
regulated  by  the  law  of  1897.  The  governor, 
who  holds  his  office  for  life,  and  the  two  deputy- 
governors,  are  appointed  by  the  state.  The 
general  council,  consisting  of  fifteen  regents, 
by  whom  the  business  is  mainly  directed,  and 
three  censors,  who  may  be  regarded  as  a  per- 
manent committee  of  audit,  are  elected  by  the 
general  assembly,  which  consists  of  the  200 
largest  shareholders.  Of  the  regents,  five  must 
be  chosen  from  among  the  manufacturers, 
itraders,  and  merchants  (manufacturiers,  fahri- 
^eamiSf  ou  commergants)  who  are  shareholders  in 
the  bank,  and  three  selected  from  amongst  the 
trisoriets-payeurs  gdn&rav^,  the  treasury  agents 
VOL.  I. 


in  the  provinces.  Thus  the  government  is 
strongly  represented  on  the  managing  body. 
The  governor  has  to  watch  that  "the  bank  per- 
forms its  duty  to  the  state  and  towards  the 
commerce  and  industry  of  the  country"  (evidence 
given  by  M.  Rouland,  then  governor,  before  the 
Enquite  sur  les  princi2Jes  et  les  fails  g6neraux 
qui  r4gissent  la  circulation  monktaire  et  fiduci- 
aire,  Paris,  1865,  which  see).  The  governor  of 
the  Bank  of  France  has  usually  been  a  man  who 
has  held  a  high  official  position.  Thus  M. 
Rouland  had  been  a  senator,  a  minister,  and 
president  of  the  council  of  state  ;  M.  Denor- 
mandie,  another  governor,  was  a  senator  for  life ; 
and  had  M.  Leon  Say,  whose  name  was  freely 
spoken  of  at  a  recent  vacancy,  and  who  has 
been  minister  of  finance,  besides  serving  in  other 
high  positions — for  example,  as  ambassador  in 
England — been  appointed,  it  would  not  have 
been  felt  that  this  would  have  been  a  lowering 
of  his  official  standing.  The  regents  and  censors 
represent  the  commerce  and  trade  of  the  country, 
to  which,  as  well  as  to  the  state,  the  bank  has  ren- 
der id  great  services.  Ithas(1913)  143  branches 
situated  in  the  different  departments  of  France ; 
besides  this  about  439  places  are,  through 
auxiliary  offices  and  other  similar  arrangements 
provided  with  banking  facilities  ;  there  are  also 
a  certain  number  of  district  offices  in  Paris. 
The  rules  of  the  bank  with  respect  to  its  dis- 
counts are  somewhat  strict,  three  signatures 
being  required,  or  a  deposit  of  security  to  take 
tlie  place  of  the  third  name,  but  the  wisdom  of 
the  rules  has  been  justified  by  the  results. 
Thus,  with  a  discount  in  round  numbers  of 
30,000,000  bills  in  1913  for  an  amount  of  over 
£800,000,000,  a  very  small  number  remained 
practically  overdue,  and  of  these  the  greater 
part  were  sound.  The  part  the  bank  occupies 
in  the  general  business  of  the  country  is  shown 
by  these  figures,  and  as  more  than  4,500,000 
of  the  bills  taken  at  Paris  alone  did  not  exceed 
£4  in  value,  retail  as  well  as  larger  trade  shares 
in  the  advantage.  Business  in  France  is, 
however,  not  connected  so  intimately  with 
banking  as  in  England.  Thus  the  note  circu- 
lation of  the  Bank  of  France,  sometimes  220 
millions  sterling,  never  now  below  200  millions, 
represents  a  business  turnover  which  would  be 
conducted  principally  by  cheques  in  England. 
The  Bank  of  France,  however,  endeavours  to 
extend  the  use  of  cheques  among  its  customers. 
Through  the  Bureau  de  Virements  it  performs 
the  functions  of  the  Clearing  House  (which 
see),  and  it  likewise  facilitates  the  transmission 
of  money  between  the  towns  in  which  the 
branches  are  situated  and  the  head  office.  The 
Bank  of  France  endeavours  to  keep  an  even  rate 
•of  discount  with  as  few  alterations  as  possible, 
as  it  considers  a  tolerable  degree  of  certainty 
in  the  charge  for  the  use  of  money  to  be,  as 
is  undoubtedly  the  case,  of  service  to  trade. 
Thus  for  about  twelve  years,  between  1901  and 


98 


BANKS,  FRANCE 


1913,  there  were  8  changes  in  its  rate  of  dis- 
count varying  from  3  to  4  per  cent,  while  there 
were  61  changes  varying  from  2^  to  7  per  cent 
at  the  Bank  of  England  during  the  same  time. 
The  rate  charged  is  uniform  at  Paris  and  the 
branches,  both  for  discounts  and  advances, 'the 
fatter  being  from  |^  to  1  per  cent  above  the  dis- 
count rate.  These  rates  are  invariable,  and  no 
addition  is  made  for  commission  or  otherwise. 
Of  the  total,  productive,  operations  of  the 
Dank,  in  1913  about  1628  millions  sterling, 
much  originates  at  the  branches.  At  some 
of  these,  particularly  at  Bordeaux,  Lyons, 
Marseilles,  Havre,  and  Lille,  the  transactions 
are  large.  Some  of  the  smaller  offices,  how- 
ever, occasionally  do  not  pay  their  expenses, 
and  the  cost  exceeded  the  profits  at  3  in  1910. 
This  fortunate  position  of  affairs  has  not  always 
been  maintained,  but  the  deficiencies  have 
been  comparatively  small.  The  Bank  of 
France  is  at  liberty  to  pay  its  notes  and  dis- 
charge its  obligations  either  in  gold  or  in  silver 
of  legal  tender,  that  is,  in  silver  pieces  of  5 
francs.  It  is  argued  that  this  facility  assists 
it  to  maintain  a  comparatively  even  rate  of  dis- 
count, even  in  the  face  of  a  movement  in  the 
foreign  exchanges  favourable  to  an  export  of 
gold,  as  it  is  absolutely  at  liberty  to  give  or 
withhold  gold  so  long  as  it  has  silver  with 
which  it  can  cash  its  notes.  This  argument 
can  hardly  be  proved  or  disproved  statistically. 
As  a  matter  of  fact  the  number  of  alterations  in 
the  rate  of  the  Bank  of  France  has  been  fewer 
since  the  year  1844  than  at  either  the  Bank  of 
England  or  at  the  Bank  of  Germany.  The 
rate  of  discount  has  been  on  average  less 
than  at  the  Bank  of  England  during  the  last 
seventy  years,  taken  as  a  whole  (see  Table, 
Bank  of  England),  and  it  has  recently  tended 
to  be  much  lower.  In  making  these  observa- 
tions, however,  the  great  difference  between  the 
condition  of  circumstances  in  the  countries  con- 
cerned should  be  borne  in  mind.  Besides  assist- 
ing commerce  and  the  general  prosperity  of 
France,  the  Bank  of  France  has  more  than  once 
in  its  history  had  to  support  the  weight  of  very 
serious  troubles,  the  proper  handling  of  which 
exceeded  in  difficulty  almost  any  ordinary 
financial  crisis.  Without  going  farther  back 
than  the  last  forty  years,  specie  payments  have 
been  suspended  twice  owing  to  political  disturb- 
ances— in  1848  and  again  in  1870.  The  earlier 
of  these  suspensions,  which  lasted  only  about  a 
year  and  a  half,  does  not  appear  to  have  had 
any  marked  effect  on  prices.  The  later  one, 
which  was  accompanied  by  the  devastation 
ensuing  on  the  Franco-German  "War,  lasted  about 
five  years,  specie  payments,  suspended  in  1870, 
having  been  partially  resumed  in  1874  and  com- 
pletely in  1875.  A  suspension  of  specie  pay- 
ments may  naturally  be  expected  to  produce  the 
ordinary  result  of  inflation,  shown  in  the  foreign 
exchanges  and  in  the  price  of  commodities.    But 


the  course  which  the  Bank  of  France  took  in 
regulating  its  issue  of  notes,  which  became  the 
circulating  medium  and  were  inconvertible,  was 
so  prudent  and  cautious  that  few,  if  any,  of  the 
dangerous  results  of  a  forced  circulation  of  paper 
followed.  There  was,  during  the  course  of  this 
time,  a  slight,  but  not  large  variation  from  the 
normal  rate  of  the  foreign  exchanges,  exemplified 
in  the  rate  between  Paris  and  London  on  several 
occasions,  but  it  was  slight,  and  if  any  alter- 
ation in  the  prices  of  commodities  followed  it 
was  only  small  in  extent.  Great  caution  and 
prudence  must  have  been  needed  to  carry  on  the 
monetary  affairs  of  a  large  country  under  such 
trying  circumstances  without  involving  it  in  the 
risks  which  usually  follow  on  a  forced  circulation. 

The  following  figures  will  give  some  idea  of 
the  ordinary  business  transactions  of  the  Bank 
of  France : — 
1913.  Aggregate  of  operations    .  £1,528,000,000 

„      Bullion  held— Gold .         .      £140,000,000 
„        Silver         .        £25,500,000 

, ,      Bills  discounted  in  Paris  and 

branches      .         .         .      £800,000,000 

„       Average  note  circulation  .       £226,600,000 

„  „         current  accounts  £25,600,000 

Besides  the  Bank  of  France,  there  are  many 
other  large  banks  in  the  country,  as  the  Comp- 
toir  d'Escompte,  founded  1848,  the  Credit 
Foncier,  and  Credit  Mobilier,  1852,  the  Credit 
Lyonnais,  1863,  the  Societe  Generale,  1864, 
besides  others,  and  many  very  wealthy  and 
powerful  private  firms  who  carry  on  the  practice 
of  banking  and  the  traditions  of  the  Haute 
BaTujue,  which  rather  corresponds  to  the  busi- 
ness of  wealthy  merchants  and  high  financial 
operators  with  us.  The  idea  of  banking,  as 
carried  on  in  this  country,  in  the  United  States, 
and  in  several  of  our  colonies,  notably  in  the 
Australias,  is,  however,  gradually  gaining  ground 
in  France,  and  further  developments  in  that 
direction  may  be  expected. 

Germany.  The  Imperial  Bank  of  Germany 
occupies  now  quite  as  commanding  a  position 
in  that  country  as  the  Bank  of  France  does 
within  its  own  sphere  of  labours  and,  with  the 
other  powerful  banks  surrounding  it,  has 
assisted  greatly  the  prosperity  of  the  Empire. 
The  present  constitution  of  the  bank  of 
Germany  is  defined  by  the  Bank  Act  of  1875, 
by  which  the  Bank  of  Prussia  was  merged  in 
the  Imperial  Bank,  and  amended  by  the  acts  of 
1889,  1899,  1901,  1902, 1906, 1909(see  Annual 
Reports  in  Bankers  Magaziiu).  In  arrange- 
ments for  accounts,  in  number  of  offices, — 
488  in  1913, — in  closeness  of  relations  with 
the  government,  the  working  of  the  Bank  of 
Germany  corresponds  very  much  with  that 
of  the  Bank  of  France.  There  is,  however, 
an  important  difference  in  respect  of  the  note 
circulation  (see  Bank  Note),  to  which,  as  the 
arrangements  are  dissimilar  both  from  those 
in  England  and  in  France,  it  is  desirable  to 


BANKS,  GERMANY 


99 


refer.  The  Bank  of  Germany  is  permitted  to 
add  to  its  circulation  against  securities  the 
issue  of  any  other  issuing  bank  whose  circula- 
tion drops,  and  also  to  exceed  the  legal  limit, 
at  first  (1875)  by  £12,500,000,  extended  1899 
to  £22,500,000,  1902  to  £23,500,000,  1906  to 
£23,641,450  by  lapse  of  issue  of  the  Bank  of 
Brunswick,  1909  to  £27,500,000  and  at  the 
end  of  each  quarter  £37,500,000,  on  payment 
of  a  tax  of  5  ]^er  cent  per  annum  on  the  total 
excess  issue.  The  limit  was  exceeded  nineteen 
times  in  1913,  the  rate  of  discount  not  rising 
above  6  per  cent.  Those  who  have  experienced 
the  effect  of  the  suspension  of  the  Bank  Act 
of  1844  in  England,  see  in  the  smoothness 
with  which  this  arrangement  acts  a  sign  of  a 
corresponding  absence  of  pressure  on  business 
of  great  advantage  to  the  industry  of  Germany, 
and  though  the  different  circumstances  of 
business  there  do  not  admit  of  an  exact  com- 
parison with  England,  the  question  deserves 
more  attention  than  is  given  it.  The  Bank  of 
Germany  is  a  "state  bank."  The  distribution 
of  the  profits  (laws  of  1875,  1889,  1899, 
1909)  is  as  follows  :  3^  per  cent  on  the  capital 
(£9,000,000)  to  the  shareholders;  of  the  re- 
mainder, the  State  receives  three-quarters  and 
the  shareholders  one-quarter,  after  deducting 
from  these  two  portions  10  per  cent  {i.e.  half 
10  per  cent  from  each  portion)  to  be  assigned 
to  the  Reserve  (£3,723,963  in  1913).  Thus 
the  shareholders  received  in  1913  £758,750, 
or  a  dividend  of  8*43  per  cent,  and  the 
state  £1,551,025  in  addition  to  the  Note 
Tax  £183,715.  The  capital  £6,000,000  in 
1900  was  raised  to  £9,000,000  in  1905.  The 
German  em]»eror  appoints  the  president  and 
council  of  the  bank  directory,  whose  office 
is  for  life,  on  the  recommendation  of  the 
federal  council,  and  the  Government,  through 
the  Chancellor  of  the  empire,  exercises  com- 
plete powers  of  control.  The  shareholders 
influence  the  management  through  a  com- 
mittee. As  with  the  Bank  of  France,  the 
arrangements  as  to  rates  of  interest  are 
uniform  over  the  whole  field  of  operation, 
and  the  facilities  given  by  this,  and  by  the 
action  of  the  bank  in  the  discount  of  commercial 
paper,  as  well  as  by  the  transmission  of  cash, 
etc.,  have  given  a  great  impetus  to  the  prosperity 
of  the  empire.  There  are  many  other  banks  in 
Germany  besides  the  Imperial  Bank,  four  of 
which  issue  notes.  This  privilege  has  been 
relinquished  by  many  banks  once  possessing 
it,  owing  to  the  restrictions  imposed  on 
banks  of  issue,  which  may  not  buy  and 
sell  securities  for  delivery,  either  for  their 
own  or  for  third  account,  nor  may  they  accept 
any  bills  nor  (1913)  in  some  conditions  discount 
below  the  Reichs-bank.  The  business  of  the 
non-issuing  banks  in  Germany,  besides  ordinary 
account  current  transactions,  consists  in  dis- 
counts, buying  and  selling  securities,  granting 


advances  to  customers  and  also  in  negotiating 
loans  for  governments  as  Avell  as  private  under- 
takings, a  business  which  in  this  country  is 
more  in  the  hands  of  private  bankers  and 
finance  companies.  The  banks  also  hold  large 
deposits  ;  yet  this  branch  does  not  attain  the 
same  proportionate  dimensions  as  in  Great 
Britain,  the  amount  of  uninvested  capital  being 
smaller  ;  and  as  interest  is  allowed  on  almost 
all  balances,  even  if  repayable  on  demand,  the 
profit  from  this  source  cannot  compare  with 
the  results  obtained  in  this  country. 

The  limits  of  space  forbid  detailed  reference 
to  several  other  banking  systems  both  in  Europe 
and  elsewhere,  but  among  these  the  Swedish 
Enskilda  Banks  may  specially  be  referred  to  as 
possessing  a  very  skilfully  planned  note  circula- 
tion, the  usefulness  of  which  compares  favour- 
ably with  the  systems  of  circulation  in  Scotland 
and  the  United  States.  The  system  on  which 
the  national  banks  of  the  United  States, 
established  1863,  were  originally  based,  was 
connected  with  the  financial  measm-es  necessi- 
tated by  the  terrible  struggle  between  "North" 
and  "South"  which  inflicted  such  heavy  losses 
on  the  Union.  A  safe  circulating  medium  was 
urgently  required,  and  Secretary  Chase  recom- 
mended an  issue  of  bank  notes,  secured  by  de- 
posit of  United  States  bonds  worked  by  local 
banks,  in  preference  to  the  issue  of  notes  by  the 
Government  itself  (see  Bank  Note  ;  Banks, 
National,  United  States  of  America). 

[See  Reports,  Covimittee  of  Secrecy  on  Bank  oj 
England  Charter,  H.  of  C.  1^2,2.— Select  Com- 
mittee on  Banks  of  Issue,  H.  of  C.  1840.  —  First 
and  Second  Reports  Select  Covimittee  on  Banks  oJ 
Issue,  H.  of  C.  1841. — First  and  Second  Ptcports 
Secret  Committee  on  Commercial  Distress,  H.  of  C. 
1848. — Report  Select  Committee  on  Bank  Acts,  H. 
of  C.  1857. — Report  Select  Committee  on  Bank 
Acts,  H.  of  C.  1858. — Report  Select  Committee  on 
Banks  of  Issiie,  H.  of  C.  1875.  —  Report  from 
Secret  Committee  of  the  House  of  Lords  on  the 
Causes  of  the  Distress  which  has  for  some  time 
prevailed  among  the  Commercial  Classes,  and  hoio 
far  it  had  been  affected  hy  the  Laws  for  regulating 
the  Issue  of  Bank  Notes  payable  on  demand, 
Session  1847-48.  (The  information  contained  in 
the  evidence  and  report  especially  valuable.) — 
Practical  Treatise  on  Banking. — Logicof  Banking, 
J.  W.  Gilbart  (title  characteristic  of  the  author). 
— History  and  Principles  of  Banking,  J.  W. 
Gilbart,  London,  1866.  —  The  Country  Banker, 
George  Rae,  London,  1886,  and  later  editions. — 
Notes  on  Banking,  R.  H.  Inglis  Palgrave,  London, 
1873. — British  Banking  Statistics,  John  Dun, 
London.  1876. — Capital,  Currency,  and  Banking, 
James  Wilson,  London,  1847. — Lombard  Street, 
W.  Bagehot,  London,  \B:'iZ,l'dlO— History  of  the 
Bank  of  England,  John  Francis,  London,  1847. — 
'The  First  Nine  Years  of  the  Bank  of  England, 
J.  E.  Thorold  Rogers,  Oxford,  1887.— TAe  Scotch 
Banks  and  System  of  Issue,  Robert  Somers, 
Edinburgh,  1873. — History  of  Scotch  Banking^ 
A.  W.  Kerr,  1884. — History  and  Development  oJ 


100 


BANKS,  CHARTERED— BANKS,  CANADA 


Banking  in  Ireland,  Malcolm  Dillon,  London  and 
Dublin,  1889. — English  Manual  of  Banking,  A. 
Crump,  London,  1877. — Principles  of  Banking, 
Thomson  Hankey,  London,  1867. — Practical  Bank- 
ing. A.  S.  Bolles,  New  York,  l^M.—Bank  Rate, 
England,  France,  and  Germany,  E.  H.  Inglis  Pg,l- 
grave,  London,  1903. — History,  Law,  and  Practice 
of  Banking,  C.  M.  Collins,  London,  1887.— TAe 
Practice  of  Banking,  John  Hutchison,  London, 
1883.  —  Bankers'  Magazine,  London.  —  Jov/mal 
Institute  of  Bankers,  London. — American  Bankers' 
Magazine,  New  York. — Dictionnaire  des  Finances, 
Paris,  1889. — Chapters  on  the  Theory  and  History 
of  Banking,  C.  F.  Dunbar,  New  York,  1891.] 

BANKS,  Chartered  (Scotland).  1. 
The  Bank  of  Scotland  ;  founded  by  Scots  act 
of  parliament  17th  July  1695,  not  by  charter, 
though  frequently  called  one  of  the  chartered 
banks  ;  a  monopoly  of  banking  for  twenty-one 
years  from  1695  ;  a  capital  of  £100,000  sterling, 
since  raised  to  £1,987,000  (£1,325,000  called 
up),  with  power  to  issue  £2,625,000  additional 
stock.  2.  The  Royal  Bank  of  Scotland  ;  first 
charter  31st  May  1727  in  pursuance  of  the  im- 
perial statute,  5  Geo.  I.  c.  20  ;  eighth,  30th 
December  1829  ;  capital  £2,000,000,  fully  paid 
up  ;  it  is  questionable  how  far  a  provision  in  the 
original  charter  of  1727  that  each  share  of  £100 
is  liable  in  five  farther  calls  of  £10  each  is  applic- 
able to  present  shareholders.  3.  The  British  Linen 
Company ;  charter  6th  July  1746  as  linen  traders 
and  manufacturers ;  banking  business  developed  ; 
charter  1806  (5th  June)  as  bankers,  capital 
£200,000  ;  last  charter  19th  March  1849,  au- 
thorised capital  £1,500, 000,  whereof  £1,250, 000 
issued  and  fully  paid  up.  The  above  three  are 
known  as  the  chartered  banks ;  they  claim 
limited  liability  (see  Company  for  purposes  of 
charter).  The  National  and  the  Commercial 
Banks  have  also  charters  ;  the  former  1825,  the 
latter  1831  (bank  founded  1810);  in  both 
charters  liability  stated  to  be  unlimited.  See 
Mr.  Fleming's  "Memorandum  as  to  Banking  in 
Scotland,"  Select  Committee  on  Banks  of  Issue, 
1875,  reprinted  in  Henry  Robertson's  Handbook 
of  Bankers'  Law  (Scotch).  The  three  oldest. 
Bank  of  Scotland,  British  Linen  Company,  and 
Royal  Bank,  have  always  had  or  claimed  a 
strictly  limited  liability  :  the  two  named  above, 
in  common  with  the  remaining  three  Scotch 
banks,  the  Clydesdale,  North  of  Scotland  and 
Town  and  County,  and  Union,  have  been 
recently  registered  as  limited  liability  companies, 
and  now  use  the  word  "  Limited."  a.  d. 

BANKS,  CANADA.  The  history  of  currency 
and  banking  in  Canada  may  be  divided  into  four 
periods :  (1)  the  French  regime  ;— (2)  from 
beginning  of  British  government  until  establish- 
ment of  first  banks  in  1817-18  ;— (3)  from 
1817-18  until  confederation  of  provinces,  1867, 
banks  being  organised  under  provincial  and 
royal  charters ; — (4)  since  1867,  the  Dominion 
parliament  having  exclusive  jurisdiction  regard- 
ing banking. 


A  complete  account  of  the  first  period,  during 
part  of  which  beaver  and  moose  skins  were  recog- 
nised currency,  wheat  a  legal  tender,  and  the 
''card  money"  of  the  French  governors  formed 
the  chief  medium ;  and  the  second  period  when  the 
coins  of  five  other  countries  were  legal  tender,  will 
be  found  in  the  writings  of  Mr.  James  Stevenson 
referred  to  below.  During  the  second  period  un- 
successful attempts  were  made  in  1 7  9  2  and  1807-8 
to  establish  banks,  and  in  consequence  during 
the  war  of  1812  government  was  obliged  to  create 
an  army-bill  ofiice  or  temporary  bank  of  issue. 

From  1817  to  1825,  however,  two  banks 
were  established  in  Lower  Canada  (Quebec)  and 
one  each  in  Upper  Canada  (Ontario),  New 
Brunswick,  and  Nova  Scotia,  all  now  doing 
business  except  one.  During  the  rebellion  of 
1837-38  the  banks  in  Upper  and  Lower  Canada 
temporarily  suspended  specie  payments  under 
permission  of  an  order  in  council. 

Before  dealing  with  the  fourth  period  it  is 
necessary  to  indicate  the  condition  of  banking 
and  currency  at  time  of  confederation,  1867. 
There  were  thirty-nine  charters,  but  only  twenty- 
seven  banks  doing  business.  The  charters  ex- 
pired at  various  dates  from  1870  to  1892  and 
varied  in  accordance  with  views  regarding  bank- 
ing in  the  different  provinces.  In  Upper  and 
Lower  Canada  (Old  Canada)  shareholders  were 
liable  for  double  amount  of  stock,  except  that 
there  was  one  bank  en  commandite,  the  "prin- 
cipal partners  "  having  unlimited  personal  lia- 
bility. In  most  cases  notes  could  be  issued 
equal  to  paid-up  capital  plus  specie,  and 
government  securities  held.  In  New  Brunswick 
charters  had  been  granted  without  double  lia- 
bility but  the  principle  was  being  insisted  on  in 
renewals,  while  in  Nova  Scotia  in  the  opinion 
of  some  there  was  no  double  liability.  In  Old 
Canada  and  Nova  Scotia  as  a  rule  total  lia- 
bilities were  restricted  to  three  times,  and  in 
New  Brunswick  to  twice  the  amount  of  capital. 
There  was  also  one  bank  with  a  royal  charter, 
head  office  in  England,  and  shareholders  not 
under  double  liability.  The  situation  was 
further  complicated  by  the  "Free  Banking  Act," 
under  which  notes  could  be  issued  secured  by 
deposit  of  government  debentures,  and  by  the 
legal  tender  issues  of  the  governments  of  Old 
Canada  and  Nova  Scotia.  In  1866-67  two  of 
the  largest  banks  in  Upper  Canada  failed, 
resulting  in  a  very  severe  financial  crisis. 

Under  these  conditions,  and  after  tentative 
legislation  in  1867  and  1870,  the  first  general 
bank  act  of  the  Dominion  was  passed  in  1871 
(34  Vict.  c.  V.)  It  confirmed  the  special 
features  in  the  bank  working  under  royal 
charter,  and  that  with  "principal  partners" 
personally  liable,  and  it  will  be  understood  in 
any  statements  hereafter  regarding  banks  as  a 
whole  that  these  institutions  are  not  referred  to. 
As  the  charters  of  other  banks  expired  they 
were  renewed  under  the  Dominion  Act.     Tho 


BANKS,  CANADA 


101 


first  act  extended  all  charters  ten  years,  which 
practice  has  been  followed  thus  far.  There 
were  various  amendments  during  the  first  few 
years,  but  since  then  changes  have  been 
infrequent,  except  at  the  regular  revisions  in 
1880  and  1890.  The  act  hereafter  referred  to 
is  that  assented  to  May  1890,  and  to  come  in 
force  July  1891  (53  Vict.  c.  xxxi.) 

Constitution  and  Powers  of  Banks. — Banking 
in  Canada  is  not  absolutely  fi-ee  as  in  the 
United  States.  A  charter  must  be  obtained  by 
application  to  parliament,  and  this  of  course 
could  be  refused.  Practically,  however,  bank- 
ing cannot  well  become  a  monopoly.  The 
minimum  subscribed  capital  permitted  is 
$500,000  (say  £100,000),  of  which  $250,000 
(£50,000),  must  be  paid  in,  and  the  fact  assured 
by  the  money  being  deposited  temporarily  in 
the  finance  department,  after  which,  on  com- 
pliance with  other  important  requirements, 
the  treasury  board  will  issue  permission  to  do 
business.  Shares  are  held  subject  to  what  is 
known  as  double  liability,  i.e.  in  the  event  of 
the  bank's  assets  being  insufficient  to  pay  its 
debts,  a  shareholder  is  liable  for  the  deficiency 
to  the  extent  of  an  amount  equal  to  the  par 
value  of  his  shares,  in  addition  to  any  amount 
unpaid  on  such  shares.  Shareholders  do  not 
escape  the  double  liability  by  transfer,  unless  a 
period  of  sixty  days  has  elaj)sed  before  sus- 
pension. There  are  elaborate  regulations  as  to 
the  constitution  and  duties  of  the  board  of 
directors,  which  cannot  be  fully  explained  here. 
Directors  become  personally  responcible  if  divi- 
dends are  declared  impairing  the  capital,  and 
no  division  of  profits  in  any  shape  exceeding 
8  per  cent  per  annum  is  permitted,  unless 
the  reserve  fund  or  rest  equals  35  per  cent 
of  the  paid-up  capital.  The  act  prescribes 
the  form  in  which  the  directors'  annual  report 
to  shareholders  shall  be  made,  and  requires 
most  comprehensive  monthly  returns  to  the 
finance  department,  which  are  printed  and  dis- 
cussed in  the  leading  newspapers.  The  finance 
minister  may  call  for  special  returns  from  any 
bank  at  any  time.  A  list  of  shareholders  in  all 
banks,  with  their  holdings,  is  published  by  the 
government  annually.  A  return  of  all  divi- 
dends and  balances  unclaimed  for  five  years  is 
required  annually,  and  in  the  event  of  a  bank's 
insolvency  such  amounts  must  be  paid  over  to 
government  to  be  held  for  owners.  The 
statute  of  limitations  does  not  run  as  against 
depositors  in  favour  of  banks.  There  are 
numerous  provisions  as  to  a  bank's  power  to 
take  securities  for  loans.  Banks  may  not  lend 
upon  security  of  real  estate.  The  act  abounds 
mth  heavy  penalties  for  breach  of  its  provisions. 

Note  Issues. — In  the  successive  banking  acts 
of  the  Dominion  parliament  banks  have  been 
empowered  to  issue  circulating  notes  to  the  ex- 
tent of  the  unimpaired  paid-up  capital.  By 
the  first  act  the  noteholders  had  no  greater 


security  than  other  creditors.  At  the  renewal 
of  charters  (1880)  the  circulating  note  was 
made  a  prior  lien  upon  all  assets  ;  and  at  the 
last  renewal  the  banks,  at  their  own  suggestion, 
are  in  addition  required  to  create  in  two  years 
a  guarantee  fund  of  5  per  cent  upon  their 
circulation,  to  be  kept  unimpaired,  the  annual 
contribution,  however,  if  fund  is  depleted,  to 
be  limited  to  1  per  cent.  The  fund  is  to  be 
used  whenever  the  liquidator  of  a  failed  bank 
is  unable  to  redeem  note  issues  in  full  after  a 
lapse  of  sixty  days.  Notes  of  insolvent  banks 
are  to  bear  6  per  cent  interest  from  date  of  sus- 
pension, until  liquidator  announces  his  ability 
to  redeem.  Banks  are  also  required  to  make 
arrangements  for  the  redemption  at  par  of  their 
notes  in  every  part  of  the  dominion.  The 
change  in  1880  was  caused  by  the  failure  of  a 
small  bank  with  a  circulation  of  about  §125,000 
(say  £25,000),  paying  all  creditors  only  57^ 
per  cent.  The  Bank  Act  of  1906  with  the 
amendments  of  1908  was  due  to  the  demand 
lor  a  currency  which  will  pass  over  the  entire 
dominion  without  discount  under  any  circum- 
stances. The  history  of  banking  in  Canada 
since  confederation  shows  no  instance  in  which 
depletion  of  the  guarantee  fund  would  have 
occurred.  Fines  from  $1000  (£200)  to  $100, 000 
(£20,000)  may  be  imposed  for  over-issue  of 
notes.  The  pledging  of  notes  as  security  for  a 
debt,  or  the  fraudulent  issue  of  notes  in  any 
shape,  renders  all  parties  participating  liable  to 
fine  and  imprisonment.  As  the  crown  preroga- 
tive to  payment  in  priority  to  other  creditors  had 
been  set  up  on  behalf  of  both  dominion  and 
provincial  governments,  the  act  places  the  claims 
of  the  Dominion  second  to  the  note  issues,  and 
those  of  the  provinces  third.  Notes  of  lesser 
denomination  than  $5  (£1)  may  not  be  issued, 
and  all  notes  must  be  multiples  of  $5  (£1). 
Notes  smaller  than  $5  are  issued  by  the 
Dominion  government.  With  a  Circulation 
Redemption  Fund,  Dec.  31,  1912,  of  $6,410, 103 
(£1,282,000),  and  capital  paid  $114,881,914 
(£23,000,000),  tlie  banks  had  in  circulation  only 
$110,048,357  (£22,000,000).  Besides  these 
assets,  the  double  liability  of  shareholders  gives 
a  further  considerable  security.  The  circulation 
expands  and  again  contracts  during  three  months 
in  each  year,  greatly  owing  to  the  products  of 
Canada  being  still  mainly  of  the  forest  and 
field.  This  fact,  and  the  necessity  for  till 
money  without  cost  at  the  branches,  have 
caused  Canadian  bankers  to  steadily  oppose  a 
currency  secured  by  special  deposit  of  securities. 
During  the  period  since  confederation  the  banks 
have  provided  a  currency  readily  convertible 
into  specie,  the  volume  rising  and  falling  with 
requirements  of  trade,  and  this,  apart  from 
legal  tender  notes  of  the  Dominion,  is  almost 
the  only  class  of  money  in  constant  use.  The 
amount  of  Dominion  notes  (legal  tenders) 
held  by  the  banks  in  March  1909,  was  about 


102 


BANKS,  CANADA— BANKS,  UNITED  STATES 


$670,000,000  (£13,400,000)  and  the  actual 
specie  held  was  £5,361,000.  The  deposits 
held  by  the  banks  were  £140,300,000. 

Beserves. — No  reserves  are  actually  required 
by  law.  The  cash  reserve  in  gold  and  legal 
tenders  has  averaged  for  some  years  abouf  10 
per  cent.  Till  money  is  almost  entirely  sup- 
plied by  the  note  circulation.  The  smaller 
banks  keep  their  available  reserve  in  deposits 
with  the  leading  banks  in  Montreal.  The 
larger  banks  have  their  immediately  available 
reserves  largely  in  security  loans  in  New  York 
and  Chicago.  Forty  per  cent  of  whatever 
cash  reserve  a  bank  may  choose  to  keep  must 
be  in  Dominion  legal  tenders,  a  provision  en- 
tirely in  the  interest  of  the  government. 

Branch  System. — Perhaps  because  the  first 
bankers  in  Canada  were  to  a  great  extent  Eng- 
lish and  Scotch,  the  branch  system  has  become 
so  firmly  established  that  there  are  no  banks 
without  branches.  Altogether  there  are  nearly 
3000  bank  offices,  including  181  city  branches 
in  Toronto,  administered  by  twenty-six  banks, 
the  largest  number  by  any  one  bank  being 
372,  two  others  having  340  and  311.  These 
three  have  branches  from  Halifax  on  the 
Atlantic  to  Vancouver  on  the  Pacific,  a  dis- 
tance of  about  3500  miles.  Any  town  of  1 0  0  0  or 
1500  people  may  thus  have  a  bank  of  deposit  and 
discount  of  high  standing,  and  administered  by 
a  trained  bank  officer.  Slowgoing  communities 
where  deposits  accumulate  thus  provide  the 
means  of  satisfying  the  wants  of  new  and  enter- 
prising localities,  where  the  demand  for  money 
is  out  of  all  proportion  to  local  supply.  As  a 
result  of  this  economy  in  the  distribution  of 
capital,  and  the  advantages  arising  from  till 
money  without  cost,  and  the  profits  of  circula- 
tion, rates  of  interest  in  Canada  are  as  low  or 
lower  than  in  any  country  except  the  three  or 
four  leading  nations  of  the  world,  and  Canadian 
banks  cannot  go  to  Great  Britain  for  deposits  as 
other  colonial  banks  do,  because  they  cannot 
afibrd  the  rates  paid  by  other  banks.  The  pro- 
portion of  deposits  to  capital  is  still  so  small 
(only  two  to  one)  that  branch  banking  could 
not  have  reached  its  present  comparatively 
perfect  development,  but  for  the  note  issues  not 
being  specially  secured.  It  has  been  argued 
that  if  this  power  was  taken  away  or  replaced 
by  a  specially  secured  issue,  perhaps  one-half 
of  the  branches  would  have  to  be  closed. 

The  growth  of  banking  in  Canada,  1856  and 
1860  being  for  Old  Canada  alone. 


Year. 

Capital  paid-up. 

1856 

$13,700,000,  say  £2,740,000 

1860 

24,400,000  „   4,880,000 

1870 

32,000,000  „   6,400,000 

1880 

60,500,000  „  12,100,000 

1890 

59,500,000  „  11,900,000 

1900 

65,154,000  „  12,030,000 

1910 

99,676,093  „  20,000,000 

1912 

114,881,914  „  23,000,000 

Year. 

Note  Issues. 

1856 

$10,500,000,  say  £2,100,000 

1860 

9,700,000  „   1,940,000 

1870 

14,100,000  „   2,820,000 

1880 

20,100,000  „   4,020,000 

1890 

32,000,000  „   6,400,000 

1900 

46,574,780  „   9,315,000 

1910 

87,694,840  „  17,639,000 

1912 

110,048,357  „  22,000,000 

Year. 

Deposits. 

1856 

$8,600,000,  say  £1,720,000 

1860 

15,900,000  „   3,180,000 

1870 

50,700,000  „  10,140,000 

1880 

84,800,000  „  16,960,000 

1890 

136,200,000  „  27,240,000 

1900 

356,394,095  „  71,279,000 

1910 

895,706,276  „  179,140,000 

1912 

1,099,468,700  „  220,000,000 

The  total  deposits  in  chartered  banks,  post  office  and 
government  savings  banks,  Montreal  and  Quebec 
savings  banks,  and  real  estate  loan  companies, 
was  30th  June  1887,  $183,756,329  (£36,751,266), 
in  1912  about  $1,200,000,000  (£240,000,000). 
The  currency  of  Canada  was  declared  by  34  Vict, 
c.  iv.,  to  be  dollars,  cents,  and  mills,  similar  to 
that  of  the  United  States,  and  British  sovereigns 
to  be  legal  tender  at  $4.86§.  United  States  gold 
coins  of  $5  and  over  are  legal  tender.  A  branch 
of  the  Royal,  Mint  is  established  at  Ottawa. 

[Trans.  Literary  and  Historical  Society,  Quebec, 
Stevenson  (1874-75, 1875-77).— Statutes,  orders  in 
council,  gazettes  of  provinces  before  confederation. 
— Dominion  of  Canada  Gazette,  1908,  acts  respect 
ing  Banks  with  current  accounts,  Banking,  Insolvent 
Banks,  Currency,  Dominion  Notes,  Savings  Banks 
(Prov.  of  Quebec),  Post  Office. — Statistical  Record, 
Canada. — Garland,  Banks,  Bankers,  and  Banking 
in  Canada,  1890.  Sir  E.  Walker,  A  History  of 
Banking  in  Canada,  1909.]  b.  e.  w. 

BANKS,  National  (United  States  of 
America),  were  established  by  an  act  of  1863, 
revised  1864,  and  amended  by  later  legislation. 
The  essential  features  of  the  system  are  the  issue 
of  bank  notes  by  local  banks  under  national 
supervision,  the  deposit  of  United  States  bonds 
as  security  for  all  notes  issued,  and  the  limitation 
of  the  right  of  issue  to  the  national  banks.  The 
act  was  adopted,  after  repeated  recommenda- 
tion by  Secretary  Chase,  as  one  of  the  leading 
financial  measures  of  the  civil  war  of  1861-65, 
partly  as  affording  a  market  for  the  large  mass 
of  bonds  required  by  the  banks  for  deposit 
under  this  plan,  but  chiefly  as  a  provision  for 
reforming  the  paper  currency  after  the  return 
of  peace.  The  direct  issue  of  legal  tender 
notes  by  the  United  States  treasury,  which 
had  begun  early  in  1862,  was  regarded  as  a 
temporary  expedient,  and  the  withdrawal  of 
the  notes  and  restoration  of  specie  payments 
after  the  close  of  the  war  appeared  not  improb- 
able. The  national  banks  would  then  supply 
a  convertible  currency,  amply  secured,  of  uniform 
value  throughout  the  Union,  and  there  could 
be  no  revival  of  the  vicious  systems  of  issue 
under  local  authority  from  which  the  country 
had  suffered  deeply.     It  was  also  an  advantage 


BANKS,  UNITED  STATES— BANKS,  EARLY  EUROPEAN 


103 


that  in  every  state  the  banks  of  issue,  having 
their  capital  invested  in  United  States  bonds, 
would  find  their  interests  identified  with  those 
of  the  union.  Part  of  these  advantages  were 
lost  by  the  delay  in  returning  to  specie  pay- 
ments (1879),  the  final  recognition  of  the  legal 
tender  notes  as  a  permanent  currency,  and  the 
temporary  decline  of  the  national  bank  circula- 
tion. The  adoption  of  the  system,  however, 
gave  the  United  States  a  large  class  of  banks  in 
high  credit,  which  have  been  of  the  utmost  ser- 
vice to  them.  They  carried  on  business  under 
strict  regulations  as  to  making  advances,  and 
were  required  by  law  to  hold  a  minimum  reserve 
in  specie  and  legal  tender  notes  against  deposits 
to  the  amount  of  25%  in  the  case  of  city,  and 
15%  in  the  case  of  country  banks.  In  case  of 
insolvency,  shareholders  were  liable  to  an  amount 
equal  to  the  face  value  of  their  shares.  The  banks 
were  required  to  publish  their  accounts  five  times 
a  year,  and  were  under  the  official  inspection  of 
the  Comptroller  of  the  Currency  who  had  power 
to  enforce  all  regulations.  Under  this  system 
the  national  banks  became  the  strongest  class  of 
banks  in  the  country,  and  grew  ra]ndly.  In  1 864 
there  were  139  banks,  with  capital  814,000,000 
(£2,800,000) ;  in  Augustl913,  7488;  capitaland 
surplus  $1,782,000,000  (£356,000,000);  total 
resources,  §10,877,000,000  (£2,175,000,000). 

In  addition  to  these  the  state  banks,  private 
banks,  and  trust  and  loan  companies,  under 
varying  degrees  of  official  supervision,  grew  up. 
These  were  18.520  in  1913,  with  a  total  ca[>ital 
of  $1,039,930,000  (£207,986,000);  surplus, 
$956,000,000  (£191,200,000);  and  deposits, 
$11,522,000,000  (£2,304,400,000). 

A  feeling  that  the  system  of  national  and 
state  banks  was  inadequate  was  brought  to  a 
head  by  the  crisis  of  1907.  A  searching  inquiry 
resulted  in  the  Federal  Reserve  Act,  1913,  the 
main  points  of  which  are  as  follows  : — The 
country  is  divided  into  not  less  than  eight  or 
more  than  twelve  Federal  Reserve  Districts, 
in  each  of  which  a  Reserve  City  is  chosen  ;  in 
this  a  Reserve  Bank  is  established  with  capital 
of  not  less  than  $4,000,000  (£800,000),  sub- 
scribed by  National  and  such  other  banks  as 
choose  to  be  *'  member  "  banks.  If  the  amounts 
subscribed  are  insufficient,  the  public  may  con- 
tribute amounts  of  not  more  than  £5000,  the 
balance  to  be  made  up  by  the  government. 
Reserve  Banks  may  issue  notes  to  "member" 
banks  to  such  an  amount  that  the  Reserve  Bank 
holds  a  gold  reserve  of  40%  against  them.  It 
may  exceed  this  amount  for  short  periods  by 
paying  a  graduated  fine  to  government  and 
when  authorized  by  the  Federal  Reserve  Board. 
They  may  discount  any  bills  enclosed  by  any 
of  its  "member"  banks  except  those  drawn  to 
carry  on  trade  in  stocks  or  bonds  other  than 
those  of  the  government,  to  an  amount  not 
exceeding  in  the  aggregate  half  its  capital  and 
surplus,  and  may  fix  the  rates  of  discount  to  be 


charged  for  each  class  of  paper.  They  may 
deal  in  government  bonds,  coin,  and  bullion,  and 
transact  all  business  usual  to  banks,  such  as 
establishing  foreign  agencies  and  discounting 
foreign  commercial  paper.  The  banks  are  con- 
trolled by  a  Federal  Reserve  Board  composed  of 
the  Secretary  to  the  Treasury,  the  Comptroller 
of  the  Currency,  and  five  members  appointed 
by  the  President  with  the  approval  of  Congress, 
who  are  carefully  guarded  from  undue  outside 
infiuences.  Their  powers  are  very  wide,  and 
include  the  right  to  require  any  Reserve  Banks 
to  rediscount  the  discounted  paper  of  any  other 
Reserve  Banks  at  rates  fixed  by  itself,  to  sus- 
pend reserve  requirements  specified  in  the  act 
for  limited  periods,  to  add  to  the  central  reserve 
cities,  and  to  enforce  the  act  generally.  It  is 
assisted  by  a  Federal  Advisory  Council  composed 
of  one  elected  member  from  each  Reserve  Dis- 
trict. "Member"  banks  not  in  a  reserve  city 
hold  reserves  equal  to  12%  of  demand  deposits 
and  5%  of  time  deposits,  five-twelfths  to  be  in 
the  Federal  Reserve  Bank.  Banks  in  reserve 
cities  hold  reserves  equal  to  15%  of  demand 
deposits,  5%  of  time  deposits,  one-third  to  be  in 
its  own  vaults,  two-fifths  in  the  Reserve  Bank. 
Banks  in  central  reserve  cities  hold  18%  of 
demand  deposits,  5%  of  time  deposits,  one-third 
to  be  in  its  own  vaults  and  seven-eighteenths  in 
the  Reserve  Bank.  Reserve  Bank  Stock  bears 
6%  cumulative  interest,  surplus  to  be  divided 
equally  between  Reserve  and  the  government, 
the  latter  to  be  applied  to  redemption  of  Public 
Debt  or  to  a  government  gold  reserve  ;  when 
the  reserve  exceeds  40%  of  total  paid-up  Capital 
Stock  of  the  Reserve  Bank  the  whole  surplus 
goes  to  the  State. 

[For  account  of  United  States  banking  down  to 
the  Civil  War,  see  Rept.  of  Comptroller  of  Cur- 
rency, 1876,  pp.  6  and  83-123.]  c.  F.  D. 

BANKS,  Early  EuROi'EAy.  Banks  founded 
in  early  times  in  Europe  carried  on  a  rather  dif- 
ferent business  than  that  known  now  as  banking. 
The  Bank  of  Venice  is  traced  by  Anderson, 
Origin  of  Commerce,  vol.  i.  p.  156,  to  the  forced 
loans  raised  by  the  republic  (1156,  1480,  1510), 
the  transfer  of  stock  and  the  payment  of  interest 
taking  place  at  a  public  office,  which  was  sub- 
sequently made  a  deposit  bank  ;  but  Lattes  and 
Ferrara  state  that,  though  the  stock,  by  its 
transfer,  became  an  important  medium  of  ex- 
change, deposit  banking  in  Venice  was  thoroughly 
established  by  private  bankers  in  the  14th  cen- 
tury, and  the  first  public  bank,  the  Banco  di 
Rialto,  was  opened  by  decree  of  the  senate  in 
1587,  after  frequent  failures  of  private  banks. 
In  1619  the  Banco  del  Giro,  known  as  the  Bank 
of  Venice,  was  established  (see  Lattes,  Liherta 
delle  Banche  a  Venezia,  p.  183),  like  its  prede- 
cessor, without  capital,  purely  as  a  bank  of  de- 
posit, under  the  management  of  public  officers. 
It  received  funds  for  the  state  and  for  indi- 
viduals,   making  a   small  charge  for  holding 


104 


BANKS,  EARLY  EUROPEAN 


private  deposits  ;  transfers  were  made  upon  the 
books  by  the  order  of  depositors  ;  bills  of  ex- 
change were  paid  by  such  transfers  ;  and  the 
tender  of  payment  in  bank  for  any  sum  not  less 
than  100  ducats  could  not  be  refused.  It 
became  an  important  aid  to  commerce,  and  was 
long  famous  throughout  Europe.  As  it  was  not 
properly  a  lender,  the  bank  should  never  have 
had  less  bullion  than  the  amount  of  its  deposits ; 
but  loans  to  the  government  compelled  it  to 
suspend  payment  more  than  once,  and  with 
some  loss  of  credit.  It  kept  its  accounts  in 
ducats  banco,  which  had  no  corresponding  coin, 
but  were  credited  or  redeemed  by  the  bank,  as 
might  be  required,  at  an  advance  of  20  per  cent 
above  the  ducat  effetivo  of  the  mint.  Whatever 
the  origin  of  this  difference  or  agio,  it  seems  finally 
to  have  represented  a  mere  difference  of  denomi- 
nation, as  if  the  Bank  of  England  were  now  to 
keep  its  accounts  in  guineas,  using  the  current 
coin  in  all  receipts  and  payments.  The  Bank  of 
Venice  declined  with  the  republic,  and  fell,  after 
the  invasion  by  the  French,  1797.  It  is  an  indi- 
cation of  the  financial  skill  of  the  managers  of  this 
bank  that  they  were  able  in  1766  to  reduce  "the 
interest  of  their  funds  to  4  p6r  cent,  at  the  same 
time  offering  payment  of  their  principal  to  those 
who  were  unwilling  to  accept  that  rate  of  in- 
terest "  (Macpherson,  Annals  of  Commerce,  vol. 
iii.  p.  444).  Banking  institutions  are  mentioned 
by  CiBRARio  as  having  existed  in  Genoa  in  the 
12th  century.  The  Bank  of  St.  George,  which 
dates  from  1407,  a  bank  of  circulation  and  de- 
posit, was  the  financial  centre  of  the  republic, 
and  carried  on  all  the  transactions  in  the  public 
funds  of  the  state.  Andeeson  (vol.  i.  p.  319) 
says  that  in  1345  Genoa  had  "run  so  con- 
siderably into  debt  to  her  own  citizens  that  in 
this  year  four  of  them  were  elected  to  make 
provision  for  those  debts,  and  for  the  current 
service  of  the  year,"  and  that  in  order  to  pay 
the  interest  on  the  debts  of  the  state  the  customs 
were  assigned  to  it.  The  council  of  the  bank 
were  one  hundred,  and  the  governors  eight  in 
number,  "  managing  their  stock  prudently,  and 
having  many  rich  men  concerned  with  them, 
they  afterwards  supplied  the  further  necessities 
of  the  republic ;  and,  for  that  end,  had  at  length 
most  of  the  cities  and  territories  of  Genoa 
pawned,  or  rather  sold  to  them,"  .  .  .  and 
(p.  414)  "In  proportion  as  the  wants  of  the 
republic  increased,  so  did  the  credit  of  this 
house  or  bank,  by  having  still  more  bonds, 
rents,  and  important  dominions  assigned  to  it," 
The  power  of  the  Bank  of  St.  George  increased, 
so  that,  according  to  De  Mailly,  there  was  ' '  seen 
in  the  same  city  two  independent  sovereignties." 
The  appropriation  of  its  property  by  the  Aus- 
trians,  1740,  and  by  the  French  in  1800,  de- 
stroyed its  credit,  which  till  then  had  remained 
unimpaired.  The  Bank  of  Sweden,  founded, 
1656,  by  a  Swede  named  Palmstruck,  claims 
to  have  been  the  first  established  on  modern 


principles  as  a  bank  which  issued  notes  payable 
to  bearer  at  sight.  The  first  bank-note  was 
issued  1658.  An  "enquete"  made  by  the 
French  government  in  1729  declares  the  bank- 
note to  be  an  admirable  Swedish  invention, 
designed  to  facilitate  commerce  (Palgrave,  Notes 
on  Banking,  p.  87).  This  bank  became  the 
Riks  bank  (Bank  of  Sweden)  1688  ;  it  still 
carries  on  business  in  Stockholm,  and  has  always 
been  national  property.  The  Bank  of  Amster- 
dam, founded  1609,  was  established  for  a  different 
purpose,  namely,  to  provide  a  common  and  per- 
manently steady  currency  in  which  the  foreign 
bills  of  exchange  domiciled  there  might  be  paid, 
without  the  loss  and  inconvenience  caused  by 
a  fluctuating  currency.  The  establishineut  of 
this  bank  is  described  by  A.  Smith  {Wealth 
of  Nations,  bk.  iv.  ch.  iii.)  "  Before  1609  the 
great  quantity  of  dipt  and  worn  foreign  coin 
which  the  extensive  trade  of  Amsterdam  brought 
from  all  parts  of  Europe,  reduced  the  value  of 
its  currency  about  9  per  cent  below  that  of  good 
money  fresh  from  the  mint.  Such  money  no 
sooner  appeared  than  it  was  melted  down  or 
carried  away,  as  it  always  is  in  such  circum- 
stances. The  merchants,  with  plenty  of  cur- 
rency, could  pot  always  find  a  sufficient  quantity 
of  good  money  to  pay  their  bills  of  exchange  ; 
and  the  value  of  those  bills,  in  spite  of  general 
regulations  which  were  made  to  prevent  it, 
became  in  a  great  measure  uncertain.  "In 
order  to  remedy  these  inconveniences,  a  bank 
was  established  in  1609  under  the  guarantee  of 
the  city.  This  bank  received  both  foreign  coin 
and  the  light  and  worn  coin  of  the  country 
at  its  real  intrinsic  value  in  the  good  standard 
money  of  the  country,  deducting  only  so  much 
as  was  necessary  for  defraying  the  expense  of 
coinage,  and  the  other  necessary  expense  of 
management.  For  the  value  which  remained, 
after  this  small  deduction  was  made,  it  gave  a 
credit  in  its  books.  This  credit  was  called 
bank  money,  which,  as  it  represented  money 
exactly  according  to  the  standard  of  the  mint, 
was  always  of  the  same  real  value,  and  intrinsic- 
ally worth  more  than  current  money."  Pay- 
ments were  made  in  transfers  of  "bank  money," 
which  were  equivalent  to  cheques.  For  the 
last  century  of  its  existence  the  bank  adopted 
the  method,  also  described  by  Smith,  of  making 
advances  in  bank  money  upon  the  pledge  of 
coin  or  bullion  deposited,  the  owner  paying 
interest  for  the  advance  and  receiving  a  rdcepisse 
to  enable  him  to  withdraw  the  pledged  metal 
upon  making  repayment.  This  system,  which 
has  been  much  misunderstood  (as  by  M'CuUoch 
in  his  edition  of  the  Wealth  of  Nations,  p.  215), 
superseded  the  earlier  practice  of  simple  deposit, 
but  appears  to  have  equally  answered  the  pur- 
pose for  which  the  bank  existed.  The  l)ank 
of  Amsterdam  rendered  great  services  to  com- 
merce for  more  than  two  hundred  years,  but 
during  the  French  occupation  at  the  close  of 


BANKS,  EARLY  EUROPEAN 


106 


the  18th  century  it  was  found  that  the  bank 
had  advanced  very  large  amounts  to  the  pro- 
vinces of  Holland  and  West  Friesland,  the 
Dutch  East  India  Company,  and  the  city  of 
Amsterdam.  The  bank  then  became  virtually 
insolvent,  but  the  city  finally  paid  the  holders 
of  bank  money  some  time  before  1802.  At- 
tempts were  made  to  revive  the  bank,  which 
languished  until  1820,  when  it  was  at  last 
closed. 

The  Bank  of  Hamburg  was  established 
1619,  for  similar  reasons  to  that  of  Amsterdam. 
To  the  prosperity  of  the  trade  of  Hamburg, 
the  most  vigorous  oflshoot  of  the  once  powerful 
Hanseatic  League  {q.v.),  the  bank  of  that 
city  largely  contributed.  It  carried  on  its 
business  under  the  protection  of  the  state,  and 
was  a  place  of  deposit,  or  warehouse  of  the 
precious  metals — principally  uncoined  silver. 
Silver  in  bars  was  the  true  foundation  of  the 
bank's  stock,  coined  silver,  gold,  and  to  a  small 
extent  copper  were  merely  received  as  pledges 
with  a  margin.  The  "mark  banco,"  or  money 
of  account,  represented  the  59^  part  of  a  metri- 
cal pound  of  fine  silver.  Any  quantity  of  fine 
silver  was  received  by  the  bank,  and  credit 
given  for  it  at  the  rate  of  59-J  mark  banco  for 
one  pound  of  fine  silver,  1  per  mill  {\  per  cent) 
being  charged  to  the  person  who  sold  the  silver 
to  the  bank.  Accounts  could  only  be  opened 
by  a  Hamburg  citizen  or  corporation.  In  order 
to  avoid  any  risk  of  loss,  no  silver  was  received 
under  the  fineness  of  ^VuV'  ^^^  every  bar  had 
to  be  assayed  by  a  sworn  assayer  (  Wardcin)  in 
the  service  of  the  bank.  In  this  manner  the 
payments  to  be  made  were  merely  transfers  from 
one  account  to  another  by  persons  who  kept  an 
account  at  the  bank.  To  transact  their  business 
they  had  either  to  appear  personally  or  to  be 
represented  by  an  attorney.  The  person  who 
appeared,  whether  the  owner  of  the  account  or 
the  attorney,  had  to  hand  over  the  check,  which 
may  more  properly  be  described  as  the  order  for 
transfer,  Avith  a  printed  signature  personally  to 
the  bank.  One  list  for  all  the  separate  sums 
dealt  with  was  handed  in.  Besides  the  business 
based  on  bar  silver,  the  Hamburg  bank  also 
advanced  bank  money  against  silver  coins,  and 
in  a  more  restricted  way  on  gold,  under  careful 
regulations  and  for  a  limited  time  only.  These 
loans,  however,  could  be  renewed.  The  pledge 
itself  could  only  be  taken  out  by  the  person 
who  took  money  for  it,  or  by  another  one  to 
whom  it  was  formally  transferred  (Palgrave, 
Notes  on  Banking,  p.  116).  The  Bank  of 
Hamburg  continued  to  do  business  on  these 
principles  for  many  years.  Modern  methods  of 
account,  however,  were  gi-adually  introduced. 
On  15th  February  1873  the  old  system  of  a 
bank  cuiTency  based  on  uncoined  silver  came 
to  an  end.  The  German  currency  was  em- 
ployed ;  the  development  of  the  Bank  of 
Gei-many,  and  an  establishment  of  a  branch 


of  that  bank  in  Hamburg,  together  with  the 
alteration  in  the  currency  of  Qennany  from  a 
silver  to  a  gold  basis,  rendered  the  continuance 
of  the  Bank  of  Hamburg  no  longer  necessary, 
and  its  business  was  merged  in  that  of  the  Bank 
of  Germany.  The  bank  had  accumulated  a 
capital  of  about  1,000,000  marks,  or  £50,000 
besides  the  value  of  its  buildings.  The  latest 
reference  to  its  separate  existence  is  found  in 
the  transactions  of  the  senate  of  Haraburg  of 
the  13th  October  1875.  In  these,  following 
the  ancient  practice  of  the  free  city,  the  senate 
formally  communicates  to  the  burghers  its 
resolution  to  sell  the  buildings  of  the  "vener- 
able institution  which  had  performed  such  great 
services  to  German  trade "  to  the  Bank  of 
Germany  for  900,000  marks  (£45,000).  The 
actual  transfer  took  place  on  1st  January  1876. 
An  agreement  was  likewise  made  that  the  officers 
and  staff  of  the  bank  should  be  transferred  on 
a  similar  footing  to  that  which  they  had  previ- 
ously held  to  the  Bank  of  Germany — seven  being 
retained  while  five  were  pensioned  by  the  State, 
including  the  two  TFardeine  (assay  officers)  ; 
and  thus  the  bank  which  had  carried  on  business 
to  a  later  date  than  any  other  of  the  banks, 
established  on  what  may  be  termed  mediaeval 
principles  in  Europe,  closed  its  honourable 
and  useful  career.  Dr.  A.  Soetbef.r  published 
( Volkicirthsdmftlkhe  Vicrteljahrschrift,  1866- 
1867),  a  very  interesting  account  of  the  Bank  of 
Plamburg  {Die  Hamburger  Bank,  1619-1866), 
which  narrates  its  remarkable  histoiy.  The 
soundness  of  the  course  of  business  followed,  at 
all  events  from  1770  onwards,  was  exemplified  in 
the  strongest  manner  on  the  5th November  1813. 
When  on  this  date  the  French  took  possession 
of  the  bank  treasure,  7,506,956  niaik  6  schill- 
ing in  silver,  the  con-esponding  liabilities  were 
found  to  be  7,489,343  mark  12^  schill.  only. 
So  unbroken  was  the  confidence  in  the  institu- 
tion that  its  operations  were  hardly  inteiTupted 
even  by  this  shock  ;  the  removal  of  the  treasure 
by  the  French  continued  till  18th  April  1814. 
After  a  further  period  of  disturbance  the  freedom 
of  Hamburg  was  re-established  1st  June  1814. 
The  bank  immediately  resumed  business  and 
the  value  of  the  mark  banco  stood  as  before. 
The  tardy  reparation  in  the  form  of  an  inscrip- 
tion of  French  rente  of  500,000  fr.  (equal  to 
7  fr.  rente  for  every  100  mark  banco  taken 
away),  was  not  made  till  1816. 

This,  though  the  most  severe  ordeal  the  Bank 
of  Hamburg  had  to  pass  through,  has  not  been 
by  any  means  the  only  one.  There  was  a  severe 
crisis  in  1763,  another  in  1799,  caused  by 
violent  fluctuations  in  prices,  another  in  1857, 
arising  out  of  speculative  business,  the  last- 
named  being  only  allayed  by  a  loan  from  Vienna, 
first  of  ten  million  mark,  then  of  five  mOlion 
more  in  current  silver  (say  £1,125,000).  As 
not  unfrequently  occurs  in  panics,  the  know- 
ledge that  the  means  to  meet  liabilities  were  at 


106 


BANKS,  LAND 


hand  sufficed  to  calm  the  crisis,  the  identical 
coins  being,  as  Soetbeer  informs  us,  returned  to 
the  national  bank  at  Vienna  in  the  selfsame 
boxes  in  which  they  had  been  despatched.  This 
loan  was  guaranteed  by  the  senate  of  Hamburg. 
The  amount  of  indebtedness  liquidated  was  very 
large,  the  total  beingl44,586,000mark banco — 
(say  £10,844,000  reckoning  the  mark  banco  at 
Is.  6d.)  This  amount  is  made  up  by  the  commer- 
cial failures  m.b.  98  millions  (say  £7,350,000), 
the  sum,  collectively  m.b.  21  millions  (say 
£1,675,000),  dealt  with  by  the  three  Com- 
mittees to  which  the  State  delegated  authority 
to  grant  loans  on  bills,  merchandise,  and  other 
securities,  (1)  the  Belehnungs  Kommission,  m.b. 
8,153,000  (say  £611,475),  (2)  the  Staats  Dis- 
coTiis  Casse,  m.b.  3,029,549  (say  £227,215)  ;  (3) 
the  Vertrauens  Commission  for  the  first  Austrian 
loan,  m.b.  10,000,000  (£750,000);  and  the 
portfolios  of  the  two  joint-stock  banks  {Akticn 
Banken),  m.b.  25  millions  (£1,875,000).  The 
loss  which  resulted  to  the  state  was  compara- 
tively small,  being  about  187,000  ijiark  banco 
(say  £14,025),  and  to  the  two  joint -stock 
banks  200,000  mark  banco  (say  £15,000). 
That  on  the  98  millions  was  unknown  although 
no  doubt  this  figure  included  some  of  the 
engagements  represented  by  the  portfolios  of 
the  banks.  The  interposition  of  the  state  alone 
prevented  a  terrible  catastrophe. 

Nothing  could  be  more  sound  than  the  busi- 
ness of  such  a  bank  as  that  of  Hamburg, 
which  consists  under  ordinary  circumstances 
only  in  transferring  "value"  from  one  holder 
to  another.  The  experience  of  the  bank  shows 
that  when  severe  pressure  comes  on,  as  in  the 
crisis  of  1857,  the  support  of  the  government 
may  enable  these  limits  to  be  safely  exceeded 
for  a  time,  with  great  advantage  to  the  com- 
munity. Dr.  Soetbeer  supplies  statements 
which  show  the  rapidity  and  the  fluctuations  in 
the  operations  of  the  bank.  The  amount  held 
by  the  bank  was  turned  over  during  each  year 
from  1856  to  1866  as  follows : 


Average  rate 

Year. 

No.  of  Times. 

of  discount 
per  cent. 

1856 

115 

6i 

1857 

136 

6i 

1858 

38 

If 

1859 

59 

2 

1860 

68 

If 

1861 

88 

2t^ 

1862 

111 

3 

1863 

111 

3A 

1864 

135 

4fV 

1865 

118 

3i^ 

1866 

119 

m 

The  relation  shown  between  rapidity  of  turn- 
over and  rate  of  interest  is  very  remarkable. 
The  fact  that  this  is  the  case  has  been  noticed 
by  men  of  business,  who  would  hardly  have 


expected  so  exact  a  statistical  confirmation  of 
their  individual  observations. 

Similar  in  many  ways  to  the  Bank  of  Ham- 
burg was  the  Bank  of  Kottekdam  (est.  1635)  ; 
one  difference  appears  to  have  been  that  accounts 
were  allowed  to  be  kept,  either  in  ' '  bank  money  " 
to  meet  bills  drawn  foreign  on  Rotterdam,  or 
in  "current  money"  to  meet  bills  drawn  in 
Rotterdam  on  foreign  countries.  Anderson 
{Annals  of  Gomm,erce,  vol.  iii.  p.  384)  mentions 
another  point,  namely,  that  "  bills  of  exchange 
are  paid  in  large  money,  and  only  10  per  cent  in 
schellings."  The  Bank  of  Middelburg  (est. 
1616)  appears  to  have  practised  lending  upon 
securities  (Mees,  Bankwezen  in  Nederland,  p. 
231),  and  so  far  to  have  departed  from  the  usual 
type  of  deposit  bank.  With  this  exception  the 
scope  of  the  business  of  all  these  banks  appears 
to  have  been  much  the  same,  the  management, 
where  necessary,  as  at  Venice  and  Genoa,  of  the 
debts  of  the  state,  and,  further,  providing 
facilities  for  foreign  commerce.  Assistance  to 
local  industry  in  the  way  of  discounts  and 
making  advances  does  not  appear,  at  first,  to 
have  been,  at  all  events  prominently,  their 
original  occupation  and  intention. 

BANKS,  JjAND.  There  are  two  species  of 
advances  which  an  agriculturist  who  owns  the 
land  he  cultivates  may  require  :  (1)  to  increase 
the  working  capital  needed  to  carry  on  cultiva- 
tion, as  wages,  purchase  of  stock,  seed,  or 
manures ;  (2)  for  permanent  improvements  in  his 
property,  as  drainage,  irrigation,  or  farm  build- 
ings. The  return  for  the  first  should  take  place 
within  one,  or,  at  most,  a  very  few  years ;  for  the 
second  it  will  be  fully  realised  only  after  a  long 
period.  A  remarkable  development  in  banking 
institutions  to  give  assistance  of  this  kind  has 
taken  place  of  recent  years.  Land  Credit 
Associations  are  now  working  in  most  countries 
of  Europe,  in  the  British  Colonies,  North  and 
South  America,  Japan,  etc.  The  record  of  the 
work  of  these  societies  is  The  Monthly  Bulletin 
of  Economic  and  Social  Intelligence  issued  by 
the  International  Institute  of  Agriculture,  pub- 
lished in  Rome  at  the  office  of  the  Institute. 
See  also  H.  W.  Wolff",  Co-operative  Banking, 
1907  ;  Co-operative  Credit  Hand-book  1909 ; 
Peopy s  Banks,  1910  ;  Banker" s  Magazine  {Lou- 
don),  Jan.  1909,  Oct.  and  Dec.  1910. 

Germany.  Distinct  institutions  have  long 
existed  in  Germany  to  meet  the  demands  for 
these  two  species  of  advances. 

The  first  kind  are  supplied,  in  the  case  of 
large  proprietors,  by  ordinary  banks.  For 
small  proprietors  there  are  in  Germany,  besides 
ordinary  banks,  institutions  on  the  basis  of 
mutual  assurance.  Such  are  the  Raiffeisen 
loan  fund  societies,  particularly  for  small  land- 
owners in  rural  districts,  to  protect  them  from 
the  exactions  of  the  local  usurers.  These  render 
effectual  aid  to  the  cultivators,  lending  somewhat; 
larger  amounts  for  long  periods.     They  have 


BANKS,  LAND 


107 


had  marked  success  in  the  Rhine-province  of 
Prussia,  Westphalia,  and  Hesse-Darmstadt. 

For  permanent  agricultural  improvements 
large  sums  become  necessary,  and  loans  can 
only  be  repaid  gradually  during  an  extended 
term.  Germany  was  the  first  country  in  which 
special  systems  of  credit  for  long  periods  on  the 
security  of  landed  property  were  organised. 
The  oldest  institution  of  this  kind  originated 
in  Silesia  in  1769,  after  the  seven  years'  war, 
under  the  auspices  of  Frederick  the  Great,  who 
gave  it  a  subvention  from  the  state  of  300,000 
thalers  at  2  per  cent.  The  plan  was  due  to  a 
Berlin  merchant  named  Biiring.  The  object 
was  to  relieve  proprietors  who  were  overwhelmed 
with  debt,  having  suffered  severely  from  the 
war,  from  the  high  rate  of  interest  and  the  low 
prices  of  agricultural  produce.  Similar  establish- 
ments, known  as  Landschaftliche  Credit-vercine 
or  Landschaften,  were  afterwards  founded  in  the 
other  provinces  of  the  Prussian  monarchy,  in 
Wiirtemberg,  Mecklenburg,  Saxony,  and  most 
of  the  other  German  states,  and  continue  to  in- 
crease in  numbers.  They  are  voluntary  associa- 
tions of  landowners,  resting  on  the  principle 
of  joint  responsibility.  Any  proprietor  who 
borrows  from  an  association  becomes  a  member 
of  it.  The  security  for  the  advances  they  make 
to  their  members  is  the  movable  property  of 
the  borrower,  his  land  and  buildings.  The 
position  of  the  association  is  usually  that  of 
first  mortgagees.  The  associations  carry  on  their 
transactions  within  limited  areas  ;  and  this  en- 
ables them  to  adapt  their  operations  to  the 
wants  of  the  district,  and,  in  particular,  secures 
that  the  valuation  of  lands  pledged  for  advances 
shall  be  made  by  persons  thoroughly  acquainted 
with  local  conditions  and  possessing  the  con- 
fidence of  the  agricultural  community.  They 
lend  at  about  4  per  cent,  plus  a  small  contribu- 
tion (^  to  ^  per  cent)  towards  expenses  of 
management ;  besides  the  annual  jmyment  ap- 
plied to  the  extinction  of  the  loan. 

The  associations  in  general  do  not  pay  the  loan 
in  money,  but  issue  obligations  {Pfandhriefe) 
for  the  amount  advanced.  These  are  negotiable, 
and  pass  from  hand  to  hand,  bringing  the  holder 
an  interest  paid  by  the  association  of  3  or  4 
per  cent  yearly.  Payment  of  the  principal  of 
obligations  cannot,  in  general,  be  claimed  by  the 
holder,  but  the  association  may  agree  to  accept 
offers  of  them,  and  can  call  them  in,  usually  by 
drawings,  on  giving  due  notice  by  advertisement. 
Not  merely  the  property  specially  represented 
by  the  Pfandhrief,  but  all  the  funds  of  the 
association  are  liable  for  the  regular  payment  of 
the  interest.  Each  of  the  coupons  into  which 
an  obligation  is  subdivided  usually  re[)resents  a 
very  moderate  amount,  and  is  used  as  a  medium 
of  exchange  in  small  transactions.  They  have 
maintained  their  value  extremely  well  in  com- 
parison with  other  debentures.  Thus,  for  ex- 
ample during  the  shock  to  commercial  confidence 


caused  by  the  revolutions  of  1848,  whilst  the 
3^  per  cent  Prussian  public  funds  were  quoted 
at  69,  and  the  shares  of  the  bank  of  Prussia 
at  63  per  cent,  the  3^  per  cent  Pfandhriefe 
stood,  in  Silesia  and  Pomerania  at  93,  in  west 
Prussia  at  83,  and  in  east  Prussia  at  96  ;  and 
they  have  maintained  their  price  well  since. 
In  some  cases  these  obligations  are  issued  direct 
to  the  borrowers,  who  themselves  undertake 
their  negotiation.  In  others  the  association 
charges  itself  with  the  negotiation  and  gives 
cash  to  the  borrower,  this  being  furnished  by 
capitalists  who  invest  in  the  obligations.  No 
dividends  are  earned  by  the  association.  The 
receipts  from  the  borrowers  provide  for  interest 
on  the  obligations,  maintenance  of  a  reserve 
fund,  gradual  redemption  of  the  obligations, 
and  cost  of  management.  In  case  the  borrower 
fails  to  pay  the  interest  on  his  loan,  the  associa- 
tion can  first  seize  his  produce  and  other  movable 
effects,  and  if  these  are  insufficient,  can  have  a 
receiver  appointed  over  the  mortgaged  estate,  or 
can  sell  it  by  public  auction.  The  debtor  can, 
in  general,  pay  off"  the  debt  at  will,  in  full  or 
by  instalments  of  not  less  than  a  certain  fixed 
amount. 

The  governments  of  the  several  German  states 
commonly  prescribe  the  conditions  {Normativ- 
hedingungen)  under  which  these  societies  can  be 
formed,  and  the  rules  to  which  they  must  con- 
form. The  minister  of  the  interior  exercises  a 
superintendence  over  their  proceedings,  usually 
through  a  commissioner  who  presides  at  their 
meetings,  and  frequently  some  of  the  directors 
are  nominated,  or  their  nomination  is  required 
to  be  approved,  by  the  state. 

Three  conditions  ai)pear  necessary  for  the 
safe  and  efficient  working  of  such  institutions. 
(1)  Public  compulsory  registration  of  titles  to, 
and  charges  on,  land,  so  as  to  make  the  existing 
liabilities  of  an  estate  easy  to  ascertain  ; — (2) 
ready  and  cheap  legal  methods  for  recovery  of 
debts  and  sale  of  the  borrower's  property  pledged 
for  a  loan ; — (3)  the  obligations  must  be  capable 
of  easy  and  inexpensive  transfer. — All  these 
conditions  are  satisfied  in  the  countries  where 
such  establishments  have  been  successful. 
Further,  there  must  be  due  care  in  the  manage- 
ment of  the  institutions,  especially  in  valuation 
of  mortgaged  lands.  When  the  Landschaftcn 
are  imder  state  control,  it  is  usually  provided 
by  law  that  the  loan  shall  be  made  only  on  first 
mortgage  and  to  an  amount  not  exceeding  half, 
or  at  most  two-thirds,  of  the  value  of  the  land. 
When  application  is  made  for  a  loan,  if  a  previous 
mortgage  on  the  land  is  found  to  exist,  it  is  first, 
with  the  consent  of  the  prior  mortgager,  paid  off 
in  obligations. 

These  institutions  offer  great  advantages  both 
to  borrowers  and  lenders.  To  an  agriculturist 
who  has  sunk  borrowed  capital  in  improvements, 
the  liability  to  a  sudden  demand  for  repayment 
of  the  loan  is  serious  j  and  that  step  may  be 


108 


BANKS.  LAND 


rendered  unavoidable  by  the  condition  of  the 
creditor's  affairs.  To  the  capitalist  who  lends, 
a  more  punctual  payment  of  interest  is  assured 
by  the  responsibility  of  the  association  than  can 
always  be  expected  of  a  private  debtor.  And 
he  is  saved  the  trouble  of  examining  into  the 
security  of  the  borrower,  all  risk  on  that  head 
being  borne  by  the  association. 

All  testimonies  on  the  subject  show  that 
these  institutions  have  been  socially  beneficial. 
They  have  lightened  the  burdens  of  proprietors, 
have  increased  the  market  value  of  land,  and 
have  determined  a  more  liberal  expenditure  on 
permanent  agricultural  improvements,  thus 
tending  to  diminish  the  immigration  from  the 
country  districts  into  the  large  towns.  They 
have  also  opposed  a  useful  counterpoise  to  the 
tendencj'^  towards  excessive  subdivision. 

So  far  we  have  dealt  only  with  institutions 
which  may  be  described  as  associations  of 
borrowers,  who  procure  loans  for  themselves  on 
the  security  of  the  whole  or  a  part  of  their 
landed  possessions,  guaranteeing  repayment  of 
the  loans  by  their  collective  responsibility. 
This  was  the  type  of  the  early  German  Vereine, 
and  new  societies  have  been  founded  on  the 
same  plan.  But,  besides  these,  other  institu- 
tions have  come  into  existence  since  1840  in 
Germany,  as  well  as  elsewhere,  which  may  be 
distinguished  as  associations  of  lenders,  for  the 
purpose  of  making  advances  for  long  terms 
on  the  security  of  immovable  property,  land, 
houses,  factories  or  workshops,  woods,  mines, 
etc.  They  have  been  created  by  capitalists  as 
modes  of  investment.  The  establishments  of 
this  kind  are  more  properly  than  the  former 
called  land-banks  ;  they  are  known  in  Germany 
as  HypotheTcen-Banken.  They  possess  a  sub- 
scribed capital,  and  pay  dividends  to  their  share- 
holders. The  bank  is  responsible,  to  the  ex- 
tent of  its  entire  resources,  to  the  capitalist 
who  purchases  its  obligations.  The  subscribed 
capital  bears  but  a  small  proportion  to  the 
amount  of  the  obligations  in  circulation,  so 
that  the  security  to  the  holders  of  the  latter 
rests  essentially  on  the  value  of  the  mortgaged 
properties.  The  annuity  paid  by  the  borrower 
consists,  as  in  the  case  of  the  Landschaften,  (1) 
of  the  interest  on  the  loan,  with  (2)  a  com- 
mission, and  (3)  the  sum  required  for  the  ex- 
tinction of  the  debt  in  the  fixed  term.  •  The 
profit  of  the  bank  depends  on  the  difference 
between  the  interest  it  pays  to  holders  of  its 
obligations  and  that  it  receives  from  its  debtors. 
The  issue  of  the  PfoAwLhriefe  of  these  banks  is, 
in  general,  limited  by  legislation,  or  by  direct 
action  of  the  public  authorities  ;  the  accounts  of 
the  banks  are,  in  some  states,  required  to  be 
periodically  submitted  to  the  government. 

A  special  stimulus  to  the  formation  of  land- 
banks  in  Germany,  as  elsewhere,  was  supplied  by 
the  success  of  the  French  Credit  Foncier(5'.u), 
founded  1852,  which,  after  surmounting  con- 


siderable difliculties,  obtained  a  position  of  stable 
credit,  and  extended  its  operations  over  the 
whole  of  France.  Foreign  financiers  studied 
with  care  an  organisation  which  had  yielded  such 
satisfactory  results  ;  and  a  powerful  impulse 
was  given  to  the  creation  of  land-banks  in  the 
other  continental  countries.  In  Germany,  in 
particular,  a  great  number  of  them  were  founded ; 
five  at  Berlin  between  1864-72,  three  at  Frank- 
fort-on -the -Main  between  1862-71,  three  at 
Munich  between  1869-71,  and  many  in  other 
parts  of  the  empire.  In  1883  there  were 
twenty-four  Hypotheken-BanTcen  in  the  German 
empire,  with  circulation  of  over  1700  millions  of 
marks  (£85,000,jOOO)  in  Pfandhriefe,  share  capi- 
tal of  over  250  millions  of  marks  (£12,500,000), 
and  holding  over  1800  millions  of  marks 
(£90,000,000)  in  mortgage. 

"Whilst  the  Landschaften  were  instituted  and 
worked  for  the  benefit  of  agricultural  proprietors 
exclusively,  it  is  said  that  the  business  of  the 
Hypotheken-Banken  has  been  principally  in  con- 
nection with  town  buildings. 

Besides  the  voluntary  associations  of  which 
we  have  spoken,  the  governments  of  some  of  the 
German  states  have  from  time  to  time  founded 
land-banks,  ehtirely  under  their  own  manage- 
ment, for  special  objects.  Thus  in  the  parts  of 
the  country  where  feudal  institutions  continued 
longest  in  force,  as  for  examjDle  in  Hesse-Cassel 
and  Hanover,  they  had  been  created  (in  1832 
and  1840  respectively)  to  furnish  the  proprietors 
of  the  *'  peasant  lands  "  with  the  means  of  re- 
deeming the  seigniorial  dues  to  which  they  were 
subject.  In  recent  times  Landescultur-Renten- 
hanken  have  been  founded  by  the  governments 
of  Saxony  and  Prussia,  to  assist  landowners  in 
draining  and  irrigating  their  estates. 

[A  list  of  books  on  land  credit  will  be  found  in 
C.  Knies's  Geldund  Credit,  2te  Abtheilung  (1879), 
p.  395.— Theod.  Frhr  von  der  Goltz,  Landwirth- 
schaft,  Theil  1,  §§  47,  48,  in  Schonberg's  Handhuch 

der    Politischen    Oekonomie    (2d   ed.   1886). V. 

Borie,   Etudes  sur  le  credit  agricole  et  le  credit 

fonder  en  France  et  d  I'Uranger  (1877). J.  B. 

Josseau,  Traits  du  credit  fancier  (3d  ed.  1885).— 
Titre  vii.,  ch.  2,  Institutions  de  credit  foncier  dans 
les  divers  itats  Europeens.  ]  j,  k,  j^ 

The  Landschaften  have  made  great  progress. 
In  1914  there  were  18  societies  in  Prussia  which 
issued  £15,000,000  in  land-bonds  in  1912. 
There  are  also  Landschaften  in  Mecklenburg 
with  land-bonds  in  circulation  amounting  to 
£2,053,000  ;  in  Brunswick,  land-bonds  in  cir- 
culation, £660,000  ;  in  VViirtemberg,  with  land- 
bonds,  £5, 192, 000  ;  in  Bavaria,  with  land-bonds, 
£7,039,000;  and  two  in  Saxony,  one  with 
bonds  in  circulation  of  £3,997,000  issued  tc 
384  large  estates  and  1358  peasant  farmers, 
the  other  with  loans  to  land-owners  amountinc* 
to£9, 126, 000  and  to  Communes  of  £1 0, 990  000^ 
— all  at  the  end  of  1912. 

The  size  of  the  peasant  holdings  on  which 
these  loans  are  granted  varies  from  under  2* 


BANKS,  POPULAR,  GERMANY— ITALY 


109 


acres  to  over  250,  the  largest  number  concerned 
being  between  2^  and  25  acres.  The  loans 
vary  from  under  £100  to  over  £5000,  the 
most  usual  size  being  between  £150  and  £400. 
The  rate  of  interest  varies  from  3  to  4  per  cent. 
Advances  are  also  made  on  the  security  of  rural 
holdings  by  the  Savings  Banks, — in  1912  they 
invested  £123,200,000  or  19%  of  their  total 
capital  in  this  way, — and  by  the  38  Mortgage 
Banks  {Hyiwlhckcn  -  Banken)  wliioh  granted 
£37,586,000  mortgages  on  rural  holdings  out 
of  a  total  of  £564,335,100.  See  Deutscher 
Okonomist  (Sept.  1913);  Monthly  Bulletin  of 
Eco'iiomic  and  Social  Intelligence,  esp.  Sept.  1910, 
Nov.  1912,  and  Feb.  1914. 

BANKS,  Popular  (Germany).  Banks  on  a 
co-operative  principle  have  been  established  in 
several  countries  in  Europe,  the  most  promi- 
nent examples  being  in  Germany  and  Italy. 
The  popular  banks  of  Germany,  which  owe 
their  initiative  to  the  efforts  of  Schulze- 
Delitzsch,  commenced  operations  in  1858-59 
on  strictly  co-operative  principles.  No  advance 
fjan  be  made  to  any  one  except  to  a  member. 
Each  bank  is  directed  by  an  administrative 
council  consisting  of  nine  members,  elected  at 
the  general  meeting  ;  a  committee  is  also  electeil 
to  manage  the  detail.  No  one  is  admitted  as  a 
member  unless  he  is  accepted  by  the  administra- 
tive council ;  members  pay  an  entrance  fee,  and 
subscribe  a  certain  share  of  the  capital,  no  one 
being  allowed  to  exceed  a  fixed  limit.  Pay- 
ments may  be  either  by  monthly  instalments  or 
in  one  sum.  Members  have  the  right,  as  soon 
as  elected,  to  ask  for  a  loan,  the  shortest  period 
for  advances  being  a  fortnight,  the  longest  three 
months.  This  may  be  renewed,  but  not  for 
more  than  nine  months.  Each  member  is  re- 
quired, before  a  loan  can  be  granted  him,  to 
have  60  per  cent  at  least  of  the  amount  paid  in 
to  his  credit,  or  to  be  guaranteed  by  another 
member  of  the  society.  The  banks  receive 
amounts  on  deposit,  on  which  interest  averaging 
about  4^  per  cent  is  paid  ;  for  these  sums  both 
the  capital  and  the  members  individually  are 
liable.  The  dividends  to  the  shareholders  aver- 
age from  5  to  7  per  cent.  The  advances  are  at 
about  8  per  cent,  but  part  of  this  is  returned  to 
the  borrower  by  way  of  dividend. 

The  troubles  which  the  revolution  of  1848 
brought  on  Germany  letl  Schulze-Delitzsch  to 
devote  his  attention  to  this  great  work.  He  per- 
ceived, with  the  intuitionof  a  statesman  and  hrst- 
rate  financier,  that  state  aid  and  charity  would 
never  help  those  who  sought  assistance  of  that 
kind  to  emerge  from  the  grinding  poverty,  the 
lot  of  too  many,  not  only  of  the  working-classes, 
but  of  the  small  traders.  Believing  that  ' '  man 
has  implanted  in  his  nature,  together  with  the 
wants  which  are  bound  up  with  his  existence, 
the  powers,  the  right  use  of  which  leads  to  the 
satisfaction  of  those  wants,"  he  steadily  per- 
severed in  his  efforts  to  apply  the  principle  of 


"self-help"  to  a  business  usually  supposed  to 
require  a  large  fund  of  capital  before  it  can  be 
set  satisfactorily  to  work.  The  rate  of  interest 
to  the  poor  but  hardworking  borrower  was  re- 
duced from  a  most  usurious  rate  (60  and  even 
730  per  cent  are  mentioned  as  rates  which  had 
been  given  previously),  while  what  the  lender 
received  made  the  effort  of  saving  worth  while. 

These  banks  take,  to  a  certain  extent,  the 
place  of  savings  banks,  and  are  of  great  service 
in  promoting  the  prosperity  of  the  districts  in 
which  they  work.  Besides  the  popular  banks 
(  VoTschussvereine),  Schulze-Delitzsch  established 
industrial  syndicates  {Genossenschaften  in  einzel- 
nen  Gewerbszweigcn)  ;  co-operative  societies  for 
articles  of  consumption  (A'b7isM?;n;ercwie)  ;  build- 
ing societies  {Baugenossenschaften). 

There  were  3481  societies  in  1881,  i.e.  1889 
popular  banks,  898  industrial  syndicates,  660 
co-operative  societies,  34  building  societies  with 
a  capital  of  £30,500,000  (£9,500,000  being 
payments  of  members  and  reserves,  and 
£21,000,000  borrowed  capital).  In  1859,  80 
popular  banks  reported  18,676  members, 
£6,100,000  advances  made,  and  £41,000  funds, 
capitals,  and  reserves.  In  1887,  886  banks  re- 
ported 456, 276  members,  £80, 000, 000  advances, 
and  £6,744,000  funds,  capitals,  and  reserves. 
The  Schulze-Delitzsch  banks  were  centralised 
in  1864  under  the  German  Co-operative  Societies 
Bank,  which  amalgamated  with  the  Dresdner 
Bank  in  1903.  There  are  15,000  local  banks 
(1913),  membership  1,500,000,  loans  abouu 
£100,000,000.  There  are  5000  banks  in  the 
Raiffeisen  Federation,  principally  in  villages  of 
under  2000  inhabitants. 

[See  Paper  on  "  People's  Banks,"  by  A.  Egmout 
Hake,  Journal  of  the  Institute  of  Bankers,  June 
1889  ;  who  remarks  on  the  opposition  the  system 
received  at  first  from  the  police — an  opposition 
which,  if  persevered  in,  must  have  caused  the  whole 
movement,  so  useful  to  the  country,  to  collapse. 
—  Vorsch%iss-U7id-  Credit-  Vereine  als  1  'olksbanken 
Praktische  Anweisung  zu  deren  Einrichtung  und 
Gr'dndung  con  Schulze-Delitzsch,  Leipzig,  5tli  ed,, 
1876.  This  volume  contains  complete  information 
on  the  method  of  establishing  the  system,  duties 
of  directors,  officials,  arrangements  for  general 
meetiugs,  amount  of  shares,  etc.,  the  act  of  1868, 
with  forms  of  account,  etc.  The  pains  taken  with 
the  detail,  and  the  high  standard  of  public  spirit 
incidentally  shown,  are  beyond  praise. 

For  history  of  these  institutions,  1890-1910,  in 
Germany  see  C.  R.  Fay,  Co-operation  at  Hmne  and 
Abroad,  London,  1908,  and  List  of  Authorities 
therein  ;  H.  W.  Wolff,  Peoples  Banks,  Lontlon, 
1910  ;  Statistisches  Handbuch  fiir  das  Deutsche 
Reich.] 

BANKS,  Popular  (Italy).  Co-operative 
banking  was  introduced  into  Italy  by  Signor 
Luigi  Luzzatti,  Minister  of  the  Italian  Treasury, 
and  "  Presidente  dell'  Associazione  fra  le  Banche 
Popolari  Italiane,"  who,  in  1864,  adapted  the 
organisation  employed  by  Schulze-Delitzsch 


no 


BANKS,  POPULAR,  ITALY— BANKS,  SAVINGS 


for  the  use  of  his  own  country.  The  leading 
principles  of  the  Italian  popular  banks,  as  of 
those  of  Germany,  are  co-operation,  mutual 
responsibility,  and  self-help.  The  system  has 
spread  over  nearly  the  whole  of  Italy.  By 
1887  there  were  608  popular  banks.  Tl\e 
method  of  organisation  is,  in  the  main,  similar 
to  that  employed  in  Germany.  The  manage- 
ment rests  on  the  intelligence  of  the  share- 
holders, working  through  different  committees 
which  undertake  separate  portions  of  the  ad- 
ministration. The  officers— president  and  com- 
jnittee— are  unpaid.  To  prevent  undue  power 
from  being  accumulated  in  the  hands  of  any 
individual,  the  number  of  sliares  any  single 
person  may  hold  is  limited  ;  and  at  the  general 
meetings  of  the  society,  no  sliareholder  has 
more  than  one  vote,  whatever  the  number  of 
his  shares  may  be.  The  advantages  obtainable 
from  joining  these  institutions  are  gi'eatly 
appreciated  by  the  smaller  shopkeepers  and 
traders,  who  form  the  largest  class  among  the 
shareholders  ;  next  in  number  are  the  small 
agricultural  proprietors  and  farmers,  working 
men  proper  being  about  10  per  cent  of  the 
whole.  The  transactions  appear  to  be  extremely 
minute,  loans  even  of  1  franc  (lOd.)  not  being 
unknown  ;  the  largest  number  of  loans  being  for 
sums  less  than  20  frs.  (16s.  8d.).  The  deposits 
correspond,  the  largest  number  being  below  50  frs. 
(£2).  Before  these  banks  had  been  introduced 
a  most  usurious  rate  had  been  charged  for  small 
advances  to  petty  traders  and  artisans,  30  to 
even  60  per  cent  being  paid,  and  even  higher 
rates.  The  local  business  done  in  these  small 
advances  appears  to  have  been  generally  sound. 
Luzzatti  quotes,  with  a  very  justifiable  satisfac- 
tion, the  following  figures  of  the  popular  banks 
of  Italy  in  his  official  publication  of  1889. 
The  amount  of  loans  and  discounts  in  1880 
was  £16,895,236,  of  which  only  -28  per  cent 
was  overdue  and  unpaid.  In  1886  those 
overdue  and  unpaid  were  -22  per  cent  of  the 
total  £45,902,837.  In  1883,  250  popular 
banks  reported  capital  £2,566,880,  deposits 
£10,421,200  ;  in  1902,  696  out  of  736 
banks  reported  capital  £3,305,068,  deposits 
£19,261,240.  The  rural  banks  in  1902 
numbered  1099.  In  Jan.  1911  there  were  862 
co-operative  credit  societies  and  popular  banks, 
1140  rural  banks,  207  ordinary  credit  com- 
panies, and  5  agrarian  credit  institutions  and  7 
credit  foficier  companies.  The  land  certificates 
amounted  to  £26,988,905  and  the  loans  to 
£24,296,367.  In  1912  the  7  cridit  fonder 
companies  granted  about  1760  loans  on  mortgage 
(for  rural  and  urban  land)  for  an  amount  of 
about  £3,235,000.  In  1913  the  2094  rural 
co-operative  banks  had  a  capital  of  about 
£120,000,  deposits  nearly  £4,000,000,  amount 
of  loans  passed  about  £10,000,000.  In  1913, 
on  the  suggestion  of  Signer  Luzzatti,  a  Federa- 
tion of  Co-operative  Credit  Institutions  of  North 


Italy  waa  formed  with  the  view  of  making  them 
more  useful  and  to  protect  their  interests.  The 
Federal  Bank  of  the  Co-operative  Credit 
Societies  was  also  formed  to  act  as  a  central 
bank  for  the  Federation.  This  new  organisa- 
tion will  give  a  great  impulse  to  the  work  of  the 
people's  banks.  Rural  banks  in  other  parts  of 
Italy  are  being  associated  in  the  same  way. 

The  practicability  of  the  system  turns  on  the 
fact  that  the  management  is  local,  and  the 
characters  of  borrowers  or  shareholders  concerned 
well  known,  and  "as  each  shareholder  mutually 
guarantees  his  fellow,  every  one  has  an  interest 
in  preventing  the  bank  from  being  defrauded" 
(^Quarterly  Review,  Jan.  1887,  p.  154). 

\I.l  credito  Popolare  in  Italia,  Relazione  di  Luigi 
Luzzatti,  Kome,  1882. — Manuale  per  le  Banche 
Popolari  Co-operative  Italiane,  E.  Levi,  Milan,  1883. 
— Statute  delta  Banca  Mutua  Popolare  di  Firenze  ; 
Societd  Anonima  Co-operativa,  Firenze,  1883. — 
Introduzione  alia  Statistica  delle  Banche  Popolari 
(1887),  Gon  una  Relazione,  di  Luigi  Luzzatti, 
Rome,  1889. — Ualia  Bancaria,  Milan,  1908.  See 
Bibliography  to  art.  Banks,  Land,  esp.  Monthly 
Bulletin  {loc.  cit.),  Jan.  and  Feb.  1914.] 

BANKS,  Savings.  Probably  the  earliest 
instance  of  a  savings  bank  in  England  was  the 
Charitable  Bank  at  Tottenham,  founded  by 
Miss  Priscilla  Wakefield  in  1804.  Six  gentle- 
men acted  as  trustees,  and  undertook  to  receive 
the  moneys  deposited,  allowing  5  per  cent 
interest  on  all  sums  of  twenty  shillings  in  their 
hands  for  one  year.  This  involved  loss  to  the 
trustees.  In  1808  a  similar  society,  opened  at 
Bath  for  domestic  servants,  allowed  4  per  cent. 
The  Parish  Bank  Friendly  Society  of  Ruthwell, 
1810,  was  a  genuine  savings  bank  efficiently 
organised.  Its  success  being  considerable,  it 
had  many  imitators.  Six  years  later  there 
were  nearly  eighty  sax.ngs  banks  in  England 
and  Ireland,  and  in  1817  legislation  was  re- 
sorted to.  Acts  57  Geo.  III.  c.  105  and  c.  130 
encouraged  and  regulated  banks  for  savings  in 
England  and  Ireland.  Trustees  were  prohibited 
from  making  any  profit  out  of  these  banks.  At 
the  same  time  they  were  bound  to  remit  all 
deposits  when  they  exceeded  £50  in  the  aggre- 
gate to  the  office  for  the  reduction  of  the 
national  debt,  where  "the  fund  for  the  banks 
of  savings  "  was  opened,  and  interest  was  allowed 
by  that  office  of  3d.  per  cent  per  diem,  or 
£4:11:3  per  cent  per  annum,  whereas  the 
banks  themselves  mostly  allowed  their  de- 
positors 4  per  cent.  The  amount  deposited  in 
any  one  year  was  restricted  to  £50,  though  in 
England  a  depositor  was  permitted  to  deposit 
£100  in  the  first  year.  In  1824  another  act 
was  passed  limiting  deposits  to  £50  in  the  first 
year  and  to  £30  in  any  subsequent  year,  and 
when  the  deposits  of  any  person  exceeded  £200 
no  interest  was  allowed  on  the  excess.  In  1828 
an  act  was  passed  to  consolidate  and  amend  the 
laws  relating  to  savings  banks,  and  this  provided 
that  the  rules  and  regulations  of  each  such  bank 


BANKS,  SAVINGS— BANK  NOTE 


111 


should  be  approved  by  the  commissioners  for 
the  reduction  of  the  national  debt ;  that  the 
interest  allowed  by  that  office  should  be  only 
2^d.  per  cent  per  diem  (£3  :  16  :  0^  per  cent  per 
annum)  ;  that  only  2^d.  should  be  allowed  by 
such  banks  to  depositors  (say  £3:8:5-^  per  cent 
per  annum)  ;  and  that  no  depositor  should  be 
permitted  to  deposit  more  than  £150,  although 
the  interest  might  be  permitted  to  accunuilate 
until  the  deposit  reached  £200.  There  were 
(20th  November  1833)  amongst  385  savings 
banks,  414,014  depositors  in  England,  their 
total  deposits  being  £13,973,243  ;  in  Wales 
there  were  23  banks,  11,269  depositors,  and 
£361,150  deposits  ;  and  in  Ireland  7<)  banks, 
49,872  depositors,  and  £1,380,718  deposits; 
making  in  all  484  banks,  475,155  depositors, 
and  £15,715,111  deposits.  A  further  act  was 
passed  in  1833  (3  Will.  IV.  c.  14). 

In  1835  Act  5  &  6  Will.  IV.  c.  57  was 
passed,  extending  the  provisions  of  these  acts 
to  Scotland,  and  military  or  regimental  sa\ings 
banks  were  established  in  1843.  In  1844 
another  act  was  passed  (7  &  8  Vict.  c.  83),  re- 
ducing the  interest  allowed  by  the  national 
debt  commissioners  to  3|  per  cent,  and  the 
maximum  interest  to  depositors  to  £3:0:10  per 
cent.  The  recent  reduction  in  the  rate  of 
interest  paid  on  consols  must  lead  to  further 
modifications  in  this.  Arrangements  were  also 
made  for  the  summary  distribution  of  deposits 
of  deceased  persons,  and  other  regulations  were 
made  in  regard  to  the  purchase  of  annuities, 
etc.  On  20th  November  1844  there  were  577 
savings  banks  in  the  United  Kingdom,  their 
deposits  being  £29,504,861  by  1,012,047  per- 
sons, averaging  £29  per  head.  It  may  be 
gathered  from  the  successive  reductions  in  the 
rate  of  interest  allowed  by  the  commissioners 
that  the  government  had  not  found  the  custody 
of  the  savings  banks'  funds  directly  profitable. 
In  fact,  as  they  had  to  invest  the  money  in 
consols  and  other  home  government  stocks, 
there  was  found  to  be  an  accumulated  loss  of 
some  millions.  Various  partial  provisions  Avere 
from  time  to  time  made  to  cover  this  ;  so  late, 
however,  as  1881  there  was  a  deficiency  of 
£2,144,562,  which  was  finally  extinguished 
by  the  creation  of  an  annuity  of  £83,673,  ex- 
piring in  1908.  In  the  year  previous  (1880) 
the  interest  allowed  by  the  commissioners  was 
lowered  from  3^  to  3  per  cent,  at  which  it  now 
remains,  while  the  interest  to  depositors  is 
mostly  2^  per  cent  per  annum. 

But  in  1861  a  gi-eat  development  of  the 
savings  banks  principle  was  effected.  Post 
office  savings  banks  (promoted  greatly  by  the 
efforts  of  the  late  Sir  C.  W.  Sikes  of  Hudders- 
field)  were  established  by  Act  24  Vict.  c.  18,- 
and  at  once  became  popular  in  England  and 
Ireland.  The  post  office  savings  banks,  how- 
ever, have  been  less  progressive  in  Scotland, 
where,  though  the  trustee  banks  were  of  later 


creation,  they  have  taken  a  firm  hold.  The  rate  of 
interest  provided  under  this  act  was  2^  per  cent. 
It  is  evident  that  since  the  establishment 
of  the  post  office  savings  banks  throughout 
the  kingdom  the  security  they  can  offer  has 
greatly  influenced  depositors,  especially  as  the 
advantage  to  be  gained  in  a  higher  rate  of 
interest  by  depositing  in   the   trustee   savings 


show  the  growth  of  these  deposits 


Savings  Banks. 
1S33— Trustees 
1844 
1800 

Trustees 
Post  Office    . 


18' 


■o{ 


,„„^ /Truslces 


)fflce 


Trustees 

Postt 
/  'J'rustin^s 
t  Post  Uflice    . 
/  Trustees 
\  Post  Office    . 
/  Trustees 
\  Post  Office    . 


>«»«{Somoe 


1900 
1910 
1913 


United  Kingdom. 

.  £15,715,111 
29,504,801 
41,J.jS,308 
37,958,549 
15,0'.'9,104 
43,970,447 
33,744,037 
43,050,000 
07,034,000 
50,022,000 

,       131,91ti,000 

51,503,000 

104,092,000 

53,558,000 

180,240,000 


The  purchase  of  government  stock  through 
the  post  office  dates  from  22nd  November  1880. 
The  amounts  remaining  to  the  credit  of  stock- 
holders at  the  end  of  the  year  1880  was  about 
£128,000  ;  Dec.  27,  1913,  £29,000,000. 

In  British  colonies  the  savings  banks  have  also 
become  a  considerable  power  both  in  the  form 
of  general  and  post  oflice  banks.  In  Australia 
in  1899-1900  nearly  25  per  cent  of  the  popula- 
tion were  depositors,  their  deposits,  aggregating 
£34,000,000,  reaching  £30:  11  :  9  per  head. 
The  interest  allowed  being  (1897)  3  per  cent  up 
to  £200,  and  2h  per  cent  on  sums  from  £200 
to  £500.  In  Canada,  on  30th  June  1888  the 
deposits  in  the  savings  banks  of  the  dominion 
reached  $41,371,058  (say  £8,481,066).  The 
total  amount,  1895,  in  all  the  savings  banks 
was  $57,500,000  (£11,500,000),  $11-11 
(£2  :  4  :  6)  per  head  of  population. 

In  many  foreign  countries  also  savings  banks 
are  well  established,  and  large  sums  are  deposited 
in  them.  In  France  the  rate  of  interest  has 
lately  been  reduced  from  4  to  3  j  per  cent  by  the 
Caisse  des  Depots  et  Consignations,  which  is 
stated  in  the  Nouveau  Dictionnaire  if  Economic 
Politique,  p.  924,  article  Caisses  d'Epargne,  to 
have  received  in  fifty  years  (1837-1887)  about 
£224,000,000  from  the  Caisses  d':^pargne,  to 
have  repaid  £96,000,000,  and  to  have  invested 
about  £20,500,000  in  the  purchase  of  govern- 
mente  Rente.  The  Caisse  Nationale  d'^pargnCy 
established  1881,  is  stated  to  have  collected  in 
eight  years  about  £13,000,000  belonging  to 
more  than  1,272,000  depositors.  In  1908  this 
had  become  £61,000,000  with  5,291,000 
depositors.  The  French  Savings  Banks  {Bulletin 
de  Statistique  et  de  Legislation  Comparie),  to 
give  another  example  of  thrift  in  France,  held 
£186,000,000,  1905. 

BANK  NOTE.   Kegulations  in  diffebbni 


112 


BANK  NOTE 


Countries.  The  arrangements  respecting  bank 
note  circulation  are  very  different  in  different 
countries. 

.  (1)  In  the  United  Kingdom  the  note  circula- 
tion is  regulated  by  the  Bank  Acts  of  1844-45. 
Sir  R.  Peel,  in  conformity  "  with  the  principles 
of  the  currency  theory  "  (see  Tooke's  History  of 
Prices,  vol.  iv.  pp.  373,  374),  stated,  in  his 
speech  in  the  House  of  Commons,  24th  June 
1844,  that  one  of  the  objects  he  had  in  view 
was  "that  the  paper  circulation  should  conform 
itself  to  gold,  that  it  should  fluctuate  like 
gold."  To  attain  this  the  accounts  of  the 
Bank  of  England  were  henceforth  to  be  divided 
into  two  parts,  issue  and  banking  departments. 
The  method  adopted  is  shown  in  the  return 
which  follows  : — 

The  Bank  of  England. 
An  account  pursuant  to  the  Act  7  &  8  Vict. 
c.    32,   for  the  week    ending  on  Wednesday, 
Jan.  7,  1914  : 

Issue  Department. 
Notes  issued     £54,469,065      Government 

Debt  .        .  £11,015,100 
Other  Securi- 
ties     .        .       7,434,900 
Gold  Coin  and 
Bullion       .     36,019,065 


£54,469,065 


£54,469,065 


Banking  Department. 

Proprietors'  Government 

Capital       .  £14,553,000  Securities      £13,098,974 

Rest       .        .       3,414,436  Other  Securities  32,092,407 

Public  Deposits  17,185,436  Notes      .        .     25,426,140 

Other  Deposits  46,544,175  Gold  and  Silver 

Seven-day  and  Coin    .        .       1,091,344 

other  Bills  11,818 


£71,708,865 


£71,708,865 


January,  8,  1914. 


J.  G.  NAIRNE, 
Chief  Cashier. 

The  banking  department  of  the  Bank  ot  Eng- 
land, though  as  entirely  separated  from  the 
note  circulation  as  if  it  were  under  different 
management,  yet  is  most  intimately  connected 
with  it  in  one  sense,  for  the  amount  of  notes 
held  in  the  banking  department  represents  the 
available  reserve  of  gold.  The  Issue  Depart- 
ment is  concerned  with  the  note  issue,  which 
after  1844  was  separated  from  the  other  busi- 
ness of  the  Bank,  and  rigidly  controlled  so  far 
as  the  amount  of  notes  allowed  to  be  issued  is 
limited  by  the  influx  and  outflow  of  bullion. 
The  Bank  of  England,  while  allowed  to  issue 
part  of  its  note  circulation  against  securities, 
either  government  or  of  an  analogous  descrip- 
tion of  a  fixed  character  (£14,000,000,  1844  ; 
£18,450,000,  1914),  was  compelled  to  hold 
bullion,  a  fourth  of  the  whole  permissibly  in 
silver,  against  the  remainder.  The  circulation 
of  notes  was  thus  automatically  linked  to  the 
supply  of  bullion,  and  as  the  Bank  has 
ceased  to  hold   silver  bullion   since   1853,   to 

1  Including    Exchequer,    Savings    Banks,    Commis- 
sioners of  National  Debt,  and  Dividend  Accounts. 


the  supply  of  gold  bullion  brought  to  it.  "The 
action  of  the  public  (said  Sir  R.  Peel,  6th  May 
1844)  will  regulate  the  amount  of  that  portion 
of  the  note  circulation  which  is  issued  upon 
bullion."  This  arrangement  has  since  been 
carried  out.  The  limit  to  the  note  circulation 
of  the  Bank  of  England  is  thus  the  amount  of 
bullion  it  may  hold.  Three  times  since  1844 
— in  1847,  1857,  and  1866 — circumstances  have 
compelled  a  relaxation  of  the  Bank  Act,  but  in 
1847  and  in  1866  the  note  circulation  did  not 
exceed  the  ordinary  legal  limit  allowed.  In 
1857  an  addition  of  £2,000,000  was  made  to 
the  "  other  securities"  held  in  the  issue  Depart- 
ment by  authority  of  a  letter  addressed  by  the 
First  Lord  of  the  Treasury  (Lord  Palmerston) 
and  the  Chancellor  of  the  Exchequer  (Sir  G.  C. 
Lewis)  to  the  Governors  of  the  Bank,  dated 
12th  November  1857.  Under  the  relaxation 
of  the  act  thus  permitted,  the  note  circulation 
exceeded  the  statutory  limit  by  £928,000  on 
the  20th  November  1857  {Proceedings  of  the 
Select  Committee  on  the  Bank  Acts,  House  of 
Commons,  1858,  p.  xli).  In  1847  and  1866, 
though  permission  was  given,  the  letter  of  the 
act  was  not  actually  infringed.  To  continue  the 
history  of  the  act  of  1844  :  the  existing  issuing 
banks  in  England  and  Wales  were  allowed  to 
continue  their  issues,  under  conditions  intended 
to  bring  about  the  gradual  extinction  of  their 
note  circulations,  no  security  whatever  being 
required  to  be  held  against  their  issues.  To  the 
note-issuing  banks  in  Scotland  and  Ireland  more 
favourable  terms  were  allowed,  but  under  con- 
dition that  for  every  £1  in  paper  issued  beyond 
the  limit  fixed  by  the  acts  of  1845,  £1  in  gold 
should  be  held,  not  as  security,  but  as  repre- 
senting the  addition  to  the  currency  circulating 
in  the  country. 

(2)  In  France  an  entirely  different  system 
prevails.  A  limit  is  fixed  to  the  note  circula- 
tion of  the  Bank  of  France  (£96,000,000,  raised 
to  £112,000,000,  1871  ;  to  £128,000,000, 
1872  ;  to  £232,000,000,  1909  ;  but  provided 
these  limits  are  not  exceeded,  the  bank  is  not 
compelled  by  law  to  hold  any  special  proportion 
of  bullion  whatever.  The  bullion  held  is  very 
large  in  amount,  thus  it  was,  2nd  Jan.  1914, 
£140,307,000  gold,  £25,543,000  silver;  the 
average  note  circulation  (1913),  £226,600,000. 

(3)  In  Germany  a  modification,  with  very 
essential  differences,  of  Peel's  act  is  in  force. 
The  German  Bank  Act  of  1875  allows  an  amount 
of  issue  against  securities  (1875,  £12,500,000  ; 
1909,  £27,500,000  and  £37,500,000  at  the  end 
of  each  quarter).  Against  the  remainder,  cash  is 
held,  thus:  "current  German  coin,  Reichskas- 
senscheine  (legal  tender  notes  of  the  empire), 
notes  of  other  German  banks,  and  gold  bars 
and  foreign  gold  coin  calculated  at  the  rate  of 
1392  marks  (£69  :  12s.)  for  a  pound  weight 
(German)  of  gold."  The  Imperial  Bank  must 
"have  in  its  coffers  at  least  one-third  of  the 


BANK  NOTE 


lis 


amount  of  notes  in  circulation,  in  German  cur- 
rency, as  defined  above.  "The  rest  of  the 
amount  of  notes  in  circulation  must  be  repre- 
sented by  discounted  bills,  due  at  latest  in  three 
months,  and  for  which  generally  three,  but  at 
least  two  persons  known  to  be  solvent  are  re- 
sponsible." Should  the  note  issue  exceed  the 
limits  assigned,  a  tax  of  5  per  cent  on  the  ex- 
cess issue  is  charged  (see  "The  German  Bank 
Act  of  1875,"  R.  H.  Inglis  Palgrave,  Journal 
of  the  Institute  of  Bankers,  vol.  vii.  1886).  The 
note  circulation  exceeded  the  statutory  limit 
on  19  occasions  in  the  year  1913. 

(4)  In  the  United  States  the  note  circulation 
of  the  national  banks,  which  provides  a  large 
part  of  the  circulating  medium  of  the  country, 
is  arranged  on  different  principles  from  those 
existing  in  any  of  the  countries  previously  men- 
tioned. For  a  fuller  description  of  this  system 
see  BA.NK  Note  (United  States  of  America), 
By  way  of  comparison  with  the  arrangements 
respecting  bank  note  circulation  in  other  coun- 
tries it  is  sufficient  to  state  here  that  bonds  of 
the  United  States  are  required  to  be  deposited 
against  the  note  circulation  which  was  not 
originally  allowed  to  exceed  90  per  cent  of  the 
full  value  of  the  bonds,  but  was  permitted  up 
to  the  amount  of  the  capital  stock  of  the  banks. 
The  proportion  to  the  bonds  was  afterwards 
diminished  to  80  per  cent,  raised  to  90  per  cent 
1898  and  to  i)ar  value  of  the  bonds  March  14, 
1900.  The  redemption  of  all  the  notes  pre- 
sented at  the  place  of  business  of  the  bank  is 
required  by  law  during  business  hours,  in 
"lawful  money  of  the  United  States,"  towards 
which  a  reserve  of  5  per  cent  in  lawful  money 
on  the  extent  of  the  note  circulation  is  required 

.  to  be  constantly  kept  on  de])osit  with  the 
treasurer  of  the  United  States.  The  safeguards 
provided  (1)  by  the  government  bonds  being 
10  per  cent  in  excess  of  the  circulation  (par  in 
1900,  see  above)  ; — (2)  that  the  circulation  is 
limited  to  90  per  cent  of  the  paid-up  capital ; — 
(3)  that  a  reserve  of  5  per  cent  on  the  circula- 
tion in  lawful  money  should  always  be  forth- 
coming,—  furnished  the  United  States  with 
a  system  of  note  circulation  which  for  many 
years  after  the  establishment  of  the  national 
banks  "was  its  most  important  feature  :  "  (Re- 
port of  the  Comptroller  of  the  Currency,  1888). 
Its  decrease  was  partly  attributable  to  the  heavy 
taxation  imposed  on  it,  partly  to  the  diminishing 
return  obtainable  from  the  bonds  on  which  it  was 
founded,  partly  also  to  the  movement  of  business 
which  economises  circulation  as  banking  facilities 
extend.  It  has  increased  greatly,  1913  (see  Ban  k 
Note,  United  States  of  America). 

(5)  In  Sweden  the  notes  of  the  "  Enskilda 
Banks"  are  protected  by  provisions  which, 
while  permitting  the  use  of  securities  more  in 
correspondence  with  those  allowed  by  the  Bank 

If  Germany,  provide,  practically,  for  the  redemp- 
lon  of  the  circulation  in  an  effectual  manner. 
VOL.  I. 


The  instances  given  are  examples  of  the  dif- 
ferent methods  on  which  circulation  may  be 
based.  In  the  case  of  the  Bank  of  England  it 
is  assumed  that  a  certain  proportion  of  the  total 
issue  cannot  be  presented  for  payment  in  specie  ; 
fixed  securities  are  held  against  that  part,  while 
bullion  has  to  be  held  against  the  remainder. 
The  two  departments,  note  circulation  and  bank- 
ing, are  entirely  separate  from  each  other.  The 
Bank  of  France  is  allowed  gi-eater  freedom 
within  the  limit  as  to  maximum  issue  prescribed 
by  the  law.  The  Bank  of  Germany,  with  a 
fixed  proportion  allowed  to  be  issued  against 
securities,  is  compelled  to  hold  good  commercial 
bills  against  the  remainder,  these  securities 
"turning  themselves  into  money,"  in  business 
phrase,  at  fixed  and  not  remote  dates.  The 
national  banks  of  the  United  States  possess  a 
circulation  as  rigidly  secured  as  that  of  the  Bank 
of  England  against  bonds  of  the  Government, 
but  applicable,  through  the  working  of  local 
banks,  to  the  wants  of  each  district.  A  maxi- 
mum limit  is  fixed. 

There  are  two  schools  of  opinion  with  respect 
to  a  bank  note  issue.  The  first,  headed  by 
A.  Smith  and  Ricaiido,  holds  "that  im- 
mediate convertibility  into  coin  is  all  that  is 
loquisite  to  prevent  the  excessive  issue  of  paper  " 
(speech  of  Sir  R.  Peel,  Gth  May  1844);  the 
second,  led  by  Peel  himself,  assumes  that  unloss 
issuers  of  notes  "vigilantly  observe  the  causes 
which  influence  the  influx  or  efilux  of  coin,  and 
regulate  their  issues  of  paper  accordingly,  there 
is  danger  tliat  the  value  of  the  paper  will  not 
correspond  with  the  value  of  coin."  Hence  the 
principle  of  Peel's  measure  "was  to  make  the 
currency,  consisting  of  a  certain  proportion  ol 
paper  and  gold,  fluctuate  precisely  as  if  the 
currency  were  entirely  metallic"  (speech  13th 
June  1844,  of  Mr.  Goulburn,  who  was  chan- 
cellor of  the  exchequer  in  the  administration  of 
Sir  R.  Peel).  It  will  be  observed  that  neither 
in  the  case  of  the  Bank  of  France  nor  of  the 
Bank  of  Germany  nor  of  the  national  banks  of 
the  United  States  is  this  rule  enjoined.  It  is 
enforced  as  to  the  extra  note  issue  of  the  Scotch 
and  Irish  banks  (Bank  Acts  of  1844-45),  but 
in  their  case  the  coin  compulsorily  held  is  not 
security  for  the  circulation  (see  Bullion  Com- 
mittee, Report  of  ;  Circulating  Medium  ; 
Convertibility  of  Bank  Notes  ;  Currency 
Doctrine). 

BANK  NOTE  (United  States  of  America). 
— In  the  United  States  the  note  circulation  of 
the  national  banks,  which  alone  are  authorised 
to  issue  bank  notes,  is  regulated  in  the  main  by 
the  provisions  of  the  act  of  1863,  bearing  the 
significant  title,  "  An  Act  to  provide  a  national 
ourrency,  secured  by  a  pledge  of  United  States 
bonds,  and  to  provide  for  the  circulation  and 
redemption  thereof."  All  notes  issued  had  to 
be  secured  by  United  States  bonds  deposited  in 
the  treasury,  the  notes  limited  to  90  per  cent 

I 


114 


BANKRUPTCY  IN  SCOTLAND 


of  the  market  value,  and  the  same  proportion 
of  the  par  value,  of  the  bonds  (altered  1900 
to  the  par  value),  no  bank  having  an  issue 
exceeding  its  capital.  The  aggregate  circulation 
of  all  the  banks  was  also  limited  originally  to 
$300,000,000  (£60,000,000);  and  in  187*0  this 
limit  was  raised  to  $354, 000, 000  (£70, 800, 000); 
but  all  limit  upon  the  aggregate  was  removed 
in  1875,  by  the  act  for  resuming  specie  pay- 
ments. The  notes  must  be  redeemed  by  the 
issuing  bank  in  "lawful  money"  (specie  or 
legal  tender  notes)  upon  presentation,  and  since 
1874  are  also  redeemable  at  the  treasury,  every 
bank  being  required  to  maintain  a  reserve  of 
lawful  money,  amounting  to  five  per  cent  of 
its  circulation,  in  the  hands  of  the  treasurer  of 
the  United  States.  The  notes  are  not  a  legal 
tender  between  individuals,  but  are  by  law 
received  and  paid  out  by  the  government  in  all 
payments  except  for  custom  duties  and  interest 
on  the  public  debt  ;  and  every  national  bank  is 
required  to  receive  in  payments  the  notes  of  any 
other.  The  ample  margin  of  security  afi"orded 
by  the  deposit  of  bonds,  the  systematic  re- 
demption at  the  treasury,  and  the  ability  to  use 
any  note  in  any  part  of  the  union  where  a 
national  bank  is  to  be  found,  have  given  the 
notes  complete  credit  and  an  entirely  unimpeded 
circulation,  which  made  the  system  for  many 
years  "  important  to  the  banks,  still  more  im- 
portant to  the  public."  At  the  close  of  1873 
the  bank  circulation  stood  at  $341,320,256 
(£68,264,051),  nearly  reaching  the  maximum 
allowed  by  law.  It  fell,  however,  during  the 
long  commercial  depression  which  followed,  and 
of  late  years  has  declined  rapidly,  owing  to  the 
diminished  return  now  obtained  from  an  invest- 
ment in  bonds,  and  to  the  tax  of  one  per  cent 
on  circulation  imposed  by  the  national  govern- 
ment. At  the  resumption  of  specie  payments 
in  1879,  after  the  limit  to  the  aggregate  circula- 
tion had  been  removed,  the  bank  notes  out- 
standing were  $303,500,000  (£60,700,000)  ; 
January  1885  they  had  fallen  to  $280,000,000 
(£56,000,000)  ;  and  in  May  1890  to 
$125,900,000  (£25,180,000).  c.  f.  d. 

Since  that  period  the  position  of  the  national 
banks  has  greatly  improved.  The  circulation 
of  the  7514  banks  carrying  on  business,  31st 
Oct.  1913,  was  $758,900,000  (£151,780,000). 
The  Bank  Act  of  1913,  however,  makes  drastic 
changes.     (See  Banks,  National.) 

BANKRUPTCY  IN  SCOTLAND.  In  early 
days  the  insolvent  debtor  in  Scotland  was 
treated  practically  as  a  criminal,  and  was  sub- 
ject to  the  penalties  of  rebellion  against  a  com- 
mand from  the  crown  enjoining  him  to  pay  his 
creditor.  From  the  Roman  law  there  was,  how- 
ever, borrowed,  a  process  of  relief — the  cessio 
honorum — under  which  he  gave  up  all  his 
property  and  thus  secured  liberation  and  im- 
munity from  imprisonment  on  the  ground  of 
his  debt,  but  was  not  discharged.    Consequently 


it  was  precarious  for  him  to  try  to  resume  busi- 
ness,  and  the  tendency  was  for  him  to  conceal 
some  property  before  creditors  could  take  steps 
against  him.  In  1621  an  act  of  the  Scots 
parliament  was  passed  directed  against  gratui- 
tous alienations  to  "conjunct  or  confident  per- 
sons" on  the  eve  of  insolvency.  In  1696 
another  act  checked  the  giving  one  creditor  any 
unjust  preference  over  others  ;  and  it  did  so  by 
providing,  in  substance,  that  where  a  person 
became  notoriously  insolvent  or  "notour  bank- 
rupt " — the  evidence  of  which  was  to  be  that 
proceedings  had  been  taken  against  him  for 
debt,  and  that  in  consequence  he  had  been  im- 
prisoned (or,  afterwards,  something  legally 
equivalent),  or  had  absconded  or  resisted  arrest 
or  retired  into  sanctuary — all  unjust  preferences 
granted  by  him  within  sixty  days  prior  to  the 
notour  bankruptcy  were  to  be  annulled.  It  is 
here  to  be  observed  that  the  effect  of  the  notour 
"bankruptcy  "  was  not  to  bring  about  a  distri- 
bution of  his  estate  ;  it  only  limited  his  status  ; 
he  might  still  continue  in  business,  but  thence- 
forth— and  indeed  at  common  law  from  the 
moment  of  actual  insolvency — he  must  act  as 
steward  (or  rather  negotiorum  gestor)  for  the 
whole  of  Ris  creditors  and  he  must  use  his  best 
endeavour  to  treat  them  equally.  But  the 
creditors  might  be  impatient ;  they  might  press 
their  individual  claims,  and  all  the  more  so  since 
the  law  still  allowed  certain  privileges  to  the 
creditor  first  in  the  race  for  "  diligence  "  or  exe- 
cution ;  whence  too  often  ensued  the  ruin  of  the 
debtor,  to  the  actual  disadvantage  of  the  general 
body  of  creditors.  In  all  this  every  creditor 
fought  for  his  own  hand  ;  the  debtor  must,  so 
far  as  he  could,  treat  them  all  equally  ;  but  the 
law  did  not  provide  any  means  of  putting  all 
the  creditors  on  an  equal  footing  until  1772, 
when  the  first  Sequestration  Act  was  passed,  to 
endure  experimentally  for  ten  years.  Seques- 
tration at  common  law  (French  mission  en 
sequestre)  was  a  well-known  proceeding  in  Scot- 
land, analogous  to  appointing  a  receiver  on  an 
estate  in  chancery  ;  a  judicial  factor  was  ap- 
pointed by  the  Court  of  Session  who  managed 
an  estate  for  the  benefit  of  those  interested 
until  it  was  judicially  ascertained  who  were  the 
parties  entitled,  or  until  the  occasion  for  taking 
the  estate  out  of  the  hands  of  the  administrator 
had  passed  over.  On  this  analogy,  the  person- 
alty (but  curiously  not  the  realty,  for  it  was 
abhorrent  to  the  ideas  of  the  conveyancers  of 
the  time  that  realty  should  pass  without 
feudal  conveyances)  became  vested  either  in  a 
judicial  factor  proposed  by  the  creditors,  or  else, 
alternatively,  in  a  trustee  to  be  appointed  by 
the  creditors  as  if  under  a  voluntary  settlement. 
The  judicial  factor  distributed  the  estate  under 
the  direction  of  the  court ;  the  trustee  did  so 
cxtra-judicially.  In  1783  the  experiment  was 
felt,  especially  on  the  trustee  system,  to  have 
been   a  success  ;  a  new  experimental   act  was 


BANKRUPTCY  IN  SCOTLAND 


115 


passed  in  which  Sequestiiatiox  was  confined  to 
the  estates  of  merchants  and  manufacturers,  the 
whole  estate,  real  as  well  as  personal,  became 
subject  to  division,  the  trustee  reported  to  and 
acted  under  the  control  of  the  Court  of  Session, 
and  those  creditors  who  had  acquired  preferences 
by  taking  proceedings  against  the  bankrupt 
within  a  certain  time  before  the  sequestration 
were  put  on  an  equal  footing.  By  successive 
statutes  this  act  was  renewed  with  improve- 
ments ;  a  permanent  act  was  passed  in  1839, 
which  introduced  the  sequestration  of  the 
estates  of  deceased  debtors  ;  and  the  present 
leading  statute  is  one  of  the  year  1856(19&20 
Vict.  c.  79)  in  which  the  same  guiding  principles 
are  applied  in  detail,  with  these  outstanding 
alterations,  that  sequestration  is  not  confined 
to  persons  in  trade,  and  that  the  procedure  may 
be  (and  in  practice  is)  carried  through  before 
the  sheriff  courts  ;  while  the  Court  of  Session 
retains  control  of  the  whole  bankruptcy  adminis- 
tration after  sequestration  has  been  granted, 
through  an  officer  of  court  called  the  Account- 
ant in  Bankruptcy, — now  the  Accountant  of 
Court, — whose  diligent  supervision  of  the  reports 
and  accounts  of  trustees  has  been  the  key-stone 
of  the  Scottish  system. 

Sequestration  proceedings  are  initiated  either 
by  a  petition  by  the  insolvent  himself  with  con- 
currence of  creditors  to  a  certain  amount,  or  by 
creditors  to  the  same  amount  alleging  notour 
bankruptcy  and  Scottish  jurisdiction.  On 
special  application,  or  for  special  reasons,  the 
court  may  appoint  an  interim  judicial  factor, 
or  may  in  any  case  seal  books,  close  premises, 
and  keep  the  key  until  a  trustee  is  elected  and 
confirmed.  Sequestration  may  be  opposed  by 
the  debtor  himself,  or  by  any  creditor  who  has 
a  special  interest ;  and  it  may  be  recalled  on 
producing  before  the  Court  of  Session  a  private 
deed  of  arrangement  agreed  to  by  a  majority  of 
the  creditors  in  number  and  four-fifths  in  value 
(rare  in  practice)  or  by  showing  the  Court  of 
Session  within  three  months  that  the  bank- 
niptcy  procedure  ought  to  be  carried  through 
in  England  or  Ireland. 

Suppose  the  court  grants  sequestration  ;  a 
meeting  of  creditors  is  appointed,  six  to  twelve 
days  ahead,  which  is  advertised  in  the  Udinburgh 
Gazette.  At  that  meeting  the  creditors  elect  a 
trustee  (or  trustees  in  succession),  who  must 
not  be  the  bankrupt  or  any  relative  or  confi- 
dential friend  of  his,  or  any  creature  of  such, 
or  one  whose  interests  are  opposed  to  those  of 
the  general  body  of  creditors  ;  otherwise,  the 
court  will  not  interfere  with  the  creditors' 
choice.  The  sheriff  presides  at  this  meeting  if 
two  creditors  call  upon  him  to  attend.  Voting 
power  in  the  election  is  according  to  amount  of 
unsecured  debt.  The  sheriff  decides  within  four 
days  whether  any  candidate  for  trusteeship  is 
ineligible,  and  confirms  the  appointment  of  the 
trustee  on  his  finding  security  either  for  his 


whole  dealings  or  for  a  sum  limited  by  the 
creditors  at  their  first  meeting.  The  trustee  at 
once  reports  himself  to  the  accountant  in  bank- 
ruptcy. The  trustee  is  assisted  or  supervised 
by  three  "commissioners  " — a  committee  of  in- 
spection chosen  at  the  first  meeting  of  creditors  ; 
they  concur  with  him  in  compromises  and  refer- 
ences to  arbitration,  they  declare  the  dividends, 
and  they  may  report  independently  to  the 
creditors. 

The  trustee  cannot  resign,  but  may  be  re- 
moved without  cause  assigned  by  a  majority  of 
creditors.  His  first  duty  is  to  make  up  an  in- 
ventory and  valuation  of  the  whole  estate  and 
to  send  that  to  the  accountant.  The  bankrupt  is 
bound  to  afford  him  every  assistance  in  prepar- 
ing this  ;  if  he  does  not,  or  if  he  obstructs  the 
administration  by  refusing  to  execute  any 
necessary  deed,  he  may  be  imprisoned  ;  but  he 
is  paid  for  his  assistance.  After  confirmation 
the  trustee  applies  to  the  sheriff  to  fix  a  day  for 
public  e:..amination  of  the  bankrupt ;  at  that 
examination  the  bankrupt  may,  if  need  be,  be 
committed  to  prison  till  he  shall  make  full  and 
satisfactory  answers  to  the  questions  put ;  and 
his  relatives  and  friends  (wife,  etc.)  may  be 
brought  before  the  sheriff  and  examined  as  to 
disposal  of  property. 

The  bankrupt  may  be  discharged  (1)  on 
acceptance  of  a  composition  by  his  creditors  (four- 
fifths  in  value  on  a  first  offer,  or  nine-tenths  in 
value  on  a  subsequent  oficr)at  their  first  or  second 
meeting  being  reported  to  the  court ;  or  (2) 
without  composition  if  the  creditors  are  unani- 
mous, or  if  a  majority  in  number  and  four-fifths 
in  value  concur  after  six  months  or  a  majority 
in  number  and  value  after  eighteen  months  or 
without  any  consent  after  two  years  ;  but  in  no 
case  can  he  get  discharge  without  showmg  the 
court,  either  that  he  has  paid  or  secured  to  the 
creditors  a  dividend  of  5s.  in  the  £,  or  that  his 
not  having  done  so  was  owing  to  circumstances 
for  which  he  could  not  justly  be  held  respons- 
ible ;  and  discharge  may  be  withheld  for  miscon- 
duct on  his  part. 

Cessio  bonorum  has  recently  (1880  and  1881) 
been  so  far  assimilated  to  sequestration  that  it 
is  now  in  substance  merely  a  cheaper  form  of 
procedure  for  small  estates.  The  trustee  is 
appointed  by  the  sheriff ;  and  there  are  no  com- 
missioners, but  proof  of  debts  takes  place,  and 
discharge  is  gi'anted  or  withheld  as  in  seques- 
tration. 

The  principal  changes  in  the  law  since  1856 
have  been  directed  towards  enabling  discharge 
to  be  withheld  for  misconduct  (1860),  towards 
extending  the  preference  of  clerks  and  workmen 
(1875),  towards  the  abolition  of  imprisonment 
for  debt  (1880  and  1882),  towards  the  amend- 
ment of  procedure  in  cessio  (1880),  and  grant- 
ing discharge  in  cessio  (1881),  towards  dealing 
with  fraudulent  debtors  and  those  who  fail  to 
keep  accounts  (1881),  and  towards  rendering 


116 


BANKRUPTCY  LAW  AND  ADMINISTEATION  (ENGLAND) 


undischarged  bankrupts  incapable  of  holding 
certain  offices  of  trust  and  bringing  them  under 
the  criminal  law  if  they  take  credit  for  more 
than  £20  without  disclosing  their  condition 
(1884). 

With  regard  to  liquidation  by  private  arrange- 
ment :  the  method  is — (1)  Conveyance  by  debtor 
to  trustee  ("trust-deed  for  behoof  of  creditors")  ; 
(2)  mutual  contract  by  all  the  creditors  to  act 
in  common  according  to  definite  scheme  ("  deed 
of  accession  ").  The  main  point  of  weakness  in 
this  is  the  inadequacT-  of  means  to  keep  the 
trustee  up  to  his  duty  ;  the  contract  should 
provide  machinery  for  this.  If  this  be  done  the 
method  is  regarded  with  favour.  Extrajudicial 
composition  contracts  between  insolvent  debtors 
and  their  creditors  are  also  not  uncommon  in 
practice. 

[Bell's  Commentaries  on  the  Law  of  Scotland, 
1870. — Mr.  Henry  Goudy's  Law  of  Bankruptcy 
in  Scotland,  1886.]  A.  D. 

BANKRUPTCY  LAW  AND  ADMINIS- 
TRATION (England).  A  good  bankruptcy 
law  must  aim  at  the  attainment  of  three  dis- 
tinct and  sometimes  conflicting  objects  ;  first, 
the  speedy  and  economical  distribution  of 
the  debtor's  property  amongst  his  creditors  ; 
secondly,  the  release  of  the  debtor  from  his  load 
of  debt,  so  far  as  this  may  be  justified  by  his 
conduct ;  and  thirdly,  the  punishment  of  fraud, 
reckless  trading,  and  personal  extravagance. 
The  policy  of  the  bankruptcy  laws  has  varied 
considerably.  Sometimes  one,  sometimes  an- 
other of  the  above-mentioned  objects  has  been 
the  guiding  principle  of  the  enactment,  and 
various  machineries  have  been  devised  for  giving 
effect  to  them.  During  the  present  century 
some  forty-six  acts  relating  to  bankruptcy  have 
been  passed.  Roughly,  their  eff"ect  may  be  de- 
scribed as  follows  :  Before  1831  the  full  control 
of  the  administration  of  bankrupt  estates  was 
in  the  hands  of  the  creditors,  the  result  being 
wholesale  mismanagement  and  general  dissatis- 
faction. In  1831  an  act,  known  as  Lord 
Brougham's  Act,  introduced  a  system  of  official 
administration.  Official  assignees  were  ap- 
pointed to  the  London  Bankruptcy  Court,  but 
not  in  the  country  districts.  After  some  years' 
trial  of  the  system  of  official  assignees  in  London, 
and  after  a  favourable  report  from  a  royal  com- 
mission, the  system  was  extended  in  1842  to 
the  country  generally.  The  official  assignees 
were  again  favourably  reported  on  by  Select 
Committees  in  1847  and  1849.  In  1861  opin- 
ion had  begun  to  turn  against  them,  and  an 
act  was  passed  considerably  limiting  their  func- 
tions. In  1864  a  select  committee,  on  what 
seems  inconclusive  evidence,  wholly  condemned 
the  system  of  official  assignees.  These  officers 
were  abolished  by  the  act  of  1869,  and  once 
more  a  system  of  voluntaryism  was  inaugurated, 
with  the  wonted  result.  Creditors  were  supine, 
and  estates  were  wrecked  and  plundered  by  the 


rapacity  of  the  lower  class  of  trustees.  Everj 
facility  was  off'ered  to  fraudulent  debtors,  and 
they  were  not  slow  to  avail  themselves  of  tlieir 
opportunities.  A  few  years'  trial  of  the  act 
resulted  in  its  general  condemnation,  but  it  was 
not  till  1883  that  any  legislative  change  was 
effected.  In  that  year  Mr.  Chamberlain,  then 
president  of  the  Board  of  Trade,  succeeded  in 
carrying  the  act  which  introduced  the  system 
now  in  operation.  The  Bankruptcy  Act  1883 
(46  &  47  Vict.  c.  52),  which  is  amended  in 
some  details  by  the  act  of  1890  (53  &  54  Vict. 
c.  71),  makes  a  fresh  departure  in  banlcruptcy 
legislation.  In  the  first  place  it  severs  judicial 
from  administrative  functions.  Judicial  func- 
tions are  necessarily  left  to  the  courts,  but 
administrative  supervision  and  control  are  in- 
trusted to  an  executive  department  of  the  state, 
namely  the  Board  of  Trade.  Creditors  still 
retain  the  general  control  over  the  debtor's 
estate,  but  his  conduct  is  subject  to  an  inde- 
pendent investigation  with  a  view  to  his  punish- 
ment if  his  insolvency  has  been  caused  by 
culpable  recklessness  or  fraud.  Trustees  are 
subjected  to  the  supervision  of  the  Board  of 
Trade,  who  require  security  from  them,  audit 
their  accounts,  and  exercise  a  general  superin- 
tendence over  their  dealings.  The  act  of  1869 
proceeded  on  the  theory  that  the  debtor  and  his 
creditors  were  the  only  parties  concerned  in  a 
bankruptcy.  The  present  measure  recognises 
the  principle  that  bankruptcy  is  a  matter  of 
public  concern  affecting  the  community  at  large. 
Speaking  broadly,  the  act  establishes  one  en- 
trance into,  and  two  exits  from,  the  state  of 
statutory  insolvency.  The  receiving  order,  as 
it  is  called,  is  the  entrance  gate.  By  the  re- 
ceiving order  the  debtor's  property  is  put  under 
the  charge  of  an  official  of  the  Board  of  Trade, 
until  the  creditors,  with  the  leave  of  the  court, 
have  determined  whether  the  debtor  shall  be 
allowed  to  terminate  his  insolvency  by  a  com- 
position or  scheme  of  arrangement,  or  whether 
he  shall  be  adjudicated  a  bankrupt  and  his 
affairs  be  wound  up  in  bankruptcy  proper.  In 
either  case  there  is  a  turnstile  through  which 
the  debtor  must  pass,  namely,  the  public  ex- 
amination at  which  his  conduct  and  financial 
dealings  are  investigated  in  open  court. 

The  courts  which  exercise  bankruptcy  juris- 
diction are  the  High  Court  and  the  county 
courts.  For  bankruptcy  purposes  England  and 
Wales  have  been  mapped  out  into  135  districts. 
The  bankruptcy  business  of  the  London  district 
is  allocated  to  the  High  Com't,  while  in  the 
country  districts  the  county  courts  are  the 
courts  of  original  jurisdiction.  To  secure  uni- 
formity of  practice,  one  of  the  High  Court 
judges  is  specially  appointed  by  the  lord  chan- 
cellor to  take  bankruptcy  business,  and  it  is 
provided  that  he  shall  always  be  a  member 
of  the  divisional  court  to  which  bankruptcy 
appeals  from  the  county  courts  are  brought. 


BANKRUPTCY  LAW  AND  ADMINISTRATION  (ENGLAND) 


in 


The  bankruptcy  department  of  the  Board  of 
Trade  consists  first  of  local  officers  called  official 
receivers,  and  secondly  of  a  central  staff  under 
the  inspector  -  general,  who  audit  trustees' 
accounts,  and  supervise  the  conduct  and  deal- 
ings both  of  trustees  and  of  the  local  officers. 
Each  bankruptcy  district  has  its  official  receiver, 
but  the  same  officer  may  be  appointed  official 
receiver  for  two -or  more  districts,  or  on  the 
other  hand,  two  or  more  receivers  may  be  ap- 
pointed to  one  district  according  to  local  re- 
quirements. An  Official  Receiver,  besides 
being  an  officer  of  the  Board  of  Trade,  is  made  an 
officer  of  the  court,  having  jurisdiction  over 
his  district.  The  object  of  the  latter  provi- 
sion is  to  give  him  free  access  to  court  docu- 
ments, and  to  enable  him  to  consult  the  judge 
without  the  formality  of  a  motion  in  open 
court.  His  reports  are  made  prima  fade  evi- 
dence of  the  matters  contained  in  them.  His 
duties  are  declared  by  the  act  to  "have  rela- 
tion both  to  the  conduct  of  the  debtor  and  the 
administration  of  his  estate"  (§  68).  As  re- 
gards the  debtor,  it  is  the  duty  of  the  official 
receiver  to  investigate  his  conduct  and  to  report 
to  the  court  thereon,  to  take  such  part  as  the 
Board  of  Trade  may  dii-ect  in  his  public  examin- 
ation, and  also  to  assist  when  requisite  in  his 
prosecution.  As  regards  the  estate,  it  is  the 
official  receiver's  duty  to  act  as  interim  receiver 
pending  the  appointment  of  a  trustee,  and  as 
manager  when  a  special  manager  is  not  ap- 
pointed ;  to  summon  and  preside  at  the  Jirst 
meeting  of  the  creditors,  to  issue  proxies,  to 
report  to  the  creditors  on  any  proposal  by  the 
debtor  for  a  scheme  or  composition,  to  advertise 
the  proceedings,  and  to  act  as  trustee  during 
any  vacancy  in  that  office.  In  cases  where  tiie 
estate  does  not  exceed  £300,  the  official  receiver 
becomes  the  trustee  unless  the  creditors  expressly 
supersede  him.  In  short,  this  office  is  made 
the  keystone  of  the  present  system,  and  the 
success  or  failure  of  the  act  must  mainly  depend 
on  the  efficiency  or  non-efficiency  of  the  official 
receivers. 

Bankruptcy  proceedings  may  be  commenced 
either  by  the  debtor  himself  or  by  a  creditor 
whose  debt  amounts  at  least  to  £50.  If  the 
petition  is  presented  by  a  creditor  it  must  be 
founded  on  one  of  the  overt  acts  of  insolvency, 
called  acts  of  bankruptcy,  which  are  specified  in 
§  4.  To  prevent  an  influx  of  paupers  a  £5 
stamp  is  charged  on  bankruptcy  petitions,  and 
a  deposit  of  £5  is  also  required  to  cover  prelim- 
inary expenses.  The  first  result  of  a  bankruptcy 
petition,  properly  substantiated,  is  the  making 
of  a  receiving  order  by  the  court.  This  order 
does  not  divest  the  debtor  of  his  property,  but 
puts  the  official  receiver  in  charge  of  his  pro- 
perty, and  stays  proceedings  by  unsecured 
creditors.  As  soon  as  the  receiving  order  is 
made  the  debtor  is  bound  to  give  the  official 
receiver  full  information  as  to  his  affairs  and 


failure,  and  to  make  out  a  formal  statement  of 
his  assets  and  liabilities  for  submission  to  the 
first  meeting  of  creditors.  The  first  meeting 
should  be  held  within  fourteen  days  of  the 
receiving  order.  Proxies  must  be  on  an  official 
form.  A  creditor  can  only  give  a  general  proxy 
to  a  person  in  his  regular  employment  or  hold- 
ing a  general  power  of  attorney  from  him,  or  to 
the  official  receiver.  At  the  first  meeting  the 
debtor  may  propose  to  his  creditors  that  his 
insolvency  should  be  terminated  by  a  composi- 
tion or  scheme,  thereby  avoiding  the  disabilities 
of  bankruptcy  proper  (§  3  of  act  of  1890).  If 
this  proposal  be  not  assented  to,  the  debtor 
must  be  adjudged  bankrupt.  If  it  be  assented 
to,  the  assent  is  provisional.  The  debtor  must 
still  go  through  his  public  examination.  At 
the  meeting  the  prowosal  for  a  composition  or 
scheme  must  be  accepted  by  a  majority  in 
number  representing  three-fourths  in  value  of 
aU  the  creditors  who  have  proved.  When  the 
public  examination  is  concluded  the  matter 
then  goes  before  the  court  for  its  approval. 
The  court,  before  sanctioning  the  composition 
or  scheme,  hears  the  report  of  the  official  re- 
ceiver, and  has  to  consider  whether  it  is  calcu- 
lated to  benefit  the  general  body  of  creditors, 
and  also  whether  the  debtor's  conduct  has  been 
such  as  to  justify  his  escape  from  the  conse- 
quences of  bankruptcy.  When  the  composition 
or  scheme  is  approved  by  the  court  it  is  binding 
on  any  dissentient  minority  of  creditors,  the 
receiving  order  is  rescinded,  and  the  debtor  is 
remitted  to  the  full  control  over  his  affairs.  If, 
however,  the  provisions  of  the  composition  are 
not  carried  out,  the  debtor  is  still  liable  to  be 
adjudged  bankrupt.  Section  23  of  the  act 
further  provides  that  a  debtor  who  has  been 
adjudged  bankrupt  may  propose  a  composition 
or  scheme  under  the  like  terms  and  conditions 
as  before  bankruptcy.  If  the  composition  or 
scheme  is  sanctioned  by  the  court,  the  adjudica- 
tion of  bankruptcy  is  annulled. 

When  it  has  been  decided  that  a  debtor's 
estate  shall  be  administered  in  bankruptcy 
proper,  the  first  business  of  the  creditors  is  to 
elect  a  trustee.  The  trustee  cannot,  however,  act 
till  he  has  received  the  certificate  of  the  Board 
of  Trade.  Before  he  gets  his  certificate  he  must 
give  security  for  the  due  performance  of  his 
duties  to  the  Board  ;  and  the  Board  have 
further  the  right  to  object  to  his  appointment 
if  he  is  an  unfit  person,  or  if  his  interests  appear 
to  clash  with  the  interests  of  the  creditors 
generally.  In  the  interim  the  official  receiver 
acts  as  trustee.  As  soon  as  a  debtor  is  adjudged 
bankrupt  the  whole  of  his  property  vests  in  his 
trustee,  and  any  further  property  which  he  may 
acquire  before  he  gets  his  discharge  also  vests 
in  his  trustee.  This  rule  does  not  apply  to  the 
debtor's  personal  earnings,  though,  if  he  has 
anything  in  the  nature  of  a  fixed  income,  the 
court  may  make  an  order  charging  a  portion  of 


118 


BANKRUPTCY  LAW— BANVIN 


it  for  a  specified  time.  It  is  to  be  noted  further 
that  the  trustee's  title  relates  back  to  the  earliest 
act  of  bankruptcy  committed  by  the  debtor 
within  three  months  of  the  petition,  and  ex- 
press provision  is  made  for  avoiding  fraudulent 
settlements  and  conveyances  made  by  the  debtor 
on  the  eve  of  his  bankruptcy  (§§  47,  48). 
The  main  duty  of  the  trustee  is  to  realise  the 
debtor's  estate  with  all  convenient  speed,  and 
to  distribute  it  rateably  among  the  creditors. 
The  bankruptcy  laws,  however,  recognise  certain 
exceptions  to  the  rule  of  equal  distribution. 
Priority  is  given  within  certain  limits  to  rates 
and  taxes  and  to  claims  for  wages  or  salary  by 
workmen,  servants,  and  clerks  (§§  40,  51  & 
62  Vict.  c.  62).  On  the  other  hand,  certain 
debts  are  postponed  ;  for  instance,  a  partner  is 
not  allowed  to  prove  against  his  co-partner's 
estate  in  competition  with  the  creditors  of  his 
firm.  The  landlord's  right  to  distrain  for  six 
months'  rent  is  preserved.  The  rights  of  credi- 
tors holding  security  are  also  saved.  A  secured 
creditor  may  either  give  up  his  security  and 
prove  for  his  whole  debt,  or,  subject  to  the 
trustee's  right  to  redeem  under  certain  condi- 
tions, retain  his  security  and  prove  for  the 
balance  of  his  claim.  The  trustee,  as  a  rule, 
exercises  his  functions  under  the  guidance  of  a 
committee  of  inspection  appointed  by  the  credi- 
tors, but  if  no  such  committee  be  appointed, 
their  duties  are  performed  by  the  Board  of 
Trade  (§  22). 

As  soon  as  a  bankrupt's  public  examination 
is  concluded  he  may  apply  for  his  discharge. 
Notice  of  this  application  must  be  given  by  the 
official  receiver  to  every  creditor  who  has  proved. 
At  the  hearing  the  court  receives  from  the 
official  receiver  a  report  on  the  debtor's  conduct 
and  the  causes  of  his  failure.  The  official  re- 
ceiver, the  trustee,  and  any  creditor  who  appears 
are  entitled  to  be  heard  on  the  matter.  If  it 
appears  that  the  debtor  has  been  guilty  of  any 
conduct  amounting  to  a  misdemeanour  under 
Part  II.  of  the  Debtor's  Act  1869,  the  court 
must  ordinarily  refuse  the  discharge.  The 
debtor  then  can  only  escape  from  banki-uptcy 
and  its  consequent  civil  disqualifications  (§§ 
32-34)  by  payment  of  his  debts  in  full  with 
costs  and  interest  (§  36).  If  the  debtor  has 
not  committed  a  misdemeanour,  but  has  been 
guilty  of  minor  misconduct,  the  court  has  a  dis- 
cretion either  to  refuse  the  discharge,  or  to  sus- 
pend it  or  make  it  conditional.  A  common 
condition  is  to  order  judgment  for  a  specified 
sum  to  be  entered  up  against  the  debtor.  This 
judgment  can  only  be  enforced  by  leave  of  the 
court.  Section  8  of  the  act  of  1890  specifies 
twelve  classes  of  facts  involving  minor  miscon- 
duct which  prevent  the  court  from  granting 
an  unconditional  and  immediate  discharge  ;  for 
instance,  not  keeping  proper  business  boot? 
(see  Book-keeping),  trading  with  knowledge 
of  insolvency,  rash  speculation,  previous  bank- 


ruptcy, fraud,  or  fraudulent  breach  of  trust,  oi 
not  being  able  to  pay  10s.  in  the  £.  Under 
previous  acts  it  was  found  that  an  undischarged 
bankrupt  frequently  began  to  trade  again  and 
to  incur  fresh  liabilities  with  no  means  of  meeting 
them.  To  meet  this  evil  §  31  of  the  act  of 
1890  makes  it  a  criminal  oftence  for  an  undis- 
charged bankrupt  to  obtain  credit  to  the  extent 
of  £20  or  upwards  from  any  person  without 
informing  such  person  that  he  is  an  undis- 
charged bankrupt.  If  the  debtor's  financial 
conduct  has  been  blameless  he  is  entitled  to  an 
unconditional  discharge.  The  order  of  dis- 
charge releases  the  debtor  from  all  debts  and 
liabilities  provable  in  the  bankruptcy,  with  the 
exception  of  certain  crown  debts  and  debts  in- 
curred through  his  personal  fraud  or  fraudulent 
breach  of  trust,  and  claims  arising  out  of  seduc- 
tion or  divorce  court  proceedings. 

Such,  briefly,  is  the  general  system  of  bank- 
ruptcy established  by  the  act  of  1883.  The 
act  of  1913  embodies  suggestions  of  the  Bank- 
ruptcy Law  Amendment  Committee  of  1906. 
Thus,  the  Summary  Jurisdiction  Act  can  now 
be  applied  to  offenders  under  the  Debtors  Acts  ; 
e.g.  failure  to  make  full  discovery  of  affairs, 
concealment  of  debt,  or  mutilation  of  books  are 
punishable  after  summary  trial  before  a  Stipen- 
diary Magistrate,  or  Justices  of  the  Peace,  the 
onus  of  proving  innocent  intent  falling  on  the 
debtor,  whereas  previously,  conviction  could 
only  be  by  trial  before  a  jury  who  had  to  bo 
convinced  that  such  offences  were  committed 
with  intent  to  defraud.  Rash  speculation  other 
than  in  the  course  of  the  debtor's  business, 
and  unjustifiable  extravagance,  are  included  as 
offences  against  the  acts,  while  failure  to  keep 
proper  books  for  two  years  previous  to  the  in- 
solvency is  a  misdemeanour  if  the  debtor  has 
previously  been  made  bankrupt  or  effected  a 
deed  of  arrangement.  Other  clauses  reduce  the 
amount  of  credit  obtainable  by  an  undischarged 
bankrupt  considerably,  and  penalise  him  for 
trading  under  a  name  unknown  to  his  credi- 
tors, and  give  facilities  for  obtaining  an  order 
against  an  alien  living  abroad  who  has  carried 
on  business  here  either  personally  or  through  a 
partner  or  agent.  Under  this  act  a  married 
woman  may  be  made  bankrupt  even  if  not  trad- 
ing separately  from  her  husband  ;  the  latter's 
claims  for  monies  lent  her  for  business  purposes 
are  postponed  to  those  of  other  creditors. 

The  administrative  working  of  the  Bank- 
ruptcy Act  is  the  subject  of  an  annual  report  by 
the  Board  of  Trade  to  both  houses  of  parliament. 
For  the  law  on  the  subject,  see  the  treatises 
of  Baldwin,  Chalmers  and  Hough,  Robson, 
Vaughan  Williams,  and  Yate  Lee.      M.  D.  c. 

BANVIN,  Droit  de.  An  oppressive  seign- 
orial  right  in  France  under  the  old  regime.  By 
it  a  certain  interval,  generally  a  month  or  forty 
days,  was  fixed  after  the  ^vintage  during  which 
the   lord's   wine   alone  could  be  sold,   and  a 


BAKBARY  COMPANY— BARBON 


119 


peasant  had  to  pay  large  sums  for  leave  to  sell 
his  wine  before  the  expiration  of  the  period. 

[De  Tocqueville,  France  before  the  Revolution, 
note  Ixxvii.]  R.  L. 

BARBARY  COMPANY,  The.  See  Turkey 
Company. 

BARBON,  Nicholas,  M.D.  (1640  ?-1698), 
probably  the  son  of  Praisegod  Barebone,  was 
bom  in  London,  studied  medicine  at  Leyden, 
graduated  M.D.  at  Utrecht  in  1661,  and  was 
admitted  an  honorary  fellow  of  the  College  of 
Physicians  in  December  1664.  After  the  great 
fire  of  1666  he  was  instrumental  in  establishing 
the  first  fire  insurance  office  in  London  (1681)  ; 
he  was  one  of  the  most  considerable  re-builders 
of  the  city.  He  was  M.P.  for  Bramber  in  1690 
and  1695,  founded  a  land  bank,  which  was 
united  with  that  of  Briscoe  in  1696  and  is  re- 
ported to  have  been  successful,  and  was  among 
the  projectors  of  the  short-lived  National  Land 
Bank.  He  died  in  1 698,  having  appointed  John 
AsGiLL,  the  economist,  to  be  the  executor  of  his 
will,  and  directed  that  none  of  his  debts  should 
be  paid. 

Barbon's  works  were  numerous  and  deserve 
some  extended  notice,  as  his  views  were,  though 
with  some  failings  which  we  shall  have  to  notice, 
remarkably  in  advance  of  his  time,  and  even 
approaching  to  modern  views  on  value,  interest, 
rent,  and  foreign  trade.  He  published  in  1684  A 
Letter  to  a  Gentleman  in  the  Country  giving  an 
Account  of  the  Two  Insurance-Offices  ;  the  Fire- 
Offlce  and  Friendly  Society,  setting  forth  the 
advantages  of  his  own  institution  and  the  disad- 
vantages of  its  rival.  In  16S5  appeared  (anony- 
mously) his  Apology  for  the  Builder;  or  a 
Discourse  sho^ving  the  Cause  and  Effects  of  the 
Increase  of  Building.  He  opposed  the  opinion 
then  prevalent  that  London  was  growing  too  large, 
and  that  the  building  new  houses  there  drained  the 
inhabitants  from  the  country.  He  discussed  ia 
this  pamphlet  the  theory  of  "  rent."  Its  origin  he 
explains  in  the  following  passage  :  "  When  man- 
kind is  civilised,  instructed  with  arts,  and  under 
good  government  .  .  .  the  rich  are  fed,  clothed, 
and  housed  by  the  labours  of  other  men,  but  the 
poor  by  their  own,  and  the  goods  made  by  this 
labour  are  the  reuts  of  the  rich  men's  land  (for  to 
be  well  fed,  well  clothed,  and  well  lodged  without 
labour  either  of  body  or  nund,  is  the  true  definition 
of  a  rich  man)."  (Reprinted  in  A  Select  Collection 
of  Scarce  and  Valuable  Econoviical  Miscellaneous 
Tracts.  Reprinted  for  Lord  Overstone,  1859,  pp. 
1-26  of  that  volume  ;  see  M'Culloch,  Literature, 
pp.  350,  351).  In  1690  Barbon  published  A  Dis- 
course of  Trade.  By  N.B.,  M.D.,  London.  Printed 
by  Tho.  Milhourn,for  the  Author,  1690.  In  this 
treatise  (92  pp.  12°),  which  hitherto  has  been 
scarcely  noticed  by  those  who  have  written  on  the 
history  of  economics,  he  displays  as  much  in- 
jenuity  as  any  one  of  his  greatest  contemporaries, 
[n  the  preface  he  attributes  the  importance  which 

ascribed   to   trade   to   the   invention   of  gun- 

)wder,  foreign  trade  being  considered  necessary 

»n   account   of    its   furnishing  the    supplies    re- 

juired  by  the  country.     But  he  thinks  that  trade 


has  been  considered  from  a  too  narrow  point  of 
view,  especially  by  merchants  like  Thos.  MuN, 
who  "  apply  their  thoughts  to  particular  parts  of 
trade,  wherein  they  are  chietiy  concerned  in 
interest."  The  first  chapter  treats  ' '  of  trade  and 
the  stock,  or  wares  of  trade."  Trade,  according 
to  him  (Barbon),  consists  in  "  the  making  and 
selling  of  goods  for  another  ; "  its  parts  are  handy- 
craft  trade  and  merchandising.  Its  aim  is  to  make 
a  bargain  ;  in  every  bargain  the  wares  to  be  sold, 
their  quantity  and  quality,  their  value  or  price, 
the  money  or  credit  by  which  they  are  bought, 
and  "  the  interest  that  relates  to  the  time  of  per- 
forming the  bargain  "  are  to  be  considered.  "  The 
Stock  and  Wares  of  all  Trade  are  the  Animals, 
Vegitables,  and  Minerals  of  the  whole  Universe, 
whatsoever  the  Land  or  Sea  produceth  "  (p.  3). 
Tliey  are  either  natural  or  artificial  wares.  Both 
are  called  staple  commodities  of  the  countries 
where  they  abound,  either  native  or  foreign.  The 
native  staple  of  each  country  consists  of  its  actual 
and  unexhausted  riches  ;  this  shows  the  error  of 
Mr.  Mun,  who  thinks  that  nations  can  get  rich  by 
parsimony  like  individuals  (p.  6).  This  native 
staple  is  the  basis  of  foreign  trade,  which  is  an 
exchange  of  commodities  (p.  7).  Foreign 
staples,  even  if  carried  on  by  monopoly,  are  un- 
certain wealth  ;  this  he  illustrates  by  the  changes 
brought  about  by  the  possession  of  the  East  India 
trade.  The  second  chapter  deals  with  "the  Quantity 
and  Quality  of  Wares, "  The  third  chapter,  "  of  the 
Value  and  Price  of  Wares  "  is  one  of  the  most 
remarkable  in  this  work.  "  The  Value  of  all  Wares 
arises  from  their  Use  ;  Things  of  no  Use  have  no 
Value,  as  the  English  Phrase  is,  they  are  good  for 
nothing."  Thus  he  approached  more  closely 
than  any  one  of  his  contemporaries  to  modern  views 
on  value  and  price.  "  The  Price  of  Wares,"  he 
says,  "  is  the  present  Value  ;  And  ariseth  by  Com- 
puting the  occasions  or  use  for  them  with  the 
Quantity  to  serve  that  Occasion  ;  for  the  Value  of 
things  depending  on  the  use  of  them,  the  Over-plus 
of  Those  Wares,  which  are  more  than  can  be  used, 
become  worth  nothing  ;  So  that  Plenty  in  respect 
of  the  occasion,  makes  things  cheap,  and  Scarcity, 
dear"  (p.  IS),  These  elements  being  variable  as 
well  as  the  Wants  of  the  Mind,  and  most  things 
being  useful  through  supplying  the  latter,  "there  is 
no  fixt  Price  or  Value  of  anything  for  the  Wares  of 
Trade"  (p.  18).  But,  "There  are  two  ways  by 
which  the  value  of  things  are  a  little  guessed  at ; 
by  the  Price  of  the  Merchant,  and  the  Price  of  the 
Artificer  ;  the  Price  that  the  Merchant  sets  upon 
his  Wares  is  by  reckoning  Piime  Cost,  Charges,  and 
Interest,  the  Artificer's  Price  includes  the  Cost  of 
the  Materials  and  the  time  of  working  them.  The 
Price  of  the  Artificer  is  according  to  the  Value  of 
the  Art"  and  his  skill  (p.  19).  "But  the 
Market  is  the  best  Judge  of  Value  ;  for  by  the 
Concourse  of  Buyers  and  Sellers,  the  Quantity  of 
Wares,  and  the  Occasion  for  them,  are  best  known" 
(p.  20).  The  next  chapter,  "of  Money,  Credit, 
and  Interest,"  begins  with  the  following  definition : 
"  Mony  is  a  Value  made  by  a  Law  ;  and  the  DiflFer- 
ence  of  its  Value  is  known  by  the  Stamp  and  Size 
of  the  Piece  "  (p.  20).  It  has  two  principal  uses  : 
"  It  is  the  Measure  of  Value,  By  which  the  Value  of 
all  other  things  are  reckoned,"  and  "  It  is  a  Change 


120 


BARBON 


or  Pawm  for  the  Value  of  all  other  Things.  For 
both  reasons,  "the  value  of  mony  must  be  made 
certain  by  Law."  Having  "  its  sole  Value  from  the 
Law,"  its  Metal,  whether  Brass  (like  in  Spain), 
or  Copper  (Sweden),  or  Tin  (English  farthings),  is 
not  material  (p.  21),  "  6d.  in  Farthings  will  buy 
the  same  thing  as  6d.  in  Silver."  Foreign  coins, 
upon  which  their  country's  law  has  no  force,  go 
therefore  by  weight  and  are  of  no  certain  value 
(p.  22).  The  chief  advantage  of  gold  and  silver 
money  is  to  prevent  counterfeiting,  besides  its 
other  uses  for  plate,  etc.,  and  its  easy  exportation, 
which  the  example  of  Spain  shows  it  is  impossible 
to  prohibit  (p.  23).  It  has  no  intrinsic  value, 
but  two  values  ;  one  certain,  because  of  the  law, 
another  variable  like  the  value  of  gold  and  silver 
or  other  metals  (p.  25).  It  is  only  time  and 
place  gives  a  difference  to  the  value  of  all  things, 
"  Nothing  in  itself  hath  a  certain  Value."  Credit 
is  "  a  Value  raised  by  Opinion"  (p.  27)  ;  Barbon 
distinguishes  two  sorts  of  credit,  the  one  grounded 
upon  the  ability  of  the  buyer,  a  short  credit 
mostly  ;  the  other  upon  his  honesty,  a  long  one. 
He  defends  the  necessity  of  erecting  a  public 
bank  in  London  (pp.  28-31).  Interest  is,  accord- 
ing to  him,  "  the  Rent  of  Stock,  and  is  the  same  as 
the  Rent  of  Land  :  the  First  is  the  Rent  of  the 
Wrought  or  Artificial  Stock  ;  the  Latter,  of  the 
Unwrought  or  Natural  Stock"  (p.  31).  Barbon 
notes  that  "  Interest  is  commonly  reckoned  for 
Mony,  .  .  .  but  this  is  a  mistake  :  for  the  Interest 
is  paid  for  Stock.  ...  No  Man  takes  up  Mony  at 
Interest  to  lay  it  by  him,  and  lose  the  Interest  by 
it "  (pp.  31,  32).  The  clear  exposition  of  this 
doctrine  places  Barbon,  as  an  economist,  above 
both  Petty  and  Locke,  and  it  was  not  till  sixty 
years  later  that  Joseph  Massie  (1750)  and  Hume 
rediscovered  the  correct  theory  of  interest.  The 
uses  of  interest  are  to  measure,  1st,  profit  and  loss  in 
trade,  2nd,  the  value  of  the  rent  of  land  ;  the  value 
of  the  last  being  reckoned  "  by  adding  three  years' 
Interest  more  than  is  in  the  Principle  (sic)." 
Therefore  interest  must  be  fixed.  The  praise 
which  Barbon  bestows  on  trade  (foil,  chapter  "  of 
the  use  and  benefit  of  trade,")  forecasts  the 
celebrated  passages  on  the  consequences  of  the 
division  of  labour  in  the  Wealth  of  Nations, 
especially  his  denying  of  the  importance  of  In- 
creasing money.  "  It  is  the  Natural  Stock  that  is 
the  Real  Value,  and  Rent  of  the  Land  "  (p.  37). 
In  a  very  interesting  digression  Barbon  describes 
the  civilising  influence  of  trade,  and  maintains  the 
chief  causes  which  promote  trade  to  be  "  industry 
in  the  poor  and  liberality  in  the  rich  "  (p.  61). 
Against  the  mercantilist  views  of  "  sparing  for 
exportation "  he  maintains,  that  "  by  not  con- 
suming the  Goods  that  are  provided  for  Man's  Use, 
there  ariseth  a  dead  Stock,  called  Plenty,  and  the 
value  of  those  Goods  fall.  .  .  A  Conspiracy  of  the 
Rich  Men  to  be  Covetous  and  not  spend,  would  be 
as  dangerous  to  a  Trading  State  as  a  foreign  War  " 
(p.  63).  Clothing  and  building  employ  a  great 
variety  of  trades,  and  the  luxury  of  town-life 
increases  the  revenues  (p.  70).  In  the  last 
chapter  Barbon  declares  that  "  the  Two  Chief 
Causes  of  the  Decay  of  Trade  are  the  many  Pro- 
hibitions and  high  Interest  "  (p.  71),  his  argument 
being  "  that  the  Prohibiting  of  any  foreign  Com- 


modity doth  hinder  the  Making  and  Exportatior 
of  so  much  of  the  Native  as  used  to  be  Made  and 
Exchanged  for  it.  .  .  .  The  Native  Stock  for  want 
of  such  Exportation  Falls  in  Value,  and  the  Rent 
of  the  Land  must  fall  with  the  Value  of  the 
Stock  "  (p.  72).  This  work  of  Barbon's  contains 
the  ablest  refutation  of  the  theory  of  the  balance 
of  trade  previous  to  Hume  and  Adam  Smith  (see 
Balance  of  Trade).  Barbou  refutes  the  com- 
mon argument  for  prohibition  that  the  consump- 
tion of  foreign  commodities  hinders  the  produc- 
tion and  consumption  of  the  native ;  for  the 
consumption  of  foreign  wares  arising  from  the 
wants  of  the  mind,  the  setting  up  obstacles  to  it 
will  not  encourage  the  consumption  of  native 
wares.  A  general  prohibition  would  be  the  ruin 
of  all  trading  nations  ;  if  the  rare  case  should 
occur  that  the  use  of  foreign  goods  checked  the 
consumption  of  native  goods,  duties  may  be  im- 
posed to  differentiate  their  consumption  (pp.  75-78). 
The  rate  of  interest  being  higher  in  England  than 
in  Holland,  is  a  second  obstacle  to  trade,  for 
through  this  the  Dutch  traders  are  enabled  to 
undersell  the  English  (pp.  78-87).  Any  injury  to 
those  persons  who  live  upon  the  interest  derived 
from  Money  would  be  remedied  through  the  rise 
of  land,  the  interests  derived  from  which  would 
be  hereby  better  secured.  "  For  the  Land  is  the 
Fund  that  must  support  and  preserve  the  Govern- 
ment ;  and  the  Taxes  will  be  lesser  and  easier 
payd  "  (p.  91^).  Its  support  is  the  more  important 
"  because  it  doth  not  Disturb,  Lessen,  nor  Alter 
the  Value  of  any  Thing  else  "  (p.  92).  The  Dis- 
course of  Trade  was  attacked  by  an  anonymous 
author  E.  H.,  Reasons  against  Reducing  Interest 
to  Four  p&r  Cent,  1694.  Barbon  answered  in  An 
Answer  to  Paper  Entituled  Reasons  against  Re- 
ducing Interest  to  Four  per  Cent,  (2  sh.  fol.,) 
without,  however,  giving  any  further  proof  for  his 
proposal.  In  1695,  it  seems,  was  written  An 
Account  of  the  Land  Bank,  shounng  the  Design 
and  Manner  of  the  Settlement,  etc.  (2  sh.  fol.) 
"  Mostly  collected  out  of  my  writings,"  says  John 
Briscoe,  referring  to  it  in  An  Account  of  the 
National  Land  Bank.  Brit.  Mus.  816  m.  10  ; 
with  John  Asgill  he  drafted  the  rules  of  the 
National  Land  Bank  ;  The  Settlement  of  the 
Land  Bank  (Lord  Somer's  Tracts,  vol.  xi.),  10th 
August  1695.  The  last  work  of  Barbon  is  A 
Discourse  Concerning  Coining  the  New  Money 
Lighter.  In  Answer  to  Mr.  Lock's  Considerations 
about  Raising  the  Value  of  Money.  By  Nicholas 
Barbon,  Esq.,  1696.  Referring  to  the  definition 
of  money  in  his  former  work  he  advocates  the 
well-known  project  of  "W.  Lowndes  of  "raising 
the  coin."  He  thinks  that  a  recoinage  accord- 
ing to  the  old  standard  would  efiect  a  want  of 
specie,  and  that  the  steady  rise  of  bullion  made 
a  proportional  raising  of  the  value  of  coin 
necessary.  For  "the  Balance  of  Trade  (if  there' 
be  one)  is  not  the  cause  of  sending  away  the 
I\Ioney  out  of  a  Nation  :  but  that  proceeds  from 
the  difference  of  the  Value  of  Bullion  in  several 
Countries,  and  from  the  Profit  that  the  Merchant 
makes  by  sending  it  away,  more  than  by  the  Bills 
of  Exchange"  (p.  59).  This  passage,  it  has  been 
remarked  by  M'Culloch,  anticipates  the  "currency 
principle "   as    expounded    by   Ricardo    in    his 


BARING— BARTER 


121 


pamphlet  on  The  High  Price  of  Bullion^  1811 
(Works,  1886,  p.  267-8).  In  order  to  prove  the 
expediency  of  his  proposal,  Barbon  repeats  his 
doctrine  of  money  as  given  in  the  Discourse  of 
Trade  (p.  20),  laying  stress  upon  the  maxim,  that 
its  value  is  not  given  by  the  quantity  of  silver  in 
each  piece,  but  by  the  authority  of  government. 
He  supports  this  opinion  by  most  incredible 
sophisms.  He  ascribes  the  affluence  of  gold  to 
inadequate  rating  of  the  value  of  silver  money  (p. 
77),  and  he  advocates  his  position  by  the  history 
of  English  and  foreign  monetary  policy  and  legis- 
lation (pp.  74-94).  Though  in  this  point  the 
opinions  of  Barbon  are  erroneous  he,  liowever, 
attacks  very  ably  Locke's  theory  that  the  value 
of  money  was  the  result  of  common  assent  (p.  9). 
Barbon  distinguishes,  with  great  ingenuity,  between 
the  value  and  the  "  vertue  "  of  a  thing,  the  latter 
being  the  same  at  all  places,  the  former  varying 
according  to  its  plenty  or  scarcity  (p.  7).  His 
refutation,  in  this  work,  of  the  doctrine  of  the 
balance  of  trade,  his  remarks  on  the  preference 
given  to  yold  and  silver,  which  he  compares  with 
the  fable  o'  Midas,  on  the  restraint  on  consumption, 
and  in  coTise(|uence  on  prohibition  of  foreign  goods 
(pp.  35-49),  are  developments  of  opinions  expressed 
in  his  former  writings.  There  is,  according  to  him, 
but  one  infallible  symptom  to  know  when  Trading 
Nations  grow  rich  :  by  the  increase  of  population 
manifesting  itself  by  tlie  enlargement  of  towns  and 
also  of  the  naval  strength  (p.  52). 

[The  Discourse  of  Trade  is  quoted  by  E.  H., 
Reasons  for  the  A  batement  of  Interest  to  four  in. 
the  Hundred,  1692,  p.  6. — E.  H.  wrote :  Decus  H 
Tutamen  ;  or  our  New  Money  as  noxo  coined  in 
full  Weight  proved  to  he  for  the  Honour,  Safety, 
and  Advantage  of  England — written  by  Way  of 
Ans^oer  to  Sir  Richard  Temple  and  Dr.  Barbon, 
1696.  On  the  latter  cp.  M'Culloch,  Literature, 
p.  157. — M'Leod,  Dictionary  of  Political  J£conoviy, 
pp.  232,  233.— K.  Marx,  Capital,  vol.  i.  pp.  2-4.— 
Cunningham,  The  Growth  of  English  Industry 
and  Commerce,  p.  351,  368,  ed.  1882.— C.  Walford, 
Insurance  Cyclopicedia,  vol.  i.  p.  251,  vol.  iii.  p. 
459,  and  the  present  writer  on  Nicholas  Barbon, 
in  "Ein  Beitrag  zur  Vorgeschichte  der  Klassischen 
Oekonomik,"  Conrad's  JahrhiXcher  fur  National- 
okonomie  und  Statistik,  xxi.  Bd.  N.F.  p.  561-590 
(1890).]  s.  B. 

BARING,  Sir  Francis,  Bart.,  was  born  in 
1740,  of  German  extraction,  the  founder  of  the 
famous  financial  house  of  Baring  Brothers  and 
Co.  Erskine  styled  him  "the  first  merchant  in 
Europe."     He  died  11th  September  1810. 

He  wrote — 

The  Principle  of  the  Commutation  Act  Estab- 
lished by  Facts,  London,  1786,  8vo  (two  editions  ; 
supports  the  reduction  of  duties  on  tea  and  other 
commodities). — Observations  on  the  Establishment 
of  the  Bank  of  England,  and  on  the  Paper  Circu- 
lation of  the  Country,  London,  1797,  8vo. — F^crther 
Observations,  London,  1797,  8vo  (describes  the 
panic  of  1793,  and  supports  the  policy  of  restric- 
tion).— Observations  on  the  Publication  of  W.  Boyd 
[entitled  Letter  on  the  Influence  of  the  Stop>page 
of  Issues  in  Specie'],  London  1801,  8vo.      h.  r.  t. 

BARNARD,  Sir  John,  was  born  at  Reading, 


of  Quaker  parents,  in  1685,  and  died  at  Clap- 
ham,  1764.  He  entered  the  London  wine  trade, 
was  M.P.  for  London  from  1728-1761,  and  was 
knighted  in  1732.  He  was  chosen  lord  mayor 
in  1737,  and  opposed  Walpole  ;  ultimately  he 
became  one  of  the  foremost  financial  authorities 
in  England,  and  helped  to  abate  the  run  on  the 
Bank  of  England  in  1745.     He  wrote — 

Reasons  for  the  llepnesentatives  of  the  People  of 
England  to  take  advantage  of  the  Present  Rate  oj 
Interest  for  the  more  Speedy  Lessening  the  National 
Debt,  London,  1737,  folio  (detailing  an  unsuccess- 
ful jDroposal  made  by  Barnard  in  parliament  to 
reduce  the  rate  to  3  per  cent). — A  Defence  of 
Several  Proposals  for  Raising  of  Three  Millions 
for  the  Service  of  the  Government,  with  a  Postscript 
on  PiMick  Credit,  London,  1746,  8vo. — Letter  to 
an  M.P.  on  the  Rejection  of  the  Scheme,  London, 
1746,  8vo. — Considerations  on  the  Propjosal  for 
Reducing  the  Interest  on  the  National  Debt, 
London,  1750,  8vo  (recommending  Pelham's  pro- 
ject),— Some  thoughts  on  the  Scarcity  of  Silver 
Coin,  ririth  a  Proposal  for  Remedy,  London,  1759, 
folio  (single  sheet).  h.  r.  t. 

BARRATOR.  One  who  incites  to  litigation 
or  quarrels.  A  person  who  is  found  to  be  a 
common  (habitual)  bari'ator  is  guilty  of  the 
oll'ence  of  barratry,  which  is  punishable  by  im- 
})risonment  and  fine  ;  and  if  the  oUender's  pro- 
fession be  in  any  way  connected  with  the  law, 
lie  may  also  be  forbidden  to  practise  for  the 
future.  The  word  barrator  in  a  now  obsolete 
sense  also  implied  a  deceitful  person,  and  from 
the  word  in  this  sense  the  expression  barratry 
as  used  in  maritime  law  is  probably  derived. 
In  this  application  the  word  means  a  wilful  or 
grossly  negligent  act  of  the  master  of  a  ship  by 
which  the  owner  is  damaged.  Barratry  is  one 
of  the  risks  generally  excepted  in  bills  of  lading, 
and  it  is  one  of  the  perils  insured  against  on 
ordinary  marine  insurance  policies.  e.  s. 

BARRINGTON,  Shute  (1734-1826),  suc- 
cessively Bishop  of  Llandafi',  Salisbury,  and 
Durham.  He  established  in  1795  one  of  the 
earliest  co-operative  stores  at  ]\longewell  (Ox- 
fordshire). He  was  president  of  the  Society  for 
Bettering  the  Condition  and  Increasing  the 
Comforts  of  the  Poor  (1796). 

[Bishop  Barrington's  practical  work  is  fully 
described  in  G.  J.  Holyoake's  Self-help  a  Hun- 
dred Years  ago,  chs.  i.  iv.  viii.  xiv.  xv.  xxviii. 
1888  (see  Bernard,  Sir  Thomas). — Dictionary  of 
National  Biography,  vol.  iii.  p.  294.]  s.  B. 

BARTER.  In  primitive  states  of  society 
exchange  of  commodities  is  efiected  directly,  and 
without  the  intervention  of  money ;  such  a 
method  of  exchange  is  called  barter.  It  is 
highly  probable  that  loan  preceded  exchange, 
at  least  as  regards  scarce  articles,  the  more 
plentiful  commodities  being  distributed  amongst 
individuals  in  joint  or  separate  ownership.  In 
the  case  of  a  loan  to  a  stranger,  an  owner 
^vould  not  have  the  same  guarantee  for  the 
return  of  the  article  as  if  the  loan  were  made 


BARTER  AND  EXCHANGE— BARTON 


to  a  member  of  his  tribe,  and  hence  he  would 
require  some  equivalent  in  return.  Thus  we 
reach  exchange  in  the  form  of  barter. 

Jevoi^s  has  pointed  out  the  inconveniences  ot' 
barter  :  (1)  want  of  coincidence  ;  (2)  want  of  a 
measTU-e  of  value  ;  and  (3)  want  of  mean§  of 
subdivision.  (Money,  and  the  Mechanism  of  Ex- 
change, London,  1882.)  These  inconveniences 
are  avoided  by  the  introduction  of  money  (see 
Money),  which  serves  as  a  medium  of  exchange. 
The  metals  prove  to  be  the  most  convenient 
commodities  for  effecting  exchanges,  and 
amongst  metals,  gold  and  silver  specially 
possess  the  qualities  essential  in  money. 

But  metallic  money  in  bulk  is  weighty ;  it 
can  be  transmitted  to  a  distance  only  at  con- 
siderable expense  and  risk ;  whilst  its  use 
involves  loss  by  wear  and  tear.  To  avoid  these 
disadvantages  representative  moneys  in  the 
form  of  promises  to  pay  have  been  introduced. 

When  promises  to  pay  came  to  be  accepted 
in  return  for  commodities,  it  was  seen  that 
wherever  mutual  dealings  existed  between  two 
persons,  equivalent  quantities  of  goods  estimated 
in  money  could  be  set  off,  so  as  to  pay  for 
each  other.  The  origin  of  this  modern  system 
of  set  off  may  be  traced  to  the  Roman  Law 
(Hunter's  Roman  Law,  London,  1885,  p.  832). 
But  the  system  was  perfected  by  the  introduc- 
tion of  Bills  of  Exchange  and  Cheques,  and 
the  development  of  the  modern  clearing  system 
(see  Clearing  House).  In  foreign  trade 
where  two  countries  are  constantly  buying  the 
one  from  the  other,  bills  of  exchange  enable  the 
goods  passing  in  one  direction  to  pay  for  those 
going  in  the  opposite  direction,  and  even  where 
two  countries  do  not  have  mutual  dealings, 
they  will  be  able  to  obtain  payment  for  their 
exports  by  imports  from  other  countries  with 
which  both  are  accustomed  to  trade  (see 
Goschen's  Foreign  Exchanges,  London,  1888). 

In  the  home  trade  cheques  are  used  as  well 
as  bills.  By  means  of  cheques  traders  are 
able  to  transfer  portions  of  their  book  credit 
at  their  banks  to  third  parties  in  exchange  for 
commodities,  and  the  institution  called  the 
Clearing  House  balances  the  mutual  indebted- 
ness for  the  traders  (Jevons's  Money).  Such  a 
method  of  exchange  is  really  barter :  metallic 
money  being  used  to  compare  the  values  of 
commodities,  and  ceasing  to  effect  exchanges, 
except  where  a  balance  of  indebtedness  can  be 
discharged  in  no  other  way. 

Barter  underlies  the  distribution  of  the 
annual  produce  of  a  nation  amongst  the  various 
classes  who  assist  in  production.  Though  the 
landlord,  the  employer,  the  capitalist,  and  the 
labourer,  receive  their  respective  shares  in 
money,  yet  to  the  economist  such  money  repre- 
sents only  produce  or  its  equivalent  in  other 
commodities.  For  instance,  the  articles  that 
the  labourer  buys  with  his  wages  are  the  real 
return   he   receives   for   his   services,   and   his 


services  may  be  regarded  as  bartered  for  such 
articles  (see  Sidgwick's  Political  Economy,  bk. 
ii.  ch.  i. ;  Marshall's  Principles  of  Economics,  p. 
395).     See  Truck  Acts.  j.  e.  c.  m. 

BARTER  AND  EXCHANGE.  Barter,  as 
distinct  from  exchange,  is  defined  by  the 
absence  of  money  both  as  a  medium  of  exchange 
and  a  measure  of  value.  In  the  absence  of  a 
measure  of  value,  complicated  transactions 
between  several  dealers  are  hardly  possible  ; 
and  accordingly  barter  is  generally  characterised 
by  the  absence  of  competition.  In  the  absence 
of  competition  bargains  are  not  determinate  in 
the  same  sense  as  in  a  perfect  market.  In  the 
former,  unlike  the  latter,  case  you  might  sup- 
pose the  dispositions  of  the  parties,  their 
demand  curves  or  "schedules"  (Marshall) 
known,  and  yet  even  theoretically  be  unable 
to  predict  what  would  be  the  terms  of  the 
bargain  (see  Competition  and  Regulation  ; 
Value).  As  Jevons  says  of  such  a  case^— - 
with,  in  the  context,  unnecessary  emphasis  on 
the  indivisibility  of  the  commodity  exchanged, 
— "The  equations  of  exchange  will  fail.  .  .  . 
I  conceive  that  such  a  transaction  must  be 
settled  upon  other  than  strictly  economical 
grounds.  The  result  of  the  bargain  will 
greatly  depend  upon  the  comparative  amount 
of  knowledge  of  each  other's  positions  and  needs 
which  either  bargainer  may  possess  or  manage 
to  obtain  in  the  course  of  the  transaction " 
(Theory  of  Political  Economy,  pp.  130-134, 
2d  ed.)  To  which  Mr.  Price  adds,  "Nor 
indeed,  did  they  possess  the  gift  of  clairvoyance, 
would  the  problem  be  necessarily  solved  "  {In- 
dustrial  Peace,  p.  54).  It  is  important  to 
study  this  property  of  barter  not  so  much  on 
account  of  the  rudimentary  transactions  to 
which  the  term  is  properly  confined  as  for  the 
sake  of  their  analogy  to  the  dealings  of  mono- 
polists and  combinations  in  advanced  societies. 

[The  subject  in  question  is  discussed  in  the  fol- 
lowing passages.  Auspitz  and  Lieben,  Theorie 
des  Preises,  p.  381. — Edgeworth,  Mathematical 
Psychics,  pp.  20-56.  —  "Observations  on  the 
Mathematical  Theory  of  Economics,"  Giornale  degli 
Economisti,  March  1891. — Marshall,  Principles  of 
Economics,"'^ oie  on  Barter," — '^&ag&c,GTundsatze, 
ch.  iv. — Price,  Industrial  Peace,  pp.  14  and  54. — 
Sidgwick,  Political  Economy,  bk.  ii.  ch.  x. 

The  formation  of  appropriate  conceptions  on 
the  subject  is  aided  by  those  economists  who,  im- 
proving on  the  ordinary  "Robinsonnade,"  introduce 
a  second  primitive  economic  man.  Good  examples 
occur  in  Courcelle  Seneuil's  Traite  theoriqiie  et 
pratique,  and  Mr.  Gonner's  textbook  of  Political 
Economy,']  f.  y.  e. 

BARTON,  John,  of  Stoughton,  the  author  of 
several  clever  but  somewhat  unsound  pamphlets. 

Observations  on  the  Circumstances  which  influ- 
ence the  Condition  of  the  Working  Classes,  London, 
1817,  8vo  (see  M'Culloch's  Principles  of  Political 
Economy). — Inquiry  into  the  Causes  of  the  Pro- 
gressive Depreciation  of  Agricultural  Labour  in 


BASTIAT 


123 


Modern  Times,  London,  1820,  8vo  (stated  to  be 
owing  to  the  depreciation  of  the  value  of  corn). 
■ — Inquiry  into  the  Expediency  of  the  Existing 
Restrictions  on  the  Importation  of  Foreign  Corn, 
London,  1833,  8vo.  H.  R.  t. 

BASTIAT,  FriSderic.  This  well-known 
French  economist,  a  friend  of  Cobden,  born 
1801  at  Mugron,  near  Bayonne,  died  1850  at 
Rome.  But  for  a  few  casual  circumstances 
which  drew  out  his  literary  powers,  Bastiat 
would  have  died  comparatively  unknown,  his 
first  book  only  appearing  in  1845,  five  years 
before  his  death.  He  had  lived  up  to  that  date 
in  retirement,  working  hard,  but  producing 
little.  The  son  of  a  merchant  in  the  Spanish 
trade,  he  Avas  left  an  orphan  when  nine  years 
old.  As  a  man,  he  tried  his  hand,  without  gi'eat 
success,  first  in  business,  in  the  establishment 
of  his  uncle,  then  in  farming  at  Mugron  on  the 
estate  Avhich  he  inherited  at  the  death  of  his 
grandfather,  1825.  Appointed  after  the  revolu- 
tion of  1830yw</g  depaix  of  his  canton,  he  seemed 
destined  to  die  in  the  little  town  where  he  had 
been  born,  limiting  his  ambition  to  the  direc- 
tion of  a  small  scientific  society  whose  discus- 
sions appear  to  have  been  dc  omni  re  scibili  et 
quibusdam  aliis.  His  first  pamphlets  were  little 
memoirs  on  local  matters,  the  interest  of  which, 
notwithstanding  the  high  qualities  of  style  and 
form  they  possessed,  was  necessarily  limited  to 
a  narrow  circle  ;  their  titles  are  A21X  Electeurs 
du  diparteiiient  des  Landes  (1830)  ;  Reflexions 
sur  les  petitions  de  Bordeaux  conccrnant  les 
douanes  (1834)  ;  Le  Fisc  et  la  Vigne  (1841)  ; 
La  question  vinicole  (1843) ;  La  Repartition  de  la 
contribution  fonciere  dans  les  Landes  (1844). 

To  England  belongs  the  honour  of  having 
lighted  up  in  Bastiat  the  sacred  fire  of  thought. 
An  English  journal  to  which  he  subscribed  al- 
most by  accident,  the  Globe,  informed  him  of  the 
foundation  and  progress  of  the  Anti-Corn  Laav 
League,  the  existence  of  which  was  barely 
known  in  France.  The  examples  of  Cobden, 
Bright,  Thompson,  Moore,  and  Fox  roused 
Bastiat,  who  resolved  to  imitate  them.  A  few 
weeks  later  and  the  Journal  des  Economistes 
received  from  the  farthest  end  of  the  district 
of  the  Landes  a  manuscript  signed  with  an 
unknown  name,  i)e  V influence  des  tarifs  franc^ais 
et  anglais  sur  Vavenir  des  deux  peuples.  The 
article  appeared  October  1844,  and  excited  a 
good  deal  of  attention.  The  author  was  asked 
for  more  ;  and  the  file  of  Sophismes  Ecmiomiques 
commenced,  to  the  joy  of  the  opponents,  and  the 
confusion  of  the  defenders,  of  privilege.  Nothing 
is  more  brilliant,  nothing  more  French,  in  the 
best  sense  of  the  word,  than  these  amusing 
pamphlets,  in  which  the  most  delicate  irony  and 
the  most  pitiless  logic  are  combined,  as  in  the 
famous  Petition  des  fabricants  de  chandelles, 
bougies,  lampes,  chandeliers,  reverberes,  mou- 
chettes,  eteignoirs,  et  des  producteurs  de  suif  huile 
r6sin£,  alcool,  et  g4n6ralement  de  tout  ce  qui  con- 


cerne  Viclairage.  This  petition  of  the  candle 
makers  is  a  humorous  complaint  against  the  sun 
for  spoiling  their  trade,  a  petition  based  on  pro- 
tectionist lines.  ''We  demand,"  say  the  peti- 
tioners at  the  close  of  their  arguments, 

"  Qu'il  vous  plaise  de  faire  une  loi  qui  ordonne 
la  fernieture  de  toutes  fenetres,  lucarnes,  abat-jour, 
contre-vents,  volets,  rideaux,  vasistas,  oeils-de-boeuf, 
stores,  en  un  mot,  de  toutes  ouvertures,  trous, 
fentes  et  fissures  par  lesquelles  la  lumiere  du  soleil 
a  coutume  de  penetrer  dans  les  maisons,  au  pre- 
judice des  belles  industries  dont  nous  nous  tiattons 
d'avoir  dote  le  pays,  qui  ne  saurait  sans  ingrati- 
tude nous  abandonner  aujourd'hui  a  une  lutte  si 
inegale." 

From  a  purely  literary  point  of  view  several 
of  these  satires  are  first-rate.  At  this  time 
Bastiat  also  wrote  his  first  book,  Cobden  et  la 
Ligue  ou  V agitation  anglaise  pour  la  liberti  des 
echanges,  and  finally  left  Mugi'on  for  Paris. 

He  soon  became  the  most  active  and  dreaded 
antagonist  of  the  protectionist  policy.  The 
war  tariff's  of  the  first  empire  had  been  con- 
tinued after  the  restoration  by  the  monarchy 
of  July  (Louis  Philippe).  The  first  Association 
pour  la  liberty  des  echanges  was  formed  at  Bor- 
deaux, February  1846  ;  another  was  established 
at  Paris  the  same  year  with  Bastiat  a^  general 
secretary,  and  le  Libre  Echange  as  its  journal. 
This  free-trade  campaign  was  roughly  interrupted 
by  the  revolution  of  1848  ;  and  the  French 
economists,  and  Bastiat  among  them,  found 
themselves  compelled  to  direct  their  eff'orts  and 
their  forces  against  the  spread  of  socialism. 
Bastiat  harassed  those  who  followed  Louis 
Blanc,  Considerant,  P.  Leroux,  Proudhon, 
with  epigrams  and  refutations,  and  thus  assisted 
in  enlightening  the  country  as  to  the  perils  with 
which  the  revolutionary  Utopia  threatened  it, 
see  Propri4t6  et  Loi,  Proprieti  et  Spoliation, 
Justice  et  Fraternite,  etc.  His  conflict  with 
Proudhon  {q.v.)  on  La  gratuite  du  credit,  will 
always  be  considered  one  of  the  most  brilliant 
passages  of  arms  of  French  economic  science  at 
this  critical  epoch. 

At  the  elections  of  August  1848,  the  depart- 
ment of  the  Landes  returned  Bastiat  to  the 
Assemblee  Gonstituante,  and  May  1849  to  the 
AssembUe  Legislative.  Here  he  rarely  spoke. 
He  did  not  possess  the  physical  qualifications 
of  an  orator,  and  the  extraordinary  exertions  he 
had  imposed  on  himself  since  he  moved  to 
Paris  completed  the  niin  of  his  health,  previously 
much  shattered.  After  having  victoriously 
refuted  the  errors  of  protection  and  socialism, 
he  thought  it  was  time  for  him  to  formulate 
what  he  considered  the  true  economic  doctrine, 
and  commenced  the  publication  of  his  Harmonies. 
In  this  brilliant  work,  unhappily  never  finished, 
Bastiat  shows  the  contrast  between  the  internal 
weakness  of  the  artificial  organisations  which 
are  founded  on  constraint,  and  the  prosperity 
spontaneously  arising  in  an  economic  condition 


124 


BASTIAT— BATBIE 


in  which  the  equilibrium  of  individual  and 
collective  forces  results  from  their  free  and 
reciprocal  balance.  This  is  the  fundamental 
thought  (id4e  mere)  on  which  the  Harmonies 
Economiques  are  based,  and  granted  this  as  a 
philosophic  basis,  it  could  not  have  begn 
developed  with  more  skill.  Some  of  Bastiat's 
opinions  have  been  criticised — notably  his  theory 
of  value — and  he  may  also  be  complained  of  as 
being  too  much  of  an  optimist.  But  for  all 
that  no  one  has  succeeded  better  in  making 
his  readers  admire  the  science  which  he  himself 
loved  so  well.  Political  economy  has  been 
indebted  to  him,  both  during  his  short  life  and 
after  it,  for  some  of  its  worthiest  followers. 
The  first  volume  only  of  his  Harmonies  had 
been  published  when  Bastiat,  wearied  and  worn 
out,  sought  rest  in  Italy.  He  died  in  Rome 
24th  December  1850,  as  a  Christian  ;  his  last 
words  were  la  verite. 

[For  life  of  Bastiat,  see  speech  on  the  occasion 
of  the  inauguration  of  monument  at  Mugron  by 
M.  Leon  Say,  1878.  Notices  by  MM.  R.  de 
Fontenay, — F.  Passy, — Paillottet, — De  Molinari, 
— Paul  Gardelle, — Baunard, — De  Foville, — A. 
Courtois  fills,  Madame  Cheuvreux  published, 
1870,  part  of  the  correspondence  of  Bastiat, 
Lettres  d'un  habitant  des  Landes.  ]  a.  de  F. 

BASTIAT  AS  A  Theorist.  The  Harmonies 
of  Bastiat  have  not  been  re-echoed  by  economists 
with  one  accord.  According  to  Cairnes  {Fort- 
nightly Review,  1870),  "all  that  is  peculiar  to 
his  scheme  of  speculation"  rests  on  his  doctrine 
oi service  ;  "and,  this  failing,  the  entire  fabric 
inevitably  collapses."  By  "the  shifting  uses 
of  an  ambiguous  term"  Bastiat  confounds 
what  RiCARDO  and  others  had  distinguished  : 
cases  where  value  is,  and  is  not,  proportioned 
to  efforts  and  sacrifices  (see  Difficulty  of 
Attainment).  Value  in  all  cases,  according 
to  Bastiat,  represents  service.  "Such  a 
generalisation,"  says  Cairnes,  "  is  no  generalisa- 
tion in  the  scientific  sense  of  the  term  ;  it  is  a 
mere  confounding  of  unanalysed  phenomena 
under  an  ambiguous  word."  Describing  all 
commercial  transactions  as  a  reciprocity  of 
services,  Bastiat  attempted  not  only  to  explain, 
but  to  justify  the  existing  regime,  and  failed  in 
both  attempts,  which  he  never  ought  to  have 
combined  {Fortnightly  Review,  vol.  viii.  p.  426, 
et  seq.)  Dr.  Sidgwick  in  the  third  book  of  his 
Principles  of  Political  Economy,  has  afforded 
the  most  complete  refutation  of  the  economic 
optimists,  "  of  whom  Bastiat  may  be  taken  as  a 
type"  {ibid.  ch.  ii.  §  1).  Professor  Marshall 
says  of  Bastiat;  "the  lucidity  of  his  style 
caused  him  to  have  great  vogue  ;  but  he  really 
understood  economic  science,  in  the  name  of 
which  he  professed  to  write,  hardly  better  than 
did  the  socialists  themselves "  {Principles  of 
Economics,  bk.  i.  ch.  iv.  §  6,  n.  2).  Cournot  also 
should  be  referred  to  among  the  profound  and 
unbiassed  thinkers  who  have  exposed  the  un- 


scientific character  of  economic  optimism  {Prin- 
cipes  de  la  tMorie  des  Richesses,  1863,  livre  iv. 
I'optimisme  economique,  Cp.  Revue  Sommaire, 
1874).  A  less  temperate  criticism  of  Bastiat'a 
theories  may  be  read  with  amusement  in  Las- 
salle's  Herr  Bastiat- Schulze  von  Delitzsch  .  .  . 
oder  Capital  und  Arbeit  (1864)  ;  addressed  to 
Schulze-Delitzsch,  but  striking  through  him 
at  Bastiat.  Lassalle  fastens  on  the  weak  point, 
the  theory  of  services,  and,  with  much  humour 
and  more  insolence,  proves  it  to  be  "no  economic 
category  "  (p.  132,  et  seq.)  but  rather  an  "  econ- 
omic enormity  without  parallel" — "Yet  this  is 
the  only  new  thing  which  that  clever  windbag 
{geistreiche  blageur)  has  said  in  his  primer 
(Jihel)." 

Severe  as  are  these  judgments,  and  in  one 
case  at  least  exaggerated,  they  cannot  be 
wholly  set  aside.  But  the  opinion  that  Bastiat 
did  not  make  any  considerable  contribution  to 
abstract  theory  is  not  inconsistent  with  grati- 
tude to  him  for  having  popularised  (in  the  best 
sense  of  the  term)  the  discoveries  of  his  prede- 
cessors. It  is  admitted  that  in  the  exposure  of 
economic  fallacies  Bastiat  is  unrivalled.  The 
same  Cairnes  who  judges  the  Harmonics  so 
severely  calls  ^Bastiat  to  his  aid  when  he  is 
combating  economic  sophisms  {Leading  Prin- 
ciples, pt.  ii.  ch.  ii.) 

[See,  in  addition  to  the  authors  who  have  been 
mentioned  as  critics  of  Bastiat,  Bohm  Bawerk, 
Geschichte  und  Kritik  der  Zinsentheorien  (1884).] 

F.Y.B. 

BATBIE,  Anselme  Polycarpe,  born  at 
Seyssan  (Gers)  1828,  died  at  Paris  1887.  He 
entered  the  Conseil  d'Uat  in  1849,  but  left  it  at 
the  coup  d'itat  of  2d  December  1851,  to  give 
himself  up  to  teaching.  It  was  not  long  before 
he  became  first  supplementary  professor  1857, 
then  full  professor,  1862,  at  the  £cole  de  Droit 
at  Paris,  in  "  Droit  administratif  "  and  "  ificono- 
mie  Politique. "  Elected  deputy  to  the  AssembUe 
Nation/lie  in  1871,  he  found  his  place  among 
the  monarchists,  and  was  one  of  the  foremost 
opponents  of  the  republican  form  of  government. 
It  was  he  who  invented  the  phrase  the  Gouverne- 
ment  de  combat,  a  mot  which  had  a  great  success. 
In  1875  he  was  elected  a  permanent  senator. 
The  delicacy  of  his  mode  of  thought  would 
always  have  held  him  back  from  becoming  the 
champion  of  the  reactionary  party. 

Besides  his  works  on  law,  of  which  the  most 
important  is  his  Traiti  theorique  et  pratique  de 
droit  public  et  administratif  {1  vols,  in  8vo,  1862- 
66),  we  may  mention  his  economic  works,  Le  credit 
popvlaire  (1864,  1  vol.  in  18mo) — Turgot,  Philo- 
sophe,  Economiste,  et  Administrateur  {1  vol.  in  8vo, 
1866)  (couronne  by  the  Institut), — Nouveau  cours 
d'iconomie  politique,  1866  (2  vols,  in  8vo), — and 
finally  Milanges  d' econoviie  politique  {Mmioire  sur 
le  pret  d  interet,  coxironne  by  the  Institut,  and 
Mevwire  sur  l'imp)6t  avant  et  apres,  1789-1861, 
1  vol.  in  8vo).  A.  c.  f. 


BATE'S  CASE— BAUMSTARK 


125 


BATE'S  CASE,  on  the  Case  of  Impositions. 
The  right  of  the  crown  to  levy  customs  duties 
without  the  consent  of  parliament  had  been 
abolished — at  all  events  in  the  case  of  wool — by 
a  statute  of  1362,  and  had  not  been  revived 
until  the  16th  century.  Mary  and  Elizabeth 
had  both  imposed  small  duties  on  articles  of 
commerce,  but  this  had  been  done  with  the 
consent  of  the  merchants,  and  had  attracted  no 
attention.  It  was  reserved  for  James  I.,  relying 
upon  the  subservience  of  the  judges,  to  make 
arbitrary  customs  an  Important  som-ce  of  re- 
venue. Tonnage  and  Poundage,  which  had 
been  granted  for  life  to  every  king  since  Henry 
v.,  included  a  duty  of  2s.  6d.  per  cwt.  of  cur- 
rants. James  by  his  own  authority  imjiosed 
another  5s.,  and  thus  trebled  the  duty.  John 
Bate,  a  merchant  of  tlie  Levant  Co.,  refused  to 
pay,  on  the  ground  that  the  tax  could  only 
lawfully  be  imposed  by  parliament.  The  case 
was  brought  before  the  exchequer  court,  and 
the  decision  of  the  judges  is  an  important  illus- 
tration of  the  legal  theories  of  the  Stuart  period. 
They  declared  that  the  king's  power  is  of  two 
kinds,  ordinary  and  absolute.  His  ordinary 
power  is  exercised  in  the  interest  of  individuals, 
and  is  limited  by  common  and  statute  law. 
His  absolute  power,  on  the  other  hand,  is  exer- 
oised  for  the  welfare  of  the  whole  state,  and  is 
not  so  limited.  Customs  are  the  effect  of  com- 
merce ;  but  commerce  and  all  foreign  relations, 
such  as  war  and  pejice,  belong  to  the  king's 
absolute  power.  He  who  has  power  over  the 
cause  has  power  also  over  the  effect.  The  sea- 
ports are  the  king's  gates,  which  he  can  open 
or  shut  as  he  pleases.  Hence  the  customs  are 
subject  to  the  king's  absolute  power,  and  can 
be  levied  or  increased  at  his  will.  This  decision 
was  acquiesced  in  at  the  moment,  and  enabled 
James  to  issue  a  Book  of  Rates  in  1608.  In 
1610  parliament  took  the  matter  up,  and  pro- 
tested against  the  claim  to  levy  impositions 
without  consent.  But  they  failed  to  carry  their 
bill  on  the  subject,  and  the  decision  in  Bate's 
case  continued  to  be  legally  valid  imtil  all 
arbitrary  taxation  was  swept  away  by  the 
Long  Parliament. 

[State  Trials,  vol.  ii. — Gardiner,  History  of 
England,  vol.  ii. — Hallam,  Constitutional  His- 
tory, vol.  i.]  li.  L. 

BAUDEAU,  Nicolas,  Abbe,  born  at  Am- 
boise  in  1730,  died,  out  of  his  mind,  it  is  be- 
lieved, about  1792.  He  gave  up  his  ecclesias- 
tic status  to  establish,  at  the  end  of  1765,  the 
Ephemirides  du  citoyen  ou  chronique  de  V esprit 
natioTial,  a  periodical  opposed  at  first  to  the 
party  of  the  Economists  ;  but  which,  by  a 
conversion  most  honourable  to  Baudeau,  be- 
came, after  1766,  the  most  accredited  organ  of 
the  Physiocrats.  For  example,  the  cause  of 
humanity,  and  the  abolition  of  negro  slavery," 
were  pleaded  by  him  with  great  warmth.  He 
even  invented,  to  keep  these  all  together,  the 


word  Humanisms.  It  was  not  long  before  he 
altered  the  sub-title  of  his  journal  to  that  of 
Biblioiheque  raisonnee  des  sciences  morales  et 
politiques.  On  accepting  a  canonry  in  Poland, 
he  handed  over,  May  1768,  to  Du  Pont  (De 
Nemours)  the  chief  editorship  of  his  review, 
which  was  suppressed  by  order  in  1772  (69  vols, 
in  1 2mo  had  appeared).  Returning  to  France, 
he  brought  his  review  out  under  the  title  of 
EpJUmArides  6conx)viiques  ou  Bibliotheque  raison- 
nie  de  I'histoire,  de  la  morale  et  de  la  politique  (19 
numbers  in  12mo,  from  December  1773  to  Jime 
1776).  His  principal  work,  was  the  Premiere 
introduction  d  la  philosophie  ^conomique  ou 
analyse  des  Stats  policis,  in  which  he  refuted 
brilliantly  the  Abbe  Galiani  (1771,  in  8vo,  in- 
serted in  the  collection  of  the  principal  econom- 
ists published  by  Guillaumin).  This  secured 
him  a  high  place  among  the  economists  of  the 
school  of  the  Physiocrats.  His  restless  spirit, 
his  changeable  disposition,  and  the  want  of 
financial  order  in  his  private  affairs,  brought  on 
him  criticisms  sometimes  not  undeserved. 

A,  c.  f. 

BAUDI,  Carlo,  di  Vesme,  was  the  author  of 
one  of  the  best  books  on  the  history  of  landed 
property  in  Italy  from  the  fall  of  the  Roman 
empire  up  to  the  establishment  of  feudalism. 
( Vicende  della  proprietcL  in  Italia  dalla  caduta 
delV  impcro  romaTW  alio  stabilimento  dei  fcudi, 
1836,  Torino).  The  academy  of  Turin  honoured 
this  work  by  a  prize.  Baudi  di  Vesme  also 
gained  a  prize  from  the  Academie  des  Inscrip- 
tions et  Belles  Lettres  for  a  book  on  the 
question  of  taxation  in  France  under  the  first 
two  dynasties :  Trihuti  nelle  Gallic  durante  le 
due  prime  dinastie.  He  edited  the  Laios  of  the 
Longobards,  and  WTote  a  book  on  the  political 
and  economical  condition  of  Sardinia  :  Con- 
siderazioni  politiche  ed  economiche  sulla  Sar- 
degna. 

Baudi  was  born  at  Cuneo  1809,  and  died 
1877.  He  was  educated  by  the  Jesuits,  and 
became  famous  as  a  Latin  and  Greek  scholar. 
In  1837  he  was  made  a  member  of  the  Academy 
of  Turin,  and  in  1850  a  senator.  m.  ]>. 

BAUMSTARK,  Edward  (1807-1889),  an 
eminent  German  economist,  born  at  Sinzlieim, 
became  privat-docent  in  cameral  science  at 
Heidelberg  in  1823,  was  appointed  professor 
at  Greifswald  in  1843,  and  the  same  year  was 
made  director  of  the  economic  academy  at  El- 
dena.  He  was  Geheimer  Regierungsratli,  and 
sat  in  the  Prussian  Herrenhaus,  acting  in 
politics  with  the  national  liberal  party.  He 
died  8th  April  1889.  The  earlier  of  his  two 
principal  economic  writings,  Staatstuissenschaft- 
liche  Versiiche  iiber  Staatskredit,  Staatsschulden, 
und  Staatspapiere,  1833,  is  founded  mainly  on 
the  Oeffentliche  Credit  of  Nebenius,  but  contains 
some  independent  investigations.  His  most 
valuable  work  was  his  excellent  translation  of 
RiCARDO's  Principles — David  Ricardo's  Grund- 


126 


BAXTER— BAZAAR 


gesetze  der  Volkswirthschaft  und  Besteueruny 
ubersetzt  und  erldutert,  1838,  which  first  made 
that  ^vrite^'s  doctrines  generally  known  in 
Germany.  Though  strongly  influenced  by  the 
abstract  method  of  his  English  master,  he  re- 
cognised his  inferiority  to  Adam  Smith,  and 
saw  the  importance  of  the  historical  direction  in 
economic  studies.  He  gave  explanations  on 
profit,  rent,  price,  taxes,  paper  money,  an(^ 
public  debts,  which  contributed  to  the  right 
understanding  of  Ricardo  ;  improved  the  lan- 
guage in  which  his  doctrines  had  been  stated, 
and  corrected  the  exaggerations  of  his  followers. 
In  1835  he  published  a  Cameralistiche  Encydo- 
pddie,  which  took  rank  as  an  instructive  work 
for  the  use  of  German  officials.  He  was  also 
author  of  a  treatise  Zur  Einkommensteuerfrage, 
1860. 

[Roscher,  Nat.  Oek.  in  Deutschland,  p.  909.] 

J.  K.  I. 

BAXTER,  Robert  Dudley,  an  eminent 
statistician,  was  born  in  Doncaster  1827,  and 
died  at  Hampstead  1875.  He  belonged  to  the 
well-known  legal  firm  of  Baxters  &  Co.  He 
combined  in  a  remarkable  degree  the  pursuits 
of  business  and  literature,  the  character  of  a 
man  of  science  and  a  love  of  poetry.  His 
energy  in  obtaining  and  classifying  information 
was  unbounded,  as  well  as  the  goodwill  with 
which  he  imparted  it  to  others. 

Baxter's  statistical  work  may  be  divided  into 
two  classes  (a)  economical,  and  (b)  political. 

(a)  To  the  first  class  belong — (1)  The  Budget 
and  the  Income  Tax,  1860.  (2)  Bailway  Exten- 
sion and  its  results,  1866 — read  before  the 
Statistical  Society,  Dec.  1866,  and  afterwards 
published  separately ;  it  contains  statistics  of  the 
growth  and  distribution  of  railways,  a  state- 
ment of  their  cost  and  estimate  of  their  benefit, 
both  for  the  United  Kingdom  and  other  coun- 
tries. (3)  The  National  Income,  ld68 — the 
income  of  the  United  Kingdom  is  estimated  as 
£814,119,000;  divided  by  "the  equatorial 
line  of  British  income,"  £100  in  tAvo  nearly 
equal  portions,  accruing  respectively  to  those 
who  have  more  or  less  than  that  annual  sum. 
Baxter's  estimate  of  the  amount  of  income 
which  is  derived  from  capital  is  approved  by 
Sir  R.  Giff'en  with  some  reservation  {Essay  in 
Finance,  series  1  ;  Essay  on  Recent  Accumula- 
tion, pp.  166-170).  The  distinction  which 
Baxter  makes  between  productive  and  unpro- 
ductive (ch.  viii.),  "the  income  that  is  an  orig- 
inal and  fresh  contribution  to  the  common 
stock  from  that  which  is  merely  derived  from 
the  first,"  requires  consideration  (cp.  Leone 
Levi,  Wages  and  Earnings  of  the  Working 
Classes,  Reports  of  the  British  Association,  1881, 
p.  275,  and  1882,  p.  299).  (4)  The  Foreign 
Cattle  Market  Bill,  1869.  (5)  The  Taxation 
of  the  United  Kingdom.  After  a  clear  statement 
of  the  amount  of  taxation,  the  writer  estimates 
itt  distribution  and  pressure.     He  pronounces 


on  many  delicate  economic  questions,  e.g. 
"Railways  and  public  carriages  are  obliged  to  a 
great  extent  themselves  to  bear  the  contribu- 
tions levied  from  them,  from  the  existence  of 
maximum  charges  limited  by  law  or  by  the 
public  capacity  of  paying."  He  maintains  that 
taxes  on  property  do  not  become  rent  charges, 
and  disputes  »1ill's  principle  of  taxing  unearned 
increment  ot  rent.  He  settles  what  proportion 
of  the  rates  on  land  and  houses  are  borne  by 
landlord  and  tenant  respectively.  He  finds 
that  the  pressure  of  taxation  on  the  manual 
labour  classes  (eight  and  a  half  per  cent  of 
workmen's  earnings),  is  heavy  in  proportion  to 
the  taxation  of  the  larger  industrial  incomes  of 
the  upper  and  middle  classes  (eight  per  cent). 
To  estimate  the  pressure  of  taxation  on  the 
working  classes  he  collected  budgets  of  family  ex- 
penditure (see  Workmen's'  Budgets).  Atten- 
tion should  also  be  called  to  his  estimate  of  the 
property  of  the  United  Kingdom  (in  1869) 
£6,000,000,000.  (6)  National  Debts  of  the 
World,  1871.  Measured  in  four  ways  by:  (1) 
nominal  capital ;  (2)  interest  actually  paid  ; 
(3)  annual  charge  per  head  of  population  ;  (4) 
proportion  of  annual  charge  to  gross  income. 
The  last,  which  is  the  most  correct  method, 
makes  the  burden  in  1870  hardly  greater  than 
in  1700,  and  less  than  in  1712.  The  progress 
of  the  indebtedness  of  the  world  as  compared 
with  the  United  Kingdom  is  shown  by  the 
statement  that,  while  in  1848  our  debt  was 
nearly  half,  in  1870  it  is  just  a  fifth  of  the 
total  debt  of  the  world.  Absolutely,  the  debt 
of  the  United  Kingdom  was  reduced  slightly 
between  1848  and  1870.  In  respect  of  the 
burden  of  debt  there  appears  a  remarkable 
equality  between  the  United  Kingdom  and 
several  of  her  great  contemporaries. 

The  subject  is  brought  down  to  a  later  date 
in(7)  "Recent  Progress  of  National  Debts,"  1874 
{Journal  of  the  Statistical  Society).  (8)  Local 
Government  and  Taxation,  1874  ;  containing  a 
criticism  of  Mr.  Goschen's  report  on  the  increase 
of  local  taxation. 

(&)  The  rest  of  Baxter's  statistical  writings 
are  rather  political  than  economical. 

(1)  The  Volunteer  Movement,  1860.  (2)  The 
New  Reform  Bill ;  the  Franchise  Returns,  etc., 
1866.  (3)  The  Redistribution  of  Seats  and  the 
Counties,  1866  [with  which  should  be  read  letters 
to  the  Tivies  on  cognate  subjects  in  the  same  and 
the  following  year].  (4)  Results  of  the  General 
Election  of  1868,  1869.  (5)  History  of  English 
Parties  and  Conservatism,  1870.  (6)  The 
Political  Progress  of  the  Working  Classes,  1871. 

[A  beautiful  picture  of  Baxter's  simple  life  and 
a  useful  analysis  of  his  elaborate  works  are  given 
in  In  Memoriam  R.  B.  Baxter,  by  his  widow.] 

F.  Y.  E. 

BAZAAR.  A  Persian  word  meaning  a 
market.  In  this  sense  it  is  employed  in  India, 
Turkey,  and  other  eastern  countries.  In  Great 
Britain  the  signification  of  the  word  has  been 


BAZARD— BECCARIA 


127 


corrupted,  implying  either  a  collection  of  shops 
for  the  retailing  of  fancy  goods  or  the  temporary 
opening  by  amateurs  of  some  place  for  the  sale 
of  such  goods  and  for  amusement,  mostly  for 
the  benefit  of  a  charity.  We  need  only  consider 
the  term  in  the  sense  in  which  it  is  used  in  the 
East.  There  every  town  of  magnitude  is  pos- 
sessed of  its  bazaar,  which  is  the  centre  of  mer- 
cantile life,  where  business  both  wholesale  and 
retail  is  transacted,  and  where  news  is  circulated. 
The  bazaar  quarter  of  the  town,  is  often  a  col- 
lection of  streets  with  shops  entirely  distinct 
which  constitute  the  bazaar,  while  in  other 
cases  a  square  is  devoted  to  the  use  of  the  mer- 
chants and  dealers.  A  very  large  amount  of 
business  is  carried  on  through  the  medium  of 
bazaars ;  and  they  are  a  recognised  institution  of 
oriental  life. 

BAZARD,  Saint -Amand,  born  at  Paris 
1791,  died  at  Courtry  near  Montfermeil,  1832. 
He  was  one  of  the  three  founders  of  the  society 
of  the  Carbonari  {q.v.)  in  France  (1821),  and 
joined  in  the  active  work  of  the  Saint-Simonians 
after  the  death  of  Saint  Simon,  whom  he  had 
never  seen.  He  held  an  important  position  as 
editor  of  the  Produdeur  (1825-26),  of  the 
Organisateur  (second  of  that  nario,  1828-30), 
and  of  the  Globe  (1831).  With  Enfantin  he 
became  the  centre  of  the  Saint-Simonian  relig- 
ion ;  but  before  long  the  opinions  of  Enfantin, 
particularly  on  the  state  of  "Woman  in  the 
Family,"  caused  him  to  leave  it  (January  1832). 
To  explain  why  he  did  this  he  published  a 
pamphlet  called  Discussions  morales,  politiques 
et  religieuses,  January  1832.  a.  c.  f. 

BEAR.  Under  Backwardation  the  posi- 
tion of  a  seller  who  is  unable  to  deliver  according 
to  contract  has  been  shown.  A  Bear  is  a  seller 
in  blank,  and  from  settlement  to  settlement  he 
must  borrow  stock  on  the  best  terms  which  he 
can  make  in  order  to  arrange  the  Continuation 
{q.v.)  of  his  contract.  The  Avord,  no  doubt, 
arose  from  the  belief  that  one  who  sells  in  anti- 
cipation of  lower  prices  is  a  desponding,  pessi- 
mistic, and  misanthropic  person,  but  it  has 
been  so  long  in  use  that  there  is  no  certain 
knowledge  of  its  derivation.  In  America  one 
who  sells  as  a  Bear  of  stock  is  said  to  be  "  sell- 
ing short."  The  simple  adjective  "bare"  may 
be  the  origin  of  the  expression,  as,  when  the 
time  of  settlement  comes,  the  Bear  seller  is  bare 
or  short  of  the  security  which  he  has  contracted 
to  deliver.  When  he  has  ' '  bought  back, "  he 
is  said  to  have  "closed"  his  "bear."      A.  e. 

BEARER,  Bonds  to  hearer,  and  sometimes 
shares,  are  those  which  are  negotiable  instru- 
ments on  their  face.  Bearer  securities  are  dis- 
tinguished, on  the  stock  exchange,  from 
registered  securities  inasmuch  as  the  title  of 
the  former  passes  from  holder  to  holder,  while 
there  is  no  legal  title  to  a  registered  share  until 
the  owner  has  had  his  name  placed  on  the 
register  of  the  company  in  which  he  has  acquired 


a  share  or  shares  (see  Commercial  Instru- 
ment), A.  E. 

BECCARIA,  Cesare  Bonesana  (Marquis) 
born  1735,  at  Milan,  was  brought  up  in  a  Jesuit 
college  at  Parma.  Through  his  interest  in  dif- 
ferent sciences  and  the  circumstances  of  his  life 
he  was  led  to  try  his  hand  at  very  difterent 
subjects,  and  succeeded  marvellously  in  every  one 
of  them.  An  able  mathematician,  he -wto  tea  note- 
worthy treatise  on  the  "nature  of  style,"  being 
an  analysis  of  the  principles  of  aesthetics  applied 
to  one  of  the  branches  of  fine  arts  (IMilan,  1770 
vol.  i.  ;  the  second  volume  never  appeared). 
He  belonged  for  twenty-five  years  to  the  highest 
magistracy,  publishing  for  the  Austrian  govern- 
ment excellent  reports  on  corn  stores,  on  the 
reform  of  coinage,  on  measures  and  weights 
(proposing  a  Metric  System  based  on  astronom- 
ical magnitudes  and  physical  properties,  1780) 
on  demogi'aphical  questions,  etc.,  marked  by 
gi-eat  lucidity  and  precision  and  full  of  ideas 
ahead  of  his  times.  His  famous  little  pamphlet, 
Dei  dclitii  e  delle  pene,  published  in  1764,  has 
been  translated  into  twenty-two  languages.  In 
1768  a  chair  of  political  economy  was  founded 
for  him  by  the  Austrian  government  in  Milan 
(the  second  chair  for  this  science  founded  in 
Italy  ;  the  first  was  founded  in  1755  in  Naples 
by  Bartolomeo  Intieri  for  Gexovesi),  and  he 
occupied  it  for  two  years.  He  died  in  1793 
without  having  published  his  lectures,  which 
were  first  published  in  1804  by  Custodi,  and 
certainly  are  very  remarkable  considering  they 
were  written  before  A.  Smith's  Wealth  of 
Nations.  Beccaria  treats  political  economy  as 
an  art  to  maximise  the  value  of  the  produce  of 
work,  regarding  labourers  as  engines  whose  duty 
has  to  be  maximised.  From  tliis  principle 
he  deduces  the  necessity  of  a  division  of  labour, 
a  determination  of  the  value  of  a  labourer, 
and  the  nature  and  function  of  capital.  His 
lectures  are  also  remarkable  for  an  exposi- 
tion of  the  laws  of  growth  of  population  in  re- 
lation to  subsistence,  now  known  as  Malthus's 
theory.  Beccaria,  however,  is  not  correct, 
according  to  our  present  standard,  in  sundry 
other  questions,  allowing  himself  to  be  misled  by 
the  prevailing  French  school,  and  is  in  this 
respect  inferior  to  his  friend  Verri,  A  special 
mention  must  be  made  of  a  quite  small  pamphlet 
Beccaria  wrote  in  a  newspaper  {il  Gaffe)  in 
1764  or  1765,  under  the  title,  Algebraical 
Essay  on  Smuggling,  in  which  he  solves  analyt- 
ically the  problem,  "How  much  of  a  given  quan- 
tity of  merchandise  must  merchants  smuggle, 
so  as  not  to  be  winners  or  losers,  although  the 
remaining  portion  of  the  merchandise  be  con- 
fiscated ? " 

The  expression,  popularised  through  Beccaria'e 
influence,  "  the  greatest  happiness  of  the  greatest 
number  "  {la  massima  feliciia  divisa  net  maggioi 
numero,  Preface  of  treatise,  Dei  delitti  et  delle  pene) 
is  one  of  those  phrases  which  have  penetrated  so 


188 


BECHER— BEDE 


deep  into  the  mind  of  civilised  man  that  some 
further  observations  on  its  origin  are  advisable. 
Beocaria  says,  §  2  of  his  treatise  Dei  delitti  et 
delle  pene  (1764),  that  coldly  (rigidly)  examining 
human  nature  we  see  that  every  man  is  absolutely 
egoistic,  and  that  on  this  basis  alone  legislation 
can  be  established,  if  it  is  not  to  be  knocked 
over  constantly.  That  nobody  cares  anything 
for  the  universal  happiness,  or  for  the  good 
of  otliers,  and  that  "ogni  uomo  si  fa  centro  di 
tutte  le  combinazioni  del  globo,"  every  man  makes 
himself  the  centre  of  all  the  things  that  happen  in 
the  world.  The  principle  which  Beccaria  announces 
may  have  been  suggested  to  him  by  his  friend  Verri, 
who  had  written  a  special  treatise  on  the  Nature 
of  Pleasure  and  Pain.  Italian  economists,  con- 
temporary with  Verri,  were  apparently  led  to  give 
great  attention  to  this  subject  through  the  book 
of  De  Maupertuis  on  Le  principe  de  la  moindre 
action.  They  were  also  greatly  influenced  by  Hel- 
VETius,  who  says,  Traiti  de  V esprit  (1759),  vol.  i. 
div.  ii,  ch.  ii.  "that  the  principle  of  interest  is 
for  the  moral  world,  what  the  principle  of  gravi- 
tation is  for  the  physical  one. "  The  general  idea 
is  found  earlier  than  the  writers  cited  {e.g.  in  Fr. 
Hutcheson's  Inquiry  (1738),  but  it  is  of  interest 
to  trace  the  channel,  through  which  it  reached 
English  economists  (see  Bentham).  m.  p. 

BECHER,  JoHANN  Joachim  (1625  ?-1685), 
was  the  principal  representative  of  Austrian 
political  economy  under  Leopold  I.  He  was 
born  at  Speyer,  probably  in  1625  ;  he  was  son 
of  a  Protestant  minister,  but,  whilst  still  young, 
became  a  Roman  Catholic.  He  was  medical 
professor  and  court  physician  at  Mainz.  He 
afterwards  removed  to  Wiirzburg  and  Munich, 
and  in  1666  to  Vienna,  where  he  was  employed 
in  the  newly  established  Commerz  -  Collegium. 
He  was  much  busied  in  the  foundation  of  East 
and  West  Indian  trading  companies,  the  intro- 
duction of  foreign  branches  of  industry,  and  the 
negotiation  of  Austrian  loans  in  Holland.  Over- 
whelmed with  debt,  he  fled  in  1678  to  Holland, 
whence  he  passed  in  1680  to  England,  where  he 
died  in  1685,  having  probably  again  become  a 
Protestant.  Leibnitz  describes  him  as  "un 
esprit  excellent,"  "  Vir  summo  ingenio,"  but  as 
morally  worthless,  insolent,  vain,  and  men- 
dacious. There  was  in  him  a  large  element  of 
the  charlatan,  but  he  had  great  ingenuity, 
activity  of  mind,  and  fertility  of  invention. 
He  was  the  originator  of  potato  cultivation  in 
Germany.  His  Physiea  Subterranea  contains 
the  fundamental  ideas  of  the  phlogistic  system 
of  chemistry  ;  Stahl  admitted  his  obligations  to 
it,  and  pronounced  it  to  be  "opus  sine  pari, 
primum  hactenus  et  princeps."  His  principal 
economic  work  was  his  Politischer  Diseurs  von  den 
cigentlichen  Ursachen  des  Auf  und  Abn^hmen 
der  Reiche,  Stddte  und  Republiken,  in  specie  wie 
ein  Land  nahrhaft  undfolkreich  zu  machen  und 
in  eine  rechte  Societatem  civilem  zu  bringen, 
1668.  It  is  written  in  the  spirit  of  the  mer- 
cantile system,  but  avoids  some  of  the  exagger- 
ations of  that  system,  and   shows   occasional 


insight  into  juster  principles.  As  Roscher  re- 
marks, most  of  the  German  economists  who 
preceded  him  had  been  theologians,  philologists, 
or  jurists  ;  he  was  a  student  of  natural  philo- 
sophy, and  this  gives  to  his  writings  a  special 
freshness,  a  freedom  from  pedantry,  and  a  practi- 
cal character,  which,  with  his  lively  and  striking 
style,  fitted  them  to  exercise  a  popular  influence, 
as  they  in  fact  did,  both  directly  and  stiU  more 
through  his  disciple  Horneck. 

[Roscher,  Oesch.  der  Nat.  Oek.  in  DeutscMand, 
p.  270.]  J.  K.  I. 

BECKMANN,  Johann  (1739-1811).  Beck- 
mann,  a  native  of  Hoya  in  Hanover,  became 
professor  of  philosophy  1766,  and  then  (from 
1770  tiU  his  death)  of  national  economy  at 
Gottingen,  in  his  native  country.  Under 
Beckmann,  Schlozer,  and  others,  Gottingen 
became  the  leading  university  at  that  date  for 
the  social  and  political  sciences.  Beckmann 
has  claims  to  be  regarded  as  the  founder  of 
scientific  technology,  and  he  had  a  wide  know- 
ledge of  the  industries,  arts,  and  sciences. 
Linnaeus  was  among  his  friends.  He  wrote  on 
commerce,  agiiculture,  botany,  finance,  book- 
keeping, technology,  etc.,  but  the  work  which 
has  been  o^  most  use  to  economists  is  his 
history  of  inventions,  Beitrdge  zur  GescMchte 
der  Erfindungen  (in  five  volumes)  (1780-1805), 
part  of  a  series  of  "Beitriige  zur  Oekonomie, 
Technologic,  Polizei  —  und  Kameralwissen- 
schaften."  The  History  of  Inventions  has 
been  translated  into  English,  and  is  included 
in  Bohn's  Standard  Library  ;  prefixed  to  that 
translation  there  is  a  good  biography. 

[For  a  general  list  of  works,  see  Professor  Elster's 
article  "Beckmann"  in  the  n^yf  Handworterbuchder 
Staatsioissenschaften.  For  criticism,  see  Roscher, 
Geschichte  der  National-Oekonomik  in  Deutschland 
(1874),  p.  912  and  note  ;  cp.  582  note.]    J.  B. 

BEDE  (see  Manor).  A  German  term  for 
certain  exactions  paid  to  the  feudal  lord  by 
those  of  his  tenants  who  did  not  hold  by  mili- 
tary tenure,  or  who  were  not  ecclesiastics. 
Originally  payable  in  kind  and  determined  only 
by  the  will  of  the  lord,  in  most  parts  of  Germany 
by  the  13th  century  the  Bede  had  become  a 
fixed  money  payment.  This  quit  rent  con- 
tinued in  existence  for  a  long  period,  and  in 
some  parts  of  Germany  was  not  disused  even 
in  the  present  century.  In  some  cases  the  rent 
was  paid  to  another  person  than  the  o\vner  of 
the  land,  forming  thus  a  kind  of  rent-charge. 

The  Bede  seems  to  be  analogous  to  the  "red- 
ditus  assisus  "  or  fixed  quit  rents  formerly  paid 
by  manorial  tenants  in  England.  But  it  differs 
from  this  in  the  fact  that  it  could  not  be  exacted 
from  military  tenants,  and  in  other  way^s.  It  is 
also  analogous  to  the  French  Taille  but  has 
no  connection  with  any  system  of  taxation.  As 
its  name  implies,  - -Jgc^e,  a  request,  a  prayer — 
it  is  a  Benevolence  extracted  from  the 
tenants  by  their  feudal  chief.     Compare  the  old 


BEEKE— BELLONl 


129 


IHnglisli  words  "bederipe,"  a  day's  reaping  due 
from  the  tenants  at  the  lord's  request,  boon- 
erth,  a  day's  ploughing,  boon-days,  a  day's 
labour,  and  the  Latin  phrases  "preces,"  Pre- 
caeIjE.  Conrad,  Ifandworterhuch  der  Staats- 
wissenschaften,  s.v.  1889.  c.  g.  c. 

BEEKE,  Rev.  Henry,  born  at  Kingsteignton, 
Devonshire,  6th  January  1751,  educated  at 
Cambridge,  where  he  proceeded  M.A.  1776  ; 
D.D.  1300.  He  was  professor  of  modern  history 
in  1801,  Dean  of  Bristol,  1814  ;  and  died  1837 
(see  Arithmetic,  Political.  History  of). 

Observations  on  the  Produce  of  the  Income  Tax, 
pt.  1.,  London,  1799,  8vo ;  new  and  coiTected 
edition,  with  additions,  London,  1800,  8vo  (an 
able  defence  of  the  tax,  showing  the  economic  state 
of  Great  Britain  at  the  time.  An  appreciative 
account  of  Beeke's  work  is  given  by  Mr.  Giffen  in 
'  bis  Ch-owth  of  Capital,  1890).  H.  R.  t. 

BELDAM,  reputed  author  of  Considerations 
on  Money,  Bullion,  and  Foreign  Exchanges; 
being  an  Inquiry  into  the  present  state  of  the 
British  Coinage,  particularly  with  regard  to  the 
scarcity  of  Silver  Money,  with  a  view  to  point 
out  the  most  probable  means  of  making  it  x)lenti- 
/wZ  (London,  1772). 

[Monthly  Review,  1772,  vol.  xlvi.  p.  243.  See 
also  Jevons's  Currency  and  Finance,  p.  368.] 

F.  Y.  E. 

BELL,  William  (1731-1816),  prebendary 
of  Westminster  and  treasurer  of  St.  Paul's,  was 
a  fellow  of  Magdalene  College  (Cambridge)  ; 
here  he  obtained  one  of  Lord  Townshend's  prizes 
by  the  work  which  entitles  him  to  be  con- 
sidered as  an  economist — A  dissertation  on  the 
following  subject  :  What  Causes  principally 
contribute  to  render  a  Nation  Populous  ?  And 
what  Effect  has  the  Populousness  of  a  Nation  on 
its  Trade  ?  1756.  In  1751  Hume  had  main- 
tained, in  opposition  to  Montesquieu  (Lettres 
Persanes,  cxii.-exxiii.  a.Tid Esprit  des  loix,  1.  xxiii. 
chs.  17-29),  the  superior  populousness  of  the 
modern  world  (see  Hume's  Essay  on  the  Populous- 
ness of  Ancient  Nations,  and  Philosophical  JForks, 
vol.  iii.  p.  56,  ed.  Greene  and  Grose).  In  this 
Hume  had  been  criticised  by  R.  Wallace 
(1753),  who  asserted  that  modern  arts  and 
institutions  tended  to  diminish  population. 
Bell  has  probably  been  inspired  by  this  writer. 
Commerce  and  the  arts  have,  according  to  him, 
a  tendency  to  diminish  population,  for  there 
are  not  "any  bounds  originally  prescribed  to 
humane  nature"  (p.  2).  They  divert  pro- 
duction from  being  employed  upon  the  neces- 
saries of  life ;  make,  through  the  influx  of 
money,  the  prices  of  provisions  high,  and 
render  the  support  of  families  difficult ;  where- 
as agriculture  and  the  more  useful  arts,  by 
lowering  prices,  must  cause  a  fall  of  wages,  but 
in  what  proportion  the  author  holds  to  be  "an 
idle  and  useless  curiosity"  (p.  1 9).  To  secure  agri- 
culture and  the  more  necessary  employments. 
Bell  thinks  that  "of  all  political  institutions 
none  seems  more  imipediately  requisite  .  .  .  than 
VOL.  I. 


an  equal  division  of  lands  "  (p.  24).  He  pro- 
poses, therefore,  that  the  right  of  Primogeni- 
ture should  be  abolished  and  a  more  equal 
division  established  between  all  the  children  of 
a  family  "  (p.  28).  He  recommends  a  republican 
form  of  government,  as  most  favourable  to  the 
increase  of  population  (p.  29).  Only  after  a 
considerable  increase  thereof  should  commerce 
be  introduced.  This  dissertation  has  been  as- 
sailed by  William  Temple,  a  clothier  of  Trow- 
bridge, in  A  Vindication  of  Commerce  and  the 

Arts,  by  J B ,  M.D.,  London,  1758. 

It  was  translated  into  German  under  the  title  : 
IVilhelm  Bells,  M.A.  zu  Cambridge,  gekr'mte 
Preisschrift  von  den  Qucllen  und  Folgen  einer 
Starken  Bevolkerung,  1762,  and  Vienna,  1768. 

[M'Culloch's  Literature,  pp.  51,  52. — Diction- 
ary of  National  Biography,  vol.  iv.  pp.  176,  177. 
— Macleod's  Dictionary  of  Political  Economy,  p. 
260.  The  Vindication  is  erroneously  ascribed  to 
Bell.]  S.B. 

BELLERS,  John,  member  of  the  Society  of 
Friends,  born  about  1654,  became  joint-lord  of 
the  manor  of  Coin  St.  Aldwyn's,  Gloucestershire, 
and  devoted  himself  to  philanthropic  projects,  in 
some  of  which  he  anticipated  John  Howard. 
Died  in  London,  8th  February  1725.  Among 
his  numerous  pamphlets  are — 

Proposals  for  Raising  a  Colledge  of  Industry, 
London,  1695  and  1696,  4to  (the  rich  are  to  pro- 
vide the  capital  and  derive  profit  from  the  college, 
in  which  destitute  men  and  women  are  to  iind  work, 
and  a  resort  in  old  age  or  illness  ;  reprinted  in 
R.  Owen's  New  View  of  Society,  1818  ;  see  also 
Eden's  State  of  the  Poor,  i.  p.  264  etc.  ;  K.  Marx's 
iJas  Capital,  and  H.  M.  Hyndman's  Socialism  in 
England,  1888,  p.  65  etc.) — Essays  about  the 
Poor,  Manufactures,  Trade,  etc.,  London,  1699, 
4to. — An  Essay  for  Employing  the  Poor  to  Profit, 
London,  1723,  4to.  h.  r.  t. 

BELLITTI,  GiACiNTO,  author  of  Consider- 
azioni  sulla  libertd,  delV  annonxi  e  sulV  abolizione 
della  assisa  del  pesce,  Napoli,  1791,  strenuously 
defends  free  trade,  much  in  the  same  way  as 
Cantalupo  {q.v.)  ("Domenico  di  Gennaro, 
duca  di  Cantalupo")  had  done  in  1785  in  his 
Annona.  m.  p. 

BELLONl,  Girolamo,  was  a  Roman  banker 
who  wrote,  in  1750,  an  Essay  on  Commerce 
(Dissertazione  sopra  il  Comvurcio)  which  had  an 
extraordinary  success.  It  was  translated  into 
several  languages  (including  English,  London, 
1752),  and  the  pope  Benedict  XIV.  (Lamber- 
tini)  made  the  author  a  marquis  for  it.  In 
1757  a  second  Italian  edition  appeared,  and  in 
the  same  year  a  Letter  on  Imaginary  Money. 
In  the  Essay  on  Commerce  Belloni  does  not 
show  himself  possessed  of  any  superiority  over 
economists  who  were  his  predecessors,  like 
Locke,  Melon,  Broggia  and  Galiani,  and  his 
great  success  is  the  more  difficult  to  understand 
as  his  book  is  not  tree  from  some  very  gross 
errors,  which  even  in  his  time  ought  to  have 
been  avoided  by  an  acute  and  lea-med  writer. 

K 


130 


BENEFICE— BENEVOLENCES 


An  example  of  such  errors  is  his  approval  of 
measures  tending  to  prohibit  the  exportation  of 
coin.  His  writings  have  been  collected  by 
CusTODi  in  his  Raccolta  degli  Economisti  classici 
italiani.  M.  P. 

BENEFICE  (l).  This  term  was  applied 
during  the  Early  Middle  Ages  to  lands  held  of 
a  person  who  retained  the  ownership  by  a 
tenant  who  enjoyed  the  usufruct.  A  tenure  of 
this  kind,  revocable  at  the  will  of  the  owner, 
and  known  as  a  jirecarium,  was  occasionally  to 
be  found  in  the  Roman  republic.  Under  the 
empire  it  appears  more  frequently  ;  and,  where 
the  conditions  of  the  grant  are  light,  it  is 
naturally  described  as  a  heneficium.  Under 
the  Merovingian  kings  the  tenure  became  still 
more  common  ;  partly  owing  to  the  action  of 
the  great  ecclesiastical  proprietors,  who  by 
grants  of  this  kind  to  dependant  tenants 
secured  the  cultivation  of  their  estates  ;  partly 
owing  to  the  surrender  of  their  lands  by  the 
weak  to  the  more  powerful  on  condition  of 
being  allowed  to  retain  the  usufruct.  The 
usual  condition  of  a  heneficium  was  a  periodical 
payment  in  money  or  in  kind  ;  it  was  not 
associated  with  military  service  until  the  8th 
century.  At  first  revocable  at  will,  and  then 
granted  only  for  a  short  term  of  years,  by  the 
middle  of  the  9th  century  heneficia  had  come 
to  be  regarded  as  hereditary.  By  that  time, 
also,  the  beneficiary  tenure  had  become  the 
almost  universal  form  of  land-holding  by  per- 
sons above  the  rank  of  Villein  ;  a  change  which 
was  largely  due  to  the  action  of  Charles  Marte] 
and  the  early  Carlovingian  princes,  who  forced 
the  ecclesiastical  proprietors  to  give  up  large 
portions  of  their  estates  to  secular  hands,  while 
allowing  them  to  retain  the  nominal  ownership. 
The  conjunction  of  the  beneficial  system  with 
the  vassal  relation — with  which  originally  it 
had  nothing  to  do — ultimately  created  feudal 
tenure,  such  as  it  was  to  be  found  in  the 
greater  part  of  western  Europe. 

[The  clearest  account  of  the  early  history  of 
precaria  and  benejicia  is  by  Fustel  de  Coulanges, 
"  Les  Origines  du  Eegime  Feodal "  in  Eevue  des 
Deux  Mondes  for  15th  May  1873.  On  the  Mero- 
vingian and  Carlovingian  heneficium,  the  standard 
works  are  those  of  Georg  Waitz,  Deutsche  Verfas- 
sungsgeschichtey  vol.  ii.  (2d  ed.  1870),  vol.  iv.  (2d 
ed.  1885),  and  Paul  Roth,  Oeschichte  des  Benefi/^ial- 
wesens  (1850),  and  Feudalitat  und  Unterthanen- 
verhand  (1863),  who,  however,  diflfer  in  important 
points.  For  brief  summaries,  see  Stubbs,  Const. 
Hist.  Engl.,  vol.  eh.  ix.  ;  and  Felix  Dahn, 
Deutsche  Oeschichte  (1888),  bk.  v.  ch.  vi.] 

w.  J.  A. 

BENEFICE  (2).  An  ecclesiastical  living  or 
promotion.  The  word  heneficium  was  applied 
to  portions  of  land  granted  by  a  feudal  lord  to 
his  followers  (see  Benefice  No.  1),  but  after- 
wards it  came  to  be  restricted  in  a  general  sense 
to  church  preferments  and  dignities,  and  in  a 
narrower  sense  to  rectories,  vicarages,  and  per- 


petual curacies,  which  were  endowed  with  lands 
and  tithes.  The  perpetual  right  of  presentation 
to  a  benefice  is  called  an  advowson  and  is 
regarded  as  a  hereditament  of  an  incorporeal 
nature.  The  right  of  next  presentation  is  only 
personal  property.  No  one  but  a  priest  can 
hold  a  benefice,  and  benefices  to  which  the  cure 
of  souls  is  attached  cannot  be  charged  with  pay- 
ments to  other  persons. 

{The  Ecclesiastical  Law  of  the  Church  of  Eng 
land,  by  Sir  R.  Phillimore,  London,  1873.] 

J.  E.  c.  M. 

BENEFICIUM  CEDENDARUM  ACTI- 
ONUM  (Scots  law  term).  Right  of  co-surety 
to  sue  for  contribution. 

BENEFICIUM  COMPETENTI^.  A  privi- 
lege  given  by  the  Roman  law  to  defendants  in 
actions  brought  by  plaintiffs  standing  in  certain 
relations  to  them  (e.g.  to  fathers  in  actions 
brought  by  their  children,  to  former  masters 
in  actions  brought  by  freedmen,  etc.)  If  a 
defendant  availed  himself  of  this  privilege, 
judgment  was  not  given  for  the  amount  of  the 
claim,  but  for  such  sum  as  the  defendant  might 
be  able  to  pay  without  depriving  himself  of  the 
necessaries  of  life.  e.  s. 

BENEFJCIUM  DIVISIONIS  (Scots  law). 
An  implied  right  of  a  surety  to  be  sued  in  the 
first  place  only  for  his  share. 

BENEFICIUM  EXCUSSIONIS.  A  privilege 
given  to  sureties  in  the  later  Roman  law, 
which  enabled  them  to  postpone  the  payment 
of  the  guaranteed  debt  until  the  principal 
debtor  had  been  sued  for  the  amount,      e.  s. 

BENEFICIUM  INVENTARII.  By  the  civil 
law,  the  property  of  a  deceased  person  goes  to 
one  or  more  persons  who  have  to  pay  all 
legacies  and  debts,  and  who,  after  once  having 
accepted  the  inheritance,  cannot  plead  in- 
sujQicient  assets,  but  are  personally  liable  for 
everything.  A  person  taking  an  inheritance 
in  this  way  is  called  an  heir  (heres)  (but  it 
must  be  remembered  that  the  word  "heir"  in 
English  law  has  a  totally  different  meaning). 
Justinian  introduced  the  heneficium  inventarii 
which  enables  the  heir  to  have  an  official  in- 
ventory of  the  estate  made  before  he  accepts 
the  inheritance  ;  when  this  is  done  the  inherit- 
ance is  said  to  be  accepted  "with  benefit  of 
inventory,"  and  the  heir  is  answerable  to  the 
extent  of  the  assets  only.  The  rules  of  law 
here  described  are  still  in  force  in  the  countries 
whose  laws  are  based  on  the  civil  law  (see  for 
instance  the  French  Code  Civil,  art.  793). 

E.  s. 

BENEVOLENCES.  Voluntary  grants  made 
to  the  king  on  application  by  him  personally, 
or  by  letter,  or  through  commissioners.  They 
were  first  exacted  by  Edward  IV.  Though 
they  were  declared  illegal  by  1  Ric.  III.  c.  2, 
Henry  VII.  resorted  to  them  in  1491  and 
obtained  an  act  (2  Henry  VII.  c.  10)  for  the 
recovery  of  all  sums  promised  but  not  paid. 


BENTHAM 


131 


Henry  VIII.  demanded  benevolences  in  1528 
and  1545,  and  many  sums  were  given  to 
Elizabeth.  During  the  struggle  between  the 
Stuarts  and  parliament,  the  crown  more  than 
once  resorted  to  this  method  of  raising  money. 
The  Petition  of  Right  (1627)  expressly  declared 
that  no  man  should  be  liable  to  any  benevolence 
or  forced  loan.  J.  E.  c.  M. 

[Dowell's  History  of  Taxation  and  Taxes  in 
England  (London,  1889). — Constitutional  Law,  by 
H.  Broom,  p.  398  (London,  1885).— 2  State  Trials, 
899.— 12  Coke,  Reports,  119.] 

BENTHAM,  Jeremy,  philosopher,  reformer, 
and  economist,  born  at  Houndsditch,  London, 
1748,  was  trained  for  the  bar,  but  soon  aban- 
doned it  for  a  life  of  study  and  travel,  which 
a  considerable  private  fortune  made  possible. 
Most  of  his  voluminous  works  were  first  pub- 
lished in  French  by  his  friend  and  admirer 
Dumont.  Bentham  died  at  "Westminster  1832, 
LQ  his  eighty-fifth  year. 

Bentham  deserves  a  place  in  the  history  of 
political  economy,  partly  from  his  writings  on 
that  subject,  perhaps  even  more  from  the  influ- 
ence of  his  philosophy  on  his  friends  James 
Mill  and  David  Ricardo.  His  first  import- 
ant economical  work,  the  Defence  of  Usury,  is  a 
series  of  lively  letters  (written  from  Russia  in 
1787),  in  which  he  appeals  to  Adam  Smith  to 
apply  his  principles  consistently,  and  withdraw 
his  sanction  from  **  legal  restraints  on  pecuniary 
bargains."  He  contends  that  no  man  should 
be  forbidden  to  make  his  own  terms  in  a  bargain 
relating  to  money,  any  more  than  in  any  other 
bargains.  He  tries  to  prove,  by  closely  reasoned 
arguments,  that,  when  the  legislature  fixes  a 
maximum  rate  of  interest,  it  does  not  benefit 
the  right  persons,  while  it  corrupts  the  public 
by  multiplying  temptations  to  law-breaking. 
He  proceeds  on  the  general  principle  that  every 
man  is  the  best  judge  of  his  own  interest,  and  it 
is  for  the  public  good  that  he  should  be  left  free 
to  seek  it.  Bentham  was  one  of  the  first  econ- 
omical writers  who  were  completely  emancipated 
from  the  old  prejudices  against  lending  of  money 
at  interest ;  and  he  combats  not  only  the  old 
arguments  against  usury,  but  Adam  Smith's 
special  plea  that,  without  a  legal  maximum, 
money  would  pass  from  the  sober  people  to  the 
prodigals  and  projectors.  The  prodigals,  said 
Bentham,  would  not  get  it,  and  the  projectors 
ought  to  get  it.  As  Adam  Smith  himself  has 
frequently  remarked,  all  industrial  progress  de- 
pends on  the  formation  of  new  industrial 
schemes,  or  in  other  words,  on  the  work  of  pro- 
jectors. In  hindering  projectors,  therefore,  we 
are  hindering  the  public  good.  So  argued  Ben- 
tham ;  and  Adam  Smith  is  said  to  have  con- 
fessed (before  his  death,  in  1790)  that  in  this 
point  the  disciple  had  bettered  the  instruction 
of  his  master.  Both  in  style  and  in  matter  this 
is  one  of  the  most  masterly  of  Bentham's  econ- 
omical  writings.     The  praise,  however,  must  be 


shared  with  t\iQ  Protest  against  Laio  Taices(1795); 
and  the  Observations  on  the  Poor  Bill  of  Mr.  Pitt. 
In  the  latter,  written  1797,  he  marshals  a  list 
of  objections  expressed  in  his  happiest  manner, 
and  acknowledged  by  Pitt  to  be  (in  conjunction 
with  the  Essay  of  Malthtjs)  completely  fatal  to 
the  success  of  his  bill.  The  relief  of  the  poor 
became  an  object  of  his  thorough  and  dispassion- 
ate investigation,  and  as  a  result  he  submitted 
to  government  an  elaborate  poor-law  scheme 
which  anticipated  many  features  of  the  law  ol 
1834,  and  was  within  an  ace  of  being  accepted. 
Bentham  was  quick  to  see  the  afiinity  of  the 
new  economical  doctrines  of  Adam  Smith  with 
his  own  political  philosophy.  Even  in  his  econ- 
omical writings  he  is  evidently  more  guided 
by  his  utilitarian  conception  of  law  and  govern- 
ment than  by  purely  economical  reasons  ;  but 
he  finds  the  two  in  harmony  with  each  other  ; 
and,  in  those  important  cases  where  political 
economy  is  inseparable  from  politics  and  legis- 
lation, he  is  original  only  in  tlie  sense  of  being 
a  very  intelligent  disciple.  His  ovm  construc- 
tive (as  opposed  to  his  critical)  work  in  political 
economy  is  most  fully  presented  in  the  Manual 
of  Political  Econoviy.  Dumont  gave  part  of 
this  to  the  world  in  the  Geneva  Bihliotheque 
Britannique  as  early  as  1798,  and  rightly 
remarks  (in  his  introductory  letter  there)  that, 
unlike  Adam  Smith,  Bentham  is  never  the  his- 
torian but  always  the  legislator,  and  that  he  laid 
special  stress  on  the  limitation  of  labour  by 
capital.  Whether  much  or  little  labour  is  to 
be  employed  in  any  industry  must  depend  on 
whether  much  or  little  capital  is  devoted  to 
that  industry.  This  was  not  a  new  idea,  but 
it  was  made  more  prominent  than  in  the  Wealth 
of  Nations,  from  which  otherwise  the  Manual 
diS'ersmore  in  method  than  in  doctrine.  Political 
economy  is  treated  as  a  science  whereby  much 
can  be  known,  rather  than  as  an  art  whereby 
government  can  do  much  for  its  citizens.  The 
part  of  government  is,  as  a  rule,  to  "be  quiet" 
and  let  self-interest  have  its  perfect  work,  so 
that,  out  of  the  three  classes  of  measures,  the 
sponte  acta  by  the  citizens,  the  agenda  by  the 
state,  and  the  non  agenda  by  the  state,  the 
first,  in  economical  matters,  must  play  the  largest 
part.  In  the  Manual,  indeed,  the  non  agenda 
cover  the  greatest  number  of  pages  ;  the  various 
forms  of  mischievous  interference  by  government 
are  described  at  length,  and  treated  very  much 
as  by  Adam  Smith.  They  are,  however,  more 
plainly  declared  by  Bentham  (as  later  by  Cob- 
den)  to  be  not  simply  unwise,  but  unjust. 
Colonisation  is  regarded  as  a  loss  to  the  mother 
country  and  a  gain  to  the  world,  a  view  which 
led  Bentham,  in  his  capacity  of  French  citizen, 
to  advise  the  French  (in  1793)  to  emancipate 
their  colonies.  Drawbacks  and  Bounties  are 
condemned  ;  but  the  granting  of  a  patent  to 
inventors  is  strongly  commended,  and  the  ex- 
pense of  procuring  one  is  denounced  as  unjust 


132 


BENTHAM 


In  a  passage,  which  does  not  appear  in  the 
Bihliothhque  Britannique,  and  may  have  been 
written  after  Malthus's  Essay,  premiums  on 
large  families  and  similar  encouragements  of 
population  are  condemned  :  "As  well  make  in- 
stitutions to  punish  men  for  not  eating,  or  pay 
them  for  eating,  with  premiums  for  them  who 
eat  most  and  oftenest."  In  regard  to  iinance, 
Bentham  considers  that  the  best  tax  is  the 
extension  of  escheats  on  failure  of  near  relations 
(which  is  also  the  subject  of  a  separate  pamphlet), 
and  the  worst  taxes  are  those  on  law  proceed- 
ings. "  In  law  a  tax  is  a  prohibition  to  every 
man  who  cannot  pay  the  tax ;  this  is  understood 
in  trade,  but  seems  not  to  be  imderstood  in 
anything  else,"  he  says  in  his  Conversations. 
He  thinks  well  of  the  redemption  of  the  national 
debt  by  an  (inviolable)  sinking  fund,  consider- 
ing that  the  money  employed  in  reducing  the 
debt  is,  at  the  time  of  repayment,  a  positive 
addition  to  the  productive  capital  of  the  country. 
This  may  be  doubtful  doctrine  ;  but  no  excep- 
tion can  be  taken  to  the  main  reason  given  for 
repayment,  namely,  that  "sum  for  sum  the 
enjoyment  produced  by  gain  is  not  equal  to  the 
suffering  produced  by  loss.  In  this  difference, 
traced  through  all  its  consequences,  lies  the 
mischief,  and  the  sole  mischief,  of  bankruptcy, 
or  of  theft. "  In  dealing  with  special  economical 
doctrines  Bentham  is  not,  on  the  whole,  in  ad- 
vance of  his  master,  while  we  miss,  throughout, 
his  master's  continual  illustrations  from  life  and 
history.  His  distinctions  are  often  expressed 
in  philosophical  terms,  without  thereby  be- 
coming either  more  subtle  or  more  profound. 
National  wealth,  as  the  total  of  the  means  of 
subsistence  or  enjoyment,  is  distinguished  from 
national  opulence  or  "relative  wealth,"  which 
varies  inversely  with  population.  He  describes 
the  "  final  cause  "  of  wealth  as  well-being,  and 
the  "material  cause"  as  "the  matter  of  wealth 
considered  in  respect  of  its  possessing  or  being 
capable  of  possessing  value,  namely,  subservience 
to  well-  being,  the  final  cause. ' '  (We  may  compare 
with  this  the  casual  remark  in  his  Conversations, 
"the  value  of  money  is  its  quantity  multiplied 
by  the  felicity  it  produces.")  In  regard  to 
machinery,  he  seems  to  have  arrived  at  a  con- 
clusion similar  to  Ricardo's  in  its  final  form. 
After  an  invention  (he  says  in  a  passage  which 
is  not  given  in  the  BihliotMque  Britannique,  and 
may  be  later  than  1798):  "  Without  an  addition 
to  the  mass  of  pecuniary  capital,  which  is  a  cir- 
cumstance accidental  and  not  belonging  to  the 
case,  the  retaining  of  the  same  number  of  hands 
would  in  no  instance  be  possible,  for  the  pro- 
duction and  keeping  up  of  the  machinery  or 
other  auxiliary  means  would  always  require  a 
considerable  quantity  of  labour,  the  payment  of 
which  would  be  attended  with  a  proportionable 
mass  of  expense,  by  which  a  proportionable  part 
of  the  capital  would  be  absorbed  ; "  and  there- 
fore the  introduction  of  machinery  may  certainly 


(he  thinks)  be  an  immediate  evil  to  the  labour- 
ing classes.  Bentham  can  hardly,  in  this  case, 
be  said  to  give  us  both  sides  of  the  question. 
But  there  are  other  economical  problems  on 
which  he  barely 'touches  at  all.  Kent  is  not 
discussed,  and  the  distinction  of  cost  from  value 
is  the  subject  only  of  passing  allusion  (in  the 
ConversatioTis).  The  assertion  of  Karl  Marx 
that  Bentham  was  the  author  of  the  theory  of 
a  wages  fund  rests  on  no  stronger  evidence 
than  the  passage  above  quoted  about  machinery. 
The  statement  that  labour  is  limited  by  capital 
does  not  by  itself  imply  so  much.  It  is  difficult 
to  be  certain  how  much  of  the  Manual  is  of  the 
18  th  century  and  how  much  of  later  date  ;  and 
we  cannot  give  its  author  the  credit  of  every 
novelty  that  distinguishes  his  treatise  from  the 
Wealth  of  Nations.  But  it  is  clear  that  Bentham, 
if  not  an  economist  of  the  first  rank,  was  at 
least  well  abreast  of  the  times. 

But  Bentham's  political  philosophy  has  ex- 
erted a  much  greater  influence  on  political 
economy  than  his  own  directly  economical 
writings.  Through  James  MiU  and  Ricardo 
political  economy  came  to  be  identified  (not 
merely  with  utilitarianism,  with  which  in  some 
degree  it  had  abeady  been  identified  by  Malthua), 
but  with  Bentham's  peculiar  form  of  utilitarian- 
ism. How  closely  the  two  were  associated  in 
the  popular  mind  we  may  see  from  Carltle's 
early  writings,  in  which  the  monster  "  Utili- 
taria  "  and  the  "  dismal  science  "  are  constantly 
presented  as  different  phases  of  one  and  the 
same  deadly  error.  "The  greatest  happiness 
of  the  greatest  number,"  a  neat  democratic 
formula  used  by  Beccaria  in  his  Treatise  on 
Crimes  and  Punishments  (1764),  and  by  Dr. 
Priestley  1  in  the  Essay  on  Government  (1768), 
was  announced  by  Bentham  (in  his  Fragment 
on  Government)  in  1776  to  be  the  ruling  prin- 
ciple and  chief  end  of  the  legislator ;  and  the 
unhampered  working  of  commercial  ambition 
and  competition  was  very  easily  translated  into 
terms  of  this  formula  (see  Beccaria).  Whatever 
distress  free  competition  might  inflict  on  indi- 
viduals, it  tended  to  the  greatest  happiness  of 
the  greatest  number.  This  was  of  course  sub- 
stantially the  doctrine  of  Adam  Smith  himself. 
The  difi'erence  between  the  two  philosophers  is, 
that  the  latter  applied  the  principle  to  economics 
alone,  and  is  not  rightly  described  as  being,  in 
philosophy,  a  utilitarian  at  all.  In  economics 
he  thinks  he  can  show  that  individual  men  left 
to  follow  their  separate  self-interest  without  let 
or  hindrance  from  the  state  will  unintentionally 
accomplish  results  that  are  for  the  public  good. 


1  "  Priestley  was  the  first  (unless  it  was  Beccaria)  who 
taught  my  lips  to  pronounce  this  sacred  truth ;  that  the 
greatest  happiness  of  the  greatest  number  is  the  founda- 
tion of  morals  and  legislation  "  (Commonplace  Book,  1781- 
85 ;  Works,  x.  142,  cp.  567  note).  The  phrase  occurs  in 
Hutcheson's  Inquiry  into  Beauty  and  Virtue,  etc.,  1738, 
p.  181.  Comp.  Mr.  F.  C.  Montague's  edition  of  the 
Fragment  on  Government,  introduction,  pages  33,  34 
(Clarendon  Press,  1891). 


BENTHAM— BEQUEST,  POWER  OF 


133 


namely,  the  greatest  wealth  and  commercial 
prosperity  possible  to  their  community.  Adam 
Smith,  in  short,  abstracts,  not  very  rigidly,  and 
in  one  class  of  actions  only,  from  all  motives 
but  self-interest.  Bentham,  on  the  other  hand, 
makes  use  of  the  same  abstraction,  not  in  one 
class,  but  in  the  whole  range  of  actions  falling 
under  consideration  of  political  philosophy.  Not 
only  ill  economical  matters  but  in  politics  and 
general  life,  "there  is  no  true  interest  but  in- 
dividual interest."  Man  is  under  two  masters, 
pleasure  and  pain,  and  his  action  results  from  a 
calculation  of  the  balance  of  consequences  in 
favour  of  greater  pleasure  or  less  pain  to  himself 
individually.  On  the  other  hand,  the  same 
Bentham  considers  that  the  aim  and  intention 
of  all  legislation  (as  distinguished  from  the  un- 
intended result  of  actions  let  alone  by  the  law) 
must  be  "  the  gi-eatest  happiness  of  the  greatest 
number,"  which  is  a  general  and  not  an  indi- 
vidual interest.  It  is  hard  to  reconcile  this 
regard  to  the  general  interest  with  Bentham's 
extreme  individualism.  He  tries  to  do  so,  when 
he  says  it  is  imperative  that  the  individual 
interest  of  the  ruler  should  be  one  with  the 
general  interest  of  the  ruled  ;  but  he  does  not 
explain  how  Bentham  the  legislator,  being  a 
mere  man,  can  rise  to  a  view  in  which  his  indi- 
vidual interest  is  certainly  lost  in  the  general. 
This  is  not  the  place  to  discuss  the  philosophical 
question  ;  and  it  must  be  gi'anted  that,  once 
Bentham  has  made  his  logical  leap  from  the 
individual  to  the  general  happiness,  he  guides 
himself  strictly  by  regard  to  the  latter  even  in 
matters  of  trade,  and  has  no  faith  in  an  abso- 
lute "harmony"  of  unregulated  interests.  He 
was  an  advanced  free-trader ;  but  we  can  see, 
from  such  proposals  as  those  for  the  extension 
of  escheats  and  for  the  taxation  of  bankers  and 
stockbrokers,  that  his  maxim  of  "greatest 
happiness "  had  lifted  him  above  the  extreme 
form  of  laissez-faire.  The  same  maxim,  when 
interpreted  as  a  claim  for  equality  of  treatment 
for  all  members  of  the  state  ("every  one  to 
count  as  one  and  no  one  as  more  than  one  "), 
had  much  to  do  with  the  influence  of  the 
followers  of  Bentham  ("  the  Philosophical  Kadi- 
cals"),  represented  by  the  early  Westminster 
Review  ;  and  the  close  association  of  Bentham's 
politics  with  Ricardo's  economics  may  therefore 
have  helped  in  many  quarters  to  secure  a  hear- 
ing for  the  latter  during  the  crusade  against 
the  com  laws. 

The  philosophy  of  Bentham  has  influenvjed 
political  economy  in  another  and  very  different 
direction.  The  idea  of  a  calculus  of  pains  and 
pleasures  which  is  used  by  Jevons  and  others 
in  building  up  the  economic  theory  of  value  is 
founded  (especially  in  the  case  of  Jevons)  very 
largely  upon  the  suggestions  of  Bentham  ;  and, 
even  if  the  theory  of  final  utility  can  be  stated 
quite  apart  from  any  utilitarian  psychology,  it 
was  certainly  in  the  language  of  this  psychology 


that  it  was  first  formally  expounded  by  English 
writers. 

It  should  be  added  that,  like  all  the  great 
modem  economists,  Bentham  was  devoted  to 
the  cause  of  education,  especially  the  education 
of  the  labouring  classes,  whom  he  regards  as  the 
most  valuable  part  of  the  community.  He  took 
shares  in  Robert  Owen's  factory  in  New  Lanark, 
when  (in  1813)  Owen  bought  out  the  old  part- 
ners. His  waitings  on  education  are  hardly  less 
numerous  than  those  on  legislation. 

[His  Avorks  and  life,  edited  by  Bowiing,  with  an 
introduction  by  Hill  Burton,  fill  eleven  volumes, 
of  which  the  tenth  and  eleventh  contain  the  Life 
(Tait,  Edinburgh,  1838  seq.)  His  chief  economi- 
cal works  are  :  (vol.  ii.)  Protest  against  Law  Taxes, 
Supply  without  Burden,  Tax  loith  Monopoly  {i.e. 
a  tax  on  bankers  and  stockbrokers)  ;  (vol.  iii.)  De- 
fence of  Usury  and  of  Projects  in  Arts,  Manual 
of  Political  Economy,  Conversion  of  Stock  into  Note 
Annuities,  Invention  and  Discovery;  (vol.  iv.) 
Hard  Labour  Bill,  Emancipate  your  Colonies; 
(vol.  viii. )  Tracts  on  Poor  Laws  and  Pauper  Man- 
agevient,  Observations  on  the  Poor  Bill  of  Right 
Hon.  William  Pitt.  The  treatises  on  r^.ewards  and 
Punishments  (vols.  i.  and  ii. )  have  frequent  econ- 
omical references,  though  those  of  greatest  length 
in  the  original  edition  have,  in  the  collected  works, 
been  transferred  to  the  Manual. 

The  Manual,  together  with  the  Principles  oj 
Legislation,  has  been  in  great  part  reproduced  in 
the  volume  on  "Bentham"  (ed.  Ratt'alovich)  in 
the  Petite  Bibliotheque  l^conoviiqne  (Guillaumin, 
1888). 

Critical  estimates  of  Bentham's  general  work  will 
be  found  in  J.  S.  Mill's  Dissert,  and  Discuss.,  i. 
330  seq.  (from  Westminster  Review,  August  1838), 
and  in  Adolf  Held's  Sociale  Geschichte  Englands, 
article  "Bentham"  (1881),  and  in  an  article  by 
Prof.  H.  Sidgwick  on  "Bentham "in  the  Fort- 
nightly Review,  1877  (comp.  also  account  of 
Bentham's  first  principle  in  Prof.  H.  Sidgwick's 
History  of  Ethics).  J,  S.  Mill's  Autobiography 
brings  out  the  influence  of  Bentham  on  Mill  and 
Austin  and  the  philosophical  radicals  in  general. 
See  also  Bain's  Life  of  James  Mill,  1882.]  J.  b. 

BEQUEST,  Power  of.  The  power  of  be- 
queathing property  on  death  has  descended  to 
modern  nations  from  the  Roman  law,  which  per- 
mitted three -fourths  of  the  inheritance  to  be 
willed  away  from  the  next-of-kin.  The  Koran 
recognises  a  similar  principle  as  regards  two- 
thirds  of  a  man's  property,  and  the  Mishna  re- 
cognises gifts  of  property  to  take  eflect  on  death ; 
but  it  is  probable  that  these  provisions  are  trace- 
able to  the  influence  of  Roman  law. 

Under  the  feudal  system  a  vassal  was  not 
permitted  to  substitute  a  stranger  in  his  place 
without  his  lord's  consent  (2  Coke,  Inst.  7),  and 
the  early  English  will  was  restricted  to  personal 
property.  At  common  law,  a  man  if  he  left  a 
widow  and  children  could  bequeath  one-thu'd 
of  his  personalty  ;  if  he  left  only  a  widow  or 
only  children  he  could  bequeath  one -half; 
and  if  ho  left  neither  widow  nor  children  he 


134 


BEQUEST,  POWER  OF— BERKELEY 


could  dispose  of  the  whole  (2  Blackstone's 
Commentaries).  Some  writers  think  that  the 
above  rules  only  prevailed  when  supported  by 
special  custom  (Williams  on  Executors).  By 
imperceptible  degrees  full  power  of  bequest  was 
introduced,  except  in  the  province  of  .York, 
Wales,  and  the  citj  of  London,  but  bv  the 
4  &  5  W.  &  M.  c.  2,  explained  by  the  2  &  3 
Anne,  c.  6  for  York  ;  7  &  8  Will.  IIL  c.  38  for 
Wales,  and  the  2  Geo.  I.  c.  18  for  London,  the 
special  customs  prevailing  in  these  places  were 
abolished. 

As  regards  real  property,  the  refusal  of  the 
common  law  to  permit  bequests  led  to  the  in- 
vention of  uses  and  trusts  by  means  of  which 
land  was  devised  indirectly.  After  the  attempted 
abolition  of  uses  by  Henry  VIIL  the  incon- 
veniences arising  from  the  want  of  testamentary 
power  resulted  in  the  32  Hen.  VIIL  c.  1,  which 
permitted  a  will  to  be  made  of  all  land  held  by 
Socage  and  two-thirds  of  land  held  by  knights' 
service  tenure.  The  12  Car.  II.  c.  24  abolished 
tenure  by  Knight's  Service,  and  the  55  Geo. 
III.  c.  192  made  Copyholds  devisable. 

The  practice  of  entailing  land  by  settling  it 
upon  a  number  of  life  tenants  in  succession  has 
greatly  curtailed  the  freedom  of  bequest,  as  the 
estate  of  a  life  tenant  must  end  with  his  death 
(see  Settlement).  In  the  United  States  and 
in  Canada,  Australia,  and  other  English  colonies, 
freedom  of  bequest  is  the  general  rule,  as  their 
legal  systems  are  based  on  English  law.  In 
Scotland  and  on  the  continent  of  Europe  the 
principle  of  the  Roman  law, — reserving  a  certain 
portion  of  the  inheritance  (legitima  portio)  for 
the  heir  has  been  followed.  The  law  of  Scotland 
gives  the  widow  one-half  the  movable  property 
if  there  are  no  children,  one-third  if  there  are 
children  ;  one-third  if  there  be  a  widow,  one- 
half  if  there  be  no  widow  is  reserved  for  the 
children  ;  what  remains  may  be  bequeathed. 

The  portion  of  the  property  that  may  be  be- 
queathed in  the  chief  European  countries  is  as 
follows : — 

In  Austria  :  one-half  if  there  are  descendants, 
two-thirds  if  ascendants  only,  the  whole  if  neither 
ascendants  or  descendants.  AusL  Civ.  Code,  par. 
765,  766,  951. 

In  Bavaria  :  one-half  if  there  are  five  or  more 
children,  two-thirds  if  there  are  four  or  fewer 
children.     Bav.  Civ.  Code,  §  15. 

In  Denmark  :  one-third  if  there  are  descendants, 
the  whole  if  no  descendants.  Dan.  Civ.  Code,  262, 
263.  Special  provisions  regulate  the  bequest  of  a 
Soedegaard  or  "family  seat,"  of  a  Bondergaard  or 
"estate  let  to  peasants."  New  entails  are  pro- 
hibited. 

In  France,  Belgium,  and  Holland  :  one-half 
if  there  is  one  child,  one-third  if  there  are  two 
children,  one-fourth  if  there  are  three  children,  and 
80  on. 

In  Germany  :  various  regulations  prevail,  but 
there  is  a  universal  rule  that  a  proportion,  vary- 
ing in  the  different  states,  cannot  be  bequeathed 
away  from  the  nearest  relatives. 


In  Greece  :  a  share  equal  to  that  which  on  an 
equal  division  would  descend  to  each  of  his  direct 
heirs. 

In  Italy  :  one-half  if  there  are  descendants, 
two-thirds  if  there  are  ascendants  only,  the  whole 
if  neither  descendants  or  ascendants.  It.  Civ.  Code, 
805. 

In  Norway  :  one-half  if  there  are  descendants, 
the  whole  if  no  descendants. 

In  Portugal  :  one-third  if  there  are  ascendants 
or  descendants. 

In  Prussia  :  all  the  property,  but  this  power  is 
greatly  limited  by  the  existence  of  settlements, 
hereditary  estates,  and  by  the  customs  of  particular 
localities. 

In  Russia  :  (1)  all  acquired  property ;  (2)  all 
patrimonial  property  if  there  are  no  descendants. 
By  the  Emancipation  Act  of  1861  the  descent  of 
property  of  the  peasants  is  to  be  governed  by  local 
usage.  The  communal  organisation  still  prevails 
in  Russia. 

In  Spain  :  one-fifth  if  there  are  descendants, 
one-third  if  there  are  ascendants  only,  the  whole 
if  there  are  neither  ascendants  nor  descendants. 

In  Sweden  :  in  towns  one-sixth  of  the  property 
if  there  are  children,  one-half  if  there  are  relatives 
only  in  the  country,  the  whole  if  there  are  no 
relatives  living. 

In  Switzerland  :  each  canton  has  its  own 
regulations,*  see  Les  Legislations  Civiles  des  Can- 
tons Swisses,  par  C.  Lardy,  Paris,  1877. 

[See  Reports  on  the  Tenure  of  Land  in  LIurqpe, 
1869  c.  66  ;  1870  c.  lb.— Succession  Laws  of  Ch/rts- 
tian  Countries,  by  E.  Lloyd  (London,  1877). 

Mill  in  his  Political  Economy,  bk.  ii.  c.  ii.,  and 
bk.  V.  c.  ix.,  discusses  the  extent  to  which  freedom 
of  bequest  should  be  permitted.]  J.  e.  c.  m. 

BERKELEY,  George,  Bishop  of  Cloyne, 
Ireland,  born  1685,  died  1753.  Bishop  Berke- 
ley's principal  contributions  to  economic  thought 
are  contained  in  the  Querist ;  of  which  the  first 
edition  appeared,  in  three  successive  parts,  1735- 
37.  A  second  edition,  increased  by  a  few  queries, 
and  diminished  by  many,  was  issued  in  1750. 
The  portions  of  the  first  edition  which  did  not 
reappear  in  the  second  are  printed  by  Professor 
Eraser  as  an  appendix  to  the  third  vol.  of  his 
edition  of  Berkeley's  works. 

Berkeley  anticipates  Adam  Smith  in  conceiv- 
ing wealth  and  weKare  philosophically  ;  and  is 
free  from  the  errors  of  the  mercantile  system 
{Queries  556-561,  and  passim).  He  rightly 
states  several  technical  points,  as  that  **  interest 
measures  the  true  value  of  land  "  (1st  ed.  part 
i.  244),  and  that  the  worse  currency  expels 
the  better  (27,  464,  2d  ed.,  1st  ed.  part  i. 
246).  Among  many  eternal  verities  stand  out 
two  or  three  doctrines  which  may  appear  to 
our  generation  less  certain,  or  less  important, 
than  Berkeley  held. 

(1)  Like  Cantillon,  Berkeley  ascribes  para- 
mount importance  to  the  direction  which  un- 
productive consumption  takes.  "Whether  the 
industry  of  the  lower  part  of  our  people  doth 
not  much  depend  on  the  expense  of  the  upper" 
(395)  ?    Whether,  by  housebuilding  and  similar 


BERLIN  DECREES— BESOLD 


135 


expenditures,  "much  of  that  sustenance  and 
wealth  of  this  nation  which  now  goes  to 
foreigners  would  not  be  kept  at  home,  and 
nourish  and  circulate  among  our  own  people" 
(402)  ?  "  Whether  an  Irish  lady,  set  out  with 
French  silks  and  Flanders  lace  may  not  be 
said  to  consume  more  beef  and  butter  than  a 
hundred  of  our  labouring  peasants"  (144)  ?  "of 
how  great  consequences  are  fashions  to  the 
public"  (99)  ?  "  Whether  it  may  not  concern 
the  wisdom  of  the  legislature  to  interpose  in 
the  making  of  fashions  "  (13)  ? 

(2)  The  wisdom  of  the  legislature  is  also  to 
be  employed  in  creating  a  national  bank. 
The  scheme  is  explained  more  fully  in  the  first 
than  in  the  second  edition.  Berkeley  asks 
"Whether  the  sure  way  to  supply  people  with 
tools  and  materials,  and  to  get  them  at  work, 
be  not  a  free  circulation  of  money  "  (239)  ?  He 
regards  the  "promoting  of  industry"  as  "the 
true  and  sole  end,  the  rule  and  measure,  of  a 
national  bank"  (314).  It  may  appear  to  us 
more  doubtful  "Whether  there  be  any  diffi- 
culty in  comprehending  that  the  whole  wealth 
of  the  nation  is  in  truth  the  stock  of  a  national 
bank"  (438)  ?  And  it  savours  now  of  heterodoxy 
to  ask  "Whether  the  true  idea  of  money  as 
such  be  not  altogether  that  of  a  ticket  or 
counter"  (23,  441)? 

(3)  A  less  prominent,  but  still  cardinal, 
part  of  Berkeley's  teaching  is  that  the  multi- 
tude as  well  as  the  quality  of  population  is  an 
element  of  well-being.  "Whether  the  main 
point  be  not  to  multiply  and  employ  our 
people"  (352)?  "Whether  it  would  not  be 
delightful  to  live  in  a  country  swarming,  like 
China,  with  busy  people"  (359)? 

Some  of  the  suggestions  made  in  the  Querist 
are  found  in  the  Essay  towards  preventing  the 
Ruin  of  Great  Britain  (1721),  where,  besides 
inculcating  moral  reforms,  Berkeley  proposes  to 
encourage  population  and  manufactures. 

\_The  Works  of  George  Berkeley,  forvierly  Bishop 
of  Cloyne,  edited  by  Professor  A.  C.  Fraser, 
Oxford,  Clarendon  Press,  4  vols.  1871.  The 
Querist,  with  notes,  1829.]  f.  y,  e. 

BERLIN  DECREES.  See  Continental 
System. 

BERNARD,  Sir  Thomas,  Bart.  (1750-1818), 
was  one  of  the  originators  of  the  co-operative 
movement  in  England.  He  was  employed  by 
his  father,  Francis  Bernard,  the  Governor  of  the 
province  of  New  Jersey,  as  his  secretary,  and 
was  called  to  the  bar  in  1780,  but  early  devoted 
himself  to  philanthropical  pursuits.  Assisted 
by  Count  Rumford,  Eliot,  Wilberforce,  and 
especially  by  the  Bishop  Shute  Barrington  of 
Durham,  he  founded  in  1796  the  "  Society  for 
Bettering  the  Condition  and  Increasing  the 
Comforts  of  the  Poor,"  the  reports  of  which  are 
for  the  most  part  his  personal  work.  The  same 
benevolent  tendencies  inspired  him  to  publish 
The  Case  of  the  Salt  Duties,  with  Proofs  and 


Illustrations,  1817,  in  order  to  bring  about 
their  repeal.  Besides  the  above-mentioned 
works  his  "Observations  on  the  different  Pro- 
posals which  have  been  made  respecting  the 
Poor  during  the  two  preceding  Centuries,"  are 
very  important,  through  their  wealth  of  in- 
formation. They  are  joined  by  way  of  an 
appendix  to  :  The  Life  of  Sir  Thomas  Bernard, 
Baronet.  By  the  Rev.  James  Baker,  his  nephew 
and  executor,  1819. 

{Dictionary  of  National  Biography,  vol.  iv.  pp. 
387,  388.— G.  J.  Holyoake,  Self-help  a  Hundred 
Years  ago,  1888,  oh.  iii.  ch.  iv.  ch.  vi.]         s.  B. 

BERNHARDI,  Theodor  von,  economist, 
historian,  and  diplomatist,  born  at  Berlin  1802, 
died  1887.  His  youth  was  spent  in  Russia.  In 
1820-23  he  studied  at  Heidelberg,  and  then, 
after  travelling  abroad,  settled  in  Silesia.  He 
was  appointed  a  Prussian  "  Legationsrath "  in 
1865,  and  for  some  years  was  actively  employed 
in  diplomatic  work  in  Italy,  Spain,  and  Portugal. 
He  is  known  as  an  economist  by  his  Versuch 
einer  Kritik  der  Grunde  welche  fiXr  grosses  und 
kleines  Grundeigenthum  angefiihrt  werden,  1848. 
"  Under  this  modest  title,"  says  Roscher,  ♦'  is 
concealed  a  series  of  thorough-going  investiga- 
tions on  the  questions  which  are  most  important 
from  a  general  point  of  view.  The  whole 
belongs  to  the  best  of  what  has  been  wi'itten 
against  whatever  is  one-sided  in  the  doctrines 
of  Smith,  and  still  more  of  Ricardo.  Were 
Bernhardi  WTiting  in  our  day,  he  would  with- 
out doubt  be  spoken  of  as  following  the  same 
direction  as  the  Socialists  of  the  Chair." 
The  point  Roscher  finds  most  characteristic  in 
liim  is  the  histm'ical  spirit  of  his  work,  seeking, 
as  it  does,  to  explain  what  are  the  views  of 
human  aff"airs  out  of  which  the  opposite  doc- 
trines on  large  and  small  properties  have  respec- 
tively taken  their  rise,  and  with  which  they 
must  stand  or  fall.  Bernhardi  is  also  author 
of  several  valuable  works  on  political  and 
military  history.  (Roscher,  Geschiehte  der  Nat. 
Oekon.  in  Deutschland,  p.  1041).  j.  k.  i. 

BESOLD,  Christoph  (1577-1638),  the 
greatest  German  master  of  political  science  in  the 
first  half  of  the  17th  century,  was  born  at  Tubin- 
gen in  1577.  After  the  battle  of  Nordlingen 
he  announced  his  conversion  to  Roman  Catholi- 
cism, entered  the  Austrian  service,  and  was  for 
a  time  privy-councillor.  So  renowned  was  he 
in  his  own  day  that  the  emperor  wished  him 
to  fill  a  chair  in  Vienna,  the  pope  one  at 
Bologna,  and  the  court  of  Denmark  one  in  that 
country.  He  died  in  1638  at  Ingolstadt,  where 
he  was  professor.  He  was  characterised  by  a 
many-sidedness  which,  says  Roscher,  reminds 
us  of  Grotiijs  and  Salmasitjs.  He  was  a  most 
voluminous  writer  on  theology  and  philosophy, 
law,  history,  and  politics.  In  his  De  Aerario 
(2d  ed.  1620)  he  gives  a  full  enumeration  of  the 
questions  to  which  statistics  should  furnish  a 
i-eply.     His  economic  doctrines  are  stated  in 


136 


BETTERMENT 


his  Synopsis  poUticoe  aodrinoe,  and  his  Vitce 
et  mortis  consideratio  politica,  1623.  His  views 
on  usury  are  remarkable,  especially  when  we  re- 
member that  they  long  preceded  the  arguments 
of  Salmasius  on  the  same  subject.  He  denies 
the  Aristotelian  doctrine  of  the  unfruitfulness 
of  money,  makes  loans  on  Interest  a  case  of 
legitimate  locatio,  disputes  the  common  inter- 
pretation of  the  Jewish  prohibition  of  interest, 
and  only  asks  for  a  legal  limitation  of  the  rate. 
He  agrees  with  the  mercantile  school  as  to  the 
necessity  of  preventing  the  exportation  of  money 
and  regulating  the  corn  trade,  and  as  to  the 
propriety  of  sumptuary  legislation.  His  great 
defect  is  the  unsystematic  character  of  his  writ- 
ings, which  often  consist  merely  of  collectanea 
from  various  sources,  loosely  connected  and  in- 
terspersed with  frequent  digressions.  Thomasius 
attributes  to  him  "multa  diligentia,  magnum 
ingenium,"  but  "  exiguum  judicium." 

[Roscher,  Gesch.  der  Nat.  Oek.  in  Deutschland, 
p.  195.]  J.K.I. 

BETTERMENT.  A  word  imported  from 
the  United  States  of  America,  and  denoting  an 
improvement  of  property.  It  has  recently 
become  familiar  in  England  as  the  name  for  a 
principle  of  taxation,  the  adoption  of  which, 
for  the  purposes  of  local  taxation  is  recom- 
mended by  some  politicians — the  principle  being 
that  persons  benefited  by  public  expenditure 
should  contribute  to  such  expenditure  to  the  ex- 
tent of  the  increased  value  of  their  property,  and 
this  not  only  if  the  improvement  effected  by  the 
public  authority  was  carried  out  for  the  purpose 
of  conferring  a  benefit  on  such  property,  but 
also  if  the  resulting  benefit  was  purely  acci- 
dental, the  expenditure  having  been  undertaken 
for  a  totally  different  purpose.  The  advocates 
of  the  principle  assert  that  it  has  been  recog- 
nised by  previous  legislation  both  in  the  United 
States  and  in  England,  and  that  in  extending 
its  application  they,  are  introducing  no  new 
system  of  taxation. 

As  regards  England  the  following  instances 
are  given : 

(1)  Various  Sewers  Acts,  beginning  with  a 
statute  of  Henry  VI.,  by  which  Commissioners 
were  appointed  for  the  purpose  of  constructing 
sewers,  drains,  seawalls,  and  other  works  for 
the  prevention  of  floods,  and  for  the  purpose  of 
apportioning  the  cost  of  such  works  among  the 
owners  of  property  within  their  respective  areas. 
The  Commissioners  were  to  ascertain  by  whose 
fault  any  damage  had  previously  been  caused, 
who  was  specially  injured  by  the  previous  state  of 
things,  and  who  would  be  specially  benefited 
by  the  new  works.  These  facts  were  to  be 
considered  in  the  apportionment  (see  the  words 
of  the  Commission  as  set  out  in  6  Henry  VI. 
c.  5,  and  23  Henry  VIII.  c.  5). 

(2)  §  159  of  the  Metropolis  Management 
Act  (18  &  19  Vict.  c.  120),  which  enables 
any  vestry  and   any  district  board   to  impose 


special  rates  on  any  part  of  the  parish  oi 
district,  or  to  exempt  any  part  of  the  parish  or 
district  from  rates,  with  respect  to  expenditure 
which  has  been  incurred  for  the  benefit  of  any 
particular  part,  or  has  not  been  incurred  for  the 
benefit  of  the  whole  of  any  parish  or  district. 

(3)  §  8  (8)  of  the  Artisans'  Dwellings  Act 
(45  &  46  Vict.  c.  64 — now  reproduced  by 
§  38  (8)  of  the  Housing  of  the  Working  Classes 
Act,  1890  —  53  &  54  Vict.  c.  70),  according 
to  which  the  arbitrator  appointed  under  that 
Act  has  power,  in  the  case  of  the  compulsory 
demolition  of  an  obstructive  building,  to  im- 
pose a  special  rate  on  the  owner  of  a  building 
previously  obstructed,  to  the  extent  of  any 
increase  in  the  value  of  such  building  resulting 
from  such  demolition.  Other  statutory  pro- 
visions have  also  been  relied  upon,  but  they 
are  either  exactly  analogous  to  those  mentioned 
or  obviously  irrelevant. 

It  is  not  difficult  to  show  that  the  principle 
brought  out  in  the  first  two  instances  is  not 
even  superficially  analogous  to  the  principle 
of  betterment  as  defined  above.  Landowners 
belonging  to  a  district  threatened  by  floods 
must  take  common  measures  for  their  protec- 
tion, and  as  some  individuals  are  more  careless 
or  more  selfish  than  others,  public  officers  are 
appointed  to  ensure  efficient  measures  and  a 
just  apportionment  of  the  expense.  There  is 
here  no  public  expenditure  in  the  proper  sense, 
nor  is  there  any  apportionment,  based  on  the 
increase  in  the  value  of  property.  The  Metro- 
polis Management  Act,  in  authorising  the  sub- 
division of  parishes  and  districts  for  rating 
purposes,  only  recognises  a  principle  which 
underlies  all  local  government  and  taxation  ; 
viz.  that  expenditure  incurred  for  the  exclusive 
benefit  of  a  particular  area  ought  to  be  borne 
by  the  inhabitants  of  that  area.  As  it  often 
happens  that  a  metropolitan  parish  or  district 
comprises  parts  widely  separated  from  each 
other,  and  public  works  undertaken  for  the 
benefit  of  one  part  may  be  useless  or  even 
hurtful  to  another  part,  it  would  be  manifestly 
unjust  to  recognise  no  other  area  for  local 
taxation  except  the  arbitrary  and  frequently 
fanciful  area  of  the  parish  or  district.  The 
Housing  of  the  Working  Classes  Act  seems,  at 
first  sight,  to  come  nearer  to  the  principle  of 
betterment  than  the  other  statutes  mentioned, 
inasmuch  as  it  expressly  declares  that  the 
increase  in  the  value  of  improved  premises  is  to 
be  considered  for  the  purpose  of  the  apportion- 
ment of  the  contributions  payable  in  respect  of 
the  compensation  to  the  owners  of  obstructive 
buildings,  and  inasmuch  as  it  introduces  special 
rates  upon  individuals  as  distinguished  from 
local  areas  ;  but  here  the  analogy  ceases.  The 
demolition  of  an  obstructive  building  is  ordered 
on  the  ground  of  its  being  injurious  to  an 
adjoining  house,  and  the  primary  object  of  the 
demolition   is,   therefore,   the  benefit   of  that 


BETTERMENT 


137 


particular  house.  The  special  rate  to  be  im- 
posed in  such  a  case  is  to  be  levied  like  a 
private  improvement  rate  under  the  Public 
Health  Acts  ;  and,  like  a  private  improvement 
rate,  it  is  not  a  tax  in  the  usual  sense  of  the 
word,  but  the  repayment  of  a  sum  spent  by 
the  local  authority  for  the  special  benefit  of 
the  party  from  whom  it  is  to  be  collected. 

In  all  these  cases  the  expenditure  is  to  be 
incurred  with  the  special  object  of  conferring 
benejfits  on  a  particular  area  or  particular 
persons,  and  it  is  from  that  area  or  from  those 
l)erson8  that  the  rate  is  to  be  collected.  As 
Mr.  Pember  tersely  says  in  his  speech  against 
the  Strand  Improvement  Bill  (p.  2) :  the 
principle  hitherto  not  departed  from  is  ' '  that 
the  incidence  of  taxation  should  be  determined 
by  the  motive  of  the  expenditure,  and  not  by 
its  accidental  results." 

The  American  legislation  on  the  subject  has 
been  summarised  by  Mr.  John  Rae  {Ccndem- 
porary  Review,  May  1890,  p.  644  seq.)  He 
defines  a  betterment  tax  as  "the  special  assess- 
ment of  the  expense  (or  part  of  the  expense)  of 
a  local  improvement  on  the  adjoining  property 
which  is  specially  benefited  by  the  improve- 
ment." This  definition  is  somewhat  ambiguous, 
as  it  is  aot  clear  whether  such  an  assessment 
IS  to  take  place  irrespectively  of  the  object  of 
the  expenditure  ;  and  the  ambiguity  is  not 
removed  by  the  instances  which  are  given  of 
the  imposition  of  a  betterment  tax,  many  of 
which  seem  explainable  in  the  same  way  as 
the  English  statutes  to  which  reference  has 
been  made.  It  is,  however,  quite  clear  that 
the  principle  of  betterment,  even  in  a  more 
restricted  sense,  is  not  recognised  in  all  tlie 
States  of  the  Union,  and  that  where  it  is 
recognised,  the  manner  of  applying  it  is  by  no 
means  uniform. 

The  argument  from  precedent  does  not,  under 
these  circumstances,  seem  well  founded,  and 
the  question  as  to  the  advisability  of  introduc- 
ing the  principle  of  betterment  must  be  decided 
on  the  merits  only.  Before  considering  whether 
the  proposed  new  method  of  taxation  is  just  or 
expedient,  it  will  be  useful  to  ascertain  how  it 
can  be  can-ied  out  in  practice.  For  this  purpose 
the  evidence  taken  by  the  Select  Committee  on 
the  London  Streets  (Strand  Improvement)  Bill 
— a  bill  promoted  by  the  London  County 
Council  and  withdrawn  after  the  rejection  of 
its  principal  provisions — is  highly  instructive. 
The  object  of  the  bill  was  the  widening  of  the 
Strand  for  the  purpose  of  facilitating  metro- 
politan traflfic.  This  clearly  appears  from  the 
preamble,  which  begins  :  **  Whereas  obstruction 
and  delay  to  traffic  is  caused  by  the  narrowness 
of  the  thoroughfare  known  as  the  Strand  near 
the  Churches  of  St.  Mary -le- Strand  and  St. 
Clement  Danes,  and  having  regard  to  the 
extent  and  character  of  the  traffic  using  the 
said  thoroughfare,  it  is  expedient  that  it  should 


be  widened  and  improved,"  etc.,  but  as  it  wag 
believed  that  the  improvement  was  likely  to 
cause  an  increase  in  the  value  of  the  adjoining 
property,  it  was  proposed  to  raise  part  of  the 
expenditure  (not  exceeding  one-half)  by  con- 
tributions from  the  owners  or  occupiers  of  such 
improved  property,  which  were  to  assume  the 
form  of  yearly  rent-cliarges.  The  bill  created 
a  betterment  area,  and  provided  that  an  arbi- 
trator was  to  determine  whether  and  to  what 
extent  the  improvement  rent-charge  Avas  to  be 
imposed  on  each  separate  plot  within  that  area. 
The  award  was  to  state  (a)  the  amount  of  the 
increased  value  which  would  accrue  to  each 
plot ;  (h)  the  amount  of  the  rent-charge  to  be 
apportioned  to  such  plot ;  (c)  the  name  of  the 
person  or  persons  by  whom  such  rent- charge 
should  be  payable  (being  the  owner  of,  occupier, 
or  person  otherwise  interested  in  such  plot). 

The  following  are  some  of  the  practical  diffi- 
culties disclosed  by  the  evidence  before  the 
Select  Committee. 

1.  The  area  of  betterment  was  settled  before- 
hand,  and  the  arbitrator  had  no  power  to  make 
an  assessment  on  any  property  outside  the  area. 
At  the  same  time  the  limits  of  the  area  were 
not  fixed  on  any  intelligible  principle.  The 
surveyor  who  made  tlie  plan  almost  admits  this 
in  his  evidence.  To  the  question  (p.  101) 
"Why  have  you  taken  one  side  of  Devereux 
Court  and  not  the  other?"  he  replies:  "I 
am  obliged  to  draw  the  line  somewhere." 
Later  on  when  asked  (p.  103)  "AVhy  have  you 
put  it  [New  Court]  in  the  betterment  area  ? " 
he  says  :  "You  cannot  always  tell  the  reason 
why  ; "  and  similar  answers  are  frequent.  It 
may  be  objected  that  these  facts  are  damaging 
to  the  proposed  scheme,  but  not  to  the  prin- 
ciple of  bettennent,  but  it  is  easy  to  see  that 
the  difficulty  is  not  due  to  the  accidents  of  this 
particular  case.  It  is  quite  impossible  to  fix 
an  area  beforehand  which  is  not  more  or  less 
arbitrary  ;  and  if  it  is  left  to  the  arbitrator  to 
find  betterment  wherever  it  exists  without  regard 
to  any  area,  the  difficulty  of  his  task  becomes 
insurmountable. 

2.  Even  within  a  limited  area  the  arbitrator's 
work  may  be  so  arduous  as  to  become  practi- 
cally impossible.  If  no  time  be  fixed  for  the 
making  of  the  final  award,  great  inconvenience 
must  result ;  and  if  a  time  be  fixed,  the  pressure 
of  time  must  interfere  with  the  completeness  of 
the  inquiry.  Mr.  R.  C.  Driver,  one  of  the  best 
known  estate  agents  in  London,  being  asked : 
"Now,  apart  from  any  machinery  in  this  parti- 
cular bill,  do  you  think  from  your  experience 
as  a  surveyor  you  could  deal  with  this  question 
of  betterment  ? "  replies  :  "  I  do  not  know  the 
surveyor  at  the  present  moment  amongst  the 
whole  range  of  them  who  is  competent  to  deal 
with  it "  (p.  229).  It  might  be  said  that  the 
difficulty  of  the  inquiry  in  the  particular  case 
was  due  to  the  large  extent  of  the  area,  but  it 


138 


BETTERMENT— BETTERNESS 


would  never  be  feasible  to  apply  the  principle 
of  betterment  to  a  small  area,  as  no  appreciable 
part  of  the  total  expenditure  could  be  recovered 
in  such  a  case. 

3.  The  arbitrator,  before  making  his  award 
with  regard  to  any  particular  plot,  would  Jiave 
to  hear  the  evidence  concerning  the  whole  area 
(see  Mr.  Tewson's  evidence,  on  p.  273).  There 
would,  therefore,  be  a  period  of  uncertainty 
extending  over  several  years,  concerning  every 
piece  of  ground  within  the  area,  and  as  no  one 
would  purchase  land  subject  to  an  uncertain 
contingent  rent -charge,  the  whole  property 
would  become  unsaleable  during  the  period  of 
suspense. 

4.  The  arbitrator  might  find  that  only  a  very 
small  part  of  the  area  derived  any  benefit.  It 
would  therefore  be  impossible  to  estimate  before- 
hand what  proportion  of  the  cost  would  eventu- 
ally become  chargeable  to  the  Metropolis. 

5.  The  metropolitan  ratepayers  are  now  pay- 
ing interest  on  sums  borrowed  for  other  metro- 
politan improvements  which  probably  have  con- 
ferred benefits  on  particular  localities.  If  some 
inhabitants  of  the  Strand  district  were  made 
to  pay  for  part  of  the  expenditure  by  which 
they  were  specially  benefited,  they  would  be 
justified  in  asking  for  a  readjustment  of  metro- 
politan taxation,  so  as  to  be  relieved  of  part  of 
the  burden  borne  by  them  for  the  benefit  of 
other  localities. 

Apart  from  these  practical  difficulties  there 
are  serious  objections  to  the  proposed  adoption 
of  the  principle  of  betterment  on  grounds  of 
justice  and  expediency.  These  may  be  shortly 
stated  as  follows : 

1.  There  is  hardly  any  public  expenditure 
which  does  not  benefit  somebody,  and  it  would 
be  obviously  unfair  to  give  away  these  benefits 
in  some  cases  and  sell  them  in  other  cases. 
The  erection  of  the  New  Law  Courts  has  in- 
creased the  value  of  property  in  the  neighbour- 
hood to  an  enormous  extent,  yet  the  cost  has 
been  paid  entirely  from  imperial  funds. 

2.  If  public  bodies  may  ask  for  contribution 
from  persons  benefited  by  their  expenditure, 
irrespectively  of  the  objects  of  the  expenditure, 
private  corporations  or  individuals  ought  to 
have  the  same  right.  A  landowner  who 
rebuilds  a  particular  plot  of  houses,  or  plants 
trees  or  gardens  for  the  benefit  of  his  own  pro- 
perty, may  thereby  increase  the  value  of  property 
within  a  whole  district.  A  railway  company 
may  open  a  new  area  for  building  purposes  ;  yet 
the  persons  benefited  are  not  required  to  con- 
tribute to  the  outlay. 

3.  It  is  dangerous  to  establish  a  principle  of 
taxation,  the  incidence  of  which,  instead  of  being 
determined  by  definite  general  rules,  depends 
on  the  discretion  of  one  or  more  individuals 
whose  fitness  cannot  be  ascertained  beforehand, 
and  upon  a  calculation  of  probabilities  which 
may  and  frequently  will  be  erroneous. 


4.  If  the  effect  of  public  expenditure  on 
private  property  is  to  be  considered  at  all,  irre- 
spectively of  the  object  of  the  expenditure,  the 
loss  ought  to  be  considered  as  well  as  the  gain. 
If  those  who  benefit  ought  to  contribute,  those 
who  lose  ought  to  be  compensated.  Some  of 
the  advocates  of  betterment  recognise  this  con- 
sequence. Mr.  James  Beal,  one  of  the  wit- 
nesses called  on  behalf  of  the  London  County 
Council,  in  reply  to  the  question  (p.  199)  :  "If 
you  adopt  that  principle  without  regard  to  dis- 
tance, would  you  also  admit  that  to  any  distance 
people  might  claim,  on  the  other  hand,  from  the 
Council,  for  what  you  call  an  improvement  doing 
damage  to  their  property?"  answers  "Cer- 
tainly." "Can  you  give  any  idea  to  the  com- 
mittee of  what  the  pecuniary  ultimate  result 
would  be,  what  your  balance-sheet  would  look 
like?"  "No."  "It  might  turn  out  to  be  a 
very  bad  principle  for  you?"  "When  you 
assert  a  principle  follow  it  to  the  death  ;  do  not 
trouble  about  results."  It  should  be  remem- 
bered in  reference  to  the  last  remark  that  in 
this  case  the  persons  who  asserted  the  principle 
were  not  the  persons  whom  the  result  would 
have  affected. 

The  metropolitan  authorities  have  hitherto 
adopted  a  plan  for  obtaining  the  benefit  of  a 
rise  in  the  value  of  property,  occurring  in  con- 
sequence of  improvements  effected  at  the  general 
expense,  which  has  produced  satisfactory  results, 
and  is  free  from  the  inconvenience  of  the  better- 
ment tax.  This  plan  is  known  as  the  method 
of  recoupment,  and  is  applied  in  the  following 
manner.  The  public  authority  acquires  com- 
pulsory powers  to  purchase  land  beyond  the 
immediate  necessities  of  the  contemplated  im- 
provement, at  a  valuation  which  does  not 
include  the  prospective  increase  in  value  which 
will  be  due  to  improvement.  Such  land  is  resold 
when  the  improvement  is  completed,  and  by 
the  profit  on  the  re-sale  a  part  of  the  cost  of 
the  improvement  is  repaid.  The  principal 
objection  urged  against  this  plan  is  that  the 
price  of  the  compulsory  purchase  includes  trade 
interests  which  are  destroyed,  and  that  this 
loss  takes  away  the  profit  which  would  other- 
wise have  been  obtained  on  a  re-sale.  There  is 
not  much  force  in  this  objection,  inasmuch  as 
most  of  the  houses  occupied  for  trade  purposes 
are  held  by  the  tenants  on  short  leases,  and  the 
public  authority  can  therefore  buy  the  freehold 
without  paying  for  any  trade  interests,  and 
allow  the  leases  to  run  out  before  re-selling. 
The  duty  to  re- sell  may  be  postponed  for  a 
number  of  years,  so  as  to  allow  for  time  for 
longer  leases  to  run  off.  This  plan,  which  is 
just  and  fair  to  everybody  concerned,  is  free 
from  most  of  the  objections  against  the  better- 
ment scheme,  and  answers  every  legitimate  pur- 
pose for  which  that  scheme  has  been  devised. 


BETTERNESS,      A  term   used   m 


E.  s. 
buUioL 


BEZANTS— BIDDLE 


13S 


transactions.  It  is  usual  in  the  older  metliods 
of  reporting  tlie  results  of  assays,  which  are  still 
retained  side  by  side  with  the  decimal  system 
of  reporting,  to  refer  the  proportion  of  gold  or 
silver  in  ingots  or  bars  to  "standards"  for  the 
respective  metals.  Standard  gold  contains 
22  parts  of  gold  and  2  of  baser  metal  in  24 
parts  ;  these  parts  are  called  carats,  the  gold 
carat  containing  4  grains,  the  grain  being  sub- 
divided into  8  parts.  The  standard  for  silver 
coin  and  plate  consists  of  11  ounces  2  dwts.  of 
silver  and  18  dwts.  of  copper  in  the  pound  of 
12  ounces  troy.  BcttevTiess,  and  worseness,  are 
merely  conventional  terms  which  have  been 
adopted  for  centuries  to  show  how  much  gold 
in  *'  carats  "  and  "  gi-ains  "  and  "  eighths,"  and 
how  much  silver  in  ounces  and  pennyweights, 
the  mass  of  metal  contains  in  addition  to,  or 
in  defect  of,  the  legal  standard,  which  standard 
affords  the  basis  for  calculating  the  money  value 
of  the  metal.  c.  r-a. 

BEZANTS.  A  name  given  to  gold  and  silver 
coins  which  were  struck  at  Byzantium  (Con- 
stantinople), the  capital  of  the  Eastern  empire, 
and  which  circulated  throughout  Europe  from 
the  6th  to  the  loth  or  16th  centuries.  The 
gold  coins  were  current  in  England  in  Anglo- 
Saxon  and  Norman  times,  and  may  be  said  to 
have  been  used  as  international  money. 

Of  the  original  bezants  the  chief  gold  coin 
was  called  the  **  Solibus  "  and  the  silver  coin 
the  "miliarision."  They  were  struck  about 
the  year  500  A.D.,  in  the  time  of  Emperor 
Anastasius,  and  were  made  of  fine  metal.  They 
were,  however,  gradually  debased,  and  by  the 
15th  century,  when  the  Eastern  empire  fell, 
they  had  become  greatly  reduced  in  fineness. 
Their  weight  also  did  not  remain  constant,  and 
it  is  impossible  therefore  to  say  what  was  their 
exact  value.  A  gold  coin,  however,  which  was 
probably  the  largest  to  which  the  title  bezant 
could  correctly  be  applied,  was  issued  in  the 
reign  of  Heraclius  (615  a.d.)  under  the  title  of 
' '  hexagram. "  The  weight  of  this  coin  was  105 
grains  (probably  fine  gold)  and  its  value  in 
sterling  therefore  would  be  18s.  7d. 

The  current  rate  at  which  gold  bezants  were 
received  throughout  Europe  has  been  estimated 
at  a  ducat  (9s.  4d.),  so  that  they  may  be  taken 
as  roughly  equivalent  to  a  Half-Sovereign  ; 
and  this  estimate  would  appear  to  be  confirmed 
by  the  fact  that  200,000  bezants,  paid  for  the 
ransom  of  St.  Louis  of  France  (1250),  were  taken 
as  equal  to  100,000  Livres  (pounds).  Bezants, 
however,  which  were  distributed  at  the  corona- 
tion of  Henry  II.  of  France  (1547),  three  cen- 
turies later,  were  equal  in  value  to  two  Ducats. 
As,  however,  it  is  certain  that  in  the  course  of 
time  the  word  bezant  came  to  be  applied  to  any 
gold  coin  in  common  use,  quite  apart  from  any 
consideration  of  its  value  or  of  its  place  of  ori- 
gin, such  discrepancies  in  their  estimated  value 
cannot  but  be  expected  to  occur.         f.  e.  a. 


BIANCHINI,  LuDOVico,  born  at  Naples 
1803,  died  1871,  was  an  economist,  statesman, 
and  historian  of  merit.  Though  much  occu- 
pied in  the  highest  official  positions  of  the 
kingdom  of  Naples,  he  found  time  to  write 
many  excellent  works  on  economical,  adminis- 
trative, and  historical  subjects. 

His  principal  ecouoniical  writings  are  the  follow- 
ing : — Principii  del  credito  pubblico,  viz.  Prin- 
ciples of  Public  Credit,  published  in  Naples  in 
1827  and  1831. — Delia  injluenza  delV  amminis- 
trazione  pubblica  sulla  industria  nazionale  e  sulla 
circolazione  delle  richezze,  viz.  On  the  Influence  oj 
the  State  on  Industry  and  Circxdation  of  Wealth, 
Naples,  1828. — Delia  storia  delle  finanze  del 
liegno  di  Napoli,  viz.  History  of  Neapolitan 
Finance,  3  vols.,  Naples,  1834  and  \%2,'d.—Sullo 
stato  delle  ferriere  nel  Regno  di  Napoli,  Napoli, 
1S35. — Sidla  conversione  delle  rendite  inscritte 
nel  gran  libro  del  debito  pubblico,  viz.  On  the 
Conversion  of  the  Public  Debt,  Naples,  1836. — 
Principii  delta  Scienza  del  ben  vivere  sociale  e  delta 
economia  pubblica  e  degli  Stati,  viz.  Principles  of 
the  Science  of  Social  Welfare  ;  the  first  volume, 
containing  the  history  of  political  economy,  was 
published  in  Naples  in  1845  ;  the  second  volume, 
containing  the  principles,  was  published  in  Italian 
iu  1855,  and  in  French  in  1857. — Storia  econo- 
mica  di  Sicilia,  viz.  Economical  History  of  Sicily, 
Naples,  1841.  m.  p. 

BIBLIA,  Fabrizio,  of  whose  life  nothing  is 
known  except  that  he  was  born  at  Catanzaro,  and 
wrote  in  1621,  by  order  of  the  Viceroy  Zapatta, 
during  one  of  the  most  serious  monetary  crises 
of  the  time,  a  pamphlet  having  the  title, 
Discorso  sopra  V aggiustamento  delta  moneta  e 
cambii  nel  Regno  di  Napoli,  in  Napoli,  1621. 
He  proves  himself  to  be  much  inferior  to 
Antonio  Serra,  who  wrote  in  1613  (see 
A.  Serra).  m.  p. 

BIDDLE,  Nicholas,  born  1786,  died  1844  ; 
president  of  the  Second  Bank  of  the  United 
States.  A  graduate  of  Princeton  College,  and 
later  a  student  of  law,  he  first  became  con- 
nected with  the  bank  as  a  government  director  ; 
was  its  president  from  1823  to  1836,  and  a 
prominent  figure  through  the  eventful  years  of 
its  unequal  struggle  with  President  Jackson. 
Biddle  managed,  on  the  whole  with  success,  the 
affairs  of  this  gi-eat  institution,  ramifying  with 
its  twenty -five  branches  through  the  United 
States.  Most  of  his  theories  of  banking  were 
sound  ;  but  his  theory  as  to  bank-note  issues 
was  mischievous.  Following  the  principle  that 
guided  the  conduct  of  the  Bank  of  England 
during  the  restriction,  he  believed  there  could 
be  no  excess  of  issues  so  long  as  the  bank's 
advances  were  confined  to  good  commercial 
paper,  arising  out  of  real  transactions.  He 
failed  to  distinguish  between  a  bank-note  proper, 
redeemable  on  demand  at  any  branch  in  coin, 
and  a  draft,  redeemable  only  at  the  branch  ob 
which  it  was  drawn,  and  therefore  practically 
irredeemable.  Nearly  all  the  difficulties  of  the 
bank  can  be  traced  to  the  vicious  effects  of  this 


140 


BIEL— BILL  BROKING 


principle.  Biddle's  theories  on  banking  are  to 
be  found  in  the  record  of  the  actual  operations 
of  the  bank  under  his  management. 

N.  Biddle's  writings  are  few ;  his  best  work  was 
Two  letters  to  the  Hon.  J,  Q.  Adams  ;  embodying 
History  of  the  recharter  of  the  Bank  of  the  United 
States,  and  a  view  of  the  Present  Condition 'of  the 
Currency  (London,  1837).  a.  c.  m. 

BIEL,  Gabriel  (1430  M495),  sometimes 
called  the  last  of  the  scholastics,  was  born  at 
Speyer  about  1430.  He  enjoyed  the  esteem  of 
the  well-known  Duke  Eberhard  of  Wiirtemberg, 
and  was  one  of  his  chief  agents  in  founding 
(1477)  the  university  of  Tiibingen,  in  which  he 
became  professor  of  theology.  He  was  after- 
wards a  member  of  the  order  of  the  Brothers 
of  the  Common  Life.  His  principal  work  is 
entitled  CoUedorium  Sententiarum,  published 
in  1501.  He  belongs  to  the  history  of  political 
economy  by  the  portion  of  this  work  in  which 
he  treats  of  money  from  the  moral  or  casuistic 
point  of  view.  Though  inferior  to  Oresme,  the 
other  distinguished  scholastic  economist,  in 
penetration  and  clearness  of  thought,  he  shows 
a  sound  understanding  of  the  fundamental 
principles  of  the  theory  of  money.  This  part 
of  the  work  was  published  separately  by  John 
Virdung  at  Mainz  in  1541  under  the  title,  De 
monetarum  potestate  simul  et  utilitate  tradatus. 
It  is  also  appended  to  the  treatise  of  Marquard 
Freher,  De  re  tnonetaria,  veterum  Roma/norv/m 
et  hodiei'ni  apud  Germanos  imperii,  1606. 
(Roscher,  Geseh.  der  Nat.  Oekon.  in  Deutschland, 
p.  21  seq. ;  and  H.  Contzen,  Gesch.  der  Volks- 
wirthschaftliehen  Lit.  im  Mittelalterf  p.  161). 

J.  K.  I. 

BIGELOW,  Erastus  Brigham,  LL.D.,  born 
1814,  died  1879,  was  an  active  and  successful 
man  of  affairs,  the  inventor  of  many  improve- 
ments in  textile  machinery,  especially  of  the 
power-loom  for  weaving  carpets.  As  an  advocate 
of  protection,  and  prominent  wooUen  manufac- 
turer, he  had  much  influence  in  shaping  the 
complicated  system  of  duties  on  wool  and 
woollens  adopted  by  the  United  States  in  1867. 
His  writings  on  tariff  subjects  show  force  and 
ability.  He  wrote  also  pamphlets  and  review 
articles  on  the  currency  and  on  general  economic 
questions. 

Among  his  pamphlets  may  be  mentioned  Re- 
marks on  the  Depressed  Condition  of  Manufactures 
in  Massachusetts,  Boston,  1859,  and  Address  on 
the  Wool  Industry  of  the  United  States,  New 
York,  1869.  f.  w.  t. 

Bigelow  was  noted  as  a  manufacturer  in  the 
textile  arts.  He  early  gave  attention  to  in- 
dustrial subjects,  and  in  particular  to  the  tariff 
question.  His  first  printed  treatise  on  the 
depressed  state  of  American  manufactures  ap- 
peared in  1858.  This  was  followed  in  1862 
by  his  best  work,  The  Tariff  Question  considered 
in  regard  to  the  Policy  of  England,  and  the 
interests  of  the  United  States.       With  Statistical 


and  Comparative  Tables,  Boston,  1862,  pp. 
103.  Appendix,  pp.  242,  quarto.  The  de- 
scriptive portion  is  largely  historical,  and  is  an 
attempt  to  show  that  the  growth  of  English 
commerce  was  not  due  to  free  trade,  but  to 
other  general  causes,  and  that  the  removal  of 
duties  by  England  was  no  sacrifice.  The 
statistical  tables  are  valuable,  and  show  a  desire 
to  bring  together  a  great  mass  of  data  m  a 
scientific  way.  The  foregoing  work  is  con- 
densed and  treated  in  a  more  popular  form  in 
The  Tariff  Policy  of  England  and  of  the  United 
States  contrasted,  Boston,  1877,  pp.  61.  Mr. 
Bigelow  also  published  an  Address  on  the 
Wool  Industry  of  the  United  States,  1869  ; 
Relations  of  Labour  and  Capital  (Atlantic 
Monthly,  1878).  He  was  the  first  president  of 
the  National  Association  of  Wool  Manufac- 
turers, organised  in  1864  ;  and  had  much  to  do 
in  framing  the  tariff  of  1867. 

[See  sketch  of  his  life  in  Bulletin  of  Nat.  Assoc, 
of  Wool  Manuf,  vol.  ix.  No.  4,  1879  ;  also  a 
brief  memoir  by  Delano  A.  Goddard  in  Proc.  of 
Mass.  Hist.  Soc,  Oct.  1882.]  d.  b.  d. 

BILL  BROKING.  Names  do  not  always 
change  with  the  things  they  describe.  This  is 
true  of  what  is  called  **bill  broking."  When 
the  business  began  early  in  this  century  the 
biU  broker  was  really  a  broker — an  agent 
between  buyer  and  seller,  procuring  bills  for 
the  buyer,  receiving  a  small  commission  for  his 
trouble,  but  incurring  no  liability  in  respect  of 
the  transaction.  The  so-called  "bill  broker" 
is  not  now  really  a  broker  at  all.  Such 
business  is  still  transacted,  and  on  a  consider- 
able scale,  but  those  known  as  bill  brokers  are 
reaUy  a  sort  of  bankers,  receiving  from  bankers 
and  others  large  deposits  which  they  invest  for 
the  most  part  in  bills  of  exchange,  agreeing  to 
repay  on  demand  or  on  short  notice.  They 
do  also  sell  bills,  but,  as  they  guarantee  the 
bills  sold  to  the  buyer,  their  liability  remains 
intact  just  as  much  as  if  they  held  them  till 
maturity.  The  bills  are  their  own,  and  they 
do  not  get  rid  of  the  risk  of  holding  them  by 
selling  them.  Thus  the  character  of  the  busi- 
ness has  entirely  changed.  That  change  was 
no  doubt  gradual,  and  arose  probably  from 
the  fact  that  bankers  wanted  to  employ  surplus 
money  without  the  trouble  and  risk  of  selecting 
biUs,  and  without  the  danger  involved  in  lock- 
ing up  their  funds  in  a  security  which  could  not 
at  all  times  be  readily  turned  into  cash.  Here 
a  distinction  must  be  made.  So  far  we  have 
referred  to  what  is  popularly  called  bill  broking. 
But  there  is  another  large  branch  of  the  bUl 
business  which  consists  in  the  negotiation  of 
bills  drawn  by  British  houses  on  firms  abroad  in 
payment  for  goods  exported  from  these  islands. 
In  dealing  with  such  bills,  questions  of  Exchange 
{q.v. )  are  all-important.  The  biUs  are  drawn  in 
the  money  of  the  country  where  payable,  and 
they  have  to  be  turned  into  English  money  foj 


BILL  BROKING 


141 


the  convenience  of  the  merchant  who  sells  them.  I 
The  bill  broker  makes  his  calculation  as  to  the 
currency  of  the  bill,  the  rate  of  exchange,  and 
the  contingencies  of  an  exchange  often  altering, 
and  names  a  price  at  which  he  buys  the  bill  and 
takes  all  risks  except  that  of  non-payment. 
The  amount  of  bills  thus  dealt  in  must  be 
very  large.  But  the  bill  broker  proper  has 
nothing  to  do  with  such  bills.  He  is  com- 
pletely ignorant  on  all  questions  of  exchange. 
The  firms  who  deal  in  such  bills  are  known  as 
"foreign  brokers,"  not  as  bill  brokers.  Leav- 
ing aside  at  present  this  special  department  of 
business  in  bills,  there  is  really  nothing  peculiar 
in  bill  broking  proper  to  distinguish  it  from 
banking  on  a  great  scale,  except  that  a  far 
larger  proportion  of  the  investments  made  by 
the  bill  broker  must  be  made  in  bills  of  ex- 
change for  two  reasons  :  (1)  That  he  requires  a 
large  supply  of  bills  of  all  dates  to  supply  his 
customers  who  desire  to  purchase  them,  or  to 
lend  money  on  the  deposit  of  bills  as  security, 
and  (2)  that,  as  he  holds  such  large  amounts 
{,ayable  at  call  or  short  notice,  he  requires  a 
security  which  is  perpetually  revolving  and 
coming  to  maturity  as  cash,  and  no  known 
security  answers  this  description  so  well  as 
bills  of  exchange.  He  takes  them  daily  of  all 
dates,  from  a  few  days  or  weeks  to  run  to  six 
months,  and  they  are  perpetually  falling  in  and 
supplying  him  Avith  money. 

It  is  a  common  observation  that  in  banking 
no  reserve  is  so  good  as  a  store  of  bills  of 
exchange,  and  there  is  a  constant  demand  for 
them  on  the  part  of  banks,  both  in  town  and 
country,  who  cannot  procure  from  their  own 
customers  a  sufficient  supply.  It  is  one  great 
part  of  the  business  of  the  bill  broker  to  supply 
banks  with  this  necessary  aliment.  The  profit 
made  on  thus  selling  bills  out  and  out  is  gener- 
ally very  small,  but  when  once  sold  there  is  no 
further  thought  about  the  bill,  if  it  is  good  ;  and 
the  seller  has  the  money  in  hand  with  which  to 
make  a  fresh  investment  of  the  same  kind.  In 
this  way  a  bill  broker  may  turn  over  his 
"money"  many  times  in  a  year,  and  in  the  ag- 
gregate obtain  a  fair  return,  though  his  liabilities 
on  bills  will  be  apparently  enormous,  but  really 
very  small,  as  the  proportion  of  unpaid  bills  in 
a  well -managed  business  is  extremely  slight. 
The  history  of  the  business  seems,  at  first  sight, 
to  imply  that  the  risks  run  are  peculiarly 
heavy,  so  many  of  the  old  firms  having  dis- 
appeared through  failure.  As  a  bill  depends 
entirely  on  names,  and  not  on  property,  except 
occasionally  where  "document  bills"  are  nego- 
tiated, it  is  obvious  that  much  knowledge  and 
experience  are  required  in  the  choice  of  such 
paper.  And  even  where  there  is  a  certainty  of 
the  ultimate  payment  of  bills,  there  may  be 
a  gi-eat  risk  of  having  to  wait  long  for  pay- 
ment, and  in  the  meantime  of  a  heavy  lock- 
up of  capital,  a  contingency  which  has  otten 


caused  much  anxiety  and  embarrassment.  Sc 
have  passed  away  the  gi-eat  house  of  Overend, 
Gurney  &  Co.,  the  house  of  Sanderson,  Sande- 
man  &  Co.,  Bruce,  Buxton  &  Co.,  and  divers 
houses  of  smaller  repute.  Such  cases  illustrate 
the  peculiar  dangers  of  the  business,  but  that 
it  can  be  maintained  with  safety  and  success  is 
abundantly  proved  by  the  history  of  some  of 
the  companies  who  have  conducted  it  during 
the  past  thirty  years,  and  of  private  concerns 
of  old  standing  still  remaining  vigorous  not- 
withstanding the  severe  competition  Avhicli  has 
arisen,  to  say  nothing  of  smaller  houses  Avhich 
have  sprung  up  and  flourished  since  1866. 
Probably  it  may  safely  be  said  that,  since  that 
famous  date,  banking  and  bill  broking  have 
been  conducted  as  a  rule  with  more  caution 
than  during  previous  periods,  and  that  the  abuse 
of  credit  generally  has  been  less  rampant,  so  that 
mere  adventurers  have  had  far  more  difficulty 
than  formerly  in  negotiating  made-up  (i.e.  ficti- 
tious) bills. 

In  this  connection  it  may  be  proper  to  note 
the  prevailing  impression  that  out  of  a  given 
amount  of  business  far  less  is  done  on  bills, 
and  far  more  by  cash  payments  than  was  done, 
say  thirty  years  ago.  As  to  the  fact,  there 
seems  no  doubt  when  the  figures  as  to  inland 
bill  stamps  are  considered.  From  these  it  is 
evident  that  with  an  enlarged  business  fewer 
bills  are  created,  i  Again  it  is  said  that  the 
custom  of  obtaining  loans  from  banks  instead 
of  accepting  bills  has  much  developed — that 
a  man  who  owes  money,  instead  of  accepting 
for  the  amount,  takes  a  loan  from  his  bankers 
and  pays  cash.  In  this  case  there  is  credit, 
only  in  another  and  less  visible  form.  A  bill 
drawn  and  negotiated  may  pass  into  many 
hands,  but  the  loan  cannot  be  transferred,  and 
remains  a  private  afiair  between  the  banker  and 
his  customer. 

In  most  cases  there  is  an  important  advan- 
tage to  the  debtor  in  paying  cash,  and  banks 
prefer  loans  within  certain  limits,  because  they 
can  generally  charge  a  higher  rate  on  a  loan 
than  on  the  discount  of  a  bill.  Probably  both 
creditor  and  debtor  prefer  this  mode  of  settle- 
ment to  the  creation  of  biUs,  because  not  only 
are  stamps  saved,  but  the  natiire  of  their  rela- 
tions in  business  is  not  in  any  way  divulged 
beyond  the  banker's  room.  Another  important 
cause  of  the  diminution  of  foreign  bills,  that  is 
of  bills  dra^vn  on  London  by  traders  residing 
in  foreign  countries,  is  the  development  of  the 
system  of  Telegraphic  Tuansfers,  by  which 
very  large  sums  are  now  paid  without  the  creation 

1  It  is  not  so  easy  to  account  for  this  change  as  to 
prove  its  existence.  One  cause,  no  doubt,  is  a  great 
increase  of  the  actual  wealth  of  those  engaged  in  the 
larger  transactions  of  the  country.  Men  who  used  to 
accept  bills  now  pay  cash,  and  procure  important  ad- 
vantages thereby.  This  is  observed  in  all  parts  of  the 
country,  and  means  of  course  that  such  traders  have 
largely  increased  their  cash  resources,  and  so  are  enabled 
to  dispense  with  Credit. 


142 


BILL  BROKING— BILL  OF  EXCHANGE 


of  a  bill.  Formerly,  for  instance,  almost  the 
whole  of  the  enormous  produce  and  credit  busi- 
ness between  America  and  England  was  effected 
by  sixty  days  bills.  Now,  it  is  said  that  the 
amount  of  bills  of  this  description  is  not  one- 
third  of  what  it  formerly  was.  This  alone 
would  mean  a  gi-eat  reduction  in  the  aggregate 
of  bills,  and  the  same  process  is  going  on,  more 
or  less,  as  to  the  trade  with  the  East,  etc.  So, 
from  various  causes,  the  creation  of  bills  no 
longer  keeps  pace  with  the  extension  of  business ; 
and  complaints  are  frequent  that  "bills  are 
scarce,"  that  "it  is  impossible  to  find  bills 
enough  for  the  demand,"  and  so  on,  the  result 
being  that  holders  of  bills  often  have  the  dis- 
count market  under  control ;  hence  the  bank 
minimum  rate  no  longer  guides  the  market  dur- 
ing considerable  periods,  and  the  machinery  of 
the  money  market  is  dislocated,  the  bank  being 
compelled  to  have  recourse  to  unusual  and  ex- 
traordinary means  of  reducing  the  supply  of 
loanable  capital  in  the  market.  It  is  perhaps 
worth  noting  here  that  while  thirty  years  ago, 
the  Bank  of  England  was  one  of  the  largest 
holders  of  bills  of  exchange,  it  is  now  believed 
to  be  one  of  the  smallest  amongst  the  larger 
holders.  This  change  arises  from  the  enormous 
growth  of  the  deposits  of  other  banks,  which 
deposits  are  largely  invested  in  bills,  and  as 
these  fall  due,  are  re-invested  in  the  same 
security,  so  that  there  arises  a  continual  de- 
mand for  bills,  and  a  tendency  to  depression 
of  rates  of  discount.  It  is  difficult  for  the  bank 
to  counteract  this  tendency.  The  amounts  in 
question  are  too  large,  and  as  deposits  seem  ever 
on  the  increase  and  bills  are  not  increasing  in 
proportion,  we  have  seen  in  recent  years  longer 
periods  of  "  cheap  money  "  than  have  ever  before 
been  known  in  the  history  of  our  commerce. 

Other  interesting  observations  arise  in  refer- 
ence to  the  comparison  of  our  own  practice  as 
to  bills  and  that  of  other  countries  of  commer- 
cial importance. 

Take  the  case  of  France.  It  is  said  that 
there  is  no  trade  in  Paris  in  bills  as  there  is  in 
London.  The  Bank  of  France  holds  always  a 
large  amount  of  bills  which  she  has  discounted 
for  customers,  but  of  course  they  are  held  till 
maturity  and  are  not  dealt  in.  She,  having 
branches  all  over  France,  is  the  great  French 
collector  of  money.  Moreover  credit  is  not  de- 
veloped in  France  as  with  us,  so  that  bills  are 
not  created  in  sufficient  quantity  to  support  a 
great  trade  in  them.  BiUs  are  of  necessity 
drawn  from  Paris  on  all  parts  of  France,  and 
they  are  said  to  be  mostly  held  by  the  Bank  of 
France,  but  the  bill  is  not,  as  with  us,  the  most 
important  of  all  banking  securities  (see  Bank 
OF  France  ;  Clearing  House). 

Take  again  the  United  States.  In  Chicago, 
for  instance,  the  great  distributing  houses  do 
not  generally  draw  on  local  centres  for  the 
amounts  due  to  them  by  smaller  traders.     They 


hold  these  as  book  debts  which  they  collect  as 
they  can,  in  the  meantime  borrowing  from 
banks  for  what  they  may  themselves  require. 
In  England,  on  the  contrary,  such  houses  draw 
bills  even  for  very  small  amounts  which  they 
discount  in  the  market,  thus  avoiding  a  lock-up 
of  capital.  It  cannot  be  said  that  credit  is  not 
fully  developed  in  America,  but  in  form  it  dif- 
fers materially  from  our  system.  In  some  of 
the  great  eastern  cities  the  custom  is  said  to 
be  different,  and  to  resemble  more  that  with 
which  we  are  familiar,  and  in  New  York  there 
is  a  limited  market  in  bills,  but  not  at  all  on 
the  London  scale.  Banks  buy  bills  and  hold 
them,  but  there  do  not  appear  to  be  great  houses 
collecting  and  dealing  in  bills  after  our  fashion. 
Bill  broking  in  fact  may  be  said  to  be  one 
of  those  British  institutions  which  are  peculiar 
to  our  country  and  arise  from  the  peculiar 
nature  of  our  commercial  operations.  It  is  a 
growth  of  that  great  expansion  of  credit  which 
has  so  long  distinguished  our  country,  and  to 
which  we  owe  so  much  of  our  prosperity.  The 
system  is  liable  to  much  abuse,  and  has  at  times 
been  grieviously  abused,  but  it  is  not,  therefore, 
to  be  set  down  as  mischievous  and  useless.  It 
is  one  of  those  means  of  economising  the  use  of 
loanable  capital  which  are  intrinsically  valuable 
and  important,  and  are  therefore  certain  to  sur- 
vive criticism,  however  severe.  w.  f. 

BILL  OF  EXCHANGE.  The  word  biU, 
meaning  generally  a  statement  in  writing,  is  de- 
rived from  bulla  (Lat. )  Bills  of  exchange,  which 
may  be  divided  generally  between  "  inland"  and 
"foreign,"  those  which  take  their  origin  in  trans- 
actions in  one  country  only,  and  those  which 
arise  from  transactions  beyond  the  limits  of  that 
country  in  which  they  are  payable,  are  among 
the  most  important  of  Commercial  Instru- 
ments {q.v.)  Bills,  properly  speaking,  repre- 
sent debts,  they  may  be  used,  by  negotiation,  to 
transfer  these  debts  from  one  person  to  another, 
and  first-class  bills  form  one  of  the  best  securities 
which  a  banker  can  hold  (see  Bill  Broking). 
They  sometimes,  however,  are  drawn  without 
being  based  on  any  genuine  transactions  ;  in 
this  case  their  standing  is  more  doubtful  (see 
Accommodation  Bill  ;  Cross  Drawing  ; 
Kite).  Foreign  bUls  sometimes  originate  in 
exchange  operations,  and  are  hence  often  em- 
ployed in  connection  with  the  financial  liabilities 
of  governments.  The  amount  of  the  bills  of 
exchange  in  existence  at  one  time  in  the  United 
Kingdom  is  very  large.  It  was  estimated  by 
W.  Leatham  {Letters  to  Sir  G.  Wood,  2d  ed.  p. 
13),  as  being  £135,000,000  in  1841,  by  W. 
Newmarch  as  not  much  less  than  £180,000,000 
or  probably  £200,000,000  in  1856  (Tooke  and 
Newmarch,  History  of  Prices,  vol.  vi.  p.  588), 
by  E,.  H.  Inglis  Falgrave,  as  being  from 
£300,000,000  to  £350,000,000  in  1872  (Notes 
on  Banking,  p.  36).  The  amount  is  probably 
not  larger  now  (1910). 


BILL  OF  EXCHANGE,  LAW  OF 


143 


There  are  some  varieties  in  form  according  as 
bills  are  drawn  in  England  on  persons  residing 
in  foreign  countries  or  otherwise.  A  very  usual 
one  is  as  follows  : 

Due  Zd  March  1891. 
£500. 

Liverpool,  Zlst  Jan.  1891. 
One  month  after  date  pay  to  us,  or  order, 
Five  Hundred  Pounds  value  received  in  goods, 
as  per  invoice  dated  25.1.91.       A.  B.  k  Co. 
Messrs.  C.  D   &  Co. 

415  Mincing  Lane, 

London,  E.G. 

[For  further  details  see  books  named  above,  and 
Goschen's  Foreign  Exchanges,  in  which  foreign 
bills  especially  are  treated  of.] 

BILL  OF  EXCHANGE,  Law  of.  The 
law  relating  to  bills,  notes,  and  cheques,  differs 
from  other  branches  o^  our  mercantile  law  in 
two  respects.  First,  it  has  been  codified  by  the 
Bills  of  Exchange  Act  1882  (45  &  46  Vict.  c. 
61),  and  secondly,  the  act  in  question  applies 
to  the  whole  of  the  United  Kingdom  ;  so  that 
with  the  exception  of  two  Scotch  rules  which 
are  specially  preserved,  there  is  now  a  practically 
uniform  body  of  rules  for  England,  Scotland,  and 
Ireland. 

By  §  3  of  the  act  a  bill  of  exchange  is  de- 
fined as  "an  unconditional  order  in  writing, 
addressed  by  one  person  to  anotlier,  signed  by 
the  person  giving  it,  requiring  the  person  to 
whom  it  is  addressed  to  pay  on  demand  or  at  a 
fixed  or  determinable  future  time  a  sum  certain 
in  money  to,  or  to  the  order  of,  a  specified 
person  or  to  bearer."  The  person  who  gives 
the  order  is  called  the  Drawer,  the  person  there- 
by ordered  to  pay  is  called  the  drawee,  and  if 
he  signifies  his  assent  to  the  order  in  due  form 
he  is  then  called  the  Acceptor.  An  acceptance 
must  be  in  writing  on  the  bill  and  be  signed  by 
the  drawee  (§  17).  When  a  bill  is  payable  to 
a  person  named  or  to  his  order,  it  may  be  trans- 
ferred by  his  endorsement.  The  person  to  whom 
it  is  so  transferred  is  called  the  endorsee.  The 
term  "  holder  "  includes  alike  the  bearer  of  a  bill 
payable  to  bearer,  an  original  payee,  and  an 
endorsee. 

Bills  of  exchange  are  said  to  have  originated 
with  the  Florentines  in  the  12th  century. 
From  Italy  their  use  spread  to  France,  and 
from  thence  to  England,  and  throughout  the 
commercial  world  generally.  A  bill  of  exchange 
in  its  origin  was  an  instrument  by  which  a 
trade  debt  due  in  one  place  was  transferred  in 
another,  thereby  avoiding  the  necessity  of  trans- 
mitting cash  from  place  to  place.  But  in 
England  mercantile  usage  adopted  into  law  by 
judicial  decisions  has  enlarged  the  original 
idea,  and  has  created,  by  means  of  bills  and 
notes,  a  perfectly  flexible  paper  currency.  Per- 
haps the  full  force  of  the  English  definition 
cited  above  is  best  brought  out  by  contrasting 


it  with  some  foreign  system.  French  law,  which 
adheres  rigidly  to  the  original  theory  of  the  uses 
of  bills,  offers  the  best  contrast.  In  France  a 
bill  represents  a  trade  transaction,  in  England 
it  is  merely  an  instrument  of  credit.  English 
law  gives  full  play  to  the  system  of  accom- 
modation paper  (see  AccoMMODATfON  Bill)  ; 
French  law  endeavours  to  stamp  it  out.  Thus 
in  England  it  is  not  necessary  to  express  on  the 
face  of  a  bill  that  value  has  been  given,  for  the 
law  raises  a  presumption  to  that  effect.  In 
Franci  the  nature  of  the  value  given  must  be 
expressed,  and  a  false  statement  of  value  voids 
the  bill  in  the  hands  of  all  parties  with  notice. 
In  England  a  bill  may  be  drawn  and  payable  in 
the  same  place.  According  to  French  law, 
though  the  rule  is  said  of  recent  years  to  be  dis- 
regarded in  practice,  the  place  where  a  bill  is 
drawn  must  be  so  far  distant  from  the  place 
where  it  is  payable  that  there  may  be  a  possible 
rate  of  exchange  between  the  two.  A  false 
statement  of  places  so  as  to  evade  this  rule  voids 
the  bill  in  the  hands  of  parties  with  notice.  As 
the  French  lawyers  put  it,  a  bill  of  exchange 
necessarily  presupposes  a  contract  of  exchange. 
In  England  a  bill  may  be  drawn  payable  to 
bearer.  In  France  it  must  be  dra\vn  payable  to 
order  ;  if  it  were  not  so  the  rule  requiring  the 
consideration  to  be  expressed  would  be  a  nullity. 
In  England  a  bill  payable  to  order  becomes 
payable  to  bearer  when  endorsed  in  blank.  In 
France  an  endorsement  in  blank  merely  operates 
as  a  procuration.  In  England  if  a  bill  be  re- 
fused acceptance,  a  right  of  action  against  the 
drawer  and  endorsers  at  once  accrues  to  the 
holder.  This  is  the  logical  consequence  of  the 
currency  theory.  In  France  no  cause  of  action 
arises  unless  the  bill  is  again  dishonoured  at 
matm-ity  ;  the  holder  in  the  meantime  is  only 
entitled  to  demand  secm-ity  from  the  drawer 
and  endorsers.  In  England  a  sharp  distinction 
is  drawn  between  current  and  overdue  bills.  A 
person  who  becomes  the  holder  of  a  bill  after  its 
maturity,  acquires  and  can  give  no  better  title 
to  it  than  the  person  from  whom  he  took  it  had. 
In  France  no  such  distinction  appears  to  be 
drawn  (see  Chalmers  on  Bills  of  Exchange,  ed. 
3,  Introd.,  pp.  xlv.-xlvii.) 

In  some  foreign  countiies  any  creditor  is 
entitled  to  draw  on  his  debtor  for  the  amount 
of  his  debt,  but  in  England  the  right  to  draw 
arises  only  from  special  agreement.  A  reason 
for  the  English  rule  may  perhaps  be  found  in 
the  fact  that  at  common  law,  apart  from  special 
agreement,  it  is  the  duty  of  the  debtor  to  seek 
out  his  creditor,  as  soon  as  the  debt  is  due,  and 
to  tender  the  money  to  him. 

BiUs  of  exchange  payable  on  demand  may  be 
stamped  with  either  impressed  or  adhesive 
stamps,  the  stamp  duty  being  one  penny. 
Foreign  notes  and  bills  must  of  course  be 
'  stamped  with  adhesive  stamps.  Inland  notes 
of  aU  kinds,  and  inland  bills  payable  otherwise 


144 


BILL  OF  EXCHANGE,  LAW  OF 


than  on  demand,  must  be  drawn  on  impressed 
stamps.  All  notes  and  bills,  other  than  bills 
payable  on  demand,  are  subject  to  an  ad  valorem 
stamp  duty  (Stamp  Act  1870,  §§  45-55  and 
Schedule).  Section  72  of  the  Bills  of  Exchange 
Act  provides  that  when  a  bill  or  note  is  igsued 
out  of  the  United  Kingdom  it  is  not  to  be  im- 
peached because  it  is  not  stamped  in  accordance 
Avith  the  law  of  the  place  of  issue.  This  affirms 
a  general  rule  that  the  courts  of  one  country 
take  no  cognisance  of  the  revenue  laws  of  an- 
other country.  The  enactment  is  clearly  a  fair 
one,  as  the  present  stamp  act  requires  bills 
issued  abroad  to  be  stamped  here,  and  makes 
no  allowance  for  the  foreign  stamp. 

The  acceptor  is  the  party  primarily  liable  on 
a  bill.  By  accepting  it  he  "engages  that  he 
will  pay  it  according  to  the  tenor  of  his  accept- 
ance "  (§  64).  The  holder  is  entitled  to  require 
an  absolute  acceptance,  but  if  the  drawee  will 
only  give  a  qualified  or  conditional  acceptance, 
the  holder  may  either  treat  this  as  a  refusal  to 
accept,  or  at  his  peril  take  the  qualified  accept- 
ance (§§  19,  44). 

The  drawer  of  a  bill  is  in  the  nature  of  a 
surety  for  the  acceptor.  He  "engages  that  on 
due  presentment  it  shall  be  accepted  and  paid 
according  to  its  tenor,  and  that  if  it  be  dis- 
honoured he  will  compensate  the  holder  or  any 
endorser  who  is  compelled  to  pay  it,  provided 
that  the  requisite  probeedings  on  dishonour  be 
duly  taken  "  (§  55).  The  endorser  of  a  bill  is 
in  the  nature  of  a  new  drawer,  and  his  obliga- 
tions to  subsequent  parties  resemble  those  of  the 
drawer.  When  a  bill  is  dishonoured  the  holder 
must,  subject  to  certain  specified  exceptions 
(§  50),  give  notice  of  dishonour  to  the  drawer 
and  endorsers  he  wishes  to  charge,  and  if  the 
bill  be  a  foreign  bill  he  must  also  protest  it. 
An  inland  bill  may  be  noted,  but  no  legal  conse- 
quences attach  to  this  proceeding,  except  the 
right  to  recover  the  noting  expenses.  When 
the  liabilities  of  the  drawer  and  endorsers  are 
fixed  by  taking  the  proper  proceedings  on  dis- 
honour, the  holder  may  either  sue  all  the  parties 
to  the  bill  concurrently,  or  he  may  sue  them  in 
succession  until  he  has  recovered  the  amount  of 
the  bill  with  his  damages  and  costs. 

Sometimes,  when  it  is  doubtful  whether  the 
drawee  will  accept  or  whether  he  will  be  in  a 
position  to  pay  when  the  bill  matures,  the  bill 
specifies  some  other  person  to  whom  the  holder 
may  resort  in  case  of  need.  This  person  is 
sailed  the  "besoin"  or  "case  of  need."  If  he 
accepts  the  bill  he  is  called  an  "acceptor  for 
honour,"  and  if  he  pays  it  he  is  called  a  "  payer 
for  honour."  He  must  not  pay  the  bill  till  it 
has  been  duly  noted  or  protested  for  non-pay- 
ment by  the  original  drawee.  On  payment  he 
becomes  entitled  to  exercise  the  rights  of  the 
holder  as  against  the  party  for  whose  honour 
he  paid  and  all  parties  antecedent  to  him 
(§§  65-68). 


Comparing  bills  of  exchange  with  other  coi: 
tracts,  it  will  appear  that  the  majority  of  the 
peculiar  rules  relating  to  them  are  deducible 
from  the  fact  of  their  negotiability.  A  contract 
or  chose  in  action  is  not  assignable  at  common 
law,  though  in  equity  the  benefit  of  it  might  be 
assigned  subject  to  all  equities  between  the 
parties.  But  a  bill  of  exchange  is  part  of  the 
mercantile  currency  of  the  country,  and  its 
primary  object  is  that  it  should  circulate  freely 
from  hand  to  hand  and  that  every  honest  holder 
should  be  able  to  deal  with  it  like  cash.  A 
bill  payable  to  order  may  be  negotiated  by  the 
endorsement  of  the  holder,  completed  by  de- 
livery. A  bill  payable  to  bearer,  or  endorsed  in 
blank,  may  be  negotiated  by  mere  delivery.  The 
consideration  for  its  issue,  acceptance,  and  ne- 
gotiation is  presumed  until  the  contrary  is  shown 
or  d,  prima  facie  case  of  fraud  is  made  out,  in 
which  case  the  onus  of  proof  is  shifted  (§  30). 
If  a  bill  gets  into  the  hands  of  a  "holder  in 
due  Course"  (§  29),  he  gets  an  absolute  title, 
and  no  antecedent  fraud  other  than  forgery 
affects  him  (§  38).  So  strong  is  this  rule  in 
English  law  that  if  a  person  puts  a  blank  signa- 
ture on  stamp  paper,  it  is  treated  as  an  authority 
to  any  person  to  whom  the  paper  is  delivered  to 
fill  it  up  as  a  bill  for  any  amount  the  stamp  wiU 
cover,  and  if  the  bill,  when  complete,  gets  into 
the  hands  of  a  holder  for  value  without  notice, 
no  objection  that  the  paper  was  improperly 
dealt  with  is  allowed  to  prevail  (§  20).  The 
laws  of  all  countries  agree  in  the  rule  that  no 
title  can  be  made  to  a  bill  through  a  forged 
signature,  but  English  law  is  peculiarly  severe 
on  the  party  who  pays  the  bill  (§  24).  Except 
in  the  case  of  a  demand  draft  drawn  on  a  banker 
(§  60)  the  person  who  pays  a  bill  pays  it  at  his 
peril  if  the  party  presenting  it  claims  under  a 
forged  endorsement.  Thus  if  the  drawee  of  a 
bill  accepts  it,  payable  at  his  bankers,  after  a 
forged  endorsement  has  been  placed  on  it,  the 
bankers  cannot  debit  his  account  with  the 
amount  of  such  payment.  Under  the  conti- 
nental codes,  a  banker  who  paid  such  a  bUl 
without  any  notice  of  the  fraud  would  be  pro- 
tected. 

A  further  peculiarity  of  English  law  is  the 
compulsory  allowance  of  three  days  of  grace  on 
all  bills  payable  otherwise  than  on  demand 
(§  14).  It  is  believed  that  aU  the  continental 
codes  now  agree  in  abolishing  this  fictitious 
maturity  for  bUls,  but  the  holder  is  generally 
entitled  to  wait  one  or  two"  days  before  the  bill 
is  protested. 

From  the  references  to  foreign  law  already 
made,  it  appears  that  the  practice  of  the  mercan- 
tile world,  with  reference  to  bills  of  exchange,  is 
by  no  means  uniform.  Rules,  therefore,  are 
required  for  regulating  this  conflict  of  laws,  and 
they  are  provided  by  §  72  of  the  act,  their 
guiding  principle  being  the  maxim  "locus  regit 
actum." 


{ 


BILL  OF  LADING— BILL  OF  SALE 


145 


A  Promissory  Note  is  defined  by  §  83  of  the 
Act  to  be  "  an  unconditional  promise  in  writing 
made  by  one  person  to  another,  signed  by  the 
maker,  engaging  to  pay  on  demand  or  at  a  fixed 
or  determinable  future  time  a  sum  certain  in 
money  to,  or  to  the  order  of,  a  specified  person 
or  to  bearer."  There  are  various  statutory  re- 
strictions on  the  issue  of  promissory  notes  pay- 
able to  bearer  on  demand  for  less  than  £5,  and 
there  are  further  restrictions  on  the  issue  by 
bankers  of  either  bills  or  notes  for  any  amount 
payable  to  bearer  on  demand.  "When  a  promis- 
sory note  is  made  by  two  or  throe  makers,  they 
are  liable,  either  jointly  or  jointly  and  severally, 
according  to  the  tenor  of  the  instrument  (§  85). 
In  this  a  note  differs  from  a  bill,  because  if  a  bill 
be  accepted  by  two  or  more  drawees,  they  are 
only  liable  jointly  and  not  jointly  and  severally. 
But  for  the  most  part  the  provisions  of  the  act 
with  reference  to  bills  of  exchange  apply,  witli 
the  necessary  modifications,  to  promissory  notes. 
In  applying  those  provisions,  the  maker  of  a 
note  is  deemed  to  correspond  with  the  acceptor 
of  a  bill,  and  the  first  indorser  of  a  note  is 
deemed  to  correspond  Avith  the  drawer  of  an 
accepted  bill  payable  to  drawer's  order  (§  89). 
The  provisions  of  the  act  relating  to  present- 
ment for  acceptance,  acceptance,  acceptance  si/^9?-« 
protest,  and  bills  in  a  set  have  no  application 
to  notes.  Moreover,  protest  of  a  foreign  note  is 
unnecessary  for  English  pm-poscs  (ibid.) 

For  the  economic  opeiation  of  bills  and  notes 
as  instruments  of  credit,  see  Bill  of  Exchange, 
Credit,  Cross  Drawing,  Goschen's  Foreign 
Exchanges  and  Mill's  Political  Economy,  bk.  ii. 
For  the  English  law  see  Byles,  Bills  of  Exchange  ; 
Chalmers,  Bills  of  Exchange  ;  Chitty,  Bills  of 
Exchange.  For  American  law,  see  Story,  Bills 
of  Excluinge  ;  Parson's  Law  of  Notes  and  Bills  ; 
Daniell,  Negotiable  Instrnments.  For  French 
law  see  Nouguier's  Lettres  de  Change  et  Effets 
de  Commerce,  ed,  4  (1875),  summarising  the 
provisions  of  the  various  continental  codes. 
For  Indian  law  on  the  subject  see  Indian 
Negotiable  Instruments  Act  1881,  as  amended 
by  Act  II.  of  1885.  Canada  and  some  of  the 
Australian  colonies  have  adopted  the  English 
Bills  of  Exchange  Act.  The  Conference 
on  Bills  of  Exchange  (the  Hague,  1910) 
agreed  to  a  general  Act  regulating  sucli  Bills 
which  it  is  to  be  hoped  Avill  be  generally 
adopted.  m.  d.  c. 

BILL  OF  LADING.  A  document  by  which 
the  master  or  some  other  agent  of  the  shipowner 
on  his  behalf  acknowledges  the  receipt  of  certain 
goods,  and  undertakes  to  deliver  them  to  the 
consignee  at  the  port  of  destination,  against  the 
payment  of  freight  and  subject  to  certain  con- 
tingencies releasing  him  from  liability.  The 
consignee  is  either  named  in  the  bill  of  lading, 
or  it  is  simply  stated  that  the  goods  are  to  be 
delivered  to  the  order  of  the  shipper,  in  which 
case  the  goods  are  delivered  to  the  person  to 
VOL.  I. 


whom  the  document  is  indorsed,  or  to  a  subse- 
quent indorsee.  If  the  bill  of  lading  is  made 
out  to  the  consignee  or  his  order,  the  goods  are 
delivered  either  to  the  consignee  or  an  indorsee, 
but  if  the  consignee  is  named  without  any 
additional  words  he  is  the  only  person  who  has 
a  legal  right  to  the  delivery  of  the  goods.  As 
a  general  rule  an  indorsee  acquires  the  property 
in  the  goods  as  soon  as  a  properly  indorsed  bill 
of  lading  is  handed  over  to  him  with  that  in- 
tention, but  this  rule  is  subject  to  several  excep- 
tions, the  most  important  one  being  the  so-called 
right  of  stoppage  in  transitu,  which  enables  an 
unpaid  seller  to  stop  the  delivery  of  the  goods 
if  the  buyer  has  become  insolvent  before  they 
came  into  his  power.  If,  however,  the  buyer 
has  in  the  meantime  transferred  the  bill  of  lading 
to  a  bona  fide  holder  for  valuable  consideration, 
the  right  is  no  longer  available.  It  must  also 
be  mentioned  that  a  bill  of  lading  is  not  negoti- 
able in  the  same  sense  as  a  cheque  or  a  properly 
indorsed  bill  of  exchange.  A  person  who  in 
good  faith  gives  value  for  a  stolen  current  bill 
of  exchange  indorsed  in  blank,  or  for  a  cheque 
to  bearer,  acquires  a  good  title,  though  the  thief 
from  whom  he  bouglit  it  had  none.  This  is 
not  the  case  with  regard  to  a  bill  of  lading,  as 
a  subsequent  holder  of  a  document  of  this  nature 
cannot  (except  in  so  far  as  he  is  not  affected  b}' 
the  light  of  stoppage  in  transitu)  acquire  a 
better  title  than  a  previous  holder  had.  In 
former  times  the  contractual  rights  and  liabilities 
arising  from  a  bill  of  lading  (e.g.  the  right  to 
sue  in  case  of  loss)  remained  with  the  original 
parties,  notwithstanding  the  transfer  of  the 
property  in  the  goods,  but  the  statute  18  &  19 
Vict.  c.  Ill  enacts  that  "every  consignee  of 
goods  named  in  a  bill  of  lading  and  every  in- 
dorsee of  a  bill  of  lading  to  whom  the  property 
in  the  goods  therein  mentioned  shall  pass  upon 
or  by  reason  of  such  consignment  or  indorse- 
ment, shall  have  transferred  to  and  vested  in 
him  all  rights  of  suit,  and  be  subject  to  the 
same  liabilities  in  respect  of  such  goods  as  if 
the  contract  contained  in  the  bill  of  lading  had 
been  made  with  himself."  Bills  of  lading  are 
generally  made  out  in  sets  of  several  identical 
copies,  which  are  forwarded  by  different  mails, 
so  that  one  may  serve  in  case  of  the  loss  of 
another.  The  system  is  not  free  from  danger, 
as  a  fraudulent  holder  may  negotiate  each  copy 
separately.  Occurrences  of  this  sort  have 
happened  on  more  than  one  occasion,  and  have 
caused  a  considerable  amount  of  litigation. 

E.  s. 
BILL  OF  SALE.  A  document  purporting 
to  assign  the  property  in  personal  chattels 
remaining  in  the  possession  of  the  assignor. 
Assignments  of  this  nature  as  a  general  rule 
are  not  made  for  the  purpose  of  a  regular  sale, 
but  merely  by  way  of  security  for  a  loan.  A 
bill  of  sale  is  void  as  against  execution  creditors, 
if  it  is  not  drawn  up  in  the  statutory  form  and 

L 


146 


BILLON— BI-METALLISM 


registered  in  the  central  office  of  the  High  Court 
within  seven  days  of  the  date  of  issue  ;  it  must 
also  be  renewed  every  five  years.  A  charge  of 
personal  chattels  in  a  debenture  need  not 
be  registered  as  a  bill  of  sale.  The  acts  of 
parliament  now  regulating  the  law  of  b^lls  of 
sale  are  those  of  1878  and  1882  (41  &  42 
Vict.  c.  31  ;  45  &  46  Vict.  c.  43).  A  bill  of 
sale  given  by  way  of  security  for  the  payment 
of  a  sum  under  £30  is  void.  E.  s. 

BILLON.  This  conventional  term,  French 
rather  than  English,  is  derived  from  a  corrup- 
tion of  the  low-Latin  word  Ullio,  or  buUio,  from 
which  springs  the  English  word  bullion.  In 
French  mint  language  it  has  certainly,  from  the 
13th  century,  if  not  before,  signified  the  degener- 
acy of  the  pure  contents  of  a  coin  through  an 
alloy,  generally  silver  in  the  gold  pieces,  or  copper 
or  lead  in  the  silver  pieces,  giving  them  a  par- 
ticular degree  of  impurity,  and  thus  debasing 
their  intrinsic  value.  In  the  old  French  coin- 
age, down  to  the  monetary  reform  in  the  first 
revolution,  the  silver  marc  of  a  given  weight 
was  imagined  as  divided  into  twelve  parts 
called  deniers  d'alloi,  eleven  of  them  pure  silver 
and  one  alloy.  This  mixture  was  silver  of  W, 
or,  in  decimals,  of  '9166  fine,  and  was  the  old 
standard.  This  was  altered  to  ^,  or,  in  deci- 
mals, to  -900  fine,  from  1804  to  the  present 
time.  All  degrees  of  fineness  below  it,  or 
below  the  standard  at  the  time  being,  were 
considered  as  changing  the  coin  to  billon. 

That  designation  is  also  largely  applied  by 
numismatists  to  ancient  silver  coins,  and 
notably  to  those  of  the  Roman  and  Greek 
series,  when  these  are  materially  below  what 
ought  to  be  the  average  standard  fineness  of  the 
metal,  according  to  the  scales  laid  down  at  the 
best  periods  for  purity  of  the  silver  coinage, 
and  it  is  even  extended  by  them  to  what  are 
really  false  coins  (although  struck  by  state  or 
other  ruling  authority)  of  copper,  or  of  brass, 
plated  or  washed  over  with  silver,  and  passed 
with  forced  currency  as  silver  coins.  Thus  the 
term  is  made  to  cover  a  wide  range  of  meaning, 
varying  from  a  comparatively  small  degree  of 
degradation  in  fineness  down  to  the  merest 
pretence  of  having  any  actual  intrinsic  value  of 
precious  metal  in  the  composition  of  such  coins. 

It  is  noticeable  that  the  term  billon  has  not 
been  applied  in  France  without  some  exceptions 
in  the  case  of  gold  below  the  standard.  It 
was  so  applied  in  the  Middle  Ages,  but,  in  the 
time  of  Louis  XIV.,  when  under  twelve  carats 
out  of  the  twenty-four  carats  were  of  pure  gold, 
the  alloy  was  called  ''silver  holding  gold,"  or, 
if  the  proportion  of  copper  to  gold  was  of  like 
amount,  the  aUoy  was  called  "copper  holding 
gold."  The  term  billon  has  also  been  generally 
used  in  France  for  all  copper  or  bronze  money, 
even  when  it  is  of  fall  weight  according  to 
mint  indentures.  In  some  points  of  view  this 
appears  contradictory,  but  the  use  of  the  word 


is  probably  intended  to  convey  the  meaning  ol 
a  token  coinage,  the  intrinsic  value  being  so 
largely  below  the  nominal  one.  Whilst  the 
full-weighted  five-franc  silver  pieces  of  France, 
Italy,  Belgium,  Switzerland,  and  other  states 
which  are  allies  in  the  now  subsisting  Latin 
monetary  union,  continue  to  be  coined  ^ 
or  '900  fine,  their  2  franc,  1  franc,  and  ^  franc 
pieces  are  still  coined  -835  fine,  or  just  on  the 
borderland  which  divided  silver  of  the  old 
standard  from  billon.  But  in  England  our 
coinage  of  crowns,  four  shillings,  half-crowns, 
florins,  shillings,  sixpences,  and  threepences,  is 
struck  of  a  higher  degree  of  fineness,  namely, 
•925.  In  the  general  result  it  would  seem  that, 
as  standards  vary  in  difierent  countries,  what 
is  locally  billon  in  any  one  of  them  need  not 
necessarily  be  so  in  others,  and  that  such  a 
variation  prevents  any  precise  general  inter- 
national agreement  as  to  what  the  word 
exactly  signifies  at  different  places  or  times  (see 
Bullion).  f.  h. 

BI-METALLISM.  This  compound  word  is 
used  to  describe  the  employment  of  two  metals, 
to  form  at  the  same  time,  in  combination  with 
each  other,  the  standard  of  value.  The  final  re- 
port of  the  Royal  Commission  on  Gold  and  Silver 
describes  bi-metallism  as  follows :  "  A  bi-metaUic 
system  of  currency  to  be  completely  effective 
must,  in  the  view  of  those  who  advocate  it, 
include  two  essential  features :  (a)  An  open 
mint  ready  to  coin  any  quantity  of  either  gold 
or  silver  which  may  be  brought  to  it.  (&)  The 
right  on  the  part  of  a  debtor  to  discharge  his 
liabilities,  at  his  option,  in  either  of  the  two 
metals,  at  a  ratio  fixed  by  law."  It  is  usually 
understood  now  to  mean  that  the  two  metals 
are  used  thus  at  a  fixed  proportion  to  each 
other,  as  in  the  countries  forming  the  Latin 
Union  {q.v.),  in  which  the  ratio  of  1  gold  to  15^ 
silver  by  weight  forms  the  legal  basis,  or  in  the 
United  States  in  which  the  ratio  is  1  to  16.  Few 
economic  subjects  have  of  recent  years  been  dis- 
cussed with  more  heat,  owing  partly  to  the  fact 
that  some  on  the  one  hand  have  considered  that 
the  adoption,  or  the  retention,  of  bi-metallism 
would  confer  certain  advantages  on  particular 
classes,  and  that  some  on  the  other  hand  think 
that  Monometallism  profits  other  classes. 

The  main  requisite  in  a  standard  is,  that  it 
should  be,  as  nearly  as  possible,  constant  in  its 
purchasing  power.  The  selection,  or  the  con- 
struction, of  a  stable  standard  of  value  is,  how- 
ever, even  more  difficult  than  that  of  an  undevi- 
ating  standard  of  time.  In  this  connection  it 
is  advisable,  while  considering  here  the  possible 
employment  of  two  metals  for  this  purpose,  to 
quote  the  words  of  John  Locke  on  the  advan 
tage  of  employing  one  metal  only, — as  this  quo- 
tation sets  forth  the  drawbacks  to  bi-metallism 
without  any  reference  to  recent  controversy, — 
bearing  in  mind  the  circumstance  that  at  the 
date  when  Locke  wrote  international  bi-metal- 


BI-METALLISM 


147 


lism  had  never  been  thouglit  of.  "Two  metals, 
as  gold  and  silver,  cannot  be  the  measure  of 
commerce  both  together  in  any  country ;  because 
the  measure  of  commerce  must  be  perpetually 
the  same,  invariable,  and  keeping  the  same  pro- 
portion of  value  in  all  its  parts"  {Further 
Considerations  concerning  raising  the  Value  of 
Money,  John  Locke).  On  the  principle  thus 
expressed  the  Standard  of  Yalije,  understood 
in  the  sense  of  the  measure  provided  by  the 
government,  through  their  engagement  to  coin 
at  a  fixed  rate  the  metal  brought  to  them  for 
the  purpose,  has  been  based  in  this  country  by 
legal  enactment  since  1798,  in  practice  nearly 
since  the  commencement  of  the  18  th  century, 
though  a  double  standard  remained  legal  till 
the  date  mentioned.  Gold  became  the  general 
medium  of  circulation  in  this  country  either 
through  choice  or,  what  seems  the  more  prob- 
able, through  the  differing  ratio  of  value  in 
foreign  countries  which  made  silver  the  best 
export.  In  1798,  shortly  after  the  suspension 
of  cash  payments  (1797),  the  government  sus- 
pended the  coinage  of  silver.  Up  to  1783 
every  man  might  make  his  payments  in  silver 
or  gold  at  his  option  ;  though  after  1774  he 
could  only  pay  in  silver  up  to  £25  "by  tale," 
but  "by  weight"  up  to  any  amount.  There 
was  no  restriction  as  to  payments  in  gold. 
The  general  practice  of  the  country  before  the 
restriction  was  confirmed  by  the  distinct  adoption 
of  a  gold  mono-metallic  basis  on  the  resumption 
of  specie  payments  in  1816.  Silver  was,  how- 
ever, allowed  to  be  held  as  part  of  the  reserve 
of  the  precious  metals  against  which  the  notes 
of  the  Bank  of  England  are  allowed  to  be  issued 
by  the  3d  clause  of  the  act  of  1844  (see  Bank 
Note,  Bank  of  England),  which  permits  the 
bank  to  retain  in  the  issue  department  silver 
bullion  to  an  amount  not  "  exceeding  one-fourth 
part  of  the  gold  coin  and  bullion  at  such  time 
held  by  tlie  Bank  of  England  in  tlie  issue  de- 
partment." Silver  bullion  was  accordingly  held 
by  the  issue  department  up  to  large  amounts 
(the  average  for  the  year  1846  was  £2,169,000  ; 
see  Bank  Rate  in  England,  France,  and  Ger- 
many, 1844-78,  Palgrave),  but  the  practice  was 
discontinued  in  1853,  and  has  never  since  been 
resumed.  While  this  country  became  mono- 
metallic, in  France  a  standard  fixed  at  the  rate 
of  1  mark  of  gold  to  15^  of  silver  was  definitely 
established  in  1785,  and  continued  by  the  law 
of  1803,  gold  and  silver,  in  5-franc  pieces,  being 
equally  legal  tender  for  any  amount.  The  Latin 
Union,  as  the  coinage  treaty  of  1865  was 
called,  which  included  France,  Belgium,  Switzer- 
land, Italy,  Greece,  and  Roumania,  carried  on 
its  mintage  operations  on  the  same  basis  as  in 
France  till  1874,  after  which  date  the  coin- 
age of  silver  was  restricted  and  practically  sus- 
pended. A  considerable  drop  in  the  market 
price  of  silver  followed.  From  having  been  4s. 
11^.  an  oz.  in  1344  it  sank  to  3s.  6d.  both  in 


1886  and  in  1889,  though  a  recovery  has  taken 
place  since.  The  results  of  this  alteration  have 
been  widespread,  the  eflFect  being  particularly 
seen  on  the  rate  of  exchange  between  countries 
with  a  gold  and  those  maintaining  a  silver 
standard  ;  and  less  distinctly  on  prices  of  com- 
modities in  general  within  the  countries  con- 
cerned. Much  discussion  has  hence  ensued. 
It  may,  however,  be  observed  that  a  real  mono- 
metallism had  not  existed  in  Europe  till  1873, 
as  the  existence  of  the  Latin  Union  counter- 
vailed its  effects  both  in  gold  and  silver  using 
countries.  The  question  has  been  treated  with 
great  scientific  power  by  Professor  Jevons,  who 
explains  in  his  book  on  Money  "that  a  compen- 
satory, or  as  I  should  prefer  to  call  it,  cquilihra- 
tory  action,  goes  on  under  the  French  currency 
law,  and  tends  to  maintain  both  gold  and  silver 
more  steady  in  value  than  they  would  otherwise 
be."  He  points  out  that  when  one  metal  be- 
comes more  sought  for  than  the  other  there  is 
an  inevitable  tendency  to  import  the  cheaper 
and  export  the  dearer,  and  continues:  "At 
any  moment  the  standard  of  value  is  doubtless 
one  metal  or  the  other,  and  not  both  ;  yet  the 
fact  that  there  is  an  alternation  tends  to  make 
each  vary  much  less  than  it  would  otherwise 
do.  It  cannot  prevent  both  metals  from 
falling  or  rising  in  value  compared  with  other 
commodities,  but  it  can  throw  variations 
of  supply  and  demand  over  a  larger  area, 
instead  of  leaving  each  metal  to  be  affected 
merely  by  its  own  accidents.  Imagine  two 
reservoirs  of  water,  each  subject  to  independent 
variations  of  supply  and  demand.  In  the 
absence  of  any  connecting  pipe,  the  level  of  the 
water  in  each  reservoir  will  be  subject  to  its  own 
fluctuations  only.  But  if  we  open  a  connection, 
the  water  in  both  will  assume  a  certain  level, 
and  the  effects  of  any  excessive  supply  or  demand 
will  be  distributed  over  the  whole  area  of  both 
reservoirs.  The  mass  of  the  metals,  gold  and 
silver,  circulating  in  Western  Europe  in  late 
years,  is  exactly  represented  by  the  water  in 
these  reservoirs,  and  the  connecting  pipe  is  the 
law  of  the  7th  Germinal,  An.  xi.  (1803)  which 
enables  one  metal  to  take  the  place  of  the  other 
as  an  unlimited  legal  tender."  The  theory  on 
which  bi-metallism  rests  is  completely  explained 
in  these  observations  of  Jevons.  With  respect, 
however,  to  the  advisability  of  a  nation  adopt- 
ing a  single  or  a  double  standard,  Jevons  ex- 
presses himself  in  cautious  terms,  adding 
(3Ion£y,  p.  141),  "The  question  seems  to  be 
entirely  one  of  degree,  and  in  the  absence  of 
precise  information  is  quite  indeterminate." 

The  final  report  of  the  Royal  Commission 
on  Gold  and  Silver,  1888,  expresses  a  decided 
opinion  that  the  bi-metallic  system  of  the  Latin 
Union  exerted  a  material  influence  upon  the 
relative  value  of  the  two  metals  (par.  193): 
"  So  long  as  that  system  was  in  force  we  think 
that,  notwithstanding  the  changes  in  the  pro 


148 


BI-METALLISM 


duction  and  use  of  the  precious  metals,  it  kept 
the  market-price  of  silver  approximately  steady 
at  the  ratio  fixed  by  law  between  them,  namely, 
15^  to  1."  "With  respect  to  the  position  of  the. 
metals  in  two  countries,  in  one  of  which  silver, 
while  in  the  other  gold,  is  employed,  ^e  may 
quote  from  an  article  in  the  Economist  of  2d 
February  1878,  which  observes  that  the  "rela- 
tive value,  the  proportions  in  which  the  two 
metals  will  exchange  for  each  other,  are  continu- 
ally fluctuating,  and  they  must  inevitably  do 
so  unless  it  were  possible  to  fetter  the  supply  in 
such  a  manner  that  only  the  right  proportions 
of  each  metal  should  be  brought  to  market  at 
the  same  time.  Two  articles,  of  course,  cannot 
remain  always  at  the  same  relative  value  to  each 
other  unless  the  production  of  both  is  maintained 
at  the  same  proportion,  and  no  excess  or  diminu- 
tion of  the  supply  exists.  Nor  can  they  do  so 
unless  they  are  of  identical  utility,  and  are 
capable  of  performing  identical  services  to  man. 
When  two  commodities  perform  exactly  the 
same  functions,  and  are  equally  capable  of  doing 
so,  being  equally  desirable  in  every  respect, 
they  will  continually  tend  to  exchange  for  other 
things  in  the  same  proportions.  But  this  cannot 
be  said  to  describe  the  exact  relations  of  gold 
and  silver  to  each  other."  The  results  of  the 
export  of  the  one  and  the  import  of  the  other 
metal  are  then  refeiTed  to  :  ''The  loss  arising 
from  these  causes  may  not  come  home  to  the 
inhabitants  of  the  country  where  it  occurs  in  a 
clear  and  obvious  way.  The  inhabitants  may, 
if  silver  is  cheap  and  gold  is  wanted  for  export, 
retain  silver  for  their  own  domestic  use  and 
employ  it  in  their  circulation  till  a  fluctua- 
tion in  the  exchanges  renders  it  possible  for 
the  gold  to  return.  The  banks  which  make 
the  remittances  will,  in  this  case,  obtain  a  pro- 
fit from  the  transaction,  while  the  people  who 
employ  the  money  will  hold  over  the  currency 
they  receive  in  the  ordina^^y  way  of  trade  till 
the  tide  sets  in  the  contrary  direction.  Thus 
the  loss  which  the  country  really  experiences 
from  employing  a  currency  which  is  depreciated, 
as  compared  with  the  currency  of  other  countries 
employing  a  more  valuable  standard,  will  be 
veiled  from  view,  though  it  really  exists."  One 
metal  out  of  the  two  is  taken  in  this  case  for 
export  because  it  is  profitable  to  the  exporter  to 
send  it  rather  than  the  other,  but  it  would  not 
be  sent  unless  its  export  were  advantageous. 
As  the  risks  to  any  single  country  which  employs 
bi-metallism  are  obvious,  the  advocates  of  the 
system  recommend  that  all  countries  should 
employ  it,  as  this  would,  they  consider,  prevent 
a  preferential  movement  of  either  metal  from 
one  country  to  another.  Thus  the  work  recently 
published  by  Sir  D.  Barbour,  The  Theory  of  BU 
metallism,  recommends  "the  adoption  of  uni- 
versal bi-metallism  at  a  fixed  ratio  to  be  deter- 
mined by  mutual  consent. "  "■  Failing  universal 
bi-metallism,"  SirD.  Barbour  continues,  it  would 


be  desirable  that  bi-metallism  should  be  adopted 
by  a  group  of  countries  sufficiently  strong  to 
maintain  the  fixed  ratio,"  Sir  D.  Barbour's  con- 
tention being  "that  the  existence  of  this  fixed 
ratio  for  the  purposes  of  the  currency  wiU.  control 
and  regulate  the  market  price  of  the  two  metals 
so  as  to  prevent  it  from  varying  in  any  material 
degree  from  the  fixed  legal  ratio  of  the  currency." 

Rochussen  is  of  the  same  opinion.  Quoting 
the  words  of  a  Belgian  writer  in  the  Eevue 
GiTdrale,  October  1887,  p.  653,  "' Si  le  kilo- 
gramme d'or  vaut  actuellement  sur  le  marche 
vingt  kilogrammes  d'argent,  c'est  apparemment 
que  le  kilogramme  d'or,  pour  Stre  extrait  de  la 
terre,  coute  autant  qu'il  en  coute  d'extraire 
vingt  kilogrammes  d'argent,'"  he  comments  on 
them  thus — ' ' '  Apparemment ' !  No  explanation 
of  the  market  price  can  be  more  in  conflict  than 
this  is  with  all  the  facts  of  mining  industry, 
and  all  the  principles  of  money.  In  the  first 
twenty  years  of  this  century  the  production  of 
gold  stood  in  comparison  to  that  of  silver 
(valued  at  1  to  15^)  as  2|  to  8.-  In  the  foUow- 
ing  period  of  twenty  years,  nearly  as  4  to 
8  ;  thereafter  from  1841  to  1850  as  8  to  8  ; 
from  1851  to  1860,  very  nearly  28  to  8  ;  in 
the  following  five  years,  as  23  to  8  ;  and  from 
that  time  ^onwards  to  1870  the  proportion  fell 
to  18  to  8,  showing  even  at  that  rate  an  increase 
of  some  675  per  cent  in  the  proportion.  Yet 
in  all  this  time  there  was  no  greater  change  in 
the  market  price,  now  of  one  metal,  now  of  the 
other,  than  about  2  per  cent. 

"  Or  if  we  choose  to  look  rather  at  the  facts 
which  concern  the  demand,  than  at  those  which 
concern  the  supply  (aanbod),  .we  shall  see  that 
the  steadiness  of  price  was  not  afiected,  though 
the  demand  for  gold  was  greatest  when  the 
supply  was  least,  and  the  demand  for  silver 
was  greatest  when  the  supply  of  that  metal 
was  least.'*  (Eochussen,  Geld-  en  Muntwezen, 
p.  287.)!- 

The  statement  given  above  shows  the  main 
features  of  the  working  of  a  bi-metallic  system. 
•Jevons  remarks  (see  Letter  from  Jevons  to  M. 
WoLOWSKi,  printed  in  Jevons's  Investigations  in 
Currency  and  Finance,  p.  304)  that  the  French 
currency  law  has  "no  doubt  assisted  to  keep 
gold  and  silver  at  a  nearly  invariable  price  as 
compared  one  witJi  the  other. "  As  mentioned 
previously,  the  Gold  and  Silver  Commission  im- 
animously  concurred  in  supporting  the  same 
opinion.  Jevons  also  observes  that  "it  is  in- 
dispensable to  remember  the  fact,  too  much 
overlooked  by  disputants,  that  the  values  of 
gold  and  silver  are  ultimately  governed,  like 

1  M.  Rochussen  held  the  position  of  minister  for 
foreign  affairs  in  Holland  1879  and  1880,  and  is  at  the 
present  time  (1890)  a  member  of  the  council  of  state. 
His  father,  it  may  be  mentioned,  was  minister  for  the 
colonies, — also  for  seven  years  governor-general  of  Dutch 
India,  and  twice  minister  of  finance.  The  circumstances 
of  Holland  give  those  engaged  in  its  administrations  very 
considerable  opportunities  for  watching  the  fluctuations 
^)f  the  standard  of  value. 


Bl-METALLISM 


149 


those  of  all  other  commodities,  by  the  cost  of 
production.  Unless  clear  reasons,  then,  can  be 
shown  why  sUver  should  be  more  constant  in  its 
circumstances  of  production  than  gold,  there  is 
no  ground  for  thinking  that  a  bi-metallic  gold 
and  silver  money  will  afford  a  more  steady 
standard  of  value  than  gold  alone"  (Jevons, 
Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finance,  p.  318). 
"Ultimately"  is  the  governing  word  in  this 
quotation,  and  is  frequently  overlooked  ;  it  may 
mean  an  almost  indefinite  period.  The  reader 
must  be  refen^ed  to  the  works  of  Jevons  here 
cited  for  the  whole  of  his  arguments  ;  it  is 
hardly  possible  to  express  them  fully  by  any 
selection. 

As  a  matter  of  history  it  appears  that  the 
value  of  silver  relatively  to  gold  has  tended 
to  diminish  as  ages  have  passed  by.  Mean- 
while France  and  the  Latin  Union,  after  trying 
the  experiment  of  an  international  bi-metallism 
on  a  very  considerable  scale,  have  abandoned, 
or  at  least  suspended  the  free  coinage  of  both 
metals  at  a  fixed  ratio.  The  United  States, 
after  employing  a  bi-metallic  ratio  of  1:15 '25  in 
1786,  changed  to  1:15  in  1792,  to  1-16002  in 
1834,  to  1:15-988  in  1837,  and  adopted  the  gold 
dollar  only  as  the  Unit  of  Value  in  1873. 
A  limited  coinage  of  silver  dollars  was  directed 
in  1878  (by  the  Allison  or  Bland  Act),  which 
possess  "full  paying  power,  except  in  cases 
where  it  is  strictly  stipulated  otherwise  in  the 
contract."  A  somewhat  limited  system  of  bi- 
metallism was  thus  in  force  in  the  United  States 
from  1878  to  1890.  In  1890  an  act  author- 
ising a  great  extension  of  the  coinage  of  silver 
was  passed  by  the  legislature  (see  Bland  Act  ; 
Silver  Legislation  in  the  United  States), 
The  question  of  the  advisability  of  adopting  a 
bi-metallic  standard  has  been  discussed  by 
many  writers  recently,  but  by  none  in  so  dis- 
passionate a  manner  as  by  Jevons,  who  observes, 
"It  may  be  safely  said  that  the  question  of 
bi-metallism  is  one  which  does  not  admit 
of  any  precise  and  simple  answer.  It  is 
essentially  an  indeterminate  problem.  It  in- 
volves several  variable  quantities  and  many 
constant  quantities,  the  latter  being  either  in- 
accurately known  or,  in  many  cases,  altogether 
unknown.  The  present  annual  supplies  of  gold 
and  silver  are  ascertained  with  fair  approach  to 
certainty,  but  the  future  supplies  are  matter  of 
doubt.  This  demand  for  the  metals  again  involves 
wholly  unknown  quantities,  depending  partly 
upon  the  coiu-se  of  trade,  but  partly  also  upon 
the  action  of  foreign  peoples  and  governments, 
about  which  we  can  only  form  surmises  "  (Jevons, 
Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finance,  p.  317). 
The  use  of  both  gold  and  silver  as  standards  of 
value  is  obviously  most  important,  and  it  equally 
cannot  be  doubted  that  the  disuse  of  either 
must  lead,  as  the  disuse  of  silver  has  recently 
done,  to  considerable  fluctuations  in  the  prices 
of  commodities.      To  recommend,  however,  a 


country  which  is  now  mono-metaUic  to  become 
bi-metallic,  or  a  corresponding  change  on  the 
part  of  a  bi-metallic  country,  requires  a  far 
more  complete  inquiry  than  has  yet  been  made. 
The  theory  may  be  explained  in  comparatively 
few  words,  but  for  any  adequate  statement  of 
the  practical  results  the  reader  must  be  referred 
to  the  following  works,  which  are  far,  however, 
from  exhausting  the  subject. 

[Bibliography. — The  following  list  is  derived  in 
part  from  the  one  at  the  end  of  Prof,  W.  S.  Jevons's 
Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finance,  and  that  in 
Appendix  to  Proceedings,  etc.,  of  the  International 
Monetary  Conference  of  1878,  drawn  up  by  Mr, 
Dana  Horton.  The  reader  is  referred  to.these  lists 
for  fuller  information.  The  literature  on  the  sub- 
ject is  very  extensive,  to  a  great  extent  in  articles 
and  letters  in  newspapers  and  other  periodicals. 
The  arguments  on  the  subject  will  be  found  stated 
in  Jevons,  Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finance, 
London,  1884. — Money  and  the  Mechmism,  of  Ex- 
change, 1875,  also  by  Jevons. — Jieports  of  Com- 
mittee of  House  of  Commons  on  Depreciation  of 
Silver,  1878. — Report  of  Commission  on  Trade 
and  Industry,  1886,  and  Api)endix  B  to  3d  Re- 
port, by  K.  H,  Inglis  Palgrave. — Report  of  Com- 
viission  on  Gold  and  Silver,  1887. — Sir  D.  Barbour, 
Theory  of  Bi-vietaZlism,  London,  1885. — S.  Dana 
Horton,  Silver  as  an  International  Question  (an 
address  to  Congress)  ;  also  much  information  in 
Proceedings  of  the  International  Monetary  Confer- 
ence of  1878,  and  other  writings. — Conference  Mone- 
taire  International,  1867. — Proces  Verhaux,  Paris, 
1867.  See  also  Prof.  H,  Sidgwick's  observations 
that  "  a  double  standard  with  a  fixed  ratio  will  be 
stable  against  minor  variations  of  supply,"  I'rin- 
ciples  of  Political  Economy,  bk.  ii.  ch.  v.  ed.  1883, 
— Prof.  J.  S,  Nicholson,  Money  and  Monetary 
Problems,  1888,  in  which  the  arguments  in  favour 
of  bi-metallism  are  stated  with  great  clearness  and 
force. — The  Silver  Question  (paper  published  by 
the  Bi-metallic  League,  whose  other  publications 
are  numerous). — H.  R.  Grenfell  and  H.  H.  Gibbs, 
The  Bi-metallic  Controversy,  London,  1886,  and 
other  works  by  these  two  writers. — Prof.  Leon 
Walras,  Theorie  de  la  Monnaie,  Lausanne,  1886. 
— Theorie  Mathematique  du  Bi-metallisme,  Paris, 
1881. — Prof.  Adolph  Soetbeer,  Materialien  zur 
Erldutenmg  und  Beurtheilung  der  wirthschaft- 
lichen  Edelmetalverhdltnisse  und  der  Wdhrungs- 
frage,  Berlin,  1886.  This  is  translated  in  the 
Appendix  Final  Report  Gold  and  Silver  Com- 
mission.— Also  see  American  Reports  from  Con- 
suls of  the  United  States,  No.  87,  Dec,  1887. — 
Ernest  Seyd,  Bi-metallism  in  1886,  London,  1886, 
— R.  Gili'en,  Essays  in  Finance,  1880,  and  other 
dates.  Paper  on  "Some  Bi-metallic  Fallacies," 
Journal  Institute  of  Bankers,  June  1886,  and  other 
works. — Prof.  Emile  de  Laveleye,  "The  Economic 
Crisis  and  its  Causes,"  Contemporary  Review,  May 
1886,  and  other  papers, — Samuel  Smith,  The  Bi- 
metallic Question,  London  1887. — Rt.  Hon.  G.  J. 
Goschen,  "  On  the  Profitable  Results  of  an  Increase 
in  the  Purchasing  Power  of  Gold,"  Journal  of  In- 
stitute of  Bankers,  May  1883. — E.  de  Parieu, 
"  Situation  de  la  Question  Monetaire  International" 
{Journal  des  Economistes,  April  1868),  etc. — Henri 


150 


BIRTH-KATE 


Cemuschi,  M.  Michael  Chevalier  et  le  Bi-m^tallisme, 
Silver  Vindicated,  The  Bland  Bill,  Bi-metallism 
in  England  and  Abroad,  Bi-metallism  at  15^  a 
Necessity,  The  Monetary  Conference,  TheBi-metallic 
Par,  London,  various  dates,  etc.  M^moire  sur  le 
Bi-mUallisme  International  et  le  moyen  juste  de  la 
realiser,  W.  F.  Kochussen,  La  Haye,  1891. — Le 
Prohlkne  Monetaire  et  sa  solution  par  O.  M. 
Boissevain,  Paris  and  Amsterdam,  1891,  translated 
by  Gr.  T.  Warner,  The  Monetary  Question,  London, 
1891. — Also  Journals  of  Statistical  Society,  Lon- 
don, Institute  of  Bankers,  London,  Economist, 
London,  ^conomiste  Frangais,  Paris,  passim ; 
many  detached  articles  and  pamphlets  by  W, 
Bagehot,  P.  Leroy  Beaulieu,  0.  Haupt,  Prof.  H. 
Sidgwick,  Sir  R.  Giffen,  etc.  The  number  of 
writings  on  this  subject  has,  in  general,  restricted 
the  reference  given  above  to  one  of  the  works  of 
the  authors  named.] 

BIRTH-RATE  means  generaUy  the  ratio 
which  the  number  of  births  per  annum  bears  to 
the  number  of  persons  in  the  population  under 
consideration.  The  rate  thus  defined  depends 
largely  on  another  rate  which  has  been  called 
fecundity,  and  has  been  defined  as  the  ratio 
which  the  number  of  births  per  annum  bears  to 
the  number  of  persons  of  reproductive  age,  or 
of  women  of  reproductive  age  (say  15-45)  ;  or 
of  married  persons,  or  wives  only,  of  that  age 
(see  Bertillon,  "Mouvement  de  la  Population" 
in  Annales  de  Dimographie,  vol.  i.  ;  also 
Quetelet,  Physique  Sociale,  bk.  ii.  §  6).  Some  of 
these  relations  are  illustrated  by  the  accom- 
panying table  which  shows  the  average  annual 
births  per  1000  in  the  kingdom  of  Bavaria 
(1871-1872).  It  is  taken  from  Mayr's  Die 
Gesetzmdssigkeit  in  Gesellschaftslehen,  p.  244. 
(Decimals  have  been  omitted.) 


Legitimate 
births 
per  1000 
wives  be- 
tween ages 
15-45. 

Illegitimate 
births 
per  1000 
unmarried 
women  be- 
tween ages 
15-45. 

Legitimate 
and  illegiti- 
mate births 
per  1000 
women 
between 
ages  15-45. 

Legitimate 
and  illegiti- 
mate births 
per  1000 
of  the 
general 
population, 

men  and 

women  of  all 

ages. 

368 

45 

182 

41 

Fixing  attention  on  legitimate  births,  we 
may  regard  the  birth-rate  as  depending  chiefly 
on  two  factors  :  (a)  the  ratio  which  the  number 
of  married  persons  of  reproductive  age  bears  to 
the  general  population,  and  (h)  the  ratio  which 
the  number  of  births  per  annum  bears  to  the 
number  of  married  persons  of  reproductive  age. 
The  first  factor  (a)  varies  with  the  number  of 
newly  married  persons  ;  this  varies  with  pros- 
perity, which  (in  many  countries)  varies  with 
the  price  of  bread.  Accordingly  it  has  often 
been  observed  that  bad  harvests  are  followed  by 
a  decline  in  the  birth-rate  and  vice  versd.  Thus 
the  year  1817,  in  which  the  price  of  corn  in 
Belgium  rose  to  twice  the  average  of  the  neigh- 


bouring years,  was  followed  by  a  great  decrease 
of  births.  Other  instances  are  referred  to  by 
Quetelet  (Physique  Sociale,  bk.  ii.  §  6)  and 
Haushofer  (Lehr-  und  Harvdhuch  der  Statistik). 
The  Swedish  statistics,  extending  over  more  than 
a  century,  have  been  arranged  in  such  a  way 
as  to  bring  out  the  connection  between  good 
or  bad  harvests  with  many  or  few  marriages  and 
births  (see  Journal  of  the  Statistical  Society, 
1862,  vol.  XXV.,  p.  140,  ''Vital  Statistics  oi 
Sweden,"  by  Mr.  Hendriks'  Table  A  ;  tJ.  1885, 
opening  address  of  Sir  Rawson  Rawson,  p.  586). 
When  several  good  or  several  bad  harvests  come 
together  the  efiect  is  conspicuous  in  the  case  ol 
Sweden.  But  this  law  is  not  universal.  It 
cannot  be  traced  in  the  case  of  the  United  King- 
dom of  late  years  (see  Journ.  Stai..  Soc,  1890, 
p.  257  et  seq.)  and  in  other  cases  where  the  price 
wheat  is  not  the  main  factor  of  prosperity. 
(b)  The  fecundity  of  marriages  depends  partly 
on  the  age  of  the  parties.  This  subject  has 
been  discussed  by  Dr.  Ogle  {Journ.  Stat.  Soc, 
1890,  p.  275),  who  shows  that,  to  cause  a 
sensible  alteration  in  the  birth-rate,  a  very  con- 
siderable displacement  of  ages  would  be  required. 
That  other  causes  beside  age  are  operative  is 
evidenced  ]?y  the  fact  that  in  France  and  New 
England  the  age  of  marriage  is  not  remarkably 
late,  while  the  fecundity  is  remarkably  small 
(see  the  table  at  the  end  of  this  article). 
Among  causes  which  may  affect  the  fecundity 
of  marriages  are  climate  a.nd  food.  These  and 
other  causes  are  discussed  by  many  of  the 
authorities  cited  here. 

As  to  the  consequences  of  variations  in  the 
birth-rate  the  most  obvious  is  the  tendency  of 
population  to  increase  more  rapidly  when  the 
birth-rate  is  high  (and  vice  versd).  But  this 
tendency  may  be  counteracted  by  a  high  death- 
rate.  That  a  high  birth-rate  is  not  a  conse- 
quence of  a  high  death-rate,  though  to  some 
extent  causally  connected  therewith,  is  main- 
tained by  Dr.  Noel  Humphreys  in  the  Journal 
of  the  Statistical  Society,  1874.  The  two 
phenomena  frequently  co-exist.  Thus  the 
statistics  of  the  Austrian  empire  compiled  by 
Hain  {Statistik  des  Osterreichischen  KaiserstaMs, 
1852-3)  exhibit  birth-rates,  marriage-rates,  and 
death-rates  varying  concurrently.  Moving 
through  the  provinces  along  a  line  in  a  south- 
easterly direction  you  would  find  the  three 
factors  constantly  increasing  together.  The 
increase  of  the  population  (the  natural  incre- 
ment, abstracting  the  effects  of  emigration  and 
immigration),  is  therefore  not  in  general  pro- 
portionate to  the  birth-rate.  Thus  the  birth-rate 
of  Russia  for  the  period  1865-1883,  viz.  4-94 
per  100  living,  was  much  greater  than  the 
birth-rate  for  England  and  Wales,  viz.  3-51; 
yet  the  annual  excess  of  births  over  deaths  per 
cent  of  the  whole  population  was  the  same  for 
the  two  countries,  viz.  1"37  (see  table  sub- 
joined).     The  natural  increment  for  England 


BIUNDI— BLACK  DEATH 


161 


and  Wales  for  1871-1881  was  greater  than  that 
of  the  previous  decade  by  about  10  per  cent  (of 
the  natural  increment)  ;  while  the  birth-rate 
increased  very  slightly,  by  about  -3  per  cent 
(census  for  1881  general  report).  There  is 
reason  to  think  that  the  state  of  a  country  in 
which  a  high  birth-rate  is  matched  by  a  high 
death-rate  is  not  satisfactory. 

See  in  addition  to  the  authorities  cited  Prof. 
Marshall,  Principles  of  Economics,  bk.  iv. 
ch.  iv.  5tli  ed.  Some  examples  of  the  statistics 
quoted  by  him  are  here  subjoined. 

Mean  Annual  Birth-rates,  Urban  and  Rural  Arecus 
Urban 
20  large  towns,   with  an    aggregate    population    ol 
9,742,404  persons  at  the  date  of  the  Census  of  1901. 


Period. 

Calculated  on  the  total  population. 

Rate  per  1000. 

Compared  with  rate  in 
1870-72  taken  as  100. 

1870-72 
1880-8-2 
1890-9:2 
1900-02 

36-7 
35-7 
32-0 

29 -S 

100-0 
97-3 

S7-2 
81-2 

11  URAL 

112  entirely  rural  registration  districts,  with  an  aggre 
gate  population  of  1,330,319  persons  at  the  date  of  tin 
Census  of  1901. 

1870-72 

1880-82 
1890-92 
1900-02 

31-6 
30-3 

27-8 
26-0 

100-0 
05-9 

ss-0 

S2-3 

BIUNDI,  G.  Known  as  the  author  of  a 
treatise  on  political  economy  ;  La  economia 
esposta  nei  suoi  principii  ragionati  e  dedotti, 
Milano,  Maisner  and  comp.,  1864. 

Author  besides  of  the  following  works  and 
articles  : — "Dell'  influenza  che  esercitano  le  priva- 
tive neir  industria,"  published  in  the  review 
Empedocle,  Palermo,  1853,  vol.  iv.  fasc.  7-10,  p. 
324. — "Sul  credito  agricolo  e  sull'  istituzione  d' 
una  banca  territoriale  in  Sicilia,"  Palermo,  1854, 
Empedode,  vol.  iv. — "  Studii  sulla  pubblica  bene- 
ficenza,"  Palermo,  1855,  Empedocle,  vol.  v.  p.  187. 
— I  Porti  franchi,  riflessioni  economicke,  1  vol., 
Palermo,  1857,  Grimaldi. — "Delia  proprieta  in- 
telletuale,  e  del  diritto  di  copia,"  Palermo, 
1859,  Empedocle,  nuova  serie,  vol.  i. — "Popo- 
lazione  e  miseria,"  Palermo,  1859,  Empedocle, 
nuova  serie,  vol.  i.  p.  299. — "Monti  di  Pieta," 
Palermo,  1859,  Empedocle,  nuova  serie,  vol.  i. — 
Sicgli  asili  infantili  e  sul  mx>do  di  istituirli  e  rego- 
larli  in  Sicilia;  discorso,  Palermo,  1860,  Lo 
Bianco. — Statistica  del  puMlico  in^egnamento  in 
Sicilia,  Palermo,  1861,  in  8vo. — Sulla  scienza 
statistica  e  sue  applicazioni  alle  forze  morali  e 
materiali  dei  varii  Stati  d'Europa  e  specialmente 
del  regno  d'ltalia,  Firenze,  1867,  in  8vo. 

M.  p. 

BLACK,  David  (about  1700),  a  Scotch 
writer,  was  the  author  of  An  Essay  upon  In- 
dustry and  Trade,  shewing  the  Necessity  of 
the  One,  The  Conveniency  and  Usefulness  of  the 
Other,  and  The  Advantages  of  Both,  Edinburgh, 


1706.  This  treatise  shows  very  clearly  the 
state  of  economic  opinion  in  Scotland  before 
Hume  and  Smith.  The  author  repeats  all 
the  traditional  dogmas  concerning  the  balance 
of  trade  and  the  necessity  of  increasing  the 
quantity  of  money.  He  opposes,  however,  the 
schemes  of  "credit  upon  a  land  security,"  by 
maintaining  that  "  the  nation's  industry  is  the 
best  fund  of  credit  to  support  it "  (p.  3).  After 
all  his  mercantilist  views  it  is  very  remarkable 
to  find  him  saying ;  "  I  do  confess  it  is  my 
private  Opinion  that  all  Imposition  whatsoever 
should  be  taken  oft  Trade,  and  that  there  should 
be  no  Taxes  upon  it.  ,  .  ,  For  it's  Evident, 
when  heavy  Duties  are  upon  Goods,  some 
Merchants  run  these  Goods  without  paying  any 
Duty,  and  then  they  Undersel  their  Neighbours 
who  pay  it.  .  .  .  Whereas,  by  an  Exemption 
of  all  Duty  and  a  freedom  of  Trade,  (with  this 
Caution  alwise,  That  what  is  superfluous  may 
be  Prohibit),  then  every  Merchant  will  be  on 
equal  footing  ;  and  he  who  is  most  Capable  to 
manage  a  Trade,  will  have  the  most  Advantage, 
and  all  will  redound  to  the  Merchant's  Interest " 
(p.  27).  Black  proposes  to  remedy  the  de- 
ticiency  in  the  public  revenue  by  an  imposition 
upon  "probative  wiits,  except  Bills  of  Ex- 
change," or  if  this  should  not  sufiice  "  the  Land 
tax  should  be  thought  the  surest  Fond."  He 
seeks  to  convince  the  landed  interest  that 
the  merchants,  though  advancing  the  amount 
of  the  duty  in  the  price  of  the  goods,  shift  the 
charge  upon  the  buyers,  and  that  the  landed 
men  bear  indirectly,  through  this  course,  a 
heavier  burden  than  by  the  way  he  proposes. 
Black  illustrates  the  advantages  of  a  free  trade 
by  the  examples  of  the  Grisons  and  Holland  (pp. 
29,  30),  the  first  of  which  had  been  suggested 
to  him  by  Bishop  Gilbert  Burnet. 

[See  Bishop  Burnet's  work  :  Some  Letters  Con- 
taining an  Account  of  what  seemed  most  remark- 
able in  Travelling  through  Switzerland,  Italy, 
some  parts  of  Germany,  etc.  Rotterdam,  1687, 
p.  306.]  s.B. 

BLACK  DEATH,  The.  The  pestilence  or 
series  of  pestilences  known  by  this  name  took 
place  in  the  middle  of  the  14th  century,  and 
was  a  partial  if  not  the  chief  cause  of  very 
vast  economic  changes  in  England.  So  far  as 
can  be  ascertained,  the  disease  first  manifested 
itself  in  central  China  in  1333,  and  thence 
spread  in  a  westward  direction  towards  Europe, 
where  its  force  was  first  felt  in  the  southern 
countries.  Taking  a  northward  course,  it 
reached  England  where,  "about  the  1st  of 
August  1348,  it  began  in  the  seaport  towns 
on  the  coast  of  Dorsetshire,  Devonshire,  and 
Somersetshire,  whence  it  drew  up  to  Bristol. 
.  .  .  whence  it  came  to  Oxford,  and  about  the 
1st  of  November  it  reached  London,  and  finally 
spread  itself  all  over  England  "  (Barnes,  History 
of  Edward  III.,  pp.  435,  436).  There  were  three 
great  attacks  of  the  pestilence,  of  which  the 


152 


BLACK  DEATH 


first  was  much  the  most  destructive — August 
1348  to  summer  1349;  Augustl361toMayl362  ; 
July  1368  to  Michaelmas  1369.  The  period 
dming  which  Europe  was  devastated  by  this 
plague  was  remarkable  for  the  occurrence  of 
great  natural  convulsions  such  as  earthquakes, 
with  which  contemporary  opinion  attempted  to 
connect  it  causally,  and  for  other  pestilences, 
attacks  of  which  took  place  in  1370,  1381-82, 
1396.  Of  its  nature  many  descriptions  re- 
main (Hecker,  Ep'ldemics  of  the  Middle  Ages). 
Whilst  the  name  it  bore  in  England  was  de- 
rived from  one  of  its  symptoms,  its  terrible 
destructiveness  won  it  its  Italian  title  of  La 
mortalaga  grande  (Hecker,  p.  2). 

It  is  of  some  importance  when  examining  its 
economic  effects  to  attempt  to  ascertain  the 
extent  of  the  mortality  which  it  occasioned. 
This  is  very  differently  estimated.  The  loss  of 
life  in  Europe  has  been  roughly  reckoned  at 
25,000,000  (Hecker).  While,  with  regard  to 
England,  accounts  nearly  contemporary  give 
estimates  which  cannot  but  be  regarded  as 
exaggerations,  e.g.  Adam  of  Usk  reckons  the  sur- 
vivors as  but  one-tenth  of  the  previous  popula- 
tion. In  more  recent  times  attempts  have 
been  made  to  found  conclusions  on  such  statisti- 
cal data  as  may  be  still  extant.  Arguing  from 
the  clergy  lists,  Mr.  Seebohm  places  the  number 
of  deaths  as  at  least  one-half.  He  assumes  that 
the  rate  of  mortality  among  the  clergy  was  not 
exceptional.  Taking  then  an  estimate  of  the 
population  living  in  1377,  drawn  from  the 
receipts  of  the  poll  tax  in  that  year,  he  con- 
cludes that  those  who  died  numbered  some 
two  millions  and  a  half  {Fortnightly  Meview, 
vol.  ii.  pp.  149,  268).  On  the  other  hand 
Professor  KoGEiis,  having  regard  to  the  quantity 
of  wheat  consumed,  considers  that  the  loss  of 
life  was  by  no  means  so  great.  It  is  possible, 
however,  that  this  conclusion  does  not  allow 
sufficiently  for  the  other  cereals  which  entered 
into  the  consumption  of  the  gi-eat  body  of  the 
people  ;  and  the  data  on  which  it  rests  seem 
less  certain  than  those  by  which  Mr.  Seebohm 
•was  guided  (Fortnightly  JReview,  vol.  iii.  p.  191). 
But  whether  the  one  or  the  other  estimate  be 
accepted,  there  can  be  no  doubt  that  a  very 
great  loss  of  life  was  the  consequence  of  the 
Black  Death.  Equally  there  is  no  doubt  as  to 
the  magnitude  and  critical  importance  of  the 
economic  change  which  it  was  instrumental  in 
producing. 

For  some  time  there  had  been  in  operation 
two  processes  of  widely  differing  tendency. 
By  slow  but  certain  degrees  fixed  money  pay- 
ments were  being  substituted  for  the  labour 
rents  or 'services  originally  due  from  the  tenants 
to  the  lord  of  the  manor.  Disproportion  between 
the  money  payment  and  the  services  had  been 
manifesting  itself.  It  was  to  ensure  the  con- 
tinuance of  the  former  substitution  that  the 
tenants  began  to  form  those ' '  alliances ' '  and ' '  con- 


gregations "  to  which  we  find  allusion  in  later 
statutes  (e.g.  1  Rich.  II.  c.  6).  To  a  people 
thus  placed  the  loss  of  a  very  large  portion  of 
the  working  population  could  not  but  be  of  the 
utmost  gravity.  The  force  of  the  economic 
laws  of  supply  and  demand  in  relation  to  wages 
began  to  make  itself  felt.  There  was  a  demand 
for  much  higher  wages  and  an  inclination  to 
enforce  this  demand  by  combination  on  the 
part  of  the  labourers,  while  the  landowners  on 
their  side  found  themselves  in  need  of  labour  as 
before,  but  unable  to  obtain  it  at  the  old  rates. 
The  payments  which  they  received  in  lieu  of 
labour  services  were  insufficient  for  the  hire  of 
the  labourers  who  might  perform  these  services. 
As  a  matter  of  fact,  this  had  natui-ally  tended 
to  be  the  case  even  before,  but  if  it  had  been 
so  before  how  much  more  was  it  the  case  now. 
In  one  instance  the  tenant  paid  in  commutation 
^d.  while  the  labourer  who  performed  the  work 
received  3d.  (Archceologia  xi.) 

But  now  legislation  intervened.  Hitherto 
rates  of  wage,  when  determined,  had  been  settled 
in  the  manorial  courts,  or  by  Corpokations 
and  Gilds,  but  wages  form  the  subject  of 
the  royal  ordinance  of  1349  (23  Edward  III.) 
enacting  "that  all  able-bodied  servants  should 
serve  their  lords,  or  if  not  requii-ed  by  them, 
any  one  so  requiring  them  at  the  same  wages  as 
were  usual  before  the  plague."  There  seems 
little  room  for  doubt  as  to  the  immediate  con- 
nection in  which  this  ordinance  stands  towards 
the  Black  Death.  But  legislation  was  in- 
effectual. Wages  did  not  diminish;  even  before 
the  pestilence  they  had  been  gradually  increasing, 
and  the  landowners  were  driven  to  seek  a  new 
remedy.  They  made  the  endeavour  to  revert 
to  the  old  system  of  labour  rents.  Commuted 
service  on  the  land  was  to  be  done  away  with, 
and  the  practice  of  earlier  centuries  was  once 
more  to  be  followed,  but  now  to  be  followed 
by  those  who  regarded  its  introduction  as 
an  innovation.  In  some  instances  indeed  it 
would  appear  that  attempts  were  made  at 
illegal  exaction,  for  we  find  the  customary 
tenants  appealing  as  against  their  landlords  to 
the  record  of  Domesday.  The  whole  country 
was  thrown  into  a  condition  of  economic  dis- 
order, for  the  tendency  toward  resistance  was 
fanned  by  the  efforts  of  the  friars  who  carried 
the  news  from  shire  to  shire,  playing  the  part 
of  the  newsagents  of  discontent.  So  matters 
stood  just  before  the  rising  in  1381.  Demands 
were  made  with  increasing  persistence  for  the 
reduction  of  the  money  payments  ;  the  land- 
.  owners  on  their  side,  finding  even  these 
payments  insufficient,  were  striving  to  return 
to  the  system  under  which  the  various  classes 
of  tenants  had  to  perform  service  in  person  or 
by  substitute  ;  while  in  the  third  place  the 
long  French  wars  had  increased  the  burden  of 
taxation  under  which  the  nation  was  gi'oaning. 
The  universality  with  which  these  three  causes 


BLACK  DEATH— BLANC 


153 


were  felt,  and  the  part  which  the  friars  played 
in  enabling  the  inhabitants  of  the  various 
districts  to  enter  into  communication  with  one 
another,  explain  the  Peasants'  Revolt,  1381. 
The  incidents  of  the  rebellion  and  the  mode  in 
which  it  was  met  and  the  means  by  which  it 
was  suppressed  are  matters  of  political  history. 
What  were  the  consequences  of  the  rising  ? 
During  the  struggle  the  rebels  had  destroyed 
many  of  the  manor  rolls,  showing  most  clearly 
their  desire  of  blotting  out  all  record  of  the 
service  wliich  might  be  exacted  from  them  ;  and 
despite  the  revocation-  of  the  royal  gi-ants  made 
to  them,  then-  demand  in  this  direction  was 
substantially  conceded.  The  practice  of  com- 
mutation was  adhered  to.  In  addition  it  is 
probable  that  the  money  payments,  which  even 
before  the  Black  Death  had  been  diminished, 
on  many  estates  underwent  reduction.  Thus 
the  second  means  of  dealing  with  the  economic 
consequences  occasioned  chiefly  by  the  mortality 
owing  to  the  pestilence  had  failed,  and  economic 
laws  asserted  their  streiigtli.  There  were,  how- 
ever, results  consequent  on  the  failure  of  these 
two  attempts  at  interference.  The  system  of 
cultivation  had  depended  for  its  protit  on  the 
existence  of  a  large  body  of  cheap  labour.  The 
value  of  labour  had  been  enhanced  by  no  cause 
more  effectually  than  the  diminution  in  the 
supply.  From  this  time  we  may  date  the 
change  from  arable  to  pasture  which  assumed 
such  gi-eat  proportions  in  the  16th  century. 
The  last  stage  of  the  mediaeval  system  of  cultiva- 
tion was  beginning. 

It  is  somewhat  difficult  to  determine  the 
eocact  importance  of  the  Black  Death  in  bring- 
ing about  the  change.  As  we  have  seen,  causes 
were  already  in  operation  wliich  tended  toward 
change  ;  but  that  cliange  was  undoubtedly 
precipitated  by  the  great  and  sudden  loss  of 
life  endured  by  the  nation  in  the  middle  of  the 
14th  centuiy.  This  then  is  the  reason 
why  the  Black  Death  deserves  so  much  at- 
tention on  the  part  of  the  economic  student. 
The  causes  of  the  events  clustering  around  it 
display  the  strength  of  economic  forces  ;  the 
attempts  at  regulation,  the  uselessness  of 
ignorant  interference  ;  and  in  its  consequences 
we  find  the  causes  of  the  peculiar  development  of 
Agriculture  in  England  in  the  Tudor  period. 
[Kogers,  History  of  Agriculture  and  Prices. — 
Nasse,  Ueber  die  mittelalterliche  Feldgemeinschaft 
und  die  Einliegungen  des  16  Jahrhundert  in 
England. — Denton,  W.,  England  in  the  Fif- 
teenth Century. — W.  von  Ochenkowski,  Englands 
loirthschaftliche  Entvnckelung  im  Av^gange  des 
Mittelalters.  — ^Fortnightly  Review,  vols,  ii.  iii.  iv. 
(1865-66). — Hecker,  Epidemics  of  the  Middle  Ages. 
— Barnes,  History  of  Edward  III.']      E.  c.  K.  G. 

BLACKLEG.  (1)  A  card-sharper  or  forger  ; 
(2)  a  person  who  works  for  an  employer  whose 
regular  workmen  are  out  on  strike.  These 
persons  are  often  exposed  to  gi'eat  annoyance 
from  the  strikers,  but  they  are  somewhat  pro- 


tected by  §  8  of  the  Conspiracy  and  Protection 
of  Property  Act  1875  (38  &  39  Vict.  c.  86), 
which  enacts  that  a  person  who  for  the  purpose 
of  preventing  a  lawful  act  (1)  uses  violence  or 
intimidation  ;  (2)  persistently  follows  the  person 
concerned  from  place  to  place  ;  (3)  hides  his 
tools  or  other  property  ;  (4)  watches  his  house 
or  the  place  in  which  he  works ;  (5)  follows  him 
in  the  company  of  others  in  a  disorderly  manner 
through  a  street,  is  liable  to  a  fine  of  £20  or  to 
imprisonment  for  three  months  with  or  without 
hard  labour  (see  Strikes).  e.  s. 

BLAIEIE,  Droit  de.  A  right  of  the  French 
lords  to  exact  payment  for  leave  to  graze  on 
open  or  waste  lands  within  their  territories.  This 
right  only  existed  in  provinces  regulated  by 
droit  coutumier. 

[De  Tocqueville,  France  before  the  lievalidion 
(London,  1873),  note  Ixxvii.J  k.  l. 

BLAKE,  William,  F.R.S.  ;  author  of— 

Observations  on  the  Principles  which  regulate 
the  Course  of  Exchange,  and  on  the  Present  De- 
jjreciated  State  of  the  Currency  (London,  1810)  ; 
Observations  on  the  Effects  produced  hy  the  Ex- 
penditure of  Government  during  the  liestriction 
of  Cash  Payments  (homlow,  1823);  ^juX  of  Observa- 
tions in  reply  to  a  Pamphlet  by  the  Rev.  Pdchccrd 
Jones,  on  the  Assessment  of  Tithes  to  the  Poors 
Pate  (London,  1839).  F.  T.  E. 

BLAKC,  Jean  Joseph  Louis,  born  at 
Madrid,  1813,  died  at  Cannes,  1882.  His  first 
work  for  some  years  after  the  Revolution  of  1830 
was  in  journalism  ;  he  Avrote  in  Le  Pr ogres  du 
Pas -de -Calais  and  in  La  Revue  democratiquc, 
then  in  La  Nouvclle  Mincrve,  all  republican 
journals.  Afterwards  he  became  chief  editor  of 
Lc  Bon  Sens,  and  then  founded  La  Revue  du 
jrrogres  social,  in  wliich  ai)pcared,  in  the  year 
1 839,  the  articles  which,  collected  and  extended, 
formed  the  volume  entitled  L'  Organisation  dit 
travail,  which  made  the  reputation  of  Louis 
Blanc  as  leader  of  the  socialist  school.  He 
afterwards  employed  his  imquestioned  talent 
as  a  writer  on  two  works,  the  one,  Histoire  de 
clix  ans,  a  pamphlet  in  five  volumes,  assuming  a 
historic  form,  and  duected  against  the  monarchy 
of  July ;  the  other,  Histoire  de  la  revolution 
frangaise,  three  volumes  of  which  had  appeared 
when  the  Revolution  of  February  1848  broke 
out.  Elected  a  member  of  the  provisional 
government,  as  he  could  not  obtain  the  forma- 
tion of  a  "ministere  du  progres,"  he  was 
appointed  president  of  a  ''Commission  de 
gouvernement  pour  les  travailleurs,"  which  ho 
established  in  the  palace  of  the  Luxembourg  in 
the  Chamber  of  Peers.  This  commission  was 
composed  of  delegates  from  the  working  classes, 
supported  from  outside  by  100,000  bayonets. 
In  its  discussions  he  put  forward  with  a  too 
feverish  eloquence,  considering  what  the  charac- 
-Cer  of  his  audience,  and  of  the  unsettled  period 
then  passing,  was,  the  most  revolutionary 
and   socialistic   ideas.      This   did   not   hinder 


154 


BLANC— BLAND  ACT 


WoLOWSKi  from  having  the  courage  to  oppose 
him  face  to  face  in  debate.  Did  Louis  Blanc 
contribute  to  the  formation  of  the  atelieis  nation- 
mix  of  unhappy  memory,  the  dissolution  of 
which  brought  on  the  insurrection  of  June  1848  ? 
This  has  never  been  proved.  Louis  !^lanc 
denied  it  vigorously.  His  powers  expiring 
with  the  opening  of  the  National  Constituent 
Assembly,  he  became  only  an  ordinary  "repre- 
sentative of  the  people  ; "  but  he  had  to  pay 
for  the  rashness  of  his  language  during  the 
discussions  at  the  Luxembourg,  the  consequences 
of  which  he  could  not  escape,  and  suffered  in 
reputation  more  from  his  speeches  when  presi- 
dent of  the  "Commission  des  travailleurs " 
than  on  account  of  his  acts  after  he  ceased  to 
hold  that  oflfice.  When  the  invasion  of  the 
chamber  of  the  15th  May  1848  occurred,  he 
had  to  take  refuge  in  England,  whence  he  did 
not  return  till  1870.  Before  doing  this  he  had 
founded  a  journal,  Le  Nouveau  Monde,  which 
had  only  a  very  limited  success  (1849-51).  He 
then  wrote  in  the  French  journal  Le  Temps  (the 
second  of  that  name)  letters  on  London,  which 
were  much  remarked  on  at  the  time.  On 
his  return  to  France  he  was  returned  a  mem- 
ber for  Paris  to  the  National  Assembly,  and 
subsequently  of  the  Chamber  of  Deputies. 
He  w^as  a  rhetorician  and  a  philanthropist 
rolled  into  one.  "C'etait  un  rheteur  double 
d'un  philanthrope,"  said  M.  G.  de  Molinari, 
of  him.  With  a  warm  heart  and  a  bad  judg- 
ment, Louis  Blanc  was  not  a  man  for  action  ; 
he  dreamed  of  the  absorption  by  the  state  of 
factories  and  shops  in  which  work  was  sus- 
pended at  the  time.  He  proposed  to  make  use  of 
these  by  handing  them  over  to  the  working  men, 
under  the  direction  of  the  state,  in  order  that 
they  might  ruin  by  their  rivalry  the  factories 
and  shops  which  still  held  on,  so  that,  some 
day  or  other,  the  state  should  become  the  sole 
mainspring  of  industry.  The  division  of  profits 
(no  one  imagined  that  losses  could  occur)  was  to 
be  made  in  the  following  manner.  There  were 
to  be  no  more  any  wages — wage  -  receiving 
being  abolished — ^but  every  one  was  to  receive 
"according  to  his  wants."  This  very  simple 
method  of  division  was  the  first  proposed  by 
Louis  Blanc.  When  he  became  president  of 
the  "Commission  de  gouvernement  pour  les 
travailleurs,"  he  modified  this  method  and  re- 
placed it  by  another  more  simple  still ;  an  equal 
division  per  head.  Honour  was  in  his  eyes  a 
sufficient  inducement  to  labour,  and  more  effica- 
cious than  self-interest.  He  had  less  knowledge 
of  technical  details  than  his  brethren  in  social- 
ism, and  his  proposals  were  always  surrounded 
by  a  mist  of  vague  uncertainty  which  renders  a 
critical  appreciation  of  them  both  difiicult  and 
at  the  same  time  little  conclusive.  The  collec- 
tivists  in  our  days,  though  on  the  wrong  path, 
have  gone  more  to  the  bottom  of  their  subject. 
[While  in  England  he  wrote,  in  English,  his 


book  entitled, — ISIfS.  Historical  Revelations,  in- 
scribed to  Lord  Norrrwmby.  By  Louis  Blanc. 
Chapman  and  Hall,  1858.]  a.  c.  f. 

BLAND  ACT.  A  law  of  the  United  States 
passed  28th  February  1878,  which  restored  the 
silver  Dollar  0^4  12|  grs.,  -^^  fine,  to  the  list 
of  coins  of  the  United  States,  and  directed  the 
secretary  of  the  treasury  to  purchase  silver 
bullion,  and  coin  into  such  dollars  not  less 
than  two  million  dollars'  worth  (say  £400,000), 
and  not  more  than  four  million  dollars'  worth 
(say  £800,000)  per  month  continually.  By 
the  Coinage  Revision  Act  of  12th  February 
1873  the  gold  dollar  of  25^^  grs.,  ^^^  fine,  was 
declared  the  Unit  of  Value  in  the  United 
States,  and  the  silver  dollar  was  omitted  from 
the  list  of  coins  authorised  to  be  struck  at  the 
mint.  This  act  did  not  make  mention  of  any 
dollar,  with  the  exception  of  the  trade  dollar  of 
420  grs.,  ^  fine,  manufactured  for  the  trade 
with  China ;  it  ordained  that  the  gold  coins 
should  have  unlimited  paying  power,  and  that 
the  silver  coins  should  have  paying  power  up 
to  the  amount  of  five  dollars.  That  portion  of 
the  act  of  1873  which  made  the  gold  dollar 
the  unit  of  value  was  not  altered  by  the  act  of 
1878,  but  under  it  the  silver  dollar  became 
legal  tender* to  an  unlimited  amount,  "except 
in  cases  where  it  is  strictly  stipulated  otherwise 
in  the  contract."  The  act  of  1878  likewise 
authorised  the  issue  by  the  treasury,  on  the 
deposit  of  coined  silver,  of  silver  certificates  of 
deposit  in  denominations  of  ten,  twenty,  fifty 
dollars,  etc.  Under  this  act  $299,708,790  (say 
£60,000,000)  had  been  coined  in  silver  dollars 
upto30thJune  1888,  but  of  these  $243,879,487 
(say  £48,700,000)  remained  in  the  treasury  on 
that  date.  Against  this  stock  of  coined  silver 
certificates  to  the  value  of  $229,491,772  (say 
£45,800,000)  had  been  granted,  but  of  these 
$29,104,396  (say  £5,820,000)  were  in  the 
treasury  (see  Report  of  the  Director  of  the  United 
States  Mint,  1888,  pp.  74,  203).  The  effect  of 
the  Bland  Act  has  been  to  cause  a  large  portion  of 
the  legal  tender  of  the  United  States  to  be  held  in 
silver  ;  the  total  metallic  stock  being  estimated 
on  1st  November  1888  approximately  as  : — 
Cost  Value. 
Gold  $711,705,050  say  £142,300,000 
Silver      $396,970,484        „      £79,400,000 


$1,108,675,534 


£221,700,000 


The    Bland    Act    is    sometimes    termed    the 
"Allison  Act." 

By  an  act  of  Congress  passed  14th  July  1890 
the  provisions  of  the  Bland  Act,  which  required 
the  monthly  purchase  and  coinage  into  silver 
dollars  of  not  less  than  $2,000,000,  and  not 
more  than  $4,000,000  worth  of  silver,  were  re- 
pealed, and  the  secretary  of  the  treasury  was 
directed  to  purchase  silver  bullion  to  the  extent 
of  4,500,000  oz.  monthly  at  a  price  not  ex- 
ceeding $1  per  371^^^  grs.  of  pure  silver,  against 


BLANK  CREDIT— BLENCH 


155 


which  silver  treasury  notes  were  to  be  issued. 
It  was  left  to  the  secretary  of  the  treasury,  at 
his  discretion,  to  redeem  these  notes  in  gold  or 
silver  coin,  it  being,  the  act  continues,  "the 
established  policy  of  the  United  States  to  main- 
tain the  tw^o  metals  on  a  parity  with  each  other 
upon  the  present  legal  ratio,  or  such  ratio  as 
may  be  provided  by  law."  This  legislation 
has  led  to  a  decrease  of  the  gold  and  an  in- 
crease of  the  silver  coin  and  bullion  held  in  the 
United  States,  the  amounts  being  approxi- 
mately estimated  in  the  Report  of  the  Director 
of  the  United  States  Mint,  1912,  p.  64,  as 
follows  : — 

Total  Metallic  Stock,  SOth  June  1912. 
Gold    $1,812,856,241    say  £362,571,248 
Silver        741,184,095     ,,       148,236,819 


$2,554,040,336 


£510,808,067 


[The  lowest  prices  of  silver  in  bars  for  the 
years  1873  to  1889  inclusive,  and  for  1889 
were: 

1873-89. 
M  to  Qth  August  1886      42d. 

(The  higliest  price  during  the  whole  mouth 
of  August  1886  was  42 ^d.) 
IS^Ai/ai/ 1888  {the  ojie  day  only)  41^d. 

(For  the  whole  of  May  to  August  1888  the  price 
did  not  rise  above  42|d.,  and  at  several  different 
dates  in  May,  June,  and  July,  stood  at  4 2d). 

1889. 
31st  May  to  28th  July  42d. 

1900.  1913. 

Average  price ,..27i|'l 27^Kd. 

[See  Report  on  International  Monetary  Confer- 
ence, Paris,  1878  (Washington  Government  Print- 
ing Press,  1879).— Reports  of  the  Director  of  the 
United  States  Mint. — Reports  of  the  Comptroller 
of  the  Currency  of  the  United  States.  Article  by 
F.  W.  Taussig,  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics, 
April  1890.] 

BLANK  CREDIT.  Credit  given  by  a  banker 
on  the  personal  security  of  his  client.  One  form 
of  blank  credit  which  is  frequently  gi-anted  by 
continental  banks  and  foreign  banks  established 
in  London  consists  in  the  acceptance  of  drafts 
issued  by  the  customers  or  for  their  account  on 
the  understanding  that  they  will  cover  the  same 
before  maturity.  The  drawer  of  such  bills  can 
discount  them  on  the  strength  of  the  banker's 
acceptance,  and  the  banker  can  give  credit  with- 
out any  cash  outlay.  The  system  of  granting 
and  using  blank  credits  is  liable  to  great  abuses, 
but  on  the  whole  it  may  be  considered  a  useful 
if  not  indispensable  element  m  the  machinery 
of  trade. 

BLANK  ENDORSEMENT.  A  biU  of 
exchange  endorsed  in  blank,  the  meaning  of 
which  is  that  a  bill  on  which  the  endorser  has 
only  signed  his  name  becomes  payable  to  bearer, 
and  is  negotiable  by  mere  delivery  (see  Bill  of 
Exchange).  See  also  for  further  particulars 
The  Practice  of  Banking,  by  John  Hutchison. 


BLANK  TRANSFER.  A  deed  purporting 
to  assign  the  property  in  shares  or  other  regis- 
tered securities  in  which  the  transferee's  name 
is  left  in  blank.  A  document  of  this  nature  is 
frequently  used  in  cases  of  sale  or  pledge,  and, 
if  accompanied  by  the  certificate  relating  to  the 
security  to  which  it  refers,  generally  authorises 
the  holder  to  fill  in  his  own  name,  and  to  have 
himself  registered  as  owner  of  the  security. 
Difficulties  may  occur  when  the  transferer 
fraudulently  executes  several  transfers  relat- 
ing to  the  same  security,  and  in  other  cases, 
and  the  holder  of  the  transfer  ought  to  exer- 
cise great  care  (see  Lindley,  Comp)any  Law, 
p.  471  seq.)  e.  s. 

BLANQUI,  Jerome  Adolphe,  born  1798, 
died  in  Paris  1854.  The  economist  Blanqui, 
who  must  not  be  mixed  up  with  liis  brother 
L.  A.  Blanqui,  the  revolutionist,  was,  from  1830 
to  his  death,  the  head  of  the  Ecole  de  Commerce 
of  Paris,  and  in  1833  replaced  J.  B.  Say  as 
professor  of  political  (and  especially  of  in- 
dustrial) economy  at  the  Couservatoire  des  Arts 
et  Metiers.  He  was  elected,  1838,  a  member  of 
the  Academic  des  Sciences  morales  et  politiques, 
and  represented  the  department  of  theGironde  in 
the  Chamber  of  deputies.  Marshal  Bugeaud, 
witli  whom  he  was  very  intimate,  thouglit  of 
making  him  the  civil  administrator  of  Algeria. 
Blanqui  had  travelled  nearly  over  all  Europe, 
and  only  left  olT  travelling  when  his  health 
compelled  him  to  remain  at  home.  It  may  be 
said  that  the  whole  of  his  life  was  spent  in  one 
long  and  laborious  inquiry,  principally  directed 
to  the  solution  of  those  questions  relating  to  the 
working  classes,  the  importance  of  which  he 
had  realised  more  clearly  than  most  of  his  con- 
temporaries. The  brilliancy  and  vigour  of  his 
language  added  an  additional  attraction  to  his 
teaching. 

Parts  of  the  course  of  lectures  delivered  by 
Blanqui  were  published  by  MM.  Blaise  and 
J.  Garnier.  Blanqui  also  was  the  axithor  of 
several  works.  Of  these  the  most  important 
are:  Resume  de  Vhistoire  du  comraerce  et  de 
Vindustrie,  Paris,  1826,  in  18mo. — Pr6cis 
eUmentaire  d'economie  politique,  Paris,  1826 
and  1842,  in  32mo. — Histoire  de  Viconomie 
politique  en  Europe,  depuis  les  anciens  jusqu'd 
nx)s  jours,  suivie  d'une  bibliographie  raisonnec 
des  principaux  ouvrages  d'economie  politique, 
Paris,  1838,  1842,  and  1845.  This  last  work 
has  been  translated  into  several  languages. 
We  may  also  mention  the  notices  written  by 
Blanqui  of  the  French  exhibition  of  1827,  and 
particularly  that  on  the  great  exhibition  of 
London  1851.  His  researches  on  the  position 
of  French  workmen  have  been  continued  by 
M.  Baudrillart.  Blanqui  left  behind  him 
several  manuscript  fragments  and  studies  which 
it  is  hoped  that  his  son-in-law,  M.  Maze,  will 
publish.  a.  de  f. 

BLENCH  (Scots   law  term).      Lands    held 


156 


BLOCKADE— BOARD  OF  AGRICULTURE 


blench  are  held  subject  to  payment  of  merely 
a  trifling  duty,  which  is  exigible  only  if  asked 
within  the  year.      Analogous  to  Petit  Sek- 

GEANTY. 

BLOCKADE.  A  blockade  may  be  defined 
as  the  prevention  of  commercial  intercourse  .be- 
tween a  port  or  a  portion  of  the  coast  in  an 
enemy's  country  and  neutrals,  by  means  of 
vessels  of  war  sufficient  in  number  to  render 
any  neutral  vessel  attempting  to  reach  such  port 
or  coast  liable  to  capture.  A  blockade  being  a 
belligerent  act,  must  be  instituted  by  sovereign 
authority,  and  a  naval  force  must  be  present  to 
maintain  it.  The  extent  of  a  blockade  is  deter- 
mined by  the  efficiency  of  the  blockading 
squadron.  Some  continental  writers,  such  as 
Heffter  {Das  Europaische  Vblkerreeht  der  Gegen- 
wartf  §  155),  and  Ortolan  (Regies  interTiationales 
et  Diplomatie  de  la  Mer,  ii.  328)  maintain  that 
the  blockading  force  should  be  anchored,  a  view 
that  lias  not  been  accepted  by  the  prize  courts 
of  England  and  the  United  States.  A  blockade 
is  violated  by  any  attempt  at  ingress  or  egress, 
but  whilst  English  and  American  prize  courts 
hold  that  the  bare  act  of  sailing  for  a  blockaded 
port  is  an  act  of  violation,  provided  there  is 
reason  to  believe  the  captain  knows  of  the  exist- 
ence of  the  blockade,  the  French  practice  is  to 
warn  the  captain  on  approaching  the  coast,  and 
only  to  seize  the  vessel  if  a  subsequent  attempt 
is  made  to  enter.  The  penalty  for  a  breach 
of  blockade  is  the  confiscation  of  the  ship,  but 
the  cargo  is  liable  to  be  condemned  if  its  owners 
are  in  any  way  privy  to  the  breach. 

The  prohibition  of  commerce  with  neutrals 
involved  in  a  blockade  is  based  by  Hautefeuille 
{Des  droits  et  des  devoirs  des  Tuitions  neutres  en 
temps  de  guerre  maritime,  3d  ed.  ii.  178,  181) 
on  a  supposed  conquest  of  the  enemy's  territorial 
waters  ;  by  Ortolan  {Diplomatie  de  la  mer,  2d 
ed.  ii.  293)  on  an  "occupation"  of  the  sea, 
which  gives  to  the  occupier  "sovereign  rights." 
Historically  the  rules  of  blockade  are  a  modifica- 
tion of  the  old  principle  that  war  was  "  omnium 
in  omnia  et  in  omnibus,"  and  therefore  he  who 
was  a  neutral  was  an  enemy.  All  intercourse 
with  an  enemy  was  unlawful.  In  process  of 
time  neutral  states  made  good  their  claim  to  a 
distinct  status,  and  it  is  now  recognised  that  in 
time  of  war  the  trade  of  neutral  individuals 
should  be  as  free  as  in  time  of  peace.  This 
principle,  however,  comes  in  conflict  with  the 
long  established  right  of  a  belligerent  to  cut  off 
commercial  communications  with  the  enemy, 
and  the  modern  rules  of  blockade  are  a  com- 
promise between  belligerent  and  neutral  rights. 
The  right  of  the  neutral  subject  to  trade  is 
recognised  in  the  fact  that,  by  violating  a 
blockade  he  does  not  violate  the  neutrality  of  his 
state,  and  if  the  vessel  escapes  he  suffers  no 
punishment.  The  belligerent  right  is  recog- 
nised by  permitting  the  blockade  to  be  estab- 
lished, and  by  authorising  the   belligerent  to 


confiscate  any  vessel  that  may  be  caught  in  the 
act  of  violation. 

A  blockade,  if  on  an  extended  scale,  may 
inflict  great  injury  on  neutral  states.  During 
the  four  years  that  the  blockade  of  the  Southern 
States  was  maintained  by  the  North  American 
States,  the  export  of  cotton  to  England  ceased, 
and  those  engaged  in  the  cotton  industry 
suffered  great  privation,  and  the  exportation  of 
wine  from  France  to  the  United  States  became 
impracticable.  Hence  the  prohibition  of  com- 
mercial blockades,  and  of  the  capture  of  all 
private  property  at  sea,  has  been  advocated. 
From  an  economic  point  of  view  it  is  certainly 
desirable  that  the  capture  of  private  property 
should  be  abolished,  but  as  FauchiUe  points 
out  {Du  Blocus  Maritime),  every  act  of  war 
affects  neutrals,  and  the  arguments  for  the  pro- 
tection of  private  property  are  arguments 
against  the  practice  of  war  itself  (see  Inter- 
national Law). 

[See  Calvo's  Droit  International,  Paris,  1881  ; 
Du  Blocus  Maritime,  par  Paul  Fauchille,  Paris, 
1882. — Hall's  International  Law,  Oxford,  1889.] 

J.  E.  c.  M. 

BOARD.  A  body  of  persons  officially  con- 
stituted for  lihe  transaction  of  some  particular 
business,  so  called  from  the  "board"  or  table 
round  which  meetings  were  held.  Some  govern- 
ment departments  are  designated  by  this  title, 
e.g.  board  of  trade,  board  of  inland  revenue, 
local  government  board,  poor  law  board.  The 
term  is  also  applied  to  the  directors  or  persons 
charged  with  the  management  of  a  company. 

J.  E.  c.  M. 

{Economic  Opinion  on  Boards.)  "Boards," 
said  Bentham,  "are  screens,"  a  phrase  which 
describes  very  well  the  extreme  position  of 
economists  who  distrust  governmental  control 
in  industry.  The  term  is  applied  to  par- 
ticular departments  of  the  administration  of 
the  central  government,  e.g.  the  board  of 
trade,  the  board  of  agriculture ;  to  similar 
divisions  of  local  government,  e.g.  board  of 
guardians,  school  board  ;  and  also  to  various 
permanent  committees  charged  with  the  super- 
vision of  particular  industries,  e.g.  the  Scottish 
fishery  board.  It  was  one  of  the  main  prin- 
ciples of  Adam  Smith,  that,  if  governmental 
control  were  proved  to  be  desirable,  it  was 
better  to  throw  the  responsibility  on  the  per- 
sons and  localities  directly  interested.  The 
constitution  of  boards  of  various  kinds  is  the 
logical  outcome  of  this  principle,  the  central 
authority  only  laying  down  general  rules  for 
guidance.  J.  s.  n. 

BOARD  OF  AGRICULTURE  (1793).  Seven 
years  after  the  reconstitution  of  the  board  of 
trade,  the  House  of  Commons,  on  the  motion 
of  Sir  John  Sinclair,  voted  £3000  a  year  to- 
wards the  expenses  of  a  board  of  agriculture  (1 7th 
May  1793).  The  board  was  duly  chartered  ; 
it  was  to  consist  of  certain  specified  government 


BOARD  OF  AGRICULTURE 


157 


officials  and  lay  coadjutors,  the  latter  including 
Sinclair  himself,  who  became  the  first  president, 
and  Arthur  Youkg,  who  became  secretary. 
Though  the  minority  in  the  House  regarded 
the  board  as  simply  a  new  refuge  for  place- 
hunters,  the  enthusiasm  of  president  and  secre- 
tary carried  it  into  good  work  at  once,  and,  for 
a  time  at  least,  falsified  fears.  On  its  first 
meeting  (4th  September  1793)  it  drew  up  a 
plan  of  inquiry  on  a  large  scale.  Intelligent 
farmers  throughout  the  kingdom  were  to  be 
provided  with  a  Hst  of  queries  relating  to  their 
business  which  they  were  to  be  invited  to  answer 
and  send  to  the  board,  for  the  general  benefit  of 
the  agiicultural  interest.  In  the  second  place, 
in  every  county  some  competent  person  was  to 
be  chosen  to  draw  up  a  survey  of  the  state  of 
agriculture  in  that  county,  to  be  remitted  to 
the  board  for  publication.  This  plan  was  duly 
carried  out,  and  the  result  was  given  to  the 
world  in  sixty  or  seventy  separate  publications, 
of  various  degrees  of  merit.  The  survey  of 
Sussex  was  by  the  son  of  Arthur  Young,  and 
the  survey  of  Suffolk  by  Young  himself,  who 
contributed  also  to  the  3d  and  6th  vohimes  of 
CommunicatioTis  published  by  the  board  between 
1802  and  1806.  These  Communications  include 
also  papers,  letters,  or  speeches  by  George 
Washington,  Dr.  Priestley,  Sir  Joseph  Banks, 
Sir  Humphry  Davy,  Morris  Birkbeck,  Watson, 
bishop  of  Llandaff,  and  Sir  John  Sinclair,  Avith 
others  of  lesser  note,  English  and  foreign.  One 
of  the  objects  of  the  board  was  to  keep  England 
alive  to  foreign  improvements.  Another  of 
course  was  to  encourage  improvements  at  home  ; 
and,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  the  lectures  of  Sir 
Humphry  Davy,  given  before  the  board  in  1802, 
made  an  epoch  in  agricultural  chemistry. 
Prizes  were  given  for  agricultural  essays  and 
experiments.  Another  object  of  the  board  was 
more  general, — to  provide  accurate  statistics  of 
lands,  produce,  stock,  and  even  population ; 
there  is,  for  example,  in  vol.  ii.  of  the  Co7n- 
munications,  an  "abstract  of  baptisms  and 
burials  "  for  four  of  the  parishes  in  each  of  fifty 
counties,  drawn  up  in  1800.  Both  in  the 
Communications  and  in  the  several  Reports 
for  the  counties,  there  is  a  mass  of  information, 
observations,  and  opinions,  not  only  in  regard 
to  the  technical  points  of  agriculture  and  pas- 
ture, but  in  regard  to  the  poor  law,  the  con- 
dition of  the  poor  labourer  and  the  farmer, 
the  incidence  and  amount  of  rent,  rates,  and 
tithes,  the  progress  and  effects  of  enclosures, 
the  movements  of  population,  and  the  working 
of  such  experiments  as  the  system  of  small  allot- 
ments. Accordingly  these  volumes  contain 
materials  for  the  social  and  industrial  history 
of  the  country  districts  of  the  kingdom,  which 
are  of  undoubted  value  though  they  have  been 
little  utilised. 

A  general  view  of  the  work  of  the  board  for 
its  first  three  years  is  given  in  the  first  volume 


of  the  Communications,  which  contains  also 
the  text  of  the  Charter  of  Foundation,  dated 
23d  August  1793.  The  grant  of  £3000  waa 
withdrawn  in  1817,  a  year  of  distress  when 
the  government  was  much  pressed  to  reduce  ex- 
penditure. No  doubt  the  Smithfield  Club,  the 
Highland  Society,  the  Bath  and  West  of  Eng- 
land Agricultural  Society  and  other  private 
bodies  were  doing  its  work  equally  well ;  but 
it  is  not  just  to  describe  the  board  as  simply 
"  the  pet  scheme  of  King  George  "  with  no  life 
of  its  own  (Martineau,  Tliirty  Years'  Peace,  iv. 
448).  In  1889  it  was  re-established,  and  in 
1903  assumed  in  addition  the  duties  of  the 
Board  of  Fisheries  then  constituted  (see  below). 

[Reports  to  Board  of  Agriculture  from  the  several 
counties  (var.  dates). —  Communications  to  the 
Board  of  Agriculture,  1802-6,  6  vols. — History  of 
the  Progress  of  Great  Britain,  R.  K.  Philp,  1859 
(specimens  are  given  of  the  queries  to  farmers,  p. 
117). — M'Culloch's  Literature  of  Political  Econ- 
omy, 1845  (a  list  of  surveyors  is  given,  but  not 
in  a  useful  or  accurate  form,  p.  215) — Corres- 
pondence of  Sir  John  Sinclair,  vol.  1.  406-407,  etc. 
— Life  of  Sir  John  Sinclair,  i.  253,  etc. — Annual 
Register,  1793,  p.  118.— R.E.  Vxoi\iQxo' a  English 
Farming,  1888,  p.  69.]  j.b. 

BOAfeD  OF  AGRICULTURE  AND  FISH- 
ERIES. A  Board  of  Agriculture  for  Great 
Britain  was  re-established  12th  August  1889. 
In  1903  certain  powers  and  duties  formerly 
exercised  by  the  Board  of  Trade  with  respect 
to  fisheries  were  transferred  to  this  department, 
the  designation  of  which  Avas  at  the  same  time 
altered. 

There  are  transferred  to  this  Board  the  duties 
of  the  Privy  Council  under  the  Destructive  In- 
sects and  Contagious  Diseases  (Animals)  Acts, 
the  duties  of  the  land  commissioners  for  Eng- 
land under  the  Tithe  commutation  acts,  the 
Copyhold  acts,  the  acts  for  inclosure,  exchange 
and  improvement  of  land  and  other  acts, 
and  those  vested  in  the  Commissioners  of  His 
Majesty's  works  and  public  buildings  under  the 
Survey  Act,  1870.  The  Board  undertakes  the 
preparation  of  statistics  relating  to  agriculture 
and  forestry  and  the  industry  of  fishing.  It 
may  also  undertake  the  inspection  of  any 
schools,  not  public  elementary  schools,  in  which 
technical  instruction,  practical  or  scientific,  is 
given  in  matters  connected  with  tliese  subjects, 
and  the  aiding  of  any  school  which  admits  such 
inspection  and  is  qualified  to  receive  such  aid, 
the  aiding  and  inspection  of  courses  of  lectures 
and  instruction,  and  examinations  in  these 
subjects,  and  the  encouragement  of  such  ex- 
periment and  research  as  they  may  think  im- 
portant for  the  purpose  of  promoting  agricul- 
ture, forestry,  or  the  industry  of  fishing.  The 
muzzling  and  keeping  dogs  under  control  art 
among  the  duties  of  the  Board  with  the  Con- 
tagious Diseases  (Animals)  Acts,  and  it  is  also 
stated  that  in  the  act  establishing  it,  the  ex- 
pression "agriculture"  includes  horticulture. 


158 


BOARD  OF  TEADE 


The  Board  are  charged  with  the  duty  of 
providing  small  holdings  and  allotments  in 
England  and  Wales  (see  Small  Holdings  Act, 
1907),  and  of  carrying  out  the  English  share 
of  the  international  investigation  of  the  North 
Sea.  They  have  also  important  duties  uijder 
the  Fertilisers  and  Feeding  Stuffs  Act,  1906, 
and  the  Butter  and  Margarine  Act,  1907. 
Useful  work  has  already  been  done  in  connec- 
tion with  agricultural  education  and  small 
holdings  (see  Agricultural  Holdings  Act, 
App.).  Instruction  in  dairying,  in  poultry 
and  bee-keeping,  in  horticulture,  in  the 
management  of  orchards  and  fruit  trees,  and 
in  school  or  other  gardens,  has  been  pro- 
vided at  many  centres  throughout  England 
and  Wales. 

The  president  of  the  Board  may  have  a  seat 
in  Parliament. 

[Board  of  Agriculture  Act,  1889  ;  do.  of 
Fisheries,  1903.] 

BOARD  OF  TRADE.  Great  Britain  pos- 
sesses no  ministry  of  commerce  nor  any  depart- 
ment specially  charged  with  the  superintendence 
of  industry.  The  home  office  has  some  super- 
vision over  factories  and  workshops,  mainly  as  to 
hours  of  labour  of  women  and  children,  fencing 
of  dangerous  machinery,  and  sanitary  condition 
of  buildings.  It  publishes  returns  of  the  princi- 
pal textile  industries,  but  with  no  details  of 
quantities  or  values  of  what  is  produced,  and 
superintends  coal  and  other  mines  in  regard  to 
safety,  and  it  is  not  concerned  with  other  mat- 
ters as  important  to  them — namely,  the  rates 
charged  for  conveying  minerals  by  railway  and 
royalties  payable  to  original  owners.  In  con- 
nection with  manufacturing  industries  the 
science  and  art  department  gives  some  assistance 
through  the  South  Kensington  and  other 
museums,  and  technical  schools.  With  these 
exceptions  there  is  little  supervision  over  com- 
merce and  industry,  except  by  what  was  origin- 
ally the  committee  of  privy  council  for  trade 
and  is  now  known  as  the  "board  of  trade." 
Temporary  councils  had  advised  parliament  con- 
cerning trade  matters  since  the  14  th  century, 
but  no  permanent  department  was  established 
until  Cromwell  instituted  such  a  department  to 
foster  trade  and  navigation,  and  check  the 
monopoly  of  the  Dutch.  This  policy  was  con- 
tinued after  the  Restoration,  a  committee  of  the 
privy  council  being  appointed,  1660,  to  ascertain 
particulars  of  imports  and  exports  and  to  improve 
trade.  Another  committee  was  appointed  a  few 
years  later  to  assist  the  crown  in  forming  and 
managing  ''foreign  plantations,"  ^.e.  colonies. 
The  Earl  of  Sandwich  was  president  and  John 
Evelyn  one  of  the  ten  members  of  this  second 
committee.  In  1672  these  two  committees 
were  united  as  a  standing  council  of  trade  and 
plantations  under  the  presidency  of  the  Earl  of 
Shaftesbury,  and,  in  1673,  John  Locke  became 
secretary.     The  joint  commission  lasted,  how- 


ever, only  two  years,  and  was  not  revived  till 
1696.  Locke  then  returned  to  office,  though 
unwillingly,  as  one  of  six  unofficial  paid 
members  of  the  board,  eight  principal  officers 
of  state  being  unpaid  members.  The  questions 
referred  to  the  establishment  included  inquiries 
into  hindrances  to  trade,  employment  of  the 
poor,  and  the  silver  currency,  the  great  re- 
coinage  of  which,  1695,  was  supported  by 
Locke's  writings.  The  new  board  were  hardly 
settled  in  their  rooms  at  Whitehall,  altered 
for  them  by  Wren,  when  the  fire  of  1697 
drove  them  to  take  refuge  in  the  building 
known  as  the  Cockpit,  on  the  site  of  the 
present  council  office.  In  1700  Locke  was 
compelled  to  resign  through  ill-health  {Life 
of  Locke,  by  Fox  Bourne).  Locke's  successoi 
was  Matthew  Prior,  well  known  in  his  literary 
capacity. 

The  navigation  acts  and  the  mercantile 
system  were  at  this  time  the  keystones  of  oui 
commercial  policy.  Raw  materials  might  be 
imported  free  of  duty,  and  with  a  bounty  in 
some  cases,  but  heavy  penalties  usually  pro- 
hibited their  exportation.  In  the  case  of  wool, 
even  movement  from  village  to  village  within 
a  few  miles  of  the  coast  was  prohibited.  British 
colonies  werS  favoured  by  Discriminating 
Duties,  but  when  conflicts  arose  between  the 
interests  of  home  manufacturers  and  colonists, 
the  latter  usually  went  to  the  wall.  A  secretary 
of  state  for  the  colonies  to  undertake  the  con- 
trol of  the  plantations  was  appointed  1760. 
This  control  passed,  1782,  to  the  home  secretary, 
1801  to  the  war  department,  1854  to  the  pre- 
sent colonial  office.  Addison  was  for  a  few  years 
one  of  the  lords  commissioners  of  trade  previous 
to  his  appointment  in  1717  as  secretary  of  state 
to  George  I.  Gibbon,  the  historian,  was  made 
one  of  the  eight  lords  commissioners  in  1779 
at  a  salary  of  £1000  a  year,  but  was  ousted 
three  years  after,  mainly  through  Burke's  attack 
on  the  public  offices  1780.  (Cobbett's  Parlia- 
mentary History,  vol.  xxi.  p.  232.)  The  con- 
test between  Burke  and  the  ministry  was,  as 
regards  the  board  of  trade,  whether  unpaid  com- 
missioners of  trade,  chosen  from  time  to  time, 
would  not  be  preferable  to  a  permanent  highly- 
paid  council,  which  Burke  described  as  "a  sort 
of  gently-ripening  hot- house,  where  eight  mem- 
bers of  parliament  receive  salaries  of  a  thousand 
a  year  in  order  to  mature  at  a  proper  season  to 
a  claim  for  two  thousand. "  Burke's  motion  for 
the  abolition  of  the  board  of  trade  and  the 
colonial  and  other  offices  was  carried  in  the 
House  of  Commons  by  a  majority  of  eight. 
Reductions  resulted  of  between  £200,000  and 
£300,000  a  year,  including  £11,000  for  the 
board  of  trade.  Another  permanent  committee 
of  the  privy  council  was  formed  in  1786,  by 
order  in  council  which  still  mainly  regulates  the 
legal  constitution  of  the  office.  The  duties  of 
the  revived  board  were  chiefly  as  a   century 


BOARD  OF  TRADE— BOARDING-OUT  SYSTEM 


159 


before,  with  questions  relating  to  food  supply 
and  restrictions  on  the  exportation  and  im- 
portation of  corn. 

Experience  of  difficulties  in  administering  any 
Sliding  Scale  of  corn  duties  had  much  to  do 
with  disposing  the  board  towards  a  free-trade 
policy.  Mr,  Husxisson's  efforts  in  removing  re- 
strictions on  foreign  trade,  followed  by  Mr.  Glad- 
stone's (1842)  carrying  out  Peel's  tariff  reforms 
were  ably  seconded  by  the  permanent  staff,  in- 
cluding Mr.  G.  R.  Porter  and  Mr.  Macgregor. 
Porter  was  the  founder  of  official  statistics,  the 
accounts  published  by  government  before  he  be- 
came chief  of  the  statistical  department,  1832, 
having  been  merely  crude  and  undigested  masses 
of  figures.  The  Progress  of  the  Nation  made  him 
famous  as  an  economist  and  he  Avas  made 
secretary  of  the  Board  of  Trade  1847.  Sir  R. 
Giffen,  afterwards  an  assistant  secretary,  be- 
came chief  of  tlie  statistical  and  commercial  de- 
partment 18  76.  Meanwhile,  as  state  supervision 
over  food  supply  and  general  trade  became 
obsolete,  joint -stock  companies,  railways,  and 
shipping  required  supervision,  and  further 
changes  were  made,  the  president  being  practic- 
ally secretary  of  state  for  trade.  The  vice-president 
became,  1867,  a  parliamentary  secretary  with 
similar  duties  to  those  of  a  parliamentary  imder 
secretary  of  state.  Efforts  have  been  made  to 
change  the  title  of  the  office  into  ''Ministry  of 
Commerce  "  presided  over  by  a  titular  secretary 
of  state,  but  a  more  obvious  improvement  would 
be  to  incorporate  with  the  board  some  consulta- 
tive members  of  technical  knowledge  and  trade 
experience,  such  as  eminent  shipowners,  mer- 
chants, and  manufacturers,  who  could  be  called 
in  to  advise  the  president. 

The  departments  must  be  described  somewhat 
in  detail. 

1.  The  Commercial  Department  deals  with 
commercial  questions  generally.  It  provides  the 
statistical  abstracts  for  the  United  Kingdom,  the 
colonies,  and  foreign  countries  :  trade,  shipping, 
railway,  and  emigration  statistics,  including  a  re- 
cord of  price  of  corn,  foreign  and  colonial  cnstoms, 
tariffs,  and  trade  regulations  ;  keeps  the  standards 
of  weights  and  measures,  and  controls  the  registra- 
tion of  joint-stock  companies.  Labour  statistics 
have  now  special  attention.  A  Monthly  Journal 
gives  commercial  information  principally  from 
oflficial  sources. 

A  separate  Bankruptcy  Department  has  been 
organised  since  the  Bankruptcy  Act  of  1883.  The 
principle  of  this  act  is  administration  of  bankrupts' 
property  by  or  under  a  department  amenable  to 
parliamentary  control  (see  Bankruptcy  Law  ; 
Deed  of  Arrangement). 

2.  The  Railway  Department,  established  1840, 
inspects  railways  before  opened,  reports  on  pro- 
posed railways,  accidents,  by-laws,  arbitrators,  and 
other  duties  under  various  railway  acts.  The  Rail- 
way and  Canal  Traffic  Act  (1888)  in  regard  to  rates 
for  conveying  goods ;  tramways,  their  by-laws,  and 
"provisional  orders,"  i.e.  omnibus  bills  approved 
by  some  public  department  before  being  submitted 


to  parliament  come  under  this  department,  with 
gas  and  water  schemes,  electric  lighting,  and 
copyright.  The  patent  office,  a  subordinate  de- 
partment, has  charge  of  Patents,  designs,  and 
Trade  Marks. 

3.  The  Marine  Department,  established  1850, 
regulates  the  survey  of  passenger  steamers,  com- 
pulsory examination  of  masters  and  mates,  shipping 
offices  for  engagement  and  discharge  of  seamen,  and 
generally  all  questions  relating  to  ships  and  their 
crews,  including  the  detention  of  imseaworthy  ships 
and  inquiries  into  wrecks.  It  also  deals  with  in- 
ternational arrangements  connected  with  the  Police 
of  the  North  Sea  and  other  fisheries,  and  matters 
relating  to  fishing  vessels;;;'and  their  crews.  Certain 
powers  and  duties  formerly  exercised  by  the  Board 
of  Trade  with  respect  to  fisheries  were  in  1903 
transferred  to  the  Board  op  Agriculture  and 
Fisheries  {q.v.). 

4.  The  Harbour  Department  has  charge  of  fore- 
shores belonging  to  the  crown,  and  protects  navi- 
gable harbours  and  channels,  lighthouse  funds, 
Holyhead  and  Ramsgate  harbours  and  Dover  pier. 
Wreckage  and  quarantine  are  also  under  the  charge 
of  this  department,  and  standards  for  weights  and 
measures,  and  hall  marks. 

5.  The  Finance  Department  deals  with  the 
accounts  of  all  branches  of  the  Board  of  Trade,  of 
harbours,  lighthouses,  and  mercantile  marine  offices, 
merchant  seamen's  fund,  consuls'  accounts  for  dis- 
abled seamen  abroad  ;  marine  savings  banks  and 
seamen's  money  orders,  life  insurance  companies' 
accounts  and  bankruptcy  estate  accounts. 

BOARDING-OUT  SYSTEM.  The  boarding- 
out  system  is  one  of  several  attempts  to  solve 
the  problem  of  training  pauper  children,  and  is 
practised  in  the  United  Kingdom,  in  France, 
Germany,  Russia,  Switzerland,  Canada,  and  the 
United  States.  In  relieving  adult  paupers  the 
main  object  may  be  said  to  be,  to  make  the 
condition  of  the  pauper  as  little  enviable  as 
possible  ;  in  the  case  of  pauper  children  there 
is  a  further  aim,  viz.  to  prevent  the  permanence 
of  a  state  of  pauperism,  and  to  train  good 
citizens.  Various  methods  have  been  suggested 
to  attain  these  ends.  It  was  at  one  time  the 
custom  to  keep  children  in  workhouses,  in  a 
separate  part  of  the  building  from  aged  and 
adult  paupers,  under  instruction  and  discipline. 
The  evils  of  this  system,  which  are  possibly 
exaggerated,  lie  in  the  danger  lest  a  child 
should  acquire  the  so-called  "  pauper  taint " — 
that  is,  a  predisposition  to  relapse  into  pauper- 
ism. To  this  must  be  added  a  total  ignorance 
of  the  world,  due  to  artificial  surroundings^  which 
not  only  unfits  a  child  for  any  walk  in  life,  but 
makes  him  an  easy  prey  to  temptation.  These 
evils  are  now,  as  a  general  rule,  modified  by  the 
practice  of  sending  children  to  the  ordinary 
parish  schools.  The  first  real  reform  in  the 
system  was  the  establishment  of  district  schools 
in  which  the  children  of  one  or  more  unions  are 
boarded  and  educated.  The  results  of  the 
training  given  in  such  schools  are  very  favour- 
able, a  comparatively  small  percentage  of  the 
children  becoming  paupers  in  later  life.     Against 


160 


BOARDING-OUT  SYSTEM— BODIN 


them  it  is  urged  that  individuality  is  lost,  that 
the  training  given  is  too  mechanical,  that  the 
little  incidents  of  daily  life  are  wanting,  so  that 
no  sense  of  property  is  acquired,  that  they  are 
favourable  to  the  development  of  certain  diseases, 
e.g.  ophthalmia,  and  that  the  diet  lacks  variety. 
A  further  modification  is  seen  in  the  building  of 
villages,  consisting  of  cottage-homes,  in  each  of 
which  a  small  number  of  children  form  an 
artificial  family,  but  an  objection  to  this  system 
lies  in  the  cost.  It  is  claimed  for  the  boarding- 
out  system  that,  whilst  avoiding  the  above- 
mentioned  evils,  it  has  great  advantages  of  its 
own.  Thus  children  are  placed  in  ordinary 
families,  are  adopted  by  foster-parents  carefully 
selected,  who  lodge,  board,  and  clothe  them  in 
return  for  a  weekly  payment  by  the  guardians, 
and  who  are  under  close  supervision.  Thus  the 
"pauper  taint"  is  wholly  absent,  and  the 
advantages  of  home  life  are  secured  to  the  child  ; 
the  relations  between  the  foster-parents  and  the 
children  often  develop  into  real  affection,  and 
the  tie  between  them  is  as  strong  or  stronger 
than  that  in  ordinary  families :  the  surroundings 
are  precisely  those  in  which  a  child  will  find 
itself  in  later  life,  for  which  therefore  it  receives 
an  appropriate  training.  Lastly,  it  is  far  cheaper 
than  any  other  system.  Thus,  the  cost  of 
maintenance  of  a  child  in  a  workhouse  may  be 
set  at  4s.  lOd.  weekly,  exclusive  of  the  cost  of 
buildings,  etc.,  the  weekly  cost  in  a  district 
school  at  8s.  6d.,  in  a  cottage-home  at  9s.  5d., 
on  the  boarding-out  system  at  4s.  3d.  Two 
kinds  of  difficulty  suggest  themselves.  Fu'st, 
the  practical  difficulty  of  securing  adequate 
supervision.  The  supervision  is  partly  in  the 
hands  of  volunteers,  partly  of  union  officials, 
subject  to  inspection  by  an  official  of  the  local 
government  board.  The  reports  of  this  last, 
Miss  Mason,  though  on  the  whole  encourag- 
ing, show  that  lamentable  shortcomings  are 
not  uncommon,  for  instances  are  quoted  of 
neglect  and  even  cruelty  on  the  part  of  foster- 
parents.  To  this  may  probably  be  attributed 
the  small  extent  to  which  the  system  has  been 
adopted,  and  its  unpopularity  among  the  poorer 
classes.  The  second  objection  is  one  of  prin- 
ciple. Under  this  system  the  children  of 
paupers  are  placed  in  a  better  position  than  the 
children  of  independent  labourers,  the  amount 
expended  upon  them  being  larger  than  these 
last  can  possibly  aff"ord.  Hence  the  motive  to 
support  his  own  family  is  weakened  on  the  part 
of  the  ordinary  man  by  the  sight  of  the  superior 
provision  made  for  the  family  of  his  improvident 
neighbour,  and  a  du-ect  incentive  is  given  to 
an  increase  of  population  by  recklessly  early 
marriages. 

The  boarding-out  system  is  regulated  by  two 
orders  of  the  Local  Government  Board,  issued  in 
1889,  which  superseded  the  orders  issued  in  1870 
and  1877.  Under  these  orders  orphan  and 
deserted  children,  or  the  children  of  permanent 


inmates  of  a  workhouse,  and  others  who  are 
practically  orphans,  may  be  boarded  out :  (1) 
outside  the  union  to  which  they  are  chargeable, 
in  which  case  they  are  under  the  supervision 
of  a  certified  committee ;  or  (2)  inside  the 
union,  when  the  responsibility  is  shared  by  a 
committee  and  the  officers  of  the  union.  The 
total  number  of  children  boarded  out  in  Eng- 
land and  Wales  on  1st  January  1890  was 
4366.      In  1909  it  was  8653  ;  in  1911,  9669. 

[The  Association  for  promoting  the  Boarding-out 
of  Pauper  Children  has  published  numerous  re- 
ports, etc.,  on  the  system.  Discussions  upon  it 
are  to  be  found  in  almost  every  annual  report  of 
the  Poor-Law  Conferences,  and  the  history  of  the 
movement  may  be  traced  in  the  annual  reports 
of  the  Local  Government  Board,  Part  I.]  l.  e.  p. 
BOCCHI,  Romeo,  who  came  from  Bologna, 
published  in  1621,  at  Venice,  a  book  on  money, 
in  two  volumes,  dedicated  to  the  pope  Gregory 
XV.  Delia  giusta  universal  misura  e  suo  typo. 
The  first  volume  has  the  sub-title  Anima  della 
moneta,  and  the  second  Corpo  della  moneta. 
Although  very  primitive  in  his  views,  this 
author  is  not  uninteresting.  m.  p. 

BOCKH,  August  (1785-1867),  the  eminent 
philologist,  was  author  of  the  classical  work  on 
the  poHticat  economy  of  ancient  Athens,  Staats- 
havshaltung  der  Athener,  1817.  This  book  was 
translated  into  English  by  Sir  G.  Cornewall 
•Lewis  (1828,  2d  ed.  1842).  Another  of  Bockh'a 
treatises  is  useful  for  the  study  of  the  economics 
of  antiquity,  namely  Metrologisdie  Untersuch- 
v/ngen  iiber  Gewicht,  Munzfiisse  und  Maasse  des 
Alterthums,  1838.  J.  k.  i. 

BOCLAND.  After  the  land  of  England  had 
been  distributed  among  the  original  German 
invaders,  a  considerable  surplus  remained  un- 
distributed, which  was  regarded  as  the  property 
of  the  tribe,  and  was  known  as  foUdatid. 
From  this  private  estates  were  in  subsequent 
times  given  to  individuals,  as  a  reward  for  emi- 
nent services,  especially  in  war.  Such  grants 
were  made  by  'hoc  or  charter,  issued  by  the  king 
and  his  witenagemot  or  council  of  wise  men :  and 
land  so  granted  was  called  bocland.  Bocland 
could  be  freely  alienated  either  during  lifetime 
or  by  will ;  and  we  learn  from  a  law  of  Alfred 
that  it  could  also  be  entailed,  i.e.  limited  in 
descent  to  a  single  family. 

[Stubbs,  Constitutional  History,  vol.  i,  ch.  v. — 
Essays  in  Anglo-Saxon  Law  (Boston  and  London, 
1876),  pp.  55  seg.'\  b.  l. 

BODIN",  Jean,  who  was  a  rival  of  Machia- 
velli  and  a  precursor  of  Montesquieu,  was  born 
at  Angers,  1520,  and  died  of  the  plague,  at  Laon, 
1596.  His  principal  work,  De  la  Eipuhlique 
(1577),  published  originally  in  French,  then 
translated  into  Latin  by  the  author  himself,  has 
not  for  its  object,  as  its  title  might  lead  the 
reader  to  suppose,  a  panegyric  on  the  republican 
form  of  government.  While  deriving  every- 
thing from  the  sovereignty  of  the  people,  Bodic 


BODY  CORPORATE— BOILEAU 


161 


admits  that  the  only  practical  method  is  the  per- 
petual alienation  of  this  sovereignty  in  favour 
of  a  monarch  and  his  heirs.  He  fixes  no  limits  to 
this  alienation,  but  he  desires  a  **  Gouvernement 
tempere  sans  etre  democratique. "  States-General 
like  those  at  Blois  (1576),  in  the  deliberations 
of  which  he  had  shared,  with  more  courage  and 
ability  than  success,  are,  in  his  eyes,  the  proper 
remedy  for  an  excess  of  absolute  power.  This 
was,  in  some  respects,  the  representative  mon- 
archy of  our  days.  He  also  supported  the  idea, 
developed  later  by  Montesquieu,  that  climate 
has  a  dominant  influence  on  the  form  of  govern- 
ment ;  theocratic  in  the  south  and  east,  militaiy 
in  the  north,  free  in  the  countries  lying  between 
these.  Maintaining  resolutely,  through  con- 
viction, liberty  of  conscience,  he  was  also 
a  declared  opponent  of  slavery.  In  political 
economy  he  supported  piinciples  universally 
admitted  in  our  days  against  a  sieur  de  Males- 
troit,  who,  had  it  not  been  for  two  pamphlets 
by  Bodin,  would  be  perfectly  unknown  at  the 
present  time  {R6ponse  aux  paradoxes  de  M. 
de  Malestroit  touchant  V encMrissem&rvt  de  toutes 
les  choses  et  des  monnaies,  Paris,  1568,  in  4 to, 
and  Discourssurle  rehaussementet  diminution  des 
monnaies,  pour  reponse  av/x  paradoxes  du  sieur 
de  Malestroit,  Paris,  1578,  in  8vo).  He  also 
published  La  Demonovnanie  (1587),  and  other 
similar  works  ;  for,  strange  as  the  fact  is,  this 
man,  of  such  powerful  intellect,  was  neverthe- 
less a  believer  in  sorcery  and  witchcraft. 

[M.  Ad.  Franck,  in  his  liifoi^mateurs  et  puUi- 
cistes  de  V Europe  (Paris,  1864,  in  8vo),  has 
written  on  Bodin  in  eloquent  terms  ;  but  tlie 
work  through  which  both  he  and  his  books  will 
be  best  known  is  the  volume  of  M.  H.  Baudrillart 
{Jean  Bodin  et  son  temps,  Paris,  1853,  in  8vo).] 

A.  c.  f. 

BODY  CORPORATE  or  Corporation  is  an 
artificial  or  juristic  person  which  preserves  its 
identity  and  the  rights  conferred  on  it  through 
a  perpetual  succession  of  natural  persons.  Cor- 
porations are  either  sole  where  composed  of  one 
person,  or  aggregate  where  composed  of  two  or 
more  persons.  They  are  also  divided  into 
ecclesiastical  corporations,  and  lay  corporations. 
Of  lay  corporations  the  most  important  are 
municipal  corporations  and  trading  companies. 
Corporations  are  created  either  by  charter  or  by 
act  of  parliament,  but  some  base  their  exist- 
ence on  prescription.  Their  powers  of  acquir- 
ing, holding,  or  disposing  of  property  depend 
partly  upon  the  instrument  calling  them  into 
existence,  and  partly  upon  the  objects  for 
which  they  were  created  (see  Corporation, 
Municipal  ;  and  Companies). 

[As  to  the  extent  to  which  a  corporation  can 
enter  into  contracts,  see  The  Principles  of  Contracts, 
by  Sir  F.  Pollock,  London,  1888.]       J.  e.  c.  m. 

BCECLER,  JoHANN  Heinrich  (1611-1672), 
a  German  writer,  born  at  Cronheim  in  Bavaria, 
was  professor  of  history,  philosophy,  and  politics 
VOL.  L 


at  Upsala  and  Strasburg.  In  his  posthumous 
Institution's  politicae :  accesseriont  Disserta- 
tiones  Politicae  ad  Selecta  Vetervm  loca  et 
libellvs  memorialis  ethicu^,  Argentorati,  1674, 
Boeder  assails  the  opinions  of  Grotius  on  the 
original  community  (p.  61),  and  those  of 
Althusius  (p.  104)  concerning  the  original 
sovereignty  of  the  people.  His  economical 
opinions  on  money,  taxation,  and  population 
are  for  the  most  part  founded  upon  Botero, 
Besold,  Bornitz,  and  Gryphiander.  The  first- 
named  may  have  suggested  his  distinction 
between  the  arts  which  assist  or  hinder  the 
increase  of  population,  trade,  schools,  and 
courts  belonging  to  the  former,  false  promises 
and  robberies  to  the  latter  (1.  iv.  c.  v.  p.  209). 
Boeder's  dissertation  "  on  the  science  and  study 
of  politics"  (p.  503  ff.),  in  which  he  deprecates 
the  study  of  Plato  and  recommends  Aristotle, 
gives  a  curious  example  of  what  was  the  state 
of  the  science  in  Germany  in  his  time. 

[See  Allgemeine  Deutsche  Biographic,  ii.  bd. 
pp.  792,  793. — Roscher,  Geschichte  der  National- 
Oehonomik  in  Deutschland,  1874,  pp.  209,  262, 
263.]  8.  B. 

BOILEAU  (or  Boyleau)  Etienne  (born 
about  1200,  died  about  1272),  is  said  to  have 
been  of  Angevin  origin.  He  joined  the  Cru- 
sades under  Louis  IX.  (St.  Louis),  was  captured, 
and  ransomed  by  that  monarch  at  a  high 
price.  At  one  time  provost  of  Orleans  ;  he 
subsequently  became  (1258-1270)  provost  of 
Paris,  by  special  appointment  of  Louis  IX. 
who  sought  a  man  of  suificient  strength  and 
integrity  to  maintain  social  and  industrial  order 
in  Paris.  Up  to  that  date  the  post  of  provost 
had  practically  been  farmed  out  to  speculators, 
who  recouped  themselves  by  exactions  and  the 
receipt  of  bribes.  Boileau,  a  man  of  noble 
birth  and  incorruptible  character,  suppressed 
venality,  meted  out  vigorous  justice,  estab- 
lished the  police  of  Paris,  and  hanged  his 
godson  for  theft,  and  a  friend  for  dishonesty. 
St.  Louis,  as  a  mark  of  confidence  and  approval, 
sometimes  sat  beside  him  at  the  Chatelet, 
where  he  administered  justice.  But  the  great 
work  of  Boileau  was  his  compilation,  about 
1268,  of  the  Livre  des  Mitiers,  a  code  of  the 
regulations  aflecting  the  various  industries  of 
Paris.  The  exordium  states  the  intention  of 
the  compiler,  to  treat  of  (1)  the  trades 
of  Paris,  their  ordinances  and  the  breaches 
thereof,  with  the  apjiropriate  fines  ;  (2)  fees, 
tolls,  taxes,  and  dues  ;  (3)  justice  and  jurisdic- 
tions in  Paris  and  the  neighbourhood.  The 
third  part  either  was  not  written  or  has  been 
lost. 

The  iQ- defined  privileges  claimed  by  the 
numerous  industrial  corporations  of  Paris  had 
become,  in  many  cases,  oppressive  and  en- 
croaching. Boileau  cited  before  his  tribunal 
representatives  of  the  separate  crafts  in  turn, 
inquired  into  the  grounds  of  their  privileges. 


162 


BOISGUILLEBERT— BONA  FIDE 


and  reduced  their  customs  to  vfriting  in  con- 
sistent order.  The  Begistres  so  formed  consti- 
tute a  highly  valuable  record  of  the  condition 
of  industrial  society  at  the  time,  and  exhibit 
the  whole  organisation  of  its  hierarchy — 
trade  privileges,  masters,  apprentices,  their 
number,  conduct,  terms  of  service,  holidays, 
quality  of  work  and  of  goods,  prices,  middle- 
men, fines,  dues,  etc.  This  compilation  has 
been  regarded  as  a  landmark  in  the  history  of 
economics.  Blanqui  devoted  to  it  a  chapter  of 
his  Histoire  de  VEcoTwmie  Politique  (t.  i.,  ch. 
xix.,  3me  ed.  1845),  in  which,  however,  he 
exaggerates  the  practical  influence  exercised  by 
Boileau's  book.  As  a  repertory  of  economic 
police  regulations  it  had,  no  doubt,  great 
administrative  utility.  But  its  place  is  rather 
in  the  economics  of  history  than  in  the  history 
of  economics. 

The  text  of  the  lAvre  des  Mitiers  was  published 
at  Paris  in  1837  under  the  title  of  Registres  des 
MStiers  et  Merchandises  de  la  ville  de  Paris,  4to, 
edited  by  G.  -B,  Dapping,  in  the  series  of  Docu- 
ments inidits  sur  V Histoire  de  France.  The  best 
edition  is  that  of  MM.  Lespinasse  and  Bonnardot, 
forming  part  of  the  Histoire  gSnirale  de  Paris,  of 
Baron  Haussman  (pub.  1886). 

[See  also  article  Boyleau,  by  Isambert  in  the 
Nouvelle  Biographie  Gin^ale,  Paris,  1855,  vii. 
194.]  H.  H. 

BOISGUILLEBEK.T,  alias  Boisguilbert, 
Pierre  le  Pesant  de,  born  at  Rouen,  1646, 
died  in  the  same  city,  1714.  Few  details  of  his 
life  are  known.  He  purchased,  in  1690,  a 
judicial  office  in  the  city  where  he  was  born. 
An  economist  and  precursor  of  the  Physiocrats, 
extremely  energetic  and  persevering  by  nature, 
he  laid  bare,  with  courage  and  much  practical 
good  sense,  the  economic  defects  in  the  system 
which  prevailed  up  to  1789.  He  attacked  Col- 
bert with  warmth,  and  not  without  reason,  for 
having  put  agriculture  on  one  side,  and  shackled 
the  trade  of  corn.  He  proposed  to  Pontchar- 
train,  Chamillart,  and  Desmarets  in  succes- 
sion reforms  which  are  recognised  as  useful  in 
our  days,  but  he  was  not  listened  to,  and  was 
even  exiled  to  Auvei^e  for  his  publications. 
His  two  principal  works,  Le  DUail  de  la  France 
(1695  or  1697),  and  Le  Factum  de  la  France 
(1707),  are  valuable  from  the  evidence  they 
supply  as  to  the  real  economic  condition  of  France 
during  the  most  fatal  part,  the  last  thirty 
years,  of  the  reign  of  Louis  XIV.  His  complete 
works,  omitting  those  of  a  purely  literary  char- 
acter, appeared  in  1707  (2  vols,  in  12mo),  under 
the  generic  title  of  B6tail  de  la  France  ;  in  the 
same  year  another  edition,  which  appears  to 
have  appeared  without  the  author's  consent,  was 
published  in  2  vols,  in  12mo,  described  as  the 
Testament  politique  de  M.  de  Vauhan.  Both  of 
these  are  without  the  name  of  the  author.  These 
same  works,  omitting  the  Trait6  du  mirite  et  des 
lumieres  des  grandn  financiers,  form  part  of  the 
Collection   Guillaumin  {Eccmomistes  finxmciers 


du  XVIIL  Sikle),  with  a  preface  and  notes  by 
M.  Eug.  Daire.  All  these  works  deserve  to  be 
read  even  in  our  days.  A.  c.  f. 

BOLLES,  John  A.,  lawyer  (bom  in  Con- 
necticut, 1809  ;  died  in  "Washington,  1878) ;  he 
wrote  A  Treatise  on  Usury  and  Usury  Laws, 
Boston,  1837,  pp.  75,  to  show  the  mischief  of 
the  usury  laws  which  generally  prevailed  in  the 
United  States  at  that  time.  The  treatise  con- 
tains a  history  and  discussion  of  principles  ; 
the  author  expresses  the  fear  that  his  argument 
will  be  regarded  with  prejudice  and  ill-will. 

D.  R.  D. 

BOLLMAN,  Justus  Erick,  M.D.  (born  in 
Hanover,  1764).  He  took  part  in  the  French 
Revolution  ;  was  imprisoned  in  Austria,  and 
became  noted  for  his  attempt  to  liberate 
Lafayette,  also  in  prison  in  the  same  country. 
He  afterwards  emigrated  to  the  United  States, 
and  became  implicated  in  Aaron  Burr's  con- 
spiracy. He  remained  in  the  United  States 
for  some  years,  then  went  to  London,  and 
died  in  the  West  Indies  in  1821.  While  in 
the  United  States,  in  1810,  he  wrote  Para- 
graphs on  Panics  and  Banking,  Philadelphia, 
(pp.  122  ;  2d  ed.,  1881).  In  this  he  defended 
the  Unitjed  States  Bank  as -a  powerful  agent 
for  strengthening  the  government,  cementing 
the  union,  and  useful  in  diminishing  and 
augmenting  the  circulating  medium  according 
to  public  necessities.  The  pamphlet  is  typical 
as  illustrating  the  acrimony  of  the  bank  dis- 
cussion. In  1 8 1 6  he  wrote  Plan  of  an  Improved 
System  of  the  Money  Con^rns  of  the  Union, 
Philadelphia  (pp.  62);  in  which  he  again  de- 
monstrates the  superiority  of  bank  money  to 
treasury  notes  ;  also  Strictures  on  the  Theories  of 
Mr.  Ricardo.  The  history  of  the  greater  por- 
tion of  his  life  is  narrated  in  Justus  Erick  Boll- 
man;  Ein  Leben^bild  aus  zwei  Welttheilen, 
by  Friedrich  Kapp,  Berlin,  1880  (pp.  439). 

D.  R.D. 

BON.  A  French  word  signifying  a  written 
authority  to  pay  a  certain  sum  of  money,  or  to 
deliver  a  certain  object  or  a  certain  quantity  of 
goods  for  account  of  the  person  signing  the 
authority.  This  is  implied  by  the  use  of  the 
words  ^'Bonpour" — (e.g.  Bon  pour  irs.  1000  ;  hc/x 
pour  pain,  etc.)  Such  authorities,  when  issued 
by  government  officials  on  the  national  treasury, 
are  called  "  Bons  sur  le  Trisor."  e.  s. 

BONA  FIDE.  Literally  in  good  faith  ;  the 
words  are  frequently  used  in  connection  with  a 
substantive  when  their  proper  meaning  is 
"genuine."  A  "  bonS,  fide  traveller  "  is  a  man 
who  is  a  genuine  traveller  ;  a  "  bon^  fide  pur- 
chaser "  is  a  genuine  purchaser — not  a  person  to 
whom  a  gift  has  been  made  in  the  form  of  a, 
sale.  The  phrase  "bona  fide  holder  for  value 
without  notice "  is  used  in  connection  with 
negotiable  instruments.  The  Bill  of  Exchange 
Act  has  by  §  29  substituted  the  shorter  form 
"holder  in  due  course."  e.  s. 


BONA  NOTABILIA— BONDED  WAREHOUSES 


163 


BONA  NOTABILIA.  Formerly,  if  a  deceased 
person  at  the  time  of  his  death  left  effects  of 
such  an  amount  as  to  be  considered  "notable 
goods  "  (fixed  by  the  93d  canon  of  1603  at  £5), 
within  a  diocese  other  than  that  in  which  he 
died,  the  will  was  required  to  be  proved  or 
letters  of  administration  taken  out  before  the 
metropolitan  of  the  province,  and  not  before 
the  ordinary  of  the  diocese.  The  transfer  of 
jurisdiction  over  wills  to  the  court  of  probate 
by  the  20  &  21  Vict.  c.  77  has  abolished  the 
legal  importance  of  bona  notahilia. 

{The  Lmo  of  Executors  and  Administrators,  by 
E.  L.  V.  Williams  and  W.  V.  V.  Williams,  p.  292, 
8th  ed.,  London,  1879. — Bona  Notahilia,  by  G. 
Lawton,  London,  1825.]  j.  e.  c.  m. 

BONA  VACANTIA.  The  term  applied  in 
Roman  law  to  the  property  of  a  deceased  person 
which,  if  not  claimed  by  the  legal  or  equitable 
heir,  went  to  the  state,  or  in  some  cases  to  the 
municipality,  or  to  the  curia,  or  to  the  corpora- 
tion of  which  the  deceased  was  a  member  (see 
Hunter's  Roman  Law,  p.  865).  In  English 
law  the  term  is  sometimes  applied  to  things 
found  without  an  apparent  owner. 

[Stephen's  Commentaries,  bk.  iv.  oh.  vii.] 

J.  E.  C.  M. 

BONCERF,  Pierre -Francois,  a  French 
publicist,  born  about  1745  at  Ohasaulx,  was 
employed  by  Turcot,  and  published  with  his 
consent,  under  the  assumed  name  of  "Fran- 
caleu "  a  pamphlet :  Les  inconvinienis  des 
droits  feodaux,  1776.  In  this  he  insists  upon 
the  freedom  of  landed  property  from  any  feudal 
impositions,  and  hopes  the  king  will  abolish 
them.  But  the  author  was  discovered  ;  the 
pamphlet  was  condemned  by  the  parliament  to 
be  publicly  burnt  23rd  February  1776,  and 
Boncerf  himself  was  saved  only  by  the  king's 
intervention  from  being  prosecuted.  After  the 
downfall  of  Turgot,  Boncerf  retired  to  Normandy 
and  devoted  himself  to  agricultural  pursuits. 
He  was  secretary  to  the  Duke  of  Orleans  when 
the  Revolution  began  ;  he  was  appointed  a  judge 
in  1790,  but  his  sincerity  led  to  his  being 
brought  before  the  revolutionary  tribunal,  and 
he  escaped  being  condemned  to  death  only  by 
one  vote.  In  consequence  of  these  persecutions 
he  died  in  1794.  In  1789  he  had  written 
De  la  N4cessit6  et  des  Moyens  d'oecuper 
avantageusement  totes  les  gros  ouvriers.  The 
first  creditors  of  the  nation,  he  says,  are  the 
hands,  which  demand  work  and  the  soil  that 
waits  for  the  labour  of  the  hands  (p.  14). 
Boncerf  proposes  to  give  work  to  the  labourers, 
for  "  everybody  has  a  right  to  subsist,  but  this 
right  supposes  a  duty — labour  "  (p.  59). 

Boncerf' s  other  writings  are  enumerated  in  the 
Nouvelle  Biographic,  t.  vi.  p.  554. — see  L.  de 
liavergne,  Les  Econoraistes  francais  du  18g  siecle, 
1870,  p.  195.  s.  B. 

BOND.  Legal  term  for  a  deed  by  which  a 
person  (called  the  "obligoi  ")  declares  himself 


bound  to  another  (called  the  ''obligee")  to 
pay  a  certain  sum  unless  he  performs  an  obliga- 
tion  specified  in  the  same  instrument  by  a  clause 
called  "  the  condition  of  the  bond."  Bonds  are 
generally  used  when  security  is  to  be  given  to 
a  public  authority  (bail  bonds,  security  to  keep 
the  peace,  security  for  costs  in  actions,  etc.), 
and  Contracts  of  Guarantee  are  frequently 
made  out  in  that  form,  but  instruments 
embodying  mercantile  contracts  do  not,  as 
a  general  rule,  assume  the  form  of  bonds. 
The  word  is  also  used  for  certain  stock  exchange 
securities,  and  in  that  sense  is  equivalent  to 
"debenture"  or  "obligation,  "meaning  a  promise 
to  repay  a  sum  borrowed  by  the  public  authority 
or  company  who  issues  the  security  (with  or 
without  an  additional  premium),  on  a  fixed  date 
or  on  a  date  depending  on  the  operation  of  a 
sinking  fund  {i.e.  an  annual  sum  to  be  applied 
in  the  purchase  of  bonds  or  in  the  compulsory 
redemption  of  some  particular  bonds,  to  be  de- 
termined by  ballot),  and  to  pay  interest  at  a 
certain  rate  on  certain  dates  up  to  the  time  of 
repayment.  Bonds  are  sometimes  secured  by  a 
charge  on  special  property  (see  also  Lloyd's 
Bonds).  e.  s. 

BOND  OF  CAUTION  (Scots  law  term). 
See  Caution. 

BOND  OF  CORROBORATION  (Scots  law). 
Bond  given  as  further  security. 

BOND  AND  DISPOSITION  IN  SECURITY. 
Scotch  equivalent  to  mortgage. 

BOND  OF  RELIEF  (Scots  law  term).  Bond 
of  indemnity  given  to  a  surety. 

BONDED  WAREHOUSES.  Warehouses  in 
which  articles  are  lodged  under  bond  for  the 
payment  of  any  revenue  duties  chargeable 
thereon. 

The  payment  of  duties  on  taxable  commodi- 
ties  at  the  time  of  importation  or  manufacture 
tends  to  increase  the  price  paid  for  them  by  the 
consumer  over  and  above  that  which  the  im- 
porter or  manufacturer  can  afford  to  take,  if  the 
payment  be  deferred  until  the  commodities  are 
about  to  be  taken  into  consumption.  Interest 
on  the  money  advanced  must  be  charged,  and 
the  quantities  on  which  the  duty  is  paid  will 
usually  be  in  excess  of  those  available  for  con- 
sumption, when  allowance  has  been  made  for 
the  waste  arising  from  natural  causes,  and  the 
various  operations  which  the  commodities  under- 
go. Inasmuch  also  as  a  drawback  of  duty  is 
ordinarily  allowed  on  exportation,  the  payment 
of  duty  before  the  ultimate  destination  of  the 
taxed  commodities  is  known,  involves  an  un- 
necessary expenditure  of  time  and  money  in 
the  case  of  goods  intended  for  a  foreign  market, 
or  of  goods  received  for  transhipment  merely. 
To  prevent  these  disadvantages,  and  at  the 
same  time  to  safeguard  the  revenue  effectually, 
Sir-R.  Walpole,  Turgot,  and  Adam  Smith 
proposed  at  various  times  that  warehouses  should 
be  established,  either  directly  by  the  state,  or 


164 


BONNET— BOOK-KEEPING 


by  pri^rate  enterprise  under  state  sanction,  in 
which  taxed  commodities  might  be  stored  until 
required  for  delivery  for  home  consumption,  in 
which  case  the  duty  would  then  be  paid,  or 
until  the  goods  were  exported  and  transhipped, 
in  which  case  they  would  be  delivered  free  of 
duty.  It  was  not,  however,  until  1848,  when 
spirits  intended  for  home  consumption  were 
allowed  to  be  warehoused  throughout  the  United 
Kingdom,  that  the  system  can  be  said  to  have 
been  established  in  this  country  on  a  basis  suffi- 
ciently wide  to  meet  the  legitimate  requirements 
of  trade.  Between  the  years  1848  and  1880 
the  number  of  bonded  warehouses  was  permitted 
to  increase  at  a  very  rapid  rate,  and  in  the  latter 
year  it  became  evident  that  the  cost  of  the 
supervising  staff  was  in  excess  of  the  expenditure 
requisite  for  the  benefit  of  the  community  as  a 
whole.  A  committee  of  inquiry  was  accordingly 
appointed  by  Mr.  Gladstone,  the  result  of  which 
has  been  to  effect  a  considerable  economy  under 
this  head,  whilst  the  substantial  advantages  of 
the  system  are  fully  maintained. 

In  order  to  prevent  the  payment  of  duty  on 
quantities  in  excess  of  the  actual  deliveries  for 
consumption,  certain  specific  allowances  from 
tlie  quantities  warehoused  are  granted  in  respect 
of  the  natural  waste  arising  from  leakage  or 
evaporation,  and  for  the  loss  arising  from  pro- 
cesses to  which  the  commodities  are  allowed  to 
be  subjected  whilst  still  in  warehouse.  These 
comprise  the  repacking  and  mixing  of  tea,  the 
racking,  vatting,  mixing,  and  bottling  of  wines 
and  spirits,  the  roasting  of  coffee,  and  the 
manufacture  of  certain  descriptions  of  tobacco, 
and  of  certain  preparations  of  that  article  for 
farm  and  horticultural  purposes. 

The  following  table  shows  the  quantities  of  the 
principal  articles  imported,  in  bonded  warehouses 
in  the  United  Kingdom  on  the  31st  December  1912 : 

Cocoa,  Raw 20,308,000  lbs. 

Coffee 18,480,000    „ 

Dried  Fruits,  Currants  and  Raisins    53,312,000    ,, 
Spirits  (Foreign)     ....      8,935,000  prf.  galls. 

Tea 138,492,000  lbs. 

Tobacco 213,129,000    „ 

Wine 4,876,000  galls. 

Sugar 385,616,000  lbs. 

Besides  the  above,  there  is  always  a  large  quantity 
of  home-made  spirits  in  bond.  On  the  31st  March 
1913,  146,825,000  prf.  gallons.  t.  h.  e. 

BONNET,  Victor,  born  1814,  died  1889. 
A  financial  publicist,  he  became  a  counsellor  of 
state  and  a  member  of  the  Institute.  He 
wrote  in  the  Revue  des  DeiiM  Mondes  from  1860 
to  1884,  in  favour  of  the  monopoly  of  a  bank 
of  circulation,  a  single  standard  (gold),  indirect 
taxation,  and  a  reduction  of  the  expenses  of  the 
budget.  His  numerous  articles  in  reviews  and 
similar  works  have  been  the  basis  of  the  follow- 
ing publications.  Questions  dconomiques  et  fin- 
ancier es  di  propos  des  crises,  Paris,  1859,  in  8vo. 
— La  liberty  des  hanques  d' imission  et  le  taux  de 
VmUrU,  Paris,  1864,  in  8vo. — Le  credit  et  les 


finances,  Paris,  1865,  in  8vo, — Etudes  d'icon- 
omie  politique  et  financidre,  Paris,  1868,  in 
8vo. — Etudes  sur  la  monnaie,  Paris,  1870,  in 
8vo. — Le  credit  et  les  banques  d' Amission,  Paris, 
1875. — La  question  des  imp6ts,  Paris,  1879. 

A.  c.  f. 

BONORUM  POSSESSIO.  The  Roman  law 
of  inheritance,  as  derived  from  the  xii.  tables, 
was  full  of  hardships  and  technicalities,  and 
frequently  caused  inheritances  to  be  forfeited  to 
the  state.  To  mitigate  these  evils  the  praetors 
introduced  the  "  bonorum  possessio,"  which  con- 
ferred on  the  persons  designated  by  them  all 
the  practical  advantages  of  heirship,  though 
they  were  not  heirs  in  the  strict  sense.  As, 
after  the  lapse  of  a  year,  the  bonorum  possessor 
acquired  an  indefeasible  title,  and  in  the  mean- 
time was  protected  by  the  equitable  jurisdiction 
of  the  prsetors,  the  difference  was  not  import- 
ant. The  practical  result  of  this  procedure 
was  that  the  formalities  of  testaments  were 
relaxed,  the  law  of  intestate  succession  was 
made  more  humane  and  just,  and  various  other 
reforms  were  introduced.  The  praetorian 
system  of  intestate  succession  was  in  its  main 
principles  embodied  in  the  rules  laid  down  by 
Justinian,  which,  with  slight  modifications, 
have  been  introduced  in  most  European 
countries.  e.  s. 

BONUS.  A  bonus  on  shares  is  sometimes 
paid  to  proprietors  as  supplementary  to  the 
regular  dividend,  and  is  generally  derived  from 
undivided  profits  of  former  years,  or  from 
profits  derived  from  exceptional  transactions. 
It  is  often  a  difficult  question  to  decide  whether 
a  bonus  on  shares  belongs  to  a  person  having  a 
life-interest,  or  whether  it  ought  to  be  paid  to 
the  person  ultimately  entitled  to  the  shares. 
Elaborate  rules  on  this  subject  are  laid  down 
by  the  House  of  Lords.  Bouch  v.  Sproule, 
Law  Reports,  12  Appeal  Cases,  385.  The 
word  bonus  is  also  used  by  insurance  companies 
to  denote  the  additions  made  to  the  amounts 
of  life  policies  at  stated  periods  from  accumu- 
lated profits  reserved  for  the  policy-holders. 

A.  E. 

BOOK  ACCOUNT  CREDIT.  As  nearly  all 
the  large  transactions  of  business  in  most  civil- 
ised countries,  and  an  increasing  proportion  of 
the  smaller  ones,  are  now  settled  through  pay- 
ment by  cheque,  the  circulation  consists  to  a 
gi'eat  extent  of  entries  in  the  books  of  bankers 
and  traders,  and  the  importance  of  these  trans- 
actions is  proportionally  great.  Credit  is  usually 
afforded  through  book -entry,  the  privilege  of 
employing  the  capital  of  others  being  thus 
given  in  the  manner  most  convenient  to  those 
who  require  the  use  of  it. 

BOOK-KEEPING,  or  the  art  of  keeping  ac- 
counts, has  for  its  object  a  systematic  record  of 
transactions  in  money  or  in  money's  worth, 
designed  to  show  the  financial  position  of  indi- 
viduals (included  in  this  term  "individuals" 


BOOK-KEEPING 


165 


are  all  mercantile  and  other  associations),  both 
as  regards  themselves,  and  also  in  relation  to 
others. 

This  object  is  carried  into  practice  in  all 
tliorough  systems  of  book-keeping  on  the  lines 
of  an  unvarying  principle  called  book-keeping 
by  double  entry,  and  which  may  be  described 
as  follows  :  There  are  two  aspects  in  every  trans- 
action, as  regards  the  person  recording,  which 
must  be  taken  account  of — its  m-ujin  and  des- 
tination ;  in  some  cases  the  terms  cause  and 
effect  would  be  more  applicable.  This  "taking 
accoimt  of"  involves  keeping  an  account  in 
these  two  aspects.  Now  an  account  may  be 
affected  in  two  ways,  there  is  the  debit  side  and 
the  credit  side  ;  a  transaction  may  be  chargeable 
against  an  account,  i.e.  be  placed  on  the  debit 
side,  or  it  may  be  to  the  credit  of  an  account, 
i.e.  be  placed  on  the  credit  side  ;  for  example, 
money  received  must  be  placed  to  the  credit  of 
an  account  in  respect  of  its  origin — the  som-ce 
from  which  it  comes  ;  and  it  must  also  be  placed 
to  the  debit  of  an  account  in  respect  of  its  des- 
tination— the  till,  the  cash-box,  the  bank,  as 
the  case  may  be,  of  the  receiver.  It  will  be 
seen  that  these  two  accounts  are  affected  by 
this  transaction  in  opposite  directions.  This 
rule  invariably  holds  in  every  transaction.  If 
in  the  one  aspect  it  has  to  be  placed  to  the 
credit  of  an  account,  in  the  other  aspect  it  will 
have  to  be  placed  to  the  debit,  and  vice  versa. 
Thus,  in  the  record  of  any  number  of  transac- 
tions the  sum  of  the  aggi-egate  of  the  entries  to 
the  debit  of  the  various  accounts  will  equal  the 
sum  of  the  aggi-egate  of  the  entries  to  the  credit 
of  the  various  accounts  ;  and  again,  if  only  the 
balance  between  the  debit  and  credit  entries  on 
each  account  be  dealt  with,  the  sum  of  the 
balances  to  the  debit  will  equal  the  sum  of  the 
balances  to  the  credit ;  but,  as  these  balances 
are  the  combined  outcome  of  the  cause  and 
efifect  of  each  and  every  transaction,  they  will 
represent  the  net  result  of  the  whole  of  the 
transactions  recorded,  and  may  be  arranged  so 
as  to  show  not  only  the  altered  financial  position 
brought  about  by  these  transactions,  but  also 
the  various  causes  by  means  of  which  this  result 
was  obtained. 

The  methods  used  to  carry  out  this  principle 
vary  with  the  nature  and  circumstances  of  the 
transactions,  with  questions  of  convenience,  of 
detail,  and  with  many  other  considerations. 

The  primary  record  of  transactions  is  made 
in  a  book  called  the  Day  Book  or  journal. 

The  accounts  of  those  transactions  which  are 
derived  from  this  record  are  kept  in  a  book 
called  the  Ledger. 

A  simple  record  of  transactions  as  they  occur 
seriatim  would  give  a  Day  Book  in  its  crude 
form.  Applying  method  to  such  a  record,  the 
entries  at  once  fall  into  natural  gi'oups  ;  those 
relating  to  money  received  or  paid  may  form  a 
Day  Book  by  themselves  ;  such  a  Day  Book  is 


called  the  Cash  Book.  Those  relating  to  sales 
of  goods  may  form  a  Sold  or  Sales  Day  Book  ; 
and  again,  records  of  purchases  may  form  a 
Bought  or  Purchases  Day  Book,  others,  a  Bill 
Book,  and  so  on,  with  any  variety  of  subdivi- 
sions desirable,  but  all  springing  from,  and 
forming  part  of,  the  original  Day  Book. 

In  the  same  manner,  the  Ledger  may  be  sub- 
divided to  suit  convenience,  such  subdivisions 
being  called  by  explanatory  names,  such  as  Sold 
Ledger,  Bought  Ledger,  Loan  Ledger,  Private 
Ledger,  etc. 

Thus  it  will  be  seen  that  the  Day  Book,  with 
its  subdivisions,  contains  the  materials  from 
which  tlie  edifice,  the  Ledger,  is  built  up. 

The  best  systems  of  book-keeping  are  based 
on  the  application  of  the  principle  of  double 
entry.  Book-keeping  by  single  entry  would  be 
better  described  as  incomplete  double  entry  ; 
there  is  no  practical  system  to  which  the  term 
of  single  entry  could  be  rightly  applied.  If  a 
person  takes  stock  of  his  assets  and  liabilities, 
and  compares  it  with  the  stock  taken  at  some 
previous  date,  he  arrives  at  what  may  be  termed 
a  single  entry  balance  sheet.  He  has  before 
him  the  result  at  two  diflerent  dates,  and,  by 
inference,  can  argue  that,  as  his  property  has 
increased  or  decreased,  such  an  alteration  must 
have  been  caused  by  his  having  made  so  much 
I)rofit  or  loss  ;  but  should  he  have  made  an 
error  in  taking  stock  of  his  })roperty,  such  infer- 
ence would  be  in  error  also  ;  whereas  by  double 
entry,  the  steps  by  which  such  increase  or  de- 
crease in  his  pro})erty  was  arrived  at  would  be 
shown,  and  the  result  would  be  open  to  demon- 
stration and  proof. 

Skill  in  book-keepmg  consists,  not  in  forcing 
the  record  of  transaction  through  any  particular 
system,  but  in  devising  and  selecting  the 
methods  best  adapted  to  the  general  nature  of 
the  transactions  to  be  recorded. 

The  omission  of  the  keeping  of  proper  business 
account  books  is  regarded  as  misconduct  under 
the  bankruptcy  law  of  this  country  (see  Bank- 
ruptcy Law).  It  is  also  punishable  under  the 
French  commercial  code.  Though  good  book- 
keeping will  not  save  an  unsound  business  from 
ruin,  it  may  be  regarded  as  one  of  the  principal 
corner  stones  in  the  edifice  of  commercial  pros- 
perity (see  Balance  Sheet). 

[Among  many  books  on  this  subject  may  bo 
mentioned,  Book-keeping,  Hamilton  &  Ball,  1882. 
—Double  Entry  Elucidated,  B.  F.  Foster,  1881.] 

J.  p. 

A  new  method  of  book-keeping  now  used  in 
Italy,  whence  many  improvements  in  this  art 
have  already  proceeded,  is  Logismography  (from 
\oyi(Tfi6$  and  ypd4)eLv)  a  system  of  keeping  ac- 
counts, based  on  double  entry,  for  which  it  is 
claimed  that  it  is  capable  of  a  far  more  general 
application  than  any  other  as  yet  known,  and 
can  be  applied  equally  to  the  domestic  and 
commercial   affairs  of  private   individuals,   to 


166 


BOOK-KEEPING 


I 


the  business  of  commercial  and  industrial 
societies,  or  to  the  budget  and  the  accounts 
of  the  state.  Logismography,  invented  by 
Giuseppe  Cerboni,  director  of  the  department 
for  government  accounts  in  Italy,  is  taught  in 
all  the  technical  schools  of  the  kingdoip.  and  in 
the  three  superior  schools  of  commerce  in  Venice, 
Genoa,  and  Bari.  It  is  applied  in  all  the 
central  departments  of  the  state ;  besides  a 
number  of  local  departments  {e.g.  the  provincial 
administration  of  Parma  and  the  municipality 
of  Reggio- Emilia)  and  of  private  societies  {e.g. 
the  popular  bank  of  Parma  and  the  "Omnibus" 
company  of  Florence).  Logismography  claims 
to  be  superior  to  any  other  method  in  the  exact- 
ness and  celerity  of  registration  of  the  transac- 
tions recorded,  and  shows  nearly  automaticaUy 
any  error  which  may  have  taken  place.  It 
consists  of  four  instruments  called — 
The  Day-Book.  I  The  Table  of  Accounts. 
The  Developments.  |  The  First  Draught. 

The  day-book  is  an  account  book  kept  on 
two  pages :  on  the  first  are  three  columns,  of 
which  the  first  serves  for  the  progressive  number 
every  transaction  receives,  the  second  one  for 
the  description  of  every  transaction,  the  third 
one  for  the  amount  of  every  transaction  in 
double  entry ;  on  the  second  (opposite)  page 
there  are  two  accounts  in  simple  columns,  ae 
in  the  day-ledger  book  in  the  American  system 
(see  Fig.  I.)  The  first  of  these  accounts  has 
the  heading.  Owner  of  the  business,  and  has 
the  cypher  A  ;  the  second  one  has  the  heading. 
Consignees  and  Correspondents,  and  has  the 
cypher  B.  At  the  end  of  these  two  accounts 
(to  the  right)  is  situated  a  column  headed 
Compensations  and  Fermutations. 

The  two  accounts  A  and  B  must  always 
balance  each  other,  because  the  debit  and  credit 
of  the  one  must  always  be  equal  for  every  single 
transaction,  and  their  total  sum  must  be  equal 
to  the  debit  and  credit  of  the  other  one.  On 
the  credit  side  of  A  are  inserted  the  sums 
representing  the  capital  of  the  owner,  and  every 
increment  it  receives  (gains,  profits) :  on  the 
debit  side  of  B  are  registered  the  diminutions 
of  the  capital  (losses,  expenses,  consumption). 
Sums  indicating  transactions  giving  no  loss  or 
gain, — buying  or  selling  for  ready  money,  ex- 
changes, paying  of  Ijills  of  exchange, — are 
inscribed  in  the  last  column  headed  compensa- 
tions and  permutations,  and  are  then  transferred 
to  the  book  described  as  developments  (of  B). 
The  accounts  of  the  day-book  show  at  every 
moment  the  net  capital  of  the  owner  ;  for  this 
purpose  the  amounts  have  only  to  be  totalled, 
and  the  debit  subtracted  from  the  credit  in 
each  account. 

The  second  instrument,  called  Developments, 
consists  of  columns  for  the  division  and  classifi- 
cation of  the  sums  registered  in  the  day-book. 
The  first  Development  has  the  cypher  A,  and  is 
called  Account  of  the  Owner.     It  consists  (1)  of 


a  column  for  the  progressive  number  of  every 
transaction  ;  (2)  of  two  columns  called  Equiva- 
lence Columns,  because  they  are  the  reproduction 
of  the  account  A  of  the  day-book  and  contain 
the  same  sums  it  contains  ;  (3)  of  a  column 
called  Fermutations,  and,  lastly,  of  a  number 
of  accounts — generally  ten  or  twelve — in  simple 
columns,  which  analyse  the  account  A  (see 
Fig.  II.)  The  sums  inscribed  in  the  credit 
column  of  the  account  of  equivalences  A  must 
be  retranscribed  in  one,  or  in  several  columns 
— after  due  subdivision — of  the  Analytical 
Accounts,  viz.  the  series  of  accounts  in  simple 
columns  following  (to  the  right)  upon  the  equi- 
valence columns.  The  sums  registered  in  the 
column  of  Fermutations  must  be  registered  on 
both  the  credit  and  the  debit  side  of  the  Arui- 
lytical  Accoumis. 

The  second  Development  has  the  cypher  B,  and 
is  called,  "Account  of  the  Consignees  and 
Correspondents,"  and  is  disposed  of  in  the 
same  manner  as  the  former  development  (see 
Fig.  III.) 

These  developments  (first  and  second)  are 
called  developments  of  first  degree.  Develop- 
ments can  be  added  of  second,  third,  etc., 
degree.  For  example,  in  the  B  development 
(Fig.  Ilf.)  there  are  the  accounts  for  cash,  for 
storehouse  or  magazine,  for  debtors,  etc.,  which 
can  be  sub-developed.  Supposing  the  account 
"storehouse"  to  be  sub-developed,  it  would 
have  the  cypher  Bl,  which  would  be  repeated 
on  a  sub-development  for  storehouse,  and  might 
contain,  say,  the  accounts  cloth,  cotton,  silk  ; 
and  if  "cloth"  were  to  be  subdivided  again, 
it  would  have  the  cypher  Bla,  and  so  on. 

The  completion  of  all  the  developments  is  the 
ledger. 

The  account  which  is  sub-developed  must 
always  be  repeated  at  the  beginning  of  the 
sub-development,  so  that  all  the  accounts  are 
closely  connected  with  each  other.  The  ledger 
can  be  divided  in  two  volumes  :  Developments 
A  and  Developments  B. 

The  Table  of  Accov/nts  is  a  statement  which 
contains  the  index  of  all  the  accounts,  disposed 
in  such  a  fashion  as  to  show  how  they  are 
placed  in  the  accounts  of  the  single  develop- 
ments, and  how  a  development  of  a  certain 
degree  depends  on  the  development  of  superior 
degree  (see  Fig.  lY.)  The  Table  is  the  instru- 
ment by  which  an  account  is  opened  and 
headed,  and  the  first  draught  is  shaped,  and 
shows  the  ramification  of  all  the  transactions. 
A  First  Draught  is  a  paper  on  which  a  transac- 
tion is  described  with  an  indication  of  the 
developments,  and  the  columns  in  which  it  has 
to  be  received. 

Every  transaction  has  its  first  draught  (see 
Fig.  V.) 

Logismography  renders  a  minute  division  of 
labour  possible  in  the  formation  of  first  draughts, 
or  in  the  registration  in  the  day-book,  and  iu 


BOOK-KEEPING— BOOK  OF  KATES 


167 


the  different  volumes  of 
developments.  Every 
registration  runs  in  a 
horizontal  line.  By  the 
first  draught  the  capital 
is  registered  in  the  day- 
book, and  credit  or  debit 
modifications  in  the  de- 
velopments. 

The  ascertaining  the 
correctness  of  accounts 
is  simple  and  rapid ;  the 
sums  must  be  added  in 
all  the  accounts,  and 
the  balance  is  registered 
in  the  usual  way.  In 
every  development,  therefore,  the  addition  of 
all  the  debit  balances  and  all  the  credit  balances 
must  be  made,  and  the  smaller  of  these  sums  is 
written  down  in  tlie  column  of  compensations, 
whilst  the  difference  is  registered  in  the  first 
account  (of  equivalences)  of  the  development. 
To  close  the  accounts  one  must  begin  by  the 
developments  of  highest  degree  and  go  back  to 
those  of  first  degree,  and  last  to  the  day-book. 
The  day-book  for  the  accounts  of  the  State  is 
more  complicated^  and  has  more  accounts  in  it 
than  the  one  described  ;  but  the  form  of  the 
developments  and  their  arrangement  is  the 
same.     In  accounts  concerning  the  finances  of 


Fig. 

III.- 

—Developments  B. 

Accounts  of  Consignees  and  Correspondents, 

1 

2 
P 

1 

B. 

11 

w 

4 

Cashier. 

storehouse. 

Debtors. 

Creditors. 

Debit. 
2 

Credit. 

a 

Debit. 

Credit. 
6 

Debit. 

7 

Credit. 
8 

Debit. 
9 

Credit. 
10 

Debit.  Credit. 
11     1     12 

1 
2 
3 
4 

5 

10 

•• 

4 

SO 
50 

15 

io 

50 
8 

'4 

25 

•• 

;; 

30 
40 

IS 

4 
14 

70 

15 

10 
5 

58 

•• 

4 

54 

25 

25 

..     1     70 

18 

18         150 

15 

15 

58 

58 

25 

25 

70    1     70 

LOGISMOGRAPHY  : 
TRATIONS, 


Type  or  Form  of  Regis- 
wiTH  AN  Example. 


Fig.  I. 

— Logismographic  Day-Bool 

Consignees 

CO     ' 

Owner. 

and  Corre- 

to 

Transac- 
tions. 

0 
S 

A. 

spondents. 
B. 

|s.o 
3^^ 

Q 

< 

^-^^ 

Debit. 

Credit. 

Debit. 

Credit. 

Ph   cS 

1 

2 

3 

4 

5 

6 

' 

8 

1 

Capital  . 

40 

10 

10 

SOB 

2 

Purchase 

50 

50  B 

3 

Profits   . 

S 

8 

8 

4 

Losses    . 

4 

4 

•• 

4 

4 

IS 

IS 

4 

SO 

5 

Saldo      . 

92 

14 

•• 

14 

IS 

194 

18 

18 

IS 

18 

158 

Fig.  lY.— Table  of  Accounts. 

Day 
Book. 

First  Draughts  Column 
Transactions . 
Amounts 

Owner   .... 

Consignees    . 
Permutations 

.        .        1 

2 
3 
/debit     4\ 
\  credit    5/ 
/debit     6\ 
\  credit    7/ 
8 

A 

B 

Develop- 
ments. 
A. 

First  Draughts  Column 
Equivalence  Account  . 
Permutations 
Capital  .... 

Profits   .... 

Losses    .... 

1 

/debit     2 
\  credit    3 

'/debit     5 
\  credit    6 
/debit     7 
1  credit    S 
/  debit     9 
\  credit  10 

Fig.  V.- 

First  Draught  No.  2. 

Bought  merchandise  for  £50,  of  which  10  paid 
and  40  still  owed. 

Day  Book. 

Column        3                £        50 
8                „        50 

Developments. 

Column        4                £        50 

6  „        10 

7  „        50 
12                „        40 

Fig. 

IL- 

-Developincnts  A. 

Accou 

nts  of 

Owner 

• 

"2 

?^ 

5.^ 

t 

q 

A. 

-2  S< 

Capital. 

Profits. 

Losses. 

Debit. 

Credit. 

1" 

Debit.!  Credit. 

Debit. 

Credit. 

Debit. 

Credit. 

1 

2 

3 

4 

5     1       6 

" 

8 

9 

10 

11 

12 

1 

10 

10 

3 

.. 

8 

8 

4 

4 

4 

4 

18 

10 

8 

4 

5 

14 

8 

14 

4 

8 

••, 

4 

18 

18 

8 

14          14 

8 

8 

4-|      4 

the  State,  logismography  receives  an  extension, 
and  has  an  importance  which  can  only  be  esti- 
mated by  financiers,  and  could  not  be  explained 
in  so  brief  a  description  as  this  must  necessarily 
be. 

[Bankers'  Magazine- 
June  1890.— For  de- 
scription  of  method,  No 
xvi.  of  the  Mamiah 
Hoepli  -  Logismografia, 
Teorica  ed  Applicazioni, 
by  Celestino  Chiesa,  Ul- 
rico  Hoepli,  Milan.  For 
large  works,  Trattato  di 
Ragionieria,  by  Gitti 
e  Massa,  Milan,  Troitato 
di  ContaUlita,  by  Mar- 
chesiui.  ]  Q.  K. 

BOOK  OF  RATES. 
Up  to  1558  Poundage 
was  levied  on  the  value 


168 


BOOM— BOSANQUET 


of  the  goods  as  sworn  by  the  merchant.  But 
in  the  year  mentioned  a  book  of  rates  was  pub- 
lished that  specified  the  values  at  which  goods 
of  different  sorts  were  to  be  valued  for  custom 
duties.  A  new  "book"  was  issued  by  Queen 
Elizabeth,  1586,  in  which  the  various  com- 
modities were  stated  in  alphabetical  ordef,  with 
their  values,  and  valued  according  to  the  real 
price.  James  I.,  after  the  decision  in  Bates's 
Case,  issued  a  "  book  of  rates  "  with  the  object 
not  merely  of  rectifying  values,  but  of  increas- 
ing the  impost.  A  new  book  was  subsequently 
issued  by  Charles  I.  with  the  object  "  of  better 
balancing  of  trade  in  relation  to  the  impositions 
in  foreign  parts  upon  the  native  commodities  of 
the  kingdom."  J.  E.  c.  M. 

[See  Dowell's  History  of  Taxation  and  Taxes  in 
England,  1889,  vol.  i.] 

BOOM.  A  slang  word,  which  originated  in 
the  United  States,  where  it  is  used  to  describe 
a  rise  of  prices  in  any  speculative  market,  accom- 
panied by  excitement  often  running  to  excess. 

A.  E. 

BOOTY.  Moveables  taken  from  the  enemy 
on  the  field  of  battle  or  in  storming  a  town. 
All  booty  belongs  to  the  state  in  whose  name 
and  by  whose  authority  it  is  made,  the  title 
becoming  complete  twenty -four  hours  after 
capture.  Modern  states  have  adopted  regula- 
tions by  which  the  whole  or  part  of  captured 
goods  or  their  proceeds  are  distributed  amongst 
those  concerned  in  the  capture.  By  the  3  &  4 
Vict.  c.  65,  §  22,  the  sovereign  may  refer  ques- 
tions of  booty  to  the  judge  of  the  prize  court, 
now  the  court  of  admiralty.  In  the  United 
States  the  president  has,  in  the  absence  of  any 
directions  given  by  Congress,  discretionary  power. 
[International  Law,  by  W.  E.  Hall,  Oxford,  1889.] 

J.  E.  0.  M. 

BOKNITZ,  Jacob,  was  born  (late  in  16th 
century)  at  Torgau  in  Saxony,  and  lived  after- 
wards at  Schweidnitz  in  Silesia  as  imperial  coun- 
cillor. He  appears  to  have  possessed  consider- 
able influence  with  the  Emperors  Rudolf  II. 
(1576-1612)  and  Matthias  (1612-1619).  He 
suffered  much  in  the  Thirty  Years'  War  from  the 
violence  of  the  soldiery,  who  robbed  him  of  his 
library.  His  economic  writings  are — (1)  De 
nummis  in  republica  percutiendis  et  conservandis, 
1608  ;  (2)  Aerariv/m,  seu  Tractatics  politicus  de 
aerario  sacro,  civili,  militari,  communi  et  sacra- 
tiori  .  .  .  conficiendo,  1612;  (3)  Tradatus  politi- 
cttsde  rerumsufficientia  in  republicaet  civitatepro- 
curanda,  1625.  In  the  last  of  these  he  professes 
to  give  the  results  of  observation  and  intercourse 
with  artificers  in  his  journeys  through  Holland, 
England,  France,  Italy,  and  Germany,  treating 
his  materials,  however,  not  from  the  technical, 
but  from  the  economic  point  of  view.  He  was 
the  first  who  did  for  Germany  what  Montchr:^- 
TIEN  de  Watteville  had  done  a  few  years  earlier 
(1615)  for  France,  namely,  attempted  to  set 
forth  with  systematic  completeness  the  economic 


knowledge  of  his  time,  which  he  illustrated  with 
much  learning,  though  of  a  somewhat  pedantic 
and  uncritical  kind,  and  with  many  facts  de- 
rived  from  his  own  experience.  He  takes,  saya 
RoscHER,  in  his  half-barbarous  period,  a  similar 
position  to  that  of  Rait  in  the  later  German 
economics.  On  the  theory  of  money  he  has 
much  that  is  sound  and  instructive  ;  he  strongly 
opposes  any  debasement  of  the  currency.  In 
the  spirit  of  the  Mercantile  System  he  favours 
extensive  and  even  minute  interference  with 
private  industry.  He  would  prohibit  the  ex- 
portation of  money,  and  would  prevent,  by 
means  of  Sumptuary  Laws,  the  introduction  of 
costly  foreign  wares,  whilst  he  would  encourage 
the  importation  of  raw  materials  (Roscher, 
Geseh.  der  Hat.  Oek.  in  .Deutschland,  p.  184). 

J.  K.  I. 

BOROUGH.  Originally  a  fortified  place,  now 
(1)  a  town  having  municipal  institutions  (see 
Corporation,  Municipal),  (2)  a  town  send- 
ing representatives  to  parliament.  As  a 
general  rule  a  municipal  borough  is  at  the  same 
time  also  a  parliamentary  borough,  but  the  area 
of  the  one  does  not  always  coincide  with  the 
area  of  the  other.  e.  s. 

BOROUGH  ENGLISH.  A  local  custom 
prevailing  in  some  boroughs  according  to  which 
lauds  witLin  the  borough  descend  to  the 
youngest  son.  e.  s. 

BOSANQUET,  Charles,  governor  of  the 
South  Sea  Company  and  an  eminent  London 
merchant,  was  born  in  1769  and  died  in  1850.  'M 
He  was  the  author  of  the  following  publica-  m 
tions :  (1)  A  Letter  on  the  proposition  sub- 
mitted  to  Government  for  taking  the  duty  on 
muscovado  sugar  ad  valorem,"  probably  written 
in  1806.  (2)  A  Letter  to  W.  Manning,  Esq., 
M.P.,  on  the  depreciation  of  West  Indian 
property,  probably  written  in  1807.  It  con- 
siders more  especially  the  trade  in  sugar  and 
rum,  as  affected  by  the  Navigation  Act  and 
other  of  our  commercial  regulations.  (3) 
Thoughts  on  the  value  to  Great  Britain  of 
Commerce  in  general,  and  of  the  Colonial 
Trade  in  particular  (1807).  This  pamphlet 
was  answered  by  "William  Spence  in  his  Badi- 
cal  cause  of  the  present  distress  of  the  West 
India  planters  pointed  out  (1807).  (4)  Prac- 
tical Observations  on  the  Beport  of  the  Bullion 
Committee  (1810). 

The  last  is  by  far  the  most  important  of 
Bosanquet's  writings.  The  author  uses  the 
term  "practical"  because  (he  tells  us)  it  is  his 
belief  that  Ricardo's  pamphlet  (on  The  High 
Price  of  Gold  Bullion),  which  had  led  the  way 
in  the  bullion  controversy,  was  "  wholly  theor- 
etical "  ;  and  the  report  of  the  bullion  com- 
mittee itself  was  expressly  brought  under  the 
same  condemnation  (see  Canning).  Bosanquet 
contends  that  the  bullion  committee  had  laid 
two  distinct  and  opposing  views  before  parlia- 
ment,  the  one  "theoretical"  and  embodied  in 


BOSELLIlsri  —BOTTOMRY 


169 


their  own  report,  the  other  "practical"  and 
embodied  in  the  evidence  of  the  "practical" 
witnesses  as  given  in  the  appendix  to  their  re- 
port. Proceeding  to  details,  he  sums  up  the 
committee's  views  in  the  following  six  proposi- 
tions :  (1)  The  variations  in  exchange  cannot 
for  any  length  of  time  exceed  the  cost  of  trans- 
porting and  insuring  the  precious  metals  ;  (2) 
the  market  price  of  gold  bullion  can  never  exceed 
the  mint  price  unless  the  currency  is  depreciated 
below  the  value  of  gold;  (3)  so  far  as  the  custom- 
house returns  of  exports  and  imports  go,  the 
state  of  the  exchanges  ought  at  this  time  (1810) 
to  be  favourable  and  not  unfavourable  ;  (4)  the 
bank,  during  the  restriction,  possesses  the  ex- 
clusive power  of  limiting  the  circulation  of  notes  ; 
(5)  the  circulation  of  country  bank  notes  depends 
on  the  issues  of  the  Bank  of  England  ;  and  (6) 
the  paper  currency  of  England  is  now  (1810) 
depreciated  in  comparison  with  gold,  and  the 
high  price  of  bullion  and  low  rate  of  excliange  are 
at  once  consequence  and  sign  of  the  depreciation. 
All  these  propositions  are  disputed  by  Bosan- 
quet.  He  adduces,  against  the  first,  the  state 
of  the  exchanges  and  the  cost  of  transmission 
of  specie  in  1797,  also  between  1764  and  1768, 
1775  and  1777,  1781  and  1783,  and  in  1804 
and  1805.  He  considers  that  the  facts  show 
that  there  is  no  "natural  limit"  of  any  kind 
to  the  variations  of  exchange,  and  points  to  the 
Swedish  exchanges  which  were  then  favourable, 
and  to  the  premium  on  English  paper  which 
then  prevailed  in  the  United  States  of  America. 
He  attacks  the  other  five  propositions  in  a 
similar  manner,  though,  in  giving  his  views  of 
the  relation  of  the  bank  to  the  paper  currency, 
he  is  fain  to  use  "theoretical"  reasonings  from 
first  principles,  and  even  to  appeal  to  the 
authority  of  Adam  Smith  (  Wealth  of  Nations, 
II.  ii.  145,  1;  M'Culloch's  ed.)  The  "obvious 
and  practical  causes  "  of  high  prices  are  (he  says) 
the  recent  vicissitudes  of  the  corn  trade  and  the 
increase  in  our  taxation  ;  to  reach  any  other, 
the  bullion  committee  have  had  to  adopt  Avrong 
principles  and  then  mis-state  their  facts.  In 
"Supplementary  Observations"  annexed  to  the 
2d  ed.  of  his  pamphlet,  Bosanquet  gives  the 
committee  some  riddles  to  explain  by  their 
theory  if  they  can,  e.g.  the  fact  that  the  ex- 
changes, after  being  6  per  cent  in  our  favour 
from  1790  to  1795,  fell  to  3  per  cent  below  par 
in  the  next  two  years,  though  there  had  been 
no  change  in  the  bank's  cii'culation  and  no  sus- 
pension of  cash  payments.  Ricardo  deals  with 
these  cruces  and  with  the  rest  of  Bosanquet's 
case  in  his  owm  Eeply  to  Mr.  Bosanquet's 
Observations,  with  appendix,  1811.  Bosanquet 
has  an  idea  that  the  standard  value  of  a 
pound  note  is  the  interest  of  £33  :  6  :  8  three 
per  cent  stock.  This  is  an  illustration  of  the 
danger  experienced  by  those  who,  being  con- 
versant with  details,  believe  that  they  thereby  ' 
understand  principles.  | 


[M'Culloch's  Literature  of  Political  Economy, 
1845,  p.  174, — Gentleman's  Magazine,  1850,  ne\» 
series,  xxxiv.  325. — Dictionary  of  National  Bio- 
graphy, art.  "Bosanquet  (Clias.)." — See  Bullion 
Committee  ;  Horner  ;  Huskisson  ;  Ricardo.  ] 

J.  B. 

BOSELLINI,  Carlo  (born  atModcna,  1765, 
died  1823),  published  in  1813  in  Modena  a 
treatise  on  political  economy  in  two  volumes. 
Although  the  title  of  the  book  is  New  Ey-a- 
mination  of  the  Sources  of  Private  and  Public 
Wealth,  it  contains  nothing  which  was  new  for 
its  times,  and  does  not  seem  to  have  had  any 
particular  success.  m.  p. 

BOSTON  PORT  BILL.  Among  the  events 
leading  to  the  revolt  of  the  American  colonies 
none  is  more  famous  than  the  attack  upon  the 
tea  ships  in  Boston  harbour  (16th  December 
1773).  This  caused  great  indignation  in  Eng- 
land, where  the  parliament  resolved  to  resort 
to  coercive  measures.  A  bill  was  introduced 
and  carried  in  1774  by  which,  after  1st  June,  the 
port  of  Boston  was  to  be  closed  to  all  trade. 
No  vessels  might  be  loaded  or  unloaded  in  the 
harbour,  and  English  men-of-war  were  sent  to 
enforce  the  act,  which  was  to  remain  in  force 
until  the  East  India  Company  had  been  com- 
pensated for  the  destroyed  tea  and  until  the 
king  in  council  was  satisfied  that  peace  and 
order  was  restored  in  Boston.  This  measure 
was  bitterly  resented  in  America,  where  the  as- 
sembly of  Virginia  decreed  that  1st  June  should 
be  observed  as  a  day  of  fasting  and  humiliation. 
The  general  sympathy  with  13oston  was  one  of 
the  prominent  causes  of  the  Congi-ess  at  Phila- 
delphia (September  1774),  which  marks  the 
beginning  of  combined  resistance  to  England. 

[Mahon,  History  of  England,  vol.  vi. — Lecky, 
History  of  England,  vol.  iii.]  b.  l. 

BOTERO,  Giovanni,  born  1540  at  Bene  in 
Piedmont,  died  1617  at  Turin.  A  powerful 
thinker,  he  opposed  energetically  the  mercan- 
tilist theories,  and  enunciated  the  law  of  in- 
crease of  population  later  known  as  Malthus's 
law.  He  occupied  some  of  the  highest  official 
positions  in  his  country. 

His  work,  Delia  ragione  di  Stato,  published 
for  the  first  time  in  Venice  in  1589,  again  there 
in  1619,  and  in  Turin  in  1596,  has  been  translated 
into  all  the  principal  modern  languages,  and  also 
into  Latin.  It  was  translated  twice  into  French, 
once  in  1599  by  Choppins,  Raison  et  Gouvernement 
d'Mat,  and  once  in  1606  by  Pierre  de  Deymier, 
Maximes  d'i^tat  militaires  et  politigues.  Not  less 
remarkable  is  his  book  on  the  causes  of  the  great- 
ness of  cities,  Delle  cause  delta  grandezza  delle 
cittdb,  published  1598  in  Rome.  Botero  Avas  an 
opponent  of  Macchiavelli.  Having  travelled  a 
great  deal,  he  published  his  so-called  Universal 
lleports,  a  treatise  on  "The  Strength  of  all  the 
Powers  of  Europe  and  Asia,'  Rome,  1592  and 
1695.  M.  P. 

BOTTOMRY,  Loan  on.  A  contract  in 
writing  in  which  the  borrower  recites  the  in- 


170 


BOTTOMRY— BOULAINVILLIERS 


tended  voyage  by  a  ship  therein  described,  and 
the  receipt  of  a  loan  upon  condition  that  if  the 
ship  escape  disasters  at  sea,  or  from  enemies,  or 
pirates,  the  lender  is  to  receive  back  his  advance 
with  a  stated  sum  for  interest  on  completion  of 
the  voyage,  but  that  the  borrower  is  to  be 
released  from  his  obligation  if  the  ship  bff  lost 
or  fall  into  the  hands  of  enemies  or  pirates. 
The  form  of  contract  used  is  of  time-honoured 
antiquity.  It  stiU  closely  resembles  in  its  out- 
lines those  of  a  specimen  extant  in  the  speeches 
of  Demosthenes.  Traces  of  the  loan  on  bottomry 
are  also  found  in  some  of  the  most  ancient  codes 
of  eastern  nations.  It  finds  a  large  place  in  the 
early  sea  laws  and  ordinances  of  the  commercial 
nations  and  communities  of  Europe  as  well  as  in 
their  legal  literature.  Do^vn  to  very  recent 
times  it  was  the  sole  method  by  which  the 
master  of  a  vessel  damaged  by  storms,  or  other 
hazards  at  sea,  in  some  distant  port  removed 
from  the  ordinary  channels  of  commerce  and 
from  any  possible  speedy  means  of  communica- 
tion with  the  owner  of  the  vessel,  could  raise 
funds  for  the  necessary  repairs  of  his  ship  and 
the  resumption  of  her  voyage.  All  this,  how- 
ever, has  been  much  changed  of  late  years.  The 
most  distant  corners  of  the  globe  have  been  knit 
as  it  were  into  one  country  by  the  economical 
revolution  which  science,  and  particularly  tele- 
graphy, have  brought  about,  now  enabling  funds 
to  be  laid  down  almost  immediately  from  and 
to  the  most  widely  separated  places  through  the 
electric  wire.  This  is  fast  rendering  the  loan 
on  bottomry  bill  or  bond  obsolete  in  practice. 
The  bottomry  loan  differed  only  from  the  ordin- 
ary loan  on  nautical  interest  of  the  Greeks 
and  Romans  in  its  good  faith,  as  it  required 
a  pecuniary  insurable  interest  to  exist  as  the 
foundation  of  the  contract,  which  the  Pcenus 
Nauticum  did  not,  the  latter  being  resorted  to 
as  a  gambling  or  speculative  wager  by  persons 
frequently  not  interested  in  the  ship  whose  loss 
or  safety  was  betted  upon,  a  description  of 
amateur  underwriting  by  means  of  which  the 
elder  Cato  and  other  wealthy  Romans  increased 
their  fortunes.  The  loan  on  bottomry  would 
seem  to  have  furnished  the  ancient  merchant 
and  shipowner  with  an  effectual  form  of  marine 
insurance.  In  reality  it  supplied  to  the  bor- 
rower not  only  a  trading  capital  but  also  what 
was  tantamount  to  a  marine  policy  of  insurance, 
with  this  peculiarity  about  it  that  he  needed  to 
be  under  no  doubt  about  the  solidity  of  the 
Underwriter,  as  in  this  form  of  contract  the 
policy  money  was  already  in  the  borrower's 
hands  at  the  very  inception  of  the  transaction, 
and  applicable  to  make  good  any  losses  from  the 
perils  of  the  sea  in  the  event  of  a  fair  claim 
arising  therefrom.  On  the  other  hand,  to  the 
lender  and  underwriter  such  contracts,  so  long 
as  the  special  interest  or  premium  was  fixed  at 
a  high  enough  rate,  afforded  a  profitable  invest- 
ment of  funds  on  average,  as  there  has  always 


existed  a  well-defined  mercantile  usage  respect 
ing  such  loans,  generally  including  proper 
control  by  public  registry,  power  to  appoint 
a  supercargo,  and  strict  enforcement  of  other 
regulations  in  his  favour.  Neither  did  the 
pecuniary  terms  of  such  contracts  present  an 
obstacle  to  their  habitual  use.  The  net  premium 
for  sea-risk  payable  by  the  borrower,  the  ship- 
owner, or  merchant,  was  conditional  on  the 
vessel  coming  safely  to  port.  It  was  only  the 
difference  between  the  extra  rate  allowed  as 
nautical  interest  and  the  ordinary  rate  of  interest 
on  loan.  The  more  modem  system  of  marine 
insurance,  in  which  the  premium  paid  is  merely 
the  pretium  pericuU  without  being  mixed  up 
with  a  loan  as  ia  the  case  of  the  bottomry  bill 
or  bond  contract,  could  scarcely  in  ancient  days 
have  been  so  conveniently  circumstanced,  as 
in  the  event  of  the  disaster  at  sea,  the  under- 
writer might  or  might  not  be  found  equal  to 
bear  the  burden  of  his  bond.  And  the  resources 
of  ancient  commerce  were  even  equal  to  those 
instances  in  which  the  taking  up  of  funds  in 
this  form  was  resorted  to  by  those  who  had 
capital  enough  of  their  own.  For  these  funds 
might  be,  and  doubtless  were,  used  for  the 
relief  of  the  borrower,  who,  when  he  did  not 
require  the  whole  advance  for  the  ship's  im- 
mediate purposes,  could  reinvest  the  balance  in 
a  temporary  way  with  an  argentarius,  or 
banker,  who  allowed  interest  on  its  deposit  at 
the  common  rate,  and  thus  diminished  the 
merchant's  or  shipowner's  outlay  to  the  bare 
differential  rate  of  interest  between  what  he 
borrowed  and  what  he  lent  at.  The  balance 
thus  resulting  would  be  neither  more  nor  less 
than  the  net  premium  of  marine  insurance,  the 
whole  system  of  which  was  inaugurated  many 
centuries  subsequently  by  a  kind  of  commercial 
evolution  (see  Insurance,  Marine),      f.  h. 

BOULAINVILLIERS,  Henri  de,  a  French 
writer,  was  bom  at  Saint-Saire  in  Normandy  in 
1658,  served  some  time  in  the  army,  but  re- 
tired soon  to  his  country  seat,  where  he  died  in  ; 
1722.  He  was  an  admirer  of  Feudalism,  and 
would  have  liked  to  restore  "feudal  liberty," 
the  decay  of  which  seemed  to  him  the  cause  of 
the  miseries  of  the  people  ;  but  his  chief  merit 
lay  in  the  frankness  with  which  he  laid  bare 
the  causes  of  the  financial  distress  of  France. 
His  works  on  finance  were  not  published  till  after 
his  death.     They  were  prohibited  in  France. 

Boulainvilliers's  works  are  as  follows  :  Etat 
de  la  France,  published  in  1727-28,  3  vols.  fol. 
This  contains  historical  and  descriptive  accounts 
of  all  the  provinces  of  France,  extracts  from  the 
memoirs  of  the  Intendants,  and  his  own  financial 
projects.  The  latter  have  been  published  • 
separately  under  the  title  of  Memoires  prisentis 
d  Monseigneur  le  Due  D'OrUans,  contenant  les 
moyens  de  rendre  ce  Royaume  tres -puissant,  et 
d'augmenter  consideraUement  les  revenus  du  Roy 
et  du  Peuple,     Par  le  Comte  de  Boulainvilliers, 


BOUNTIES 


171 


2  vols,  k  La  Haye  et  i  Amsterdam,  1727. 
Among  these  the  second  memoir,  directed  against 
the  "financiers"  and  proposing  a  state-treasurer's 
office,  the  third  against  arbitrary  taxation,  the  fifth 
against  the  excessive  salt-tax,  the  sixth  against  dis- 
orderly financial  administration  in  general,  are  still 
of  especial  interest.  His  economic  ideas  (see  pp. 
215-225,  vol.  ii.  of  the  last  named  work)  are  on 
the  level  of  the  ordinary  mercantilism  of  the  day. 
[Nouvelle  Biographie,  t.  vi.  p.  937  ;  Montes- 
quieu, Esprit  des  Lois,  liv.  xxx.  ch.  xi.,  Alphonse 
Gallery,  Les  riformateurs  de  Vancienne  France, 
Boulainvilliers,  1883.  Charles  Smith  ascribes  to 
him  Les  interets  de  la  France  mal  entendus,  1756. 
But  this  work  is  written  by  Ange  de  Goudar  (see 
Three  Tracts  on  the  Corn  Laws,  1766,  p.  161), 
Levasseur,  La  Population  Frangaise,  1889,  p.  202, 
and  Dr.  Stephen  Bauer  in  an  article,  "Zur  Entste- 
hung  der  Physiokratie,"  Conrad's  Jahrhucher  fur 
Nationalokonomie  und  Statistik,  N.F.  bd.  xxi. 
p.  151].  S.B. 

BOUNTIES.  A  bounty  is,  in  principle, 
something  received  by  producers  in  addition  to 
the  price  received  from  consumers  through  the 
ordinary  operation  of  the  market.  In  political 
economy  the  term  is  usually  confined  to  such 
additions  as  are  given  by  governments.  We 
may  distinguish  (1)  intentional  bounties,  de- 
signed to  encourage  export  or  to  stimulate  pro- 
duction ;  (2)  unintentional  bounties,  begun 
unconsciously  but  afterwards  recognised  to  be 
such,  e.g.  the  sugar  bounties  of  to-day  ;  (3) 
virtual  or  disguised  bounties,  neither  intended 
nor  recognised,  but  actually  operating  as  such  ; 
e.g.  Great  Britain's  subsidies  to  the  continental 
powers  last  century — which  really  stimulated  her 
exports  at  her  own  expense,  but  were  not  de- 
signed to  do  so  ;  endowments  which  enable 
learning  and  teaching  to  be  obtained  at  less 
than  actual  cost  price,  prizes  for  inventions, 
and  premiums  of  many  kinds. 

Adam  Smith  criticises  them  severely,  and, 
after  his  usual  manner,  adduces  detailed  in- 
stances of  their  failure.  Eicardo  joins  in  the 
condemnation,  but  on  somewhat  different  theor- 
etical gi'ounds  ;  and  he  goes  on  to  point  out  that 
Adam  Smith  failed  to  go  far  enough  through  con- 
fining himself  to  the  case  of  supply  not  being 
affected  in  amount.  The  effect  upon  supply  is, 
however,  most  important,  and  Ricardo  shows 
that  the  increased  supply  necessitates,  in  the 
case  of  corn,  recourse  to  less  advantageous  em- 
ployment of  capital,  and  so  to  increased  prices 
and  to  a  rise  in  the  rent  of  land.  Since  the 
change  in  British  industry  from  agricultural  to 
manufacturing,  it  is  necessary  to  dwell  upon 
the  working  in  manufactures  of  diminution  of 
cost  as  amount  of  supply  increases,  and  an 
important  school  of  protectionists  follow  List,  in 
recommending  bounties  as  stimulants  to  this 
class  of  production  only  (List,  NatioTial  Political 
Economy,  trans.  S.  S.  Lloyd,  London,  1885 J, 
Ricardo  condemns  bounties  as  the  worst  kind  of 
taxation,  because  they  not  only  raise  a  tax  but 


divert  capital  perniciously.  Against  this  have 
to  be  set  the  considerations  that  a  bounty  is  not 
lost  to  the  nation  which  pays  it ;  and  it  is  often 
advocated  in  cases  where  there  is  an  amount  of 
capital  or  labour,  or  both,  which  cannot  find 
employment  otherwise.  All  petitions  for 
bounties  on  the  part  of  trades  contain  the  as- 
sumption that  capital  and  labour  will  be  rendered 
inoperative  unless  assisted. 

Many  free-traders  find  justifications  for 
bounties  in  order  to  obtain  other  objects  than 
strictly  economic  ones,  e.g.  J.  B.  Say,  who  in- 
culcates free  principles  as  the  rule,  justifies 
Louis  XIV. 's  bounties  on  shipping,  their  pur- 
pose being  to  raise  a  body  of  sailors,  and  the 
English  bounties  on  refined  sugar.  He  also 
declines  to  follow  Adam  Smith  in  his  general 
rejection,  so  long  as  custom  and  legal  restrictions 
interfere  with  the  free  investment  of  capital, 
and  so  long  as  artisans  require  training ;  and 
specifically  commends  "les  sages  encourage- 
ments" of  Colbert  as  having  issued  in  the 
French  silk  industry.  Sismondi  allows  them 
for  "surete"  or  *'sante,"  and  Roscher  agrees 
that  they  may  be  useful  in  a  transitional  stage. 
J.  S.  Mill's  remark  (bk.  v.  ch.  x.)  that  the 
bribing  of  customers  is  going  beyond  what  any 
shopkeeper  ever  did,  is  neither  accurate,  as  it 
is  often  done,  nor  profound,  as  a  nation  is  shop- 
keeper, farmer,  and  manufacturer  in  one. 

One  advantage  claimed  specifically  for  boun- 
ties is  that  the  amount  drawn  from  the  national 
purse  is  known,  and  it  can  be  definitely  accepted 
as  a  definite  subsidy,  as  one  of  the  expenses  of 
national  life  for  an  end  deemed  desirable. 
Against  this  it  is  urged  that  the  amount  so 
raised  does  not  measure  the  change  caused.  In 
the  complications  of  modem  industry  there  are 
no  isolated  changes  ;  production  and  trade  are 
disturbed,  and  it  is  because  of  the  complication 
of  effects  that  economic  theory  is  not  able  to 
establish  convincingly  the  limits  of  the  effects 
produced.  Again,  the  manifest  simplicity  of 
aiding  industry  by  a  dip  into  the  national  purse 
must  be  regarded  as  a  disadvantage.  The 
facility  is  a  fatal  one,  until  governments  are 
found  both  honest  enough  and  wise  enough  to 
resist  the  solicitations  of  particular  industries, 
A  special  advantage  is  claimed  for  bounties  on 
production,  that  there  is  nothing  invidious  in  them 
as  against  foreign  nations :  they  are  free  from 
the  charges  to  which  bounties  on  export  and 
prohibitory  duties  are  liable,  in  that  they 
are  purely  domestic  in  intention  ;  and,  how- 
ever justly  a  foreign  nation  may  resent  having 
our  exports  thrust  upon  it  or  its  own  produce 
kept  off,  it  can  hardly  protest  against  our  tak- 
ing what  measures  we  please  to  develop  our 
power  of  supplying  ourselves. 

Recent  history  shows  many  examples  in  which 
the  whole  subject  of  bounties  may  be  effectively 
studied.  Adam  Smith's  caustic  account  of  the 
herring  fishery    bounties    (bk.    iv.   ch.    v.)    is 


172 


BOUNTIES 


well  followed  up  by  MHDulloch  {Diet,  of  Com- 
merce), and  their  nugatory  character  appears  to 
be  demonstrated.  The  linen  bounty  affords 
another  good  example ;  Chambers  of  Commerce 
pleaded  in  vain  for  its  continuance,  and  the 
event  showed  that  on  its  suspension  in  1834 
export  paused  for  a  little  while,  but  resumed  Its 
former  volume  in  three  years,  and  went  on 
steadily  increasing  until  1848,  after  which  it 
rushed  forward  under  the  impetus  of  the  new 
industrial  policy  (see  Linen  Trade,  Ancient 
and  Modern,  London,  1864,  pp.  663-670). 
The  corn  bounties  are  thoroughly  discussed  by 
the  English  economists  ;  their  interest  might 
again  become  actual  if  any  foreign  nations  or 
colonies  should  choose  to  stimulate  their  com 
exports  ;  and  a  virtual  bounty  is  claimed  to  be 
in  operation  in  favour  of  the  Indian  producer 
through  the  fall  in  the  value  of  silver  in  gold- 
using  countries.  An  instance  of  a  temporary 
bounty  effecting  its  purpose  in  a  way  difl&cult 
to  deprecate  is  found  in  a  bounty  on  the  export' 
of  engravings  given  soon  after  the  founding  of 
the  Royal  Academy  (1769)  ;  of  which  it  is  said 
that  it  called  a  number  of  talents  into  action, 
e.g.  WooUett,  and  attracted  to  London  a  crowd 
of  foreigners,  Cipriani,  Kaufmann,  Pastel, 
Moser,  and  Bartolozzi,  and  secured  for  English 
engraving  a  permanent  place  among  the  arts. 
(Cassell's  History  of  Engraving^  London,  p. 
336).  Bounties  on  shipbuilding  and  shipown- 
ing  have  been  in  high  favour  with  maritime 
countries  for  reasons  of  state.  France  at  this 
time  gives  1^  francs  a  ton  for  every  thousand 
miles  run  by  ships  both  built  and  owned  in 
France,  and  half  that  premium  for  ships  owned 
at  home  but  built  outside  (see  Fawcett,  Free 
Trade  and  Protection,  eh.  ii.)  The  bounties 
on  sugar  have  a  complicated  history — begun 
without  this  intention,  their  result  has  been  to 
revolutionise  the  production  of  sugar  by  giving 
beetroot  an  advantage  against  cane  which  has 
issued  in  the  former  being  now  the  larger  source  of 
supply  (see  Bounties  on  Sugar).  The  bounty- 
giving  countries  expressed  themselves  unani- 
mously in  favour  of  abolition  at  the  recent 
conference,  provided  that  united  action  can  be 
secured.  Resistance  is  made  by  some  English 
free-traders  who  regard  the  cheapness  in  England 
as  the  primary  advantage  ;  and  an  obstacle  is 
interposed  by  the  refusal  of  the  United  States  to 
enter  into  any  undertaking  not  to  begin  a  bounty 
system.  The  foreign  office  (see  statement  by 
under-secretary  in  parliament)  knows  of  only 
the  following  "considerable "  bounties  in  opera- 
tion in  1889  :  on  shipping,  on  sugar,  and  on 
the  Newfoundland  fisheries  (French). 

The  employment  of  a  bounty  by  the  state 
may  be  justified  as  a  measiu-e  of  equity  when 
industries  are  affected  by  the  action  of  state. 
When,  for  example,  a  treaty  of  commerce  or  a 
general  change  of  state  policy  alters  suddenly 
the  industrial  situation,   there  may  be  some 


claim  on  the  part  of  the  owners  of  fixed  capital 
and  the  persons  in  whom  there  is  fixed  skill, 
for  some  supplement  to  the  lowered  market- 
price  which  will  allow  their  industry  to  diminish 
or  die  away  gradually.  But  bounties  are  artificial 
interferences  with  production,  in  the  same  sense 
that  protective  duties  are,  from  an  opposite  point 
of  view.  A  bounty  has  been  happily  called  a  nega- 
tive tax  (see  Bounties,  Abstract  Theory  of). 
The  question  is  discussed  more  or  less  in  all  the 
standard  works  on  political  economy,  and  the 
history  of  various  bounties  is  given  in  the  commercial 
histories  and  parliamentary  papers  relating  to  the 
different  trades.  a.  c. 

BOUNTIES,  Abstract  theory  of.  The 
theoretical  inquiry  whether  a  country  can  pos- 
sibly benefit  itself  by  a  bounty,  may  be  sub- 
divided according  as  the  arrangement  considered 
is  only  temporary  or  more  enduring.  (1)  The 
arguments,  by  which  Mill,  in  a  well-known 
passage  (Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  v.  ch.  x.  §  1),  defends 
temporary  protection  of  nascent  industries  seem 
applicable,  mutatis  mutandis,  to  bounties  as  well 
as  to  duties.  The  same  may  be  said  of  the  con- 
siderations in  favour  of  temporary  protection, 
adduced  by  Dr.  Sidgwick  in  his  Political  Econ- 
omy (bk.  iii.  ch.  v.  §  1),  and  his  Method  and 
Scope  of  Political  Economy  i^-^.  1-20).  (2)  The 
arguments  on  the  side  of  a  less  transitory 
bounty  are  more  abstract.  Cournot  argues  that 
a  bounty  to  a  monopolist  might  possibly  cause 
greater  gain  to  consumers  than  loss  to  the 
treasury  {Recherches  ...  1838  ;  ch.  vi.)  In 
this  reasoning  Cournot  takes  no  account  of  those 
consumers,  who  are  induced  by  the  fall  of  price 
to  increase  their  purchases.  But  of  course, 
when  this  circumstance  is  taken  into  account, 
the  argument  in  favour  of  a  bounty  becomes  a 
fortiori.  The  omission,  however,  seems  fatal 
to  the  arguments,  which,  in  the  case  of  free 
competition,  Cournot  has  urged  in  favour  of 
protecting  duties  and  bounties  {Ibid.,  chs.  x. -xii. 
and  see  M.  Bertrand's  criticisms  in  the  Journal 
des  Savans  for  1 8 8 3).  Some  presumption  is  per- 
haps derivable  from  Cournot's  principle  that  a 
"  bounty  is  in  algebraic  language  a  negative 
tax,  so  that  the  same  formulae  should  apply  to 
a  tax  and  bounty";  taken  in  connection  with 
the  proposition  admitted  by  many  economists 
that  it  is  possible  for  a  country  to  benefit  itself 
at  the  expense  of  foreigners,  by  a  duty  on  im- 
ports or  exports,  in  certain  cases.  Such  a  case 
is  stated  by  Mill  {Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  v.  ch.  iv. 
§  6,  beginning),  and  more  simply  by  Dr.  Sidg- 
wick in  the  following  passage  :  ' '  Suppose  that 
a  5  per  cent  duty  is  imposed  on  foreign  silks, 
and  that  in  consequence,  after  a  certain  interval, 
half  the  silks  consumed  are  the  product  of 
native  industry,  and  that  the  price  of  the 
whole  has  risen  2^  per  cent.  It  is  obvious 
that,  under  these  circumstances,  the  other  half 
which  comes  from  abroad  yields  the  state  5 
per  cent,  while  the  tax  levied  from  the  con- 


BOUNTIES  ON  SUGAR 


173 


sumers  on  the  whole  is  only  2|  per  cent ;  so 
that  the  nation  in  the  aggregate  is  at  this  time 
losing  nothing  by  protection,  except  the  cost 
of  collecting  the  tax,  while  a  loss  equivalent  to 
the  whole  tax  falls  on  the  foreign  producers " 
{Pol.  Ucon.,  bk.  iii.  ch.  v.  §  2,  and  context). 
It  seems  possible  to  imagine  a  converse  case,  in 
xvhich  a  bounty  would  not  be  detrimental  to 
**  the  nation  in  the  aggregate."  Professor  Mar- 
shall argues  (Principles  of  Uconomics,  bk.  v,  ch. 
vii.)  "that  it  might  even  be  for  the  advantage 
of  the  community  that  the  government  should 
levy  taxes  on  commodities  which  obey  the  law 
of  diminishing  return,  and  spend  part  of  the 
proceeds  on  bounties  to  commodities  which 
obey  the  law  of  increasing  return." 

Such  speculative  considerations  are  not  in- 
consistent with  a  firm  adherence  to  the  practi- 
cal principle  of  free  trade.  Thus  Dr.  Sidgwick, 
while  he  regards  it  as  "erroneous  to  maintain, 
on  the  ordinary  economic  grounds,  that  tem- 
porary protection  must  always  be  detrimental 
to  the  protecting  country,"  does  not  therefore 
accept  the  practical  conclusion  which  that  re- 
mark seems  to  favour.  A  decisive  consideration 
against  it  is  that  no  government  is  wise  enough 
to  discern  in  what  cases  protection  would  not 
be  detrimental,  or  strong  enough  to  confine 
itself  to  those  cases  (Method  and  Scope,  p.  19). 
It  may  be  added  that  refined  arguments  on  the 
side  of  protection  are  useful  as  correctives  to 
exaggerations  of  the  case  on  the  other  side.  It 
behoves  not  to  accept  even  right  conclusions 
with  more  confidence  than  they  deserve.  It  is 
dangerous  to  exaggerate  the  preponderance  of 
evidence  in  favour  of  what  we  believe.  The 
balance  of  judgment  may  suffer  a  strain  which 
will  be  felt  on  some  other  occasion  where  nice 
estimation  is  required.  Thus  Adam  Smith's 
contention  that  a  bounty  on  corn  cannot  be 
beneficial,  because  "the  nature  of  things  has 
stamped  upon  corn  a  real  value"  (Wealth  of 
Nations,  bk.  iv.  ch.  v.),  is  of  little  moment  as  an 
addition  to  the  weighty  practical  considerations 
in  favour  of  free  trade  ;  while  it  is  apt  to  distort 
the  judgment  on  the  delicate  questions  con- 
nected with  a  Measure  of  Value.      f.  y.  b. 

BOUNTIES  ON  SUGAR.  The  operation  of 
bounties  is  best  illustrated  by  a  practical 
example,  such  as  the  sugar  bounties  give. 
France,  Austria,  and  Germany  supply  collect- 
ively rather  more  than  two-thirds  of  the  total 
sugar  production  of  Europe,  at  the  present  date 
(1890).  Each  of  these  countries  grants  bounties 
on  export ;  Austria  openly,  limiting,  however, 
the  amount  to  be  spent  under  this  head  ; 
Germany  and  France  (who  have  long  had 
boimties)  in  a  more  indirect  but  quite  as 
effective  way.  These  two,  Germany  for  half  a 
century  and  France  since  1884,  have  adopted 
the  system  of  levying  duties  on  home-produced 
sugar  on  the  weight  of  the  beetroot  when 
delivered  for  manufacture.    Even  if  established 


with  a  purely  fiscal  object,  this  system  is  open 
to  the  objection  that  it  is  only  based  on  the 
probable  average  saccharine  richness  of  the  root, 
making  no  allowance  for  increased  or  reduced 
yield  caused  by  varying  meteorological  and 
agricultural  circumstances. 

It  had  been  admitted  in  Germany  in  1840 
that  20  centners  of  roots  would  give  1  centner 
of  raw  sugar.  Thirty  years  later  the  propor- 
tions of  12*5  to  1  had  been  reached.  Not- 
withstanding the  more  stringent  fiscal  legisla- 
tion which  ensued,  the  factories  continued  to 
spread  wonderfully,  and  the  production  ol 
sugar  trebled  between  1877  and  1884.  From 
1875  to  1884  the  annual  exports  had  increased 
in  an  almost  fabulous  proportion. 

About  this  time,  although  protected  by  a  Sur- 
taxe  on  foreign  sugar,  the  French  manufacture 
rather  declined  ;  the  annual  production  had  re- 
mained stationary,  but  on  foreign  markets  France 
was  beaten  by  German  competition,  and  the  ex- 
ports had  fallen  from  327,000  to  184,000  tons. 

Assailed  by  clamours  of  distress,  the  French 
ministry  resolved  in  1884  to  apply  the  system 
which,  as  German  economists  boasted,  had  in 
their  country  performed  an  "educational  mis- 
sion "  (ein£.  erziehende  Mission  as  it  is  called  in 
Schonberg's  Handhitchdcr  Politischen  Oekonomie, 
article  ' '  Zuckersteuer  ").  The  French  minister  of 
finance  declared  that  the  proposed  law  would 
act  as  a  law  of  progress,  stimulating  the  im- 
provement of  agiiculture,  the  adoption  of  im- 
proved machinery,  and  consequently  ensuring  a 
considerable  increase  of  the  quantities  of  sugar 
extracted.  Up  to  1st  September  1887  the 
factories  were  allowed  an  option  between  the 
old  and  the  new  system,  but,  after  that  date 
the  duty  was  to  be  uniform,  imposed  on  the 
basis  of  a  legal  yield  of  6  kil.  250  of  refined 
sugar  for  100  kil.  of  roots,  and  this  percentage 
was  to  be  gradually  increased,  so  as  to  reach  7 
kil.  in  the  present  year  (1890). 

It  cannot  be  denied  that  what  had  been 
stated  to  be  the  principal  object  of  the  law  of 
1887  has  been  fully  realised.  Everywhere  the 
"fabricants"  have  abandoned  the  antiquated 
process  of  extraction  by  presses  for  the  more 
exhaustive  system  of  diffitsion.  To  reconcile 
their  own  interests  with  those  of  the  farmers, 
they  have  supplied  the  latter  with  seeds  of 
richer  and  less  bulky  varieties  of  beetroot,  and 
have  agreed  to  pay  higher  prices  for  higher 
saccharine  degree.  More  land  (about  200,000 
instead  of  120,000  hectares)  is  now  employed 
for  this  cultivation,  and  as  beetroot  affords  the 
opportunity  of  a  better  rotation  of  crops,  it 
promotes  the  growing  of  wheat,  that  favourite 
of  French  farmers  and  landowners. 

In  Germany  the  task  of  the  revenue  officers 
ends  with  registering  the  weight  of  the  roots. 
In  France  they  are  instructed  to  keep  a  strict 
control  over  the  whole  fabrication  and  an 
account  of  the  sugar,   raw  or  refined,   which 


174 


BOURGEOIS— BOURSE  DU  TRAVAIL 


leaves  the  factory.  Government  is  thus  enabled 
to  ascertain  if  a  surplus  is  obtained  which  re- 
mains "duty  free"  at  the  disposal  of  the 
manufacturer.  It  was  thus  found  that  during 
the  three  years  since  the  law  was  passed  (1887) 
the  real  extraction  had  amounted  to  7*27,  8-12 
and  8-87  per  cent,  and  that  the  quantities' of 
duty  free  sugar  have  amounted  respectively  to 
22-56,  31-21  and  36-44  per  cent  of  the  whole 
French  production.  The  treasury  had  been  a 
loser  by  25,  43,  and  92  million  francs  (saj' 
£1,000,000,  £1,720,000,  and  £3,680,000 
sterling)  in  bounties  to  manufacturers  and 
refiners  {Bulletin  de  Statistique,  January  1888). 
To  counteract  this  drain  the  legal  yield  was 
raised  so  as  to  reach  7  kil.  750  ;  moreover 
a  special  duty  of  30  frs.  (say  £1  :  4s.) — the 
ordinary  duty  being  60  frs,  (say  £2  :  8s.) — was 
imposed  on  the  surplus  sugar.  In  Germany 
the  legal  yield  had  already  been  increased  in 
1883,  and  the  drawback  has  since  been  lowered 
by  about  5  per  cent. 

Although  the  joint  production  of  France  and 
Germany  doubled  in  the  ten  years  1880-1890, 
there  was  only  a  temporary  reduction  of  price 
for  the  French  consumer  of  loaf  sugar  (96  and 
98  frs.,  say  £3  :  16  :  9  and  £3:18:  4,  per  100 
kil.  in  1886  and  1887);  in  1890,  as  in  1884,  it 
again  cost  him  104  frs.  (£4 :  3 :  2).  The  foreign 
purchaser  alone  had  beyond  question  gained,  and 
the  staunchest  supporters  of  the  factories  con- 
fessed that  England  obtained  French  sugar  6  frs. 
(say  5s. )  per  1 0  0  kil.  cheaper  than  it  could  be  pur- 
chased in  France.  Only  they  shifted  the  respon- 
sibility on  the  bounties  enjoyed  by  the  French 
refiners,  the  rival  brothers  of  the  "  fabricants  " 
(PouUin,  L'lmpdt  sur  les  Raffineurs,  Paris,  1890). 
As  the  refiners  were,  however,  henceforward  to 
be  subject  to  the  constant  supervision  of  the 
officers  {exercice)  and  were  to  pay  the  duties  on 
the  manufactured  produce,  there  would  not  be 
much  left  of  disguised  bounties  for  them.  In  fact 
the  system  of  the  impdt  d  la  consommation  or 
Fahrikaisteuer,  already  adopted  in  Austria  and 
Russia,  alone  gives  all  parties  concerned  a  clear 
insight  in  this  maze  of  conflicting  interests. 
Bounties  might  still  exist,  as  in  Austria,  but  it 
would  be  known  to  what  extent.  With  the 
actual  French  and  German  system,  it  is  im- 
possible to  determine  beforehand  the  amount 
of  bounty  which  will  be  awarded  ;  this  varies 
almost  in  every  case,  according  to  the  soil,  the 
accidents  of  the  season,  and  the  skill  and  in- 
dustry of  the  manufacturer. 

[The  Liste  G^nirale  des  Fabricants  de  Sucre, 
Paris,  gives  a  compendium  of  the  legislation  in 
France  and  other  countries.  No  special  book, 
up  to  date,  on  the  subject  can  well  be  named, 
which  can  only  be  studied  in  the  files  of  special 
papers,  as  Le  Journal  des  Fabricants  de  Sucre, 
La  Sucrerie  Indigene,  Licht's  German  Eeports  ; 
all  these,  however,  are  written  with  a  strong  bias. 
See  also  Sir  T.  H.  Farrer,  Free  Trade  versus  Fair 
Trade,  2d  ed.,  chapter  on  sugar.]  e.  ca. 


The  German  Reichstag  in  the  session  May  1891 
voted  a  law  doing  away  with  the  system  of  taxa- 
tion according  to  the  weight  of  the  beet  roots.  In 
future  the  duty  was  to  be  levied  on  the  quantities 
of  sugar  produced.  Direct  premiums  of  1*25  to 
2  marks  (say  Is.  3d.  to  2s.)  were  allowed  during 
5  years  on  every  100  kil.  exported,  the  duty  being 
18  marks  (say  18s.)  per  100  kil. 

BOURGEOIS  (Fr.)  was  no  doubt  originally 
citizen  of  a  town  in  the  wide  sense,  but  (unlike 
citoyen)  it  has  been  constantly  narrowed  into  a 
term  of  disparagement.  So  it  means  commoner 
as  opposed  to  noble  ("Bourgeois  Gentilhomme," 
in  Moli^re's  comedy  of  1670,  is  really  a  playful 
union  of  opposites),  civilian  as  opposed  to 
military,  rude  as  opposed  to  refined.  At  present 
in  the  language  of  social  agitation  it  means  em- 
ployer (patron)  as  opposed  to  workman  (ouvrier) ; 
and  the  title  Citizen  King,  on  which  Louis 
Philippe  prided  himself,  would  now  be  no  com- 
pliment, simply  king  of  the  middle  classes.  So 
in  the  discussions  of  the  Miners'  Congress  at 
Paris,  1891,  in  regard  to  the  proposed  general 
strike  :  "la  bourgeoisie  vous  pousse  h.  la  faire, 
parce  qu'elle  est  preparee  k  ce  moment "  (report 
in  Le  Temps,  3d  April  1891).  j.  b. 

BOURSE.  A  French  word  for— (1 )  The  meet- 
ings of  bankers  and  merchants  for  the  transac- 
tion of  business ;  (2)  the  place  where  such 
meetings  are  held.  The  French  Code  de  Com- 
merce defines  the  Bourse  de  Commerce  as  the 
meeting  of  merchants,  masters  of  vessels,  stock 
and  bill  brokers  (agents  de  change),  and  mer- 
chandise brokers  (courtiers),  which  is  held  under 
the  authority  of  the  government  (Code  de  Com- 
merce, §  71).  The  same  definition  may  be  given 
to  this  word  and  its  etymological  equivalents 
(borse,  borsa,  bolsa,  etc.)  in  most  countries  if  we 
omit  the  government  authority,  which  is  gener- 
ally unnecessary.  The  word  used  in  the  sense  re- 
ferred to  is  in  all  cases  also  used  for  the  place  of 
meeting.    As  to  England,  see  Change,     e.  s. 

BOURSE  DU  TRAVAIL,  a  labour  exchange, 
or  registry,  for  the  use  of  persons  offering  or 
seeking  employment.  There  is  at  present  a 
workmen's  movement  in  France  and  Belgium 
for  the  extensive  establishment  and  intercom- 
munication of  such  institutions,  which  have 
long  been  advocated  by  M.  de  Molinari.  The 
muncipal  council  of  Paris  voted  1,200,000 
francs  (£48,000)  to  found  a  hourse  du  travail, 
which  was  installed  on  20th  June  1887,  at 
35  Rue  Jean- Jacques  Rousseau,  Paris,  pending 
the  transformation  of  the  old  corn  market.  The 
administration  consists  of  workmen  chosen  by 
different  trade  -  unions.  Employers  are  not 
represented.  Some  irritation  exists  as  to  the 
exclusion  of  several  workmen's  associations. 
The  bourse,  it  is  alleged,  is  confined  to  a  clique. 
Bourses  du  travail  have  been  formed  at 
Nimes,  St.  Etienne,  Marseilles,  and  some 
other  places  in  the  provinces  of  France.  [See 
Unemployed,  App.]  h.  h. 


BOWEN— BKANDS 


175 


BOWEN,  Francis,  bom  1811,  died  1890 ;  he 
graduated  from  Harvard  College  in  1833  ;  was 
instructor  there  from  1833  to  1847,  and  pro- 
fessor in  Harvard  University  from  1853  to  1889. 
Professor  Bowen's  interests  and  attainments 
were  great  and  varied.  He  wrote  not  only  on 
economic  topics,*  but  on  history,  politics,  the 
classics,  and  most  of  all  on  the  subject  con- 
nected with  his  professorship  —  philosophy. 
He  was  editor  of  the  North  American  Revieiv 
from  1843  to  1854,  and  in  that  capacity,  as 
well  as  in  independent  publications,  gave  the 
fruits  of  a  vigorous  intellect  and  a  remarkable 
industry.  His  economic  writings  in  the  main 
are  in  the  nature  of  text-books,  stating  and 
illustrating  the  doctrines  of  the  classic  econo- 
mists. But  on  the  subject  of  international 
trade  he  diverged,  and  reasoned  in  favour  of 
the  doctrine  of  protection.  He  laid  stress  on 
the  need  of  national  independence,  and  of  aid- 
ing young  industries  ;  and  he  made  application 
also  of  Mill's  reasoning  as  to  the  possible  effects 
of  duties  on  the  play  of  international  demand. 
On  this  subject,  as  on  all  he  touched,  he  was 
clear,  positive,  and  effective,  and  his  reasoning 
is  much  above  the  level  of  that  usually  adduced 
against  the  principle  of  free  trade. 

The  larger  writings  of  F.  Bo  wen  on  economics 
were :  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  Boston, 
1856  ;  American  Political  Economy,  New  York, 
1870.  P.  w.  T. 

BOXHORN,  Marcus  Zuerius,  bom  1602 
(or  1612)  at  Bergen-op-Zoom  (North  Brabant), 
was  professor  of  rhetoric  at  the  university  of 
Leyden,  1632  ;  professor  of  history  there,  1648  ; 
and  died  1653.  He  wrote  no  books  exclusively 
on  economics,  but  dealt  with  economic  subjects 
in  the  following  works  : — 

1st,  Institutiones  politicce,  Lipsise,  1650  ;  fol- 
lowing editions  (Hagse  Comitis,  1668,  Ultrajecti 
1702). — Gum  Commentariis  eiusdem  et  dbservation- 
ibus  Oeorgii  Eornii  (his  successor  at  the  university). 
— 2d,  Disquisitiones politicce,  i.e.  60  castis politici 
ex  omni  historia  selecti  (Hagae  Comitis,  1650). — 3d, 
Commentariolits  de  Statu  confoederatarum  pro- 
vindarum  Belgii  (2d.  ed.  1650),  and  an  extract  of  it : 
lieipiiblicce  Batavicce  brevis  et  accurata  descriptio. 
— In  a  special  work,  Dissertatio  de  Trapezitis,  vulgo 
Longdbardis,  qui  infcederato  Belgio  Mensas  fcene- 
bres  exercent  (Lugd.  Bat.  1640),  Boxhom  treated 
the  question  of  interest.  According  to  him  a 
principal  duty  of  government  is  the  promoting  of 
industry,  not  only  by  indirect  ways  {privilegiis, 
itinerum  securitate,  etc.),  but  by  direct  ones  too, 
guilds  preventing  merchandise  from  deteriorating, 
and  therefore  trade  from  declining.  A  well-regulated 
currency  is  also  of  extreme  importance.  His  ideas 
on  taxes  are,  considering  his  date,  remarkable. 
Taxes  should  be  levied  conveniently,  ought  to  be 
proportionate  to  the  wealth  of  the  contributors, 
and  may  be  used  as  a  means  even  to  promote 
morality.  They  should  never  be  imposed  on 
articles  of  export  except  on  those  nowhere  else 
obtainable.  a.  f.  v.  l. 

BOYCOTTING,    an    expression    of    recent 


origin,  and  derived  from  the  name  of  Captain 
Boycott,  who  was  the  first  known  person  sub- 
jected to  the  treatment  indicated  by  it.  Cap- 
tain Boycott  (the  name  is  sometimes  written 
Boycatt)  was,  in  1880,  living  at  Lough  Mask 
House,  County  Mayo,  as  land  agent  to  Lord 
Erne,  an  Irish  nobleman.  The  circumstances 
which  gave  rise  to  the  term  occurred  during  the 
land  agitation  of  1880-1881.  A  boycotted 
person  is  cut  off  from  all  intercourse  with  his 
neighbours ;  nobody  is  allowed  to  take  his 
land,  to  work  for  him,  to  supply  him  with 
goods,  or  to  help  or  assist  him  in  any  way. 
This  treatment  has  in  many  districts  of  Ireland 
been  applied  to  landlords,  who,  in  the  opinion 
of  the  agi-arian  association  by  which  it  is 
directed,  have  been  harsh  to  their  tenants  ;  or 
to  persons  who  have  taken  farms  the  former 
tenants  of  which  had  been  evicted  ;  or  gener- 
ally to  persons  who  in  their  dealings  with  land- 
lords have  not  conformed  to  the  instructions 
laid  down  by  the  association  to  the  poAver  of 
which  the  tenant  farmers  of  the  district  submit. 
Persons  who  combine  to  compel  or  induce  any 
one  to  take  part  in  the  process  of  boycotting 
may  under  the  general  criminal  law  be  subject 
to  a  prosecution  for  conspiracy,  and,  in  so  far 
as  this  is  the  case,  tliey  may  in  a  district  pro- 
claimed under  the  Criminal  Law  and  Procedure 
(Ireland)  Act,  1887,  be  tried  by  a  court  of 
summary  jurisdiction  (50  &  51  Vict.  c.  20 
§  2  [1]). 

[The  word  boycotting  is  now  frequently  used  in 
a  wider  sense,  meaning  simply  avoiding,  holding 
aloof  from,  and  in  that  sense  it  has  also  been  in- 
troduced into  foreign  languages  (German,  boykot- 
tiren  ;  French,  boycottier).  For  the  boycott  in 
America  see  article.  Economic  Journal,  vol.  i. 
No.  1.  The  Boycott  as  an  Element  in  Trade  Dis- 
putes, by  John  Burnett.]  e.  s. 

BRADLAUGH,  Charles  (born  1833,  died 
1891).  Bradlaugh  was  best  known  as  a  radical 
reformer,  secularist,  and  neo-Malthusian.  But 
towards  the  end  of  his  life,  when  he  was 
allowed  to  take  his  seat  in  the  House  of 
Commons  for  Northampton,  and  his  force  of 
intellect  received  fair  scope,  he  confined  him- 
self mainly  to  political  work,  and  especially  to 
questions  affecting  labour,  finance,  and  Indian 
government.  Though  he  never  read  for  the 
bar,  he  had  a  wide  and  accurate  knowledge  of 
law  ;  and,  throughout  his  whole  career  as  an 
agitator,  he  always  (like  Cobbett)  strove  to 
keep  every  movement  in  which  he  Avas  con- 
cerned within  the  bounds  of  strict  legality. 
He  was  a  staunch  free-trader  and  individualist ; 
and  his  latest  published  writing  was  in  opposi- 
tion to  the  proposal  for  a  legal  restriction  of 
the  hours  of  adult  labour.  J.  b. 

BRANDS  and  other  CERTIFICATES  OF 
QUALITY,  Government.  The  most  im- 
portant case  in  which  the  British  government 
gives  a  guarantee  of  the  quality  of  an  article  of 


176 


BRASSAGE— BBAY 


commerce  is  that  of  the  crown  brand  on  barrels 
of  herrings  cured  in  Scotland.  Till  1830  a 
bounty  was  paid  on  barrels  which  were  branded 
as  coming  up  to  a  certain  standard  of  quality, 
and  after  the  bounty  was  abolished  the  practice 
of  branding  baiTels  which  reached  the  standard 
continued.  In  1856  Messrs.  Bonamy  PfeiCE 
and  F.  St.  John,  and  Capt.  B.  J.  Sulivan,  were 
commissioned  to  inquire  whether  it  would  be 
better  to  abolish  the  brand  or  charge  a  fee  for 
it,  as  the  Treasury  was  no  longer  willing  to  pay 
for  the  inspection  which  it  involved.  Messrs. 
Price  and  St.  John  (Captain  Sulivan  dissenting) 
recommended  that  it  should  be  maintained  and 
4d.  a  barrel  charged  for  it.  This  plan  was 
adopted.  In  1881  a  committee  of  the  House 
of  Commons  made  an  exhaustive  inquiry  as  to 
its  effects,  and  by  a  large  majority  reported  in 
favour  of  maintaining  it.  Opponents  of  the 
brand  say  that  it  is  inimical  to  improvements 
in  curing,  that  it  encourages  speculation,  and 
that,  though  it  affords  no  real  guarantee,  curers 
are  obliged  to  apply  for  it  by  the  unfounded 
prejudices  of  their  continental  customers,  which 
would  necessarily  disappear  with  its  abolition. 
Its  supporters  maintain  that  it  enables  small  and 
little-known  curers  to  compete  with  great  houses, 
and  prevents  frauds,  and  they  add  that  as  appli- 
cation for  the  brand  is  purely  voluntary,  branding 
would  fall  into  disuse  if  it  were  really  of  no  value. 

The  arrangements  of  the  Cork  butter  market 
necessitate  the  testing  and  branding  of  butter 
by  an  oflScial  inspector,  a  system  condemned  by 
the  royal  commission  on  agriculture  in  1881. 
Under  acts  of  parliament  passed  in  1864,  1871, 
and  1874,  all  chain-cables  and  anchors  sold  for 
British  ships  have  to  undergo  an  official  test 
and  obtain  the  official  stamp.  Gun  barrels  are 
subject  to  similar  regulations,  and  many  gold 
and  silver  articles  cannot  legally  be  sold  with- 
out the  hall  mark.  In  all  ordinary  cases  the 
buyers  are  obviously  the  best  judges  of  the  kind 
ol  commodity  they  want,  and  their  demand 
suffices  to  cause  its  production  and  in  many 
cases  its  progressive  improvement  in  quality. 
"  Caveat  emptor  {q.v.)  is  the  sound  general 
rule  economically  and  socially  as  well  as  legally  " 
(Farrer,  State  in  Relation  to  Trade,  p.  150).  A 
government  certificate  is  likely  to  be  of  value 
only  when  it  certifies  to  quite  definite  facts 
which  are  not  easily  ascertainable  by  the 
buyers.  It  is  admitted  by  nearly  every  one  to 
be  useful  in  the  case  of  coins,  which  are  pieces 
of  metal  certified  by  a  government  stamp  to  be 
of  a  certain  weight  and  quality. 

(See  Administeation  ;  Conditioning  ; 
Laissez  faire.) 

[Report  on  the  Fishery  Board  of  Scotland,  Pari. 
Papers,  1857  (65  Sess.  1),  xv.  39.— Report  on 
Herring  Brand  (Scotland),  Pari.  Papers,  1881, 
293,  ix.  1.— T.  H.  Farrer,  The  State  in  Relation 
to  Trade,  pp.  145  to  151. — J.  S.  Mill,  Principles 
of  Political  Economy,  bk.  v.  ch.  xi.  §§  7  and  8.] 

B.C. 


BRASSAGE.  A  charge  made  for  coining, 
sometimes  called  a  seigneuriage.  The  word 
means  "strictly  the  stirring  in  the  furnace  ol 
the  molten  metals,  and  next  the  allowance 
made  to  the  individual  by  whom  the  operations  of 
coining  were  farmed  "  (Paper  by  J.  B.  Martin 
"Seigneuriage  and  Mint  Chfirges"  {Journal, 
Institute  of  Bankers,  April,  1884).  No  charges 
of  this  description  are  made  at  the  royal  mint  in 
England,  though  they  are  made  at  the  branches 
of  the  mint  at  Sydney  and  Melbourne  (see 
Mint).  In  England  the  Bank  of  England,  by 
arrangement  with  the  government,  buys  gold  at 
£3  :  17  :  9  per  standard  ounce,  and  sells  again 
at  £3  :  17  :  10-^.  In  France,  a  charge  exists  of 
6*70  frs.  per  kilo  (=  -0025)  equivalent  to  about 
■^d.  per  £  sterling,  the  corresponding  expense  in 
England,  covered  by  the  arrangement  made 
with  the  bank  named  above,  being  estimated  at 
fVd.  per  £.  The  advisability,  or  otherwise,  of 
making  such  a  charge  appears  to  be  an  open 
question  which  can  best  be  decided  by  those 
immediately  concerned. 

["Seigneuriage  and  Mint  Charges,"  by  J.  B. 
Martin,  Journal  of  the  Institute  of  Bankers,  April 
1884. — Seigniorage  and  Charge  for  Coining, 
Ernest  Seyd,  1868. — Arbitrages  et  Parit^s,  Ott. 
Haupt,  1883, — Report,  International  Coinage 
Commission,  1868. — Mint  Reports,  etc.] 

BRASSEY,  Thomas  (1805-1870),  bom  in 
Cheshire,  where  his  family  had  flourished  for  six 
centuries,  illustrated  an  ancient  house  by  his 
distinguished  success  in  the  new  calling  of 
railway  contractor.  In  his  dealings  with 
labourers  in  different  parts  of  the  world — em- 
ploying the  English  navvy  at  3s.  6d.,  the 
Indian  coolie  at  6d.  a  day — Brassey  had  an  un- 
rivalled opportunity  of  verifying  the  truth  that 
the  cost  of  labour  to  the  employer  is  not  pro- 
portioned to  the  amount  of  daily  wages.  He 
is  even  said  to  have  found  "that  for  the  same 
sum  of  money  the  same  amount  of  work  was 
everywhere  performed  "  (  Work  arid  Wages,  by 
Mr.  Thomas  (now  Lord)  Brassey,  ch.  iii.  ;  Life 
and  Labours  of  Mr.  Brassey,  by  Sir  Arthur  Helps, 
ch.  v.,  end).  But  this  proposition,  understood 
exactly,  is  not  only,  as  Cairnes  points  out 
{Leading  Principles,  pt.  ii.  ch.  iii.  §  7)  a  priori 
improbable,  but  inconsistent  with  several  of 
Brassey's  experiences.  With  respect  to  many 
other  questions,  the  comparative  efficiency  of 
labour  in  different  countries,  the  effect  of  short 
hours  on  efficiency,  the  alleged  deterioration  of 
the  labourer — the  experiences  of  Brassey  re- 
corded by  his  son  in  the  work  referred  to  are 
valuable  to  the  economist.  Mr.  Frederick 
Harrison's  interpretation  of  the  facts  stated  by 
Lord  Brassey  is  remarkable  (Review  of  Work 
and  Wages  in  the  Fortnightly  Review  for  1872). 

[For  the  particulars  of  Brassey's  noble  and  bene- 
ficent life,  see  Sir  Arthur  Helps's  Life  and  Labours 
of  Mr.  Brassey.']  F.  T.  b. 

.  BRAY,  Charles  (1811-1 884)  born  at  Coven- 
try,  was  a  ribbon  manufacturer  in  that  city,  but 


BRAY— BRECK 


177 


retired  from  that  business  in  1856.  From  his 
youth  upwards  Bray  had  been  active  in  social 
and  educational  reforms ;  and  in  his  principal 
work  he  proceeded  on  the  lines  of  Owen  and 
Carlyle,  advocating  Co-operation  and  organ- 
isation of  labour  against  Competition. 

See  the  2d  vol.  of  The  Philosojphy  of  Necessity; 
or,  The  Law  of  Consequences,  as  applicable  to 
Mental,  Moral,  and  Social  Science,  by  Charles 
Bray,  London,  1841,  pp.  301-389,  2d  ed.  1863, 
3d,  1889.  The  appendix  to  this  work  has  been 
published  separately  in  1844  {An  Outline  of  the 
various  Social  Systems  and  Communities  which 
have  been  founded  on  the  Principle  of  Co-operation) ; 
this  was  written  by  his  sister-in-law,  Mary 
Hennell  {d.  1843),  and  gives  valuable  information 
on  socialistic  doctrines  in  England.  Bray's  other 
works  concerning  social  economy  ai-e  :  Address  to 
the  Working  Classes  on  the  Education  of  the 
Body,  1837  (see  his  autobiography.  Phases  of 
Opinion  and  Experience  during  a  Long  Life,  1884, 
ch.  vi.  and  vii.)  An  Essay  upon  the  Union  of 
Agriculture  and  Mamfactures,  and  upon  the 
Organisation  of  Industry,  1844,  and  two  papers 
read  before  the  British  Association  for  the  Advance- 
ment of  Social  Science,  October  1857  :  The 
Industrial  Employment  of  Women,  and  The 
Income  of  the  Kingdom,  and  the  Mode  of  its 
Distribution,  in  which  he  computes  that  one- 
seventh  of  the  population  possess  two-thirds  of 
the  annual  income. 

[Holyoake,  The  History  of  Co-operation  in 
England,  1875,  vol.  i.  p.  I7,"329n.— A.  Menger, 
Das  Recht  anf  den  vollen  Arbeitsertrag,  1886, 
p.  58.]  s.  B. 

BRAY,  J.  F.,  early  in  19th  century,  is  the 
author  of  Labour's  Wrongs  and  Labours 
Remedy  ;  or,  the  Age  of  Might  and  the  Age  of 
Right,  Leeds,  1839.  He  was  a  follower  of 
Owen  and  Thomson  ;  his  book  tries  to  prove 
"  that  all  those  who  perform  equality  of  labour 
ought  likewise  to  receive  equality  of  reward  " 
(p.  30),  and  though  he  admits  that  even  this 
does  not  involve  perfect  justice,  that  "such 
equality  is  infinitely  more  just  than  the  mode  of 
rewarding  labour  under  the  present  system  "  (p. 
206).  Impressed  by  the  modern  growth  of  joint- 
stock  companies.  Bray  proposes  a  "joint-stock 
modification  of  society,  admitting  of  individual 
property  in  productions  in  connection  with  a 
common  property  in  productive  powers"  (p.  194), 
and  proposes  a  paper  and  pottery  currency, 
whose  foundation  is  labour,  in  order  "to  secure 
the  public  against  any  other  variations  in  the 
value  of  the  currency  than  those  to  which  the 
standard  itself  is  subject"  (pp.  143,  198).  This 
book  is,  notwithstanding  all  illusions,  written 
in  a  remarkably  lively  style. 

[Holyoake,  The  History  of  Co-operation  in 
England,  1875,  vol.  i.  p.  224. — A.  Menger,  Das 
Recht  auf  den  vollen  Arbeitsertrag,  1886,  pp.  58, 
94  (corrects  the  statements  given  in  K.  Marx,  La 
misere  de  la  Philosophic,  1847,  p.  62).]        s.  B. 

In  Bray's  work,  mentioned  above,  Labours 
Wrongs    and    Laborers  Remedy,    or   the   Age 

VOL.  T. 


of  Might  and  the  Age  of  Right  (Leeds, 
1839),  the  current  economical  doctrines  were 
examined  with  acuteness  and  force,  and  were 
said  to  involve  "that  under  the  present 
system  there  is  no  hope  for  the  working  man." 
At  present  (Bray  considers)  no  political  or  fiscal 
reforms,  and  no  Trade  Unions  or  Savings 
Banks,  will  permanently  lessen  poverty.  So 
long  as  property,  whether  in  land  or  in  the 
instruments  of  production,  remains  as  it  is,  one 
man's  gain  is  another  man's  loss  ;  the  only  way 
to  be  rich  is  to  seize  the  fruits  of  another  man's 
labour  ;  and  the  only  permanent  remedy  is  a 
complete  overturning  of  the  present  system  and 
an  organising  of  production  by  the  community 
itself.  In  place  of  individual  employers  would 
come  groups  of  joint-stock  companies  under 
general  and  local  boards  of  trade.  All  men 
would  be  workers,  and  would  receive  "the 
whole  fruits  of  their  labour."  The  labour 
necessary  to  life  would  gradually  fall  from  8  or 
10  hours  a  day  to  5  hours,  production  being 
immensely  increased  by  the  new  system,  and 
being  likely  to  keep  ahead  of  population  "  for 
thousands  of  years."  Among  writers  of  his 
school  Bray  deserves  more  recognition  than  he 
usually  obtains.  His  errors  of  theory  (such  as 
the  confusion  of  value  with  cost)  are  not 
peculiar  to  him,  but  are  shared  by  Karl  Marx 
and  (j^^enerally  speaking)  the  Ricardian  school 
of  socialists.  j.  b. 

BREACH  OF  TRUST  (Scots  criminal  law 
term).  Fraudulent  appropriation  by  trustee,  or 
failure  in  duty  by  oflicial,  etc. 

BREACH  OF  TRUST.  Any  act  or  omis- 
sion on  the  part  of  a  trustee  violating  the  con- 
ditions of  the  trust  or  the  rules  of  law  concern- 
ing the  investment  or  administration  of  trust 
property.  The  liability  of  trustees  for  breach 
of  trust  is  a  very  stringent  one,  but  the 
Trustee  Act  1888  (51  •&  62  Vict.  c.  59)  has 
relaxed  it  to  a  certain  extent.  It  is,  for 
instance,  the  rile  that  advances  on  mortgage  of 
freehold  property  must  not  exceed  two-thirds  of 
the  value  of  the  mortgaged  property.  Accord- 
ing to  the  former  law  trustees  having  once  gone 
beyond  the  limit  were  liable  for  whatever  loss 
might  subsequently  have  been  incurred  ;  since 
the  date  of  the  new  act  they  cannot  be  called 
upon  to  replace  more  than  the  difference 
between  the  amount  which  they  would  have 
been  authorised  to  advance  and  the  amount 
actually  lent.  The  trustees  are  also  placed  in 
a  more  favourable  position  with  regard  to  un- 
authorised investments  made  at  the  request  or 
with  the  consent  of  a  beneficiary.  In  the  case 
of  express  trusts  the  trustees  were  not  author- 
ised to  plead  any  statute  of  Limitations,  but 
they  may  now,  in  the  absence  of  fraud  or  mis- 
appropriation, rely  on  the  statute.  E.  s. 

BRECK,  Samuel,  was  bom  in  1771  in  Boston 
and  afterwards  settled  in  Philadelphia.  He 
wrote  in  1843  a  small  -pamiplilettJIistorical Sketch 


178 


BREHON  LAW— BREWSTER 


of  ContiTiental  Paper  Money,  Philadelphia,  pp. 
40.  In  this  he  attempts  to  demonstrate  that 
the  non-redemption  of  the  paper  money  after  the 
revolution  acted  as  a  moderate  tax  by  reason  of 
its  gradual  depreciation,  and  that  the  issue  was 
not  so  unfortunate  as  is  generally  claimed. 
Throughout  his  life — in  congress  and  in  private 
— he  took  a  decided  stand  in  favour  of  internal 
improvements.  For  details  see  Memoir  by  J. 
Francis  Fisher,  Philadelphia,  1863,  pp.  45. 

D.  R.  D. 

BREHON  LAW.  The  Brehons  were  a  heredi- 
tary class  of  judges  in  Ireland,  to  whom  disputes 
were  referred  for  arbitration,  and  whose  decisions 
were  regarded  as  binding,  though  there  was 
no  sanction  to  enforce  them.  It  is  probable, 
though  by  no  means  certain,  that  the  Brehons 
were  descended  from  the  earlier  Druids,  who 
lost  their  priestly  functions  on  the  introduction 
of  Christianity,  but  retained  their  judicial 
power.  The  decisions  of  the  Brehons  formed  a 
vast  mass  of  customary  law,  a  knowledge  of 
which  was  the  exclusive  property  of  the  class. 
Gradually  this  law  was  reduced  to  writing,  and 
has  been  preserved  to  us  in  the  Senchus  Mor 
and  the  Book  of  Aicill,  which  have  been  pub- 
lished in  the  Irish  RoUs  Series. 

The  Brehon  law  throws  great  light  on  the 
important  part  played  by  consanguinity  in  the 
formation  of  society.  The  unit  of  the  social 
system  in  Ireland  was  the  tvMth  or  tribe,  con- 
sisting of  the  real  or  supposed  descendants  of  a 
common  ancestor.  The  tribe  owned  a  district 
of  land,  which  was  unequally  distributed  for 
occupation  among  its  free  members.  Rank, 
originally  a  matter  of  birth,  had  come  to  depend 
mainly  upon  wealth,  and  wealth  was  estimated 
not  in  land  but  in  cattle.  The  authority  of 
the  tribal  chief  belonged  to  him,  not  as  lord  of 
the  land,  but  because  he  supplied  cattle  to  the 
poorer  occupiers  of  tribal  land.  For  this  grant 
the  recipient  had  to  pay  a  rent  either  in  kind 
or  in  service.  The  more  cattle  belonged  to  a 
flaith,  or  noble,  the  larger  number  of  retainers 
could  he  possess,  and  the  higher  was  his  social 
position.  The  lowest  freeman  was  the  oc-aire, 
who  possessed  a  cottage,  and  a  right  over  the 
common  pasture.  If  he  could  acquire  ten  cows 
he  rose  to  the  rank  of  bo-aire,  or  cow  possessor. 
As  time  went  on  the  nobles  gradually  seized  the 
unoccupied  portions  of  the  tribal  land,  and  the 
idea  of  private  property  supplanted  the  earlier 
theory  of  joint  ownership. 

But  a  clear  trace  of  the  latter  survived  in  the 
rale  of  succession,  known  as  Gavelkind  (q.v.) 
On  the  death  of  the  occupant  of  land,  the 
estate  passed  neither  to  his  eldest  son  nor  to 
the  joint  or  separate  occupation  of  his  children. 
On  the  contrary  the  land  fell  back  into  the 
common  property  of  the  tribe,  and  the  chief 
made  a  redistribution  of  all  the  lands  among 
the  members.  This  custom  is  unquestionabl}' 
due  to  the  original  idea  that  a  tribe  constituted 


a  family,  and  that  the  whole  kindred  were 
joint-heirs  of  any  individual  member.  But 
gavelkind  did  not  apply  to  the  succession  to  the 
lands  of  nobles,  which  was  regulated,  like  the 
succession  to  the  office  of  chief,  by  the  custom 
ofTANiSTRT.  By  this  custom  a  successor  or 
tanist  was  elected  by  the  members  of  the  sept 
or  tribe  during  the  lifetime  of  the  chief  or 
noble.  The  object  was  to  secure  the  succession 
of  the  fittest  member  of  a  family  instead  of 
merely  the  nearest  blood  relation. 

Both  gavelkind  and  tanistry  were  disliked 
by  the  English  rulers,  as  being  less  definite 
and  orderly  than  the  rule  of  Primogeniture. 
Under  James  I.  they  were  abolished  as  ' '  lewd  i 
and  damnable  customs."  From  this  time  the 
Brehon  law  was  jealously  suppressed,  and  the 
English  legal  system,  which  had  hitherto  been 
enforced  only  in  the  counties  of  the  Pale  was 
now  applied  to  the  whole  of  Ireland. 

[Ancient  Laws  of  Ireland  (Irish  Rolls  Series). 
— 0' Curry,  Manners  and  Otistoms  of  the  Ancient 
Irish. — Maine,  Early  History  of  Institutions. — 
Richey,  A  Short  History  of  the  Irish  People.'] 

K.   L. 

BREVI  MANU  TRADITIO.  An  expression 
used  by  mediaeval  writers  on  Roman  law  to 
express  tlie  fictitious  delivery  which  takes 
place,  when  a  person  who  is  in  physical  posses- 
sion of  another  person's  property  acquires  the 
ownership  of  the  same  by  purchase  or  otherwise. 

BREWSTER,  Sir  Francis  (fl.  1674-1702), 
was  in  1674  lord  mayor  of  Dublin,  and  in 
1698  appointed  commissioner  to  inquire  into 
the  forfeited  estates  in  Ireland.  He  wrote 
Essays  on  Trade  and  Navigation.  In  Five 
Pa/rts—The  First  Part,  London,  1695.  They 
seem  to  be  written  with  the  design  of  supporting 
the  Dutch  against  the  growing  commercial 
power  of  the  French.  He  proposes  a  council  of 
trades,  a  national  bank,  hospitals,  working 
schools,  and  the  naturalisation  of  foreign 
protestants,  especially  in  Ireland  ;  he  makes 
objections  to  the  projects  of  erecting  free  ports 
and  recommends  sumptuary  laws.  His  state- 
ment that  England  upon  an  average  of  six 
years  gained  by  Ireland  two  millions  sterling  ■ 
per  annum,  and  his  denunciation  of  the  9 
oppressive  treatment  to  which  that  country  was  ^ 
subjected  (p.  15  ff.)  were  strongly  controverted 
by  Davenant  (see  his  Works,  edited  by  Ch. 
Whitworth,  vol.  i.  p.  377).  His  New  Essays 
(sic)  on  Trade,  1702,  make  him  rank  among 
those  pessimistic  authors  who  constantly 
foresee  the  decline  of  trade  (p.  2).  Neverthe- 
less he  insists  upon  the  necessity  of  allowing 
the  exportation  of  wool,  England  being  not  able 
to  work  up  two-thirds  of  its  own,  and  forced 
*'  either  to  Burn  or  Export  it "  (p.  9).  He 
recommends  manufactures  as  a  means  of 
employing  the  poor  (p.  124).  **  I  think  him 
a  great  Man  tliat  employs  Twenty  Men  at  his 
Lpoms,  and  Five  Hundred  Spinners,  and  wondej 


BRIGANTI— BRISSOT  DE  WARVILLE 


179 


we  have  no  more  such  in  Parliament "  (p.  11). 
He  recognises  the  dangers  of  the  money  projects 
(p.  20),  and  of  the  stock-jobbing  mania  of  his 
age  (p.  30).  In  all  other  respects  his  mercan- 
tilist views  are  the  same  as  in  his  first  essays 
(see  e.g.  p.  41),  and  only  his  considerations  on 
the  advantage  of  a  union  between  England  and 
Ireland  (pp.  66-115),  with  many  statistical 
abstracts,  may  be  considered  as  valuable. 
[Macleod,  Dictionary  of  Pol.  Econ.,  p.  284.] 

S.  B. 
BRIGANTI,  FiLiPPO,  born  at  GallipoH  1725, 
died  1804.  In  1780  he  published,  in  two 
volumes,  his  Esame  economico  del  sistema  civile 
(viz.  Economical  Analysis  of  Society),  which  is 
really  a  refutation  of  the  social  doctrines  of 
Mably,  Rousseau,  and  Linguet,  particularly 
of  their  paradoxes  concerning  the  obnoxiousness 
of  commerce,  industry,  and  intellectual  progress. 
Briganti  was  a  profound  thinker,  and  had  a  vast 
fund  of  information.  Discussing  the  advantages 
of  exchange  and  commerce,  he  anticipates  many 
of  the  views  which  are  now  advanced  in  this 
connection  concerning  sensations  of  pleasure 
and  pain,  and,  in  general  the  hedonistical 
calculus,  as  the  basis  of  economical  activity. 
In  tracing  the  history  of  human  progress  and 
following  it  up  in  the  history  of  agriculture, 
commerce,  navigation,  population,  and  intel- 
lectual and  moral  development,  he  shows  him- 
self to  be  possessed  of  a  great  store  of  informa- 
tion. His  book,  however,  has  lost  its  interest, 
because  its  principal  object,  viz.  the  refutation 

i      of  Rousseau's  theories,  has  likewise  ceased  to 
interest.  m.  p. 

BRIGHT,  John  (b.  1811,  d.  1889)  M.P., 
president  of  the  board  of  trade  (1868-1870), 
eminent  orator  and  statesman.  The  creation 
of  a  numerous  proprietary  in  Ireland  was 
eloquently  advocated  by  Bright.  The  clauses 
in  the  Irish  Land  Bill  of  1870,  which  facilitate 
the  sale  of  land  to  tenants,  are  ascribed  to 
his  influence  and  associated  with  his  name. 
The  part  which  Bright  played  in  the  abolition 
of  the  corn  laws  is  also  memorable.  But  there 
are  limits  to  the  application  of  the  idea  of  non- 
intervention which  did  not  occur  to  him.  He 
carried  the  principle  of  Laissez-Faire  so  far  as  to 
oppose  factory  legislation  ;  concerning  which  he 
thus  defines  his  position — "  I  was  opposed  to  all 
legislation  restricting  the  work  of  adult  men 
and  women.  I  was  in  favour  of  legislation 
restricting  the  labour  and  guarding  the  health 
of  children." 

[Speeches  on  Questions  of  Public  Policy,  edited 
by  J.  E.  Thorold  Rogers,  1868  ;  Hansard,  Ixxiii. 

I      p.  1132,  Ixxxix.  p.  1136,  exciv.  p.  731,  et  passim; 

:      Public  Letters,  edited  by  J.  Leech,  1885.] 

F.  Y.  E. 

BRINDLEY,  James  (born  1716,  died  1772), 
an  emment  engineer,  celebrated  for  the  con- 
struction of  canals,  of  which  the  earliest  and 
raost    famous,     connecting    Manchester    with 


Worsley  and  Liverpool,  was  executed  under  the 
auspices  of  the  Duke  of  Bridgewater  (1759- 
1773),  and  called  after  his  name.  Almost 
totally  uneducated,  Brindley  owed  his  success 
to  the  sheer  force  of  genius.  In  thinking  out 
his  mechanical  designs  he  sought  no  aid  from 
books  or  models  ;  and  would  even,  for  the  pur- 
pose of  greater  abstraction,  retire  to  bed  for  two 
or  three  days.  The  saying  that  "  the  natural 
use  of  rivers  was  to  feed  navigable  canals," 
is  characteristically  attributed  to  Brindley. 

[Bibliotheca  Britannica. — Lives  of  the  Engin- 
eers, by  Smiles.]  f.  y.  e. 

BRISCOE,  John  (17th  century),  ranks  second 
to  H.  Chamberlin  among  the  projectors  of 
land  banks  who  flourished  in  the  latter  part 
of  the  17th  century.  Briscoe's  project  is 
set  forth  in  his  Discourse  on  the  Late  Funds 
.  .  .  (1694,  third  ed.  1696).  An  Abstract 
of  this  discourse,  and  also  a  Dialogue  (between 
Freeholder  and  Philanglus)  "explanatory" 
thereof  followed  soon  (1694)  from  Briscoe's 
pen.  He  continued  in  a  series  of  broadsheets 
to  repeat  with  variations  his  proposals  for 
setting  up  a  land  bank.  A  proposal  which  he 
made  for  regulation  of  the  coin  (1695)  is  not 
unconnected  with  his  darling  project.  He 
accuses  J.  Asgill  (q.v.)  of  having  appropriated 
his  ideas,  see  3fr.  John  Asgill,  his  Flagiarism 
detected,  .  .  .  1696.  Briscoe  himself  is  accused 
of  plagiarising  from  Chamberlin,  by  the  author 
of  A  Rod  for  the  Fool's  Back,  or  Dr.  Chamberlin 
and  his  Proposals  Vindicated,  1694,  attributed 
to  Chamberlin.  However,  Briscoe  appears 
as  the  **  literary  advocate  of  Chamberlin's  land 
bank "  (Thorold  Rogers)  in  a  letter  to  the 
doctor  dated  1693,  published  in  1696  by 
Chamberlin.  In  some  remarks  prefixed  to  this 
letter  Chamberlin  speaks  of  the  "  great  reputa- 
tion Mr.  Briscoe  hath  among  some  of  our 
senators."  Chamberlin  adds  (at  the  end  of  the 
letter),  "  As  a  stronger  confirmation  of  the  good 
opinion  Mr.  B.  had  of  the  doctor's  100  years 
proposal,  he  subscribed  £200  per  annum." 
Briscoe  shares  with  Chamberlin,  in  proportions 
which  it  is  not  easy  to  assign,  the  responsibility 
of  having  originated  the  land  bank,  which 
proved  such  a  complete  failure  in  1696  (see 
Hugh  CHAMBEPtLEN  or  Chamberlin). 

[Macaulay,  History  of  England,  ch.  xx.  and 
xxii.  (vol.  iv.  pp.  496  and  701,  large  8vo  ed.) — 
Tliorold  Rogers,  First  Nine  Years  of  Bank  of 
England,  pp.  15  and  50. — Quarterly  Journal  of 
Economics,  vol.  ii.  p.  490. — Macleod's  Dictionary, 
sub  voce  "  Briscoe. "]  f.  t.  k. 

BRISSOT  DE  WARVILLE,  Jean-Pierre, 
was  born  1754,  at  Ouarville  near  Chartres.  He 
was  executed  in  Paris  in  1793.  After  having 
been  imprisoned  in  the  Bastille,  he  went  to 
England  and  to  the  United  States,  and  returned 
to  Paris  at  the  outbreak  of  the  Revolution,  in 
which  he  played  a  remarkable  part,  being  accused 
of  federalism  by  Robespierre.     After  the  revolu 


180 


BROGGIA— BROKER 


tion  of  31st  May  1793,  he  was  proscribed  ;  he 
tried  in  vain  to  escape,  but  was  arrested,  and 
died  on  the  scaffold,  31st  October  1793.  In 
his  writings,  Brissot  de  Warville  advocated  the 
reform  of  the  penal  laws  and  attacked  the  slave- 
holders in  the  colonies. 

His  works  are  collected  under  the  title : 
Bihliotheque  philosophique  du  Legislateur  du 
politique  et  du  jurisconsulte  (10  vols.,  Berlin, 
1782-1785).  One  of  these  works  is  remarkable 
on  account  of  its  influence  on  later  socialists : 
Recherches  philosophiques,  sur  le  droit  de 
proprUti  et  sur  le  vol  considirSs  dans  la  nature 
et  dans  la  sociSti,  1780  (Biblioth^que,  etc. 
vol,  vi.  p.  260  ff.)  The  defence  of  the  right  of 
property  by  the  Phtsiockats  as  being  founded  in 
nature,  and  the  ridicule  bestowed  upon  this  axiom 
by  Voltaire  in  his  Homme  d  quarante  ^cus,  induced 
Brissot  de  Warville  to  inquire  into  the  justifiability 
of  this  doctrine  in  the  natural  and  actual  state  of 
society.  He  reasons  thus :  the  natural  title  of 
property  being  the  human  wants  of  self-preserva- 
tion and  freedom  of  locomotion  (p.  274),  there  is 
no  property  beyond  these  limits  founded  in  nature. 
But  civil  property  reaches  farther.  "  In  the  state 
of  nature  everybody  has  a  right  to  all ;  in  the 
social  state  a  man  who  has  nothing  left  by  his 
parents  has  a  right  to  nothing.  The  thief  in  the 
natural  state  is  the  rich  man,  who  possesses 
superfluities  ;  in  the  social  state  he  is  called  a 
thief  who  steals  them  from  the  rich.  What 
an  upturn  of  ideas!"  (p.  382).  The  object  of 
this  work  was  to  mitigate  the  rigour  of  the  penal 
laws  against  theft.  In  this  direction  its  efl'ect  was 
not  inconsiderable,  but  its  influence  upon  the 
formation  of  the  creed  of  Babeuf  and  Proudhon  has 
incidentally  been  distinctly  greater  (see  Babeuf  ; 
Communism  ;  Proudhon). 

[Villegardelle,  Histoire  des  idees  sociales,  etc. 
1846,  pp.  124-129. — J.  J.  Thonissen,  Le  Socialisms, 
1852,  vol.  i.  pp.  286-291.— A.  Menger,  Das  Recht 
aufden  vollen  Arbeitsertrag,  1886,  pp.  8,  40,  71.] 

s.  B. 

BROGGIA,  Antonio,  a  learned  Neapolitan 
merchant,  also  a  politician  and  author  of  two 
treatises,  one  on  taxation  {Trattato  dei  trihuti, 
1743),  which  was  translated  into  German,  and 
the  other  on  money  {Trattato  delle  Trumete  con- 
siderate nd  rapporti  di  legittima  riduzione,  di 
drcolazione  e  di  depodto,  1743).  Both  treatises 
are  still  interesting  to  read,  as  they  contain  a 
great  deal  of  what  at  the  present  time  is  still 
taught  and  thought  correct  concerning  these 
subjects.  As  is  natural  for  a  writer  living 
when  he  did,  Broggia  is  not  free  from  physio- 
cratic  prejudices.  In  his  treatise  on  taxation 
he  says  the  aim  of  the  theory  is  the  wealth  of 
the  state  ;  wealth  reposes  on  the  development 
of  agriculture,  industry,  and  commerce ;  industry 
in  general  ought  to  be  left  free  and  not  ham- 
pered by  vexatious  taxes  ;  the  working  classes, 
and  especially  peasants,  ought  to  have  their 
interests  particularly  considered,  as  on  their 
welfare  depends  much  of  the  prosperity  of  the 
state  ;  tithes  are  the  least  oppressive  taxes  and 
the  surest ;  taxes  ought  not  to  be  personal ; 


care  must  be  taken  that  taxes  do  not  crush  out 
trades  ;  agiicultural  animals  and  machinery  and 
tools  ought  not  to  be  taxed.  State  monopolies 
are  unadvisable.  Excise  and  custom  duties 
ought  not  to  be  leased  out  by  the  government. 
The  direct  land  tax,  if  necessary,  ought  to  be 
increased  rather  than  custom  duties  imposed. 
Notwithstanding  his  predilection  for  taxes  on 
rent,  Broggia  is  not  in  favour  of  one  single 
tax.  He  shows  the  advantages  of  indirect  taxes 
as  complementary  ;  he  only  insists  strongly  on 
custom  duties  being  moderate,  so  as  not  to 
molest  trade.  In  his  treatise  on  money,  a 
cardinal  point  is  that  the  wealth  of  a  country 
does  not  depend  upon  the  quantity  of  money 
existing  in  it  or  in  circulation,  but  upon  the 
amount  of  the  turnover  in  business.  In  1754 
Broggia  was  exiled  from  Palermo  for  having 
written  a  pamphlet  against  the  ministers.  This 
pamphlet  (a  volume  in  4to  of  136  pages)  was  a 
criticism  on  their  acts.  He  wrote  also  a  treatise 
on  public  hygiene  {Trattato politico  della  sanitd). 
This  treatise  and  the  two  other  ones  before 
mentioned  constitute  one  single  volume  in  the 
original  and  only  edition,  which  was  published 
before  Custodi  took  up  classifying,  correcting, 
and  publishing  Broggia's  writings.  The  title  of 
the  first  edition  is :  Trattato  dei  trihuti,  delle 
monete  e  del  govemo  politico  della  Sanitd.  In 
Napoli,  presso  Pietro  Palombo,  1743.  As  a 
complement  of  his  monetary  doctrines  must  be 
considered  a  pamphlet  he  wrote  in  defence  of 
them  under  the  extraordinary  title  which 
follows :  Risposte  alle  objezioni  state  fatte  da 
varj  Soggetti,  intorno  al  sistema  del  prezzo  cor- 
r&rUe,  che  assolutamente  dee  tenersi  per  la  ricom- 
pensa  degli  arrendamenti,  e  similmente  a  quelle 
state  anche  fatte  intorno  alia  rinnovazio'/ie  della 
moneta  di  rame,  che  dee  ancK  essa  avere  tutto 
quel  valore  intrinseco  che  di  giustizia  gli  spetta  ; 
e  tanta  farsene  che  nan  ecceda  il  puro  hisogno 
degli  scambj  minuti,  Napoli,  a  dl  14  Novembre 
1755.  Of  his  life  no  particulars  are  known, 
not  even  when  he  was  born  and  when  he  died. 
It  is  commonly  maintained  that  he  was  born 
in  1683,  and  that  he  died  in  1767,  but  the 
dates  are  contested.  His  works  are  included 
in  the  CoUezione  Custodi.  m.  p. 

BROKER,  General  A  broker  may  be 
generally  described  as  a  go-between,  who  brings 
buyers  and  sellers  together  ;  not  exactly  face  to 
face,  but  acting  as  an  intermediary  who  intro- 
duces their  bargains  rather  than  their  persous. 
The  position  is  a  responsible  one,  inasmuch  as 
the  principals  who  employ  a  broker  very  often 
keep  a  rimning  account  and  trust  him,  in  goods 
or  money,  to  large  amounts.  As  a  rule,  brokers 
are  under  the  rules  of  a  syndicate  or  corporate 
body  of  which  they  become  members,  and  to 
whose  rules  they  are  usually  amenable  on  pain 
of  expulsion.  There  are  tea  brokers,  cotiee 
brokers,  sugar  brokers,  and  so  on  without  end  in 
almost  every  wholesale  trade,  and  their  practice 


BROKER— BRYDGES 


181 


varies  with  their  standing,  some  brokers  being 
virtually  factors  or  warehousemen,  others  being 
simply  agents,  paid  by  fee,  instead  of  by  a 
varying  salary.  a.  e. 

BROKER,  Stock.  A  stock-broker  may  be 
either  a  member  of  the  stock  exchange  of 
London,  Dublin,  Manchester,  Liverpool,  Glas- 
gow, or  elsewhere  ;  or  only  what  is  known  as 
an  outside  broker.  His  duty  is  to  buy  or  sell 
for  a  "principal."  On  the  London  stock  ex- 
change, nobody  who  is  not  a  recognised  member 
is  permitted  to  deal.  A  broker,  having  received 
an  order  to  buy  say  £500  stock,  goes  to  any 
member  of  the  stock  exchange,  knoAvn  indifter- 
ently  as  a  jobber  or  dealer,  and  asks  for  a  quota- 
tion. The  dealer  quotes  two  prices,  say  80 j 
to  80^,  meaning  that  he  will  sell  to  the  broker 
at  the  higher  price  and  buy  at  the  lower  quota- 
tion. If  the  broker  consider  this  fair  he  will 
say,  "  I  buy  £500  at  SOi,"  and  the  contract  is 
binding  between  these  two  members  of  the 
stock  exchange.  Members,  their  admitted 
clerks,  or  officials  only  are  permitted  to  enter 
the  London  stock  exchange,  therefore  brokers 
must  be  employed  by  all  outsiders  desii'oas  to 
do  business  there.  a.  e. 

BROKERAGE.  A  charge  made  by  a  broker 
on  the  purchase  or  sale  of  securities  or  other 
property. 

BROUGHAM,  Henry  (born  1778,  died 
1868),  Baron  Brougham  and  Vaux,  lord  chan- 
cellor, touched  nearly  all  subjects  and  adorned 
some  by  his  eloquence  and  dialectical  skill. 
The  contact  seems  least  superficial,  the  orna- 
ment particularly  solid,  in  the  case  of  political 
economy.  Brougham's  fii*st  considerable  work 
was  An  Inquiry  into  the  Colonial  Policy  of 
European  Powers,  1803.  Criticising  Adam 
Smith,  he  maintains  that  the  monopoly  of  the 
colonial  trade  did  not  produce  all  the  detri- 
mental effects  ascribed  to  it  (bk.  i.  §  2,  part 
ii.)  Refening  to  the  slave  colonies.  Brougham 
not  only  denounces  the  slave  trade  as  iniquit- 
ous— "not  a  trade,  but  a  crime" — but  also 
argues  that  it  is  unprofitable.  The  argument 
is  renewed  in  A  Concise  Statement  of  the  Question 
regarding  Hhe  Abolition  of  Slave  Trade  (1804). 
Slavery,  as  well  as  slave  trade,  was  assailed  by 
Brougham's  oratory  {Speeches,  published  in 
1838,  voL  ii.) 

Free  trade  owes  something  to  Brougham's 
advocacy.  He  exposed  the  folly  of  retaliation, 
as  counsel  (1808)  for  the  merchants  who  peti- 
tioned parliament  against  the  orders  in  council 
directed  against  Napoleon's  continental  system. 
After  Brougham's  masterly  speech  in  1812,  the 
obnoxious  orders  were  withdrawn  (Speeches,  vol. 
i)  In  the  speech  on  manufacturing  distress 
(1817)  Brougham  strikes  at  the  complicated 
taxes  which  fettered  trade  (ibid.)  But  in  the 
equally  able  speech  on  agiicultural  distress 
(1816)  there  is  a  good  word  for  the  corn  law 
{iMd.  p.  533). 


Other  economic  topics  handled  by  Brougham 
are :  (1)  depreciation  of  money,  with  reference 
to  Sir  E.  Shuckburgh's  standard  (article  on 
"Currency  and  Commerce,"  Contributions  to 
Edinburgh  Revieio,  published  1856,  vol.  iii.  p. 
22 ;  E.R.,  Oct.  1803) ;  (2)  usury  (Contributions, 
vol.  iii.  p.  52  ;  E.  R.,  Dec.  1816)  ;  (3)  over- 
population (speech  on  the  poor  laws,  1834, 
Speeches,  vol.  iii.)  ;  (4)  combinations  (I'ran^ac- 
tions  of  the  Society  for  promoting  Social  Science 
for  1860,  p.  51).  Brougham  is  also  to  be 
mentioned  as  a  promoter  of  education  and  educa- 
tional institutions — the  London  University,  the 
Society  for  the  Diffusion  of  Useful  Knowledge, 
Mechanics'  Institutes,  and  the  Society  for  pro- 
moting Social  Science. 

In  addition  to  the  works  which  have  been  cited 
may  be  noticed  :  (1)  ^  Manual  for  Mechanics' 
histitutions,  1839  (by  B.  F.  Duppa,  with  outlines 
of  lectures  on  political  economy  by  Brougham)  ; 
(2)  Political  Philosophy,  1842  ;  (3)  Works,  1st 
ed.  1855-61,  2d  ed.  1873.  In  the  11th  vol.  of 
the  2d  ed.  there  is  a  list  of  Brougham's  publica- 
tions, numbering  133.  F.  T.  E. 

BROWN,  John  (1715-1766),  was  vicar  of 
St.  Nicholas,  Newcastle.  He  maintained  that 
"  commerce  in  its  first  and  middle  stages  is 
beneficent,  in  its  last  dangerous  and  fatal"; 
that  it  is  answerable  for  selfishness,  luxuiy, 
and  want  of  religion  ;  and  that  by  causing 
a  drain  of  money  and  by  the  invention  of 
machines  it  diminishes  the  population.  He 
asserts  that  the  country  parish  registers  prove 
that  from  1710  to  his  time  the  population  was 
at  least  stationary.  See  his  book  An  Estimate 
of  the  Manners  and  Principles  of  the  Times. 
By  the  author  of  Essays  on  the  Characteristics, 
etc.,  London,  1757,  pp.  151,  185,  188. 

[For  a  contemporary  reference  see  :  A  Vindica- 
tion of  Commerce  and  the  Arts.  By  J.-B.,  M.D., 
1758,  p.  xvi.,  and  Wallace,  Characteristics  of  iht 
Present  State,  1758,  p.  193. — Brown's  own  book 
Essays  on  the  Characteristics,  etc.  is  of  no  econo- 
mic value.]  s.  B. 

BRYDGES,  Sir  Egerton,  Bart.  (b.  1762, 
d.  1837).  To  any  one  disposed  to  make  a 
psychological  study  of  a  defunct  antiquary, 
topographer,  essayist,  bibliographer,  poet, 
novelist,  and  critic,  and  who  added  to  these 
occupations  the  study  of  political  economy  and 
occasional  authorship  in  that  science,  Sir  E. 
Brydges  would  attbrd  an  excellent  subject. 
On  the  good  side  may  be  placed  his  industry 
and  power  of  research,  considerable  originality, 
and  a  deep  acquaintance  with  the  ancient 
literature  of  England  and  of  foreign  countries. 
On  the  bad  side  should  be  ranged  his  excess- 
ively morbid  temperament,  a  craze  about  an 
assumed  right  to  an  ancient  barony,  an  in- 
tense suspicion  of  the  motives  of  those  who 
drftered  from  him,  and  an  unfounded  notion 
that  he  was  not  sufficiently  rewarded  for  his 
services    in    the    cause    of    learning.      Much 


182 


BUBBLE  ACT— BUBBLES 


material  bearing  on  all  this  exists  in  Ms 
Autobiography  and  Letters  from  the  Continent, 
as  well  as  in  his  voluminous  published  and 
privately  printed  works,  which  in  the  course 
of  his  long  life  extended  to  no  less  than  one 
hundred  and  forty  volumes.  We  find  in  a 
quantity  of  his  letters,  which  have  never  been 
printed,  addressed,  from  1818  to  1832,  to  Mr. 
James  S.  Brooks,  member  of  a  firm  of  solicitors 
who  acted  for  him,  and  with  whom,  in  a 
characteristic  manner,  he  often  fell  out,  many 
striking  examples  of  Sir  Egerton  Brydges' 
talent  as  a  political  economist.  It  is  a  curious 
fact  that  in  his  most  desponding  and  brooding 
moments  he  would  fly  to  political  economy  as 
a  relaxation  of  thought  and  as  a  favourite  study, 
just  as  many  of  our  first-class  English  statesmen 
have  relieved  tension  of  mind  and  the  excite- 
ment of  political  conflict  by  Homeric  studies 
or  the  composition  of  Greek  and  Latin  verses. 

His  published  works  touching  on  economics 
are :  (1)  Tests  of  the  National  Wealth,  1799, 
8vo.— (2)  Letters  on  the  Poor  Laws,  1814,  8vo. — 
(3)  Arguments  for  the  Employment  of  the  Poor, 
1817,  8vo.— (4)  Three  Tracts  on  ''Copyright," 
1817-18,  8vo. — (5)  The  Population  and  Riches  of 
Nations  considered,  Geneva,  1819,  8vo.  A  second 
edition  of  this  was  afterwards  printed  at  the 
author's  private  Lee  Press. — (6)  What  are  Riches  t 
Geneva,  1821,  8vo. — (7)  Letter  on  the  Com  Ques- 
tion, 1822,  folio. — (8)  Letter  on  the  Proposed  Plan 
for  reducing  the  National  Debt,  Florence,  1820, 
4to.  Although  Sir  Egerton  Brydges'  works,  above 
cited,  contain  flashes  of  insight  into  correct  deduc- 
tions, practical  as  well  as  theoretical,  they  are  a 
good  deal  disfigured  by  his  want  of  study  of  the 
statistics  and  practice  of  commerce,  and  his  ignor- 
ance of  business  generally.  f.  H. 

BUBBLE  ACT.  Popular  name  for  an  act 
passed  in  the  reign  of  George  I.  with  the  inten- 
tion of  preventing  the  creation  of  joint  stock 
companies.  The  name  is  derived  from  the 
fact  that  one  of  its  objects  was  to  protect  the 
privileges  of  the  South  Sea  Company.  It  had 
no  practical  effect,  and  was  repealed  in  1825. 

E.  s. 

The  phenomenon  of  bubbles  (or  joint-stock 
undertakings  the  shares  of  which  were  "blown 
up  by  the  air  of  great  words "  )  first  showed 
itself  prominently  in  England  at  the  end 
of  the  17th  century  (see  Anderson,  Hist,  oj 
Commerce,  esp.  under  dates  1695,  1697),  when 
the  Royal  Exchange  became  so  crowded  with 
projectors  and  stock-jobbers  that  they  were 
provided  with  an  exchange  of  their  own,  first 
in  Exchange  Alley  and  later  in  Capel  Court.  An 
act  was  passed  in  1696  "for  restraining  the 
practices  of  brokers  and  stockjobbers."  It 
limited  the  number  of  licensed  brokers  to  one 
hundred,  and  put  difficulties  in  the  way  of  their 
dealingwith  government  stock  and  Tallies  {q.v.) 
The  outburst  of  speculation  a  quarter  of  a  century 
later  was  associat'3d  with  the  South  Sea  Com- 
pany     It  led  to  more  ambitious  legislation. 


The  act  specially  known  as  the  Bubble  Act 
was  passed  in  1720,  principally  to  define  the 
privileges  of  the  companies  that  were  afterwards 
known  as  the  London  Assurance  and  the  Royal 
Exchange  Assurance  Companies,  but  also  to 
punish  bubble  companies  for  trading  (a)  under 
obsolete  or  forfeited  charters,  or  (b)  for  purposes 
not  allowed  in  their  charters,  or  (c)  with  no 
charters  at  all.  This  act  was  not  to  apply 
to  undertakings  established  before  1718.  The 
South  Sea  Company  had  promoted  it  in  the 
belief  that  the  bubble  companies  were  rivals, 
whereas  they  were  really  allies ;  money  was 
gained  in  them  to  be  invested  in  the  greater 
company.  As  the  act  and  subsequent  royal 
proclamation  proved  ineffectual,  the  South  Sea 
Company  procured  a  writ  of  scire  fa/iias  against 
**  those  airy  projects  called  bubbles  ; "  but  the 
effect  was  to  bring  down  the  credit  of  smaU  and 
great  together  (Anderson,  ib.  under  date  1720, 
esp.  p.  101  seq.),  and  to  cause  the  ruin  of  mul- 
titudes of  rich  and  poor  subscribers.  To  relieve 
the  sufferers  acts  were  passed  (1721)  to  attach 
the  estates  of  the  South  Sea  Company's  directors, 
to  relieve  subscribers  from  part  of  their  obliga- 
tions, and  (1722)  to  enable  the  company  to 
improve  its  position  by  an  arrangement  with 
the  Bank 'of  England.  The  act  (1722)  to 
punish  fraudulent  transfers  of  stock  may  per- 
haps be  counted  the  last  of  the  series,  though 
the  affairs  of  the  South  Sea  Company  were  a 
frequent  subject  of  legislation  for  some  years 
afterwards.  J.  B. 

BUBBLES  (History  of).  The  term  bubble 
has  been  commonly  applied  since  the  17th 
century  to  any  unsound  commercial  undertaking 
accompanied  by  a  high  degree  of  speculation. 
The  first  bubble  of  historical  importance  was 
connected  with  the  growth  of  varieties  of  tulips 
in  Holland.  It  reached  its  height  in  1636  in 
Amsterdam,  and  in  the  most  of  the  Dutch  cities 
regular  markets  were  established  for  speculation 
in  the  roots.  In  the  end  tulips  were  bought  and 
sold  like  shares  in  a  gold  mine,  for  purely  specu- 
lative purposes,  without  any  idea  of  actually 
growing  the  flowers.  Fabulous  prices  were 
paid  for  single  bulbs,  e.g.  2500  florins  for  a 
"viceroy,"  a  "semper  augustus"  6500  florins, 
etc.  The  mania  spread  to  some  extent  to 
London  and  Paris,  and  tulips  were  dealt  in  by 
the  stock-jobbers  of  both  cities. 

In  1719  and  1720  occurred  the  greatest 
speculative  mania  on  record,  arising  from  the 
Mississippi  scheme  of  John  Law  {q.v.)  The 
rage  for  speculation  in  Paris  was  incredible,  and 
affected  aU  classes  of  society.  John  Law's 
schemes  were  not  in  themselves,  according  to 
most  modern  writers,  unreasonable,  and  in 
many  respects  he  only  anticipated  the  natural 
development  of  banking  and  credit,  but  his 
whole  system  was  ruined  by  the  extravagant ' 
speculation  with  which  it  at  once  became  as- 
sociated.    The  extent  of  the  mania  may  be 


BUBBLES— BUCHANAN 


183 


indicated  by  the  fact  that  for  a  time  John  Law 
became  the  most  powerful  man  in  France. 

In  England,  however,  the  word  bubble  is 
generally  associated  with  the  South  Sea  Bubble 
which  burst  in  1720,  and  was  the  English 
counterpart  of  the  Mississippi  scheme.  The 
South  Sea  Company  was  originated  by  Harley, 
Earl  of  Oxford,  in  the  year  1711.  The  original 
idea  was  to  found  a  company  which  should  take 
over  the  floating  debt  of  nearly  ten  millions, 
arising  from  the  expenses  of  the  army  and  navy. 
The  company  was  to  receive  interest  from  the 
government  at  the  rate  of  six  per  cent,  and 
for  this  purpose  certain  duties  were  allocated. 
In  addition  the  monopoly  of  trade  to  the 
South  Seas  was  granted,  and  the  company  be- 
came known  by  that  name  ;  as  a  matter  of 
fact,  owing  partly  to  the  opposition  of  Spain, 
the  trade  with  the  South  Seas,  or  ratlier  South 
America,  produced  very  little  revenue  at  any 
time.  But  the  directors  of  the  company  thought 
that  they  might  imitate  the  success  of  John 
Law  by  other  operations  in  finance,  and  they 
competed  Avith  the  Bank  of  England  in  offers 
to  undertake  the  reduction  of  the  national 
debt,  which  amounted  to  about  £30,000,000. 
After  a  debate  in  the  House  of  Commons  the 
proposals  of  the  South  Sea  Company  were 
accepted  in  preference  to  those  of  the  Bank  of 
England  !  Sir  Robert  Walpole  was  almost 
the  only  prominent  statesman  who  spoke  against 
it,  and  warned  the  House  of  the  dangers  of 
stock -jobbing  as  carried  on  in  France.  During 
the  time  the  bill  was  being  passed  through  the 
House  of  Commons  the  most  extravagant 
rumours  were  set  afloat,  especially  by  the  chair- 
man. Sir  John  Blunt,  as  to  the  trading  possi- 
bilities of  the  company,  with  the  view  of  forcing 
up  the  price  of  the  shares.  Before  the  bill 
reached  the  Lords  the  price  of  the  stock  had 
reached  400.  It  was  opposed  by  several  peers 
of  good  standing,  but  was  hurried  through  with 
unexampled  rapidity.  By  this  time,  7th  April 
1720,  the  whole  nation  had  begun  to  be  in- 
fected with  the  stock-jobbing  mania.  Exchange 
Alley  and  Cornhill  were  almost  impassable  with 
the  crowds.  The  South  Sea  stock,  which  curi- 
ously enough  suffered  a  momentary  fall  on  the 
passing  of  the  bill  in  favour  of  the  company, 
was  soon  subjected  to  all  kinds  of  adroit  mani- 
pulation. In  consequence  the  directors  were 
enabled  in  a  few  days  to  issue  a  million  of  stock 
at  £300  for  the  nominal  £100,  and  a  little  later 
another  million  was  issued  at  £400,  for  which 
"in  a  few  hours,  a  million  and  a  half  was 
subscribed." 

In  the  meantime,  numberless  other  joint- 
stock  companies  were  started,  which  soon  began 
to  be  called  bubbles.  The  highest  persons  in 
the  state,  including  the  Prince  of  Wales,  were 
interested  in  one  or  more  of  those  companies. 
Some  of  them  only  lasted  a  few  days,  and  the 
infatuation  was  at   length  carried  to  such  a 


pitch  that  one  project  was  advertised  in  the 
newspapers  as  follows:  "For  subscribing  two 
millions  to  a  certain  promising  or  profitable 
design,  which  will  hereafter  be  promulgated." 
It  is  hardly  credible  that  the  bold  projector  of 
this  scheme,  in  a  few  hours,  sold  1000  shares 
on  which  he  received,  by  way  of  deposit,  £2  per 
share,  and  was  able  to  decamp  with  £2000. 

The  South  Sea  stock  continued  to  rise  for 
nearly  two  months,  and  at  the  end  of  May 
reached  about  550.  At  this  time  it  took  a 
tremendous  leap  of  340  per  cent,  and  was 
quoted  on  the  3d  of  June  at  890.  On  this 
day,  however,  it  fell  as  rapidly,  but  was  again 
bolstered  up  by  the  directors  getting  their 
agents  to  buy.  The  speculation  continued 
during  the  summer,  the  stock  at  one  time 
reaching  1000  ;  but  by  the  beginning  of  Septem- 
ber a  serious  fall  had  commenced,  and  the 
directors  became  alarmed.  Negotiations  were 
attempted  ■with  the  Bank  of  England,  but  a 
panic  had  set  in  which  nothing  could  check. 
Thus  the  bubble  burst  after  a  run  of  eight 
months.  The  greatest  popular  indignation  was 
aroused  against  the  directors,  and  found  expres- 
sion in  parliament.  An  inquiry  was  instituted 
and  pushed  on  rapidly.  In  the  sequel  upwards 
of  two  millions  was  taken,  in  the  shape  of  fines, 
from  the  estates  of  the  directors,  and  they  were 
allowed  to  retain  only  a  small  residue. 

[Full  details  of  these  bubbles  are  given  in  Mac- 
pherson's  Annals  of  Commerce,  under  the  years 
named.  Popular  accounts  are  given  in  Mackay'a 
Memoirs  of  Extraordinary  Popular  Delusions, 
London,  1852,  and  Francis's  Chronicles  and  Char- 
acters of  the  Stock  Exchange,  London,  1849.  See 
also  Tavereel.]  J.  s.  n. 

BUCHANAN,  David  (1779-1848).  A 
journalist  and  economist,  was  a  son  of  David 
Buchanan,  a  printer,  and  was  born  at  Montrose 
in  1779.  At  an  early  period  of  his  life  he 
commenced  his  career  as  an  economist  by  a  con- 
tribution to  Cobbett's  Political  Register.  He 
contributed  articles  to  the  Edinburgh  Review, 
publislied  a  pamphlet  on  Pitt's  volunteer  system 
(1807),  contributed  to  the  seventh  edition  of  the 
Encyclopcedia  Britannica,  and  edited  the  Edin- 
burgh Gazetteer.  As  a  journalist,  his  experience 
was  varied,  since  he  was  editor  successively  of 
the  Weekly  Register  {1^0^-1^0^),t\iQ  Caledonian 
Mercury  (1810-1827),  the  Edinburgh  Courant 
(1827-1848).  As  an  economist,  in  1814  he 
edited  an  edition  of  Adam  Smith's  Inquiry  into 
the  Causes  of  the  Wealth  of  Nations  in  four 
volumes,  the  last  volume  consisting  of  addi- 
tional matter  supplied  by  himself  by  way  of 
illustration  and  correction  (this  edition  of  Adam 
Smith  was  translated  into  French  in  1843).  In 
1844  he  published  a  work  entitled  Inquiry  into 
the  Taxation  and  Commercial  Policy  of  Great 
Britain,  with  Observations  on  the  Principles  of 
CurrcTicy  and  Exchangeable  Value.  To  a  large 
extent  this  latter  work  is  a  mature  reproduo- 


184 


BUCHEZ— BUCKLE 


tion  of  the  matter  contained  in  his  additional 
volume  of  comments  of  1814.  While  he  goes 
beyond  the  theories  laid  down  by  Adam  Smith, 
his  final  treatise  does  not  indicate  any  develop- 
ment due  to  the  study  of  those  economic  works 
which  had  been  published  since  he  began  to 
write  in  1814.  He  displays  a  consid^able 
understanding  of  the  causes  which  determine 
prices,  and  brings  out  with  great  lucidity  the 
effect  of  the  interaction  of  supply  and  demand. 
Thus  he  performed  no  little  service  to  economic 
theory  by  disentangling  the  many  important 
elements  underlying  the  work  of  Adam  Smith. 
On  the  other  hand  he  failed  altogether  to 
understand  the  main  basis  of  the  Ricardian 
theory,  recognising  no  distinction  between  an 
"increase  in  wealth"  and  an  "increase  in 
valioe."  In  consequence  he  is  unable  to  com- 
prehend the  technical  use  by  Ricardo  of  the 
term  "profits,"  and  will  not  allow  that  that 
author  was  right  in  asserting  that  a  fall  or  rise 
in  profits  depended  on  a  rise  or  fall  in  wages. 
This  was  owing  to  his  misunderstanding  the 
interpretation  applied  to  these  terms  by  Ricardo. 
Of  a  somewhat  similar  nature  is  his  attack  on  the 
theory  of  rent.  He  confuses  the  theory  with  its 
practical  application  ;  while  he  further  failed  to 
understand  the  treatment  by  Ricardo  of  the 
case  of  a  country  where  all  the  soil  is  under 
cultivation,  but  where  the  difference  of  quality 
as  to  retm-n  to  respective  "doses"  renders  the 
law  of  rent  like  to  that  obtaining  where  cultiva- 
tion has  not  yet  covered  the  whole  surface. 
He  does  not  give  Ricardo  sufficient  attention 
in  this  instance,  while  in  another  he  accuses 
him — again  no  doubt  through  misconception — 
of  having  thought  and  said  that  the  high  price 
of  corn  was  the  effect  of  the  higher  expense  of 
cultivation,  urging  on  his  part  that  this  high 
price  it  was  which  caused  people  to  be  willing 
to  encounter  the  high  expense.  Again  he 
asserts  that  in  theory  the  tithes  are  paid  out  of 
the  rent. 

For  these  and  other  reasons  it  is  impossible 
to  attribute  to  his  treatises  any  great  value  on 
the  side  of  theory.  On  the  other  hand  his 
treatment  of  taxation  is  sensible  and  very 
practical. 

{^Dictionary  of  National  Biography. — Montrose 
Standard,  18th  August  1848  ;  works  as  cited 
in  text.  ]  E.  c.  k.  g. 

BUCHEZ,  Philippe  Joseph  Benjamin, 
bom  1796  at  Mattaigne  (Belgium,  at  that  time 
a  department  of  the  Ardennes),  died  1865  at 
Rodez.  Left  dependent  on  his  own  resources 
at  twenty,  he  commenced  life  with  the  study  of 
natural  science.  In  1821  he  established,  in  con- 
junction with  Bazard  and  Flottard,  the  society 
of  the  Carbonari  {q.v.)  in  France.  Devoting 
himself  to  the  service  of  this  secret  society  with 
the  fury  of  youth,  he  barely  escaped,  1822, 
being  sentenced  to  death.  Altering  then  the 
scope  of  his  operations,  he  worked  after  the 


death  of  St.  Simon,  whom  he  never  had 
known,  on  the  Producteur  (1825-26).  About 
this  date  he  began  to  be  detached  from  the 
followers  of  St.  Simon,  with  whom,  however, 
he  did  not  definitely  part  company  till  1829. 
He  then  published  several  works  on  medical 
science,  and,  during  the  revolution  of  1830 
attended,  with  gi-eat  courage,  the  wounded 
imder  fire.  Taking  his  pen  up  again,  he  pub- 
lished his  Introduction  d  la  Science  de  VHistoire 
(1833,  reprinted  1842),  and  afterwards,  in  con- 
jimction  with  Roux  Lavergne,  the  work  by 
which  he  is  best  known  {Histoire  parlementaire 
de  la  E4volution  Frangaise,  1833-38,  40  vols., 
reprinted — the  first  seven  alone  1846).  In 
this  work,  without  approving  the  violence  and 
bloodshed,  he  rehabilitated  the  principal  per- 
sonages of  the  first  revolution.  This  was 
followed  by  his  Bssai  d'un  traite  complet  de 
Philosophic  au  point  de  vue  du  Catholicisrm  et 
du  Progr^s  (1838-40,  3  vols.),  in  which  he 
sought,  in  harmony  with  his  St.  Simonian 
views,  to  reconcile  philosophy  with  Catholi 
cism.  He  had  founded  (May  1847  to  July 
1848)  the  Eeime  Nationale  when  the  Revolution 
of  1848  broke  out.  Appointed  Maire-adjoini  of 
Paris,  he  took  great  part  in  the  suppression  of 
the  disturbances  in  the  streets,  particularly  of 
the  socialist  manifestation  of  16th  April. 
Elected  by  135,000  votes  a  representative  of 
the  people,  he  was  chosen,  4th  May,  president, 
on  the  opening  of  the  Assemble  Oonstitvmite, 
and  was  in  the  chair,  15th  May,  when  the 
chamber  was  invaded  by  the  revolutionary 
socialists.  The  firmness  and  dignity  of  his 
conduct  brought  him  respect  from  all.  He 
continued  actively  to  fulfil  the  duties  of  his 
post,  but  was  not  elected  a  member  of  the 
Assemhlie  Legislative.  He  was  arrested  at  the 
Coup  d'6tat,  December  1861,  but  was  soon  set 
at  liberty,  and  occupied  himself  in  writing, 
1856,  the  Histoire  de  la  formation  de  la  Nation- 
ality Frangaise,  2  vols,  in  32mo,  reprinted  1859 
under  the  title  of  Les  Mdrovingiens  et  les  Car- 
lovingiens.  He  was  the  first  to  speak  in  France 
in  favour  of  Associations  Ouvri^res,  which  he 
desired  to  establish  under  a  form  approaching 
that  of  a  religious  order,  not  only  to  secure  pro- 
priety of  conduct,  but  perpetuity  and  increase 
of  capital.  His  disciples  and  friends  MM.  L. 
Cerise  and  A.  Ott  published,  in  1866,  after  his 
death,  a  posthumous  work,  TraitS  de  Politique 
et  de  Scien/ie  Sociale,  preceded  by  a  notice  of  his 
life  and  works  by  M.  A.  Ott.  a.  c.  f. 

BUCKLE,  Thomas  Henry,  born  1821,  led 
a  student's  recluse  life,  devoted  to  the  great 
historic  work  which  he  left  unfinished  on  his 
death  in  his  forty -first  year  (1862).  In 
the  introduction  to  this  work,  the  principle 
that  human  actions  obey  laws  verifiable  by 
statistics,  was,  as  Mill  says  {Logic,  bk.  v.  ch.  ii„ 
§  1),  "  most  clearly  and  triumphantly  brought 
out "  by  Buckle.    Mill  does  not  however  agree 


BUDGET 


185 


in  the  opinion  tliat  the  moral  qualities  of  man- 
kind are  little  capable  of  being  improved,  and 
conduce  little  to  the  progress  of  society  {Ih.  %  2). 
Dr.  Venn  has  protested  more  strongly  against 
Buckle's  fatalistic  interpretation  of  statistics 
{Logic  of  Chance,  2d  ed.  pp.  235-241).  An 
erroneous  impression  of  the  futility  of  human 
effort  is  conveyed  by  such  statements  as 
'*  suicide  is  merely  a  product  of  the  general  con- 
dition of  society,  and  the  individual  felon  only 
carries  into  effect  what  is  a  necessary  con- 
sequence of  preceding  circumstances"  (Venn, 
Logic  of  Chance.  2d  ed.  ch.  xviii.  §  14  ;  Buckle, 
History  of  Civilisation,  vol.  i.  ch.  i.)  The 
same  disposition  to  underrate  the  force  of  human 
will  appears  in  Buckle's  theories  as  to  the  in- 
fluence of  pliysical  conditions  on  wages  and 
population:  "There  is  a  strong  and  constant 
tendency  in  hot  countries  for  wages  to  be  low, 
in  cold  countries  for  them  to  be  high.  The 
evil  condition  of  Ireland  was  the  natural  result 
of  cheap  and  abundant  food  "  (History  of  Civil- 
isation, ch.  ii.)  He  here  maintains  that 
"potato  philosophy  of  wages,"  which  Prof. 
Walker  stigmatised  {Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  v. 
ch.  iii.)  Buckle's  economical  reflections  are 
indeed  not  always  sound,  but  they  bear  the 
impress  of  originality,  enhanced  by  copious 
learning  and  recondite  references.  His  account 
of  the  discoveries  made  by  political  economists 
is  masterly  (ch.  iv.)  The  remarks  on  the  lead- 
ing economists,  in  particular  Adam  Smith  and 
Hume,  are  instructive,  even  when  disputable. 
The  description  of  Adam  Smith's  method 
as  deductive,  is  a  half-truth  cliaracteristic  of 
Buckle. 

History  of  Civilisation  in  England,  vol.  1. 
1857,  vol.  ii.  1861.— New  Edition  (with  index) 
1869.  — Miscellaneous  and  Posthumous  Works, 
edited  by  Helen  Taylor,  1872  ;  with  a  biographi- 
cal notice  by  the  editor.  (Among  the  posthuiuous 
works  are  fragments,  some  of  which  relate  to 
economical  topics  :  e.g.  History  of  Money,  p.  438  ; 
Wages,  p.  459  ;  Statistics,  and  Political  Economy, 
pp.  526,  528).  [Life  and  Writings,  by  A.  H. 
Huth  (1880). — Pilgrim  Memories,  by  J.  S.  Glennie, 
1875  ;  2d  ed.,  with  a  preface,  1880.1       f,  Y.  e. 

BUDGET,  The,i  is  the  statement  of  the 
nation's  accounts,  drawn  up  and  presented  once 
a  year  to  parliament  by  the  chancellor  of  the 
exchequer.  In  opening  his  budget,  the  finance 
minister  first  lays  before  the  House  the  complete 
accounts  of  the  past  financial  year,  with  its 
actual  revenue  and  expenditure,  and  the  realised 
surplus  or  deficiency.  For  this  purpose,  and 
to  enable  an  accm-ate  estimate  of  the  revenue 
of  the  coming  year  to  be  made,  the  budget 
is  never,  except  under  peculiar  circimistances, 
taken  until  a  week  or  two  after  the  close  of  the 
financial  year,  which  now  runs  from  1st  April 

1  From  the  Old  French  "bougette,"  diminutive  of 
"  boulge,"  a  purse.  The  term  and  method  of  a  Budget 
are  used  in  other  countries,  see  R.  Stourm,  Cours  de 
Finances:  le  Budget,  2d  ed.,  Paris,  1891,  8vo. 


to  31st  March.  2  On  the  other  hand,  the  budget 
is  seldom  postponed  for  more  than  a  short  time 
after  that  date,  so  that  the  period  of  disturb- 
ance to  trade,  due  to  the  uncertainty  of  the 
financial  proposals  of  the  year,  may  be  as  far 
as  possible  curtailed. 

The  result  of  the  finance  of  the  past  year 
having  been  stated,  the  chancellor  of  the 
exchequer  proceeds  to  detail  the  expenditure  of 
the  coming  year,  as  estimated  by  the  different 
departments  after  review  and  criticism  by 
cabinet  and  treasury.  These  estimates  are 
divided  into  two  parts — the  Consolidated 
Fund  (q.v.)  and  the  Supply  services.^ 

The  amount  of  the  expenditm-e  for  the 
coming  year  is  generally  known  before  the  budget 
is  introduced,  for  the  estimates  of  the  supply 
services  have  as  a  rule  already  been  presented 
to  the  House  ;  and  portions  of  them,  or  "votes 
on  account,"  have  probably  already  been  taken. 

Against  the  total  of  the  estimated  expenditure 
("  ordinary"  or  "  extraordinary,"  the  latter  term 
being  now  usually  applied  to  war  expenditure 
of  any  kind)  it  becomes  necessary  to  jirovido 
the  "  ways  and  means  "  ;  and  this  is  the  budget 
proper.  The  taxation  in  force  dming  the  year 
just  come  to  a  close  is  almost  invariably  as- 
sumed as  the  basis  of  the  estimate  of  the  revenue 
for  the  coming  year,  any  variations  which  are 
likely  to  ensue  being,  especially  since  1874, 
taken  into  account.'* 

On  a  comparison  of  the  estimated  revenue 
with  the  estimated  expenditure,  a  surplus  or  a 
deficit,  as  the  case  may  be,  appears.  Since 
Peel's  time  it  has  been  the  almost  invariable 
custom,  except  under  great  stress  of  war  charge, 
for  the  chancellor  of  the  exchequer  to  take  care 
that,  in  his  final  budget  estimates  of  revenue 
and  expenditui-e,  an  estimated  surplus  of  three 


2  The  tinancial  year  used,  till  1S3'2,  to  run  Ironi  1st 
January  to  Slst  Deeeinber.  The  budget  is  usually 
taken  about  the  middle  of  April.  In  1860,  in  con- 
sequence of  the  necessity  of  an  early  ratification  of  the 
Fi-ench  commercial  treaty,  the  budget  waa  introduced 
on  10th  February.  In  1S59,  in  consequence  of  the 
change  of  government,  it  was  not  introduced  until  18th 
July.  In  1880  there  were  two  budgets,  one  on  11th 
March  (Northcote's)  before  the  dissolution,  the  other  on 
10th  June  (Gladstone's)  after  the  assembling  of  the  new 
House. 

3  The  Consolidated  FtJND — created  by  Pitt  in  1787,  for 
the  greater  security  of  the  Debt  and  other  fixed  charges, 
and  the  more  certain  maintenance  of  his  Sinking  Fund — 
includes  the  Civil  List,  debt  charge,  certain  pensions, 
judicial  and  other  salaries,  constituting  an  annual  charge 
fixed  by  statute,  and  only  to  be  altered  by  statute. 

The  Supply  services  include  thp  rest  of  the  ordin- 
aiy  expenditure  of  the  country, — the  army,  the  navy, 
the  civil  service  and  the  revenue  departments,  which 
last  include  the  post  office  and  the  cost  of  the  collection 
of  the  revenue.  These  supply  services  are  annually 
voted  item  by  item  in  committee  (the  money  being  now- 
adays very  strictly  "  appropriated  "),  and  the  amounts 
can  be  criticised  and  reduced,  but  not  increased,  by  the 
House.  The  accounts  are  subsequently  audited,  and 
go  before  the  Public  Accounts  Committee. 

4  This  is  almost  invariably  the  case.  In  1868  and  in 
1885,  however,  the  special  taxation  imposed  in  the 
previous  year  was  eliminated  from  the  estimate,  and  in 
1858  Mr.  Disraeli  took  the  income  tax  at  5d.  in  accord, 
ance  with  the  arrangement  of  1853,  instead  of  at  the  7d 
of  the  previous  year. 


186 


BUDGET 


or  four  hundred  thousand  pounds  shall  be 
shown.  This  he  does  for  the  twofold  object  of 
providing  for  unforeseen  contingencies  to  ex- 
penditure or  diminution  of  revenue;  so  that, 
if  possible,  the  year  shall  not  end  with  an 
addition  to  the  national  debt,  in  other  words  a 
deficit,  but  rather  that  something  shall  renlain 
in  hand  to  go  towards  its  further  redemption. 
This  policy  has  become  especially  essential  since 
1874,  in  which  year  the  system  of  close  estimates 
was  finally  adopted  ;  for  under  the  old  system, 
in  which  practically  no  account  was  taken  of 
the  normal  annual  increase  of  revenue,  a  sur- 
plus was  ready  to  hand  if  the  revenue  of  the 
year  exceeded  that  of  its  predecessor.  Unfore- 
seen circumstances  may  indeed,  affect  the  surplus, 
but  a  surplus  ought  distinctly  to  be  allowed  for 
in  the  budget — a  chancellor  of  the  exchequer, 
according  to  Mr.  Lowe's  definition,  being  "an 
animal  who  ought  to  have  a  surplus." 

The  "ways  and  means"  of  the  year  include 
the  whole  of  the  sources  of  national  revenue, 
and  not  only  those  derived  from  actual  taxation 
— not  only  the  so-called  "tax  revenue,"  but 
the  gross  receipts  from  the  business  depart- 
ments (post  office,  etc. ),  the  net  revenue  derived 
from  the  crown  lands,  and  miscellaneous 
receipts  of  different  sorts.  The  continuation  of 
the  annual  taxes,  together  with  any  alteration 
that  may  be  proposed  in  them  or  in  the  per- 
manent taxes  with  the  view  of  either  distribut- 
ing the  surplus  or  filling  up  the  deficit,  are 
embodied  in  resolutions  which,  in  order  to 
obviate  possible  evasion,  are  almost  always 
provisionally  confirmed  on  the  night  of  the 
introduction  of  the  budget. 

The  resolutions  agreed  to,  they  are  annually 
embodied  in  one  bill — the  customs  and  inland 
revenue  biU — which  goes  through  the  House  of 
Commons  in  the  ordinary  course,  and  is  liable 
to  amendment  like  any  other  bill.  After 
passing  the  Lower  House,  the  bill  goes  up  to  the 
Lords,  who  can,  if  they  choose,  reject,  but  are 
precluded  from  amending  it. 

The  system  of  including  all  the  Ways  and 
Means  proposals  of  the  year  in  one  bill  dates 
from  1861.  In  the  previous  year  the  govern- 
ment had  proposed  to  repeal  the  paper  duty, 
and  this  proposal  had  been  embodied  in  a  bill 
separate  from  the  other  budget  proposals  ;  and 
this  bill  the  House  of  Lords  rejected.  To  pre- 
vent the  House  of  Lords  from  in  future  dis- 
criminating between  the  different  budget  pro- 
posals, it  was  decided  that  in  future  they 
should  be  all  included  in  one  bill. 

Occasionally — especially  under  stress  of  war 
expenditure — it  becomes  necessary  for  the 
chancellor  of  the  exchequer  later  in  the  year  to 
introduce  a  supplementary  budget,  and  to  pro- 
vide further  ways  and  means  to  meet  additional 
expenditure.  This  additional  taxation  is  voted 
in  the  same  way  as  the  ordinary  taxation  of  the 
year,  though  sometimes  it  is  made  retrospective, 


or  a  double  amount  is  placed  on  the  last  hall 
of  the  year. 

During  the  last  twenty  years — since  the 
system  of  more  strict  appropriation  has  come 
into  force — supplementary  civil  service  esti- 
mates have  become  a  permanent  institution, 
though  additional  money  is  seldom  or  never 
voted  for  them,  and  on  balance  they  are  (or 
ought  to  be)  met  by  savings  on  other  items  of 
expenditure. 

The  nature  of  the  sources  of  "  supply  "  is  de- 
tailed elsewhere  (see  Taxation  ;  Customs), 
but  the  policy  that  has  more  or  less  actuated 
successive  chancellors  of  exchequer  since  the 
first  quarter  of  the  century,  and  its  effect  on  the 
financial  resources  of  the  nation,  may  be  briefly 
summarised.  The  modern  era  of  fiscal  and 
financial  reform  dates  from  the  time  of  HusKis- 
SON,  mainly  between  1824-1828;  intermittently 
followed  by  his  immediate  successors,  his  policy 
was  zealously  adopted  and  carried  distinctly 
further  by  Peel  between  1842andl846.  Taken 
up  with  vigour  by  Gladstone  in  1853,  and,  as 
far  as  the  principle  was  concerned,  finally 
adopted  in  1860,  it  has  since  in  detail  been 
carried  ever  farther  and  farther. 

This  policy,  thus  gradually  and  slowly  brought 
to  completioa,  has  been  as  follows :  first,  the 
abolition  of  all  petty,  vexatious,  and  unremuner- 
ative  duties ;  secondly,  the  repeal  of  all  prohibi- 
tive, protective,  differential,  and  discriminating 
duties,  and  the  introduction  of  perfect  equality 
and  unrestricted  competition  between  home, 
colonial,  and  foreign  goods  in  regard  to  the  rate 
of  taxation  ;  thirdly,  the  general  reduction  of  the 
duties  to  a  minimum,  and  the  choice  for  taxation 
of  those  articles  from  which  the  necessary  revenue 
can  be  raised  most  evenly,  most  easUy,  with  the 
smallest  cost  and  discomfort  to  the  consumer 
and  taxpayer,  and  in  the  manner  least  burden- 
some to  trade.  And,  in  the  case  of  the  duties  ' 
stiU  retained,  for  the  most  part  to  carry  out  the 
seeming  paradox,  as  Pitt  once  called  it,  "in- 
crease by  reduction" — to  increase  the  yield  of 
the  tax  by  decreasing  the  duty,  and  thus  at  the 
same  time  encouraging  consumption  and  mini- 
mising fraud  and  evasion.  In  the  case,  how- 
ever, of  one  branch  of  revenue,  that  namely 
derived  from  intoxicants,  these  principles  only 
partially  prevail ;  such  taxation  being  governed 
by  politico-moral  even  more  than  by  fiscal 
considerations.  The  practical  result  of  this 
policy  has  been  to  reduce  the  articles  or  sub- 
divisions of  articles  on  which  import  or  export 
duties  were  charged,  from  1046  in  1841  to  less 
than  half  that  number  in  1846,  to  400 
in  1859,  and  to  143  in  1860.  They  now 
number  but  47,  and  even  of  these  only  12 
yield  an  appreciable  revenue,  the  rest  being 
duties  retained  either  in  order  to  counter- 
vail excise  duties,  or  levied  on  articles  which 
bear  such  a  resemblance  to  those  charged  with 
duty  that  evasion  and  fraud  would  take  place 


BUDGET 


187 


if  tliey  were  not  also  taxed.  Staple  articles  of 
commerce  such  as  timber,  sugar,  cotton-wool, 
silk,  woollen  goods,  "  fancy "  goods,  corn,  and 
other  articles  of  food,  which  in  early  days  were 
either  prohibited  or  heavily  charged  with  duty, 
now  go  free.  Similarly,  a  great  deliverance  has 
come  to  many  important  articles  of  home  pro- 
duction formerly  hampered  and  injured  by 
heavy  and  vexatious  excise  duties,  such  as  those 
on  glass,  paper,  soap,  candles,  printed  calicoes, 
and  cottons.  Indeed  practically  every  article 
of  home  production  is  now  free  except  those 
connected  with  the  manufacture  of  intoxicants. ^ 

No  one  nowadays  would  probably  venture 
to  assert  that  the  general  adoption  of  free  trade 
in  fiscal  matters,  and  the  abolition  of  all  small, 
vexatious,  or  unremunerative  duties  has  not  been 
of  infinite  advantage  to  the  country  ;  but  it  may 
well  be  argued  that  the  policy  of  concentration 
has  been  carried  somewhat  too  far  in  the  re- 
linquishment of  considerable  taxation  on  articles 
of  general  consumption,  raised  with  ease  and 
producing  considerable  revenue, — such  taxes, 
for  instance,  as  the  "nominal"  duty  on  corn 
abolished  in  1869  ;  the  duty  on  sugar  abolished 
in  1874,  though  the  uneconomical  reduction  of 
1873  made  final  abolition  inevitable- ;  and  the 
horse  duty  abolished  in  the  same  year. 

But  the  fact  was  that  these  three  duties, 
probably  the  only  duties  about  which  any 
question  of  expediency  can  arise,  were  relin- 
quished at  a  time  when  the  expenditure  was 
almost  stationary,  while  the  revenue  was  so 
buoyant  that  the  difficulty  of  the  chancellor  of 
the  exchequer  was  not,  as  now,  to  make  both 
ends  meet,  but  to  know  what  to  do  "with  all 
the  money  that  persisted  in  pouring  in  upon 
him. "  Perhaps  our  chancellors  of  the  exchequer, 
in  the  heyday  of  their  financial  prosperity 
between  fifteen  to  twenty  years  ago,  ought  to 
have  realised,  on  the  one  hand,  that  the  national 
expenditure  would  increase  and  could  not  be 
diminished ;    and,    on    the    other,    that    the 


1  In  1840,  according  to  the  Report  of  the  celebrated 
Import  Duties  Committee,  import  customs  duties  were, 
in  1838,  charged  on  868  articles  (exclusive  of  subheads), 
the  yield  from  which  could  be  divided  as  follows : — 
17  articles  produced  95  per  cent  .  .  £21,700,000 
29        „               „            4        ,,  .         .  899,000 

144       „              „            1         ,,  .         .  363,000 

531       „ .        .  80,000 


loss,  deduct 


In  1888. 
3  articles  produced  90  per  cent 
3      „  „  9        „ 

47      „  .,  1        .. 


53 


£23,042,000 
5,000 

£23,037,000 

£18,100,000 

1,800,000 

200,000 

£20,100,000 


The  47  are  principally  nominal. 

2  The  duties  on  sugar  were  reduced  in  1873  to  the 
moiety  of  what  they  had  been  in  1870.  In  that  year 
also  there  had  been  a  reduction,  so  that  they  were  in 
1870  but  the  quarter,  speaking  generally,  of  what  they 
stood  at  in  1867. 


"ravages  of  temperance  "  would  play  havoc  with 
one  of  the  principal  branches  of  the  revenue. 
But  this  they  did  not  foresee,  and  hence  they 
lightly  relinquished  the  many  millions  of 
revenue  that  the  aforementioned  three  taxes 
would  probably  now  be  producing — taxes,  two 
of  which  at  least  could  never  be  with  advantage 
re-imposed. 

One  chief  result  of  this  policy  of  abolition 
has  been,  no  doubt,  that  the  income  tax,  intro- 
duced forty-six  years  ago  for  a  temporary  pur- 
pose, and  now  finally  a  permanent  tax,  is  ever 
more  and  more  looked  to  as  a  source  of  revenue 
to  make  up  a  deficiency.  But,  after  all,  the 
Income  Tax  has  the  advantage  of  being  a  direct 
tax,  and  the  additional  advantage  of  being  more 
or  less  a  tax  on  wealth.  Moreover,  in  con- 
sequence of  the  relinquishment  of  so  many 
indirect  taxes  (to  the  advantage  of  trade  and 
the  taxpayer),  though  the  total  gi-oss  receipt 
from  the  income  tax  stands  at  a  figure  which 
would  have  astounded  our  fathers,  the  pressure 
on  each  individual  taxpayer  is  less  than  in  the 
old  days. 

A  word  or  two  may  be  said  in  reference  to  the 
most  famous  of  English  budgets  of  the  last 
hundred  years.  Pitt's  gi-eat  budget  of  1798, 
wherein  he  unfolded  his  scheme  for  financing 
the  life  and  death  struggle  with  France,  is 
memorable  for  the  first  imposition  of  the  income 
tax,  and  the  Huskisson-Kobinson  budgets  of 
1823-26,  for  the  first  beginning  of  fiscal  reform. 
Althorp's  first  budget,  that  of  1831,  was  re- 
markable in  that  it  attempted  so  much  and 
accomplished  so  little.  The  Whigs  in  their 
abortive  budget  of  1841 — the  first  budget  pro- 
fessedly based  on  free-trade  principles — proposed, 
in  addition  to  dealing  with  the  corn  laws,  greatly 
to  reduce  the  protective  and  diff"erential  duties 
on  the  two  most  important  articles  of  general 
consumption — sugar  and  timber.  Then  followed 
Peel's  budgets,^  each  more  progi-essive  than  its 
predecessor.  Beginning  with  that  of  1842, 
which  involved  the  re-imposition  of  the  income 
tax  (swept  away  in  1816),  and  ending  with  that 
of  1846,  the  proposals  they  contained,  together 
with  the  repeal  of  the  corn  laws,  made  the 
practical  adoption  of  free  trade  only  a  question 
of  years. 

The  Whig  budget  of  1851,  like  Althorp's  of 
twenty  years  before,  and  that  of  Lowe  twenty 
years  later,  is  chiefly  remembered  for  its 
failures.  In  that  year  the  House,  for  the 
first  time  since  the  re-imposition  of  the  income 
tax,  refused  to  renew  it  for  a  term  of  years,  and 
voted  it  for  a  single  year  only ;  a  precedent 
which  (except  during  the  Crimean  War)  has  ever 
since  been  followed. 

The  free-trade  budget  of  December  1852 — ■ 

3  As  a  matter  of  fact,  Goulburn  was  chancellor  of  tha 
exchequer,  but  the  budgets  were  those  of  Peel ;  and  he 
himself  (as  prime  minister)  introduced  those  of  1842  and 
1845,  as  well  as  the  bill  for  the  repeal  of  the  corn  laws 
in  1846. 


188 


BUDGET— BUILDING  SOCIETIES 


brought  forward  by  Mr.  Disraeli  as  chancellor 
of  the  exchequer  in  Lord  Derby's  protectionist 
ministry — marked  the  total  collapse  of  the  pro- 
tectionist party,  while  it  brought  about  the 
defeat  and  resignation  of  the  Government.  The 
following  year  saw  Mr.  Gladstone's  famous 
budget  of  1853  which,  together  with  those*  of 
1842-46,  and  that  of  1860,  formed  a  series  of 
fiscal  measures  which  resulted  in  the  complete 
emancipation  of  trade  from  prohibitive,  pro- 
tective, and  differential  duties.  The  budget  of 
1853  dealt  also  with  the  income  tax,  the 
chancellor  of  the  exchequer  proposmg  gradually 
to  extinguish  it  in  seven  years.  The  Crimean 
War  frustrated  the  plan  ;  and  the  income  tax 
also  surviving  the  subsequent  attempts  to  ex- 
tinguish it,  made  by  the  same  hand,  under  the 
scheme  of  1864  and  again  in  1874,  is  now 
unquestionably  a  permanent  institution.  The 
budget  of  1860 — also  Mr.  Gladstone's — was 
additionally  marked  by  the  fact  that  it  was 
contingent  on  the  negotiation  of  the  French 
commercial  treaty,  a  treaty  which  was  adopted, 
and,  to  the  great  benefit  of  England  and  France, 
remained  in  force  for  twenty  years.  The  budget 
of  1860  was  followed  by  a  succession  of  Glad- 
stonian  budgets,  marked  by  much  financial 
ability.  Mr.  Lowe's  budgets  of  1869-73  were 
chiefly  remarkable  for  the  extraordinary  leaps 
and  bounds  of  the  revenue,  which  enabled  him 
greatly  to  reduce  taxation,  as  well  as  consider- 
ably to  reduce  the  national  debt.  The  budget 
of  1874 — the  "six  millions  surplus"  budget — 
was  not  so  far-reaching  or  satisfactory  as  it 
probably  would  have  been  if  the  chancellor  of 
the  exchequer.  Sir  Stafford  Northcote,  could 
have  had  a  longer  time  in  which  to  consider 
and  develop  his  financial  schemes.  Sir  Staflbrd 
Northcote's  three  last  budgets,  1878-80,  were 
chiefly  memorable  from  the  fact  that  no  real 
effort  was  made  to  provide  a  surplus  of  revenue 
over  expenditure. 

The  budget  of  1880  (Mr.  Gladstone  again) 
was  marked  by  the  commutation  of  the  malt 
tax  into  a  beer  duty.  Under  that  of  1883  (Mr. 
Childers)  an  arrangement  was  made  for  prevent- 
ing any  break  or  diminution  in  the  annual  sum 
applied  to  the  redemption  of  the  debt,  by  replac- 
ing on  a  sound  and  satisfactory  basis  the  large 
amount  of  Terminable  Annuities  that  other- 
wise would  have  lapsed  in  1885.  Under  this 
scheme,  without  any  addition  to  the  debt  charge, 
some  123  millions  of  debt  were  to  be  redeemed 
in  twenty  years.  The  Liberal  budget  of  1886, 
under  which  it  was  proposed  to  meet  a  deficit  of 
14  millions  by  the  imposition  of  7  millions  of 
additional  taxation  and  the  temporary  suspension 
of  the  sinking  fund,  was  rejected  ;  and,  for  the 
second  time  in  the  century,  a  defeat  on  a  budget 
was  followed  by  the  resignation  of  the  Govern- 
ment. The  year  1888  was  noticeable  for  the 
reduction  of  all  the  3  per  cent  stocks  to  2j  per 
cent,  a  rate  which  was  to  fall  to  2^  per  cent  in 


fourteen  years  (see  Conversion  of  BritIkSh 
National  Debt).  The  most  important  budgets 
of  the  last  150  years  are  those  of  1798,  1842, 
1846,  1853,  1860,  and  1911.  By  Mr.  Lloyd 
George's  budget  of  1910-1911,  the  Death 
Duties  {q.v.),  first  imposed  by  Mr.  Gladstone 
in  1863,  were  heavily  increased,  and,  by  means 
of  a  valuation  of  the  land  throughout  the 
country,  a  foundation  was  attempted  to  be  laid 
on  which  increment  arising  from  any  increase 
in  its  value  should  be  taxed.  This  source  of 
revenue  has,  however,  up  to  the  present  proved 
unremunerative.  The  observation  of  J.  S.  Mill 
was  not  borne  in  mind  that  the  market  value 
of  land  at  the  time  should  be  offered  to  existing 
owners  to  obviate  injustice. 

[The  authorities — ^historical,  fiscal  and  financial 
— that  could  be  quoted  are  innumerable.  Financial 
works — Dowell,  History  of  Taxes  and  Taxation. — 
M'Culloch,  writings. — Porter,  Progress  of  the 
Nation. — Levi,  History  of  Commerce. — Tayler, 
History  of  Taxation. — Northcote,  Twenty  Years' 
Financial  Policy. — Buxton,  Finance  and  Politics, 
an  Historical  Stvdy,  1786-1886.  Also  the  speeches 
of  the  chancellors  of  the  exchequer  (Hansard) ; 
parliamentary  blue-books,  reports  of  committees 
and  commissions,  the  annual  "  finance  accounts  " 
and  "  statistical  abstracts  "  ;  the  large  blue-book 
published  in  18&8,  Public  Income  and  Expenditure 
Return  ;  Report  of  the  Import  Duties  Committee  of 
I84O. — See  also  Bernard  Mallet,  British  Budgets, 
1887-88  to  1912-18,  London,  1913.]        s.  c.  b. 

BUILDING  SOCIETIES.  Bmlding  societies 
are  societies  formed  "  for  the  purpose  of  raising 
by  the  subscription  of  the  members  a  stock  or 
fund  for  making  advances  to  members  out  of  the 
funds  of  the  society,  upon  security  of  freehold, 
copyhold,  or  leasehold  estateby  way  of  mortgage" 
(37  &  38  Vict.  c.  42,  §  13).  Societies  of  this 
nature  existed  for  some  time  before  they  be- 
came the  subject  of  legislation.  "There  were 
certain  persons  who  had  saved  or  were  saving 
money  and  were  desirous  of  investing  it  at  a 
higher  rate  of  interest  than  the  usury  laws 
enabled  them  to  obtain  at  the  time,  and  other 
persons  who  were  desirous  of  either  building  or 
buying  houses  for  their  own  habitation.  These 
two  classes  came  together :  the  persons  who 
had  saved  money  or  were  saving  money  paid 
it  into  the  society,  and  it  was  lent  to  persons 
who  were  desirous  of  building  or  buying  houses 
on  the  security  of  the  houses,  and  on  terms 
which  compelled  the  borrowers  to  pay  a  larger 
sum  by  way  of  interest  than  6  per  cent  per 
annum  .  .  .  Under  these  circumstances  the 
act  6  &  7  William  IV.  c.  32,  for  the  regula- 
tion of  building  societies,  was  passed "  (Sir 
George  Jessel,  in  re  Guardian  Benefit  Building 
Society,  Law  Reports,  23  Ch.  Div.  p.  457). 
The  Act  of  William  IV.  provided  for  the 
registration  of  building  societies  and  gave 
them  certain  privileges,  but  the  liability  of  the 
members  remained  unlimited,  and  no  corporate 
rights    were    given    to    such   societies   (whose 


BUILDING  SOCIETIES 


189 


property  was  therefore  required  to  be  vested  in 
trustees,  a  circumstance  causing  much  practical 
inconvenience).  The  act  of  William  lY.  was 
repealed  by  the  Building  Societies  Act,  1874 
(37  &  38  Vict.  c.  42),  which,  together  with 
several  amending  acts,  now  regulates  the  law  on 
the  subject.  There  are  termxTiating  and  per- 
manent  buUding  societies,  the  latter  being  of 
more  recent  growth  than  the  former.  A  ter- 
minating society  is  one  which  by  its  rules  is  to 
terminate  at  a  fixed  date,  or  when  a  result 
specified  in  the  same  is  attained  ;  while  a 
permanent  society  is  one  which  has  not,  by  its 
rules,  any  such  fixed  date  or  specified  result  at 
which  it  shall  terminate.  The  amount  of  the 
shares  in  either  case  is  raised  by  periodical 
(generally  by  monthly)  subscriptions  ;  any 
member  may,  on  the  security  of  freehold,  copy- 
hold, or  leasehold  property,  obtain  loans  from 
the  society,  in  which  case  the  amount  of  the 
subscriptions  is  raised  so  as  to  provide  for 
interest  and  repayment  of  capital.  It  is  a 
common  practice  for  persons  to  become  members 
for  the  sole  purpose  of  borrowing.  The  liability 
of  investing  members  is  limited  to  the  amount 
actually  paid,  or  in  arrear,  on  their  respective 
shares,  while  the  liability  of  borrowing  members 
extends  to  the  total  amount  of  the  subscriptions 
payable  by  them  under  the  particular  mortgage 
deed,  or  under  the  rules  of  the  society.  Mem- 
bers may  generally  withdraw  their  shares  on 
terms  specified  in  the  rules.  The  societies 
called  Bowkett  societies  are  terminating  societies, 
making  advances  to  their  members  which  are 
repayable  within  a  fixed  time  without  any 
interest.  The  rotation  of  the  members  is 
determined  by  ballot.  It  is  obvious  that  this 
system  gives  an  undue  advantage  to  those 
members  who  obtain  advances  in  an  early  stage 
of  the  society's  progress,  and  this  inequal- 
ity has  been  modified  by  the  Starr -BowJcett 
societies.  Every  building  society  is  regulated  by 
rules  which  must  contain  certain  particulars 
enumerated  in  the  act  of  1874.  These  rules 
must  be  examined  by  the  registrar  of  friendly 
societies,  who,  after  being  satisfied  that  they 
are  in  accordance  with  the  requirements  of  the 
law,  grants  a  certificate  of  incorporation.  The 
act  authorises  building  societies  to  take  de- 
posits and  generally  to  obtain  loans  within 
certain  limits,  it  requires  that  every  deposit- 
book  or  acknowledgment,  or  security  of  any 
kind  given  for  a  deposit,  or  a  loan  by  a  society, 
shaU  have  printed  or  Avritten  therein  or  thereon 
the  sections  of  the  act  relating  to  the  liability 
of  the  members,  and  the  regulation  of  the 
borrowing  powers.  Building  societies  may 
hold  land  as  far  as  it  is  necessary  for  their 
purposes  ;  summary  remedies  in  the  county 
court  are  given  against  defaulting  ofiicers,  and 
there  are  special  facilities  offered  for  the 
criminal  prosecution  of  persons  defrauding  such 
societies.      On  the  repayment  of  a  loan  by  a 


member  no  formal  reconveyance  of  the  mort- 
gaged property  is  necessary.  Building  societies 
are,  when  necessary,  wound  up  by  the  county 
court  of  the  district  in  a  manner  similar  to 
that  directed  by  the  Companies  Acts  for  joint- 
stock  Companies.  Building  societies  registered 
under  the  act  of  1836  were  authorised  to  take 
out  certificates  of  incorporation  under  the  new 
act,  and  most  of  them  have  availed  themselves 
of  this  privilege,  but  some  unincorporated 
societies  are  still  in  existence.  Besides  these 
there  are  also  co-operative  building  societies, 
which  are  not  essentially  diff'erent  from  other 
co-operative  societies.  The  diff'erence  between 
building  societies  and  joint-stock  companies 
is  pointed  out  in  a  very  lucid  manner  by  the 
royal  commissioners  (whose  report,  published 
in  1872,  preceded  the  passing  of  the  act  of 
1874).  They  poiiit  out  that,  while  in  a 
joint  -  stock  company  the  leading  idea  is 
capital,  membership  is  the  essential  principle  of 
a  building  society.  "  In  the  building  society 
the  capital  is  never  fixed.  The  number  of 
shares  is  always  indefinite,  and  the  share  has 
no  permanence.  The  capital  is  constantly 
increasing  by  the  addition  of  new  shares,  or 
decreasing  by  the  withdrawal  of  existing  ones. 
...  Its  membership  remaining  always  open,  it 
knows  no  share  jobbing,  fattens  no  brokers, 
and  needs  no  settling  day  on  the  Stock  Ex- 
change. .  .  .  The  two  forms  of  undertaking, 
we  venture  therefore  to  think,  have  an  equal 
right  to  subsist,  the  one  for  the  use  of  them 
who  seek  to  make  capital,  the  others  for  those 
who,  having  made  it,  seek  to  use  it."  The 
antithesis  of  the  last  sentence  is  not  quite 
accurate  from  the  economical  point  of  view  ; 
it  might  be  more  correct  to  say  that  the 
building  society  gives  an  opportunity  to  invest 
savings  which  are  gi-adually  accumulating, 
while  the  joint-stock  company  as  a  general 
rule  does  not  offer  the  same  facilities  for  that 
purpose  ;  but  the  main  point  is  that  the 
building  societies  absorb  the  savings  of  a  class 
of  investors  who,  as  a  rule,  could  not  invest 
in  the  shares  of  joint-stock  companies.  It  is 
right  that  societies  established  for  this  purpose 
should  enjoy  certain  facilities  not  accorded  to 
ordinary  joint  -  stock  companies,  but  special 
care  should  be  taken,  on  the  other  hand,  that 
the  funds  so  provided  should  be  managed  by 
competent,  prudent,  and  honest  persons,  and 
that  the  safety  of  the  capital  should  be  con- 
sidered of  greater  importance  than  a  high 
return  of  interest.  Recent  judicial  decisions 
have  established  the  principle  that  the  directors 
of  building  societies  have,  in  the  absence  of  any 
special  rules,  the  same  freedom  of  action  as  the 
directors  of  financial  companies.  This  principle, 
though  it  may  be  in  accordance  with  the  words 
of  the  statute,  does  not  harmonise  with  the 
ideas  expressed  by  the  commissioners,  which 
the   Building  Societies  Act   was   intended   to 


190 


BUILDING  SOCIETIES— BULL  OF  BOEGIA 


embody,  and  the  interference  of  tlie  legislature 
would  be  clearly  desirable.  The  following 
figures  illustrate  the  growth  of  building  societies. 
Those  of  1870  are  derived  from  the  com- 
missioners' second  report,  and  are  partly  based 
on  estimate  ;  later  figures  are  from  the  annjial 
reports  by  the  chief  registrar  of  friendly  societies 
(building  societies).  Some  societies  do  not  make 
returns,  or  only  return  certain  items.  The  num- 
ber of  these  is  added  in  square  brackets  : 


Ko.  of 

Members. 

Annual 

Societies. 

Beceipts. 

England   . 

1888 

2444 

682,866 
[1940] 

£19,480,489 
[2146] 

1908 

1691 

581,026 

39,898,872 

England 

[1665] 

[1665] 

and  "Wales 

1912 

1503 

573,212 
[1474] 

21,407,405 
[1474] 

,^1870 

88 

20,685 

1,000,000 

iS88 

50 

8,968 
[37] 

403,617 
[44] 

Scotland    - 

1908 

138 

30,970 
[132] 

681,292 
[132] 

1912 

119 

27,814 

617,062 

[114] 

[114] 

flS70 

17 

3,836 

no  estimate 

1888 

51 

12,310 
[44] 

531,751 
[44] 

Ireland 

1908 

90 

10,618 
[67] 

445,034 
[67] 

1912 

81 

8,908 

330,769 

[49] 

[49] 

Due  to 

Liabilities  on 

investing 

Loans  and 

Total  Assets. 

Members. 

Deposits. 

ri870 

£9,000,000 

£6,000,000 

£17,000,000 

1888 

34,705,963 

14,734,511 

61,218,823 

Eng. - 

[2157] 

[2157] 

[2157] 

19081 

42,154,539 

24,929,500 

70,957,594 

[1665] 

[1665] 

[1665] 

J9121 

43,073,924 

16,464,309 

62,126,159 

ri870 

823,282 

474,916 

1,500,000 

1888 

729,970 

242,198 

1,011,961 

Scot.  J 

[45] 

[45] 

[45] 

19081 

1,430,092 

377,584 

1,933,374 

[132] 

[132] 

[132] 

. 19121 

1,429,763 

399,183 

1,962,133 

f  1870 

419,984 

147,139 

no  estimate 

1888 

680,816 

248,314 

991,514 

Tt'pI 

[4] 

[4] 

[4] 

"®^-  ■    19081 

764,775 

275,206 

1,150,973 

[67] 

[67] 

[67] 

1 19121 

581,575 

212,254 

883,499 

1  1908  and  1912,  holders  of  shares.  1912,  number  of 
societies  making  returns :  England,  1474;  Scotland,  114 ; 
Ireland,  49. 

Number  of  Societies  whose  returns  show  amounts 
exceeding  £100,000  under  any  of  the  heads  named 
[England  and  Wales]. 


Annual 
Beceipts. 

Due  to 

investing 
Members. 

Liabilities 
on  Loans 

and 
Deposits. 

Total 
Assets. 

1870 
1888 
1908 

10 
26 
33 

8 

44 
64 

8 

17 
24 

13 
64 
94 

It  will  be  seen  that  in  England  the  number 
of  members  has  decreased,  as  also  the  number 
of  societies,  while  the  business  done  has  in- 
creased. The  figures  seem  to  point  to  the  fact 
that  a  much  wealthier   class  of  shareholders 


has  come  in  since  the  passing  of  the  act.  In 
Scotland  the  figures  have  followed  the  same 
variations.  In  Ireland  the  progress  is  by  no 
means  uniform.  The  act  of  1894  required  all 
the  societies  established  after  1856  to  be  incor- 
porated under  the  act  of  1874.  e.  s. 

BtJLAU,  Friedkich  von  (1805-1859),  a 
German  economist  of  note,  Mas  born  at  Freiberg ; 
he  studied  at  Leipsic,  where  he  became,  in  1833, 
professor  of  philosophy,  and  in  1840  of  political 
science,  filling  the  latter  chair  till  his  death. 
He  held  from  1837  the  censorship  of  the  periodi- 
cal press.  He  took  a  prominent  part  in  the 
propagation  of  the  doctrines  of  Adam  Smith  in 
Germany.  His  principal  economic  writings  are 
— Encydopedie  der  Staatswissensehaften,  1832  ; 
Der  Stoat  und  der  Landhau,  1834  ;  Der  Staat 
und  die  Industrie,  1834  ;  HaTidhuch  der  Staats- 
wirthschaftslehre,  1835  ;  Die  Behorden  in  Staat 
tend  Gemeinde,  1836.  He  was  a  writer  of  no 
mean  ability,  though  taking  only  a  second  rank 
among  the  economists  of  his  time.  "He  has 
not,"  says  Roscher,  "the  keen  analysis  of 
Hermann,  the  learned  thoroughness  of  Kait, 
nor  the  exact  observation  and  creative  fancy  of 
Von  Thijnen.  Even  such  of  his  books  as  were 
intended  as  manuals  for  instruction  have  the 
tone  of  essays  or  good  leading  articles  ;  and  he 
devotes  himself  rather  to  the  discussion  of  the 
practical  questions  of  the  day  than  to  the 
examination  of  fundamental  principles."  He 
advocated  the  most  unlimited  freedom  of  the 
individual  in  the  economic  sphere,  and  insisted 
that  the  state  must  not  interfere  with  com- 
petition, or  prescribe  to  citizens  the  way  in 
which  they  should  pursue  their  own  interest. 
He  thought  the  most  important  office  of 
political  economy  was  to  reverse  the  mistaken 
policy  of  the  past,  which  impeded  the  opera- 
tion of  natural  laws.  He  was,  in  particular, 
strongly  in  favour  of  removing  the  legal  fetters 
which,  in  his  time,  in  Germany  restricted  the 
alienation  of  land.  (Roscher,  Nat.  Okon.  in 
Deutschland,  p.  902).  j.  k.  I. 

BULL.  A  term  usually  applied  to  a  buyer 
on  borrowed  money.  The  term  on  the  stock 
exchange  distinguishes  the  speculator  for  the 
rise  from  the  pure  investor.  The  latter  buys  a 
stock,  pays  at  the  date  of  settlement  ;  the 
bull  pays  a  rate  of  interest  in  order  to  "  con- 
tinue" his  bargain  till  the  next  settlement. 
"Bull"  is  the  opposite  to  a  "Bear"  (see 
Bear;  Continuation  or  Contango.)     a.  e. 

BULL  OF  BORGIA.  A  bull  issued  in  1493 
by  Pope  Alexander  VI.  professing  to  grant  to 
the  crown  of  Castile  and  Aragon  all  lands  dis- 
covered, or  to  be  discovered,  beyond  a  line  drawn 
from  pole  to  pole,  100  miles  west  from  the 
Azores — the  crown  of  Portugal  to  have  all  lands 
eastward  of  such  line.  All  lands  previously 
occupied  by  any  Christian  king  were  excepted. 
The  object  of  the  bull  was  to  confer  a  monopoly 


BULLION— BULLION  COMMITTEE 


191 


of  trade  with  the  new  world  on  Spain  and 
Portugal.  J.  E.  0.  M. 

[For  copy  of  the  bull,  see  Bullarium  Magnum 
Romanum  (Luxembourg,  1727).] 

BULLION.  The  precious  metals  Gold  and 
Silver  {q.v.)  are  generally  spoken  of  as  bullion 
when  at  or  near  the  standard  fineness  accepted 
at  the  mints  of  the  different  countries  of  the 
world  (see  Standard).  The  term  is  sometimes 
applied,  with  some  qualifying  epithet,  to  ores 
containing  only  a  very  small  portion  of  the 
precious  metals,  which  are  called  "dore  bullion" 
or  "base  bullion,"  etc.  A  statement  in  the 
report  of  Mr.  J.  P.  Turnbull,  director  of  the 
U.S.  mint,  on  the  production  of  the  precious 
metals  in  the  United  States,  pp.  14-15  (1887), 
will  explain  this.  The  reference  in  it  is  to 
certain  ores  found  in  Mexico  more  or  less 
argentiferous,  the  value  of  which  "has  been 
generally  estimated  in  Mexico  by  the  assay  of 
the  precious  metals,  or  of  silver  to  the  exclusion 
of  the  minute  proportion  of  gold  "  contained 
in  the  ore  ;  the  base  metals  not  entering  into 
the  estimated  value.  The  report  then  refers  to 
**  the  small  tenor  of  gold  extracted  from  dore 
bullion."  The  metallic  compound  is  then 
termed  "dore  bullion"  or  " base  bullion "  ac- 
cording to  the  proportion  of  the  metals  of 
which  it  is  composed — mainly  silver  or  lead, 
but  the  term  bullion  is  properly  applicable  to 
the  precious  metals  alone  (see  Billon). 

[See  Eeports  of  the  Deputy  Master  of  the  Mint, 
London. — Reports  of  the  Director  of  the  Mint, 
United  States,  Washington. — Reports  on  the  Pro- 
duction of  the  Precious  Metals  in  the  United  States, 
Washington,  etc.] 

BULLION  COMMITTEE,  Report  of.  The 
Report  of  the  Select  Committee  of  the  House  of 
Commons  on  the  High  Price  of  Gold  Bullion, 
ordered  to  be  printed  8th  June  1810,  deserves 
notice  from  (1)  the  circumstances  which  led  to 
the  appointment  of  the  committee  ;  (2)  the 
information  and  opinions  expressed  in  the 
Report ;  (3)  the  controversy  which  the  publica- 
tion of  the  Report  called  forth  ;  and  (4)  the 
influence  which  resulted  on  the  financial  policy 
of  the  country.  (1)  The  note  circulation  of 
the  Bank  of  England  had  expanded  from  an 
average  of  about  10  to  11  millions  in  1795  to 
nearly  20  millions  in  1809.  Specie  payments 
having  been  suspended  1797,  and  the  paper 
circulation  having  been  increased,  the  foreign  Ex- 
changes became  unfavourable  to  this  country, 
and  the  paper  circulation  was  depreciated  in  com- 
parison with  gold  (average  depreciation  of  value 
of  currency  13-5  per  cent  1810. — Mushet)  ; 
gold  in  bars  being  at  the  price  of  from  £4  :  10s. 
to  £4  :  12s.  per  oz.  in  the  early  months  of  1810, 
at  that  date  about  15|-  per  cent  above  the 
mint  price  of  £3  :  17  :  lo|  per  oz.  (2)  The 
Report  expressed  the  opinion  that  the  divergence 
then  observable  between  the  gold  and  the  paper 
was  caused  by  an  over-issue  of  the  latter,  and 


that  it  was  "difficult  to  resist  the  inference 
that  a  portion  at  least  of  the  great  fall  which 
the  exchanges  lately  suffered  must  have  resulted, 
not  from  the  state  of  trade,  but  from  a  change 
in  the  relative  value  of  our  domestic  currency." 
The  remedy  then  suggested  was  "That  the 
system  of  the  circulating  medium  of  this  Country 
ought  to  be  brought  back,  with  as  much  speed  as 
is  compatible  mth  a  wise  and  necessary  caution, 
to  the  original  principle  of  Cash  payments  at  the 
option  of  the  holder  of  Bank  paper."  (3)  A 
sharp  controversy  was  excited  by  these  resolu- 
tions of  the  committee.  The  directors  of  the 
Bank  of  England  had  stated  to  the  committee 
"a  doctrine,  of  the  truth  of  which  they  pro- 
fessed themselves  to  be  most  thoroughly  con- 
vinced, that  there  can  be  no  possible  excess  in 
the  issue  of  Bank  of  England  paper  so  long  as 
the  advances  in  which  it  is  issued  are  made 
upon  the  principles  which  at  present  guide  the 
conduct  of  the  Directors,  that  is,  so  long  as  the 
discount  of  mercantile  Bills  is  confined  to  paper 
of  undoubted  solidity,  arising  out  of  real  com- 
mercial transactions,  and  payable  at  short  and 
fixed  periods "  (Report,  High  Price  of  Gold 
Bullion,  §  3).  The  Report  of  the  Bullion  Com- 
mittee was  printed  20th  June  1810,  the  day 
before  the  prorogation,  hence  it  was  not  con- 
sidered till  the  next  session,  when  it  "was  made 
the  gi'ound  for  a  set  of  sixteen  resolutions, 
moved  in  the  House  of  Commons  6th  May 
1811,  by  Mr.  Horner,  the  chairman  of  that 
committee ;  the  last  of  these  resolutions  being  h\ 
pursuance  of  the  recommendation  in  the  Report, 
to  make  it  imperative  on  the  Bank  to  resume 
cash  payments  at  the  end  of  two  years.  A 
counter  set  of  resolutions  Avas  moved  by  Mr. 
Vansittart  ;  the  third  of  them  being  the 
memorable  one  *  That  the  promissory  notes  of 
the  Bank  of  England  have  hitherto  been  and 
are  at  this  time  held  to  be  equivalent  to  the 
legal  coin  of  the  realm. '  The  rival  resolutions 
of  Mr.  Vansittart,  including  this  last,  which, 
has  been  a  standing  topic  of  ridicule  ever  since, 
were  canied  on  the  9th  of  May,  by  a  majority 
of  151  to  75"  (Tooke,  History  of  Prices,  vol. 
iv.  p.  99).  The  vote  on  this  occasion  was 
doubtless  influenced  far  more  by  a  belief  that 
it  was  inexpedient  to  bind  the  Bank  to  resume 
cash  payments  in  so  short  a  period,  irrespective 
of  the  question  whether  peace  were  restored  at 
the  end  of  that  time  or  not,  than  by  any  con- 
viction  as  to  the  truth  of  the  opinion  which 
Mr.  Vansittart  maintained,  contrary  to  the 
evidence  given  before  the  committee.  (4)  The 
influence  of  these  proceedings  on  the  financial 
policy  of  the  United  Kingdom  was  considerable, 
as  they  had  great  weight  with  Sir  R.  Peel  in 
1844,  when  introducing  the  Bank  Act  of  that 
year.  He  referred  to  the  appointment  of  this 
committee  in  his  speech,  6th  May  1844,  as 
follows — "In  1810  men  of  sagacity  observed 
that  the  exchanges  had  been,  for  a  considerable 


192 


BUONARKOTI— BUREAU  OF  LABOUR 


period,  unfavourable  to  this  country,  more  un- 
favourable than  could  be  accounted  for  by  the 
balance  of  trade  or  the  monetary  transactions 
of  this  country."  Sir  R.  Peel,  after  defining 
the  pound  sterling  and  the  standard,  continued 
his  observations  on  the  Measure  of  Value  «,nd 
the  coinage,  stating  "that  in  using  the  word 
money,  I  mean  to  designate  by  that  word  the 
coin  of  the  Realm  and  promissory  notes,  payable 
to  bearer  on  demand,"  addiag,  "  I  think  experi- 
ence shows  that  the  paper  currency,  that  is,  the 
promissory  notes  payable  to  bearer  on  demand, 
stands  in  a  certain  relation  to  the  gold  coin  and 
the  foreign  exchange  in  which  other  forms  of 
paper  credit  do  not  stand.  There  are  striking 
examples  of  this  adduced  in  the  Report  of  the 
Bullion  Committee  of  1810."  Sir  R  Peel  pro- 
ceeded to  argue,  basing  his  theory  on  facts 
shown  to  exist  during  a  period  of  suspension  of 
specie  payments,  contrary,  as  he  admitted,  to 
"the  high  authority  of  Adam  Smith  and  of 
RiOAKDO,"  that  "  convertibility  into  coin  at  the 
will  of  the  holder  "  was  * '  not  an  adequate  security 
against  the  excessive  issue  of  promissory  notes." 
Hence  we  may  trace  the  theory  on  which  Sir 
R.  Peel  based  the  act  of  1844,  to  the  interpre- 
tation he  put  on  the  Report  of  the  Bullion  Com- 
mittee (see  Bank  Note  ;  Bank  of  England  ; 

CUEEENCY  DoCTEINE,  ctc.) 

[Report,  together  with  minutes  of  evidence  and 
accounts,  from  the  Select  Committee  on  the  High 
Price  of  Gold  Bullion  (ordered  by  the  House  of 
Commons  to  be  printed,  8th  June  1810).  For  the 
history  of  the  controversy  mentioned  see  The  High 
Price  of  Bullion  a  Proof  of  the  Depreciation  of 
Bank  Notes,  D.  Ricardo,  London,  4th  ed,,  1811, 
with  Appendix,  the  most  complete  edition.  In 
this  pamphlet  Ricardo  showed  conclusively  that 
the  value  of  the  note  was  depreciated  from  excess 
of  issue. — Practical  Observations  on  the  Report  of 
the  Bullion  Committee,  Chas.  Bosanquet,  London, 
1810 ;  the  ablest  of  the  pamphlets  in  opposition 
to  the  Report. — Reply  to  Mr.  Bosanquet' s  Practi- 
cal Observations  on  the  Report  of  the  Bullion  Com- 
mittee, D.  Ricardo,  London,  1811 ;  a  complete 
answer,  based  on  a  knowledge  both  of  the  theory 
and  the  practice  of  the  subject. — The  Question 
respecting  the  Depreciation  of  the  Currency  t^ated 
and  Examined,  by  William  Huskisson,  M.P., 
London,  1810,  and  included  in  Private  Reprints, 
by  Lord  Overstone,  1857,  with  other  "Select 
Tracts  on  Paper  Currency." — History  of  Prices, 
1792-1856,  Tooke  and  Newmarch,  London,  v.d., 
see  particularly  vols.  i.  and  iv.,  specially  interesting 
.as  contemporary  history. — Thoughts  and  Details 
on  the  High  and  Low  Prices  of  the  Thirty  Fears 
from  1793  to  1822,  London,  Thomas  Tooke,  2d 
ed.,  1824 ;  to  a  great  extent  incorporated  with  the 
preceding,  but  also  interesting. — A  Series  of  Tables 
Exhibiting  the  Gain  and  Loss  to  the  Fundholder 
arising  from  the  Fluctuations  in  the  Valu^  of  the 
Cwrrency  from,  1800  to  1821,  Robert  Mushet, 
London,  1821 ;  the  standard  work  of  reference  on 
this  subject.] 

BUONARROTI,  Philippe  (1761-1837),  com- 


munist conspirator  and  writer,  was  bom  at 
Pisa.  He  became  a  student  of  literature,  and 
was  for  a  time  in  high  favour  at  the  Tuscan 
court.  His  enthusiasm  for  the  French  Re- 
volution led,  however,  to  his  banishment. 
He  retired  to  Corsica,  and  served  French 
interests  so  well  there  that  when  he  came  to 
France  the  Convention  created  him  a  French- 
man by  decree.  He  associated  himself  with 
the  Jacobins,  and  became  one  of  the  chief 
leaders  of  the  conspiracy  of  Babeuf  {q.v.). 
For  this  he  was  condemned  to  transportation, 
but  the  sentence  was  never  canied  out,  and, 
after  imprisonment  and  detention  in  several 
places,  he  was  allowed  in  1806  to  leave  France. 
He  established  himself  first  at  Geneva,  and  after- 
wards in  Belgium,  where  he  supported  himself 
by  composing  and  teaching  music.  In  1828 
he  published  at  Brussels  his  Conspiration  pour 
V6galit6  dite  de  Babeuf,  suivie  du  proems  auquel 
elle  dovma.  lieu  et  des  pieces  justijicaiives,  etc., 
which  contains  the  most  complete  scheme  for 
the  actual  establishment  of  communism,  as  dis- 
tinguished from  the  description  of  a  mere  ideal 
state,  that  has  ever  been  put  forward.  The 
author  ascribes  the  whole  scheme  to  Babeuf, 
but  there  can  be  little  doubt  that  this  is  to  a 
great  extent  a  literary  fiction,  and  that  the 
scheme  is  mostly  his  own  (see  Communism). 
He  returned  to  Paris  in  1830. 

A  letter  from  him  to  J.  Bronterre  O'Brien  com- 
paring the  schemes  of  Babeuf  and  Owen  is  quoted 
in  Holy oake's  History  of  Co-operation,  vol.  i.  p.  258. 
A  translation  of  his  Conspiration  was  published  by 
O'Brien  in  1836,  and  had  some  circulation  among 
the  Chartists  (Holyoake,  Hist,  of  Co-operation,  vol. 
i.  p.  44).  E.  c. 

BUQUOY,  Georg  Franz,  Count,  was  born 
at  Brussels  1781,  and  died  at  Prague  1861. 
Proficient  in  several  sciences,  Buquoy  en- 
deavoured to  apply  mathematics  to  political 
economy  in  his — 

Theorie  der  Nationalwirthschaft,  1815  ;  supple- 
mented by  Da^s  national-udrthshaftliche  Princip, 
1816. — Erlduterung  einiger  eignen  Ansichten, 
1817. — Begrilndung  des  Begriffs  von  reellem 
Werth,  1819. — (The  author's  ethical  and  poli- 
tical principles  are  set  forth  in  SMzze,  1819. — 
His  views  on  currency,  in  Einauf  echten  National- 
credit  fundirtes  Geld,  1819). — See  Wiu-zbach, 
Biographisches  Lexicon  des  Kaiserthums  Oster- 
reichs.  p.  t.  e. 

BUREAU  OF  LABOUR.  In  large  industrial 
communities  the  establishment  of  a  department 
of  government  dealing  specially  with  the 
numbers,  movements,  and  condition  of  the 
working  classes  has  been  recommended  for  two 
reasons  :  (1)  in  the  interest  of  the  state  itself, 
to  furnish  information  which  may  guide  the 
legislature ;  (2)  in  the  direct  interest  of  the 
working  classes,  that  employers  and  employed 
may  be  brought  together,  and  workers  may  go 
where  they  are  most  wanted  and  best  paid  (see 
Bourse  du  Travail).     The  existing  bureaus 


BUREAU  OF  LABOUR,  UNITED  STATES— BUREAUCRACY 


193 


confine  themselves  to  the  first  object.  The 
second  seems  better  secured  by  well-organised 
trades  societies  than  by  a  bureau  of  labour, 
which  might  be  used  against  them  in  labour 
disputes.  Even  a  purely  statistical  bureau,  if 
its  figures  are  to  be  full  and  trustworthy,  must 
be  above  suspicion  of  collusion  with  employers  ; 
and  this  requisite  seems  best  fulfilled  by  the 
appointment  of  a  representative  of  the  working 
classes  on  the  staff  of  officials.  England  since 
1886  has  had  a  "labour  correspondent,"  under 
the  board  of  trade  ;  and  the  present  holder  of 
the  office  was  a  well-known  trades  unionist. 
SAvitzerland  has  not  only  a  bureau  of  labour,  but 
a  labour  secretary  of  state,  in  close  connection 
with  the  trades  societies  of  the  republic. 
Germany  has  no  separate  labour  bureau,  but 
the  collection  of  labour  statistics  is  carried  on 
by  the  general  statistical  bureau  with  great 
carefulness,  in  view  of  the  administration  of  the 
workmen's  insurance  acts.  The  experiment  is 
being  tried  on  a  large  scale  in  the  United 
States  (see  below),  where  there  is  a  national 
bureau  at  Washington  (established  1884),  and 
more  than  twenty  of  the  states  have  also  estab- 
lished bureaux,  the  earliest  being  JSIassachusetts 
(1869)  and  Pennsylvania  (1872).  The  forma- 
tion of  an  International  Bureau  of  Labour  was 
suggested  in  connection  with  the  Labour  Con- 
ference held  at  Berlin  in  March  1890  ;  but  the 
project  remains  as  yet  unrealised.  For  recent 
developments  of  Labour  Bureaux  see  Unem- 
ployed, Appendix. 

[See  Report,  Board  of  Trade,  Relation  of  Wages 
in  certain  Industries  to  the  Cost  of  Production 
(T.  H.  Elliott),  1891.]  J.  B. 

BUREAU  OF  LABOUR  IN  THE  UNITED 
STATES.  Histonj.  — In  1869  the  state  of 
Massachusetts  established  a  bureau  of  statistics 
of  labour.  In  1872  Pennsylvania  organised  a 
bureau  of  industrial  statistics.  Neither  of  them 
seems  to  have  been  owing  to  any  demand  on 
the  part  of  labour  organisation.  But  after  the 
great  railroad  strikes  of  1877,  bureaus  were 
established  in  rapid  succession  in  Ohio  (1877), 
in  New  Jersey  (1878),  in  Illinois,  Indiana,  and 
Missouri  (1879).  A  little  later  the  powerful 
organisation  known  as  the  Knights  of  Labour 
made  the  establishment  of  such  bureaus  one  of 
their  "demands,"  and  they  were  organised  in 
New  York,  California,  Michigan,  and  Wis- 
consin (1883)  ;  Iowa  and  Maryland  (1884)  ; 
Kansas  and  Connecticut  (1885)  ;  Maine,  Min- 
nesota, Colorado,  North  Carolina,  Rhode  Island, 
and  Nebraska  (1887).  A  national  bureau  of 
labour  was  established  18th  January  1885, 
which  became  the  department  of  labour  in 
1887.  Its  head  (commissioner  of  labour)  is 
not,  however,  a  cabinet  officer. 

The  main  ohject  of  all  these  bureaux  is  to  inves- 
tigate the  condition  of  the  labouring  class.    The 
Massachusetts  statute,  which  has  been  followed 
in  most  of  the  other  states,  reads  as  follows  : 
VOL.  T. 


"The  bureau  shall  collect,  assort,  arrange,  and 
present  in  annual  reports  .  .  .  statistical  details 
relating  to  all  departments  of  labour  in  the 
Commonwealth,  especially  in  relation  to  the 
commercial,  industrial,  social,  educational,  and 
sanitary  condition  of  the  labouring  classes,"  etc. 

In  many  of  the  states  [e.g.  N.  J.,  Penn.,  Ind., 
111.,  Wis.,  la.,  Kan,,  and  Neb.)  the  bureau  is 
also  a  bureau  of  industrial  statistics,  and  is 
expected  to  collect  and  publish  information 
relating  to  the  chief  industries  of  the  state. 

In  Wisconsin  and  Missouri  the  commissioner 
of  labour  is  also  the  chief  factory  inspector,  and 
in  Illinois  the  board  of  labour  commissioners 
appoint  the  inspectors  of  mines. 

The  financial  resources  of  most  of  the  bureaus 
are  extremely  meagre  ;  the  officers  consist  of  a 
chief  and  one  or  two  clerks  ;  and  only  a  few 
hundred,  or  at  most  a  few  thousand,  dollars  are 
allowed  for  the  work  of  gathering  statistics. 

The  legal  powers  are  not  extensive  ;  for 
although  in  many  states  penalties  are  prescribed 
for  refusal  to  give  the  information  demanded 
by  the  bureau,  yet  these  penalties  are  seldom 
enforced.  Most  of  the  bureaus  simply  send  out 
circular  schedules  to  employers  of  labour,  a 
large  proportion  of  which  are  never  answered. 

The  scientific  value  of  the  reports  of  the 
state  bureaus  is  very  unequal.  Those  of  Massa 
chusetts  (twenty -three  in  number)  form  an 
extremely  valuable  series,  and  contain  the  best 
information  we  possess  in  regard  to  the  condi- 
tion of  American  labour.  The  New  Jersey  and 
Illinois  reports  also  contain  valuable  informa- 
tion.    The  others  are  of  little  consequence. 

The  national  bureau  (department)  of  labour 
is  better  equipped  than  any  of  the  state  bureaus. 
It  undertakes  special  investigations  and  has 
published  reports  on  The  Depression  of  Trade 
(1886)  ;  Strikes  and  Lockouts  (1887)  ;  Convict 
Labour  (1888)  ;  Marriage  and  Divorce  (1889)  ; 
Working- women  in  Great  Cities  (1889)  ;  Cost 
of  Production  (1890) ;  and  Condition  of  Rail- 
road employes  (1890). 

[Reports  of  the  various  bureaus  (generally 
annual,  in  some  cases  biennial). — Proceedings  of 
convention  of  the  chiefs  of  labour  bureaus  (annu- 
ally since  1883). — Political  Science  Quarterly, 
vol.  i.  1886,  pp.  45  seq.  and  438  seg.] 

R.  M.-S. 

BUREAUCRACY.  The  administration  of 
many  branches  of  business,  public  and  private, 
by  functionaries  centralised  in  bureaux  (whence 
the  name  is  derived),  is  the  rule  in  most  of  the 
important  countries  of  Europe.  It  is  less  the 
case  in  Great  Britain  and  Ireland  than  on  the 
continent, — but  the  complex  character  of  the 
requirements  of  modern  life,  and  especially  the 
aggregation  of  large  masses  of  the  population 
in  cities,  have  called,  in  recent  times,  for 
increased  superintendence  in  matters  of  health, 
police,  education,  etc.  W.  Bagehot,  in  his  work 
on  The  English  Constitution,  describes  the  advan- 

o 


194 


BUKEAUCRACY— BURKE 


tages  a7id  the  defects  of  a  liiglily  organised 
bureaucracy  very  clearly.  The  necessity  for 
organisation  requires  no  explanation — on  the 
other  hand,  as  Bagehot  remarks,  the  defects  of 
bureaucracy  are  well  known  :  "  It  is  an  inevit- 
able defect,  that  bureaucrats  will  care  more 
for  routine  than  for  results  ;  or,  as  Burke  put 
it,  that  they  will  think  the  substance  of  business 
not  to  be  much  more  important  than  the  forms 
of  it."  Their  whole  education  and  all  the 
habit  of  their  lives  make  them  do  so.  Men 
so  trained  must  come  to  think  the  routine  of 
business  not  a  means  but  an  end  ;  to  imagine 
the  elaborate  machinery  of  which  they  form  a 
part,  and  from  which  they  derive  their  dignity, 
to  be  a  grand  and  achieved  result,  not  a  work- 
ing and  changeable  instrument. 

An  over -organised  "bureaucracy  tends  to 
under-government,  in  point  of  quality  ;  it  tends 
to  over-government  in  point  of  quantity."  The 
risk  is  that  it  comes  to  be  considered  that  **  the 
functionaries  are  not  there  for  the  benefit  of 
the  people,  but  the  people  for  the  benefit  of  the 
functionaries."  Yet,  though  this  risk  is  well 
known — the  weakness  of  separate  individuals 
when  dealing  with  the  organised  forces  of 
powerful  companies  and  corporations,  has  been 
felt  to  be  so  dangerous  and  the  necessity  for 
providing  for  the  health,  the  protection,  and 
the  instruction  of  the  masses,  the  feeble,  and 
the  young,  to  be  so  great,  that  the  tendency  of 
the  day  is  towards  increasing  the  power  of 
official  superintendence  and  inspection.  In  the 
words  of  JEV0Ns(7%e  State  in  Relation  to  Labour, 
p.  166),  "  there  can  be  no  royal  road  to  legisla- 
tion in  such  matters.  We  must  consent  to 
advance  cautiously  step  by  step,  feeling  our 
way,  adopting  no  foregone  conclusions,  trusting 
no  single  science,  expecting  no  infallible  guide. 
"We  •  must  neither  maximise  the  functions  of 
government  at  the  back  of  quasi-military 
officials,  nor  minimise  them  according  to  the 
theories  of  the  very  best  philosophers.  We 
must  learn  to  judge  each  case  upon  its  merits, 
interpreting  with  painful  care  all  experience 
which  can  be  brought  to  bear  upon  the  matter." 
The  gradual  growth  of  this  opinion  is  character- 
istic of  modern  thought.  H.  Sidgwick  (bk.  iii. 
of  his  Principles  of  Political  JEconomy,  ch.  ii. 
"The  system  of  Natural  Liberty  considered  in 
relation  to  Production  "),  while  weighing  carefully 
the  advantages  and  disadvantages  of  govern- 
mental interference,  observes  "  first,  that  these 
disadvantages  are  largely  such  as  moral  and 
political  progress  may  be  expected  to  diminish  ; 
so  that  even  where  we  do  not  regard  the  inter- 
vention of  government  as  at  present  desirable, 
we  may  yet  look  forward  to  it,  and  perhaps 
prepare  the  way  for  it.  And,  secondly,  even 
where  we  reject  governmental  interference,  we 
may  yet  recognise  the  expediency  of  supplement- 
ing or  limiting  in  some  way  or  other  the  results 
of  private  enterprise."     Again,  on  the  cognate 


subject  of  Laissez-Fatre,  we  find  Cairnes, 
in  his  essay  on  "  Political  Economy  and  Laissez- 
faire,"  Essays  in  Political  Economy,  Theoretical 
and  Applied,  saying,  "the  maxim  of  laissez- 
faire  has  no  scientific  basis  whatever,  but  is  at 
best  a  handy  rule  of  practice,  useful  perhaps 
as  a  reminder  to  statesmen  on  which  side  the 
presumption  lies  in  questions  of  industrial 
legislation,  but  totally  destitute  of  all  scientific 
authority."  Compare  with  this  the  sterner 
teaching  of  J.  S.  Mill  {Principles  of  Political 
Economy,  bk.  v.  ch.  xi.,  "Limits  of  the  Pro- 
vince of  Government") — "  Even  if  the  govern- 
ment could  comprehend  within  itself,  in  each 
department,  all  the  more  eminent  intellectual 
capacity  and  active  talent  of  the  nation,  it 
would  not  be  the  less  desirable  that  the  conduct 
of  a  large  portion  of  the  afiairs  of  society  should 
be  left  in  the  hands  of  the  persons  immediately 
interested  in  them.  The  business  of  life  is  an 
essential  part  of  the  practical  education  of  a 
people,  without  which  book  and  school  instruc- 
tion, though  more  necessary  and  salutary,  does 
not  suffice  to  qualify  them  for  conduct,  and  for 
the  adaptation  of  means  to  ends"  (see  Laissez- 
Faire). 

BURET,  Antoinb  Eugene,  born  at  Troyea 
1810,  died»at  Paris  1842.  He  wrote  in  the 
Courrier  franqais,  and  the  Journal  des  econom- 
istes.  But  what,  during  his  short  career,  won 
for  him  chiefly  the  esteem  of  the  economic  world, 
is,  notwithstanding  the  manifest  tendencies  the 
book  contains  towards  the  opinions  of  the  then 
rising  socialist  school,  his  work,  De  la  Mishre  des 
classes  lahoriev^es  en  Angleterre  et  en  France  (2 
vols,  in  8vo).  This  book  is  the  expansion 
of  an  essay  which  obtained  for  the  author  the 
sum  of  £100 — the  half  of  the  quinquennial  prize 
(F^lix  de  Beaujour),  in  1840  awarded  by  the 
Acaddmie  des  Sciences  morales  et  politique  ; 
it  is  written  with  vigour,  and  in  a  conscien- 
tious spirit,  and  is  attractive  to  read,  though 
the  author,  by  representing  exceptional  cases 
as  the  general  rule,  has  drawn  too  gloomy  a 
picture.  Buret  also  revised,  in  conjunction 
with  J.  A.  Blanqui,  the  translation  of  Smith's 
Wealth  of  Nations  by  G.  Garnier,  in  the 
"Collection  Guillaumin."  a.  c.  f 

BURGH,  a  word  used  in  Scotland  for  the 
same  purposes  as  the  wcrd  Borough  {q.v.)  in 
England.  e.  s. 

BURGHER.     See  Citizen. 

BURIDAN",  Jean,  rector  of  the  university 
of  Paris  in  1327,  alive  in  1358,  a  celebrated 
philosopher,  discusses  the  "commutation  of 
moneys  "  and  interest  in  his — 

Qucestiones  super  decern  libros  ethicorum  Aris- 
totelis.  F.  T.  E. 

BURKE,  Edmund,  born  1728  or  1729,  died 
1797.  A  rich  vein  of  economic  wisdom, 
mixed  with  other  precious  materials,  runs 
through  the  whole  vast  tract  of  Burke's 
political   writings.     The   mine   is   deepest,    oi 


BURKE— BUSCH 


195 


at  least  the  ore  purest,  in  the  Thoughts  on 
Scarcity,  dated  1795.  Here  Bui'ke  enunciates 
general  principles  worthy  of  the  Wealth  of 
Nations,  though  perhaps  not  derived  from 
that  source,  if  it  be  true,  as  Prior  relates,  that 
Adam  Smith  described  Burke  as  "the  only 
man  he  had  met  with  who  thought  as  he  did 
on  the  chief  topics  of  political  economy  with- 
out previous  communication."  Bm-ke  says, 
"  Labour  is  a  commodity  like  every  other,  and 
rises  or  falls  according  to  the  demand."  The 
rate  of  wages  thus  determined  "has  no  direct 
relation"  to  the  price  of  provisions.  "The 
balance  between  consumption  and  production 
makes  price.  The  market  settles,  and  alone 
can  settle,  that  price.  .  .  .  Nobody,  I  believe, 
has  observed  with  any  reflection  what  market 
is  without  being  astonished  at  the  truth,  the 
correctness,  the  celerity,  the  general  equit}^, 
with  which  the  balance  of  wants  is  settled." 
Burke  extols  "the  laws  of  commerce  which  are 
the  laws  of  nature,  and  consequently  the  laws 
of  God."  He  condemns  the  "political  canting 
language  "  of  those  who  speak  compassionately 
of  the  "labouring  poor."  Similar  reflections 
occur  in  the  third  letter  on  a  Regicide  Peace. 
There  Burke  says  "to  force  any  market  is  of 
aU  things  the  most  dangerous."  And  again, 
"the  love  of  lucre  is  the  grand  cause  of  pros- 
perity to  all  states."  Just  views  as  to  the 
nature  of  foreign  trade  are  to  be  found  in 
several  places.  Two  Letters  to  Gentlemen  in  the 
City  of  Bristol  denounce  the  restrictions  on 
Irish  trade.  In  a  letter  on  a  ])roposed  Irish 
Absentee  Tax,  Burke  says,  "No  man  living 
loves  restrictive  regulations  of  any  kind  less 
than  I  ;  at  best,  nine  times  in  ten,  they  are 
little  better  than  laborious  and  vexatious 
foUies."  The  fallacies  of  the  mercantile  theory 
did  not  ensnare  Burke.  "To  state  the  whole 
of  the  foreign  import  as  loss  is  exceedingly 
absurd."  Wealth  "consists  in  the  stock  of 
useful  commodities  as  much  as  in  gold  and 
silver"  {Observations  on  a  Late  State  of  the 
Nation).  However,  Burke  seems  not  alto- 
gether to  disapprove  of  the  laws  restricting  the 
commerce  of  America.  "I  am  sure  they  are 
still,  in  many  ways,  of  great  use  to  us  ;  and  in 
former  times  they  have  been  of  the  greatest" 
{Speech  on  Conciliation  with  America).  In- 
deed he  appears  to  treat  the  Balance  of 
Trade  as  not  absurd  (Third  Letter  on  a  Regicide 
Peace).  He  is  no  bigoted  preacher  of  laissez- 
faire.  He  says : — "  It  is  one  of  the  finest 
problems  in  legislation  .  .  .  what  the  state 
ought  to  take  upon  itself  to  direct  by  the 
public  wisdom,  and  what  it  ought  to  leave, 
with  as  little  interference  as  possible  to  indi- 
vidual discretion.  Nothing,  certainly,  can  be 
laid  down  on  the  subject  that  will  not  admit  of 
exceptions,  many  permanent,  some  occasional " 
{Thoughts  on  Scarcity).  In  fine,  Burke  never 
forgets  that  wealth  is  but  one  element  of  well- 


being,  and  not  to  be  separated  from  "the  great 
contexture  of  the  mysterious  whole." 

The  Thoughts  and  Details  on  Scarcity  were 
published  posthumously  in  1800,  with  an  inter- 
esting preface  by  the  editors.  The  groundwork  of 
the  TJioughts  and  Details  consists  of  a  memorial 
addressed  to  Pitt  in  1795  ;  with  which  the  editors 
in  1800  have  incorporated  fragments  of  a  letter 
addressed  to  Arthur  Young  concerning  "  rural 
economics."  Tlie  Thoughts  and  Details  are  to  be 
found,  along  with  the  other  writings  referred  to 
above,  in  the  collective  editions  of  Burke's  works  ; 
of  which  there  are  several,  the  best  perhaps  being 
that  of  1852,  "Works  and  Correspondence"  in 
eight  volumes.  f.  t.  e. 

BURLAMAQUI,  Jean  Jacques  {h.  1G94, 
d.  1748),  professor  of  law  at  Geneva,  has  some 
striking  remarks  about  the  dependence  of  price 
on  rarity  and  utility  in  his  Ll^mens  du  di'oit 
Naturel,  1775  (part  iii.  ch.  xi.)  The  sub- 
stance of  this  work  appeared  in  another  form 
under  the  title  Principes  du  droit  de  la  Nature 
et  des  Gens,  with  matter  added  by  the  editor, 
Prof,  de  Felice,  1766  ;  new  edition,  1820. 
The  remarks  of  Burlamaqui  on  value  have  been 
quoted  by  Walras,  lillements  de  Vl^conomie 
Politique,  2d  ed.  Legon  xvi.  f.  y.  e. 

BURTON,  J.  HILL.    See  Hill  Burton,  J. 

BtJSCH,  JoHANN  Georg  (1728-1800),  was, 
as  Roscher  says,  the  best  representative  of 
liberal  tendencies  among  the  German  eclectic 
economists  in  the  last  thirty  years  of  the  18th 
century.  Materials  for  the  history  of  his  life 
are  supplied  by  his  autobiography  {Ueber  den 
Gan^  mein£S  Geistes  u/nd  meiner  Thdtigkeit). 
He  was  bom  in  the  territory  of  Liineburg,  and 
accompanied  his  father  in  1731  to  Hamburg, 
where  he  resided,  except  dm-iug  his  student- 
years  at  Gottingen  and  occasional  absences,  till 
his  death.  He  is  described  as  an  excellent 
man,  disinterested,  independent,  frank,  modest, 
and  industrious,  and  a  good  citizen,  devoted  to 
the  interests  of  his  adopted  city.  He  was  pro- 
fessor of  mathematics  in  the  local  gymnasium, 
and  conducted  a  trade  academy  at  Hamburg 
which  celebrated  its  centenary  in  1867.  He 
had  a  very  high  reputation  in  Germany  ;  LiJDER 
speaks  of  him  as  "  our  greatest  political  writer," 
but  this  is  a  somewhat  exaggerated  estimate, 
Roscher  characterises  him  as  "a  cultivated, 
experienced,  and  right-minded  man,  disinclined 
to  all  doctrinaire  one-sidedness  and  practical 
extravagance."  He  is  an  original  wTiter,  but 
has  not  the  art  of  orderly  arrangement  and  clear 
exposition.  His  views  were  formed  rather  by 
experience  and  observation  than  by  the  study 
of  books.  The  economic  theorist  whom  he 
most  valued  was  Steuart  ;  he  shows  a  certain 
captiousness  and  even  bitterness  towards  Adam 
Smith,  whom  he  considered  to  be  popularly 
over-rated.  He  is,  however,  more  favourable 
to  Free  Trade  than  most  of  his  German  prede- 
cessors, and  protests  against  the  "hot-bed  culti- 
vation "  of  certain  branches  of  production  at  the 


196 


BUSCHING— BY-LAW 


cost  of  the  community.  He  unfortunately  fell 
into  the  mistake  (indicated  by  the  title  of  his 
principal   work,  Ahhandlung  von  Geldumlauf, 

1780)  of  regarding  economic  phenomena  with 
reference  not  to  wants  and  their  satisfaction, 
but  to  the  circulation  of  money,  a  view  which 
dominates  the  Avhole  circle  of  his  ideas.  *  This 
confuses  much  of  his  reasoning,  obscures  the 
deeper  and  more  essential  facts  of  economic  life, 
and  tends  to  lead  him  back  into  the  errors  of 
mercantilism,  from  which,  accordingly,  he  is 
only  partially  free.  His  most  permanently 
valuable  writings  are  probably  his  treatise  on 
universal  commerce  {Entwurf  einer  Geschichte 
der  merkiviirdigsten  Welthdndel  neuerer  Zeit, 

1781)  and  his  history  of  the  trade  of  Hamburg 
(Gesch.  der  Hamhurgisdmi  Handlung,  1797), 
in  which  he  shows  a  thorough  familiarity  with 
the  course  of  trade  and  the  commercial  relations 
of  diflFerent  countries  (Roscher,  Gesch.  der  Nab. 
Oek.  in  Deutschland,  p.  559).  j.  k.  i. 

BUSCHING,  Anton  Friedrich  (1724- 
1793),  was  one  of  the  two  most  distinguished 
German  statisticians  of  the  18  th  century, 
AoHENWALL  being  the  other.  Like  the  latter, 
he  belongs,  as  regards  his  economic  opinions, 
to  the  more  liberal  branch  of  the  mercantilist 
school.  The  work  on  which  his  reputation 
chiefly  rests  is  his  VorhereituTig  zur  Europdischen 
Lander-  und  Staatskunde,  1759.  He  rendered 
an  important  service  by  initiating  in  his  Neue 
Erdheschreihung  the  new  "politico-statistical" 
method  in  geography,  which  supplies  full  infor- 
mation on  the  natural  resources  and  capabilities, 
the  industry  and  trade,  the  political  system 
and  general  culture  of  each  of  the  countries 
described.  j.  k.  i. 

BUTEL  -  DUMONT,  George  Marie,  was 
bom  at  Paris  in  1725,  and  died  towards  the 
end  of  the  18th  century.  By  profession  he 
was  an  advocate,  and  was  appointed  secretary 
to  the  French  embassy  at  St.  Petersburg. 
His  works  are  chiefly  concerned  with  colonial 
and  commercial  history.  He  is  said  to  have 
^sisted  GouRNAY  in  translating  Child's  New 
Discourse  of  Trade  (1754).  He  translated  and 
enlarged  the  Discourse  on  Trade  of  John  Gary 
(Essai  sur  I'^tat  du  Commerce  d' Angleterre, 
2  vols.  1755).  The  best  known  of  his  works 
is  the  TMorie  du  Luxe,  ou  traiU  dans  lequel  on 
entreprend  d'itablir  que  le  Luxe  est  un  ressort 
non-seulement  utile,  mais  mSmeindispensablement 
nicessaire  A  la  prospirite  des  lEtats,  two  parts, 
1771.  This  does  not,  however,  merit  the  praise 
sometimes  bestowed  upon  it ;  it  is  a  superficial 
apology  for  luxury  without  any  originality, 
attacking  the  "  Tableau  hieroglyphique  "  of  the 
economists,  and  their  theory  of  the  detrimental 
influence  of  luxury  (pt.  ii.  p.  36),  ridiculing 
the  definite  sense  they  give  to  it,  though  con- 
fessing their  merits  in  other  respects  (p.  39). 

His  other  works  are  :  Memoires  historiques 
sur  la  Louisiane,   17 5S.—Histoire  et  Commerce 


des  Colonies  Angloises  dans  VAmirique  Sep' 
tentrionale,  1755. —  Histoire  et  Commerce  des 
Antilles  Angloises,  1758. — Acte  du  Parleijient 
d' Angleterre,  connu  sous  le  nom  Acie  de  Naviga- 
tion, traduit  de  I'Anglois,  1760. — Conduite  des 
Frangais  par  rapport  d  la  Nouvelle-JiJcosse  traduit 
de  I'anglois  (of  Jeffreys),  1765. — And  Recherches 
sur  V administration  des  terres  chez  les  Remains, 
Paris,  1779.  (See  M'Culloch,  Literature,  pp.  34,  46, 
223. )  A  Traite  de  la  circulation  et  du  credit,  is 
sometimes  ascribed  to  Butel-Dumont,  Amsterdam, 
1771.  But  the  author  of  this  tract  is  Isaac  de 
Pinto,  who,  like  Butel-Dumont,  had  written  an 
Essai  sur  le  luxe.  s.  B. 

BUTLERAGE.  A  commuted  toll  or  tax, 
paid  in  specie,  from  about  the  year  1302  on- 
wards, at  a  fixed  rate  upon  every  cask  of  wine 
imported  into  England  by  alien  traders — part 
of  the  additional  duties  termed  the  new  or 
small  customs,  as  opposed  to  the  ancient  or 
great  customs  granted  in  1275 — nova  sive  parva 
custwrn/i — as  opposed  to  antique  sive  magna 
custuma.  This  duty,  as  such,  ceased  to  be 
levied  5th  July  1809,  by  the  Customs  Con- 
solidation Act,  49  Geo.  IIL  c.  98,  §  36.  The 
duty  was  in  commutation  of  the  rights  of  the 
king's  butler  (see  Prisage). 

[Dowell,  History  of  Taxation,  2d.  ed.  vol.  1. 
p.  80;  voL^ii.  p.  237.— H.  Hall,  The  Customs 
Revenue  of  England,  ed.  1885,  vol.  ii.  p.  92.] 

BUYING  IN.  A  transaction  known  only  to 
the  stock  exchange,  where,  if  a  member  haa 
sold  stock,  shares,  or  other  securities,  which  he 
fails  to  deliver  on  a  stipulated  date,  the  buyer 
is  at  liberty  to  purchase  from  any  other  mem- 
ber of  the  stock  exchange,  and  to  claim  against 
the  original  seller  the  difference  between  the 
two  prices,  supposing  the  latter  to  be  higher 
than  the  original  contract  price.  This  is  the 
process :  the  buyer  who  claims  stock,  employs 
the  official  broker  of  the  stock  exchange  to 
"buy  in"  against  the  member  failing  to  deliver. 
That  is,  open  tenders  of  stock  are  invited  ;  and 
he  who  sells  must  be  prepared  to  deliver  im- 
mediately. A.  E. 

BY-LAW,  BYELAW.  A  regulation  of  a 
municipal  or  other  local  authority,  or  of  any 
corporation,  for  the  management  of  its  internal 
affairs.  The  word  is  also,  but  much  less  fre- 
quently, used  in  the  sense  of  additional  or 
secondary  law.  It  is  probably  derived  in  the 
same  manner  as  the  archaic  word  byr-law,  which 
is  still  to  be  found  in  some  dialects  in  the 
original  sense  of  law  or  custom  of  a  Township 
or  Manor,  "byr"  (Swedish  and  Danish = by) 
being  the  old  Norse  word  for  dwelling-place, 
township,  etc.  The  power  of  municipal  cor- 
porations to  make  by-laws  is  now  regulated  by 
the  Municipal  Corporations  Act,  1882,  §  23,  and 
that  of  local  authorities  under  the  Public  Health 
Act,  1875,  by§§  182-188  of  that  act;  those  made 
by  the  former  bodies  may  be  disallowed  by  order 
in  council ;  those  made  by  the  latter  must  be 
confirmed    by    the    local    government    board 


BY-PRODUCT— CABET 


197 


The  Local  Government  Act  of  1888  gives  county- 
councils  the  same  power  of  making  by-laws  in 
relation  to  their  county  as  borough  councils 
have  in  relation  to  their  borough  (§  16). 
There  are  several  statutes  dealing  with  the 
power  of  railway  -companies  to  make  by-laws, 
among  which  the  Railway  Regulation  Act, 
1840  (§§  7-9)  and  the  Companies'  Clauses  Act, 
1845  (§§  124-127)  are  the  most  important. 
The  by-laws  made  by  railway  companies  may 
be  disallowed  by  the  board  of  trade.         e.  s. 

BY-PRODUCT.  A  by-product  is  one  which 
is  obtained  incidentally,  together  with  the  pro- 
duct which  it  is  the  main  object  of  a  particular 
process  to  secure.  Such  products  are  met  with 
in  almost  every  industry  ;  those  connected  with 
metallurgy  will  alone  be  considered,  as  they  will 
serve  for  the  purpose  of  general  illustration.  It 
is,  however,  often  difficult  to  separate  the  results 
of  a  particular  operation  or  process  into  the  main 
and  the  fty-products.  For  instance,  in  the  con- 
version of  coal  into  coke  by  certain  modern 
methods,  the  tar,  ammonia,  benzol,  and  other 
organic  substances  are  collected  as  by-products, 
but  their  value  is  very  gi-eat  when  considered 
in  relation  to  that  of  the  coke  which  is  the  main 
product  of  the  coke  ovens.  In  the  case  of  the 
metallurgical  treatment  of  certain  kinds  of  ii'on 
pyrites,  or  sulphide  of  iron,  the  mineral,  which 
contains  small  quantities  of  copper,  silver,  and 
gold,  is  treated  mainly  with  a  view  to  the  con- 
version of  the  sulphur  it  contains  into  sulphuric 
acid.  The  residue  may  then  be  considered  to 
be  a  poor  ore  of  copper,  gold,  and  silver,  but  it 
is  rich  in  iron,  and  is  useful  for  certain  metal- 
lurgical purposes.  The  iron  can,  however,  only 
be  considered  to  be  a  by-product,  as  it  certainly 
would  not  have  been  possible  to  treat  profitably 
the  iron  pyrites  with  a  view  to  extract  the  iron 
it  contained. 

In  the  metallurgy  of  copper,  gold,  silver,  lead, 
nickel,  and  cobalt,  the  associated  metals  are 
extracted  as  by-products,  and  during  the  ex- 
traction of  silver  from  certain  ores  of  lead  and 
copper,  small  quantities  of  gold  pass  into  the 
silver,  and  conversely  a  small  quantity  of  silver 
is  always  associated  with  gold.  The  separation 
of  a  small  amount  of  one  precious  metal  from  a 
large  mass  of  another  in  which  it  is  hidden  may 
be  effected  very  cheaply,  and  both  the  gold  and 
the  silver,  in  the  respective  cases,  must  be  con- 
sidered to  be  by-products.     It  has  been  estim- 


ated that  no  less  than  500,000  ounces  of  silver 
are  annually  extracted  from  gold,  the  silver 
being  entirely  a  by  -  product,  but,  on  the 
other  hand,  it  would  be  a  very  difficult  question 
to  determine  how  far  the  30,000,000  ounces  of 
silver  obtained  by  the  desilverisation  of  lead 
ores,  and  the  7,000,000  ounces  obtained  during 
the  treatment  of  copper  ores,  are  by-products. 
The  whole  question  of  by-products  is  so  exten- 
sive that  it  is  not  possible  to  do  more  than 
indicate  its  general  nature. 

[The  specialimportanceof  the  subject  in  reference 
to  the  production  of  the  precious  metals,  and  in 
particular  of  silver,  is  shown  in  great  fulness  of 
detail  in  the  Memorandum  by  Professor  Roberts 
Austen,  F.  R.  S. ,  Chemist  to  the  Royal  Mint,  on  the 
Cost  of  Production  of  Silver,  laid  by  him  before 
the  Gold  and  Silver  Commission,  1886.] 

w.  R.-A. 

BY-PRODUCTS,  Theory  op  Yalue  of. 
By-products  may  be  considered  as  a  special 
case  of  Joint-Products  (g.f.)  ;  that  in  which 
one  of  the  joint-products  is  of  relatively  small 
value.  This  incident  does  not  invalidate  the 
general  theory  that  the  prices  of  joint-products 
are  such  that  (1)  the  supply  of  each  commodity 
just  meets  the  demand  ;  (2)  the  net  ad- 
vantages of  the  producer  are  equal  to  those  of 
any  other  occupation  between  which  and  the 
occupation  under  consideration  there  exists 
Industrial  Competition.  It  is  conceivable  in- 
deed that  the  gains  incident  to  the  by-product 
may  be  so  small  as  not  to  exercise  any  influence 
in  determining  the  flow  of  capital  and  labour  to 
the  occupation.  Since  the  mobility  of  labour 
is  subject  to  considerable  friction,  a  very  small 
motive  which  is  not  sufficient  to  overcome 
friction  may  produce  not  so  much  a  small  effect 
as  none  at  all.  Upon  this  view  the  prices  of 
by-products  would  be  determined  only  by  the 
first  of  the  conditions  above  stated.  Their 
value  would  be  altogether  market  as  dis- 
tinguished from  normal  value.  This  hypothesis 
hardly  admits  of  verification.  The  **  equation 
of  net  advantages"  in  different  occupations 
(Marshall,  Economics  of  Industry)  is  not  in 
general  fulfilled  so  exactly  that  it  is  possible  to 
determine  whether  small  items  are,  or  are  not, 
taken  account  of.  It  is  at  least  safe  to  say  that 
it  is  even  more  difficult  to  predict  price  in  the 
case  of  a  by-product  as  here  defined  than  it  is 
(Sidgwick,  Pol.  Econ.  bk.  ii.  ch.  ii.  §  10)  in  the 
case  of  joint-products  generally.  f.  y.  e. 


CABET,  Etienne,  born  at  Dijon  1788,  died 
at  Saint  Louis  (Missouri),  8th  November  1856. 
The  son  of  a  working  man,  he  received  in  his  first 
youth  an  education  to  correspond  with  his  posi- 
tion in  life.  He  soon,  however,  broke  through 
these  early  trammels,  and  at  the  age  of  twelve 
attended  the  lectures  of  his  fellow  townsman, 
Jacotot,  well  known  for  his  method  of  instruc- 


tion, his  own  invention,  which  at  the  time  was 
greatly  in  vogue.  Here  Cabet  made  such  pro- 
gress that  he  was  able  at  fourteen  to  enter,  as  a 
teacher,  the  Lycee  of  Dijon.  Public  instruction 
appeared  at  that  time  to  be  the  occupation  he 
was  likely  to  follow  ;  but  changing  his  course, 
he  turned  first  to  medicine,  then  to  the  study 
of  the  law,  passed,  1812,  as  doctor  en  droit,  and 


198 


CABET 


took  a  distinguished  position  among  tlie  bar  of 
the  department  of  the  Cote  d'or.  He  became, 
1815,  founder  and  director  of  the  FMiration 
Bourguignonne  for  the  defence  of  the  national 
territory,  and  mixed  himself  up  with  the  party 
of  the  Carbonari  {q.v.)  He  appears  to*  have 
derived  his  republican  convictions  from  his 
father,  who  was  a  fiery  patriot.  About  1820-22 
he  fixed  himself  at  Paris,  and  was  specially 
appointed  director  of  the  Vente  Suprenu — the 
name  given  by  the  Carbonari  to  their  political 
meetings.  The  Revolution  of  1830  naturally 
found  him  in  the  first  line  of  its  adherents,  and 
urging  strongly,  but  in  vain,  the  convocation  of 
the  Assemblee  Constituante.  Abandoning  this 
cry,  he  consented,  1st  August  1830,  to  be 
appointed  general  secretary  to  the  ministry  of 
justice,  then,  a  few  weeks  later,  Procureur-g4n4ral 
in  Corsica.  Having  offered  himself  as  a  candi- 
date at  the  election  for  the  legislature,  he  pub- 
lished a  statement  of  his  opinions  which  the 
government  looked  on  as  an  attack  on  established 
institutions.  His  old  comrade  in  carbonarism, 
M.  Barthe,  then  minister  of  justice,  dismissed 
him  from  his  office.  Two  months  later  he  was 
elected  deputy  for  Dijon,  and  immediately  made 
himself  conspicuous  among  the  democratic  opposi- 
tion. He  published,  among  other  things,  a  His- 
toire  de  la  revolution  de  1830  ;  for  this  he  was 
tried  before  a  jury  which  acquitted  him.  After 
escaping  a  second  time,  when  tried  before 
another  judge,  he  was  less  fortunate  on  a  third 
occasion ;  and,  in  1834,  was  condemned  to  two 
years'  imprisonment  for  an  article  in  which  he 
accused  the  government  of  July  of  watching 
with  anxiety  for  the  moment  when  it  could 
cannonade  Paris.  After  a  moment's  delay  he 
fled,  first  to  Brussels,  then  to  London,  whence 
he  did  not  return  till  1839,  when  the  period  of 
his  penalty  had  expired.  He  composed,  in  the 
last-named  city,  several  historical  compilations 
more  or  less  revolutionary  in  tone,  such  as  his 
JSistoire  de  la  revolution  fran^aise,  in  which  the 
most  advanced  adherents  of  the  "mountain" 
were  glorified,  and  their  acts  excused  if  not 
approved.  Up  to  this  date  politics  had  absorbed 
him  ;  he  was  converted  to  communism  by  read- 
ing the  Utopia  of  Sir  T.  More  ;  and  he  shortly 
became  the  most  accredited  high  priest  of  that 
school  of  Socialism,  though  his  communism 
was  not  so  thorough-going  as  might  have  been 
logically  inferred  from  his  principles. 

He  proposed,  in  the  first  place,  a  transitional 
period  of  fifty  years  between  the  actual  regime 
and  that  which  he  dreamed  of.  The  acts  of  the 
administration  and  the  laws  especially  were  to 
be  framed  so  as  to  permit  the  definitive  establish- 
ment of  communism  at  the  end  of  a  half  century. 
Successions  to  property,  gifts,  and  transfers 
were  to  be  severely  scrutinised.  Taxation 
was  no  longer  to  be  levied  on  the  poor,  nor 
on  objects  of  primary  necessity,  nor  on  labour. 
Wealth  and  superfluity,  on  the  other  hand,  were 


to  be  subject  to  Progressive  Taxation.  The 
pay  of  working  people  was  to  be  fixed  by  law, 
and  in  a  sense  favourable  to  them.  An  amount 
of  500  millions  frs.  (20  millions  sterling)  was  to 
be  employed  in  supplying  occupation  to  the 
working  classes  and  dwellings  for  the  poor. 
The  army  was  to  be  suppressed  as  far  as  possible 
— the  men  dismissed  from  the  ranks  being  in- 
demnified and  employed  on  public  works  till 
the  whole  of  the  force  could  be  disbanded. 
Marriages  among  the  working  classes,  the  in- 
struction and  education  of  the  rising  generation, 
were  to  be  encouraged  and  aided  by  an  annual 
charge  of  100  millions  frs.  (4  millions  sterling) 
on  the  budget. 

When  the  half  century  mentioned  above  had 
gone  by  every  one  of  the  age  of  sixty-five  was 
to  be  exempt  from  work,  and  provided  with  a 
retiring  allowance.  At  this  date  also  complete 
communism  was  to  begin  —  at  least  Cabet's 
communism.  As  it  would  be  impossible  to 
attain  direct  government  on  account  of  the  ex- 
tent of  the  country,  resort  was  to  be  had  to 
representative  government,  liberty  of  the  press 
was  to  be  absolutely  suppressed,  one  single 
official  journal  being  allowed  to  appear. 

Work,  according  to  his  plan,  is  obligatory, 
according  to  strength  and  capacity,  for  all — for 
men  from  eighteen  to  sixty-five — for  women  from 
seventeen  to  fifty.  "Work  is,  besides,  so  agree- 
able in  Icaria,  as  this  fortunate  country  is 
named,  that  no  one  is  ever  lazy  there.  All 
working  people  are  separated  according  to  pro- 
fessions, and  then  employed  in  common  work- 
shops. Hence  beyond  question  an  abundance 
of  products  would  result,  marvellously  diversi- 
fied, and  necessarily  adapted  to  the  various 
wants  of  the  community, — made  with  the  mini- 
mum of  effort,  rather  only  with  pleasure,  for 
such  is  the  nature  of  work  in  the  communism 
of  Icaria, — and  divided  equally,  regard  being 
had  to  age  and  sex,  among  all  the  citizens,  at 
least  up  to  the  point  first  of  what  was  necessary, 
then  of  what  was  useful,  finally  of  what  was 
agreeable.  What  is  the  necessary,  the  useful, 
the  agreeable  ?     Cabet  forgot  to  define  all  this. 

But  the  family  ?  Our  communist  is  not  able 
to  suppress  that,  he  maintains  it.  Less  logi- 
cal than  Plato,  he  thodght  he  might  abolish 
property  and  respect  the  rights  of  the  family. 
Children  were  to  know  who  was  their  father  and 
their  mother  ;  to  the  mother  the  education  of 
her  child  was  absolutely  entrusted  up  to  five 
years  old.  It  was  only  after  this  age  that  the 
state  took  charge  of  it  to  make  of  it  a  complete 
communist.  Concubinage  was  forbidden,  vol- 
untary celibacy  was  branded  as  an  act  of  in- 
gratitude worthy  of  suspicion.  All  these 
attractive  things  and  many  more  are  to  be  found 
in  a  stout  volume  of  from  500  to  600  pages 
called  the  Voyage  en  Icarie,  which  Cabet  wrote 
in  London,  and  published  in  Paris  first  in  1840. 
This  ran  through  many  editions. 


I 


CABET— CADASTRAL  SURVEY 


199 


The  Voyage  en  Icarie  is  a  romance  into  the 
web  of  which  the  whole  of  Cabet's  peculiar 
system  is  interwoven.  Everything  is  mixed 
up  in  it — political  reflections,  administrative 
decisions,  the  cleansing  of  the  streets  side  by 
side  with  the  laws  concerning  the  organisation 
of  labour.  Municipal  reforms  come  side  by  side 
with  the  solution  of  social  problems.  The  city 
of  Icaria  is  described  with  the  utmost  detail,  and 
is,  as  may  be  supposed,  a  model  city  such  as  is 
not  beheld  in  this  individualistic  world.  Every- 
thing in  it  is  polished,  clean,  and  dusted. 
It  is  perfect  down  to  the  minutest  detail ;  "  the 
very  dogs  (p.  44)  cause  no  scandal."  The 
deputies  who  are  late  are  to  come  in  through  a 
door  specially  set  apart  for  them,  and  provided 
with  a  bell  so  that  their  entrance  should  be 
marked  to  their  more  exact  colleagues.  All  these 
charming  arrangements  inflamed  the  imagina- 
tions of  those  unhappy  wretches  who  trusted  their 
lives  to  Cabet's  system.  For  after  having  dis- 
seminated, ever  since  1841,  through  the  journal 
the  Populaire,  his  dangerous  doctrines,  Cabet, 
to  whose  good  faith  we  desire  to  do  full  justice, 
convinced  in  his  own  mind  of  the  advantages  to 
be  derived  from  his  system,  bought  a  million 
acres  of  land  in  Texas,  and  sent  forward  sixty- 
nine  trusty  followers  to  carry  out  the  Icarian 
doctrines  in  this  domain.  This  first  exodus 
took  place  3d  February  1848.  The  colonists 
reached  New  Orleans  the  end  of  March,  and  hear- 
ing there  the  news  of  the  revolution  of  24th 
February  at  Paris,  hesitated  for  a  moment  to  go 
forward,  but  finally  resolved  to  make  their  way 
to  the  appointed  rendezvous.  This  first  attempt 
tm-ned  out  most  disastrously,  and  the  disciples 
of  Cabet,  decimated  by  disease,  made  up  their 
minds  to  return  to  the  capital  of  Louisiana, 
marking  their  way  with  the  corpses  of  many  of 
their  number,  who  sank  victims  of  fatigue  and 
disease.  On  reaching  New  Orleans  they  met 
Cabet,  who  had  quitted  Paris  December  1848 
to  join  them.  The  interview  was  stormy  ; 
bitter  reproaches  were  addressed  to  the  high 
priest  of  communism,  who,  however,  was  not 
disconcerted.  In  March  1849  the  Icarians, 
numbering  two  hundred  and  eiglity,  including 
the  new-comers,  and  having  this  time  Cabet  at 
their  head,  turned  their  steps  to  Nauvoo  in 
Illinois,  where  they  met  with  fewer  trials  than 
in  Texas. 

Meanwhile  Cabet  had  been  condemned  to 
two  years'  imprisonment  on  a  charge  of  fraud. 
There  was  obvious  exaggeration  in  this  charge. 
Cabet  was  a  fanatic,  not  a  rogue.  He  was  in- 
dignant at  the  accusation  ;  returned  for  a  short 
time  to  France  ;  appealed  against  the  sentence, 
and  had  the  good  fortune  to  see  it  reversed  by 
the  court  of  appeal  in  Paris,  26th  July  1851. 
On  his  return  to  Nauvoo  he  found  his  colony 
making  progress  ;  the  numbers  mounted  up  to 
five  hundred  in  1855. 

Divisions,  however,  existed  in  this  population, 


which  had  few  bonds  of  coherence.  Many  times 
a  separation  was  thought  of.  At  last  it  came  ; 
Cabet  left  Nauvoo  at  the  head  of  some  two 
hundred  of  his  partisans,  and  soon  after  died  at 
St.  Louis.  The  cause  of  the  s})lit  appears  to 
have  been  that  Cabet  desired  to  induce  the  popu- 
lation to  submit  to  an  over-severe  discipline, 
analogous  to  that  of  some  convents  of  the  Middle 
Ages.  The  colony  of  Nauvoo  continued  to  exist, 
surroimded  by  difficulties  of  many  kinds,  up  to 
1880,  after  which  date  we  have  lost  sight  of  it. 

With  respect  to  Cabet  himself  we  may  add, 
to  complete  what  has  been  said  as  to  his  opin- 
ions on  matters  of  a  social  character,  that  he  is 
distinguished  from  communists  of  other  schools 
in  that  he  gives  a  quite  peculiar  religious  form 
to  his  opinions.  He  connected  his  communistic 
convictions  with  the  earlier  ages  of  the  church, 
and  wrote  on  this  subject  several  books,  of  which 
the  most  important  has  for  its  title  the  words, 
Le  vrai  ehristianisTne  suivant  Jdsus-  Christ  (1846), 
and  for  its  conclusion,  "  Le  communisme  c'est  le 
christianisme  "  (see  Communism).         a.  c.  f. 

[For  a  fuller  account  of  the  Icarian  colony  in 
America,  see  Dr.  Shaw's  Icaria  (1874)  and  Nord- 
hoff  s  Communistic  Societies  of  the  United  States 
(1875),  pp.  333  et  scq^.] 

CABLE  TRANSFER.  A  telegraphic  order 
from  one  banker  to  another  to  make  a  payment 
to  a  person  or  firm  indicated  in  the  cablegram. 
Cable  transfers  are  most  frequently  used  in  the 
commercial  intercourse  between  England  and 
the  United  States  of  North  America.  Those 
bankers  who  are  in  the  habit  of  transacting  this 
class  of  business  take  very  elaborate  precautions, 
by  means  of  codes  and  keywords,  to  avoid  fraud. 
An  ingenious  chancellor  of  the  exchequer  a  few 
years  ago  remarked  that  the  revenue  from  bill 
stamps  had  fallen  off  on  account  of  the  frequent 
use  of  cable  transfers,  but  this  can  hardly  be 
borne  out  by  the  facts,  as  the  bills  which  were 
formerly  remitted  by  the  persons  who  now  make 
their  payments  by  means  of  cable  transfers  are 
now  used  by  the  bankers  to  cover  their  friends 
for  the  payments  they  effect  on  their  telegraphic 
order.  e.  s. 

CADASTRAL  SURVEY.  A  survey  made 
for  the  purpose  of  compiling  a  public  register  of 
the  quantity,  value,  condition,  and  ownership 
of  the  real  property  of  a  country.  But  the 
term  is  loosely  applied  to  every  official  survey  of 
the  surface  of  a  country.  Thus  Domesday 
Book  and  the  Ordnance  Survey  have  alike  been 
referred  to  as,  in  a  sense,  cadastral  surveys.  The 
purposes  served  by  such  surveys  include  the 
determination  of  the  sums  to  be  contributed  to 
the  revenue,  or  to  any  other  common  fund,  by 
individual  owners  and  occupiers  of  property,  or 
by  the  community  resident  within  any  prescribed 
area ;  the  registration  of  boundaries  and  of 
changes  of  ownership ;  the  division  and  sub- 
division of  a  country  into  administrative  and 
representative  areas  ;  and  the  arrangement  o/ 


200 


CADET— CAGNAZZI 


schomes  for  public  works,  or  drainage  and  other 
local  improvements. 

In  the  United  Kingdom  the  general  survey 
known  as  the  ordnance  survey  was  intended  at 
first  for  purely  military  purposes,  and,  in  par- 
ticular, to  provide  plans  for  purely  military 
purposes  (hence  the  name  the  ordnance  depart- 
ment) ;  but  as  the  real  value  of  the  work  and 
the  various  uses  which  it  might  serve  were  per- 
ceived, the  scheme  expanded,  and  in  England 
and  Wales  it  is  now  proceeding  on  the  following 
scale  :  Towns  having  4000  or  more  inhabitants 
are  surveyed  on  a  scale  of  1*500  of  the  linear 
measurement,  which  is  equivalent  to  126*72 
inches  to  a  mile,  or  41f  feet  to  an  inch  ;  parishes 
(in  cultivated  districts)  1*2500  of  the  linear 
measurement,  equal  to  25*344  inches  to  a  mile, 
or  1  square  inch  to  an  acre  ;  counties  on  a  scale 
of  6  inches  to  a  mile  ;  kingdom,  a  general  map 
1  inch  to  a  mile.  The  maps  issued  by  the  sur- 
vey are  largely  used  for  evidencing  the  particular 
properties  referred  to  in  legal  and  other  docu- 
ments, for  planning  public  and  private  works, 
and  for  the  delimitation  of  boundaries.  But 
the  absence  of  any  information  as  to  the  value 
of  the  property  delineated — an  essential  ele- 
ment in  a  true  cadastral  survey — makes  the 
ordnance  survey  inapplicable  to  purposes  of 
taxation,  and  the  system  of  land  registration 
and  transfer  which  such  a  survey  renders  pos- 
sible has  not  yet  been  fully  organised  in  the 
United  Kingdom. 

In  France,  cadastral  survey  has,  since  1790, 
been  a  matter  of  great  importance  owing  to  the 
prominent  position  of  the  contribution  foncUre  in 
the  financial  system  of  that  country.  The 
French  literature  of  the  subject  is  proportion- 
ately extensive.  In  Germany  a  fairly  accurate 
cadastral  survey  has  (1861-1864)  been  com- 
pleted. 

Adam  Smith  (  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  v.  chap, 
ii.  art.  i.)  gives  some  examples  of  cadastral 
surveys,  and  appears  to  think  that  the  labour 
and  expense  they  entail  is  out  of  proportion  to 
their  value.  The  point  of  view  from  which  he 
is  considering  the  subject  is,  however,  that  of 
taxation  alone.  The  labour  and  delay  incident 
to  an  adequate  cadastral  survey  in  England 
have  been  regarded  as  a  fatal  practical  objection 
to  schemes  like  J.  S.  Mill's  for  appropriating 
the  Unearned  Increment  of  rent. 

[See  report  of  the  progress  of  the  ordnance  survey 
to  the  31st  December  1886  {Parliamentary  Paper 
[c.  5005]). —  Dictionnaire  de  V Administration 
Frangaise,  par  M.  M.  Block  (2d  ed.,  1881). — 
Recueil  Methodique  des  lois,  decrets,  reglements 
(be.  sur  le  Cadastre  de  France  (Paris,  1811). — Du 
Cadastre  et  de  la  Limitation  des  Heritages,  par  F. 
II.  V.  Noizet  (Paris,  1%QI).—Denkschrift  iiber  die 
Ausfuhrung  des  Oesetzes  vom  21st  May  1861, 
hetreffend  die  anderweitige  Regelung  der  Grund- 
siewer  (Berlin,  1865).]  T.  H.  E. 

CADET,  FjtLix,  born  at  Paris  1827,  died  at 
Viroflay  near  Paris  1888.     After  brilliant  pro- 


gress in  his  university  studies,  he  commenced 
his  career  as  a  professor,  lecturing  first  on  his- 
tory, then  on  philosophy.  He  gave,  1866-67, 
with  great  success,  a  course  of  lectures  on  politi- 
cal economy,  before  the  Soci6t6  Industrielle,  of 
Reims  ;  and  divided  with  Horn,  in  1866,  the 
L6on  Faucher  prize,  given  by  the  Academic  des 
Sciences  moi'ales  et  politiques  {Pierre  de  Boisguil- 
hert,  pricurseur  des  ^conomistes,  1870,  in  8vo). 
He  then  undertook  a  series  of  conferences  (dis- 
cussions) at  Rheims,  also  under  the  wing  of  the 
Societe  Industrielle  of  that  city,  the  object  of 
these  being  to  examine  curiously  the  lives  and 
criticise  the  works  of  Boisguilbert,  Vauban. 
Quesnay,  Turgot,  Smith,  and  Franklin. 
After  1870  he  gave  himself  up  principally  to 
teaching,  a  career  which  he  pursued  with  great 
success,  and  died  honorary  inspector-general  of 
public  instruction.  A.  c.  f. 

CAGNAZZI,  LuoA  Samuele,  born  at  Alta- 
mura,  in  the  province  of  Bari,  1764,  died  1852. 
By  profession  originally  a  teacher  of  mathe- 
matics, he  was  appointed,  1806,  to  a  professor- 
ship in  this  study  in  the  university  of  Naples. 
His  life  was  full  of  trouble  ;  having  been  con- 
cerned in  political  intrigues,  he  had  to  flee 
from  Naples  and,  after  wandering,  nearly  always 
on  foot,  through  Italy  and  Switzerland,  and 
after  being  imprisoned  more  than  once,  he  had 
to  seek  refage  in  Florence.  He  returned  to 
Naples  under  Murat's  government.  After  the 
change  of  government,  he  was  elected  deputy 
for  Bari,  and  was  President  of  the  chamber  on 
the  15th  May  1848,  when  it  was  dissolved  by 
the  troops.  To  escape  capture  he  fled  again  and 
returned  to  Florence,  where  he  fell  ill.  Feeling 
his  end  at  hand,  and  wishing  not  to  die  in 
exile,  he  obtained  his  pardon  from  the  King  of 
Naples,  through  the  intervention  of  the  Grand 
Duke  of  Tuscany.  He  deserves  mention  for 
having  written  on  parallel  Curves,  in  a  time 
when  this  method  of  demonstration  had  some 
novelty.  As  an  economist  he  wrote,  besides  an 
Fssay  on  the  x^opulation  of  the  Realm  of  Naples, 
Saggio  sulla  popolazione  del  regno  di  Puglia  ne' 
passati  tempi  e  nel  presente  (Napoli,  stamperia 
Trani,  1820  and  1839,  2  vols,  in  8vo),  what 
was  perhaps  his  most  important  work,  in  1813, 
a  little  manual  of  political  economy,  Elementi 
di  Economia  politica  (Napoli,  stamperia  S. 
Giacomo),  and,  1827,  a  pamphlet  on  La  Scienza 
della  economia  politica  (Venice).  Some  years 
earlier  he  had  published  a  manual  of  statistics  : 
Elementi  dell'  arte  statistica,  Napoli,  stamperia 
Flautina,  1808,  2  vols.  In  1839  he  published 
his  latest  statistical  work :  Sullo  stato  della 
Statistica  nel  Beame  di  Napoli  al  cadere  del 
secolo  XVIII.  e  comin/^idre  del  XIX.  Napoli. 
He  desires  government  interference  whenever 
practicable,  and  wrote,  in  particular,  a  book  on 
ancient  and  modern  economical  principles 
{Analisi  delV  economia  privata  e  pubblica  degli 
antichi,    relativamente   a   quella   dei  modcrni, 


CAIRNES 


201 


1^ 


Xapoli,  stamperia  della  soc.  Filomatica,  1830) 
to  point  out  that  modem  principles  are  pre- 
ferable !  M.  p. 

CAIRNES,  John  Elliot  (1823-1875),  was 
bom  at  Castle -Bellingham,  County  Louth. 
His  childhood  was  spent  at  Drogheda,  whither 
his  father,  who  was  a  large  brewer,  moved  tAvo 
years  later.  He  was  educated  first  at  Kingstown 
and  afterwards  at  Chester  ;  and,  as  his  teachers 
did  not  consider  that  his  abilities  fitted  him  for 
college  life,  he  was,  on  leaving  school,  placed  in 
his  father's  counting-house.  Here  he  remained 
three  years,  developing  a  taste  for  study,  and 
gi'adually  finding  business  grow  more  and  more 
irksome.  Eventually  his  father  made  him  a 
smaU  allowance,  upon  which  he  lived  at  Trinity 
College,  Dublin.  He  took  the  degi-ee  of  B.A. 
in  1848,  and  that  of  M.  A.  in  1854.  He  subse- 
quently studied  law,  and  was  called  to  the  Irish 
bar  in  1857,  but  he  does  not  appear  to  have  ever 
practised.  During  this  period  he  also  studied 
chemistry,  engineering,  and  political  economy, 
and  engaged  in  journalistic  work,  his  favourite 
topics  being  social  and  economic  questions  affect- 
ing Ireland.  In  1856  he  competed  successfully 
for  the  Whately  professorship  of  political  econ- 
omy in  the  university  of  Dublin,  and  from  this 
time  political  economy  became  the  study  of  his 
life.  He  held  the  professorship  for  five  years, 
the  full  period  during  which  it  was  tenable.  It 
was  a  condition  of  the  tenure  that  the  professor 
should  publish  annually  at  least  one  lecture  ; 
and  accordingly  in  1857  he  published  the  whole 
of  his  first  course  of  lectures  under  the  title  of 
The  Character  and  Logical  Method  of  Political 
Economy.  (A  second  edition  appeared  in  1875, 
shortly  before  the  author's  death.)  In  1859, 
while  still  holding  the  Whately  professorship, 
he  was  appointed  by  Mr.  Cardwell,  then  Irish 
secretary,  professor  of  political  economy  and 
jmisprudence  at  Queen's  College,  Galway.  In 
1859-60  he  published  in  Fraser's  Magazine  and 
the  Edinburgh  Eeview  three  papers  on  the  efiects 
of  the  Australian  and  Californian  gold  dis- 
coveries. In  1862  appeared  The  Slave  Power, 
a  work  that  grew  out  of  his  last  course  of  Dublin 
lectm-es.  This  book,  which  was  dedicated  to 
J.  S.  Mill,  contained  a  philosophical  analysis 
of  the  characteristics  of  slave  labour,  and  of  the 
social  and  economic  effects  of  slavery,  and  was 
at  the  same  time  a  defence  of  the  cause  of  the 
Northern  States  in  the  American  Civil  War. 
It  was  an  immediate  success,  and  exerted  a 
powerful  influence  upon  English  opinion.  A 
second  edition  was  called  for  in  the  following 
year. 

From  this  time  Prof.  Cairn es  enjoyed  a  high 
reputation  as  an  economist.  The  period  in 
question  was  one  when  political  economy,  and 
the  Ricardo-MiU  school  in  particular,  was  in 
t]ie  ascendant.  In  many  departments  of  the 
Qcience  the  doctrines  taught  by  Mill  were  gener- 
ally  accepted  as  complete  and  final.     It  was  to 


this  dominant  school  that  Caimes  belonged,  and 
amongst  contemporary  English  economists  he 
came  to  be  ranked  second  only  to  Mill  himself. 
In  1860  he  married  Eliza  Charlotte  Alexander, 
sister-in-law  of  his  gi'cat  friend  Prof.  Nesbitt. 
In  1865  he  moved  to  tlie  neiglibourhood  of 
Loudon,  and  in  the  following  year  he  was  ap- 
pointed professor  of  political  economy  at  Uni- 
versity College,  London.  He  did  not,  however, 
resign  the  Galway  professorship  till  1870,  it 
being  allowed  him  to  appoint  a  deputy  to  lec- 
ture in  his  place  during  the  last  three  years  of 
his  tenm-e.  He  was,  at  the  time  of  his  moving 
to  London,  a  confirmed  invalid,  subject  to 
attacks  of  rheumatic  gout  of  constantly  iucreas- 
ing  severity.  Gradually  he  was  reduced  to  a 
state  of  complete  physical  helplessness,  and  his 
sufferings  were  gi'eat.  His  intellectual  vigour 
was,  however,  in  no  way  impaired,  and  he  re- 
tained to  an  extraordinary  degree  his  accustomed 
energy  and  cheerfulness.  He  is  spoken  of  by 
those  who  knew  him  as  possessing  great  conver- 
sational gifts  and  admirable  humour ;  and  whilst 
himself  cut  off  from  active  political  life,  he  con- 
tinued to  take  the  strongest  interest  in  current 
politics.  He  was  an  intimate  friend  of  J.  S. 
Mill,  and  also  of  Prof.  Fawcett  and  IMr.  L.  H. 
Courtney.  Through  them  and  others  his  politi- 
cal influence  was  considerable,  espscially  on 
Irish  questions.  Prof.  Fawcett  has  himself  put 
on  record  the  great  reliance  that  he  placed  on 
Cairnes's  political  judgment,  and  the  frequency 
with  which  they  discussed  cun-ent  political 
questions  together.  Cairnes  had  always  been  a 
strong  advocate  of  united  education  in  Ireland 
(see  his  Letter  to  J.  S.  Mill  on  "  University 
Education  in  Ireland,"  1866),  and  it  is  said 
on  the  best  authority  that  he  was  the  unseen 
centre  of  the  operations  that  led  to  the  defeat 
of  Mr.  Gladstone's  Irish  University  Bill  in  1873. 
The  state  of  his  health  compelled  him  in  1872 
to  resign  his  post  at  University  College,  and  on 
his  retirement  the  honorary  title  of  Emeritus 
Professor  Avas  conferred  upon  him.  In  the 
following  year  he  received  from  the  university 
of  Dublin  the  honorary  degi-ee  of  LL.D.  In 
1873  he  published  a  volume  of  Political  Essays, 
about  half  of  which  is  taken  up  with  Irish 
questions,  and  also  a  volume  of  Essays  in  Poli- 
tical Economy,  Theoretical  and  Applied.  The 
latter  volume  contained  the  '  *  Essays  on  the 
Gold  Question  "  already  referred  to,  and  other 
essays  that  he  had  written  for  various  periodicals 
in  the  course  of  the  preceding  fourteen  years. 
In  1874  appeared  Some  Leading  Principles  of 
Political  Econ,omy  newly  Expounded,  a  work 
which  is  usually  regarded  as  his  most  important 
contribution  to  economic  literature.  He  died 
on  8th  July  1875,  after  gi-eat  suffering,  borne, 
for  many  years,  with  extraordinary  fortitude. 
He  left  a  widow  and  three  children. 

After  MiU's   death   in    1873,   Cairnes  occu- 
pied in  general  estimation  the  foremost  place 


202 


CAIRNES 


amongst  English  economists,  though  it  may  be 
doubted  whether  his  subsequent  influence  upon 
the  development  of  the  science  has  been  as  great 
as  that  of  his  contemporary  Jevons.  His  work 
in  economics  belongs  to  three  departments  of 
economic  inquiry  broadly  distinguishable  frqm 
one  another,  namely  (1)  the  logic  of  political 
economy,  (2)  the  investigation  and  interpreta- 
tion of  contemporary  economic  facts,  (3)  econo- 
mic theory. 

(1)  The  Logical  Method  of  Political  Economy 
is  an  admirably  precise  and  clear  exposition  of 
the  province  and  method  of  economics  from  the 
point  of  view  of  the  Ricardo-Mill  school,  and  it 
has  long  been  regarded  as  the  authoritative 
text-book  of  English  political  economy  so  far  as 
its  logic  is  concerned.  Cairnes  urges  with  great 
force  that  political  economy  is  properly  concerned 
with  what  is,  not  with  what  ought  to  be,  and 
that  its  principles  are  therefore  theorems  of 
fact,  not  rules  of  conduct.  It  falls  into  line 
accordingly  with  theoretical  sciences  such  as 
astronomy  and  physiology,  not  with  practical 
arts  such  as  the  art  of  medicine  or  the  art  of 
legislation.  The  method  of  study  appropriate  to 
the  science  is  held  to  be  the  Deductive  Method, 
and  the  ultimate  premises  of  political  economy 
are  found  to  consist  in  a  few  simple  facts  of 
human  nature  taken  in  connection  with  certain 
physical  properties  of  the  soil  and  man's  physio- 
logical constitution.  The  body  of  doctrine  thus 
established  is  in  itself  abstract  and  hypothetical, 
since  the  forces  taken  into  account  are  not  the 
sole,  although  they  are  by  far  the  most  import- 
ant, forces  determining  the  phenomena  of  wealth. 
Hence  in  the  application  of  economic  laws  a 
constant  appeal  to  facts  is  necessary,  in  order  to 
discover  and  allow  for  the  effects  of  disturbing 
causes,  that  is,  for  the  modifications  that  happen 
to  be  introduced  in  particular  instances  by  the 
minor  influences  aff"ecting  economic  phenomena. 
Cairnes's  whole  treatment  of  the  subject  is  con- 
servative in  tone,  and  he  has  no  sympathy  either 
with  those  who,  like  Cliffe  Leslie,  advocate  the 
use  of  the  historical  method  in  political  economy, 
or  with  those  who,  like  Jevons,  regard  the 
science  as  essentially  mathematical  in  character. 

(2)  The  best  examples  of  Cairnes's  method  of 
dealing  with  contemporary  economic  problems 
of  a  concrete  kind  are  to  be  found  in  the 
economic  chapters  of  the  Slave  Power,  and  in 
the  Essays  on  the  Gold  Question.  In  both  these 
cases  he  was  fortunate  in  selecting  topics  of 
peculiar  interest  at  the  time  when  he  wrote, 
and  he  discussed  them  with  such  originality, 
lucidity,  and  force,  as  necessarily  to  command 
attention.  His  treatment  of  the  problems  is, 
however,  of  more  than  merely  temporary  value  ; 
and  in  particular  his  conclusions  in  regard  to 
the  general  economic  characteristics  of  slave 
labour,  and  the  conditions  essential  in  order  that 
such  labour  may  be  temporarily  profitable,  are 
exceptionally  good  instances  of  established  econ- 


omic doctrines,  resting  mainly  on  an  Inductive 
Method.  The  Essays  on  the  Gold  Question,  th  ough 
open  to  criticism  in  certain  respects,  may,  in 
regard  to  style,  be  taken  as  models  of  clear  and 
well-arranged  exposition.  They  deal  with  the 
eff'ects  of  the  Australian  and  Californian  gold 
discoveries,  and  the  most  striking  of  them  is 
perhaps  that  which  treats  of  the  "course  of 
depreciation."  Cairnes's  theory  is  that  whilst 
an  increased  supply  of  gold  will  raise  the  prices 
of  different  classes  of  commodities  and  services 
with  unequal  rapidity,  there  is  in  the  apparent 
irregularity  nothing  capricious  or  abnormal. 
He  holds,  on  the  other  hand,  that  the  movement 
is  governed  throughout  its  course  by  economic 
laws,  and  that  it  is  possible  broadly  to  determine 
the  order  in  which  different  kinds  of  things  will 
be  affected.  The  working  out  of  this  theory 
is  exceedingly  acute  and  suggestive  ;  and  the 
statistical  verification  that  Cairnes  offers  of  his 
theoretical  anticipations  may  be  taken  as  an 
example  of  his  work  as  a  statistician. 

(3)  The  improvement  of  economic  theory  in 
general  accordance  with  the  doctrines  of  Mill 
and  his  predecessors  is  given  as  the  main 
purpose  of  the  Leading  Principles  of  Political 
Economy  newly  Expounded.  This  work  was 
not  intended  to  constitute  an  exhaustive  treatise 
on  economic  science.  It  may  rather  be  regarded 
as  a  critical  commentary  on  Mill's  Principles  oj 
Political  Economy.  The  chief  topics  discussed 
are  Supply  and  Demand,  the  analysis  of 
Cost  of  Production,  the  Wages  Fund  theory, 
Trade  Unions,  International  Trade  and 
International  Value.  It  is  impossible 
in  the  space  at  our  disposal  to  give  even 
the  briefest  outline  of  Cairnes's  views  on 
the  above  questions.  His  method  of  treat- 
ing them  is  nearly  always  ingenious  and  subtle. 
The  wages  fund  theory,  for  instance,  as  re- 
suscitated by  him,  is  a  far  more  complex  and 
ingenious  doctrine  than  that  which  Mill  first 
formulated  in  his  Political  Economy  and  after- 
wards repudiated.  Cairnes's  theory  is  that 
wages  are  paid  out  of  capital,  and  that,  given 
the  nature  of  the  prevailing  industries,  the 
whole  amount  expended  in  wages  necessarily 
bears  a  definite  relation  to  a  nation's  total 
capital.  In  further  working  out  the  theory,  he 
lays  great  stress  upon  the  law  of  the  tendency 
of  profits  to  a  minimum,  and,  in  fact,  assumes 
that  profits  are  already  at  or  within  a  hand's 
breadth  of  the  minimum.  Little  note  is  taken 
of  the  distinction  between  profits  and  interest. 
The  laws  regulating  wages  are  therefore  made 
to  depend  ultimately  on  the  laws  regulating  the 
accumulation  of  capital. 

Cairnes  is  emphatic  in  his  recognition  of  the 
existence  of  non-competing  industrial  groups. 
"No  doubt,"  he  says,  "the  various  ranks  and 
classes  fade  into  each  other  by  imperceptible 
gradations,  and  individuals  from  all  classes  are 
constantly  passing  up  or  dropping  down  ;  but 


CAIENES— CALL 


203 


while  this  is  so,  it  is  nevertheless  true  that  the 
average  workman,  from  whatever  rank  he  be 
taken,  finds  his  power  of  competition  limited 
for  practical  purposes  to  a  certain  range  of 
occupations,  so  that,  however  high  the  rates  of 
remuneration  in  those  which  lie  beyond  may 
rise,  he  is  excluded  from  sharing  them."  This 
is  in  itself  not  much  more  than  a  restatement 
of  a  passage  in  Mill's  chapter  on  the  differences 
of  wages  in  different  employments.  Much  more 
prominence  is,  however,  given  to  the  doctrine 
by  Cairnes,  especially  in  its  bearing  on  the 
theory  of  normal  value  ;  and  it  has  hence  come 
to  be  particularly  associated  with  his  name. 

While  the  Leading  Principles  exercised  a  very- 
stimulating  influence  upon  economic  discussion 
in  England,  the  doctrines  laid  down  in  it  cannot 
be  said  to  have  met  with  anything  like  general 
acceptance,  even  amongst  those  economists  who 
belong,  broadly  speaking,  to  the  same  school  as 
Cairnes  himself.  On  the  whole,  the  effect  of 
the  book  was  more  destructive  than  construc- 
tive, for  it  helped  to  shake  faith  in  the  finality 
of  the  Ricardo-Mill  doctrines.  Cairnes  tended 
to  exaggerate  the  degree  of  divergence  between 
Mill  and  himself,  and  the  net  result  of  his 
criticism  was  to  impair  Mill's  authority  to  a 
much  greater  extent  than  he  can  himself  have 
anticipated. 

It  has  been  said  that  as  a  controversialist 
Cairnes  was  deficient  in  intellectual  sympathy, 
and  the  charge  must  be  allowed.  With  the  best 
intentions,  he  often  fails  to  convey  to  his  readers 
a  fair  idea  of  the  real  meaning  of  the  doctrines  he 
is  combating.  A  striking  instance  of  this  is  to 
be  found  in  his  treatment  of  Jevons's  theory  of 
the  relation  of  value  to  utility.  The  theory  in 
question  is  based  entirely  upon  the  distinction 
between  total  utility  and  final  degi-ee  of  utility, 
and  yet,  while  criticising  Jevons's  views  some- 
what severely,  Cairnes  never  once  refers  to  this 
distinction.  He  confesses  himself  unversed  in 
mathematics,  and  to  this  may  perhaps  be  attri- 
buted both  his  misunderstanding  of  Jevons,  and 
also  a  certain  characteristic  looseness  of  thought 
in  several  cases  where  quantitative  notions  are 
involved.  He  analyses  cost  of  production,  for 
instance,  into  effort  and  Abstinence,  which  are 
in  themselves  incommensurable  quantities,  with- 
out ever  seeming  adequately  to  realise  the  neces- 
sity of  reducing  these  incommensurables  to  terms 
of  some  common  unit.  True  to  the  views  ex- 
pressed in  his  earliest  work,  he  always  showed 
great  confidence  in  the  validity  of  deductive 
reasoning  in  economics,  and  he  was  never  afraid 
of  pushing  his  theories  to  their  logical  conclu- 
sions. We  have  a  remarkable  instance  of  this 
in  his  working  out  of  the  wages  fimd  theory, 
where  he  does  not  shrink  from  the  paradox  that 
an  increase  in  the  supply  of  labour  will  cceteris 
paribiis  diminish  not  merely  the  average  rate  of 
wages,  but  actually  the  whole  amoimt  expended 
in  wages. 


Cairnes  will  always  be  remembered  as  at  once 
one  of  Mill's  most  distinguished  disciples,  and 
one  of  his  most  vigorous  critics  ;  and  his  works 
are  likely  to  retain  on  their  own  account  an 
important  place  in  the  history  of  economic 
literature.  All  that  he  wrote  has  a  striking 
individuality,  and  he  expounds  his  views  with 
a  literary  skill  and  a  persuasive  force  that  it 
would  be  difficult  to  surpass. 

[See  Articles  in  the  Tivies  for  9th  July  1875,  by 
Mr.  L.  H.  Courtney. — In  the  Fortnightly  Review 
for  August  1875,  by  Professor  Fawcett. — In  the 
Encyclopcedia  Britannica,  by  Professor  Adamson. 
— In  the  Dictionary  of  National  Biography,  by  Mr. 
Leslie  Stephen. — Clifle  Leslie,  Essays  IV.  aud 
VI.,  pp.  41  and  60.]  '     J.  n.  k. 

CAISSE.  French  word  for  (1)  a  chest  where 
money  is  kept ;  (2)  the  cashier's  office  or  desk 
in  a  commercial  or  banking  establishment ;  (3) 
the  money  in  hand  ;  (4)  the  cash  book  or  the 
cash  account ;  (5)  an  establishment  where 
money  is  administered,  e.g.  Caisse  de  depots, 
Caisse  d' amortisation.  e.  s. 

CALL.  This  is  an  Option  {q.v.)  and  an 
option  is  usually  worth  something.  On  the 
stock  exchange  there  are  dealers  in  puts  and 
calls  (see  Put  and  Call)  ;  a  call  meaning  the 
privilege  of  calling  for  a  specified  amount  of 
stock  bonds  or  shares  at  an  arranged  price  at  a 
specified  date  in  advance.  Calls  extend  from 
one  day  to  three  months  and  even  longer. 
Thus,  the  agreement  may  bo  that  a  buyer  of  a 
call,  in  January,  gives  to  the  seller  1  per  cent 
on  £10,000  Egyptian  unified  bonds  for  the 
privilege  of  calling  for  the  delivery  of  these 
bonds  at  the  end  of  February.  The  price  usu- 
ally taken  is  the  actual  quotation  plus  interest, 
or  (to  use  the  stock  exchange  phrase)  continua- 
tion, rates  which  may  accrue  in  the  interval. 
We  will  say  the  specified  stock  is  worth  80  in 
the  middle  of  January,  and  to  this  price  is 
added  three  fortnights'  rates  of  continuation  or 
interest  at  j  per  cent  per  fortnight,  so  bringing 
up  the  call  price  to  80|.  If,  in  the  meanwhile, 
the  buyer  of  the  call  has  been  able  to  sell  this 
amount  of  the  stock  at  anything  above  80|, 
the  difference  represents  his  profit  on  the  opera- 
tion against  which  has  to  be  set  his  first  outlay 
of  1  per  cent. 

Call  is  also  used  in  connection  with  joint- 
stock  companies  and  loans  which  are  not  fully 
paid  up  at  the  time  of  issue.  For  the  conveni- 
ence of  subscribers  it  is  usually  arranged  that 
the  amounts  paid  shall  be,  on  application,  say 
5  per  cent  of  the  amount,  on  allotment,  10  per 
cent,  and  the  remainder  is  paid  by  degrees 
according  to  the  dates  of  the  "calls."  Often, 
also,  it  is  arranged  that  only  part  of  the  nominal 
capital  shall  be  paid  up,  the  remainder  not  to 
be  called  up  without  the  sanction  of  the  share- 
holders. In  the  case  of  the  City  of  Glasgow 
Bank,  in  which  the  liability  of  shareholders  and 
trustees  of  shareholders  was  "unlimited,"  the 


204 


CALONNE— CALVIN 


calls  continued  until  many  contributors  had 
paid  up  to  the  utmost  farthing  of  what  they 
possessed.  Limited  and  reserved  liability  acts 
have  put  some  limit  to  this  terrible,  because 
indefinite,  risk.  A.  E. 

CALONNE,  Charles  Alexandre  de, 
bom  at  Douai  1734,  died  in  Paris  1802.  Ori- 
ginally a  magistrate,  he  became,  9  th  November 
1783,  comptroller-general  of  the  finances,  which 
office  he  held  till  8th  April  1787,  and  in  which 
he  proved  himself  singularly  incompetent.  The 
commencement  of  his  official  career,  however, 
at  least  in  those  points  which  were  concerned 
with  the  chamber  of  discount,  la  caissed'escompte, 
was  successful  enough  ;  but  before  long  the 
treasury,  under  his  direction,  became  an  insti- 
tution only  kept  going  by  expedients.  The 
fertility  of  his  pen  dazzled  him  ;  he  considered 
difficulties  as  solved  the  solution  of  which  was 
only  deferred.  Under  his  ministry  the  first 
assembly  of  Notables  was  convened.  Having 
emigrated  to  England  when  the  Revolution 
broke  out,  he  returned  to  France  in  1802,  and 
died  there  a  few  months  afterwards. 

He  successively  published  :  Correspondance  de 
Necker  et  de  Calonne  (1787,  in  4to). — Requite  au 
iJot  (London,  1787,  in  8vo). — R^onsede  Calonne 
vL  I'icrit  de  Necker  (London,  1788,  in  4to). — 
Lettres  de  Calonne  au  Roi,  9  fevrier  et  3  avril, 
1789. — Note  sur  le  memoire  remis  par  Necker  au 
comitS  de  sviisistance  (London,  1789). — De  Vital 
de  la  France  tel  qu'il  pent  et  tel  quHl  doit  itre 
(London,  1790).  —  Observations  swr  les  finances 
(London,  1790,  in  4to). — Esquisse  de  Vetat  de  la 
France  (1791,  in  8vo). — Tableau  de  V Europe 
(1795,  in  8vo). — Des  finances  publiques  de  la 
France  (London,  1797,  in  8vo).  a.  o.  f. 

CALVIN,  Jean  (1509-1564).  The  name  of 
this  illustrious  theologian  rightly  finds  a  place 
in  an  economic  dictionary.  His  writings  stand 
in  the  same  relation  to  the  Reformation  as 
those  of  Aquinas  to  the  Middle  Ages.  The 
clearest  and  wisest  thoughts  of  the  Reformers  on 
political,  social,  and  economical  questions  are 
to  be  found  in  his  works.  He  was  qualified 
in  no  common  measure  to  form  just  conclusions 
on  these  subjects.  A  profound  lawyer,  con- 
versant with  ancient  and  modern  history, 
familiar  with  the  state  of  society  in  different 
countries,  engaged  habitually  in  the  discussion 
and  settlement  of  questions  of  government, 
administration,  law,  and  police,  he  combined 
theoretical  with  practical  knowledge  in  an 
unusual  degree.  Added  to  these  qualifications 
were  a  sagacity,  a  historical  insight,  and  an 
expository  and  dialectical  power  rarely  equalled. 

Calvin's  writings  consist  of  his  Institutes, 
the  greatest  theological  product  of  the  Reforma- 
tion, his  Commentaries  on  Scripture,  his  letters, 
and  some  polemical  and  theological  tracts. 
These,  coupled  with  information  furnished  by 
the  records  of  Geneva,  are  the  authorities  for 
his  views  on  economical  questions.  His 
opinions   may   be    best    discussed    under   the 


following  heads  (1)  church  and  state,  (2)  pro- 
perty and  related  questions,  and  (3)  usury. 

1.  Calvin  regards  church  and  state  as  two 
separate  and  independent  institutions.  The 
state  exists  for  man's  temporal,  the  church  for 
his  eternal  welfare.  Each  has  its  own  officers 
and  organisation.  Neither  should  intrude  into 
the  sphere  of  the  other  :  each  should  assist  the 
other.  All  citizens  are  subject  to  both.  The 
clergy  are  not  exempt  from  the  jurisdiction  of 
the  state.  The  church  inflicts  spiritual 
penalties  only.  Calvin  was  the  first  to  dis- 
tinguish the  church  from  the  state  in  such  a 
way  that  both  became  independent  powers, 
possessing  an  inherent  jurisdiction.  Up  to  his 
time  the  state  had  been  subordinated  to  the 
church,  or  the  church  merged  in  the  state. 
This  view  of  the  separateness  and  autonomy  of 
the  church  and  state  has  been  of  immense 
indirect  effect  on  political  economy.  It  has 
fostered  the  spirit  of  freedom :  it  has  done 
justice  to  man's  secular  interests  :  it  forms  the 
foundation  for  the  modern  movement  in  favour 
of  the  separation  of  church  and  state.  Such 
a  separation  was,  however,  far  from  Calvin's 
thoughts  :  on  the  contrary,  he  instituted  the 
closest  alliance  between  church  and  state. 
Magistrates  perform  sacred  and  legitimate 
functions.  They  must  vindicate  both  tables 
of  the  law.  Tyrannical  magistrates  are  to  be 
endured,  but  no  obedience  is  due  to  commands 
at  variance  with  God's  will.  Tributes  and 
taxes  are  the  legitimate  income  of  princes  :  but 
their  revenues  are  not  so  much  private  as  public, 
the  "  blood  of  the  people  which  it  is  inhuman 
not  to  spare."  Alike  in  church  and  state  the 
one  supreme  ruler  is  God  (Instit.  iv.  20). 

2.  Calvin  saw  clearly  that  the  existence  of 
Property  was  morally  necessary.  If  there  were 
no  such  thing  as  property  there  would  be  no 
test  of  justice  and  integrity  (on  Numb,  xxxi, 
28).  The  Libertines  of  his  age  advocated  a 
community  of  goods,  drawing  their  favourite 
argument  from  the  practice  of  the  primitive 
church  recorded  in  Acts  ii.  44  ;  iv.  32.  Calvin 
wrongly  denies  that  such  a  community  of 
goods  ever  existed.  He  contends  that  the 
community  which  prevailed  had  reference  ex- 
clusively to  the  wants  of  the  poor :  that  the 
surrender  of  their  property  was  not  made  by 
all :  that  it  did  not  embrace  all  their  posses- 
sions, and  that  all  did  not  receive  equal  shares. 
He  is  as  opposed  to  the  exaltation  of  voluntary 
poverty  as  he  is  to  a  community  of  goods.  It 
is  an  ordinance  of  God  that  some  should  be 
richer  than  others.  All  men  are  not  com- 
manded to  sell  all.  The  rich  young  man  of 
the  Gospel  was  covetous  and  was  bidden  to 
sell  all  for  his  soul's  sake.  But  the  farmer  sins 
who,  forced  by  no  necessity,  sells  the  farm  by 
which  he  supports  his  children  (on  Matt.  xix. 
16).  Experience  and  observation  had  taught 
Calvin  the  importance  of  Trade  anc'  Commerce, 


CALVIN 


205 


and  he  was  not  slow  to  defend  their  lawfulness 
and  value.  He  knew  that  Poverty  arose  when 
trade  fell  off,  and  hence  at  a  memorable  con- 
juncture in  the  social  history  of  Geneva  he 
proposed  to  set  up  the  weaving  of  cloth  and 
velvet  as  a  means  of  preventing  poverty.  His 
advice  was  taken,  and  for  many  years  Geneva 
was  famous  for  its  manufactures  of  cloth  and 
velvet.  It  has  been  too  hastily  inferred  from 
this  circumstance  that  Calvin  was  favourable  to 
the  "  industrial  ideal "  of  society.  No  passages 
can  be  quoted  which  prove  that  such  was  the 
case.  It  is  unquestionable  that  he  was  ready 
to  do  all  he  could  to  augment  the  j^rosperity 
of  Geneva,  but  his  ideal  was  moral  rather  than 
industrial.  Luxury  he  condemned  as  sinful. 
He  was  a  strenuous  upholder  of  Sumptuary 
Laws.  (For  particulars  see  St'dhelin,  i.  342.) 
But  his  legislation  regarding  the  colour  and 
shape  of  clothes,  adornment,  and  so  forth, 
was  not  conceived  in  an  illiberal  temper. 
He  was  equally  opposed  to  those  who  would 
limit  men's  use  of  earthly  goods  to  the  bare 
necessaries  of  life,  as  to  those  who  would  allow 
them  to  live  as  they  pleased  (InsHL,  iii.  10). 
Calvin  put  down  idleness  and  begging  as 
immoral,  but  for  those  in  real  poverty  he  made 
admirable  provision.  To  care  for  the  poor  Avas 
in  his  view  the  duty  of  the  church.  A  special 
grade  of  officers  had  been  formed  for  this 
purpose  in  apostolic  times  (on  Acts  vi.),  and 
this  grade  he  revived.  He  distinguishes 
between  twa  classes  of  deacons :  those  who 
administer  the  affau-s  of  the  poor,  and  those 
who  tend  the  sick  poor,  the  former  being 
specially  deacons  (Instit.  iv.  3^  9  ;  iv.  5,  15). 
His  famous  Ecclesiastical  Ordinances  provide 
for  the  yearly  election  of  both  classes  of  deacons. 
The  first  class  took  charge  of  the  poor  funds, 
the  poor  throughout  the  city,  and  the  manage- 
ment of  the  hospital.  The  deacons  tending  the 
sick  lived  in  the  hospital  (Kampschulte,  p.  466). 
Ecclesiastical  property  he  held  it  unlawful  to 
alienate.  What  has  once  been  devoted  to 
Christ  and  the  church  is  not  the  property  of 
the  magistrate.  The  magistrates  should  have 
the  power  of  supervising  and  the  deacons  of 
administering  this  property  (letter  to  Viret, 
1542  ;  on  Acts  iv.  32).  It  is  clear  that  Calvin 
was  as  anxious  as  Knox  himself  to  preserve 
ecclesiastical  property  for  ecclesiastical  uses,  and 
that  he  did  not  wish  the  church  to  draw  its 
revenues  direct  from  the  state.  Tithes  were 
public  burdens  and  should  be  paid. 

3.  Calvin  was  the  first  theologian  who  re- 
jected the  current  opinions  regarding  the  sinful- 
ness of  Usury.  His  views  on  this  subject  are 
to  be  found  in  his  commentaries  on  Ex.  xxii. 
25  ;  Lev.  xxv.  35  ;  Deut.  xxiii.  19  ;  Ps.  rv. 
5  ;  Ezek.  xviii.  ;  Luke  vi.  35,  and  in  the  famous 
letter  (Works,  vol.  viii.  223,  ed.  Amst.)  Usury 
is  not  condemned  by  Scripture.  Scripture 
forbids  the  exaction  of  usury  from  the  poor, 


but  allows  it  in  the  case  of  the  rich.  The 
laws  of  the  Jews  which  prohibited  the  taking 
of  interest  by  Jews  from  Jews  are  political  not 
moral  laws :  these  very  laws  permitted  Jews  to  re- 
ceive interest  from  Gentiles.  Usury  is  repeatedly 
condemned  in  the  Old  Testament,  but  never  on 
grounds  which  are  valid  for  all  Christians.  The 
prohibition  of  interest  in  the  Old  Testament  is 
a  provision  in  the  interests  of  the  poor.  The 
exaction  of  interest  from  the  poor  has  often 
produced  tumults,  as  in  Rome.  Calvin  rejects 
with  proper  scorn  the  substitution  of  "usuva" 
for  "the  detested  word  fcemis,"  holding  that 
there  is  no  description  of  "foenus"  to  which 
the  name  "usura"  may  not  be  given.  He 
exposes  the  evasions  by  which  usury  was 
exacted  without  being  mentioned  by  name,  a 
poor  man  requiring  to  repay  the  loan  of  six 
measures  of  wheat  by  a  return  of  seven.  The 
question  is  one  not  of  words  but  of  things. 
Aristotle's  argument,  accepted  by  Ambrose 
and  Augustine,  that  usury  is  unnatural  because 
money  is  barren,  is  worthless.  May  not  a 
cheat  make  much  profit  by  trading  with  another 
man's  money  ?  A  man  purchases  a  farm.  Is 
not  the  produce  convertible  into  money  ? 
Usury  is  not  unlawful  unless  it  contravenes 
equity.  Usury  therefore  (1)  must  not  be  ex- 
acted from  the  needy  ;  (2)  the  lender  must  not 
forget  to  be  charitable  ;  (3)  regard  must  always 
be  had  to  natural  equity  ;  (4)  the  borrower 
must  be  as  much  enriched  by  the  transaction  as 
the  lender  ;  (5)  our  conception  of  justice  must 
be  drawn  from  the  Word  of  God  and  not  from 
prevailing  usage  ;  (6)  the  interests  of  the  state 
as  well  as  the  individuals  concerned  must  be 
considered  ;  and  (7)  the  limit  of  interest  fixed 
in  each  state  must  not  be  exceeded.  But  usury 
should  not  be  made  a  means  of  livelihood.  It 
is  plain  from  this  passage  that  Calvin  rejected 
the  two  chief  arguments  against  usury — its 
condemnation  by  Scripture,  and  the  barrenness 
of  money  ;  but  that  he  felt  rather  than  saw 
the  distinction  between  usury  and  Interest. 
Whether  he  discerned  the  principle  on  which 
the  payment  of  interest  rests  is  doubtful.  He 
says,  indeed,  that  no  creditor  can  ever  lend 
money  without  loss  to  himself,  and  that  usury 
ought  to  be  paid  to  the  creditor  in  addition  to 
the  original  sum  to  compensate  him  for  loss, 
but  it  is  uncertain  whether  he  saw  that  this 
principle  applies  in  all  cases.  (On  Ex.  xxii. 
25  and  related  passages.) 

The  best  edition  of  Calvin's  wiitings  is  that 
under  the  charge  of  Baum,  Cunitz,  and  Reuss,  the 
publication  of  which  began  in  1 863.  The  Amster- 
dam edition  of  1667-71,  9  vols,  folio,  is  that 
commonly  quoted.  See  also  Henry,  Das  Leben 
Calvin's,  Hamburg,  1835-44.— Stahelin,  Johannes 
Calvin  Leben  und  ausgevMhlte  Schriften,  Elberfeld, 
1863. — Kampschulte,  Johann  Calvin,  Seine  Kirche 
und  Sein  Staat  in  Gen/,  Leipzig,  1869. — Dyer, 
The  Life  of  John  Calvin,  1850. — Reybum,  John 
Galvin :  His  Life,  Letters,  and  Work,  1914. — And 


206 


CAMBAGE— CAMBON 


Herzog,  Real-Ency.  "  Wucher." — Bohm  Bawerk, 
QapitaZ  and  Interest,  Mr.  Smart's  translation  I. 
28. — Wiskemann,  Darstellung  der  in  Deutschland 
zur  Zeit  der  Reformation  herrschenden  Nationul- 
okonomischen  Ansichten  (1861). — Elster,  Johann 
Calvin  als  Staatsmann,  etc. — Jahrbiicher  fur  Nat. 
Okonomie,  1878,  vol.  xxxi.  p.  163  et  seq. — Lecky, 
Rationalism,  ii.  265,  ed.  1878.  w.  P. 

CAMBAGE,  Droit  de.  This  was  a  due 
payable  in  parts  of  mediaeval  Germany,  France, 
and  the  Netherlands,  by  the  tenants  to  their 
lord  for  the  privilege  of  brewing  ale.  The  term 
occurs  in  some  chartularies  during  the  first  half 
of  the  12th  century,  and  about  a  hundred 
years  later  cambage  with  other  dues  was 
granted  by  Guy,  count  of  Flanders,  to  the 
hospital  of  St.  Bartholomew  of  Bethany.  In 
England  the  seignorial  revenues  from  ale  appear 
to  have  been  almost,  if  not  entirely,  derived  from 
Ameecements  in  the  manor  courts  for  breaches 
of  the  assize  of  ale,  and  the  term  "cambage"  was 
not  used.  The  word  was  no  doubt  derived  from 
the  low  Latin,  carriba,  an  aleshop,  and  camum. 
The  latter  was  a  kind  of  effervescent  ale  brewed 
from  barley  with  ginger  and  other  spices. 

[Ducange,  Olossarium  medice  et  inflmcB  Latini- 
talis,  1733.]  A.  H. 

CAMBIST.     See  Exchange  Broker. 

CAMBON,  Pierre  Joseph  (1756-1826), 
the  greatest  financier  of  the  period  of  the 
French  Revolution,  was  a  native  of  Mont- 
pellier,  where  his  father  carried  on  a  large 
business  as  a  wholesale  grocer.  He  was  well 
educated,  and,  as  he  showed  a  great  aptitude 
for  business,  was  admitted,  while  still  young, 
a  partner  in  his  father's  firm.  He  was  highly 
esteemed  by  his  fellow-citizens,  was  elected  in 
1790  a  municipal  councillor  of  Montpellier, 
and  in  1791  a  deputy  for  the  department  of 
the  Herault  to  the  Legislative  Assembly.  He 
was  already  well  known  in  Paris,  where  he  had 
resided  for  several  months  during  1789  and 
1790  as  a  diput6  suppUant  to  the  Constituent 
Assembly,  and  was  immediately  appointed 
reporter  of  the  committee  of  the  national 
treasury.  In  this  capacity  he  showed  such 
complete  mastery  of  financial  detail  that  he 
was  in  1792  chosen  by  the  financial  committee 
of  the  Assembly  to  be  their  ordinary  reporter. 
The  declaration  of  war  with  Austria  made  it 
imperative  for  the  Assembly  to  raise  large  sums 
of  money  at  once,  and  Cambon  in  three  elabor- 
ate reports  laid  the  financial  state  of  France 
before  his  colleagues.  A  careful  study  of  these 
reports,  which  were  entitled  Tableau  des  besoins 
et  des  ressources  de  la  Nation,  presented  on  3d 
April  1792  ;  Rapport  sur  la  situation  des  Fin- 
ances, on  17th,  18th,  and  19th  April ;  and  Rap- 
port sur  la  situation  genArale  des  Fina/tiees,  on 
15th  May,  is  absolutely  necessary  for  any  one 
who  would  appreciate  the  financial  condition 
of  France  when  foreign  war  added  to  the  com- 
plications of  the  Revolution.     The  ability  of 


the  reporter  was  generally  recognised  ;  Cambon 
was  elected  President  of  the  Assembly  in  August 

1792,  and  in  the  following  month  first  deputy 
for  the  Herault  to  the  Convention.  He  was 
naturally  elected  to  its  financial  committee, 
of  which  he  became  the  ordinary  reporter.  The 
war  with  Austria  had  been  followed  by  war 
with  Prussia,  and  after  the  execution  of  Louis 
XVI.  by  war  with  Europe.  The  financial  con- 
dition of  France  was  desperate.  AH  Cambon 
could  do  was  to  propose  issues  of  Assignats,  of 
which  400,000,000  of  livres  (£16,000,000)  in 
nominal  value  were  directed  to  be  created  17th 
October  1792,  and  800,000,000  (£32,000,000), 
1st  February  1793.  Cambon  was  elected  a 
member  of  the  Committee  of  General  Defence 
in  January  1793,  and  of  the  first  Committee 
of  Public  Safety  in  April  1793.  This  com- 
mittee was  replaced  14th  July  1793  by  what 
is  known  as  the  great  Committee  of  Public 
Safety,  to  which  Cambon  was  not  elected. 
Thus  freed  from  the  cares  and  responsibilities 
of  general  administration,  Cambon  devoted 
himself  wholly  to  the  management  of  the  fin- 
ances of  France.  The  two  chief  causes  of  the 
confusion  which  prevailed  were  the  excessive 
amount  of  assignats  in  circulation  and  their 
consequent  depreciation,  and  the  ignorance  pre- 
vailing as  to  the  actual  debt  of  the  country. 
To  remedy  them  Cambon  proposed  to  prepare 
a  Grand  Livre  of  the  national  debt.  His 
aims  are  best  indicated  in  the  title  of  his  report, 
presented  to  the  Convention  on  15th  August 

1793,  Rapport  sur  la  dette  publique,  sw  les 
moyens  d  employer  pour  I'enregisirer  swr  un 
grand  livre;  pour  admettre  la  dette  publique 
enpayement  des  biens  nationMux  qui  sont  en  vente; 
pou/r  retirer  et  annuler  les  anciens  titres  de 
criance;  pour  acciUrer  la  liquidation;  pou/r 
rigler  le  mode  actual  de  payement  de  la  dette 
consolidie  darvs  les  chefs-lieux  de  district ;  etpour 
retirer  les  assignats  de  la  circulation.  This  is 
the  great  measure  on  which  Cambon's  fame  as 
a  financier  rests.  There  is  no  need  to  examine 
his  other  reports  ;  they  aU  had  the  same  intent, 
to  realise  the  property  of  the  nation  and  thus 
extinguish  the  assignats  as  far  as  possible. 
He  was  aided  in  his  endeavours  by  other  less 
known  deputies,  who  worked  in  the  Financial 
Committee,  of  whom  the  ablest  were  Ramel 
and  Johannot,  and  by  Robert  Lindet,  who  had 
charge  of  the  department  of  "national  sub- 
sistences or  resources  "  in  the  great  Conmiittee 
of  Public  Safety.  Throughout  the  Reign  of 
Terror,  Cambon  worked  at  the  finances,  and 
practically  administered  them.  He  had  no 
sympathy  with  the  views  of  Robespierre,  and 
disliked  the  measure  of  the  "maximum,"  which 
was  forced  on  the  Convention  for  political 
reasons,  and  was  economically  indefensible. 
This  attitude  made  him  most  obnoxious  to 
Robespierre,  who  attacked  him  by  name  in  his 
last  speech  in  the  Convention  on  8th  Thermidoi 


CAMBON— CAMERALISTIC  SCIENCE 


207 


year  II.  (26th  July  1794),  and  would  have 
proscribed  hiin  had  not  he  himself  been  over- 
thrown on  9  th  Thermidor.  During  the  first 
months  of  the  rule  of  theThermidorians,  Cambon 
maintained  his  position,  but  after  the  return  of 
the  proscribed  Girondins,  and  the  insurrections 
of  Germinal  and  Prairial  year  III.  (April,  May 
1795),  he  was  attacked  as  a  terrorist,  because 
he  had  not  opposed  the  Terror,  and  he  was 
ordered  to  be  arrested.  He  was,  however, 
amnestied  in  the  general  amnesty  of  Brumaire 
year  IV.  (October  1795),  and  then  retired  from 
public  life.  In  1797,  in  a  published  Lettre 
d,  ses  concitoyens  sur  les  Finances,  he  promised 
to  write  a  history  of  his  administration  of  the 
finances  with  illustrative  documents,  but  im- 
fortunately  he  never  fulfilled  this  promise.  He 
returned  to  Montpellier  a  poorer  man  than 
when  he  became  a  deputy,  and  continued  peace- 
fully occupied  in  his  business  until  1815,  when 
he  gave  in  his  adhesion  to  Napoleon  on  his 
return  from  Elba.  This  caused  him  to  be 
exiled  from  France  as  a  regicide  in  1816,  and 
he  died  at  Brussels  in  1826.  Cambon  was 
without  doubt  the  greatest  financier  of  the 
French  Revolution ;  he  shared  Mirabeau's 
abhorrence  of  national  bankruptcy  ;  he  strove 
to  draw  his  country  from  the  financial  embar- 
rassment caused  by  the  depreciation  of  the 
assignats  ;  he  managed  the  treasury  skilfully 
and  with  absolute  honesty,  and  he  possessed 
Montesquieu's  power  of  making  financial  state- 
ments lucid  and  even  interesting. 

There  exists  no  work  devoted  to  Cambon  and 
his  measures  ;  the  best  biographical  sketch  is  in 
the  Biographic  Rabhe  (1836)  ;  there  are  some  in- 
teresting notices  in  Montpellier  sous  la  Revolution, 
by  Duval-Jouve,  Montpellier,  1878  ;  on  his  ad- 
ministration see  Les  Finances  de  I'ancien  Rigime 
et  de  la  Revolution,  by  Rene  Stourm.  The  follow- 
ing list  of  Cambon's  most  important  financial 
speeches  and  reports  is  extracted  from  M. 
Ren6  Stourm's  Bihliographie  des  Finances  au 
XVIIIi^me  Siecle,  published  in  the  Annales  de 
VJ^cole  Libre  des  Sciences  Politiques,  for  15th 
October  1890. — Legislative  Assembly,  Rapport 
sur  la  situation  de  la  Trisorerie  nationale  (10th 
October  1791). — Rapport  sur  les  Hats  de pyrevisions 
de  depenses  pour  1792  et  les  comptes  d  presenter 
par  les  ministres  (11th  November  1791). — Opinion 
8ur  le  rapport  du  Comite  de  la  caisse  de  V  extraor- 
dinaire et  sur  la  dette  publique  (24th  November 
1791). — TaJ)leau  des  besoins  et  des  ressources  de 
la  nation  (3d  April  1792). — Aper^u  des  recettes 
et  des  dipenses  de  1792  (6th  April  17^2).— Rapport 
sur  la  situation  des  finances  d  la  date  du  Her 
AvrU  1793  (17th,  18th,  19th  April  1792).— Rap- 
port sur  la  situation  gin^ale  des  finances  (15th 
May  1792). — Convention,  Rapport  et  projet  de 
dScret  sur  une  nouvelle  criation  de  400,000,000 
d' assignats  (17th  October  1792).— Rapport  et 
projet  de  decret  concemant  la  stippression  de  la. 
caisse  de  V extraordinaire  et  sa  rkinion  d  la  Tre 
sorerie  genirale  (24th  December  1792). — Prqfet 
de  dicret  pour  une  nouvelle  creation  d' assignats  de 


800,000,000  (1st  February  17 9^).—Rapport  sui 
la  dette  publique,  etc.,  quoted  in  text  (15th  August 
1793). — Projet  de  dicret  pour  difendre  la  vente, 
cession,  negociation,  ou  transport  de  litres  actuels 
constatant  les  creances  non  viageres  stir  la  nation 
(11th  September  1793). — Rapport  sur  lesdomaines 
alienis  (1st  Frimaire  year  II.,  21st  November 
1793). — Projet  de  dicret  pour  demonitiser  les  mon- 
naies  d'or  et  d^ argent  (11th  Frimaire  year  II.,  1st 
December  1793). — Projet  de  decret  relatif  aux 
assignats  dimonitisis  (24th  Frimaire  year  II.,  14th 
December  1793). — Rapport  sur  le  compte  des  re- 
cettes et  des  dipenses  de  la  nation,  depids  le  lier 
Mai  1789  jusquau  lier  Septembre  1793  (3d  Ger- 
minal year  II.,  23d  Marcli  1794). — Rapport  et 
projet  de  dicret  sur  les  mutations  par  dices  des 
inscriptions  au  grand  livre  (18th  Fructidor  year 
II.,  4th  September  1794). — Rapport  et  projet  de 
dicret  sur  la  liquidation  des  compagnies  financieres 
connues  sous  le  nom  de  caisse  d^escompte,  assurances 
sur  la  vie,  assurances  contre  les  incendies  (25th 
Fructidor  year  II.,  11th  September  1794). — Rap- 
port sur  les  pensions  dites  ecclisiastiques  (2d  Sans- 
culottide  year  II.,  18th  September  1794). — Dis- 
cours  au  sujet  du  compte  de  Vargenterie  des  iglises 
(12th  Brumaire  year  III.,  2d  November  1794). — 
Rapport  et  projet  de  dicret  sur  les  taxes  revolution- 
naires  (6th  Frimaire  year  III.,  26th  November 
1794). — Rapport  sur  les  moyens  d  prendre  pour 
retirer  les  assig^iats  de  la  circulation  et  sur  la  cria- 
tion  d'une  loterie  (3d  Pluviose  year  III.,  22d  Janu- 
ary 1795). — Risume  des  diverses  opinions  prisen- 
ties  d  la  Convention  Nationale  sur  le  projet  du 
Comiti  des  Finances  pour  accdirer  le  retirement 
des  assignats  (7th  Ventose  year  III.,  25th  February 
1795). — Rapport  sur  la  fixation  de  la  contribution 
fonciere  d  imposer  sur  les  inscriptions  consolidies 
et  viagires  (16th  Ventose  year  III.,  6th  March 
1795).     (See  Assignats  ;  Maximum.)     h.  m.  s. 

CAMBRELENG,  Churchill  C,  born  in 
North  Carolina  1786  ;  died  in  Long  Island 
1862.  He  was  engaged  in  business  in  New 
York  ;  and  became  member  of  congress  1821- 
39.  An  ardent  free  trader,  he  published  anony- 
mously, in  1821,  An  Examination  of  the  Neu 
Tariff  proposed  by  the  Hon.  Henry  Baldwin,  a 
Representative  in  Congress,  by  one  of  the  People, 
New  York,  pp.  268.  In  1830,  as  chairman  of 
committee  on  commerce,  he  made  a  Report  on 
Commerce  and  Navigation,  which  was  exten- 
sively circulated  even  in  England  ;  in  this  he 
strongly  condemns  the  commercial  policy  of  the 
preceding  fifteen  years  ;  in  1838,  from  the  Com- 
mittee on  Ways  and  Means,  he  made  a  Report 
on  the  Currency,  National  Bank,  Independent 
Treasury,  in  which  he  argued  for  the  separa- 
tion of  the  banking  and  fiscal  operations  of  the 
government.  d.  r.  d. 

CAMERALISTIC  SCIENCE  {Kameral- 
wissenschaft).  So  called  because  in  the  progress 
of  time  the  private  chamber  of  the  king  became 
the  treasury,  and  the  camerariu^  assumed  a  new 
and  fiscal  importance.  Strictly  speaking,  the 
science  treats  of  the  adaptation  of  means  to  ends, 
and  the  effects  of  expenditure  on  the  fund  of 
wealth  from  which  revenue  can  be  drawn.    Thus 


208 


CAMEKARIUS— CANALS 


it  is  nearly  equivalent  to  "  Science  of  Finance." 
There  can  be  no  doubt  tliat  in  the  ISth.  century 
the  term  was  applied  to  a  subject  wbicli  might 
have  been  perfectly  described  by  the  latter  phrase. 
There  are,  however,  two  reasons  for  treating 
them  as  separate  and  distinct.  While  writers 
on  Finance  {q.v.)  generally  treat  of  the  natiorfal 
revenue  and  expenditure  from  an  isolated  point 
of  view,  the  cameralistic  writers  considered  the 
financial  as  but  a  part  of  entire  economic  science. 
Thus  we  are  entitled  to  speak  of  cameralistic 
as  well  as  of  financial  science.  In  the  second 
place  finance  is  frequently  used  as  almost  if 
not  quite  synonymous  with  taxation.  The  dis- 
tinctions thus  drawn  are  not,  however,  unexcep- 
tionable. Many  treatises  on  cameralistic  science 
are  in  point  of  fact  treatises  on  the  art  of  taxa- 
tion, while  on  the  other  hand  such  a  work  as 
RiCARDo's  Principles  of  Political  Economy  and 
Taxation,  despite  its  incomplete  nature,  belongs 
in  great  part  to  the  department  of  cameralistic 
science.  (Another  branch  of  this  subject  may 
be  studied  under  Commeecial  Science,  g'.v.) 

[Good  examples  of  treatises  on  KaTneralwissen- 
schaft  in  its  early  sense  as  related  to  other  branches 
of  VolkswirthschOift  or  more  generally,  Wirthschaft- 
licheswissen  are  furnished  in  Baumstark  (Edward), 
Kameral,  etc.,  Encyclopadie,  and  Rau  (C.  D.), 
Ueber  die  KameraZwissenschafi  ;  while  for  its  more 
matured  form  the  works  of  Rau,  Wagner,  and 
Leroy  Beaulieu  should  be  studied.]      E.  c.  k.  g. 

CAMERARIUS,  Joachim  (born  1500,  died 
1574),  an  eminent  scholar  and  "humanist," 
the  friend  of  Melanchthon,  the  *'  glory  of  the 
German  name  "  according  to  the  learned  Casau- 
bon,  deserves  notice  here  as  the  author  of  a 
history  of  Greek  and  Roman  money  ;  and  as 
having  combated  the  mediaeval  prejudice  against 
the  payment  of  interest  (see  Aquinas).  * '  Why, ' ' 
he  asks,  "should  you  not  pay  for  the  use  of 
money  as  well  as  for  the  use  of  a  house  ? " 

Historia  rei  NummaHce  sive  De  NumisTnatis 
Grcecis  et  Latinis,  in  the  ninth  volume  of  Gron- 
ovius's  Thesaurus  Grcecarum  Antiquitatum.  An- 
other work  on  an  economic  subject  was  Politi- 
corum  et  (Economicorum  Aristotelis  interpreta- 
tiones  et  expUcationes,  1581.  f.  y.  e. 

CAMPANELLA,  Tommaso  (1568-1639),  (a 
Dominican,  born  in  Calabria),  a  much  persecuted 
philosopher,  wrote  among  many  other  works, 
Civitas  Solis,  an  "idea  of  a  philosophical  re- 
public," resembling  the  Platonic  republic  in  the 
community  of  wives  and  goods,  and  in  many 
other  features,  but  not  in  slavery.  In  the  city 
of  the  Sun  "no  one  thinks  it  lowering  to  wait 
at  table  or  to  work  in  the  kitchen  or  fields. 
While  duty  and  work  are  distributed  among  all, 
each  one  has  only  to  work  about  four  hours  a 
day."  The  remaining  hours  are  spent  in  pleas- 
ant mental  and  bodily  exercises.  Commerce 
plays  a  small  part  in  the  simple  economics  of 
the  Solarians.  Money,  given  in  exchange  for 
foreign  goods  is  not  received. 

{Civitas   Solis,    begun    In    1602    (during    the 


author's  imprisonment),  was  published  as  part  oi 
Realis  PhilosopMce  Epilogisticoe  partes  quatuor, 
Frankfort,  1623. — Fra  Tommaso  Campanella  .  .  . 
Luigi  Amabile,  1%%7 .—Thomas  Campanella  .  .  . 
Ernest  Nys,  1889.  Abstract  in  Jowett's  Republic, 
Preface.  An  English  translation  in  Morley's 
Universal  Library,  Routledge.]  f.  y.  e. 

CAMPOMANES,  Pedro  Rodriguez,  Count 
of  (1723-1802),  an  eminent  Spanish  jurist, 
economist,  and  statesman.  As  a  member  of  the 
group  of  enlightened  ministers  who  gave  lustre 
to  the  reign  of  Charles  III.,  he  laboured  for  the 
reform  of  taxation,  the  promotion  of  agriculture 
and  manufactures,  the  diffusion  of  education, 
and  the  adaptation  of  Spanish  institutions  to 
the  needs  of  the  age.  Eminently  upright  and 
disinterested,  he  was  one  of  the  foremost  bene- 
factors of  his  country.  His  theoretic  views  and 
practical  efforts  strikingly  resemble  those  of  his 
illustrious  contemporary  Turgot. 

The  principal  economic  writings  of  Campomanes 
are  : — Respuesta  fiscal  sdbre  aholir  la  tasa  y  estdb- 
lecer  el  com^rdo  de  granos,  1764. — Discurso  sobre 
el  fomento  de  industria  popolar,  1774,  and  Dis- 
curso sdbre  la  educacion  de  los  artesanos  y  su  fo- 
mento, 1775.  Robertson  eulogises  the  two  latter 
works  in  his  History  of  America  (note  193),  and 
justly  says  of  Campomanes — "  There  are  not  many 
authors,  who  hat^e  united  more  happily  the  calm 
researches  of  philosophy  with  the  ardent  zeal  of  a 
public-spirited  citizen."  j.  k.  i. 

CANALS  may  be  defined  as  artificial  water- 
ways constructed  for  the  purpose  of  navigation 
or  irrigation.  Navigable  canals  may  be  divided 
into  two  classes :  (1)  those  used  for  inland 
navigation,  and  (2)  those  used  to  shorten  sea 
voyages.  The  former  have  been  constructed  to 
carry  boats  and  barges  limited  on  the  smaller 
canals  to  a  carrying  capacity  of  25  to  30  tons, 
and  on  the  larger  canals  to  a  capacity  of  from 
50  to  300  tons.  In  the  Amsterdam  and  Man- 
chester ship  canals,  a  successful  attempt  has 
been  and  is  being  made  to  construct  a  waterway 
of  sufficient  size  to  permit  of  the  passage  of  large 
sea-going  vessels.  The  chief  examples  of  the 
second  class  are  the  Suez  Canal,  the  Languedoc 
Canal,  and  the  Caledonian  Canal.  Though 
known  in  Egypt  and  China,  and  constructed  in 
Holland  in  the  12th  century,  it  was  not  until 
the  invention  of  locks  in  Italy  in  the  14th  cen- 
tury that  inland  navigation  made  any  progress 
in  Europe.  The  development  of  canals  in 
Holland  greatly  extended  that  country's  com- 
merce, as  by  their  means  a  large  inland  trade 
was  carried  on  with  Germany  and  France. 
Several  important  canals  are  found  in  France 
towards  the  end  of  the  I7th  century,  but  in 
England  the  first  modern  canal  was  not  author- 
ised until  1755.  Five  years  later  the  Duke  of 
Bridgwater  obtained  his  first  Canal  Act,  and 
the  success  attending  the  construction  of  the 
canal  from  Worsley  to  Manchester  gave  such 
an  impulse  to  such  undertakings  that  Porter 
{Progress  of  the  Nation,  §  iii.  ch.  i.,  1836-1843) 


CANALS— CANCEL 


!09 


pointed  out  that,  owing  to  the  construction  of 
canals,  there  was  no  spot  south  of  the  county  of 
Durham  at  a  greater  distance  than  fifteen  miles 
from  water  conveyance.  It  was  expected  that 
canals  would  prove  formidable  rivals  to  railways, 
but  in  1845  began  the  gradual  transfer  of  canals 
to  railway  companies.  This  transfer  was  in 
some  cases  due  to  the  dread  that  railways  would 
secure 'all  the  traffic,  and  the  withdrawal  of 
opposition  to  the  construction  of  the  railway 
was  secured  by  the  purchase  of  the  canal.  In 
other  cases  the  railways  offered  tempting  terms 
so  as  to  secure  a  monopoly  of  traffic.  The  result 
was  that  nearly  one-half  the  inland  navigable 
canals  are  controlled  by  railway  companies 
(see  Evidence  taken  before  select  committee  on 
canals,  1883).  Some  canals  have  been  closed 
or  allowed  to  fall  out  of  repair,  on  others  heavy 
tolls  called  "bar  tolls"  have  been  imposed  to 
prevent  their  use  by  traffic  from  neighbouring 
canals,  whilst  no  adequate  attempt  has  been 
made  to  establish  through  communication  or 
speedy  service  (see  Eeport  of  committee  on 
railways,  1882).  In  1872  a  joint  committee 
of  the  House  of  Lords  and  of  the  House  of 
Commons  recommended  that  no  internal  navi- 
gation in  the  hands  of  the  public  should  be 
placed  under  a  railway  company,  and  in  1882 
a  select  committee  of  the  House  of  Commons 
on  railways  expressed  the  ojnnion  that  it  was 
"impolitic  that  railway  companies  should  have 
the  control  either  directly  or  indirectly  of  canal 
navigation,  and  that  wliere  canals  are  already 
under  the  control  of  railway  companies,  parlia- 
ment should  endeavour  to  ensure  their  use  to 
the  fullest  possible  extent." 

The  advantages  of  canals  over  railways  have 
been  summed  up  by  L.  F.  Harcourt  in  his 
treatise  on  Rivers  and  Canals  (Oxford,  1882),  as 
follows — "They  are  frequently  less  costly  in 
construction,  and  their  cost  of  maintenance  and 
their  working  expenses  are  considerably  smaller. 
Moreover,  the  proportion  of  dead  weight  to  the 
load  carried  is  much  less  in  canal  barges  than 
in  railway  waggons  ;  and  the  barges  not  only 
cost  much  less  proportionately  to  their  capacity 
than  waggons,  but  are  also  far  more  easily  re- 
paired. The  resistance  also  to  traction  is  much 
smaller  in  water  than  on  rails,  amounting,  ac- 
cording to  M.  Malezieux,  to  only  one-fifth  of 
the  average  resistance  on  railways.  Barges  on 
canals  can  be  loaded  or  unloaded  at  any  places 
they  pass  ;  whilst  goods  trains  can  only  stop  at 
stations."  See  also  the  Evidence  given  before 
the  Committees  on  the  Manchester  ship  canal, 
1883,  1884,  1885,  and  Canals  by  M.  Stevens 
(London,  1887). 

[On  the  economic  aspects  of  canals  reference  may 
be  made  to  Observations  sur  les  tarifs  de  nos  can- 
aux,  F.  Aulagnier,  1837. — Observations  on  Canals 
and  Navigable  Rivers,  G.  Beadon,  1848.— Xe  Canal 
Indo-Europien  et  la  navigation  de  VEuphrate  et  du 
Tigre,  E.  Ende,  1886. — Kanale  und  Eisenbahn^n 
VOL.  I. 


in  ihrer  wirthschaf  (lichen  Bedeutung,  C.  Hauser, 
1880. — Des  Canaux  de  Navigation,  M.  La  Lande, 
1778. — Die  Canalisation  des  preussischen  Staates 
nebst  Beweis,  Z.  Puttkammer,  1868.  —  Canal 
und  Eisenhahn,  Eeimherr,  1884. — Canals,  by  M. 
Stevens,  London,  1887. — Eisenbahn  oder  Kanal, 
E.  Wiss,  1878. —  Ueber  die  Kanalbahn  und  deren 
Rentabilitat  in  der  Eisenbahnzeit,  E.  Wiss,  1866. 
— Die  selbstartende  Eisenbahn  Transporte  und 
die  Wasserstrassenfrage,  L.  Zells,  1887. —  Ueber 
Wasserstrassen,  L.  Zells,  1887.  —  Waterways  and 
Water  Transport,  by  J.  S.  Jeans,  Loudon,  1890. 

The  relative  advantages  of  railways  and  water- 
ways in  Germany  are  discussed  in  the  Journal  of 
the  Royal  Statistical  Society,  vol.  li.  1888.  As 
regards  the  canal  system  of  different  countries, 
see  as  to  English  Canals,  History  of  Inland  Navi- 
gation, by  J.  Phillips,  London,  1803. — Historical 
Account  of  the  Navigable  Rivers,  Canals,  and 
Hallways  throughout  Great Britain,\)j  J .  I'riestley, 
London,  1831. — Reports,  Evidence,  and  Returns, 
Royal  Commission  on  Canals  and  Waterways, 
1906.  Their  final  Report  received  much  attention, 
followed,  about  1912,  by  the  establishment  of  the 
Midland  Waterway's  Association  to  press  for  im- 
proved water  communication  with  Hull,  Liverpool, 
London  and  the  Severn  Ports.  As  to  France  : 
Histoire  de  la  Navigation  intericure  de  la  France, 
par  M.  Dutens. — Les  Voies  navigables  en  France, 
par  P.  MuUer,  1866. — Manuel  des  Voies  navigables 
de  la  France,  par  A.  Larme,  1S78.  As  to  Germany 
and  Austria:  Die  Kancd-Verbindung  des  RJieines 
viit  der  Donau,  C,  T.  Kleinschrod. — Deutschlands 
Wasserstrassen  in  deren  Verwendung  in  ihrem 
jetzigen  Zusiande  fur  den  Export,  von  W.  J. 
Mulvany,  1881. —  Vienne  port  de  mcr,  Traite  de 
V exploitation  des  Voies  comprises  d'Autriche  et  de 
V Allemagne.  Le  Grand  Danube,  par  Saint  Hubert, 
1881.  As  to  Holland:  Ncderland  als Polderland, 
A.  A.  Beckman,  Zutphen,  1888.  —  Le  Canal 
d' Amsterdam  d  la  mer  du  Nord,  C.  Boissay,  1871. 
As  to  United  States  :  Die  Wasserstrassen  in  den 
Vereinigten  Staaten  von  Amerika  in  ihrer  com- 
merziellen  und  industriellen  Bedeutung,  C.  Hosier, 
1877.]  J.  E.  c.  M. 

CANARD,  Nicholas  Francois,  professor 
of  mathematics  at  the  College  cle  Moulins  (h. 
about  1750,  f?.  1833).  He  was  the  author  of 
Prineipes  d'J^conomie  Politique,  Paris,  1802, 
crowned  by  the  French  Academy.  "Ces  pre- 
tendus  prineipes,"  says  Cournot,  "  sont  si  radi- 
calement  faux,  et  I'application  en  est  tellement 
erronee,  que  le  sufii-age  d'un  corps  eminent  u'a 
pu  preserver  I'ouvrage  de  I'oubli." 

Canard  also  wrote  Memoires  sur  les  causes  qui 
produisent  la  stagflation  et  le  decroissement  du 
commerce  en  France,  et  qui  tendent  d  aneantir 
Vindustrie  commerciale  ;  moyen  simple  de  les  f aire 
cesser,  Paris,  1826. 

[Canard  is  criticised  by  M.  Bertrand,  Journal 
des  Savants,  1883,  p.  499.]  f.  t.  e. 

CANCEL,  Cancellation.  The  discharge 
of  a  document,  usually  by  marking  across  the 
operative  signature,  or  signatures,  either  the 
word  "cancelled"  or  some  recognised  mark. 
"The  cancellation  of  a  signature  operates  as  a 

P 


210 


CANCRIN— CANNING 


discharge,  unless  proof  can  be  given  that  the 
cancellation  was  done  by  mistake." 

[Hutchison,  Tlce  Practice  of  Banking,  vol.  i. 

p.  125.] 

CANCRIN,  George  (1774-1845),  an  emi- 
nent Russian  financier,  son  of  Franz  Ludwig 
Cancrin,  the  distinguished  German  mineralo- 
gist.    Born  at  Hanau  in  Electoral  Hesse,  he 
studied  law  and  political  economy  at  the  uni- 
versities of  Giessen  and  Marburg,   and   early 
showed  a  remarkable  faculty  for  work  and  a 
spirit  of  restless  activity.     He  filled  successively 
several  posts  in  the  administration  of  Anhalt- 
Bernburg.     He  j  oined  his  father  in  Russia,  1796. 
In  1800  he  was  employed  in  the  ministry  of  the 
interior,   and,   having   attracted   attention  by 
writings  on  military  economy,  he  was  made, 
1812,  intendant-general  of  the  army  of  the  West, 
and  in  that  capacity  accompanied  the  Russian 
forces  in  their  march  through  Germany.     In 
1813  he  was  appointed  intendant-general  of  all 
the  ' '  active  "  armies.     This  office  he  resigned  in 
1820,  and  in  1823  became  minister  of  finance,  a 
position  which  he  held  till  1844.     He  possessed 
in  a  high  degree  the  esteem  and  confidence  of 
the   Emperor   Alexander,    as   well    as    of    his 
successor.     He  was  most  diligent  and  energetic 
in  discharging  his  ministerial  duties,  founded 
many  useful  establishments,  and  gave  a  great 
impulse  to  the  national  industries.      He  had 
special   agents   at   Paris,   at  London,    and   in 
Germany,  who  kept  him  informed  on  the  pro- 
gress of  the  arts  and  the  introduction  of  new 
processes.      By  his   financial   management  he 
increased  the  revenue,  and  raised  the  credit  of 
the  empire,  previously  on  the  verge  of  bank- 
ruptcy.    But  his  system,  though  successful  in 
providing  resources   for   the  government,   was 
founded  on  rigid  prohibition  and  state-manu- 
factures, and  appears  to  have  been  burdensome 
to  the  community.     His  term  of  office,  we  are 
told,  is  now  regarded  by  the  Russian  people  as 
the  most  unfortunate  period  of  their  history. 
He  died  at  St.  Petersburg  in  1845.     Roscheb 
thinks  his  general  economics  were  injured  by 
his  pre-occupation  with  the  question  of  military 
supply,  immediate  results  being  aimed  at  in  the 
latter  case,  whilst  in  the  conduct  of  national 
aff'airs  as  a  whole  permanent  prosperity  is  the 
object  to  be  achieved.    He  represented  a  reaction 
against  Adam  Smith  from  the  point  of  view 
of  a  man  of  the  world  who  had  to  conduct  the 
economic  practice  of  a  country  much  less  ad- 
vanced than   England,  in  fact,   as  he  himself 
calls  it,  "infra-European."     Strictly  conserva- 
tive in  his  economics,  he  disliked  new  institu- 
tions, being  thus  sometimes  led  to  paradoxical 
conclusions ;    he   opposed,    e.g.    the   establish- 
ment of  banks  and  the  extension  of  railways,  at 
least  in  Russia.     (Roscher,  Geschichte  der  Nat. 
Oek.  in  Deutschland,  p.  813.) 

Cancrin  was  author,  besides  minor  publications, 
of  a  treatise  Ueber  die  Militdro/conomie  im  Frieden 


und  im  Kriege,  und  iiber  ihr  Wechselverhdltniss  zu 
den  Operationen,  1820-23,  of  Weltreichthum, 
National-Reichthum  und  Staatswirthschaft,  oder 
Versuch  neuer  Ansichten  der  politischen  Oekonomie 
(published  anonymously),  1821,  and  Die  Oekonomie 
der  m^nschlichen  Gesellschaften  und  des  Finanz- 
wesen,  von  einem  ehemaligen  Finanzminister,  1845. 

J.  K.  I. 
CANDAREEN.  A  denomination  of  the 
Chinese  money  of  account,  but  not  a  coin. 
10  cash  =  l  candareen  (see  Cash).  10  candar- 
eens  =  l  mace.  10  mace  =  l  tael  (the  unit  of 
value).  r.  e.  a. 

CANNING,  George,  bom  in  Marylebone, 
1770,  died  at  Chiswick,  1827,  is  most  famous 
for  the  unique  services  which  he  rendered  as 
foreign  secretary,  especially  in  the  autumn  of 
1807,  when  he  directed  the  capture  of  the 
Danish  fleet,  and  in  1822  and  1826,  when  he 
stood  firm  against  France  and  the  Holy  Alliance 
in  the  aifairs  of  Spain  and  Portugal.  His 
"Needy  Knife  Grinder"  and  other  witty  papers 
in  the  Anti-JacoUn  have  given  him  a  place  of 
his  own  in  our  minor  literature.  In  economical 
history  his  place  is  subordinate.  His  first  views 
of  commercial  policy  inclined  him  to  compro- 
mise. Though  he  was  not  a  profound  student 
of  finance  and  political  economy,  his  close  alli- 
ance with  »HusKissoN  counteracted  his  own 
shortcomings,  and  justifies  his  inclusion  among 
the  pioneers  of  a  free-trade  policy.  His  uttei 
ances  on  the  bullion  controversy,  the  Cor> 
Laws,  and  the  navigation  acts,  had  a  distinct 
influence  on  the  public  as  well  as  on  the  House 
of  Commons. 

When  the  Report  of  the  Bullion  Committee 
came  up  for  discussion.  May  1811,  Canning  as 
a  private  member  gave  (in  two  speeches — 8th 
May  and  13th  May)  a  general  support  to  the 
resolutions  of  the  committee,  though  he  refused 
to  vote  for  the  sixteenth  (or  last)  which  pledged 
the  bank  to  resume  cash  payments  in  two  years' 
time.     Vaksittart  and  Perceval  had  urged 
that  continued  suspension  of  cash  payments  wa3 
necessary  to  the  successful  prosecution  of  the 
war  with  France.     Canning  answered  that  our 
best  strength  was  to  support  the  credit  of  the 
country,  and  the  soundness  of  the  currency. 
There  must  be  no  uncertainty  in  the  public 
mind  as  to  the  real  standard  of  the  currency.     _ 
The  question  of  depreciation  was  a  question  not    M 
of  the  soundness  of  the  bank  itself  but  of  the    ^ 
relation  of  the  notes  of  the  bank  to  the  real 
standard,    which    Canning    defined    (as    Peel 
afterwards  defined  it)  as  a  definite  measurable 
quantity  of  the  metal  gold,  of  a  certain  ascer- 
tainable  fineness.     Vansittart   had    talked    of 
the  standard  as  being  a  "sense  of  value,"  or 
as  "public  estimation"  ;  and  Canning  had  no 
difficulty   in   showing  the  vagueness  of  these 
phrases,  and,  contrariwise,  the  clearness  of  the 
terms  employed  by  the  bullion  committee,  who 
had  been  slighted  as  "abstract  theorists,"  only 
because  in  addition  to  practical  knowledge  they 


CANNING— CANON  LAW 


211 


had  acquaintance  with  iirst  principles.  They 
were  right  in  finding  a  sufficient  proof  of  de- 
preciation in  the  fact  that  there  was  a  difference 
between  the  price  of  Bullion  in  bank  notes,  and 
the  Mint  Price  of  gold  ;  and  it  was  an  import- 
ant confirmation,  to  find  the  exchanges  continu- 
ing for  some  time  progressively  unfavourable  to 
this  country.  It  seemed  to  Canning  (as  to 
Cobbett)  that  Burke's  description  (1791)  of 
the  contrast  between  English  notes  and  French 
AssiGNATS  can  fairly  be  applied  to  the  contrast 
between  English  notes  as  they  were  in  Burke's 
time,  and  English  notes  as  they  were  in  1811. 
The  resolutions,  introduced  by  Vansittart, 
though  not  of  Vansittart's  own  invention 
(see  Canning's  Speech  on  Bank  Charter  Act, 
13th  Feb.  1826),  in  opposition  to  those  of  the 
bullion  committee,  called  forth  all  the  re- 
sources of  Canning's  wit  and  sarcasm,  especi- 
ally the  famous  third  resolution  that  the 
bank  notes  ''have  hitherto  been  and  are  at 
this  time  held  in  public  estimation  to  be 
equivalent  to  the  legal  coin  of  the  realm." 
He  compares  this  to  Bonaparte's  proclamation 
that  beet  and  maple  sugar  are  infinitely  better 
than  cane  sugar,  and  must,  therefore,  be  used 
in  place  thereof,  under  penalties.  These  two 
speeches  of  1811  are  striking  examples  of 
Canning's  power  to  master  at  second  hand 
the  principles  of  a  subject  to  which  he  does 
not  appear  either  then  or  afterwards  to  have 
given  any  special  study.  In  the  Quarterly 
Review  (Nov.  1810  and  Feb.  1811,  dealing 
with  two  pamphlets  of  Sir  John  Sinclair)  he 
treats  the  same  subject  (of  the  bullion 
committee)  in  his  lighter  vein  (see  Bullion 
Committee,  Report  of  ;  Currency  Theory, 
etc.)  He  had  to  deal  with  a  kindred  topic 
(in  his  speech  of  13th  Feb.  1826)  when  the 
government  were  taking  steps  to  stop  the 
circulation  in  England  of  bank  notes  under 
five  pounds  ;  but  except  perhaps  for  a  telling 
quotation  from  a  private  letter  of  Burke's  ("If 
Pitt  consents  to  the  issue  of  one  pound  notes 

,       he  will  never  see  a  guinea  again  "  )  the  speech 

I       is  not  of  special  importance. 

!  In  office  along  with  Huskisson  in  1823  and 

i  1826,  he  gave  willing  and  admiring  support  to 
the  reforms  in  commercial  policy  introduced  by 
his  colleague.  It  was  in  the  negotiations  for 
a  reciprocity  treaty  with  Holland,  in  amend- 
ment of  the  navigation  acts,  that  he  sent  (in 
1826)  in  answer  to  Falck,  the  Dutch  minister 
at  the  Hague,  the  well-known  despatch  in 
cipher : 

"  In  matters  of  commerce  the  fault  of  the  Dutch 
Is  giving  too  little  and  asking  too  much  ; 
With  equal  advantage  the  French  are  content. 
So  we'll  clap  on  Dutch  bottoms  just  twenty  per 
cent. 

(Chorus.)    Twenty  per  cent.     Twenty  per  cent. 
Nous  frapperons  Falck  with  twenty  per  cent." 

In  1827   he  helped  Huskisson  to  frame  a 


sliding  scale  of  duties,  in  amendment  of  the 
com  laws  of  1815  and  1822  (see  Corn  Laws 
and  Sliding  Scale).  His  policy  here,  as  well 
as  in  the  case  of  West  Indian  slavery  (see 
speeches  of  1823,  1824,  and  1826),  was  that 
of  compromise  and  gi-adual  reform.  He  ad- 
mitted in  1827  (speech  of  1st  March)  that  the 
paternal  power  he  had  claimed,  in  1826,  for 
government,  to  relax  the  corn  laws  and  open  the 
jiorts  on  emergency,  had  not  proved  to  work  well 
in  practice,  and  the  confession  was  one  sign 
amongst  many  that  he  was  inclining  toAvards 
a  policy  opposed  to  all  interference  of  govern- 
ment with  trade.  His  single  budget  speech, 
1st  June  1827  (when  he  was  at  once  prime 
minister  and  chancellor  of  the  exchequer), 
cannot  fairly  be  taken  as  a  measure  of  his 
financial  ability,  for  the  circumstances  were 
exceptional,  and  the  budget  a  makeshift.  His 
conception  of  the  relation  of  economics  to 
politics  may  be  gathered  from  his  short 
speech  in  defence  of  Huskisson  against  the 
silk  manufacturers  (24th  Feb.  1826):  "We 
must  deal  with  the  affairs  of  men  on  abstract 
principles,  modified,  however,  of  course,  accord- 
ing to  time  and  circumstances  ; "  we  must 
soar  to  "the  heights  from  which  alone  ex- 
tended views  of  human  nature  can  be  taken." 
He  was  careful  to  point  out  that  reform  of 
commercial  policy  had  been  hitherto  identified 
with  neither  political  party  ;  it  was  his  master, 
Pitt,  who  carried  the  treaty  of  commerce  with 
France  in  1786,  when  Fox  opposed  it. 

[77ie  Speeches  of  the  Right  Hon.  George  Canning, 
with  a  Mevioir  of  his  Life,  by  R.  Tlierry,  6  vols., 
1828. — The  Life  of  the  Right  Hon.  George  Canning, 
by  R.  Bell,  1846. — George  Canning  and  his  Times, 
by  A.  G.  Stapleton,  1859. — Statesmen  of  the  Time 
of  George  II L,  Henry,  Lord  Brougham,  1839-43.] 

J.B. 

CANON  LAW.  The  canon  law  is  a  body 
of  rules  (Kauoves)  laid  down  by  the  early  and 
medifEval  Christian  church  for  the  government 
of  its  members.  It  consists  accordingly  of 
citations  from  scripture,  the  fathers,  and  the 
popes,  together  with  commentaries  and  glosses. 
The  several  compilations  of  this  character, 
beginning  at  the  end  of  the  3d  century  and 
carried  down  to  his  own  day,  were  reduced  to 
something  like  their  present  systematic  shape 
(in  the  "corpus  juris  canonici")  in  the  middle 
of  the  12th  century  by  Gratian,  a  monk  of 
Bologna,  the  founder  of  the  study  of  canon  law. 
His  successors  appended  to  his  collection  (or 
"Decretum")  the  decretals  of  the  popes  in  the 
next  three  centuries.  It  need  hardly  be  said 
that  only  such  of  its  topics  as  bear  on  economi- 
cal theory  or  history  will  be  considered  here. 

At  the  beginning  of  the  book  we  are  told 
that  the  human  race  is  under  two  kinds  of 
IJaws, — the  law  of  nature  and  the  law  of  cus- 
tom (or  positive  institution)  "uaturali  jure  et 
moribus."     Civil  law  and  canon  law  are  two 


212 


CANON  LAW 


branches  of  the  second  species.  By  the  law 
of  nature  there  is  no  private  property,  but  "all 
things  are  common  to  all  men"  (*' jure  naturali 
omnia  sunt  communia  omnibus"),  as  they  were 
among  the  first  disciples.  St.  Augustine  argues 
that,  as  "the  earth  is  the  Lord's  and  the  fulness 
thereof,"  private  property  is  not  of  divine  but 
of  purely  human  appointment.  "Tolle  jura 
imperatorum,"  and  no  one  can  say  "this  is 
my  house,"  or  "this  is  my  slave,"  etc.  It 
would  seem  natural  after  this  to  hear  that 
private  property  is  forbidden  by  canon  law ;  but 
this  is  not  so.  It  is  forbidden  to  the  clergy, 
who  are  to  hold  their  property  collectively  for 
the  good  of  the  poor  ;  they  are  not  to  marry  ; 
and  they  are  to  be  "victu  et  vestitu  contenti." 
But  it  is  allowed,  grudgingly,  to  the  laity,  who 
are  to  hold  it  in  trust  for  the  poor,  and  who 
are  therefore  to  give  liberally  to  the  poor  and 
to  the  clergy  as  the  almoners  of  the  poor.  It  is 
hinted  that  among  Christians  the  ideal  distri- 
bution is  community  of  goods,  and  that  only  for 
the  hardness  of  men's  hearts  is  any  compromise 
admitted.  In  the  same  way  the  ideal  industry 
is  agriculture  ;  and  the  only  right  way  of  in- 
creasing wealth  is  to  till  the  ground  and  breed 
cattle.  These  pursuits  and  the  simple  manu- 
facturing industries  of  an  agricultural  people 
are  allowed  with  reservations  even  to  the  clergy, 
who  may  thus  work  for  their  own  livelihood, 
like  the  apostles.  Labour  within  these  limits 
is  indeed  commended  by  the  canon  law  ;  and  it 
is  one  of  the  glories  of  the  early  and  mediaeval 
church  that  it  did  its  best  to  enfranchise  the 
labourer.  Eoman  Law  had  more  regard  for 
property  than  for  human  beings  ;  canon  law 
erred  on  the  safer  side.  In  their  aspirations 
after  an  idyllic  life  it  is  clear  that  the  writers 
would  have  gone  back  to  barter  if  they  dared. 
As  it  was  they  followed  Apjstotle  in  treating 
money  as  a  "barren  metal,"  and  they  gave 
literal  effect  to  the  words  of  the  gospel :  ' '  Lend, 
hoping  for  nothing  again"  ("Mutumn  date 
nihil  inde  sperantes"),  by  strictly  forbidding 
usury  and  by  giving  every  assistance  to  the 
debtor  as  presumably  poorer  than  the  creditor. 
At  first  (by  the  council  of  Mcaea,  325  a.d.) 
the  prohibition  of  XJsuey  applied  only  to  the 
clergy  ;  but  a  century  later  it  was  extended  to 
the  laity,  and  the  "corpus  juris  canonici" 
abounds  in  emphatic  assertions  of  it.  "  Etiam 
laicis  usura  damnabilis."  "Usura"  did  not 
simply  mean  a  high  rate  of  Interest  ;  it  meant 
all  and  every  interest  whatever,  and  the  notion 
was  even  stretched  so  as  to  embrace  aU  and 
every  gain  beyond  what  was  considered  a  just 
and  proper  price,  in  ordinary  buying  and  selling. 
"  Qui  plus  quam  dederit  accipit,  usuras  expetit," 
whether  the  "  superabundantia "  be  money  or 
wheat  or  wine.  "  Quidquid  sorti  accedit,  usura 
est."  "Turpe  lucrum  sequitur  qui  minus  emit 
ut  plus  vendat."  "Rapinam  facit  qui  usuram 
accipit."     As  late  as  the  14th  century  (at  the 


Council  ofVienne,  1311)  Clement  V.  declared 
the  prohibition  of  usury  to  be  absolute,  all 
civil  laws  to  the  contrary  notwithstanding. 
Dante  puts  the  usurers  in  the  lowest  division 
of  his  seventh  circle  of  Hell  as  doing  violence 
to  God  and  nature  {Inferno  XL,  46-50,  cp. 
95-111).  Thomas  Aquinas  (in  13th  century) 
speaks  of  usury  as  "  contra  legem  naturae,"  as 
weU  as  against  the  law  of  the  church  ;  and  this 
unnaturalness  had  been  one  of  the  grounds  of 
prohibition  from  the  first.  Usury  might  be 
practised  only  as  a  form  of  war,  "  Ubi  jus  belli, 
ibi  etiam  jus  usurse." 

"  If  thou  wilt  lend  this  money,  lend  it  not 
As  to  thy  friends, — for  when  did  friendship  take 
A  breed  for  barren  metal  of  his  friend  ? — 
But  lend  it  rather  to  thine  enemy." 

The  arguments  by  which  the  unnaturalness 
of  interest  was  maintained  ran  somewhat  as 
follows  :  When  money  is  lent,  the  lender  parts 
with  it,  and  the  borrower  has  it  to  use  ;  if  there 
were  any  productiveness  in  it,  the  man  who  has 
used  it,  and  not  the  man  who  has  parted  with 
it,  would  justly  have  the  benefit.  There  is, 
however,  no  productiveness  in  it.  The  lender 
gives,  say,  ten  pieces  of  silver  ;  now  these  ten 
pieces  are  not  like  seeds  in  the  earth,  or  trees 
in  the  orchard  ;  they  do  not  become  anything 
else  than  ten  pieces  of  silver,  through  however 
many  hands  they  pass.  Why  then  should 
they  become  eleven  or  twelve  when  delivered 
again  to  the  lender  ? 

Again,  it  was  said,  we  must  distinguish  two 
kinds  of  loans.  There  are  objects  which,  when 
we  have  borrowed  (or  hired),  we  use  without 
destroying  them  in  the  use — e.g.  a  field,  or  a 
horse,  or  a  sjiftde.  We  return  them  not  "in 
genere,"  but  specifically,  in  their  identity,  with 
compensation  to  the  lender  for  any  deterioration 
we  may  have  caused.  This  loan  is  the  Com- 
MODATUM  of  Roman  law,  as  distinguished  from 
MUTUUM.  In  the  latter  instance  ("mutu- 
um"),  as  in  the  case  of  fruit  or  wine,  the  borrowed 
objects  are  destroyed  in  the  using,  and  are  re- 
turned to  the  lender  in  kind.  Now,  money  is 
of  the  latter  sort;  it  has  no  "use"  which  is 
distinct  from  itself,  and  consistent  with  its 
retention  by  the  possessor  ;  to  use  it,  he  must 
part  with  it.  But,  if  we  allow  usury,  we  are 
claiming  that  money  has  a  use  distinct  from 
itself,  and  that,  when  the  sum  bon-owed  is  re- 
turned, an  additional  sum  should  be  added  in 
payment  of  this  supposed  use, — in  other  words 
"id  venditur  quod  non  est."  Of  the  other 
arguments  used  against  usury  by  the  canonists, 
it  wUl  be  enough  to  cite  perhaps  the  most  famous 
one.  To  pay  interest  is  to  pay  for  time.  Now 
time  is  the  common  property  of  all  men  ;  and, 
besides,  time  is  like  barren  metal  itself ;  it  can 
of  itself  produce  nothing ;  why  then  should 
anything  be  paid  for  it  ?  Thomas  Aquinas  laid 
special  stress  on  this  argument,  which  he  was 


CANON  LAW 


213 


the  first  distinctly  to  formulate.  It  does  not 
appear  very  explicitly  in  the  canon  law  itself. 

The  motive  for  the  prohibition  is  clearer 
than  the  arguments  advanced  for  it.  It  is  the 
I  same  motive  which  led  the  church  to  forbid  a 

m  in  any  case  to  take  advantage  of  his 
leighbour's  need,  and  wTing  from  him  an  ex- 
sptionally  high  price.     Christian  brotherliness 

[uired  that  my  neighbour's  extremity  should 
lever  be  my  opportunity,  and  I  should  never 
large  him  more  than  the  lair  price  Justum 
i*RETiUM  for  my  goods,  the  said  price  being 
16  one  assessed  in  money  by  the  church  or 
(it  might  be)  by  the  civil  authorities,  and  rati- 
fied as  customary.  The  same  principle  would 
irevent  me  from  exacting  any  recompense  for 
loan.  Otherwise,  in  either  case,  I  should  be 
jceiving  what  I  had  not  earned  by  the  sweat 
of  my  brow,  and  violating  the  law  of  God 
and  nature. 

The  European  world,  with  settled  order  and 
increasing  commerce,  chafed  under  this  en- 
forced unselfishness  ;  and  the  church  was  forced 
to  tolerate  evasions  of  the  prohibition  of  usury. 
These  evasions  will  be  more  fully  treated  under 
the  head  of  usury  ;  but  the  chief  instances  may 
be  mentioned  here.  The  buyer  on  credit  was 
allowed  to  ])ay  more  (in  the  final  settlement)  for 
his  article  tlian  the  buyer  for  cash,  in  all  cases 
where,  in  tlie  first  instance,  there  had  been  a 
real  uncertainty  from  ordinary  causes  about  the 
future  price  of  the  article  concerned.  But  it 
was  to  be  clearly  understood  that  the  difference 
in  time  was  to  have  nothing  to  do  with  the 
difference  in  the  price  (decretal  of  Alexander 
III.  in  12th  century,  confirmed  by  Gregory  IX. 
in  13th  century). 

This  was  a  comparatively  early  concession 
made  to  the  Genoese  when  Italian  commerce 
was  beginning  to  giow,  after  the  first  crusades. 
It  was  followed  by  others.  It  was  found  pos- 
sible, for  example,  to  exclude  the  Bill  of 
Exchange  from  the  category  of  usury  by  repre- 
senting any  Discount  or  Interest  it  involved 
as  a  payment  for  work  done,  namely,  the  work  of 
transporting  money  (or  at  least  the  payment  of 
money)  from  one  place  to  another.  Though 
money  by  itself  was  (to  the  canon  law)  unpro- 
ductive, "  money  conjoined  with  human  labour  " 
( ' '  pecunia  juncta  cum  hominis  operatione ' ')  could 
be  productive.  Accordingly,  when  companies 
were  formed  some  of  whose  members  contri- 
buted money  and  labour,  others  only  their 
money,  yet  all  shared  in  the  gains,  it  was 
allowed  (not  without  misgivings)  that  this  con- 
formity to  the  letter  of  the  law  was  sufficient. 

A  third  kind  of  exception  was  made  in  cases 
where  loans  were  attended  with  unusual  risks 
to  repayment ;  the  lenders  were  allowed  to 
receive  a  sum  over  and  above  their  principal  as 
a  compensation  for  the  risk  they  had  run. 
This  concession  was  very  grudgingly  made  ;  but 
(asHallam  has  noticed)  marine  Insurance  seems 


from  the  first  to  have  passed  unchallenged. 
Not  unlike  these  cases  was  that  of  creditors 
whose  debtors  were  behind  their  time  ;  interest 
in  such  a  case  was  counted  a  justifiable  penalty 
for  breach  of  contract  ("  usura  punitoria  "). 

Finally,  the  Jews  were  allowed  to  lend 
money  at  interest,  because,  not  being  Christians, 
they  were  not  bound  by  canon  law.  There 
were  always  some  canonists  who  (like  Aquinas) 
objected  to  this  toleration  ;  but  its  practical 
convenience  saved  it ;  and,  till  the  Lombard 
money-lenders  became  their  competitors,  the 
Jews  had  the  monopoly  of  nearly  all  the  credit 
transactions  that  could  not  be  brought  within 
the  letter  of  the  canon  law.  Communities  of 
lax  Christians,  like  the  traders  of  Genoa  and 
Cahors,  seemed  to  have  imperilled  their  ortho- 
doxy to  gain  similar  advantages. 

The  church  itself,  especially  in  the  later 
centuries,  found  reason  to  relax  its  prohibition 
of  usury  where  its  oum  material  interests  were 
seriously  involved.  The  sale  of  offices,  for 
example,  such  as  those  of  chamberlain  and 
treasurer  in  the  papal  court,  realised  a  higher 
price  wlien  purchasers  were  allowed  to  club 
together  to  bid  for  them  ;  the.  result  was, 
however,  that  many  of  those  joint  purchasers, 
who  had  no  intention  of  holding  the  offices 
themselves,  shared  in  the  revenues  in  a  way 
indistinguishable  from  the  receiving  of  interest 
on  capital  invested.  Again,  the  sale  of  land 
for  a  fixed  yearly  ground  rent  ("census  consigna- 
torius  "),  instead  of  a  sum  paid  down  once  for  all, 
was  conceded,  on  the  subterfuge  that,  not  the 
yearly  income,  but  the  right  to  the  yearly 
income  was  the  subject  matter  of  the  sale. 
Pius  V.  (in  the  16th  century)  decided  that 
such  arrangements  were  not  unlawful,  provided 
that  they  related  to  land  only,  and  were 
strictly  determined  by  the  actual  yearly  pro- 
duce of  it.  Had  he  decided  otherwise,  the 
revenues  of  large  numbers  of  religious  houses, 
especially  in  Germany,  would  have  been  seri- 
ously affected. 

But  in  the  toleration  of  the  "montes  pietatis" 
(which  date  from  the  15th  century),  both  the 
letter  and  the  spirit  of  the  older  canon  law  were 
violated.  These  institutions  were  formed  by 
the  joint  subscriptions  and  donations  of  phil- 
anthropic Christians ;  and  they  were  simply 
banks  which  advanced  money  to  the  poor  at 
interest.  This  interest  was  represented  as  simply 
a  "recompense"  for  the  trouble  of  managing 
the  institutions  that  advanced  the  money,  and 
thus  the  obnoxious  name  of  usury  was  avoided, 
though  the  fact  was  certainly  present.  Besides, 
the  "montes,"  to  attract  subscriptions,  gave 
interest  on  the  sums  subscribed,  and  thus  be- 
came simply  an  investment  for  capital.  There 
were  also  "montes  profani,"  secular  banks, 
Bi/unded  on  their  model,  but  without  their 
charitable  object,  and  dealing  with  ordinary 
men  of  business.     But  even  the  "montes  pro- 


214 


CANTALUPO— CANTILLON 


fani "  escaped  condemnation  ;  it  was  held  that 
they  were  of  service,  if  not  to  the  poor,  at  least 
to  the  public,  and  the  interest  they  gave  on 
investments  represented  a  Lucrum  Cessans,  or 
loss  which  the  investors  were  presumed  to  have 
incurred  by  withdrawing  their  money  from.trade 
and  putting  it  into  these  banks.  When  ' '  usury ' ' 
had  been  tolerated  in  the  case  of  these  societies, 
it  could  not  be  long  before  the  like  concession 
would  be  made  in  the  case  of  individuals  (see 
articles  Fathers,  The  ;  Monts  De  Pifex^.) 

[Corpus  Juris  Canonic,  ed.  E.  L.  Kichter,  large 
4to,  Leipzig  (Tauchnitz),  1839.  The  chief  passages 
relating  to  usury  begin  on  pp.  147  and  630.  In 
the  companion  volume  containiug  the  decretals  of 
Pope  Gregory  IX.,  etc.,  see  especially  pp.  782, 
1017,  1101.— The  edition  of  E.  Friedberg  is  con- 
sidered by  some  to  have  superseded  Richter's. — 
Die  Nationalokonomische  Gfrundsdtze  der  canonist- 
ischen  Lehre,  Dr.  W.  Endemann  (Jena),  1863,  the 
most  complete  monograph  on  this  subject. — Ge- 
schichte  der  National- Oekonomik  in  Deutschland 
(see  Einleitung),  W.  Roscher  (Miiuchen),  1874. — 
Geschichte  der  volkswirthschaftlichjen  Literatur  im 
Mittelalter,  Dr.  H.  Contzen  (Leipzig),  1869.  The 
same  aiithor  has  also  published  Zur  Wilrdigung 
des  Mittelalters  (Cassel),  1870,  and  De  Thomae 
Aquinatis  Sententiis  ad  Oecon.  Politicam  pertin- 
entibus  (Basel),  1861. — Das  deutsche  Genossen- 
schaftsrecht,  vol.  iii.  Staats-  und  Korporations- 
lehre  des  Alterthu7ns  und  des  Mittelalters.  Dr. 
Otto  Gierke  (Berlin),  1881.— Geschichte  und 
Kritik  der  Kapitalzinstheorieen  (oh.  ii. )  Dr.  Bbhm 
Bawerk  (Innsbruck)  1884. — Neue  Untersuchung 
der  Nat.  Oek.  und  der  natiirl.  Volkswirthschafts- 
ordnung,  J.  Schon  (Stuttgart),  1835. — Economia 
politica  del  medio  evo,  L.  Cibrario,  1839. — History 
and  Future  oj  Interest  and  Profit,  Cliffe  Leslie 
(Fortnightly  Review,  November  1881).  History  of 
Political  Economy,  J.  K.  Ingram  (London),  1888. 
Introduction  to  English  Economic  History  and 
Theory,  vol.  i. — {The  Middle  Ages),  W.  J.  Ashley 
(London  and  New  York),  1888.]  J.  b. 

CANTALUPO,  DoMENico,  a  Neapolitan, 
author  of  a  very  successful  essay  on  the  com 
trade,  published  in  1783  at  Palermo.  The 
third  edition  was  published  in  Nice  and  Genoa 
'in  1795,  and  the  fourth  edition  by  Custodi  in 
his  Economisti  classici  Italiani.  Cantalupo 
strenuously  recommends  free  trade,  full,  sure, 
and  equal  liberty  for  all,  and  traces  the  history 
of  corn  laws  from  the  times  of  King  Ladislaus 
(1400)  down  to  his  own  times  to  prove  the  bad 
effects  which  a  restrictive  system  always  pro- 
duced. M.  p. 

CANTILLON,  Philip,  author  of  ''The 
Analysis  of  Trade,  Commerce,  Coin,  Bullion, 
Banks,  and  Foreign  Exchanges:  .  .  .  Taken 
chiefly  from  a  Manuscript  of  a  very  ingenious 
Gentleman  deceas'd,  and  adapted  to  the  pre- 
sent situation  of  our  Trade  and  Commerce.  By 
Philip  Cantillon,  late  of  the  City  of  London, 
Merchant,  London,  1759."  215  pp.  8vo.  This 
Philip  was  the  eldest  son  of  James  CantiUon 
of  the  city  of  Limerick,  who  was  first  cousin 


of  Richard  Cantillon,  author  of  the  Essai  sui 
la  Nature  du  Commerce.  Philip  carried  on  a 
banking  business  with  David  Cantillon  at 
Wamford  Court,  Throgmorton  Street,  London, 
at  least  as  early  as  1725.  In  1738  he  was  t 
director  of  the  Royal  Exchange  Assurance :  in 
1742  became  bankrupt:  in  1747  was  trading 
alone  as  insurance  agent  and  policy  broker  :  in 
1753  was  partner  with  one  Thomas  Mannock 
in  the  same  business  :  and  in  1759  had  retired. 
He  married,  14th  July  1733,  Rebecca,  daughter 
of  William  Newland  of  Gatton,  Surrey,  by 
whom  he  had  two  daughters.  There  is  reason 
to  think  that  he  was  engaged  for  a  short  time 
at  Richard  Cantillon's  bank  in  Paris,  but  that 
his  litigious  character  made  him  unamiable  and 
brought  about  his  speedy  return.  On  the 
death  of  Richard,  Philip  intervened  in  the 
management  of  his  estate,  and  thus  obtained 
possession  of  several  papers,  including  probably 
the  English  manuscript  of  the  Essay,  which 
professedly  served  as  the  groundwork  of  the 
Analysis  of  Trade.  He  must,  however,  have 
mutilated  the  manuscript  almost  beyond  re- 
cognition. Much  of  the  closely  packed  original 
is  omitted,  and  much  is  replaced  by  vague  and 
general  summaries,  most  unskilfully  made, 
with  the  result  that  little  indeed  of  the  Analysis 
fairly  represents  the  views  of  Richard  Cantillon. 
Philip  added  a  preface  on  the  history  and 
importance  of  commerce,  some  strictures  upon 
close  corporations,  new  matter  on  inland  and 
foreign  trade,  bankers  and  banks,  and  exchanges, 
interspersed  with  quotations  from  Hume's 
Essays,  and  from  The  Universal  Merchant,  etc. 
(see  N.  Magens),  concluding  with  a  criticism 
of  the  law  relating  to  bills  of  exchange. 

The  book  was  reviewed  in  the  Monthly  Review 
or  Literary  Journal  for  April  1759,  London, 
vol.  XX.  309.  Sir  James  Steuabt  (Works,  ed.  1805, 
iii.  22)  says,  "Mr.  Cantillon,  in  his  Analysis  of 
Trade,  which  I  suppose  he  understood  by  practice 
as  well  as  by  theory,  has  the  following  passage,"  etc. 

"A  small  treatise  of  Arithmetic,"  explaining 
the  foreign  exchanges  "  vulgarly  and  decimally " 
without  "  unintelligible  jargon,"  was  designed  by 
the  author  of  the  Analysis  (p.  85),  but  does  not 
seem  to  have  ever  been  published.  h.  h. 

CANTILLON,  Richard.  The  economic 
repute  of  Cantillon,  for  a  time  completely 
obscured  by  the  glory  of  Adam  Smith,  can 
never  have  rested  upon  the  popularity  of  his 
little  book,  now  one  of  the  scarcest  works  in 
economic  literature.  For  Gournay  had  to 
exercise  his  great  personal  influence  to  persuade 
his  disciples  not  to  neglect  it  as  others  were 
doing.  And  the  elder  Mirabeau,  himself  an 
adept  in  the  craft  of  popular  writing,  deplores, 
and  accounts  for,  the  failure  of  the  book  as  due 
to  the  defects  of  its  style  and  the  aridity  of  its 
subject.  The  perverted  Analysis  of  Trade 
(see  Philip  Cantillon),  sometimes  confused 
with  it,  probably  conduced  to  its  disrepute. 
On  the  other  hand  it  was  thought  worth  while 


CANTILLON 


215 


to  reprint  it  at  least  twice  within  a  year  of  its 
publication.  And  the  references  to  it  in  so 
widely-read  a  book  as  L' Ami  des  Rommes  must 
have  made  known  the  name  of  Cantillon  to 
many  who  never  saw  his  JEssai. 

The  influence  of  the  book  is  evidenced  not  by 
the  number  but  by  the  distinction  of  its  students, 
including  Gournay,  Quesnay,  Mirabeau,  Tur.- 
GOT,  and  Adam  Smith.  It  gave  birth  to  Mira- 
beau's  L'Ami  des  Hommes  and  apparently  sug- 
gested much  of  the  Tableau  CEconomique  of 
Quesnay  and  parts  of  the  Wealth  of  Nations. 
It  was,  however — perhaps  because  of  its  con- 
cise style — much  misrepresented  and  misunder- 
stood. Cantillon  avoided,  as  Jevons  has  pointed 
out,  the  one-sidedness  of  the  Physiocrats  ;  and 
yet  has  been  marked  out  as  a  Physiocrat.  He 
was  declared  by  Mirabeau  to  hold  the  doctrine 
that  population  is  the  source  of  riches,  though, 
in  Jevons's  opinion  again,  he  anticipated  in 
condensed  form  the  celebrated  essay  of  Malthus. 
And  Adam  Smith  loftily  imputed  to  him  an 
attempt  to  form  exact  estimates  in  matters 
where  Cantillon  expressly  disclaimed  any  such 
pretension. 

The  importance  of  the  book  in  the  history  of 
the  development  of  economic  science  may  be 
best  indicated  by  a  short  analysis  of  its  con- 
tents. It  consists  of  three  parts.  Part  I. 
opens  by  delining  Wealth  and  resolving  it 
into  the  elements  Land  and  Labouh,  explains 
the  ** natural"  formation  of  societies  and  social 
classes,  villages,  towns,  cities,  and  capitals  ; 
the  "natural  "  variations  of  Wages  in  dilFerent 
employments  (due  to  time,  expense  and  difficulty 
of  learning,  risk  in  Avork,  capacity  and  trust 
required) ;  the  "natural  "  adjustment  of  Supply 
of  labour  to  Demand  ;  contrast  between  real  or 
intrinsic  (normal)  value,  and  market  value — 
the  first  depending  upon  cost  of  production,  the 
second  upon  supply  and  demand  ;  the  equation 
between  land  and  labour ;  the  minimum  wage 
for  family  maintenance  :  the  difl'usion  of  wealth 
through  the  agency  of  the  landed  classes  ;  con- 
duct of  European  commerce  by  employers  at  a 
venture  (robbers,  beggars,  artists,  lawyers,  etc. , 
employers  of  their  own  labour) ;  wages  certain, 
profits  uncertain ;  changes  of  demand  (Fashion); 
population  adjusts  itself  to  the  means  of  sub- 
sistence ;  labour  the  "natural"  riches  of  a 
state  :  gold  and  silver  convenient  for  money 
because  useful,  beautiful,  durable,  portable, 
divisible,  easily  transported  and  guarded, 
cognoscible,  indestructible  by  fire,  of  equal 
goodness,  not  too  cheaply  produced,  etc. 

Part  II.  treats  of  Barter  ;  market  prices  ; 
circulation  of  money  in  mass  and  rapidity  ; 
how  much  money  does  a  country  require  ? 
increased  and  decreased  currency ;  effects  of 
appreciation  on  fixed  contracts  and  wages ; 
Credit  ;  Interest,  its  causes,  rise  and  .fall  of 
rate,  not  dependent  upon  scarcity  or  abundance 
of  money. 


Part  III.  deals  with  foreign  trade  ;  Foreign 
Exchanges  ;  variations  in  relative  value  of 
monetary  metals ;  alterations  of  coinage ; 
Banks  ;  national  banks  ;  reserves  ;  guarantees ; 
banking  and  credit. 

The  lost  supplement  included  a  precise  and 
comparative  account  of  the  economic  condition 
of  the  workmen  of  Europe  as  reflected  in  their 
expenses — much,  apparently,  upon  the  lines  of 
Le  Play's  great  work  exactly  one  hundred  years 
later  {Les  Ouvriers  Europeens,  1855).  It  de- 
scribed the  actual  diffusion  of  a  large  income  ; 
minutely  analysed  the  cost  of  production  of 
certain  articles  through  their  several  com- 
ponent elements,  etc.  etc. 

The  execution  of  this  ample  programme  is  no 
less  remarkable  than  its  conceittion.  Jevons 
thought  Cantillon  wrote  "with  the  scientific 
precision  of  a  Cairnes  or  a  Cournot,"  and  Prof. 
Marshall  refers  to  his  "thoroughly  scientific 
manner  "  of  discussion  (Frin.  vol.  i.  p.  593  n.) 
At  once  terse  and  subtle,  he  united  close  observa- 
tion of  concrete  fact  with  keen  detluctive  power. 
To  consumption  and  demand  he  assigned  an 
importance  not  generally  recognised  till  much 
later.  And  his  beautiful  examples  of  accurate 
reasoning  were  rendered  tedious  to  his  contem- 
poraries by  very  reason  of  his  careful  limitations 
and  guarded  hypotheses.  The  indirect  influence 
of  the  book  is  difficult  to  trace.  In  France  the 
Bssai  has  been  pretty  continuously  read  (see 
e.g.  Ganilh,  Des  Systemes  d'^lconomie  Politique^ 
2ded.  1821,  vol.  i.  pp.  xv.  134  ;  vol.  ii.  p.  107), 
and  so  stimulating  and  suggestive  does  it  remain 
that  its  direct  influence  may  be  found  to  be  not 
yet  exhausted. 

Essai  sv/r  la  Nature  du  Commerce  en  gineral 
traduit  de  Vanglois.  X  Londres,  chez  Fletcher 
Gyles  ;  dans  Holborn,  M.DGG.L  V.  (being  reprinted 
for  Harvard  University,  1891).  H.  H. 

Cantillon  enunciates  most  of  the  leading 
principles  of  political  economy  relating  to 
supply  and  demand,  normal  value,  the  role 
of  the  Entrepreneur,  population,  currency, 
banking,  and  other  important  subjects.  But  it 
Avill  be  found  that  the  statements  often  involve 
ideas  peculiar  to  the  writer,  or  the  age  ;  in  par- 
ticular, his  difficult  definition  of  value  as 
regulated  by  quantity  of  land  as  well  as  of 
labour.  The  similarities  between  Cantillon's 
views  and  those  now  received  are  not  more 
instructive  than  the  differences.  A  full  analysis 
of  Cantillon's  work,  and  an  extreme  estimate 
of  its  importance,  will  be  found  in  Jevons's 
article  on  "Richard  Cantillon  ;ind  the  Nation- 
ality of  Political  Economy,"  in  tlie  Contemporary 
Review,  1881.  In  Investigations  in  Currency 
and  Finance,  Jevons  discusses  Cantillon's  re- 
marks with  respect  to  the  statement  on  the 
ratio  between  gold  and  silver  made  by  Newton. 

F.  Y.  e. 

It  has  been  a  matter  of  some  difficulty  to 
explain  the  connection  of  Richard  Cantillon's 


216 


CANTILLON 


Essai  with  Paris,  where  it  was  published,  and 
the  influence  it  had  on  contemporary  French 
economic  thought.  The  following  additional 
particulars  respecting  his  life  may  assist  in 
the  elucidation  of  these  points. 

1.  TJie  Life  of  Cantillon. — One  Richard  Can- 
tillon,  probably  a  cousin  of  the  economist,  is 
described  in  some  documents  in  the  Archives 
Nationales,  at  Paris  (E  804,  p.  157  ;  E  913, 
p.  253,  and  E  1948,  fol.  98),  under  dates  1706, 
1709,  and  1718,  as  a  merchant  and  banker  at 
Paris,  Rue  de  I'arbre  sec.  Among  his  customers 
were  Irish  Catholics,  and  he  was  "Receveur 
general  de  la  lotterie  accordee  a  la  Princesse 
d'Angleterre  en  faveur  des  religieuses  Irlandaises 
transferees  h.  Ypres."  In  August  1717,  the 
ticketholders  in  that  lottery  petitioned  to  have 
their  claims  settled,  the  deceased  Richard  Can- 
tillon (E  918,  No.  253),  having  left  only  68,200 
livres  of  assets,  and  310,000  livres  of  liabilities. 
Another  document  (Y.  11080)  states  that  after 
the  decease  of  one  Thomas  Cantillon,  an  Irish- 
man, officer  in  the  regiment  of  Lally,  in  1764, 
his  brother  Jean  and  his  father  Philippe  Can- 
tillon claimed  to  be  his  heirs. 

The  will  of  Richard  Cantillon,  of  St.  George's, 
Hanover  Square  (the  economist)  (Somerset  House, 
dated  the  12th  July  1732,  and  proved  the  21st 
May  1735),  shows  that  he  had  bought  a  house 
in  I'aris  through  the  intervention  of  Edmund 
Gough,  and  he  names  Francis  Gar  van  and  Lord 
Viscount  Micklethwaite  (died  1734)  as  his  ex- 
ecutors. Another  point  relating  to  Cantillon's 
position  is  mentioned  by  Horace  Walpole,  who 
writes  25th  April  1743,  to  Sir  H.  Mann: 
"Lord  Stafford  is  come  over  to  marry  Miss 
Cantillon,  a  vast  fortune,  of  his  own  religion. 
She  is  daughter  of  the  Cantillon  who  was  robbed 
and  murdered,  and  had  his  house  burned  by 
his  cook  a  few  years  ago"  [1734]  {The  Letters 
of  Horace  Walpole,  Earl  of  Orford,  ed.  by  Peter 
Cunningham,  1857,  vol.  i.  pp.  241,  242,  298, 
and  the  works  of  Jonathan  Swift,  ed.  by  Sir  W. 
Scott,  1824,  vol.  xvi.  p.  262,  263). 

2.  His  WorTcs. — There  are  three  editions  of 
the  Essai  sur  la  nature  du  commerce  en  g6n6ral ; 
one  of  1755,  430  pp.  besides  table  des  chapitres  ; 
one  of  1756,  427  pp.  and  that  of  1756  in  the 
Discours  Politiques  de  Mr.  David  Hume,  traduits 
de  I'Anglois  par  M.  de  M.,  Amsterdam,  vol.  iii. 
pp.  153-428,  1766.  It  is  significant  that 
Turgot's  translation  of  Josiah  Tucker's  Re- 
flections on  the  Expediency  of  a  Law  for  the 
Naturalisation  of  Foreign  Protestants,  1751-52 
{Questions  importantes  sur  le  Commerce  d  Voc- 
casion  des  oppositions  au  dernier  Bill  de  Na- 
turalisation, etc.),  ^  bears  the  name  of  the 
same  publisher:  A  Londres,  chez  Fletcher 
Gyles,  dans  Holborn,  1755.  That  Goumay 
studied  Cantillon  is  clear,  for  of  Gournay  it  is 
said  that  "il  fit  surtout  lire  beaucoup  I' Essai 
sur  le  commerce  en  g4n6raly  par  Cantillon, 
Duvrage  excellent  qu'on  negligeait "  {Memoires 


inAdits  de  VAhU  Morellet,  t.  i.  pp.  37,  38, 
1823).  The  work  was  highly  praised  by  Mably, 
Entretiens  de  Fhocion,  p.  239,  1763;  and  by 
Graslin,  Essai  analytique  sur  la  Fichesse  et  sur 
I'impdt,  Londres,  p.  365,  1767.  The  most  de- 
tailed account  of  its  origin  has  been  given  by 
the  Marquis  of  Mirabeau  in  his  Ami  des 
Hommes,  vol.  i.  1756.  He  holds  CantiUon  to 
be  a  Protestant  (p.  58V  professes  to  have 
adopted  all  his  principles  (p.  78),  and  frequently 
quotes  passages  of  the  Essai  (pp.  34,  108,  115, 
116,  171,  206).  The  seventh  chapter  too 
opens  with  a  quotation  and  is  followed  by  some 
details  concerning  its  author.  "He  was,"  says 
Mirabeau,  "without  contradiction,  the  most 
clever  man  in  these  matters  who  ever  existed. 
This  work,  one  of  a  crowd  of  similar  productions 
of  the  description  then  in  fashion,  is  but  the 
hundredth  part  of  the  writings  of  that  ingenious 
man,  which  perished  with  him  by  a  catastrophe 
both  jsingular  and  fatal.  This  work  itself  is 
mutilated,  for  the  supplement  to  which  he  often 
refers,  and  in  which  he  had  established  all  his 
calculations,  is  wanting.  Cantillon  himself  had 
translated  the  first  part  for  the  use  of  one  of 
his  friends,  and  it  was  printed  from  this  manu- 
script more  than  twenty  years  after  the  author's 
death"  (pp.  237-239).  In  1767  Mirabeau,  ex- 
pounding to  RotrssEAU  the  ideas  of  the  econo- 
mists upon  the  subject  of  population,  and 
refuting  his  own  former  opinions,  contained  in 
the  Ami  des  Hommes,  says,  he  had  borrowed 
them  exclusively  from  Cantillon,  "whose  work 
I  had  had  since  sixteen  years  in  manuscript " 
{i.e.  1740).  See  also  his  Fhilosophie  Fur  ale, 
Amsterdam,  1764,  t.  ii.  ch.  ix.  pp.  141,  142. 
Mirabeau  was  shaken  in  his  belief  by  Quesnay, 
who  denied  population  to  be  the  source  of 
riches,  and  said  "that  Cantillon,  as  a  political 
instructor,  was  a  fool "  (see  Fousseau  Ses  amis 
et  ses  ennemis,  correspondance  publiee,  par  M.G. 
Streckeisen-Moulton,  t.  ii.  p.  358,  1865).  A 
rough  MS.  abridgement  of  Cantillon's  Essai,  of 
Mirabeau's  own  making,  is  among  the  "  Papiers 
Mirabeau,"  at  the  Archives  Rationales  at  Paris 
(M  779,  No.  1).  It  contains  a  dedication 
"A.M.1.D.D.K,"  no  doubt  the  Duke  of 
Noailles,  "under  whose  auspices  he  had  studied 
that  part  of  politics  which  is  based  on  '  imagina- 
tion '  (obviously  contrasting  this  with  '  Science ' 
Calcul),  and  who  had  charged  him  never  to 
forget  that  other  part  of  the  subject  which  de- 
pends upon  calculation,  and  is  included  in  the 
general  name  of  commerce  ;  if  these  matters  are 
not  studied  from  the  very  bottom,  if  their  basis 
is  not  well  laid,  they  incur  the  risk  of  being  as 
frivolous  and  useless  as  many  other  essays  on 
commerce."  The  essay  which  follows  bears  al] 
the  marks  of  revision  by  Mirabeau  ;  it  begins 
with  what  is  p.  56  of  the  printed  copy,  but 
contains  some  passages,  especially  the  introduc- 
tory ones  of  the  chapters,  in  addition  to  those 
contained  in  the  printed  book. 


CAPELLO— CAPITAL 


217 


Cantillon's  opinions  were  based  on  the  econo- 
mics of  the  commercialist  school,  and  of  some 
of  his  English  physiocratic  predecessors.  The 
"equation  between  land  and  labour,"  which 
he  quotes  from  Petty,  is  contained  in  the  latter's 
Political  Jnatomy  of  Ireland^  ch.  ix.  1691  (see 
Tracts,  chiefly  relating  to  Ireland,  p.  344,  Dub- 
lin, 1769).  Like  Adam  Smith  at  a  later  epoch 
Cantillon  combined  the  theoretical  reasoning 
of  the  English  with  the  systematic  turn  of  the 
French,  thereby  promoting  the  economics  of 
both  countries. 

[With  Cantillon's  view  of  the  tlieory  of  rents 
compare  J.  Arbuthnot,  An  Inquiry  into  the  Con- 
nection between  the  present  Price  of  Provisions  and 
the  Size  of  Farms,  p.  34,  1773. — Arthur  Young, 
Political  Arithmetick,  2d  part,  p.  29,  1779,  and 
Alex.  Wedderbiirn  of  St.  Gerniains,  Essay  upon  the 
Question  What  Proportion  of  the  Produce  of 
Arable  Land  ought  to  be  paid  as  Pent  to  the  Land- 
lordl  p.  4,  Edinburgh,  1776.  For  Cantillon's 
part  in  economics  see  Dr.  Bauer's  remarks 
in  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  1890,  vol.  v. 
No.  1,  p.  102,  and  Dr.  Bauer's  article  on  the 
Physiocrats  in  Conrad's  Jahrbucher  fur  National- 
ohonomie  und  Staiistik,  Bd.  xxi.  H.  2  N.F,,  p.  145. 
— F.  von  Sivers,  ibid.  Bd.  xxii.  158.— Prof.  Mar- 
shall, Principles  of  Economics,  1890,  vol.  i.  p. 
63n. — H.  Higgs,  Economic  Journal,  vol.  i.  No. 
2,  p.  262.]  8.  B. 

CAPELLO,  Pier  Andrea,  author  of  a  book 
having  the  title  Nuovo  trattato  del  modo  di  re- 
golare  lamoneta,  published  1752  at  A^cnice,  and 
containing  an  analysis  of  the  terms  "  value  " 
and  "price,"  for  which  it  is  still  noticed  in 
books  of  dogmatic  liistory.  m.  p. 

CAPITAINERIE.  A  privilege  granted  in 
France  by  the  king,  down  to  the  time  of  the 
Revolution,  to  princes  of  the  blood,  by  which 
they  obtained  possession  of  the  property  of  all 
game,  even  on  lands  not  belonging  to  them  ; 
including  manors  granted  before  to  individuals  ; 
so  that  the  erecting  of  a  district  into  a  capitain- 
erie,  was  an  annihilation  of  all  manorial  rights 
to  game  within  it.  Arthur  Young,  Travels  in 
France,  2d  ed.  vol.  i.  p.  600,  says  "in  speaking 
of  the  preservation  of  the  game  in  these  capi- 
taineries,  it  must  be  observed,  that  by  game  must 
be  understood  whole  droves  of  Avild  boars,  and 
herds  of  deer  not  confined  by  any  wall  or  pale, 
but  wandering,  at  pleasure,  over  the  whole 
country  to  the  destruction  of  crops  ;  and  to  the 
peopling  of  the  gallies  by  the  wretched  peasants, 
who  presumed  to  kill  them,  in  order  to  save 
that  food  which  was  to  support  their  helpless 
children. "  The  capitaineries  were  only  one  form 
of  the  oppressions  of  the  seigneurs,  which  will 
be  found  described  in  considerable  detail  by 
A.  Young. 

CAPITAL.  Definitions  in  political  economy 
present  great  difficulties  owing  partly  to  the  fact 
that  the  words  employed  are  in  general  drawn 
from  ordinary  language,  and  partly  because  the 
fundamental    ideas   often   overlap,    and    it  is 


necessary  to  leave  a  debatable  margin.  There 
is  probably  no  term  in  economics  which  has 
given  rise  to  so  much  controversy  as  capital, 
and  in  the  limits  of  this  article  it  will  only  be 
possible  to  indicate  the  main  points  in  dispute, 
and  their  bearing  upon  fundamental  questions. 
As  usual  the  historical  aspect  of  the  subject  has 
been  treated  most  fully  by  German  writers 
(compare  the  masterly  introduction  of  Knies  to 
his  work  on  Money  and  Credit  (Geld  und  Credit)  ; 
Kapital  und  Kapital-Zins  by  Bohm-Bawerk  ; 
and  the  article  on  "Capital"  in  Schonberg's 
Randhuch).  The  Avord  capital  is  connected 
with  caput,  and  in  mediaeval  Latin  we  read 
constantly  of  the  capitalis  pars  dchiti,  i.e.  the 
principal  sum  as  distinct  from  the  interest. 
Thus  originally  the  term  seems  to  have  been 
confined  to  loans  of  money.  As  tlie  chm-ch 
forbade  the  lending  of  money  for  interest  oi 
usury  (Interest  and  Usury),  and  as  this 
moral  prohibition  was  generally  given  effect  to 
by  the  law,  all  sorts  of  devices  were  resorted  to 
in  order  to  disguise  the  real  nature  of  a  loan 
(see  Canon  Law).  A  thing  was  nominally 
bought  by  the  borrower  to  be  sold  back  after  a 
time  at  a  lower  price  to  the  lender  (a  dry  bar- 
gain as  it  was  termed),  and  gradually  exce])tions 
were  admitted  on  the  ground  of  wear  and  tear 
of  the  thing  lent  or  indirect  loss  to  the  lender. 
In  England  before  the  time  of  the  Tudors 
(compare  Schanz,  op.  cit.  infra)  it  had  become 
generally  recognised  by  merchants  and  legis- 
lators that  it  was  impossible  to  distinguish 
between  lending  money  itself  and  lending  the 
things  which  had  a  money  value.  Thus  in  the 
natural  course  of  historical  development  the 
term  capital  received  a  Avider  meaning.  Accord- 
ingly later  on  we  find  Turcot,  as  Knies  points 
out,  expressly  saying  that  capital  consists  of 
accumulated  values  (yaleurs  accumulees),  and 
that  it  makes  no  difference  whether  tlic  accumu- 
lations consist  of  precious  metals  or  of  other 
things.  Turgot  states  also  that  a  man  can  live 
on  capital,  or  rather  the  interest  of  capital,  just 
as  well  as  from  personal  labour  or  from  funds 
derived  from  possession  of  lands.  Thus  capital 
is  considered  primarily  as  a  source  of  profit. 
This  historical  usage  of  the  term  capital  is  still 
found  implied  in  ordinary  thought,  and  a 
Socratic  inquiry  on  the  modern  mercantile 
mind  would  probably  give  as  a  first- fruit  that 
capital  is  (1)  wealth  which  yields  a  revenue. 

It  is  quite  obvious,  however,  as  the  writers 
on  canon  law  were  so  fond  of  pointing  out, 
that  the  precious  metals  are  in  themselves 
barren  (nummus  numrtium  par  ere  non  potest), 
and  it  is  almost  as  obvious  that  any  form  of 
hoarded  wealth  is  equally  barren,  that  is  to 
say  unless  it  is  actively  employed  so  as  to 
produce  more  wealth.  In  the  earlier  stages  of 
agricultural  development,  for  example,  it  is 
quite  common  to  find  that  the  stock  is  let  with 
the  land  (and  the  custom  still  survives  in  the 


218 


CAPITAL 


mitayer  system),  but  unless  the  stock  were  used 
for  productive  purposes  it  could  not  possibly 
yield  a  revenue.  It  may  further  be  noticed 
that  although  one  private  person  may  lend  to 
another  capital  which  may  be  used  unjjroduc- 
tively  (e.g.  money  lent  on  mortgage)  and, the 
interest  of  which  may  still  be  paid  punctually, 
it  would  be  impossible  for  a  whole  nation 
(apart  from  lending  to  foreigners)  to  subsist 
on  this  barren  use  of  capital.  So  much  has 
this  consideration  impressed  itself  upon  econo- 
mists that  many  of  them,  especially  English 
wi'iters,  have  given  as  the  root  idea  of  capital 
(2)  that  pai't  of  wealth  set  aside  for  future  pro- 
duction (see  Abstinence).  This,  for  instance, 
is  Mill's  view  to  the  exclusion  of  the  older 
notion  of  revenue  simply.  Mill  indeed  makes 
the  idea  of  production  fundamental  even  in  the 
case  of  individuals,  and  would  only  include  in 
a  man's  capital  that  part  of  his  wealth  intended 
to  be  used  in  producing  more  Wealth. 

A  little  reflection,  however,  will  show  that 
either  the  meaning  of  production  must  be 
strained,  or  else  the  definition  of  capital  thus 
obtained  will  be  much  more  narrow  than  in 
the  popular  acceptation.  In  estimating,  for 
example,  the  accumulations  of  capital  in  the 
United  Kingdom  in  recent  years  Sir  R.  Giffen 
{Essays  on  Finance,  vol.  i.)  takes  into  account 
the  movables,  furniture,  pictures,  etc.,  in  private 
houses,  and  roughly  surmises  that  they  amount 
to  about  half  the  value  of  the  houses  them- 
selves, and  although  in  a  certain  sense  the  term 
• '  productive  "  might  be  stretched  to  cover  houses, 
it  could  hardly  be  made  to  cover  pictures  and 
ornaments.  As  the  result  of  this  line  of 
criticism  some  writers  (notably  Knies)  have 
made  the  fundamental  idea  in  capital  to  be 
"wealth  intended  directly  or  indirectly  to 
satisfy  future  needs."  If  a  fair  allowance  be 
made  for  Adam  Smith's  want  of  scientific  and 
technical  phraseology  his  views  on  the  funda- 
mental nature  of  capital  (or  stock  as  he  prefers 
to  call  it)  come  very  near  to  this  exposition. 
For  Adam  Smith  carefully  distinguishes  be- 
tween the  wealth  that  is  immediately  consumed 
and  the  stock  that  is  reserved  or  set  aside  out 
of  a  possible  surplus.  It  is  instructive  to  note 
that  Adam  Smith,  in  order  to  emphasise  the 
distinction  between  Income  and  its  source,  or, 
in  other  words,  between  immediate  consump- 
tion and  capital,  gives  a  very  wide  and  unusual 
meaning  to  the  term  immediate.  "A  stock  of 
clothes  may  last  several  years ;  a  stock  of 
furniture  half  a  century  or  a  century  ;  but  a 
stock  of  houses,  well  built  and  properly  taken 
care  of,  may  last  many  centuries.  Though  the 
period  of  their  total  consumption,  however,  is 
more  distant,  they  are  stiU  as  really  a  stock 
reserved  for  immediate  consumption  as  either 
clothes  or  household  furniture."  In  spite  of 
the  authority  of  Adam  Smith,  however,  it  may 
be  questioned  if  it  is  advisable  to  give  to  the 


term  immediate  such  a  paradoxical  interpreta- 
tion, and  to  exclude  houses  and  the  like  from 
the  capital  of  a  country.  A  man,  it  may  be 
argued,  might  well  choose  between  living  up  to 
his  income  and  saving  so  much  a  year  in  order 
to  build  a  house  for  himself,  and  when  once 
the  house  was  built  it  would  appear  to  form  a 
part  of  the  capital  not  only  of  the  individual 
but  of  the  nation.  In  fact,  on  analysis  it  seems 
that  we  ought  to  distinguish  between  immediate 
(in  the  more  usual  sense  of  the  term)  and  de- 
ferred Consumption.  Even  from  this  point  of 
view,  however,  it  is  impossible  to  take  the  term 
"immediate"  too  strictly,  and  it  seems  best  to 
construe  it  relatively  to  the  kind  of  income. 
The  immediate  consumption  of  a  labourei 
earning  weekly  wages  might  be  embraced 
within  the  week,  whilst  in  the  case  of  a  high- 
salaried  official  a  year  might  be  taken  as  the 
unit,  and  in  the  case  of  a  great  nation  spend- 
ing money  on  armaments,  etc.,  the  term  might 
be  extended  for  some  years.  But  even  in  this 
last  example  there  is  still  a  plain  diflFerence 
between  building  forts  or  strategic  railways 
which  are  supposed  to  last  for  centuries,  and 
providing  for  present  wants  by  the  personal 
equipment  of  soldiers.  Practically  it  is  of 
course  always  difficult  to  know  how  much  may 
be  fairly  charged  to  capital  account,  and  how 
much  ought  to  be  reckoned  as  part  of  immediate 
consumption.  Logically,  however,  the  distinc- 
tion seems  clear  enough,  and  it  has  given  rise 
to  that  description  of  capital  (3)  called  by 
the  Germans  especially  consumption  capital. 
The  principal  difficulty  in  this  conception  of 
capital  is  that,  in  the  language  of  one  of  Mill's 
"four  fundamental  propositions  on  capital," 
aU  capital  is  consumed,  which,  in  the  sense  that 
nothing  lasts  for  ever,  is  obviously  true.  Yet, 
even  the  schoolboy  who  decides  between  a  tin- 
whistle  and  a  penny  pie,  knows  that  the  rate 
of  consumption  in  the  latter  case  is  infinitely 
quicker  than  in  the  former,  and  it  may  be  said 
that  if  he  eats  the  tart  he  is  only  an  unpro- 
ductive consumer,  whilst  if  he  buys  the  whistle 
he  is  a  small  owner  of  consumption  capital. 
And,  in  fact,  Mill's  object  in  this  proposition 
appears  to  have  been  rather  to  emphasise  the 
distinction  between  hoarding  (the  wealth  not 
being  productively  consumed)  and  saving  (the 
wealth  being  used  as  productive  capital),  (see 
Abstinence). 

So  far  then  the  result  of  the  investigation  on 
the  connotation  pf  the  term  capital  appears  to 
be  that  there  are  three  species  of  capital  in  each 
of  which  a  different  quality  is  emphasised, 
accordingly  as  we  consider  (1)  the  yield  of 
a  revenue,  (2)  the  production  of  more  wealth, 
(3)  the  reservation  of  means  for  future  enjoy- 
ment.  It  remains  then  to  consider  whether 
there  is  not  some  root-idea  from  which  these 
three  branches  spring.  The  line  of  thought 
suggested  by  Adam  Smith  and  developed  by 


CAPITAL 


219 


Knies  is  found  to  lead  to  this  result : — Capital 
is  wealth  set  aside  for  the  satisfaction — directly 
or  indirectly — of  future  needs.  This  satisfaction 
may  be  obtained  by  the  individual  by  lending 
his  wealth  at  "usury" — "usury  of  money, 
usury  of  victuals,  usury  of  anything  that  is 
lent  upon  usury  " — or  by  reserving  means  for 
future  production  as  in  the  case  of  the  husband- 
man and  his  corn  or  cattle,  or  by  laying  up  for 
himself  a  treasure  which  will  be  a  delight  for 
many  days. 

In  the  different  departments  of  political 
economy  the  stress  is  laid  in  general  on  one 
of  these  three  characteristics  to  the  exclusion  of 
the  other  two.  In  the  department  of  pro- 
duction, for  example,  as  the  very  name  implies, 
capital  is  regarded  almost  entirely  as  one  of  the 
principal  agents  in  production,  as  sustaining 
or  auxiliary  to  labour.  Logically,  it  is  not 
necessary  to  consider  at  this  stage  how  the 
product  is  divided,  or  even  that  it  is  intended 
for  future  or  immediate  consumption.  But  in 
the  departments  of  distribution  and  exchange, 
the  characteristic  of  yielding  profit  or  revenue 
is  fundamental,  whilst  in  taxation  several  ques- 
tions of  importance  spring  from  the  distinc- 
tion involved  in  consumption  capital. 

The  principal  points  of  fundamental  imjiort- 
ance  in  the  qualitative  definition  have  now  been 
considered,  but  there  are  several  minor  questions 
which  have  given  rise  to  much  controversy. 
(1)  Is  all  capital  the  result  of  labour,  and  ought 
we  to  exclude  the  forces  and  free  gifts  of  nature  ? 
The  answer,  as  in  all  questions  of  definition, 
must  depend  purely  on  the  convenience  of 
the  classification  for  the  subject  or  problem 
in  hand.  In  the  department  of  Phoductiox 
it  is  often  necessary  to  contrast  capital  in 
the  sense  of  accumulations  due  to  labour  (fest- 
geronnene  Arhcit-Zeit  as  the  German  socialists 
phrase  it)  and  ' '  the  natural  and  indestructible 
powers  of  the  soil "  of  Ricardo,  as,  for  example, 
that  no  exception  may  be  taken  to  the  language, 
advantages  of  situation.  In  the  department  of 
Distribution,  again,  stress  is  often  laid  on 
analogies  between  the  limitation  of  natural 
sources  of  supply  (and  the  consequent  Uneaiined 
Increment)  and  the  ordinary  forms  of  capital, 
which  with  sufiScient  labour  are  capable  of 
indefinite  extension  at  an  ordinary  rate  of 
profit.  On  the  other  hand,  however,  it  is 
extremely  difficult  practically  to  draw  the  line 
between  the  gifts  of  nature  and  the  results 
of  labour,  and  between  earned  and  unearned 
increments.  Even  sheep  farms  in  mountain 
districts  require  a  certain  amount  of  surface 
drainage,  fencing,  etc.,  and  once  the  necessary 
labour  has  been  bestowed,  it  is  hard  to  tell 
how  much  is  due  to  man,  and  how  much  to 
nature.  If  we  consider  the  question  from  the 
national  point  of  view,  and  take,  as  is  natural 
with  a  nation,  long  periods,  the  labour  in 
the  mere  appropriation  or  first  occupancy  of  the 


natural  sources  will  be  found  to  be  considerable. 
Compare  for  example  the  condition  of  England 
before  the  invasion  of  the  Romans  and  during 
the  Roman  occupation,  or  mediaeval  England 
with  the  England  of  to-day.  Rivers  have  been 
diverted,  extensive  forests  cleared,  swamps  and 
marshes  drained,  and  natural  harbours  im- 
proved and  protected.  Thus  even  in  pro- 
duction it  would  not  seem  unreasonable  to 
include  these  so-called  natural  sources,  in  order 
to  emphasise  the  fact  that  they  can  only  be 
made  available,  as  with  other  forms  of  capital, 
by  the  labour  and  ingenuity  of  man.  And 
although  this  admission  is  made,  it  would  still 
be  possible  to  discuss  Adam  Smith's  favourite 
position  that  in  some  things,  notably  agricul- 
ture, nature  labours  with  man  to  a  greater 
extent  than  in  others,  e.g.  the  manufacture 
of  scientific  instruments  of  gi-eat  delicacy. 
It  may  be  observed  that  in  estimates  of 
national  capital,  such  as  that  made  by  Mr. 
Giften,  not  only  is  land  included,  but  it  stands 
first  on  the  list  in  order  of  importance.  It 
is  obvious  also  that  the  capital  value  of  land 
would  certainly  include  from  the  practical 
standpoint  the  minerals,  etc.  not  yet  ex- 
tracted, as  well  as  the  value  due  merely  to 
such  a  quality  as  situation.  Logically,  any 
difficulty  may  be  technically  overcome  by 
speaking  (with  Held)  of  the  "labour  oi 
appropriation,"  especially  if  we  take  into 
account  the  contribution  made  by  the  state 
as  such  to  the  organisation  and  secmity  of 
labour.  (2)  A  second  controversy  has  arisen 
on  the  question  on  which  Mill  lays  such 
stress,  namely: — "Z>oe.s  the  distinction  hetweoi 
capital  and  non-capital  depend  on  the  intention 
of  the  cajntalist,  or  in  other  words,  the  owiur  of 
the  potential  capital  ?"  If  the  answer  be  in 
the  affirmative,  we  are  confronted  with  the 
difficulty  from  the  point  of  view  of  the 
individual,  that  the  same  thing  would  at  one 
time — even  on  the  same  day — be  considered 
capital,  and  at  another  non-capital.  Thus 
Professor  Marshall  in  the  Economics  of  Industry, 
argues  that  a  doctor's  carriage  Avlien  used  on 
professional  visits  would  be  capital,  but  when 
used  for  pleasure  merely  would  not  be  capital. 
(Compare,  however,  the  later  treatment  by  the 
same  writer  in  the  Principles  of  Economics.) 
This  difficulty,  however,  would  be  overcome  by 
admitting  the  species  of  consumption  capital. 
Again,  there  are  certain  forms  of  wealth, 
machinery,  tools,  instruments,  etc.,  which  from 
their  natm-e  could  only  be  considered  as  capital, 
whilst  other  forms,  e.g.  seed-corn  in  a  famine, 
may  or  may  not  be  immediately  consumed 
according  to  the  intention  of  the  owners. 
After  all,  however,  the  difficulty  is  only  one  of 
degree,  and,  as  in  other  cases,  we  may  leave 
open  a  debatable  margin  in  the  case  of  the 
individual,  whilst  with  a  nation  it  would  be 
easy  to  determine  roughly  by  means  of  statistics 


220 


CAPITAL 


between  the  amount  of  goods  or  wares  im- 
mediately consumed  and  the  amount  on  the 
average  reserved  directly  or  indirectly  for  the 
future.  On  the  whole  it  may  be  doubted  if  it 
is  possible  or  desirable  to  arrive  at  the  intention 
except  by  arguing  from  the  accomplished  fact, 
or  from  the  nature  of  the  things,  and  the  only 
use  of  the  discussion  is  to  emphasise  again 
the  fundamental  distinction  between  the  satis- 
faction of  immediate  and  future  needs. 

(3)  A  third  question  has  been  much  debated, 
which  is,  however,  more  properly  dealt  with 
under  Wealth  (q.v.),  namely  : — Does  capital 
include  what  are  called  immaterial  as  distinct 
from  mateHal  utilities  ?  The  answer  is  similar 
to  that  in  question  (1)  as  to  the  connection 
between  Labour  and  capital,  and  must  depend 
on  the  convenience  of  emphasising,  or  not 
certain  points  of  analogy  and  contrast.  On  the 
one  side  the  "fixed  skill"  of  a  workman  is  in 
many  respects  similar  to  the  nice  adjustment  of 
the  wheels  of  a  machine,  and  resembles  still 
more  closely  the  trained  qualities  of  the 
domestic  animals.  The  objection  that  the 
skill  is  attached  to  the  man  may  be  answered, 
as  by  Mill,  that  a  coal  mine  is  also  attached  to 
a  place,  or,  still  better,  by  the  analogy  that  in 
matters  of  contrast  the  technical  skill  may  be 
considered  as  separated  from  the  higher  qual- 
ities of  the  personality  of  the  individual.  On 
the  other  hand,  however,  it  is  often  necessary 
to  contrast  the  worker  \vith  the  work  done,  and 
the  wealth  produced  with  the  people  for  whom 
it  is  produced.  By  some  writers  {e.g.  List) 
the  acquired  skill  of  a  people,  the  greater  part 
of  which  has  been  inherited  from  the  past,  and 
is  due  to  the  labour,  and  saving,  and  self- 
restraint  of  past  generations,  is  reckoned  as  the 
most  important  element  in  the  national  capital, 
and  both  in  the  department  of  production  and 
in  distribution  the  contribution  of  this  "social 
capital "  to  the  annual  produce  must  be  care- 
fully considered.  The  principal  reason  why  a 
civilised  nation  can  so  soon  recover  from  the 
effects  of  a  devastating  war  is  to  be  found  in 
the  acquired  skill  of  the  inhabitants,  and  the 
same  remark  applies  to  the  rapid  development 
of  new  colonies.  Thus  Adam  Smith  might 
well  include  the  skill  of  the  workers  in  a  nation 
in  its  fixed  capital.  But  when,  as  is  usual  in 
questions  of  economic  definition,  we  appeal  to 
popular  usage,  we  find  that  hitherto,  at  any 
rate,  the  contrast  has  overcome  the  analogy. 
No  statistician  has  yet  attempted  to  give,  even 
roughly,  a  value  to  this  "social  capital,"  or  to 
estimate  the  capital  value  of  the  skill  of 
labourers,  although  in  particular  cases,  such  as 
compensation  for  injury  or  death,  some  such 
computation  must  be  made.  The  distinction 
■  will  be  found  to  be  of  vital  importance  in  dis- 
cussing the  connection  between  capital  (in  the 
narrower  sense)  and  Wages. 

Besides   the  skill   of  the  inhabitants  of  a 


country  are  other  so-called  immaterial  utilities 
which  have  sometimes  been  included  in  capital, 
and  sometimes  excluded.  Precious  metals 
which  form  the  material  money  of  a  country 
have  always  been  included  under  its  capital,  and 
the  question  arises  whether,  if  an  efficient 
substitute  can  be  found,  this  substitute  is  not 
equally  capital.  There  can  be  no  doubt  that 
without  the  banking  organisation  of  the 
United  Kingdom  the  business  even  of  producing 
wealth  could  not  be  carried  on,  at  least  to  the 
same  extent.  Banking  is  an  essential  part  of 
natural  division  of  labour,  and  Bank  Notes  and 
other  forms  of  representative  money  are  quite 
as  efficient  agents  of  production  as  the  precious 
metals  themselves.  These  questions  are, 
however,  discussed  separately  under  Credit 
(g.v.)  From  the  individual  point  of  view  such 
immaterial  utilities  as  the  Good- Will  of  a 
business,  Copyrights,  Patents,  and  the  like 
would  fall  under  capital  unless  the  material 
characteristic  is  considered  essential. 

Besides  the  three  species  of  capital  already 
discussed  there  are  other  divisions  which  have 
found  a  place  in  the  text-books.  The  most 
important  is  the  distinction  between  fixed  and 
circulating  capital.  Adam  Smith  took  the 
terms  apparently  in  their  literal  sense  and  con- 
sidered the  essence  of  the  difference  to  lie  in  the 
fact  whether  or  not  the  capital  changed  hands 
(or  circulated)  in  order  to  obtain  a  revenue. 
"If  it  {i.e.  stock)  is  employed  in  procuring 
future  profit  (as  distinct  from  present  enjoy- 
ment) it  must  procure  this  profit  either  by 
staying  with  him  or  by  going  from  him.  In 
the  one  case  it  is  a  fixed,  in  the  other  it  is  a 
circulating  capital."  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk. 
ii.  ch.  i.  Mill,  on  the  other  hand,  and  most 
recent  English  economists,  define  circulating 
capital,  as  that  which  performs  the  whole  of  its 
functions  in  a  single  use,  whilst  fixed  capital 
can  be  used  more  than  once  in  the  same  way. 
Of  course  in  particular  cases  it  would  be  diffi- 
cult to  draw  the  line  accurately,  but  the  broad 
distinction  is  quite  obvious.  Compare  and 
contrast,  for  example,  machinery  as  the  type  of 
fixed,  with  food  supplies  and  raw  materials  of 
manufacture  as  the  types  of  circulating  capital. 
Very  often  by  English  writers  circulating  is 
used  as  equivalent  to  wages  capital.  Thus, 
under  the  title  of  the  conversion  of  circulating 
into  fixed  capital  Mill  really  discusses  the 
effects  of  the  introduction  of  machinery  upon 
the  working  classes  (see  Wages,  vol.  iii.  and 
App,).  This  confusion  between  circulating  and 
wage-capital  has  been  one  of  the  causes  of  the 
extreme  and  untenable  form  of  statement  of  the 
wages-fund  theory,  and  of  the  narrow  views  of 
the  relations  of  industry  and  capital  expressed 
in  Mill's  four  fundamental  propositions  {Political 
Economy,  bk.  i.  ch.  v.)  The  terms  sustaining 
and  auxiliary  capital  seem  to  be  more  free 
from  ambiguity  or  question  beggiiig.      Other 


CAPITAL 


221 


divisions  of  capital  are  sufficiently  described  by 
the  words  used  e.g.  floating  and  sunk,  special- 
ised and  non- specialised,  etc. 

It  may  here  be  observed  that,  considering 
the  complicated  controversies  which  have  arisen 
in  connection  with  the  definition  of  capital,  it 
is  often  useful  to  employ  qualifying  adjectives 
when  the  term  is  applied  beyond  the  limits 
within  which  there  is  no  dispute.  We  might, 
for  example,  speak  of  the  skill  of  a  workman 
as  personal  capital,  and  the  various  industrial 
organisations  of  a  nation  as  social  capital.  It 
seems  also  worthy  of  remark  that  those  Avriters 
who  take  the  most  narrow  definition  of  capital, 
and  confine  it  merely  to  material  production- 
capital,  really  bring  in  the  wider  content  of  the 
idea,  indirectly  under  different  headings,  e.g. 
the  accumulation  of  capital,  the  efficiency  of 
the  industrial  agents,  organisation  of  industry, 
the  influence  of  credit,  etc.  Thus  it  often 
happens  that  a  -vniter  imagines  that  he  has 
made  some  important  discovery  on  the  nature 
of  capital  when  he  has  simply  made  an  altera- 
tion on  the  arrangement  or  classification  of 
topics,  a  most  useful  operation  if  well  carried 
out,  but  of  subordinate  importance  to  a  positive 
addition  to  the  materials  of  a  science.  The 
latest  systematic  work  on  Capital  {Kapital  und 
Kapital-Zins  by  E.  von  Bohm-Bawerk),  which 
is  full  of  excellent  material  from  the  historical 
standpoint,  gives  many  examples  tliat  incur 
some  part  of  tliis  stricture. 

In  conclusion  it  must  be  allowed  that  it  is 
impossible  to  thoroughly  discuss  such  a  compre- 
hensive term  as  capital  without  travelling  over 
every  department  of  economics.  Similarly  a 
complete  bibliography  would  involve  a  reference 
to  almost  every  important  economic  work. 

[Besides  the  works  referred  to  in  the  text,  special 
attention  may  be  called  to  the  following.  On  the 
historical  side  (that  is  of  fact,  not  theory),  as  re- 
gards antiquity  one  of  the  most  instructive  works 
on  the  effects  of  capital  is  Mommsen's  History 
of  Rome.  In  the  mediaeval  period  the  work  of 
Schanz,  England's  Wirthschaftliche  Entwickelung, 
etc.,  gives  excellent  material  from  the  Saxon  to 
the  Tudor  period  ;  Thorold  Rogers  on  Six  Centuries 
of  English  Work  and  Wages  and  Brentano  on 
Gilds  and  Trade  Unions  give  the  later  develop- 
ment. On  the  history  of  the  theory  the  principal 
works  have  already  been  noticed.  On  the  theory 
in  recent  times,  the  reader  may  consult  the  chapter 
on  "Capital"  in  the  Principles  of  Pol.  Econ.,  by 
Prof.  H.  Sidgwick,  for  an  excellent  analysis  of 
"common"  and  scientific  English  thought;  the 
Works  of  P.  Leroy  Beaulieu,  e.g.  La  Repartition 
des  Richesses :  La  Science  des  Finances.  New 
ed.j  1912.  The  work  of  Karl  Marx  ( Das  Ka,pital) 
which  has  been  translated  into  English,  must  be 
read  with  caution  as  regards  the  deductions  from 
the  masses  of  adroit  quotations  from  English 
sources,  whilst  the  central  theory  has  not  been 
accepted  by  any  economist  of  repute  though  still 
apparently  the  basis  of  German  socialism.  Com- 
pare A.  Held  on  Socialismus  und  Capitalismus  and 


Schaffle  on  the  Quintessence  of  Socialism  (trans- 
lated into  English).  List  on  National  Systems  oj 
Political  Economy  may  be  compared  with  the 
Wealth  of  Nations,  bks.  ii.  and  iv.]         J.  s.  N. 

History  of  the  word. — The  word  "capital "  in 
its  economic  sense,  like  the  word  "principal," 
and  like  the  word  "capital"  itself  in  its  geo- 
graphical sense,  is  an  adjective  elliptically  used 
as  a  substantive  (Murray,  New  English  Diction- 
ary, s.v.)  The  full  phrase  is  "capital  stock." 
"  Capital "  was  used  for  "capital  stock,"  at  least 
as  early  as  1635  {e.g.  in  Dafibrne,  Merchant's 
Mirrour,  Ex.  No.  96),  but  the  fact  that  it  was 
merely  an  adjective  was  by  no  means  forgotten. 
The  Act  8  &  9  W.  and  M.  c.  20  (1697)  "for 
enlarging  the  capital  stock  of  the  Bank  of 
England,"  provides  that  before  the  enlargement 
is  made,  "the  common,  capital,  and  principal 
stock  of  the  said  governor  and  company  shall 
be  computed  and  estimated  by  the  principal 
and  interest  owing  to  them  by  the  king,  or  by 
any  others,  and  by  cash,  or  by  any  other  effects 
whereof  the  said  capital  stock  shall  then  really 
consist  over  and  above  the  value  of  the  debts 
which  they  shall  owe  at  the  same  time  for 
principal  and  interest  to  any  other  person  or 
persons  whatsoever."  In  Dyche  and  Pardon's 
Dictionary,  1735,  the  article  on  "Capital" 
begins,  "Chief,  head,  or  principal;  it  relates 
to  several  things,  as  the  capital  stock  in  trading 
companies  is  the  fund  or  quantity  of  money 
they  are  by  their  charter  allowed  to  employ  in 
trade."  Adam  Smith  frequently  uses  the  full 
phrase.  e.  c. 

Legal  ruling  that  Capital  need  not  he  replaced 
from  profits. — A  trader's  assets  are  in  most  cases 
whoUy  or  partly  of  a  perishable  nature.  Before 
ascertaining  the  profits  derived  from  such  assets 
in  a  given  year  provision  ought  to  be  made  for 
the  depreciation  estimated  to  have  taken  place 
during  that  year.  If,  for  instance,  a  person  who 
invested  £1000  in  the  purchase  of  a  patent  having 
five  years  to  run,  and  producing  an  annual  profit 
of  £500,  treats  the  whole  of  the  annual  £500 
as  the  profit  of  the  respective  year,  he  will  find, 
at  the  end  of  the  five  years,  that  his  source  of 
income  has  disappeared.  If,  on  tlie  otlier  hand, 
at  the  end  of  each  year  a  sum  of  £200  is  carried 
to  the  credit  of  a  sinking  fund  and  the  remaining 
£300  only  are  treated  as  income,  the  owner  of  the 
patent  will  at  the  end  of  the  five  years  be  able  to 
invest  his  original  £10 00  in  some  other  profitable 
manner.  Where  the  facts  are  so  very  plain 
this  seems  almost  a  truism,  but  in  many  cases 
it  is  more  difficult  to  distinguish  between  income 
in  the  proper  sense  and  repayment  of  capital. 
The  inquiry  ought,  however,  always  to  be  made 
and  acted  on.  The  importance  of  taking  the 
depreciation  of  property  into  account  in  ascer- 
taining the  profits  of  a  given  year  is  even  more 
obvious  in  the  case  of  a  company  than  in  tlie 
case  of  a  private  individual.  The  gradual  dis- 
appearance of  wasting  property  must  in  the  end 


222 


CAPITAL 


materially  damnify  Preference  shareholders, 
Debenture  holders,  and  ordinary  creditors,  and 
must  also  cause  great  injustice  as  between  the 
persons  entitled  to  the  income  of  shares  for 
limited  periods  and  the  persons  ultimately 
entitled  to  the  property  of  the  shares.  It  seems 
strange  that  although  the  integrity  of  the  capital 
of  limited  companies  is,  in  other  directions, 
most  jealously  watched  by  our  courts,  the 
greatest  laxity  is  allowed  mth  reference  to  the 
valuation  of  assets  of  a  wasting  nature. 

In  the  leading  case  of  Lee  v.  Neuchatel 
Asphalte  Company  (Law  Reports,  41  Chancery 
Division,  p.  1)  it  was  held  by  the  Court  of 
Appeal  that  "  there  is  nothing  in  the  Companies 
Acts  to  prohibit  a  company  formed  to  work  a 
wasting  property,  as  e.g.  a  mine  or  a  patent, 
from  distributing,  as  dividend,  the  excess  of  the 
proceeds  of  working  above  the  expenses  of 
working,  nor  to  impose  on  the  company  any 
obligation  to  set  apart  a  Sinking  Fund  to  meet 
the  depreciation  in  the  value  of  the  wasting 
property." 

The  following  observations  of  Lord  Justice 
Lopes  deserve  special  notice — "  It  is  said  by 
the  appellant  that  a  company  is  not  at  liberty 
to  pay  a  dividend  unless  they  can  show  that 
their  available  property  at  the  time  of  declaring 
the  dividend  is  equivalent  to  their  nominal  or 
share  capital.  In  my  opinion  such  a  contention 
is  untenable.  Where  nominal  or  share  capital 
is  diminished  in  value,  not  by  means  of  any 
improper  dealing  with  it  by  the  company,  but 
by  reason  of  causes  over  which  the  company  has 
no  control,  or  by  reason  of  its  inherent  nature, 
that  diminution  need  not,  in  my  opinion,  be 
made  good  out  of  revenue. " 

The  result  of  the  doctrine  so  laid  down  may 
be  illustrated  by  an  example.  A  company 
having  invested  the  whole  of  its  capital  in 
licensed  premises  at  a  price  securing  an  excellent 
return  during  the  continuance  of  the  licence, 
divides  the  whole  of  the  net  revenue  in  each 
year  among  its  shareholders.  The  licence  is 
withdrawn  before  the  dividend  for  the  last  year 
has  been  declared.  This  is  a  diminution  of  the 
value  of  the  company's  property  **  by  reason  of 
causes  over  which  the  company  has  no  control," 
and  the  company  may  divide  the  whole  of  the  last 
year's  profit  among  the  shareholders,  although 
the  value  of  the  land  and  buildings  since  the 
withdrawal  of  the  license  is  far  below  the 
amount  of  the  debts  owing  by  the  company. 
We  are  bound  to  bow  to  the  ruling  of  the  Court 
of  Appeal,  and  must  therefore  assume  that  this 
result  is  in  accordance  with  the  Companies  Acts, 
but  economically  it  cannot  be  considered  sound  ; 
while,  from  the  point  of  view  of  persons  having 
dealings  with  limited  companies,  and  relying  on 
the  correctness  of  their  annual  balance-sheets, 
it  is  highly  inconvenient,  and  further  it  contra- 
dicts every  sound  principle  of  business  and  of 
bookkeeping.  E.  s. 


Capital  rarely  permanent. — The  constant 
need  of  renewal  of  capital  is  a  point  often  not 
remembered.  Capital,  as  Professor  Sidgwick 
says  {Principles  of  Political  Economy,  ch.  v.),  is 
"a  semi-technical  term,  being  habitually  used 
not  by  men  generally  in  their  ordinary  thought, 
but  by  men  of  business  and  others  when  dis- 
cussing industrial  matters,"  **  In  its  original 
use  by  practical  men,"  Professor  Sidgwick  con- 
tinues, "capital"  undoubtedly  means  "wealth 
employed  so  as  to  yield  a  profit."  The  distinc- 
tions which,  as  Professor  Sidgwick  shows,  must 
be  made  as  to  the  use  of  the  term  thus  defined, 
are  stated  under  the  head  of  Capital  (q.v.), 
the  remarks  on  the  subject  in  this  place  are 
confined  to  the  point — that  the  "wealth"  thus 
"  employed "  stands  constantly  in  need  of 
renewal.  Whether  "capital"  exists  in  the 
form  of  machinery  or  any  other  finished  pro- 
duct of  intelligent  skill,  or  in  the  form  of 
the  floating  capital  or  cash  used  in  paying  the 
labour  employed  in  keeping  that  machinery  in 
motion,  or  in  purchasing  the  materials  needed 
to  maintain  any  product  of  intelligent  skill — 
a  mint  for  instance  in  working  order — constant 
renewal  is,  in  by  far  the  gi-eatest  number  of 
cases,  needed  to  maintain  not  merely  its  effici- 
ency, but  its  ,very  existence.  A  railway,  for 
example,  needs  not  merely  a  continual  repair 
but  perpetual  reconstruction,  which  has  properly 
to  be  charged  to  the  fund  which  is  properly 
profit,  but  which  in  this  technical  sense  is 
called  "revenue."  As  trafiic  increases  new 
rails  have  to  be  laid  down,  old  stations  enlarged 
and  renewed,  old  bridges  replaced  by  new  ones 
capable  of  bearing  the  heavier  weights  of  the 
more  powerful  locomotives  and  the  larger  trains 
which  they  draw.  In  cases  like  this  "capital" 
— the  word  is  used  here  in  the  technical  sense 
described  by  Professor  Sidgwick — has  already 
been  charged  with  the  cost  of  construction  of 
the  stations  and  bridges  which  are  now  super- 
seded, and  hence  have  to  be  rebuilt.  It  is 
"revenue"  therefore,  the  produce  of  "capital," 
not  capital  itself,  which  has  to  bear  the  cost 
of  the  renewal  so  far  as  this  renewal  merely 
replaces  what  is  actually  superseded.  Thus,  in 
the  case  of  a  station  which  cost  originally 
£10,000,  and  owing  to  the  increased  traffic  has 
become  insufficient  to  meet  the  needs  of  the 
locality,  and  has  to  be  replaced  by  one  costing 
£50,000,  in  all  well-managed  railways  the  rule 
is  that  capital  bears  only  the  difierence  between 
the  two  sums,  and  revenue  is  charged  with  the 
replacement  of  the  original  outlay.  This  ex- 
ample is  given  as  merely  one  instance  of  a  pro- 
cess which  has  to  be  followed  in  every  instance 
in  which  "  capital "  has  to  be  perpetually  main- 
tained, however  it  is  employed.  It  show.i 
further,  not  only  the  proper  method  of  appor- 
tioning the  difference  between  gross  and  net 
"revenues,"  that  is  between  gross  and  net  pro- 
fit,  but  the  very  heavy  drafts  which  must  cou- 


CAPITATION— CAPITATION  TAXES 


223 


stantly  be  made  on  "revenue,"  that  is  on  net 
"profit,"  to  meet  a  class  of  expenditure  which 
to  many  appears  exceptional,  but  which  is  really 
a  normal  incident  in  the  cost  of  production. 
When  examined  into  thus,  it  is  interesting  to 
trace  how  little  of  what  is  ordinarily  termed 
"fixed"  capital  is  really  permanent.  The  ap- 
parent permanence  of  "capital"  is  occasionally 
spoken  of  as  something  which  may  always  be 
depended  on,  something  which  endures  for  ever. 
Because  the  payment  of  the  interest  on  the 
"debt"  of  a  nation,  or  the  "stock"  of  a  com- 
pany is  continued  from  year  to  year,  it  is 
assumed  that  the  wealth  represented  by  the 
original  outlay  continues  in  existence  and  that 
the  "capital"  remains — capital  described  as  the 
"  saved  produce  of  past  labour."  The  "  capital 
considered  either  in  the  concrete  as  (mainly)  the 
accumulated  stock  of  instruments  auxiliary  to 
labour,  or  more  abstractedly  as  the  power  of 
directing  labour  to  the  attainment  of  gi-eater 
but  remoter  utilities  through  the  control  over 
the  produce  of  labour  possessed  by  the  o-w-ners 
of  accumulated  wealth,"  is  only  maintained 
through  a  perpetual  process  of  reproduction. 

[See  Mill,  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  bk.  i. 
cb.  v.  For  connection  between  KecpdXaiou,  caput, 
and  capital,  see  Macleod,  Dictionary  of  Political 
Economy,  s.v.  "  Capital,"  pp.  324-67,  and  Roscher, 
Volkswirthschaft,  p.  89,  §  42.] 

CAPITATION  (in  France).  The  capitation 
was  a  graduated  poll-tax,  first  imposed  in  1695 
during  the  war  with  the  league  of  Augsburg  ; 
abolished  in  1697,  on  the  conclusion  of  the 
treaty  of  Rysv/ick,  it  was  renewed  when  the  war 
of  the  Spanish  Succession  broke  out  in  1701. 
From  this  time  it  became  a  regular  source  of 
income  until  the  Revolution. 

The  imposition  of  the  capitation  is  a  proof  of 
the  immense  power  of  the  monarchy  under 
Louis  XIV.  No  consent  was  asked,  and  no 
regard  was  paid  to  class  privileges.  The  tax  was 
to  press  upon  all  classes  including  the  nobles. 
The  mendicant  orders,  and  all  whose  contribu- 
tions to  the  state  did  not  exceed  40  (afterwards 
20)  sous  were  exempted.  The  rest  were  divided 
into  twenty-two  classes  according  to  rank,  with 
a  diminishing  scale  of  payment.  The  first  class, 
which  consisted  of  the  dauphin  alone,  paid 
2000  livres  ;  the  second,  viz.  the  princes  of  the 
blood,  paid  1500  ;  and  so  on  to  the  four  lowest 
classes,  which  paid  respectively  40,  30,  10,  and 
3  livres.  In  principle,  at  least,  the  tax  was 
more  equitable  than  any  other  in  France. 

The  nobles  and  clergy  had  been  powerless  to 
prevent  the  imposition  of  the  tax,  but  they  soon 
succeeded  in  modifying  its  assessment  in  their 
own  interests.  The  clergy,  in  fact,  succeeded 
in  escaping  it  from  an  early  period.  In  1695, 
and  again  in  1701,  they  agreed  to  pay  4,000,000 
livres  a  year  as  long  as  the  war  lasted.  In 
1709,  when  the  government  was  reduced  to  the' 
greatest  straits,  they  purchased  permanent  im- 


munity from  the  capitation  by  an  immediate 
payment  of  24,000,000  livres,  most  of  which 
they  raised  by  loan.  The  pays  d'etat  and  many 
of  the  towns  compounded  for  a  fixed  annual 
payment,  as  in  the  case  of  the  taille  (see 
Taille).  The  nobles  obtained  the  appoint- 
ment of  special  receivers  for  their  own  order,  and 
succeeded  in  escaping  great  part  of  the  burden. 

But  tlie  most  fatal  change  was  tlie  adoption 
(in  those  provinces  where  the  taille  was  levied 
on  personalty)  of  the  assessment  for  the  taille 
as  the  basis  of  that  for  the  capitation.  The 
division  of  the  twenty-two  classes  was  soon  lost 
sight  of,  and  the  burden  upon  the  lower  classes 
was  enormously  increased.  If  the  taille  was 
increased,  the  capitation  of  theRoTURiERwas  ipso 
facto  increased  too.  Thus  the  practice  grew 
up  of  collecting  the  tax  first  from  the  non- 
privileged,  and  then,  if  there  was  a  deficit,  it 
was  imposed  upon  the  privileged  classes.  Thus 
it  was  reckoned  that  in  1788  a  roturier  paid 
about  12  sous  per  livre  ;  and  a  noble  only  2. 
The  class  which  ought  to  have  paid  3  livres  by 
the  original  arrangement  had  come  to  pay  24  ; 
the  class  which  ouglit  to  have  paid  10  paid  60, 
and  that  which  ought  to  have  paid  30  paid  180. 
This  enormous  change  was  produced  within  a 
century,  not  by  formal  enactment,  but  by  the 
steady  pressure  of  the  privileged  classes  upon 
the  administration.  The  result  was  disastrous 
to  the  state,  as  the  tax,  according  to  Necker, 
only  produced  41,000,000  livres,  whereas  it 
was  estimated  to  produce  54,000,000. 

[Necker,  I)e  V Administration  des  Finances  de 
la  France  (1784). — Gasquet,  Precis  des  Institu- 
tions Politiques  et  Sociales  de  V Ancienne  France 
(Paris,  1885).]  R.  l. 

CAPITATION  TAXES.  Taxes  directly  im- 
posed  on  each  individual  to  be  charged  there- 
with, the  amount  payable  being  either  a  uniform 
sum  or,  as  in  later  times,  a  sum  regulated  by 
reference  to  a  prescribed  scale  varying  with  the 
rank  and  station,  and,  in  some  instances,  Avith 
the  supposed  fortune  of  the  person  charged. 
Such  taxes  are  frequently  described  as  poll 
taxes. 

The  first  capitation  or  poll  tax  was  imposed  in 
England  in  1377  at  the  uniform  rate  of  4d.  per 
head.  It  is  stated  in  the  Subsidy  Ptoll  printed 
in  the  Archccologia,  vii.  37,  that  the  sum  pro- 
duced was  £22,607  paid  by  1,376,442  persons, 
although,  as  Mr.  Dowell  remarks,  the  "sum 
raised  does  not  correspond  with  the  stated 
number  of  taxpayers."  In  1379  and  1380 
graduated  poll  taxes  were  imposed,  the  tax  levied 
in  the  latter  year  leading  to  the  movement  in 
which  Wat  Tyler  was  the  moving  spirit.  There- 
after, capitation  taxes  were  levied  at  rare  inter- 
vals, the  principle  of  classification  being  present 
in  all  of  them  and  on  an  increasingly  elaborate 
basis.  In  1692  a  poll  tax  paid  in  each  quarter 
of  that  year  produced  £580,000,  and  in  1698  a 
similar  tax  estimated  to  yield  £800,000  pro- 


224 


CARACCIOLI— CARAFA 


duced  no  more  than  £321, 397.  "  When  a  tax," 
said  Davenant,  "yields  no  more  than  half  what 
in  reason  might  be  expected  from  it,  we  plainly 
see  tliat  it  grates  upon  all  sorts  of  people  ;  and 
such  ways  and  means  of  raising  money  should 
be  rarely  made  use  of  by  any  governmei^t." 
Accordingly,  the  poll  tax  of  1698  was  the  last 
imposed  in  this  country,  although  the  system 
survives  in  several  Eurojiean  countries. 

Adam  Saiith  (  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  v.  chap, 
ii.  art.  iv.)  condemns  capitation  taxes  as  alto- 
gether arbitrary  and  uncertain,  to  which  he 
adds  that  "the  greatest  sum  which  they  have 
ever  afforded  might  always  have  been  found  in 
some  other  way  much  more  convenient  to  the 
people."  It  may,  however,  be  said,  that  it  is 
in  the  inequality  of  capitation  taxes,  rather 
than  in  their  uncertainty  or  arbitrary  character, 
that  the  essential  objection  to  them  consists. 
They  need  not  necessarily  be  uncertain,  and 
their  arbitrary  character  depends  mainly  upon 
the  manner  in  which  they  are  administered. 
If  levied,  however,  without  distinction  of  age, 
sex,  or  fortune,  they  are  so  manifestly  unequal 
that  they  have  been  described  as  the  taxation 
of  men  as  if  they  were  beasts,  and  as  constitut- 
ing "a  mark  of  slavery."  And  even  when 
attempts  have  been  made  to  remedy  this  in- 
equality by  suitable  gradations,  sufficient  care 
has  seldom  been  taken  in  constructing  them  to 
avoid  the  imposition  of  a  direct  burden  upon 
those  above  the  condition  of  beggary  but 
possessed  of  the  means  of  a  bare  subsistence 
only.  Graduated  capitation  or  poll  taxes  may 
be  described  as  rough  and  ready  attempts  to 
achieve  that  species  of  direct  taxation  which  is 
more  scientifically  accomplished  by  a  well-con- 
structed income  tax  (see  Income  Tax),  to 
which  tax,  as  then  known,  many  of  the  observ- 
ations of  the  earlier  economists  on  the  subject 
of  capitation  taxes  are  indeed  equally  directed. 

T.  H.  E. 

[See  Dowell's  History  of  Taxation  and  Taxes  in 
England  (London,  1888). — Block's  Dictionnaire 
O&neral  de  la  Politique  (Paris,  1873).] 

CARACCIOLI,  DoMENico  (marquis  and 
viceroy  of  Sicily),  born  in  Naples  1715,  died 
1789  ;  published  (1785)  a  pamphlet  on  com 
laws,  having  seen  their  bad  consequences 
during  a  great  famine  which  devastated  Sicily 
in  1784  and  1785.  However,  he  is  not  a 
thorough  free  trader,  and  he  is  more  of  a  political 
writer  than  an  economist.  Custodi  published 
his  pamphlet  in  his  Economisti  classici  Italiani, 
Milano,  1804.  M.  p. 

CARAFA,  DioisrEDE,  perhaps  the  first  seri- 
ous writer  in  Italy  on  public  finance.  When 
he  was  born  is  not  known.  He  died  in  1487. 
He  was  duke  of  Maddaloni  and  was  invested 
with  the  highest  political  offices  under  Alfonso 
I.  of  Aragon,  who  only  succeeded  in  taking 
Naples  from  Renato  of  Anjou  through  the 
bravery  and  ability  of  his  captain  Carafa. 


Carafa's  book  consists  only  of  eighty-eight 
pages,  and  its  full  title  is :  De  regis  et  boni  Prin- 
cipis  officio  opusculum  a  Diomede  Carafa,  primo 
Magdalunensium  Comite,  compositutn,  Neap, 
apud  Castaldum,  1668  (edition  now  circulat- 
ing). He  wrote  his  book  between  1469  and 
1482  in  Italian,  and  the  Duchess  Eleonora, 
daughter  of  Alfonso  I.,  and  wife  of  Ercole  L, 
Duke  of  Ferrara,  whose  instructor  Carafa  had 
been,  dii-ected  it  to  be  translated  into  Latin. 
It  is  divided  into  four  parts :  (1)  De  imperio 
tuendo,  (2)  de  jure  dicendo  et  justitia  servanda, 
(3)  de  re  familiari  et  vectigalibus  adminis- 
trandis,  (4)  de  subditorum  civitatisque  com- 
modis  procurandis. 

In  the  third  part,  which  is  the  financial  one, 
of  his  treatise,  Carafa  makes  some  original  re- 
mai'ks.  He  maintains  that  the  revenue  must  be 
regulated  in  proportion  to  the  expenditure,  and 
that  this  has  three  principal  divisions — expenses 
for  the  protection  of  the  state  ;  those  necessary 
for  the  court  of  the  prince  ;  and  lastly  a  category 
of  varying  importance  relative  to  the  general 
welfare  of  the  state.  As  this  last  category  is 
the  variable  and  unforeseen  one,  whilst  the  two 
other  ones  are  certain,  the  greatest  possible 
margin  should  be  left  for  it  on  the  side  of  income, 
and  the  othef  expenditure  should  be  reduced  to 
a  minimum.  The  revenue  should  be  minutely 
accounted  for  and  examined  into  every  year  by 
a  special  body  of  officers.  Taxes  should  be 
stable  and  in  every  detail  indisputable  (Carafa 
says :  taxes  should  be  formulated  so  clearly 
that  people  need  not  go  to  law  about  them  to 
know  what  they  have  to  pay)  and  not  oppres- 
sive ;  but  taxes  wiU  be  certain  to  be  oppressive 
if  the  greatest  economy  does  not  prevail  in  the 
expenditure.  Economy  in  the  expenditure 
makes  it  possible  for  the  prince  to  choose 
amongst  the  many  possible  taxes  only  the 
very  best,  and  eliminate  especially  those  which 
are  iniquitous  or  unequal  in  their  incidence. 
Moderation  in  the  expenses  will  also  have  the 
good  effect  that  the  prince  need  not  have  re- 
course to  forced  loans,  which  he  thus  character- 
ises, "  Quid  aliud  existimari  debet,  quam  tutum 
quoddam  rapinae  aut  furti  genus  ?  "  Such  loans 
induce  population  and  capital  to  emigrate,  and 
it  would  be  highly  immoral  for  the  prince  to 
endeavour  to  search  out  where  wealth  was,  by 
employing  spies  so  as  to  plunder  his  subjects 
the  better.  He  thinks  the  collecting  of  taxes 
ought  to  be  farmed  out,  because  the  "publi- 
cans "  act  with  greater  zeal,  intelligence,  and 
activity  than  government  officials.  Carafa 
clearly  recognises  that  the  wealth  of  the  sub- 
jects is  the  foundation  of  the  whole  state 
machinery,  and  must  therefore  be  spared,  "Sub- 
ditorum facultates  potentise  regise  fundamenta 
existimari  oportet."  Far  bolder  than  S, 
Thomas  Aquinas  (q.v.),  Carafa  does  not  feai 
moral  evils  from  a  development  of  commerce, 
the  first  great  source  of  the  wealth  of  subjects  •, 


CARBONARI—CAREY 


225 


I 


therefore  commerce  must  be  left  absolutely  free. 
Carafa's  powerful  intellect  discerned  how  bene- 
ficial for  a  country  are  foreign  merchants  who 
settle  in  it,  and  strongly  opposed  every  sort  of 
oppression  tending  to  give  foreigners  a  posi- 
tion inferior  to  that  of  native  citizens.  His 
formula  of  liberty  is  "Sicut  indignum  est  a 
civibus  officia  Regentis  invadi,  ita  civium  negotia 
occupari  a  Hege  non  decet. "  Nevertheless  Carafa 
cannot  yet  quite  free  himself  of  the  prejudice 
that  state-help  is  of  some  good,  and  he  advises 
the  prince  to  lend  money,  to  give  prizes  and  aid 
industry  in  many  other  ways,  since  the  prince, 
he  says,  is  sure  never  to  lose  in  the  long  run  by 
doing  so,  because  "  princeps  inops  esse  non  potest, 
cujus  imperio  ditissimi  homines  subjiciuntur. " 
Especially  agiiculture  needs  the  indulgence  of 
the  prince,  because  peasants  often  need  loans, 
and  when  the  seasons  have  not  favoured  them, 
the  tax  collectors  ought  not  to  aggravate  their 
situation,  but  give  them  a  little  time  to  pay 
their  taxes  and  their  debts.  The  labour  of  the 
subjects  is  tlie  source  of  the  wealth  of  a  nation 
and  the  government  must  never  crush  them 
and  if  it  can,  must  help  them  ;  ' '  nee  tavun 
Tiegaverim  non  posse  hoc  (state-help)  ab  omnibus 
et  ubique  praestari  ;  sed  ubi  etfacultatum  copia, 
et  locorum  commoditas  suppetit,  ibi  s^ibditos  a 
Principibus  suis,  et  consilio,  et  re  excitandos  ad- 
juvandosque  esse  cesser o." 

Is  it  not  remarkable  to  find  a  statesman  and 
a  warrior  of  those  rough  times  speaking  in  sucli 
terms  ?  M.  P. 

CARBONARI.  This  secret  society  (referred 
to  in  the  notice  of  the  life  of  Etienne  Cabet). 
claims  a  history  of  much  antiquity,  and  Francis 
I.  of  France  as  founder.  Its  recent  activity 
dates,  however,  mainly  from  the  revolutionary 
period,  at  the  close  of  the  last  century,  when 
its  principal  sphere  of  action  lay  in  Italy.  The 
project  formed  by  the  society  of  a  united  Italy, 
under  the  name  of  the  Ausonian  Republic, 
proved  abortive  ;  but  the  fall  of  Murat  was  in 
great  measure  due  to  its  influence.  After  the 
restoration  of  the  Bourbons,  however,  to  the 
kingdom  of  Naples,  the  Carbonari  were  thrown 
on  one  side,  and  the  society  was  proscribed 
throughout  Italy.  Expelled  thence,  it  began 
to  take  root  in  France,  and  Lafayette  became 
its  chief  (c.  1820-1821).  After  many  vicissi- 
tudes the  society  was  revived  about  1825,  and 
some  ten  years  later  coalesced  with  the  society 
named  Young  Italy.  The  course  which  the 
society  of  the  Carbonari  took  marks  "a  transi- 
tion period  in  the  history,  of  secret  societies. 
From  secret  societies  occupied  with  religion, 
philosophy,  and  politics  in  the  abstract,  it  leads 
us  to  the  secret  societies  whose  objects  are  more 
immediately  political.  And  thus  in  France, 
Italy,  and  other  centres  it  gave  rise  to  numer- 
ous and  various  sects,  wherein  we  find  the  men 
of  thought  and  those  of  action  combining  for 
one  common  object — the  progress,  as  they 
YOlu  I. 


understood  it,  of  human  society  "  (Heckethorn. 
vol.  ii.  p.  115). 

[For  literature,  see  The  Secret  Societies  of  all 
Ages  and  Countries,  C.  W.  Heckethorn,  2  vols., 
London.] 

CARDOZO,  Isaac  N.,  born  in  1786  in 
Georgia,  U.S.,  settled  in  Charleston,  S.C.  ; 
engaged  in  journalism,  and  died  in  1850. 
In  1826  wrote  Notes  on  Folitical  Economy, 
Charleston,  S.C,  pp.  125.  This  was  called 
forth  by  the  publication  of  Professor  M'Vickar's 
edition  of  M'Culloch's  article  on  "Political 
Economy,"  originally  published  in  the  Encyclo- 
paedia Britannica,  a  statement  of  the  jDrinciples 
of  political  economy  which  Cardozo  regarded  as 
erroneous  when  applied  to  the  United  States.  The 
Ricardian  theory  of  rent  was  especially  attacked  ; 
many  critics  at  that  time  saw  that  the  condi- 
tions of  land  tenure  and  cultivation  were  so 
dillerent  in  the  United  States  from  those  in 
England  that  they  concluded  that  Ricardo's 
theory  was  fundamentally  erroneous.  As  editor 
of  the  Southern  Patriot,  1816-45,  and  of  the 
Evening  News,  1845-50,  Cardozo  wrote  in 
favour  of  free  trade,  and  showed  an  unusual 
acquaintance  with  the  subject  of  finance.  He 
frequently  contributed  to  the  Southern  Quar- 
terly Peview.  D.  R.  D. 

CAREY,  Henry  Charles  (born  in  Phila 
delphia,  United  States,  1793,  died  in  that  city 
1879),  was  the  son  of  Matthew  Carey,  an  Irish 
exile,  who  had  become  a  man  of  mark  as  a 
publisher,  and  as  a  waiter  on  economic  and 
]iolitical  questions.  The  son  succeeded  his 
lather  as  head  of  the  publishing  house,  but  re- 
tired with  a  competency  in  1835,  and  from 
that  time  devoted  his  energies  to  economic 
science  and  related  subjects.  Thirteen  octavo 
volumes  and  three  thousand  pages  of  pamphlets 
remain  as  the  fruit  of  his  activity,  besides  an 
amount  of  matter,  supposed  to  be  twice  as  great, 
contributed  by  him  to  the  newspaper  press.  Of 
his  more  important  works  there  are  translations 
in  French,  Italian,  Portuguese,  German,  Swedish, 
Russian,  Magyar,  and  Japanese,  attesting  his 
remarkable  power  of  commanding  attention  in 
spite  of  the  difificulties  created  by  gi-eat  prolixity, 
eccentric  style,  and  frequent  obscurity  of 
thought. 

Carey  began  his  scientific  career  at  a  juncture 
when  the  English  School  appeared  to  have 
exhausted  its  deductions  fi-om  assumed  premises. 
and  to  shrink  from  adjusting  its  conclusions  to 
the  conditions  of  actual  life.  His  treatment  of 
Social  Science  was  original,  and  led  him  to  a 
series  of  supposed  discoveries,  the  order  of  which 
he  has  stated  in  the  introduction  to  his  most 
important  work.  The  Principles  of  Social 
Science.  His  point  of  departure  was  a  theory 
of  Value  which  he  defined  as  the  "measure  of 
the  resistance  to  be  overcome  in  obtaining 
things  required  for  use,  or  the  measure  of 
nature's  power  over  man  " — in  simpler  terms 

Q 


226 


CAEEY 


the  cost  of  reproduction.  This  theory  Carey 
applied  to  every  case  of  value — to  commodities, 
services,  and  land,  and  in  some  passages  seem- 
ingly to  man  himself.  Reasoning  that  every 
gift  of  nature  is  gratuitous,  he  found  a  universal 
tendency  to  a  decline  of  value  as  the  arts 
advance,  and  to  a  decrease  in  the  value  of 
accumulated  capital,  as  compared  with  the 
results  of  present  labour,  with  a  resulting 
harmony  of  interests  between  capitalist  and 
labourer.  This  theory  Carey  enunciated  in  his 
Principles  of  Political  Economy,  published  in 
1837-40,  and  its  appearance  in  slightly  modi- 
fied terms  in  Bastiat's  Harmonies  Economiques 
in  1850,  led  to  a  sharp  discussion  between  the 
two  authors,  in  the  Journal  des  itconomistes  for 
1851.  The  attempts  of  Diihring  in  Germany 
to  establish  the  claims  of  Carey  as  a  reformer  of 
economical  doctrine,  led  to  an  equally  sharp 
controversy  between  Diihring  and  Lange,  in 
which  the  latter  had  the  best  of  the  argu- 
ment. 

Ten  years  later,  in  his  Past,  Present,  and 
Future,  Carey  announced  a  law  of  produc- 
tion from  land  the  exact  reverse  of  Ricardo's 
With  great  wealth  of  illustration,  he  laid  down 
the  principle  that,  in  the  progress  of  society, 
men  first  till  the  easily  worked  and  poorer  soils, 
and  descend  upon  the  richer  lands  as  capital 
and  numbers  increase,  so  that  with  the  advance 
of  the  community  the  rate  of  return  from  land 
rises  instead  of  falling.  Closely  connected  with 
this  supposed  reversal  of  Ricardo's  doctrine,  and 
a  natural  deduction  from  the  continually  in- 
creasing ability  to  support  increasing  numbers, 
was  the  total  rejection  of  the  Malthusian  law. 
Logical  necessity,  however,  forced  Carey  to 
seek  for  some  ultimate  limiting  principle,  and 
this  he  found  at  last  in  Herbert  Spencer's  con- 
jectured physiological  law  of  the  diminution  of 
human  fertility,  and  ultimate  equilibrium 
between  numbers  and  subsistence.  It  may  be 
also  noted  in  passing,  that  with  the  Ricardian 
and  Malthusian  doctrines  Carey  also  abandoned 
his  earlier  belief  in  free  trade,  from  a  conviction 
that,  in  the  present  state  of  the  world,  the 
co-ordinating  power  of  the  government  must 
be  used,  in  order  to  preserve  economic  harmony 
and  to  arrive  at  ultimate  freedom. 

Finally,  in  the  second  chapter  of  his  Social 
Science,  Carey  announced  the  crowning  dis- 
covery of  "the  great  law  of  molecular  gravita- 
tion as  the  indispensable  condition  of  the 
existence  of  the  being  known  as  man."  The 
laws  of  being  he  declared  to  be  the  same  in 
matter,  man,  and  communities.  As  in  the 
solar  world  attraction  and  motion  are  in  the 
ratio  of  mass  and  proximity,  so  in  the  social 
world,  association,  individuality,  responsibility, 
development  and  progress  are  proportionate 
to  each  other.  This  theory,  not  of  analogy, 
but  of  absolute  identity  of  law,  in  the  physical 
and  in  the  social  world,   is  maintained  with 


great  vigour  in  the  Unity  of  Law,  published 
when  Carey  was  in  his  seventy-ninth  year. 

The  scientific  importance  of  these  theories 
has  been  maintained  by  Diihring,  Ferrara,  and 
"Wirth,  and  has  been  questioned  by  Held  and 
Lange.  However  revolutionary  the  theories 
may  be  logically,  they  had,  outside  of  the 
middle  United  States,  little  effect  in  establishing 
a  school,  even  in  the  author's  lifetime,  and 
since  his  death,  under  the  changed  conditions 
of  economic  discussion,  have  ceased  to  attract 
much  attention. 

In  his  own  country,  Carey  is  probably  best 
recollected  as  an  advocate  of  the  policy  of  pro- 
tection. This  policy  he  urged  upon  grounds  so 
unusual,  that  it  may  be  said  that,  in  the  dis- 
cussion, he  seldom  pursued  his  opponents  far 
upon  their  own  lines  of  argument,  nor  has  he 
often  been  followed  by  them  upon  his  own. 
The  central  point  of  his  social  philosophy  was 
the  importance  of  association  as  the  primary 
condition  of  progress.  In  mere  trade,  as 
between  countries  exchanging  manufactured 
goods  and  raw  products,  he  found  an  influence 
which  centralises  power  and  wealth  on  the  one 
side  and  acts  towards  dispersion  and  decay  on 
the  other  :  but  in  the  commerce  of  services  and 
ideas  carried  on  by  men  exchanging  with  each 
other  directly,  he  found  a  tendency  to  closer 
association,  increased  economic  efficiency,  and 
general  well-being.  His  treatment  of  Interna- 
tional Trade,  then,  turned  chiefly  upon  the 
stimulus  to  be  given  to  producers  by  the  home 
market,  a  consequent  rapid  societary  move- 
ment, an  early  diversification  of  pursuits, 
quickened  thought,  and  a  resulting  gain  in 
productive  power.  In  this  manner  he  de- 
veloped many  of  the  arguments  for  the  protec- 
tive system  which  have  now  become  common, 
and  perhaps  helped  in  giving  to  those  arguments 
a  currency  much  wider  than  the  acceptance,  or 
even  the  knowledge,  of  his  general  system, 
among  protectionists  to-day.  (See  American 
School  of  Political  Economy.) 

Carey  held  no  public  office,  but  his  mental 
and  social  qualities  made  him  for  many  years  a 
central  figure  among  men  of  cultivation  and 
influence  in  his  own  community.  A  brief 
memoir  of  him  was  published  in  Philadelphia 
(1880)  by  his  friend.  Dr.  William  Elder,  from 
which  is  taken  the  following  list  of  his  prin- 
cipal works,   omitting   the   long   catalogue  of 


Essay  on  the  Rate  of  Wages,  1835. — Harmony 
of  Nature  (privately  printed),  1836. — Principles 
of  Political  Economy  (3  vols.),  1837  '38  'iO.—The 
Past,  the  Present,  and  the  Future,  1848. — Har- 
mony of  Interests,  Agricultural,  Manufacturing, 
and  Commercial,  1850. — Slave  Trade,  Domestic 
and  Foreign,  1853. — Principles  of  Social  Science 
(3  vols.),  1858-59. — Manual  of  Social  Science 
(edited  by  Miss  M'Kean),  1864:.— The  Unity  of 
Law,  as  exhibited  in  the  relations  of  Physical, 
Social,  Mental,  and  Moral  Science,  1872. 


CAREY— CARL  YLE 


227 


Closely  related  to  the  above  is  the  Manual  of 
Political  Economy,  by  E.  Peshine  Smith,  1868. 
The  Claims  of  Carey  to  a  high  place  among 
modern  economists  have  been  maintained  in 
Germany  especially  by  Eugen  Diihring  (Carey's 
Umwalzung  der  Volksvnrthschaftslehre  und  Social- 
wissenschaft,  1865)  and  in  America  especially  by 
Mr.  Carey-Baird.  Readers  who  may  wish  to  see 
a  statement  of  the  case  rather  from  the  side  of  his 
followers  than  from  that  of  his  critics  are  referred 
to  the  writings  of  these  authors.  C.  r.  D. 

CAREY,  Matthew  (father  of  H.  C.  Carey) 
born  in  Ireland  in  1760,  emigrated  to  United 
States  in  1788  in  consequence  of  political 
troubles.  His  career  was  varied  and  successful ; 
editor  of  newspapers  and  magazines,  pamphlet- 
eer, publisher,  he  was  till  his  death  in  1840 
(at  Philadelphia)  a  prominent  figure.  He  wrote 
numerous  pamphlets,  partly  political,  partly 
economical.  In  1820-40  he  was  the  most  active 
among  the  advocates  of  protection  in  the  United 
States.  Among  his  pamphlets  (all  published  at 
Philadelphia)  may  be  mentioned  : — 

Brief  Examination  of  Lord  ShefHeld's  Observa- 
tions on  Commerce  of  United  States,  1791. — 
Appeal  to  Common  Sense  and  Common  Justice, 
1822. — Essays  on  Political  Economy,  or  the  most 
certain  Means  of  promoting  Wealth,  etc.  (1822). 
— The  Crisis,  etc.,  1823. — Examination  of  the 
Boston  Report,  etc.,  1828.  f.  w.  t. 

CARLI,  GiAN  RiNALDO,  born  at  Capo  d'Istria 
1720,  died  at  Milan  1795.  In  1744  he  became 
professor  of  astronomy  at  Padua.  In  1753 
he  settled  at  Milan,  where  he  was  appointed 
president  of  the  financial  board  by  the  Aus- 
trian government. 

Between  1751  and  1760  he  published  his 
famous  work  on  Coins  and  Minting.  (A  part 
of  the  first  volume  was  published  in  1761  in 
Venice  under  the  title,  Delia  originc  e  del  com- 
mercio  della  moneta,  e  della  instituzione  delle 
zecche  d'  Italia ;  the  whole  of  the  first  volume 
was  published  at  the  Hague  in  1754  under  the 
title,  Belle  monete  e  dell'  instituzione  delle  zecche 
d'  Italia;  in  1757  he  published  the  second 
volume  at  Pisa,  and  in  1759  the  third  volume, 
in  two  parts,  at  Lucca.)  In  1766  he  published 
at  Milan  a  pamphlet  on  the  deterioration  of 
the  coin  in  Milan,  and  the  rules  he  gives  for 
amelioration  were,  later  on,  the  basis  of  the 
reform  which  was  effected.  Ten  years  later 
appeared  his  report  on  the  "Census  of  the 
State  of  Milan,"  containing  a  critical  history 
of  methods  for  valuations  of  property.  In 
1770  he  wi-ote  a  very  able  refutation  of  the 
mercantile  theories  concerning  the  wealth  of 
nations  as  measured  by  exports  and  imports 
{Breve  ragionamento  sopra  i  bilanci  economici 
delle  nazioni),  hence  it  is  somewhat  surprising 
to  find  him  writing  in  1771  a  pamphlet  on  the 
1  oom  trade  {Del  commercio  libera  dci  grani) 
in  support  of  Galiani,  combating  his  critics, 
and  strongly  in  favour  of  governmental  regula- 
tion of  this  branch  of  commerce.      Most  of 


I 


his  economical  writings  have  been  reprinted  ic 
CusTODi's  Economisti  Italiani,  Milan,  1804 
Besides  being  an  economist  he  was  a  good 
antiquarian  and  historical  writer.  He  tar- 
nished his  character  by  his  excessive  hatred 
and  jealousy  of  Pietro  Verri,  the  economist. 

M.  p. 
CARLYLE,  Thomas,  born  1795,  died  1881. 
Carlyle  conceived  that  a  true  political  economy 
should  be  a  political  philosophy  and  tell  us 
"what  is  meant  by  our  country,  and  by  what 
causes  men  are  happy,  moral,  religious,  or  the 
contrary  "  (see  Life  by  Froude,  vol.  ii.  p.  78). 
Economics  in  a  narrower  sense  was  associated 
by  him  with  Bentham  and  M'Culloch 
("  M'Croudy  "),  and  nicknamed,  through  a  mis- 
conception, pointed  by  the  power  which  paradox 
sometimes  exercised  even  over  his  happiest 
thoughts,  the  "dismal  science."  His  praises 
of  Work  and  Thrift  {Past  and  Present,  etc.  etc, ), 
his  description  (from  Franklin)  of  man  as  a 
tool-using  animal  {Sart.  Res.),  and  his  respect 
for  pioneers  who  drain  fens  (see  Cromwell)  or 
make  railroads,  like  "the  rugged  Brindley" 
{Past  and  Present),  or  reclaim  the  moors  and 
forests  {Latt.  D.  P.,  No.  1),  even  his  cardinal 
principle  "know  what  thou  canst  work  at" 
{Sart.  Res.),  are  the  outcome  of  his  character 
as  moral  teacher,  and  point  to  no  special  econo- 
mical bent,  though  the  last  no  doubt  implies 
the  economical  principle  of  division  of  labour. 
He  is  courteous  to  ' '  national  economy  "  when 
identified  with  Old  Frederick  William  (see 
Frederick  the  Great,  bk.  iv.  ch.  iii.),  and  he  even 
allows  that  English  political  economy  has  had 
its  lesson  to  teach  us  {Latt.  D.  P.,  No.  1). 
Even  "mammonism"  itself  "has  seized  some 
portion  of  the  message  of  nature  to  man  ;  and, 
seizing  that  and  following  it,  will  seize  and 
appropriate  more  and  more  of  nature's  message  " 
{Past  and  Present).  The  English  people  are 
the  wisest  in  action,  and  their  practical  material 
work  is  the  one  thing  they  have  to  show  for 
themselves  that  is  true  and  solid  {Past  and 
Present).  But  he  has  done  most  service  to 
economics  by  his  criticisms.  When  Past  and 
Present  appeared  (1843)  the Deutsch-Franzosische 
Jahrbiicher  of  Marx  and  Engels  (App.)  took 
note  of  it  as  the  most  important  book  of  the  day 
on  social  questions.  Carlyle  there  showed  that 
extreme  Laissez-Faire  may  mean  disintegra- 
tion of  society  and  simple  anarchy  ;  it  removes 
old  bonds,  and  leaves  men  disjoined  from  each 
other,  except  for  the  "nexus  of  cash  payments." 
The  result  is  the  "nomadic  servitude"  of  the 
working  classes  and  the  destruction  of  all 
security  and  permanence  in  their  conditions  of 
life.  In  the  Nigger  Question  (1849)  he  allows 
no  advantage  to  the  English  labourer  over  the 
West  Indian  slave  ;  the  slaves  were  "hired  for 
life,"  and  the  workman  are  hired  by  the  job. 
He  is  on  safer  ground  when  he  points  to  the 
common   liability  to  disease   as   a  wholesome 


228 


CAROLUS— CARRYING  TRADE 


reminder  to  the  rich  of  their  common  humanity 
with  the  poor  (Past  and  Present),  and  when  ho 
impresses  on  economists  the  fact  that  their 
Economic  Man  is  an  abstraction,  and  the 
universe  is  not  one  huge  shop.  He  derides 
mere  skill  in  selling  cheap  {Bohus  of  Hounds- 
ditch),  and  even  industrial  enterprise,  so  far  as 
it  aims  at  profit-making  (Hudson,  Plugson  of 
Undershot,  etc.).  But  he  is  firm  against  corn 
laws,  and  against  the  landowners  who  * '  refuse 
to  take  the  market  rate  for  their  onions,"  and 
forget  that  they  did  not  make  the  land  of  Eng- 
land. He  goes  farther  than  most  economists  in 
his  estimate  of  "captains  of  Industry,"  and  in 
his  view  that  the  relation  of  Master  and  Ser- 
vant is  eternal  (Nigger  Question).  He  shows  :io 
appreciation  of  the  power  of  workmen's  com- 
binations :  and  has  no  sympathy  with  nations 
and  peoples  as  distinguished  from  individuals. 
On  the  whole  economists  have  learned  more  from 
his  protests  against  abstract  Ricardian  political 
economy  and  its  tendency  to  reduce  the  state  to 
"anarchy  plus  the  constable"  than  from  any  of 
his  positive  teachings.  His  pleadings  had  their 
influence  even  with  men  like  John  Mill,  who 
were  perfectly  aware  of  their  defects  of  logic. 
It  should  be  added  that  the  "theory  of  depend- 
ence and  protection "  criticised  by  Mill  in  his 
chapter  on  the  "  Probable  Futurity  of  the 
Labouring  Classes  "  (Pol.  Econ.  iv.  vii.  §  1)  is 
essentially  that  of  Carlyle.  J.  b. 

CAROLUS  (English).  Gold  coin  (Charles  I. ) 
rated  at  20s.  Also  called  a  "unit"  or  "broad." 
Weight,  140-5  grains.  Fineness,  916-6.  Value 
at  £3  :  17 :  10^  an  ounce,  £1:2: 9^.      F.  E.  A. 

CAROLUS  DOLLAR.  A  name  sometimes 
given  to  the  Spanish  dollar  which  circulated 
for  many  years  throughout  America  and  in 
China  and  the  East  generally,  and  which  bore 
the  effigy  of  either  Carolus  III.  or  IV.  of  Spain. 
The  coin  was  also  known  as  a  "pillar  dollar," 
a  name  which  it  derived  from  the  fact  that  part 
of  the  device  on  its  reverse  consisted  of  two 
pillars,  intended  to  represent  the  Pillars  of 
Hercules  (the  Straits  of  Gibraltar).  Its  Spanish 
name  was  "peso  duro"  (or  hard  dollar).  It 
was  also  called  an  "eight  piece  "  on  account  of 
its  division  into  8  reals.  (For  the  dates  of 
issue,  weight,  and  fineness,  see  Dollar,  Hard.) 

F.  E.  A. 

CARRIER,  Common.  A  common  carrier  is 
one  who  plies  his  trade  between  certain  places 
and  regularly  undertakes  for  a  pecuniary  con- 
sideration to  transport  the  goods  of  all  who 
choose  to  employ  him.  At  common  law  the 
principal  duties  of  a  common  carrier  are :  (1) 
To  carry  all  things  belonging  to  the  description 
of  articles  which  he  publicly  professes  to  carry  for 
any  person  who  is  ready  to  pay  him  his  custom- 
ary hire,  provided  he  has  room  for  the  things 
in  his  cart  or  carriage,  or  other  means  of  trans- 
port.    (2)  To  take  proper  care  of  the  goods  he 


carries,  and  to  make  safe  delivery  to  'the  con- 
signee. He  is  responsible  for  loss  from  any 
cause  except  negligence  of  the  owner,  or  from 
their  nature,  or  from  any  occurrence  independ- 
ent of  man.  He  is  regarded  as  an  insurer  of 
the  goods,  and  cannot  by  public  notice  limit 
his  liability.  (3)  Every  carrier  of  passengers  for 
hire  is  answerable  for  the  least  want  of  fore- 
thought, skill,  or  care  in  himself  or  his  servants, 
arising  from  the  discoverable  defectiveness  of 
his  conveyance,  horses,  or  equipments.  He  is 
not  an  insurer  like  the  carrier  of  goods,  and  is 
not  therefore  responsible  for  latent  defects  which 
no  skill  or  care  could  have  detected.  ^  The  status 
of  a  common  carrier  at  common  law  has  been 
modified  by  the  following  statutes.  By  the 
Carriers  Act  11  Geo.  IV.  and  1  Will.  IV.  c.  68 
he  is  not  to  be  liable  for  the  loss  of  or  injury  to 
gold,  silver,  plated  articles,  precious  stones, 
jewellery,  watches,  clocks,  trinkets,  bills,  notes, 
securities,  stamps,  maps,  writings,  pictures, 
glass,  china,  silks,  furs,  or  lace  if  the  value  ex- 
ceeds £10,  unless  the  value  be  declared  and  an 
increased  charge  be  demanded  and  paid.  The 
act  does  not  apply  to  any  loss  or  injury  arising 
from  his  own  misfeasance  or  the  felonious  acts 
of  his  servants.  By  the  29  &  30  Vict.  c.  69  he 
is  not  bound  to  receive  specially  dangerous  goods. 

[Chitty  on  Contracts,  London,  1881. — Law  oj 
Carriers,  W.  H.  Maciiamara,  London,  1889. — 
Smith's  Mercantile  Law.  ]  J.  E.  c.  m. 

CARRYING  OVER.  On  all  stock  exchanges 
there  are  dates  for  settlements  of  bargains 
which  it  is  not  convenient  for  operators  to  ne- 
gotiate for  ready  money.  The  largest  settle- 
ments are  those  which  are  carried  on  in  the 
middle  and  near  the  end  of  each  month  on  the 
London  stock  exchange.  Before  the  dates  of 
settlement  those  who  have  bought  securities 
which  they  are  unwilling  to  pay  for,  and  those 
who  have  sold  what  they  cannot  deliver,  come 
to  an  agi-eement  by  which  the  bargains  are 
"carried  over."  Carrying  over,  then,  is  the 
process  of  postponing,  by  agreement,  the  date 
of  settlement.  If  the  stock  can  be  easily 
borrowed  in  the  market,  the  buyer  pays  a  rate 
of  interest,  sometimes  called  Continuation  or 
Contango,  for  the  privilege  of  prolonging  his 
bargain  till  the  next  settlement.  If  the  stock 
is  scarce,  it  sometimes  happens  that  a  seller, 
who  cannot  deliver  or  borrow  his  stock,  must 
pay  a  fine  called  Backwardation  {q.v.)  to  the 
buyer.  a.  e. 

CARRYING  TRADE.  "The  carrying 
trade,"  says  Adam  Smith,  "is  employed  in 
transacting  the  commerce  of  foreign  countries, 
or  in  carrying  the  surplus  produce  of  one  to 
another"  (bk.  ii.  ch.  5).  He  remarks  that 
the  line  of  distinction  is  often  not  drawn  with 
sufficient  clearness  between  it  and  the  foreign 
trade  of  consumj^tion.  In  a  celebrated  passage 
he  institutes  a  comparison  between  the  encour- 
agement and  support  given  to  the  productivp 


CARRYING  TRADE— CARUCAGE 


labour  of  a  country  by  the  wholesale  home 
trade,  the  foreign  trade  of  consumption,  and  the 
carrying  trade,  greatly  to  the  disadvantage  of 
the  last.  "That  part  of  the  capital  of  any 
country  which  is  employed  in  the  carrying  trade 
is  altogether  withdrawn  from  supporting  the 
productive  labour  of  that  country  to  support 
that  of  some  foreign  country.  Though  it  may 
replace  by  every  operation  two  distinct  capitals, 
yet  neither  of  them  belongs  to  that  particular 
country."  The  carrier's  profits  are  the  only 
addition  it  makes  to  the  wealth  of  the  country, 
except  in  so  far  as  the  part  of  the  capital  em- 
ployed in  it,  which  pays  the  Freight,  puts  into 
motion  a  certain  number  of  productive  labourers. 
The  carrying  trade,  being  carried  on  with  the 
surplus  remaining  after  the  home  and  foreign 
trades  are  provided  for,  is,  in  his  opinion,  ' '  the 
natural  effect  and  symptom  of  great  national 
wealth,  but  does  not  seem  to  be  the  natural 
cause  of  it."  Holland  had  still,  in  his  time, 
the  largest  share  of  the  carrying  trade  of  Europe, 
because  it  was,  in  proportion  to  its  territory 
and  population,  by  far  the  richest  country  in 
Europe  ;  England,  too,  was  held  to  have  a  large 
part,  but  much  of  it  was  really  a  "  round-about 
foreign  trade  of  consumption. "  Some  of  Adam 
Smith's  successors  have  disputed  his  views  re- 
specting the  economic  nature  of  the  carrying 
trade,  and  have  maintained  that  it  is  a  matter 
of  indifference  to  a  nation  how  a  capital  is  em- 
ployed so  long  as  the  ordinary  rate  of  profit  is 
obtained.  But  see  Prof.  Nicholson's  Preface 
to  his  edition  of  the  Wealth  of  Nations. 

There  is  a  tract  entitled  "  Observations 
touching  Trade  and  Commerce  with  the  Hol- 
landers and  other  Nations,"  which  is  commonly 
attributed  to  Sir  Walter  Raleigh,  and  which 
appears  at  least  to  have  been  laid  by  him  in 
manuscript  before  James  I.  In  this  a  very  in- 
teresting account  is  given  of  the  caiTying  trade 
of  Holland.  The  origin  of  it  he  represents  as  due 
to  the  mismanagement  of  the  Portuguese.  The 
"home-bred  commodities"  of  the  Hollanders 
he  represents  as  insignificant  in  amount,  and 
"not  a  timber  tree,"  he  says,  "grows  in  their 
country";  yet  "  their  traffick  with  the  Hans- 
towns  exceeds  in  shipping  all  Christendom." 
They  transported  the  "merchandises  of  France, 
Portugal,  Spain,  Italy,  Turkey,  East  and  West 
Indies,  into  the  east  and  north-east  kii;gdoms 
of  Pomerland,  Spruceland,  Poland,  Denmark, 
Sweedland,  Leifland  and  Germany,  and  the 
merchandises  brought  from  the  last-mentioned 
kingdoms  .  .  .  into  the  southern  and  western 
dominions. "  Their  success  he  attributes  mainly 
to  their  judicious  and  liberal  regulations  for  the 
encouragement  of  commerce. 

It  is  commonly  believed  that  the  first  heavy 
blow  to  the  Dutch  carrying  trade  was  dealt  by  the 
English  Navigation  Act  of  1651,  re-enacted, 
with  some  modifications,  after  the  Restoration 
('12   Chas.    II.    ch.    18).     Some   have   denied 


this,  but,  it  would  seem,  on  insufficient  grounds. 
That  the  Dutch  sufiered  by  this  legislation  can 
scarcely  be  doubted,  though  it  may  well  be 
questioned  whether  England  gained  by  it  in  a 
commercial  sense.  Politically,  that  is  to  say, 
in  relation  to  the  strength  and  security  of  the 
state,  Adam  Smith  pronounces  the  acts,  though 
prompted  in  some  degree  by  national  animosity, 
to  have  been  "as  wise  as  if  they  had  been  dic- 
tated by  the  most  deliberate  wisdom." 

J.  K.  I. 

CARTEL.  Cartel  means,  in  international 
law,  the  terms  of  agi-eement  between  belligerents 
for  the  exchange  or  ransom  of  prisoners.  The 
"  cartel "  of  chivalry  meant  first  of  all  the  terms 
of  a  combat,  and  then  simply  the  challenge  ; 
and  the  second  is  still  its  ordinary  meaning  on 
the  Continent.  By  analogy,  the  word  Kartell 
is  now  often  used  by  German  economists  to 
denote  a  Trust,  i.e.  an  agreement  between 
rival  merchants  to  limit  production  or  other- 
wise temper  the  extremity  of  competition  ;  so 
in  1889  it  was  used  of  the  suspension  of  hos- 
tilities between  conservative  and  liberal  parties 
in  view  of  the  common  defence  of  the  empire. 

J.  B. 

CARTOGRAM.  A  cartogram  is  a  representa- 
tion ' '  in  which  the  geographical  map  shows 
the  totals  or  the  ratios  of  the  different  units  by 
various  inserted  diagrams  and  hexagrams " 
(see  Graphical  Method). 

[I'aper  by  E.  Levasseur,  "La  Statistique  Graph- 
ique,"  Jiihilee  Volume  of  the  Statistical  Society , 
London  1885. — Annals  of  the  American  Academy, 
Supplement,  May  1891,  "The  liistory,  Theory, 
and  Technique  of  Statistics,"  by  A.  Meitzen.] 

CARUCAGE.  A  tax  levied  on  the  carucate, 
the  amount  of  land  cultivated  by  one  full 
plough  team  of  eight  oxen.  It  has  been 
asserted  that  the  carucage  was  levied  on  the 
plough  (caruca),  and  that  a  tax  levied  on  the 
carucate  of  land  was  neither  a  carucage  nor  so 
termed  by  contemporary  authorities.  That  the 
mention  of  the  carucate  Avas  much  earlier  than 
that  of  the  carucage  can  hardly  be  doubted. 
Equally  surely  may  it  be  surmised  that  con- 
temporaries recognised  a  tax  levied  on  the 
carucate  as  a  carucage  (Leland,  Coll.  p.  223). 
The  point  is  one  of  considerable  importance. 
In  the  first  place  were  the  incidence  of  the 
carucage  on  the  plough,  not  on  the  soil,  valu- 
able information  would  be  furnished  as  to  the 
steps  in  the  transfer  of  taxation  from  "land" 
to  "movables"  (cp.  Scutage  and  Knight's 
Fee).  In  the  second  place  the  discussion  as  to 
carucage  has  included  a  close  investigation  of 
the  circumstances  of  the  tax  levied  by  Richard  I. 
in  1198  towards  the  payment  of  his  ransom 
{Eng.  Hist.  Rev.  iii.  501,  702  ;  iv.  105). 
Though  this  levy  has  been  customarily  spoken 
of  as  a  carucage,  there  is  no  doubt  that  it  is  not 
so  referred  to  in  documents  of  the  time  ;  there  is 
equally  no  doubt  that  it  was  levied   on  the 


230 


GARY— CASH 


caracate.  Indeed,  its  chief  importance  in  the 
history  of  taxation  lies  in  the  fact  that  it  was 
levied  after  a  new  and  careful  survey  of  the 
country  had  been  made,  whereby  the  actual 
ploughland  was  to  be  substituted  for  the 
nominal  Hide  "as  the  unit  of  taxation."  In 
this  aspect  it  marks  an  important  stage;  The 
carucate  contained  four  bovates,  and  has  been 
estimated  from  Fleta  as  comprising  160  acres  in 
a  two-course,  and  180  in  a  three-course  Manor. 

[Eng.  Hist.  Hev.,  op.  cit. ;  Dowell,  History  of 
Taxation,  vol.  i.  ch.  v.  ;  Madox,  Exchequer.'] 

E.  c.  K.  a. 

GARY,  John  (died  soon  after  1719),  an 
influential  Bristol  merchant,  author  of  An 
Essay  on  the  State  of  England  in  Relation  to  its 
Trade,  its  Poor,  and  its  Taxes,  1695,  which 
Locke  calls  **the  best  discourse  I  ever  read  on 
that  subject,"  and  speaks  of  "the  undoubted 
evidence  of  most  of  it "  (Letter  to  Gary,  Brit. 
Mus.  Addit.  MS.  5540,  p.  70).  This  work 
was  reissued  several  times,  with  alterations,  and 
under  different  titles — An  Essay  towards  Regu- 
lating the  Trade  and  employing  the  Poor  in  this 
Kingdom,  1717  and  1719  ;  A  Discourse  on 
Trade,  1745.  It  was  translated  into  French, 
1755,  with  additions  said  by  M'Golloch  to  be 
improvements,  and  retranslated  into  Italian 
1764.  Some  extracts  from  Gary's  work  were 
published  separately,  and  some  tracts  originally 
separate  have  been  bound  up  with  the  main 
work. 

The  most  valuable  part  of  Gary's  work  is 
perhaps  that  which  relates  to  the  employment 
of  the  poor,  for  which  purpose  he  proposed  a 
combination  between  parishes  (Essay  suh  finem, 
appendix  to  Discourse).  Gorrect  views  on  the 
relation  between  the  quality  of  coin  and  the 
exchanges  are  found  in  the  tract  On  the  Coin 
and  Credit  of  England,  1696  (see  Macleod, 
DictioTiary ;  also  Banking,  vol.  i.  p.  403).  In 
An  Essay  towards  Settling  a  National  Credit, 
1696,  a  national  bank  is  proposed.  Other  re- 
commendations embody  the  doctrines  of  protec- 
tion and  the  balance  of  trade  in  their  most 
specious  forms.  Bullion  imported  "adds  to 
the  wealth  of  the  nation"  (Essay,  pp.  2,  116), 
but  not  so  much  as  raw  material,  "  the  subject 
matter  of  a  great  manufacture."  The  difficulty 
of  applying  these  principles  is  illustrated  by 
Gary's  observations  on  different  branches  of 
British  trade.  He  reckons  that  England  loses 
by  the  East  India  trade  (see  Ghild),  and  wishes 
fashion  would  encourage  native  woollens  rather 
than  Oriental  calicoes  (Essay,  pp.  52-65).  He 
would  discourage  the  Irish  woollen  manufacture 
in  the  interest  of  Ireland  as  weU  as  England  (ibid. 
p.  91).  He  would  encourage  the  Irish  linen 
manufacture  (Essay,  p.  109,  appendix  to  the  Dis- 
course) and  the  export  from  Ireland  both  of  raw 
wool  and  of  cattle  and  other  agricultural  produce 
(ibid.  p.  107).  He  would  "open"  the  African 
trade  in  negroes,  "being  indeed  the  best  traffick 


the  kingdom  hath,  as  it  doth  occasionally  giva 
so  vast  an  employment  to  our  people  both  by  sea 
and  land  "  (ibid.  p.  75). 

Some  of  these  topics  are  discussed  in  letters 
to  and  from  Gary,  Brit.  Mies.  Addit.  MS. 
5540.  F.  Y.  E. 

GASAREGIS,  Josephus  Latjeentius  Maria 
DE,  born  1670  at  Genoa,  died  1737  at 
Florence. 

The  author  of  the  Discursus  legates  de  Com- 
mercio,  Flor.  1719-29,  and  of  a  treatise  bearing 
the  title  ;  II  cambista  instruito  per  ogni  modo  di 
fallimenti,  Venezia,  1737.  m.  p. 

GASE  OF  NEED.     See  Bill  of  Exchange. 

GASH.  Monet  :  Giroulation  :  Gurrbnoy. 
All  that  may  be  reckoned  as  equivalent  to 
money,  or  the  owner  can  at  option  obtain 
possession  of  in  money  on  demand.  Thus 
coin,  bank-notes,  postal  notes,  bankers' 
balances  on  current  account,  and  cheques  to 
bearer,  may  aU  be  reckoned  as  cash  in  the 
country  where  they  are  current,  their  instant 
convertibility  into  currency  being  alone 
requisite  to  bring  under  the  designation 
"  cash."  It  is  evident  from  this  that  cash  and 
money  are  words  having  a  very  different  signi- 
fication. The  money  in  a  country  in  coin  is  a 
determinable  quantity  ;  the  cash  resources  of 
the  community  are  in  this  country  nearly  as 
much  greater  than  the  actual  money  in  circula- 
tion as  the  banking  deposits  are  greater  than 
the  cash  actually  held  by  the  banks  holding 
those  deposits.  It  may  safely  be  assumed  that 
all  who  are  possessed  of  banking  accounts  hold 
the  bulk  of  their  cash  in  their  bankers'  hands, 
and  there  are  estimates  formed,  or  statistics 
available,  of  aU  these  descriptions  of  cash  in 
the  hands  of  the  public.  If,  therefore,  bankers' 
current  accounts,  say,  half  their  deposits  are 
included  among  the  "cash"  resources  of  this 
country  the  whole  may  be  briefly  estimated  as : — 

Gold  In  circulation      ....  £100,000,000 

Silver           „ 25,000,000 

Bronze         „ 5,000,000 

Postal  notes  and  orders      .        .        .  2,000,000 

Banking  accounts  current          .        .  600,000,000 

Bankers'  notes  and  drafts  at  sight     .  50,000,000 


Total  cash  resources  U.  K. 


£782,000,000 


This  is  a  rough  estimate  for  the  year  1914,  the 
coin  in  circulation  excluding  that  in  bankers' 
hands,  and  the  banking  accounts  excluding 
money  at  notice.  The  coin  in  the  banks  is 
excluded  from  the  gold  in  circulation  because 
it  is  represented  in  the  accounts  current,  and 
cheques  outstanding  are  included  in  the  same 
item.  It  is  not  intended  here  to  enlarge  upon 
the  different  forms  of  Gash,  for  which  reference 
should  be  made  to  the  articles  Banking  ;  Bank- 
note  ;  Gheques,  Law  of. 

GASH  (or  Li).  The  lowest  denomination  of 
the  Ghinese  money  of  account ;  a  brass  coin  ;  the 
only  coin  as  yet  issued  by  the  Ghinese  govern- 
ment.   Nominally  1000  cash  =  1  Tael  (the  unit 


CASH  ACCOUNT— CASTE 


231 


of  value),  but  in  consequence  of  successive  reduc- 
tions in  their  weight  they  are  now  only  received' 
in  circulation  at  from  one  1600th  to  one  1800th 
of  a  tael.  By  a  proclamation  in  1889,  cash 
from  the  Canton  mint  were  ordered  to  be  re- 
ceived at  their  nominal  value,  one  1000th  of  a 
Tael.  This  was  disregarded.  The  decree  of  May 
1910  fixed  the  silver  dollar,  suggested  value  two 
shillings,  as  the  unit  of  the  currency,    r.  R.  a. 

CASH  ACCOUNT.  A  record  of  current 
cash  receipts  and  payments,  usually  kept  in  a 
book  termed  the  cash-book.  Hence  it  follows 
that  the  difference  between  the  one  side  of  the 
account  and  the  other  exactly  represents  the 
cash  balance  to  date,  and  available  for  all 
current  purposes.  This  account  is  essential  for 
purposes  of  book-keeping,  and  in  important 
businesses  its  total  should  be  made  day  by  day 
to  agree  with,  and  in  fact  be  the  same  as,  the 
current  account  at  the  bank  ;  as  of  course  it 
will  when  all  receipts  are  paid  into  the  bank, 
and  payments  are  made  by  cheque.  The 
auditor,  for  instance,  who  thus  has  all  the 
receipts  and  payments  for  a  given  period  veri- 
fied by  the  pass-book,  together  with  the 
balances  owing  and  receivable  at  the  date  of 
closing  the  accounts,  is  at  once  placed  in  a 
position  to  construct  a  revenue  account  for  tlie 
period  under  consideration,  and  possesses  a 
general  voucher  as  to  the  accuracy  of  the  cash 
transactions  entered. 

Some  further  description  of  the  cash-book, 
however,  is  necessary.  In  its  simj)lest  form  it 
is  ruled  for  debtor  and  creditor  entries — the 
first  column  for  the  entry  of  the  date  ;  the 
second  for  the  entry  of  the  description  of  the 
receipt  on  the  one  side,  or  payment  on  the 
other  side  ;  the  third  for  the  entry  of  the  ledger 
folio  ;  and  the  fourth  for  the  pounds,  shillings, 
and  pence  received  or  paid  under  that  particular 
head.  Many  cash-books,  however,  are  ruled 
with  a  considerable  number  of  cash  columns,  so 
as  to  separate  and  classify  the  different  items  of 
receipt  and  payment.  For  instance,  the  cash- 
book  of  a  gas  company  may  contain  on  the 
receipt  side  four  columns  representing  so  many 
collecting  districts,  a  fifth  column  for  cash 
received  for  sales  of  coke,  a  sixth  column  for 
residual  products  and  miscellaneous,  and  a 
seventh  column  for  the  weekly  totals.  On  the 
other  side  there  would  be  six  columns  recording 
different  descriptions  of  wages  and  salaries, 
coal,  buildings,  implements,  and  repairs  of 
mains,  and  the  weekly  total ;  the  account  thus 
arranged  would  be  regularly  examined  by  the 
board,  and  compared  with  the  corresponding 
periods  of  previous  years.  The  cash-book  in 
this  instance  indicated  much  more  than  the 
simple  receipts  and  payments  of  money :  it 
indicated  the  progress  made  in  each  district  and 
in  all  branches  of  their  operations.  This  is  but 
an  illustration  of  what  a  properly  constructed 
cash  account  is  made  to  show. 


CASH  CREDIT.  In  Scotch  banking,  a 
mode  of  advancing  money  by  permitting  an 
account  current  to  be  regularly  operated  on  and 
overdrawn  up  to  a  certain  specified  limit.  The 
advances  are  secured  to  the  bank  by  two  cau- 
tioners or  securities,  and  interest  is  paid  on 
actual  overdrafts.  In  earlier  years  this  method 
of  advancing  served  largely  to  develop  com- 
mercial enterprise  in  Scotland,  but  during  recent 
years  the  country  has  become  richer  and  the 
Scotch  banks  have,  since  they  set  up  branch 
offices  in  London,  applied  themselves  to  negoti- 
ating bills  at  current  market  rates  rather  than 
to  employing  money  in  cash  credits.        A.  d. 

CASH,  Sale  for.  On  the  stock  exchange 
bargains  are  sometimes  done  for  cash  as  dis- 
tinguished from  payment  and  delivery  on  the 
succeeding  settling  day.  That  for  Consols  ia 
the  onlymarket  on  the  London  stock  exchange  in 
which  a  broker,  asking  for  a  price,  would  receive 
a  quotation  "for  cash."  This  "consol  market" 
includes  Metropolitan  Board  of  Works  stocks, 
Indian  sterling  stocks,  also  Colonial  inscribed 
stocks.  In  other  stock  markets  the  quotation 
would  be  for  purchase  or  sale  on  the  date  of  the 
next  settlement.  a.  e. 

CASHIER.  In  English  banks  and  offices 
the  clerk  appointed  to  take  charge  of  the  cash 
is  designated  by  this  title,  occasionally  by  that 
of  "teller."  For  convenience  sake  the  work  is 
sometimes  divided  between  receiving  and  paying 
cashiers.  The  duties  of  the  office  require  intelli- 
gence, quickness,  and  firmness,  with  a  pleasant 
manner  of  addressing  people.  The  position 
differs  in  some  banks.  The  chief  officer,  the 
general  manager  of  a  bank  as  he  would  more 
usually  be  termed,  is  sometimes  spoken  of  as 
the  cashier.  In  the  United  States  the  cashier 
is  spoken  of  much  in  the  same  way.  Horton, 
C.  J.,  has  remarked,  "The  cashier  is  the  execu- 
tive of  the  financial  department  of  the  bank, 
and  whatever  is  to  be  done,  either  to  receive  or 
pass  away  the  funds  of  the  bank  for  banking 
purposes,  is  done  by  him  or  under  his  direction ; 
he  therefore  directs  and  represents  the  bank  in 
the  reception  and  emission  of  money  for  bank- 
ing objects"  (Asher  v.  Sutton,  31  Kan.  p.  289, 
quoted  in  American  Banker's  Magazine,  July 
1889).  The  care  and  management  of  the 
property  of  the  bank,  and  the  conduct  of  its 
business  in  the  usual  and  ordinary  way  are  in 
these  cii'cumstances  among  the  duties  of  the 
cashier  ;  their  scope  is  in  England  restricted 
usually  in  the  narrower  sense. 

[J.  W.  Gilbart's  Practical  Treatise  on  Banking. 
— G.  Rae's  Country  Banker. — J.  Hutchison's  The 
Practice  of  Banking. — The  English  Bankers 
Magazine,  and  the  American  Bankers  Magazine, 
passim,  may  be  cited.] 

-  CASTE.  This  word  is  derived  from  the 
Portuguese  casta  "white,  pure;"  and  is  used 
by  Em-opeans  as  the  name  of  an  institution 


232 


CASTE 


which  they  believed  themselves  to  have  found 
in  the  East  Indies.  There  is  no  native  word 
exactly  corresponding  to  the  idea  formed  by 
Europeans;  but  jdti  "birth,"  and  varna 
"colour,"  supply  its  place.  In  the  oldest 
records  of  the  Aryan  race  in  India,  that  is 
the  oldest  hymns  contained  in  the  Vedasj  there 
is  no  mention  of  caste.  It  is  in  a  celebrated 
hymn  called  the  Perrusha  Siikta,  which  is  in 
a  later  appendix  to  the  older  ones,  that  we 
first  find  a  reference  to  the  four  principal 
divisions  of  Indian  caste  : — the  Brahmins,  the 
Kshakiyas  or  nobles,  the  Vaishyas  or  peasantry 
and  traders,  and  the  Shudras  or  servants.  But 
caste  itself,  as  an  institution,  is  neither  men- 
tioned nor  even  inferred  in  the  actual  words 
of  the  poem,  which  may  be  dated  approximately 
at  about  800  B.C.  In  a  passage  repeated  in 
both  recensions  of  the  Gajur  Veda  we  have  a  long 
list  of  seven  hundred  and  sixty  divisions  into 
which  the  people  of  India  were  then  divided.  It 
is  very  interesting  as  containing  many  names 
(partly  of  trades,  partly  of  tribes)  which  after- 
wards became  caste-names.  But  that  it  is  not 
a  list  of  castes  is  clear  from  the  fact  that  it 
includes  also  a  number  of  such  divisions  as 
thief,  back-biter,  dwarf,  leper,  red-eyed  man, 
barren  woman,  and  so  on — a  classification  quite 
independent  of  the  idea  of  caste.  From  that 
time  onwards  each  later  Hindu  book  shows 
a  marked  growth  of  the  development  of  caste 
feeling,  until  in  the  law  book  of  the  Manavas, 
also  called  the  Laws  of  Mann,  which  may  have 
reached  its  present  shape  about  a  century  before 
our  era,  we  find  the  institution  of  caste,  as  at 
present  understood,  in  full  vitality.  Import- 
ant privileges  are  accorded  to  men  of  the  higher 
castes  ;  crimes  are  punished,  not  only  according 
to  the  nature  of  the  crime,  but  according  to  the 
caste  of  the  criminal ; — it  may  be  inferred, 
though  it  is  nowhere  actually  stated,  that 
occupations  are  usually  hereditary  and  depend- 
ent upon  caste  ; — caste  is  lost  by  eating  or 
drinking,  and  of  course  by  sexual  intercourse 
with  the  lower  castes  ;  marriage  is  restricted  by 
the  distinctions  of  caste  ;  and  to  lose  caste 
altogether,  to  become  an  "outcaste,"  has  become 
almost  the  greatest  of  disasters.  On  looking 
more  carefully,  however,  into  the  castes  men- 
tioned in  Manu,  sixty  in  number,  we  find  them 
to  be  mostly  diff"erent  not  only  from  the  castes 
now  actually  existing,  but  also  from  the  quasi- 
caste  names  in  the  early  list  of  divisions  of  the 
people  mentioned  above,  and  in  other  similar 
lists  found  in  the  Milindu  and  in  the  Rama- 
yana  (which  are  somewhat  later  than  Manu). 
This  is  to  be  explained  by  the  fact  that  the 
caste  divisions  of  the  many  peoples  in  the  great 
continent  of  India  have,  from  the  first,  been 
constantly  though  sloAvly  changing.  The 
institution  has  remained,  and  remained  with 
similar  restrictions.  But  the  lines  of  the  divi- 
sion have  varied.     The  history  of  each  caste 


requires,  indeed,  to  be  separately  examined  ; 
and  examined  from  each  of  its  various  sides — 
as  a  trade  guild,  as  a  racial  division,  as  a  circle 
within  which  marriage  is  permitted,  as  a  com- 
munity with  legal  powers  over  its  own  members, 
even  as  a  religious  sect.  The  commonly-received 
notion  of  "  The  immovable  East "  is  due  simply 
to  the  ignorance  of  Western  writers.  And 
there  is  no  better  example  of  the  mistakes  into 
which  that  idea  may  lead  us  than  the  concep- 
tion of  an  iron  system  of  caste  whose  bounds 
none  may  pass  over.  "When  the  Dutch  began 
cinnamon  planting  in  Ceylon  they  were  in  need 
of  labourers,  ' '  coolies "  as  they  are  called, 
"men  working  for  hire."  A  peasant  in  India 
looks  upon  the  labourer  for  hire  as  a  disgrace. 
Those,  of  whatever  caste,  whose  necessities 
drove  them  to  accept  the  terms  off'ered,  were 
looked  down  upon.  And  so  rapid  was  the 
effect  of  this  feeling  that  in  a  couple  of  genera- 
tions an  entirely  new  caste  was  formed,  that  of 
the  "  cinnamon-pealers. "  For  nearly  a  century 
the  trade  flourished,  and  their  numbers  in- 
creased. For  the  last  seventy  years  the  trade 
has  steadily  diminished.  But  the  caste,  the 
members  of  which  are  now  engaged  for  the 
most  part  in  other  occupations,  remained. 
Throughout  its  short  but  most  instructive 
history  it  had  never  been  (as  the  majority  of 
the  castes  have  been)  identical  with  a  division 
of  race.  For  some  generations  it  had  fulfilled 
many  of  the  functions  of  a  trade  guild  and  of  a 
trades  union,  functions  now  only  feebly  surviv- 
ing. But  it  is  still  in  full  vitality  as  a  restric- 
tion on  marriage,  and  as  an  index  of  social 
position.  This  instance  has  been  chosen  because 
all  the  facts  are  ascertainable  from  the  official 
documents  of  European  administrators.  But  a 
comparison  of  the  lists  referred  to  above,  and 
of  lists  of  the  different  castes  now  existing  in 
different  parts  of  India,  show  that  it  is  only  a 
sample  of  many  changes  that  have  occurred  in  the 
caste-system  of  that  continent.  There  are  about 
one  hundred  and  fifty  castes  to-day  in  the  Bom- 
bay Presidency.  No  one  has  yet  attempted  to 
-write  their  history.  It  is  probable  that  most  of 
them  are,  as  castes,  of  comparatively  recent 
origin,  and  each  one  of  the  one  hundred  and  fifty 
must  be  considered  apart  from  the  others  in  order 
to  ascertain  the  vitality  of  its  caste  powers  and 
feelings  in  respect  of  race,  of  religion,  of  trade, 
and  of  family  ties.  There  are  numerous  instances 
in  the  books  of  transition  of  an  individual  from 
one  caste  to  another.  It  is  quite  common  for 
a  man  of  one  caste  to  follow  the  occupation 
usually  assigned  to  another.  And  there  are, 
on  the  other  hand,  trade  guilds  independent 
of  caste  ;  and  castes  within  castes,  so  far  as 
marriage  is  concerned.  Even  among  the 
Brahmins,  very  few  can  trace  their  descent 
from  pure  Brahmins.  They  are  split  up  into 
innumerable  exogamous  gotras  or  families,  somt 
of  which  are  not  Brahmins  at  all  by  descent 


CASTE— CATASTO 


233 


And  they  follow  every  imaginable  sort  of  occupa- 
tion except  only  those  assigned  to  certain  of 
the  lower  castes.  Certain  Beldars,  for  instance, 
excavated  as  navvies  the  now  sacred  lake  of 
Pushkara  or  Pokhar  in  Marwar.  Their  de- 
scendants rank  as  Brahmins,  have  raised  the 
pick -axe  into  an  object  of  worship,  and  are 
found  to  the  number  of  twenty  or  thirty 
thousand,  throughout  Rajputana  and  Sind, 
as  a  special  gotra  called  tlie  Pokhar  Brahmins. 
Each  of  the  constantly  recuiTing  religious 
movements  in  India  has  had  a  profound 
influence  on  caste.  Many  of  the  greatest 
leaders,  from  Gotama  the  Buddha  downwards, 
have  commenced  by  protesting  against  caste 
distinctions,  and  entirely  abolishing  them 
within  the  inner  circle  of  their  more  ardent 
followers.  Caste  among  the  laymen  of  the 
new  communities  was  for  the  most  part  left 
undistm-bed.  But,  though  in  different  degrees, 
the  new  religious  communities  became  them- 
selves the  source  of  new  caste  divisions,  and 
people  of  the  same  caste,  but  of  different 
religions,  ceased  to  intermarry.  It  will  be 
seen  that  the  subject  of  caste  in  India  is  one 
of  very  great  complexity.  Dr.  "Wilson  of 
Bombay  had  intended  to  undertake  the  gigantic 
task  of  bringing  order  into  the  chaos  of  our 
knowledge  of  the  subject.  He  died  when  the 
work,  though  he  had  laboured  at  it  for  years, 
was  really  only  begun.  There  were  published, 
however,  two  volumes  entitled  Indian  Caste 
(Blackwood  and  Sons,  London  and  Edinburgh, 
1877,  pp.  450  and  228)  in  the  first  of  which 
he  has  collected  together  all  the  references  to 
caste  he  could  find  in  Hindu  literature  from 
the  Vedic  times  downwards  ;  and  in  the  second 
of  which  he  attempts  to  trace  in  detail  the 
history  and  the  present  occupations  of  one  caste 
only,  that  of  the  Brahmins,  in  all  its  numerous 
details.  Even  that  is  confessedly  imperfect ;  and 
there  is  no  other  work  in  which  even  an  attempt 
has  been  made  to  explain  either  the  past  history 
or  the  present  position  of  any  of  the  other  castes. 
Various  details  as  to  the  numbers  of  the 
different  castes,  not  in  India  as  a  whole,  but 
in  particular  districts,  can  be  found  in  the  local 
Gazetteers  and  Census  reports  of  the  Indian 
Government.  But  they  have  not  yet  been  pro- 
perly summarised  or  analysed.  It  would  be  un- 
desirable, in  the  present  state  of  our  ignorance 
of  the  subject,  to  attempt  to  form  any  estimate  of 
the  economic  influence  of  the  caste  system.  It 
is  doubtful  to  the  writer  whether  it  has  really 
had  any  practical  effect  in  restraint  of  trade. 
But  the  few  words  here  devoted  to  the  subject 
may  remove  some  misconceptions,  and  the 
numerous  authorities  quoted  by  Dr.  Wilson 
will  assist  those  who  wish  to  investigate  tlie 
problem  further.  T.  w.  E.  D. 

CASUEL.  A  general  term  in  France  for  a 
revenue  which  was  not  fixed,  but  proportioned 
to  the  performance  of  work.     It  was  specially 


applied  to  the  fees  charged  by  the  clergy  foi 
baptism,  marriage,  burial,  and  the  other  sacra- 
ments of  the  Roman  Catholic  chm-ch.      r.  l. 

CASUS.  An  expression  used  by  Roman 
la^vyers  to  express  events  which  could  not  have 
been  avoided  by  the  strictest  amount  of  diligence 
required  by  the  law  in  ordinary  cases.  The 
expression  does  not  quite  correspond  with  the 
English  "Act  of  God,"  which  is  the  equivalent 
of  the  Roman  vis  major,  and  includes  those 
events  only  which  could  not  by  any  amount  of 
care  have  been  foreseen  or  controlled  under  the 
special  circumstances.  e.  s. 

CATALLACTICS,  or  the  Science  of  Ex- 
changes, is  a  name  proposed  by  Archbishop 
Whately  as  conveying  a  much  better  idea  of 
the  nature  of  economic  science  than  is  conveyed 
by  the  name  political  economy.  Other  writers, 
e.g.  Mr.  H.  D.  Macleod,  have  also  regarded  the 
exchange  of  wealth  as  constituting  par  excellence 
the  subject-matter  of  the  science.  More  gener- 
ally, however,  it  is  held  that  while  the  laws  of 
exchange  occupy  a  fundamentally  important 
place  in  economics,  the  science  is  equally  con- 
cerned with  the  laws  of  the  Production,  Dis- 
tribution, and  Consu:mi'tion  of  Wealth. 

A  Catalladic  community  has  been  defined  as 
one  in  which  individuals  freely  exchange  com- 
modities one  with  another,  each  with  a  view  to 
making  the  enjoyment  he  derives  from  his 
possessions  a  maximum. 

[An  anonymous  treatise  was  published  in  Lon- 
don, 1842,  entitled  Letters  on  the  rudiments  of  a 
Science  called  Catallactics.]  j.  n.  k. 

CATASTO.  Taxation  in  mediseval  Florence 
was  an  important  political  weapon,  because  it 
was  based  upon  an  arbitrary  assessment  of  real 
and  personal  property.  Thus  the  party  in 
power  could  ruin  its  political  opponents  by 
excessive  taxation.  In  1427,  when  the  oligarch- 
ical party  had  the  upper  hand  under  Rinaldo 
degli  Albizzi  and  Nicolo  da  Uzzano,  the  opposi- 
tion, headed  by  Giovanni  de  Medici,  endeav- 
oured to  reform  this  abuse  by  securing  the 
adoption  of  the  catasto.  The  object  of  this 
reform  was  to  obtain  a  careful  and  impartial 
registration  of  property,  so  that  the  incidence 
of  taxation  should  depend  upon  wealth  alone, 
and  not  upon  political  opinion.  Every  citizen 
was  to  make  a  return  to  the  gonfalonier  of  his 
district  of  his  whole  income,  from  whatever 
source.  His  income  from  capital,  whether 
fixed  or  circulating,  was  to  be  reckoned  at  7 
per  cent.  If  a  man  concealed  anything  the 
penalty  was  confiscation.  These  returns  were 
to  be  collected  into  four  books,  one  for  each 
quarter  of  the  city.  The  assessment  of  taxes, 
which  was  to  be  strictly  based  upon  the  record 
of  these  books,  was  entrusted  to  a  commission 
.  of  ten,  who  were  elected  out  of  sixty  citizens 
-chosen  by  lot.  A  new  catasto  was  to  be  made 
every  three  years. 

This   admirable   reform   was    abrogated    by 


234 


CATTANEO— CAVOUR 


Cosimo  de  Medici,  the  son  of  Giovanni,  to  whom 
Machiavelli  ascribes  the  chief  credit  of  the 
change.  Cosimo,  who  overthrew  the  oligarchy 
in  1434,  and  laid  the  foundation  of  the  Medici 
dynasty,  returned  to  the  system  of  arbitrary 
assessment.  It  was  said  of  him  that  he  used 
the  taxes  as  the  northern  despots  used  *  the 
dagger.  His  object,  however,  was  not  only  to 
ruin  his  opponents,  but  also  to  conciliate  the 
lower  classes  by  diminishing  the  burden  of 
taxation  upon  them  and  throwing  it  upon  the 
rich. 

[Machiavelli,  History  of  Florence,  bk.  iv.  ch.  iii. 
Gino  Capponi,  Storia  deUa  Itepublica  di  Firenze, 
libro  iv.  cap.  vii.]  R.  l. 

CATTANEO,  Carlo,  bom  1801  in  Milan. 
He  wrote  frequently  in  the  Annali  Universali 
di  Statistica  and  in  the  PoUtecnico.  He  dis- 
tinguished himself  in  the  defence  of  Milan  in 
1848,  against  the  Austrians,  but  was  a  feder- 
alist, opposing  the  union  of  Lombardy  with 
Piedmont.  He  was  elected  three  times  a  deputy, 
but  never  sat  in  Parliament,  because,  as  a  re- 
publican, he  refused  to  take  the  oath.  He 
died  in  1869  at  Castagnola,  close  to  Lugano. 
His  works  are  as  yet  only  partially  published. 
His  principal  subject  was  land  tenure.  Besides 
his  economical  writings,  in  which  he  shows 
himself  a  decided  opponent  of  List  and  his 
?ystem,  he  wrote  historical  and  literary  com- 
positions of  value. 

Among  his  writings  are  the  following :  Notizie 
naturali  della  Lowhardia,  Milano,  1844. — Storia 
delta  rivoluzione  del  48,  Lugano,  tipogr.  Svizzera, 
1849.— C7"^o  Foscolo  e  V Italia,  Milano,  1861.— 
Della  jpena  di  morte,  Milano,  1860.  —  Alcuni 
scritti,  Milano,  1846-47,  vol.  iii. — Borroni  e 
Scotti. — V Italia  armata,  Milano,  1861.      m.  p. 

CATTLE  PLAGUE  ORDERS.  By  the  41 
&  42  Vict.  c.  74,  47  &  48  Vict.  cc.  13,  43,  47, 
and  49  &  50  Vict.  c.  32,  very  extensive  powers 
are  given  to  the  privy  council  for  the  preven- 
tion of  contagious  diseases  amongst  animals. 
These  powers  are  exercised  by  means  of  "  orders  " 
issued  when  necessary.  The  privy  council  may 
declare  what  places  are  infected  areas,  and  regu- 
late the  destruction  or  movement  of  animals  in 
or  out  of  such  area  :  it  may  make  orders  rela- 
tive to  dairies,  cowsheds,  and  milkshops ;  and 
may  prohibit  or  regulate  the  importation, 
slaughter  or  quarantine  of  animals  coming  from 
foreign  countries.  j.  e.  o.  m. 

CAUTION  (Scots  Law  Term).  In  Scotland 
the  law  has  been  very  largely  assimilated  to  that 
of  England.  No  consideration  need  be  proved, 
and  the  period  of  limitation  is  seven  years  from 
the  date  of  the  bond  of  caution,  at  the  end  of 
which  time  the  surety,  if  known  to  the  creditor 
to  be  a  surety  and  not  a  principal,  becomes  free, 
unless  the  creditor  shall  then  have  begun  execu- 
tion proceedings  against  him.  When  sureties 
become  bound  by  way  of  collateral  security,  each 
for  the  performance  of  the  whole  of  an  obliga- 


tion, the  Scottish  ride  is  that  the  creditor  can 
rank  for  the  whole  upon  the  estate  of  each,  but 
not  so  as  to  do  more  than  draw  full  payment  of 
the  debt. 

[Bell's  Commentaries  on  the  Law  of  Scotland,  ii. 
416.]  A.  D. 

CAUTION.  Security  given  in  the  course  of 
judicial  proceedings.  The  word  is  not  used  in 
England  except  in  the  practice  of  the  ecclesias- 
tical courts  ;  in  Scotland  it  is  a  regular  term  of 
art  used  in  acts  of  parliament  and  legal  docu- 
ments. In  the  French  language  the  word 
caution  is  equivalent  to  the  English  Guarantee, 
and  is  used  to  express  the  security  as  well  as 
the  person  acting  as  surety. 

[Fournir  caution  de  payer  les  frais,  Code 
de  Procedure  civile,  §  166. — La  solvabiliti  d'une 
caution,  Code  civil,  §  2019.]  E.  s. 

CAVEAT.  An  expression  used  in  the  pro- 
cedure of  the  probate,  divorce,  and  admiralty 
Division  of  the  High  Court.  A  person  wishing 
to  dispute  the  validity  of  a  will,  by  entering  a 
"caveat"  compels  the  executors  to  bring  an 
action  to  obtain  probate.  In  admiralty  pro- 
ceedings a  person  can  prevent  the  arrest  of  hia 
ship  or  cargo  by  entering  a  "  caveat,"  if  at  the 
same  time  he  undertakes  to  appear  in  the  action 
and  gives  security  in  accordance  with  the  rules 
of  court.  E.  s. 

CAVEAT  EMPTOR.  A  maxim  of  the 
common  law  applicable  to  sales  of  personal 
property  as  regards  the  quality  of  the  things 
sold.  The  buyer  (in  the  absence  of  fraud) 
purchases  at  his  own  risk  unless  the  seller  has 
given  an  express  warranty  or  unless  a  warranty 
be  implied  from  the  nature  and  circumstances 
of  the  sale.  The  rule  does  not,  however,  apply 
if  the  buyer  has  had  no  opportunity  of  inspect- 
ing the  article  bought.  Hence,  where  a  chattel 
is  to  be  made  or  supplied  to  the  order  of  the 
purchaser,  or  where  it  is  sold  by  description  or 
by  sample,  or  for  a  particular  purpose,  the  law 
implies  a  Warranty. 

[The  Sale  of  Personal  Property,  by  J.  P. 
Benjamin,  Q.C.  4th  ed.  London,  1888.] 

J.  E.  0.  M. 

CAVOUR,  Count  Camillo  Benso  di  (1810- 
1861),  can  be  considered  in  this  place  only  as 
an  economist.  His  career  as  a  statesman  lies 
outside  our  boundaries.  A  few  biographical 
remarks  will,  however,  not  be  out  of  place. 
Cavour,  like  the  sons  of  all  the  Piedmontese 
nobility,  was  placed  in  the  military  academy 
as  soon  as  of  age  to  be  received  there.  He 
left  this  school  at  eighteen  as  a  lieutenant 
in  the  Engineers,  and  was  sent  to  work  at 
the  fortifications  of  Genoa.  He  had  a  parti- 
cular talent  for  mathematics,  and  one  of  his 
teachers,  the  well-known  Plana,  desired  him 
to  devote  himself  to  pure  mathematics,  telling 
him  he  would  rival  Lagrange.  Cavour's  answer, 
eminently  characteristic  of  the  man,  is  preserved 
in  his  correspondence  :  it  is  to  the  effect  **  that 


CAVOUR 


235 


mathematics  are  not  the  thing  required  just 
now,  but  economics."  Much  later  (14th 
December  1849)  Cavour  wrote  in  the  Msorgi- 
Tnento,  "The  greatest  problems  our  time  is 
called  upon  to  solve  are  not  political  ones,  but 
social  ones  ;  questions  relative  to  the  forms  of 
governments  arc  quite  secondary,  compared  with 
those  reflecting  the  economic  position  of 
society."  Cavour  left  the  army  in  1831,  after 
having  been  punished  for  speaking  out  too 
freely  on  political  matters.  This  misadventure 
turned  out  to  be  his  good  fortune  ;  it  caused 
him  to  travel  in  Switzerland,  France,  and 
England,  where  he  remained  several  years  and 
formed  himself  as  an  economist.  He  is  in  this 
respect  a  disciple  of  Cherbuliez,  of  P.  Rossi, 
and  of  what  is  now  called  the  Classical  School. 
His  writings  and  his  speeches  abound  with 
quotations  from  Ricardo,  and  he  wrote  an  essay 
in  defence  of  Malthus.  In  one  of  his  first 
writings.  On  the  State  of  Ireland,  he  speaks  of 
England  in  the  following  terms:  "From  St. 
Petersburg  to  Madrid,  in  Germany  and  in 
Italy,  the  enemies  of  progress  and  the  friends 
of  revolution  alike  consider  England  as  their 
greatest  obstacle.  The  one  set  regards  England 
as  the  hearth  upon  which  all  revolutionary 
flames  are  kindled,  the  refuge  and  citadel  of  all 
the  subversionists.  The  other,  perhaps  more 
truly,  considers  the  English  aristocracy  as  the 
central  pivot  of  the  European  social  system  and 
as  the  greatest  obstacle  their  democratic  tenden- 
cies meet  with.  This  hatred  which  England 
meets  with  from  all  extreme  parties  ought  to 
endear  that  country  to  the  intermediate  ones,  to 
all  men  who  wish  for  the  moderate  progress,  and 
for  the  gradual  and  regular  evolution  of  human- 
ity, i.e.  to  all  men  who  from  principle  are  opposed 
alike  to  all  violent  tempests  and  to  stagnation 
in  social  affairs.  But  this  is  not  the  case.  The 
motives  which  might  lead  them  to  sympathise 
with  England  are  counteracted  by  an  enormous 
mass  of  prejudice,  old  tales,  and  old  passions, 
whose  force  is  nearly  irresistible.  Therefore 
there  are  but  few  men,  scattered  here  and  there 
and  solitary,  who  feel  for  the  English  Nation 
that  esteem  and  that  regard  which  ought  to  be 
inspired  by  one  of  the  greatest  nations  which 
has  distinguished  mankind, — a  nation  which 
has  effectively  co-operated  in  the  moral  and 
material  development  of  the  world,  and  whose 
mission  of  civilisation  is  very  far  from  being  at 
an  end."  Cavour's  admiration  for  England  and 
English  thought  was  a  subject  for  which  he 
was  often  attacked.  But  he  had  been  trained 
from  his  youth  upwards  to  stand  fearlessly 
isolated  by  his  opinions  from  his  countrymen 
and  to  face  their  opposition.  His  family  cir- 
cumstances were  at  first  a  formidable  obstacle 
to  his  rising  rapidly  to  the  front.  His  father 
was  what  would  now  be  called  the  chief  of  the 
police,  and  as  such  had  many  a  disagreeable 
duty  to  perform.     The  nobility,  to  the  very 


highest  ranks  of  which  Cavour  belonged  by  birth, 
looked  down  upon  him  as  the  son  of  the  councillor 
of  an  unpopular  king,  and  of  a  man  who  exer- 
cised a  somewhat  despised  calling ;  by  the 
middle  classes  he  was,  if  not  hated,  certainly 
received  very  coldly  for  the  same  reason. 
Besides  this,  his  independence  of  thought, 
which  led  him  not  to  agree  either  with  the 
aristocratic  or  the  democratic  party,  put  him 
for  a  long  time  between  two  fires,  with  no 
friends  to  back  him.  And  in  parliament,  when 
he  first  entered  it,  the  fact  that  he  did  not  stick 
to  any  party,  and  sometimes  supported  the 
government  and  sometimes  the  opposition,  was 
at  first  harshly  judged,  and  only  appreciated 
when  people  came  to  imderstand  that  Cavour 
was  a  new  leader,  with  a  programme  of  his 
own.  As  a  minister  he  continually  showed 
unusual  courage  in  expressing,  without  any 
regard  for  the  prejudices  of  his  audience,  his 
scientific  convictions  on  economic  questions, 
he  even  ventured  to  explain  in  the  chamber 
economic  theories — rebuking  those  who  affected 
to  despise  theory.  As  an  example  of  the  high 
tone  of  parliamentary  discussions  under  his 
leadership,  and  of  his  sincere  respect  for  science, 
not  concealed  from  an  assembly  which,  also  in 
those  times,  often  declared  economical  laws 
good  for  some  other  planet  than  our  owti,  the 
following  passage  of  a  speech  of  his,  made 
in  defence  of  the  treaty  of  commerce  with 
France  (8th  April  1852),  and  in  answer  to 
Menabrea's  attacks,  may  be  quoted.  Cavour 
spoke  French  on  this  occasion,  as  on  several 
others,  so  as  to  be  clearly  understood  by  the 
Savoyards.  The  law  would  even  now  permit  the 
use  of  French  in  the  Italian  parliament.  The 
quotations  from  the  speech  which  follows  is 
therefore  given  in  French  ;  the  reader  will  bear 
in  mind  that  Savoyards,  though  fluent  in  that 
language,  do  not  speak  perfect  French.  "Et 
d'abord,  messieurs,  il  est  facile  de  demontrer 
mathematiquement,  qu'une  fois  les  principes 
du  libre  echange  etablis,  si  on  veut  proceder 
par  degres  dans  leur  application,  en  suivant 
une  marche  rationelle  et  logique,  on  devrait  les 
appliquer  d'abord  aux  produits  de  I'agriculture 
avant  de  les  appliquer  k  ce  qui  a  rapport  h.  I'in- 
dustrie  manufacturiere.  Malheureusement,  pour 
faire  cette  demonstration,  je  serai  oblige  de  re- 
courir  pendant  quelques  instants  aux  lumieres 
de  la  theorie.  J'en  demande  bien  pardon  a  M. 
Menabrea,  mais  je  ne  puis  m'empecher  de  lui 
manifester  I'etonnement  que  j'ai  eprouve,  voy. 
ant  un  homme  aussi  savant  que  lui,  un  membre 
de  I'Academie  des  Sciences,  manifester  un  si 
superbe  dedain  pour  les  theories,  et  surtout 
pour  la  theorie  de  I'economie  politique  qui  a 
tant  d'affinite  avec  celles  des  sciences  exactes, 
qu'il  possede  si  bien  et  qu'il  professe  d'une 
maniere  si  distinguee.  Car,  messieurs,  le  sys- 
tems protecteur  a  des  consequences  bien  plus 
funestes    lorsqu'il   est   applique   aux   produits 


236 


CAVOUR 


du  sol,  que  lorsqu'il  est  applique  aux  produits 
de  rindustrie.  Le  systeme  protecteur  applique 
k  rindustrie  n'a  qu'un  seul  effet  facheux,  celui 
de  detourner  les  capitaux  et  le  travail  national 
des  industries  naturelles  pour  les  pousser  vers 
des  industries  factices,  ou  les  capitaux  et  le 
travail  trouvent  un  emploi  moins  productif. 
C'est  Ih  un  inconvenient  grave  sans  doute,  mais 
qui  est  restreint  a  cette  quantite  de  capitaux  et 
de  travail  qui  par  I'effet  de  la  protection  sont 
detournes  de  leur  voie  naturelle.  Et  encore 
cet  efFet  est-il  attenue  par  la  concurrence  inte- 
rieure  qui,  au  bout  d'un  certain  temps,  ram^ne 
le  taux  des  capitaux  et  celui  de  la  main  d'ceuvre 
des  industries  privilegiees  au  niveau  des  profits 
et  des  salaires  des  industries  qui  ne  le  sont  pas. 
Mais  le  systeme  protecteur  applique  k  la  culture 
du  sol  a  des  effets  bien  plus  etendus,  et,  je 
n'hesite  pas  a  le  dire,  bien  plus  funestes.  En 
effet,  lorsque  par  la  suite  d'un  droit  protecteur, 
vous  elevez  le  prix  des  produits  du  sol,  le  prix 
du  vin  et  du  ble,  par  exemple,  qu'est-ce  qu'il 
arrive  ?  II  arrive  deux  choses  :  en  premier  lieu 
certains  terrains  qui  n'etaient  pas  assez  fertiles 
pour  produire  du  ble  ou  du  vin  dans  les  condi- 
tions anterieures  du  marche,  sont  mis  en  culture, 
ou  bien  encore,  on  consacre  k  la  terre  des  capi- 
taux et  du  travail  qui  n'aurait  pas  ete  productifs 
si  le  prix  n'avait  pas  vari^.  Cette  premiere 
consequence  du  systeme  protecteur  appliqu^  h. 
I'agriculture  est  analogue  kcelle  que  j'ai  signalee 
lorsqu'il  a  pour  objet  I'industrie  manufacturike. 
C'est-k-dire  qu'il  y  a  une  certaine  masse  de  capi- 
taux et  de  travail,  qui  re9oivent  une  destination 
moins  productive  qu'ils  n'auraient  re§us  si  les 
cboses  avaient  ete  abandonn^es  k  leur  courant 
naturel.  C'est  Ik  un  inconvenient  grave  qui 
oependant  n'aurait  pas  une  grande  portee,  si 
I'elevation  des  prix  des  produits  du  sol  n'avait 
d'effet  que  sur  les  produits  des  terrains  nouvelle- 
ment  mis  en  culture  ou  des  capitaux  et  du  tra- 
vail additionnels  consacres  k  I'exploitation  des 
terrains  depuis  longtemps  defriches.  Mais 
I'elevation  factiee  des  prix  s'etend  aux  produits 
de  tous  les  terrains,  k  ceux  d'ancienne  aussi 
bien  qii'k  ceux  de  nouvelle  culture.  Qui  est- 
ce  qui  profite  de  cette  elevation  ?  Lorsqu'elle 
a  lieu  elle  se  partage  entre  les  proprietaires  et 
les  fermiers,  surtout  si  ceux-ci  sont  en  possession 
de  long  baux  :  apres  quelque  temps,  le  profit  se 
concentre  tout  entier  entre  les  mains  des  proprie- 
taires. Ainsi  done,  le  systeme  protecteur  applique 
aux  produits  du  sol  a  pour  effet,  d'une  part,  de 
pousser  ainsi  que  le  fait  le  systeme  protecteur 
industriel  des  capitaux  et  du  travail,  dans  une 
voie  pen  productive,  et  de  I'autre  d'augmenter 
la  rente  des  terrains  precedemment  cultives  aux 
depens  des  consommateurs.  Ce  qui  en  definitive 
constitue  un  veritable  impSt  supporte  par  les 
consommateurs  au  profit  des  proprietaires.  .  .  ." 
Cavour  also  ventured  occasionally  to  give 
parliamentary  discussions  an  academical  tone, 
quoting  economic  authority,  as  in  the  following 


instance :  "  It  is  my  opinion,  in  accordance 
with  that  of  all  the  most  enlightened  people  in 
England,  and  not  alone  with  the  men  of  the 
present  generation,  but  with  the  economists 
who  have  preceded  the  present  generation,  with 
A.  Smith  and  Ricardo  and  his  followers,  that 
England  has  prospered,  not  in  virtue  of  the 
protective  system,  but  notwithstanding  this 
system.  .  .  .  If  you  examine  English  industries 
you  will  see  that  those  which  have  been  least 
protected  are  precisely  those  which  have  suc- 
ceeded best.  .  .  .  The  progress  of  English 
industry  has  always  been  in  an  opposite  ratio 
to  the  degree  of  protection  it  received.  The 
silk  industry  (strongly  protected)  remained 
nearly  stationary  ;  the  woollen  industry  pro- 
gressed slowly,  and  the  cotton  industry,  which 
was  hardly  at  all  protected,  grew  gigantically. 
I  therefore  maintain  that  protection  in  England 
not  only  has  failed  to  aid  the  increase  of  wealth, 
but  has  even  been  a  hindrance  to  it."  Thus  he 
explained  to  the  chamber  the  economic  prin- 
ciples as  to  the  basis  of  wages  : — "  Le  taux  des 
salaires,  selon  les  principes  non  contestes  de  la 
science,  se  regie  par  la  masse  des  capitaux 
destines  k  payer  les  salaires,  c'est-a-dire  par  la 
quantite  de  denrees  de  premiere  necessite  k 
I'usage  des  Islasses  ouvrieres  que  possede  la 
nation,  comparee  avec  le  nombre  des  bras  qui 
cherchent  de  I'emploi."  He  further  argued 
that  Protection  cannot  augment  capital,  and 
therefore  does  not  raise  wages.  All  that  Pro- 
tection can  do,  he  said,  is  to  cause  Capital  to 
**  flow  rather  in  one  channel  of  industry  than 
in  another.  .  .  .  And  it  does  this  by  driving 
them  (capital  and  labour)  into  the  less  remuner- 
ative branches  of  industry. "  The  best  example, 
however,  perhaps  which  can  be  given  of  his 
scientific  spirit  in  discussing  practical  problems 
in  parliament  is  his  definition  of  the  individu- 
alist and  of  the  socialist  policy.  *  *  For  reaching 
this  goal  (the  amelioration  of  the  economic  con- 
dition of  the  lower  classes)  two  ways  are  open 
for  us.  All  the  systems  supported  in  modern 
times  by  the  wisest  and  by  the  boldest  men  can 
be  classified  under  two  heads.  The  one  school 
relies  on  the  principle  of  liberty,  on  the  principle 
of  competition,  on  the  free  development  of  the 
morals  and  intelligence  of  men.  Those  who 
hold  this  opinion  think  that  the  larger  the 
application  of  this  principle  is,  the  greater  will 
be  the  welfare  of  all,  but  particularly  of  the 
lower  classes.  This  is  the  school  of  economists, 
these  are  the  principles  held  by  the  men  who 
are  in  office,  in  England.  Another  school  pro- 
fesses principles  diametrically  opposed  to  these. 
It  believes  that  human  misery  cannot  be  allevi- 
ated, and  that  the  condition  of  the  lower  classes 
cannot  be  ameliorated,  unless  individual  action 
is  limited,  and  the  central  action  of  the  whole 
social  body,  represented  by  a  government  which 
has  still  to  be  created,  is  made  more  powerful, 
and  concentrates  all  individual  forces  into  itseK 


CAVOUR— CENS 


237 


This  is  the  socialist  school.  Now,  no  illusions 
must  be  indulged  in :  although  this  school 
reaches  fatal  and  sometimes  even  atrocious  con- 
clusions, it  cannot  be  denied  that  there  is  some- 
thing in  its  principles  which  captivates  many 
generous  and  elevated  minds.  And  the  only 
way  to  combat  this  school,  which  threatens  to 
invade  all  Europe,  is  to  oppose  principles  to 
principles.  In  economics  as  in  politics,  as  in 
religion,  ideas  can  only  be  fought  by  other  ideas, 
and  principles  by  other  principles  ;  forcible  re- 
pression is  useless.  For  a  short  time  guns  and 
bayonets  may  repress  theories  and  maintain 
order  ;  but  if  these  theories  find  entrance  with 
the  intellectual  class,  you  may  be  sure  that 
they  will  thrive  and  triumpli.  Now,  I  say  that 
the  strongest  ally  of  socialism  is  protection. 
Both  start  from  the  same  base.  .  .  .  Given  the 
protectionist  system,  logic  will  compel  you  to 
admit,  if  not  all,  a  great  many  of  the  doctrines 
of  Socialism." 

When  Cavour  defended  Free-Thade  he  gave 
in  just  as  little  to  absolute  protectionists  as  to 
fair  traders  ;  he  explained  on  more  than  one 
occasion  that  if  a  foreign  country  commits  the 
error  of  protecting  its  own  industries,  this  is  no 
reason  for  making  the  same  error  ourselves. 
Again,  he  argues  with  great  acuteness  ' '  that 
if  a  nation  has  to  undergo  great  sacrifices  and  to 
bear  heavy  taxation,  it  must  be  left  the  more 
unfettered  in  its  commercial  and  industrial 
activity,  so  as  to  bear  the  weight  easier."  The 
best  protection,  he  repeatedly  declares,  is  the 
maximum  of  liberty.  "It  is  my  opinion  tliat 
those  elements  of  production  and  of  prosperity 
which  we  possess,  ought  to  be  left  to  develop 
themselves  unfettered ;  that  neither  agiiculture, 
industry,  nor  commerce  ought  to  be  protected. 
I  believe  firmly  that  the  gi-eatest  encourage- 
ment is  to  be  had  from  the  gi-eatest  possible 
amount  of  liberty :  '  che  il  massimo  degli  in- 
coraggiamenti  sia  il  massimo  della  possibile 
liberta.'  "  This  speech  of  his  marks  distinctly 
Cavour's  position  as  an  economist. 

The  success  of  Cavour's  speeches  in  a  parliament 
in  which  even  men  of  the  greatest  merit  ignored 
the  most  elementary  truths  of  political  economy, 
was  due  to  his  unmatched  knowledge  of  commer- 
cial and  technical  details.  This  enabled  him  to 
give  each  man  the  right  argumentum  ad  hominem 
which  would  bring  home  to  him  the  theory  under 
discussion.  He  was  himself  a  practical  agricul- 
turist, and  a  very  successful  one  into  the  bargain. 
This  gave  him  a  high  authority  with  all  those 
deputies  who  were  also  landlords  and  knew  he 
could  beat  them  in  any  practical  question.  And 
he  liked  to  quote,  on  the  right  occasion,  instances 
of  personal  experience  in  agricultural  matters. 
To  his  mind,  highly  speculative  as  it  was,  sophistry 
and  legal  casuistry  were  completely  alien ;  he  would 
appeal  to  historical  facts,  recent  and  ancient,  and 
generalise  skilfully  on  them  ;  he  would  show  the 
interests  of  different  parties,  explain  their  actions 
by  their  motives  ;  but  he  would  not  stoop  to  play 


with  the  sense  of  words  and  base  political  action 
on  some  legal  nicety — a  method  of  reasoning  very 
frequent  in  Latin  countries,  in  which  parliaments 
are  largely  composed  of  lawyers.  Naturally  he 
was  the  object  of  much  sarcasm.  At  one  time  he 
was  called  "Lord  Camillo,"  and  from  the  name  of 
the  jmu-nal  which  he  had  founded  and  was  directing 
"My  Lord  Risorgimento,"  to  ridicule  his  Anglo- 
mania. Risorgiviento  means  resurrection,  and  is 
here  used  in  the  sense  of  political  resurrection  or 
revival.  Cavour  was  no  orator,  he  had  always  to 
win  his  way  by  the  weight  of  the  matter  of  his 
speeches.  His  voice  was  disagreeable,  his  tone 
harsh,  and  he  had  some  difficulty  in  finding  the 
proper  words  rapidly.  But  he  was  first-rate  in 
reply  and  at  making  a  good  pun,  and  was  seldom 
worsted  in  debate.  When  Cavour  was  not  allowed 
to  answer  an  opponent  in  the  Chamber,  because  his 
turn  to  speak  was  past,  he  employed  Mirabeau's 
system,  publishing  the  same  evening  or  the  next 
morning  his  answer  in  the  "  Eisorgimento."  This 
journal  is  therefore  one  of  the  great  sources  of  in- 
formation concerning  his  economic  and  political 
views,  together  with  the  collection  of  his  speeches 
(eleven  volumes  published  by  Botta  at  the  expense 
of  the  government),  his  con'espondeuce  (five  volumes 
edited  by  Chiala  and  published  by  Eoux,  Turin, 
1881-86),  and  his  Ouvrages  politiques  et  econo- 
miques  (published  in  1885  by  Galiraberti,  Coni). 
His  best  known  economical  pamphlets  are  : — the 
memoir  already  quoted,  Sur  Vetat  actuel  de 
Virlande  et  sur  son  avenir. — Des  idees  communisies 
et  des  moyens  d'en  comhattre  le  developpement. — 
Des  cheviins  de  fer  en  Itcdie. — He  ^vrote  Sur 
V Influence  de  la  politique  commerciale  de  I'  Angle- 
terre  dans  le  monde  'econoraique  (in  the  Review 
I'Antologia),  and  a  pamphlet  on  Prof.  Ferrara's 
inaugural  address  on  Political  Economy.  As 
an  economist  Cavour  contributed  nothing  to  the 
theory  of  the  science.  He  is  rather  one  of  those 
who  are  well  acquainted  with  the  state  of  science 
in  their  time,  and  utilise  it  for  practical  purposes. 
His  opinions  in  economic  matters  may  be  summed 
up  as  those  of  the  Manchester  School,  as  the 
Germans  qualify  Orthodox  political  economy 
{Mayichesterthum)  when  it  is  accompanied  with 
an  optimistic  view  of  the  effects  of  natural  laws, 
and  reduced  to  the  basis  of  absolute  Laissez- 
Faire  and  Laissez-Passer.  m.  p. 

CAYLEY,  Edward,  author  of  the  tract, 
Corn  trade,  Wages,  and  Rent,  1826  ;  a  plea 
for  protection  backed  by  some  curious  statistics 
(see  pp.  8,  16,  31).  f.  y.  e. 

CEDULA.  A  Spanish  word,  used  on  the 
London  stock  exchange,  chiefly  to  describe 
certain  guaranteed  bonds  issued  by  Argentine 
banks,  corresponding  to  loans  made  by  these 
banks  against  land  to  proprietors  in  various 
Argentine  provinces.  The  word  originally 
meant  something  ceded,  and  has  reference  prob- 
ably to  the  land  or  property  which  has  been 
ceded  as  security  for  the  advances  made  by  the 
Argentine  banks.  A.  E. 

CENS.  The  French  term  for  a  Quit-Eent  ; 
but  it  has  a  special  meaning  in  the  history  of 
France.     De  Tocqueville  has  shown  the  error 


238 


CENSUS 


of  supposing  that  Serfdom  survived  in  France 
until  the  Revolution.  Most  of  the  French 
peasants  in  the  18th  century  held  their  lands, 
either  as  proprietors  or  as  Metayer  tenants. 
In  the  former  case,  however,  the  lord  still 
retained  the  cens,  or  quit-rent,  as  a  synjbol 
that  he  retained  the  ownership,  though  he  had 
parted  with  the  property  of  the  soil.  The  cens 
was  almost  invariably  a  fixed  sum,  arranged 
at  the  time  of  the  original  bargain,  and  had 
become  insignificant  in  the  18  th  century, 
owing  to  the  decline  in  the  value  of  money. 
For  this  the  lord  was,  to  some  extent,  compen- 
sated by  the  droit  de  lods  et  ventes,  by  which, 
every  time  the  land  changed  hands,  the  lord 
was  entitled  to  a  share  in  the  purchase-money, 
usually  a  twelfth,  but  sometimes  as  much  as  a 
fourth. 

[De  Tocqueville,  France  before  the  Revolution 
(London,  1873),  note  Ixxvii.]  k.  l. 

CENSUS  may  be  defined  as  an  enumeration 
of  the  persons  in  a  country,  and  in  each  of  its 
principal  classes  :  such  as  those  constituted  by 
sex,  age,  occupation,  and  so  forth.  An  enumer- 
ation of  houses  and  other  property  is  often 
included.  The  institution  is  very  ancient.  Its 
existence  is  evidenced  by  several  passages  in  the 
Old  Testament  (Exodus  xii.  37  ;  Numbers  i. 
xxvi. ;  and  2  Samuel  xxiv. ;  1  Chronicles  xii.  23, 
xxi.  2-3,  xxiii.  3-5 ;  Esdras  ii.  viii. ;  Nehemiah 
vii.  ix.)  The  ancient  Egyptians  and  the 
ancient  Persians  were  not  without  a  sort  of 
census  {Herodotus,  bk.  ii.  ch.  cxix.  clxxvii. ; 
bk.  iii.  ch.  Ixxxix.-xc.)  In  Greece  there  were 
enumerations  of  the  citizens  for  political  pur- 
poses. In  Rome  the  census  was  instituted  in 
the  age  of  the  kings,  and  formed  an  im- 
portant branch  of  administration  down  to  the 
age  of  the  emperors.  It  is  recorded  that 
Augustus  wrote  out  with  his  own  hand  a  Brevi- 
arium  totius  imperii,  containing  the  number 
of  citizens  and  allies  in  arms,  the  statistics  of 
the  fleets  and  provinces,  and  even  the  names  of 
freedmen  and  slaves.  The  care  of  Augustus 
was  imitated  by  his  successors.  In  the  ages 
which  followed  the  fall  of  the  Roman  empire 
the  most  remarkable  compilations  of  the  nature 
of  a  census  were  the  Breviary  of  Charlemagne  and 
the  Domesday  Book  of  William  the  Conqueror. 

A  more  detailed  notice  of  the  census  in 
modern  times  may  be  arranged  under  the 
following  three  heads :  (1)  The  United  King- 
dom ;  (2)  The  Continent  of  Europe  ;  (3)  The 
United  States  of  America. 

(1)  The  first  census  in  England  was  in  1801. 
An  abortive  attempt  to  introduce  a  census  had 
been  made  in  1753,  when  Thomas  Potter  in- 
troduced a  bill  for  taking  and  registering  an 
annual  account  of  the  total  number  of  marriages, 
births,  and  deaths.  The  bill  was  violently 
opposed.  Mr.  Thornton,  who  spoke  against  it 
frequently,  said  :  'I  did  not  believe  that  there 
was  any  set  of  men,  or  indeed  any  individual  of 


the  liuman  species,  so  presumptuous  and  so 
abandoned  as  to  make  the  proposal  which  we 
have  just  heard. "  The  bill,  carried  in  the  House 
of  Commons,  was  thrown  out  by  the  Lords.  In 
1801  there  was  no  opposition.  The  fear  of  ex- 
posing the  paucity  of  our  numbers  had  given 
place  to  a  dread  of  over-population.  Mr.  C. 
Abbot  {q.v.),  in  introducing  the  Population  Bill, 
said  :  "In  times  like  these,  when  the  subsistence 
of  the  people  is  in  question,  it  is  surely  import- 
ant to  know  the  extent  of  the  demand  for  which 
we  are  to  supply." 

It  might  have  been  expected  that  the  new 
machinery  would  not  work  well  the  first  time. 
But  Mr.  Rickman,  one  of  the  clerks  of  the 
House  of  Commons,  the  able  superintendent  of 
the  operation,  argues — in  the  reports  accom- 
panying the  second  and  third  censuses — that 
the  return  of  the  population  is  fairly  accurate. 
The  overseers  of  the  poor,  whose  agency  was 
employed,  had  good  opportunities  for  ascertain- 
ing, and  no  motive  for  misrepresenting,  the 
numbers.  Errors  in  particular  parishes  would 
compensate  each  other  in  the  aggregate.  We  may 
therefore  accept  a  statement  which,  compared 
with  the  enumeration  of  1881,  shows  that  the 
population  of  England  and  Wales  almost  trebled 
itself  during  tte  first  eighty  years  of  this  century. 
Equal  success  did  not  attend  another  depart- 
ment of  the  first  census.  It  was  attempted  to 
group  the  population  by  occupations  into  three 
classes  :  agriculture,  trade,  etc.,  and  a  residual 
class  of  others.  But  it  was  left  uncertain 
whether  the  householder  should  speak  for  him- 
self or  his  family.  The  want  of  uniformity  in 
this  respect  rendered  these  returns  almost  use- 
less. The  statistics  of  the  present  were  not  the 
only  object  of  the  first  census.  It  was  at- 
tempted to  reason  backwards  to  the  numbers  of 
the  population  in  the  preceding  century  by 
means  of  entries  in  the  parish  re^sters — an 
attempt  which  had  been  initiated  by  Graunt  in 
his  Bills  of  Mortality,  1661,  and  sanctioned  by 
Laplace  in  his  TMorie  des  Prdbabilit6s  (bk.  ii. 
ch.  vii.)  The  baptisms,  marriages,  and  burials 
were  obtained  for  several  years  of  last  century. 
Then,  as  the  number  of  entries  in  1801  is  to 
the  (enumerated)  population  in  1801,  so  is  the 
number  of  entries  in  any  assigned  year  of  the 
eighteenth  century  to  the  population  of  that 
year.  Of  the  three  kinds  of  record  the  marriages 
are  the  best  for  the  purpose  of  this  reasoning. 
Especially  after  the  marriage  act  of  1754  there 
is  reason  to  think  that  the  registry  of  marriages 
is  pretty  complete.  As  Mr.  Rickman  puts  it, 
"  The  solicitude  of  the  female  and  her  family, 
aided  by  the  precision  and  severity  of  the 
marriage  act"  precluded  omissions.  Accord- 
ingly the  reasoning  may  pretty  safely  be  carried 
back  as  far  as  that  date.  As  we  go  farther 
back  there  is  danger  that  the  reasoning  may  be 
falsified  by  a  continual  increase  in  the  number 
of  omitted  entries.    But  Mr.  Rickman's  statistics 


CENSUS 


239 


appear  to  establish  that  the  danger  is  not  fatal 
for  recent  periods  (see  Census  1821,  Prelimin- 
ary Observations,  p.  xxviii.)  Altogether  the  re- 
trospective census  seems  to  establish  certain 
broad  statements,  as  that  the  population  of 
England  increased  by  about  45  per  cent  in 
the  latter  half  of  the  eighteenth  century,  and 
that  in  the  former  half  of  the  century  the 
advance  was  much  slower,  and  retarded  by 
occasional  retrogression  (see  Census  1821,  Pre- 
liminary Observations,  p.  xxix.  ;  1831,  Preface, 
p.  xlv.  and  1851,  Report,  p.  Ixviii.) 

The  second  census  took  place  in  1811.  The 
growth  of  the  population  during  the  decade 
1801-11  was  rather  more  than  14  per  cent ;  a 
rate  of  increase  to  which  we  have  now  returned, 
after  exceeding  it  for  one  generation  (1811-41) 
andfalling  short  of  it  for  another(1841-71).  The 
mistake  which  had  marred  the  first  census  was 
avoided  in  the  second  by  counting  the  families, 
not  the  persons,  in  each  of  the  three  classes — 
agricultui-al,  trade  etc,  and  others.  In  1821 
questions  as  to  age  were  first  put.  But  it  was 
left  optional,  both  to  the  returning  officer  to 
ask  the  question  and  to  the  citizen  to  answer. 
The  returns  were  fuller  than  might  have  been 
expected,  eight-ninths  of  the  total  population 
enumerated.  In  1831  the  only  return  relating 
10  age  was  the  number  of  males  aged  twenty  and 
upwards.  In  this  year  a  more  elaborate  classifica- 
tion of  occupations  was  introduced.  One  of  the 
principal  classes,  trade,  was  subdivided  into  a 
hundred  specifications.  Into  the  compartments 
thus  prepared  the  statistical  matter  did  not  flow 
very  freely.  Accordingly  at  the  census  of  1841 
each  individual  was  left  free  to  declare  his  own 
occupation.  The  returns  were  made  for  the  indi- 
vidual, not  for  the  family,  as  previously.  The 
inquiry  as  to  age  was  again  introduced  in  1841 
and  made  obligatory.  This  census  had  the 
benefit  of  the  newly  created  registration  office 
which  supplanted  the  antiquated  machinery  of 
the  parish  registers.  At  the  census  of  1851  and 
on  the  two  succeeding  occasions,  the  advantage 
of  Dr.  Fare's  collaboration  was  felt.  The  re- 
ports embody  many  of  his  valuable  contributions 
to  vital  statistics.  His  scientific  work  is  enriched 
with  a  vein  of  philosophical  speculation  and 
a  wealth  of  literature,  which  do  not  often  adorn 
parliamentary  papers.  To  Dr.  Farr  is  due  the 
sixfold  classification  of  occupations  which  is 
perhaps  destined  to  be  permanent — the  pro- 
fessional, domestic,  commercial,  agricultural, 
industrial,  and  the  unoccupied  class.  The 
grounds  of  this  division  are  set  forth  by  Dr. 
Farr  in  a  note  appended  to  the  report  for  1861. 
A  special  feature  in  the  census  for  1851  was 
an  attempt  to  ascertain  the  extent  of  church 
accommodation  and  the  size  of  congregations  for 
the  different  religious  denominations.  In  the 
same  year  conjugal  condition  was  first  made  an 
object  of  inquiry.  In  1861  there  was  a  return 
of  the  number  of  houses  containing  one,  two, 


or  any  assigned  number  of  inhabitants,  for 
twenty -four  selected  districts.  In  1871  the 
first  imperial  census  was  taken. 

The  history  of  the  census  for  England  and 
Wales  is  nearly  coincident  with  that  of  Scot- 
land down  to  1861,  when  a  separate  census  for 
Scotland  was  first  taken.  A  peculiar  difficulty 
attending  the  Scotch  census  is  caused  by  the 
definition  of  a  house  which  the  imperial 
authorities  have  adopted  :  "a distinct  building, 
separate  from  others  by  party  walls."  This 
definition  has  been  far  from  "distinct"  to  the 
provincial  mind.  A  whole  block  of  buildings 
have  often  been  returned  as  a  house.  The 
statistics  of  the  number  of  rooms  to  a  family 
are  more  valuable.  There  are  many  contrasts 
between  the  results  of  the  census  in  North  and 
South  Britain — for  instance,  the  much  greater 
preponderance  of  the  female  sex  in  Scotland — 
which  cannot  be  adequately  treated  here. 

The  history  of  the  Irish  census  deserves  a 
separate  notice.  From  the  age  of  Petty  to  the 
beginning  of  the  present  century  estimates  of  the 
population,  based  mostly  on  Hearth-Money, 
were  attempted.  If  this  method  may  be 
trusted,  there  were  in  Ireland  at  the  end  of  the 
18th  century  from  four  to  five  million  persons  ; 
that  is  about  half  the  contemporary  population 
of  England  and  Wales.  A  census  was  instituted 
in  1812.  But  it  was  not  successful,  having  been 
taken  in  different  years  and  for  partial  districts. 
The  Irish  census  of  1821  was  more  satisfactory. 
Its  result,  in  round  numbers  6,802,000,  com 
pared  with  the  contemporary  population  of 
England  and  Wales,  12,000,000,  shows  a  rela- 
tion very  different  from  that  which  now  prevails; 
the  proportion  of  the  Irish  population  to  that 
of  England  and  Wales  being  in  1821  about  a 
half,  in  1891  about  a  sixth.  In  1831  and  1841 
returns  as  to  occupations  were  obtained  on 
much  the  same  lines  as  in  England.  But  the 
answers  were  worked  up  into  different  summa 
genera.  Families  are  divided  into  those  who 
live  by  (1)  capital  in  wealth  or  in  professional 
knowledge  ;  (2)  the  direction  of  labour  ;  (3) 
manual  labour.  The  somewhat  indefinite  second 
class  comprised  50  per  cent  of  the  families  in 
1841.  The  difficulties  of  obtaining  occupational 
statistics  are  illustrated  by  the  incident  that  in 
the  whole  of  Dublin  only  five  coffin -makers 
were  returned,  whereas  in  a  single  street  it  was 
ascertained  that  there  were  twelve  persons  so 
occupied.  Only  one  person  in  the  Irish  capital 
designated  himself  as  an  author !  Great  diffi- 
culties attended  the  preparation  of  vital  statis- 
tics in  Ireland.  The  number  of  births  in  any 
year  used  to  be  inferred  by  adding  the  numbers 
alive  at  each  year  of  age  to  the  numbers  whose 
ages  at  death  proved  them  to  have  been  bom 
in  the  year  under  consideration  (Report  for 
1841,  p.  xl.)  There  is  a  large  deficiency  due 
to  Emigration  and  imperfect  returns  of  deaths. 
Still  it  is  interesting  to   observe  with  what 


240 


CENSUS 


accuracy  the  well-known  proportion  of  male  and 
female  births  comes  out  in  the  aggregates.  The 
commissioners  for  1841  claim  to  have  made 
some  contribution  to  the  theory  of  that  remark- 
able phenomenon.  In  the  census  of  1851  a 
gloomy  feature  was  the  decrease  of  population 
by  almost  20  per  cent,  due  to  the  famine  of 
1847.  A  decrease  of  29  per  cent  is  recorded 
for  directors  of  labour,  the  second  of  the  three- 
fold division  of  occupations  above  mentioned. 
The  decrease  of  population  has  continued  ever 
since  ;  the  rate  of  decrease  continually  diminish- 
ing down  to  the  last  decade ;  when,  as  shown  by 
the  Preliminary  Report  for  1911,  the  decrease 
dropped  from  5*2  per  cent  in  the  decade  1891- 
1901  to  1*5  per  cent.  Much  the  same  dis- 
tribution as  in  1841  is  presented  by  another 
classification  of  occupied  persons  as  those 
ministering  to  food,  clothing,  and  six  other 
primary  wants.  In  1861  this  classification 
is  modified  by  the  addition  of  twelve  new 
categories.  For  example,  out  of  1 0, 0  0  0  occupied 
persons  18  minister  to  religion,  5  to  amusement, 
1  to  science  and  art,  and  1816  to  food.  A 
feature  of  interest  in  the  census  of  1861  was 
the  inquiry  concerning  the  religious  profession 
of  the  people.  The  proportions  were,  Roman 
Catholics  77-69  per  cent ;  Protestants  22-23  per 
cent ;  not  quite  1  per  cent  being  left  for  Jews 
and  unspecified.  Of  the  Protestants  a  little 
more  than  half  belonged  to  the  Established 
Church.  These  proportions  continue  to  be 
approximately  maintained.  The  latest  returns 
give  Roman  Catholics  73-9  per  cent,  Protestants 
(Episcopalians,  Presbyterians,  and  Methodists) 
24-5  per  cent ;  Jews  and  other  persuasions,  as 
before,  about  1  per  cent.  In  1871,  as  in  1861, 
the  returns  as  to  occupation  are  arranged  both 
according  to  the  English  sixfold  classification 
and  the  system  grounded  on  the  wants  to  which 
different  occupations  minister.  The  Irish  com- 
missioners defend  the  indigenous  system  with 
much  warmth.  The  census  of  1881  conforms 
to  the  English  classification  with  more  docility. 
The  later  censuses  of  Ireland  deserve  commenda- 
tion for  the  completeness  of  the  agricultural 
returns.  The  principal  points  to  be  noticed  in 
the  census  of  1911  are — the  smallest  decline  in 
population  on  record,  a  decrease  in  emigration, 
an  increase  in  the  number  of  houses,  a  general 
improvement  in  house  accommodation,  a  de- 
crease in  poverty,  and  a  decrease  in  the  death 
rate  (Sir  W.  J.  Thompson,  M.D.,  Registrar- 
General  of  Ireland,  "The  Census  of  Ireland, 
1911,"  Journ.  of  the  Statistical  and  Social 
Inquiry  Society  of  Ireland,  Dec.  1913). 

A  general  idea  of  the  scope  and  purpose  of  a 
census  may  be  obtained  by  noticing  the  salient 
points  in  a  particular  report,  that  for  1901  for 
England  and  Wales  being  a  good  example.  (1) 
Number  of  the  population  and  rates  of  increase. 
The  number  slightly  exceeded  thirty-two  and  a 
half  million.     The  rate  of  increase  per  cent  was 


12*17  per  decade  ;  greater  by  -52  than  for  the 
preceding  decade.  The  increase,  determined 
by  actual  enumeration,  differs  little  from  the 
"natural  increment"  determined  by  subtracting 
the  number  of  deaths  from  the  number  of  births. 
Hence  two  methods  of  forecasting  the  future 
increase  of  population.  Either  we  may  observe 
the  natural  increment  for  the  year  or  two  im- 
mediately adjacent  to  1901,  and  assume  that 
this  rate  will  remain  constant  for  the  following 
decade  ;  or  we  may  assume  that  the  actual  rate 
of  increase  for  the  decade  1891-1901  will  con- 
tinue to  prevail  for  the  next  decade.  A  variant 
of  the  second  method  takes  account  of  the  fact 
that  the  decennial  rate  of  increase  is  itself 
greater  than  in  the  preceding  decade.  The 
average  of  the  results  obtained  by  these  three 
methods  gives,  as  the  probable  population  in 
1911,  over  36,400,000.  The  Report  for  1911 
records  36,075,269  as  the  actual  population  of 
England  and  Wales  in  that  year.  The  Economic 
Journal  for  March  1911  contains  a  forecast  of 
the  census  results  worked  out  by  two  students 
of  statistics  from  the  recorded  births  and  deaths 
and  Board  of  Trade  returns  of  emigrants  and 
immigrants.  The  figures  of  England  and  Wales 
were  put  at  35,914,000,  or  about  half  a  million 
less  than  tlie  estimate  given  above,  which  dis- 
regards all  records  of  migration,  and  about 
160,000  less  than  the  actual  figures.  (2) 
Density  of  the  population  and  habitations.  The 
density,  whether  expressed  as  the  mean  distance 
between  individuals,  or  in  more  familiar  terms, 
is  found  to  vary  from  place  to  place  and  to 
increase  from  age  to  age.  The  proportion 
between  the  number  of  persons  and  the  number 
of  habitations  is  less  variable.  (3)  Sexes.  The 
excess  of  females  over  males  was  more  than  6 
per  cent ;  a  slight  increase  over  the  preceding 
decade.  It  remained  at  that  figure  in  1901- 
1911.  (4)  Ages.  At  this  stage  we  reach  less 
solid  ground.  The  returns  of  age  are  falsified 
by  various  causes.  Many  are  ignorant  and  put 
down  a  round  number  at  random.  The  very 
old  desire  to  appear  still  older.  Very  young 
women  overstate  their  age  with  a  view  to 
obtaining  employment ;  women  not  very  young 
understate  their  age.  From  this  double  cause 
the  category  of  female  ages  between  fifteen  and 
twenty -five  is  enormously  exaggerated.  All 
that  can  be  done  is  to  distribute  the  answers  in 
periods  of  five  years  ;  and,  assuming  that  these 
totals  are  correct,  to  determine  by  interpolation 
the  numbers  for  each  year.  (5)  Condition  as  to 
marriage  or  civil  condition.  The  immense  army 
of  over  five  and  a  half  million  wives  supplies 
an  effective  force  of  nearly  four  million  "of 
reproductive  age,"  between  fifteen  and  forty-five. 
The  number  of  single  women  and  widows  of  this 
age-period  exceeded  the  number  of  wives  by 
over  400,000.  The  proportion  of  married 
persons  to  the  adult  population  is  declining. 
(6)  *  *  The  most  laborious,  the  most  costly,  and 


CENSUS 


241 


after  all,  perhaps,  the  least  satisfactory  part  of 
the  census  "  is  that  which  is  concerned  with  the 
occupations  of  the  people.  One  difficulty  is 
obscurity  of  the  answers  given.  What  sort  of 
occupation  is  designated  by  an  "all-rounder," 
or  a  "baubler"?  The  same  designation  may 
have  diiFerent  meanings.  Thus  clothier  means  in 
some  parts  cloth-maker,  in  others  cloth-dealer. 
There  is  also  the  difficulty  of  multiple  occupa- 
tions. For  the  census  of  1901  the  classification 
of  the  occupations  was,  to  a  great  extent,  recast 
to  bring  the  census  statistics  more  in  harmony 
with  those  issued  by  the  Home  Office  and  the 
Board  of  Trade.  In  earlier  censuses  the  six- 
fold classification  framed  by  Dr.  Farr  had  been 
adopted  and  modified  from  time  to  time.  To 
reproduce  the  figures  in  detail  would  be  out  of 
place  here.  The  following  round  numbers  strike 
the  imagination  and  impress  the  memory.  The 
number  of  persons  engaged  in  transport  is  over 
a  million  and  a  quarter ;  the  number  employed  on 
textile  fabrics  about  a  million  and  a  quarter  ;  the 
number  employed  on  dress  about  a  million  and 
a  quarter  ;  the  number  of  agincultural  labourers 
over  a  million  ;  of  miners  nearly  half  a  million. 
The  number  of  the  professional  classes  is  about 
600,000,  and  of  those  employed  in  preparing 
food,  drink,  tobacco,  and  concerned  with  lodg- 
ings about  a  million.  (7)  Under  the  head 
Birthplaces  of  the  population  we  learn  what 
proportion  of  the  inhabitants  have  filtered  into 
England  from  other  countries  :  about  1  per  cent 
from  Scotland,  1*3  per  cent  from  Ireland,  and 
from  abroad  about  1  per  cent.  (8)  Infirmities 
comprise  blindness,  deaf-mutism,  and  the  various 
forms  of  mental  unsoundness.  It  is  gratifying 
to  find  the  relative  numbers  of  the  blind  (about 
1  per  1285  of  the  population)  diminishing. 
That  men  should  become  blind  oftener  than 
women  is  not  surprising. 

A  more  recent  model  of  a  census  is  presented 
by  the  preliminary  report  of  the  census  of  1911 
for  England  and  Wales.  The  Report  begins 
by  stating  the  total  number  of  persons  returned 
as  living  in  England  and  Wales  at  12  p.m.  on 
2nd  of  April  1911  :  namely  36,075,269.  The 
deficiency  of  this  number,  as  compared  with  the 
estimate  formed  (see  above),  is  accounted  for 
partly  by  a  diminution  in  the  natural  increase, 
partly  by  an  increase  in  the  net  emigration 
from  England  and  Wales  during  the  decade 
which  far  exceeded  that  of  the  decade  1891- 
1901.  The  decline  in  the  natural  increase  was 
not  due  to  increased  mortality  but  a  decrease 
in  the  birth-rate.  The  number  of  families, 
8,005,290,  has  increased  in  proportion  to  the 
population  by  "55  per  cent ;  the  number  of 
inhabited  houses,  7,141,781,  has  increased  in  a 

ther  smaller  proportion.  The  rate  of  increase 
population  varies  in  different  areas  ;  with 

me  exceptions,  being  highest  in  the  counties 
adjacent  to  London  and  counties  in  which  coal- 

KmiT„-«-y  jg  ^jjQ  predominant  industry.     Eight 
DL.  I. 


rural  counties  show  an  actual  decrease.  The 
general  law  that  a  district  increases  more 
rapidly  the  more  decided  its  urban  character  is 
not  overthrown  by  the  figures  which  show  in 
some  cases  a  smaller  percentage  increase  for 
districts  with  populations  above  100,000  than 
for  districts  with  populations  between  20,000 
and  100,000.  For  "probably,  or  at  any  rate 
possibly,"  the  contradiction  is  only  apparent, 
the  newcomers  in  the  larger  towns  having  to 
settle  outside  the  municipal  or  official  boundary. 
Accordingly  the  falling  off  of  increase  in  some 
large  towns  need  not  imply  a  decline  in  pro- 
sperity. The  population  of  the  Administrative 
County  of  London  has  decreased  "29  between 
1901  and  1911 — the  first  time  that  such  a 
phenomenon  has  presented  itself.  Twenty  out 
of  the  twenty-nine  Metropolitan  Boroughs  show 
a  decrease,  while  the  City  of  London  fell  about 
27  per  cent.  The  "  Outer  Ring,"  on  the  other 
hand,  increased  33*49  per  cent. 

The  following  table  shows  the  figures  for  the 
United  Kingdom  at  the  last  two  censuses  : — 

Enumerated  population  of  the  United  Kingdom. 


1901. 

1911. 

England  and  Wales   

Scotland    

Ireland 

United  Kingdom.       .   ... 

32,526,075 
4,471,957 
4,456,540 

30,075,209 
4,759,445 
4,881,951 

41  454  578  1  4r.  'ue,  fi(ir> 

'       ' 

The  rate  of  increase  of  tlie  United  Kingdom 
in  the  decade  1901-1911  was  8-2  per  cent.  It 
was  thus  lower  than  in  the  decatle  1891-1901 
when  it  was  9 '5  per  cent,  equal  to  the  rate 
in  the  decade  1881-91,  but  lower  than  in  the 
earlier  decades  1861-71  and  1871-81,  when 
it  had  been  8*8  per  cent  and  10*8  per  cent 
respectively.  The  movement  in  the  rate  of 
growth  was  unequally  shared  by  all  the  divisions 
of  the  kingdom.  In  England  and  Wales  the 
population  showed  an  increase  of  nearly  9*6 
per  cent  as  compared  Avith  the  enumeration  in 
1901  ;  in  Scotland  there  was  an  increase  of 
14-7  and  11*7  per  cent  in  the  large  town  and 
small  town  districts  respectively,  and  a  decrease 
of  5*6  per  cent  in  the  insular-rural  districts. 
In  Ireland  there  was  a  decrease  of  1 7  per  cent 
over  the  whole  country,  Leinster  alone  having 
increased  by  -7  per  cent,  while  Connaught  de- 
creased by  5  '7  per  cent.  The  population  of  the 
islands  in  the  British  seas  enumerated  in  1911 
was  148,915  ;  showing  a  decrease  of  1*455  ]ier 
cent  as  compared  with  the  enumeration  of  1901, 
and  a  considerable  decrease  in  the  rate  of  growth. 

Valuable  as  these  results  are,  and  though 
the  British  census  may  be  described  as  a  good 
article  at  the  price,  there  is  room  for  many 
improvements.  The  reform  most  loudly  called 
for  is  that  the  ensus  should  be  quinquennial. 
A -committee  of  the  Royal  Statistical  Society 
{Jmirnal,  1888,  p.  817)  urged  that  the  addi- 
tional cost  incurred   by  the  reform  would  be 

B 


242 


CENSUS 


small  ill  comparison  with  the  advantage  of 
obtaining  correct  returns  of  population.  They 
pointed  out  that  the  estimated  population  for 
certain  districts  was  inaccurate  to  the  extent 
of  11,  and  even  .18  per  cent.  This  argument 
has  now  become  a  fortiori,  owing  to  th^  imper- 
fections disclosed  by  recent  censuses.  Dr.  Noel 
Humphreys,  in  his  "Kesults  of  the  Recent 
Census  and  Estimates  of  Population  in  the 
largest  English  Towns"  (Journ.  Stat.  Sac, 
1891),  gives  instances  of  towns  in  which  the 
hypothetically  estimated  death-rate  differed 
from  the  true  figure  by  as  much  as  20  and  even 
26  per  cent.  The  estimates  based  on  the 
decennial  census  were  so  worthless  that  they 
seemed  to  evidence  a  decline  in  the  death-rate 
of  Salford  and  Liverpool,  while  in  reality  there 
was  an  increase.  For  recent  work  on  this  point 
see  yearly  volumes  of  the  Journ.  Stat.  Soc.  under 
heading  "  Census,"  especially  vol.  Ixxiv.,  1911, 
arts,  by  E.  C.  Snow — "The  Application  of  the 
Methods  of  Multiple  Correlation  to  the  Estima- 
tion of  Post-Censal  Populations, "  and  *  'Estimates 
of  Population."  The  Statistical  Society  has 
also,  through  the  mouth  of  various  committees, 
advised  that  the  character,  as  well  as  the  number, ' 
of  dwellings  should  be  returned.  Sir  I.  Palgrave 
shows  {Journ.  Stat.  Soc,  1869,  p.  411)  that 
information  as  to  the  house  accommodation  of 
the  people  is  very  deficient.  This  has  not  yet 
been  completely  supplied.  Another  recom- 
mendation sanctioned  by  the  Statistical  Society 
is  that  the  religious  profession  of  each  inhabitant 
should  be  obtained.  Mr.  Longstaff,  in  his 
"Suggestions  for  the  Census  of  1891 "  {Journ. 
Stat.  Soc,  1889),  proposes  that  the  number  of 
rooms  in  dwelling-houses  should  be  recorded. 
An  annual  census  has  been  proposed  by  the  late 
Sir  Edwin  Chadwick  {Journ.  Stat.  Soc,  1889, 
p.  468  ;  Internet.  Stat.  Congress,  The  Hague, 
pt.  ii.  p.  164).  Major  Craigie  demands  more 
conformity  between  the  census  and  the  returns 
of  the  agricultural  department.  "There  must 
be  large  omissions  in  the  ranks  of  land  occupiers 
in  our  census."  (Journ.  Stat.  Soc,  1887,  pp. 
98,  149,  and  Jubilee  vol.)  For  Imperial  Census 
see  Sir  J.  A.  Baines'  "Under  the  Crown,"  and 
"The  Census  of  the  Empire,  1911,"  Journ. 
Stat.  Soc,  vol.  Ixxiv. 

The  glory  of  instituting  the  first  census  does 
not  belong  to  England.  While  the  Population 
Bill  of  1753  was  denounced  in  the  House  of 
Commons  as  subversive  of  liberty,  Sweden  was 
already  enjoying  a  tolerably  perfect  census. 
Sweden  had  the  advantage  of  very  complete 
parish  registers,  recordiug  not  only  births, 
deaths,  and  marriages,  but  also  the  number  of 
persons  migrating  to  or  from  each  parish  and 
residing  in  it.  By  the  agency  of  the  clergy 
these  materials  were  embodied  in  a  census  in 
1749  and  subsequent  years,  first  at  intervals  of 
three,  subsequently  of  five  years.  The  results 
of  the  early  Swedish  census,  communicated  to 


the  scientific  world  by  the  celebrated  Wargentin, 
were  utilised  by  Dr.  Price  {q.v.)  and  Milnb 
(q.v.)  {Annuities,  ch.  xii.-xiii.)  Malthus  {q.v.) 
builds  upon  these  statistics  {Essay,  bk.  ii.  ch. 
ii.),  noticing  the  correlation  between  the  lean 
years  and  the  diminution  of  marriages.  In  the 
recent  publications  of  the  Swedish  Bureau  the 
study  of  such  correlations  is  facilitated  by  affix- 
ing to  each  year  a  numeral  (from  I.  to  X.)  indi- 
cating the  quality  of  the  harvest  (see  Journal 
of  the  Statistical  Society,  xxv.  p.  141).  Looking 
at  the  whole  series,  "  the  gradual  diminution  of 
mortality  since  the  middle  of  last  century  is  very 
striking "  now,  even  more  than  when  Malthus 
made  this  observation.  The  increase  of  suicides 
is  less  gratifying.  The  unrivalled  length  of  the 
Swedish  records  affords  particularly  striking 
instances  of  those  uniform  relations  which  con- 
stitute what  has  been  called  physique  sociale. 
The  proportion  of  male  to  female  births  was 
1-043  to  1  in  1751-60,  1*050  to  1  in  1851-55. 

Spain  has  some  claims  to  priority.  A  toler- 
ably complete  census  of  the  dominions  of  Castile 
was  taken  as  early  as  1594.  There  was  a 
general  census  of  Spain  in  1787  and  in  1797. 
But  then  occurred  a  pause  down  to  the  census 
of  1 857.  During  the  first  half  of  the  nineteenth 
century  Spain  lagged  behind  the  statistical 
movement  which  was  general  in  Europe. 

The  age  initiated  by  the  French  Revolution 
was  truly  called  by  Burke  the  "  age  of  statists." 
In  France  a  census  was  ordered  in  1791  and 
executed  in  1801.  In  Prussia  a  statistical 
bureau  was  founded  in  1805.  The  impulse  was 
followed  by  other  states,  at  different  times  and 
with  varying  pace — some  with  quinquennial, 
some  with  triennial  intervals.  The  inquiries 
have  become  more  fruitful  by  the  addition  of 
new  questions,  and  the  fruit  has  become  more 
accessible  through  increasing  uniformity  of  the 
questions  in  diSerent  countries.  The  branches 
of  the  European  census,  as  they  lengthen, 
become  not  only  broader,  but  more  parallel. 
The  possibility  of  international  comparison  is 
partly  due  to  the  action  of  the  International 
Statistical  Congress  during  the  quarter  century 
which  followed  its  first  meeting  in  1853.  The 
extent  to  which  its  recommendations  have  been 
adopted  may  be  expressed  by  the  following 
statement.  At  the  congress  of  St.  Petersburg 
(1872)  consolidating  the  results  of  discussions 
which  had  been  carried  on  at  several  preceding 
congresses,  twelve  questions  or  rubrics  (as  to 
name,  sex,  age,  etc.)  are  proposed  as  "essen- 
tial," or  obligatory.  Of  these  recommendations 
the  first  seven  are  already  adopted  in  twenty- 
five  continental  bureaus,  with  only  one  or  two 
exceptions.  The  remaining  five  directions  are 
carried  out,  roughly  speaking,  in  about  half  of 
the  continental  states.  Among  the  headings 
about  which  it  is  difficult  to  obtain  uniformity 
may  be  instanced  conjugal  condition.  At  the 
Florence  congress   (1867)  it  was  proposed   to 


CENSUS 


243 


ascertain  the  relationship  of  husband  and  wife. 
The  question  is  put  in  Sweden  and  some  other 
countries.  Population,  de  fait  and  de  droit — 
The  Italian  census  grapples  with  the  difficult 
questions  connected  with  domicile  by  an  elabor- 
ate arrangement  distinguishing  the  birds  of 
passage  from  the  residents,  and  the  temporary 
from  the  i^ermanent  absentees.  Age — Consider- 
ing the  inaccuracy  of  returns  under  this  head,  is 
it  worth  while  publishing  them  in  full  and 
without  manipulation?  Some  European  bureaus 
have  decided  in  the  affirmative.  Language 
spoken — What  does  this  heading  mean  ?  the 
language  most  used  in  good  society,  or  in 
the  family,  or  in  the  church  1  Occupations 
form  a  rubric  which  is  the  despair  of  the 
international  statisticians.  The  diversity  of 
employment  in  different  countries  is  aggra- 
vated by  the  difficulties  of  language.  What 
would  a  Frenchman  understand  by  "clerk 
of  the  parish,"  even  when  translated  (?) 
into  "clerc  de  paroisse"  {sic)'i  ** Carvers," 
one  of  the  designations  in  the  St.  Petersburg 
scheme,  should  not  have  been  rendered  in 
French  as  "agens  des  abattoirs."  On  these 
and  other  topics  perfect  unanimity  is  still  only 
an  ideal.  Even  when  agreement  has  been  ob- 
tained as  to  the  questions  to  be  asked,  there 
still  remains  diversity  in  the  arrangement  of 
the  answers.  To  smooth  these  remaining  dif- 
ferences may,  it  is  hoped,  be  a  function  of  the 
International  Statistical  Institute,  founded  in 
1885.  As  M.  Korosi,  one  of  the  ablest  advo- 
cates of  uniformity,  points  out,  the  diverse 
practices  mostly  involve  no  question  of  prin- 
ciple ;  it  would  give  no  additional  trouble 
to  act  in  concert.  It  is  needless  to  dwell  on 
the  advantages  of  increased  uniformity.  The 
census  was  used  by  ancient  Rome  as  an  engine 
of  government ;  modern  Europe  should  make 
it  also  an  instrument  of  science. 

[For  the  antiquities  of  the  subject  Gabaglio, 
Storia  .  .  .  delta  Staiistica  (2d  ed.,  1888),  may 
be  consulted.  For  the  history  and  scope  of  the 
census  in  the  United  Kingdom,  see  the  preface  or 
report  which  is  attached  to  every  census  except 
the  first.  Proposals  for  reform  are  expressed  in 
the  recomraendatious  made  by  a  committee  of  the 
Statistical  Society  before  each  census  (see  Journal 
of  the  Statistical  Society  for  1840,  1850,  and  sub- 
sequent decades).  Sir  I.  Palgrave's  paper,  Jour- 
nal of  the  Statistical  Society,  1869  ;  and  Dr. 
Lougstaffs  paper  in  Ibid.  1889  contain  other 
proposals  besides  those  which  have  been  noticed. 
A  general  view  of  the  earlier  methods  of  taking  the 
census  on  the  continent  is  presented  in  the  Journal 
of  the  Statistical  Society,  vol.  iii.  Mr.  Hendriks' 
detailed  accounts  of  the  Spanish  and  the  Swedish 
census,  in  the  23d  and  25th  volumes  of  the  same 
journal,  are  very  valuable.  As  to  the  history  and 
scope  of  the  census  in  the  different  European  states, 
copious  information  will  be  found  in  the  records  of 
the  International  Statistical  Congress,  especially  in 
.the  reports  made  by  the  members  for  each  nation. 
In  the  same  publication  will  be  found  repeated 


proposals  for  securing  greater  uniformity.  A  con- 
spectus of  these  recommendations  is  presented  by 
M.  Korosi  in  his  Projet  d'un  Recensement  du 
Monde  (Paris,  1881).  Attention  is  due  to  his 
own  recommendations  offered  in  that  work  and  in 
his  address  to  the  Jubilee  meeting  of  the  Eoyal 
Statistical  Society  (Jubilee  volume,  1885),  and  in 
his  contribution  to  the  second  Bulletin  of  the  In- 
ternational Statistical  Institute,  p.  200.  A  com- 
parison of  the  statistics  obtained  by  the  census  in 
different  countries  is  afforded  by  Confronti  Intcr- 
nazionali  (published  by  the  Direzione  Generale 
della  Statistica),  Roma,  1884.  Many  of  the  figures 
there  compiled  have  been  extracted  by  Sir  Rawsou 
Rawson,  who  has  added  explanatory  comments 
(Presidential  address  to  the  Statistical  Society, 
Journal,  1885).  The  most  recent  results  for 
several  European  countries  and  for  the  Cape 
Colony  and  Victoria  are  presented  together  in  the 
Notes  on  the  Preliminary  P<,etums  of  the  Censuses, 
1890-91,  in  the  Journal  of  the  Statistical  Society 
for  Sept.  1891.  Less  recent  comparisons  are  Movi- 
mento  della  Popolazione  in  Italia  e  in  altri  Stati 
d'Europa,  by  ]\L  Bodio  ;  Archivio  di  Statistica, 
1876  ;  Mouvevients  de  la  Population  dans  les  divers 
etats  de  V Europe,  by  M.  Bertillon  ;  Annates  de  la 
Demographie  Internationale,  vol.  i. ;  and  other 
articles  in  that  series  (extending  from  1877  to 
1883).    See  also  Quetelet,  Physique  Sociale,  1869.] 

F.  T.  E. 

CENSUS,  United  States.  The  mode  of 
conducting  the  census  of  the  United  States  is 
so  important  as  to  demand  special  notice. 

History  of  the  Census. — The  origin  of  the 
census  system  in  the  United  States  lay  in  the 
necessity  of  establishing  some  basis  for  the  dis- 
tribution of  representatives  and  direct  taxation 
among  the  dillerent  states.  When  the  colonies 
associated  themselves  together  to  resist  the 
mother  country  it  was  necessary  to  find  some 
method  of  distributing  the  expenses  of  the  w^ar. 
The  congress  which  assembled  in  1775  had  no 
power  to  assess  and  collect  taxes  through  officers 
of  its  own.  The  draft  of  the  articles  of  con- 
federation (1776)  provided  that  expenses  should 
be  distributed  according  to  the  population  of 
the  states,  which  should  be  ascertained  trienni- 
ally  and  transmitted  to  the  assembly  of  the 
United  States.  The  southern  members  objected 
to  the  slaves  being  counted  with  the  whites, 
and  in  the  articles  of  confederation  finally 
adopted  (1777-1781)  it  was  provided  that  all 
expenses  for  war  or  the  common  welfare  should 
be  apportioned  among  the  states  "according  to 
the  value  of  all  land  within  the  state  granted 
to  or  surveyed  for  any  person,  as  such  land,  and 
the  buildings  and  improvements  thereon,  shall 
be  estimated  according  to  such  mode  as  the 
United  States  in  congress  assembled,  shall  from 
time  to  time  direct  and  appoint "  (art.  8). 
The  land  force,  on  the  other  hand,  was  to  be 
furnished  by  the  different  states  according  to 
the  number  of  white  inhabitants  in  each  (art. 
9).  Neither  of  these  provisions  ever  led  to  a 
census  ;  in  fact  in  1783  congress  recommended 


244 


CENSUS 


the  levying  of  money  in  proportion  to  the 
population  rather  than  according  to  land- 
value,  and  drew  up  a  table  of  the  estimated 
population  in  each  state.  In  this  estimate  only 
three-fifths  of  the  slaves  were  counted.  This 
amendment  did  not  prevail,  hut  we  »ee  here 
the  origin  of  the  three-fifths  rule  which  crept 
into  the  constitution  of  1787  (art.  1,  §  2), 
which  is  the  legal  basis  of  the  census  at  the 
present  time.     That  clause  reads  as  follows  : 

"Representatives  and  direct  taxes  shall  be 
apportioned  among  the  several  states  which  may 
be  included  within  this  union,  according  to 
their  respective  numbers,  which  shall  be  deter- 
mined by  adding  to  the  whole  number  of  free 
persons  including  those  bound  to  service  for  a 
term  of  years,  and  excluding  Indians  not  taxed, 
three-fifths  of  all  other  persons.  The  actual 
enumeration  shall  be  made  within  three  years 
after  the  first  meeting  of  the  Congress  of  the 
United  States,  and  within  every  subsequent 
term  of  ten  years,  in  such  manner  as  they  shall 
by  law  direct." 

To  carry  out  this  provision  of  the  constitu- 
tion, congress  passed  the  first  census  law,  1st 
March  1790.  The  law  has  since  been  so 
extended  that  from  a  mere  enumeration,  the 
census  has  become  an  elaborate  description  of 
the  social  and  industrial  condition  of  the  people 
of  the  United  States.  This  progress  has  in  one 
sense  been  gradual,  but  the  census  of  1850  and 
that  of  1880  stand  out  as  marking  epochs, 
setting  the  standard  for  those  that  followed. 

The  census  of  1790  was  a  simple  enumeration 
of  the  people  under  the  following  classification  : 
free  white  males  of  16  years  and  upwards,  free 
white  males  under  16  years,  free  white  females, 
all  other  free  persons,  and  slaves.  The  census 
of  1800  was  similar  in  scope  except  that  the 
age  classification  was  slightly  more  elaborate, 
namely :  under  10  years,  from  10  to  16,  from 
16  to  26,  from  26  to  45,  over  45,  with  distinc- 
tion of  sex.  The  same  population  schedule 
was  used  in  1810  ;  in  addition  questions  were 
asked  in  regard  to  manufactures,  but  the  latter 
returns  were  so  incomplete  as  to  be  of  no  value. 
They  were  equally  incomplete  in  1820,  and 
in  1830  the  inquiry  was  omitted.  In  1820 
the  age  classification  was  further  elaborated  ; 
"foreigners  not  naturalised"  distinguished  ;  and 
the  people  divided,  according  to  occupation, 
under  agriculture,  commerce,  and  manufactures. 
The  census  of  1830  adopted  the  age  classifica- 
tion :  under  5  years,  from  5  to  10,  from  10  to 
15,  from  15  to  20,  from  20  to  30,  and  then  by 
decennial  periods.  It  also  distinguished  the 
blind,  and  deaf  and  dumb,  by  colour  and  certain 
ages.  In  1840  the  number  of  insane  and 
idiotic,  white  illiterates,  and  statistics  of  schools 
were  added.  A  manufacturers'  schedule  was 
again  attempted,  but  without  much  success. 
The  census  of  1850  was  more  elaborate.  It 
included   the   number  of  dwelling-houses,   of 


families,  of  persons  according  to  sex,  age,  colour, 
free  or  slave,  profession  or  occupation,  value  ol 
real  estate,  number  of  persons  married  within 
the  year,  attendance  at  school,  illiteracy,  the 
deaf  and  dumb,  blind,  insane,  idiotic,  pauper, 
and  convicts,  mortality  statistics  for  the  year, 
products  of  agriculture  and  industry,  wages, 
capital,  taxes,  colleges  and  schools,  newspapers 
and  periodicals,  and  churches.  Most  of  our 
comparisons  at  the  present  time  go  back  to  this 
census.  In  1879  a  new  act  was  passed  which 
resulted  in  the  elaborate  "tenth  census  of  the 
United  States,"  a  description  of  which  is  given 
below. 

Method  of  talcing  the  Census. — The  returns  of 
1790  were  taken  under  the  supervision  of 
United  States  marshals  and  sent  to  the  presi- 
dent of  the  United  States.  From  1806  to 
1840  they  were  sent  to  the  secretary  of  state 
and  published  by  him.  In  1850  the  census 
oflSce  was  created  in  the  newly-established  de- 
partment of  the  interior ;  since  then  a  super- 
intendent of  the  census  has  been  appointed  for 
each  census.  The  law  of  1st  March  1889,  for 
the  taking  of  the  eleventh  census  (1890),  pro- 
vided for  the  appointment  of  (not  more  than) 
175  supervisors  who  were  to  appoint  enumera- 
tors, the  latter  to  visit  personally  every  family 
in  their  subdivisions  and  by  inquiry  obtain  all 
particulars  required  by  the  law,  which  also 
allowed  schedules  to  be  distributed  in  advance, 
to  be  filled  up  by  householders  and  others.  The 
schedules  to  be  employed  were  (as  in  1880)  a 
population  schedule,  one  for  farms,  for  manu- 
factures, for  mortality  and  vital  statistics,  for 
social  statistics,  and  for  transportation  com- 
panies. Where  there  was  an  official  registration 
•of  deaths,  the  superintendent  might  withhold  the 
mortality  schedule  from  the  ordinary  enumera- 
tors and  obtain  the  statistics  through  official 
records.  The  superintendent  might  withhold 
also  the  schedules  for  manufacturing,  mining, 
and  social  statistics,  and  charge  the  collection  of 
these  statistics  upon  experts  and  special  agents. 
He  might  also  employ  special  agents  to  investi- 
gate the  statistics  of  the  manufacturing,  rail- 
road, fishing,  mining,  cattle,  and  other  industries 
of  the  country,  and  of  telegraph,  express,  trans- 
portation, and  insurance  companies  as  he  might 
require.  The  census  also  took  on  a  special 
schedule  the  names,  organisations,  and  length  of 
service  of  those  who  had  served  in  the  array, 
navy,  or  marine  corps  of  the  United  States  in 
the  war  of  the  rebellion,  and  who  were  survivors 
at  the  time  of  the  inquiry,  and  widows  of 
soldiers,  sailors,  or  marines.  The  population 
schedule  included  an  inquiry  as  to  the  number 
of  negroes,  mulattoes,  quadroons,  and  octo- 
roons. The  superintendent  also  collected  the 
statistics  relating  to  the  recorded  indebtedness 
of  corporations  and  individuals  ;  also,  informa- 
tion relating  to  animals  not  on  farms.  The 
cost  of  the  census  of  1890  was  not  to  exceed 


CENSUS 


246 


$6,400,000  (say  £1,280,000),  exclusive  of 
printing,  engraving,  and  binding.  The  cost 
of  the  census  of  1880  was  about  $4,853,350 
(say  £970,000).  One  of  the  criticisms  made 
on  census  methods  in  the  United  States  had 
much  weight,  namely,  that,  the  census  office 
should  be  permanent.  Formerly,  as  soon  as 
the  census  was  completed,  the  office  was 
abolished,  and  the  skilled  force  was  disbanded. 
The  result  was  that  every  census  was  taken  by 
inexperienced  men,  and  all  the  benefit  of 
previous  practice  in  statistical  work  was  lost. 
By  the  act  of  1902,  a  permanent  Bureau  of  the 
Census  was  created.  One  of  the  chief  objects  of 
this  act  was  the  retention  of  a  certain  number 
of  persons  familiar  with  decennial  census  work, 
but  also  to  provide  an  organisation  to  deal  in 
the  -interval  between  the  censuses  with  certain 
statistics  now  crowded  upon  the  decennial 
enumerations,  such  as  investigations  as  to  in- 
dustries, public  indebtedness,  social  statistics,  etc. 

The  Scope  of  the  Census. — This  may  be  seen 
by  a  survey  of  the  tenth  census,  an  extraordinary 
undertaking,  unlike  anything  that  preceded  it 
in  the  United  States.  In  the  words  of  the 
superintendent,^ — "It  was  intended  to  form 
a  grand  monumental  exhibit  of  the  resources, 
the  industries,  and  the  social  state  of  the 
American  people  on  the  occasion  of  their  tenth 
ten-year  enumeration.  In  its  nature  much  of 
the  work  done  from  1880  to  1883  is  detinitive 
or  else  such  as  to  require  only  slight  additions 
or  corrections  from  time  to  time." 

The  tenth  census  falls  into  two  parts  :  the 
ordinary  statistics  of  population,  wealth,  and 
industry ;  and  the  special  investigations  and 
reports  of  experts  having  only  a  semi-statistical 
character.  It  will  be  necessary  to  dismiss  these 
latter  with  only  a  word.^  They  are  not  pro- 
perly census  work,  and  their  value  can  be  esti- 
mated only  by  scientific  men.  The  ' '  Forest  trees 
of  North  America,"  for  instance,  is  an  elaborate 
description  of  the  trees  of  the  United  States, 
their  distribution,  their  value  as  lumber,  the 
strength  of  different  kinds  of  wood,  etc.  The 
volumes  on  "Cotton-growing"  contain  a  similar 
elaborate  description  of  the  cotton -growing 
states  of  the  south,  soil  and  climate,  strength 
of  cotton  fibres,  methods  of  cultivation,  etc. 
Other  volumes  do  the  same  for  tobacco,  the 
cereals,  petroleum,  coke,  building  stones,  pre- 
cious metals,  other  metals,  and  the  natural 
water  power  of  the  United  States.  Still  others 
contain  elaborate  descriptions  of  machinery  used 
in  various  industries,  and  the  processes  of  pro- 
duction. Such,  for  instance,  are  the  reports  on 
flouring  mills,  on  the  ice  industry,  on  pumps 
and  steam  engines.  Still  further  removed  from 
a  statistical  investigation  is  the  volume  con. 
i   Wning  the  mining  laws  of  the  United  States 

^  Quartefly  Journal  of  Economics,  ii.  143,  145. 

"^  See  titles  of  volumes  of  the  Tenth  Census  at 
end  of  this  article. 


and  of  the  several  states  and  territories.  Two 
volumes  contain  "Statistics  of  Cities,"  giving 
a  history  of  each  city  and  town  in  the  United 
States  and  a  description  of  its  government,  in- 
stitutions, sewerage  system,  pavements,  etc. 
All  this  is  scientific  work,  not  census  work. 
"It  is  not  to  be  expected  that  succeeding 
censuses  will  be  of  such  colossal  magnitude. " 

Real  census  work  falls  under  the  following 
heads  :  (1)  population  ;  (2)  mortality  and  vital 
statistics ;  (3)  agriculture  and  fisheries ;  (4) 
manufactures,  miningand mechanical  industries; 
(5)  transportation ;  (6)  taxation  and  public 
indebtedness. 

The  thirteenth  census  (1910)  covers  the  sub- 
jects (1),  (3)  and  (4).  The  twelfth  census  had  in- 
cluded (2),  but  mortality  statistics  are  now  col- 
lected annually  by  the  Permanent  Census  Bureau. 

Population. — There  are  some  peculiarities  of 
United  States  census  work  which  explain  the 
size  of  the  publications,  and  are  of  scientific 
interest'  as  differentiating  it  from  census  work 
in  Europe. 

(1)  One  is  the  size  of  population  and  the  ex- 
tent of  country  covered  by  the  census.  In  1880 
the  enumeration  covered  fifty  million  people,  the 
census  of  1910  covers  over  ninety-three  millions. 
The  country  is  divided  into  forty-eight  states. 
All  the  facts  of  the  census  are  presented  for  eacli 
state,  for  the  purpose  of  satisfying  local  inteiest. 
Still  further,  the  states  are  divided  into  counties, 
sometimes  more  than  a  hundred  in  a  state,  and 
most  of  the  tables  carry  the  figures  out  for  the 
counties.  The  counties  are  divided  into  town- 
ships, wards,  etc.  The  towns  and  cities  often 
differ  from  these  in  their  boundaries,  and  some- 
times separate  presentations  are  made  for  these 
minor  civil  divisions. 

(2)  An  elaborate  attempt  was  made  to  con- 
nect population  with  the  facts  of  physical  and 
political  geography,  such  as  climate,  altitude, 
rainfall,  eastern,  western,  and  southern  sections, 
etc.  The  immense  territory  of  the  United  States 
offers  such  a  variety  of  physical  characteristics, 
and  the  history  and  colonisation  of  the  several 
sections  have  been  so  different,  that  a  wide  field 
(it  was  hoped)  would  be  opened  for  the  use  ol 
statistics  in  sociological  speculation. 

(3)  Two  elements  in  the  population  of  the 
United  States  are  of  very  great  interest.  One  is 
the  coloured  population,  the  other  the  foreign- 
born.  In  no  other  population  do  we  find  the 
opportunity  to  study  such  social  questions  as 
those  presented  by  the  presence  of  a  race  dif- 
ferent in  blood  from  the  dominant  race  and  just 
lately  emancipated  from  servitude,  and  by  the 
presenceof  a  numerous  body  of  foreigners.  Ethnic 
questions  have  nowhere  such  a  field  for  statisti- 
cal determination.  With  this  feeling  the  census 
has,  in  almost  all  its  investigations,  analysed 
the  results  with  distinction  of  race  and  place  of 
birth.  Such  are  the  characteristics  of  the  census 
which  make  it  of  particular  scientific  importance. 


246 


CENSUS 


We  will  now  examine  sonie  of  the  results  : — 

The  total  area  of  the  United  States  is  over 
3,000,000  square  miles,  but  of  this  only 
1,569,570  square  miles  had  (1880)  a  density 
of  population  of  2  to  the  square  mile.  This 
is  called  the  settled  area,  and  has  steadily 
increased  since  the  beginning  of  the  occ\ipation. 
The  growth  of  population  and  of  settlement  at 
the  successive  census  periods  is  seen  in  the 
following  table : — 


Year. 

Popula- 
tion. 

Settled 
Area. 

Density  per 
sq.  mile  of 
settled  area. 

Increase  per 

cent  of 
Population 
in  Decade. 

1790 

3,924,214 

239,935 

16-4 

.... 

1800 

5,308,483 

305,708 

17-4 

35 -io 

1810 

7,239,881 

407,945 

17-7 

36-38 

1820 

9,633,822 

508,717 

18-9 

33-06 

1830 

13,866,020 

632,717 

20-3 

32-51 

1840 

17,069,453 

807,292 

21-1 

33-52 

1850 

23,191,876 

979,249 

23-7 

35-83 

1860 

81,443,321 

1,194,754 

26-3 

35-11 

1870 

38,558,371 

1,272,239 

30-3 

22-65 

1880 

50,155,783 

1,569,570 

32-0 

30-08 

This  table  shows  the  rapid  growth  of  popula- 
tion and  its  slight  increase  in  density  on  ac- 
count of  the  constant  extension  of  the  area  of 
settlement.  For  further  illustration  the  census 
has  adopted  the  following  classification  of  dens- 
ity of  population.  Group  1,  from  2  to  6  to  a 
square  mile,  represents  a  very  sparse  popula- 
tion, supported  perhaps  by  grazing  (frontier)  ; 
group  2,  from  6  to  18  to  a  square  mile,  repre- 
sents agriculture  in  early  stages  or  on  a  rugged 
soil ;  gi-oup  3,  from  18  to  45  to  a  square  mile, 
represents,  in  the  United  States,  well-developed 
agriculture ;  group  4,  from  45  to  90  to  a 
square  mile,  indicates  the  presence  of  manufac- 
turing industry ;  group  5,  over  90  to  the 
square  mile,  represents  advanced  industry.  A 
series  of  tables  and  coloured  Caetograms  pre- 
sents the  distribution  of .  population  according 
to  these  groups  at  each  decade  since  1790.  It 
is  a  most  interesting  and  unique  study  of  the 
process  of  settlement  in  a  new  country,  at  first 
the  tide  of  settlement  being  controlled  by  the 
course  of  navigable  rivers  and  the  removal  of 
hostile  Indians,  and  later  by  lines  of  railroads. 
The  following  table  will  show  the  area  of 
settlement  for  the  different  groups  in  1880  : — 

Sq.  miles. 
Group  1,  from    2  to    6  to  a  sq.  m.    .     384,820 
,,      2      ,,       6  „  18      ,,     ,,        .     373,890 
,,      3      „     18  „  45      „     „        .     554,300 
„      4      „     45,,  90      ,,     „        .     231,410 
,,      5      ,,      over  90      „     ,,         .       25,150 
Outside   of  cities  only  a  very  small   strip  of 
territory    along    the    Atlantic    seaboard    has 
acquired   the    density   of    population   due    to 
advanced  industry. 

In  a  similar  way  the  distribution  of  popula- 
tion is  shown  according  to  latitude  and  longi- 
tude (the  greater  part  of  the  population  live 
between  latitude  38°  and  43°,  one  half  to  the 
north  of  39°  of  latitude,  and  to  the  east  of  83° 


of  longitude  ;  according  to  elevation  above  sea- 
level  (nearly  two -fifths  live,  below  500  feet, 
and  three-fourths  below  10^/0  feet)  ;  according 
to  drainage  basins  (the  greater  part  of  the 
population  is  in  the  Mississippi  valley)  ;  accord- 
ing to  mean  annual  temperature,  to  mean 
temperature  in  July,  to  mean  temperature  in 
January,  to  maximum  temperature,  to  mini- 
mum temperature,  to  annual  rainfall,  and  to 
spring  and  summer  rainfall.  The  centre  of 
population  is  said  to  be  at  39°  4'  1"  latitude, 
and  84°  39'  7"  longitude,  or  at  a  point  about  8 
miles  west  by  sou  ill  of  Cincinnati.  All  these 
calculations  except  the  last  are  carried  out  for 
the  foreign-born  and  the  coloured  as  well  as  for 
the  total  population. 

Turning  now  to  the  distinctions  of  colour  and 
race,  the  population  of  the  United  States  in 
1880  was  as  follows  : 
Total  population        .         50,155,783 

White  ,,  .         43,402,970 

Coloured  „  .  6,580,793 

Native  „  .         43,475,840 

Native  white         „  .         36,8)13,291 

Foreign-born         ,,  .  6,6»'9,944 

The  coloured  population  is  mostly  in  the 
southern  states ;  in  three  (South  Carolina, 
Mississippi,  and  Louisiana)  the  coloured  were 
(1880)  in  excess  of  the  whites.  The  foreign-born 
are  principally  in  the  north,  and  especially  iij 
the  large  cities.  The  coloured  are  almost  ali 
of  them  of  native  birth,  and  the  foreign-born 
are  almost  all  of  them  whites,  so  that  the  two 
elements  are  entirely  separate  in  the  statistics. 
It  is  to  be  borne  in  mind  that  the  terms 
"native"  and  "foreign"  refer  always  to  place 
of  birth,  not  to  descent  or  alien  condition. 
Children  of  immigrants  born  on  the  soil  of  the 
United  States  are  classed  as  natives.  This  is 
unavoidable,  but  has  led  to  many  false  conclu- 
sions in  regard  to  the  influence  of  the  foreign 
element  in  the  United  States.  We  cannot 
say,  for  instance,  how  many  of  the  people  ol 
the  United  States  are  descendants  of  the 
original  settlers,  and  how  many  of  immigrants 
since  1820.  The  census  did  inquire  as  to  the 
birthplace  of  the  parents,  and  by  means  of  this 
inquiry  discovered  that  nearly  15,000,000  in- 
habitants of  the  United  States  were  either  born 
abroad  or  children  of  parents  born  abroad. 
It  is  one  of  the  most  interesting  points  of  the 
tenth  census  to  follow  out  these  foreign-born. 
They  congregate  largely  in  cities,  34 '2  per  cent 
of  the  total  number  being  found  in  the  largest 
44  cities  (of  Irish  45-26  per  cent,  of  Germans 
38*73  per  cent,  and  of  Italians  60-80  per  cent 
were  in  large  cities).  The  census  follows  the 
foreign-born  into  different  occupations.  Of  all 
the  persons  engaged  in  agriculture  in  the 
tJnited  States,  10*60  per  cent  were  of  foreigu 
birth  ;  of  those  engaged  in  prcfessional  and 
personal  services,  24-48  per  cent;  of  those  in 
trade  and  transportation,  25-33  percent;  and 


CENSUS 


247 


of  those  engaged  in  manufactures,  mining,  and 
mechanical  industries,  31*95  per  cent  were  of 
foreign  birth.  Other  statistics  show  the  pro- 
portion of  foreign -born  among  illiterates, 
prisoners,  convicts,  paupers,  deaf  and  dumb, 
insane,  blind,  etc.  The  figures  must  be  used 
with  caution,  because  the  census  was  not  alto- 
gether successful  in  the  enumeration,  and  be- 
cause no  regard  was  paid  to  the  age  classification, 
although  the  abnormal  proportion  in  some  of 
these  cases  (insane,  blind,  etc. )  is  due  to  the  ab- 
normal proportion  of  adults  among  the  foreign- 
bom.  This  whole  inquiry  as  to  the  foreign-born 
is  a  characteristic  part  of  the  American  census. 

The  other  population  tables  do  not  dilfer 
from  those  in  use  in  Europe.  The  classification 
by  sex  shows  a  proportion  of  only  965  females 
to  1000  males,  contrary  to  the  usual  case  in 
Europe,  but  easily  explained  by  immigration. 
In  the  eastern  states  there  was  an  excess  of 
females,  owing  to  emigration  of  males  west- 
ward, in  the  south  also  an  excess  of  females,  due 
apparently  to  the  usual  cause,  namely,  greater 
mortality  among  males.  The  age  classification 
showed  a  large  number  of  children,  especially 
among  natives,  but  this  latter  figure  must  be 
used  with  great  care  because  children  of  immi- 
grants born  on  this  soil  were  classed  as  natives. 
The  urban  and  rural  classification  showed  22-5 
per  cent  of  the  population  living  in  towns  of 
8000  inhabitants  and  over  (in  1790  it  was  only 
3*3  per  cent),  and  25-5  per  cent  living  in  towns 
of  4000  and  over.  Of  the  people  of  the  United 
States  engaged  in  gainful  occupations,  44-1  per 
cent  were  engaged  in  agriculture,  23 '4  per  cent 
in  personal  and  professional  services,  10*4  per 
cent  in  trade  and  transportation,  and  22*0  per 
cent  in  manufactures,  mining  and  mechanical 
industries. 

II.  Mortality  and  Vital  Statistics, — As  there 
has  been  no  uniform  registration  of  births  and 
deaths  for  the  whole  country,  and  in  many  states 
having  registration  it  was  imperfect,  American 
mortality  and  vital  statistics  of  former  years 
are  sadly  deficient.  The  tenth  census  tried  to 
collect  the  number  of  deaths  during  the  census 
year  and  the  ages  of  the  deceased.  By  com- 
parison with  one  or  two  states  where  there  was 
registration,  it  was  estimated  that  the  census 
returns  were  thirty  per  cent  short  of  the  actual 
number  of  deaths.  The  office,  in  addition,  by 
correspondence  with  nearly  thirty  thousand 
physicians,  tried  to  make  up  this  deficiency,  and 
to  ascertain  with  accuracy  the  cause  of  death. 
This  inquiry  was  only  partially  successful.  In 
large  cities  where  there  was  already  a  registration 
of  deaths,  the  census  office  simply  copied  the 
list.  The  births  were  obtained  by  adding  to  the 
number  of  children  under  one  year  of  age  the 
number  of  children  reported  as  born  and  dying 
during  the  census  year.  The  number  was  sup- 
posed to  be  15  per  cent  short  of  the  actual 
births.  With  such  imperfect  material,  the  birth- 


and  death-rates,  the  proportion  of  deaths  from 
different  diseases  according  to  age,  sex,  locality, 
race  and  nationality,  the  mortality  tables,  etc., 
must  have  a  very  uncertain  value.  The  birth- 
rate was  probably  about  36  per  1000,  the  death- 
rate  about  18  per  1000.  The  only  excuse  for 
the  census  undertaking  this  impossible  task  was 
that  no  one  else  would. 

III.  Agriculture. — These  returns  were  made 
on  a  separate  farm  schedule  filled  by  each  farmer 
under  the  direction  of  the  enumerator.  The 
figures  as  to  acreage  rest  on  no  ofiicial  survey, 
but  simply  on  the  statements  of  the  farmer. 
The  statistics  serve  a  double  purpose  :  to  display 
the  condition  of  farming  as  a  national  industry, 
and  to  show  the  value  of  agiicultural  products  as 
a  contribution  to  national  wealth.  Under  the 
first  head,  the  number  of  farms  was  4,008,997, 
comprising  536,081,835  acres,  or  28*9  per  cent 
of  the  total  land  area.  But  nearly  one  half 
(46-9  per  cent)  of  the  land  in  farms  Avas  unim- 
proved, mostly  woodland  and  forest.  The  aver- 
age size  of  farms  was  134  acres,  but  this  varied 
greatly  with  localities.  About  74  per  cent  of 
the  farms  were  cultivated  by  owners,  about  8 
per  cent  by  tenants  paying  a  money  rent,  18 
per  cent  were  cultivated  by  tenants  paying  a 
share  of  the  product  as  rent.  The  value  of 
farms  including  buildings  was  estimated  as 
$10,197,096,776  (say  £2,040,000,000).  Under 
the  second  head  the  census  gives  detailed  in- 
formation as  to  number  and  value  of  live  stock 
on  farms,  acreage  devoted  to  different  crops, 
amount  and  value  of  different  products,  such 
as  wheat,  com,  cotton,  etc.  for  1879,  details 
which  it  would  be  useless  to  repeat  here. 

IV.  Manufactures. — These  statistics  were  col- 
lected with  great  care  and  comprise  all  factories 
and  workshops  producing  to  the  value  of  $500 
(say  £100)  per  annum  and  over  down  to  the 
village  blacksmith  or  carpenter.  The  statistics 
of  industry  are  regarded  with  gi-eat  interest  in 
the  United  States  as  indicative  of  the  growth  and 
material  prosperity  of  the  community.  Especi- 
ally is  this  true  in  the  rivalry  of  state  with 
state,  and  of  city  with  city,  and  many  bitter 
attacks  were  made  on  the  census  office  because 
the  results  did  not  come  up  to  local  expectation. 
None  of  these  was  substantiated.  The  statistics 
have  been  collected  since  1850  on  the  same  plan, 
and  give  some  interesting  points  of  comparison, 
as  shown  in  the  following  table  (values  foi 
1870  reduced  to  gold  basis)  : 


1 

Value 
of  gross 
product. 

Value 

of  raw 

materials. 

Total 
amount  of 
wages  paid. 

Capital. 

Number 
of  hands 
employed 

1850 
1860 
1870 
1880 

£ 

203.823,923 

377,17:i,335 

677,172,070 

1.073,915.838 

£ 

111,024,764 
206,321,018 
398.148,359 
679,364,710 

£ 
47.351,893 
75,775,793 
124,093.495 
189,590,759 

£ 
106,649,050 
219,971,143 
338,913,403 
558,055,521 

958,079 
1, 311.246 
2.053,996 
2,732.535 

(.lu  £.  steiiiiig,  $  converted  as  5  =  £1.) 

These  figures  seem  to  give  a  fair  picture  of  the 
manufacturing  industry  of  the  United  States. 


248 


CENSUS 


The  return  of  total  value  has  been  criticised  on 
the  ground  that  the  finished  product  of  one 
industry  is  the  raw  material  of  another,  and 
that  thus  the  same  material  is  valued  several 
times  in  succession.  But  there  seems  to  be  no 
objection  to  this  so  long  as  value  is  added  to 
the  product  at  each  stage.  In  another  rfespect 
the  census  figures  have  been  greatly  abused. 
Persons  have  taken  the  cost  of  raw  materials 
plus  the  total  wages  paid,  and  deducting  it  from 
the  value  of  the  finished  product,  treated  the 
result  as  employer's  profit.  For  the  whole  of 
the  United  States  (1880)  this  figure  would  be 
$1,024,801,847  (say  £200,000,000),  or  more 
than  the  total  wages  paid.  On  the  basis  of 
the  capital  returned,  this  represented  a  profit 
of  36 '5  per  cent  in  manufacturing  industries. 
In  some  cases  it  was  still  greater,  as  for 
instance  in  the  boot  and  shoe  industry  there 
appeared  to  be  a  profit  of  nearly  50  per  cent. 
The  fallacy  arose  from  considering  wages  and 
raw  materials  as  representing  total  cost  of  pro- 
duction, and  from  the  diflBiculty  of  determining 
the  real  amount  of  capital  invested.  The 
eleventh  census  attempted  to  remedy  the  false 
impression,  in  part,  by  adding  to  the  cost  of 
production  the  amounts  paid  for  rent,  for  taxes, 
for  insurance,  for  commissions,  for  interest,  for 
freight  and  transportation,  and  other  expenses. 
It  also  proposed  to  follow  the  example  of  the 
Massachusetts  census  of  1885,  and  include 
under  the  head  of  capital,  credit  capital,  i.e. 
money  borrowed,  bills  receivable  in  excess  of 
bills  payable,  etc.  This  would  doubtless  pre- 
vent any  such  excessive  sum  appearing  as  profits 
again  ;  but  the  whole  attempt  to  show  the  rate 
of  profit  by  means  of  a  census  enumeration  is 
fallacious,  and  destined  to  failure. 

Wages. — The  total  sum  paid  for  wages  during 
the  census  year  divided  by  the  whole  number 
of  employees  gave  an  average  wage,  |346-90 
(say  £70)  per  annum.  This  figure  has  no  value 
because  many  of  the  persons  were  employed 
during  only  a  part  of  the  year,  and  because  it 
averages  the  wages  of  men,  women,  and  children. 
The  average  wage  of  employees  in  the  principal 
industries  is  fallacious  for  the  same  reasons. 
In  1890  it  was  proposed  to  attempt  a  classified 
wage,  i.e.  ascertain  the  number  of  men  receiving 
$5  (£1)  per  week,  between  $5  and  $6  (£1  and 
£1  :  4s.),  etc. 

V.  Transportation. — The  statistics  for  rail- 
roads were  collected  on  special  schedules  filled 
out  by  the  companies  themselves  (1017  com- 
panies working  87,781*97  miles  of  road),  and 
covering  financial  statistics,  such  as  income  and 
expenditure,  amount  of  stock,  bonds,  and 
general  indebtedness,  traffic  statistics,  rolling 
stock,  employees,  accidents,  etc.  There  are 
similar  reports  for  telegraphs,  telephones,  steam 
navigation,  canals,  etc. 

VI.  Taxation  and  Public  Indebtedness. — This 
report  (vol  vii.)  deserves  notice  as  our  only 


source  of  information  in  respect  to  the  amount 
of  wealth,  the  burden  of  taxation,  and  the  sum 
of  public  indebtedness  for  the  whole  of  the 
United  States.  Each  state  had  its  own  system 
of  valuation  and  taxation,  and  its  own  stat- 
istics of  local  indebtedness,  but  these  were  not 
uniform  and  had  never  before  been  combined. 
The  census  office  was  able  to  accomplish  this 
by  extensive  correspondence  with  state  and 
local  officers,  and  prominent  bankers,  and  busi- 
ness men  throughout  the  country.  The  results 
in  regard  to  taxation  were  not  entirely  satis- 
factory. As  regards  wealth,  the  census  office 
estimated  the  total  wealth  of  the  United  States 
to  be  $43,642,000,000  (say  £8,700,000,000). 
The  statistics  of  indebtedness  reveal  for  the 
first  time  the  amount  of  state  and  local 
indebtedness,  the  cause  for  which  it  was 
contracted,  rate  of  interest  paid,  amount  of 
sinking  funds  for  its  extinction,  etc.  The 
report  analyses  also  the  public  debt  of  the 
United  States,  number  of  holders,  amount  of 
their  holdings,  amount  in  the  hands  of  banks 
and  corporations,  the  section  of  country  where 
held,  etc.  This  may  not  be  true  census  work, 
but  the  student  of  finance  is  to  be  congratulated 
that  the  census  ofiBice  was  willing  to  do  it. 

State  Censuses. — Some  of  the  states  take  a 
census  at  the  intermediary  period  between  the 
national.  Most  of  these  are  mere  enumerations 
of  the  people  for  the  purpose  of  readjusting  the 
distribution  of  representatives.  The  census 
law  of  1879  tried  to  encourage  the  states  to 
prosecute  such  work  by  providing  that  if  any 
state  or  territory  should  take  such  a  census  at 
the  intermediary  period  and  in  accordance  with 
the  schedules  of  the  United  States  census,  the 
United  States  government  would  pay  one  half 
of  the  expense  of  supervisors  and  enumerators. 
The  provision  had  no  effect,  and  was  quietly 
dropped  out  of  the  act  of  1889.  The  census 
of  Massachusetts  of  1885  was  probably  the 
most  perfect  piece  of  statistical  work  done  in 
the  United  States  up  to  that  date. 

Census  of  1910. — The  thirteenth  census  was 
taken  as  of  date  15th  April  1910.  The  total 
area  enumerated  included  the  United  States, 
Alaska,  Hawaii  and  Porto  Rico,  and  persons 
stationed  abroad  in  the  service  of  the  govern- 
ment. The  figures  given  below  are  for  the 
United  States  only  : 


1 

^(2"^ 

py 

li 

m 

ill 

1890 
1900 
1910 

62,947,714 
75,994,575 
91,972,266 

12,791,931 
13,046,861 
15,977,691 

25-e 

20-7 
210 

2,973,965 
2,974,159 
2,973,890 

21-2 
25-6 
30-9 

The  statistics  of  population  and  agriculture 
(except  those  relating  to  irrigation  collected 
by  special  agents)  were  collected  by  a  force  of 
supervisors  and  enumerators.  There  were  330 
supervisors   of  the   census   appointed   by   the 


CENSUS 


249 


President,  controlling  about  70,000  enumera- 
tors of  population  and  agricultural  statistics, 
the  candidates  being  subjected  to  a  practical 
examination.  In  general  each  supervisor  had 
jurisdiction  over  one  congressional  district,  but 
in  the  more  populous  districts  the  work  was 
subdivided.  The  statistics  of  manufactures, 
and  of  mines  and  quarries,  were  collected  by 
special  agents  or  by  clerks  detailed  from  the 
Census  Bureau.  Statistics  of  population  are 
classified  with  regard  to : — number ;  distribution 
in  territorial  divisions,  in  states,  in  counties, 
in  urban  and  rural  districts,  in  cities  over 
2500,  and  cities  over  25,000  inhabitants  ; 
colour,  or  race,  nativity,  parentage  ;  sex  ;  age  ; 
marital  condition  ;  place  of  birth,  native  or 
foreign  (with  date  of  immigration) ;  school  at- 
tendance and  illiteracy ;  dwellings  and  families. 
Some  recent  results  are  as  follows  : — 


Population. 


Under  '2  to  a  sq.  mile 

From    2  to    6    ,,  ,, 

„        6  „  18     „ 

„      ^8  „  45     „ 

,,      45  ,,  00     ,, 

Over  90     „ 


3-21,255  sq.  miles. 

434.242 

9t52,s71 

f)3L),207  „ 

396,670 

210,769 


Proportion  of  Urban  and  Rural  Population 
to  Total.      Totals  100. 


ISSO. 

1890. 

1900. 

1910. 

Urban . 
Kural  . 

29-5 
70-5 

86-1 
63-9 

40-5 
59-5 

4(;-:! 
53-7 

White  and  Negro  Population. 


Total. 

White. 

Negro. 

§i  lo- 
ll P 

Per  cent  of 
Total. 

X, 
IS- 

2 

t    ; 

O   1 

1890 
1900 
1910 

62.947,714 
75,994,.575 
91,972,266 

65,101,258 
66,809,196 
81,731,957 

7.488,676 
8,83.S,994 
9,827,763 

357,780    87-5 
351,385  1  87-9 
412,546  J  88 -9 

11-9 
11-6 

10-7 

% 

Native  and  Foreign-horn  Population. 


62,947,714 
75,994,575 
91.972,266 


53,698.154 
65,653,299 
78,456,380 


Percent  of  Total. 

Foreign-      

'^°'""-  Native.    F^reign- 


9,249,560  85-3 

10.341,276    I      86-4 
13,515,886    !      853 


14-7 
13-6 
14-7 


Population  by  Sex. 


Population. 

Males  to  100  Females. 

Male. 

Female. 

Total. 

Nntive 
White. 

Foreigu- 

boru 
White. 

Negro. 

1890 
1900 
1910 

32.237,101 
38,816,448 
47.332,277 

.30.710,613 
37,178,127 
44,639,989 

105  0 
104-4 
106-0 

102-9 

102-8 
1027 

118-7 
117-4 
129-2 

99-5 
98-6 
98-9 

Agricultural  statistics  relate  to  (1)  farms  ; 
(2)  tenure,  mortgage  indebtedness,  race  of 
fanners,  size  of  farms  ;  (3)  livestock  ;  (4)  crops, 
acreage,  production  and  value  ;  (5)  irrigation. 
In  1910  there  were  6,361,502  farms  in  the 
States,  total  acreage  878,798,000  acres,  of 
which  478, 452,000  acres  were  improved.  Total 
value  of  farm  property,  £8,198,289,818. 


The  census  statistics  of  manufactures  are 
compiled  primarily  for  the  purpose  of  showing 
the  absolute  and  relative  magnitude  of  the 
different  branches  of  industry  and  their  growth 
or  decline,  and  incidentally  to  present  data 
showing  character  of  organisation,  location 
and  size  of  establishments,  labour  force  and 
similar  subjects.  These  statistics  are  classified 
according  to  industries,  states  and  cities.  The 
statistics  of  mines  and  quarries  are  also  classified 
according  to  industries  and  states. 

The  number  of  manufacturing  establish- 
ments was  268,491  ;  persons  engaged  in  manu- 
factures, 7,678,578;  primary  horse  -  power, 
18,675,376;  capital,  £3,685,654,000;  ex- 
penses, £3,690,818,000  (wages  and  salaries, 
£873,122,600;  materials,  £2,428,558,000); 
value  of  products,  £4,134,410,000;  value  added 
by      manufacture,      £1,705,852,000.  The 

number  of  mines,  quarries  and  wells  was 
193,688 ;  persons  engaged  in  mining,  1,166,948  ; 
primary  horse  -  power,  4,699,910;  capital, 
£732,505,413  ;  expenses,  £214,838,285  (sal- 
aries and  wages,  £131,116,893  ;  materials, 
£52,022,000);  valueof  products, £247,682,000. 

{The  First  Census,  1790.  (Return  of  the  whole 
number  of  persons  within  the  several  districts  of 
tlie  United  States,   1791.)— TAe  Second  Census, 

1800.  (Return  of  the  whole  number  of  persons,  etc., 

1 801.  )—The  Third  Census,  1810,  2  vols.  (Aggre- 
gate amount  of  each  description  of  persons  within 
the  United  States  of  America  and  the  Territories, 
tables  showing  the  several  branches  of  American 
manufactures.) — The  Fourth  Census,  1820,  2  vols. 
(Census  for  1820  ;  digest  of  accounts  of  manu- 
facturing establishments,  1823.) — TheFifth  Census, 
1S30, 1SS2.— The  Sixth  Census,  1840,  4  vols.  ( (1) 
Enumeration  of  the  inhabitants  of  the  United  States 
as  corrected  at  the  Department  of  State  in  1840, 
1841 ;  (2)  statistics  of  the  United  States  as  returned 
by  the  marshals  of  the  several  judicial  districts, 
1841  ;  (3)  compendium  of  the  enumeration  of  the 
inhabitants  and  statistics  of  the  United  States, 
1841 ;  (4)  census  of  pensioners  of  revolutionary  and 
military  service. ) — TheSerentk  Census,  1850, 4  vols. 
( (1)  Seventh  Census  of  the  United  States,  1853  ; 
(2)  mortality  statistics,  1855  ;  (3)  statistical  view 
of  the  United  States  compendium  of  the  Seventh 
Census,  1854  ;  (4)  Report  of  the  superintendent  of 
the  census  for  Dec.  1,  1852,  1853.)— TAe  Eighth 
Census,  1860,  5  vols.  ((1)  Preliminary  Report, 
1862  ;  (2)  population,  1864  ;  (3)  manufactures, 
1865  ;  (4)  agriculture,  1864  ;  (5)  statistics  (includ- 
ing mortality,  property,  etc.),  being  the  final  exhibit 
of  the  Eighth  Census,  1866.)— TAe  Ninth  Census, 
1870,  4  vols.  ( ( 1 )  Population  and  social  statistics, 
1872;  (2)  vital' statistics,  1872;  (3)  statistics  of 
wealth  and  industry,  1872  ;  (4)  compendium  of 
the  Ninth  Census,  1872.)— TAe  Tenth  Census 
of  the  (Inited  States,  1880.  (a)  Compendium  of 
the  Tenth  Census,  1883.  (6)  Tenth  Census  of  the 
United  States,  22  vols.  :  I.  Population  ;  News- 
papers and  Periodicals ;  Public  Schools ;  Illiteracy ; 
Defective,  Dependent,  and  Delinquent  Classes. 
II.  Manufactures,  embracing  general  Statistics  and 
Monographs   on    Power   used    in    Manufactures ; 


250 


CENT— CENTEALISATION 


Factory  System ;  Interchangeable  Mechanism  ; 
Hardware,  Cutlery,  etc.  ;  Iron  and  Steel ;  Silk 
Manufacture  ;  Woollen  Manufacture  ;  Chemical 
Products  and  Salt ;  Glass  Manufacture,  1883. 
III.  Agriculture,  general  Statistics  and  Monographs 
on  Cereal  Production  ;  Flour  Milling  ;  Tobacco 
Culture  ;  Manufacture  and  Movement  of  Tobacco  ; 
Meat  Production,  1883.  IV.  Transportation,  in- 
cluding Eailroads  ;  Steam  Navigation  ;  Canals  ; 
Telegraphs,  Telephones  ;  Postal  Telegraphs,  1883. 
V.  and  VI.  Cotton  Production  (general  discussion 
and  special  reports  for  fifteen  states),  1884.  VII. 
Valuation,  Taxation,  and  Public  Indebtedness, 
1884.  VIII.  Special  Eeports  on  :  the  Newspaper 
and  Periodical  Press  ;  Alaska,  its  Population,  In- 
dustries, and  Resources ;  the  Seal  Islands  of  Alaska ; 
Shipbuilding  Industry,  1884.  IX.  Forests  of  North 
America.  X.  Special  Reports  on  Petroleum,  Coke, 
and  Building  Stones,  1884.  XI.  and  XIL  Mortality 
and  Vital  Statistics,  1885, 1886.  XIII.  Statistics 
and  Technology  of  Precious  Metals,  1885.  XIV. 
United  States  Mining  Laws  and  Regulations  there- 
under, and  State  and  Territorial  Mining  Laws.  XV. 
Mining  Industries  (exclusive  of  Precious  Metals), 

1886.  XVL  and  XVIL  Water  Power,  1885, 1887. 
XVIII.  and  XIX.  Social  Statistics  of  Cities,  1886, 

1887.  XX.  Statistics  of  Wages  in  Manufacturing 
Industries  ;  Prices  of  Necessaries  of  Life  ;  Trades 
Societies  ;  Strikes  and  Lock-outs,  1886.  XXI. 
Defective,   Dependent,    and    Delinquent    Classes, 

1888.  XXII.  Power  and  Machinery  employed  in 
Manufactures  (six  Monographs)  ;  Ice  Industry, 
1888.  Th&  Eleventh  Census :  Report  of  the  Super- 
intendent of  the  Census,  6th  Nov.  1889. — Report 
of  a  Commission  on  different  Methods  of  tabulating 
Cens^is  Data,  Washington,  1889.  Bulletins  of  the 
Eleventh  Census.  For  History  and  methods  :  Re- 
port of  the  Committee  of  the  House  of  Representatives 
on  the  Ninth  Census,  Jan.  18,  1870.  E.  C.  Lunt, 
Key  to  the  Publications  of  the  United  States  Census 
(Publications  of  American  Statistical  Association, 
1888).  Francis  A.  Walker,  ' '  The  Eleventh  Census 
of  the  United  States  "  {Quart.  Journ.  of  Econ.,  vol. 
ii.,  1888).  Carroll  D.  Wright,  "The  Census,  its 
Methods  and  Aims  "  {International Review,  vol.ix.). 
R.  Mayo-Smith,  "Wage  Statistics  and  the  next  Cen- 
sus" {Quart.  Journ.  of  Econ., vol.  ii.,  1888).  Many 
of  the  statistics  of  the  Tenth  Census  will  be  found 
in  the  Encyclopcedia  Brit.,  9th  ed.,  art.  "United 
States  :  Political  Geography  and  Statistics  "  (F.  A. 
Walker).  The  Thirteenth  Census ;  publications 
of  the  Bureau  of  the  Census,  Washington  ;  esp. 
Abstract  of  the  Census,  1  vol.,  1913.]     R.  m.-s. 

CENT,  Centesimo  or  Centavo  (words  used 
as  equivalent  to  each  other — Cent  in  the  United 
States  of  America,  Centesimo  in  Peru  and  the 
Argentine  Republic,  Centavo  in  Chili,  the 
United  States  of  Columbia,  the  Philippines  and 
Mexico).  The  100th  part  of  any  Dollar,  e.g. 
the  dollar  of  the  United  States  of  America  or 
equivalent  coin  (e.g.  Peso,  Sol,  Duro,  of  Chili, 
Peru,  etc. ).  Copper,  nickel,  or  bronze  token 
coins  of  various  weights  and  dimensions. 

Cent  (Dutch).  Bronze  token  coin  weighing 
69-34  grains;  2|-  and  \  cents  in  proportion. 
100  cents  =  1  florin.  F.  E.  A. 

CENTESIMI   (Italy);    Centimes   (France, 


Belgium,  and  Switzerland)  ;  Centimos  (Spain), 
Bronze  token  coins  weighing  1  gramme  (1 5  •4323£ 
grains)  each.     100  =  1  franc  (or  its  equivalent). 

F.  e.  a. 

CENTRALISATION.  A  term  applied  to 
the  concentration  of  the  functions  of  govern- 
ment, more  usually  those  of  an  administrative 
character,  in  the  hands  of  a  single  directing 
authority. 

It  is  obvious  that  the  supreme  authority 
existing  in  any  community  is  able  to  exercise 
a  paramount  influence  upon  its  wealth  and 
economic  position.  On  this  account  many  of 
the  leading  writers  on  economics  have  discussed, 
in  some  detail,  "the  proper  limits  of  the  func- 
tions and  agency  of  governments,"  and  incident- 
ally the  organisation  by  which  those  functions 
and  that  agency  should  be  exercised.  The 
results  arising  from  the  regulation  and  control 
of  individual  action  by  public  authority  have 
been  seen  to  be  frequently  determined  by  the 
manner  in  which  the  authority  is  brought  into 
existence,  and  the  nature  of  the  responsibility 
attaching  to  its  actions  ;  and  some  at  least  of 
the  economic  objections  which  present  them- 
selves to  the  multiplication  of  the  duties  of 
government,  disappear  when  these  are  placed  in 
the  hands  of  local  and  sectional,  as  distinguished 
from  imperial  and  national,  authorities.  Thus 
Mill  points  out  that  the  evil  of  entrusting  toe 
much  business  to  the  government  is  "felt  in 
great  magnitude  under  some  of  the  governments 
of  the  Continent,  where  six  or  eight  men  living 
at  the  capital  and  known  by  the  name  of 
ministers,  demand  that  the  whole  public  busi- 
ness of  the  country  shall  pass,  or  be  supposed 
to  pass,  under  their  individual  eye."  But  he 
adds  that  "  the  inconvenience  would  be  reduced 
to  a  very  manageable  compass  in  a  country 
in  which  there  was  a  proper  distribution  of 
functions  between  the  central  and  local  offices 
of  government"  {Political  Economy,  6th  ed., 
1865,  p.  567).  Sir  Arthur  Helps,  too,  calls 
attention  to  the  now  well-recognised  fact  that 
a  carefully  devised  system  of  Local  Government 
affords  an  opportunity  of  practising  that ' '  habit 
of  spontaneous  action  for  a  collective  interest " 
without  which  the  education  of  a  people,  as 
MUl  observes,  "is  defective  in  one  of  its  most 
important  branches." 

The  extent  to  which  it  is  better  that  the 
functions  of  government  should  be  entrusted  to 
a  minor  authority  and  dissociated  from  the 
national  executive  is  not  capable  of  any  exact 
definition.  It  will  differ  in  different  nations, 
and  at  different  periods  of  then-  existence.  It 
must  depend  upon  the  willingness  of  those 
upon  whom  authority  is  to  devolve  to  exercise 
it  for  the  common  good,  and  to  sink  individual 
interests  in  the  desire  to  advantage  the  general 
welfare  ;  much  too,  will  depend  on  the  educa- 
tion and  intelligence  of  the  constituency  within 
which  administrative  powers  are  to  be  exercised, 


CENTRALIS  ATION—CERTIFICA  TE 


and  of  the  class  or  classes  which  are  to  wield 
them.  The  decision  as  to  whether  any  given 
function  may  more  properly  be  entrusted  to  an 
authority  under  the  direct  control  of  the  national 
government,  or  to  an  authority  independent 
thereof,  rests  rather  with  the  statesman  than 
with  the  economist.  If,  however,  it  be  true  that 
"people  can  understand  their  own  business  and 
their  own  interests  better,  and  care  for  them  more 
than  the  government  does,  or  can  be  expected  to 
do,"  then  it  would  appear  that  the  onus  prohandi 
should  always  rest  upon  the  advocates  of  the 
exercise  of  governmental  power  in  any  direction. 
It  must  be  shown  to  be  for  the  general  advan- 
tage that  individual  action  should  be  replaced 
by  the  action  of  a  small  section  of  the  commun- 
ity, and  similarly  that  the  nation  as  a  whole 
will  perform  any  given  function  better  than  the 
section  immediately  concerned.  In  other  words 
the  endeavour  should  be  to  restrict  the  exercise 
of  public  authority  to  the  smallest  possible 
area,  and  above  all  to  secure  that  all  who 
either  directly  or  indirectly  are  responsible  for 
the  administration  of  public  business  should 
have  an  actual  interest  in  the  success  of  their 
administration. 

In  thus  limiting  the  executive  area,  and 
restricting  the  exercise  of  public  authority,  as 
far  as  other  ch-cumstances  will  admit,  to  those 
directly  concerned,  care  must  be  taken  to  pre- 
serve for  the  general  use  the  wider  experience 
and  clearer  insight  into  principles  which  a 
central  authority  will  usually  possess,  and  it 
will  frequently  be  necessary  to  reserve  some 
power  of  review  to  be  exercised  in  the  interests 
of  minorities  or  of  other  sections  of  the  com- 
munity. 

The  English  poor-law  system  afibrds  a  good 
niusti-ation  of  a  system  of  independent  local 
administration  combined  with  centralised  super- 
vision and  control  within  certain  prescribed 
limits.  The  maintenance  of  the  poor  being  a 
matter  of  national  concern,  and  it  being  impos- 
sible to  localise  the  effects  of  good  or  bad 
administration  in  such  a  matter,  parliament 
has  prescribed  the  jjrinciples  upon  which  relief 
shaU  be  afforded  and  its  cost  raised.  A  depart- 
ment under  a  responsible  minister  has  also 
been  established  to  see  that  these  principles 
are  observed,  and  to  furnish  the  best  advice  and 
information  available.  But  it  rests  with  the 
local  authority  to  adjudicate  on  applications  for 
relief,  and  generally  to  make  provision  for  the 
due  administration  of  the  law. 

Much  of  the  legislation  by  means  of  "  private 
bills  "  would  be  more  efficient  if  it  were  entrusted 
to  a  less  important,  but  more  interested,  author- 
ity than  the  imperial  parliament,  and  the 
establishment  of  County  Councils  may  eventu- 
ally afford  a  means  of  relegating  many  of  the 
fimctions  at  present  performed  by  the  national 
executive  to  a  minor  authority  better  able  to 
discharge  them  to  the  advantage  of  the  section 


of    the    community    more    immediately    con- 
cerned. 

In  view  perhaps  of  the  fact  that  the  British 
government  is  the  least  centralised  in  Europe,  our 
own  literature  on  the  subject  is  much  less  ample 
than  that  of  the  Continent,  and  especially  ol 
France.  John  Stuart  Mill's  Representative  Govern- 
ment and  Principles  of  Political  Economy  (book 
v.),  and  Sir  Arthur  Helps's  Thov^hts  upon  Govern- 
ment may,  however,  be  consulted.  For  the  view 
of  the  Manchester  School  which  is  against  Central- 
isation, see  e.g.  Mallet,  Free  Exchange,  pp.  97, 
etc.  Speech  of  Cobden  in  ed.  Bright  and  Rogers, 
vol.  i.  No.  XX.  pp.  362-3.  ["  Government  will 
revert  to  something  like  the  municipal  system."] 

T.  H.  E. 

CERTAINTY.  Certainty  is  an  economic  con- 
ception of  great  importance  in  several  depart- 
ments. The  certainty  of  enjoying,  partially  at 
least,  the  fruits  of  one's  own  exertion  is  one  of 
the  principal  elements  in  the  efficiency  of  labour 
(contrast  slave  with  free  labour).  In  the 
accumulation  of  capital,  and  in  the  institution 
of  private  property,  certainty  is  again  funda- 
mental. The  essence  of  Capital  {q.v.)  is  held 
to  be  in  the  reservation  of  "Wealth  for  future 
consumption  or  the  satisfaction  of  futui-e  needs, 
which  implies  that  the  fund  reserved  will  be 
secured  to  a  gi'eater  or  less  degree.  The  degi'ee 
of  certainty  naturally  operates  upon  the  rate  of 
interest  when  capital  is  lent.  Certainty  is 
also  used  in  reference  to  taxation  as  regards  the 
manner,  time,  and  amount  of  payment,  and  as 
the  basis  of  Adam  Smith's  second  canon.  He 
considers  certainty  to  be  of  such  importance 
that  a  very  considerable  degree  of  inequality  is 
"  from  the  experience  of  all  nations,  not  near  so 
great  an  evil  as  a  very  small  degree  of  uncer- 
tainty." In  insurance  the  certainty  attaching 
to  groups,  relatively  to  the  uncertainty  in  the  case 
of  individuals,  is  the  fundamental  conception. 

[Uncertainty  of  employment,  as  an  evil  of  the 
present  industrial  regime,  is  dealt  with  by  Prof. 
Foxwell  in  Claims  of  Labour  (Edinburgh,  1886)]. 

J.  s.  N. 

CERTIFICATE,  Shake.  A  broker,  when 
he  has  bought  shares  in  a  company  for  a  client, 
has  to  deliver  a  document  called  a  certificate, 
which  is  the  only  visible  sign  of  the  property  in 
the  share.  It  is  signed  by  one  or  more  officials 
of  the  company,  and  when  the  shares  are  sold 
must  in  most  cases  be  given  up.  Several  de- 
cisions in  the  courts  have  shown  that  a  certificate, 
although  registered  in  buyer's  name,  is  worthless 
in  the  event  of  forgery  of  the  seller's  name  on 
the  transfer,  and  no  claim  can  be  upheld  against 
a  company,  notwithstanding  the  registration 
of  transfer  and  issue  by  it  of  the  certificate  in 
the  buyer's  name.  The  Forged  Transfer  Act, 
1891,  gives  a  company  power  to  compensate  a 
holder  so  defrauded,  but  a  certificate  is  not 
absolute  security.  American  railroad  share 
certificates  are  peculiar  ;  as  the  certificate  may 
be  made  in  the  name  of  another  person,  whereas 


252 


CESARE— CHAD  WICK 


the  owner  of  the  document  may  have  paid  for 
it  without  his  name  appearing  as  the  owner 
either  on  the  certificate  or  on  the  company's 
books.  The  American  share  document  usually 
carries  a  transfer,  and  this  is  almost  as  usually 
left  blank  when  the  seller  has  given  up  his 
interest  in  the  share,  not  naming  the  buyer. 
These  certificates  therefore  pass  very  much  as 
bonds  to  bearer.  Awkward  legal  cases  have 
arisen  out  of  this  loose  custom.  A.  E. 

CESARE,  Caklo  de,  born  at  Spinazzola 
(Bari)  1824,  died  at  Rome  1882.  First  as  a 
deputy,  and  later  as  a  senator,  he  was  employed 
in  reporting  on  important  laws  and  charged 
with  delicate  commissions,  such  as  the  inquiry 
into  the  condition  of  the  navy  after  the  battle 
of  Lissa,  and  on  the  state  of  Sicily  in  1875. 
He  was  Counsellor  of  the  "  cour  des  comptes  "  ; 
having  been,  before  reaching  this  dignity,  in- 
spector-general of  the  banks  of  issue.  He  was 
the  author  of  a  manual  of  political  economy, 
putting  forward  principally  the  doctrines  of 
RiOARDO  ;  this  book  is  useful  even  now  on 
account  of  a  chapter  it  contains  of  historical 
notices  concerning  political  economy  in  Italy. 
Manuale  di  Economia  pubblica,  2  vols.  Torino, 
1862.  De  Cesare  wrote  also  upon  a  great  many 
economical  problems  of  the  day  in  his  country, 
and  earned  thus  a  considerable  reputation  as 
politician  and  practical  economist. 

The  following  list  of  his  publications  will  give 
an  idea  of  his  activity : 

Intorno  alia  ricchezza  pugliese,  Bari,  1853  ;  R 
mondo  civile  e  industriale  nel  secolo  xix.,  Napoli 
1857  ;  DelV  indiustria  asiatica,  Napoli  1857  ; 
Delia  protezione  e  del  libera  cambio,  Napoli  1858  ; 
Delia  proprietd  intellettuale,  Napoli  1858  ;  Delle 
condizioni  econoniiche  e  morali  delle  dassi  agricole 
(published  by  the  Accademia  Pontoniana),  Napoli 
1859  ;  DelV  educazione  alle  arti  e  mestieri,  Pal- 
ermo 1859  ;  Progetto  di  perequazione  delV  imposta 
fondiariaper  tutto  il  regno  d' Italia,  Torino  1863  ; 
II  credito  fondiario  e  agricolo,  Torino  1863  ;  La 
legge  delV  affrancamento  del  Tavoliere  di  Puglia  e 
gli  interessi  economici  delle  provincie  meridionali, 
Torino  1863  ;  II  Passato,  Present e  e  I'Awenire 
della  pubblica  amministrazione  del  regno  d' Italia, 
Frrenze  1865  ;  Disarmonie  economiche,  Firenze 
1865  ;  La  finanza  italiana  nel  1867,  Firenze 
1867  ;  Relazione  sullo  stato  del  materiale  e  sulV 
amministrazione  della  r.  marina,  Firenze  1867 ; 
Le  due  scuole  economiche,  Firenze  1875.      m.  p. 

CESS.  The  land-tax  of  Scotland,  perma- 
nently fixed  at  £47,954  per  annum,  subject  to  a 
power  of  redemption.  It  is  payable  partly  from 
burghs,  and  partly  from  shires  ;  the  incidence 
of  taxation  is  determined  by  the  local  authorities. 

A.  D. 

CESSIO  BONORUM.  See  Bankruptcy 
IN  Scotland. 

CESSIONARY  (Scots  law  term).    Assignee. 

CEVA,  Giovanni,  born  in  the  province  of 
Milan  in  1647  or  1648 — is  a  remarkable  author, 
and  will  probably  attract  a  growing  interest,  as 
the  first  clear-aighted  and  decided  mathematical 


economist.  He  has  also  the  merit  of  clearly 
defining  hypothetical  economics  and  insisting  on 
pure  economics  as  being  the  only  possible  exact 
science  of  which  the  subject  permits  the  con- 
struction. He  was  by  profession  a  mathe- 
matician and  hydraulic  engineer,  and  as  such 
was  several  times  employed  by  the  government 
of  Mantua.  His  death  took  place  during  the 
siege  of  Mantua  in  1734. 

Ceva's  economical  work  has  the  following 
long  title — De  re  nummaria,  quoad  fieri  potuii 
geometrice  tractata,  ad  illustrissimos  et  excellentis- 
simos  dominos  Frcesidem,  Qucestoremque  huius 
areiducalis  Ccesarcei  Magistratus,  Mantuae, 
1711. 

He  divides  the  causes  influencing  the  value 
of  money  into  two  groups:  those  which  "ex- 
trinsecus  adveniunt "  and  those  which  "ex 
nummo  ipso  procedunt."  The  "  valor  externus 
omnis  rei  nummarise"  varies  in  a  direct  ratio 
to  the  population  and  inverse  ratio  to  the 
"quantitas  rei."  When  "nummi  serosi"  and 
"cuprsei,"  are  in  excess  of  the  quantity  needed 
for  small  transactions  true  coin  gets  appreciated 
a,nd  vice  versd  .  .  .  "  in  eadem  quantitate  nmn- 
mis  aureis  persistentibus  eorum  externi  valores 
componuntur  ex  ratione  quantitatum  aerosse 
monetae  et  exf  reciproca  quantitatum  argentece. 
As  to  the  causes  of  variations  in  value  classified 
as  depending  "ex  ipso  nummo,"  he  enumerates 
the  principal  ones  which  can  be  called  expenses 
of  production,  viz.,  the  distance  and  nature  of 
the  mines,  the  expenses  of  coinage,  etc. 

Passages  characterising  his  conception  of 
economic  science  and  his  condemnation  of 
inductive  methods  are  the  following :  Mag- 
num aliquid  est  commercium  illud  reconditum 
atque  complexum,  quo  humana  respublica, 
pecuniae  occulto  gyro,  florens  atque  incolumis 
perpetuo  servatur ;  .  .  .  sed  huiusmodi  naturam 
explorare  difficUlimum  est,  nee  aliter  possum/us, 
nisi  qucedam  geometrarum  modo  ponantur. 
Alias  necesse  est  nos  versari  in  quadam  obscur- 
issima  nocte,  nee  de  re  huiusmodi  posset  quid- 
quam  constitui  neque  cognosci.  .  .  .  Quibusdam 
petitionibus  proefixis,  sic  rem  intellectui  pro- 
ponemus,  ut  si  fieret,  quod  ratio  admonet  fieri 
debere,  geometrice  ostendi  possit,  unde  oriantur 
au^menta  Tnonetarvmi,  et  quot  quibusque  ex 
rationibus  componantur  valores  ipsi  nummorum. 
Quamvis  plura  contingant,  quae  praxim  minus 
exactam  reddunt,  regula  tamen  eiusque  vis  fixa 
atque  immobilis  perseverat.  m.  p. 

CHADWICK,  Sir  Edwin.  This  distin- 
guished economist  and  statistician  was  born  in 
1800  and  died  at  his  residence  at  East  Sheen, 
Surrey,  on  the  5th  April  1890.  He  preserved 
his  untiring  energy  and  enthusiasm  to  the  end 
of  this  long  term  of  ninety  years,  and  happily 
lived  to  see  a  vast  degree  of  success  resulting 
from  the  great  social  reforms  he  had  instituted, 
fostered,  and  practically  carried  through  to  tlie 
advantage  of  the  health,  well-being,  and  general 


CHAD  WICK 


252 


improvement  of  his  country.  Bom  of  a  Lan- 
cashire family  of  the  middle  class,  and  with 
immediate  ancestors  gifted  with  little  riches  but 
with  much  earnestness  of  purpose,  he  had  to 
work  out  his  own  way  to  fortune.  Intended 
at  first  for  the  bar,  Chadwick  was  soon  forced 
to  change  his  legal  reading  for  the  more  im- 
mediately bread-winning  occupations  of  report- 
ing and  review  writing.  A  contribution  of  his 
to  the  Westminster  Review,  in  1828,  on  the 
subject  of  "Life  Assurance,"  and  another  on 
"Preventive  Police,"  gained  him  the  acquaint- 
ance and  support  of  Grote,  the  elder  and 
younger  Mill,  and  Bentham.  Soon  after  the 
caU  to  the  bar  of  Chadwick,  Bentham  engaged 
him  as  an  assistant  to  complete  his  own  cele- 
brated treatises  on  civil  and  penal  legislation, 
and  in  this  capacity  Chadwick  went  to  reside 
with  the  octogenarian  philosopher  until  his 
death  in  1832.  Bentham  left  him  a  legacy 
and  a  small  library,  and  would  fain  have  wished 
Chadwick  to  have  succeeded  him  in  the  propa- 
ganda of  what  may  be  called  Benthamism. 
Fortunately  Chadwick  prefeiTed  a  practical  to 
a  speculative  career.  National,  social,  and 
sanitary  subjects,  such  as  the  condition  of 
labour,  the  housing,  living,  and  over-crowding 
of  the  population,  and  especially  of  the  working 
classes,  the  improvement  of  the  water  supply 
of  great  cities,  the  interment  of  the  dead  in 
cemeteries  removed  from  the  immediate  neigh- 
bourhood of  the  living,  and  other  similar  great 
questions,  had  become  Chadwick's  earnest 
study.  His  well-earned  reputation  for  this 
soon  led  to  his  being  offered  and  accepting 
official  employment.  In  1832,  during  the  ad- 
ministration of  Lord  Grey,  the  first  poor-law 
commission  was  appointed,  and  Chadwick's 
duty,  in  the  post  of  assistant-commissioner  to 
which  he  was  promoted,  demanded  his  per- 
sonal visit  to  all  parts  of  the  country  where 
investigation  of  facts  seemed  needful,  and  his 
collection  of  them  led  to  such  astounding  revela- 
tions of  the  then  condition  of  the  labourer,  of 
the  poor,  and  of  the  evils  to  be  remedied,  that 
the  government,  impressed  with  the  talent  and 
genius  displayed  in  his  reports,  appointed  him 
a  commissioner.  The  commission  itself,  of 
which  Chadwick  was  the  real  heart  and  soul, 
carried  out  the  most  sweeping  reform  in  the 
old  English  Poor- Law  system.  Even  this  was 
not  sufficient  to  satisfy  his  almost  perfervid 
imagination  of  view  of  the  advantages  to  be 
expected  from  a  root-and-branch  substitution 
of  complete  centralisation,  in  place  of  the  ex- 
cessive and  costly  decentralisation  and  its  many 
abuses  that  were  rampant  when  each  of  the 
16,000  parishes  of  England  looked  to  the 
wants  of  its  own  poor  much  in  its  own  way. 
In  1833  Chadwick  had  the  chief  share  in 
drawing  up  the  report  upon  the  condition  ol' 
Children's  Labour  which  led  to  the  Ten  Hours 
Act     In  1834  he  was  appointed  secretary  to 


the  new  poor-law  board,  and  during  his  tenure 
of  that  office  for  about  twelve  years  his  exer- 
tions for  the  public  good  were  unceasing. 
In  1838  he  presented  a  report  of  the  commis- 
sioners on  a  special  inquiry  into  the  local  and 
preventible  causes  of  disease,  and  the  improve- 
ment of  habitations  in  the  metropolis.  This 
report  proposed  a  venous  and  arterial  system  of 
water  supply  and  drainage  for  the  improvement 
of  towns,  and  works  for  the  application  of 
sewage  to  agricultural  production.  Similar 
inquiries  were  pursued  throughout  England 
and  Wales  under  his  guidance,  and  led  to  very 
substantial  reforms.  His  report  of  1843,  on 
the  results  of  a  special  inquiry  into  the  practice 
of  interments  in  towns,  formed  the  basis  of  the 
legislation  which  substituted  a  better  system. 
In  the  same  year  he  read  to  the  Royal  Statisti- 
cal Society  of  London  a  paper  on  the  best  mode 
of  representing  by  returns  the  duration  of  life 
and  causes  of  mortality.  In  1844,  Chadwick 
suggested  to  Sir  Robert  Peel  the  appointment 
of  a  Commission  to  make  a  general  investiga 
tion  into  the  national  health  and  the  best 
means  of  improving  it.  Quarrels  ensued  be- 
tween Chadwick  and  the  other  commissioners, 
and  the  new  poor-law  board  was  dissolved. 
It  was  not  perhaps  to  be  expected  that  a  man 
of  the  enthusiastic  and  optimistic  type  of  Chad- 
wick could  steer  clear  of  conflict  with  his  col- 
leagues. Nor  can  it  be  said  with  truth  that 
there  existed  no  well-founded  cause  of  complaint 
on  their  part,  for  Chadwick  was  egoistic  and 
dogmatic  even  when  not  positively  domineering, 
and  was  gifted  with  a  readiness  of  pen  and  a 
volubility  of  tongue  which  often  wearied  out 
his  opponents.  But  as  gi-eat  public  benefits 
often  accrued  from  his  contentions,  the  private 
evil  to  his  colleagues  does  not  count  for  much. 
Socially,  as  we  and  many  of  his  survivors  can 
vouch,  Chadwick  was  a  most  interesting  and 
valued  acquaintance.  The  fact  is  that  the 
necessity  for  speedy  action  to  remedy  evils 
glaring  and  grievous  was  so  obvious  that  the 
urging  of  them  on  in  a  nation  wedded  as  we 
are  to  a  long  retention  of  old  forms  and  ways 
and  systems,  was  a  positive  public  good  ;  and, 
in  the  case  of  Chadwick,  the  man  was  fortu- 
nately equal  to  the  work.  Sometimes,  indeed, 
on  occasions  when  he  had  to  stir  up  apathy  or 
Laissez-Faire  into  reform,  he  was  in  the  habit 
of  profusely  spicing  his  statements  with  statistics 
which  would  not  bear  Ihe  test  of  strict  actuarial 
investigation,  and  which  were  incorrect  in  respect 
of  their  collocation  with  results,  or  of  their  com- 
parative percentages.  The  year  after  the  poor- 
law  board  was  dissolved  Chadwick  was  ap- 
pointed one  of  the  commissioners  to  inquire 
into  the  health  of  London,  and  in  the  next 
following  year  (1848)  one  of  the  commissioners 
of  the  general  board  of  health,  for  improving 
the  supplies  of  water,  and  the  sewage,  drainage, 
and  cleansing  of  great  towns.     In  the  same 


254 


CHADWICK— CHALMERS 


year  he  was  nominated  to  the  Companionship 
of  the  Bath,  although  he  was  not  promoted  to 
the  knighthood  of  the  order  until  1889,  the 
year  before  his  death.  When  the  board  of 
health  was  dissolved,  Chadwick  retired  upon  a 
pension  of  £1000  per  annum.  But  there  .was 
no  retirement  by  him  from  the  active  pursuit 
of  his  life-long  researches  and  labours  for  the 
practical  advancement  of  all  that  concerns  the 
health  and  educational  and  social  progress  of 
the  nation.  On  sanitation  especially  he  con- 
tinued to  be  its  chief  authority  to  consult. 
He  had  much  influence  in  such  matters,  for  ex- 
ample, in  the  sending  out  of  commissioners  to 
the  Crimea  for  the  relief  of  our  soldiers  there. 
This  was  followed  up  in  1858  by  inquiries  into 
the  heavy  mortality  amongst  the  troops  in 
India,  a  subject  he  fully  explained  in  a  paper, 
"On  the  application  of  Sanitary  Science  to  the 
protection  of  the  Indian  Army,"  read  before 
the  Social  Science  Congress  at  Liverpool.     In 

1860  he  was  vice-president  of  the  public  health 
department  of  the  meeting  of  the  same  congress 
at  Glasgow,  and  delivered  a  remarkable  address 
on  sanitation.  In  1861,  he  followed  up  the 
same  subject,  as  president  of  the  section  of 
economic  science  and  statistics,  at  the  health 
association  at  Cambridge.  It  would  be  tedious 
to  prolong  the  list  of  his  contributions,  from 

1861  to  1890,  to  the  journals  of  aU  the  numer- 
ous scientific  societies  to  which  he  belonged, 
and  for  whose  researches  and  practical  public 
objects  he  continued  to  labour  to  the  end  of 
life.  A  long  career  thus  well  spent  deserves 
the  gratitude  alike  of  his  contemporaries  and 
of  posterity.  England  certainly  has  erected 
statues  and  memorials  of  many  men  of  far 
inferior  worth  to  Chadwick.  There  remains, 
however,  an  ever-present  memorial  of  him  in 
the  improvements  that  have  taken  place  in  this 
country  in  almost  every  direction  that  he  laboured 
in,  and  which  are  briefly  indicated  in  the  present 
outline  of  the  chief  points  in  his  biography. 

See  TAe  Health  of  Nations,  a  Review  of  the 
Works  of  Edtuin  Chadvyick,  with  a  Biographical 
Dissertation,  by  B.  W.  Richardson,  2  vols.,  8vo, 
London,  1887.  Chadwick's  papers,  printed  in 
the  Journal  of  the  RoyaZ  Statistical  Society, 
extend  over  a  period  of  thirty-six  years.  Their 
titles  are — "On  the  best  mode  of  representing 
by  Returns  the  Duration  of  Life  and  Causes  of 
Mortality,"  vol.  vii.  p.  1. — "On  the  Economical, 
Social,  Educational,  and  Political  Influences  of 
Competitive  Examinatious,  as  Tests  of  Qualifica- 
tion for  Admission  to  the  Junior  Appointments 
in  the  Public  Service,"  vol.  xxi.  p.  16. — "On  the 
Progress  of  the  Principle  of  Competitive  Examina- 
tion for  Admission  into  the  Public  Service,  with 
Statistics  of  Actual  Results  and  an  Investigation 
of  some  of  the  Objections  raised,"  vol.  xxii.  p.  44. 
— "Results  of  Different  Principles  of  Legislation 
and  Admiuistration  in  Europe  ;  of  Competition 
for  the  Field  as  compared  with  Competition  within 
the  Field  of  Service,"  vol.  xxii.  p.  381.— "Post- 


Ofiice  Savings'  Banks,"  vol.  xxiv.  p.  519. — Ad- 
dress as  President  of  Section  F.  ("Economic 
Science  and  Statistics  ")  of  the  British  Association, 
October  1862,  printed,  vol.  xxv.  p.  502. — "On 
the  Subject  Matters  and  Methods  of  Competitive 
Examinations  for  the  Public  Service,"  vol.  xxvi. 
p.  72.  —  "Poor -Law  Administration,  its  Chief 
Principles  and  their  Results  in  England  and  Ire- 
land as  compared  with  Scotland,"  vol.  xxvii.  p. 
492. — Opening  Address,  as  President  of  the  De- 
partment of  Economy  and  Trade,  at  the  Meeting 
of  the  National  Association  for  the  Promotion  of 
Social  Science,  York,  1864,  printed,  vol.  xxviii. 
p.  1. — "  Treatment  of  Pauper  Children  on  a  Larger 
Scale,"  table  illustrative  of  school  organisation  for 
reducing  expenses  with  increased  eflBciency,  vol. 
xliii.  p.  245.  f,  h. 

CHAFFER,  now  a  verb,  was  originally  a 
noun,  and  meant  a  journey  for  the  purpose  of 
buying  and  selling,  from  the  words  chap  (as  in 
Jcaufen,  caupo,  KdTrrjXos),  and  fare,  a  journey. 
Chap  appears  in  chapman  or  merchant,  also  in 
cheap,  which  was  at  first  a  noun,  and  meant 
simply  market,  as  in  Eastcheap,  and  Cheapside. 
Articles  sold  on  terms  favourable  to  the  buyer 
were  to  him  "good  cheap"  or  good  market 
(compare  "bon  marche").  The  adjective  was 
dropped  and  the  substantival  character  for- 
gotten ;  hence  the  adjective  "cheap."  Chaffer 
in  popular  language  is  a  form  of  what  Adam 
Smith  calls  Higgling  of  the  Market,  or 
the  disputing  of  buyer  and  seller,  which  is  the 
usual  preliminary  to  the  striking  of  a  bargain  ; 
but  it  is  used  of  retail  dealers  and  their  cus- 
tomers more  often  than  of  wholesale ;  and  is 
associated  rather  vnth  petty  than  with  impor- 
tant interests.     [See  also  Chapman.]      j.  b. 

CHALMERS,  Geoege  (1742-1825),  Scotch 
antiquarian,  historian,  and  economist,  born  at 
Fochabers  in  Moray,  and  educated  there  and  at 
Aberdeen.  He  afterwards  studied  law  at  Edin- 
burgh. He  went  to  America,  and  practised  as 
a  lawyer  at  Baltimore.  Returning  home  at  the 
beginning  of  the  civil  difficulties  in  1775,  he 
settled  in  London.  He  was  appointed,  1786, 
chief  clerk  of  the  committee  of  the  privy  council 
for  trade  and  foreign  plantations.  His  works 
were  chiefly  historical  and  antiquarian,  includ- 
ing the  well-known  Caledonia. 

His  economic  works,  as  their  titles  suggest, 
are  chiefly  statistical,  and  as  such  are  of  the  very 
highest  importance  ;  the  Estimate  in  particular 
furnishing  the  student  with  valuable  infor- 
mation, which,  bearing  in  mind  Chalmers's 
official  position,  may  be  deemed  more  than 
usually  trustworthy.  In  his  Considerations  on 
Commerce  he  deals  with  more  theoretical  matters, 
committing  himself  to  the  opinion  that  the 
high  price  of  Bullion  was  owing  to  the  state  of 
the  Foreign  Exchanges.  It  cannot,  however, 
be  said  that  his  arguments  or  facts  tend  to  estab- 
lish his  position. 

His  economic  works  were  as  follows :  The 
Propriety  of  allovnng  a  Qualified  Export  of  Wool 


CHALMERS 


25£ 


discussed  historically ,  1782. — An  Estimate  of  the 
Comparative  Strength  of  Great  Britain  diiring 
the  Present  and  Four  Preceding  Reigns,  1782. — 
Opinions  on  Interesting  Subjects  of  Public  Laws 
and  Commercial  Policy  arising  from  Amencan 
Independence,  1784. — Observations  on  the  Strength 
of  England  in  1696,  by  Gregory  King,  vnth  a 
Life  of  the  Author,  1804. — A  Chronological  Ac- 
count of  Commerce  and  Coinage  in  Great  Britain 
from  the  Restoration  till  ISIO,  1810. — Considera- 
tions on  Commerce,  Bullion  and  Coin,  Circulation 
and  Exchanges,  with  a  View  to  our  Present  Cir- 
cumstances, 1811  (3d  ed.  1819). 

There  is  also  attributed  to  him,  but  on  very- 
slender  grounds,  a  small  anonymous  pamphlet 
entitled  Useful  Suggestions  favourable  to  the  Com- 
fort of  the  Labouring  People,  1795.        e.  c.  k.  g. 

CHALMERS,  Thomas  (bom  at  Anstruther 
in  Fife  1780,  died  at  Edinburgh  1847),  the  son 
of  a  prosperous  merchant,  and  the  sixth  of  a 
family  of  fourteen  children,  was  educated  at  St. 
Andrews  University,  and  became  minister  of 
Kilmany  parish  1803.  He  was  at  first  more 
attached  to  mathematics,  physics,  and  political 
philosophy  than  to  theology ;  and  brought 
himself  into  notice  by  his  scientific  lectures  given 
at  St.  Andrews,  first  for  the  university  and  then 
in  competition  with  it.  In  1808  he  published 
An  Inquiry  into  the  Extent  and  Stability  of 
National  Resources,  in  connection  with  the 
continental  Blockade.  The  doctrines  of  this 
pamphlet  were  incorporated  with  his  Political 
Economy  (ch.  vi.  p.  221  of  vol.  xix.  ed.  Collins), 
under  the  heading  "Limits  of  a  Country's 
Foreign  Trade,  and  its  supposed  power  to  fur- 
nish a  people  with  Employment  and  Mainten- 
ance." In  1815,  transferred  to  Glasgow,  he 
carried  out  his  famous  voluntary  organisation 
of  charitable  relief,  to  show  (as  he  expressed  it) 
the  "sufficiency  of  the  parochial  system"  and 
the  needlessness  of  a  Poor  Law.  The  scheme 
worked  successfully  for  more  than  twenty  years. 
Chalmers  was  professor  of  moral  philosophy 
and  political  economy  in  St.  Andrews  (1825- 
1828),  and  then  of  divinity  in  Edinburgh 
(1828-1843),  holding  the  latter  office  till 
the  Disruption  of  the  Church  of  Scotland  in 
1843,  and  the  formation  of  the  Free  Church, 
in  whose  service  he  laboured  (both  in  its  college 
and  in  its  church  courts)  to  the  day  of  his 
death.  It  was  no  doubt  a  bitterness  to  him 
that  by  aiding  this  schism  he  helped  to  bring 
about  the  establishment  of  a  Poor  Law  in  Scot- 
land, which  took  place  in  1845,  two  years 
before  his  death. 

In  his  book  on  Political  Economy  (1832)  his 
aim  is  not  to  develope  a  body  of  doctrines  but 
to  secure  the  moral  and  thereby  the  economic 
elevation  of  society.  Political  economy,  in  the 
sense  in  which  he  treats  of  it,  is  regarded  as 
aiming  at  the  ' '  diffusion  of  sufficiency  and 
comfort."  Economists  and  ecclesiastics  (he 
repeatedly  says)  liave  stood  too  much  aloof 
from  each  other  ;  and  for  his  part  he  will  write 


as  an  ecclesiastic  who  recognises  the  value  oi 
economics.  He  follows  Adam  Smith  and 
Malthus,  rather  than  Ricardo,  accepting  the 
"  Ricardian  "  theory  of  rent  with  the  modi- 
fications of  Malthus  and  Perronet  Thomp- 
son, and  the  theory  of  population  with  less 
reserve  than  its  author  ( ' '  Population  tends  to 
double  itself  in  fifteen  years,"  Pol.  Econ.  ch. 
xiii.  p.  382).  Like  J.  S.  M.11A,  {^ee  Dissert,  ch. 
ii.  p.  183,  "Claims  of  Labour,"  written  1845) 
he  saw  that  the  theory  of  population,  instead 
of  closing  the  way  to  progress,  had  really  for 
the  first  time  opened  it.  He  regards  the  theory 
of  Malthus  as  the  vinculum  between  moral 
character  and  economic  comfort.  "By  the 
indefinite  control  which  the  collective  mind 
and  habit  of  society  have  over  the  element  of 
population,  the  general  standard  of  enjoyment 
in  a  country  is  capable  of  being  indefinitely 
raised "  (ch.  i.  p.  44)  ;  and,  as  a  matter  of 
fact  it  has  been  raised  :  * '  The  labourers  of 
our  day  work  harder  than  before  but  live  better 
than  before."  "  The  rate  of  wages  depends  on 
the  proportion  which  the  inclination  of  the 
people  for  marriage  bears  to  their  inclination 
for  the  comforts  and  decencies  of  life  "  (ch.  ix. 
p.  279)  ;  and  without  a  Christian  education 
to  give  self-control  progress  cannot  be  assured. 
The  philanthropy  of  the  few  cannot  save  the 
many  from  "that  most  overmastering  of  all 
oppressions,  the  oppression  of  their  own  num- 
bers" (ib.  p.  285).  Neither  home  colonisation 
(on  Dutch  or  other  models),  nor  emigration, 
which  is  a  worse  alternative,  nor  a  Poor  Law, 
which  is  worst  of  all,  can  do  more  than  cause 
multiplication  and  misery.  Government  can 
administer  justice,  but  humanity  is  out  of  its 
province  {Chr.  and  Econ.  Pol,,  pref.  viii.)  He 
speaks  of  the  fallacy  of  "finding  employment" 
for  the  poor.  People  forget  that  a  manufacture 
is  creative  of  nothing  but  its  own  products  ; 
the  equivalents  of  these  products  must  come  from 
elsewhere.  The  benefit  of  a  Foreign  Trade, 
too,  lies  simply  in  the  article  it  brings  us  ;  the 
tea  trade  gives  us  tea,  and  if  it  were  abolished 
we  should  lose  tea,  and  nothing  more  (cli.  ii. 
pp.  63,  67,  etc.)  Chalmers,  therefore,  thinks 
lightly  of  the  loss  of  foreign  markets.  In  his 
book  on  Christian  and  Economic  Polity  (ch. 
xxii.)  he  says  quite  truly  "that  the  worth  of 
that  by  which  a  thing  is  done  is  all  derived 
from  the  worth  of  that  for  which  the  thing  is 
done ; "  but  from  that  and  similar  maxims 
(there  and  in  the  Pol.  Econ.)  he  argues  in  a  way 
that  would  logically  lead  to  the  conclusion  that 
it  is  indifferent  to  a  shopkeeper  whether  we 
deal  with  him  or  not  (see  Mill,  Unsettled  Ques- 
tions, pp.  53  scq.)  He  saw  that  the  importance 
of  the  home  trade  had  been  under-estimated  by 
statesmen  like  Pitt,  who  idolized  foreign  trade  ; 
but  he  went  too  far  in  asserting  that  it  was  the 
desti-uction  of  British  trade  that  made  Britain 
successful  against  Napoleon  (see  Pol.  Econ.,  ch. 


256 


CHALMERS— CHAMBERLAYNE 


viii.  p.  264).  His  own  idol  is  Agriculture,  as 
giving  not  merely  "employment"  but  "main- 
tenance "  ;  as  long  as  agriculture  is  unairected, 
any  stoppage  of  trade  is  "only  a  shift,  not  a 
subtraction  "  {Ohr.  arid  JEcon.  Pol. ,  ch.  xxii. )  In 
everything  except  agriculture  there  may  b^  over- 
supply,  over- population,  and  over -supply  of 
capital — too  many  ploughmen  and  too  many 
ploughs.  If  either  the  "appetite  for  present 
indulgence  "  or  the  "  appetite  for  future  wealth  " 
were  to  become  universal,  society  would  lose  its 
balance  {Pol.  JEcon.,  ch.  iv.  p.  127).  As  popula- 
tion follows  food,  capital  follows  openings  in  busi- 
ness ;  and,  where  they  fail,  it  becomes  de  trop. 
Like  the  Physiocrats,  Chalmers  considers  that 
all  taxes  fall  eventually  on  the  net  Rent  of  Land, 
and  should  therefore  be  placed  there  directly, 
and  the  landowning  class,  as  they  bear  all  the 
burdens  of  the  country,  should  have  all  the 
political  power.  He  would  maintain  Primo- 
geniture to  prevent  ' '  infinite  subdivision  "  of 
lands,  and  to  secure  that  the  ship  of  state  shall 
not  have  more  sail  than  ballast  {Pol.  Econ.,  ch. 
xvi.)  He  assents  to  repeal  of  the  Corn  Laws 
and  commutation  of  Tithes  ;  but  he  thinks  the 
good  effects  will  be  transitory,  the  real  causes 
of  distress  being  over -speculation  and  over- 
population (ch.  ix.  p.  303).  He  is  against 
the  Funding  System,  government  loans  being 
always,  he  says,  paid  twice  over  by  the  pubUc, 
first  in  the  form  of  high  general  prices  caused 
by  the  withdrawal  of  the  capital  lent,  and 
afterwards  in  repayment  of  the  principal  to 
the  lenders  {Pol.  Econ.,  Append.)  Government 
should  raise  enough  for  the  year's  needs  by 
taxation  within  the  year.  Finally,  it  may  be 
noted  that  he  stands  by  his  order  when  he 
refuses  to  confine  the  term  productive  labour  to 
labour  that  produces  material  objects,  to  the 
exclusion  of  professional  labours  like  his  own. 

Perhaps  Dr.  Chalmers  is  better  known  to 
later  economical  readers  by  his  phrases  than 
by  his  doctrines.  As  he  has  made  current  in 
ethics  "the  expulsive  power  of  a  new  affec- 
tion," so  he  has  given  to  economics  "the 
margin  of  cultivation"  {Pol.  Econ.,  ch.  i.  pp. 
19,  etc.) — "Disposable  population"  (or  non- 
agricultural),  "secondaries"  (makers  of  second- 
ary necessaries),  "rotation"  (or  transfer  as 
opposed  to  creation  of  wealth),  were  less  happy ; 
but,  as  John  Mill  says,  Chalmers  has  always 
"the  merit  of  studying  phenomena  at  first 
hand  and  expressing  them  in  a  language  of  his 
own  "  (Mill,  Pol.  Econ.,  i.  v.  §  7).  MiU  was 
specially  referring  to  the  explanation  given  by 
Chalmers  of  the  rapidity  with  which  a  country 
recovers  from  a  war  in  which  it  has  been  over- 
run by  the  enemy.  The  reason  was  not  to  be 
sought  in  any  mystical  vis  medicatrix  Tiaturce, 
but  simply  in  the  everyday  fact  that  the  greater 
part  of  Capital,  fixed  as  well  as  circulating,  is 
being  constantly  renewed  by  human  eff'orts 
year  by  year,  and  the  stimulus  of  higher  gains 


than  usual  will  lead  to  an  energetic  direction 
both  of  the  "immediate"  and  of  the  "ante- 
cedent" labour  on  the  most  urgently  needed 
production.  "  By  one  revolution  of  the  econo- 
mic cycle  the  circulating  capital  would  be 
nearly  restored  ;  and  by  a  few  revolutions 
more  the  fixed  capital  would  be  fully  restored, 
not  by  the  parsimony  of  successive  generations, 
but  by  the  privations  of  a  few  successive 
seasons"  {Pol.  Econ.,  ch.  iv.  §  13,  pp.  140-142). 
It  may  be  added  that  our  author  anticipated 
Mill  in  maintaining,  against  the  opinion  of  Adam 
Smith,  that  the  Stationary  State  of  wealth 
and  population  might  be  happier  than  the  pro- 
gressive {Pol.  Econ.,  vol.  XX.  ch.  xv.  §  12,  p.  28). 

(1)  An  Inquiry  into  the  Extent  and  Stability  of 
National  Resources,  1808. — (2)  Vol.  vL  Commercial 
Discourses  (in  Works,  published  by  Collins,  Glas- 
gow, twenty -five  volumes,  1836-42).  — (3)  Vol. 
xiv.  to  xvL  On  the  Christian  and  Economic  Polity 
of  a  Nation,  more  especially  vdth  reference  to  its 
Large  Tovms  (an  expansion  of  "  The  Christian  and 
Civic  Economy  of  ou/r  Large  Toums,"  1821). — (4) 
xvii.  Church  and  College  Establishments  (a  defence 
of  endowments  against  Adam  Smith  and  Turgot). 
— (5)  xix.,  XX.  On  Political  Economy  in  Connec- 
tion with  the  Moral  State  and  Moral  Prospects  of 
Society. — (6)  xxi.  On  the  Sufficiency  of  the  Par- 
ochial System. — (7)  Ih.  On  the  Application  of 
Statistics  to  Moral  and  Economical  Questions. — 
(8)  Sundry  economical  articles  in  North  British 
Review  (*'Corn  Laws,"  "Political  Economy  of  the 
Bible,"  "Poor  Laws  of  Scotland,"  "Savings 
Banks,"  "  Stirling's  Philosophy  of  Trade,"  "  Poli- 
tical Economy  of  a  Famine").  For  criticism, 
see  M'CuUoch's  Literature  of  Political  Economy 
(1845),  and  his  article  on  "  Chalmers's  Pol.  Econ." 
in  Edinburgh  Review,  October  1832.  j.b. 

CHAMBERLAYNE,  Edward,  LL.D.  (1616- 
1703).  His  reputation  rests  on  his  statistical 
and  descriptive  work,  Anglice  Notitia,  which 
went  through  no  fewer  than  twenty  revised 
editions  under  his  name,  and  was  then  (1704) 
continued  by  his  son  John  Chamberlayne,  the 
last  edition  being  issued  in  1755.  It  consists 
of  three  parts,  the  first  relating  to  history  and 
general  conditions,  the  second  to  government, 
and  the  last  to  manners  and  customs.  Cham- 
berlayne's  work  was  the  Whitaker's  Almanack 
of  the  period.  Its  information  is  varied  and 
detailed,  but  only  in  certain  cases  are  the 
statistics  given  available  for  use  at  the  present 
time.  Such  statistics  are  more  frequent  in  the 
later  issues  of  the  work,  where  reference  is 
frequently  made  to  the  estimates  of  Petty, 
Davenant,  and  King,  though  even  in  the  early 
editions  the  description  of  the  trades  and  the 
economic  condition  of  the  people  occupies  a 
prominent  place. 

The  Rise  and  Fall  of  the  Late  Favourite  of 
Spain,  the  Count  Olivares,  1632. — The  Present 
Warre  Paralleled:  or  a  Brief  Relation  of  the 
Five  Years'  Civil  Warres  of  Henry  the  Third, 
1647. — England's  wants,  or  General  Propositions 
probably  Beneficial  for  England,  humbly  offered  to 


CHAMBERLEN— CHAMBERS  OF  AGRICULTURE 


257 


the  Consideration  of  all  good  Patriots,  etc.,  1667. 
— Anglice  Notitia,  or  the  Present  Slate  of  England, 
1669,  also  other  works,  educational  and  religious. 

E.  c.  K.  o. 

CHAMBERLEN,  Hugh.  Hugh  Chamber- 
lain, Chamberlin,  or  Chamberlen  (born  1664, 
died  1728),  son  of  a  court  physician  of  the  same 
name,  was  educated  at  Trinity  College,  Cam- 
bridge. He  devoted  himself,  like  his  father, 
to  obstetrics,  and  is  said  to  have  practised  in 
France  and  Holland  before  finally  building  up 
a  professional  reputation  in  his  own  country. 
But  as  early  as  1693  he  took  the  field  as  a 
financial  projector.  In  that  year,  after  vainly 
approaching  the  Scottish  parliament  on  the 
subject,  he  induced  the  English  House  of 
Commons  (Dec.  1693)  to  submit  his  plan  for  a 
land  bank  to  a  committee,  which  reported  in 
its  favour.  No  effect,  however,  was  given  to  its 
recommendations  till  1696  (10th  Feb.)  when 
Foley  and  Harley  procured  an  act  in  favour  of 
the  land  bank.  William  was  in  need  of 
money  for  his  continental  war  ;  and  the  re- 
form of  the  currency  had  brought  the  Bank  of 
England  into  difficulties  of  which  the  gold- 
smiths and  the  country  gentlemen  were  in- 
clined to  take  full  advantage.  The  Bank  of 
England  at  its  foundation  in  1694  had  lent  to 
government  £1,200,000  at  8  per  cent ;  Cham- 
berlain offered  to  find  more  than  2  millions 
at  7  per  cent,  the  security  to  be  a  special 
salt  tax,  and  the  subscribers  to  be  incorporated, 
in  recognised  rivalry  with  the  Bank  of  England, 
for  the  lending  of  money  on  land  securities,  at 
3  to  4  per  cent  interest,  and  with  paper 
issues  limited  for  each  year  to  the  total  amount 
of  the  loan  to  government.  The  scheme  was 
vigorously  pushed,  but  the  subscriptions  were 
not  completed  within  the  date  fixed  by  the  act 
of  foundation,  and  Chamberlain  seems  to  have 
lost  money  as  well  as  reputation.  He  retired 
to  Holland  in  1699  ;  and  after  two  fresh 
attempts,  still  unsuccessful,  to  recommend  his 
project  to  the  Scottish  parliament  (1700,  1705) 
he  seems  to  have  quietly  resumed  his  profes- 
sional work  in  England,  where  he  died  1728. 

Chamberlain's  land  bank  was  open  to  the 
general  criticism  that  applies  to  all  schemes  for 
the  issue  of  a  paper  currency  based  on  land 
securities  ; — the  securities  are  not  speedily  and 
certainly  convertible,  and  they  are  not  every- 
where negotiable.     But  it  had  special  defects 
of  its  own.     The  security  proposed  was  lament- 
.bly  inadequate.     Its  calculations  were  drawn 
i     up  on   its   projector's   curious   idea   that   the 
ji    value  of  an  estate  is  in  direct  proportion  to  the 
I    length  of  time  from  which  an  income  is  derived 
\    from  it.     Chamberlain  off'ered,  for  example,  to 
'     give  eighty  years'  purchase  for  a  rent  charge  of 
£100  for  100  years,   from   property  in  land. 
^The  market  value  of  the  fee  simple  in  those 
I^Hfeys  would  have  been  about  twenty  years'  pur- 
|^B|^e,  or  one-fourth  of  Chamberlain's  estimate. 

VK^        ^OL.  I. 


[Macaulay,  History  of  England,  ch.  xx.,  xxii. — 
Thor.  Rogers,  First  Nine  Years  of  the  Bank  of 
England  (Clar.  Press,  1887),  ch.  ii. — Anderson, 
Hist,  and  Chron.  Deduction  of  Commerce,  vol.  ii. 
year  1696. — Macleod  (H.  D.),  Dictionary  of 
Pol.  Econ.,  gives  a  useful  list  of  his  pamphlets 
(art.  "Chamberlain  ").]  J.  b. 

CHAMBERS  OF  AGRICULTURE  are,  in  the 
United  Kingdom,  voluntary  associations  for  col- 
lecting, maturing,  and  expressing  the  opinions  of 
persons  engaged  in  or  familiar  with  agricultural 
pursuits  on  public  questions  concerning  the 
weU-being  of  the  agricultural  interest.  All  the 
chambers  now  in  existence  have  been  formed 
wathin  the  last  quarter  of  a  century.  Their 
origin  may  be  traced  to  the  general  recognition, 
in  the  period  1862-1865,  of  the  want  of  any 
adequate  machinery  for  ascertaining  the  balance 
of  opinion  among  agriculturists,  and,  in  particu- 
lar, in  the  last  named  year,  to  the  absence  of 
official  acquaintance  with  agricultural  conditions, 
and  the  helplessness  and  isolation  of  the  farming 
classes  in  the  face  of  the  disastrous  invasion  of 
cattle  plague  at  that  date.  The  functions  of 
these  chambers  diff"er  from  those  of  the  older 
farmers'  clubs  and  agricultural  societies  by  in- 
cluding discussions  on  matters  of  a  distinctly 
political  or  economic  character.  By  means  of  the 
central  chamber  in  London  and  the  interven- 
tion of  a  representative  council,  opportunity  is 
given  to  concentrate  and  focus  the  separately 
expressed  views  of  agi-iculturists,  and,  where 
anything  like  unanimity  is  found  to  prevail,  for 
bringing  pressure  to  bear  on  the  legislature  in 
cases  of  necessity. 

The  first  formed  chamber  was  the  Scottish,  in 
1864.  In  organisation  it  differs  somewhat  from 
the  English  chambers  by  its  membership  being 
more  closely  restricted  to  actual  tenant-farmers 
or  owners  farming  their  own  land.  While  in 
corresponding  association  with  the  central 
chamber,  its  business  is  independently  con- 
ducted by  means  of  a  board  of  directors  in 
Edinburgh  aided  by  county  committees.  The 
English  central  chamber  was  projected  by 
Mr.  Charles  Clay  of  Wakefield  in  1865,  and, 
since  its  establishment  in  1866,  its  chairmen, 
chosen  as  a  rule  alternately  from  different 
political  parties,  have  been  among  the  most 
prominent  or  characteristic  leaders  of  agi-icul- 
tural  opinion  in  parliament.  The  membership 
of  the  central  chamber  embraces  leading  agri- 
culturists residing  in  all  parts  of  England,  and 
includes  many  peers  and  M.P.'s.  The  local 
chambers  for  the  most  part  are  formed  for  com- 
plete counties.  In  some  instances  branch 
chambers  reporting  to  the  county  chamber  are 
formed.  In  others  an  area  less  than  that  of  a 
county  is  chosen  as  the  district  of  the  chamber 
where  special  local  or  market  facilities  have 
established  an  individuality  of  agricultural 
character.  Recently,  in  an  increasing  number 
of  cases,  certain  farmers'  clubs  or  societies  have 


258        CHAMBERS  OF  AGRICULTURE— CHAMBERS  OF  COMMERCE 


become  chambers  by  adding  the  special  debating 
functions  of  a  chamber  to  their  primary  work, 
and  by  aifiliating  themselves  with  the  central 
organisation.  The  membership  of  all  the 
English  chambers  has  been  gradually  increasing, 
and  the  total  includes  landowners,  yeomen, 
and  tenant-farmers,  and  other  persons  engaged 
in  businesses  dependent  on  agriculture.  But  the 
strength  and  activity  of  the  several  local  bodies 
varies  very  greatly.  Some  are  small,  and  in 
others,  where  the  numbers  are  large,  much  of 
the  work  is  left  in  the  hands  of  standing 
committees  of  the  more  active  and  intelligent 
members,  owing  to  the  practical  difficulty  of 
obtaining  largely  attended  meetings  among  a 
community  so  scattered  as  the  farmers.  No 
chamber  possessing  less  than  fifty  members  is 
recognised  by  the  central  association,  and  the 
representatives  of  a  hundred  and  ten  active  and 
fully  accredited  chambers  now  meet  the  repre- 
sentatives of  the  central  chamber  periodically  in 
London  in  a  body  known  as  the  Council  of  the 
Central  and  Associated  Chambers  of  Agriculture. 
Its  deliberations  are  generally  accepted  as 
affording  a  fair  index  of  the  drift  of  agricultural 
opinion ; — and  an  enumeration  of  at  least  some  of 
the  more  prominent  subjects  dealt  with  by  this 
Council  in  recent  years,  will  afford  the  readiest 
means  of  appreciating  the  class  of  business — 
political,  social,  and  economic — coming  under 
discussion  by  the  chambers  of  agriculture. 

Partly  from  the  circumstances  above  referred 
to  in  connection  with  the  origin  of  the  cham- 
bers, and  partly  from  the  events  of  recent  years, 
no  subject  has  had  a  greater  prominence  than 
that  of  the  repression  of  cattle  disease.  Ques- 
tions of  the  regulation,  of  the  home  trade  and 
traffic  in  animals,  the  restriction  or  stoppage  of 
importation  from  countries  infected  with  con- 
tagious diseases,  and  the  treatment  of  outbreaks 
cf  cattle  plague,  pleuro-pneumonia,  and  foot-and- 
mouth  disease  have  been  under  frequent  con- 
sideration, and  much  of  the  existing  successful 
legislation  on  this  subject,  and  the  policy  adopted 
by  successive  governments,  as  well  as  the  altered 
position  of  public  opinion  generally,  has  been 
admittedly  due  to  the  initiative  and  pressure  of 
the  agricultural  chambers. 

The  incidence  and  distribution  of  taxation  in 
rural  districts  have  naturally  furnished  another 
important  series  of  questions  for  the  considera- 
tion of  the  chambers.  The  incidence  of  rating, 
the  special  burdens  falling  on  land,  the  relief  of 
localities  from  the  entire  cost  of  obligations 
imposed  for  national  objects,  the  improvement 
of  our  systems  of  poor-law  relief,  of  valuation 
and  assessment,  the  management  of  highways 
and  main  roads,  and  the  reform  of  local  govern- 
ment, have  all  been  largely  discussed,  and  effect 
given  in  various  instances  to  the  views  of  the 
chambers.  Questions  also  of  imperial  taxa- 
tion, the  adjustment  and  collection  of  the  income 
tax,  the  malt  tax,  and  the  beer  duties  have  led 


to  frequent  communication  between  the  cham- 
bers and  the  executive  government.  More 
recently,  and  under  the  pressure  of  agricultural 
distress,  it  has  been  observed  that  a  disposition 
exists  among  some  of  the  local  chambers,  especi- 
ally in  wheat-growing  districts,  to  raise  discus- 
sions on  the  propriety  of  reverting,  in  some  form, 
to  import  duties  on  competing  foreign  produce. 

The  methods  for  efiectively  compensating 
outgoing  tenants  for  the  unexhausted  value  of 
improvements  effected  on  their  farms  have  been 
the  subject  of  prolonged  inquiries  set  on  foot 
by  practical  and  experienced  committees  of  the 
chambers  of  agriculture,  and  to  these  efforts 
must  be  ascribed  a  large  share  in  securing  the 
Agricultural  Holdings  Acts. 

The  relations  of  the  various  railway  companies 
with  the  agricultural  producers  have  been 
frequently  debated,  and  legislation  has  been 
secured  forbidding  the  preferential  railway  rates 
allowed  to  foreign  produce.  The  chambers 
were  also  very  largely  occupied  in  such  questions 
as  the  prevention  of  food  adulteration,  the 
securing  of  purity  in  fertilizers  and  feeding  stuffs 
and  the  provision  of  agricultural  instruction. 

Among  the  earlier  debates  of  the  chambers, 
the  question  of  amending  the  game  laws  was 
prominent.  Legislation  accordingly  was  passed 
in  1880  and  1908.  Various  reforms  of  the 
existing  land  laws  have  furnished  topics  for 
debate,  especially  in  the  Scottish  chambers, 
while  a  consolidation  of  the  scattered  functions  of 
tlie  government  in  relation  to  agriculture  has 
always  been  a  favourite  recommendation, 
realised  in  the  Board  of  Agriculture  and 
Fisheries.  Apart  from  the  discussion  of 
questions  more  or  less  matters  of  controversy, 
the  machinery  of  the  chambers  has  been  used 
for  spreading  information  on  agricultural 
matters,  and  in  some  instances  for  the  diffusion 
of  agricultural  education  and  the  conduct  of 
practical  experiments.  p.  g.  c. 

CHAMBERS  OF  COMMERCE,  or  at  least 
bodies  similarly  named,  flourished  on  the  con- 
tinent and  in  the  United  States,  the  New  York 
Chamber  of  Commerce,  for  example,  being 
incorporated  under  a  Georgian  charter  before 
their  rise  is  noted  in  Great  Britain.  One  at 
Marseilles  is  reported  as  existing  in  the  14th 
century.  Chambers  in  several  of  the  chief 
cities  of  France  are  mentioned  early  in  the  18th 
century.  It  would  appear  that  these  bodies 
were  suppressed  in  France  in  1791,  but  restored 
by  official  decree  in  1851.  The  foreign  type  of 
chamber  has,  in  its  quasi-official  character,  al- 
ways differed  from  the  purely  voluntary  form  of 
association  for  promoting  trade  interests,  recog- 
nised as  a  chamber  in  the  United  Kingdom.  One 
of  the  earliest  chambers  here  is  that  of  Glasgow 
1773.  Edinburgh  possessed  a  chamber  in  1785, 
Manchester  in  1820,  and  Hull  in  1837.  Origin- 
ally chambers  were  formed  with  purely  local  ob- 
jects, as  the  promotion  or  protection  of  particular 


CHAMBERS  OF  COMMERCE 


259 


businesses.  A  federation  of  individual  chambers 
of  commerce  for  concerted  action  on  common  sub- 
jects of  general  interest  was,  however,  suggested 
at  a  meeting  of  the  Social  Science  Association  in 
1859  ;  in  the  following  year  what  is  now  known 
as  the  Association  of  Chambers  of  Commerce  of 
the  United  Kingdom  held  its  first  annual  gather- 
ing. The  chambers  of  Belfast,  Birmingham, 
Bradford,  Glasgow,  Gloucester,  Hull,  Kendal, 
Leeds,  Liverpool,  Norwich,  Sheffield,  Southamp- 
ton, Staffordshire  potteries,  Wolverhampton, 
and  Worcester,  took  part  in  this  movement, 
Coventry  and  Dundee  being  also  in  communi- 
cation with  the  central  body.  Some  of  the  larger 
provincial  chambers  did  not  at  first  join  the 
central  body.  Glasgow  at  the  present  time  is 
the  only  one  of  the  larger  members  which  keeps 
aloof.  But  the  forma  Lion  of  local  chambers  and 
their  affiliation  with  the  central  association  has 
proceeded  rapidly  ;  twenty-seven  bodies  being 
thus  connected  in  1865,  forty-six  in  1873,  and 
117  at  the  present  time  (1910). 

The  London  chamber  of  commerce,  although 
one  of  the  most  recently  formed,  and  dating 
only  from  1881,  is  the  largest  existing  chamber, 
with  (1902)  a  membership  of  over  4000, 
individuals  and  firms,  and  an  annual  income  of 
£8000.  It  is  an  entirely  voluntary  organisa- 
tion independent  both  of  the  Government  and 
of  the  municipality  of  London.  Its  sphere  of 
activity  extends  practically  over  the  commercial 
world.  Its  work  is  to  facilitate  business  in  the 
broadest  sense, — incidentally  this  tends  to 
prevent  strikes  and  lock-outs  in  tlie  port  of 
London, — to  supply  information  as  to  com- 
mercial treaties,  and  to  improve  commercial 
education.  The  size  and  relative  importance 
of  the  provincial  chambers  of  commerce  varies 
very  greatly.  In  the  case  of  the  larger  bodies 
such  as  Manchester,  Glasgow,  and  Liverpool, 
the  work  of  each  chamber  embraces  diffeient 
interests  and  is  divided  into  three  or  four  trade 
sections  ;  the  smaller  chambers  usually  exist  in 
towns  where  there  are  but  one  or  two  prominent 
trades  of  which  a  single  general  committee  can 
be  made  fairly  representative. 

In  the  case  of  the  London  chamber  a  more 
general  sphere  of  duties  is  necessarily  entered 

j  on  than  is  attempted  elsewhere.  Besides  possess- 
ing direct  relations  with  thirty-two  separate 
affiliated  associations,  among  which  very  im- 
portant special  bodies  like  the  institute  of 
bankers,  the  London  corn  trade,  London  timber 
trade,  shipowners'  societies,  etc. ,  are  represented, 
there  are  here  over  forty  organised  ' '  trade 
sections."  Separate  provision  is  thus  made  for 
the  East  Indian,  the  Canadian,  the  Australian, 
and  the  African  trades,  the  metal,  textile,  pro- 
vision, and  many  other  groups  of  businesses.  To 
an  extent  unknown  among  the  older  chambers, 
the  London  chamber  endeavours  to  collect  and 

I  disseminate  statistical  and  other  information, 
and  to  promote,  by  the  holding  of  public  con- 


ferences and  lectures  by  distinguished  explorers 
and  others,  a  knowledge  of  new  openings  for 
foreign  trade.  The  services  of  the  commercial 
chambei's  have  been  made  practically  useful  in 
cases  of  mercantile  arbitrations.  Their  advice  i» 
frequently  sought  on  specific  points  by  the 
government,  and  at  their  suggestion  much 
additional  information  is  obtained  from  consular 
representatives  abroad  and  circulated  widely. 

It  may  be  interesting,  however,  in  further 
illustration  of  the  range  of  business,  to  quote  a 
few  of  the  earliest  and  of  the  most  recent  topics 
of  debate  in  the  biennial  meetings  which  take 
place  of  the  delegates  of  these  chambers  in  the 
central  association.  But  when  it  is  remembered 
that  as  many  as  sixty  different  topics  have  been 
occasionally  disposed  of,  besides  purely  formal 
business,  at  a  single  three  days'  meeting  of  the 
central  association,  it  will  be  seen  that  no 
enumeration  of  the  functions  of  these  bodies 
can  pretend  to  be  exhaustive.  Among  the  sub- 
jects prominently  recurring  in  the  earlier  years 
of  the  association's  existence,  and  still  in  some 
form  under  discussion  in  1886,  1887,  and  1888, 
may  be  named  the  improvement  of  the  laws  of 
bankruptcy  and  of  partnership,  of  legal  and 
county  court  facilities,  of  the  extension  of 
postal  and  telegi-aphic  facilities,  and  the  bearing 
of  foreign  tariffs  and  consular  arrangements  on 
British  trade,  as  well  as  a  numerous  gi-oup  of 
questions  of  internal  taxation,  shippingdues,  local 
tolls,  and  assessments.  Discussion  on  patent- 
law  reforms,  on  uniformity  of  weights  and 
measures,  and  on  tribunals  of  commerce  were 
perhaps  more  notable  in  the  earlier  years,  while 
debates  and  suggestions  on  the  regulation  of 
railway  charges,  on  the  constitution  of  a  ministry 
of  commerce,  or  on  improvements  in  parlia- 
mentary and  private  bill  procedure,  come  more 
frequently  under  notice  in  the  later  years.  In 
the  past  quarter  of  a  century,  during  which  the 
machinery  of  these  chambers  has  been  more 
especially  developed,  their  activities  have  taken 
a  Avide  range,  which  is  summarised  in  "  The 
London  Chamber  of  Commerce  and  its  Work  " 
by  Mr.  C.  E.  Town. 

To  illustrate  the  class  of  subjects  with  which 
chambers  of  commerce  actually  deal,  we  may 
remark  that  a  list  of  the  business  transacted  under 
the  auspices  of  the  London  chamber  alone,  in  the 
past  twenty-eight  years,  embraces  the  following 
numerous  and  varied  items  : — The  Anglo-French 
Treaty  negotiations,  affairs  in  Burmah,  Postal  and 
Telegraphic  Rates,  Coffee  Adulteration,  Bills  of 
Lading  Reform,  Bankruptcy  Law  Reform,  the  Suez 
Canal,  the  Anglo-Spanish  Treaty  negotiations,  the 
Coal  and  Wine  Dues,  Arbitration  and  Codification 
of  the  Laws  relating  thereto.  Dock  Charges,  the 
Congo  Treaty,  Thames  Communication,  Railway 
Communication  and  Extensions  in  India  and 
the  Colonies,  Home  Railway  Rates  and  Fares, 
Indo-Chinese  Railways  as  projected  by  Messrs. 
Colquhoun  &  Hallett,  the  development  of  South 
Africa,  the  London  Corn  Dues,  Commercial  Treaties 


260 


CHAMBRE  ARDENTE— CHAMPION  AND  SEVERALTY 


with  Foreign  Countries,  Sixpenny  Telegrams,  Co- 
lonial and  Imperial  Federation,  Emigration,  the 
Merchant  Shipping  Bill  of  1884,  Trade  Marks,  the 
preparation  of  Average  Wages  Tables,  the  questions 
of  the  Eoyal  Commission  on  Depression  of  Trade  (to 
which  the  Chamber  replied),  organisation  of  seven 
Congresses  of  Chambers  of  Commerce  of  the»British 
Empire,  the  Colonial  and  Indian  Exhibition  of  1886 
(in  which  the  West  African  Court  was  initiated  by 
the  Chamber),  the  State  Guarantee  of  War  Risks, 
Code  Telegraphy,  Technical  and  Commercial 
Education,  Protection  from  Fire  in  London  and 
Fire  Insurance  Rates,  Codification  of  the  Factors' 
Acts,  Canadian  Preference  Claims,  Commercial 
Museums,  the  Imperial  Institute,  the  Silver 
Question,  the  Shop  Hours'  Regulation  Bill,  the 
Baku  Petroleum  Conference,  Decimal  Coinage, 
Post  Office  Investments,  Colonial  and  International 
Exhibitions,  Income  tax,  the  Japan  and  Franco- 
Chinese  Treaties,  the  Merchandise  Marks  Act,  1887, 
the  Submarine  Telegraph  Monopoly,  Railway  Rates, 
Port  of  London  Authority,  Labour  Conciliation  and 
Arbitration  Boards,  and  a  varied  range  of  topics  of 
an  industrial  or  commercial  character.      P.  G.  c. 

CHAMBRE  ARDENTE.  This  name,  though 
most  commonly  used  in  relation  to  occasional 
tribunals  erected  in  France  for  the  examination 
of  persons  accused  of  heresy  or  poisoning,  was 
applied  to  all  extraordinary  commissions,  estab- 
lished outside  of  the  ordinary  course  of  law,  for 
the  trial  of  alleged  criminals  of  whatever  kind. 
Thus  the  student  of  the  economic  history  of 
France  will  find  the  title  given  to  the  commis- 
sions appointed  in  the  reign  of  Louis  XHL,  and 
under  the  regency,  to  inquire  into  the  frauds  of 
the  farmers  of  the  public  revenues  and  to  enforce 
restitution  of  their  unlawful  gains.  Accordingly 
Littre,  in  his  French  Dictionary,  gives  as  the 
more  recent  meaning  of  the  term  "commission 
nomm^e  pour  connaitre  des  malversations  de 
deniers  publics,  etc." 

[See  also  Dictionnaire  de  la  Conversation  et  de 
la  Lecture,  tome  xiii.,  under  the  head  *'Chambre," 
and  H.  Martin's  Histoire  de  France,  Index,  s.v.] 

J.  K.  I. 

CHAMILLART,  Michel  de  (J.  1653,  d. 
1721).  After  filling  several  minor  positions 
Chamillart,  by  favour  of  Madame  de  Main- 
tenon,  was  set  in  1695  over  the  school  at  Saint 
Cyr, — then  a  recognised  stepping-stone  to  high 
office  in  the  state.  Appointed  controller- 
general  of  finance  in  1699,  and  minister  of  war 
in  1701,  he  combined  for  seven  years  the  rdles 
which,  taken  singly,  had  taxed  the  respective 
energies  of  Colbert  and  of  Louvois.  Without 
aptitude  for  either  office,  he  wore  himself  out 
to  little  purpose.  According  to  Montyon  (Par- 
ticularitis  sur  les  ministres  des  finances,  1812, 
p.  87),  the  last  argument  always  appeared  to 
Chamillart  the  most  convincing,  so  that  his 
studies  were  filled  with  unexecuted  draughts, 
referred  alternately  to  their  promoters  and  their 
critics.  The  popular  songs  of  the  day,  probably 
influenced  by  tho  necessity  of  rhyming  his  name, 
represent  him  as  the  king's  boon  companion  at 


billiards — "a  hero  at  billiards,  a  zero  in  the 
ministry,"  etc.  His  want  of  administrative 
ability  was  well  known  to  the  public,  and  he 
frequently  appealed  to  the  king  to  be  relieved 
from  burdens  which  he  felt  unable  to  support. 
But  the  Grand  Monarque,  who  had  said  L'Mat, 
cest  moi  !  had  encouraged  Chamillart  to  assume 
office  by  the  promise  "I  will  second  you,"  and 
still  flattered  himself  that  he  could  train  a 
minister  or  repair  his  deficiencies.  Chamillart 
was,  therefore,  retained  in  office  until,  in  1708, 
he  resigned  the  ministry  of  finance,  and  a 
year  later,  having  given  umbrage  to  Madame 
"de  Maintenon,  was  called  upon  to  quit  the 
ministry  of  war. 

Historians  are  agreed  as  to  the  personal 
probity  and  amiability  of  Chamillart,  no  less 
than  as  to  his  ineptitude.  His  term  of  office, 
however,  included  a  period  of  seven  years' 
disastrous  war,  during  which  desperate  expedi- 
ents were  almost  forced  upon  a  financier  of  less 
than  the  highest  ability.  The  measures  of 
Chamillart  are  examined  by  the  judicious 
Forbonnais  (Eecherches  et  considerations  sn/r  les 
finances  de  France,  1758,  ii.  104,  109-171),  who 
gives  him  credit  for  establishing  a  special 
council  of  commerce  to  deal  with  state  matters 
of  industry  and  trade.  It  was  by  Chamillart 
that  Boisguillebert  was  deprived  and  punished 
for  publishing  his  Factum  de  la  France,  1706. 

[For  some  graphic  touches  descriptive  of  Chamil- 
lart see  the  Memoires  of  his  friend  St.  Simon. — 
Vuitry,  Le  desordre  des  finances  d  la  fin  du  rigne 
de  Louis  XIV.,  1885,  pp.  138  seq.,  emphasises 
the  ruinous  nature  of  his  makeshift  finance.] 

H.H. 

CHAMPART.  The  right  of  the  feudal  lord 
in  many  parts  of  France  to  receive  a  fixed  share 
of  the  tenant's  produce.  It  was  collected  after 
the  ecclesiastical  tithe,  and  the  proportion 
varied  in  different  districts  according  to  custom 
or  agreement.  Sometimes  it  was  a  fourth  or  a 
fifth,  but  occasionally  it  was  as  little  as  a 
twentieth.  The  lord's  share  is  known  by  the 
various  names  of  champart,  airier,  and  terrage. 

R.  L. 

CHAMPION  AND  SEVERALTY.  The 
change  from  champion,  or  the  system  of  com- 
mon lands  and  common  cultivation,  to  severalty 
was  the  first  act  in  the  history  of  enclosures, 
the  second  act  in  which  took  place  in  the  reign 
of  George  III.  The  first  period,  during  which 
the  tendency  to  enclosure  was  denoted  by  the 
terms  used  above,  consisted  chiefly  of  the  reigns 
of  Henry  VII.,  Henry  VIIL,  and  Edward  VI., 
though  it  must  not  be  supposed  that  it  was^ 
rigidly  confined  within  these  boundaries.  Two 
movements  may  be  detected  on  a  close  examina- 
tion. The  first,  the  turning  of  arable  into  pas- 
ture land  ;  the  second,  the  "violent  in  closure  of 
commins  without  just  recompence  of  them  that 
have  right  to  commen  therein"  (Stafford's  Brief 
Conceipt,  N.S.S.,  p.  41).     But  both  these  move- 


CHAMPION  AND  SEVERALTY— CHANGE 


261 


ments  were  denoted  by  the  term  enclosure,  and 
it  was  into  their  common  action  that  a  commis- 
sion of  inquiry  was  appointed  in  2  Edward  VI. 
By  enclosure,  said  John  Hales,  is  meant  "when 
any  man  hath  taken  away  and  enclosed  any  other 
man's  commons,  or  hath  pulled  down  houses  ol 
husbandry  and  converted  the  lands  from  tillage 
to  pasture  "  (Strype,  Ecd.  Mem.  ii.  pt.  ii.  p.  362, 
cf.  Brief  Conceipt,  ut  siipra).  The  nature  of 
the  change  is  not  hard  to  understand.  The 
effect  of  the  Black  Death  {q.v.)  had  been  to 
materially  accelerate  the  dissolution  of  old 
habits  of  cultivation  and  the  introduction  of  a 
system  of  pecuniary  payment  in  place  of  the 
interchange  of  dues  and  privileges.  Leases  had 
been  granted,  and  the  semi-feudal  ties  connect- 
ing landowners  and  labourers  were  snapped. 
There  was  another  change  in  progi-ess  of  im- 
portance equal  to  this.  Though  towns  and 
hamlets  dependent  on  husbandry  were  decaying 
(Strype,  ut  supra,  p.  352  ;  Stubbes,  Anatomic 
of  Abuses,  p.  116),  the  more  mercantile  com- 
munities were  rising  in  wealth.  The  era  of 
trade  and  manufacture  was  opening.  "We  begin 
to  catch  glimpses  even  of  the  system  of  concen- 
trated industries  (or  those  organised  in  large 
establishments).  The  effect  of  this  system  was, 
however,  felt  forcibly  only  towards  the  close  of 
the  Tudor  period.  During  the  earlier  reigns, 
though  trade  was  developing,  its  progress  was 
not  evident  enough  to  be  recognised  as  mitigat- 
ing the  suffering  consequent  on  so  gi'eat  a 
change  as  that  described.  Other  causes  served 
to  heighten  the  discontent,  while  ifc  intensified 
the  real  suffering.  There  was  continual  de- 
basement of  the  coinage.  Prices  were  chang- 
ing, and  all  prices,  e.g.  the  prices  of  labour  and 
commodities,  did  not  change  at  the  same  time, 
or  in  the  same  rate  {v.  The  Brief  Conceipt). 
Again,  the  dissolution  of  the  monasteries  left 
the  poor  without  their  most  common  source  of 
relief.  Thus  it  came  about  that  the  change 
from  champion  into  severalty,  while  necessarily 
a  source  of  distress,  was  but  one,  though  by 
far  the  gi-eatest,  of  several  changes  leading  to 
social  disorganisation.  Such  is  the  position  to 
be  assigned  to  it  as  an  influential  event  of  the 
16th  century. 

Viewed  in  its  relation  to  the  after  history  of 
England,  in  connection  with  the  later  repetition 
of  the  policy  of  enclosure,  its  results  are  im- 
portant indeed.  They  may  be  summarised  as 
follows  : — (1)  Large  ownerships  in  land  encour- 
aged, small  ones  discouraged  ;  (2)  the  yeoman 
class  deprived  of  its  importance  ;  (3)  consequent 
tendency  on  the  part  of  those  with  small  for- 
tunes to  occupy  themselves  in  trade  rather  than 
in  agriculture. 

[Harrison,  Description  of  Englaiid. — Stafford, 
Brief  Conceipt  of  English  Policy.  —  Starkey, 
England  in  the  reign  of  Henry  the  Eighth. — Lati- 
mer's Sermons. — Tusser,  Five  hundred  points  of 
Uusbandrjj.  —  Stubbes,    Anatomie  of  Abuses. — 


Strype,  Ecclesiastical  Memorials. — Nasse,  Uebe'T 
die  Feldgemeinschaft  in  England.  —  Report  oj 
Select  Committee  of  the  House  of  Commons,  1844, 
vol.  V. — For  a  description  of  tLe  system  of  com- 
mon cultivation  v.  Seebohm,  English  Village 
Community.']  e.  c.  k.  q. 

CHANGE.  Abbreviation  for  Exchange 
{q.v.) — (1)  The  meeting  of  bankers  and  mer- 
chants for  the  transaction  of  business  ;  (2)  the 
place  where  they  meet.  In  London  there  are 
separate  exchanges  for  the  various  classes  of 
business.  The  Royal  Exchange  is  used  alter- 
nately for  transactions  in  foreign  bills  and  for 
business  in  drugs  and  chemicals,  and  there  are, 
besides  the  stock  exchange,  the  corn  exchange, 
the  metal  exchange,  the  hop  exchange,  the  wool 
exchange,  the  coal  exchange,  etc.  The  "Com- 
mercial Sale  Rooms  "  in  Mincing  Lane  and  the 
"  Baltic,"  though  not  called  exchanges,  are  used 
for  similar  purposes. 

This  word  is  also  used  for  small  coins,  etc., 
given  in  exchange  for  one,  or  perhaps  more, 
coins  or  notes,  and  in  the  aggi-egate  of  similar 
value :  the  balance  returned  in  cash  Avhen  goods 
of  one  value  are  purchased  with  money  of  a 
greater  value.  One  of  the  advantages  of  the 
cheque  over  coins  or  notes  of  specific  amounts 
is  that  it  can  have  assigned  to  it  any  required 
amount,  and  that  changcis  rendered  unnecessary. 

E.  s. 

CHANGE  (Agents  de) — the  official  name 
of  the  licensed  brokers  who  possess  in  France 
the  exclusive  privilege  of  negotiating  the  pur- 
chase and  sale  of  public  secmities.  As  early 
as  the  16th  century  the  State  exercised  a  con- 
trol over  the  business  of  courtier  or  broker  for 
the  exchange  of  money  or  merchandise  by  re- 
quiring agents  to  obtain  letters  of  license.  The 
7iext  step  was  to  limit  the  number,  to  exact  pay- 
ment for  the  monopoly,  and  to  fix  the  rates  of 
brokerage.  At  one  time  the  exercise  of  the 
office  was  hereditary.  In  1720  the  two  branches 
of  the  profession  were  separated,  the  name  of 
courtier  being  reserved  for  brokers  in  merchan- 
dise, while  that  of  agent  de  change  was  created 
for  intermediaries  in  letters  of  exchange  and 
moneys.  A  gi-eat  number  of  decrees  and  ordi- 
nances regulating  the  privilege  were  issued 
down  to  the  Revolution,  when  the  business  of 
agent  de  change  was  made  free,  but  after  the 
re-establishment  of  order  the  monopoly  was 
revived,  and  the  privilege  was  afihmed  by  art. 
76  of  the  Code  de  Commerce  promulgated  in 
1807.  A  law  of  1816  fixed  the  number  of 
ageiits  de  change  in  Paris  at  sixty,  and  con- 
ferred on  them  the  right  to  nominate  their 
successors,  subject  to  the  approval  of  the  cor- 
porate body  and  the  Minister  of  the  Interior. 
As  their  number  has  since  remained  unchanged, 
thfi  value  of  the  office  has  increased  with  the 
iihmense  expansion  of  business.  The  first 
transfer  made  was  for  a  premium  of  £1200, 
but  the  purchase  price  has  since  risen  as  high 


262 


CHAPMAN— CHARITABLE  FOUNDATIONS 


as  £90,000,  although  it  varies  with  the  standing 
of  the  holder  of  the  office  transferred,  the 
amount  of  business  transacted  by  the  different 
agcTvts  de  change  being  very  unequal.  Sleeping 
partners  generally  supply  the  greater  part  of 
the  capital,  the  nominal  holder  contributing 
the  business  qualifications,  which  are  to  have 
been  employed  not  less  than  four  years  with  an 
agent  de  change,  a  banker,  or  a  public  notary. 
Besides  the  various  laws  relating  to  agents  de 
change,  which  were  codified  by  a  decree  of  7th 
October  1890,  in  eighty-four  articles,  the  dis- 
cipline of  the  body  is  exercised  by  an  elected 
council  called  the  Syndical  Chamber,  in  each 
town  possessing  a  bourse.  Members  are  for- 
bidden to  operate  on  their  own  account ;  they 
are  bound  to  secrecy  as  to  the  parties  for  whom 
they  are  acting,  unless  with  their  consent,  or  the 
nature  of  the  operation  justifies  a  departure  from 
the  rule  ;  they  cannot  refuse  to  execute  orders, 
nor  can  they  form  associations  with  each  other  in 
the  exercise  of  their  profession ;  they  are  liable  for 
the  regularity  of  the  securities  they  deliver  ;  and 
they  are  bound,  by  a  recent  decree,  to  give  receipts 
for  the  money  or  securities  they  receive.  Al- 
though not  legally  obliged,  agents  de  change, 
in  Paris  at  least,  guarantee  in  common  the 
liabilities  of  their  members  in  their  professional 
engagements,  and  possess  a  fund  for  the  purpose. 
They  meet  at  the  close  of  each  market  and  draw 
up  the  official  price  current  for  the  day.  The 
syndical  chamber  decides,  subject  to  the  approval 
of  the  Minister  of  Finance,  on  the  admission  of 
new  secm-ities  to  official  quotation.  The  num- 
ber of  agents  de  change  in  Paris,  not  having 
been  increased  since  1816,  is  quite  insufficient 
for  the  present  volume  of  business,  and  they 
have  abandoned  dealings  in  coin  and  bullion 
and  bills  of  exchange,  which  they  formerly 
transacted  and  which  properly  belong  to  them. 
The  same  cause  has  led  to  the  rise  of  an  outside 
market,  unauthorised  but  tolerated,  called  the 
Coulisse  {q.v.)  t.  l. 

CHAPMAN.  A  person  engaged  in  trade  or 
commerce  ;  a  merchant.  Up  to  the  Tudor 
period  it  is  impossible  to  discover  any 
distinction  in  the  use  of  the  two  words  chap- 
man and  merchant.  Chaucer,  e.g.  in  the  "  Man 
of  Lawe's  Tale,"  and  in  the  "  Shipman's  Tale," 
uses  the  two  words  indifierently.  The  returns 
for  the  poll-tax  of  1379  in  the  West  Riding  of 
Yorkshire  show  that  the  chapman  is  on  the 
whole  a  less  important  and  wealthy  person  than 
the  man  described  as  a  merchant  or  mercator, 
but  there  is  nothing  in  the  documents  to  show 
that  the  "  marchand  de  bees,"  or  cattle  dealer 
of  Pontefract,  who  pays  a  tax  of  2s.  is  in  any 
superior  or  diff"erent  position  to  his  fellow 
townsman  who  calls  himself  a  *'  chapman  de 
bees  "  and  also  pays  2s.  It  is  not  until  the 
great  expansion  of  commerce  in  the  15  th  and 
16  th  centuries  that  the  word  chapman  is 
definitely  restricted  to  the  small  pedlar  or  retail 


dealer.  The  transition  is  markedly  seen  in 
the  act  5  &  6  Edward  YI.  c.  21,  in  which  one  of 
the  terms  used  for  pedlar  is  "  petty  chapman." 
By  the  l7th  century  the  distinction  between 
the  chapman  or  small  trader  or  pedlar  and  the 
merchant  was  firmly  established.  In  modern 
times  chapman  is  only  used  as  an  antiquarian 
or  romantic  synonym  for  merchant,  or  in  certain 
districts  as  the  local  name  for  pedlar. 

Besides  this  signification  of  seller  or  merchant, 
the  word  was  frequently  used  in  the  converse 
sense  of  purchaser,  a  usage  still  to  be  found  in 
some  dialects. 

{Poll-Tax  Returns,  West  Riding  Yorkshire. 
Archaeological  and  Topographical  AssociatioUj 
1882.— Chaucer  (c.  1340-1400),  Canterbury  Tales. 
— Dr.  Murray's  Neiv  English  Dictionary,  1890.] 

c.  G.  c. 

CHARGING  ORDER.  Where  a  judgment 
has  been  entered  up  in  any  of  the  superior 
courts  against  a  person  interested  in  any 
government  stock,  funds,  annuities,  or  stock  or 
shares  in  any  public  company,  a  "charging 
order  "  may  be  obtained  from  the  court  by  the 
judgment  creditor  to  the  eSect  that  such  stock, 
funds,  etc.,  shall  be  charged  with  the  payment 
of  the  amount  for  which  judgment  was  recovered. 
The  effect  of  a  charging  order  is  to  entitle  the 
judgment  creditor  to  all  such  remedies  as  he 
would  have  been  entitled  to  if  such  charge  had 
been  made  in  his  favour  by  the  judgment 
debtor. 

[Daniel's  Chancery  Practice,  6th  ed.  London, 
1882. — Wilson's  Judicature  Acts.l        J.  e.  c.  m. 

CHARITABLE  FOUNDATIONS.  These 
may  be  defined  as  "gifts  to  a  general  public 
use,  which  extend  to  the  poor  as  well  as  to  the 
rich  "  (Lord  Camden).  A  charity  is  said  to  be 
constituted  by  "any  legitimate  dedication  of 
property  upon  a  trust,  whether  express  or 
implied,  capable  of  permanent  duration  for  the 
benefit,  whether  they  be  rich  or  poor,  of  the 
public,-  or  a  class  of  the  public  as  distinct  from 
individuals"  (29th  Report  of  Charity  Com- 
missioners, 1882).  To  such  foundations  the 
state  has  always  stood  in  a  peculiar  position. 
It  has,  in  England,  maintained  that  they 
required  especial  care,  partly  because,  like 
infants  and  lunatics,  they  are  inopes  consilii, 
partly  because,  owing  to  their  permanence, 
they  are  liable  to  every  kind  of  vicissitude, 
and  partly  because  those  who  administer  them 
have  not  that  inducement  to  good  management 
which  self-interest  gives  in  private  business. 
This  attitude  on  the  part  of  the  state  implies 
two  things,  first,  the  duty  of  protecting,  secondly, 
the  right  of  controlling.  Both  of  these  are 
necessary  that  the  foundation  may  be  adminis- 
tered and  applied  to  promote  the  charitable 
intent  of  the  founder,  or  as  near  as  may  be  ; 
which  last  proviso  has  given  rise  to  the  doctrine 
of  cy-prhs  which  is  set  forth  in  the  celebrated 
Campden  case  (Law  Report,  18  Ch.  Div.  310), 


CHARITABLE  FOUNDATIONS 


26? 


The  Court  of  Appeal  here  laid  it  down  that  it 
is  the  duty  of  the  state  to  review  the  means 
which  the  founder  of  a  charity  has  prescribed 
for  carrying  out  the  general  intention  of  his 
foundation,  whenever  those  means,  by  reason  of 
changes  which  may  take  place  either  in  the 
value  of  the  endowment,  in  the  circumstances  of 
the  locality  or  the  population  for  the  benefit  of 
which  the  charity  is  administered,  in  the  times, 
in  the  habits  of  society,  or  in  the  ideas  and 
practices  of  men,  have  become  unfitted  to  secure 
the  end  which  the  founder  had  in  view.  This 
position  is  illustrated  by — (1)  trusts  for  appren- 
ticeship, where  the  end  is  to  give  the  objects  of 
the  charity  such  an  education  as  will  enable 
them  to  gain  their  livelihood  in  an  honest  and 
respectable  manner ;  and  (2)  doles,  a  "  practice," 
says  Sir  G.  Jessel,  "which  should  be  more 
honoured  in  the  breach  than  in  the  observance," 
which  may  be  turned  into  permanent  pensions 
or  used  for  any  method  of  promoting  thrift. 
These  objects  were  originally  carried  out  by  the 
courts  of  equity,  a  method  of  procedure  which 
proved  to  be  ii-regular,  costly,  dilatory,  and  to 
give  great  openings  for  fraud.  The  state  of 
things  became  so  little  satisfactory  that  in 
1818  a  commission  was  appointed,  commonly 
known  as  Lord  Brougham's  Commission,  to 
inquire  into  the  state  of  the  charities  of  Eng- 
land, and  sat,  wdth  various  changes,  until  1837. 
In  1835  and  1849  committees  of  the  House  of 
Commons  were  appointed  to  deal  with  the  results 
of  its  labours.  Ultimately,  in  1 853,  a  permanent 
charity  commission  was  appointed  with  a  two- 
fold aim  :  viz.  (1)  to  supplement  the  means 
provided  by  founders,  where  those  means  were 
inadequate,  to  give  full  effect  to  the  purpose  of 
the  foundations  ;  (2)  to  protect  the  property  of 
charities  against  waste  and  loss,  and  so  preserve 
it  for  the  purpose  to  which  it  had  been  dedicated 
by  the  founders.  These  objects  the  commis- 
sioners have  continued  to  discharge  down  to  the 
present  time.  In  the  year  1870  the  work  of 
the  endowed  schools  commissioners  was  trans- 
ferred to  the  charity  commissioners,  and  in  1883 
under  a  special  act  of  parliament  (46  &  47 
Yict.  c.  36)  a  department  was  formed  to 
supervise  the  administration  of  the  city  paro- 
chial charities.  It  was  hardly  to  be  expected 
that  the  powers  of  the  commissioners  could  be 
exercised  without  a  considerable  amount  of 
friction  and  of  adverse  public  criticism.  The 
friction  has  arisen  between  the  central  board 
and  the  trustees  and  other  local  administrators 
of  "charitable  funds,  but  the  line  between  the 
spheres  of  the  two  bodies  is  clearly  marked.  It 
is  for  the  local  body  to  administer  the  charity, 
i.e.  its  annual  income,  the  duty  of  the  commis- 
sioners is  to  secure  its  permanence  ;  they  and 
they  only  are  the  judges  of  all  applications  of  its 
capital,  and  of  the  prescribed  mode  of  giving 
effect  to  the  objects  of  the  charity.  It  is 
enough  to  say  of  the  criticism  that  it  is  not 


uncommonly  the  result  of  ignorance,  prejudice 
and  disappointed  self-interest,  or  of  a  strong 
local  feeling  which  has  for  a  time  obscured 
the  judgment.  The  total  number  of  charities 
registered  by  the  commissioners  was  on  31st 
December  1889,  31,350,  and  the  funds  invested 
in  their  name  amounted  to  £14,497,836  in 
15,511  accounts. 

It  is  quite  clear  that  whatever  be  their  origin 
or  their  aim,  charitable  foundations  will  have 
considerable  economical  effects.  (1)  They  will 
determine  for  long  periods  of  time  the  employ- 
ment of  considerable  amounts  of  property.  In 
the  case  of  real  estate  the  accumulation  in  the 
hands  of  charitable  trustees  has  been  limited  by 
the  mortmain  acts  and  by  the  statute  9  Geo. 
II.  c.  36,  but  with  regard  to  personal  property 
there  is  no  such  limit.  (2)  The  effect  of  founda- 
tions on  the  habits  and  character  of  a  population 
may  be  very  great,  as  will  be  best  seen  by  some 
practical  instances.  In  1793  George  Jarvis 
left  a  large  property,  £100,000  in  all,  for  the 
benefit  of  the  poor  of  three  parishes  in  Hereford- 
shire, the  united  population  of  which  did  not 
exceed  900.  The  consequences  are  thus  sketched 
by  Mr.  Hare  of  the  Charity  Commission. 
"The  pauper  population  increased  in  ten  years 
upwards  of  20  per  cent ;  in  twenty  years  almost 
40  per  cent ;  and  in  thirty  years  60  per  cent. 
The  cottages  became  more  and  more  crowded, 
houses  not  more  than  sufficient  for  one  family 
were  divided  into  two  or  more,  other  dwellings 
were  built,  some  on  waste,  others  on  remote 
spots,  with  regard  to  little  else  than  mere 
shelter.  The  inhabitants  of  the  country  round 
the  parishes,  who  remember  their  state  some 
years  ago,  are  uniform  in  their  testimony  of  the 
demoralisation  of  which  the  poor  were  by  this 
means  made  the  victims  :  their  mode  of  existence 
resembled  that  alternation  of  want  and  reple- 
tion which  is  characteristic  of  the  savage  state. 
Idleness,  discontent,  and  improvidence  were 
found  to  be  the  fruits  of  this  ill-conceived  and 
ill-judged  gift,  to  which  must  be  added  an  im- 
morality of  life  the  results  of  which  are  yet 
distinctly  felt."  Of  the  endowed  charities  of 
Bristol  it  is  said  by  the  Education  Commission 
of  1861,  "these  charities,  by  their  operation, 
are  teaching  indolence,  mendicancy,  servility, 
and  falsehood  to  the  poor  of  Bristol."  The 
judgment  of  the  poor  law  commissioners  of 
1 834  is  thus  stated.  ' *  In  some  cases,  charitable 
foundations  have  a  quality  of  evil  peculiar  to 
themselves.  The  majority  of  them  are  dis- 
tributed among  the  poor  inhabitants  of  particular 
parishes  and  towns.  The  places  intended  to  be 
favoured  by  large  charities  attract  therefore  an 
undue  proportion  of  the  poorer  classes,  who,  in 
the  hope  of  trifling  benefits  to  be  obtained 
without  labour,  often  linger  on  in  spots  most 
unfavourable  to  the  exercise  of  their  industry. 
Poverty  is  thus  not  only  collected  but  created 
in  the  very  neighbourhood  where  the  benevolent 


264 


CHARITABLE  INSTITUTIONS 


founders  have  manifestly  expected  to  make  it 
disappear."  These  reports,  and  others  of  the 
same  nature,  suggest  the  question  : — How  far  it 
is  for  the  good  of  a  country  that  the  characters 
of  thousands  should  be  at  the  mercy  of  one  man's 
folly  ?  By  some  the  answer  is  made,  that  all 
endowments  for  specific  purposes  are  ba'd,  and 
that  if  foundations  be  recognised  at  all,  they 
should  be  determined  in  their  object  and  method 
wholly  by  the  state.  By  others,  again,  a  large 
increase  of  the  power  of  interference  on  the 
part  of  a  public  body,  a  large  discretion  as  to 
purpose,  and  a  constant  living  control  are 
urged.  How  far  this  last  can  be  attained  is  at 
present  very  doubtful.  In  1869,  Mr.  Mill 
wrote,  "  We  have  well-nigh  seen  the  last  of  the 
superstition  which  allowed  a  man  who  owned  a 
piece  of  land  or  sum  of  money  500  years  ago, 
to  make  a  binding  disposition,  determining 
what  should  be  done  with  it  as  long  as  time  or 
the  British  nation  should  last,"  but  the  antici- 
pation must  still  be  reckoned  sanguine.  (3) 
Special  effects  will  be  produced  by  foundations 
having  an  educational  purpose.  Adam  Smith 
in  a  well-known  passage  has  pointed  out  that 
endowments  to  assist  those  preparing  for  the 
clerical  calling  had  attracted  large  numbers 
into  it,  and  so  damaged  the  position  and  pros 
pects  of  all  {Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  i.  ch.  10). 
Other  writers  have  urged  that  teachers  require 
the  stimulus  of  competition,  that  students 
are  more  productive  when  their  self-interest  is 
involved,  that  scholarships,  bursaries,  and  the 
like  tend  to  stereotype  lines  of  study  long  after 
they  have  ceased  to  be  profitable,  and  give 
them  a  great  advantage  in  competing  with  new 
and  perhaps  more  valuable  subjects.  But,  on  the 
other  hand,  it  is  maintained  that  by  endowments 
only  can  variety  be  ensured,  that  many  subjects 
could  not  possibly  be  studied  or  taught  as  a 
means  of  gaining  a  livelihood,  that  education  as 
a  whole  cannot  be  safely  left  to  the  action  of 
competition. 

[Lord  Brougham's  Commission,  1837. — H.  C. 
Committee,  1835.  — H.  C.  Committee,  1849.— 
Charity  Commission  1854  onwards  (especially 
1882). — Endowed  Schools  Commission,  1861. — 
Lord  Hobhouse,  The  Dead  ITawc?,  1880. — LordSher- 
brooke,  Endoioment  and  Free  Trade  (answered  in 
Macrrdllaris  Magazine),  April  1869. — J.  S.  Mill, 
"Endowments,"  Fortnightly  Review,  April  1869. 
— R.  E.  Mitcheson,  Charity  Comviission  Acts, 
1887. — Anon.,  On  the  Principles  of  Charitable 
Institutions,  1834.  See  also  Turgot's  article 
"  Fondation  "  in  the  French  Encydopedie.] 

CHARITABLE  INSTITUTIONS,  "charit- 
able institutions  may  be  classified  in  various 
ways.  If  distinguished  according  to  their  ob- 
jects, they  are  designed  to  give  (1)  permanent 
help  in  old  age,  in  almshouses  or  by  pension  ; 
(2)  permanent  help  to  the  incapacitated,  in 
asylums  for  lunatics,  imbeciles,  incurables  ;  (3) 
temporary  relief  in  homes  for  convalescents, 


orphans,  cripples,  inebriates,  hospitals  for  surgi- 
cal and  medical  cases,  nurseries  for  children  ; 
(4)  educational  advantages,  in  schools  for  the 
bKnd,  the  deaf,  and  dumb,  for  children  of  all 
classes  and  all  creeds  ;  (5)  miscellaneous  forma 
of  help,  aids  to  prisoners,  homes  to  penitents, 
shelter,  drugs,  etc.  The  general  supervision 
of  all  institutions  supported  by  endowments  is 
in  the  hands  of  the  charity  commissioners  (see 
Chaeitable  Foundations)  ;  the  administra- 
tion is  sometimes  carried  on  by  trustees,  some- 
times by  representatives  of  local  councils,  etc., 
sometimes  by  co-opting  boards,  sometimes,  in 
the  case  of  those  supported  by  subscriptions, 
by  representatives  of  the  subscribers. 

The  general  principle  may  be  laid  down  that 
a  charitable,  institution  will  be  useful  in  pro- 
portion as  it  is  an  aid  and  not  an  obstacle  to 
self-help.  But  provision  for  any  one  of  the 
above  mentioned  objects  on  a  large  scale  may 
check  the  spirit  of  provident  foresight  and  thrift. 
Asylums  for  the  aged  may  be  multiplied  to  such 
an  extent  as  to  discourage  provision  for  what  is 
an  inevitable  contingency  in  life.  Many  such 
institutions,  again,  run  the  risk  of  destroying 
family  life,  or  at  least  lessening  its  usefulness. 
Not  only  is  it  difficult  to  imagine  any  public 
institution^for  children  which  is  not  inferior  to 
their  home,  but  the  fact  is  often  forgotten  that 
the  aged  and  the  young,  even  the  cripple  and  the 
bedridden,  have  their  place  and  use  in  family 
life.  Parents  and  children  are  taught  to  under- 
value their  responsibilities  when  facilities  are 
given  for  escaping  them.  Reckless  living  and 
early  marriage  are  often  encouraged.  It  is 
found  almost  impossible  to  establish  a  provident 
dispensary  in  the  neighbourhood  of  a  great 
hospital  with  its  free  out-patient  system.  The 
existence  of  institutions  may  also  encourage 
imposture,  for  to  secure  their  benefits  is  the 
aim  of  the  artificial  pauper  who  lives  by  writing 
begging  letters.  Case  after  case  has  come  to 
light  in  recent  years  in  which  the  benefits  of. 
institutions  have  been  the  prey  of  such  impostors 
to  the  discouragement  of  every  honest  and  inde- 
pendent man.  Again,  vice  is  often  fostered  by 
such  institutions.  The  impression  is  easily  cre- 
ated in  men's  minds  that  a  certain  degree  of  bad- 
ness is  sure  to  excite  compassion,  and  so  the  care 
of  children  may  be  evaded  or  a  retreat  secured. 

These  evils  can  only  be  avoided  by  very  care- 
ful administration,  for  which  two  things  are 
needed. 

First. — Watchfulness  on  the  part  of  the 
managers.  Too  often  boards  and  trustees  are 
negligent  of  their  business,  leave  everything  to 
paid  officials,  and  scandals  ensue  in  the  manage- 
ment and  in  allotting  the  benefits.  In  many 
institutions  the  regulations  as  to  admission  are 
framed  with  a  view  to  exclusion  rather  than 
selection.  In  some  cases  admission  is  gained 
only  by  the  votes  of  subscribers — a  systenn 
which  ensures  success  to  those  who  have  influ 


CHARITY 


265 


ential  Mends,  and  wlio  are  therefore  in  many 
cases  the  least  in  need  of  help.  This  system 
is  defended  on  the  ground  that  subscribers  ex- 
pect a  quid  pro  quo,  but  the  experience  of 
institutions  which  have  abandoned  it  does  not 
justify  the  argument.  Again,  watchfulness  is 
needed  to  avoid  waste  in  salaries,  general  ex- 
penditure, and  advertising,  and  the  proportion 
of  income  devoted  to  working  expenses  often 
points  to  the  absence  of  such  care. 

Secondly. — Elasticity.  The  objects  of  an 
institution  may  disappear  under  changed  condi- 
tions. Almshouses,  e.g.,  which  were  once  the 
solution  of  the  problem  of  housing  the  poor, 
are  now  generally  condemned.  The  class  for 
whose  benefit  the  institution  was  intended  may 
have  ceased  to  exist.  Thus  in  many  cities  and 
boroughs  are  large  endowments  for  the  use  of 
freemen,  an  entirely  different  class  of  persons 
to-day  from  those  for  whom  they  were  originally 
intended.  In  all  such  cases  careful  reform  is 
needed  on  the  lines  of  attaining  a  kindred 
object  to  that  originally  proposed,  and  the 
wisest  founders  are  those  who  leave  a  complete 
discretion  to  posterity. 

In  general  terms  it  may  be  said  that  those 
institutions  are  the  best  which  provide  (1)  for 
the  result  of  temporary  disaster  —  first-rate 
medical  and  surgical  skill  must  always  be 
beyond  the  reach  of  the  poor,  and  no  amount 
of  foresight  on  their  part  can  guarantee  them 
such  professional  aid  ;  (2)  for  objects  which  are 
beyond  attainment,  owing  to  the  scale  on  which 
they  are  needed,  as  for  instance,  large  establish- 
ments for  technical  training,  libraries,  and 
museums  ;  (3)  for  deplorable  instances  of  break- 
down in  old  age,  due  to  no  fault  of  the  aged 
themselves.  But  even  in  these  cases  it  is 
difficult  to  oveiTate  the  importance  of  careful 
administration.  No  action  has  yet  followed  the 
Report  of  the  Royal  Commission  of  1909. 

[For  the  charitable  institutions  of  England,  see 
Reports  of  Charity  Commission. — ChaHties  Regis- 
ter and  Digest,  by  the  London  Charity  Organisa- 
tion Society  (1890). — Essays  on  the  Principles  of 
Charitable  Institutions,  anonymous,  1836. — Re- 
ports of  Charity  Boards,  etc.,  in  America  are 
published  by  the  various  States.  ]  l.  r.  p. 

CHARITY.  ''  In  the  minds  of  all  ordinary 
persons  charity  implies  the  relief  of  poverty. " 
Lord  Esher  in  Court  of  Appeal  Q.  B.  Law 
Reports,  22  Q.B.D.  296.  But  how  poverty 
may  be  relieved  is  a  question  beset  with  diffi- 
culties. First,  it  is  almost  impossible  to  avoid 
weakening  the  motive  to  exertion.  If  a  thrifty 
man  finds  his  thriftless  neighbour  placed  by 
charity  in  as  good  a  position  as  that  which  he 
has  won  for  himself  by  his  own  industry  and 
self-control,  a  great  discouragement  is  given 
to  thrift.  It  is  easy  to  multiply  instances  of 
this.  Towns  with  largely  endowed  charities 
are  almost  always  full  of  paupers,  and  a  con- 
nection may  be  traced  between  the  two  facts. 


The  vagrant  class  is  created  and  maintained  by 
thoughtless  charity  ;  the  out-patient  system  in 
hospitals  is  fatal  to  medical  clubs  ;  it  is  found 
almost  impossible  to  establish  a  provident  in 
the  neighbourhood  of  a  free  dispensary.  All 
experience  goes  to  show  that  men  wUl  not  make 
provision  for  themselves  if  they  know  that  they 
can  fall  back  on  others.  Charity  is  too  often 
morally  as  well  as  economically  harmful. 
Secondly,  it  is  difficult  to  avoid  weakening  the 
family  tie — parental  and  filial  responsibility. 
Thus  all  provision  made  by  charity  lor  the  aged 
will  discourage  children  from  doing  their  duty, 
the  applicants  for  almshouses  and  still  more  for 
pensions  are  always  in  excess  of  the  vacancies  ; 
foundling  hospitals  increase  the  number  of  il- 
legitimate births  and  of  desertions,  wliilst  theii* 
abolition  is  not  found,  as  was  feared,  to  increase 
child-murder  ;  facilities  given  to  parents  to  get 
rid  of  their  children,  on  whatever  ground — 
cruelty,  neglect,  bad  surroundings,  etc. — will 
ensure  an  increasing  number  of  such  cases. 
Thirdly,  charity,  by  lowering  wages,  often  inflicts 
a  serious  blow  on  the  independent  wage-earning 
class.  Persons  who  are  in  the  receipt  of  charity 
are  certain,  when  competing  for  work,  to  under- 
bid those  Avho  have  to  live  wholly  by  it ;  pro- 
vision by  charity  for  old  age  will  prevent  wages 
from  rising  to  a  point  which  allows  of  securing 
it  by  the  labourer's  own  efforts  ;  to  transfer 
employment  or  to  "make  work"  on  charitable 
grounds  is  to  tax  the  independent  labourer  for 
the  benefit  of  his  poorer  competitor  ;  the  pro- 
vision of  model-dwellings,  etc.,  by  charity  at 
less  than  cost  price  attracts  crowds  of  work- 
men competing  for  employment.  Lastly,  some 
miscellaneous  evils  may  be  added.  Charity 
often  leads  to  a  congestion  of  population  in  a 
favoured  district,  with  all  the  evil  conse- 
quences of  overcrowding.  In  country  villages 
the  fear  of  admitting  strangers  to  share  in  the 
charities  has  before  now  led  to  intermarriage  in 
a  small  circle,  with  disastrous  results.  Charit- 
able endowments  often  keep  alive  useless  and 
sometimes  injurious  occupations  with  a  view  to 
qualification  for  their  enjoyment, — those  which 
are  confined  by  a  religious  test  become  in  many 
cases  a  premium  upon  hypocrisy. 

The  first  duty  then  of  those  who  would  relieve 
poverty  without  increasing  it  is  that  of  inquiry 
into  its  causes.  Poverty  may  be  deserved — 
the  result  of  non-production  from  laziness,  or 
reckless  consumption,  self-indulgence,  thrift- 
lessness,  etc.  ; — or  undeserved,  being  either 
from  general  causes — the  result  of  commercial 
depression,  failure  of  crops,  hurricanes,  inunda- 
tions, etc.,  or  from  personal  misfortune — the 
result  of  bodily  or  mental  infirmity.  Prelimin- 
ary inquiry  on  these  points  will  prevent  many 
of  the  evils  of  thoughtless  charity.  It  clears 
-off  impostors  and  prevents  charity  from  being 
the  prey  of  the  idle  and  dissolute  ;  it  showa 
that  in  many  cases  charity  will  do  no  good, 


266 


CHARITY— CHAEITY  ORGANISATION 


but  rather  harm,  either  because  the  power  of 
recovery  is  wanting,  or  because  repeated  failures 
show  that  some  such  discipline  as  that  of  the 
workhouse  is  necessary  ;  in  other  cases  it  brings 
to  light  elements  of  hopefulness,  it  shows 
grounds  for  thinking  that  with  timely  aid  in- 
dependence may  be  regained.  But  inquiry  does 
more  than  this.  It  not  only  gives  a  thorough 
knowledge  of  the  circumstances  of  those  to  be 
relieved  (character,  history,  opportunities,  etc.), 
but  as  a  result  of  such  knowledge  it  gives  a  clue 
to  the  best  method  of  relieving.  It  is  to  the 
charitable  what  diagnosis  is  to  the  physician — 
it  shows  who  can  safely  be  helped  and  how  they 
can  be  most  helped. 

Nothing  is  more  difficult  than  to  formulate 
methods  of  charity,  i.e.  of  relieving  poverty. 
It  may  be  questioned  whether  experience  has 
as  yet  yielded  any  but  negative  results,  and  the 
constant  changes  in  the  conditions  of  life  forbid 
any  hope  of  finality — thus  though  the  housing 
of  the  aged  poor  has  been  a  problem  for  centuries, 
the  old  solution,  viz.  the  provision  of  almshouses, 
is  at  the  present  time  generally  condemned.  The 
following  general  principles  may  be  laid  down — 
(1)  that  aU  charity,  to  be  useful,  must  be  ade- 
quate, that  is  to  say  it  must  be  sufficient  to 
secure  some  definite  object,  or  to  put  the  re- 
cipient beyond  the  need  of  charity.  Inadequate 
charity  is  worse  than  useless.  The  old  system 
of  doles  illustrated  this.  People  got  into  debt 
up  to  the  amount  which  they  anticipated,  or 
not  uncommonly  wasted  the  whole  in  excess. 
A  small  sum  given  to  a  beggar  is  just  enough  to 
make  him  go  on  begging  and  to  give  him  and 
others  an  excuse  for  doing  so.  (2)  Charity 
should  never  be  directed  to  providing  the  neces- 
saries of  life.  For  those  who  lack  them,  viz. 
the  destitute,  provision  is  made  by  the  poor 
law.  Now  the  poor  law  embodies  in  its 
regulations,  etc.,  the  experience  of  some  of  the 
wisest  and  most  skilled  in  the  relief  of  the  poor. 
It  is  very  dangerous  to  attempt  to  relieve  desti- 
tution without  the  safeguards  which  the  poor 
law  provides.  It  is  almost  as  dangerous  to 
attempt  to  remedy  or  deal  with  the  ordinary 
ills  of  life.  Thus  sickness  and  old  age  are 
inevitable  for  all,  and  it  is  the  duty  of  all  to 
make  provision  for  them.  To  relieve  people 
from  the  responsibility  is  to  weaken  self-reliance 
and  self-control,  and  so  in  the  long  rim  to 
increase  poverty.  Charity  therefore,  when  it 
deals  with  individuals,  should  aim  at  helping 
those  of  whom  there  is  good  gi'ound  for  hoping 
that  they  may  be  restored  to  independence, 
those  whose  poverty  is  inevitable,  the  blind, 
dumb,  etc.,  or  those  who  in  old  age  have  been 
defrauded  of  their  savings,  or  those  whose  needs 
are  on  a  scale  which  is  beyond  any  power  of 
provision — the  result  of  accident  or  sickness  of  a 
kind  requiring  special  knowledge  and  skill  in 
treatment.  (3)  The  wisest  charity  is  that  which 
does  not  wait  till  poverty  is  a  fait  accompli 


to  relieve  it,  but  aims  at  removing  its  causes. 
In  individual  cases  this  work  is  moral  rather 
than  economical,  it  aims  at  the  formation  oi' 
character  by  personal  friendship,  moral  suasion, 
the  creation  of  opportunities,  friendly  guidance. 
Material  assistance  will  be  best  employed  in 
improving  the  general  conditions  of  life,  and 
that  form  of  charity  is  least  open  to  objection, 
under  present  circumstances,  which  does  not 
come  into  direct  contact  with  individuals  at  all, 
but  seeks  to  provide  on  a  large  scale  the  con- 
ditions of  good  living,  open  spaces,  museums, 
picture  galleries,  etc.,  the  requisites  of  culture, 
bodily  and  mental. 

Any  such  scheme  of  charity  is  clearly  beyond 
the  power  of  the  individual  to  realise  ;  both  for 
inquiry  and  administration  some  organisation 
is  needed.  The  question  arises  whether  this 
should  be  the  work  of  the  state  or  left  to  volun- 
tary bodies.  Precedents  may  be  found  for 
almost  every  possible  combination  of  the  two 
systems.  In  England  the  spheres  of  the  state 
and  private  charity  are  distinct.  The  state 
undertakes  the  relief  of  destitution,  leaving 
poverty  to  voluntary  effort. 

[Reports  of  Charity  Commissioners  (1833  seq.). 
— Publications  of  Charity  Organisation  Society 
London. — Defoe,  Giving  Alms  . ..  no  Charity. — 
Walker,  The  Original. — For  foreign  countries  : 
Twining's  Poor  Relief  in  Foreign  Countries^ 
also  Senior,  1835,  and  blue  book,  1875-77.— 
Report,  Royal  Commission  on  Poor  Laws  and 
Relief  of  Distress,  1909.]  L.  B.  p. 

CHARITY  ORGANISATION.  Charity  or- 
ganisation is  an  application  of  the  principle  of 
division  of  labour  to  the  relief  of  poverty, 
with  the  further  object  of  giving  the  assist- 
ance required  by  the  poor  in  the  manner  most 
beneficial  to  them,  while  leading  the  more 
prosperous  to  understand  that  it  is  their  duty 
to  join  in  meeting  the  wants  of  those  in  distress. 
With  a  limited  area  and  a  small  population 
the  problems  of  charity  are,  by  comparison, 
simple,  for  the  well-to-do  know  their  poorer 
neighbours,  and  the  conditions  under  which 
they  live,  and  so  can  help  them  personally. 
All  this  is  changed  in  a  city  with  a  dense 
population,  a  wide  separation  between  rich  and 
poor,  a  complex  social  system  in  which  the 
causes  of  poverty  and  its  remedies  are  hard 
to  see ;  here  some  organisation  among  the 
charitable  is  needed  to  ensure  greater  knowledge, 
and  greater  efficiency  as  a  result  of  knowledge. 
The  knowledge  requisite  is  of  two  kinds  :  first, 
to  guarantee  that  charity  is  bestowed  on  fitting 
objects,  and  secondly,  that  it  is  given  in  the 
most  useful  form.  Such  knowledge  is  only  to 
be  gained  by  thorough  inquiry,  and  its  value 
may  be  shown  by  examples  of  the  evils  caused 
by  ignorant  almsgiving.  (1)  In  every  com- 
munity in  which  charity  abounds  there  will 
grow  up  a  class  of  persons  who  live  by  it  in 
preference  to  living  ty  independent  work.     The 


CHARITY  ORGANISATION 


267 


existence  and  growth  of  such  a  class  is  often 
the  result  of  ignorance  on  the  part  of  charitable 
persons  who,  whilst  striving  to  mitigate  the 
evils  of  poverty,  increase  them  by  fostering 
mendicancy,  hypocrisy,  idleness,  and  improvi- 
dence. In  proportion  as  the  charitable  act 
together  in  some  organisation  they  will  avoid 
creating  these  mischiefs,  for  diligent  inquiry 
will  prevent  the  diversion  of  alms  to  such 
recipients.  (2)  Unless  there  is  some  common 
action  among  the  charitable  there  is  danger  of 
overlapping.  Some  persons  will  be  assisted  by 
three  or  four  institutions  and  half  a  dozen 
individuals  at  one  and  the  same  time.  This 
danger  is  greatest  when  charity  is  distributed 
on  several  different  principles,  as  in  England, 
where  we  have  municipal  and  parochial  charities, 
charities  for  members  of  various  religious  bodies, 
trades,  and  professions,  charities  for  persons 
suffering  from  various  forms  of  mental  and 
bodily  disease,  and  the  like.  Here  ignorance 
of  what  others  are  doing  causes  waste. 

It  was  these  evils,  amongst  others,  which  the 
late  Edward  Denison  had  in  his  mind  when,  in 
1869,  he  gave  the  impetus  which  started  the  Lon- 
don Charity  Organisation  Society.  He  desired 
to  establish  a  union  of  charities  having  a  regis- 
tration office  in  each  parish  and  a  central  office 
auditing  and  controlling  the  parochial  charities. 
It  was  to  be  an  organisation  of  existing  charities 
with  a  view  of  checking  imposture  and  waste, 
and  of  teaching  sound  principles  in  almsgiving  ; 
it  was  not  to  add  another  to  the  sources  of 
help,  but  to  increase  the  efficiency  of  those 
already  in  existence  by  their  co-ordination.  As 
a  result,  we  have  now  in  London  a  central  com- 
mittee with  district  committees  in  every  poor-law 
union.  The  central  committee  does  not  relieve 
directly,  but  aims  at  propagating  sound  views  on 
the  subject  of  charity  by  publication  and  discus- 
sion, promoting  co-operation,  suggesting  new 
institutions  on  good  principles,  collecting  infor- 
mation relating  to  individuals  and  of  general 
import,  and  preventing  misapplication.  The 
district  committees  in  London,  and  the  sixty- 
eight  affiliated  societies  in  England  and  Scot- 
land, not  only  organise,  but  also  administer 
relief  on  certain  principles.  Those  principles 
may  be  summed  up  as  follows:  (1)  That  all 
relief  should  aim  at  making  the  recipient  inde- 
pendent of  relief.  (2)  That  no  relief  should  be 
given  without  thorough  inquiry  and  investi- 
gation. Quite  apart  from  the  detection  of 
impostors  mentioned  above,  inquiry  is  to  the 
charitable  worker  what  diagnosis  is  to  the  phy- 
sician. Nothing  short  of  thorough  knowledge 
can  ensure  the  discovery  of  the  best  means  of 
helping ;  only  thus  can  we  see  the  germs  of 
hopefulness  which  it  is  for  charity  to  develop — 
the  gi'ounds  for  thinking  that  restoration  to 
independence  is  possible.  Knowledge  of  the 
past  is  necessary  as  a  guide  to  the  future.  In 
the  best  societies  the  term  ** deserving,"  as  im- 


plying that  charity  should  be  given  on  a  test 
of  merit  in  the  past,  has  been  dropped.  (3) 
That  existing  institutions  should  be  utilised  as 
far  as  possible.  Thus  a  person  may  be  referred 
to  medical  or  general  institutions,  to  private 
persons  co-operatingwith  the  society,  to  relations 
or  friends  ;  he  may  also  be  helped  by  finding 
employment,  by  loan,  or  a  grant  from  the 
society's  funds.  (4)  That  all  relief  should 
be  adequate  to  secure  the  object  with  which 
it  is  given.  If  on  the  one  hand  organisa- 
tion prevents  overlapping,  on  the  other  it 
secures  co-operation — it  can  bring  a  number  of 
persons  together,  and  by  joint  elfort  do  what 
individuals  acting  separately  cannot.  By 
putting  these  principles  into  practice  the 
various  societies  train  workers,  promote  discus- 
sion, and  spread  knowledge. 

The  administration  of  charity  in  England  is 
bound  up  with  the  existence  of  a  poor  law  (see 
Poor  Law),  and  one  of  the  aims  of  charity  or- 
ganisation is  to  establish  relations  with  the 
official  forms  of  relief.  It  is  the  duty  of  the 
poor-law  authorities  to  relieve  destitution,  and 
in  administering  relief  to  take  into  account  the 
amount  of  destitution  and  that  only.  But  even 
among  the  destitute  there  are  many  cases  which 
can  be  treated  far  better  by  the  assistance  of 
the  charitable  than  by  the  poor  law, — all  those 
cases,  that  is,  which  give  gi'ound  for  hope  that 
independence  may  be  restored.  Charity  can 
ensure  more  thorough  inquiry  and  knowledge  ; 
it  can  induce  relations  and  friends  not  legally 
liable  to  give  substantial  help  ;  the  help  which 
it  gives  directly  is  far  more  elastic,  determined 
by  futm-e  possibilities  rather  than  by  existing 
needs.  Above  all,  charity  can  give  moral  assist- 
ance. In  many  cases,  e.g.  widows  left  with 
large  families,  the  poor  require  not  so  much 
material  help,  as  the  encouragement  and  support 
which  sympathy  brings  (an  American  society 
takes  as  its  motto  "not  alms,  but  a  friend  ") — 
these,  together  with  opportunities  for  work, 
openings  for  children,  and  the  like,  can  be  given 
by  charitable  volimteers  working  together,  but 
they  are  beyond  the  scope  of  an  official  system. 
It  may  be  said  shortly  that  in  many  cases 
charity  can  restore  independence  more  quickly, 
more  cheaply,  with  a  smaller  risk  to  family 
affection  and  self-respect,  than  the  poor  law, 
whilst  at  the  same  time  it  enforces  social  duties 
and  binds  classes  together. 

The  relations  between  voluntary  and  state 
help  differ  in  different  countries.  In  France, 
the  right  to  relief  is  recognised  only  in  the  cases 
of  lunatics  and  deserted  children,  all  other  relief 
may  be  described  as  organised  charity  distri- 
buted by  public  bodies.  Institutions,  such  as 
Hdpitaux  for  the  sick,  hospices  for  the  aged 
and  infirm,  are  supported  by  endowments  and 
voluntary  contributions,  and  managed  by  un 
paid  bodies  constituted  and  controlled  by  the 
state.     The  Bureaux  de  Bienfaisance,  consist- 


268 


CHARITY  ORGANISATION— CHARITY,  STATE 


ing  of  elected  and  nominated  members,  tlie 
Maire  presiding  ex  officio,  distribute  relief  in 
the  communes  to  the  poor  at  their  own  homes. 
The  funds  which  they  administer  are  derived 
almost  wholly  from  endowments  and  voluntary 
contributions,  a  small  proportion  only  cpming 
from  taxation.  Inquiry  is  conducted  mainly 
by  sisters  of  charity,  and  is  very  thorough.  It 
is  claimed  fbr  the  French  system  that  it  com- 
bines the  efficiency  of  voluntary  effort  with  the 
regularity  and  consistency  of  official  manage- 
ment ;  it  is  objected  to  it  that  in  practice  the 
relief  given  is  rarely  adequate.  The  value  of 
inquiry  is  illustrated  by  the  case  of  Elberfeld 
in  North  Germany.  Here  the  prevalence  of 
pauperism  induced  the  authorities  to  enlist 
volunteer  aid  very  largely.  Relief  is  now  ad- 
ministered by  18  overseers  and  252  visitors, 
to  each  of  whom  is  entrusted  on  the  average  4 
cases  ;  as  a  result,  pauperism  of  all  kinds  has 
largely  diminished,  able-bodied  pauperism  has 
disappeared,  thrift  and  providence  have  greatly 
increased. 

The  difficulties  in  the  way  of  extending  or- 
ganised charity  in  the  United  Kingdom  lie  first 
in  the  absence  of  strictly  binding  principles. 
The  reports  of  the  various  societies  show  a 
great  variety  both  of  principle  and  practice. 
It  is  with  the  greatest  difficulty  that  even 
the  local  government  board,  with  its  statutory 
limitations  and  its  official  machinery  of  in- 
spection and  audit,  can  secure  even  an  approach 
to  uniformity  in  administering  poor  relief ;  it 
would  be  far  more  difficult  to  do  so  with 
voluntary,  uncontrolled,  irresponsible  bodies. 
Secondly,  gi'anting  a  general  acceptance  of 
principles,  and  loyalty  to  them,  a  difficulty 
arises  from  the  scarcity  of  individuals  with  the 
skill  and  experience  necessary  to  apply  them. 
Charity  organisation  makes  way  but  slowly  in 
the  United  Kingdom.  Charitable  persons  and 
the  governors  of  institutions  are  unwilling  to 
subrait  themselves  to  its  discipline,  and  misin- 
terpret its  objects  and  methods  ;  and  yet  the 
best  hope  for  improving  the  relief  of  the  poor 
lies  in  supplementing  the  poor  law  by  volun- 
tary and  organised  effort. 

[Mai thus,  Principle  of  Population,  bk.  iy.  ch. 
X, — Edward  Denison,  Letters. — Charity  Organis- 
ation Society,  Annual  Eeports  and  Publications. — 
Moggridge,  Handbook  for  Helpers. — Emminghaus, 
Das  Armenwesen  in  Europaischen  Staaten  (1870). 
— Eastwick,  Poor  Belief  in  Different  Parts  of 
Europe  (1873). — Aschrott,  Das  Armenwesen  Eng- 
lands  (Eng.  trans,  contains  much  information  as 
to  relations  of  Poor  Law  and  Charity).  — Twining, 
Poor  Relief  in  Foreign  Countries  and  Out-door 
Relief  in  England  (1889).— C.  S.  Loch,  Charity 
Organisation. — L.  Bequet,  Regime  et  Ligislation 
de  I' assistance  publique  etprivSe  en  France  (1885). 

L.  R.  P. 

CHARITY,  State.  A  distinction  may  be 
drawn  between  the  supply  of  the  necessaries  of 
life,  of  the  minimum,  i.e.  of  food,  clothing,  and 


shelter  needful  to  support  it,  and  the  supply  of 
sources  of  comfort  over  and  above  these,  which 
technically  fall  under  the  head  of  luxuries,  in 
short,  between  the  relief  of  destitution  and  oi 
poverty.  The  action  of  the  state  with  regard 
to  the  former  is  determined  in  this  country  by 
the  Poor  Law  (see  Poor  Law),  we  are  now  con- 
cerned with  proposals  that  the  state  should 
supply  or  guarantee  certain  of  the  latter.  Such 
action  on  the  part  of  the  state  may  be  con- 
veniently summed  up  under  the  head  of  state 
charity.  The  growth  of  such  a  theory  of  the 
duty  or  functions  of  the  state  is  not  difficult  to 
trace.  The  poor-law  system  guarantees  to  every 
citizen  the  necessaries  of  life,  but  the  conception 
of  these  necessaries  is  constantly  changing.  As 
Ricardo  has  pointed  out,  it  differs  in  different 
countries,  and  at  different  times  in  the  same 
country.  In  popular  parlance  the  term  "neces- 
saries of  life  "  implies  a  great  deal  niore  in  this 
country  to-day  than  it  did  a  hundred  years  ago. 
And,  as  the  conception  has  grown,,  so,  not  un- 
naturally, the  state  has  come  to  be  regarded  in 
some  quarters  as  responsible  for  all  the  individual 
things  which  are  contained  in  the  new  concep- 
tion. 

We  must  distinguish,  in  limine,  two  kinds 
of  provision  made  by  the  state.  There  are, 
first,  services  common  to  the  nation  as  a  whole, 
which  are  open  to  all  alike,  and  of  which  all 
avail  themselves,  of  which  it  is  difficult  to 
say  that  any  individual  or  any  class  is  more 
benefited  by  them  than  any  other  ;  as,  for 
instance,  the  administration  of  justice,  the 
guarantee  of  security  at  home  and  abroad,  the 
enforcement  of  contracts,  the  means  of  com- 
munication, the  medium  of  exchange.  There 
are,  also,  advantages  accruing  to  certain  indi- 
viduals or  certain  classes  only,  which  practi- 
cally are  given  by  one  part  of  the  community 
to  another ;  such  at  the  present  time  in  England 
would  be  free  education  ;  it  would  be  provided 
by  one  section  or  class  for  the  use  and  enjoy- 
ment of  another,  whereas  in  the  United  States, 
it  is  said,  the  whole  population,  without  dis- 
tinction, send  their  children  to  the  common 
schools.  Free  libraries  might  come  under 
either  head ;  picture-galleries  under  the  first ; 
and  baths  and  wash-houses  under  the  second 
only.  Again,  a  distinction  must  be  drawn 
between  England,  where  there  is  a  poor  law, 
i.e.  provision  for  the  destitute,  and  countries 
where  there  is  none.  The  poor-law  system  in 
England  is  practically  the  outcome  of  a  drastic 
reform  of  a  system  of  state  charity  which 
was  working  untold  ill,  and  many  of  the  pro- 
posals of  modern  times,  e.g.  free  dinners,  may 
be  treated,  and  indeed  would  naturally  be  treated, 
as  part  of  the  poor-law  system,  and  administered 
under  the  safeguards  which  are  embodied  in 
that  system  as  the  result  of  a  bitter  experi- 
ence. On  the  other  hand,  the  attitude  of  a 
country  towards  such  a  question  as  Government 


CHARITY,  STATE 


269 


Insurance  may  be  determined  by  the  presence 
or  absence  of  a  poor  law,  the  arguments  pro 
and  con  will  be  of  a  different  kind  in  the  two 
cases,  and  even  the  same  arguments  will  have 
very  different  weight. 

A  few  instances  will  show  the  nature  of 
state  charity.  I.  Allotments.  All  through 
history  we  find  pressure  put  upon  the  state  to 
"find  land"  for  the  poorer  citizens.  At  the 
present  time  proposals  of  this  kind  are  common, 
as,  by  50  &  51  Vict.  c.  48,  the  local  authority 
is  empowered  to  purchase  land,  by  compulsory 
sale  if  need  be,  for  the  purpose  of  allotments 
(see  Allotment).  Now  when  the  powers 
granted  by  this  act  have  been  put  in  force,  the 
question  arises  as  to  the  terms  on  which  sucli 
allotments  shall  be  let,  whether  at  the  market 
value  (a)  as  agricultural,  or  (6)  as  building  land, 
or  at  any  of  the  thousand-and-one  varieties  of 
"  fail'  rent."  If  they  are  let  at  anything  under 
the  market  rent  they  come  at  once  under  the 
head  of  state  charity.  For  the  rates  then 
provide  for  certain  citizens  advantages  which 
they  cannot  command  for  themselves,  or,  at 
least,  the  advantage  secured  to  them  from  the 
rates  is  out  of  all  proportion  to  their  contribu- 
tion. The  question  of  riglit — how  far,  e.g., 
in  country  parishes  the  allotments  represent 
a  repair  of  wTong  done  by  enclosure  acts — 
is  outside  the  economical  question  which 
refers  to  the  probable  effect  of  a  course  of 
conduct.  Now,  if  a  piece  of  land  be  let  to 
a  labourer  at  less  than  its  market  value, 
he  clearly  is  benefited  to  the  extent  of  the 
difference,  in  other  words,  his  wages  are  in- 
creased out  of  the  rates.  The  results  of  such 
policy,  on  a  large  scale,  may  be  seen  in  the 
well-known  allowance  system.  In  the  long 
run  wages  will  be  lowered  by  almost  exactly 
the  amount  of  advantage  given  ;  in  other  words, 
the  employer  of  labour  will  profit  by  the  fact 
that  a  part  of  his  wages  bill  is  paid  for  him  by 
the  whole  body  of  ratepayers.  Again,  if  the 
experience  of  the  past  may  be  trusted,  the 
results  to  the  labourers  themselves  will  be 
disastrous  (see  Allowance  System).  A  practi- 
cal difficulty  arises  from  the  fact  that  it  is  almost 
impossible  to  ensure  that  the  letting  of  allot- 
ments on  easy  terms  shall  not  be  an  engine  of 
political  corruption.  As  it  is,  the  promise  to  pro- 
cure cheap  allotments  is  fast  becoming  a  favour- 
ite device  to  catch  votes  at  a  parliamentary 
election.  In  considering  this  question  we  must 
bear  in  mind  that  if  an  open  space  be  acquired 
out  of  the  rates  and  let  in  allotments  at  its 
market- value,  no  charity  is  involved.  The  ad- 
vantage to  the  ratepayers  of  an  open  space  may 
fairly  be  set  off  against  the  difference  of  value 
for  agricultural  and  building  purposes,  and  the 
opportunity  given  for  open-air  exercise,  etc.,  is 
clear  gain  to  the  community.  II.  Buildings. 
A  form  of  state  charity  which  finds  many 
supporters  at  the  present  day  is  the  provision 


of  houses,  or  sites  of  houses,  for  the  working 
classes,  by  the  state.  The  question  involved 
here  is  twofold,  viz.  :  (a)  how  far  is  such  action 
on  the  whole  for  the  good  of  the  community, 
and  (J)  how  far  is  it  likely  to  achieve  its  im- 
mediate end.  That  end,  it  must  be  confessed, 
is  most  attractive.  The  moral  and  economical 
loss  to  the  nation  involved  by  the  conditions 
under  which  the  poor  live — bad  air,  bad 
materials,  confined  space,  want  of  sun,  and  the 
consequent  habits  of  ill-health  and  intemper- 
ance— cannot  well  be  overstated.  But  it  must 
always  be  borne  in  mind  (1)  that  an  attempt  to 
improve  dwellings  which  is  not  the  result  of  a 
rise  in  the  standard  of  comfort  on  the  part  of  the 
occupants  is  not  likely  to  have  a  lasting  success, 
though  it  may  foster  such  a  rise ;  (2)  that  a  supply 
of  houses  at  less  than  the  market  value  will  not 
only  have  the  same  results  as  a  supply  of  allot- 
ments, but  also  will  attract  workmen  from 
other  districts,  and  even  other  countries,  who 
will  increase  the  pressure  upon  accommodation  ; 
(3)  that  it  is  veiy  difficult  to  confine  the 
benefits  of  such  a  system  to  tlie  class  for  whom 
it  is  intended,  with  the  result,  if  a  different 
class  enjoy  them,  of  increased  pressure  in  other 
quarters.  All  these  considerations,  coupled 
with  the  actual  experience  of  success  on  the 
part  of  various  joint-stock  enterprises,  point  to 
the  provision  of  dwellings  as  a  matter  which  may 
well  be  left  outside  the  sphere  of  state-action. 
III.  Three  forms  of  state  charity  are  so  closely 
connected  that  they  may  be  considered  together. 
(a)  Free  Schools. — Comparatively  few  writers 
have  maintained  that  elementary  education 
should  be  left  to  private  enterprise,  and  it  is 
probably  undertaken  or  organised  by  the  state 
in  every  civilised  country.  But  much  contro- 
versy has  arisen  on  the  point  whether  it  should 
be  given  free  of  charge.  On  the  one  hand  it 
is  said  that  if  the  poor  are  deprived  of  their 
children's  earnings  by  the  compulsory  system, 
it  is  right  that  at  least  they  should  have  them 
taught  for  nothing ;  and  again  tliat  educational 
endowments  have  been  in  very  many  cases 
monopolised  by  the  rich,  who  may  fairly  make 
compensation  by  paying  for  the  education  of  the 
poor.  With  these  arguments  the  economist  is 
not  concerned.  It  is  also  said  to  be  well  worth 
while,  inasmuch  as  education  diminishes  crime 
and  pauperism — a  statement  vigorously  denied 
by  some  writers,  as  by  Mr.  Herbert  Spencer  ; 
or  again,  because  it  increases  the  efficiency  of 
a  nation's  labour,  by  assuring  the  genei'al 
education  which  is  a  necessary  preliminary  to  a 
technical  one,  and,  lastly,  because  it  raises  a 
nation's  moral  tone  indirectly  if  not  directly  ;  in 
short  that  education  is  so  necessary  a  condition 
of  civic  life,  in  any  real  sense,  that  it  cannot 
be  left  to  the  option  or  power  of  a  parent  to 
provide  it.  All  these  arguments,  it  will  be  noted, 
presuppose  that  education  cannot  be  general  or 
compulsory  unless  it  is  free,     (h)  Free  Libraries. 


270 


CHARITY,  STATE 


— Free  schools  cany  with  them  free  libraries, 
that  is  to  say,  if  it  be  worth  while  to  give  ele- 
mentary education,  it  is  also  worth  while  to  give 
the  necessary  complement,  without  which  the 
educated  youth  is  turned  loose  with  his  mental 
appetite  sharpened  and  nowhere  to  graze.  No 
complaint  is  more  common  in  the  countsy  dis- 
tricts than  that  the  effects  of  elementary  educa- 
tion disappear  in  a  few  years.  It  is  also  argued 
that  the  amount  of  good  done  is  out  of  all 
proportion  to  the  cost.  It  is  a  striking  case,  says 
Prof.  Jevons, ' '  of  the  principle  of  multiplication 
of  utility."  Thus  the  cost  of  each  issue  from  the 
Birmingham  Free  Library  is  under  twopence. 
Economically,  too,  there  is  a  direct  advantage. 
The  supply  of  wholesome  literature  not  only 
cheers  and  brightens  a  workman's  life,  making 
him  a  better  producer,  but  it  also  helps  him  to 
special  knowledge.  At  a  free  library  he  learns 
where  his  labour  is  in  demand,  and  so  the 
mobility  of  labour  is  increased.  He  learns  also 
the  lessons  of  history,  gets  a  wider  horizon  of 
knowledge,  and  greater  familiarity  with  the 
points  at  issue  in  trade  disputes,  etc.  (c) 
Free  Dinners. — Free  schools  are  said  also  by 
some  to  carry  free  dinners  with  them.  It  is 
useless,  and  even  cruel,  it  is  urged,  to  force 
children  into  school  who  cannot  profit  by  in- 
struction for  want  of  nourishment,  and  it  is 
"beyond  question  that  in  large  towns  numbers 
of  children  come  in  that  condition  every  day. 
Now  it  is  the  duty  of  the  state  to  provide  the 
conditions  of  mental  development,  of  which 
teaching  is  only  one,  and  therefore  in  such  cases 
as  the  above  it  is  argued  that  it  should  provide 
dinners  as  in  other  cases  it  provides  desks.  The 
objections  to  the  provision  of  education,  libraries, 
and  dinners  by  the  state  are  up  to  a  certain  point 
common  to  all  three.  Thus  we  may  say  that 
so  far  as  experience  and  history  are  any  guide, 
the  only  motive  which  can  be  tnisted  to  work 
generally  and  constantly  in  making  men  in- 
dustrious is  self-interest,  i.e.  the  desire  for 
necessaries  and  luxuries.  Anything  which 
weakens  this  motive  by  supplying  the  results 
of  industry  without  its  exercise  helps  to  in- 
crease the  idle  class  in  the  community — the 
least  profitable  and  probably  the  least  happy  of 
all — and  so  to  decrease  the  amount  of  production. 
Again,  any  measures  which  guarantee  the  means 
of  supporting  children  will,  in  the  long  run, 
diminish  providence  in  the  matter  of  marriage 
and  increase  population ;  in  other  words,  the 
evils  it  is  sought  to  cure  will  grow  greater  and 
not  less.  Now  both  the  training  and  feeding 
of  children,  it  is  argued,  are  matters  for  which 
persons  should  make  provision,  or  should  see 
their  way  to  supplying  before  they  marry  ;  and 
it  is  unwise  to  enable  them  to  dispense  with 
such  provision.  The  general  contention  that 
free  schools  weaken  or  diminish  the  sense  of 
parental  responsibility  is  met  by  two  special 
arguments.    First,  by  pointing  out  that  the  bulk 


of  the  expense  of  a  child's  schooling  is  already 
borne  by  other  than  its  parents,  and  alwayg 
must  be.  Subscribers,  endowments,  voluntary 
or  compulsory  rates  contribute  by  far  the  larger 
part  of  the  cost  of  carrying  on  a  school.  Con- 
sequently free  schools  present  a  question  of  degree 
rather  than  of  kind.  This  argument  applies 
only  to  the  special  circumstances  of  England. 
Secondly,  by  denying  the  truth  of  the  statement. 
In  such  matters  disproof  is  not  easy.  We  may 
trace  a  connection  between  a  motive  and  a  fact, 
or  vice  versd,  as  between  the  absence  of  outdoor 
relief  and  the  strength  of  family  affection  in 
Ireland,  but  it  is  hardly  possible  to  demonstrate 
more  than  this.  It  is  said,  however,  that  in  the 
United  States  the  strongest  sense  of  responsi- 
bility goes  hand  in  hand  with  free  schools,  the 
parents  straining  every  nerve  to  provide  for  their 
children  a  secondary  education,  the  primary 
being  found  for  them  by  the  state.  Again  it  may 
be  questioned  whether  educational  endowments 
have  had  any  such  result  as  the  weakening  of 
responsibility  on  the  part  of  middle-class  parents, 
who,  in  the  main,  enjoy  them.  So  again  with 
regard  to  free  libraries.  The  existence  of  these 
is  not  found  to  diminish  men's  zeal  for  the 
possession  of  books  ;  on  the  contrary,  the  busi- 
ness of  bool^sellers  increases  in  towns  where  they 
are  opened.  The  existence  of  a  state-supported 
library  in  the  British  Museum,  or  endowed 
libraries  as  those  of  Oxford  and  Cambridge,  is 
not  found  to  have  any  bad  effect  on  those  who  use 
them.  There  is  no  difference  in  principle  be- 
tween supplying  at  the  public  cost  rare  books 
and  any  other — rareness  is  wholly  relative. 
Libraries  stand  on  the  same  footing  as  picture 
galleries,  the  provision  of  which  is  a  recognised 
function  of  the  state.  As  to  free  dinners  it 
may  be  said,  whilst  in  all  countries  the  pro- 
vision of  education  is  a  state  matter,  and  is 
never  kept  wholly  to  individual  effort,  etc.,  the 
provision  of  meals  is  a  family  or  domestic 
matter.  The  difference  between  the  two  is  one 
of  principle,  and  the  supply  of  food  should 
never  be  undertaken  by  the  state,  except  in 
cases  of  destitution,  when  it  falls  within  the 
province  of  the  poor  law.  Further,  an  inquiry 
conducted  in  1889  by  the  Charity  Organisation 
Society  showed  that  the  evil  to  be  met  by  free 
dinners  was  of  such  small  dimensions  as  to 
call  for  no  exceptional  measures,  and  that  where 
exceptional  measures  had  been  adopted  the  evil 
had  greatly  increased. 

The  sphere  of  state  action,  including  state 
charity,  is  rarely  if  ever  determined  by  logical 
considerations :  it  is  more  often  the  result  of 
historical  events.  "When  we  ask  ourselves  the 
abstract  question,  how  far  will  the  state  do  more 
good  than  harm,  or  vice  versd,  by  the  provision 
of  necessaries  or  comforts,  experience  gives  no 
certain  answer.  The  conditions  of  the  problem 
vary  with  each  succeeding  generation  and  in 
each  country.     The  answer  will  depend  largely 


CHARTER— CHARTISM 


271 


on  a  balance  of  probabilities.  How  far  will 
industry  and  thrift  be  weakened,  family  life 
threatened,  and  human  feeling  deadened,  by 
state  charity  ?  How  far,  again,  is  improve- 
ment made  possible,  a  higher  standard  con- 
ceived, by  the  provision  of  certain  conditions  of 
realising  an  end  in  life?  (For  Pensions,  Old 
Age.     See  Appendix.)  l.  r.  p. 

CHARTER.  A  ^vritten  document  by  which 
the  crown,  in  virtue  of  its  prerogative,  confers 
special  privileges  on  an  individual,  or  group  of 
individuals.  The  term  was  at  one  time  applied 
to  conveyances  of  land,  and  to  measures  adopted 
by  the  crown  by  way  of  legislation.  In  modern 
times,  the  crown's  assent  to  the  formation  of  a 
corporation,  such  as  a  university,  a  city,  a  bank, 
or  a  trading  company,  is  frequently  given 
by  charter.  Trading  corporations  are  usually 
formed  under  the  companies  acts,  but  where 
these  are  not  applicable,  a  charter  of  the  crown 
has  sometimes  been  obtained.  The  North 
Borneo  Company  was  incorporated  in  this  way 
in  1881  (see  charter  in  London  Gazette,  8th 
Nov.  1881,  pp.  5448-5453).  In  the  charter 
of  this  company,  it  is  expressly  declared  that 
the  grant  is  not  to  authorise  the  setting  up 
of  any  monopoly  of  trade,  and  is  to  be  sub- 
ject only  to  customs  duties  imposed  for 
revenue  purposes,  and  to  restrictions  on  import- 
ation similar  to  those  existing  in  the  United 
Kingdom.  Formerly,  it  was  thought  that  foreign 
trade  could  be  best  promoted  by  conferring  a 
monopoly  of  trading  with  certain  countries, 
and  various  companies  were  incorporated  by 
charter  with  this  object.  The  chief  companies 
so  formed  were  the  East  India  Company,  1600  ; 
the  South  Sea  Company,  1711  ;  the  African 
Company,  1618  ;  the  Russia  Company,  1553  ; 
the  Eastland  Company,  1579,  and  the  Turkey 
Company,  1593.  (See  African  Companies, 
Early.) 

[Chitty,  in  his  Commercial  Law,  vol.  i.  p.  661, 
gives  a  concise  account  of  these  companies.  Adam 
Smith  in  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  v.  ch.  i.  discusses 
the  economic  effects  of  such  monopolies.  The  right 
of  the  crown  to  grant  a  trading  monopoly  depends 
on  the  21  Jac.  I.  c.  3,  and  is  discussed  in  Broom's 
Constitutional  Laiv,  1886,  p.  239.]     J.  e.  c.  m. 

CHARTER  PARTY.  A  document  embody- 
ing a  contract  by  which  a  ship  or  part  of  a  ship 
is  let  to  a  merchant  for  the  conveyance  of  goods 
on  a  determined  voyage  to  one  or  more  places. 
The  instrument  expresses  the  freight  to  be  paid, 
the  tonnage,  the  nature  of  the  cargo,  and  other 
particulars.  The  merchant  usually  covenants 
to  load  and  unload  within  a  specified  time,  or 
if  he  delay  the  ship  for  a  longer  time,  to  pay  a 
fixed  daily  sum,  which  is  called  demurrage. 
It  frequently  happens  that  the  option  of  a 
number  of  ports  is  given  to  the  consignee  (the 
person  to  whom  the  ship  is  addressed),  a  certain 
port  or  several  ports  being  named  in  which  the 
master  of  the  ship  is  to  call  for  orders.    B.  s. 


CHARTISM.  The  chartist  movement  was 
in  its  origin  and  its  aim  economic.  It  arose 
out  of  the  economic  necessities  of  the  time,  and 
its  leaders  had  before  them,  as  their  ultimate 
object,  social  and  industrial  amelioration.  To 
understand  fully  this  aspect  of  chartism  we 
must  study  the  movement  in  its  two  phases : 
(1)  from  1836  to  1839  ;  (2)  from  1840  to  1848. 

(1)  1836  to  1839.  Three  circumstances 
may  be  regarded  as  bringing  about  the  chartist 
movement :  the  commercial  and  industrial 
distress  immediately  preceding  it  in  time  ;  the 
introduction  of  machinery  with  its  effects  ;  and 
the  new  poor  law  of  1834.  Various  men  were 
of  course  variously  affected  by  these  causes  ; 
but  their  common  action  was  secured  by  the 
predominant  influence  of  one  man,  and  the 
action  of  another,  supported  as  he  was  by  his 
colleagues.  The  influence  referred  to  was  that 
of  Robert  Owen,  Avho  had  preached  the  gospel 
of  optimism  and  social  regeneration  when  all 
around  seemed  overshadowed  with  a  gloomy 
present  and  a  threatening  future,  and,  further, 
urged  on  his  followers  and  all  with  whom  he 
came  in  contact,  the  need  of  education  and 
moral  elevation.  It  was,  however,  the  action 
of  Lord  John  Russell  that  brought  into  united 
action  bodies  so  diverse  in  aim  and  constitution 
as  the  working  men's  association  of  London,  the 
Birmingham  political  union,  and  the  unions  of 
the  north,  these  latter  being  under  the  guidance 
of  Feargus  O'Connor.  Briefly  described,  the 
first  was  educational  and  moderate,  the  second 
unstable,  partly  desirous  of  bringing  about  the 
adoption  of  Mr.  Attwood's  currency  scheme, 
and  partly  anxious  for  general  industrial  ameli- 
oration, while  the  latter  formed  centres  for 
violent  denunciation  of  the  rise  of  machinery, 
and  of  the  application  of  the  new  poor  laws. 
All,  however,  hoped  to  attain  their  ends  by 
bringing  pressure  to  bear  on  parliament,  itself 
to  be  rendered  more  amenable  by  a  further 
extension  of  the  franchise  ;  and  hence  Lord 
John  Russell's  declaration  against  all  further 
reform  united  them  together  and  led  to  the 
formation  of  the  national  convention.  The 
task  to  which  this  body  devoted  itself  was 
mainly  political,  and  to  attain  its  object  re- 
course was  had  first  to  menaces  and  then  to 
open  revolt.  The  former  were  disregarded  and 
the  latter  was  suppressed.  Meantime,  however, 
in  the  northern  unions  an  almost  socialistic  at- 
titude had  been  taken  by  some  of  the  leaders. 
Throughout  the  entire  movement,  indeed,  there 
had  been  symptoms  that  many  were  thinking  of 
and  aiming  at  an  entire  social  reconstruction. 

(2)  1840  to  1848.  The  second  phase  of  chart- 
ism differed  essentially  from  the  first.  It  was 
of  smaller  account  in  every  way  but  one.  Its 
strength  was  less,  its  adherents  fewer,  its  organ- 
isation less  stable  ;  but  the  views  of  its  leaders 
were  much  more  advanced.  In  theory,  Bronterre 
O'Brien  stood  far  ahead  of  any  other.     He  wag 


272 


CHARTISM 


socialistic  in  his  aims,  but,  unlike  some  of  his 
associates,  he  did  not  confuse  socialism  and  in- 
dustrial retrogression.  His  schemes  were,  it  is 
true,  somewhat  immature,  but  he  may  be  de- 
scribed as  feeling  about  for  a  new  social  organis- 
ation, Feargus  O'Connor,  on  the  other  hand, 
was  neither  so  consistent  nor  so  advanced  m  his 
aims.  Thus  at  one  time  he  was  advocating  the 
claims  of  the  ''National  Charter  Association," 
for  so  the  organisation  of  the  chartists  was 
called,  while  at  another,  in  defiance  of  the  advice 
of  his  associates,  he  advocated  a  new  scheme  for 
bringing  the  people  into  connection  with  the 
land.  In  opposing  the  Anti-Corn  Law  League, 
it  should  be  noticed,  however,  that  he  based 
his  antagonism  on  the  need  which  he  alleged  to 
exist  of  general  social  reconstruction  (see  especi- 
ally speech,  5th  August  1844).  But  the  direct 
effect  of  the  agitation  at  this  period  was  small. 
Discussions  among  the  leaders  and  mutual  accusa- 
tions " of  interested  motives"  diminished  their 
following,  and  it  was  to  little  or  no  purpose  that 
O'Connor  sought  to  win  them  back  by  his  ap- 
parent advocacy  of  their  interests  in  a  periodical 
called  Labour^  or  by  his  national  land  scheme. 
The  latter,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  was  financially 
unsound.  The  movement  failed.  That  the 
leaders  were  really  in  earnest  in  their  agitation 
is  probable  from  the  circumstances  which  have 
been  alluded  to,  as  also  from  their  decided 
refusal  to  form  any  alliance  with  the  middle 
class,  or  capitalist,  reformers  of  Birmingham. 

In  its  two  phases,  then,  chartism  was  of  econ- 
omic importance.  During  the  earlier  period  it 
aimed  at  economic  regeneration  ;  during  the 
second,  it  not  only  aimed  at  this,  but  assumed 
a  socialistic  character. 

[Historical  Review,  October  1889. — Gammage, 
History  of  the  Chartist  Movement. — Place,  MSS. 
— Northern  Star  and  other  papers.]      E.  c.  K.  g. 

Chartism.  The  Points  of  the  Charter. 
The  Charter  itself  was  a  document  in  the  form 
of  an  act  of  parliament,  drafted  by  Francis 
Place  from  materials  supplied  by  William  Lovett. 
Its  proposals  were  always  summed  up  under 
six  heads  or  ''points,"  viz.  Universal,  i.e.  adult 
male.  Suffrage,  the  Ballot,  Annual  Parlia- 
ments, Payment  of  Members,  Equal  Electoral 
Districts,  and  Abolition  of  Property  Qualifica- 
tion. No  one  of  these  proposals  was  in  any 
sense  new,  and  the  great  majority  of  them  had 
been  continuously  agitated  for  more  than  fifty 
years.  The  Duke  of  Richmond  introduced  a 
proposal  for  adult  suffrage  and  equal  electoral 
districts  into  the  House  of  Lords  in  1780.  All 
or  nearly  all  the  charter  "  points  "  were  adopted 
by  the  Society  of  the  Friends  of  the  People,  and 
the  Corresponding  Society  in  the  earlier  years  of 
the  French  Revolution,  and  by  that  Edinburgh 
Convention  for  taking  part  in  which  Muir  and 
Palmer  Avere  sentenced  in  1793.  The  "  points  " 
were  generally  spoken  of  as  the  Duke  of  Rich- 
mond's,   or   Sir   Francis   Burdett's,    or   Major 


Cart  Wright's  "plan  of  radical  reform,"  and 
were  undisguisedly  intended  by  all  their  work- 
ing class  supporters  to  be  used  for  bringing 
about  economic  as  well  as  political  equality. 
During  the  ten  years  following  the  French  war 
every  period  of  high  prices  and  low  wages  pro- 
duced a  fierce  agitation  for  "radical  reform" 
in  the  manufacturing  districts  and  sometimes 
also  in  London.  In  1830-32  the  "plan"  was 
for  a  time  given  up  in  favour  of  the  Reform  Bill, 
but  in  London  amendments  in  favour  of 
universal  suffrage  were  carried  at  the  public 
meetings  held  in  support  of  Lord  Grey's  bill. 
These  were  generally  moved  by  members  of  the 
"Rotunda  Gang,"  or  National  Union  of  the 
"Working  Classes,  many  of  whom  had  been  per- 
sonal disciples  of  Robert  Owen.  The  reformers  of 
1790-1820  had  advocated  Tom  Paine's  proposal 
of  a  graduated  income  tax,  or  had  been  followers 
of  "Spence's  plan"  of  land  municipalisation. 
These  men  went  further,  and  were  strongly 
though  vaguely  socialistic  in  tone.  Place 
describes  them  as  "filled  with  bitter  notions  of 
animosity  against  everybody  who  did  not 
concur  in  the  absurd  notions  they  entertained, 
that  everything  which  was  produced  belonged 
to  those  who  by  their  labour  produced  it,  and 
ought  to  Be  shared  among  them  ;  that  there 
ought  to  be  no  accumulation  of  capital  in  the 
hands  of  any  one  to  enable  him  to  employ 
others  as  labourers,  and  thus  by  becoming  a 
master  make  slaves  of  others  under  the  name  of 
workmen,  to  take  from  them  the  produce  of 
their  labour,  to  maintain  themselves  in  idle- 
ness and  luxury  while  their  slaves  were  gi-ound 
down  to  the  earth  or  left  to  starve.  They  .Jj 
denounced  every  one  who  dissented  from  these  m 
notions  as  a  political  economist  under  which 
appellation  was  included  the  notion  of  a  bitter 
foe  to  the  working  classes  —  enemies  who 
deserved  no  mercy  at  their  hands." 

Place  also  gives   a  good  specimen  of  their 
teaching  in  a  song  published  about  this  time — 

"  Wages  should  form  the  price  of  goods, 

Yes,  wages  should  be  all ; 
Then  we  who  work  to  make  the  goods 

Should  justly  have  them  all. 
But,  if  the  price  be  made  of  rent. 

Tithes,  taxes,  profits  all, 
Then  we  who  work  to  make  the  goods 

Shall  have — just  none  at  all. " 

From  among  these  men  came  Lovett,  Cleave, 
Hetherington,  and  others  who  were  afterwards 
leaders  of  the  Chartist  movement.     It  is  signifi- 
cant that  their  organisation  was  called  success- 
ively the  "British  Association  for  Co-operative 
Knowledge  "  (i.  e.  of  Robert  Owen's  principles)  in     j 
1829;   "The  Metropolitan  Trades  Union  "in    M 
1830,  when  one  of  their  declared  objects  was      1 
to  "enhance  the  value  of  labour  by  diminish- 
ing the   hours   of    employment,"    and   "The 
National  Union  of  the  Working  Classes,"  for 
nbminally  political  purposes,  in  1831. 


CHASTELLUX— CHEQUES 


273 


After  the  complete  failure  of  the  chartist 
movement  in  1848,  working-class  reformers 
generally  returned  to  the  work  of  co-operation 
and  trade-unionism,  so  that  the  economic  side 
of  the  agitation  which  carried  the  Reform  Bills 
of  1867  and  1884  was  not  so  apparent  as  the 
political  side.  But  the  bill  of  1 867  was  opposed 
on  economic  grounds  by  Robert  Lowe  (afterwards 
Lord  Sherbrooke),  Lord  Shaftesbury,  and  others. 
Lord  Shaftesbury  on  that  occasion  said : — 
**I  am  sure  that  a  large  proportion  of  the 
'working  classes  have  a  deep  and  solemn  convic- 
'tion — and  I  have  found  it  among  working 
people  of  religious  views — that  property  is  not 
distributed  as  property  ought  to  be  ;  that  some 
checks  ought  to  be  kept  on  the  accumulation  of 
property  in  single  hands  ;  that  to  take  away, 
by  a  legislative  enactment,  that  which  is  in 
excess,  with  a  view  to  bestow  it  on  those  who 
have  insufficient  means,  is  not  a  breach  of  any 
law,  human  or  divine." 

[Authorities  as  above,  and  William  Lovett's 
Autobiography. — Bamford's  Life  of  a  Radical. — 
The  Anntud  Register,  and  Hansard's  Parlia- 
mentary Debates. — Scribner's  Century  Magazine, 
January  1882.]  aw. 

CHASTELLUX,  FiiANgois  Jean,  Marquis 
de,  born  at  Paris  1734,  died  1788.  By  pro- 
fession a  soldier,  he  was  received,  1755,  into 
the  Academie  franraise,  a  distinction  which  he 
owed  to  the  success  of  his  principal  work,  De 
la  fdicitd  puhlique  ou  considerations  sur  le  sort 
des  hommes  dans  les  diffdrcntes  6poquesde  Vliistoire 
(1st  ed.  1772,  2  vols,  in  8vo  ;  2d  ed.  1776,  2 
vols,  in  8vo  ;  3d  ed.  1 822,  2  vols,  in  8vo,  with 
notes  by  Voltaire).  This  work,  if  out  of  date 
in  form,  is  yet  full  of  ideas  which  would  do 
no  discredit  to  a  book  of  our  own  times.  In 
particular  he  discussed  the  question  of  the 
population  a  quarter  of  a  century  earlier  than 
Malthus,  and  from  the  same  point  of  view  as 
that  distinguished  economist.  A.  c.  f. 

CHATTEL  or  Chattel  Personal.  Any 
movable  thing  which  can  be  part  of  a  person's 
property.  The  expression  "chattels  real"  is 
applied  to  interests  in  land  granted  for  a  fixed 
number  of  years,  as,  for  instance,  leasehold 
interests.  Chattels  real  are  thus  classed  with 
ordinary  chattels  (with  which  they  have  other- 
wise nothing  in  common),  because  after  the 
death  of  an  intestate  owner  the  devolution  is  in 
both  cases  the  same,  while  the  descent  of  im- 
movable freehold  property  is  regulated  in  a 
different  manner.  This  somewhat  anomalous 
and  artificial  distinction  may  soon  disappear 
and  the  expression  * '  chattels  real "  will  then, 
no  doubt,  become  obsolete.  E.  s. 

CHECKS  ON  Population.  According  to 
the  theory  of  Malthus  (g'.'W.),  population 
invariably  increases  when  the  means  of  sub- 
sistence increase  unless  prevented  by  some 
powerful  and  obvious  checks.  These  checks,  and 
the  checks  which  repress  the  superior  power 
VOL.  I. 


of  population  and  keep  its  effects  on  a  level 
with  the  means  of  subsistence,  are  all  resolvable 
into  moral  restraint,  vice,  and  misery.  These 
checks  are  classified  as  preventive  and  positive ; 
by  the  former  the  birth-rate  is  diminished,  by 
the  latter  the  death-rate  is  increased.  Person- 
ally Malthus  was  the  strongest  supporter  of 
moral  restraint  as  exemplified  in  late  and 
provident  marriages,  and  he  makes  no  mention 
even  of  those  physical  cheeks  with  which,  in 
the  present  day,  his  name  is  often  associated 
{e.g.  by  the  late  Mr.  Bradlaugli). 

[Malthus,  Essay  on  Popidation. — Doubleday's 
Ti^e  Theory  of  Population,  London,  1846. — 
Bonar,  Malthus  and  his  Work.  ]  J.  s.  N. 

CHEQUES,  Law  of.  The  law  relating  to 
cheques  is  now  mainly  contained  in  §§  73  to  82 
of  the  Bills  of  Exchange  Act  1882  (45  &  46 
Vict.  c.  61),  which  codifies  the  law  relating  to 
bills,  notes,  and  cheques.  A  cheque  may  be 
described  as  an  order  by  a  customer  to  his 
banker  to  pay  on  demand  a  given  sum  of  money 
to,  or  to  the  order  of,  a  specified  person,  or  to 
bearer.  Its  strict  legal  definition  is  contained 
in  §  73  of  the  act,  and  is  as  follows:  **A 
cheque  is  a  bill  of  exchange  drawn  on  a  banker 
payable  on  demand."  The  section  then  goes 
on  to  enact  that,  subject  to  the  special  rules 
contained  in  §§  74  to  82,  the  provisions  of  the 
act  applicable  to  bills  payable  on  demand  shall 
apply  to  cheques.  It  follows  from  this  enact- 
ment that  the  paying  banker  is  not  bound  to 
verify  the  indorsements  on  a  cheque  (§  60), 
though  he  pays  at  his  own  risk  if  the  drawer's 
signature  be  forged  ;  that  a  cheque  is  not  entitled 
to  days  of  grace  (§  14)  ;  that  the  expenses  of 
noting  a  dishonoured  cheque  are  recoverable 
(§  57)  ;  and  that  notice  of  dishonour  must  be 
given  to  the  drawer  and  indorsers  unless  excused 
under  §  50  of  the  Act.  A  cheque  should  be 
stamped  with  a  penny  stamp  in  the  same 
manner  as  any  other  bill  payable  on  demand. 

When  a  banker  opens  an  account  with  a 
customer  the  relationship  between  them  is  that 
of  debtor  and  creditor,  with  a  superadded  obli- 
gation on  the  part  of  the  banker  to  honour  his 
customer's  cheques  as  long  as  there  is  sufficient 
money  to  his  credit  to  meet  them.  The  right 
to  overdraw  only  arises  from  special  agreement. 
A  banker's  authority  to  pay  his  customer's 
cheques  may  be  determined  by  countermand  of 
payment,  by  notice  of  the  customer's  death, 
or  that  he  has  committed  an  actual  act  of 
bankruptcy,  or  by  the  fact  that  a  leceiving 
order  has  been  made  against  him.  If  a  banker 
wrongfully  dishonours  his  customer's  cheque, 
he  is  liable  to  the  customer  in  an  action  for 
damages,  and  it  has  been  said  that  the  smaller 
the  cheque  the  greater  the  wrong,  inasmuch  as 
it  implies  a  greater  reflection  on  the  customer's 
credit.  The  holder  of  a  cheque  which  is  wrong- 
fully dishonoured  has  no  remedy  against  the 
banker,    for    there   is    no   privity   of  contract 

T 


274 


CHEQUES— CHEVAGE 


between  them,  and  a  cheque,  being  a  bill  of 
exchange,  does  not,  according  to  English  law, 
operate  as  an  assignment  of  the  funds  in  the 
banker's  hands,  even  though  it  be  drawn  for 
the  exact  amount  of  the  customer's  balance 
(see,  however,  §  53  as  to  Scotland). 

Though  a  cheque  is  an  instrument  intended 
for  prompt  presentment,  the  drawer,  in  case  of 
delay,  is  not  relieved  from  his  obligation  to  the 
holder  unless  he  suffers  actual  damage  through 
the  delay,  as,  for  instance,  through  the  failure 
of  the  bank  on  which  the  cheque  was  drawn. 
In  such  case  the  drawer  is  discharged  to  the 
extent  that  he  has  been  damnified,  but  the 
holder  is  allowed  to  take  the  drawer's  place  in 
proving  against  the  bank  (§  74). 

Crossed  Cheques.  The  practice  of  crossing 
cheques  first  received  legislative  recognition  by 
the  statute  19  &  20  Vict.  c.  25.  This  act 
was  amended  by  the  21  &  22  Vict.  c.  79,  in 
consequence  of  a  decision  to  the  effect  that  the 
crossing  was  not  an  integi-al  part  of  the  cheque. 
In  a  case  decided  in  1875  it  was  held  that  if  a 
crossed  cheque  was  stolen  and  got  into  the 
hands  of  a  bona  fide  holder,  the  true  owner  had 
no  remedy,  even  though  the  cheque  was  paid 
in  contravention  of  the  crossing  directions.  To 
meet  this  defect  the  Crossed  Cheques  Act  1876 
was  passed,  which  introduced  the  "not  negoti- 
able "  crossing.  These  enactments  are  now 
repealed,  and  §§  75  to  82  of  the  Bills  of  Ex- 
change Act  take  their  place. 

A  cheque  may  be  crossed  either  generally  or 
specially.  A  general  crossing  makes  it  payable 
only  when  presented  through  a  bank,  but  any 
bank  will  do.  A  special  crossing  names  the 
bank  by  which  the  cheque  must  be  presented. 
A  cheque  may  be  crossed  either  by  the  drawer 
or  by  the  holder,  and  the  holder  may  convert 
a  general  crossing  into  a  special  crossing. 
When  a  cheque  is  crossed  specially  the  banker 
to  whom  it  is  crossed  may  again  cross  it  speci- 
ally to  another  banker  for  collection,  but  a 
cheque  must  not  otherwise  bear  two  crossings. 
A  collecting  banker  is  also  allowed  to  cross  to 
himself  an  uncrossed  or  generally  crossed  cheque. 
If  a  crossed  cheque  be  paid  contrary  to  the 
directions  of  the  crossing,  the  paying  banker  is 
liable  to  the  true  owner  for  any  loss  he  may 
sustain  thereby.  A  cheque  which  is  crossed 
either  generally  or  specially  may  further  be 
crossed  with  the  words  "not  negotiable." 
These  words  are  a  little  misleading.  They  do 
not  mean  that  the  cheque  is  no  longer  transfer- 
able. The  cheque  may  be  transferred  as  before, 
but  the  person  who  takes  it  with  these  words 
on  it  does  not  obtain,  and  is  not  capable  of 
giving,  any  better  title  to  the  cheque  than  that 
which  the  person  from  whom  he  took  it  had. 
A  cheque  so  crossed  is  very  much  on  the  same 
footing  as  an  overdue  bill  of  exchange.  Sup- 
pose a  cheque  payable  to  bearer  and  crossed 
"not  negotiable"  is  stolen.     The  thief  gets  a 


tradesman  to  cash  it  for  him,  and  the  trades- 
man passes  the  cheque  through  his  bank  and 
gets  it  paid.  The  paying  and  collecting  banka 
would  incur  no  liability  if  they  obeyed  the 
directions  of  the  crossing,  but  the  tradesman 
would  be  liable  to  refund  the  money  to  the 
true  owner  ;  or  again,  assuming  payment  of  the 
cheque  to  have  been  stopped,  he  could  not  sue 
the  drawer.  For  further  information  as  to 
cheques,  see  the  headings  Bill  of  Exchange  ; 
Clearing  System  ;  Dividend  Warrant. 
^  M.  D.  c. 

CHERBULIEZ,  Antoine  Elys^e,  bom  at 
Geneva  1797,  died  at  Zurich  1869.  Originally 
a  barrister,  then  a  magistrate,  he  replaced  Rossi, 
1833,  at  the  academy  of  Geneva  as  professor  of 
law  {droit),  and,  1835,  as  professor  of  political 
economy.  His  first  works  were  political,  as  he 
was  a  member  of  the  legislature  of  the  canton 
from  1831  to  1846,  then  of  the  representative 
council,  and  finally  of  the  general  assembly  and 
great  council  up  to  1848.  His  political  works 
are  TMorie  des  garanties  constitutionnelles  (2 
vols,  in  8vo,  1839)  ;  J^tvdes  sur  la  loi  6lectorale 
delSSl  (in  8vo,  1840) ;  finally,  Z>g  laD6mocratie 
en  Suisse  (2  vols,  in  8vo,  1845).  But  it  was 
especially  as  an  economist  that  he  made  his 
mark,  and  his  works  on  this  branch  of  study 
are  much  valued.  By  1840  he  published  Riche 
ou  Pauvre,  exposition  succinate  des  causes  et  des 
effets  de  la  distribution  aduelle  des  richesses 
sociales  (in  8vo).  Then  after  1848,  the  date 
when  he  fixed  himself  in  France,  Ze  socialisme 
c'est  la  barbarie,  an  examination  of  the  social 
questions  raised  by  the  revolution  of  24th  Febru- 
ary 1848  (in  8vo,  1848).  Simples  notions  de 
I'ordre  social,  for  the  use  of  every  one  (in  18mo, 
1848).  Le  potage  A  la  tortus,  popular  conversa- 
tions on  social  questions  (in  18mo,  1849). 
Finally  J^tude  sur  les  causes  de  la  misere  tant 
morale  que  physique,  and  on  the  means  of 
remedying  them  (1  vol.  in  8vo,  1853).  He  was 
a  very  active  member  of  the  Political  Economy 
Society.  He  returned  to  Switzerland  at  the 
time  of  the  coup  d'6tat  of  1851,  and  was  im- 
mediately appointed  to  the  chair  of  political 
economy  at  Zurich  at  the  polytechnic  federal 
school  of  Switzerland.  It  was  while  thus  en- 
gaged (in  1862)  that  Cherbuliez  wrote  his  most 
important  work — Pr6cis  de  la  science  4conomique 
et  de  ses  principales  applications  (2  vols,  in  8vo) ; 
the  value  of  which  was  recognised  by  the  insti- 
tute of  France,  and  led  to  his  election  as  a  cor- 
responding member.  Cherbuliez  also  assisted 
in  the  preparation  of  the  Bibliothhqus  universelle 
de  Genbve  in  which,  and  in  the  Journal  des  £ccm- 
omistes,  he  wrote  numerous  articles,      a.  c.  f. 

CHEVAGE.  The  use  of  this  word  in 
mediaeval  documents  is  a  little  vague,  and  in 
consequence  the  exact  sense  in  which  it  is  em- 
ployed is  not  always  clear.  Bracton,  at  page  48 
of  vol.  i.,  describes  chevage  as  a  fixed  payment 
to  the  lord  made  at  fixed  times  by  "  nativi  "  or 


CHEVAGE— CHEVALIER 


275 


bondmen  who  are  engaged  in  trade,  or  as 
soldiers,  or  who,  from  any  other  reason,  have 
ceased  to  reside  on  the  lord's  manor  ;  this  pay- 
ment is  "made  as  a  sign  of  subjection,"  and 
' '  so  long  as  the  bondmen  pay  chevage  they  are 
said  to  be  in  the  power  of  the  lord,  nor  is  his 
power  destroyed,"  even  though  they  cease  to 
reside  on  the  manor.  Britton,  bk.  i.  c,  32, 
gives  a  slightly  different  account  but  does  not 
define  chevage.  He  says  '*  that  in  order  that 
the  lord  may  retain  his  power  over  his  bond- 
men, it  is  only  necessary  that  he  be  in 
possession  of  their  services,  so  that  he  may  take 
services  from  their  holdings,  and  from  those 
who  hold  no  land  in  villenage  may  take  a 
penny  a  year  of  *  chefage '  and  a  day's  work  in 
harvest  time,  or  other  little  or  great  service 
according  to  their  ability."  It  is  clear  from 
this  passage  that  chevage  was  a  payment 
made  by  a  man  of  villein  status,  who  was  for 
some  reason  not  in  the  ordinary  position  of  a 
villein,  and  that  it  was  made  either  in  return 
for  the  privilege  of  being  allowed  to  reside  olf 
the  manor,  or  merely  as  a  recognition  of  the 
fact  that,  although  he  had  no  holding  in  the 
manor  like  other  villeins,  he  was  nevertheless 
one  of  the  lord's  bondmen.  An  instance  of 
the  first  kind  of  chevage  can  be  found  in 
the  account  of  the  manor  of  Ansty  for  the  year 
2  &  3  Henry  IV.,  which  is  printed  at  })age 
521  of  Cunningham's  Growth  of  English 
History  mid  Commerce,  ed.  1890.  The 
amount  paid  for  licence  to  leave  the  manor  for 
a  time  is  one  shilling  in  one  case,  and  sixpence 
in  another.  But  in  many  manorial  accounts 
an  enti-y  can  be  found  of  the  chevage  of  a  whole 
manor,  and  it  is  probable  that  if  this  meant  a 
payment  for  leave  to  remain  off  the  manor,  the 
name  of  the  person  making  the  payment  would 
have  been  given.  It  is  not  possible  to  speak 
definitely  on  the  point.  Britton  clearly 
suggests  the  existence  of  a  class  of  villeins  out- 
side the  land  organisation  of  the  manor,  and, 
from  a  comparison  of  his  account  with  Bracton's, 
it  would  appear  that  the  class  of  villeins  not 
included  in  the  manor  as  landholders  grew  up 
in  the  time  which  elapsed  between  the  two 
writers.    (See  Villanus.) 

In  the  court  rolls  of  some  manors  the  word 
occurs  in  yet  another  sense.  Strictly  speaking 
all  the  villein  tenants  of  a  manor  were  bound 
to  appear  at  the  manorial  court  to  assist  in  the 
decision  of  the  matters  discussed  there.  But 
in  some  manors  a  kind  of  representative  system 
was  in  use,  under  which  each  tithing  or  group 
of  tenants  was  represented  at  the  court  by  its 
chief  man  ;  and  for  this  privilege  of  attending 
the  manor  court  by  deputy  a  payment  at  the 
opening  of  each  court  was  made  to  the  lord  ;  to 
which  the  name  of  chevage  is  sometimes  given. 

For  instance  in  the  court  roll  of  the  manor  of 
Hemingford  printed  at  page  88  of  Prof.  Maitland's 
Select   Pleas  of  Manorial    Courts,   the    persons 


who  attend  the  court  give  as  chevage  13s.  4d 
Other  instances  of  this  payment  are  given  in  the 
same  book.  The  poll-tax  paid  by  the  Jews  before 
their  expulsion  from  England  was  sometimes  also 
called  chevage. 

[Bracton,  De  Legibus  Anglice  (Rolls  Series, 
1878).— Britton,  edited  by  F.  M.  Nicholls,  1865. 
— Select  Pleas  in  Manorial  Courts,  vol.  i.  edited  by 
F.  M.  Maitland  (Selden  Society),  1^%%.— Growth 
of  English  Industry  and  Commerce,  Cunningham, 
1890.]  c.  G.  c. 

CHEVALIER,  Michel,  born  at  Limoges 
1806,  died  at  the  Chateau  de  Montj)laisir  near 
Lodeve  (Herault)  1879.  Having  distinguished 
himself  at  the  polytechnic  school,  he  commenced 
life  in  the  departevient  du  nord  as  a  mining 
engineer,  a  post  which  he  gave  up  in  1829  to 
join  Saint-Simonism  (q.v.)  His  style,  the 
brilliancy  of  which  was  early  recognised,  won 
for  him  the  position  of  editor-in-chief  of  the 
Globe,  the  organ  of  that  school  of  socialism  of 
which  he  rapidly  became  one  of  the  most  active 
and  influential  members.  Faithful,  through 
the  troubles  which  ensued,  to  the  Saint-Simonian 
faith,  he  was  condemned,  28th  August  1832,  to 
a  year's  imprisonment  and  one  hundred  francs 
(£4)  fine,  as  the  responsible  agent  of  the  Globe, 
in  which  articles  appeared  which  were  accused 
of  being  outrages  on  public  morality.  His  in- 
tentions were  worthy,  and  his  habits  of  life  more 
strict  than  appearances  would  have  led  the  world 
to  suppose  ;  hence  the  government  itself,  which 
discovered  at  this  time  M.  Chevalier's  abilities, 
remitted  half  the  penalty,  and  also  entrusted 
to  him  the  mission  of  studying  the  railways  of 
the  United  States.  It  is  enough  to  say  of  the 
labours  of  our  economist  in  this  direction  that  in 
a  memoir  entitled  the  Systhne  de  la  MMiteri-anee 
(1832,  in  8vo),  he  foresaw  with  rare  intelligence 
the  future  of  these  new  methods  of  communica- 
tion. He  sent  from  America  to  the  Journal  des 
D6hats,  which  had  taken  him  on  its  staff  even 
while  he  was  in  prison,  articles  which,  pub- 
lished in  two  volumes,  furnish  a  collection 
of  the  highest  value,  even  after  the  lapse  of 
fifty  years  —  the  Lettres  sur  VAmdrique  du 
nord  (2  vols,  in  8vo,  1836).  He  commenced 
also  at  this  date  to  write  in  the  Remie  des 
Deux  Mondes.  Soon  after  his  return  from 
America  he  published,  as  the  result  of  his 
mission,  the  Histoire  et  Description  des  voies  de 
cmnmunication  aux  J^tats-Unis  et  des  Travaux 
qui  en  dependent  (1840,  2  vols,  in  4to),  with 
an  atlas  in  folio. 

His  pen,  from  this  date,  was  able  to  render 
aU  the  subjects  which  it  treated  interesting  ; 
but  his  judgment,  especially  on  its  economic  side, 
only  formed  itself  into  shape  gi-adually.  The 
successive  stages  through  which  he  passed  are 
all  the  more  obvious  in  his  writings,  as  with  a 
rare  sincerity,  he  never  sought  to  cloak  them 
from  view.  A  volume  in  18mo,  Des  Int^rSts 
mat^riels  en  France, — on  public  works,  roads, 
canals,  railways, — appeared  in  1838,  bringing 


276 


CHEVALIE] 


ioto  one  series  those  articles  of  his  which  had 
appeared  before  on  these  different  subjects. 
M.  Chevalier  intended  to  have  completed 
this  volume,  which  put  forward  a  kind  of 
economic  programme,  by  adding  to  it  two 
other  parts ,  credit  institutions  and  those 
which  supply  professional  education.  This 
idea,  unfortunately,  was  never  realised.  De- 
voted to  peace,  he  opposed,  in  a  pamphlet 
addressed  to  M.  Mole,  the  fortifications  of 
Paris.  He  replaced,  1841,  Rossi  at  the  College 
de  France  in  the  chair  of  political  economy. 
The  lectures  of  the  two  first  years,  taken  down 
in  shorthand  by  one  of  his  pupils,  Michel 
Broet,  form  the  material  of  two  volumes  in 
8vo,  which  appeared  in  1842  and  1844  (1st  ed.), 
and  in  1855  and  1856  (2d  ed.)  One  can  see, 
by  reading  each  volume  alternatively  in  the 
first  and  the  second  editions,  what  the  modi- 
fications were  which  the  judgment  of  the  author 
passed  through,  gradually  and  almost  uncon- 
sciously, as  the  years  of  his  professional  work 
went  by. 

Thus,  to  quote  only  one  example,  freedom  of 
competition  at  first  inspired  him  with  alarm, 
and  caused  him  to  advocate  reservations,  the 
necessity  of  which  he  no  longer  felt  in  1855 
and  1856.  We  may  add  that  in  1850  a  third 
volume  of  his  lectures  appeared,  of  which  a 
second  edition  was  published  in  1866.  The 
subject  was  La  Monnaie ;  the  work  is  full  of 
technical  details  of  the  highest  interest,  and 
written  with  a  masterly  hand.  In  1845  he 
was  elected  a  deputy  by  the  department  of 
I'Aveyron  ;  but  his  resolute  acceptance  of  the 
principle  of  free  trade  hindered  him  from  being 
re-elected  the  next  year. 

The  Revolution  of  1848,  which  Chevalier 
submitted  to  rather  than  joined,  found  him  none 
the  less  disposed  to  combat  courageously,  step 
by  step,  the  socialistic  errors  which  triumphed  at 
the  Luxembourg  in  the  Commission  du  gouverne- 
mentpour  les  travailleurs,  presided  over  by  Louis 
Blanc.  He  wrote  at  that  time  in  the  Journal 
des  Dihats  a  series  of  letters  called  Lettres  sur 
V organisation  du  travail,  which,  collected  under 
this  title,  form  a  stout  volume  in  18mo.  This 
and  the  Lettres  sur  VAmirique  du  nord,  may  be 
considered  as  the  most  characteristic  and  remark- 
able works  of  this  author.  The  result  of  the 
appearance  of  these  letters,  written  off-hand, 
and  under  the  pressure  of  the  events  which  were 
happening  around  him,  was  a  decree  from  the 
government  suspending  him  from  lecturing  at 
the  College  de  France.  The  AssembUe  constitu- 
■ante  annulled  this  decree  the  December  following, 
and  Michel  Chevalier  was  able  to  return  to  his 
chair. 

The  Institut  {Acadimie  des  Sciences  morales 
et  politiques)  opened  its  doors  to  him  February 
1851.  At  the  end  of  that  year  he  gave  in  his 
adhesion  to  the  government  of  the  Coup  d'etat, 
following  in  this  rather  his  judgment  than  his 


inclination.  He  believed  liberty  to  be  more  in 
peril  under  the  class  of  parliamentary  govern- 
ment of  which  he  had  seen  the  working,  than 
under  a  personal  government.  Called  to  the 
council  of  state  February  1852,  he  had  to  ask  for 
a  substitute  to  give  in  his  stead  his  course  of 
lectures  at  the  College  de  France.  It  was  M. 
Henri  Baudrillart  who  undertook  this  duty 
for  him.  At  the  same  date  M.  Chevalier 
published  the  Mmvun  du  syst^me  commercial 
connu  sous  le  nom  de  syst^me  protecteur  (in  8vo. ), 
a  work  in  which  protectionism  was  demolished 
completely,  and  the  advantage  of  commercial 
liberty  shown. 

Immediately  after  this  he  rendered  the  last- 
named  cause  a  service  of  a  very  different  char- 
acter. Holding  as  he  did  the  same  opinions  as 
Richard  Cobden,  whom  he  presented  in  1859  to 
the  emperor,  he  induced  Napoleon  III.  to  sign 
the  famous  commercial  treaty  with  England  of 
23d  January  1860,  which  was  the  precursor 
of  the  French  treaty  of  1'861  with  Belgium,  of 
1862  with  the  ZoUverein,  of  1863  with  Italy,  of 
1864  with  Switzerland,  of  1865  with  Sweden 
and  Norway,  the  free  cities  of  Bremen,  Lubeck, 
and  Hamburg,  and  the  grand -duchies  of 
Mecklenburg -Schwerin,  Strelitz,  and  Holland, 
of  1866  Vith  Portugal,  then  with  Austria, 
and  finally  of  1866  with  the  pontifical  states. 
These  treaties  introduced,  so  to  say,  free  trade 
into  the  public  international  law  of  Europe. 
But  this  system  is  at  the  present  time  destroyed 
in  France,  where  protectionism  has  struck  its 
roots  afresh,  and  causes  all  consumers  to 
pay  toll  for  the  advantage  of  the  privileged 
producers. 

In  1859  Michel  Chevalier  published  a  new 
volume  with  the  significant  title,  De  la  baisse 
probable  de  I'or  (in  8vo).  It  was  translated  into 
English  by  Cobden  in  the  same  year.  Facts, 
as  is  well  known,  have  shown  he  was  wrong  in 
his  opinion  on  this  point. 

He  strove  later  against  Louis  Wolowski  in 
favour  of  the  single  standard  (gold,  this  time) 
against  the  system  of  a  double  standard  com- 
bined with  a  fixed  ratio.  The  question  of  the 
banks  became  also  in  his  hands  the  occasion 
for  a  vigorous  contest.  Wolowski  strove  for 
the  unity  of  banks,  Michel  Chevalier  for  their 
duality  (1864).  He  resumed  his  duties  as 
professor  in  1866,  and  carried  them  on  till 
1878,  when  he  took  afresh  a  coadjutor,  this 
time  one  of  his  sons-in-law,  M.  Paul  Leroy- 
Beaulieu,  who  was  destined,  after  his  death, 
to  become  his  successor. 

A  strong  supporter  of  exhibitions,  especially 
of  universal  exhibitions,  he  wrote  a  brilliant 
introduction,  in  8vo,  to  the  reports  of  several 
juries  of  the  magnificent  industiial  and  inter- 
national/^te  which  took  place  at  Paris  in  1867. 

This  economist,  though  his  natural  predilee- 
tions  for  the  less  rigid  side  of  economic  science 
were  too  strongly  marked,  is  justly  reckoned 


CHICKERINQ— CHILDREN'S  LABOUR 


277 


on  account  of  his  strictly  scientinc  exactness, 
his  brilliant  style,  and  the  depth  of  his  views, 
among  the  highest  of  his  class  in  France.  His 
pen  was  most  fertile,  but  we  have  only  thought 
it  needful  to  enumerate  above  his  chief  works. 

A.  c.  f. 
CHIOKERING,  Jesse,  M.D.,  born  in  New 
Hampshire  1797  ;  entered  the  Unitarian  minis- 
try, then  practised  medicine,  and  died  in  West 
Roxbury,  Massachusetts,  1855.  He  was  in- 
terested in  statistical  inquiries  and  published 
A  Statistical  View  of  the  Population  of  Massa- 
chusetts, from  1765  to  I84O,  Boston,  1846, 
pp.  160  ; — Immigration  into  the  United  States, 
Boston,  1848,  pp.  94,  in  which  he  questions 
whether  too  much  encouragement  has  not  been 
given  to  immigration  to  the  United  States  ; 
and  also  Comparative  View  of  tM  Population  of 
Boston  in  1850,  ivith  the  Births,  Marriages, 
and  Deaths,  in  1849  and  1850,  Boston,  1851, 
pp.  7-58.  D.  R.  D. 

CHIEF  RENT.  See  Rent-Charge. 
CHILD,  Sir  Josiah  (born  1630,  died  1699), 
the  chairman,  and  virtually  the  ruler,  of  the  East 
India  Company  for  some  years.  He  aimed  at 
aggrandising  the  Company  by  extending  its 
political  power,  and  restraining  competition 
with  its  trade.  Several  anonymous  Avritings  in 
defence  of  the  Company  are  attributed  to  Child. 
Under  the  sobriquet  ^tXoTrdrpts  (sic)  (1681)  he 
maintains  that  "the  clamours,  aspersions,  and 
objections  made  against  the  present  East  India 
Company  are  sinister,  selfish,  or  gi'oundless, " 
While  contending  that  "the  trade  of  the  East  j 
Indies  cannot  be  carried  on  to  a  national  advan- 
tage in  any  other  way  than  by  a  joint  stock,"  he 
enumerates  many  enlightened  principles,  as  that 
"silver  and  gold,  coined  or  uncoined,  though 
they  are  used  as  a  measure  of  all  other  things, 
are  no  less  a  commodity  than  wine,  oil,  tobacco, 
cloth,  or  stutf,  and  may  in  many  cases  be 
exported  as  much  to  national  advantage  as 
any  other  commodity.  That  no  nation  ever 
was  or  will  be  considerable  in  trade  that  pro- 
hibits the  export  of  bullion."  In  the  Humble 
Answer  of  the  Governor  ...  to  a  Paper  of  Pro- 
positions for  Regulation  of  the  East  India  Com- 
pany .  .  .  (Somers's  Collection  of  Tracts,  vol. 
iii.),  "the  great  monopolist,"  as  Macaulay  says, 
"took  his  stand  on  the  principle  of  free  trade." 
Similar  antinomies,  as  they  appear  to  our  age, 
are  noticeable  in  Child's  principal  work,  the 
Discourse  itpon  Trade.  He  asserts  the  j)rinciple 
of  competition,  the  law  of  market,  thus  unequi- 
vocally :  "They  that  can  give  the  best  price 
for  a  commodity  shall  never  fail  to  have  it, 
by  one  means  or  another,  notwithstanding  the 
opposition  of  any  laws,  or  interposition  of  any 
power  by  sea  or  land  ;  of  such  force,  subtlety, 
and  violence  is  the  general  course  of  trade" 
(chap,  viii.)  Yet  the  panacea,  the."unum 
magnum,"  which  is  recommended  is  a  legalised 
rate  of  interest.     Child  admits,  with  regard  to 


the  navigation  laws,  that  unrestricted  commerce 
might  be  best  "if  the  present  profit  of  the 
generality  be  barely  and  singly  considered " ; 
but  holds  that  "  profit  and  power  ought  joyntly 
to  be  considered  "  (chap,  iv.)  (This  was  also 
his  contention.)  He^  considers  that  the  doe- 
trine  of  the  balance  of  trade  does  not  apply 
to  the  trade  with  East  India,  "both  in  point 
of  strength  and  warlike  provisions,  in  regard 
of  shij^ping  and  saltpetre,  but  [and]  also  in 
respect  of  the  furtherance  it  gives  to  many 
other  trades,"  by  means  of  which  England 
regains  more  specie  than  the  company  exports 
(chap,  ix.)  But  the  trade  with  Venice  in 
"currance  purchased  with  our  ready  money" 
is  to  be  discouraged.  "Concerning  plantations" 
(chap.  X.),  Child  argues,  in  a  manner  worthy 
of  Malthus,  that  the  colonies  have  not  caused 
the  depopulation  of  the  kingdom.  It  is  a  more 
disputable  proposition  that  "most  nations  in 
the  civilised  parts  of  the  world  are  more  or  less 
rich  or  poor  proportionable  to  the  paucity  or 
plenty  of  their  people."  Equally  instructive  is 
Cliild's  scheme  for  the  relief  and  employment  of 
the  poor  (chap,  ii.)  There  is  a  spirited  criti- 
cism of  this  scheme  in  Eden's  State  of  the  Poor. 

The  first  draft  of  this  work  was  published  in 
1668.  The  original  title  appears  to  have  been 
Brief  Observations  Concerning  Trade  and  Interest 
of  Money  (British  Museum  Library  ^^^),  This 
tract  was  reissued  in  a  later  edition,  together 
with  a  preface  and  ten  additional  chapters  ;  the 
whole  work  being  designated  by  the  title  The 
New  Discourse  of  Trade. 

[Macaulay's  History  of  England,  vol.  iv. — R. 
Grant's  Sketch  of  the  History  of  the  East  India 
Company. — Macpherson's  History  of  Covimerce., 
vol.  ii.]  F.  Y.  E. 

CHILDREN'S  LABOUR  (Factory  Acts). 
Few  records  exist  anterior  to  the  rise  of  the 
factory  system  which  throw  light  upon  the 
conditions  attending  the  labour  of  children. 
Lord  ]\Iacaulay  {History  of  England,  ch.  iii.), 
states  that  in  the  17th  century,  the  practice  of 
setting  children  to  work  prematurely  existed 
"to  an  extent  which,  Avhen  compared  with  the 
extent  of  the  manufacturing  system,  seems  al- 
most incredible.  At  Norwich,  the  chief  seat  of 
the  clothing  trade,  a  little  creature  of  six  years 
old  was  thouglit  fit  to  labour."  In  1677,  a 
Worcestershire  ironmaster,  Andrew  Yarranton, 
published  a  pamphlet  entitled  "England's  Im- 
})rovement  by  Land  and  Sea,"  in  which  the 
schools  then  existing  "in  all  the  towns  of 
Germany,"  for  the  purpose  of  training  girls 
in  the  art  of  spinning  linen,  are  described 
Children  of  six  years  old  and  upwards  were, 
sometimes  to  the  number  of  two  hundred  in 
a  single  room,  systematically  employed  in  this 
industry,  producing  large  quantities  of  excellent 
yarn.  The  writer  lu-ged  that  efforts  should  be 
'made  to  follow  the  German  plan  in  England, 
especially  in  the  counties  of  Warwick,  Leicester 


278 


CHILDREN'S  LABOUR 


Northampton  and  Oxford.  His  advice  was,  how- 
ever, not  adopted.  About  the  beginning  of  the 
1 7th  century  the  manufacture  of  lace  by  machin- 
ery was  introduced  into  this  country  by  refugees 
from  the  Continent.  In  Bedfordshire  and  Buck- 
inghamshire, schools  were  established  for  teach- 
ing the  art  to  young  children  (Felkin's  ISistory 
of  Machine-  Wrought  Hosiery  and  Lace  Manu- 
factures, 1867).  But  throughout  the  greater 
part  of  that  century  the  manufacture  of  textile 
fabrics  was  mainly  a  domestic  industry,  and  the 
children  of  the  household  were  compelled  to 
labour  long  and  hard.  Dr.  Cooke  Taylor  {Silk, 
Cotton,  and  Woollen  Manufacture)  holds  that 
the  system  of  overworJcing  children  "  was  at  its 
worst  and  greatest  height  long  before  anybody 
thought  of  a  factory."  Probably  the  most  com- 
prehensive account  of  the  employment  of  juvenile 
labour  in  productive  industry  before  the  rise  of 
the  factory  system  is  to  be  found  in  Mr.  R. 
Whateley  Cooke  Taylor's  Introduction  to  a  His- 
tory of  the  Factory  System. 

The  latter  half  of  the  18th  century  witnessed 
a  number  of  remarkable  inventions,  each  of 
which  aided  in  the  establishment  and  spread  of 
that  highly  organised  method  of  industry  known 
as  the  factory  system.  The  discovery  of  the 
spinning  machine,  of  the  mechanical  loom,  of 
the  steam  engine,  of  the  cotton  gin,  of  the 
calico-printing  machine,  and  of  coal  gas  for 
illuminating  purposes,  successively  tended  to 
the  aggregation  of  workpeople  in  textile  manu- 
factories. They  aided  too  in  that  separation  of 
processes,  known  as  the  "division  of  labour," 
which  opened  the  way  for  an  extensive  employ- 
ment of  children  in  the  lighter  and  simpler  pro- 
cesses calling  rather  for  dexterity  than  strength. 
But  it  was  not  alone  in  the  textile  manufac- 
tures that  this  conversion  of  domestic  into  factory 
industry  was  going  on.  It  gradually  spread 
into  other  productive  departments.  Unquestion- 
ably, however,  it  was  in  the  textile  occupations 
that  the  growing  employment  of  infantile  labour, 
and  the  abuses  accompanying  it,  first  drew  public 
attention  to  the  necessity  of  factory  legislation. 
In  Lancashire  and  Derbyshire  the  rapid  increase 
of  the  cotton  manufacture  created  a  great  de- 
mand for  labour,  and  the  population  grew  faster 
than  the  means  of  decent  habitation.  There 
was  consequently  much  overcrowding,  and  the 
mills  themselves  were  unhealthy,  whilst  the 
labour  was  long  and  exhausting.  Large  num- 
bers of  pauper  children  were  brought  from 
southern  parishes,  where  the  local  authorities 
were  glad  to  get  rid  of  them,  and  the  accom- 
modation provided  for  these  young  and  over- 
(vorked  immigrants  was  very  defective.  The 
result  was  a  serious  epidemic  disease,  which  at 
the  close  of  last  century  wrought  great  havoc 
amongst  the  factory  population,  and  especially 
amongst  the  children.  In  1802,  therefore,  the 
first  factory  act  (the  Health  and  Morals  Act) 
was  passed.     However,  beyond  ordaining  some 


sanitary  regulations  of  a  general  kind,  the  act 
did  not  apply  to  others  besides  the  apprenticed 
children,  drawn  chiefly,  as  already  stated,  from 
distant  portions  of  the  country.  Children  ol 
families  living  near  the  factories  were  still  sub- 
ject to  oppressive  treatment,  their  parents  being 
as  a  rule  regardless  of  their  health.  The  need 
of  further  interference  being  demonstrated  by 
an  inquiry  conducted  by  parliament  in  1815- 
1816,  a  second  act  was  passed  in  1819,  but  its 
operation  was  confined  to  cotton  mills.  No 
child  might  begin  to  work  under  nine  years 
old,  and  between  that  limit  and  sixteen  years 
the  hours  of  labour  were  not  to  exceed  twelve 
per  day,  and  night  work  was  prohibited.  The 
next  act,  that  of  1825,  restricted  the  labour  of 
children  to  nine  hours  per  day,  and  these  were 
not  to  extend  beyond  five  o'clock  in  the  morn- 
ing and  half-past  four  in  the  afternoon.  Still 
further,  meal  hours  were  carefully  defined,  and 
employers  were,  for  the  first  time,  compelled  to 
keep  a  register  of  the  children  working  for 
them.  Then  came  the  early  days  of  the  trade 
unions,  which  were  marked  by  much  violence, 
the  issue  of  which  was  the  Act  of  1st  and  2d 
William  IV.  c.  39,  consolidating  and  improving 
previous  factory  acts,  but  without  afiecting  very 
seriously  the  status  of  children.  Later  on,  how- 
ever. Lord  Althorp's  Act  of  1833  defined  the 
ages  at  which  boys  and  girls  might  be  allowed 
to  work  in  factories  as  that  of  nine  years.  Be- 
tween that  age  and  thirteen  years  children  were 
to  work  only  nine  hours,  and  were  to  attend 
school  during  two  hours.  Thus  the  "half 
time"  system  was  introduced,  which  was  im- 
proved in  1844  by  Sir  Robert  Peel's  act.  That 
measure  provided  that  children  of  eight  (no 
longer  nine)  years  of  age  and  up  to  thirteen 
might  be  employed  for  six  and  a  half  hours 
only,  and  three  days'  attendance  at  school  pel 
week  was  required.  Afterwards  protective  legis- 
lation for  children  was  further  improved  and 
extended  by  the  Factory  Extension  Act,  and 
the  Workshop  Regulation  Act.  (1878  (Con- 
solidation) Factory  and  Workshop  Act.)  Not 
only  textile  and  other  factories  in  which  large 
numbers  of  workpeople  are  employed,  but  also 
small  industrial  establishments,  were  brought 
under  governmental  control.  The  regulations 
of  the  Workshops  Act  were  placed  under  the 
control  of  local  authorities.  The  intention 
was  to  ascertain  by  experiment  how  far  local 
control  might  prove  equal  or  superior  to  central 
administration.  Practically  the  act  was  ignored 
by  the  local  authorities,  and  further  legislation 
was  deemed  necessary.  This  has  tended  rather 
in  the  direction  of  extending  the  protection  of 
the  law  to  children  in  various  occupations  not 
coming  within  the  factory  system,  than  of  in- 
creasing the  restrictions  upon  the  employment « 
of  youthful  labour.  The  act  (1889)  for  the] 
prevention  of  cruelty  to  children  gave  to  those 
employed  in  theatrical  and  other  entertainments 


CHIMINAGE— CHREMATISTIC 


279 


the  benefit  of  the  factory  acts.  That  of  1904  i 
forbade  children  to  sing,  perform,  or  offer 
things  for  sale  in  any  public  place  without  a 
licence,  licences  being  only  granted  to  children 
over  10  and  under  stringent  conditions.  It 
forbids,  as  did  the  Children's  Dangerous  Per- 
formances Act,  1879  (amended  1897),  the  train- 
ing of  children  under  16  as  acrobats  or  for  any 
dangerous  performance.  The  act  1908  made 
the  punishments  for  misdemeanours  under  these 
headings  still  more  severe.  Similar  legislation 
has  been  gradually  adopted  in  foreign  countries. 
In  France,  the  desire  to  protect  young  children 
from  exhausting  labour  has  taken  practical  shape 
in  recent  enactments.  In  the  United  States 
labour  is  regulated  by  the  several  state  legis- 
latures. There  has  been  in  recent  years  a  steady 
tendency  in  several  states,  stimulated  by  the 
reports  of  the  various  "  bureaus  of  statistics 
of  labour,"  to  provide  for  the  protection  of 
children  employed  in  industry.  e.  h, 

CHIMINAGE.  Among  the  special  revenues 
arising  from  the  exceptional  position  of  forest 
land  was  a  toll  on  traffic  known  as  chiminage 
(Forests,  Medi/Eval).  The  law  naming 
those  from  whom  such  toll  could  be  taken,  and 
its  amount,  is  to  be  found  in  the  Charter  of 
the  Forest,  9  Henry  III.  §  14.  The  special 
mention  of  this  toll  suggests  that  it  had  been 
made  an  excuse  for  unreasonable  exaction  before 
the  issue  of  the  charter.  Under  the  law  so 
settled  no  forester  is  allowed  to  take  chiminage 
unless  he  holds  his  office  in  fee  by  the  payment 
of  a  rent  for  it ;  no  persons  but  those  who  come 
into  the  forest  to  buy  brushwood,  timber,  or  char- 
coal to  sell  again  are  to  be  liable  to  pay  the  toll ; 
and  all  other  travellers  and  even  those  who  came 
to  fetch  away  brushwood  on  their  own  backs 
without  the  use  of  beasts  or  carts  were  to  pass 
free.  The  amount  of  the  toll  was  fixed  at  two- 
pence for  each  cart  for  each  half-year,  and  one 
halfpenny  for  each  horse.  The  toll  so  limited 
seems  to  have  formed  no  grievance,  and  its 
amount  is  usually  unimportant.  For  instance  in 
Sherwood  forest  in  the  15tli  century  the  chimin- 
age is  farmed  out  at  6s.  8d.  a  year.  The  word 
is  sometimes  used  for  any  toU  paid  for  passing 
along  a  road. 

[Manwood's  Forest  Law  (4th  ed.),  1717. — 
Records  of  the  Borough  of  Nottingham^  vol.  ii., 
1883. — Dr.  Murray's  New  English  Dictionary^  s.v., 
1889.]  CO.  c. 

CHITTI,  LuiGi,  by  birth  an  Italian,  passed 
the  greatest  part  of  his  life  abroad  ;  tlds  ex- 
plains how  he  came  to  write  his  books  always 
in  French.  In  1833  he  published  a  Cours 
d'^conomie  politiqtce  and  in  1839  at  Brussels, 
a  pamphlet — Des  crises financieres  et  de  la  r6forme 
du  Systhme  MovAtaire.  He  had  occasion  to  ob- 
serve a  very  severe  monetary  crisis  in  Belgium, 
the  origin  of  which  he  assigns  to  excessive 
emissions  of  paper  money.  He  proposes  the 
gradual  abolition  of  metallic  money,  substitut- 


ing paper  money  for  it,  which,  if  only  not 
superabundant,  cannot  become  depreciated,  a 
doctrine  which  is  clearly  taken  from  Ricardo's 
Reply  to  Mr.  Bosanquet.  Chitti  proves  himself 
to  be  well  versed  in  questions  of  capital,  credit, 
money,  exchange,  but  is  no  original  thinker. 

M.  p. 

CHOROGRAM.  "A  chorogram  is  the 
result  when  different  aggregates  are  indicated  by 
surfaces,  showing  the  size  of  each,  and  portions 
of  the  surface  are  coloured  or  shaded  differently 
to  indicate  the  result  of  the  enumeration  in 
each  aggregate.  It  can  be  profitably  employed 
to  show  the  different  degrees  of  the  occurrence 
of  a  single  phenomenon  in  different  aggregates." 

^Annals  of  the  American  Academy,  Supplement 
May  1891,  '*  The  History,  Theory,  aud  Technique 
of  Statistics,"  by  A.  Meitzen.] 

(See  Graphical  Method.) 

CHOSES  IN  ACTION.  The  term  applied 
by  early  lawyers  to  rights  of  action. 

Choses  in  action  were  not  at  common  law 
assignable  except  in  the  case  of  bills  of  exchange 
and  other  negotiable  instruments  which  by  the 
custom  of  merchants  were  assignable  by  indorse- 
ment and  delivery  of  the  bills.  In  the  reign 
of  Henry  VIII.  it  was  held  that  a  chose  in 
action  might  be  assigned  as  satisfaction  for  a 
debt,  the  assignee  to  sue  if  necessary  in  the 
assignor's  name.  Afterwards  by  various  statutes 
promissory  notes,  bills  of  lading,  and  life  and 
sea  policies  of  assurance  were  made  assignable, 
but  it  was  not  until  the  36  &  37  Vict.  c.  QQ, 

25  (6),  that  it  was  provided  generally  that  a 
chose  in  action  may  be  assigned.  The 
assignment  must  be  in  Avriting,  and  notice  of 
the  assignment  has  to  be  given  to  the  person 
liable  to  pay  the  debt. 

A  right  of  action  conferred  by  a  suit  in  equity 
was  always  assignable  in  equity. 

[Principles  of  the  Law  of  Personal  Property ^  by 
J.  Williams,  London,  1887.]  J.  e.  c.  M. 

CHOSES  IN  POSSESSION.  Movable 
tangible  property,  as  opposed  to  rights  of  action 
which  are  called  choses  in  action.  Property  of 
this  nature  could  not  at  common  law  be  held 
by  estates  though  settlements  were  always 
enforced  in  equity.  As  compared  with  real 
property,  choses  in  possession  descend  to  the 
administrator  or  executor,  and  not  to  the  heir, 
but  title  deeds,  heirlooms,  fixtures  and  chattels 
vegetable  are  exceptions  to  the  rule,  as  they 
partake  of  the  nature  of  real  property. 

[Williams's  Personal  Property,  London,  1887.] 

J.  E.  0.  M. 

CHREMATISTIC  (or  Money- making).  The 
locus  classicus  on  chrematistic  is  in  the  Politics 
of  Aristotle,  bk.  i.  ch.  viii.  -xi.  The  passage  is 
somewhat  obscure,  from  the  nice  distinctions 
dwelt  on  ;  but  the  general  purport  is  that  there 
are  two  sorts  of  chrematistic — one  natural  and 
necessary,  being  the  art  of  acquiring  the  material 
resources  to  be  placed  at  the  disposal  of,  and 


280 


CHRISTIAN  SOCIALISM— CHRISTIANITY  AND  ECONOMICS 


used  by,  the  higher  art  of  economic,  of  which 
this  kind  of  chrematistic  is  the  handmaid, 
whilst  the  other  sort  is  devoted  to  the  unlimited 
pursuit  of  gain  for  its  own  sake,  without  rela- 
tion to  the  real  wants  of  the  household  or  the 
community.  The  word  is  now  usually  applied  to 
systems  of  theoretical  or  practical  economy  which 
overlook  the  higher  ends  of  society,  and  exclude 
from  consideration  questions  of  moral  obliga- 
tion and  political  well-being  (see  Akistotle). 

J.  K.  I. 

CHRISTIAN  SOCIALISM  is  a  name  which 
properly  belongs  to  the  propagation  of  co- 
operative production  or  working  men's  associa- 
tions by  F.  D.  Maurice  and  his  disciples  in  the 
years  1849  to  1853.  For  its  use  merely  as  a 
name  for  socialism  inspired  by  Christian  motives 
see  Socialism.  Its  origin  is  to  be  found  in  a 
letter  from  J.  M.  Ludlow  to  Maurice  (March  184  8) 
saying  that  the  socialism  of  Paris  workmen  was 
a  real  power  which  would  shake  Christianity  if  it 
were  not  Christianised.  After  the  publication 
of  Henry  Mayhew's  letters  on  the  London  poor 
in  the  Morning  Chronicle,  in  1849,  Maurice  and 
his  followers  at  Lincoln's  Inn,  who  had  already 
been  trying  to  persuade  the  Chartists,  in  Politics 
for  the  People  (6th  May  to  29th  July  1848),  and 
in  discussions  at  the  Cranbourne  Tavern,  that 
moral  and  sanitary  reform  were  of  much  more 
importance  than  extension  of  the  suffrage, 
turned  their  attention  to  economic  questions. 
They  were  led  to  deny  any  beneficence  to  the 
operation  of  self-interest.  *  *  Free  competition, ' ' 
said  Ludlow,  "mars  everywhere,  instead  of 
making,  the  wisest  distribution  of  labour" 
{Christian  Socialism,  p.  35).  "We  have  pro- 
tested," Maurice  wrote  to  Dr.  Jelf,  12th  Nov- 
ember 1851,  "against  the  spirit  of  competition 
and  rivalry  precisely  because  we  believe  it  is 
leading  to  anarchy,  and  must  destroy  at  last  the 
property  of  the  rich  as  well  as  the  existence  of 
the  poor  "  {Life,  ch.  ii.  p.  83).  As  a  remedy  they 
proposed  "Christian  Socialism,"  or  friendly 
association  for  productive  purposes.  They 
sometimes  went  so  far  as  to  imagine  a  state  of 
things  in  which  all  producers  might  "combine 
regularly  into  one  body  which  should,  after 
mutual  explanations  and  by  mutual  concert,  fix 
the  terms  upon  which  each  member  should  dis- 
pose of  his  wares  to  the  others"  (Ludlow, 
Christian  Socialism,  p.  35)  ;  but  they  suggested 
no  principle  of  distribution  on  which  this 
agreement  should  be  based.  They  founded  an 
association  of  tailors  (February  1850)  of  which 
Walter  Cooper,  formerly  a  Chartist,  was  manager, 
and  organised  a  society  for  promoting  working 
men's  associations  under  a  council  of  promoters 
among  whom  were  Maurice,  Charles  Kingsley, 
T.  Hughes,  E.  V.  Neale,  and  F.  J.  Fumivall. 
Alton  Locke,  which  represents  the  ethical  side 
of  the  Christian  Socialist  doctrine,  was  pub- 
lished early  in  1850,  and  was  followed  by 
Tracts  on  Christian  Socialism,  Tracts  by  Chris- 


tian Socialists,  and  the  Christian  Socialist,  a 
weekly  penny  paper  which  lasted  from  2d 
November  1850  to  the  end  of  1851.  Its  place 
was  then  taken  by  the  Journal  of  Association, 
which  endured  tHl  28th  June  1852.  The 
evidence  of  the  "Promoters"  before  Slaney's 
Committee  of  the  House  of  Commons  on  "In- 
vestments for  the  savings  of  the  middle  and 
working  classes"  in  1850,  aided  in  bringing 
about  the  legalisation  of  co-operative  societies 
by  the  "  Industrial  and  Provident  Partnerships 
Act"  of  1852.  After  the  passing  of  that  Act 
the  society  for  promoting  associations  was  re- 
modelled and  the  term  "Christian  Socialism," 
as  employed  in  this  connection,  was  abandoned. 
It  was  oftensive  alike  to  theologians,  economists, 
and  socialists.  The  hostility  displayed  towards 
the  Christian  Socialists  in  many  quarters  was 
more  due  to  the  name  they  assumed,  and  to  the 
vehemence  with  which  Kingsley  denounced  com- 
petition, than  to  dislike  of  their  Associations, 
though  these  were  doubtless  looked  on  with 
some  suspicion  as  copies  from  French  models 
(see  Co-operation.  For  recent  history  see 
Socialism,  Appendix). 

[F.  Maurice,  Life  of  Frederick  Denison  Maurice, 
2  vols.,  2d.  ed.,  1884.— T.  Hughes,  Prefatory 
Memoir  in  the  Eversley  ed.  of  Alton  Locke,  2  vols., 
1881. — L.  TBrentano,  Die  christlich  -  soziale  Be- 
loegung  in  England,  2  Aufl.,  Leipzig,  1883,  con- 
taining bibliography,  pp.  75-78. — J.  M.  Ludlow, 
Christian  Socialism  and  its  Opponents,  1851.: — 
Abp.  Benson,  Fishers  of  Men,  1894.— Dr.  E.  W. 
Donald,  The  Expansion  of  Religion,  1896. — Bp. 
Chas.  Gore,  The  Mission  of  the  Church,  1892.]  e.c. 

CHRISTIANITY  AND  ECONOMICS 

Church,  the  Mediaeval,  Economic  Influence  of,  p.  280 ; 
Roman  Catholic  School  of  Economics,  p.  283  ;  Influ- 
ence of  Protestant  Thought  on  Economic  Opinion 
and  Practice,  p.  285. 

CHURCH,  The  Medieval,  Economic 
Influence  of.  The  following  article  is  not 
concerned  with  the  origin  of  church  property 
or  the  title  by  which  it  is  held — subjects  which 
belong  rather  to  the  historian  or  the  jurist  than 
to  the  economist ; — it  is  limited  to  two  points  : 
the  influence  of  the  church  upon  social  ranks, 
and  the  influence,  chiefly  in  England,  of  church- 
men and  ecclesiastical  bodies,  as  landowners, 
upon  agriculture. 

1.  If  it  be  true  that  the  mediaeval  church 
was  always  the  great  leveller,  that  the  clerical 
order  was  the  one  profession  in  which  it  was 
possible  for  a  man  of  the  humblest  birth  to 
attain  to  the  highest  position,  this  was  less  by 
virtue  of  express  enactment  than  in  consequence 
of  the  facts,  {a)  that  the  church  remained  free 
from  the  distinctions  of  classes  that  grew  up  in 
the  civil  state,  and  (&)  that  the  churchman,  as 
the  rule  of  celibacy  became  universally  accepted 
in  Latin  Christendom,  could  be  raised  to  any 
rank  without  the  drawback  of  his  founding  a 
family  of  nobles.  The  possibility  of  rising  was, 
it  is  true,  not  confined  to  churchmen  :  but  thai 


CHRISTIANITY  AND  ECONOMICS— THE  MEDIEVAL  CHURCH       281 


which  was  the  exception  among  the  laity  was 
common  among  the  clergy  ;  and  in  one  import- 
ant point,  with  respect  to  slavery,  the  exemp- 
tion of  the  clerical  status  from  the  classes  of 
civil  society  produced  a  remarkable  relaxation 
of  class  conditions. 

It  was  not,  however,  for  many  centuries  that 
it  became  the  accepted  doctrine  that  an 
ordained  person  was  ipso  facto  a  free  man.  At 
first  the  only  question  that  arose  was  that, 
when  a  slave  was  ordained  or  received  into  a 
monastery,  his  lord  was  robbed  of  his  service. 
Accordingly,  by  a  number  of  ordinances  con- 
tained in  the  civil  law  {Cod.  i.  tit.  iii.  37 ; 
Novell.  V.  2,  cxxiii.  35),  and  reinforced  by 
ecclesiastical  decrees  which  became  incorporated 
in  the  canon  law,  it  was  repeatedly  laid  down 
that  no  bishop  should  ordain  a  slave  without 
the  consent  of  his  lord.  The  rule  was  not 
merely  intended  to  protect  the  lord's  rights  :  it 
was  found  also  that  slaves  guilty  of  crime 
availed  themselves  of  the  refuge  alforded  by 
holy  orders  or  admission  to  a  monastery  to 
escape  punishment ;  and  churchmen  on  their 
side — St.  Leo  the  Great  is  a  prominent  instance 
— objected  to  the  clerical  profession  being 
"defiled  by  the  baseness  of  association"  with 
slaves  {Can.  apost.  Ixxxi.  (cp.  Cone.  Chalced. 
A.D.  451,  can.  iv.)  ;  Leo  1.  Epist.  iv.  1). 

If,  however,  in  the  fifth  century  it  could  be 
conceived  as  possible  that  a  man  might  be  a 
clergyman  and  yet  a  slave,  this  idea  early  gave 
way  before  another  which  presumed  that  if  a 
slave  were  ordained  with  the  knowledge  of  his 
lord,  and  without  any  objection  raised  by  him, 
he  was  a  free  man,  though  not  formally  manu- 
mitted. It  was  still,  however,  conceded  that 
supposing  the  lord  were  not  aware  of  the  act, 
he  had  a  right  to  claim  his  slave  within  the 
space  of  a  year :  and  that  ordination  did  not 
for  a  long  time  involve  of  itself  emancipation 
is  shown  by  the  enactments  in  the  civil  law, 
that,  supposing  an  ordained  slave  retm-ns  to 
secular  pursuits,  his  lord  may  claim  him  ;  and 
that  it  was  lawful  to  ordain  a  bondman  bound 
to  the  soil  on  his  lord's  land  even  without  his 
lord's  consent,  so  long  as  he  continued  to  fulfil 
his  servile  duties  {Novell,  cxxiii.  17).  This 
latter  rule  was  soon  modified  by  the  provision 
that  the  ordained  person  might  perform  his 
services  by  a  deputy  {Novell.,  I.e.  ;  cp.  gloss,  in 
God.  i.  tit.  iii.  37) — an  arrangement  which 
was  accepted  by  ecclesiastical  authority  ;  but  on 
this  side  it  was  maintained  that  in  no  case 
could  a  man  in  priest's  orders  be  claimed  back 
as  a  slave  (Gelas.  I.,  epistt.  in  Deer.  Grat.,  dist. 
liv.  9-11). 

So  far,  therefore,  it  appears  that  it  was  the 
lord's  assent,  express  or  implicit,  which  made 
the  clerk  free  ;  that,  failing  such  assent,  the 
lord  was  compensated  by  substituted  service  ; 
and  that  a  distinction  made  itself  felt  between  ' 
priest's  orders  and  the  inferior  degi-ees  which 


admitted  a  very  large  and  heterogeneous  com- 
pany of  ordained  persons  to  ecclesiastical 
privileges.  It  was  unquestionably  the  admis- 
sion of  slaves  to  the  lower  orders  which  led  to 
the  gi-avest  abuses  ;  and  the  prohibition  of  the 
ordination  of  slaves  without  their  lord's  consent, 
which  is  repeated  through  Frankish  times, 
(Karol.  Magn.  Admon.  gen.  (a.  789),  cap.  Ivii. 
(cp.  cap.  xxiii.)  ;  Hludow.  Pii,  Capit.  eccl.  (a. 
818-819),  cap.  vi.),  and  of  which  a  famous 
instance  occurs  in  the  sixteenth  constitution-  of 
Clarendon  {Const.  Clar.  xvi.,  c]).  Stubbs,  Sel, 
Charters  {ed.  5, 1884),  p.  137  ;  Assis.  Clar.  xx.i), 
was  directed  principally  against  this  practice. 
Not  merely  were  the  lord's  rights  infringed,  but 
persons  of  suspicious  character  were  able  to 
remove  themselves  from  the  ordinary  jurisdic- 
tion of  the  country.  In  spite,  however,  of 
positive  enactments,  the  view  that  a  priest  was 
necessarily  free  became  extended  to  the  diaconate 
and  the  inferior  orders  ;  and  the  petition  of 
the  commons  in  1391  that  the  villeins  miglit 
not  be  allowed  to  send  their  sous  to  school  in 
order  to  raise  them  by  holy  orders  {qe  null  neif 
on  vileyn  met  scs  enfantz  de  cy  en  avant  a  cscoles 
2)ur  eux  arancer  par  clergic)  {Hot.  Pari.  iii.  294, 
cp.  Rogers,  Hist,  of  Agric.  and  Prices  (1866),  i. 
78,  93)  may  be  taken  as  proof  that  by  that  time 
the  result  was  established. 

With  reference  to  the  influence  of  the  church 
upon  slavery  outside  its  own  body,  there  can 
be  little  doubt  that  the  humaner  piinciples  of 
jurisprudence  by  which,  at  least  in  England,  it 
was  guided  were  favourable  to  the  bondman  (cp. 
Theodor,  Penit.  xiii.  3  ;  Egbert,  Penit.  Addit.  35). 
Alike  in  Francia  and  in  England  ordinances 
were  passed  moderating  the  abuses  of  the  slave- 
trade  (Freeman,  Norm.  Conq.  i.  (ed.  3, 1877)  335 
seq.,  435),  and  in  these  the  h;i,nd  of  the  church- 
men is  hardly  doubtfril.  Still  more  striking  is 
the  public  action  of  St.  Wulistan,  bishop  of 
Worcester,  to  whose  arguments  and  those  of 
Lanfranc  was  attributed  the  express  prohibition 
by  William  the  Conqueror  of  the  export  of 
slaves  (Stubbs,  Sel.  Charters,  p.  85  ;  Will. 
Malmesb.  Gestt.  Eegg.  iii.  269  ;  cp.  Freeman, 
iv.  (ed.  2,  1876)  380  seq.),  a  prohibition  which 
was  extended  by  St.  Anselm  in  1102  to  any  sale 
into  slavery  whatever  (Eadmer,  Hist.  Nov.,  a. 
1102  ;  cp.  Freeman,  v.  (1876)  223  seq.)  The 
emancipation  of  slaves  was  from  an  early  time 
recognised  as  a  religious  act,  and  the  practice 
of  including  such  a  deed  in  testamentary  dis- 
positions was  manifestly  promoted  by  clerical 
persuasion.  If  religious  corporations  were  not 
specially  forward  in  manumitting  their  own 
bondmen,  it  was  rather  because  the  law  of  the 
church  was  precise  against  diminishing  their 
property,  than  through  any  reluctance  to  in- 
crease the  body  of  freemen.    But  the  process  by 

1  Gamier  de  Pont-Sainte-Maxence's  attack  upon  the 
constitution  (St.  Thomas  le  Martyr,^  lines  24SS-2490  ed. 
Hippeau,  1859)  rests  rather  on  fjk  priori  grounds. 


282       CHRISTIANITY  AND  ECONOMICS— THE  MEDIEVAL  CHURCH 


whi3h  the  bondman  rose  through  the  ambiguous 
rank  of  tho  villein  to  that  of  the  copyholder 
is  traceable  to  known  economical  causes  and 
only  in  isolated  cases  to  ecclesiastical  influence. 

2.  Lands  in  the  possession  of  a  church  were 
distinguished  from  other  real  property  in  so 
far  as  they  were  protected  against  aliensftion, 
and  enjoyed  certain  immunities  from  the  pay- 
ment of  taxes. 

{a)  According  to  the  civil  law,  church  lands 
could  not  as  a  rule  be  alienated,  though  they 
might  be  exchanged  between  two  religious 
corporations  or  mortgaged  up  to  a  limited 
amount  {Novell,  cxx.)  They  could  only  be 
alienated  by  an  act  performed  in  the  presence 
of  the  metropolitan  and  of  two  bishops  of  the 
vicinity  {Novell,  xlvi.  1,  Ixvii.  4).  Except  as 
subject  to  some  such  condition,  alienation  was 
totally  forbidden  by  the  early  councils  {Cod. 
Canon.  Ecd.  Afric.  xxvi.,  xxxiii.),  and  by  the 
later  canon  law  it  was  not  permitted  sine  iusta 
causa,  that  is  without  evident  necessity  or 
advantage  (6  Deer.  iii.  tit.  ix.  1).  But  the 
power  which  was  reserved  of  granting  leases  of 
land  not  brought  into  cultivation  made  it 
possible  to  frustrate  the  intention  of  the  accepted 
rule.  Setting  on  one  side  the  numerous  cases 
of  alleged  unlawful  appropriation  of  church 
lands  by  the  civil  ruler,  cases  in  which  there  is 
often  reason  to  suspect  exaggeration  in  the 
record  of  the  misdoing  (cp.  Freeman,  ii.  (ed.  3, 
1877)  554-567),  we  find  abundant  instances  in 
the  Domesday  Book  and  elsewhere,  of  church 
lands  being  granted  not  merely  for  life  but  for 
several — commonly  three — lives  (see  examples, 
in  Freeman,  v.  778-785),  at  the  expiration  of 
which  it  was  not  always  easy  for  the  grantor  to 
resume  possession.  By  degrees  it  was  attempted 
to  restrict  the  practice,  and  the  canon  law  as 
laid  down  by  Clement  Y.  prohibited  all  grants 
for  life  or  even  a  term  of  years,  allowing  them 
only  **ad  modicum  tempus"  {Clevient.  iii.  tit. 
iv.  1),  an  ambiguous  phrase  which  was  after- 
wards restricted  by  Paul  II.  to  three  years 
{Extrav.  conim.  iii.  tit.  iv.) 

{b)  Among  the  earliest  grants  of  land  to 
churches  or  monasteries,  in  England  there  are 
examples  in  which  it  appears  that  the  lands  in 
question  were  entirely  freed  from  the  common 
burthens  of  property  (Bed.  Vit.  S.  Bened.  vi., 
Epist.  ad  Ecgherct,  xii.) ;  but  soon,  as  such 
grants  were  multiplied,  it  became  a  matter  of 
public  policy  to  subject  them  to  the  trinoda 
necessitas.  With  regard,  however,  to  the  other 
payments  to  which  land  was  liable,  the  usage 
varied  ;  sometimes  the  land  was  wholly  en- 
franchised, sometimes  only  in  part  ;  sometimes 
it  bought  its  enfranchisement  by  payment  at 
the  time  of  the  grant  or  by  a  surrender  of  lands 
in  lieu  of  future  obligations  (Lingard,  Hist  and 
Antiq.  of  the  Anglo-Saxon  Church  (1845),  i. 
240-250).  Gradually  the  rule  was  established 
that  lands  held  by  a  church  or  religious  house 


were  held  in  "free  alms"  (libera  et 
or  Frank- ALMOIGN  {q.v.),  a  form  of  tenure  ( 

which  is  found  in  Domesday  as  not  exclusively 
ecclesiastical  (Freeman,  vol.  v.  p.  804,  seq.), 
and  which  is  legally  understood  to  involve  ex- 
emption from  all  temporal  dues  (Digby,  Introd. 
to  the  Hist,  of  the  Law  of  Real  Property  (ed.  3), 
p.  38  ;  Bracton,  iv.  28  f.  207  ;  Ellis,  Gen.  In- 
trod. to  Domesday  (1833),  vol.  i.  p.  258  seq.)  On 
the  other  hand  the  liberty  thus  implied  in  the 
possession  of  lands  by  the  church  did  not  extend  \ 

to  all  lands  held  by  the  church,  nor  was  it  at 
first  admitted  by  all  statesmen.  The  latter 
point  is  suflBiciently  illustrated  by  the  notorious 
policy  of  Randolph  Flambard  ;  and  as  to  the 
former,  it  is  clear  that  the  recognised  obligation 
of  the  trinoda  necessitas  might  naturally  be 
construed  in  the  light  of  feudal  ideas  as  carrying 
with  it  the  obligation  to  feudal  military  service. 
That  this  was  in  fact  the  case  is  shown  by  the 
way  in  which  Archbishop  Lanfranc — to  name 
no  other  instance — compounded  for  the  services 
due  from  the  convent  of  Christ  Church,  Canter- 
bury, by  maintaining  a  certain  number  of 
knights  {Epistt.  Cantuar.  ccxliii.  ;  cp.  Freeman, 
V.  p.  372)  ;  and  when  in  1159  the  imposi- 
tion of  ScuTAGE  {q.v.)  was  carried  out,  it  was 
levied  also  upon  church  lands  (cp.  J  oh.  Saresb. 
epist.  cxlv.)  But  from  the  reign  of  Henry  II. 
onwards,  the  payment  of  taxes  directly  levied 
on  church  lands  was  repeatedly  resisted  as  an 
infringement  of  ecclesiastical  immunities  (cp. 
Stubbs,  Const.  Hist,  of  Engl.  (ed.  1880),  i.  647 
seq.,  ii.  187  seqq.,  etc.)  ;  and  it  was  to  prevent  a 
fraudulent  multiplication  of  lands  for  which 
such  immunities  could  be  claimed  that  Edward 
I.,  in  1279,  enacted  the  statute  of  Mortmain 
{Stat,  de  Vir.  Relig.,  ap.  Stubbs,  Sel.  Charters, 
p.  458  seq.l 

The  lands  held  by  a  religious  house,  at  least 
those  in  its  immediate  vicinity,  were  as  a  rule 
cultivated  by  the  brotherhood  itself,  and  the 
personal  interest  thus  devoted  to  the  work  pro- 
duced better  results  than  the  enforced  labour 
of  bondmen.  The  evidence  of  the  Domesday 
survey  goes  to  show  that  the  church  lands  were 
in  a  higher  state  of  cultivation  than  other 
property.  The  monks  also  employed  them- 
selves in  clearing  forests,  draining  marshes, 
and  making  roads  and  bridges  (cp.  Lingard,  i. 
2Q7seq. ;  Cunningham,  Growth  of  Engl.  Industry 
and  Commerce  in  the  Early  and  Middle  Ages,  p. 
64  seq.,  1890) ;  and  the  Cistercian  order,  through 
the  activity  which  it  displayed  in  sheep  farming, 
promoted  in  a  singular  degree  the  production 
of  the  staple  commodity  of  England.  Through 
the  immense  extent  of  their  property,  variously 
estimated  in  the  13th  and  14th  centuries  from 
a  quarter  to  a  half  of  the  total  landed  property 
of  England  (Wycliffe,  de  Eccl.  xv.  p.  338  ;  cp. 
Pearson,  Hist,  of  Engl.  ii.  497  (1867)),  the 
churches  and  religious  houses  came  to  take  an 
important  share  in  the  industrial  development 


CHRISTIANITY  AND  ECONOMICS— ROMAN  CATHOLIC  SCHOOL      283 


of  the  country  ;  and  it  is  acknowledged  that  the 
clergy  were  mild  landlords  (see  generally  Stubbs, 
Cmst.  Hist.  iii.  662).  The  attacks  of  the 
Lollards  upon  the  landed  property  of  the  church 
were  inspired  rather  by  a  prioi'i  objections  to 
the  system  itself  than  by  any  actual  abuses  to 
which  it  led  ;  and  the  considerations  which 
Bishop  Pecock,  writing  in  the  middle  of  the 
15th  century,  alleged  on  the  opposite  side  are 
probably  in  the  main  just.  "The  treuthe  is," 
he  says,  "that  the  tenementis  and  alle  the 
possessiouns  with  her  purtenauncis,  which  the 
clergie  (religiose  or  not  religiose)  holden  and 
hauen,  is  better  meintened  and  susteyned  and 
reparid  and  kept  fro  falling  into  noujt  and  into 
wildirness,  than  if  tho  same  tenementis  and 
possessiouns  Avith  her  purtenauncis  weren  in  the 
hondis  of  grete  lordis,  or  of  knyjtis,  or  of 
squyeris.  .  .  .  The  tenauntis,  occupiyng  tho 
tenementis  and  possessiouns  with  purtenauncis 
vndir  the  clergie,  ben  esilier  tretid,  lasse  disesid, 
and  not  greened  bi  extorcioun,  as  thei  schoulden 
be,  if  thei  helden  the  same  tenementis  and 
possessiouns  of  temporal  lordis  or  of  kny^tis 
and  squyers."  Among  other  points  in  favour 
of  those  who  held  of  the  church,  Pecock 
notices  that  their  tenure  was  less  liable  to  be 
disturbed  than  that  of  those  who  held  under 
lay  lords  {liepressor  of  overmicch  hlaming  of  the 
Clergy,  vol.  ii.  p.  370  seq.  (ed.  Babington, 
I860)).  It  has  been  noticed  by  critics  least 
friendly  to  the  mediaeval  church  that  it  was 
such  causes — the  known  advantage  to  the  tenant 
— that  did  much  to  reconcile  public  opinion  to 
the  enormous  estates  held  by  the  church  (Pear- 
son, Hist,  of  Engl.  vol.  ii.  p.  502  ;  Rogers, 
vol.  i.  p.  160).  That  at  the  close  of  the  Middle 
Ages  the  state  of  things  was  somewhat  altered, 
and  the  abuses  which  had  arisen  with  respect 
to  the  management  of  church  property  called 
forth  well-founded  complaints  (cp.  Dyalogc 
hetwene  a  Gentillman  mid  a  Husbandman,  1530 
ed.  Arber,  1871,  p.  134  scqq..  Ballads  from 
Manuscripts,  ed.  Furnivall  (1869),  vol.  i.),  need 
not  be  denied  ;  but  the  question,  which  is  a  very 
debatable  one,  lies  beyond  the  province  of  the 
present  article.  n.  l.  p. 

[See  Sir  F.  Palgrave,  History  of  Normandy  and 
England,  esp.  In  trod,  to  vol.  iii.] 

The  Roman  Catholic  School  (as  the 
economic  school  of  thought  which  has  developed 
within  the  Roman  Catholic  Church  has  been 
termed)  is  of  comparatively  recent  origin. 
Though  the  date  of  its  birth  cannot  be  fixed 
with  exactness,  it  certainly  goes  as  far  back  as 
September  1869,  when  a  conference  of  bishops 
giving  special  attention  to  social  questions  met 
at  Fulda  in  Germany. 

No  doubt  the  Catholic  church,  through  the 
fathers  in  the  first  ages  of  Christianity,  and 
through  its  doctors  in  the  Middle  Ages,  had 
always  occupied  itself  with  the  social  question 
from  certain  points  of  view,    especially  with 


regard  to  the  relations  between  the  rich  and 
the  poor.  Through  its  agency,  indeed,  lending 
at  interest  had  been  forbidden  by  the  civil 
law  (see  Aquinas  ;  Canon  Law  ;  Church, 
MEDiiEVAL).  But  it  was  not  till  quite  recently 
that  it  published  a  programme  of  economic 
reforms,  and  turned  its  activity  particularly  to 
labour  questions.  Without  imputing  any  in- 
terested motive,  it  may  be  supposed  that  this 
action  of  the  Roman  Catholic  church  has  been 
not  uninfluenced  by  the  desire  to  regain  the 
power  over  the  labouring  classes  which  socialism 
threatened  to  wrench  from  its  hands.  Up  to 
the  present  time,  however,  this  object  does  not 
appear  to  have  been  attained.  In  spite  of  the 
armies  of  workmen  Avhich  the  church  leads  as 
pilgrims  to  the  feet  of  the  Pope,  in  spite  of  the 
"workmen's  clubs "  {Oercles  ouvriers)  which  the 
church  strives  to  multiply  in  France,  no  pro- 
found impression  seems  yet  to  have  been  made 
on  the  masses  of  the  labouring  population  ;  and 
it  is  from  the  ranks  of  the  higher  clergy  and 
the  aristocracy  that  it  has  almost  exclusively 
drawn  its  leaders  and  even  its  adherents. 

In  England  the  late  Cardinal  JManning  was 
prominent  in  labour  questions.  In  the  United 
States,  Cardinal  Gibbons  has  undertaken  the 
defence  of  the  Knights  of  Labour.  In  France 
Cardinal  Langenieux,  Comte  Albert  de  Mun — 
an  ex-cavah-y  officer  and  one  of  the  most 
eloquent  speakers  in  the  French  legislature, 
M.  Harmel — a  large  manufacturer, — all  three 
are  organisers  of  workmen's  pilgrimages.  In 
Switzerland,  M.  Decurtins,  deputy  of  the 
canton  of  the  Grisons,  has  taken  an  active  part 
in  the  labour  laws  passed  in  Switzerland  of  late 
years.  In  Germany,  the  Bishop  of  Mayence, 
Monsignnr  von  Ketteler,  now  dead,  was  one  of 
the  initiators  of  the  movement ;  at  present 
there  is  the  Bishop  of  Breslau,  Monsignor 
Kopp,  who  played  an  important  part  at  the 
International  Conference  of  Berlin  on  the 
regulation  of  labour.  In  Austria,  there  have 
been  Baron  de  Vogelsang,  now  dead,  the  Prince 
of  Liechstentein,  and  others.  Pope  Leo  XIII. 
has  placed  himself  at  the  head  of  the  movement. 
On  several  occasions  he  has  shown  great  interest 
in  social  questions,  especially  by  his  famous 
encyclical  of  15th  May  1891  and  his  addresses 
to  the  workmen  pilgrims. 

By  the  vehemence  of  its  criticisms  of  the 
economic  organisation  of  the  day,  more  particu- 
larly by  opposing  itself  to  individualism,  self- 
help,  competition,  and  the  inordinate  search 
for  gain,  also  by  the  sombre  picture  which  it 
paints  of  the  condition  of  the  working  classes, 
the  "Roman  Catholic  school"  makes  common 
cause  with  democratic  socialism.  Like  it,  in 
deed,  it  protests  against  Manckesterthum, 
against  the  body  of  teaching  which  regards 
personal  interest  as  the  only  motive  force  of 
human  activity,  and  the  law  of  supply  and 
demand  as  the  sole  regulator  of  wages.     Hence 


284      CHRISTIANITY  AND  ECONOMICS— ROMAN  CATHOLIC  SCHOOL 


the  appellation  of  **  Catholic  socialism  "  which 
it  sometimes  receives.  However,  it  always 
refuses  to  accept  this  title.  Indeed,  it  stands 
really  at  the  opposite  pole  to  the  socialist 
school,  for  its  objects  are  not  only  to  conserve 
but  also  to  restore  the  fundamental  institutions 
of  society,  id  est — religion, — family, — prop^ty, 
— employer  system.  It  sees  the  solution  of  the 
social  question,  first  of  all,  in  the  fulfillment 
of  the  laws  of  morality  and  religion,  then  in 
that  corporative  system  which,  in  the  words  of 
Leo  XIII.,  "  comprises  in  itself  almost  all  other 
works.""  This  corporative  system  must  not  be 
confused  with  the  co-operative  system,  so  much 
extolled  by  some  of  the  Protestant  schools  of 
socialism,  or  even  with  trade-unionism.  The 
"Roman  Catholic  school"  understands  by  this 
phrase  associations  of  trades,  composed  at  one 
and  the  same  time  of  masters  and  of  men,  re- 
gulating in  sovereign  fashion,  and  by  decrees 
fitted  to  each  particular  industry,  the  number 
of  hours  of  labour,  the  rate  of  wages,  and  so 
forth  ;  and  invested  with  the  rights  of  property 
in  consequence  of  their  status  as  corporate 
bodies,  and  with  political  power  through  their 
ability  to  elect  their  representatives  in  the 
chamber.  The  works  of  M.  Harmel  in  the  Val 
des  Bois  near  Rheims  are  usually  given  as  a 
type  of  the  industrial  organisation  which  is 
the  ideal  of  this  school. 

In  France  and  in  the  countries  which  have 
felt  the  influence  of  the  French  Revolution  and 
of  the  movement  of  ideas  which  thence  took 
its  rise,  the  "Roman  Catholic  school"  violently 
attacks  the  Principles  of  '89,  holding  them 
responsible  for  the  state  of  agitation  and  un- 
rest through  which  the  nations  of  Europe  are 
struggling.  Thus  the  law  of  equal  division  of 
estates  between  all  the  children  is  regarded  by 
the  "  Roman  Catholic  school "  as  the  chief  cause 
of  the  disorganisation  of  the  family,  whilst 
from  the  abolition  of  the  corporative  system 
the  misery  of  the  working  classes  is  held  to 
have  mainly  arisen. 

The  question  of  state  interference  has  caused 
the  division  of  the  "Roman  Catholic  school" 
into  two  clearly-marked  sections.  The  inter- 
ventionist school,  the  names  of  whose  repre- 
sentatives have  been  given  above,  labours 
steadily  for  state  interference  to  regulate  the 
length  of  the  day's  labour,  for  the  enforcement 
of  Sunday  rest,  for  the  abolition  of  usury,  for 
the  prevention  of  monopoly  and  speculation  ; 
in  fact,  for  all  measures  which  seem  likely  to 
raise  the  condition  of  the  poorer  classes.  On 
the  other  hand,  the  "Liberal"  section  of  the 
"  Roman  Catholic  school "  entertains  a  distrust 
of  state  interference  in  a  coercive  shape,  which 
is  no  whit  less  than  that  felt  by  the  economic 
school  of  Adam  Smith.  It  sanctions  the  ap- 
plication of  state  interference  only  in  cases  of 
clearly-proved  necessity,  and  upholds  liberty  of 
labour  and  freedom  of  contract.      It  is  also  less 


bitter  in  its  criticisms  of  the  economic  organisa- 
tion of  the  day  and  confines  its  programme  of 
social  reform  to  the  restoration  of  the  authority 
of  the  church  in  society,  of  the  father  in  the 
family,  of  the  employer  in  the  workshop,  and 
to  the  exercise  of  social  duties.  Further,  its 
characteristics  are  more  of  a  lay  nature  ;  it 
refuses  to  be  called  "Catholic"  in  the  narrow 
sense  of  the  word,  and  opens  its  arms  to  all 
who  desire  to  apply  the  historical  method  to 
the  study  of  social  facts.  M.  Le  Play  (q.v.), 
who  died  in  1883,  is  usually  regarded  as  the 
chief  of  this  school,  which  includes  among  its 
members  several  distinguished  professors,  for 
instance  M.  Claudio  Jannet,  jjrofessor  at  the 
Catholic  university  of  Paris  ;  Charles  Perin, 
formerly  professor  at  the  university  of  Louvain, 
and  his  successor  in  the  same  chair,  M.  Victor 
Brants.  It  was  believed  that  the  Pope  would 
give  his  opinion  on  the  delicate  point  involved 
in  these  discussions  in  such  a  way  as  to  decide 
the  question.  But  the  holy  father,  in  his  en- 
cyclical of  May  1891  de  Conditione  Opifieum, 
expressed  himself  in  such  general  formulae  and 
made  use  of  such  diplomatic  and  guarded  lan- 
guage, that  each  of  the  two  sections  of  the 
school  has  been  able  to  claim  his  high  approval. 
Thus  the  encyclical  declares  "that  the  force 
and  authority  of  laws  are  necessary  to  save  the 
unhappy  workman  from  those  speculators  who 
treat  men  as  if  they  were  machines, — who  use 
them  up  in  order  to  glut  their  own  insatiable 
cupidity."  Nevertheless,  it  also  condemns 
state  socialism  "which  aims  at  substituting 
state  control  for  paternal  care."  Moreover,  in 
his  address  to  the  workmen  pilgrims  on  19th 
September  1891,  in  which  he  commented  on 
his  encyclical,  the  Pope  declared  "  that  it  must 
be  taken  as  certain  that  no  true  and  practical 
solution  of  the  labour  and  the  social  question 
would  ever  be  found  in  purely,  civil  laws,  how- 
ever good  they  might  be."  It  is  therefore 
probable  that  these  two  main  lines  of  thought 
— the  one  seeking  a  remedy  for  all  human  ills 
by  methods  closely  allied  to  those  of  socialism, 
the  other  by  strictly  religious  influences, — will 
continue  to  divide  the  "Economic  school"  now 
existing  in  the  Roman  Catholic  church. 

[Francesco  Nittl,  II  socialismo  cattolico,  2d  ed. , 
Roux,  Turin,  1891. — "  The  Catholic  Church  and 
Economics,"  J.  J.  Keane,  Quarterly  Journal  of 
Economics,  Oct.  1891. — C.  S.  Devas,  Political 
Economy,  London,  1892.  Stonyhurst  Series. — 
Von  Ketteler,  Die  Arbeiterfrage  uiid  das  Christ- 
enthum,  Mayence,  Kirchheim,  1866. — Liberal- 
ismus,  Socialismus,  und  Christenthum,  Mayence, 
Kirchheim,  1871,  by  the  same  author. — Rudolph 
Meyer,  Der  Emancipationskampf  des  vierten 
Standes,  Berlin,  1882,  2d  ed.,  2  vols.— Charles 
Perin,  Le  Socialisme  chritien,  Paris,  Lecoft're,  1879. 
— Decurtins,  La  question  de  la  protection  ouvriere 
Internationale,  Berne,  1889. — De  Mun,  Discours, 
Paris,  Poussielgue,  3  vols.  — Harmel,  Catechisme  du 
patron,  Paris,  1889, — also  Manuel  d'une  corpwa- 


CHRISTIANITY  &  ECONOMICS— INFLUENCE  OF  PROTESTANT  THOUGHT  285 


Hon  chrHienne,  Tours,  1879. — Manning,  The 
Rights  and  Dignity  of  Labour,  London,  1887. — 

The  Journals  and  Reviews  which  are  the  organs 
of  the  "Roman  Catholic  school"  are  very  numer- 
ous. The  following  are  the  most  important  in 
France ;  V Association  Catholique,  a  monthly  review 
(organ  of  the  school  of  the  Comte  de  Mun). — La 
Refarme  Sociale  (organ  of  the  school  of  Le  Play). 
— In  Germany  :  Arbeiterwohl,  conducted  by  Abb6 
Hitze. — Historisch-politische  Blatter  ; — CJiristlich- 
sociale  Blatter.  —  In  Austria  :  Oesterreichische 
Monatsschrift  fur  christliche  Social  Reform,  for- 
merly conducted  by  Baron  de  Vogelsang  ;  Das 
Vaterland.]  c.  a. 

The  Influence  of  Protestant  Thought 
ON  Economic  Opinion  and  Practice. 

The  intention  of  this  article  is  to  trace  the 
influence  of  Protestant  thouglit,  mainly  on  the 
continent  of  Europe,  both  in  its  original  tend- 
encies and  in  its  historical  development  on 
economics.  The  outcome  of  these  influences 
may  be  generalised  under  four  heads,  viz.  :  I. 
the  principle  of  Individualism  encouraging 
individual  .enterprise,  the  stability  of  private 
property,  and  the  development  of  industrial 
progress  ;  11.  the  principle  of  libre  examen  (the 
expression  is  that  of  Guizot),  which  in  freeing 
the  mind  led  indirectly  to  the  liberation  of 
trade,  free  competition,  and  the  doctrine  of 
laissez-faire  as  further  developed  by  the  French 
revolution  ;  III.  the  Protestant  idea  of  the 
state  during  the  transition  period,  which  helped 
in  establishing  the  mercantile  theory  in  Holland 
and  England,  and  the  cameralistic  conception 
of  political  economy  in  Germany,  since  economic 
science  was  then  regarded  merely  as  a  method 
of  action,  the  object  of  which  was  the  furnish- 
ing the  state  or  its  head  with  ways  and  means 
to  carry  on  the  government ;  IV.  Protestant 
ethics  in  relation  to  the  modern  economic 
method,  introducing  the  Caritativc  element  of 
Christianity  {i.e.  that  not  only  the  selfish  prin- 
ciple of  supply  and  demand  but  Christian  love 
and  duty  should  be  the  guiding  laws  in  eco- 
nomic action — the  doctrine  of  Adolph  Wagner) 
as  a  corrective  of  the  purely  egoistic  theory. 

I.  Individualism. — Friends  and  enemies, 
Guizot,  Seebohm,  K.  Marx,  and  E.  de  Laveleye, 
declare  alike  that  the  "history  of  capital  and 
the  supremacy  of  private  interest,"  i.e.  commerce 
in  its  modern  aspect,  commenced  contempor- 
aneously with  the  period  of  the  reformation, 
accompanied  as  that  movement  was  by  many 
discoveries  and  inventions,  and  the  recovered 
sense  of  personal  freedom  and  responsibility. 
In  Protestantism  and  Catholicism  in  their  hear- 
ing upon  the  Liberty  and  Prosperity  of  Nations, 
by  Emile  de  Laveleye  (1875),  the  progress 
of  economic  enterprise  is  attributed  to  the 
superior  education  and  enlightenment  fostered 
by  Protestantism,  De  Tocqueville  ascribing  to 
the  Pm'itan  discipline  of  the  first  settlers  the 
same  result  in  the  commercial  expansion  of  the 
United   States.     From    Luther   to   Protestant 


divines  of  the  present  day  the  moral  force  of 
the  dignity  of  labour  and  the  duty  of  cheerful 
exertion  in  the  subduing  the  earth  by  economic 
effort,  have  been  held  up  to  admiration,  and 
have  given  an  impulse  to  the  economic  life  of 
Protestant  countries.  The  Wealth  of  Nations 
appeared  in  1775-76,  and  marks  a  revolution 
of  thought  in  Protestantism  in  the  author's 
mind,  and  a  revolution  of  industry  then  com- 
mencing. "The  machine  is  somewhat  in  the 
nature  of  Protestantism,"  says  Dean  Uhlhorn  in 
his  brochure  on  Katholicismus  und  Protestant- 
ismus  gegeniiber  der  socialen  Frage  (1887). 
Private  property  is  encouraged  by  Protestant- 
ism. Luther,  in  his  Sermon  on  Usury  (1579), 
speaks  of  three  gi-ades  "of  dealing  well  and 
worthily  with  temporal  goods."  The  highest 
is  to  allow  ourselves  to  be  despoiled  of  it  with- 
out off'ering  opposition,  the  lowest  is  to  take 
neither  profit  nor  interest,  though  he  sees  objec- 
tions to  this  ideal  being  realised.  Whilst 
Erasmus  complained  of  the  "rage  of  owner- 
ship," Protestantism  endeavoured  to  make  a 
compromise,  maintaining  the  ideal  in  theory 
and  encouraging  what  Fr.  A.  Lange  calls  a 
"moderate  egoism,"  or  "ethical  materialism," 
in  practice  (see  Gcschiclite  des  Materialismus,  i. 
254,  294.  Cp.  J.  E.  Thorold  Rogers  on  The 
Econoinic  Interpretation  of  History  {\  888),  p.  83). 
Resold  in  the  17th  century  speaks  of  private 
property  as  of  human  origin,  yet  approved  of  in 
Holy  Scripture.  H.  Grotins,  at  the  head  of  the 
classical  school  of  political  economy  in  Holland, 
defends  it.  Pufendorft'  adopts  it  from  him,  and 
the  theory  dominated  the  old-fashioned  eco- 
nomics in  Prussia,  until  the  new  school  of 
economists,  with  Ad.  Wagner  at  their  head, 
pointed  out  the  importance  of  correcting  the 
rigid  theory  of  private  rights  as  to  ])orperty  by 
the  recognition  of  what  is  due  to  the  com- 
munity, and  thus  reconciling  the  principle  of 
private  interest  with  that  of  public  advantage. 
This  naturally  followed  on  the  growth  of 
altruistic  ideas  affecting  alike  Protestant  and 
economic  thought.  II.  Liberation  of  In- 
dustry follows  logically  from  that  of  liberty  of 
thought,  developing  the  five  points  of  industrial 
independence  :  freedom  of  labour,  free  trade  in 
land,  free  movement  of  capital,  freedom  of  in- 
dustrial enterprise,  and  a  free  market  regulated 
by  demand  and  supply,— it  further  implies  the 
removal  of  all  governmental  and  trade  restric- 
tions. But  between  the  original  conception  of 
these  princijiles  in  the  16th  century,  and  their 
realisation  in  the  18tli,  lies  the  intermediate 
economic  period  of  III.  Mercantilism,  the 
reign  of  the  "  regal  theory  "  of  political  economy 
as  then  held  in  Germany.  It  means  that  the 
object  of  all  economic  effort,  and  legislation 
directing  it,  is  for  the  benefit  of  the  state  and 
its  head.  This  view  of  directing  the  economics 
of  the  nation  by  royal  mandate  is  encouraged 
by  the  Protestant  idea  of  the  state.     With  the 


286 


CHRISTIANITY  AND  ECONOMICS 


break-up  of  the  old  feudal  and  ecclesiastical 
systems  of  social  organisation  a  fusion  is  effected 
of  all  private  and  corporate  economics  in  one 
political  or  iicdional  economy.  The  whole  com- 
munity assumes  the  character  of  an  economic 
society,  while  it  is  directed  by  the  central 
power, — absolute  monarchy  {Geschichte  der 
Nationalokonomie  von  H.  Eisenhart,  1881,  pp. 
6,  7  ;  also  Bau  und  Leben  des  socialen  Korpers, 
von  A.  E.  Fr.  Schaffle,  vol.  i.  p.  17,  1875). 
Thus  Luther  favoured  state  magazines  for  pro- 
viding the  people  with  food.  In  England  the 
secularisation  of  church  property  became  a 
measure  of  state  policy,  and,  in  turning  public 
into  private  property  in  land,  had  very  import- 
ant results  to  the  rural  economy  of  the  country 
(see  T.  E.  Cliffe  Leslie's  Land  Systems,  p.  213 
seq.  and  passim).  Measures  affecting  commercial 
tariffs  for  the  encouragement  of  native  industry, 
even  the  proposal  of  graduated  taxation  for  the 
purposes  of  mitigating  the  evil  effects  of  a 
debased  currency,  and  the  rapid  growth  of 
pauperism,  which  K.  Marx  attributes  to  the 
contemporaneous  rise  of  Protestantism  and  com- 
mercial industry  (see  Das  Kapital,  Kritik  der 
Politischen  Oekonomie,  2d  ed.,  1872,  p.  760 
seq.,  and  cp.  p.  128  ib.  on  the  progress  of 
capitalism  in  Protestant  lands),  all  these 
aflFected  the  development  of  economic  science 
at  this  time.  It  simply  became  a  method 
for  increasing  the  resources  of  the  country. 
Roscher  shows  how  closely  connected  such 
questions  were  with  the  doctrine  of  mercan- 
tilism (see  Mercantilism).  Bornitz,  Besold, 
Klock  are  the  German  representatives  in  the 
earlier  part  of  the  I7th  century  of  this  stage 
of  economics  as  a  science  of  state  finance. 
Petty,  Locke,  North  represent  the  same  tend- 
ency in  a  more  advanced  state  in  England. 
Cromwell's  Navigation  Act  (1651)  is  a  practical 
illustration  of  it.  They  show  the  influence  of 
Protestantism,  encouraging  national  egoism  as 
a  national  duty.  In  more  recent  times  the 
various  forms  of  state-legislation,  favoured  by 
Prince  Bismarck  under  the  name  of  "practical 
Christianity,"  or  of  government  interference 
with  factory  labour,  as  promoted  by  Lord 
Shaftesbury  in  the  name  of  Christian  philan- 
thropy, as  well  as  the  previous  liberation  of  the 
Prussian  peasantry  by  Von  Stein,  and  the 
''organised  benevolence"  of  Wichem  and  Huber, 
the  pioneer  of  German  co-operation,  are  all 
the  outcome  of  Protestant  Christianity  and 
patriotism  combined,  with  a  view  to  give  effect 
to  the  theory  of  "freedom  of  person  and  pro- 
perty under  a  simple  and  strong  government." 
IV.  The  Ethics  of  Protestantism,  as  modified 
by  the  philosophy  of  Fichte  and  Hegel,  have 
exercised  a  profound  influence  on  the  principal 
writers  belonging  to  the  modern  "historical 
school "  of  political  economy  in  Germany.  The 
state  now  comes  to  be  regarded  as  the  ethos  or 
representative  of  what  is  best  morally  in  the 


community,  and  the  church  in  alliance  with  it 
as  the  upholder  of  a  higher  ideal  of  the  economic 
man.  Thus  in  the  Handhuch  der  Politischen 
Oekonomie  (1st  ed.,  1882 ;  3d  ed.,  1890), 
among  whose  contributors  we  mention,  as  mem- 
bers of  the  historical  school,  L.  Brentano,  H. 
von  Scheel,  and  Ad.  Wagner,  who  lay  stress 
on  the  importance  of  Protestant  Christianity, 
we  are  told  that  ethics  teach  "social  man  the 
duty  of  not  only  following  egotistically  his  own 
interest,  but  also  the  welfare  of  others,  and 
unselfishly  to  provide,  according  to  his  ability, 
the  community  with  the  requisites  for  the 
material  and  spiritual  elevation  of  his  fellows  " 
(p.  49,  1st  ed.)  The  state  is  defined  as  the 
grandest  moral  institution,  bound  to  use  its 
force  in  the  pursuit  of  all  economic  interests, 
and  by  rational  state-intervention  to  supplement 
the  deficiencies  of  self-help  {ih.  pp.  62-54). 
Wagener,  the  privy  councillor  (to  be  distin- 
guished from  Ad.  Wagner  the  professor,  several 
times  mentioned  in  this  article),  as  a  leading 
Protestant  layman  in  Prussia,  and  Bishop 
Martensen,  as  a  Danish  churchman,  both  look 
up  to  the  state  as  the  power  which  should 
bring  about  "a  just  distribution  of  the  com- 
mon social  product  of  all  for  all."  Sismondi, 
representing  Genevan  Protestantism,  was  one  of 
the  first  to  discard  on  religious  grounds  the 
supreme  rule  of  laissez-faire,  and  calls  on  the 
state  "to  regulate  the  progress  of  wealth," 
defining  political  economy  as  la  phis  sublime 
Science  de  la  bienfaisance.  Schaffle,  as  the 
representative  of  South  German  Protestant- 
ism, is  the  most  cautious,  as  weU  as,  next  to 
Roscher,  the  most  erudite  advocate  of  this 
theory,  which  makes  man,  not  money,  the 
object  of  all  economic  exertion,  and  in  which 
humanistic  Protestantism  and  economic  human- 
ism may  be  said  to  be  mixed  and  merged.  By 
humanistic  Protestantism  we  mean  the  modern 
form  of  it,  which  lays  stress  on  the  humanities 
taught  in  Christianity,  and  by  economic  human- 
ism we  mean  the  more  recent  efforts  to  treat 
political  economy  as  a  science  which  has  for  its 
object  the  improved  condition  of  humanity  as 
a  whole.  The  question  is  no  longer,  says 
Roscher,  "what  are  the  laws  of  political  econ- 
omy, but  what  ought  they  to  be, — not  an 
inquiry  into  the  principles  which  govern  the 
accumulation  of  wealth,  but  as  to  what  is  man 
in  his  economic  relations,  what  he  does,  what 
he  wants,  what  he  is  to  be"  (Geschichte  der 
National- okonomik  in  Deutschland,  1874,  pp. 
1033-34).  To  conclude,  from  the  days  of 
Luther  to  those  of  Leibnitz,  and  down  to  our 
own  times,  Protestantism,  faithful  at  heart  to 
its  original  aim,  the  liberation  of  the  mind 
— though  for  a  time  diverted  from  this  object 
by  yielding  to  the  opposing  opinion — submis- 
sion to  dogmatic  assertion, — again  accepting 
the  simpler  doctrines  of  earlier  Christianity, — 
has  continually  exercised  a  weighty  influence  on 


CHRONOGRAM— CINQUE  PORTS 


287 


the  evolution  of  economic  thought.  Political 
economy  itself  is  regarded  by  one  school  of  the 
present  day  as  having  gone  through  somewhat 
similar  successive  stages,  establishing  at  one 
time  as  its  foundation  the  principle  of  sturdy 
self-dependence,  accepting  at  another  the  silken 
fetters  of  state  tutelage,  then  passing  on  to  the 
absolutism  of  scientific  dogmatism  during  the 
era  of  "liberal  mammonism,"  and  rising  at  last 
to  an  ethical  conception  of  its  mission  as  the 
science  of  a  free  yet  harmonious  organisation  of 
industry,  destined  to  attain  the  highest  eco- 
nomic interests  of  mankind,  the  highest  develop- 
ments of  human  culture. 

[Frederick  Seebohm,  The  Era  of  the  Protestant 
Revolution,  1874. — M.  Guizot,  De  la  Civilisation 
en  Europe,  6eme  ed.,  1861,  12eme  Le^on. — W. 
Hohoff,  Protestantismus  und  Socialismus  : — His- 
torisch-politische  Studien,  Paderborn,  1881.  The 
chief  value  of  this  work  consists  in  its  quotations 
from  Comte,  L.  Blanc,  and  German  authorities  on 
the  economic  influences  of  the  Reformation  from  a 
Roman  Catholic  standpoint,  see  esp.  pp.  83-116, 
162-168. — Alexis  de  Tocqueville,  De  la  Democratic 
en  Amerique,  16eme  ed.-,  1874,  iii.  pp.  8-10,  42, 
213-215,  226-227.— Friedrich  von  Baerenbach, 
Die  Socialwissenschaften  (1882),  pp.  241,  244, 
278. — T.  E.  Clifle  Leslie,  Essays  on  Political  and 
Moral  Philosophy,  p.  167  scq.,  this  passage  was 
originally  published  in  the  Fortnightly  Pi.evieiv, 
July  1875.— A.  E.  Fr.  Schaffle,  Das  fjesellschaft- 
liche  System  der  menschlichen  Wirthschaft  (1873), 
i.  p.  41  ;  ii.  15,  527-528. — Bau  U7id  Leben  {loc. 
cit.  supra),  i.  691-693. — C.  Kantsky,  Thomas 
Morus.]     See  Socialism  in  Appendix.       m.  k, 

CHRONOGRAM  AND  HEXOGRAM. 
Chronograms  and  hexograms  are  diagrams 
"showing  the  intensity  of  a  phenomenon  at 
various  periods  of  time,  by  the  rise  and  fall  of 
a  curve  within  a  system  of  co-ordinates  express- 
ing a  measure  and  time.  If  this  occurs  in  an 
automatic  register,  observation  and  representa- 
tion take  place  simultaneously.  But  the  hexo- 
gram  may  also  be  constructed  later"  (see 
Graphical  Method). 

[A  nnals  of  the  A  merican  A  cademy.  Supplement, 
May  1891,  "  The  History,  Theory,  and  Technique 
of  Statistics,"  by  A.  Meitzen.] 

CHURCH-SEED  (cherchesed,  chercheomer, 
chercheambre).  '  *  A  certain  measure  of  threshed 
wheat  that  every  man  was  bound  to  bring  to 
the  church,  in  the  time  of  the  Britons  and 
Angles,  on  St.  Martin's  Day.  But,  since  the 
coming  of  the  Northmen,  many  lordships  took  it 
to  their  use  and  gave  it  according  to  the  ancient 
law  of  Moses  by  the  name  of  "first  fruits,"  as 
you  will  find  in  the  letters  of  King  Knut  that 
he  sent  to  Rome,  and  is  called  church-seed 
qicasi  semen  ecdesiae."  The  above  definition  is 
given  in  the  Expositio  vocabulorum  in  MSS. 
St.  Paul's,  Liber  Pilosus,  Red  Book  of  Ex- 
chequer, and  other  Anglo-French  glossaries  of 
the  13th  century.  In  the  Saxon  laws,  however, 
under  the  head  of  DeprimUiis  seminum  we  read 


"And  church-scot  at  Martinmas ;  and  whosoever 
holds  it  over  that  day  let  him  pay  it  to  the 
bishop  and  indemnify  him  xj  fold  and  to  the 
king  120s."  (Cnut,  Eccles.  Dooms,  8).  From 
this  it  would  seem  that  the  word  is  a  corruption 
of  church-scot  (cherchescaet) — the  "c"  becom- 
ing mute — and  in  the  Norwich  MS.  of  the  glos- 
sary the  termination  is  given  as  "soht." 

H.  Ha. 

CIBRARIO,  Giovanni  Antonio  Luigi, 
Count,  was  born  1802,  in  Turin.  He  entered 
the  service  of  the  Sardinian  government  1824, 
was  entrusted  in  1832  with  diplomatic  mis- 
sions in  Switzerland  and  France,  and  in  1833 
with  Austria,  and  took  possession  of  Venice  on 
the  7th  of  August  1848  in  the  name  of  King 
Charles  Albert  of  Sardinia.  In  1852  he  was 
appointed  minister  of  finance  in  the  cabinet  of 
D'Azeglio,  and  in  the  same  year  became  minister 
of  public  instruction.  In  1 8  5  5  he  was  appointed 
minister  of  foreign  affairs.  He  died  at  Salo 
(Brescia)  in  1870.  This  distinguished  states- 
man has  written  an  amazing  quantity  of  his- 
torical studies,  principally  concerning  the  house 
of  Savoy.  As  an  economist  he  owes  his  fame 
to  two  books,  the  Storia  delV  economia  politica 
nel  medio  evo  (2  vols.,  Turin,  1839),  translated 
into  French,  with  a  preface  by  Wolowski  (in 
1859,  Guillaumin,  Paris),  and  the  historical 
treatise  Delia  Schiavitit  e  del  Scrvaggio  e 
spcciahnente  dei  Servi  agricoltori  (2  vols. ,  Milan, 
1868-69).  Besides  these  larger  works,  some 
financial  essays,  reprinted  in  his  Opuscoli  (Turin, 
1841),  should  he  mentioned.  m.  p. 

CINQUE  PORTS.  The  name  applied  to 
the  five  towns  of  Hastings,  Sandwich,  Dover, 
Romney,  and  Hythe,  which  were  incorporated 
for  the  defence  of  the  realm  and  other  purposes 
probably  by  Edward  the  Confessor.  The ' '  ancient 
towns "  of  Winchelsea  and  Rye,  and  several 
other  places,  corporate  and  non-corporate,  were 
afterwards  added  as  members.  Some  writers 
have  tried  to  identify  the  five  leading  ports 
with  the  five  Roman  fortresses,  which,  under 
the  comes  littoris  saxonici,  guarded  the  south- 
eastern shore,  but  the  better  opinion  seems  to 
be  that  they  were  of  Teutonic  origin.  It  is 
probable  that  the  trading  interests  of  the  ports 
first  brought  them  into  prominence.  The  in- 
habitants were  fishermen,  and  they  were  ac- 
customed to  resort  northwards  a  considerable 
distance  to  the  banks  at  the  mouth  of  the  Yare 
to  dry  their  nets  and  pack  their  fish.  This 
practice  developed  into  an  important  annual 
fair  at  Great  Yarmouth,  which  was  attended  by 
fishermen  and  traders  from  various  parts  of  the 
Continent.  The  maintenance  of  order,  and  the 
exercise  of  jurisdiction  at  this  fair  belonged  to 
the  portsmen  from  the  earliest  period  of  their 
history.  Professor  Montagu  Burrows  (Cinque 
Ports,  London,  1888)  traces  the  origin  of  all 
their  distinctive  institutions  to  their  connection 
with  this  fair. 


!88 


CIOMPI— CITE  OUVRlfiRE 


Jurisdiction  was  exercised  in  the  "Court  of 
Shepway,"  a  body  composed  of  the  bailiff,  and 
a  certain  number  of  freemen  from  each  port, 
but  the  assemblies  known  as  the  "BrodhuU" 
and  the  "Gestling,"  usurped  its  administrative 
powers,  and  the  Lord  Warden  and  his  courte  of 
admiralty,  chancery,  and  pilotage,  gradually 
encroached  on  its  judicial  powers. 

The  chief  duties  of  the  assembly  were  as 
follows  :  (1)  to  exercise  jurisdiction  at  Yarmouth 
fair ;  (2)  to  fix  the  number  and  size  of  ships  to  be 
furnished  for  the  defence  of  the  realm  ;  and  (3) 
to  safeguard  the  franchise  of  the  ports. 

The  ports  were  at  the  height  of  their*  power 
during  the  reigns  of  John,  Henry  III.,  and 
Edward  I.,  when  their  ships  constituted  the 
only  existing  English  navy.  During  the  15th 
and  16th  centuries  they  gradually  declined 
owing  to  the  filling  up  of  their  harbours,  the 
necessity  of  a  state  naval  organisation,  and 
the  growth  of  other  commercial  seaports.  The 
assemblies  stiU  continue  in  name,  and  the  Lord 
Warden  may  exercise  certain  minor  judicial 
functions. 

[Charters  of  the  Cinque  Ports,  by  Samuel 
Jeakes,  London,  1728. — Cinque  Forts,  by  Mon- 
tagu BuiTOws,  London,  1888. — Art.  on  "Cinque 
Ports  "  in  Encyclojocedia  Britannica.]  J.  e.  c.  m. 

CIOMPI  (name  supposed  to  be  derived  from 
the  Fr,  compare,  used  by  the  French  soldiery  of 
the  Duke  of  Athens).  The  sudden  uprising  of 
the  Ciompi  in  Florence,  1378,  was  one  of  those 
movements  in  Europe  which  took  place  during 
the  half-century  subsequent  to  the  Black  Death, 
and  may  possibly  be  regarded  as  due  to  the 
dislocation  of  industrial  conditions  brought 
about  by  the  diminution  in  the  numbers  of  the 
people.  Immediately,  however,  the  movement 
in  Florence  was  due  to  (a)  the  rising  of  the 
lower  guilds  against  the  upper,  especially  against 
the  great  wool  guild ;  (b)  reaction  against 
Guelfic  tyranny  ;  (c)  political  restlessness  of  the 
populace.  Regarded  from  the  standpoint  of 
history,  the  rising  of  the  Ciompi  may  be  said 
to  have  been  successful  in  bringing  about  a 
relaxation  of  the  excessive  domination  of  the 
greater  guilds,  but  its  effects  at  the  time  were 
somewhat  various.  At  first  it  was  entirely  suc- 
cessful, the  inferior  guilds  obtaining  a  much 
greater  power,  and  the  guild  of  the  popolo 
minuto  being  established,  but  in  1382  the  force 
of  reaction  led  to  the  abolition  of  this  latter, 
and  to  a  considerable  restriction  of  the  advan- 
tages attained.  The  ground  gained  was,  how- 
ever, not  entirely  lost. 

[Oino  Capponi  (Muratori,  Ital.  Script.,  p. 
1104,  etc.). — Machiavelli,  Storia  di  Firenze.] 

E.  c.  K.  G. 

CIRCULATING  MEDIUM.  The  circulating 
medium  in  all  civilised  countries  consists  at  the 
present  time  to  a  very  large  extent  of  orders  to 
pay  sums  of  money  in  the  form  of  bills  and 
cheques.    At  the  present  time ' '  Bank  notes  are  no 


more  than  the  mere  small  change  of  the  ledger '" 
(Newmarch,  Address  as  President  of  the  Section 
of  Economic  Science,  British  Association,  Man- 
chester, 1861).  Coin  plays  a  large  part  in 
retail  trade,  but  its  share  in  the  more  important 
transactions  is  now  comparatively  small.  The 
circulating  medium  at  the  present  time  in  this 
country  may  be  said  to  consist  of  cheques,  bills 
of  exchange,  notes,  and  coin ;  to  these  book 
transfers,  where  the  accounts  are  under  the  same 
administration,  may  be  added  (see  Banking  ; 
Cash  ;  Clearing  System  ;  Cukrency.) 

[For  details  "  Paper  on  the  Proportional  Use  of 
Credit  Documents  and  Metallic  Money  in  English 
Banks."  G.  H.  Pownall,  Journal,  Institute  oj 
Bankers,  October  1881 ; — other  papers  in  same 
journal,  and  those  of  the  Statistical  Societies  of 
Lond6n  and  Manchester,  etc.] 

CITATION.     See  Jurisdiction,  Scotch. 

CITATION.  A  document  issued  by  the 
High  Court  in  probate  and  divorce  matters. 
Probate  actions,  which  were  formerly  begun  by 
the  service  of  a  citation  on  the  defendant,  are 
now  opened  by  the  issue  of  an  ordinary  writ  of 
summons,  but  "citations  to  see  proceedings"  may 
be  served  on  third  parties  who  may  possibly  be 
interested  in»the  matter,  so  as  to  bind  them  by 
the  result.  In  divorce  proceedings  a  citation  is 
"  extracted  "  and  served  on  the  respondent  and 
the  co-respondents  immediately  after  the  filing  of 
the  petition.  e.  s. 

CIT]6  OUVRIME.  This  term  is  applied  by 
French  economists  in  a  general  sense  to  blocks 
of  buildings  rented  to  working-class  families  on 
such  conditions  that  they  may  by  payment  of 
fixed  instalments  become  the  owners  of  their 
houses.  The  best  known  instance  on  the  Con- 
tinent is  that  at  Miilhausen,  where  there  is  a 
settlement  of  7000  persons,  mostly  employed 
in  the  industries  of  the  town.  Used  in  this 
sense,  it  is  equally  applicable  to  groups  of  work- 
men's dwellings  in  England  and  America  which 
have  been  purchased  by  the  occupiers  through 
the  medium  of  building  societies  or  co-operative 
banks.  But  the  term  is  used  in  a  narrower 
sense  to  describe  the  famous  Familistere  founded 
at  Guise  by  M.  Godin.  The  cit6  ouvriere  may 
be  roughly  described  as  an  attempt  to  reconcile 
the  capitalistic  enterprise  of  the  modern  world 
with  the  craft  association  of  the  mediaeval 
world.  It  is  not  a  municipality  established 
to  provide  for  certain  common  wants  out  ot 
revenues  levied  on  individual  inhabitants, 
but  it  is  a  manufactory  so  managed  that  its 
surplus  profits  are  api>ropriated  to  develop 
human  nature  in  all  its  mental,  moral,  and 
physical  relations.  The  supervision  ^f  the 
municipality  may  be  said  to  be  superseded 
by  the  organisation  of  industry.  Sanitation, 
education,  and  poor  relief  are  all  provided  by 
a  voluntary  apportionment  of  the  net  rewards 
of  common  work,  and  public  opinion  takes  the 
place  of  police.     Perfect  freedom  of  volurtarj 


CITE  OUVHIEKE— CITIZEN 


289 


association  has  eliminated  the  force  of  com- 
pulsory association.  The  city  is  dead  but  the 
citizen  is  alive,  and  the  church  based  on  labour 
has  overcome  the  state,  whose  basis  is  taxa- 
tion. The  settlement  at  Guise,  where  this 
form  of  city  life  has  been  developed  to  the 
highest  point  (see  the  Co-operative  Traveller ,  by 
E.  0.  Greening,  Labour  Association,  1  Norfolk 
Street,  Strand,  1888),  comprises  about  86  acres, 
of  which  11^  acres  are  covered  by  the  iron 
works,  25  by  public  gardens,  and  the  rest 
by  the  social  palace,  schools,  institutes,  and 
surrounding  grounds.  The  iron  works  were 
opened  by  M.  GoDiN  {q.v.)  in  1846,  and  from 
that  date  up  to  1852  he  was  gradually 
building  up  the  business.  An  ardent  disciple 
of  the  school  of  Fourier,  he  was  determined  to 
use  his  business  as  a  means  of  elevating  his 
employes,  and  he  began  to  carry  out  his  ideas 
by  reducing  the  hours  of  labour,  abolishing 
fortnightly  payment  of  wages,  altering  the  pay 
day  from  Saturdays  to  Thursdays  and  Fridays, 
and  establishing  a  sick  club  governed  by  a 
committee  of  workmen.  In  1859  he  bought 
15  acres  of  ground  and  began  to  build  the  iirst 
wing  of  the  Familist^ire  {q.v.)  or  social  palace 
for  his  workpeople  to  live  in.  Building  after 
building,  institution  after  institution,  have  been 
added  to  the  original  plan,  and  now  the  settle- 
ment not  only  includes  a  co-operative  store 
with  departments  for  grocery,  bakery,  con- 
fectionery, drapery,  boots  and  shoes,  coals, 
butchery,  and  every  article  of  prime  necessity, 
but  it  provides  its  members  with  employment 
in  a  gigantic  iron  work,  houses  them  in  palatial 
buildings,  nurses  their  babies  as  far  as  their 
mothers  desire  it,  educates  their  childi-en, 
provides  library,  news  room,  billiard  room, 
refreshment  saloon,  theati'e,  music  master, 
doctors  and  dispensary,  assists  them  to  wash 
and  dry  their  clothes  by  machinery,  assures 
them  against  the  needs  of  old  age,  the  acci- 
dents and  ailments  of  life,  and  the  loss  by 
death  of  the  wage- earner,  and  furnishes  them 
with  all  the  luxuries  of  life,  including  a  co- 
operative garden  filled  with  fruit  and  flowers. 
How  has  all  this  been  done  ?  The  answer  is, 
by  the  capitalist  sharing  the  profits  of  the  iron 
foundry  among  the  workers,  instead  of  keeping 
them  aU  to  himself.  In  1877  M.  Godin  com- 
menced the  plan  of  sharing  profits  by  giving  a 
.  bonus  on  wages  and  accumulating  the  sum  for 
the  wage -earners.  In  1880  he  formed  the 
works,  social  palace,  etc.  etc.,  into  one  gi-eat 
co-operative  society  with  certain  provisions  for 
the  whole  becoming  the  property  of  the  workers. 
The  accumulated  bonuses  of  the  workers  then 
amounted  to  £10,490,  and  the  share  capital 
held  by  M.  Godin  to  £150,000.  The  division 
and  appropriation  of  profits  for  the  future  were 
fixed  as  follows : — after  payment  of  material  and 
wages  at  market  prices,  a  preferential  5  per  cent 
of  the  gross  profits  goes  to  interest  on  capital 
VOL.  I. 


and  the  remainder  is  divided  in  certain  propor- 
tions between  capital,  labour,  the  latter  includ- 
ing mental  as  well  as  manual  labour,  and  social 
and  benevolent  institutions.  There  were,  in 
1884,  1452  persons  employed  in  the  foundry, 
and  they  were  divided  into  five  classes  :  (1)  the 
director — M.  Godin  was  director  for  life,  and 
after  his  death  he  was  succeeded,  in  1888,  by  M. 
Dequenne,  one  of  the  workers  ;  (2)  a  committee 
of  nine  ;  (3)  64  associates,  persons  of  not  less 
than  25  years'  age,  of  5  years'  em])loyraent 
on  the  works,  with  capital  of  £20  ;  (3)  148 
societaires  or  special  members  who  had  worked 
3  years  ;  (4)  574  participants  or  ordinary  mem- 
bers of  1  year's  work  and  not  less  than  21  years' 
age  ;  (5)  656  auxiliaries  of  less  than  1  year's 
work.  Besides  these  there  were  209  outside 
shareholders  who  had  been  workers  but  had  gone 
elsewhere  or  were  on  military  service.  Classes 
(1)  and  (2)  receive  special  remuneration  for 
management,  (3)  and  (4)  receive  proportionate 
bonuses  on  wages  accumulated  as  share  capital, 
(5)onlyenjoys  the  benefits  of  amedical  provident 
fund.  From  1880  to  1884  over  £115,000  of 
profits  were  ajtjiropriated  to  workers  :  in  share 
capital  about  £100,000,  in  cash  about  £10,000, 
in  education  about  £5000.  Since  then  the 
share  of  the  workers  in  the  business  has  steadily 
increased.  At  M.  Godin's  death  it  amounted 
to  about  one  half  of  the  capital.  A.  K.  c. 

[A.  I'affalovich,  Logement  de  VOuvrier  et  du 
jMuvre  (1887),  pp.  448,  acq. — E.  0.  Greening,  Co- 
operative Traveller  Abroad  {IS8S),  pp.  60-173. — 
A.  Perrot,  Les  cites  ouvrieres  de  Midhouse  (1889). 
Twenty  -  eitjht  Years  of  Co-piartnersMp  at  Guise, 
trans,  by  Aneurin  Williams,  Labour  Co-partnersliip 
Association  (1908).] 

CITIZEN.  The  term  citizen  ought  logically 
to  be  exactly  correlative  witli  the  term  city  ; 
but  in  actual  usage  this  coiTclation  is  not 
observed.  The  term  citizen  is  used  to  express 
three  distinct  shades  of  meaning  ;  sometimes  as 
equivalent  to  "member  of  a  sovereign  state" 
sometimes  as  equivalent  to  ' '  member  of  a  body 
of  townsmen  invested  with  municipal  rights," 
sometimes  as  equivalent  to  "dweller  in  a  town  " 
as  distinct  from  "dweller  in  the  country." 
The  title  of  a  well-known  series,  the  "English 
Citizen  series,"  exemplifies  the  first  of  these 
uses  ;  the  second  is  exemplified  in  such  a  phrase 
as  "the  mayor,  aldermen,  and  citizens  of  Liver- 
pool "  ;  and  there  would  be  no  gross  impropriety 
in  speaking  of  the  "  citizens  of  Constantinople  " 
although  Constantinople  is  neither  a  state  nor 
a  municipality.  When  used  in  the  first  sense, 
the  term  "citizen"  connotes  more  especially 
the  rights  and  privileges,  as  the  term  ' '  subject " 
connotes  more  especially  the  duties  and  burthens, 
of  membership  in  a  body  politic.  For  this  use 
of  the  term  citizen  is  derived  from  ancient 
usage.  The  fully  qualified  citizen  of  an  ancient 
city  was  member  of  a  sovereign  state,  and  within 
its  bounds  was  a  highly  privileged  person  as 

u 


290 


C!ITY,  ANCIENT 


compared  either  with  the  slave,  with  the  serf, 
or  with  the  alien.  The  associations  of  the  term 
"subject,"  on  the  other  hand,  are  derived  from 
the  imperial  and  feudal  phases  of  political 
society.  The  political  changes  of  the  last  hun- 
dred years  have  lessened  the  interval  between 
ancient  and  modern  conceptions  of  p(?litical 
society,  and  have  made  the  use  of  the  term 
"citizen"  in  the  above  sense  increasingly 
common.  In  the  second  sense  referred  to,  as 
expressing  membership  of  a  body  of  townsmen 
invested  with  self-government,  the  term  "citi- 
zen "  has  had  a  more  continuous  use.  The 
establishment  of  the  Roman  Empire  reduced  the 
free  cities  of  antiquity  from  sovereign  states  to 
municipalities.  It  was  only  as  burgesses  of 
one  or  other  of  these  municipal  towns  that  the 
inhabitants  of  the  rural  districts  had  any  rights 
of  self-government.  In  the  Middle  Ages  self- 
government  attained  its  full  growth  only  in 
the  towns,  being  restricted  in  the  country  by 
the  power  of  feudalism.  In  some  mediaeval 
cities — in  those  of  Flanders,  of  Germany,  and 
above  all  of  Italy, — municipal  self-government 
expanded  into  something  like  the  sovereignty 
of  the  Greek  city.  It  is  only  in  modem  times 
that  town  and  country  have  been  generally 
assimilated  in  point  of  self-government.  In 
the  third  of  the  above  senses,  as  expressing  no 
more  than  the  fact  of  dwelling  in  a  town,  the 
term  "  citizen "  is  of  comparatively  little  im- 
port for  politics  or  economics  (see  City: 
Ancient  ;  Medieval  ;  Modern),     f.  c.  m. 

CITY 

Ancient,  p.  290 ;  Mediaeval,  p.  292  ;  Modem,  p.  295. 
City,  Ancient.  The  city  with  its  corre- 
lative ideas  of  citizen  and  citizenship  is  the 
special  feature  of  the  stage  of  political  develop- 
ment reached  by  the  ancient  civilisation  of 
Europe.  Cities  are  to  be  found  in  the  history 
of  oriental  civilisation  along  the  river  valleys 
of  the  Nile,  Tigris,  and  Euphrates  ;  but  they 
were  hardly  more  than  gigantic  collections  of 
waUed-in  populations  depending  for  their  exist- 
ence on  the  conquest  of  some  monarch  or  the 
cult  of  some  god,  and  destitute  of  any  inherent 
life  of  their  own.  The  inhabitants  were  slaves 
and  serfs  rather  than  citizens.  It  is  ancient 
Greece  and  Italy  that  gave  birth  to  true  city 
life,  the  life  of  self-governing  freemen  ;  and  the 
political  history  of  these  countries  is  the  history 
of  a  number  of  cities,  their  growth,  their  revolu- 
tions, their  wars  and  their  alliances,  their  con- 
quests and  their  defeats.  This  preponderance 
of  city  life  is  reflected  in  Greek  and  Latin 
literature.  To  the  ancient  Greek  city,  society 
and  state  seemed  identical  terms,  and  Roman 
statesmanship  knew  no  other  method  of  concili- 
ating the  conquered  than  that  of  enrolling  them 
on  the  civic  registers  of  Rome.  The  history  of 
the  conquest  of  the  European  world  by  Rome 
is  in  fact  the  history  of  the  conquest  and  founda- 


tion of  a  multitude  of  cities,  and  of  their  con- 
nection by  a  system  of  roads.  The  Roman 
empire  was  mainly  a  confederation  of  cities 
under  an  emperor  or  chief  magistrate  elected 
by  the  citizens  or  soldiers  of  the  conquering 
city,  and,  when  it  fell,  the  cities  that  were  its 
members  survived  as  units  of  government,  and 
the  roads  that  connected  them  as  channels  of 
commerce  for  modern  civilisation. 

The  origin  of  the  Greek  or  Italian  city  is  lost 
in  the  legendary  past,  but  in  all  probability  it 
grew  out  of  the  union  of  some  great  leaders  of 
patriarchal  clans  or  families,  who,  after  subduing 
the  aborigines,  seized  on  and  settled  round  some 
commanding  position,  safeguarded  their  new 
settlement  with  walls,  and  sanctified  it  with 
religious  worship.  The  city-state  thus  began 
as  a  military,  but  soon  became  a  commercial 
colony.  Around  the  original  dominant  families, 
supporting  themselves  by  the  produce  of  the 
surrounding  fields,  cultivated  by  the  help  of 
the  conquered  natives,  and  submitting,  for  all 
the  purposes  of  mutual  protection,  to  the  com- 
bined government  of  the  heads  of  the  families 
or  clans,  there  would  be  gradually  collected  a 
mixed  population  of  settlers,  traders,  and 
refugees.  The  latter  contributed  to  the  wealth 
and  impoi>tance  of  the  settlement,  but  had  no 
voice  in  its  management.  As  these  outsiders 
grew  in  numbers — and  this  was  especially  the 
case  in  maritime  settlements — and  were  called 
on  to  assist  in  protecting  it,  they  naturally 
claimed  a  voice  in  deciding  questions  of  peace 
and  war,  in  dividing  the  spoils,  and  in  making 
laws.  The  internal  history  of  these  ancient  cities 
is  largely  taken  up  with  the  struggles  between 
the  bodies  of  old  and  new  settlers  for  political 
power.  In  some  cities  the  old  families  held 
their  own,  and  then  the  government  was  called 
an  aristocracy,  in  others  the  wealthier  classes 
belonging  to  the  old  or  new  families  secured 
power,  and  then  it  was  called  an  oligarchy,  in 
others  the  mass  of  independent  inhabitants 
gained  power,  and  then  it  was  called  a  dcTno- 
cracy.  Often  these  various  forms  of  govern- 
ment alternated  with  each  other  according  to 
external  or  internal  changes  of  conditions,  and 
sometimes  a  single  individual,  relying  on  the 
support  of  the  excluded  classes,  seized  the  reins 
of  government,  and  then  it  was  called  a  tyranny. 
Except  in  cities  like  Athens,  Sparta,  and  Rome, 
where  conditions  were,  for  a  long  time,  especi- 
ally favourable  to  one  form  of  government,  the 
political  equilibrium  remained  very  unstable. 

The  political  power  for  which  the  inhabitants 
of  an  ancient  city  contended  was  something 
unknown  in  the  mediaeval  and  modem  world. 
(1)  each  city  with  the  country  dependent  on 
it,  was  originally  no  part  of  a  larger  state  oi 
system  to  whose  authority  it  had  more  or  less 
to  bow,  but  was  an  independent  sovereign 
power,  waging  war  and  making  peace  on  its 
own  account,   like  the  governments  of  large 


CITY,  ANCIENT 


291 


European  kingdoms  in  the  present  day.  The 
chief  officers  of  the  city  had  not  merely  to  pre- 
serve peace  at  home,  they  had  to  defend  it  from 
foreign  foes,  they  had  to  play  the  part  of 
generals  and  diplomatists  as  well  as  of  magis- 
trates and  councillors,  and  each  citizen  had  to 
be  ready  to  fight  as  well  as  to  vote,  to  run  the 
risks  as  well  as  reap  the  rewards  of  war.  (2) 
the  city  was,  in  the  eyes  of  the  ancient  citizen, 
his  church,  and  the  city  magisti'ates  were  ex 
officio  priests.  He  might  continue  to  take  part 
in  the  ancestral  worship  of  the  family,  the  clan, 
and  the  tribe,  but  the  gods  and  temples  and 
ceremonies  of  the  city  overshadowed  the  divini- 
ties and  altars  and  festivities  of  the  hearth  ; 
and  where,  as  at  Athens,  the  state  religion  gave 
rise  to  the  state  drama,  the  city  wielded  the 
power  of  the  pulpit  and  the  stage.  Everywhere 
the  secular  arm  of  the  state  was  supported  and 
consecrated  by  its  spiritual  authority,  and 
patriotism  and  piety  became  indissoluble  senti- 
ments. Exile  carried  with  it  all  the  terrors 
of  excommunication,  and  the  cityless  man  be- 
came a  social  outcast  without  gods  and  without 
duties. 

One  consequence  inevitably  followed  from 
the  supreme  position  of  the  city-state.  The 
individual  liberty  of  the  citizen  was  greatly  cur- 
tailed, and  against  the  demands  of  the  state 
he  had  no  rights.  In  such  a  small  community 
the  tax  upon  person  and  property  was  universal 
and  practically  unlimited,  and  private  life  was 
never  free  from  state  interference.  There  were 
state  regulations  about  dress,  food,  marriage, 
exposure  of  deformed  children,  education, 
religious  observances,  political  services,  suc- 
cession to  property,  and  indeed  very  few 
matters  were  left  to  individual  choice  and 
conscience.  Civil  liberty,  as  we  understand  it, 
did  not  exist.  The  liberty  of  the  ancient 
citizen  was  twofold — political  and  personal.  He 
was  free  from  the  dictation  of  any  person  out- 
side the  city,  and  he  was  free  from  the 
dominion  of  any  person  inside  the  city.  He  was 
neither  the  subject  of  a  king  nor  the  slave  of  a 
master,  but  he  was  the  servant  of  the  constitu- 
tion. Whether  the  constitution  was  aristo- 
cratic, oligarchic,  or  democratic,  the  essence  of 
citizenship  was  everywhere  much  the  same.  It 
consisted  in  the  privilege  to  own  land,  to  serve 
in  the  ranks  of  the  heavily  armed  soldiery,  to 
vote  at  the  civic  assembly,  to  elect  and  be  elected 
to  office,  deliberative  or  judicial. 

The  government  of  the  city-state  always 
turned  on  the  general  assemblage  of  the  body 
of  citizens,  whether  the  title  to  citizenship 
rested  on  birth,  wealth,  or  personal  freedom  ; 
but  subject  to  this  principle,  the  functions  of 
government  were  distributed,  and  the  control 
of  government  exercised  very  differently  under 
an  aristocratic,  oligarchic,  or  democratic  system. 
Under  the  latter  system,  as  developed  at 
Athens,   the  public  assembly  was   practically 


omnipotent.  It  supervised  all  the  chief 
functions  of  government,  it  voted  taxation,  it 
debated  on  and  passed  laws,  it  appointed  sub 
committees  to  act  as  courts  of  justice  and 
financial  and  administrative  commissioners,  it 
elected  its  executive  officers,  it  exacted  an 
account  from  every  official  at  the  end  of  hia 
term  of  office,  it  received  ambassadors,  and 
decided  questions  of  peace  and  war.  The  dis- 
tinction of  judicial,  legislative,  and  executive 
powers  was  recognised,  but  the  division 
rejected.  In  an  aristocratic  or  oligarchic  con- 
stitution a  large  portion  of  the  functions  of 
government  was  invested  in  irresponsible  officers, 
or  in  a  small  council  of  state,  elected  possibly 
by  the  whole  body  of  citizens,  but  rendering 
no  account  to  it.  There  were  also  mixed  forms 
of  government  to  be  found,  such  as  that  of 
ancient  Rome,  where  the  popular  assemblies 
were  large,  but  had  little  practical  control 
over  state  policy,  which  was  directed  by  the 
senate,  consisting  of  all  those  who  held  or  had 
held  the  chief  executive  and  judicial  offices  of 
the  state.  Below  the  citizens,  occupied  chiefly 
with  war  and  politics,  are  to  be  found  in  most 
city-states  a  body  of  inhabitants  not  possessing 
political  rights,  but  enjoying  a  large  amount  of 
civil  privileges  in  return  for  special  taxation. 
These  aliens  consisted  either  of  conquered 
"natives,"  cultivating  the  soil  in  a  serf-like 
dependence  on  the  citizen  owners,  or  immigrants 
carrying  on  commerce  in  a  more  independent 
condition.  Many  of  the  latter  might  have  been 
citizens  of  some  other  city,  and  were  from  time 
to  time,  under  a  democratic  regime  admitted  to 
the  full  privileges  of  citizenship  in  their  adopted 
place  of  residence.  At  the  bottom  of  the  social 
structure  in  every  city-state  came  the  slaves. 
No  form  of  constitution  in  the  ancient  world 
made  any  difference  in  this  respect,  and  a 
democracy  of  freemen  was  at  bottom  an  aristo- 
cracy of  slave-owners.  Thus  at  Athens  and  in 
the  dependent  country,  there  Avere  at  one  time 
over  400,000  slaves,  as  against  10,000  resident 
aliens  and  21,000  male  citizens  of  full  age  ; 
and  at  Rome  the  increase  of  slaves  was  pro- 
digious as  conquests  extended.  These  slaves 
were  not  only  employed  in  domestic  service, 
but  in  mining,  manufacture,  and  agriculture. 
Much  of  the  commercial  and  clerical,  and  even 
the  professional  work  was  done  by  them,  so  that 
free  labour  found  itself  hemmed  in  on  every 
side  by  servile  labour.  Slaves  formed,  in  fact, 
the  bulk  of  what  may  be  called  the  working 
classes ;  and  as  slaves  multiplied,  manual 
labour  naturally  became  despised  by  the  free 
citizen.  Two  gigantic  evils  ensued.  First, 
there  was  always  danger  of  servile  revolts  ;  these 
when  they  broke  out,  as  w^as  often  the  case, 
had  to  be  put  down  with  relentless  cruelty, 
especially  in  small  states  where  the  body  of 
citizens  formed  a  minority  of  the  inhabitants. 
Second,     class    antagonism     was    engendered 


292 


within  the  civic  circle.  Finding  very  few 
openings  for  his  energy,  enterprise,  or  intel- 
ligence ;  forced  into  no  intimate  social  relations 
with  the  rich  by  common  industrial  work  ; 
feeling  the  contrast  between  the  real  inequality 
of  fortune  and  the  nominal  equality  of  political 
power, — the  poorer  citizen  was  filled  with  envy 
and  hatred  against  the  rich.  He  began  to  look 
to  the  state  as  a  means  of  re-adjusting  the 
distribution  of  wealth.  Civil  war  became  the 
order  of  the  day.  If  the  poor  got  the  upper 
hand,  then  confiscation  and  banishment,  if  not 
massacre,  followed  ;  if  the  rich  maintained  their 
position,  it  was  only  by  means  of  doles  and 
bribes.  The  state  was  either  paralysed  by 
internal  conflict  or  demoralised  by  corruption. 
A  period  of  disturbance  destroyed  the  delicate 
organism  of  the  city  polity ;  loss  of  civic 
independence  and  absorption  into  the  Roman 
empire  were  welcomed  as  the  only  refuge  from 
the  weary  round  of  revolution.  The  city-state 
lost  its  local  sovereignty,  and  became  an  organ 
of  imperial  administration.  Slavery,  however, 
which  was  the  curse  of  the  city-states,  was 
equally  the  curse  of  the  Roman  empire.  It 
spread  from  the  towns  to  the  country.  It  had 
poisoned  the  life-blood  of  citizens  by  corrupt- 
ing the  artisan  ;  it  destroyed  the  nurseries  of 
soldiers  by  supplanting  the  peasant. 

[See  La  CiU  Antique,  by  Fustel  de  Coulanges, 
Strasburg,  1864.  — History  of  Civilisation  in 
Ewrope,  by  Guizot  (trans.),  ch.  ii. — Aristotle^ s 
Politics,  by  Newman,  Oxford,  1887. — Historical 
Essays,  by  Freeman,  2d  series. — Public  Economy 
of  Athens,  by  Bockh. — History  of  Greece,  by 
Grote. — History  of  Rome,  by  Mommsen.]  a.  k.  c. 

City,  Medieval.  After  the  downfall  of 
the  Roman  empire  and  the  recolonisation  of 
Europe  by  the  various  bands  of  invading  tribes 
it  was  the  cities  planted  or  fostered  by  Rome  that 
safeguarded  the  political  heirloom  of  ancient 
civilisation.  But  when  their  inhabitants  found 
breathing  space  to  look  round,  they  found  the 
world  completely  changed.  The  centre  of 
political  power  had  drifted  from  the  town  to  the 
country,  and  in  the  towns  themselves  the 
secular  traditions  of  Rome,  which  had  found 
support  in  civic  aristocracies,  resting  on  the 
sovereignty  of  Caesar,  were  overshadowed  by  the 
spiritual  influence  of  the  Christian  clergy  looking 
more  and  more  to  the  supremacy  of  the  Pope. 
On  the  one  hand  the  status  of  citizen  with  his 
urban  dependents  had  given  way  before  that  of 
the  chieftain  with  his  rural  retainers,  and  the 
citadel  was  being  eclipsed  by  the  castle  ;  on  the 
other  hand  the  prestige  of  the  curia  and  the 
magistrate  was  paling  before  that  of  the  church 
and  the  bishop.  In  many  a  town  through  the 
dark  ages  the  buckler  of  religion  was  the  only 
weapon  of  defence  against  the  arm  of  worldly 
power,  and  the  altar  the  only  asylum  for  tlie 
victims  of  oppression.  But  as  the  two  great 
powers  of  the  Middle  Ages  became  organised 


into  feudalism  and  clericalism,  municipalism 
was  left  to  fight  for  itself.  With  the  re-settle- 
ment of  Em-ope  and  the  revival  of  the  demand 
for  manufactures  the  cities  naturally  became  the 
centres  of  industry  and  exchange.  They  found 
themselves,  however,  no  longer  independent 
states  like  the  cities  of  ancient  Greece  and  Italy, 
nor  units  of  an  imperial  rdginie,  but  the  frag- 
ments of  an  old  system  or  the  factors  of  a  new, 
surrounded  on  all  sides  by  a  fierce  military 
aristocracy  looking  with  greedy  eyes  on  their 
growing  wealth.  Increase  of  resources  natu- 
rally inspired  the  townsfolk  with  the  spirit  of 
resistance,  and  about  the  12th  century  there  was 
a  general  movement  among  them  for  securing 
a  distinct  status  in  the  mediaeval  world.  Where 
the  feudal  regime  was  weak,  and  where  muni- 
cipal traditions  were  strong,  as  in  the  south  of 
France,  north  Italy,  and  the  eastern  portion  of 
Spain,  or  where  natural  conditions  were  favour- 
able, as  on  the  northern  coast  of  Europe,  on 
the  Rhine,  or  on  the  Adriatic,  there  the  towns- 
folk easily  succeeded  in  winning  quasi-sovereign 
powers,  waging  wars  and  making  peace,  forming 
alliances  and  embarking  on  conquests  like  the 
cities  of  old.  But  in  the  north  of  France,  in 
England,  Flanders,  and  Germany,  where  the 
feudal  rigvme  was  strong,  or  where  civic  life  was 
not  deeply  rooted  in  the  soil,  but  was  a  plant 
of  recent  growth,  there  the  cities,  whether 
Roman  or  Teutonic  in  origin,  had  to  engage  in 
a  tough  struggle  with  their  feudal  lords,  whether 
barons,  bishops,  or  abbots,  to  secure  some 
measure  of  self-government.  Although  fight- 
ing separately,  they  found  a  centre  of  support  in 
the  power  of  the  rising  monarchies  of  France 
and  England  and  in  the  prestige  of  German 
imperialism,  and  by  the  tacit  acquiescence  or 
active  assistance  of  their  respective  allies  the 
communes  of  France,  the  towns  of  England,  and 
the  free  imperial  cities  of  Germany,  won  valuable 
privileges. 

The  revival  of  civic  life  in  the  cities  of  western 
Europe  is  therefore  the  common  feature  of  the 
11th  and  12th  centuries,  but  the  development 
of  that  life  varied  greatly  with  siurounding 
conditions.  The  reception  of  a  fierce  feudal 
nobility  into  the  bosom  of  the  Italian  republics, 
the  commercial  enterprise  of  the  Hanseatic 
League  (q.v.),  coupled  with  the  weakness  of  the 
central  power  in  Germany,  the  natural  ad- 
vantages of  the  Flemish  towns,  the  frequent 
appeals  of  the  French  communes  for  the  interven 
tion  of  the  Crown,  the  closer  touch  of  town  and 
country  in  England,  necessarily  reacted  on  the 
civic  politics  of  each  country.  But,  in  spite  of 
the  differentiation  of  structure  by  environment, 
certain  features  were  general  in  most  of  the 
mediaeval  cities.  They  were  based  on  work,  not 
on  war,  and  they  flourislied  rather  by  commerce 
than  by  conquest.  Whether,  like  most  Englisli, 
German,  and  Flemish  cities,  the  mediaeval  city 
gradually  grew  out  of  the  new  rural  colonisation  ; 


CITY,  MEDIEVAL 


293 


or  whether,  like  the  French,  Italian,  and  Spanish 
towns,  it  was  a  revival  of  old  urban  life,  still 
the  mainspring  of  its  existence  was  the  demand 
of  the  country-folk  for  the  industrial  products 
of  the  townsfolk.  The  shopkeeper  and  the 
merchant  Avere  in  most  cases  the  founders  and 
restorers  of  civic  life  in  the  Middle  Ages,  and 
its  humble  origin  explains  the  timidity  that 
often  characterised  its  action.  Even  when  the 
cities  rebelled  against  their  feudal  lords,  they 
did  so  in  self-defence,  and  were  eager  to  purchase 
terms  of  peace.  It  was  only  the  Italian  cities 
with  their  feudal  nobles  that  developed  the 
haughty  and  aggressive  spirit  of  the  ancient 
republics,  and  made  a  business  of  bloodshed 
rather  than  of  barter.  The  close  of  the  period 
of  conflict  between  the  cities  and  their  lords 
was  in  most  cases  marked  by  articles  of  peace 
called  charters,  and  even  in  those  parts  of 
Europe,  where  no  actual  conflict  broke  out,  the 
granting  of  charters  became  the  fashion. 
Though  diff'eriug  in  style  and  substance,  these 
charters  confen'ed  much  the  same  public  liberties 
everywhere  —  exemption  from  arbitrary  taxa- 
tion, right  to  local  jm-isdiction,  the  privilege  of 
enfranchising  the  villein  who  had  been  received 
for  a  year  or  a  year  and  a  half  within  the  city's 
walls,  and  the  power  of  electing  officers  and 
raising  militia.  To  these  public  liberties 
private  liberties  were  generally  added,  such  as  the 
right  of  citizens  to  marriage  without  the  consent 
of  their  lord,  the  right  of  leaving  their  property 
to  their  children,  and  the  like.  But  such 
privileges  were  not  gi-anted  without  fixed  pay- 
ments to  the  feudal  lord  on  the  part  of  the 
community  in  lieu  of  the  uncertain  exactions 
that  had  been  previously  levied  in  the  shape  of 
poll  taxes  and  transit  dues  from  individual 
traders.  One  important  result  followed  from 
such  fixed  payments,  namely,  freedom  of  trade 
within  the  area  belonging  to  the  feudal  lord,  an 
area  which  gradually  extended  with  the  exten- 
sion of  the  domain  of  the  feudal  over-lord  or 
king.  As  the  wealth  of  the  cities  increased 
under  these  favourable  conditions,  the  fixed 
payments,  which  had  taken  the  place  of  the 
old  services  and  taxes,  were  supplemented  by 
demands  for  extraordinary  subsidies,  and  in 
settling  these  extra  payments  the  cities  came 
to  be  represented  in  the  council  of  the  nation, 
like  the  other  feudal  tenants,  and  an  urban 
commonalty  was  eventually  formed  by  the 
bond  of  common  interests.  When  once  the 
status  of  the  city  was  more  or  less  secure,  its 
civic  constitution  underwent  a  change.  The 
democratic  equality  of  an  age  of  confusion, 
based  on  individual  strength  and  courage,  gave 
way  to  the  oligarchical  inequality  of  a  more 
settled  state  of  society,  based  on  Avealth  and 
intelligence.  The  meeting  of  all  the  inhabitants 
of  the  city  to  resist  feudal  aggression  was  super- 
seded by  the  meeting  of  the  chief  owners  of 
houses  and  shops  to  promote  commercial  enter- 


prise. Trade  being  more  and  more  the  gi-eat 
interest  of  the  city,  the  great  merchants  grew 
in  prestige,  and  in  their  associations  or  guilds 
gained  political  power. 

The  origin  of  the  civic  Gilds  {q.v.)  is  to  be 
sought  in  remote  antiquity.  The  simple  idea 
(see  Stubbs)  of  a  confraternity  united  for  the 
discharge  of  common  or  mutual  good  ofiices, 
supported  by  contributions  of  money  from  each 
member,  and  celebrating  its  meetings  by  a 
periodical  festival,  may  find  parallels  in  any 
civilised  nation  at  any  age  of  the  world.  The 
ancient  guild  is  simj)ly  the  club  or  associa- 
tion of  modern  life.  It  was  formed  on  the 
analogy  of  the  family  gi'oup,  and  was  in  many 
cases  consecrated  by  religious  ceremonies.  The 
ends  it  subserved  were  very  various — relief  in 
poverty,  sickness,  old  age,  or  in  temporary  difli- 
culties,  in  loss  of  property,  in  making  pilgrim 
ages,  dowry  on  marriage,  repair  of  roads  and 
bridges,  and  churches.  The  tendency  to  unite 
in  frith  guilds  or  clubs  for  mutual  protection 
became  general  throughout  Europe  in  the  9th 
and  10th  centuries.  In  parts  of  the  continent 
these  guilds  were  roughly  repressed,  but  in 
England  and  in  the  more  inde]iendent  towns  of 
the  continent  they  formed  more  and  more  the 
basis  of  urban  life,  and  as  trade  and  commerce 
became  the  chief  interests  of  the  towns,  mer- 
cliants  and  traders  naturally  formed  their  guilds 
or  associations  on  the  analogy  of  those  already 
existing.  As  the  maintenance  of  the  privileges 
and  immunities  of  towns  became  more  and  more 
a  matter  of  money  payment,  the  wealthy  part 
of  the  commercial  community  that  made  itself 
responsible  for  this  payment,  and  thereby  pro- 
tected the  town  and  its  trade  from  feudal 
encroachment,  absorbed  civic  power.  In 
many  cases  charters  of  incorporation  were 
granted  or  confirmed  to  the  chief  guilds  or 
guild.  In  fact  these  corporations  were  invested 
A\-ith  an  urban  lordship,  ranking  side  by  side 
with  the  smaller  rural  lordships,  exercising 
jurisdiction,  enacting  bye-laws,  levying  taxation, 
organising  the  militia,  repairing  the  city  walls, 
in  short,  carrying  on  all  the  functions  of  govern- 
ment within  a  limited  area.  The  membership 
of  a  guild  then  became  recognised  as  the  pass- 
port to  civic  privileges,  and  so  long  as  the 
membership  in  some  guild  was  open  to  every  in- 
habitant with  a  stake  in  the  city,  the  constitu- 
tion remained  more  or  less  democratic.  But 
the  enhancement  of  the  commercial  privileges 
secured  by  the  cities  made  the  merchant  guilds 
more  and  more  reluctant  to  admit  new  mem- 
bers. Below  the  merchant  guilds  and  outside 
the  constitution,  there  were  formed  crade  or  craft 
guilds  of  the  small  manufacturers  or  artisans, 
weavers,  shoemakers,  carpenters,  and  the  like. 
The  greater  folk  of  the  large  capitalists  stood 
over  against  the  lesser  folk  of  the  small  capital- 
ists, and  as  the  numbers  of  the  latter  increased 
with  the  growth  of  manufactures,  and  the  influx 


294 


CITY,  MEDIEVAL 


of  countrymen  into  the  towns,  a  struggle  for 
power  ensued  between  the  two  classes  of  guilds, 
and  in  some  of  the  continental  cities,  especially 
in  the  Rhine  valley,  took  the  form  of  civil  war. 

The  result  of  this  struggle  was  in  many  in- 
stances the  enlargement  of  the  civic  constitution 
by  the  admission  of  the  craft  guilds,  but  these 
in  turn  became  exclusive,  and  largely  directed 
towards  securing  markets  for  their  goods,  while 
with  the  growth  of  capitalist  manufacturers  and 
the  separation  of  masters  and  men  in  various 
industries,  the  artisan  population  of  modern 
times  began  to  grow  up  and  form  a  fresh  urban 
community.  With  the  spread  of  the  Reforma- 
tion a  strong  tide  of  feeling  set  in  against  guilds 
in  general,  and  we  find  in  England  a  succession 
of  laws  passed  in  restraint  of  their  authority. 
Although  shorn  of  some  of  their  powers  and 
privileges,  the  merchant  and  trade  guilds 
managed  to  survive  in  a  less  exclusive  form, 
and  proved  valuable  sources  of  revenue  in  times 
of  emergency.  Henry  VIII.,  Elizabeth,  the 
Stuarts,  and  Cromwell  alike  received  money  out 
of  their  coffers,  and  in  return  were  content  to 
leave  them  the  real  centres  of  civic  power. 

In  spite,  however,  of  the  prevalence  of  the 
oligarchical  form  of  civic  government,  the  medi- 
aeval cities  were  the  nurseries  of  modem  freedom, 
of  civil  and  religious  rights.  Within  their 
walls  there  grew  up  the  professional  classes — 
lawyers,  doctors,  teachers,  writers,  and  the  like, 
who  gradually  formed  the  intellectual  leaders 
of  the  commonalty.  The  separation  of  munici- 
pal and  ecclesiastical  authority  in  the  persons 
of  the  magistrate  and  town  council  and  the 
bishops  and  clergy,  tended  to  create  a  liberty 
of  thought  and  action  such  as  had  been  un- 
known in  the  ancient  world  with  its  identifica- 
tion of  church  and  state,  and  prepared  the  way 
for  the  Reformation  movement.  At  the  bottom 
of  the  social  scale  the  influence  of  civic  life  was 
equally  beneficial.  Although  the  mass  of  the 
townsfolk  were  in  a  very  degraded  condition,  yet 
they  were  freemen  and  not  slaves,  like  the 
artisans  of  ancient  Greece  and  Rome,  or  serfs, 
like  the  rural  population  outside  the  city  walls. 
The  town  labourers,  too,  enjoyed  some  portion 
of  civil  liberty  and  knew  how  to  combine  against 
oppression,  and,  while  struggling  to  raise  them- 
selves in  the  town,  found  a  response  from  their 
brothers  on  the  land.  The  barriers  between 
the  rich  and  the  poor  were  regarded  as  fixed, 
not  as  in  the  past  by  a  supposed  law  of  nature, 
but  by  a  contrivance  of  man.  The  church  had 
from  early  times  set  its  face  against  slavery ;  the 
city  bred  the  spirit  that  eventually  killed  serf- 
dom. While  the  growth  of  the  capitalistic 
classes,  the  rise  of  the  professional  classes, 
and  the  increase  of  the  wage-earning  masses 
were  gradually  modifying  the  life  of  the  cities 
from  within,  their  external  relations  to  the  mon- 
archical regime  which  was  being  consolidated  in 
most  parts  of  Europe  during  the  14th,   15th, 


and  16th  centuries,  were  slowly  but  surely  modi- 
fying civic  life  from  without.  In  France,  Spain, 
Holland,  and  England,  if  not  in  Germany  and 
Italy,  the  cities  began  to  lose  their  local  inde- 
pendence and  quasi-sovereign  powers,  and  to 
take  their  place  in  a  more  centralised  system 
of  national  government.  In  Germany,  owing 
to  the  weakness  of  the  central  authority;  and 
in  Italy,  owing  to  the  absence  of  any  centre  of 
national  authority  and  the  standing  conflict 
between  the  adherents  of  the  imperial  and  papal 
principle,  the  great  Hanseatic  cities  and  the 
republics  of  Lombardy,  were  able  for  a  longer 
time  to  maintain  their  independence,  but  the 
outbreak  of  the  Thirty  Years'  War  in  Germany 
and  the  invasion  of  Italy  by  Spain  and  France 
undermined  their  sovereign  strength,  and  in 
those  countries,  too,  the  cities  began  to  sigh 
for  the  strong  hand  of  central  control  visible  in 
western  Europe.  The  signs  of  central  control 
were  to  be  seen  in  the  limitation  of  local 
administration  of  justice,  in  the  extension  of 
national  taxation,  in  the  formation  of  a  national 
army  and  navy,  and,  in  some  countries,  in  the 
nomination  of  civic  magistrates  by  the  central 
government.  The  ideas  of  self-government 
nurtured  in  the  seedplots  of  cities  were  being 
transplanted  to  the  national  soil,  and  what 
the  citizens  lost  in  local  privileges  they  regained 
in  national  rights.  The  conception  of  national 
free  trade,  national  freedom  of  thought,  national 
freedom  of  action,  took  the  place  of  that  of  local 
liberties  and  immunities.  In  a  country  like 
France,  with  a  strongly  centralised  government, 
and  with  an  undeveloped  system  of  national 
representation,  the  decay  of  local  independence 
was  too  rapid  for  national  well-being,  but  in 
England  the  spirit  of  local  independence  took 
fuU  possession  of  the  central  government.  With 
the  growth  of  industry  in  the  17th  and  18th 
centuries  and  the  spread  of  democratic  ideas 
that  found  their  most  emphatic  expression  in 
the  French  Revolution,  the  system  of  commercial 
monopolies  and  privileges  was  shaken  to  the 
centre.  With  the  improvement  of  communica- 
tions by  road,  river,  and  canal  the  demand  for 
national  free  trade  and  the  destruction  of  re- 
maining barriers  between  town  and  country  or 
districts  and  provinces  became  louder  and  louder, 
and  with  the  fall  of  the  old  commercial  system 
civic  constitutions  cried  out  for  reform. 

Ghent  may  supply  an  example  of  the 
mediaeval  city  on  a  very  large  scale.  Favoured 
by  natural  conditions,  it  was  one  of  the 
earliest  places  of  the  north-west  part  of 
continental  Europe  to  become  the  centre  of 
trade  and  industry ;  and  to  develop  the  power 
of  defending  its  growing  wealth.  Towards  the 
close  of  the  12th  century  it  purchased  com- 
mercial and  political  privileges  from  its  feudal 
lord,  the  Count  of  Flanders,  and  secured  some 
increase  of  municipal  self-government.  Civic 
jurisdiction  took  the   place  of  manorial,   and 


CITY,  MODERN 


29S 


although  at  first,  as  in  other  cities,  the  local 
magisti-ates  were  appointed  by  the  feudal  lord, 
yet  in  time  the  power  of  election  was  granted 
to  the  citizens.  A  later  charter  gave  the  power 
of  fortifying  the  city  and  of  raising  a 
militia.  By  the  beginning  of  the  15th  cen- 
tury the  external  circuit  measured  9  miles, 
the  city  area  was  broken  up  into  easily  de- 
fensible districts  by  the  arms  of  the  river,  the 
banks  being  connected  by  drawbridges,  and 
at  the  sound  of  the  famous  bell  Koland,  20,000 
armed  men  prepared  to  fight  for  their  liberties. 
The  constitution  of  the  city  Avas  originally 
democratic  though  controlled  by  the  feudal 
authority  above  it,  but,  when  municipal 
charters  had  conferred  complete  self-govern- 
ment, the  power  of  the  merchant  guilds 
gradually  transformed  it  into  an  oligarchy.  In 
the  14th  century  the  city  was  torn  asunder  by 
the  internal  factions  of  the  merchant  and  craft 
guUds.  The  latter,  especially  those  of  the 
wool-weavers,  had  been  established  very  early 
in  Flanders  owing  to  the  wealth  of  the  manu- 
facturing industries  and  the  necessity  of  defend- 
ing them  against  the  merchants,  and  it  Avas 
only  after  a  fierce  and  bloody  struggle  that 
political  power  was  redistributed  on  a  broader 
principle  by  the  absorption  of  the  merchants' 
guilds  into  the  trade  guilds.  The  final  shape 
the  constitution  assumed  in  the  15  th  century 
was  as  follows  : — The  population  was  divided 
into  fifty-two  guilds  of  manufacturers  and  into 
thirty- two  ti'ibes  of  weavers,  each  fraternity  elect- 
ing annually  or  biennially  its  own  deans  and  sub- 
ordinate officers.  The  senate,  which  exercised 
functions  legislative,  judicial,  and  administra- 
tive, subject  to  the  feudal  court  of  appeal 
sitting  at  Mechlin  and  to  the  sovereign  authority, 
consisted  of  twenty-six  members.  These  were 
appointed  partly  from  the  upper  class  or  the  men 
who  lived  upon  their  means,  partly  from  the 
manufacturers  in  general,  and  partly  from  the 
weavers.  They  were  chosen  by  a  college  of  eight 
electors  who  were  appointed  by  the  sovereign 
on  nomination  by  the  electors.  The  whole 
city  in  its  collective  capacity  formed  one  of  the 
four  estates  of  the  province  of  Flanders.  The 
quarrels  of  Ghent  with  its  liege  lord  generally 
arose  from  the  demands  of  the  latter  for  extra- 
ordinary subsidies  to  raise  a  mercenary  force. 
If  the  subsidy  was  refused,  war  as  often  as  not 
ensued,  and  though  the  burghers  might  be 
defeated  on  the  open  field,  yet  they  were 
unassailable  behind  therr  walls  against  the 
armed  force  of  feudalism.  It  was  only  when 
standing  armies  took  the  place  of  feudal  militia 
and  political  passions  divided  the  city,  that 
Ghent  had  to  submit  to  the  loss  of  its  liberties. 

[Motley,  History  of  the  Dutch  RepMic. — 
Froissart.  —  Philippe  de  Comines.  —  Hallam's 
Middle  Ages. — Guizot,  Civilisation  in  Europe 
and  France. — Sismondi,  Histoire  de  la  chute  de 
V Empire  Roviain  et  du  D6clin  de  la  Civilisation — 


Histoire  des  Republiques  Italiennes  du  Moyen  Age. 
— Stubbs,  Constitutional  History.  — Hallam's  Con- 
stitutional History  of  Europe  during  the  Middle 
Ages. — Freeman's  Essays,  2d  series. — Gneist's 
Self- Government  in  England  and  History  oj 
English  Constitution. — English  Guilds,  by  Toul- 
min  Smith. — Guilds,  hj  C.  Walford.  —  Wealth  of 
Nations,  by  Adam  Smith,  bk.  iii.  ch.  iii.  and  iv. — 
Hanse  Towns,  by  H.  Zimmeru. — Histoire  des 
Frangais  by  Lavallee,  vol.  i. — Maurer's  Geschichte 
der  Stadt-verfassung  in  Deutschland.  —  Bryce's 
Holy  Roman  Empire.']  a.  k.  c. 

City,  Modern.  The  modern  city  is  in 
some  respects  a  revival  of  the  ancient  city  of  the 
Roman  empire.  It  is  a  unit  of  administration 
in  a  larger  state,  and  its  powers  and  privileges 
are  strictly  dependent  on  the  central  authority, 
whatever  be  the  nature  of  the  latter.  It 
difiers  from  its  prototype  :  first,  because  the 
principle  of  its  government  is  democratic, 
not  aristocratic  ;  second,  because  the  scope  of  its 
governmental  authority  is  strictly  defined  by 
statute  law,  and  not  by  custom  or  conquest. 
Residence  or  payment  of  rates  in  a  certain  area 
are  the  modern  titles  to  urban  citizenship ; 
popular  election  or  selection  by  an  elected  body 
is  the  general  method  of  appointing  the  munici- 
pal administrator  ;  bye-laws  form  the  extreme 
limit  of  the  city  council's  legislative  power  ;  and 
rates  raised  in  a  certain  manner  are  the  main 
sources  of  civic  revenue.  The  time  of  residence, 
the  amount  of  the  rates,  the  method  of  elec- 
tion, the  qualifications  requisite  for  municipal 
honours,  the  extent  of  administrative  functions 
and  of  the  by-laws,  the  incidence  and  assess- 
ment of  rates,  may  vary  enormously  in  the 
ditferent  countries  of  Europe,  in  America,  in  the 
British  colonies  and  Indian  empire  ;  but  in  all 
parts  of  the  world  of  modem  civilisation,  with 
the  exception  perhaps  of  Russia,  the  above 
features  characterise  the  modern  city.  Any 
man,  and  in  the  most  advanced  countries  any 
woman,  is  at  liberty,  by  taking  a  certain  course 
of  action  which  is  open  to  all,  to  exercise  the 
rights  of  citizenship  in  an  urban  community. 
He  can  be  only  prevented  from  exercising  such 
rights  by  his  own  choice,  fault,  or  misfortune. 
Physical,  mental,  or  moral  obstacles,  that  is  to 
say  personal  impediments,  may  stQl  exist,  but 
there  are  no  insurmountable  barriers  of  law  or 
custom. 

The  subordination  of  the  modern  city  to  a 
central  authority  shows  itself  chiefly  in  the 
sharper  line  which  is  drawn  in  modern  times 
between  local  and  national  affairs,  only  those 
affairs  being  local  which  are  by  their  very  nature 
rooted  in  a  clearly  defined  area.  The  mediaeval 
city  in  the  time  of  its  strength  had,  as  we  have 
seen,  within  its  boundaries  almost  complete 
self-government.  It  administered  its  own 
justice,  largely  based  on  customary  precedents, 
it  assessed  its  own  rates  and  taxes,  and  handed 
over  a  lump  sum  to  the  central  government,  it 
preserved  its  own  peace  and  order,  and  it  raised 


29G 


CITY,  MODERN 


its  own  militia.  The  only  sovereign  power  it 
did  not  possess  after  the  rise  of  national  govern- 
ment was  the  right  of  making  peace  and  war. 
The  modern  city  has  almost  entirely  lost  the 
right  of  local  jurisdiction,  it  raises  its  own  rates 
but  has  its  taxes  collected  for  it  by  national 
officials,  it  is  in  many  cases  responsible  for  its 
own  peace  and  order,  but  it  has  no  control  over 
an  armed  force,  and  has  to  ask  for  its  help  if 
it  requires  it.  On  the  other  hand  it  exercises 
many  local  functions  which  in  the  Middle  Ages 
were  either  left  to  the  church  or  to  private 
enterprise  or  to  compulsory  service,  or  were 
disregarded.  Poor  relief  and  education  are  now 
supplied  or  supervised  by  the  chief  civic  body 
or  by  co-ordinate  bodies.  Sanitation  is  a  matter 
of  public  concern  not  of  private  caprice,  roads 
and  bridges  are  constructed  and  repaired  at  the 
public  expense  not  by  means  of  private  tolls, 
and  lighting  and  water  supply,  in  old  times  left 
to  nature,  are  controlled  if  not  provided  by  the 
municipality.  The  line  drawn  between  local 
and  national  affairs  varies  in  certain  points  in 
different  countries,  but,  speaking  generally,  local 
affairs  are  those  matters  that  touch  on  interests 
which  are  more  immediately  connected  with  the 
city's  welfare,  which  the  ordinary  self-interest 
of  the  citizens  is  supposed  to  be  capable  of 
managing,  and  which  do  not  admit  of  uni- 
form regulation,  e.g.  roads,  bridges,  markets, 
harbours,  lighting  and  watering  ;  while  national 
atlaii-s  are  those  in  which  the  nation  as  a  whole 
is  more  immediately  concerned,  which  would 
not  be  provided  for  by  civic  self-interest,  and 
which  require  uniformity  of  treatment.  Such 
are  civil  and  criminal  justice,  based  on  general 
principles  of  legal  rights  and  penalties,  national 
defence,  postal  communications,  commercial 
regulations,  and  the  provision  of  revenues  re- 
quired for  effecting  such  purposes.  Between 
the  two  fairly  distinct  classes  of  local  and 
national  affairs  come  those  that  are  local  in 
their  application,  and  yet  national  in  their 
interest — such  as  sanitation,  police,  poor  relief, 
and  education. 

In  the  case  of  sanitation,  the  administration, 
though  generally  left  in  the  hands  of  the  city, 
tends  more  and  more,  with  the  spread  of 
sanitary  science,  to  be  supervised  by  the  central 
government.  This  at  least  is  the  principle  on 
which  local  government  in  Great  Britain  is  now 
conducted  under  various  sanitary  acts,  and 
other  countries  are  beginning  to  follow  its  ex- 
ample. In  the  case  of  police  there  is  great 
diversity  of  practice  in  modern  cities.  From 
one  point  of  view  nothing  is  more  distinctly  a 
local  affair  than  the  preservation  of  peace  and 
order  within  a  given  area,  but  from  another 
point  of  view,  namely,  the  grave  danger  to  the 
nation  as  a  whole  of  any  local  outbreak  in  a 
large  centre  of  industry,  it  becomes  a  national 
affair.  In  all  European  countries  as  well  as  in 
America   the   police  in  the   capital   is  under 


national  not  municipal  control,  but  in  the  pro- 
vincial cities  practice  varies  according  as  the 
more  or  less  direction  is  left  to  the  central 
government.  But  in  no  country  is  the  city  left 
responsible  to  its  own  citizens  alone  for  the 
efficiency  of  its  police  force,  and  in  some  cases, 
as  in  France  and  Belgium,  there  is  a  national 
or  state  police  acting  side  by  side  with  the  local 
police.  In  the  administi-ation  of  poor  relief 
there  is  also  much  divergence  of  practice. 
Sometimes  the  local  body  that  administers  relief 
is  a  committee  appointed  by  the  municipal 
council — this  is  the  case  in  Germany  and  in 
some  American  cities ;  sometimes  it  is  the 
municipal  council  itself,  as  in  France  ;  some- 
times it  is  a  separate  local  body  for  the  most 
part  locally  elected  but  supplemented  by  justices 
of  the  peace,  as  in  England  ;  but  in  all  countiies 
there  is  a  tendency  towards  central  control  of 
local  bodies  in  the  matter  of  poor  relief,  and  in 
this  respect  the  local  government  board  of 
England  has  led  the  way.  Lastly,  popular 
education  is  locally  administered,  but  as  a  rule 
by  bodies  elected  ad  hoc,  if  not  by  a  committee 
of  the  municipal  council.  The  local  body  as  a 
rule  acts  under  state  laws  and  sometimes  by 
help  of  state  subsidies,  but  it  raises  a  local  ra:te 
where  schobls  are  civic  and  not  voluntary  estsrt)- 
lishments. 

But  however  much  the  scope  of  local  affairs 
and  the  methods  of  administering  them  may 
vary  in  different  countries,  yet  in  all  there  is 
a  large  and  on  the  whole  an  increasing 
amount  of  central  control,  financial  and  ad- 
ministrative. This  control  is  exercised  in 
England  chiefly  through  the  central  depart- 
ments, in  America  through  the  state,  in  France 
and  Germany  through  the  national  executive, 
which  has  a  voice  in  the  appointment  of  the 
mayor  and  burgomaster,  but  in  each  case  it  is 
vital  and  vigilant.  The  local  bodies  are  no  longer 
independent  organisms  self-acting  ;  they  are  the 
appendages  of  a  larger  organism.  Local  self- 
government  has  given  way  to  local  government. 

Manchester  may  be  taken  as  a  typical  ex- 
ample of  the  modern  English  city.  Although 
a  flourishing  town  in  the  Middle  Ages,  and 
possessed  of  certain  limited  rights  of  self- 
government  exercised  through  the  court-leet, 
yet  it  did  not  become  a  municipality  propel 
until  the  passing  of  the  Municipal  Reform  Bill  of 
1835.  It  became  a  City  in  1853  and  a  County 
Borough  in  1 8  8  9 .  With  a  population  of  7 1 4, 4  2  7, 
1911 ;  it  is  now  the  third  (if  Salford  is  included, 
population  1911,  231,380,  the  second)  largest 
city  in  Great  Britain.  Its  municipal  business  is 
administered  by  a  Lord  Mayor  and  City  council 
of  123  members,  93  being  councillors  elected  by 
the  ratepayers  in  30  wards,  and  30  aldermen 
co-opted  by  the  councillors.  The  Lord  Mayor 
(title  granted  1893)  is  elected  by  the  council  for  , 
a  year,  and  is  paid  ;  the  rest  of  the  council  is 
unpaid.     The  council  administers  the  sanitary 


CITY,  MODERN— CIVIL  LAW 


297 


acts,  maintains  the  jjolice  force,  makes  and 
repairs  urban  roads,  controls  building  opera- 
tions, and  supplies  electricity.  It  also, 
in  virtue  of  special  acts,  supplies  the  town 
with  water  and  gas.  It  manages  the  City  Art 
Galleries,  the  Free  Library,  the  Ship  Canal, 
Higher  and  Elementary  Education  includin^^ 
the  Municipal  Secondary  School,  the  municipal 
School  of  Art,  and  the  School  of  Technology, 
the  Principal  of  which  is  on  the  Council  of 
the  Victoria  University  of  Manchester.  The 
Guardians  of  the  Poor  for  the  varidus  Poor 
Law  Unions  are  elected  by  the  ratepayers  or 
magistrates.  Justice  isadministered  by  officers  of 
the  crown,  a  stipendiary  police  magistrate,  the 
Manchester  city  justices,  the  mayor  and  ex- 
mayor  being  ex  q^cw  justices,  a  recorder  for  more 
important  criminal  cases,  a  county  court  judge 
for  small  civil  suits,  and,  finally,  the  assize  judges 
as  the  highest  criminal  and  civil  court. 

The  town  council's  legislative  power  only  ex- 
tends to  that  of  passing  by-laws  ;  the  reason- 
ableness of  by-laws  can  be  disputed  in  a  court 
of  law,  and  they  are  not  binding  like  acts  of  par- 
liament. The  corporation  and  town  council  can 
sue  and  be  sued  like  an  individual.  It  must 
meet  four  times  a  year  at  least,  it  must  appoint 
a  finance  and  police  committee,  it  must  send  in 
its  accounts  to  the  local  government  board,  it 
cannot  borrow  money  except  with  the  consent 
of  the  local  government  board  or  some  other 
central  department,  and  it  cannot  raise  money 
except  in  certain  specified  ways,  chiefly  by  a  rate 
on  occupied  houses,  and  for  certain  specified  pm-- 
poses.  It  it  wants  to  have  its  powers  in  any 
way  enlarged  it  must  apply  to  parliament,  whose 
creature  it  is. 

\Local  Government  and  Taxation  in  the  United 
Kingdom,  Cobden  Club  Series. — Local  Govern- 
ment, Chalmers  (English  Citizen  Series). — De- 
mocracy in  America,  De  Tocqueville  (tr.  Henry 
Reeve). — A  merican  CommonwealthyBryce. — Stein's 
Life,  by  Seeley. — Maurer's  Geschichte  der  Stadt- 
Verfassung  in  Deutschland.]  A.  K.  c. 

CITY  OF  LONDON,  COMPANIES  OF. 
See  Companies,  City  of  London. 

CIVITj  law,  in  the  widest  sense  of  the  term, 
denotes  the  law  of  the  state,  as  distinguished 
from  the  law  Christian  or  Canon  Law  (q.v.) 
In  a  narrower  sense  the  term  is  used  to  denote 
the  Roman  law,  the  great  storehouse  of  rules 
and  principles  from  which  the  institutions  of 
modern  states  have  been  in  great  part  derived. 
The  history  of  Roman  laAv  begins  with  the  un- 
written customary  rules  observed  by  the  gentes 
and  curia}  which  made  up  the  ancient  city-state, 
and  with  the  leges  or  written  laws  in  which 
the  sovereign  people  declared  its  will.  When 
the  plebeians  made  good  their  claim  to  political 
rights,  the  most  important  rules  of  the  early 
law  were  roughly  codified  in  the  Twelve  Tables 
(450  B.C.),  and  in  process  of  time  new  laws 
came  to  be  made  by  the  assembly  of  the  plebeian 


tribes  ;  a  plebiscitum  had  the  authority  of  a  lex. 
As  the  ti-ade  of  the  city  increased,  it  was  found 
necessary  to  supplement  the  old  civil  law  by 
rules  of  a  less  formal  and  more  rational  character, 
such  as  might  be  applied  to  traders  and  others 
who  were  not  Romans  ;  these  rules  formed  the 
so  called  law  of  nations,  i.e.  the  law  administered 
by  Roman  magistrates  to  men  of  all  civilised 
nations.  This  wider  laAV  was  afterwards  identi- 
fied with  the  law  of  nature,  a  conception 
borrowed  from  Greek  philosophy.  Nature 
implants  in  man  the  instincts  which  lead  him 
to  form  societies  and  states,  and  nature  endows 
man  with  reason,  the  power  which  enables  him 
to  improve  legal  rules,  and  to  administer  the 
law  in  a  spirit  of  equity.  With  these  philo- 
sophic notions  the  Romans  combined  great 
practical  skill ;  their  forms  of  conveyancing, 
their  system  of  accounts,  and  the  procedure  of 
their  courts  have  exercised  and  still  continue 
to  exercise  an  important  influence  on  all  the 
commercial  transactions  of  the  modern  world. 
The  success  of  their  imperial  policy  gave  them 
a  wide  field  for  legislation  and  administration  ; 
but  empire  brought  with  it  a  change  in  the 
character  of  the  civil  law.  The  public  law  of 
the  ancient  city  was  subverted  in  the  interest 
of  a  centralised  despotism  ;  the  private  law, 
i.e.  the  law  relating  to  property,  contracts, 
family  relations,  etc.,  was  gi'eatly  developed 
and  improved  ;  the  emperors  began  by  using 
the  senate  as  their  instrument  of  legislation  ; 
then  they  dispensed  with  formalities  and 
assumed  the  right  to  make  constitutions  or 
new  laws  by  their  own  authority.  In  applying 
the  Roman  law  throughout  the  provinces, 
magistrates  were  much  embarrassed  by  the 
number  and  complexity  of  legal  rules  and  text- 
books. Several  attempts  were  made  to  codify 
the  whole  law  ;  and  Justinian  finally  gave  his 
sanction  to  a  code  of  imperial  constitutions,  a 
digest  of  the  works  of  the  best  jurists,  and  a 
book  called  the  Institutes,  which  was  to  form 
the  basis  of  legal  education.  These  three  works 
form  the  Corpus  Juris,  the  authoritative  exposi- 
tion of  the  civil  law. 

In  the  history  of  Roman  law  we  may  study 
the  origin  of  those  commercial  conceptions  of 
property  and  contract  which  modern  economists 
make  the  basis  of  their  science.  According  to 
the  old  customary  law,  property  belonged  to 
family  groups  ;  the  paterfamilias  had  no  very 
extensive  rights  of  alienation  ;  things  necessary 
to  the  family  existence,  such  as  land  and  slaves, 
were  alienated  with  the  cumbrous  form  called 
mancipation,  other  things  only  with  the  forms 
of  a  fictitious  lawsuit.  By  the  later  law,  the 
dominus  or  owner  had  extensive  and  wsll- 
defined  rights  of  use  and  abuse ;  he  could 
alienate  inter  vivos,  and,  within  certain  limits, 
by  will,  at  his  own  discretion.  The  full  rights 
of  dominium  were  conceded  to  persons  not 
recognised  as  owners  by  the  formal  customary 


298 


CIVIL  LAW 


law ;  possession  of  land  allotted  by  the  state 
came  to  be  equivalent  to  ownership  ;  and  equit- 
able ownership  came  to  be  as  safe,  under  the 
protection  of  the  praetor,  as  the  dominium  of 
the  Quiritarian  or  ancient  Roman  law.  A  thing 
which  could  legally  be  owned  was  said  to  Ije  in 
commercio,  a  thing  to  be  disposed  of;  such 
things  were  corporeal  or  tangible  (land,  goods, 
money,  etc.)  or  incorporeal  (debts  and  valuable 
rights).  Immovable  things  (land  and  house 
property)  are  distinguished  from  movable 
things  (goods,  etc.)  It  is  to  be  observed  that 
the  Eoman  law  does  not  attach  any  special 
importance  to  property  in  land  ;  the  dominus 
of  land  came  to  have  very  much  the  same 
freedom  of  alienation  as  the  owner  of  goods  ;  a 
person  not  the  owner  of  land  acquired  rights 
over  it  only  by  virtue  of  some  definite  contract 
or  transfer  of  property  rights  on  the  part  of 
the  owner.  The  complication  and  difl&culty  of 
property  law  arise  from  the  various  arrange- 
ments by  which  the  rights  constituting  full 
ownership  may  be  separated  from  one  another 
and  vested  in  different  persons.  The  custody 
and  use  of  a  thing  which  belongs  to  A  may  be 
transferred  by  agreement  to  B  ;  A  may  be 
restricted  in  the  use  and  alienation  of  his 
property  by  reason  of  rights  vested  in  B  :  in 
other  words,  B  may  enjoy  a  servitude  over  the 
property  of  A.  B  may  have  a  right-of-way  over 
the  land  of  A,  a  right  •  to  use  the  land  for  his 
own  convenience,  and  this  we  may  call  a  posi- 
tive servitude.  Or  he  may  have  a  right  to 
forbid  the  erection  of  a  building  on  A's  land 
which  would  obstruct  the  passage  of  light  to  a 
neighbouring  house,  and  this  we  may  call  a 
negative  servitude.  Rights  of  way  and  rights 
to  light  are  prsedial  servitudes  ;  they  cannot 
be  claimed  unless  by  the  owners  or  occupiers  of 
neighbouring  property.  There  are  also  personal 
servitudes,  rights  over  the  property  of  another 
enjoyed  by  an  individual  without  regard  to  his 
ownership  or  occupation  of  property.  Of  these 
the  most  important  is  usufruct,  the  right  to  use 
and  take  the  fruits  or  profits  of  property  belonging 
to  another.  Where  money  and  goods  are  treated 
as  capital,  one  person  may  have  the  usufruct  or 
quasi-usufruct,  the  capital  stock  being  preserved 
intact  for  the  persons  interested  in  the  corpus. 
The  law  of  contract  exhibits  the  same  gradual 
extension  of  individual  liberty  as  we  observe  in 
the  law  of  property.  Primitive  custom  hardly 
permits  a  person  to  alter  his  rights  by  his  own 
act,  or  by  private  agreement  with  another.  But 
in  time  reasons  are  found  for  enforcing  certain 
kinds  of  agreement.  These  are  (a)  real  contracts, 
i.e.  those  which  are  concluded  by  transfer  of  a 
thing.  If  e.g.  a  person  actually  receives  a  thing 
by  way  of  loan  or  deposit,  he  is  compelled  to 
restore  the  thing  or  its  equivalent.  Barter  is  a 
real  contract ;  it  becomes  binding  when  one 
party  has  actually  performed  his  part  of  the 
bargain,  do  ut  des.     In  the  case  of  (6)  formal 


contracts,  Avhere  the  agreement  is  binding  be- 
cause the  parties  have  used  some  solemn  form  ; 
they  have  exchanged  the  words  of  question  and 
answer  known  as  a  stipulation  (verbal  obligation), 
or  they  have  joined  in  making  an  entry  of  the 
debt  in  the  creditor's  ledger  (literal  obligation). 
Further,  the  law  recognises  consensual  contracts, 
which  owe  their  binding  force  to  the  agreement 
of  the  parties.  In  an  action  on  a  formal  con- 
tract, claim  and  defence  must  be  founded  on  the 
strict  letter  of  the  law  ;  in  an  action  on  a  con- 
sensual contract,  plaintiff  and  defendant  might 
be  ordered  to  do  what  was  fair  and  right.  To 
the  class  of  consensual  contracts  belong  the 
most  important  commercial  transactions — sale, 
letting  and  hiring,  partnership,  and  mandate. 
Such  were  the  lines  on  which  the  Roman  lawyers 
constructed  their  system  of  proprietary  and  con- 
tractual rights.  To  give  effect  to  the  rights 
recognised  by  law  is  the  ofiice  of  courts  and 
magistrates.  At  Rome  and  elsewhere  the  reign 
of  force  precedes  the  reign  of  law ;  self-redress 
is  the  rule  of  aU  early  communities  ;  it  is  only 
by  degrees  that  the  state  assumes  authority  to 
decide  private  disputes.  First  we  have  custom- 
ary rules  by  which  money  payments  might  be 
made  in  atonement  for  wrongful  acts  ;  there 
are  also  cusloms  and  forms  by  which  private 
transactions  are  placed  under  public  protection 
— a  sale,  a  will,  or  a  contract  is  made  in  presence 
of  the  people,  or  of  witnesses  representing  ihe 
people,  and  the  community  is  thus  bound  to  see 
that  the  parties  perform  their  duty.  Finally, 
disputes  when  they  arise  are  referred  to  arbitra- 
tion, and  forms  of  process  are  prescribed  by  the 
magistrates.  Of  the  forms  of  action  known  to 
the  oldest  Roman  law,  one  was  a  request  that 
the  magistrate  would  appoint  an  arbitrator  ; 
another  took  the  form  of  a  solemn  wager,  each 
party  depositing  a  stake  which  was  forfeited  if 
he  failed  to  prove  his  case.  On  the  analogy  of 
this  action  by  wager  was  framed  the  amdictio, 
a  remedy  which  seems  to  have  been  introduced 
in  the  interest  of  creditors  and  the  money- 
lending  class.  There  were  also  forms  of  execu- 
tion, by  which  a  creditor  could  seize  his  debtor's 
property  and  hold  it  as  a  pledge,  or  lay  hands 
on  the  debtor  himself  and  bring  him  before  the 
praetor.  If  the  debtor  did  not  discharge  or 
formally  contest  his  liability,  the  creditor  might 
take  him  away  and  detain  him  in  custody  ; 
after  the  lapse  of  a  prescribed  time  the  debtor 
might  be  sold  into  slavery  or  put  to  death. 
These  early  forms  of  process  were  superseded  by 
an  improved  system,  under  which  cases  were 
sent  by  a  magistrate  to  a  private  arbitrator, 
each  case  being  reduced  to  a.  formula,  in  which 
the  issue  to  be  tried  was  exactly  set  forth. 
Cases  not  suited  for  arbitration  were  tried  by 
the  magistrate  himself ;  by  the  imperial  legisla- 
tion arbitrators  were  almost  altogether  dispensed 
with,  and  all  questions  of  law  and  fact  were 
decided  by  the  judges. 


CIVIL  LAW 


299 


When  the  Roman  empire  was  broken  up,  the 
nations  of  Europe  framed  for  themselves  those 
laws  which  are  generally  described  as  the  feudal 
system.  Feudalism,  as  Sir  H.  Maine  points 
out,  combines  the  surviving  forms  of  Roman 
law  with  the  customs  of  the  barbaric  tribes 
which  overran  the  empire,  and  with  the  Chris- 
tian sentiment  which  bound  men  together  by 
the  tie  of  mutual  service.  The  object  of  the 
whole  system  was  to  fix  the  social  order  by 
defining  each  man's  duties,  and  by  connecting 
these  duties  as  far  as  possible  with  the  tenure 
of  land.  The  defects  of  the  system  were  that 
it  left  too  little  room  for  individual  enterprise, 
and  that,  by  making  each  man  look  only  to  his 
immediate  superior,  it  strengthened  small  local 
powers  at  the  expense  of  national  governments. 
With  the  revival  of  learning  and  the  Reforma- 
tion there  came  a  demand  for  greater  liberty, 
and  about  the  same  time  the  renewed  study  of 
Roman  law  directly  and  powerfully  influenced 
the  laws  of  continental  nations  ;  but  the  feudal 
customs  held  their  ground  until,  in  the  18th 
century,  political  writers  began  to  speculate  on 
the  possibility  of  framing  laws  of  a  more  simple 
and  rational  character,  based  on  general  notions 
of  justice  and  humanity.  It  was  almost  taken 
for  gi-anted  that  social  inequalities  and  abuses 
were  due  to  bad  laws  ;  philosophers  drew  up 
ideal  codes,  and  sovereigns,  like  Frederick  the 
Great,  Joseph  IL,  and  Catherine  of  Russia, 
busied  themselves  with  large  schemes  of  legisla- 
tion. In  France,  the  Revolution  swept  away 
old  institutions  ;  the  Convention  began,  and 
Napoleon  carried  through  the  work  of  providing 
the  people  with  a  new  system  of  laws.  There 
are,  of  course,  infinite  diff'erences  of  detail  in 
the  laws  of  modern  states,  but  in  all  of  them 
we  find  the  distinctions,  classifications,  and 
expedients  of  the  Roman  law,  adapted  to  the 
existing  condition  of  society.  It  is,  therefore, 
not  surprising  that  socialist  writers  should 
endeavour  to  break  down  the  rigid  legal  ideas 
which  the  modem  world  has  derived  from  the 
Corpus  Juris.  To  the  socialist,  property  does 
not  seem  to  fall  into  the  domain  of  private 
rights  ;  he  regards  it  as  forming  part  of  a 
common  social  stock  ;  he  will  not  permit  con- 
tracts to  be  rigidly  enforced,  for  to  him  a  con- 
tract is  only  an  arrangement  between  indi- 
viduals, to  be  revised  or  set  aside  if  the  general 
interest  seems  to  require  it. 

The  history  of  our  own  law  possesses  a 
peculiar  importance.  Though  deeply  indebted 
to  the  Roman  jurists,  English  lawyers  never 
accepted  the  Corpus  Juris  as  an  authoritative 
text-book  ;  they  worked  out  a  system  of  their 
own  on  the  basis  of  the  common  law,  i.e.  of 
the  custom  common  to  the  whole  kingdom. 
English  customary  law  was  never  codified,  in 
whole  or  in  part  ;  it  was  handed  down  in  the 
form  of  an  unwritten  tradition,  of  which  the 
freemen  themselves,  assembled   in  their  local 


courts,  were  the  interpreters  and  the  guardians, 
When  the  king's  judges  began  to  go  circuit, 
administering  justice  in  every  part  of  the 
country,  their  decisions  were  accepted  as  the 
most  complete  expression  of  the  common  law. 
In  applying  legal  rules  to  land,  the  judges 
began  by  expounding  the  feudal  tenures  with  a 
subtlety  which  savours  of  the  logic  of  the 
schoolmen  ;  but  their  bias  was  in  favour  of  free 
alienation  ;  they  invented  or  permitted  devices 
by  which  entails  were  barred,  and  settlements 
brought  within  strict  limits.  The  tendency 
towards  freedom  of  disposition  was  also  apparent 
even  in  our  early  legislation,  and  the  chancellor, 
in  the  exercise  of  his  equitable  jurisdiction,  did 
much  to  enlarge  the  power  of  an  owner  to  deal 
with  land  in  the  way  of  commerce.  Feudal 
restraints  have  now  been  almost  entirely  re- 
moved ;  the  modern  law  gives  to  an  OAvner  in 
fee  simple  all  the  rights  enjoyed  by  the  dominus 
of  Roman  law.  But  the  transfer  of  land  is 
beset  with  difiiculties  ;  legislation  has  removed 
many  of  the  sul)tleties  of  the  old  law,  but  the 
statute-law  is  so  voluminous  and  complicated 
that  conveyancing  is  still  an  art  reverenced 
by  practitioners  and  little  understood  by  the 
general  public.  The  acts  passed  in  England 
and  Ireland  for  the  benefit  of  tenants  and 
labourers,  represent  the  result  of  efforts  to 
combine  some  of  the  ideas  of  social  democracy 
with  the  rigid  notions  of  individual  ownership 
which  commended  themselves  to  the  judgment 
of  legal  experts.  Of  those  who  are  most  active 
in  promoting  changes  in  the  land  laws,  some 
would  be  content  with  "  free  trade  in  land  "  ; 
others  again  would  nationalise  or  municipalise 
the  land,  with  a  view  to  having  it  managed  for 
the  general  good,  on  principles  inconsistent 
with  individual  ownership  and  freedom  of 
disposition.  Political  discussion  is  much  em- 
barrassed by  the  obscurity  of  the  subject ;  the 
economist  or  the  legislator  who  resorts  to  legal 
treatises  for  information  is  bewildered  and 
sometimes  misled  by  the  technical  character  of 
the  language  employed. 

English  law  has  always  professed  to  favour 
trade  ;  but  the  trade  of  old  time  was  carried 
on  under  the  narrow  regulations  which  were 
rendered  necessary  by  the  privileges  of  cor- 
porations and  companies.  Even  in  the  18th 
century  mercantile  law  was  almost  undeveloped ; 
in  the  early  editions  of  Blackstone's  Com- 
mentaries only  a  few  pages  here  and  there  are 
given  to  the  subject.  Lord  Mansfield  was  then 
beginning  the  long  series  of  his  decisions, 
applying  the  principles  which  he  derived  from 
his  study  of  Roman  and  English  law  to  the 
business  of  a  great  and  rapidly  advancing 
commercial  nation.  Since  his  time,  every 
species  of  contract  and  security  has  been  made 
the  subject  of  prolonged  and  repeated  legal 
discussion  ;  it  would  almost  be  possible  to  write 
a  history  of  English  commerce  from  the  law 


300 


CIVIL  LAW— CIVIL  LIST 


reports  alone.  Freedom  of  contract  has  been 
the  avowed  policy  of  the  courts  ;  the  law  leaves 
men  free  to  dispose  of  their  property  and  services 
at  their  own  discretion,  and  compels  them  to 
carry  out  the  bargains  which  they  choose  to 
make.  But  all  private  bargains  are  controlled 
by  public  policy  ;  the  law  will  not  permit,  for 
example,  a  wager  to  be  made  in  the  guise  of 
a  contract  of  insurance  ;  and  agents  have  often 
been  forbidden  to  plead  mercantile  usages  which 
would  enable  them  to  make  profit  of  their  agency 
without  the  knowledge  of  their  principals.  The 
policy  of  the  common  law  would  not  permit 
partners  in  a  concern  to  limit  their  liability  ; 
but  this  principle  has  been  departed  from  in 
modern  legislation  relating  to  joint  stock 
companies.  In  studying  these  and  other  topics 
belonging  to  mercantile  law,  we  perceive  that 
rules  of  law  are  not  the  arbitrary  invention  of 
legislators  or  judges  ;  they  arise  naturally  out 
of  the  usages  and  transactions  of  ordinary  life. 
Some  difficult  problems  are  suggested  to  the 
jurist  by  the  conditions  of  modern  commerce. 
Free  trade  and  open  competition  lower  the 
standard  of  profit,  and  capitalists  form  trusts  and 
syndicates  with  a  view  to  obtaining  the  control 
of  great  markets :  is  it  necessary  or  desirable 
that  the  law  should  limit  their  freedom  of 
action  ?  Trade  unions  claim  to  dictate  terms  to 
employers  and  labourers  :  where  shall  we  draw 
the  line  between  lawful  and  unlawful  com- 
bination ?  These  are  legal  questions,  but  they 
are  not  to  be  solved  by  the  application  of  any 
legal  formula  :  the  law  merely  gives  an  authori- 
tative form  to  the  notions  of  justice  and  expedi- 
ency which  prevail  in  the  community  at  large. 
[The  history  of  law  may  be  studied  in  Ancient 
Law  and  other  works  of  Sir  H.  Maine  ;  for  the 
legal  analysis  of  the  ideas  of  property,  contract, 
etc.,  see  Holland's  Jurisprudence,  and  works  of 
Austin  and  others  there  cited.  Roman  law  is  set 
forth  in  the  Corpus  Juris  Civilis  and  in  the 
numerous  commentaries  thereon  ;  a  compendious 
view  is  given  in  Colquhoun's  Summary  of  the 
Civil  Law. '  For  the  laws  of  modern  European 
nations,  reference  may  be  made  to  Roger  et 
Sorel,  Codes  et  Lois  Usuelles. — Stobbe,  Handbuch 
des  Deutschen  Privatrechts,  etc.  English  law  is 
expounded  in  Blackstone's  Commentaries, — Smith's 
Mercantile  Law  ;  for  the  rules  relating  to  bills  of 
exchange,  sale  of  goods,  and  bankruptcy,  the 
works  of  Judge  Chalmers  may  be  consulted  with 
advantage.  The  Anglo-Tndian  Codes  (edited  by 
Mr.  Whitley  Stokes)  contains  a  compendious  state- 
ment of  the  chief  rules  of  English  law  relating  to 
contracts,  etc.  ;  these  rules  apply  to  the  natives  of 
India  if,  and  in  so  far  as,  their  occupations  bring 
them  within  the  circle  of  British  civilisation.  A 
native  merchant  at  Calcutta  frames  his  contracts 
according  to  British  law,  while  the  peasant  culti- 
vator's rights  are  determined  by  the  custom  of  his 
village.  Lord  Mansfield's  most  famous  judgments 
may  be  found  in  Smith's  Leading  Cases  ;  see  espe- 
cially Carter  v.  Boehm  (insurance),  and  Miller  v. 
Race  (property  in  bank-notes),  and  observe  the 


use  made  by  an  English  judge  of  the  maxims  of  the 
civil  law.  Lassalle's  System  der  Erworhenen  Rechte 
is  an  interesting  study  of  Roman  law  by  a  jurist 
who  became  one  of  the  leaders  of  socialism.]  t.  e. 

CIVIL  LIST.  The  arrangement  by  which 
an  amount  was  set  apart  under  this  head  for 
the  ordinary  service  of  the  establishments  of  the 
royal  household  and  other  expenses  of  the 
crovm  dates  from  the  Restoration  (1660).  The 
hereditary  revenues  arising  from  the  crown 
lands,  and  certain  minor  taxes,  were  appropriated 
for  this  purpose,  the  amount  being  about 
£680,000  a  year  (temp.  Will.  IIL)  From 
this  the  incomes  of  the  lord  chancellor,  the 
judges,  ambassadors  at'  foreign  courts  were 
defrayed,  together  with  the  pensions  granted 
by  the  monarch  as  well  as  his  personal  expenses. 
This  arrangement,  which  was  open  to  many 
abuses,  lasted  to  the  end  of  the  reign  of  Geo.  IV. 
When  WiUiam  IV.  ascended  the  throne,  a 
select  committee  of  the  House  of  Commons  was 
appointed  to  inquire  into  the  matter,  and  resolved 
that  it  was  expedient  that  the  civil  list  should 
be  applied  only  to  such  expenses  as  affect  the 
dignity  and  state  of  the  crown  and  the  proper 
maintenance  of  the  royal  household,  and  that 
many  expenses  which  up  to  that  date  had  been 
included  in  it,  and  had  no  immediate  connection 
with  these  objects — which  were  really  part  of 
the  expenses  of  the  civil  government  of  the 
state,  ought  to  be  removed  from  the  civil  list 
and  placed  under  the  cognisance  and  constant 
control  of  parliament.  These  charges  were 
therefore  transferred  to  the  Consolidated 
Fund  (q.v.)  and  the  civil  list  established 
mainly  on  its  present  footing  ;  some  pensions, 
however,  were  included  in  it. 

According  to  Parliamentary  Paper  22,  Session 
1837, — being  the  report  from  the  select  com- 
mittee of  the  House  of  Commons,  appointed  to 
inquire  into  the  accounts  of  income  and  expendi- 
ture of  the  civil  list,  from  1st  January  1831 
to  31st  December  1836  ;  with  an  estimate  of 
the  probable  future  charge  of  the  civil  list  of 
Her  Majesty, — the  civil  list  of  Will.  IV.  was 
apportioned  for  the  following  purposes  : 

1st  Class      Privy  Purse        .         .       £110,000 

2d  Class  Salaries  of  the  several 
Departments  of  the 
Royal  Household, 
and  Superannuation 
and  Retired  Allow- 
ances    .         .         .  130,300 

3d  Class      Tradesmen's  Bills        .  171,500 

4th  Class     Royal  Bounty,  Special 

and  Secret  Service  .  23,200 

5th  Class     Pensions    .         .         .  76,000 


£510,000 


The  report  proceeds  to  state  that,  in  con- 
sidering an  estimate  for  the  future  civil  list  of 
the  sovereign,  the  committee  had  been  guided. 


CIVIL  LIST 


301 


to  a  considerable  extent,  by  the  expenditure 
during  the  late  reign.  The  payments  pro- 
posed were  divided  under  five  heads  described 
as  below. 

Class  I 
The  privy  purse  of  the  sovereign  has  been 
for  upwards  of  half  a  century  (now  more  than 
a  century),  fixed  at  £60,000.  During  the  late 
reign  (Will.  IV.),  there  being  a  queen  consort,  a 
further  sum  of  £50, 000  was  allotted  to  this  class. 
Under  existing  circumstances,  your  committee 
recommend  that  an  annual  sum  of  £60,000  be 
provided  for  this  branch  of  the  royal  expenditure. 

Class  II 

The  second  class  comprehends  the  salaries  of 
the  great  officers  of  state,  those  of  the  officers 
and  menial  servants  of  the  royal  household,  and 
the  superannuation  and  retired  allowances 
payable  to  persons  of  the  latter  class.  The 
committee,  concurring  in  the  opinion  expressed 
in  the  report  of  1831,  "that  it  was  not  con- 
sistent with  the  respect  due  to  her  Majesty  to 
scrutinise  the  details  of  her  domestic  household," 
have  not  undertaken  any  minute  investigation 
into  that  branch  of  the  subject ;  but  they  have 
received,  as  already  stated,  a  very  full  analysis 
of  the  whole  of  this  branch  of  expenditure. 

The  principal  officers  of  state  in  attendance 
on  the  sovereign  were  the  lord  steward,  lord 
chamberlain,  master  of  the  horse,  and  groom  of 
the  stole.  It  was  not  proposed  to  fill  up  the 
office  of  gi'oora  of  the  stole,  or  to  create  any 
analogous  office  in  the  household  of  Her  ]\Iajesty. 
It  was  also  proposed  to  reduce  the  number 
of  lords-in-waiting  from  twelve  to  eight,  and 
of  grooms-in-waiting  to  eight  from  thirteen. 
The  consolidation,  when  a  vacancy  should 
arise,  of  certain  other  offices  was  recommended. 
In  considering  the  amount  to  be  recommended 
for  this  class,  your  committee  feel  it  their  duty 
to  call  the  attention  of  the  house  to  the  fact 
that  no  application  is  now  made  to  parliament 
for  the  grant  of  pensions  for  the  servants  of  the 
late  king.  With  these  explanations,  your  com- 
mittee recommend  the  estimate  of  £131,260 
for  the  second  class  of  the  civil  list. 

Class  III 
Considering  the  disbursements  which  have 
taken  place  in  the  late  reign  under  the  head 
of  bills  of  tradesmen,  your  committee  recom- 
mend the  proposed  estimate  of  £172,500  for 
this  branch  of  the  royal  expenditure. 

Class  IV 
The  fourth  class  of  the  civil  list  of  his  late 
Majesty  included  the  following  heads  : — 
Royal  Bounty     ....  £9,000 

Home  Secret  Service    .         .         .  10,000 

Alms  and  Charity        .         .         .  4,200 


£23,200 


After   much  consideration,   your  committee 


have  determined  to  recommend  that  the  sum  of 
£10,000,  now  charged  on  the  civil  list  for  secret 
service,  may  be  transferred  to  the  consolidated 
fund  by  act  of  parliament,  to  be  applied  to  the 
same  purposes,  and  under  the  same  authority, 
as  heretofore. 

The  provision  for  this  class  will  consequently 
be  reduced,  as  a  charge  on  the  civil  list,  to 
£13,200. 

Class  V 

The  committee  approached  the  consideration 
of  the  pensions  charged  on  the  fifth  class  of  the 
civil  list  with  a  full  sense  of  the  attention 
which  the  subject  has  exacted.  Your  com- 
mittee refer  to  the  following  passage  in  the 
report  of  1831  : — "The  house  must  recollect, 
that  the  principle  on  which  the  sum  is  allotted 
by  parliament  for  the  purpose  of  the  civil  list  is 
as  a  payment  for  the  personal  advantage  of  the 
sovereign,  and  for  the  support  of  the  dignity 
of  the  crown,  in  lieu  of  the  hereditary  revenue 
which  at  the  commencement  of  each  reign  the 
sovereign  sacrifices  for  the  benefit  of  the  public : 
some  provision  ought  in  all  cases  to  be  made 
for  such  payments,  as  it  miglit  be  presumed 
the  sovereign  would  have  been  desirous  of 
making  had  he  remained  in  possession  of  the 
hereditary  revenue.  That  one  class  of  such 
payments  would  be  pensions  to  those  of  his 
subjects  whom  he  wished  to  favour  cannot  be 
doubted."  In  conformity  with  this  opinion, 
your  committee  recommend  that  the  provision 
for  the  grant  of  pensions  should  continue  to 
form  a  part  of  the  civil  list  of  Her  Majesty. 

But  in  order  to  guard  against  the  sujjposition 
that  an  enactment  founded  on  this  principle 
should  in  any  degree  interfere  with  the  inquiry 
into  pensions,  of  which  notice  has  been  given 
in  the  House  of  Commons  (if  it  appears  fitting 
that  such  inquiry  should  be  instituted),  it  is 
the  opinion  of  your  committee  that,  in  place  of 
gi-anting  a  sum  of  £75,000  for  civil  list 
pensions,  Her  Majesty  should  be  empowered  to 
grant  in  every  year  new  pensions  on  the  civil 
list  to  the  amount  of  £1200  ;  these  pensions 
to  be  gi'anted  in  strict  conformity  with  the 
following  resolution  of  the  House  of  Commons, 
passe''  on  the  18th  of  February  1834  : 

"That  it  is  the  bounden  duty  of  the  respon- 
sible advisers  of  the  crown  to  recommend  to 
His  Majesty  for  grants  of  pensions  on  the  civil 
list,  such  persons  only  as  have  just  claims  on 
the  royal  beneficence,  or  who,  by  their  personal 
services  to  the  crown,  by  the  performance 
of  duties  to  the  public,  or  by  their  useful  dis- 
coveries in  science,  and  attainments  in  literature 
and  the  arts,  have  merited  the  gi'acious  con- 
sideration of  their  sovereign,  and  the  gratitude 
of  their  country. " 

Your  committee  recommend  that  this  resolu- 
tion should  be  engrafted  in  the  Civil  List 
Act,  and  that  annual  returns  of  the  pensions 
granted,  and  the  names  of  the  several  parties, 


302 


CIVIL  LIST 


should  be  laid  before  Parliament.  The  civil  list  of 
Queen  Victoria  wasfixed  accordingly  at£385, 000. 
ArrangeTuentswere  also  made  as  the  Queen's  chil- 
dren grew  up  and  for  other  members  of  the  Eoyal 
Family.  At  the  accession  of  King  Edward  VII. 
thecivil  list  wasfixed  at  the  following  amount: — 
Glass  I  Privy  Purse  ....  £110,000 
Class  II    Retired    Allowances,   Salaries, 

and  Wages      ....       125,800 
Class  III  Expenses  of  Household    .        .       193,000 

Class  IV  Works 20,000 

Class  V     Royal     Bounty,     Alms,     and 

Special  Services     .        .        .         13,200 

Unappropriated  Monies    .        .  8,000 

£470,000 

At  the  accession  of  King  George  V.,  1910,  the 
same  amount  was  passed.  On  the  death  of  King 
Edward  V 11. ,  the  Queen  Dowager  became  entitled 
to  an  annuity  of  £70,000  provided  under  §5  of 
the  Civil  List  Act.  The  Prince  of  Wales  being 
entitled  to  the  revenues  of  the  Duchy  of  Corn- 
wall receives  no  further  provision,  but  on  his 
marriage,  £10,000  a  year  is  assigned  to  the 
Princess  of  Wales  to  be  increased  to  £30,000 
should  she  survive  the  Prince.  Under  the 
Prince  of  Wales's  Children  Act  (1889)  provision 
was  made  for  annuities  of  £10,000  to  each  of 
the  King's  younger  sons  on  reaching  the  age  of 
21,  with  an  increase  of£l5,000a  year  on  his 
marrying,  and  an  annuity  of  £6000  a  year  to 
each  daughter  on  her  attaining  her  majority  or 
marrying.  Further  charges  on  the  Consolidated 
Fund  are  the  payments  in  each  year  of  the  Civil 
List  Pensions  to  the  extent  of  £1200  a  year,  and 
a  maximum  provision  of  £18, 000  a  year  to  meet 
pensions  to  former  members  of  the  households 
of  King  Edward  VII.  and  of  Queen  Victoria, 

The  comparison  between  the  charge  for  the 
late  and  the  present  reigns  stood  as  follows  :— 
1901  1910 

Civil  List £470,000    £470,000 

Pensions  transferred  to  Consoli- 
dated Fund  .        .        .       25,000        18,000 

Provision  for  other  members  of 
Royal  Family  .        .        .     126,000       146,000 

£621,000    £634,000 


CIVILISATION.  Ricardo  pointed  out  (PHn- 
cvples,  ch.  V.)  that  the  natural  price  of  labour 
varies  greatly,  and  "essentially  depends  on  the 
habits  and  customs  of  the  people."  The  closer 
political  and  industrial  communication  estab- 
lished between  civilised,  half- civilised,  and  un- 
civilised peoples  since  Ricardo's  time  has  con- 
firmed the  truth  of  this  observation  and  shown 
the  difiiculty  of  applying  many  economic  maxims 
universally  when  local  conditions  vary  gi-eatly. 
The  industrial  life  of  each  people  harmonises 
with  its  environment  of  political  structure, 
customary  morality,  and  current  intelligence. 
Any  observed  type  of  industrial  organism  is 
greatly  determined  by  the  conditions  of  civilisa- 
tion existing  there  and  then,  both  in  regard  to 
the  wealth  of  the  community  as  a  whole  and 
the  economic  relationships  between  its  parts. 
The  family,  in  its  various  forms,  is  the  one 
constant  social  element,   and  offers  the   best 


basis  for  economic  observations  (F    Le  Play, 
Les  Ouwriers  Uurop^ens,  I.) 

1.  It  is  at  first  sight  natural  to  ascribe  the 
poverty  of  any  tribe  to  the  physical  conditions 
under  which  they  live,  such  as  the  barrenness 
of  the  soil,  or  the  rigour  of  the  climate.  Such 
hindrances  set  definite  limits  to  progress  at  any 
given  time,  but  every  increase  in  intelligence 
or  social  improvement  removes  them  farthei 
back ;  they  form  a  relative,  not  an  absolute 
check  to  the  increase  of  prosperity.  The  success 
of  the  Dutch  in  forming  a  rich  community 
despite  disadvantages  of  every  kind,  shows  how 
skill  and  energy  may  overcome  nature  and  over- 
pass limits  that  would  otherwise  prove  insuper- 
able barriers.  The  example  of  Sweden  may 
likewise  be  cited.  The  use  to  which  the  wealth 
of  a  people  is  put  depends  on  the  current  view 
of  utility  or  enjoyment;  it  may  be  spent  in 
warfare,  embellishment,  or  extravagance ;  it 
may  be  devoted  to  improving  the  country  and 
the  condition  of  the  people.  Unless  some  por- 
tion is  carefully  devoted  to  these  latter  purposes, 
a  civilisation  will  be  short-lived,  however  bril- 
liant it  may  be.  The  rapid  decline  of  some  East- 
ern empires  and  of  the  glories  of  Athens  may  bt 
thus  explained ;  the  Romans,  on  the  other  hand, 
devoted  much  energy  to  developing  the  resources 
of  their  empire,  and  gave  it  more  stability. 

2.  Though  the  chief  economic  activity  of 
societies  of  men  has  always  had  the  same  object 
of  securing  sustenance,  clothing,  and  shelter,  they 
have  been,  and  are,  grouped  for  these  purposes 
in  diflerent  ways.  We  may  distinguish  four 
types :  (i)  In  the  early  village  community 
(Maine's  Village  Community,  Laveleye,  Primi- 
tive Property,  see  Agricultural  Community) 
the  work  is  undertaken  collectively,  and  wealth 
forms  a  common  fund.  Unwritten  custom,  ad- 
ministered by  patriarchal  or  elected  authority  is 
supreme  ;  and  individual  energy  is  devoted  to 
the  common  good  of  a  small  self-dependent 
group,  (ii)  In  municipal  societies,  like  the 
mediaeval  cities,  the  inhabitants  are  organised 
according  to  their  callings  in  separate  guilds  ; 
the  status  in  life  of  each  inhabitant,  generally 
speaking,  is  determined  by  the  standing  of 
the  guild,  on  the  regulations  of  which  the  con- 
ditions for  labour  and  rate  of  pay  depend.  The 
individual  cannot  rise  out  of  his  sphere  in  life, 
and  to  hold  a  good  position  in  his  o%vn  guild  is 
cJie  chief  object  of  ambition  (see  Gild),  (iii) 
By  national  organisation  the  central  govern- 
ment may  direct  the  economic  energies  of  a 
whole  nation,  so  that  each  village  and  each 
town  shall  contribute  as  much  as  possible  to 
the  maiatenance  of  national  power.  Corbert 
may  be  specified  in  this  connection,  and  the 
various  economic  systems  which  were  criticised 
so  eff'ectively  by  Adam  Smith  (Wealth  of 
Nations,  iv.,  see  Commercial  System),  (iv)  In 
modern  society  each  individual  is  left  free,  so 
far  as  possible,  to  pursue  his  own  greatest  ad- 


CLASSICAL  ECONOMISTS— CLASSIFICATION 


303 


vantage,  and,  for  this  purpose,  employs  his 
labour  or  his  capital  in  any  direction  which 
seems  likely  to  be  profitable,  without  being 
hampered  by  family  ties  and  local  regulations  ; 
or  he  unites  in  voluntary  associations  where  it 
appears  that  he  can  reap  a  greater  measure  of  per- 
sonal advantage  (seeCo-oPERATiON;  Companies). 

It  may  be  noticed  in  regard  to  the  distinct 
types  of  economic  organisation  found  under 
different  civilisations,  that  the  higher  forms  are 
extended  over  very  large  areas  and  give  mucli 
free  play  for  individual  energy.  Working  on  a 
large  scale,  while  they  are  very  complicated  in 
their  details,  they  are  far  more  effective  for  the 
purposes  of  providing  food,  clothing,  and  shelter 
than  the  simpler  machinery  found  in  less  de- 
veloped societies.  Again,  the  history  of  any 
one  great  civilisation  shows  how  the  industrial 
organisms  of  the  simpler  type  have  been  in  turn 
displaced  by  more  effective  institutions  ;  though 
fragments  of  the  old  may  remain,  cramped  prob- 
ably by  regulations  that  have  become  unwise 
since  they  are  out  of  date.  Hence  we  may  find 
in  an  old  society  some  arrangements  which 
appear  to  be  wholly  at  variance  with  modern 
modes  of  thought,  which  only  become  intellig- 
ible when  understood  to  be  survivals  of  institu- 
tions once  really  important,  though  now  mere 
machronisms.  While  much  interest  attaches 
to  the  study  and  working  of  any  economic  sys- 
tem, the  higher  civilisations  with  their  more 
effective  arrangements  for  organisation  offer  the 
best  field  for  investigating  the  causes  which 
affect  the  growth  and  maintenance  of  national 
wealth.  w.  c. 

CLARKSON,  Thomas  (born  1760,  died 
1846),  a  leader  in  the  crusade  against  the  slave- 
trade,  the  evils  of  which  he  first  realised  when 
competing  at  Cambridge,  1785,  for  a  prize  to 
be  given  for  the  best  essay  on  the  subject  Anne 
liceat  invitos  in  servitutetn  dare.  Clarkson  won 
the  prize,  and  published  his  essay,  translated 
and  enlarged,  1786  (2d  ed.  1788).  In  a 
subsequent  essay  On  the  impolicy  of  the 
African  slave  trade,  1788,  he  argued  that  the 
ti'affic  which  he  had  proved  to  be  iniquitous 
was  also  unprofitable.  Among  many  publica- 
tions on  the  same  subject  may  be  noticed 
History  of  ...  the  Abolition  of  the  African 
Slave  Trade  .  .  .,  1808.  In  a  new  edition  of 
this  work,  1839,  there  is  a  preface  describing 
Clarkson's  later  labours  in  the  cause  of  the 
slave.  To  the  second  series  of  his  philanthropic 
efforts  belong  Thoughts  on  the  Necessity  of 
Improving  the  Condition  of  the  Slaves  in  the 
British  Colonies  with  a  View  to  their  Ultiviate 
Emancipation  .  .  .,  1823  ;  and  The  cries  of 
Africa  to  the  Inhabitants  of  Europe  .  .  . 
( ?  1822).  Clarkson  also  wrote.  Not  a  labourer 
wanted  for  Jamaica,  to  which  is  added  an 
account  of  the  newly  erected  villages  by  the 
peasantry  and  their  beneficial  results,  1842  ; 
and    The    Grievances   of  our    Mercantile   Sea- 


men a  National   and  Crying  Evil,   1845    (see 
Abolitionist). 

{Biographical  Sketch  of  Thomas  Clarlcson,  by 
Thomas  Taylor,  l%?>^ .  — Sketch  of  the  Life  oj 
Thomas  Clarkson,  1S76. — Clarkson,  William, 
author  of  An  Inquiry  into  the  Cause  of  the  In- 
crease of  Pauperism  and  Poor  Plates,  with  a 
remedy  for  the  same  and  a  Proposition  for  Equal- 
izing the  Rates  throughout  England  and  Wales 
(1815)].  F.  T.  E. 

CLASSICAL  ECONOMISTS.  Tliis  name 
has  been  applied  to  Adam  Smith  and  his  im- 
mediate successors,  Malthus,  Ricardo,  James 
Mill,  M'Culloch,  and  Senior,  and,  less  often, 
to  the  French  physiocrats. 

In  keeping  with  the  Latin  derivation  of 
"classical,"  and  with  the  use  of  the  term 
"classical  authors,"  the  name  might  simply 
denote  economic  writers  of  the  first  rank  who 
have  left  models  which  all  others  must  follow. 
A  less  complimentary  interpretation  is  given  by 
Professor  Brentano,  who  compares  classical  eco- 
nomics to  classical  sculpture,  where,  he  says, 
personal  peculiarities  are  ignored  in  favour  of 
broad  general  human  characteristics,  and  of  an 
"abstract  man"  without  scars  or  wrinkles. 
Economists,  he  says,  belong  to  the  classical 
school  when  they  reason  deductively  from  the 
assumption  of  an  "abstract  (economic)  man." 
The  justice  of  this  description  need  not  be  dis- 
cussed here.  See  Deductive  Method  ;  His- 
torical School;  M'Culloch  ;  Malthus; 
Mill,  James  ;  Physiocrats  ;  Ricardo. 

[Brentano  (Prof.  L.),  Die  classische  National- 
okonomie,  Leipzig,  1888. — Bohm-Bawerk(Prof.  E.), 
"  Review  of  Brentano's  Class.  Nationalokonomie." 
— Gottingische  Gelehrte  Anzeigen,  June  1889. — 
Dietzel  (Prof.  H.)  "Die  classische  Werth-tlieorie," 
Jahrb.  fir  Nat,  ok.  und  Statistik,  21st  June  1890 
cp.  paper  by  the  same  writer,  ibid.  May  1891. — 
Gide  (Prof.  Ch.)  Principles  of  Political  Economy, 
pp.  16-20,  Eng.  Transl,  Heath  &  Co.,  New  York, 
and  Isbister,  London,  1891.]  j.  b. 

CLASSIFICATION  is  described  by  Mill 
{Logic,  vol.  ii.  p.  258,  4th  ed.,  bk.  iv.  c.  vii.)  as 
"a  contrivance  for  the  best  possible  ordering  of 
the  ideas  of  objects  in  our  minds  ;  for  causing 
the  ideas  to  accompany  or  succeed  one  another 
in  such  a  way  as  shall  give  us  the  greatest 
command  over  our  knowledge  already  acquired, 
and  lead  most  directly  to  the  acquisition  of 
more. "  From  this  description  we  may  conclude 
that  classification  is  more  than  a  matter  of 
neatness  or  convenience.  We  can  classify  things 
correctly  only  in  so  far  as  we  can  see  them  in 
their  true  relations,  and  to  see  them  in  their 
true  relations  is  nothing  less  than  to  know  their 
true  nature.  ' '  The  value  of  classification, "  saya 
Jevons  {Principles  of  Science,  vol.  ii.  p.  345), 
"is  co-extensive  with  the  value  of  science  and 
general  reasoning."  Or,  as  the  same  writcT 
puts  it  elsewhere,  "Science  can  extend  only  so 
far  as  the  power  of  accurate  classification  ex- 
tends," p.  421.     It  is  not,  therefore,  surprising 


304 


CLASSIFICATION— CLAY 


that  the  theory  of  classification  should  have 
been  discussed  at  length  by  the  most  eminent 
writers  upon  scientific  method,  or  that  success 
in  classification  should  be  one  of  the  distinguish- 
ing marks  of  scientific  genius. 

Classifications  have  frequently  been  distin- 
guished as  natural  and  artificial,  or  as  Ihey 
might  better  be  termed,  scientific  and  arbitrary. 
In  artificial  classifications  "some  characters 
arbitrarily  chosen  serve  to  determine  the  place 
of  each  object  ;  we  abstract  all  other  characters, 
and  the  objects  are  thus  found  to  be  brought 
near  to  or  to  be  separated  from  each  other 
often  in  the  most  bizarre  manner.  In  natural 
systems  of  classification,  on  the  contrary,  we 
employ  concurrently  all  the  characters  essential 
to  the  objects  with  which  we  are  occupied, 
discussing  the  importance  of  each  of  them  ; 
and  the  results  of  this  labour  are  not  adopted 
unless  the  objects  which  present  the  closest 
analogy  are  brought  most  near  together" 
(Ampere  quoted  by  Jevons,  Principles  of 
Science,  vol.  ii.  p.  351).  Or,  as  Mill  puts  it  in 
his  Logic(h\i.  i.  ch.  vii.,  vol.  i.  p.  137  e^  seq.),  some 
objects  are  separated  from  each  other  by  difi"er- 
ences  of  kind,  that  is  to  say,  by  an  indefinite 
and  inexhaustible  number  of  particular  differ- 
ences ;  other  classes  of  objects  are  separated 
only  by  certain  specific  diff'erences  which  are 
not  indices  of  any  others. 

But  too  much  must  not  be  made  of  these 
distinctions.  The  diff"erence  between  an  arti- 
ficial and  a  natural  classification  is  only  one  of 
degree.  Any  classification,  however  subordinate 
the  diff'erences  upon  which  it  is  based,  tells  us 
something  about  the  nature  of  the  objects 
classified.  The  classification  which  is  useless 
for  the  purposes  of  one  science  may  be  all- 
important  for  the  purposes  of  another  science. 
Thus  crystals  will  be  classified  by  the  chemist 
with  reference  to  their  chemical  composition, 
and  by  the  crystallographer  with  reference  to 
their  peculiar  crystalline  form,  and  the  two 
classifications  will  be  altogether  discrepant 
with  each  other.  Again,  the  progress  of  know- 
ledge has  shown  that  hardly  any  distinctions 
of  kind  are  absolute,  that  indefinite  variation, 
not  orderly  grouping,  is  the  way  of  nature,  and 
that  scientific  precision  is  to  be  found  not  in 
drawing  distinctions  between  classes,  but  in 
tracing  the  laws  of  development.  Even  before 
the  idea  of  evolution  had  attained  to  its  present 
distinctness,  it  was  remarked  that  in  the 
sciences  known  par  excellence  as  classificatory, 
the  sciences  of  botany  and  zoology,  classification 
was  based  not  on  definition  but  on  types.  In 
other  words  it  was  found  that  the  individual 
forms  of  animal  or  vegetable  life  clustered 
themselves  around  certain  types  to  which  few 
if  any  conformed  with  exactness,  whilst  all  were 
closely  akin.  But  since  a  type  in  this  sense 
is  but  the  compendious  symbol  of  a  number  of 
nearly  related  classes,  it  is  clear  that  a  classifica- 


tion by  types  is  either  an  inaccurate  classifica' 
tion  or  else  a  classification  which  has  not  been 
fully  carried  out. 

In  the  moral  and  political  sciences,  including 
political  economy,  classification  is  beset  with 
peculiar  difficulties  and  dangers.  The  most 
obvious  of  these  lies  in  the  fact  that  none  of 
these  sciences  possesses,  or  is  ever  likely  to 
possess,  a  complete  scientific  vocabulary,  the 
terms  of  which  have  the  same  precise  sense  for 
every  student,  whilst  they  remain  undefaced  by 
loose  popular  use.  Classification  is  at  every 
step  dependent  upon  nomenclature  ;  and  it  is 
only  in  sciences  which,  like  botany,  possess  a 
complete  and  precise  technical  nomenclature 
that  classification  can  be  carried  out  to  the 
utmost  extent.  But  a  more  serious  hindrance 
to  classification  is  to  be  found  in  the  nature  of 
the  subject-matter  of  moral  and  political  science. 
Their  subject-matter  is  far  more  complex  than 
the  subject-matter  of  botany  or  zoology.  If  it 
be  true  that  practically  every  individual  in  the 
vegetable  or  animal  kingdom  embodies  a  more 
or  less  considerable  variation  from  a  type,  how 
much  more  is  this  true  of  every  human  being 
and  of  every  human  institution.  Anybody 
who  compares  with  the  classifications  of  natural 
science  the  ^classifications,  say,  of  feelings  or 
motives  in  a  treatise  of  psychology,  wiU  feel 
how  much  less  adequate  is  the  latter  to  the 
object  aimed  at  by  the  writer.  And  in  the 
study  of  society  Mr.  Herbert  Spencer's  De- 
scriptive Sociology  affords  a  striking  example  of 
the  difficulties  which  beset  classification  and  of 
the  limited  advantages  to  be  derived  from  it. 
When  we  look  closely  into  ideas  or  institutions 
which  at  first  sight  appear  very  similar,  we 
usually  find  diff'erences  of  a  momentous  nature. 
This  may  be  exemplified  by  the  well-known 
hazard  in  predicting  from  some  instance  in  the  ^ 
past  the  working  of  a  new  institution  which 
seems  to  resemble  it.  It  may  almost  be  said 
that  in  the  sphere  of  moral  and  social  science 
the  only  true  kinds  are  individuals.  The  most 
sagacious  and  suggestive  wiiters  upon  these 
topics  have  shunned  elaborate  classification  as 
they  have  shunned  the  use  of  highly  technical 
language. 

[J.  S.  Mill,  Logic.  — W.  S.  Jevons,  Principles  oj 
Science. — J.  N.  Keynes,  Scope  and  Method  of  Poli- 
tical Economy,  pp.  166-8. — K.  Menger,  Methode 
der  Socialwissenschaften  (1883),  especially  Ap- 
pendix IV.  (classification  of  economic  sciences). 
— K.  Menger,  Grundzuge  einer  Klassifkation  der 
Wirtschaftswissenschaften  (1889).  —  H.  Spencer, 
Classification  of  the  Sciences. — P.  Geddes,  Classi- 
fication of  the  Sciences.']  r.  c.  m. 

CLAY,  Henry,  bornin  Virginia  2d  Aprill777. 
After  receiving  but  a  poor  and  elementary  educa- 
tion ;  he  became  a  lawyer  and  removed  to  Ken- 
tucky, where  he  entered  on  a  political  career  of 
national  importance,  and  three  times  in  his  life 
—  in  1824,  1832,  and  1844 — was  a  candidate  for 


CLAYTON— CLEARING  SYSTEM 


306 


the  presidency.  Although  not  an  author,  Clay 
is  noteworthy  in  economics  as  intimately 
associated  with  the  development  of  the  so- 
called  "American  system"  in  the  United 
States,  or  the  policy  of  protection  to  manu- 
factures by  means  of  tariff  duties,  and  the 
liberal  encouragement  of  internal  improvements 
under  national  authority.  In  1806,  he  became 
a  member  of  the  U.S.  Senate,  and  for  nearly 
forty  years,  with  the  exception  of  brief  periods, 
was  a  member  of  this  body  or  of  the  House  of 
Representatives.  His  most  important  speeches 
bearing  upon  the  subjects  of  protection  and  in- 
ternal improvements  are  the  following  :  Manu- 
factures, 6th  April  1810  ;  Internal  Improve- 
ments, 13th  March  1818  ;  Protection  to  Home 
Industries,  26th  April  1820  ;  Internal  Improve- 
ments, 16th  Jan.  1824  ;  American  Industry, 
30th  and  31st  March  1824  ;  Influ^n^e  of  the 
American  System,  2d,  3d,  and  6th  Feb.  1832  ; 
Introducing  the  Compromise  Bill,  12th  Feb. 
1833  ;  Support  of  the  Compromise  Act,  25th 
Feb.  1833  ;  and  On  the  Tariff,  1st  March  1842. 
In  favour  of  protection  he  argued  that  it 
was  necessary  to  establish  a  home  market  for 
agriculture,  as  American  power  of  production 
was  increasing  in  a  ratio  four  times  greater 
than  foreign  powers  of  consumption  ;  that  the 
United  States  should  not  permit  itself  to  be  a 
commercial  slave  ;  that  a  well  -  established 
system  of  manufactures  promoted  political 
peace  with  foreign  countries  ;  that  manufactures 
would  bind  the  various  interests  of  the  coxmtry 
into  a  closer  union.  Clay  repeatedly  insisted 
in  1820,  1824,  and  1832,  that  the  question  of 
protection  must  be  decided  in  face  of  the  fact 
that  European  nations  maintained  similar 
systems.  "I,  too,  am  a  friend  to  free  trade," 
he  said  in  1820,  "but  it  must  be  a  free  trade 
of  perfect  reciprocity."  It  will  be  noticed  that 
the  arguments  referred  to  are  mostly  of  a 
political  nature  ;  by  1832,  Clay  advanced  more 
prominently  reasons  of  a  more  strictly  economic 
character ;  and  then  argued  that  through  the 
tariff  of  1824,  the  commodities  which  had  been 
protected  were  cheaper,  and  that  products  of 
agriculture  commanded  a  higher  price  owing  to 
the  creation  of  a  home  market.  Little  was 
said  about  the  mercantile  theory  of  balance  of 
trade.  The  advocacy  of  internal  improvements 
undertaken  by  the  national  government  in  the 
first  third  of  this  century,  was  due  to  reasons 
which  would  not  be  appreciated  at  the  present 
time.  Settlements  west  of  the  seaboard  were 
scattered,  and  it  was  difficult,  and  in  many 
cases  perilous  to  reach  the  advance  guard  of 
western  emigrants.  Improvements  were  urged 
not  only  on  political  but  on  economic  grounds. 
The  agricultural  products  of  Ohio  were  of  little 
value  as  long  as  the  only  commercial  outlet 
was  the  Mississippi,  reached  by  the  Ohio  river. 
Even  Jefferson,  who  in  general  with  the 
Republican  party  favoured  the  strict  construc- 
VOL.  I. 


tion  of  the  powers  of  the  constitution,  yielded 
to  the  general  demand  that  the  national 
government  should  actively  assist  in  building 
roads  and  canals  and  improving  rivers.  In 
judging  then  the  position  of  many  public  men 
of  the  United  States  at  this  time  in  regard  to  a 
wide  interference  of  the  state  in  industrial 
affairs,  one  must  bear  in  mind  the  political  ex- 
igencies due  to  the  fact  that  it  was  impossible 
to  secure  from  the  several  states  harmonious  and 
wise  action,  necessary  for  an  inter-state  route. 
Clay  was  one  of  the  founders  of  the  Whig  party, 
and  in  general  acted  in  harmony  with  it  on 
political  questions.  For  his  speeches  on  the 
United  States  Bank,  see  the  following  :  A 
National  Bank,  1811  ;  The  Bank  Charter,  3d 
June  1816  (delivered  at  Lexington,  Kentucky)  ; 
Veto  of  the  Bank,  12th  June  1832  ;  and  for  his 
speeches  on  the  sub-treasury  system  in  which 
he  urged  the  necessity  of  convertible  paper 
money,  and  argued  against  relying  upon  the 
precious  metals  as  the  sole  crn'rency,  see  speeches 
delivered  25th  Sept.  1837  ;  19th  Feb.  1838  ; 
20th  Jan.  1840.  From  1842  till  1849  Clay 
retired  from  active  political  life,  although  retain- 
ing the  position  of  adviser  of  the  Whig  party. 
He  died  in  1852,  For  life  and  works  see  JVwks 
of  Henry  Clay,  edited  by  Calvin  Colton,  6  vols. , 
New  York,  1863.  The  last  two  volumes  contain 
tlie  speeches.  d.  k.  d. 

CLAYTON,  David,  author  of  ^  Short  System 
of  Trade,  or  an  account  of  tohat  in  trade  must 
necessarily  he  advantageous  to  the  nation,  and 
what  must  of  consequence  he  detrimental,  London, 
1719.  "Multitudes  of  people  fully  employed 
in  beneficial  trades "  being  advantageous,  the 
importation  of  foreign  manufactured  goods  is 
"of  consequence  detrimental."  The  writer 
alludes  to  "a  pamphlet  published  about  two 
years  since,  entitled  'A  short  but  thorough 
search,  etc.',  which  is  now  again  reprinted 
with  some  alterations  and  large  additions." 

F.  Y.  E. 

CLEARING  SYSTEM 

Clearing  Houses,  p.  306  ;  London  Bankers'  Clearing 
House,  p.  306 ;  Provincial  Clearing  Houses,  p.  307  ; 
Foreign  Clearing  Houses,  p.  807 ;  Statistics,  p.  309 ; 
Other  Classes  of  Clearings,  p.  310 ;  Stock  Exchange 
Clearing,  p.  310  ;  Beetroot  Sugar  Association,  p.  310 ; 
London  Produce  Clearing,  p.  311 ;  Railway  Clearing, 
p.  311  ;•  Cotton  Clearing,  p.  311. 

CLEARING  HOUSES.  The  circulation  of  a 
bill  of  exchange,  draft,  or  cheque  through 
several  hands  accomplishes  something  more 
than  the  settlement  of  the  original  transaction 
out  of  which  it  arose.  It  completes  many  in- 
termediate business  operations  by  the  delivery 
perhaps  of  a  single  document  instead  of  by 
telling  over  a  quantity  of  currency  several 
times.  It  thus  effects  important  economies  of 
currency  and  of  labour.  But  for  the  final 
liquidation  of  the  document  there  is  still  re- 
quired the  trouble  of  presentation,  the  provision 
of  currency,  and  the  labour  of  counting  this, 
besides  the  risk  of  storing  and  of  carrying  it. 


306 


CLEARING  SYSTEM 


In  some  or  all  of  these  points  a  clearing  system 
carries  economy  yet  further.  The  principle  of 
the  clearing  system  is  payment  by  "  set-otf,"  or 
the  "clearing"  off  certain  claims  by  counter- 
presentation  of  other  claims,  leaving  only  a 
single  balance  to  be  settled  by  actual  payment. 
Economy  to  this  extent  may  be  obtained  by  the 
least  developed  system  of  clearing,  as  existing 
in  many  towns,  where  each  bank  presents  to 
the  other  banks  all  drafts  which  it  holds  on 
them  without  requiring  payment  at  the  time, 
settlement  being  made  subsequently  by  paying 
the  balances  between  the  cross  deliveries.  The 
next  advance  is  the  establishment  of  a  clearing 
house  or  common  place  of  meeting.  By  this 
means  presentation  may  be  made  to  many 
different  members  within  the  compass  of  a 
single  room,  and  each  of  those  members  will 
have  but  the  labour  of  a  single  journey.  A 
further  economy  is  secured  in  the  settlement 
by  book  entry  of  the  final  balances  resulting 
from  the  claims  mutually  admitted.  "With  this 
arrangement  the  use  of  currency  is  eliminated 
from  the  whole  chain  of  transactions,  from  the 
first  drawing  of  a  bill  or  draft  to  its  final 
payment.  The  system  is  effective  entirely  in 
proportion  to  the  economy  obtained,  and  our 
estimate  of  its  value  must  depend  upon  (a)  the 
completeness  of  the  chain  of  adjustment ;  (&) 
the  magnitude  of  amounts  discharged  ;  (c)  the 
number  of  drafts  presented  ;  (d)  the  number  of 
parties  making  and  receiving  presentation  ;  and 
(e)  the  difiiculties  of  separate  presentation,  other- 
wise necessary.  Great  diversity  may  exist  in 
the  arrangements.  It  will  therefore  be  de- 
sirable to  describe  the  methods  adopted  at  some 
of  the  chief  clearing  houses  of  the  world. 

The  London  Bankers'  CLEARika  House, 
established  between  1750  and  1770,  now  in- 
cludes (1891)  twenty-six  members,  all  being 
bankers,  doing  cash  deposit  business  in  the  city. 
The  clearing -room  is  a  large  apartment  of 
irregular  shape,  lighted  from  the  roof.  Around 
the  walls  and  in  a  double  row  in  the  centre  are 
placed  desks  allotted  to  each  bank,  according 
to  the  extent  of  its  business.  The  banks  are 
placed  in  alphabetical  order,  so  that  the  clerks 
can  pass  around  the  room  and  deliver  the 
*  *  charges  "  without  confusion  or  risk  of  error.  In 
describing  the  operations  it  is  necessary  to  use 
technical  terms  and  to  remember  that  the  "  out " 
and  the  "  in  "  clearing  comprise  the  same  items, 
having  regard  to  their  presentation  by  one  bank 
and  their  reception  for  payment  by  another. 
Thus  the  "out"  clearing  of  each  bank,  i.e.  the 
cheques,  etc.,  for  which  each  bank  has  to  receive 
payment,  becomes  part  of  the  "in "  clearing  of 
every  other  bank,  i.e.  the  cheques,  etc.,  which 
every  other  bank  has  to  pay.  The  ' ' out"  clearing 
is  taken  down  at  the  bank  ofiices  in  sheets  or 
books  in  separate  "charges,"  according  to  the 
bankers  drawn  upon,  whilst  the  "in"  clearing 
is  taken  down  in  the  same  way  at  the  clearing 


house  by  clerks  who  go  there  for  the  pur- 
pose. 

The  first  "clearing"  is  held  from  10.30  a.m. 
till  12.0  noon,  all  drafts  having  to  be  delivered 
at  the  desks  by  11.  The  clerks  receiving  the 
"  charges  "  enter  the  items  in  their  "  in  "  clear- 
ing-books, and  cast  them,  agreeing  the  totals 
with  amounts  placed  on  the  back  of  the  last 
cheque.  When  this  is  completed  the  clerks 
leave  the  house,  taking  the  drafts  to  their  re- 
spective offices.  No  balances  are  struck  for 
this  clearing,  the  total  of  each  "charge"  being 
carried  forward  to  the  beginning  of  the  second 
clearing.  This  opens  at  2.30  p.m.,  and  con- 
tinues until  4,  when  the  last  delivery  must  be 
made.  The  arrangements  differ  from  those  of 
the  morning  clearing  only  in  the  fact  that  the 
deliveries  are  continuous  and  frequent  through- 
out the  afternoon.  At  4  the  doors  of  the  house 
are  closed,  and  no  more  drafts  can  be  presented. 
As  soon  as  the  last  drafts  have  been  despatched 
from  the  banks,  the  "out"  books  are  cast  close 
and  sent  down  to  the  house  to  be  agreed  with 
the  "in"  books  of  the  other  banks.  Differ- 
ences in  adding  the  figures  together  are  rectified 
by  the  bank  in  error,  but  differences  in  items 
are  altered  by  the  "  out "  clearers  to  agree  with 
the  "  in  "  cjearers.  Subsequently  the  difference 
may  be  reclaimed  by  production  of  the  draft. 
Drafts  refused  payment  are  returned  at  any  time 
during  the  afternoon  by  inclusion  in  the  "out " 
charges  to  the  banks  by  whom  they  were  pre- 
sented. "Returns"  are  also  received  at  the 
house  after  the  close  of  the  clearing,  and  up  to 
5.0  P.M.  The  totals  having  been  agreed,  the 
balance  between  the  "out"  and  "in"  amounts 
is  struck  by  each  bank  with  every  other  one, 
and  the  last  "returns  "  are  charged  and  allowed 
on  either  side.  All  these  balances  then  form 
items  in  a  general  balance-sheet,  which  is  pre- 
pared by  the  head  clearer  of  each  bank,  and 
shows  at  foot  the  final  balance  which  his  bank 
has  either  to  pay  or  receive.  This  balance  is 
settled  with  the  clearing  house  by  means  of 
transfers  made  at  the  Bank  of  England  between 
the  clearing  house  account  and  those  of  the 
various  banks.  Of  course,  if  the  final  balance- 
sheets  are  all  correctly  made  out,  the  total  of 
the  transfers  to  the  credit  of  the  clearing  house 
will  exactly  equal  the  total  of  the  amounts 
transferred  from  that  account  to  those  of  the 
creditor  banks.  Errors  are  charged  or  credited 
to  the  banks  in  the  next  day's  clearing. 

Country  Cheque  Clearing. — Besides  the  clear- 
ing between  the  city  bankers,  a  clearing  for 
drafts  drawn  upon  banks  throughout  England 
and  Wales  is  held  daily  at  the  London  clearing 
house.  In  economy  of  labour  this  is  the  most 
complete  example  of  the  advantages  of  the 
system,  its  net  result  being,  shortly,  this — that 
every  country  banker  can  make  presentation  of 
any  number  of  cheques,  drawn  on  any  of  about 
2100  country  banking  offices,  by  sending  ont 


CLEARING  SYSTEM 


307 


letter  to  his  London  agent ;  he  can  receive  pay- 
ment therefor  by  one  line  in  his  London  banking 
account,  and  can  in  the  same  manner  make  due 
payment  for  any  number  of  cheques  drawn  upon 
himself.  The  clearing  is  limited  to  cheques 
or  drafts  on  demand,  and  by  the  boundaries 
of  England  and  Wales,  being  one  day's  post 
from  London.  With  only  the  most  insignificant 
exceptions  it  embraces  every  bank  outside  the 
metropolis,  from  Land's  End  to  the  Tweed. 

The  particulars  of  the  arrangement  are  as 
follows.  Every  country  bank  has  as  London 
agent  one  of  the  London  clearing  bankers,  who 
conducts  on  his  behalf  the  clearing  now  referred 
to,  as  well  as  other  business  that  he  may  re- 
quire to  do  in  London.  Each  country  banker 
makes  up  daily  all  the  cheques  drawn  on  other 
country  banks  which  he  has  received,  and  for- 
wards them  by  the  evening  mail  to  his  London 
agent,  accompanying  the  parcel  with  a  detailed 
list  of  the  items.  The  London  banker,  receiv- 
ing them  on  the  following  morning,  after  ex- 
amination of  the  parcel,  sorts  the  cheques 
according  to  order  of  the  various  clearing 
bankers,  as  agents  of  the  banks  drawn  upon, 
charging  them  in  "out"  clearing  books,  and 
delivering  them  at  the  clearing  house.  The 
meeting  for  this  purpose  is  held  daily  from  12.0 
noon  till  2.15  p.m.,  the  cheques  being  entered 
at  the  house  in  "in"  clearing  books,  and  the 
totals  agreed  in  the  same  manner  as  in  the 
town  clearing.  No  balances  are  struck  until 
the  day  next  but  one,  when  the  head  clearer  of 
each  bank  prepares  a  balance-sheet,  composed 
of  the  various  balances  he  has  to  pay  or  to 
receive,  on  account  of  the  cheques  exchanged 
two  days  before.  The  final  balance  shown 
between  his  own  bank  and  the  clearing  house 
is  carried  forward  as  an  item  in  the  general 
balance-sheet  prepared  at  the  close  of  the  day's 
town  clearing.  On  the  first  day,  when  the 
exchanges  are  made,  the  cheques  received  by 
each  bank  as  "in"  clearing  are  taken  to  the 
office  and  sorted  afresh  in  order  of  the  country 
banks  on  which  they  are  drawn.  They  are 
then  entered  in  books,  and  sent  down  by  the 
evening's  post,  accompanied  by  lists.  The 
country  bankers,  receiving  them  the  next 
morning,  have  the  whole  day  for  examination, 
and  then,  in  the  daily  letter  to  their  London 
agents,  advise  them  to  debit  their  account  with 
the  total.  On  receipt  of  this  advice  the  London 
bankers  are  able  to  make  payment  at  the  clear- 
ing house  as  already  described.  Unpaid  cheques 
are  returned  through  the  post  by  the  banker 
refusing  them,  direct  to  the  banker  whose  name 
is  stamped  across  them,  and  the  particulars  are 
communicated  (technically  advised)  to  the 
London  agents,  who  claim  the  amounts  from 
the  agents  of  the  bankers  to  whom  they  have 
been  returned. 

No  official  figures  are  available  to  show  either 
the  number,  or  the  total  amount,  of  the  cheques 


included  in  the  country  cheque  clearing.  Cal- 
culations appear  to  show  that  the  number  of 
cheques  passing  thus  through  London  has  prob- 
ably reached  20,000,000  in  a  single  year,  with 
a  total  value  of  about  £450,000,000.  In  this 
case  the  economy  of  currency  is  considerable, 
but  the  economy  of  labour  is  even  greater,  and 
still  more  important  is  the  expansion  in  the 
business  of  the  country  bankers  rendered  pos- 
sible by  it,  as  it  enables  them  to  otter  theii 
customers  facilities  for  the  negotiability  of  their 
cheques  equal  to  those  enjoyed  by  customers  of 
London  Banks.     [See  Clearing  House,  App.] 

Peovincial  Clearing  Houses.  There  are 
(blearing  houses  or  systems  at  Manchester, 
Liverpool,  Birmingham,  Newcastle,  Leeds, 
Sheffield,  Bristol,  Leicester,  and  Nottingham. 
The  aggregate  amount  dealt  with  by  these 
clearing  houses  was  £507,600,000  in  1898, 
£624,800,000  in  1903,  and  £824,000,000  in 
1912.  In  several  instances  the  clearing  includes 
cheques  drawn  not  only  on  the  members  actually 
j>resenting,  but  also  on  their  branches  within  a 
specified  distance  of  the  centre.  At  Sheffield 
the  local  clearing  circle  has  a  radius  of  some 
twenty-five  miles.  There  are  also  various  de- 
grees of  economy  and  convenience  in  the  manner 
of  paying  the  balances  due.  Sometimes  they 
are  settled  by  bank  notes,  sometimes  by  trans- 
fers between  their  accounts  at  the  Branch  Bank 
of  England,  or  by  payments  made  and  received 
through  the  London  agents.  In  Scotland  there 
are  clearing  houses  at  Edinburgh,  Glasgow, 
Aberdeen,  Dundee,  Greenock,  Inverness,  Leith, 
and  Paisley.  The  arrangements  generally  in- 
clude note  exchanges,  and  also  a  highly  organised 
system  of  clearing  for  drafts  on  any  or  all  of 
the  numerous  branches.  In  Ireland  the  only 
clearing  house  is  at  Dublin.  In  Canada  there 
are  clearings  at  Montreal,  Toronto,  and  Hali- 
fax ;  in  Australia,  at  Melbourne  and  Sydney. 
As  all  the  Australian  banks  have  many  branches 
their  internal  transactions  do  much  to  diminish 
the  necessity  for  clearing  houses. 

Foreign  Clearing  Houses.  In  the  United 
States  great  use  has  been  made  of  the  clearing 
system.  Although  not  introduced  there  till 
1853,  when  the  New  York  Clearing  House  was 
established,  the  number  of  such  institutions, 
and  the  extent  of  their  transactions,  already 
exceed  those  of  Great  Britain.  This  is  due  not 
only  to  the  general  readiness  with  which  the 
Americans  avail  themselves  of  every  economic 
arrangement,  but  more  particularly  to  the 
peculiarity  of  their  banking  system.  None  of 
the  banks  in  the  United  States  have  any 
branches,  but  there  is  a  considerable  number  of 
large  banks,  which  increases  continually.  The 
deposits  of  the  7488  National  Banks  were 
over  £1,150,000,000  in  1913,  whilst  the 
whole  banking  deposits  of  the  country,  about 
£3,500,000,000,  are  divided  among  25,993 
banks.     {Report,  Comptroller  of  the  Currency, 


308 


CLEARING  SYSTEM 


1914.)  Each  bank  being  a  separate  institution, 
there  is  little  of  that  internal  clearing  per- 
formed in  every  large  bank  by  the  cancellation 
of  drafts  appearing  on  both  sides  of  the  books. 
Thus  the  clearing  house  becomes  a  necessity, 
even  where  the  total  amount  of  banking  business 
is  comparatively  small.  In  1890  there  w'ere  60 
clearing  houses  operating  in  the  United  States  ; 
in  1913,  162  including  New  York.  All  these 
institutions  have  arrangements  much  alike,  con- 
forming generally  to  those  of  the  New  York 
Clearing  House,  where  the  method  of  transacting 
business  differs  entirely  from  that  adopted  in 
London.  The  New  York  Clearing  House  includes 
64  members,  whose  representatives  meet  once  a 
day  only,  at  10  A.M.  Each  bank  sends  two 
representatives,  a  clerk  and  a  messenger,  who 
arrive  before  the  hour  named,  at  which  time 
every  clerk  is  required  to  be  at  his  appointed 
desk,  with  his  messenger  standing  outside  it. 
At  a  signal  from  the  manager,  who  is  stationed 
in  an  elevated  desk  overlooking  the  room,  every 
messenger  moves  forward  to  the  desk  next  his 
own  and  presents  to  the  clerk  there  a  sealed 
envelope  containing  the  cheques  drawn  on  the 
bank  for  which  that  clerk  acts,  with  a  slip 
pasted  outside  showing  the  particulars  of  the 
items  and  their  total  amount.  He  presents  also 
a  list  printed  with  the  names  of  all  the  banks, 
and  having  the  amount  presented  entered 
against  each  of  them.  The  clerk  receiving  the 
envelope  signs  for  the  amount  and  returns  the 
list  to  the  messenger,  who  goes  to  the  next 
desk  in  the  same  manner,  and  so  on  until  he 
has  made  the  circuit  of  the  room,  and  delivered 
all  his  envelopes.  The  whole  operation  of  ex- 
change is  thus  performed  in  about  ten  minutes. 
The  clerks  receiving  the  envelopes,  without 
opening  them,  enter  the  amounts  on  printed 
lists,  and  make  up  the  total,  which,  compared 
with  the  total  of  the  list  of  envelopes  de- 
livered by  their  own  messengers,  gives  a  balance 
to  be  paid  to,  or  received  from,  the  clearing 
house.  The  messengers  then  take  back  to  their 
respective  offices  the  envelopes  received,  and 
the  clerks  remain  behind  to  report  their  amounts 
to  the  managers,  and  to  agree  on  the  balance 
due.  This  done,  the  clerks  leave  the  house  ; 
the  whole  clearing  having  occupied  probably 
less  than  one  hour.  The  debtor  banks  have 
then  to  pay  over  to  the  clearing  house,  by  1.30 
P.M.,  the  balances  due  from  them,  after  which 
the  creditor  banks  can  receive,  at  the  same 
place,  the  balances  in  their  favour.  Neither 
in  New  York  nor  in  any  city  in  the  Union  is 
there  any  bank  occupying  a  position  similar  to 
that  of  the  Bank  of  England,  and  therefore  the 
balances  cannot  be  paid  by  transfer.  Formerly 
they  were  paid  in  legal-tender  notes,  or  in 
gold  coin,  but  this  entailed  a  vast  amount  of 
labour.  On  one  day,  in  1879,  the  value  of 
coin  passing  through  the  clearing  house  Avas 
£1,660,000,  and  its  weight  was  about  15|  tons. 


Besides  cost  of  time  and  labour  involved  in 
handling  the  coin,  much  loss  was  suffered  by 
abrasion.  Subsequently  the  clearing  banks 
made  a  deposit  of  gold  in  the  vaults  belonging 
to  one  of  their  number,  and  certificates  were 
issued  against  it  for  $1000,  |5000,  and  $10,000 
each,  which  were  passed  in  payment  of  balances. 
Kecently  this  plan  has  been  abandoned,  and 
payment  is  made,  as  to  the  chief  amounts,  in 
certificates  issued  by  the  United  States  Treasury 
for  gold  coin  deposited  there,  and  as  to  lesser 
amounts,  in  legal-tender  notes  and  minor  coins. 

There  is  not  at  present  any  system  similar 
to  that  of  our  country  cheque  clearing,  and 
the  inconveniences  suffered  by  the  banks  in  the 
United  States  for  want  of  such  a  system  aflFord 
a  good  illustration  of  the  advantages  derived 
from  it  here.  In  the  absence  of  due  facilities 
the  banks  have  a  custom  of  forwarding  cheques 
drawn  on  one  town  to  any  town  in  its  vicinity 
to  which  they  may  be  making  remittance,  on 
the  chance  of  the  bank  there  having  to  remit 
to  the  town  on  which  the  cheque  is  drawn. 
Frequently,  however,  this  turns  out  not  to  be 
the  case,  and  the  cheque  is  sent  backwards  and 
forwards  between  one  town  and  another,  some- 
times remaining  out  for  many  days  before 
finally  presented,  and,  if  unpaid,  taking  as 
many  days  more  in  return.  The  enormous 
distances  comprised  within  the  limits  of  the 
Union  would  render  it  difficult,  if  not  impossible, 
to  arrange  for  a  general  system  of  clearing 
through  a  single  centre.  The  course  of  develop- 
ment will  therefore  probably  be  in  the  direction 
of  the  establishment  of  local  clearing  circles. 

On  the  continent  of  Europe,  the  entirely 
different  degree  in  which  banking  has  progressed 
has  tended  greatly  to  restrict  the  use  of  clearing- 
houses. Although  the  earliest  system  of  clearing 
of  which  anything  is  known  was  that  which 
existed  for  some  centuries  at  Lyons,  France  has 
even  now  made  but  little  progress  towards 
adopting  this  economy.  The  Paris  Chamber  of 
Compensation,  established  1872,  is  the  only 
one  in  the  country,  and  its  transactions  are 
very  small.  Several  causes  have  led  to  this, 
chief  among  which  is  the  small  extent  to  which 
the  daily  transactions  of  trade  are  carried  out 
through  banks.  Cheques  were  quite  imknown 
before  1859,  and  their  use  has  not  even  now  be- 
come general.  Business  is  chiefly  carried  on  by 
means  of  notes,  coin,  and  small  bills,  the  latter 
being  generally  payable  at  the  offices  or  resi- 
dences of  the  drawees.  On  one  day,  31st  March 
1913,  the  Bank  of  France  collected  in  Paris 
400,375  bills,  payable  at  97,495  dwellings,  the 
total  value  being  £10,285,480.  The  Bank  o( 
France,  through  which  the  greater  part  of  the 
banking  operations  of  the  country  is  carried  on, 
had  in  1913,  127,963  current  accounts  at  Paris 
and  at  the  217  branches  and  auxiliary  offices  of 
the  Bank.  The  need  for  a  clearing  house  is 
still  further  lessened  by  the  fact  that  the  greater 


CLEARING  SYSTEM 


309 


part  of  such  business  is  carried  on  through  three 
banks  only,  namely  the  Bank  of  France,  the 
Societe  Generale,  and  the  Credit  Lyonnais.  As 
these  establishments  have  between  them  some 
1402  branches,  they  are  able  to  settle  a  large 
proportion  of  their  transactions  within  their 
own  offices.  The  Bank  of  France  has  special 
arrangements  for  this  purpose,  and  the  amount 
annually  "cleared"  within  its  walls  is  seven 
or  eight  times  as  large  as  the  total  passing 
through  the  Chambre  de  Compensation.  A  still 
greater  amount  is  probably  that  which  is  aflected 
by  the  arrangement  under  which  the  operations 
of  the  Bourse,  not  only  in  Paris,  but  in  the 
other  chief  cities,  are  liquidated  within  the 
Bourse  itself  by  means  of  the  "Compagnie  des 
Agents  de  Change  de  Paris."  These  remarks 
apply  with  little  variation  to  the  banking 
arrangements  in  the  other  countries  of  Europe. 
Where  there  is  no  general  use  of  cheques  there 
is  no  gi-eat  necessity  for  a  clearing  house,  and 
throughout  the  continent  a  "bank"  exists 
more  as  an  establishment  of  credit  than  as  a 
medium  of  currency.  In  Berlin,  the  clearing 
was  established  by  the  Reichsbank  so  recently 
as  1884,  as  part  of  a  general  movement  to 
extend  the  use  of  cheques.  There,  also,  the 
transactions  of  the  stock  exchange  are,  and  have 
been  since  1871,  liquidated  by  "set-oif"  in  a 
separate  institution,  the  Bank  des  Berliner 
Cassen  - Veremes:  A  clearing  liouse  exists  at 
Hamburg,  continuing  arrangements  long  carried 
on  by  the  Bank  of  Hamburg  ;  and  clearin.i^^s  are 
also  conducted  by  24  branches  of  the  Reichsbank. 
A  clearing  house  was  established  in  Brussels 
in  1908,  and  has  gi-eatly  assisted  business  in 
Belgium.  At  Vienna,  arrangements  which  previ- 
ously existed  among  several  banks,  were  con- 
solidated, in  1872,  into  a  regidar  clearing  house. 
Its  operations  have  not  been  very  considerable, 
nor  have  they  shown  any  tendency  to  in- 
crease. The  operations  of  the  Bourse  are 
liquidated  separately  by  the  Wiener  Giro-  und 
Cassen  -  Vereine.  In  1881  the  amounts  so 
liquidated  were  fom-teen  times  as  gi-eat  as  those 
passed  through  the  clearing  house.  In  Italy, 
thirteen  clearing  houses  were  established  by 
royal  decree  in  1881,  to  assist  the  resumption 
of  specie  payments,  but  the  development  of 
banking  there  did  not  require  their  continuance, 
and  only  those  of  Rome,  Milan,  Florence, 
Genoa,  Catania,  and  Bologna  still  exist,  besides 
that  at  Leghorn,  established  long  previously. 

Statistics.  Full  tables  of  the  amounts 
passing  through  the  various  clearing  houses  of 
the  world  cannot  be  given  here,  but  a  few  of 
the  most  important  figures  wiU  show  the  extent 
to  which  currency  at  least  is  economised  by 
the  system.  Some  considerations  should  always 
be  borne  in  mind  in  connection  with  tables  of 
clearings  which  are  otherwise  likely  to  mislead. 
The  amounts  cleared  at  one  time  or  place,  as 
impared  with  other  times  or  places,  do  not 


directly  indicate  the  relative  extent  of  trade  or 
of  banking  development.  They  may  vary  with 
(1)  the  number  of  separate  members  included 
in  the  clearing  ;  (2)  the  proportion  they  bear 
to  the  whole  banking  system  of  the  place  ;  (3) 
the  existence  there  of  other  institutions  having 
similar  objects  ;  (4)  the  manner  in  Avliich  returns 
are  made.  In  connection  with  point  1,  it  is 
evident  that  the  greater  the  number  of  banks 
in  the  clearing  the  greater  Avill  be  the  proportion 
of  their  whole  transactions  passing  through  th« 
house.  The  larger  any  individual  business  is, 
the  larger  will  be  the  proportion  of  its  transac- 
tions cancelled  in  its  own  office.  The  same 
applies  to  point  2,  because  banks  outside  the 
clearing,  though  they  may  clear  through  mem- 
bers of  it,  have  still  a  large  number  of  transac- 
tions settled  internally,  and  thus  removed  from 
view.  This  also  applies  with  still  gi'eater  force  to 
banks  with  many  branches.  Point  3,  the  extent 
to  which  aiTangements  are  in  existence  for  liqui- 
dating separately  any  particular  class  of  financial 
engagements,  must  obviously  materially  affect 
the  amounts  cleared.  The  remarks  already 
made  on  this  subject  as  to  the  clearings  at  Paris, 
Vienna,  and  Berlin  sufficiently  show  its  import- 
ance. On  the  other  hand,  the  absence  of  special 
settling  days  for  bargains  between  members  of 
the  Stock  Board  in  New  York  tends  to  increase 
the  amounts  passing  through  tlie  bankers'  clear- 
ing. Point  4,  the  totals  of  one  side  only  are 
usually  quoted,  but  in  the  earlier  returns  of 
some  American  clearings,  and  in  some  con- 
tinental clearings  at  the  present  time,  both 
cheques  brought  in  and  those  taken  away  ar^ 
included,  thus  doubling  the  figures. 


[jQudon — Annual  Average 


Clearings. 

Millious. 
1868-1877  £-1,941 
1878-1887 
1888-1890 
1891-1900 
1901-1910 
vear  1912 
"  „     1912 


1913 


1913 
1913 


1913 


5,747 

7,454 

7,501 

11,831 

15,962 

347 

19,624 


15,129 
12,392 

3,682 
between 
over  in 


aompari 

Ik 


Manchester. 

New  York  .... 

162  Other  Clearing  Houses, 

U.S.A 

Paris,  Bank  of  France 
Berlin,  Reichsbank — 
24  Clearing  Ollices  . 
With  regard  to  the  proportion 
amounts  cleared  and  balances  paid 
settlement,  their  relation  will  depend  generally 
upon  the  number  of  members  in  the  "  clearing," 
but  it  may  also  be  affected  by  other  circum- 
stances. Thus  the  balances  paid  in  the  London 
Clearing  House  are  very  largely  increased  by 
the  Bank  of  England  clearing  on  one  side  only, 
the  debtor  balances  of  all  the  other  banks  being 
thus  increased  to  the  extent  of  the  whole  of  their 
claims  upon  the  Bank,  which  are  by  the  present 
arrangement  paid  in  as  "credits"  at  the  Bank 


tflO 


CLEARING  SYSTEM 


counter.  In  point  of  economy  of  currency, 
however,  this  is  immaterial  as  the  final  settle- 
ment is  made  by  book  entry. 

Other  Classes  of  Clearings.  The  prin- 
ciples of  clearing  have  been  applied,  with  more 
or  less  completeness  and  success,  to  the  settle- 
ment of  transactions  in  commodities  other  than 
money,  and  some  examples  of  those  arrange- 
ments must  now  be  briefly  referred  to.  Whilst 
the  clearing  houses  described  above  have  differed 
only  in  the  degree  of  their  organisation,  institu- 
tions for  dealing  with  commoditiei/^are  capable 
of  variation  in  another  direction.  They  may 
deal  with  either  or  both  of  two  terms  instead 
of  with  the  single  term,  money.  A  number 
of  bargains  in  any  movable  property  may  be 
settled  by  the  principle  of  "set-off","  either  as  to 
delivery  of  the  property  or  as  to  payment  of  its 
value,  or  as  to  both  of  these  points.  One  feature, 
however,  is  common  to  all  clearings,  and  that 
is  uniformity  of  the  article  dealt  in.  A  clearing 
can  only  be  held  under  these  circumstances,  as 
it  is  the  essence  of  the  principle  that  the  last 
buyer  or  receiver  is  equally  satisfied  by  delivery 
from  the  first  seller  as  he  would  be  by  delivery 
from  the  person  of  whom  he  actually  bought. 

These  conditions  are  present  in  bargains  in 
stocks  and  shares,  and  it  is  in  connection  with 
stock  transactions  that  the  most  extended  ap- 
plication of  the  clearing  system  to  dealings 
other  than  those  in  money  has  been  made. 

The  Stock  Exchange  Clearing  has  been 
in  operation  in  London  since  1874,  and  though 
its  use  is  neither  obligatory  nor  universal  among 
the  members  of  the  stock  exchange,  it  has  un- 
doubtedly effected  a  very  material  saving  of 
labour.  Nothing  whatever  is  known  of  the 
amounts  settled  by  its  means,  although,  no 
doubt,  they  are  already  very  considerable,  but 
it  cannot  be  said  to  effect  any  economy  in  cur- 
rency, as  the  transactions  liquidated  there  would 
otherwise  be  settled  by  cheques.  Still,  those 
amounts,  whatever  they  may  be,  are  so  much 
withdrawn  from  the  returns  of  the  Bankers' 
Clearing  House. 

The  clearing  is  held  within  the  precincts  of 
the  stock  exchange,  and  is  under  the  sanction 
and  control  of  the  committee.  It  is  not  applied 
to  the  settlement  of  general  business,  but  only 
to  bargains  in  certain  stocks,  and  those  such  as 
are  the  subject  of  frequent  speculative  transac- 
tions. These  comprise  most  classes  of  foreign 
government  bonds  and  some  particular  English 
railway  stocks.  As  it  is  not  in  universal  use 
among  the  members  of  the  exchange,  any  dealer 
who  desires  to  settle  his  bargains  through  the 
clearing  is  able  to  do  so  only  with  regard  to 
certain  stocks,  and  even  in  those  is  limited  to 
his  bargains  with  such  other  members  as  also 
clear.  The  clearing  is  carried  on  entirely  by 
means  of  balance-sheets  and  tickets  ;  neither 
stock  nor  money  in  any  form  being  received  at 
the  clearing  house.     On  the  settling  day  each 


member  forwards  to  the  clearing  house  a  balance- 
sheet  for  each  particular  stock,  giving  on  the 
one  side  the  amounts  of  the  stock  purchased 
and  to  be  received  by  him,  and  on  the  other 
the  amounts  he  has  sold  and  has  to  deliver, 
together  with,  in  each  case,  the  name  of  the 
seller  or  buyer.  At  foot  is  shown  the  net 
balance  which  he  has  to  receive  or  to  deliver. 
At  the  clearing  house  each  item  in  this  list  is 
ticked  off"  or  cancelled  against  the  corresponding 
item  in  the  sheet  furnished  by  the  other  party, 
until  the  balances  only  remain  outstanding. 
The  total  of  the  balances  of  stock  deliverable 
will  then  exactly  equal  the  total  of  the  balances 
of  stock  receivable,  although  the  items  making 
up  each  total  will  be  diff"erent.  Those  who  have 
to  deliver  stock  are  then  furnished  with  tickets 
giving  the  separate  amounts  into  which  their 
balance  has  to  be  divided  and  the  parties  to 
whom  they  are  to  be  delivered ;  whilst  those 
who  have  to  take  in  stock  receive  tickets  show- 
ing by  whom  it  will  be  delivered.  The  receiver 
pays  to  the  party  delivering  the  stock  its  value 
at  a  fixed  price,  which  is  settled  on  the  account 
day,  and  is  called  the  "making -up  price." 
All  diff"erences  between  this  price  and  those  at 
which  the  yarious  bargains  were  made  are  settled 
directly  between  the  dealer  and  those  with  whom 
he  has  dealt.  No  particulars  are  obtainable  of 
the  transactions  which  are  settled  in  this 
manner,  but  as  the  clearing  is  chiefly  used  by 
those  dealers  and  brokers  who  transact  specula- 
tive business,  and  the  stocks  which  clear  are 
only  the  most  speculative  and  "active"  classes, 
it  is  probable  that  the  bargains  "cleared"  are 
among  the  heaviest  in  each  "account."  The 
existence  of  this  arrangement  is  therefore  a 
consideration  of  some  importance  in  any  com- 
parison of  the  returns  of  the  London  Bankers' 
Clearing  House  before  and  after  1874.  The 
liquidation  of  transactions  on  the  Boiirse  at 
Paris  is  much  more  complete  in  its  organisation, 
and  applies  to  all  the  operations  of  the  Agents 
de  Change.  In  Vienna  and  Berlin  the  com- 
pensations effected  by  the  institutions  already 
mentioned  also  cover  the  greater  part  of  the 
Bourse  transactions. 

The  Beetroot  Sugar  Association  of 
London  established  (in  1888)  some  arrangements 
for  clearing  bargains  in  beetroot  sugar  upon  the 
following  basis.  The  bargains  to  be  cleared 
must  always  have  reference  to  sugar  of  a  certain 
range  of  quality,  and  to  lots  of  500  bags,  each 
containing  a  certain  weight.  A  broker  having 
sold  a  quantity  of  sugar,  starts  a  filiere  for  each 
500  bags,  describing  thereon  the  ship  or  ware- 
house marks,  and  all  other  necessary  particulars. 
The  filUre  is  a  sheet  of  paper  printed  at  the 
head  with  the  conditions  of  sale,  and  with 
spaces  for  insertion  of  the  particulars  referred 
to.  It  contains  also  a  series  of  transfer  forms 
which  are  filled  up  and  signed  by  each  success- 
ive holder,  transferring  the  property  to  a  new 


CLEARING  SYSTEM 


3U 


purchaser.  At  the  same  time  the  purchaser 
signs  a  coupon  form  which  is  printed  at  the 
side  of  the  transfer,  quoting  the  date  and  hour 
of  the  sale.  This  is  detached,  and  retained  by 
the  seller  as  evidence  to  determine  any  liability 
consequent  on  delay  in  passing  on  the  filiere. 
Any  pm-chaser  requiring  delivery  of  the  sugar 
can  send  the  filUre  to  the  clearing  house, 
instead  of  passing  it  on,  and  his  name  is  then 
communicated  by  the  officials  to  the  first  seller 
who  tenders  him  the  warrant  direct.  The 
filUres  may  pass  from  hand  to  hand  within  a 
limit  of  six  days,  at  each  transfer  a  stamp  being 
affixed  for  the  clearing  fee.  The  differences 
between  each  of  the  successive  bargains  are 
calculated  to  the  profit  or  loss  of  the  seller.  In 
the  former  case,  the  clearing  house  issues 
a  cheque  in  his  favour  ;  in  the  latter  case 
notice  is  sent  of  the  amount  due,  which  he 
is  required  to  pay  immediately  to  the  bankers 
of  the  association.  All  the  intermediate  parties 
being  struck  out,  any  difference  in  the  quality 
or  weight  of  the  sugar  ultimately  delivered 
concerns  only  the  first  and  last  parties,  who 
settle  it  between  themselves.  The  arrangement 
appears  to  be  very  complete,  and  as  the  advan- 
tages are  considerable,  it  is  already  largely  used. 
1 1  must  therefore  make  a  great  difference  in  the 
amoimts  of  money  passing  in  the  trade.  It  is 
not  unusual  iov  filler es  to  pass  through  twenty 
hands  before  delivery  of  the  sugar,  and  as  a  lot 
of  500  bags  is  worth,  roughly,  about  £600,  the 
transactions  represented  in  such  a  case  would 
amount  to  £11, 400,  of  which  eighteen  transfers 
amounting  to  £10,800,  would  be  struck  out, 
leaving  only  one  amount  of  £600,  and  sundry 
small  differences  to  be  settled  by  actual  pay- 
ment. Besides  this  economy,  there  is  the 
saving  in  clerical  work,  the  avoidance  of  risk 
in  delivering  warrants  from  hand  to  hand,  and 
of  delay  in  tendering  warrants,  with  a  con- 
sequent saving  of  much  expense  in  demurrage. 

London  Produce  Clearing.  An  instil  u- 
tion  under  this  name  was  started  in  1888,  to 
regulate  and  adjust  bargains  in  colonial  and 
foreign  produce.  At  first  its  operations  were 
confined  to  coffee  and  sugar,  but  they  have  since 
been  extended  to  wheat  and  silver.  The  chief 
object  of  the  company  is  to  guarantee  both  to 
buyer  and  seller  the  fulfilment  of  bargains  for 
future  delivery.  This  it  does  upon  payment 
by  the  contracting  party  of  a  margin  sufficient 
to  secure  the  company  from  loss.  Indii'ectly, 
a  certain  amount  of  economy  by  clearing  is 
effected,  because  transactions  accumulate  on 
either  side  during  the  month,  and  are  settled 
at  the  end  by  payment  of  balances  only.  In 
this  case  also  bargains  are  for  commodities  of 
a  certain  quality,  and  in  specified  quantities, 
or  multiples  thereof.  If  the  clearing  came 
to  be  extensively  used,  there  would  be  a  great 
saving  in  the  amounts  of  cheques  drawn.  Other 
institutions  upon  the  same  lines  are  the  ' '  Caisse 


de  Liquidation"  at  Havre,  and  the  "Waaren 
Liquidations  Casse"  at  Hamburg.  For  the 
"Cotton  Brokers'  Bank"  in  Liverpool,  v.  Cotton 
Clearing.  In  the  tea-trade,  the  Tea  Clearing 
House  is  only  for  economy  of  labour,  by  pro- 
viding a  central  office  for  the  lodgment  and 
delivery  at  the  various  docks  and  warehouses 
of  warrants,  and  orders  for  various  purposes. 
Further,  it  is  to  be  observed  that  by  the  exten- 
sion of  the  warehouse  system,  a  species  of  clear- 
ing is  effected  as  regards  the  handling  of  goods, 
by  warrants,  which  are  used  for  intermediate 
transfer,  whilst  delivery  is  only  made  to  the 
last  buyer.  Among  the  most  important  ex- 
amples are  the  warrants  of  Connal's  Stores 
at  Glasgow,  for  pig-iron  ;  and,  in  the  United 
States,  the  certificates  of  the  United  Pipe  Line 
for  petroleum,  and  the  system  of  grading  and 
storing  wheat  as  adopted  at  Chicago. 

Finally,  the  Railway  Clearing  House 
requires  some  notice,  although  it  has  other 
objects  than  settlement  by  "set-off'."  Its 
main  purpose  is  to  settle  all  the  balances  that 
arise  out  of  through-booking,  and  to  split  up 
into  different  proportions  the  sums  that  are 
received  for  transport  of  goods  or  passengers, 
where  they  pass  over  different  lines.  For  this 
purpose  the  railways  send  to  the  clearing 
house  daily  reports  of  all  compound  tickets 
issued  at  each  station,  and  of  all  amounts 
charged  for  through  carriage  of  goods.  All 
spent  tickets  collected  are  also  sent  up  to  be 
compared  with  the  accounts  rendered.  From 
these  particulars  the  various  companies  are 
debited  with  the  amounts  received  by  them,  and 
credited  with  their  proportion  of  the  work  done 
according  to  the  mileage  of  theii-  line  covered, 
the  haulage,  and  the  ownership  of  coaches, 
trucks,  or  tarpaulins  used.  Of  course  the 
principle  of  clearing  is  brought  into  play  in 
effecting  the  settlement  of  all  these  claims.  A 
regular  debit  and  credit  account  is  kept  with 
every  railway,  and  it  is  only  called  on  to  make 
payment  when  a  considerable  sum  is  cwing,  or 
when  the  set  of  the  balances  is  all  one  way. 

[See  Clearing  House,  App.  ;  also  Our  CleaHng 
System  and  Clearing  Houses  (Howarth). — CleaHng 
Iloiises  et  Chambres  de  Compensation  {Fran9ois); 
and  also  various  papers  in  Journcd,  Institute  oj 
Bankers,  vol.  iii.  1881-82,  and  subsequent  years 
As  to  amounts  settled  outside  of  clearing  houses, 
see  "  Proportionate  use  of  Credit  Documents  and 
Metallic  Money  in  English  Banks"  (Pownall),  /o«r- 
nal,  Inst.  Bankers,  vol.  ii.  1880-81.]        r.  w.  b. 

Cotton  Clearing  (Cotton  Brokers' Bank). 
The  prmciple  of  payment  by  "set-off"  of 
differences  has  been  applied  to  the  very  heavy 
monetary  transactions  arising  from  dealings  in 
cotton  at  Liverpool.  The  system  employed  is 
fully  described  in  the  Bankers'  Magazine  for 
July  1887.  No  fewer  than  forty-six  different 
forms  for  contract,  orders  for  delivery,  etc.,  may 
have  to  be  employed  in  the  process,  and  eleven 


312 


CLJ&MENT 


more  connect  the  "Cotton  Brokers'  Bank, 
Limited,"  as  the  association  through  which 
the  business  passes  is  termed,  with  the  clearing 
conducted  by  the  branch  Bank  of  England  at 
Liverpool.  The  numerous  forms  mentioned  are 
requu-ed  to  meet  the  various  requirements  arising 
out  of  the  re-sale  of  the  bales  of  cotton  dealt 
with.  These  may  pass  through  many  hands 
after  being  in  the  possession  of  the  original  pur- 
chaser, before  being  finally  disposed  of.  In- 
surance against  risk  by  fire,  the  possibility  of 
need  for  arbitration,  in  case  of  dispute  and  of 
appeal  against  an  award,  the  difiierent  methods 
of  dealing  according  to  the  special  rules  in 
force,  whether  the  cotton  comes  from  America 
or  India,  all  the  various  incidents  which  may 
arise  in  the  conduct  of  a  very  complicated 
business,  are  provided  for  through  these  ar- 
rangements, as  well  as  the  ultimate  disposal 
of  the  money  arising  therefrom.  The  result 
has  been  a  vast  economy  in  labour,  as  well 
as  in  the  use  of  the  cu'culating  medium. 
"Formerly  all  cotton  was  paid  for  in  cash. 
Now  all  the  effects,  whether  cash,  cheques, 
bankers'  drafts,  or  transfers  (both  by  post  and 
telegraph)  are  lodged  with  the  Bank  of  England 
for  the  credit  of  the  Liverpool  Cotton  Bank, 
Limited,  clearing  account.  The  members  of 
the  cotton  bank  then  transfer  the  amounts  re- 
quired from  one  to  another  at  the  cotton  bank, 
and  at  the  end  of  the  day  the  cotton  bank 
sends  the  completed  pay  list  to  the  Bank  of 
England,  and  the  ultimate  receivers  have  cheques 
for  their  amounts.  The  object  of  the  clearing 
house  of  the  Cotton  Association  is  to  settle  the 
very  numerous  sales  and  re-sales  of  an  individual 
parcel  of  cotton  by  collecting  and  distributing 
the  'differences'  due  by,  or  to,  the  respective 
buyers  and  sellers.  Formerly  each  transaction 
was  settled,  as  any  ordinary  purchase  or  sale 
is,  by  the  parties  concerned ;  a  very  great 
economy  in  the  labour  of  the  process,  as  well  as 
in  the  use  of  the  circulating  medium,  is  obviously 
eflfected  by  means  of  the  *  cotton  bank '  and  its 
connection  with  the  Bank  of  England  "  {Bankers' 
Magazine,  1887,  p.  591).  The  arrangements, 
though  apparently  simple,  must  have  required 
an  immense  amount  of  technical  knowledge  and 
intelligence  to  put  into  shape. 

CLEMENT,  Ambroise,  born  at  Paris  1805, 
died  there  1886.  From  1838  to  1848  and 
from  1850  to  1860  A.  Clement  was  secretary 
to  the  mayoralty  of  Saint  Etienne,  and,  in 
this  capacity,  rendered  important  services  to 
that  city,  for  example,  successfully  opposing, 
the  establishment  of  store  houses  for  grain 
(Greniers  D'abondance,  q.v.)  desired  by  the 
imperial  prefect  of  the  Loire.  He  was  one  of 
the  organisers  and  workers  from  the  beginning 
in  the  Didionnaire  de  V6conomie  politique, 
and  wrote  many  articles  in  the  Joxirnal  des 
4conomistes.  His  works  are  noteworthy  on 
account  of  the  firmness  of  their  principles  and 


their  logical  accuracy.  He  was  faithful  all 
his  life  to  the  principles  of  his  master,  J.  B. 
Say,  as  his  following  works  show  ;  Rccherches 
sur  les  causes  de  l' indigence  (1846  in  8vo). — Des 
nouvelles  idees  de  r^forme  industrielle,  referring 
in  particular  to  the  project  for  the  Organisation  of 
labour  by  M.  Louis  Blanc  (1848  in  18mo) ;  £ssai 
sur  la  science  sociale  (1867,  2  vols,  in  8vo). — Le 
bon  sens  dans  les  doctrines  morales  et  polUiques, 
or  the  apjjiication  of  the  experimental  method 
to  philosophy,  moral  sciences,  and  political 
economy  (2  vols,  in  8vo) ;  finally,  La  crise 
ioonomique  et  sociale  en  France  en  1886  (large 
8vo),  his  last  work.  A.  c.  f. 

CLEMENT,  Pierre,  born  at  Draguignan 
1809,  died  8th  November  1870.  He  held  a  high 
ofiicial  post  in  the  ministry  of  finance,  and 
entered  the  Institute  (^Academic  des  Scien^ces 
morales  et  politiques)  through  the  imperial 
decree  of  14th  April  1855 — All  PieiTC  Clement's 
works  consist  of  historical  investigations  con- 
scientiously written,  laboriously  treated,  and 
touching  on  financial  questions,  approached  on 
the  economic  side.  The  following  is  a  list  of 
his  principal  works  in  order  of  publication : 
Histoire  de  la  vie  et  de  V administration  de  Col- 
bert pr4c4d^e  d'une  dtude  sur  Nicolas  Fouqiiet^ 
1846  in  8vo  (his  best  work,  which  obtained  a 
prize  from  the  Acad^m-le  Frangaise  in  1848) ;  Le 
Gouvemement  de  Lmiis  XIV.  (1683  to  1689) 
a  continuation  of  the  preceding  (honoured  with 
the  second  Gobert  prize  by  the  AcadAmie  des 
Inscriptions  et  Belles-lettres  in  1848). — Jacques 
Ooeur  et  Charles  VII.  (1853  in  18mo,  prize  from 
the  Acad6mie  Frangaise). — Histoire  du  systeme 
protecteur  en  France  de  Colbert  A  1848  (1854  in 
8vo),  a  work  written  in  the  spirit  of  free  trade  ; 
Portraits  Mstoriques  (1855  in  18mo). — Trois 
dramies  historiques  (in  18mo). — Engv^rrand  de 
Marigny,  Beau/ne  de  Semblangay  et  le  Chevalier 
de  Rohan  (in  8vo  and  in  18mo)  ;  lastly  M.  de 
Silhouette,  Bouret  et  lesdemiersfermiersgdn^raux 
(1872  in  18mo),  this  work  was  completed  by 
Alfred  Lemoine  and  published  after  the  death 
of  P.  Clement.  It  was  due  to  the  labours  of 
Pierre  Clement  that  an  important  publication, 
Les  Lettres,  Instructions,  et  Mimoires  de  Colbert 
(1861-73,  7  vols,  large  8vo),  undertaken  by 
the  imperial  government  was  successfully  com- 
pleted. The  AcadAmie  Frangaise  voted  its 
highest  honours  to  this  collection.        a.  c.  f. 

CLEMENT,  Simon  (fl.  1695-1720),  merchant 
of  London,  In  1696  he  was  concerned,  along 
with  other  merchants,  in  an  infringement  of 
the  Navigation  Act  (q.v.)  by  allowing  a  ship 
to  be  worked  with  a  crew  less  than  three-fourths 
of  whom  were  English  sailors.  A  plan  which 
he  proposed  in  1708,  for  the  importation  of 
pitch  and  tar,  was  favourably  considered  by 
the  government.  From  1712-1714  he  appears 
to  have  resided  at  Vienna  ;  and  in  1720  we 
find  him  presenting  a  memorial  on  behalf  of 
the  widow  of  William  Penn,  whose  will  was 


CLERGy,  BENEFIT  OF— COASTING  TRADE 


313 


disputed.  He  publislied  A  Discourse  of  the 
General  Notions  of  Money,  Trade,  and  Exchanges 
as  tJiey  stand  in  relation  each  to  other,  attempted 
by  way  of  Aphorism,  etc.,  by  a  Merchant, 
London,  1695  ;  and  The  interest  of  England  as 
it  stands  toith  relation  to  the  trade  of  Ireland 
considered,  etc.,  London,  1698,  4to.  Clement's 
pamphlets  are  well  worth  studying.  Though  not 
free  from  mercantilist  errors,  he  anticipatcui 
in  some  respects  the  conclusion  of  later  writers. 
He  pointed  out  that  ' '  silver  and  gold  .  .  .  arc 
to  be  considered  but  as  a  liner  sort  of  com- 
modities ;  and  as  such  are  capable  of  rising 
and  falling  in  price,  and  may  be  said  to  be  of 
more  or  less  value  in  divers  places,  according 
to  their  plenty  or  scarcity.  Bullion  then  may 
there  be  reckoned  to  be  of  the  higher  value, 
where  the  smaller  weight  will  purchase  the 
greater  quantity  of  the  product  of  manufacture 
of  the  county."  In  an  appendix,  "offering 
some  further  reasons  against  raising  the  value 
of  our  coin,"  he  opposed  the  views  expressed  by 
William  Lowndes  {q.v.)  in  his  Essay  for  the 
Amendment  of  the  Silver  Coins  (1695).  Davc- 
nant  quotes  with  approval  Clement's  "judicious 
observation,"  in  his  pamphlet  on  the  trade  of 
Ireland,  "that  if  any  one  oflers  his  goods 
cheaper  than  the  usual  price,  that  will  then 
become  the  market  price  ;  and  every  one  else 
must  sell  at  the  same,  or  keep  his  goods." 

[Cal.  of  Treasury  Papers,  xxxviii.  56  ;  evii.  40  ; 
cix  22  ;  clxxxii.  37  ;  ccxxviii.  18. — Davenant, 
Essay,  etc.  on  the  Balance  of  Trade  (1699),  123  ; 
Brit.  Mus.  Catalogue;  Cat.  Bibl.  Bodl.]  w.  a.  s.  h. 

CLERGY,  Benefit  of.  "Originally  con- 
sisted in  the  privilege  allowed  to  a  clerk  in 
orders,  when  prosecuted  in  the  temporal  court, 
of  being  discharged  from  thence  and  handed 
over  to  the  Court  Christian,  in  order  to  make 
canonical  pm-gation."  —  (Stei)hen's  Cvmvien- 
taries  on  the  Laws  of  England,  vol.  iv.  bk.  vi. 
ch.  xix.) 

CLIENT.  This  word  is  derived  through  the 
French  from  the  Latin  cHctis  (cluens  from  cluere, 
to  hear),  which  in  one  of  its  derivative  senses 
signified  a  person  who  employed  a  patronus  or 
advocatus  to  assist  him  in  his  cause  (see 
Smith's  Diet,  of  Antiquities,  s.  v.  cliens). 

A  client  is  a  person  who  engages  a  barrister 
or  solicitor  for  the  purpose  of  obtaining  their 
professional  advice  or  assistance.  It  is  a  rule 
of  professional  etiquette  that  a  barrister  should 
be  engaged  through  the  agency  of  a  solicitor. 
Hence  the  solicitor  is  called  the  client  of  the 
barrister  he  briefs.  The  person  whose  cause  is 
in  question  is  also  said  to  be  the  client  of  the 
barrister.  The  relation  between  barrister  and 
client  is  not,  like  that  of  solicitor  and  client,  a 
contractual  one,  a  barrister  not  having  a  right 
like  a  solicitor  to  sue  his  client  for  his  fees. 
This  rule,  that  only  an  honorarium  is  due  to  a 
barrister,  is  derived  from  Roman  law.  E.  A.  w. 

CLIENT,  Stockbroker's.     The  stockbroker 


regards  his  principal  very  much  as  a  solicitor 
regards  his  client.  In  most  cases  a  novice  has 
to  be  advised  as  carefully  about  his  investments 
as  a  litigator  is  advised  by  his  solicitor,    a.  e. 

CLIFFE  LESLIE.   See  Leslie,  T.  E.  Cliffe. 

CLIPPED  MONEY.  Until  1663,  English 
coins  were  not  marked  or  milled  on  the  edges, 
and  the  practice  arose  of  clipping  small  pieces 
off  the  coins.  By  3  Henry  V.  c.  6,  clipping 
washing,  or  filing  the  coin  of  the  realm  was 
declared  high  treason.  This  act  was  repealed 
by  1  Mary,  sess.  1,  c.  1,  but  its  provisions 
were  re-enacted  and  extended  by  5  Eliz.  c.  11, 
and  18  Eliz.  c.  1.  The  introduction  of  milling 
tended  to  prevent  clipping,  but  during  the  17th 
century  clipj)ing  was  a  common  offence  owing 
to  the  large  gains  resulting.  Notwithstanding 
the  re-coinage  of  Elizabeth  and  the  issue  of  new 
coins  in  subsequent  years,  the  amount  of  clipped 
coins  steadily  increased,  the  new  coin  being 
melted  down  or  exported.  It  was  estimated 
that  the  coinage  had  lost  one-third  its  weight. 
In  1695,  provision  was  made  for  restoring  the 
coinage  to  its  full  weight :  the  cost,  amounting 
to  £2,703,164,  being  met  from  the  hearth-tax. 

[Lowndes'  Essay  fm-  the  Aviendment  of  the  Silver 
Coins,  1695. — Macaulay's  History  of  England,  vol. 
iv. — First  Nine  Years  of  the  Bank  of  England, 
by  J.  E.  T.  Rogers,  Oxford,  1887.]        J.  E.  c.  M. 

CLOFF  OR  CLOUGH.  An  allowance  of  2 
lb.  in  every  cwt.  after  tare  and  tret  have  been 
deducted.  It  is  given  to  cover  small  losses  in 
retailing.  j.  e.  c.  m. 

COALITIONS.     See  Tiiade  Unions. 

COASTING  TRADE.  Coasting  trade  is 
trade  carried  on  by  sea  between  the  various 
ports  of  the  same  country  or  state,  and  there- 
fore in  the  case  of  this  country  includes  the 
intercourse  between  Great  Britain  and  Ireland 
(39  &  40  Vict.  cap.  36,  §  140).  From  the 
time  of  EKzabeth,  if  not  before,  the  coasting 
trade  was  reserved  to  British  subjects  by  various 
acts  of  parliament  including  the  navigation  acts 
of  1651  and  1660  ;  but  by  the  act  of  17  Vict, 
cap.  5,  this  restriction  was  swept  away,  and  all 
nations  have  since  participated  in  our  coasting 
trade.  As,  however,  only  121,000  tons  of 
foreign  shipping  were  entered  in  1888  in  the 
coasting  trade,  compared  with  the  27,000,000 
tons  of  British  shipping,  the  eliect  of  this  free 
trade  measure  may  be  regarded  as  more  moral 
than  material.  Many  foreign  countries  have 
followed  our  example  in  this  respect,  allowing 
ships  of  other  nations  to  share  in  their  coasting 
trade,  but  there  are  still  several  notable  excep- 
tions, such  as  France,  Russia,  Spain,  Greece, 
and  the  United  States,  where  this  trade  is  still 
reserved  to  the  national  flag.  If  the  policy  of 
allowing  the  utmost  competition  in  carrying 
goods  to  and  from  our  shores  •  is  a  riglit  one,  it 
is  difficult  to  maintain  that  the  same  competi- 
tion is  undesirable  in  trade  between  the  vari- 
ous ports.     The  great  Indk  of  the  articles  so 


k 


314 


COASTING  TRADE— COBBETT 


carried  are  raw  materials,  such  as  coals,  bricks, 
timber,  and  the  like,  for  which  the  cheaper 
carriage  of  the  sea  compared  with  that  of  the 
railway  is  a  necessity,  and  we  do  not  wish  to 
endanger  this  cheap  carriage  by  excluding  com- 
petition. The  regulations  imposed  on  ships 
and  cargoes  in  coasting  trade  are  much  less 
stringent  than  those  on  foreign-going  ships. 
The  following  are  the  principal  regulations  pre- 
scribed by  the  act  39  &  40  Vict.  c.  36. 
Foreign  ships  are  subject  to  the  same  regula- 
tions as  British  as  to  stores,  etc.,  and  may  not 
be  subjected  to  higher  local  dues  (§  141). 
Under  the  following  section  (142)  no  goods  are 
to  be  carried  coastwise  except  those  laden  at 
some  port  or  place  in  the  United  Kingdom, 
but  under  recent  regulations  in  pursuance  of 
the  Revenue  Act  of  1884,  a  ship  arriving  from 
abroad  is  allowed  to  ship  non- dutiable  goods 
for  coasting  after  discharging  part  of  her  cargo, 
and  conversely  a  vessel  which  has  been  convey- 
ing goods  coastwise  is  allowed  to  retain  part  of 
the  cargo  on  board  for  exportation  abroad. 
The  master  of  the  coasting  ship  has  to  keep  a 
cargo  book  in  which  he  enters  particulars  of  the 
goods  taken  on  board  and  discharged  at  the 
various  ports,  for  the  correctness  of  which  he  is 
liable  under  a  penalty  of  £20  (Customs  and 
Inland  Revenue  Act  1879,  §  9).  Before  leaving 
any  port,  a  document  called  a  traoisire  has  to 
be  signed  by  the  collector  of  customs,  and  is 
the  authority  to  the  master  to  clear  for  the 
next  port  (39  &  40  Vict.  c.  36,  §  145). 
Fishing  boats  are  exempt  from  even  the  light 
regulations  of  the  ordinary  coasting  trade,  and 
are  entitled  to  carry  from  one  part  of  the  coast 
to  another,  besides  their  own  fish  and  fishing 
appliances,  a  variety  of  bulky  goods,  such  as 
ashes,  bavins  for  bakers,  bricks,  stones,  slates, 
clay,  sand  and  gravel,  lime,  tiles,  timber,  and 
hay  and  straw.  Fishing  boats,  however,  exceed- 
ing 15  tons  burthen  must  be  registered  under 
the  Merchant  Shipping  Act  of  1854. 

The  following  table  shows  the  growth  of  the 
coastiug  trade  of  the  United  Kingdom  since  1860, 
at  intervals  of  ten  years. 


1850.1 

1860.2 

Tons. 

Tons. 

Tonnage  employed  in  the  gene- 

ral coasting  trade- 

British.    .... 

10,979,574 

11,342,532 

Foreign  .... 

82,443 

Intercourse     between     Great 

Britain  and  Ireland — 

British    .... 

1,585,057 

5,558,656 

Foreign  . 
Total- 

•• 

19,780 

British.    .... 

12,564,631 

16,901,188 

Foreign  .... 
Total 

102,223 

12,564,631 

17,003,411 

1  Foreign  vessels  not  admitted  to  the  coasting  trade 
previous  to  1854. 

2  Before  1856,  vessels  employed  between  Great  Britain 
and  Ireland  were  returned  as  entered  at  ports  in  Great 
Britain  only.  From  1856,  entries  at  Irish  ports  are  in- 
cluded. 


1870. 

1880.3 

1888. 

Tons. 

Tons. 

Tons. 

Tonnage  employed  in 

the  general  coast- 

ing trade- 

British     . 

11,357,651 

16,046,071 

17,955,119 

Foreign     . 

74,079 

88,212 

103,024 

Intercourse    between 

Great  Britain  and 

Ireland- 

British     .        . 

6,852,868 

9,878,950 

9,049,090 

Foreign    . 

15,677 

10,316 

18,436 

Total — 

British     . 

18,210,519 

25,924,021 

27,004,209 

Foreign    . 
Total 

89,756 

98,528 

121,460 

18,300,275 

26,022,549 

27,125,669 

In  1913,  the  figures  were  :- 
British     .... 
Foreign    .... 


Divided  as  follows  : — 
1912.  British- 
Sailing  Vessels  2,513,450 
Steam  Vessels  30,025,552 
32,5897002 


1912,  Foreign- 
Sailing  Vessels        45,409 
Steam  Vessels       256,324 
301,733 


A.  E.  B. 

COBBETT,  William,  born  at  Farnham, 
Surrey,  1762,  passed  his  early  years  in  farm- 
labour,  and,  ^fter  a  few  unhappy  months  in  a 
lawyer's  office  in  London,  enlisted  (1784)  in 
the  54th  regiment  of  the  line,  and  served  with 
it  seven  years  in  Nova  Scotia.  Retiring  as 
sergeant-major,  in  1792  he  began  his  literary 
career  as  well  as  his  married  life.  He  settled 
in  Philadelphia,  but  he  was  too  stout  a  cham- 
pion of  England  against  France  to  be  left  in 
peace,  and  in  1800  he  found  himself  again  in 
England.  He  was  at  first  well  received  by 
Pitt  and  his  supporters,  but  soon  broke  off 
connection  with  all  political  parties,  becoming 
convinced  that  corruption,  and  place-hunting, 
and  waste  of  public  money  prevailed  with  little 
difference  among  Whigs  and  Tories.  He  was 
thus  a  radical  reformer  ;  but  neither  republican 
nor  revolutionist.  His  ideals  lay  as  much  in  the 
past  as  in  the  future.  He  deplores  the  Protest- 
ant Reformation,  but,  since  there  is  now  no 
hope  of  return  to  monastic  charity,  he  lauds 
the  old  poor  law,  as  being  with  Magna  Charta 
the  foundation  of  English  liberties  (see  Man- 
chester Lectures).  He  talked  not  of  abstract 
rights  of  man,  but  of  rights  of  Englishmen, 
founded  on  the  old  laws  of  England  ;  his  desire 
was  to  make  the  poor  labourers  as  comfortable 
as  in  his  father's  time.  This  was  his  strain  in 
the  Political  Register,  which  he  issued  week  by 
week  for  over  thkty  years  (1803-1835).  There 
was  only  one  serious  break,  from  1810  to  1812, 
when  the  editor  lay  in  Newgate,  under  punish- 
ment for  a  severe  article  on  flogging  in  the 

3  Before  1873,  vessels  employed  in  conveying  ashes, 

bavins,  bricks,  tiles,  clay,  lime,  gravel,  iron  ore,  fresh 

meat  and  fish,  hay  and  straw,  timber  and  wood,  and 

various  other  raw  materials  were  omitted  in  the  retume 

I  of  tonnage. 


COBBETT 


315 


araiy.  In  prison,  besides  studying  Tull's  Hus- 
baiidry,  he  wrote  his  letters  to  the  people  of 
Salisbury,  best  known  by  the  title  Paper  against 
Gold. 

On  his  release  he  continued  from  his  Hamp- 
shire farm  to  edit  the  Register.  Embittered  in 
spirit  and  reduced  in  fortunes,  he  was  never 
more  full  of  vigour  in  mind  and  body.  The 
"White  Terror"  under  Lord  Sidmouth  drove 
lum  in  1817  again  to  America,  but  he 
kept  up  his  Register  from  his  iarm  in  Long 
Island,  and  retm-ned  in  1819  to  his  native 
country,  with  the  bones  of  Paine  as  proof 
positive  of  his  political  conversion.  Bankrupt 
through  lawsuits  in  1820,  he  quitted  Hamp- 
shire for  Kensington,  still  keeping  tight  hold 
of  his  pen.  In  the  reformed  parliament  of  1832 
he  sat  as  member  for  Oldham  till  his  death  in 
June  1835. 

His  work  in  parliament  was  far  sm-passed  in 
brilliancy  and  originality  by  his  earlier  achieve- 
ments as  a  journalist.  He  was  right  in  think- 
ing that  he  was  ' '  of  most  weight  as  a  spectator 
and  commentator."  As  an  agitator  or  man  of 
action  he  showed  little  tact,  taste,  or  know- 
ledge of  men  ;  he  was  not  a  man  of  the  world 
any  more  than  he  was  a  worldly  man.  The 
gi-eat  obstacles  to  social  reform  seemed  to  him 
to  be  political,  and  it  was  because  of  what  he 
thought  to  be  their  evil  political  influence,  that 
he  disliked  the  gi-owth  of  the  stock -jobbing 
yommercial  aristocracy  of  his  day.  He  was  in 
his  eccentric  way  a  labom-er  in  the  cause  of 
popular  education ;  he  was  an  agricultural 
improver,  importing  the  "locust  tree,"^  and 
trying  to  induce  English  fanners  to  grow 
Indian  corn  ;  he  tried  to  revive  cottage  indus- 
tries, especially  straw-plaiting.  He  was  in- 
tensely national,  and  yet  his  writings  did  more 
than  most  men's  to  make  the  American  nation, 
and  in  a  less  degree  the  French,  better  under- 
stood by  his  countrymen.  His  strength  lay  in 
his  clear  logic  and  wonderful  command  of  good 
homely  English,  as  well  as  in  his  happy 
epithets.  His  chief  failing  was  his  vanity, 
pardonable  in  one  who  owed  all  his  success  to 
his  own  pertinacity,  and  all  his  education  to 
his  own  diligence. 

The  discussion  of  economics  apart  from 
politics  had  no  interest  for  him.  Even  his 
favourite  subject,  taxation,  is  treated  simply 
with  the  sturdy  common-sense  of  one  whose 
views  are  limited,  but  whose  powers  of  expres- 
sion are  boundless.  Like  Swift,  he  made 
excursions  into  economical  regions,  not  because 
he  was  at  all  anxious  to  find  truth  there  for  its 
own  sake,  but  because  some  prevalent  economic 
error  or  other  seemed  to  be  hindering  some 
project  of  reform  which  was  dear  to  him.  His 
antipathy  to  the  economists  of  his  time  was 
not  due  to  any  general  economic  theories  of  his 

1  The  acacia,  which  was  then  better  known  under  its 
American  name  of  "  locust  tree. " 


own  fundamentally  different  from  theirs.  He 
denounced  Malthus,  and  he  denounced  Ricardo, 
because  he  saw  their  doctrines  affbrded  too  easy 
a  handle  to  his  political  enemies,  the  ' '  borough- 
mongers."  But,  in  his  diatribes  against  a 
potato-diet,  he  uses  arguments  identical  with 
those  of  Malthus  ;  and,  in  protesting  against 
the  new  corn  law  of  1815,  he  states  the  case  as 
Eicardo  or  any  free-trader  would  have  stated  it. 
"There  are  few  articles"  (he  says  in  his  letter 
' '  To  the  Journeymen  and  Labourers  of  England, 
Wales,  Scotland,  and  Ireland")  "which  you 
use,  in  the  purchase  of  which  you  do  not  pay  a 
tax.  On  your  shoes,  salt,  beer,  malt,  hops, 
tea,  sugar,  candles,  soap,  })aper,  cofl"ee,  spirits, 
glass  of  your  windows,  bricks  and  tiles,  tobacco. 
On  aU  these  and  many  other  articles  you  pay  a 
tax,  and  even  on  your  loaf  you  pay  a  tax, 
because  everything  is  taxed  from  which  the 
loaf  proceeds.  In  several  cases  the  tax  amounts 
to  more  than  one-half  of  what  you  pay  for  the 
article  itself ;  these  taxes  go,  in  part  to  support 
sinecure  placemen  and  pensioners  ;  and  the 
ruffians  of  the  hhed  press  call  you  the  scum  of 
society."  For  the  most  part,  when  Cobbett 
has  hold  of  an  economical  truth,  he  can  put  it 
more  clearly  than  another  man,  and  there  is 
little  fault  to  find  except  the  exaggeration 
which  seems  to  be  inseparable  from  all  political 
writing.  The  "  Letter  to  the  Luddites  "  (30th 
November  1816,  Weekly  Political  Register)  is 
not  only  one  of  Cobbett's  most  characteristic 
and  ingenious  papers,  but  it  contains  one  of  the 
clearest  popular  descriptions  ever  penned  of 
the  economical  benefits  of  the  invention  of  tools 
and  machinery.  If  he  treats  taxation  as  if  it 
were  the  only  cause  of  distress,  we  must 
remember  that  in  his  days,  and  indeed  till  the 
repeal  of  the  corn  laws,  it  was  probably  the 
most  potent  cause.  Even  dm-ing  the  course 
of  the  French  War,  when  there  was  more  ap- 
parent reason  for  high  taxes  than  in  1816,  he 
was  never  tired  of  declaiming  against  excessive 
expenditure  and  over-taxation  ;  and  his  letters 
on  Paper  against  Gold  are  simply  one  skirmish 
in  his  general  attack  on  these  evils.  The  letters 
in  question  are  a  lively,  and  in  the  main  an 
accurate  history  of  the  suspension  of  cash 
payments  by  the  Bank  of  England  in  1797, 
and  the  effects  of  it  on  the  cm-rency.  He  gets 
his  principles  not  directly  from  the  economists, 
but  from  Paine's  Decline  and  Fall  of  the  English 
SysteTJi  of  Finance  (1796)  ;  he  compares  the 
English  inconvertible  notes  to  the  French 
assignats  ;  and  is  not  careful  to  avoid  the 
exaggerations  of  the  "  Ultra-bullionists, "  who 
explained  all  the  high  and  low  prices  of  those 
times  by  the  state  of  the  currency.  His 
assertion  that  the  bank  neither  would  nor  could 
ever  return  to  cash  payments  was  not  confirmed 
by  facts.  But,  with  all  its  defects,  the  book  is 
valuable  for  its  pictures  of  the  opinions  and 
conduct  of  average  Englishmen  at  a  momentoua 


316 


COBDEN 


period  in  the  economical  history  of  the  country. 
In  the  same  way  we  owe  much  to  the  Register 
for  its  glimpses  of  English  working  men,  and 
their  views  in  the  darkest  years  of  this  century. 

Of  Cobbett's  numerous  works  the  following  are 
of  most  importauce  economically  : —  • 

The  Weekly  Political  Register,  1803  to  1835.— 
Paper  against  Gold,  1810,  1811,  reprinted  1817. 
— Rural  Rides  (reprinted  from  the  Register),  1830. 
— Two-penny  Trash,  1831.  — Tour  in  Scotland  and 
in  the  four  northern  Counties  of  England,  1833. — 
A  Year  s  Residence  in  the  United  States  of  America, 
1818. — Cottage  Economy,  1821. — Manchester  Lec- 
tures, 1832. — Surplus  Population  and  Poor  Law 
Bill,  1835. — Legacy  to  Labourers,  1835. — Legacy 
to  Peel,  1835. — Legacy  to  Parsons,  1835. 

[His  biography  is  given  by  himself  incidentally 
throughout  his  works  (for  example,  in  Advice  to 
Young  Men,  1830,  and  in  the  Year's  Residence 
in  America). — See  also  William  Cohhett,  a  Bio- 
graphy, by  Edward  Smith,  2  vols.  (Sampson  Low, 
1878).— George  Gilfillan,  (second)  Gallery  of 
Literary  Portraits,  1849. — Adolf  Held,  Sociale 
Qeschichte  Englands,  1881.]  J.  b. 

COBDEN,  Richard,  born  1804,  died  1865. 
In  1841,  being  already  a  well-known  and 
vigorous  writer  on  public  questions  as  well  as 
an  active  advocate  of  free  trade,  he  entered 
parliament,  having  contested  Stockport,  the 
borough  which  first  returned  him,  in  1837.  In 
1857  he  was  not  returned.  In  1859  he  was 
returned,  while  absent  in  America,  for  Roch- 
dale, and  sat  for  this  constituency  till  his  death. 
In  these  pages  it  is  impossible  to  enter  into  the 
details  of  his  public  life. 

Cobden  was  supposed,  especially  by  those 
who  did  not  know  him,  to  be  a  mere  advocate 
of  laissez  faire  ;  and  the  school  which  he  was 
reputed  to  have  founded  was  nicknamed  the 
Manchester  school,  chiefly  by  Germans,  and 
especially  by  German  socialists.  He  might  have 
been  excused  if  he  set  great  store  on  the  liberation 
of  industry  from  fiscal  absurdities  and  shackles, 
and  thought  that  the  best  service  government 
could  do  to  society  was  to  let  it  alone,  for  he 
had  abundant  experience  of  the  mischief  which 
the  meddlesomeness  of  government  does.  But 
he  was  far  too  wise  and  experienced  a  man  to 
be  satisfied  with  mere  negations,  and  there  were 
few  persons  who  interpreted  the  constructive 
side  of  politics  with  more  acuteness  and  more 
perseverance.  Perhaps  one  of  the  most  obvious 
illustrations  of  this  statement,  made  by  the 
writer  who  probably  knew  him  more  in- 
timately than  any  other  person,  was  his  negotia- 
tion of  the  commercial  treaty  with  France.  A 
commercial  treaty  is  in  direct  antagonism  to 
laissez  faire,  and  at  the  time  was  criticised  on 
this  ground.  Similar  to  this  was  his  attitude 
on  national  education,  on  which  he  entertained 
opinions  which  have  not  yet  been  accepted, 
though  the  country  is  manifestly  bent  on  accept- 
ing them  in  the  end.  His  views  on  foreign 
politics   too,    and    especially    the    politics    of 


trade,  are  gaining  ground  among  the  most 
thoughtful  and  intelligent  public  men.  Cobden 
always  refused  public  office,  mainly  owing  to 
his  antipathy  to  a  statesman  who  was  then  in 
the  ascendant.  j.  t.  r. 

[In  this  reference  the  notice  of  Cobden's  sensitive- 
ness preserved  by  Bagehot  is  interesting.  Bagehot 
remarks  in  his  vivid  sketch  of  Cobden  and  his 
work  :  "  He  said  at  Drury  Lane  Theatre,  in  tones 
of  feeling,  almost  of  passion,  curiously  contrasting 
with  the  ordinary  coolness  of  his  nature,  '  I  could 
not  serve  with  Sir  Robert  Peel. '  "  Bagehot's  Bio- 
graphical Studies,  1881,  p.  336.] 

Cobden's  early  life  was  in  many  ways  a  fit 
training  for  his  later  career  ;  he  passed  from  his 
father's  farm  at  Dunford  near  Midhurst  in  Sussex 
to  a  London  warehouse,  and  became  traveller  for 
his  firm  ;  in  1832  he  began  business  in  Manches- 
ter on  his  own  account,  and  his  cotton  printing 
works  at  Manchester  and  Salden  brought  him 
the  wealth  which  enabled  him  to  conduct  the 
long  campaign  against  the  corn  laws. 

Cobden  is  associated  with  three  gi'eat  politi- 
cal movements,  the  first  for  the  repeal  of  pro- 
tective duties,  especially  the  repeal  of  the  com 
laws,  the  second  against  wars  and  military 
expenditm-e,  and  the  third  in  favour  of  com- 
mercial treaties.  The  two  first  of  these  were 
parts  of  a  comprehensive  but  simple  political 
programme,  which  he  held  consistently  through 
life.  Like  his  friend  Bright,  he  looked  at 
political  questions  with  the  eyes  of  a  man  of 
business,  and  without  much  (if  any)  respect  for 
tradition.  In  two  early  pamphlets,  England, 
Ireland,  and  Armrica  (1835),  and  Russia 
(1836),  he  gave  his  ideas  to  the  world  substan- 
tially in  the  shape  which  they  ever  afterwards 
retained  in  his  mind,  though  the  necessity  of 
negotiating  commercial  treaties  seems  to  have 
been  recognised  by  him  only  after  the  force  of 
England's  example  had  proved  evidently  insuffi- 
cient to  convert  other  nations  to  free  trade. 
The  general  spirit  of  his  whole  policy  is  well 
expressed  in  the  motto  quoted  by  himself  (in 
England,  Ireland,  and  America)  from  George 
Washington  : —  '  The  great  rule  of  conduct  in 
regard  to  foreign  nations  is,  in  extending  our 
commercial  relations,  to  have,  with  them,  as 
little  political  connection  as  possible."  We, 
he  contends,  have  no  commission  to  administei- 
justice  to  the  whole  world  ;  and  our  interference 
will  do  more  harm  than  good.  We  must  set 
our  own  house  in  order  and  provide  for  our  o^vn 
people  first.  Further,  if  we  are  to  pay  our  great 
national  debt  we  must  have  a  larger  population 
and  a  larger  trade  ;  and,  if  we  are  to  have  these 
we  must  throw  off"  our  feudal  traditions  and  our 
habits  of  excessive  military  and  civil  expendi- 
ture, and  above  all  our  protective  duties.  After 
the  repeal  of  the  corn  laws,  Cobden's  opposition 
to  all  indirect  taxation  became  more,  and  not 
less,  pronounced  ;  and  his  failure  to  prevent 
the  war  with  Russia  (1854),  and  the  war  with 


COCHUT— CODE  NAPOLEON 


317 


Cliina  (1857)  only  increased  his  ardour  in 
preaching  a  policy  of  what  has  been,  not  verj' 
happily,  called  non-intervention,  or,  not  truly, 
peace  at  any  price.  His  efforts  to  secure  com- 
mercial treaties  have  been  sometimes  sup- 
posed inconsistent  with  his  general  principles 
(see  Mallet's  Free  Exchange,  1891,  where  this 
objection  is  well  rebutted).  The  "Manchester 
School "  of  politicians  has  ceased  to  play  a 
distinct  part  in  our  parliamentary  life,  partly 
no  doubt  because  its  programme  was  inadequate 
to  the  problems  of  the  new  era,  and  largely  also 
because  many  of  its  most  important  principles 
from  being  paradoxes  have  become  truisms. 

Besides  the  "Cobden  Club,"  the  Financial 
Reform  Association,  advocating  direct  taxation 
and  the  abolition  of  all  taxation  of  goods,  may 
be  considered  to  represent  his  disciples.  In 
matters  of  economic  theory  he  drew  his  inspira- 
tion from  Adam  Smith  ;  and,  though  he  added 
little  or  nothing  of  his  own,  he  had  a  remark- 
able power  of  making  clear  to  a  popular  audience 
the  several  steps  of  an  economical  argument. 
As  Bagehot  said  of  him,  Cobden  "was  not  the 
discoverer  of  the  free-trade  principle.  He  did 
not  first  find  out  that  the  corn  laws  were  bad 
laws.  But  he  was  the  most  etiectual  of  those 
who  discovered  how  the  com  laws  were  to  be 
repealed,  how  free  trade  Avas  to  change  from  a 
doctrine  of  the  '  Wealth  of  Nations '  into  a 
principle  of  tariffs  and  a  fact  of  real  life " 
('Ragehot's  Biographical  Stiulies,  1881,  p.  337). 
His  association  with  Bastiat  was  of  first-rate 
importance  for  the  cause  of  repeal,  but  it  has 
induced  too  many  of  his  followers  to  adopt  the 
economics  of  Bastiat  as  a  whole  (see  e.g. 
Mallet's  Free  Exchange,  p.  23,  "without 
Bastiat,  Cobden's  policy  would  not  have  been 
elaborated  into  a  system ").  The  economical 
writings  of  Perronet  Thompson  had  an  influence 
on  Cobden  of  which  he  gave  practical  recogni- 
tion by  editing  them  for  the  League. 

[The  political  loritings  of  Richard  Cobden,  with 
an  introduction  by  Sir  Louis  Mallet,  C.B.  (1878). 
This  includes  the  pamphlets  of  1835  and  1836 
above  mentioned,  the  four  later  pamphlets  (1) 
"1793  and  1853"  (2)  "How  wars  are  got  up  in 
India"  (3)  "What  next,  and  next?"  (4)  "The 
Three  Panics,"  and  letter  on  "Rights  of  Belliger- 
ents."— Speeches  on  Questions  of  Public  Policy 
(ed.  John  Bright  and  J.  E.  Tliorold  Rogers),  new 
ed.  1878. — Translation  of  the  treatise  of  M. 
Chevalier  on  the  Probable  Fall  in  the  Value  of 
Gold  with  a  Preface  (1859). — Financial  Reform 
Tracts,  No.  6.  (on  the  Budget  of  1849).— Life  of 
Cobden  by  John  Morley  (1882). 

See  also  Bastiat's  Cobden  et  la  Ligue  (1854). — H. 
A.sh worth's  Recollections  of  R.  Cobden  and  the  Anti- 
Corn  Law  League  (1876). — J.  E.  Thorold  Rogers's 
Cobden  and  Modern  Political  Opinion  (1875). — 
Bagehot's  Biographical  Studies  (1881). — "The 
Policy  of  Commercial  Treaties,"  John  Morley, 
Fortnightly  Review,  June  1881.]  J.  B. 

COCHUT,  Pierre  Andre,  who  was  born  at 


Paris  1807,  and  died  there  1890,  was  from  1838 
to  1869  one  of  the  most  laborious  and  valued 
contributors  to  the  Revue  des  deux  Mondcs.  His 
style  was  brilliant,  his  mind  firm  and  indepen- 
dent. His  articles  were  much  valued,  particu- 
larly those  on  Algeria.  The  Rapport  general 
sur  VAlgerie,  which  was  altogether  his  work, 
was  about  to  be  distributed  officially  to  the 
chambers  at  the  time  when  the  revolution  of 
1848  broke  out.  It  was  then  that  he  published 
Les  associations  ouvi'ieres  (1  vol.  in  8vo,  1851), 
a  work  which  -is  still  not  out  of  date.  Soon 
after  appeared.  Law,  son  systhne  et  son  ipoque 
(1  vol.  in  18mo,  1853)  which,  while  brilliant  in 
style,  shows  itself  to  be  the  work  of  an  economist 
and  a  financier  of  the  best  school.  Long  a 
contributor  to  the  National,  he  wi-ote  afterAvards 
in  Le  Temps.  Questions  of  price  and  money 
occupied  his  attention  much,  and  his  opinion  in 
these  matters  carried  great  authority.  From 
1870  to  1885  he  was  a  director  of  the  Mont  de 
Pi6te  at  Paris,  a  post  which  had  been  offered 
him  as  far  back  as  1848.  He  was  president  of 
the  Socidte  de  Statistique  de  Paris,  1888,  and 
also  vice-president  from  1881  of  the  Sociite 
d' economic  politique.  a.  c.  f. 

CODE  NAPOLEON.  Before  the  French 
Revolution  there  were  two  kinds  of  law  in  France, 
the  droit  6crit  or  Avritten  law,  and  the  droit  cou- 
tumier  or  customary  law  ;  and  the  latter  varied 
so  much  from  place  to  place  that  Voltaire  said 
a  traveller  changed  his  law  as  often  as  he 
changed  his  jjost-horses.  Consolidation  Avas 
attempted  from  time  to  time  ;  the  most  suc- 
cessful efibrt  in  that  direction  was  Colbert's 
Ordonnance ;  but  practically  the  chaos  remained 
until,  on  4th  August  1789,  the  Constituent 
Assembly  ordered  a  code  common  to  the  whole 
kingdom  to  be  drawn  up ;  but  Cambaceres 
failed  for  various  reasons  to  accomplish  the  task 
then  set  him.  Napoleon  ordered  the  work  to 
be  taken  up  ;  he  appointed  a  commission,  con- 
sisting of  IVonchet,  Bigot  de  Preameneu,  Malle- 
ville,  and  Portalis  to  prepare  a  code.  They 
did  so,  basing  their  labours  largely  on  the  then 
existing  French  legal  traditions,  together  with 
the  Institutes,  the  Pandects,  the  Codex,  and  the 
Epitome  Juliani.  The  successive  portions  were 
subjected^  to  public  criticism  ;  the  suggestions 
of  the  various  tribunals  and  iribunaux  de  com- 
merce were  invited ;  the  Tribunal  of  the  year  X. 
then  discussed  the  clauses,  but  when  they  had 
got  as  far  as  the  end  of  part  iii.  of  the  civil 
code.  Napoleon  found  them  troublesome  and 
withdrew  the  code,  expelled  the  opposition,  and 
broke  up  the  remainder  into  committees  which 
were  to  discuss  the  clauses  with  the  Conseil 
d'etat.  This  was  done ;  and  the  various  portions, 
as  they  successively  passed  the  Corp)s  Lig'islatif, 
were  separately  promulgated  between  the  years 
1804  and  1810.  These  portions,  independent 
of  one  another,  are  (1)  the  code  civil,  (2)  the 
code  de  procedure  civile,  (3)  the  code   de  com- 


318 


CODICIL— COKE 


meree,  (4)  the  code  d' instruction  criminelle, 
and  (5)  tlie  code  p6nal.  This  code  superseded 
all  previous  legislation,  and  where  it  does  not 
provide  for  every  case,  much  is  left  to  the  equity 
and  good  sense  of  the  judge.  This,  with 
the  multiplicity  of  co-ordinate  jurisdictions  in 
France,  has  brought  about  considerable  conflict 
of  decisions,  and  as  precedents  have  there  but 
little  binding  force,  there  is  some  considerable 
uncertainty  as  to  what  in  a  doubtful  case  the 
decision  may  be.  The  brevity  of  the  code  is 
condemned  by  Savigny  and  Austin,  the  latter 
of  whom  points  out  that  there  is  an  absence  of 
definition  of  terms  and  of  statement  of  guiding 
principles.  The  result  of  this  has  been  the 
growth  of  a  very  full  literature  of  the  com- 
mentary order.  On  the  civil  code,  which  treats 
of  civil  rights  under  the  three  main  heads  of 
persons,  property  and  its  modifications,  and  the 
modes  of  acquisition  of  property,  the  commen- 
taries of  Duranton,  Troplong,  Toullier,  Demo- 
lombe,  Sirey  and  Gilbert,  and  (German) 
Zacharia  may  be  consulted.  The  code  de 
commerce  treats  of  commercial  law  under  the 
following  heads  : — (1)  commerce  in  general : 
traders,  traders'  books,  partnership  and  com- 
panies, partition  of  property,  stock  exchanges, 
stockbrokers  and  brokers,  pledges,  agents  and 
common  carriers,  sales  and  purchases,  bills  of  ex- 
change, promissory  notes  and  limitation  ;  (2) 
maritime  commerce :  ships  and  other  vessels, 
seizure  and  sale  of  ships,  shipowners,  the  captain, 
hiring  and  wages  of  crews,  charter  parties  and 
freight,  bills  of  lading,  the  freight,  bottomiy, 
insurance,  average,  jettison  and  contribution, 
limitations  of  actions,  exceptions  or  bars  to 
actions  ;  (3)  bankruptcies  and  fraudulent  bank- 
ruptcies :  dealing  with  bankruptcy,  fraudulent 
bankruptcy,  reinstatement ;  and  (4)  jurisdic- 
tion in  commercial  cases :  the  organisation  of 
the  trihunaux  de  commerce,  their  jurisdiction, 
their  procedure,  and  the  procedure  in  courts  of 
appeal.  With  reference  to  the  code  de  com- 
merce, the  following  works  may  be  consulted  : 

Napoleon  Argles,  French  Mercantile  Law,  1882, 
and  references  therein,  pp.  xvii-xxiv ;  Mayer's 
French  Code  of  Commerce,  1887. — Alauzet,  Commen- 
taires ; — and  with  regard  to  the  development  of 
French  law  and  legal  tradition,  Laferri^re,  Histoire 
du  droit  frangais.  A.  D. 

.CODICIL.  A  document  executed  for  the 
purpose  of  modifying  the  directions  of  a  will, 
and  subject  to  the  same  requirements  as  to  form 
as  the  will  itself  {see  Will).  e.  s. 

COINAGE,  The  Right  of.  ''In  constitu- 
tional  law  the  right  of  coining  has  always  been 
held  to  be  one  of  the  peculiar  prerogatives  of 
the  Crown,  and  it  is  a  maxim  of  the  civil  law 
that  mon^tandi  jus  principitm  ossihus  inhaeret" 
(Jevons,  Money,  p.  65).  A  hard  use  has  often 
been  made  of  this  prerogative,  A.  Smith  says 
{Wealth  of  Nations,  book  i.  ch.  iv.)  ''In 
every  country  of  the  world,  I  believe,  the  avarice 


and  injustice  of  princes  and  sovereign  states, 
abusing  the  confidence  of  their  subjects,  have 
by  degrees  diminished  the  real  quantity  ol 
metal  which  had  been  originally  contained  in 
their  coins."  J.  S.  Mill  has  expressed  himself 
much  to  the  same  effect  {Principles  of  Political 
Economy,  book  iii.  ch.  vii.  §  2).  Governments 
found  it  their  interest  "to  interdict  all  coining 
by  private  persons  ;  indeed  their  guarantee  was 
often  the  only  one  which  would  have  been  relied 
on,  a  reliance,  however,  which  very  often  it  ill 
deserved."  The  English  standard  for  the  gold 
coin  has  remained  unchanged  in  fineness  since 
1600,  and  the  number  of  grains  of  fine  gold  in 
the  pound  sterling  since  1717,  when  Sir  Isaac 
Newton  was  master  of  the  mint.  The  process 
of  coining  requires  to  be  carried  on  with  great 
scientific  care.  See  Alloy  ;  Assay  ;  Better- 
NEss  ;  Brassage  ;  Bullion  ;  Mint. 

[W.  S.  Jevons,  Money. — Lord  Liverpool,  Letter 
to  the  King  on  the  Coinage. — F.  A.  Walker, 
Money. — E.  Seyd,  Bullion  and  Foreign  Exchanges. 
— W.  Bagehot,  A  Universal  Money, — Select  Tracts 
on  Money,  printed  for  the  Political  Economy  Club, 
etc.] 

COINAGE,  Decimal.  See  Decimal  System. 

COKE,  Roger  (fl.  1643-1696)  was  the  third 
son  of  Henry  Coke  of  Thorington,  by  his  wife 
Margaret,  daughter  and  heiress  of  Sir  Richard 
Lovelace  of  Kingsdown,  Kent,  and  grandson  of 
Sir  Edward  Coke.  He  was  educated  at  the 
University  of  Cambridge,  where  "he  became 
well-vers'd  in  several  parts  of  learning,  and 
wrote  a  treatise  against  Hobbes'  Leviathan." 
His  principal  study  for  some  time  was  mathe- 
matics, but  he  also  took  great  delight  in 
commercial  questions.  "Tho'  in  his  day  he 
had  good  speculative  notions  in  trade,  he  was 
not  so  successful  in  the  practice  of  it."  He  fell 
into  distress,  and  the  "best  support  he  had " 
was  an  annuity  of  £100,  which  was  settled 
upon  him  by  his  nephew.  "  He  lived  for  some 
years  within  the  rules  of  the  Fleet,  and  died  a 
bachelor  about  the  77th  year  of  his  age."  In 
his  writings  Coke,  erroneously  assuming  the 
accuracy  of  Samuel  Fortrey's  {q.v.)  statistics, 
maintained  that  English  trade  and  commerce 
were  decaying  ;  but  he  made  many  sound  sug- 
gestions for  their  improvement.  He  denounced 
the  trading  corporations,  which  had  "the  arti- 
ficers at  their  mercy,"  and  suggested  that  they 
should  be  made  free  to  all  English  citizens. 
The  Statute  of  Apprenticeship  (see  Apprentice- 
ship, Statute  of)  in  his  view  prepared  materials 
for  the  Poor  Law  to  work  upon.  He  advo- 
cated the  repeal  of  the  laws  of  naturalisation 
and  of  the  acts  restraining  the  importation  of 
Irish  and  Scotch  cattle.  The  exclusive  privi- 
leges of  the  trading  companies  (see  Foreign 
Trade,  Regulation  of),  which  restrained 
English  foreign  trade  within  narrow  limits, 
should  be  abolished.  The  Navigation  Act 
{q.v.)  had,  in  his  opinion,  secured  the  monopoly 


COKE— COLBEKT 


319 


of  the  foreign  trade  of  the  country  to  a  few 
merchants,  to  the  detriment  of  the  producing 
classes.  Similar  laws  had  been  found  by  ex- 
perience to  be  mischievous  in  their  operation, 
and,  in  support  of  his  objections,  he  quoted  the 
evidence  laid  before  the  committee  on  trade  in 
1668  (v.  Free  Trade).  He  maintained  that 
the  free  importation  of  raw  material  and  of 
foreign  manufactures  should  be  permitted. 
This  would  lead  to  "plenty  and  cheapness" 
of  all  things  needed  by  "the  poor  artificers," 
and  to  the  increase  of  trade  and  commerce. 

Amongst  Roger  Coke's  works  may  be  mentioned 
— 1.  A  Detection  of  the  Court  and  State  of  England 
during  the  four  last  reigns  and  the  interregnum, 
consisting  of  private  Memoirs,  etc.  .  .  .  Also  an 
Appendix  discovering  the  present  state  of  the 
Nation,  2  vols.,  London,  1694,  8vo. — 2.  A  Dis- 
course of  Trade,  in  Two  Parts.  The  first  part 
treats  of  the  reason  of  the  decay  of  the  strength, 
wealth,  and  Trade  of  England.  The  latter  of  the 
growth  and  increase  of  the  Dutch  trade  above  the 
English,  London,  1670,  4to. — 3.  England's  Im- 
provement. In  two  parts :  in  the  former  is  dis- 
coursed how  the  Kingdom  of  England  mxiy  he 
improved  in  strength,  employment,  wealth,  and 
trade :  in  the  latter  is  discoursed  how  the  naviga- 
tion of  England  may  be  increased,  London,  1675, 
4to. — 4.  A  Treatise  wherein  is  demonstrated  that 
the  Church  and  State  of  England  are  in  equal 
danger  with  the  trade  of  it :  Treatise  1.  Reasons 
of  the  increase  of  the  Dutch  trade :  Treatise  2, 
London,  1671,  4to. — 5.  Reflections  upon  tlie  East 
Indy  and  Royal  African  Companies :  vnth  an- 
imadversions concerning  the  naturalisation  of 
foreigners,  London,  1695,  4to. 

[Coko's  Detection,  etc.,  4th  ed.  (1719),  1.  xiil. — 
MacCullocli's  Literature  of  Political  Economy 
(1845),  4to. — Adam  Smith's  Wealth  of  Nations, 
ed.  MacCulloch,  4th  ed.  (1853),  xxxvii.  536.— 
Carthew's  Hundred  of  Launditch,  iii.  109. — Brit. 
Mus.  Catalogue^  w.  a.  s.  h. 

COLBERT,  Jean  Baptiste,  born  at  Rheims 
1619,  died  at  Paris  1683.  The  son  of  a  wool- 
merchant,  Colbert  became  one  of  the  greatest 
ministers  France  has  ever  seen  ;  he  formed  part 
of  the  establishment  of  Cardinal  Mazarin  from 
1649  to  the  death  (9th  March  1661)  of  that 
statesman,  who  on  his  deathbed  recommended 
him  to  Louis  XIV.  Appointed  immediately, 
16th  March  1661,  intendant  of  the  finances,  he 
succeeded,  on  the  day  of  the  arrest  of  Nicolas 
Fouquet, — 5th  September  1661, — to  him  as 
superintendent,  directing  the  finances  from 
that  date,  originally  under  cover  of  a  financial 
council,  afterwards,  from  1666,  as  comptroller- 
general.  His  first  step  was  to  reduce  the  Taille 
{g_.v.\  a  direct  property  tax  ;  he  then  established 
a  departmental  ojQBce  {chambre  de  justice),  which 
carried  on  its  operations  from  1662  to  1665, 
and  was  only  definitely  closed  in  1669,  after 
having  brought  in  110  millions  (say  £4,400,000) 
to  the  state.  After  some  trifling  reforms,  he 
promulgated  the  customs  tariff  of  September 
1664,  which,  establishing  a  more  complete  unity 


of  plan,  was  certainly  an  improvement  on  the 
preceding  order  of  things.  It  might  even  have 
produced  real  progress  had  Colbert,  supported 
as  he  was  by  Louis  XIV.,  been  more  confident 
in  his  own  strength,  and  had  he  abolished,  as  the 
Jitats  giniraux  of  1614  desired,  all  internal  cus- 
toms restrictions,  and  removed  the  fiscal  baiTiers 
to  the  frontier.  But  beyond  this  there  remained 
still  to  be  carried  out  the  settling  of  the  rate  of 
duties.  Colbert's  regulations,  certainly  severe, 
though  preferable  to  those  of  his  predecessors, 
were  rendered  more  strict,  first  in  1667,  then 
again  in  1672,  when  they  even  were  the  cause 
of  the  war  with  Holland. 

Colbert,  we  must  admit,  while  he  put 
down  with  laudable  strictness,  and  even  severity 
sometimes,  financial  dishonesty,  was  carried 
away  by  his  love  of  system  and  of  making 
regulations  for  the  control  of  commerce  and 
industry.  Thus  he  established,  1664,  the 
two  commercial  companies  of  the  East  Indies 
(Hindustan),  and  of  the  West  Indies  (America). 
Notwithstanding  his  support,  and  in  spite  of 
the  liberality  of  Louis  XIV.,  these  two  associa- 
tions, based  on  monopoly,  gradually  sank.  The 
first  vegetated  on  even  to  the  times  of  Law 
(1719),  but  the  second  died  in  1674.  Tho  ordi- 
nance of  1666  on  manufactures  and  coi-porations 
was  a  new  manifestation,  and  a  more  regrettable 
one,  of  his  tendency  towards  regulation.  To 
organise  an  industrial  movement,  to  sustain  it  by 
custom-house  regulations,  always  protectionist, 
at  times  prohibitive,  to  create  model  manufac- 
tures— or  at  least  manufactures  having  those 
pretensions,  sometimes  through  the  intervention 
of  the  state  and  with  the  money  of  the  taxpayer 
(Beauvais,  1664,  the  Gobelins,  1667),  at  other 
times  (St.  Gobain,  1665)  through  a  privileged 
concession  ;  this  is  the  whole  of  the  economic 
method  which  goes  by  the  name  of  the  system 
of  Colbert.  This  great  minister  was  not,  after 
all,  systematic  enough  to  have  deserved  to  give 
the  name  of  Colbertism  to  his  system.  His 
methodical  mind  only  occupied  itself  with  over- 
coming difficulties,  with  adopting  reforms  one 
by  one,  after  having  maturely  studied  the  con- 
sequences, particularly  the  immediate  conse- 
quences. Though  a  hard  worker,  energetic  in 
character,  supplying  the  deficiencies  of  ignorance 
through  supremely  good  sense,  Colbert  was 
never  able  to  rise  to  the  level  of  a  general  idea. 

His  activity  gradually  extended  itself  to  the 
shipping  interest,  the  care  of  which  was  added, 
1669,  to  his  duties  ;  and  to  the  arts,  which  he 
encouraged  both  in  France  and  even  in  other 
countries  by  presents,  pensions,  or  payments, 
considerable  in  amount,  especially  when  the 
date  is  considered.  He  founded,  1663,  under 
the  title  of  the  Petite  Acad4mie,  the  Academy 
of  Inscriptions  and  Belles-Lettres  ;  then,  1668,, 
the  academy  of  the  sciences.  He  encouraged 
the  taste  and  the  expenses  of  luxury,  particu- 
larly in  the  way  of  building,  in  Louis  XIV.,  and 


320 


COLBERT— COLLEGIUM 


even  spent  large  sums  on  festivities  in  the 
furtherance  of  that  economic  error,  faire  aller 
le  cominerce,  to  "make  trade  go."  He  founded 
the  opera  in  1667.  He  jjresented  Riquet — and 
this  was  more  useful — with  the  concession  of 
the  canal  to  join  the  two  seas,  constructed, be- 
tween 1665  and  1681,  by  means  of  the  subsidy 
voted  by  the  states  of  Languedoc.  The  canal  of 
Orleans  (1679)  was  also  undertaken  about  the 
same  time,  and  the  canal  of  Burgundy  projected. 

Colbert  thought  it  his  duty  also  to  give 
encouragement  to  the  growth  of  the  population 
by  pensions  to  large  families — but  all  that  he 
did  by  this  was  to  supply  misery  with  fresh 
victims.  Unfortunately  all  this  activity  turned 
capital  aside  from  employment  in  agriculture, 
which  suffered  the  more  under  the  administra- 
tion of  Colbert  because  he  put  hindrances  on 
the  circulation  of  corn  by  regulating  both  the 
inland  and  foreign  trade  in  it. 

Besides  this,  the  passion  for  extravagant 
expense  took,  with  Louis  XIV.,  a  development 
which  ended  by  making  Colbert  uneasy.  A 
more  serious  consequence  followed.  The  taste 
for  war  seized  the  king,  and  Louvois,  secretary 
of  state  for  the  war  department,  1662-1691, 
overweighed  the  influence  of  Colbert  in  the 
mind  of  the  king,  and  contributed  powerfully 
to  develop  this  taste,  to  the  misery  of  France. 
A  few  hard  words  addressed  by  the  king  to 
Colbert  completely  overwhelmed  him  and  re- 
sulted in  the  illness  which  brought  him  to  the 
tomb.  An  honest  soul,  deeply  attached  to  his 
country,  he  sought  its  prosperity  by  purely 
practical  means.  He  loved  his  king,  and 
favoured  peace.  When  the  condition  of  aflfatrs 
which  surrounded  him  is  considered — the  diffi- 
culties he  had  to  overcome  —  the  indomitable 
energy  with  which  he  endeavoured  to  institute 
reforms,  and  the  perseverance  he  displayed  in 
bringing  them  about,  no  doubt  can  exist  that 
posterity  has  been  right  in  giving  him  the  title 
of  the  Great  Colbert. 

[The  "  Lettres,  instructions,  et  miynoires  de  Col- 
bert "  were  collected  and  published  by  M.  Pierre 
Clement  (1861-1873  in  7  vols.  gr.  in  8vo). 
Besides  this,  among  other  works  on  this  great 
minister,  there  may  be  read :  Histoire  de  la 
vie  et  de  V administration  de  Colbert,  par  Pierre 
Clement  (1  vol.  in  8vo,  1846). — Etudes  sur  Col- 
bert, par  Felix  Joubleau,  ouvrage  couronnt  par 
I'Acadimie  des  sciences  morales  et  politiques  (2 
vols,  in  8vo,  1856). — Colbert  et  son  temps,  par  M. 
Alfred  Neymarck  (2  vols,  in  8vo,  1877).  We  may 
quote  among  biographies  of  Colbert  those  of 
Forbonnais,  Bailly,  Montyou,  Necker,  Lemontey, 
Ad.  Seviez,  and  Jean  Reynaud.]  a.  c.  f. 

COLLATERAL  SECURITY.     See  CArxiON. 

COLLATION.     See  Succession,  Scotland, 

COLLECT.  To  obtain  payment  of  a  bill  of 
exchange  or  cheque  as  agent  for  another  person. 
An  indorsement  "  for  collection  "  does  not  trans- 
fer the  property  to  the  indorsee  ;  it  is  merely 
an  authority  to  encash  the  amount  at  maturity. 


If  the  indorser  becomes  insolvent  before  matur- 
ity, the  indorsee  has  to  account  for  the  proceeds 
to  the  estate,  and  cannot  set  them  oft'  against 
a  debt  due  to  him  from  the  indorser.        e.  s. 

COLLECTIVE  GOODS  include  all  those 
desirable  things  which  are  not  appropriated  by 
particular  individuals  to  the  exclusion  of  others, 
but  are  available  to  all  members  of  the  com- 
munity, e.g.  turnpike  roads,  great  rivers  such 
as  the  Thames,  public  museums,  free  libraries, 
the  right  to  a  free  education.  Such  goods  con- 
stitute a  very  important  element  of  national 
wealth.  Compare  Marshall,  Principles  of  Econ- 
omics (2d  ed.),  bk.  ii.  ch.  ii.  §  4.         J.  N.  K. 

COLLECTIVISM  is  the  theory  which  teaches 
that  land  and  capital,  or  the  means  of  produc- 
tion, should  be  the  property  of  the  whole 
community  in  order  to  secure  effective  produc- 
tion and  equitable  distribution.  It  is  thus  not 
a  different  doctrine  from  that  which  is  now 
usually  meant  when  the  Avord  socialism  is  used. 
''The  word  is  new,  but  the  idea  is  found  in 
every  system  of  radical  socialism"  (^.  de 
Laveleye,  Le  Socialisme  Gontemporain,  3""®  6d., 
1885,  p.  285).  M.  Paul  Leroy  Beaulien,  in 
his  book  Xe  CoUectivisme  (1884,  2""'  ed.,  1885), 
which  is  in  large  measure  a  criticism  of 
Schaffle's  Die  Quintessenz  des  Socialismus,  de- 
fends the  neologism  on  the  ground  that  it 
is  more  definite  than  Socialisme,  which  he 
understands  in  a  large  and  vague  sense  as 
nearly  equivalent  to  what  is  in  England  called 
state  interference.  The  name  "  coUectivist " 
was  at  one  time  appropriated  by  the  socialists 
who  opposed  what  they  called  the  authoritative 
communism  of  Marx.  Bakounin  (q.v.)  declared 
himself  "a  coUectivist  and  not  a  communist" 
at  the  fourth  general  meeting  of  the  Inter- 
national (q.v.)  in  1869  (J.  Garin,  L'Anarchie 
et  les  Anarchistes,  1885,  p.  79).  The  whole 
subject  will  be  found  fully  treated  under 
Anarchism  and  Socialism,  vol.  iii.  and  App. 

[Authorities  quoted  in  the  text.]  B.  C. 

COLLEGIUM.  This  term  in  ancient  Rome 
signified  a  corporate  body  composed  of  indi- 
viduals in  partnership  for  the  pursuit  of  some 
common  end.  Collegia  existed  at  different 
times  for  the  pursuit  of  the  most  various  ends, 
religious,  social,  and  political,  but  the  collegia 
of  most  interest  to  the  economist  were  the 
Collegia  Artificum  and  the  Collegium  Merca- 
torvm.  The  free  workmen  in  Rome  from  very- 
early  times  were  organised  according  to  their 
respective  trades  into  collegia.  The  foundation 
of  the  system  is  variously  ascribed  to  Numa 
Pompilius  and  to  Servius  Tullius.  Authorities 
agree,  however,  in  fixing  the  original  number 
at  nine,  and  the  extreme  antiquity  of  the 
system  is  vouched  for  by  the  fact  that  among 
the  nine  was  a  collegium  of  workers  in  bronze, 
but  none  of  workers  in  iron.  Early  in  the 
4th  century  B.C.,  a  collegium  of  merchants  was 
added  to  the  number,  and  in  later  times  the 


COLONIES:    DESCRIPTION  OF 


321 


publicani  appear  to  have  formed  a  collegium. 
There  is,  unfortunately,  very  little  positive 
evidence  as  to  the  precise  constitution  and 
importance  of  these  collegia.  Like  the  medi- 
aeval craft -guilds  they  appear  to  have  com- 
bined a  social  and  religious  with  an  industrial 
side.  It  cannot  be  ascertained  to  what  extent 
their  organisation  applied  to  the  provinces  ; 
but  they  apparently  resembled  the  craft-guilds 
in  being  local  organisations.  The  collegium 
of  the  sailors,  however,  resembled  the  Com- 
PAGNONNAGES  (q.v.)  in  possessing  local  branches 
in  the  provinces.  The  original  nine  collegia  of 
craftsmen  were  always  exempt  from  the  repres 
sive  legislation  which  was  from  time  to  time 
promulgated  against  other  collegia,  and  they 
continued  to  exist  in  Italy  until  the  Middle 
Ages,  when  the  compagnonnages  and  craft- 
guilds  were  developed  from  them.  Owing  no 
doubt  to  the  preponderance  of  slave  over  free 
labour  in  Rome,  the  collegia  of  workmen  had 
little  direct  influence  on  history.  They  never 
appear  to  have  attained  an  importance  at  all 
comparable  with  that  of  a  Trade  Union  in 
modern  times. 

[Smith,  Dictionary  of  Roman  Antiquities,  1891. 
— Mommsen,  History  of  Rome. — Mommseu,  De 
CoUegiis  et  Sodaliciis,  Kiel,  1843.]  a.  H. 

COLONIES. 

Colonies,  description  of,  p.  321 ;  Colonial  Policy,  p.  322  ; 
Colonial  Lands,  p.  323  ;  Public  Debts,  Colonies,  p. 
324  ;  Trade  and  the  Flag,  p.  324  ;  Metliods  of  Govern- 
ment, p.  326 ;  Currency,  British  Colonies,  p.  S2«3 : 
Denominational  Currency,  p.  328 ;  Government  by 
Companies,  p.  329  ;  Colonisation,  Systems  of,  p.  333. 

COLONIES.  The  definition  of  the  term 
"colony"  is  elastic,  and  its  use  is  much 
governed  by  accidental  circumstances,  e.g. 
Ceylon  is  styled  a  "colony,"  and  Burmah 
not,  because  they  are  directed  by  diiferent 
departments  of  state  at  home. 

Modern  colonies,  which  are  those  treated  of 
here,  have  been  founded  by  the  nations  of  western 
Europe  since  the  time  when  their  energy  sent 
them  one  after  another  in  quest  of  profit  and  ad- 
venture away  from  the  Mediterranean  lands  which 
had  fallen  into  the  power  of  the  Mohammedans. 
They  fall  into  four  economic  types: — (1) 
Factories,  those  established  for  trade  with 
natives  ;  (2)  Provinces,  for  exploiting,  more  or 
less  explicitly,  the  countries  taken  possession 
of;  (3)  Plantations,  for  industrial  occupation 
through  employment  of  capital  ;  and  (4) 
Colonies  proper,  for  complete  industrial  occu- 
pation. .  Other  than  economic  motives  have 
influenced  the  origination  of  modern  colonies : 
religious  liberty  sent  out  the  Jews  of  Portugal 
to  Brazil ;  the  Puritans  to  New  England ; 
religious  enterprise  the  Jesuits  to  Paraguay  ; 
political  disaffection  sent  cavaliers  to  Barbados  ; 
social  offences  supplied  Australia  with  her  first 
colonists. 

1.  The  Factory  system  was  the  earliest,  and 
VOL.  I. 


was  prosecuted  with  great  vigour  by  the  Portu- 
guese, who,  in  rivalry  with  Venice  and  Genoa, 
drew  a  chain  of  factories  from  Madeira  to  Japan. 
When  Portugal  fell  (1580)  for  a  time  into  the 
clutches  of  Spain,  the  Dutch  stepped  in  and 
secured  many  of  their  positions  ;  in  time  the 
French  and  British  followed  up  the  Dutch. 
The  Portuguese  factories  were  royal  enterprises 
nominally,  but  were  farmed  out ;  the  Dutch 
were  purely  commercial  undertakings,  governed 
by  the  approved  methods  of  trade  found  suc- 
cessful in  Holland,  and  adopting  a  method 
known  in  present  days  as  limitation  of  output, 
where  thought  necessary.  The  concentration  of 
aim  upon  profit  proved  eventually  their  weakness. 
The  yielding  of  heavy  dividends  promptly  and 
regularly  can  hardly  be  an  adequate  basis  for 
great  human  movements  such  as  colonisation, 
and  a  clear  example  of  the  failure  of  such  an 
attempt  is  to  be  found  in  the  brief  duration 
of  the  Dutch  power  in  Brazil,  1624-1654. 

2.  Provinces.  In  these  the  inhabitants  al- 
ready in  possession  are  governed  and,  in  most 
cases,  made  use  of  for  industrial  employment. 
The  story  of  Spanish  colonisation  is  iound  in 
the  histories  of  Mexico  and  Peru.  The  Span- 
iards were  misled  by  the  idea  that  gold  and  silver 
were  identical  with  wealth,  and  fanatical  in 
their  preference  for  ecclesiastical  system  over 
humanity.  The  end  of  their  dominion  was 
sudden.  In  thirty  years  the  Spanish  empire 
in  the  new  world  was  gained  ;  it  lasted  two 
hundred  and  fifty  years ;  in  another  thirty 
years  it  fell,  leaving  behind  but  Cuba,  Puerto 
Rico,  and  the  Philippine  Islands.  Still,  the 
Spaniard  did  a  little  for  the  economic  develop- 
ment of  those  countries :  he  taught  the  use 
of  horses,  of  ploughs,  and  of  money.  France 
has  recently  formed  a  new  province  in  Africa,  but 
its  interest  is  mainly  military,  and  the  econo- 
mical value  of  their  rule  in  Tonquin  and  Cochin 
China,  to  either  party,  is  at  present  obscure. 
The  greatest  example  of  the  province  in  the 
history  of  the  world  is  undoubtedly  that  agglo- 
meration of  peoples,  nations,  and  languages 
called  "India."  The  economic  and  the  educa- 
tional value  of  the  relationship  between  Britain 
and  India  has  continually  become  more  and 
more  important,  as  that  relationship  has  gradu- 
ally taken  its  legitimate  form. 

3.  Plantations.  This  type  of  colony  has 
furnished  a  varied  and  interesting  chapter  in 
the  history  of  each  of  the  colonising  countries 
of  western  Europe.  When  regions  entered  upon 
were  inhabited  by  races  in  primitive  stages  of 
industrial  life,  these  were  either  brought  into 
service,  as  in  Brazil,  Ceylon,  and  the  mines  of 
Mexico  and  Peru,  or  pushed  aside,  as  in  North 
America.  The  primary  purpose  of  these  planta- 
tions was  the  employment  of  capital,  not  the 
application  of  the  planter's  labour — which 
indeed  the  climate  as  a  rule  rendered  impossible. 

I  Native   labour   was    brought   into   subjection. 

Y 


322 


COLONIES  :   COLONIAL  POLICY 


Gaols  at  home  were  emptied  of  their  lawful 
inhabitants  to  furnish  labourers  for  Virginia, 
and  the  sad  history  of  the  extermination  of  the 
natives  of  the  West  Indies  by  the  Spaniards, 
and  the  crushing  of  the  natives  of  Mexico,  Peru, 
and  BrazU  by  Spaniards  and  Portuguese  was 
marked  by  the  most  disgraceful  subordination  of 
moral  principle  to  industrial  circumstances  ever 
practised  on  such  a  scale  and  in  so  gross  a  manner 
— the  deportation  and  enslavement  of  African 
negroes  (see  Slavery  and  Slave  Trade). 

This  extraneous  supply  was  resorted  to  on 
the  extermination  of  the  inhabitants  of  the 
West  Indies,  the  proof  of  ineffectiveness  of 
those  of  Brazil,  and  of  the  inability  to  domesti- 
cate the  Red  Indians  of  North  America  ;  and 
it  has  resulted  in  the  settlement  of  an  important 
fraction  of  the  Negro  race  in  the  western  hemi- 
sphere. Recent  years  have  witnessed  the  de- 
velopment of  a  system  of  regulated  voluntary 
migration  of  tropical  labourers  from  the  east  to 
the  ^vest  under  the  name  of  Coolies  (see  Coolie 
System). 

In  spite  of  the  mediaeval  character  of  the 
Virginia  or  Jamaica  planter  in  many  respects, 
he  was  more  the  prototype  of  the  modern  agri- 
culturalist or  manufacturer  in  England  than 
was  the  New  England  or  Pennsylvania  farmer 
who  owned  his  land,  employed  his  own  capital, 
and  with  his  family  supplied  a  considerable 
part  of  the  labour.  And  as  time  went  on 
plantation  -  owners  were  only  represented  by 
"attorneys"  and  managers,  and  yet  their 
revenues,  being  derived  from  invested  capital, 
were  always  regarded  as  profits,  not  rents. 
What  has  changed  is  the  political  and  social 
status  of  the  labourer.  He  still  remains  eco- 
nomically dependent  so  long  as  he  has  no 
capital,  but  his  condition  is  gradually  im- 
proving. 

4.  Colonies  Proper.  England  only,  of  all 
European  countries,  was  in  a  position  to  put  forth 
vigorous  reproductions  of  herself  throughout  the 
18th  and  the  19th  centuries.  Of  recent  years 
(1910),  since  the  settlement  of  northern  Europe 
and  the  formation  of  the  German  empire,  the 
spirit  of  colonisation  has  developed  both  in 
France  and  Germany,  but  at  present  few  of  the 
Colonies  of  either  of  these  nations  have  a  revenue- 
suffieient  foi  the  cost  of  administration. 

Emigration  from  European  nations  con- 
tributes an  element  to  the  primarily  English 
life  of  the  United  States,  and  the  English 
colonies  of  North  America,  South  Africa,  and 
Australasia.  The  Dutch  settlement  in  South 
Africa,  and  the  French  remnants  in  Canada 
and  Mauritius,  show  a  certain  persistence. 
A  conspectus  of  the  present  situation  shows  a 
varied  spectacle.  Relics  of  four  empires, 
Spanish,  Portuguese,  Dutch,  and  French,  strew 
the  seas  ;  but  all  of  them  are  of  the  factory, 
province,  or  plantation  type.  Nations,  once 
European   colonies,    occupy   the   western    con- 


tinent from  the  St.  Lawrence  to  Cape  Horn, 
British,  Spanish,  or  Portuguese  in  origin  and 
in  economic  character.  The  British  empire 
stands  out  unique  in  magnitude,  in  variety, 
and  in  promise.  It  shows  every  type  in  full 
working  order.  Factories  flourish,  as  Lagos, 
Hong-Kong,  and  Singapore  ;  provinces,  as 
India,  Burmah,  Fiji ;  plantations,  as  Ceylon, 
Mauritius,  Guiana,  and  the  West  Indies  ;  and 
reproductions  of  the  British  nationality  in  the 
dominion  of  Canada,  in  South  Africa,  and  in 
Australasia.  Besides  these,  are  the  military, 
naval,  and  commercial  out-stations  of  Gibraltar, 
Malta,  Cyprus,  Aden,  St.  Helena,  Bermuda, 
and  the  Falkland  Islands. 

[For  full  accounts  of  the  present  condition  of 
European  colonies,  see  the  list  of  books  at  the  end 
of  this  article,  and  also  "British  and  Foreign 
Colonies,"  Sir  R.  Rawson,  address  to  Statistical 
Society,  London,  1884. — For  a  continuous  history, 
see  E.  J.  Payne,  Ev/ropean  Colonies,  Macmillan, 
London,  1877.] 

Colonial  Policy.  The  economic  policies 
which  have  prevailed  have  been  applications 
in  new  fields  of  policies  already  in  vogue  in  the 
home  countries.  To  reap  the  advantages  of 
the  new  territories  either  by  direct  acquisition 
of  their  products  or  by  exchange  at  enormous 
profit,  and  to  appropriate  these  advantages  as 
against  other  European  nations,  was  the  chief 
aim  of  the  attention  devoted  to  colonies 
throughout,  and  is  to  some  extent  in  active 
operation  at  this  day.  Holland  still  derives 
a  substantial  revenue  from  her  remaining 
possessions,  and  the  reiteration  of  the  question 
"of  what  use  are  the  colonies  to  us?"  shows 
that  in  England  economic  advantage  is  still  a 
prominent  factor  in  the  Englishman's  care  for 
the  "empire."  The  chief  differences  in  policy 
lay  in  the  exact  relationship  of  the  home 
government  to  the  new  communities ;  some 
reserved  full  control,  as  Spain  and  Portugal ; 
some  reserved  only  partial  control,  and  dele- 
gated considerable  power  to  the  original 
companies,  and  afterwards  to  the  colonial 
governments  ;  but  all  agreed  in  regarding  them 
as  fresh  sources  of  supply,  or  fresh  markets  for 
home  products.  It  seemed  to  contemporary 
statesmen  plain  common  sense  to  provide  that 
the  colonies  should  be  content  to  supply  what 
their  territory  was  able  at  once  to  produce, 
to  buy  and  sell  in  the  markets  of  the  home- 
country  alone,  and  not  to  compete  with  her  in 
foreign  markets.  The  aggi-egate  of  these 
restrictions,  monopolies,  and  privileges  consti- 
tutes what  is  usually  set  forth  as  the  "colonial 
system,"  which  prevailed  for  some  three  hun- 
dred years.  But  this  system  must  not  be 
considered  as  consisting  only  in  these  restric- 
tions. A  brief  consideration  of  it  as  designed 
by  Colbert,  for  example,  or  as  nursing  the 
young  colonies  of  North  America,  shows  that 
at  its  early  stages  the  advantage  was  not  all  on 


COLONIES:  COLONIAL  POLICY— LANDS 


323 


one  side.  If  Great  Britain  monopolised  the 
products  of  lier  colonies,  and  restricted  them 
to  herself  for  their  purchases,  this  was  in 
some  important  respects  only  confining  them 
to  their  best  customer  and  their  cheapest 
market.  And  besides  this,  the  imperial  army, 
navy,  and  credit  were  behind  them,  and  left 
them  free  to  their  industrial  pursuits.  But  as 
the  colonies  grew  stronger  the  necessity  for 
fostering  lessened,  and  the  situation  began  to 
be  disadvantageous.  Practical  protests  in  the 
way  of  smuggling  began  to  shake  the  legal 
position,  and  the  eventful  year  1776  saw  both 
the  declaration  of  independence  of  the  thirteen 
British  colonies  in  North  America,  and  the 
reasoned  demonstration  that  restrictions  were 
operating  perniciously,  in  Adam  Smith's  criticism 
of  the  whole  system.  It  may  be  said  that  his 
condemnation  is  based  on  the  cessation  of  the 
idea  that  the  colonies  were  property,  and  the 
substitution  for  this  of  the  economic  idea  that 
we  and  they  were  concerned  in  the  production 
of  as  much  material  wealth  as  possible,  and 
that  it  was  not  to  the  advantage  of  either  that 
restrictions  based  on  "artificial"  (or  non- 
economic)  relations  should  continue. 

In  the  general  movement  towards  free  trade 
as  British  economic  policy,  the  Navigation  Act 
was  modified,  and  eventually  abolished  (see 
Free  Trade).  The  diff'erential  duties  in  favour 
of  her  colonies  were  relinquished,  and  the 
country  which  was  the  latest  to  apply  the 
restrictive  method  strictly  was  the  first  to 
abandon  it.  The  issue  has  been  a  complete 
dissolution  of  the  old  relationship,  relaxation  of 
control  has  proceeded  to  the  bitter  end,  and 
the  spectacle  is  now  seen  of  colonies,  not  only 
not  tied  to  the  mother  country,  but  setting  up 
tarifis  which  put  her  on  the  same  footing  as 
every  other  nation — in  some  cases  even  care- 
fully excluding  her  products  as  much  as  theirs. 
Some,  indeed,  are  only  accidentally  protec- 
tionist, raising  their  customs  duties  for  revenue, 
as  South  Africa  and  New  Zealand,  but  two  at 
least,  Canada  and  Victoria,  are  avowedly  pro- 
hibitive in  their  intentions.  This  situation 
has  given  rise  to  many  proposals  for  a 
resumption  of  economic  relationship  by  means 
of  a  commercial  union  of  the  empire,  a  British 
"ZoUverein,"  and  this  constitutes  the  most 
burning  question  of  economic  colonial  policy 
at  this  day.  It  should  be  noted  that  the  vari- 
ous members  of  the  United  States  of  America 
form  a  compact  union  with  free  intercourse 
within,  and  protection  against  outsiders  ; 
that  neither  Holland  nor  Spain  have  allowed 
their  colonies  commercial  independence,  while 
France  is  moving  towards  restriction  again  for 
hers  ;  and  that  the  German  political  economist 
List  in  urging  Germany  to  begin  colonies,  did  so 
on  the  supposition  that  the  old  system  of 
union  rather  than  the  new  system  of  absolute 
freedom  would  be  the   basis   of  relationship. 


The  efiiects  on  the  economic  growth  of  a 
community  of  its  being  a  "colony,"  depend 
largely  upon  the  relative  force  of  the  national 
and  cosmopolitan  feelings.  In  early  days  of 
rivalry  and  hostility  between  nations,  the 
connection  was  of  vital  importance,  because 
people  would  not  incur  expatriation,  nor  would 
capital  venture  itself  beyond  the  nation's 
protection. 

But  now  what  colonies  secure  is  only  some 
advantage  in  the  movement  of  capital,  not 
an  exclusive  advantage.  The  feeling  that  the 
Government  of  the  empire  is,  somehow,  behind 
them,  that  they  are  in  some  ways  still  under  a 
department  of  state,  operates  with  considerable 
effect  in  their  favour,  and  is  preparing  the 
public  mind  for  the  extension  of  the  invest- 
ments of  trust  funds  to  colonial  government 
securities.  As  to  advantage  in  the  movement 
of  labour,  the  colonial  relationship  cannot  be 
said  to  count  for  very  much  in  the  face  of  the 
preponderance  of  emigration  from  Britain  and 
Germany  and  Sweden  to  the  United  States  ; 
but  prpbably  less  skilled  and  professional 
labour  would  go  to  Australia  were  it  not  a  part 
of  the  Empire.  Looked  at  broadly,  it  may  be 
seen  that  to  the  ex-colonies  of  North  America, 
and  the  present  colonies  in  Australia,  there  has 
been  a  movement  of  capital  and  labour  which 
has  enabled  Chicago,  Melbourne,  and  Montreal, 
to  attain  their  population  and  opulence  with  a 
rapidity  far  outstripping  anything  known  in 
the  old  world  with  all  its  inheritance  of  endow- 
ments and  equipments  for  industrial  develop- 
ment. 

The  effect  on  the  home  countries  of  having 
colonies  was  more  important  under  the  old 
system  than  now.  Then  they  were  direct 
sources  of  revenue,  or  monopolised  spheres  ot 
trade.  The  increase  of  intercommunication 
through  facilities  in  travelling,  the  settling 
down  of  the  new  free  trade  policy,  and  the  rise 
of  competitors  in  manufactoring  industry  on 
the  continent,  have  brought  into  full  view 
what  the  outer  empire  means  for  British 
industry  to-day.  We  can  see  clearly  how  it  has 
been  a  field  for  emigration,  and  so  has  assisted 
in  the  rise  of  wages  ;  an  outlet  for  capital,  and 
so  has  helped  to  check  the  fall  of  interest  and 
of  profits  ;  a  market  for  manufactures,  and  so 
has  called  into  action  the  law  of  increasing  re- 
turns, and  eff'ected  a  cheapening  of  commodities 
in  spite  of  the  rise  of  wages  ;  and  a  source  of 
agricultural  supply  which  has  checked  the 
operation  of  the  law  of  diminishing  returns. 
It  has  contributed  largely  to  the  development 
of  our  manufacturing  powers,  and  has  thus 
helped  to  pay  back  the  debt  which  List  says  it 
owes  when  he  bases  the  British  empire  on  the 
capacity  of  Great  Britain  for  becoming  a  predomi- 
nantly manufacturing  nation.  [See  Colonial 
Policy,  Recent  Developments,  in  App.] 

[Colonial  Lands.    The  tenure  of  laud  has 


324 


COLONIES  :   COLONIAL  POLICY— PUBLIC  DEBTS 


in  the  main  been  on  the  simple  basis  that  the 
crown  was  possessor,  and  could  grant  lands  in 
•perpetuvmi  or  on  leases,  and  in  colonies  which 
acquired  responsible  governments  these  govern- 
ments have  taken  over  the  rights  of  the  crown. 
The  raising  of  revenue  by  the  sale  of  lan^  has 
been  common,  especially  in  order  to  allure 
immigration.  Gradually  a  more  far-sighted 
policy  is  being  adopted  ;  the  colonies  are  ceasing 
to  live  on  capital  in  this  way.  Victoria  now 
carries  the  proceeds  of  public  sale  of  lands  to  a 
reserve  fund  ;  New  Zealand,  since  1879,  has 
reserved  the  whole,  Tasmania  about  one  half. 
An  important  question  of  policy  is  raised  by 
the  supposition  that  the  colonists  at  any  given 
time  are,  corporately,  the  possessors  of  the 
lands  of  their  territory — a  supposition  which, 
on  its  face,  is  barely  reasonable  for  Victoria 
with  a  population  of  a  million  in  a  region 
larger  than  England  and  Wales,  and  incon- 
gruously absurd  when  the  60,000  people  at 
present  in  Western  Australia  lay  claim  to  a 
third  of  the  Australian  continent.  The  im- 
portance of  this  to  the  mother-country  lies  in 
the  consequent  claim  of  the  colonists  to  restrict 
farther  emigration  at  their  discretion. 

The  Public  Debts  of  the  Colonies.  The 
colonies  have  borrowed  capital,  as  corporations, 
to  the  extent  of  something  like  390  millions  at 
present  outstanding.  But  exception  is  taken, 
and  with  justice,  to  this  being  regarded  as 
analogous  to  the  national  debts  of  European 
countries  rather  than  to  the  debts  of  traders 
who  have  legitimately  bon-owed  for  use  as 
capital.  The  chief  portions  of  the  national 
debts  of  the  continental  nations,  of  Britain,  and 
even  of  the  United  States,  have  been  borrowed 
for  the  expenses  of  war ;  the  chief  portions  of 
these  colonial  government  debts  have  been 
borrowed  for  public  works,  especially  railways. 
The  interest  on  the  debts  is  largely  provided 
by  the  receipts  from  these  public  works,  and 
from  this  source  much  of  the  debts  themselves 
will  gradually  be  paid  off.  It  is  maintained  by 
some,  but  denied  by  others,  that  in  some  cases 
colonies  have  been  too  sanguine,  and  have 
drawn  somewhat  in  excess  of  what  is  easily 
repaid,  but  only  because  they  may  have  con- 
structed more  public  works  than  they  were 
immediately  able  to  make  remunerative. 

[See  papers  by  Sir  F.  Dillon  Bell,  "  Indebtedness 
of  the  Australian  Colonies  in  relation  to  their 
Resources,"  with  discussion,  Roy.  Col.  Inst.  Pro- 
ceedings, vol.  xiv.  thereon  ;  and  by  H.  F.  Billing- 
hurst,  "  Colonial  Indebtedness,"  Journal  of  Inst, 
of  JBanlcers,  March  1889,  and  discussion. — W. 
Westgarth,  "Australasian  Public  Finance," 
Colonies  and  India,  March  27,  and  discussion, 
April  3,  1889.  The  first  principles  of  this  subject 
are  well  discussed  by  Dr.  Sidgwick  in  the  third 
book  of  his  Political  Economy.] 

The  rate  of  interest  in  the  colonies  has  proved 
a  clear  index  of  their  growth,  of  the  increase  of 
confidence  in  their  stability  and  future,  and  of 


the  security  of  their  commercial  connection 
with  the  home  country  whether  the  political 
continues  or  not.  Loans  to  private  borrowers 
used  to  range  at  fancy  rates  until  the  formation 
of  joint-stock  companies  in  England  with  boards 
of  directors  composed,  partly  at  least,  of  well- 
known  Englishmen.  Sixtyyears  ago  government 
loans  were  at  6  per  cent,  and  even  then  taken 
only  at  a  discount,  but  gradually  the  rates 
fell  until,  in  the  period  from  1895  to  1905, 
the  4  per  cent  of  some  colonies  were  at  a 
premium,  and  Canada  issued  a  3  per  cent  loan, 
while  the  Australian  colonies  were  advised 
severally  to  consolidate  their  loans  at  that 
figure.  The  " '  inscribing  "  of  stock,  permitting 
the  amount  to  stand  in  the  names  of  individuals, 
has  attracted  investors  to  whom  changes  of 
investment  are  objectionable  ;  the  lengthening 
of  the  periods  of  redemption  has  operated  in 
the  same  direction.  The  conversion  of  the  3 
per  cents  in  England,  the  tendency  towards 
3  per  cents  of  municipal  corporations  in  the 
United  Kingdom,  with  a  fluctuating  taste  for 
foreign  investments,  all  incline  the  flow  of 
capital  to  the  colonies.  Of  this,  however,  they 
have  availed  themselves  so  freely  that  during 
the  past  few  years  the  rate  at  which  they  can 
borrow  has  again  shown  a  tendency  to  rise. 

[See  paper  in  Proceedings  of  Roy.  Col.  Inst. ,  vol. 
ix.,  by  Dr.  J.  Forbes  Watson,  "Character  of 
England's  Colonial  and  Indian  Trade  contrasted 
with  her  Foreign  Trade."] 

Trade  and  the  Flag. — This  is  a  figurative 
expression  for  the  connection  between  commercial 
intercourse  and  political  union.  Much  argu- 
ment is  used  and  masses  of  statistics  have  been 
compiled  on  both  sides  of  the  question,  which  is, 
indeed,  of  very  great  interest  and  importance. 

To  those  who  regard  the  political  connection 
as  effective  in  the  commercial  sphere,  it  is  of 
extreme  importance  that  the  political  connection 
should  be  retained,  and  strengthened,  if  need 
be,  by  judicious  improvements ;  this  is  the 
primary  consideration  with  many  of  those  en- 
gaged in  the  Imperial  Federation  propaganda, 
though  not  a  plank  in  their  oflBcial  platform. 

Those  who  think  that  purely  economic  con- 
siderations are  now  —  perhaps  ought  to  be 
always — adequately  powerful  to  guide  peoples 
in  the  pursuit  of  material  well-being,  regard 
lightly  the  continuance  of  political  ties,  especially 
when  so  attenuated  as  those  between  the  English- 
speaking  countries  and  the  mother  country  have 
become.  They  hold  that  natural  propensities 
are  self-acting,  and  will  operate  in  keeping  up 
a  close  commercial  relationship,  and  that  govern- 
ment relations  are  either  worthless  because  quite 
unnecessary,  or  pernicious  because  distorting  the 
natural  procedure. 

It  is  evident  that  the  influence  of  statistics 
upon  this  discussion  is  limited  ;  but  the  feder- 
ationists  can  certainly  at  present  point  out  some 
striking  figures,  such  as  Great  Britain's  exports  to 


COLONIES:    COLONIAL  POLICY— TKADE  AND  THE  FLAG 


325 


France  being  1 6s.  a  head  of  French  population, 
when  those  to  Australia  are  196s.  ;  and  U.S.A., 
English-speaking  but  outside  the  flag,  15s.,  to 
Canada's  45s.  But  the  opponent  replies,  (1) 
that  this  trade  is  due  to  the  large  loan  opera- 
tions :  and  the  question  then  resolves  itself,  so 
far,  into  the  fundamental  question  of  the 
mobility  of  capital  and  labour,  is  this  helped  or 
hindered  by  the  political  connection  ?  and  (2) 
that  the  Canadian  tariff  is  not  so  hostile, — 
but  this  may  be  one  consequence  of  the  flag. 

[See  Forster,  Art.  in  Nineteenth  Century^  Feb. 
1885,  and  the  publications  of  the  Imp.  Fed. 
League  generally,  and  on  the  other  side  Sir  T, 
Farrer,  Free  Trade  versus  Fair  Trade,  4th  edition, 
1887,  and  the  publications  of  the  Cobden  Club. 
The  subject,  however,  is  not  to  be  discussed  as 
between  protectionists  and  free-traders,  as  the  chief 
men  on  both  sides  claim  to  be  the  latter.  The  im- 
perial unionists  are  reinforced,  however,  by  the 
fair-traders  and  by  the  supporters  of  national  econ- 
omics ;  see  S.  S.  Lloyd's  translation  of  List.  ] 

A  problem  of  growing  interest  is  the  claim  of 
the  colonists  to  consider  themselves  as  owing  no 
effective  allegiance  to  the  mother  country.  The 
elaborate  tariff's,  already  mentioned,  form  tlie 
backbone  of  the  problem.  There  are  also  the 
questions  of  the  right  of  the  colonists  at  any 
given  time  to  stop  farther  immigration  from 
Britain  or  elsewhere  into  lands  which  British 
policy  has  secured  from  possession  by  other 
nations,  and  the  British  navy  has  secured  from 
physical  aggression  ;  and  the  right  of  the  colon- 
ists of  the  day  to  throw  possible  embarrassment 
on  the  future  development  of  the  colonies,  and 
their  utility  to  the  mother  coimtry  by  injudicious 
allotments  of  the  land  of  the  colony,  and  in  dis- 
regard of  the  fact  that  the  inhabitants  of  Great 
Britain  and  Ireland  pay  interest  on  a  vast  debt 
partly  acquired  in  maintaining  the  sovereignty 
of  the  seas  which  has  kept  France  and  Germany 
out  of  Australia,  while  the  colonists  are  under 
no  liability  for  this  debt.  New  effects  of  eco- 
nomic conditions  upon  social  and  political 
organisation  will  present  themselves  in  some  of 
our  colonies.  For  example,  Victoria  is  a  state 
in  which  labour  more  or  less  skilled,  and  guided 
by  higher  average  of  intelligence  than  in  Europe, 
is  the  prime  political  power  ;  fixed  property  and 
even  movable  capital  being  secondary  in  influ- 
ence. The  interest  that  depends  on  uncertainty 
will  not  be  wanting  to  political  economy  in 
view  of  these  new  phenomena. 

Colonial  policy  as  regards  this  country  is  far 
from  having  arrived  at  the  stable  position  which 
seemed  promised  by  the  steady  displacement  of 
the  old  system  during  the  first  three-quarters  of 
this  century.  The  removal  one  by  one  of  the 
restrictions  on  colonial  trade  by  Mr.  Huskisson 
between  1814  and  1825,  the  abandonment  of 
differential  duties,  and  of  the  Navigation  Act, 
1850,  seemed  to  point  to  an  era  of  complete 
freedom.  But  the  gradual  adoption  of  protec- 
tionist policy  by   several    important   colonies 


has  reversed  the  position  by  placing  barriers, 
which  oppose  Great  Britain  most,  because  in 
freedom  it  is  her  trade  which  would  naturally 
be  the  largest.  And  so  the  colonies  are  drawn 
into  the  vortex  of  the  great  protection  versm 
free -trade  agitation.  Two  parties  aim  at  a 
new  colonial  policy :  one  bases  its  recommenda- 
tions on  the  conception  of  national  economics 
in  preference  to  cosmopolitan  ;  the  other,  on 
the  greater  amount  of  real  "freedom"  which, 
under  present  circumstances,  Avould  result  from 
freedom  within  this  vast  empire  of  300  million 
people,  though  combined  with  protection  against 
outside  protectionist  nations.  The  means  of 
reaching  their  goal  is  the  same  for  both  parties, 
a  commercial  union  of  the  empire.  The  opposi- 
tion has  also  two  parties — the  free-traders  who 
prefer  the  amount  of  free  trade  at  present  in 
force,  with  hope  that  it  will  by  its  own  virtue 
continually  increase,  and  so  break  down  barriers 
both  colonial  and  foreign  ;  and  the  colonists 
who  severally  place  their  own  colonies  in  the 
front  of  their  schemes,  and  are  content  to  be 
protectionist  for  their  own  reasons.  On  each 
side,  therefore,  there  is  a  band  of  free-traders 
and  a  band  of  protectionists — Mr.  W.  E.  Forster 
and  Mr.  Goschen  have  taken  a  place  side  by 
side  with  the  disciples  of  List ;  Sir  Thomas 
Farrer  and  the  Cobden  Club  are  the  allies  of  the 
protectionists  of  Victoria  and  Canada.  Mean- 
while the  bounty  of  nature,  the  extension  of 
industrial  ideas  as  determinants  of  national 
ambitions  and  national  policies,  and  the  con- 
tinuous development  of  science  and  civilisation, 
combine  to  cause  a  rapidity  of  industrial  progress 
in  British  colonies  which  exceeds  all  known  else- 
where, except  in  our  own  ex-colonies,  the  United 
States.  And  in  spite  of  obstructions,  and  while 
waiting  for  general  agreement  as  to  the  next  steps 
to  be  taken,  the  mother-country  largely  benefits 
by  the  industrial  prosperity  of  the  outer  empire. 

For  systems  on  which  colonies  have  been  founded, 
see  Colonisation,  Systems  of. 

[The  library  of  the  Royal  Colonial  Institute  con- 
tains books  of  reference,  statistical  publications, 
and  histories,  both  general  and  special,  to  the 
number  of  9500  volumes  (catalogue  price  2s.  6d., 
oflSce  of  the  institute),  and  219  colonial  journals 
and  newspapers  are  regularly  taken,  tiled  for  a 
year,  and  then  deposited  in  the  British  Museum. 
Statistical  Abstracts  for  the  colonies  are  published 
annually  by  the  Board  of  Trade,  and  Returns  of 
Trade  and  Navigation  monthly.  For  British 
colonies  see  Historical  Geography  of  the  British 
Colonies,  Introduction,  vols.  i.  ii.  (others  follow- 
ing), C.  P.  Lucas,  Oxford. — Official  Reports  on 
Colonial  Products  (1887).— The  Colonial  Office 
List,  published  annually. — British  and  Foreign 
Colonies,  Sir  E.  Rawson,  Statistical  Society,  1884. 
— Synopsis  of  Tarij^s  and  Trade  of  the  British 
Empire  1888,  and  Sequel,  Sir  R.  Rawson,  London, 
1889.  Ax\,ic\Q?,milciQ  Proceedings  of  the  Roy.  Col. 
Inst,  1874  onwards. — TTie  Colonies  and  India, 
a  weekly  journal,  London.  For  History  :  Adam 
Smith's  ch.  viii.    in  bk.    iv.  —  Smith's  polemic 


326 


COLONIES:    METHODS  OF  GOVEENMENT 


against  the  colonial  system  is  criticised  by  Lord 
Brougham  in  An  Inquiry  into  the  Colonial  Policy  of 
European  Powers,  1803  (see  Brougham,  Lord). 
— Merivale,  Lectures  on  Colonies  and  Colonisation, 
delivered  1839-40-41*  corrected  edition,  London, 
1862. — Payne,  European  Colonies,  London,  ^1877, 
and  Seeley,  Expansion  of  England,  London,*  1882. 
— Dilke,  Problems  of  Greater  Britain,  London, 
1890. — Caldecott,  English  Colonisation  .and  Em- 
pire, London,  1891. — These  form  an  adequate 
library  for  the  preliminary  study  of  colonial  history. 
The  Statistical  Abstracts  of  the  Board  of  Trade  and 
the  Statesman's  Year-Books  supply  some  economic 
statistics  for  foreign  countries,  revised  annually. 

Foreign  Works. 

French:  Leroy-Beaulieu,  De  la  colonisation 
chez  les  peuples  modernes. — Louis  Vignon,  Les 
colonies  frangaises. — Jules  Duval,  L'Algirie  et  les 
colonies  frangaises  (all,  Librairie  Guillaumin,  Paris). 
■ — J.  Rambosson,  Les  colonies  frangaises  (Paris, 
1868). — L.  Deschamps,  Histoire  de  la  qicestion 
Coloniale,  1891.  —  Notices  statistigues  sur  les 
colonies  frangaises  (Berger  Levrault,  Paris,  1883). 
— Anmbairespiibliispar  chaqv^  colonic. — Tableaux 
annuaires. — Rembe  maritime  et  coloniale. — Also 
French  Colonies  and  their  Resources^  J.  Bonwick 
(London,  1886). 

German  :  Roscher,  KolonieUy  Kolonial  politik, 
und  Auswanderung  (Leipzig  and  Heidelberg, 
1856).— K.  E.  Tung,  Deutsche  Kolonien,  1884.— 
Deutsche  Kolonial  Zeitung,  organ  der  D.  Kolonial- 
gesellschaft,  Berlin,  every  Saturday. 

Dutch. — Bijdragen  tot  de  Taal-Land-en  Volk- 
enkunde  der  Nederlandsch- Indie,  began  to  appear 
1886,  'Sgravenhage. — A  copious  bibliography  of 
works  on  Dutch  colonies  is  prefixed  to  Catalogue 
of  Amsterdam  Exhibition,  Colonial  Section  (Ley  den, 
1883).  — Information  respecting  the  system  of 
Dutch  administration  and  colonisation  in  the  East 
Indies  and  the  Cape  to  the  French  Huguenot  emi- 
gration from  Europe  to  South  Africa  towards  end 
of  17th  century  is  given  in  ITie  Voyage  of  Fran- 
gois  Legvxit,  of  Bresse,  to  Rodriguez,  Mauritius, 
Java,  and  the  Cape  of  Good  Hope.  London : 
printed  for  the  Hakluyt  Society. 

Portuguese.  —  Bulhoes,  Les  Colonies  Portu- 
gaises,  1878. — Martins,  0  Brazil  e  as  Colonias 
Portugue'ms,  3d  ed.  1888. — Corvo,  Estudos  sobre 
as  Provincias  Ultramarinas,  4  vols.  1883-87. — 
Annuario  Estatistico  de  Portugal  (official  by  the 
ministry  of  public  works,  Lisbon),  As  Colonias 
Portuguezas,  fortnightly  ;  Boletim  da  Sociedade  de 
Geographia  de  Lisbda,  monthly ;  Boletim  official 
da  Angola,  ditto,  da  MogamMqu^. 

Italian. — Bolletino  delta  Societd  AJHcana 
D^Italia  (Napoli,  fortnightly). 

A  Revue  Coloniale  Internationale  was  issued  at 
Amsterdam  with  French,  English,  and  German 
articles  in  1885,  but  lasted  only  three  years  ;  it 
is  of  interest  as  showing  readily  different  points  of 
view.]  A.  c. 

Methods  of  Government.  A  colony 
(Lat.  Colonia;  colere  to  till,  to  cultivate)  may 
be  defined  as  distant  possessions  or  dependen- 
cies of  a  country  ;  more  particularly  the  word 
signifies  communities  of  settlers  in  a  new  or  a 


foreign  country  politically  dependent  on  a  parent 
state.  Colonies  are  lawfully  acquired  by  a 
country  in  respect  of  other  states  either  by  title 
of  occupancy,  or  of  cession,  or  of  prescription. 
As  to  the  rules  of  international  law  relating  to 
the  acquisition  of  colonies  and  the  disputes 
which  have  arisen  on  the  subject,  see  Hall's 
Int.  Law,  pt.  ii.  ch.  2. 

According  to  our  municipal  law  English  sub- 
jects who  occupy  a  new  country  carry  our  com- 
mon law  with  them,  as  far  as  it  is  applicable  to 
their  circumstances ;  and  the  crown,  apart  from 
parliament,  has  no  legislative  power  over  them. 
On  the  other  hand  countries  acquired  by  con- 
quest or  cession,  called  crown  colonies,  retain 
their  own  laws  till  they  are  altered,  and  are  sub- 
ject to  the  absolute  legislative  control  of  the 
crown,  except  in  so  far  as  parliament  interferes 
with  the  prerogative  of  the  crown  in  this 
respect,  for  over  all  our  colonies  and  depen- 
dencies, however  acquired,  parliament  has 
supreme  legislative  authority  (cp.  Dicey,  Law 
of  the  Constitution,  Lecture  IL  ;  Todd,  Parlia- 
mentary Government  in  the  British  Colonies). 
Conquered  and  ceded  countries  cease  to  be 
subject  to  the  legislation  of  the  crown  if  the 
crown  has^granted  them  a  representative  legis- 
lature. 

The  government  of  each  colony  is  carried  on 
in  the  name  of  the  crown  under  a  governor  who 
is  appointed  by  the  crown,  and  who,  in  our 
self-governing  colonies  is  advised  by  ministers 
responsible  to  the  legislature,  like  our  cabinet 
(as  to  the  veto  of  the  governor  in  respect  of 
colonial  legislation,  and  other  restrictions  on 
such  legislation,  see  Dicey,  op.  cit.  Lecture  III.) 
The  legal  supremacy  of  the  imperial  parliament 
over  the  colonies  is  only  exercised  in  cases 
which  do  not  involve  any  encroachment  on 
the  province  of  colonial  self-government. 

British  dependencies  may  be  either  directly 
under  the  government  of  the  crown  or  they 
may  be  under  the  immediate  government  of  a 
chartered  company,  such  as  the  old  East  India 
Company  and  Hudson  Bay  Company,  or  the 
present  South  African  Company.  When  the 
East  India  Company  was  abolished,  and  India 
was  brought  under  the  direct  control  of  the 
crown,  the  control  of  the  government  was  not 
assigned  to  the  colonial  secretary,  but  to  a 
special  secretary  of  state  for  India.  Hence 
India  is  not  styled  a  colony.  E.  A.  w. 

Currency  in  British  Colonies.  In  theory 
British  currency  followed  the  British  flag  to 
the  New  World  "  plantations,"  which  were  the 
beginning  of  our  colonial  empire.  In  practice, 
however,  itwas  only  the  denomination  of  sterling, 
and  not  the  sterling  coin,  which  followed  the  first 
settlers.  With  new  countries  to  develop,  they 
required  from  the  mother  country  not  coin,  but 
commodities  in  exchange  for  the  produce  they 
shipped  home.  Barter  was  the  common  mode 
of  conducting  the  internal  exchanges,  — tobacco^ 


COLONIES:   CURRENCY  IN  BRITISH  COLONIES 


327 


sugar,  rum,  indigo,  wampum,  skins,  and  timber, 
forming  the  more  usual  media.  It  was  not 
until,  with  increased  production,  trade  sprang 
up  between  some  of  the  British  colonies  and 
the  Spanish  Islands  and  the  Spanish  Main,  that 
metallic  money  began  to  flow  in.  This  money 
was  Spanish  silver  (the  real  and  its  multiples 
up  to  the  "piece  of  eight"  reals,  see  Dollar), 
which  the  colonists  rated  in  denomination  of 
sterling  at  arbitrary  prices,  the  dominant  rating 
of  the  first  half  of  the  17th  century  being  4s. 
for  the  piece  of  eight,  based  on  the  popular 
currency  (Barbados,  Bermudas,  Jamaica)  of  the 
real  as  a  "Spanish  sixpence."  Clipping  and 
competitive  raisings  of  the  local  ratings  of 
Spanish  silver  in  the  several  colonies  led,  soon 
after  1650,  as  a  rule,  to  the  5s.-rating  of  the 
piece  of  eight,  which  was  familiar  in  England 
before  that  date,  and  which  is  preserved  to  the 
present  day  as  the  basis  of  "Halifax  currency"  ; 
whilst,  by  the  close  of  the  17th  century  a 
6s. -rating  was  partially  established  both  on 
the  mainland  and  in  some  of  the  West  India 
Islands.  Meantime,  other  colonies  had  adopted 
the  accepted  silver- parity  of  4s.  6d.  for  the 
piece  of  eight,  and  in  1652  New  England  had 
struck  the  silver  "pine-tree  coinage"  (Is.,  6d., 
3d.,  2d.)  for  its  own  use.  Shortly  after  1700 
complaints  of  the  evils  of  colonial  currency 
began  to  pour  in  on  the  Board  of  Trade  and 
Plantations,  and  in  1704  a  royal  proclamation 
was  issued  fixing  the  maximum  rating  of  a 
piece  of  eight  at  6s.-"  currency "  with  other 
silver  coins  proportionately  rated  for  concurrent 
circulation.  Thus  arose  ' '  proclamation  money, " 
i.e.  the  colonial  rating  of  silver  coins  at  a  tliird 
above  their  accepted  sterling  value.  As  this 
proclamation  was  generally  disobeyed  ("owing 
to  the  liberty  that  trading  men  will  always 
take  in  their  own  bargains  "),  the  act  6  Anne, 
cap.  30  was  passed,  making  it  felony  to  pay 
or  receive  the  specified  silver  coins  above  pro- 
clamation rates.  The  result  was  entirely  un- 
expected, for  (1)  the  West  Indian  colonies 
evaded  the  act  by  conventionally  overrating 
the  gold  coins  of  Spain  (see  Doubloon),  and 
so  passing  in  practice  to  a  gold  standard  ;  whilst 
(2)  the  mainland  colonies  (now  the  United 
States)  issued  inconvertible  and  unsecured 
paper  money  in  profligate  profusion.  The 
gold  standard  persisted  in  the  West  Indies 
into  the  present  century  ;  but  on  the  mainland 

tthe  standard  coin  continued  to  be  the  silver 
Spanish  dollar.  In  1739  and  1740,  it  should 
be  added,  the  question  of  colonial  cuirency 
engaged  the  attention  of  parliament,  but  no 
practical  results  followed. 
In  the  years  round  1800  the  colonial  empire 
of  Great  Britain,  whilst  it  was  diminished  by 
the  loss  of  the  United  States,  was  increased  by 
the  settlement  of  Australia,  by  the  gain  of  the 
Cape,   Ceylon,   and   British   Guiana  from  the 


and  some  additional  West  Indian  Islands  from 
the  French.  And,  further,  the  decade  from 
1810  to  1820  witnessed  two  important  changes 
in  the  Spanish  and  British  monetary  systems. 
For  (1)  Spain  lost  the  American  colonies  from 
which  came  the  supplies  of  bullion  which  had 
made  the  Spanish  dollar  the  universal  coin  for 
some  three  centuries  ;  and  (2)  in  1816  the 
United  Kingdom  adopted  gold  as  the  sole 
measure  of  value,  reducing  silver  coins  to  the 
subsidiary  position  of  mere  tokens.  The  now 
bewildering  complexities  of  the  colonial  cur- 
rency systems,  the  stoppage  of  the  supply  of 
the  Spanish  dollar,  and  the  novel  experience 
of  retaining  silver  in  circulation  at  home,  led 
the  imperial  government,  after  striking  rix- 
doUars  (worth  Is.  6d.)  for  Ceylon,  guilders 
(worth  about  Is.)  for  British  Guiana,  and 
"anchor  money"  equivalent  to  i-,  -},  ^,  and 
^  of  a  Spanish  dollar  for  Mauritius  and  the 
West  Indies,  to  pass  an  order  in  council  and 
proclamation  on  23d  March  1825,  for  the  pur- 
pose of  introducing  British  silver  and  copper 
coins  into  general  circulation  throughout  the 
colonies.  Apart  from  the  fact  that  tokens 
representing  the  standard  gold  sovereign  were 
wholly  unsuited  to  silver-using  colonies  such  as 
Ceylon  and  Mauritius,  there  was  the  funda- 
mental en'or  in  the  legislation  of  1825  that 
the  Spanish  dollar,  then  worth  4s.  2d.  sterling, 
was  rated  at  4s.  4d.  for  concurrent  circulation 
with  sterling  coins.  And,  further,  no  account 
was  taken  of  the  fact  that,  following  the  monet- 
ary system  of  Spain,  most  of  the  colonies  re- 
garded the  gold  doubloon  (sterling  value  64s.) 
as  the  equivalent  of  sixteen  silver  dollars.  Con- 
sequently British  silver  was  undervalued  some 
3  per  cent  as  against  the  dollar,  and  a  further 
5  per  cent  as  against  the  doubloon,  with  the 
natural  result  that  the  scheme  of  1825  was 
abortive.  Taught  by  experience,  the  imperial 
government  in  1838  revoked  the  legislation  of 
1825,  so  far  as  respected  the  colonies  "in 
America  and  in  the  West  Indies,"  and  ordained 
that  throughout  the  West  Indies  the  dollar 
and  doubloon  should  be  rated  at  4s.  2d.  and 
64s.  respectively,  for  concurrent  circulation 
Avith  sterling  coins.  No  limit  was  placed  on 
the  tender  of  the  doubloon,  the  dollar,  or 
British  silver.  Consequently,  though  in  the 
following  years  the  several  West  Indian  Islands 
formally  passed  acts  assimilating  their  currency 
to  that  of  the  United  Kingdom,  the  gold 
sovereign  has  been  unable  to  circulate  in  com- 
petition with  the  shilling,  and  the  doubloon 
has  been  driven  out.  The  history  of  currency 
in  the  West  Indies  may  here  be  completed  by 
stating  that,  when  in  1876  the  gold- price  of 
silver  made  it  profitable  to  re-introduce  the 
then  practically  unknown  dollar,  acts  were 
forthwith  passed  demonetising  that  coin,  and 
leaving  the  field  to  British  silver  coin,  and  the 
notes  of  the  Colonial  Bank.      The  exceptions 


328 


COLONIES:  DENOMINATIONAL  CURRENCY 


are  (1)  the  Bahamas,  where,  by  a  popular — 
but  not  legal — over- valuation  of  the  gold  U.S. 
dollar  at  4s.  2d. ,  the  practical  standard  is  the 
gold  currency  of  the  United  States,  with  British 
silver  iii  subsidiary  circulation,  and  (2)  British 
Honduras,  where  in  1886  the  silver  dollar  of 
Honduras  was  made  the  legal  standard.  '  At 
various  times  endeavours  have  been  made  to 
induce  the  West  Indies  to  impose  a  limit  on 
the  legal  tender  of  token  silver ;  but  local 
opinion  is  not  ripe  for  this  reform. 

In  other  colonies  the  history  of  currency  has 
no  unity  except  in  the  principle  that,  since 
1838,  "currency  areas"  have  been  recognised, 
e.g.  Ceylon  and  Mauritius  have  been  allowed 
to  adopt  as  their  standard  the  Indian  rupee, 
which  dominates  the  "  currency  area  "  in  which 
they  are  included  by  virtue  of  trade-relations, 
etc.  ;  the  currency  of  Spain  has  been  adopted 
for  Gibraltar  ;  in  Hong  Kong  and  the  Straits 
Settlements  the  Mexican  dollar  (see  Dollar) 
has  been  established  as  the  proper  standard  for 
colonies  trading  with  silver-using  China,  which 
recognises  no  coin  but  the  Mexican  dollar  ;  and, 
lastly  and  chiefly,  Canada  has  adopted  the 
gold  currency  of  the  neighbouring  United  States, 
a  weight  of  fine  gold,  which  is  the  exact  equiva- 
lent of  the  U.  S.  gold  dollar,  being  the  standard 
of  value.  Newfoundland  stands  alone  in  hav- 
ing a  standard  (gold)  coin  peculiar  to  itself, 
viz.  the  two-dollar  pieces  struck  at  the  British 
mint.  But  numerous  colonies  (Canada,  Ceylon, 
Mauritius,  Hong  Kong,  the  Straits,  etc.)  possess 
tolcens  of  their  own.  In  concluding  this  brief 
survey  of  the  history  of  metallic  currency  in  the 
British  colonies,  the  most  important  matter  of 
aU  remains  to  be  noted,  viz.  the  discovery  of 
gold  in  Australia  in  1850,  and  the  subsequent 
establishment  of  the  Sydney  and  Melbourne 
branches  of  the  Royal  Mint  in  1853  and  1866 
respectively,  for  the  coinage  of  sovereigns  and 
half-sovereigns  (only),  which  are  now  legal 
tender  equally  with  the  coins  struck  at  the 
London  mint. 

As  regards  paper  currency,  space  forbids 
more  than  the  brief  mention  that,  except  in 
the  American  colonies,  there  was  practically  no 
paper  money  in  circulation  in  the  British 
colonies  before  this  century  ;  that  at  the  Cape 
and  in  Ceylon  and  British  Guiana  we  inherited 
a  damnosa  hereditas  of  inconvertible  paper, 
which  under  British  mismanagement  increased 
in  volume,  and  drove  out  coin  in  the  first  forty 
years  of  this  century  ;  that  during  the  same 
period  Jamaica  and  Prince  Edward  Island 
debased  their  currency  in  a  similar  fashion  ; 
that  in  Ceylon  and  Mauritius  government  note- 
issues  have  been  established,  which  are  fully 
secured,  and  have  at  least  one-third  of  the 
reserve  in  coin ;  that  the  modern  policy 
appears  to  be  to  ensure  (always  in  the  case  of 
new  issues,  and  as  far  as  possible  in  the  case  of 
existing  issues)  the  two  essentials  of  security 


and  convertibility,  leaving  it  open  whether  the 
issue  shall  be  by  the  government  or  by  a  bank. 
But  much  of  the  paper  which  circulates  in  the 
British  colonies  is  not  adequately  secured. 

The  following  is  a  classified  list  of  the 
colonies  as  regards  cm-rency  : — 

I.  Sterling  Standard. 

(a)  With  40s.  limit  on  silver  : 

Australasia,  the  Cape,  Natal,  British 
Bechuanaland,  Fiji,  St.  Helena. 
(&)  With  a  £5  limit : 

Malta. 
(c)  With  no  limit : 

West  India  Islands,  British  Guiana, 
West  African  Colonies,  Falkland 
Islands. 

II.  Non-Sterling  Standard. 
({a)  U.S.  gold  dollar: 

The  dominion  of  Canada  (sovereign 
legal  tender  at  $4-66). 
(h)  Newfoundland  gold  dollar  : 

Newfoundland  (eagle  and  sovereign 
legal  tender), 
(c)  Spanish  (Latin  Union)  "bimetallic" 
standard : 
Gibraltar. 
f  (d)  Mexican  silver  dollar  : 

Hdng  Kong,  the  Straits  Settlements, 
Labuan,  British  North  Borneo. 
(e)  Indian  rupee : 

India,  Mauritius  and  Ceylon. 
(/)  Honduras  dollar : 
Biitish  Honduras. 
[The  Currency  of  the  British  Colonies,  anon., 
London,  1848. — £arlp  Coins  of  America,  Crosby, 
Boston,  1878.  —  Conference  MonStaire  Interna- 
tionale de  1878,  Paris,  1878.— 27ie  Mrniey  of 
the  British  Umpire,  by  Mr.  A.  Leslie  Probyn  in 
Vol.  XXL  of  the  Proceedings  of  the  Royal 
Colonial  Institute,  1890. — Coins  of  British  Pos- 
sessions and  Colonies,  Atkins,  London,  1889. — • 
The  acts  of  the  several  colonies,  colonial  histories, 
and  pamphlets  of  the  last  and  present  century, 
dealing  with  currency  in  individual  colonies,  and, 
particularly,  the  valuable  MSS.  in  the  record 
oflSce.]  R.  c. 

Denominational  Currency.  In  connection 
with  colonial  currency  the  term  Denomina- 
tional Currency  requires  explanation.  It  has 
been  used  by  writers  of  repute  ;  but  it  is  illogical 
and  unscientific,  and  it  would  be  desirable  to 
get  rid  of  it.  In  transactions  with  many  of 
the  English  colonies,  especially  the  North 
American  and  West  Indian  colonies,  even  as 
late  as  the  middle  of  the  present  century,  the 
term  ''currency,"  as  opposed  to  "sterling," 
was  well  known  ;  and  perhaps  "currency,"  in 
a  strictly  limited  and  almost  local  sense,  with- 
out a  defining,  or  rather  a  confusing,  epithet, 
is  the  simplest  name  to  adopt  for  the  state  of 
facts  which  we  proceed  to  explain. 

"Currency,"  it  will  be  found,  implied  the 
current  use,  in  account,  of  the  denominations  of 
a  standard  coinage  to  represent  values  widelj 


COLONIES  :    GOVERNMENT  OF,  BY  COMPANIES 


329 


varying  from  the  standard,  produced  by  the 
mis-rating  of  coins  foreign  to  the  standard. 

The  original  colonists  of  the  Americas  natur- 
ally adopted  in  their  new  home  the  denomina- 
tion of  money  with  which  they  were  familiar, 
and  made  it  their  money  of  account.  At  first 
their  transactions  were  almost  entirely  in  com- 
modities. When  coins  became  in  request,  those 
which  came  to  them  were  foreign  coins,  chiefly 
Spanish  and  Portuguese  (v.  Currency  in 
British  Colonies).  They  consequently  at- 
tempted to  adapt  these  coins  to  their  familiar 
denominations  of  account,  in  other  words,  to  rate 
them  to  the  pound.  This  rating  was  incorrect ;  it 
varied  in  ditierent  colonies,  and  was  often  made 
worse  by  further  attempts  to  correct  it.  Hence  a 
pound's  worth  of  dollars,  according  to  local  rat- 
ing, was  a  very  different  thing  from  the  number 
of  dollars  equivalent  in  intrinsic  value  to  the 
pound  sterling  ;  and  it  usually  fell  considerably 
short  of  that  equivalent,  as  was  shown  by  the 
high  rates  of  exchange  which  prevailed  against 
the  American  and  West  Indian  colonies  for 
many  years.  The  £  s.  d.  in  which  the  colon- 
ists reckoned  did  not  correspond  in  value  either 
with  those  denominations  in  the  sterling  of  the 
mother  country  or  with  similar  denominations 
in  neighbouring  colonies.  There  thus  existed  a 
number  of  differing  pounds  of  account,  each  of 
which  came  to  be  known  locally  as  a  "  currency 
pound." 

The  same  state  of  facts  is  not  likely  to  be 
repeated  except  in  the  dependencies  of  a  domin- 
ant country.  In  Ireland,  during  a  good  part 
of  the  18th  century,  the  moidore  was  the  pre- 
valent coin  apart  from  debased  half-pence  and 
farthings,  and  Irish  "currency"  was  in  the 
same  position  as  that  of  the  Plantations. 

0.  A.  H. 

Government  of  Colonies  by  Companies. 
Adam  Smith,  in  a  passage  which  has  been 
quoted  with  approval  by  at  least  one  modern 
writer  of  authority,  states  that  "the  govern- 
ment of  an  exclusive  company  of  merchants 
is  perhaps  the  worst  of  all  governments  for 
any  country  whatever."  The  statement,  if  it 
were  unchallenged,  would  stand  for  ever  as  a 
condemnation  of  all  past  or  present  projects 
conferring  territorial  sovereignty  on  a  company. 
But  this  dictum  of  Adam  Smith's  is  somewhat 
too  sweeping  and  somewhat  out  of  accord  with 
the  facts.  So  far  as  it  is  good,  it  needs  eluci- 
dation. 

The  possession  of  ten-itorial  sovereignty  by 
private  individuals  or  companies,  the  subjects 
of  some  supreme  government,  is  apparently 
associated  with  a  special  set  of  conditions. 
It  has  rarely  been  found  except  at  those  times 
and  in  those  parts  of  the  world  in  which  rival 
nations  have  been  actively  competing  for  new 
trade  or  settlements.  In  the  17th  century, 
when  the  power  of  Spain  was  broken,  and  Eng- 
lish. Dutch,  French,  and  Danes  were  rushing  in 


to  share  the  spoil,  the  method  which  national 
caution  dictated  to  the  new  comers  was  that  of 
the  chartered  company  ;  and  the  early  history 
of  North  America,  the  West  Indies,  and  Guiana 
is  virtually  the  history  of  many  such  companies  ; 
the  rest  of  South  and  all  Central  America  was 
too  secure  in  the  hands  of  Spaniards  and  Portu- 
guese to  offer  a  field  for  rivalry.  The  struggle 
for  the  trade  of  the  East  was  a  struggle  of 
companies.  The  latter  half  of  the  18th  cen- 
tury was  a  time  of  continual  fighting ;  the 
present  century  has  been  a  time  of  recovery 
and  development  on  the  lines  settled  by  that 
fighting  ;  there  was  no  room  for  that  rivalry  in 
new  fields  which  produced  the  privileged  com- 
panies ;  Australia  was  the  great  addition  to  the 
Avorld  in  this  period,  and  there  was  no  question 
who  should  colonise  it.  In  our  generation  a 
fresh  example  of  the  theorem  has  arisen  ;  Africa 
has  been  suddenly  presented  to  us  as  the  great 
prize  open  to  all  nations,  and  the  recent  efilor- 
escence  of  chartered  companies  is  the  result. 

The  encouragement  of  such  companies  springs 
from  the  timidity  or  caution  of  governments. 
Companies  rush  in  where  the  messenger  of 
government  fears  to  tread.  If  they  succeed, 
the  government  of  their  country  gladly  supports 
them,  and  may  ultimately  reap  the  fruits  of 
their  labours  ;  if  they  fail,  no  blame  is  taken 
by  the  government.  If  their  actions  prove 
premature  or  inconvenient  they  can  be  dis- 
avowed, the  company  being  made  a  buffer  to 
ease  off  friction  or  conceal  the  reality  of  some 
blow  at  a  rival. 

Not  that  acquisition  of  temtory  or  the  govern- 
ment of  a  new  domain  has  been  the  original 
aim  of  any  of  these  companies.  In  ancient  and 
modern  instances  alike  the  profits  of  trade  have 
been  the  guiding  motive  in  their  formation. 
Certain  arrangements  for  the  preservation  of 
order  have  been  included  in  the  charter,  and 
formed  the  germs  of  any  government  which 
afterwards  grew  up.  It  will  be  found  that  in 
their  essence  there  is  no  difference  between  the 
chartered  company  of  the  17th  century  and  that 
of  1890.  All  through  the  document  on  which 
they  base  their  rights  the  prominent  idea  is  the 
security  of  their  business  ;  all  through  the  his- 
tory of  their  operations  their  real  anxiety  is  the 
development  of  their  trade.  The  real  difference 
between  ancient  and  modem  companies  is  to  be 
found  in  the  extent  of  their  commercial  privileges 
and  the  influence  of  modern  conscientiousness 
or  timidity. 

It  will  be  useful,  for  reference,  and  wiU  illus- 
trate the  activity  of  enterprise  in  the  16th  and 
17th  centuries,  to  give  a  list,  Avhich  is  at  least 
approximately  complete,  of  the  numerous  com- 
panies which  obtained  charters  for  exclusij 
trade  in  nearly  all  the  knoAvn  quarters 
globe  previous  to  the  19th  century. 

The  Merchant  Adventurers'  Company  apji^Btigf^^f^' 
to  have  been  the  first  body  of  men  froi 


330 


COLONIES:    GOVERNMENT  OF,  BY  COMPANIES 


nation  who  obtained  a  charter  (dated  in  1564) 
for  foreign  trade.  The  Muscovy  Company  was 
probably  next,  and  its  charter  is  quoted  as  a 
precedent  for  others,  e.g.  for  the  Company  of 
Cathay,  which  received  its  charter  in  1576. 
The  Turkey  Company  was  formed  about  the 
same  time :  the  Company  of  Adventurers  for 
Guinea  and  Benin,  followed  ten  years  later. 
The  East  India  Company  of  London  was  incor- 
porated in  1 600,  and  thus  preceded  by  three  years 
the  great  Dutch  Universal  East  India  Company, 
which  was  destined  to  drive  it  into  difficulties 
out  of  which  arose  the  only  company  (commonly 
known  as  the  British  East  India  Company), 
which  became  a  mighty  territorial  sovereign. 
The  governor  and  company  of  Merchants  of 
London  for  the  discovery  of  the  North -West 
Passage  were  incorporated  at  this  period.  And 
the  first  half  of  the  seventeenth  century  was 
rich  in  companies,  the  majority  turning  their 
eyes  towards  America.  The  Virginia  Company, 
the  Bermuda  Company,  the  Newfoundland 
Company,  the  first  African  Company  (which  was 
reconstituted  four  times),  the  Dutch  West  India 
Company,  an  Amazon  Company,  a  Guiana  Com- 
pany which  never  did  anything,  the  New  Eng- 
land Company,  the  Providence  Company,  the 
Canada  Company,  the  Massachusetts  Bay  Com- 
pany, the  Nova  Scotia  Company,  rapidly  suc- 
ceeded one  another.  There  were  also  the  French 
East  and  West  India  Companies — the  latter 
known  as  theCompany  of  the  Islands  of  America, 
and  Canada  Company  formed  during  the  same 
period  ;  an  English  West  India  Company  was 
projected  but  never  became  a  reality.  Most  of 
the  charters  granted  after  1650  are  reconstitu- 
tions  of  old  companies  on  a  new  basis,  as  in 
the  case  of  the  New  Royal  African  Company. 
Charles  11. 's  reign  teems  with  such  new  grants. 
The  Hudson's  Bay  Company's  first  charter  was 
granted  in  1670. 

An  alternative  method  of  encouraging  colon- 
isation, which  must  be  noticed  here,  was  the 
grant  to  a  body  of  lords  proprietors,  or  some- 
times to  a  single  lord.  All  the  British  Caribee 
Islands  were  so  granted  in  1627  ;  Maryland  in 
1669  ;  the  Bahamas  and  Carolina  in  1670.  In 
the  case  of  these  grants  there  seems  to  have 
been  a  clear  understanding  that  the  sovereignty 
rested  with  the  crown  ;  whereas  the  companies 
merely  reserved  a  fixed  nominal  tribute  to  the 
sovereign  in  case  he  should  come  into  their 
dominions  ;  and  when,  as  in  the  case  of  Virginia, 
the  Bermudas,  or  more  recently  India,  the 
Crown  was  required  to  intervene,  a  suspension 
or  complete  alteration  of  the  charter  was 
necessary. 

It  is  well  to  mention  the  notorious  South 
Sea  Company,  early  in  the  18th  century.  And 
the  list  of  older  companies  is  closed  towards 
the  end  of  that  century  by  a  new  departure 
in  economical  history,  a  politico -philanthropic 
settlement,  namely  the  Sierra  Leone  Company. 


The  old  charters  and  grants  -svhich  conceded 
their  rights  to  the  above-named  companies  or 
to  lords  proprietors  were  very  much  on  the 
same  lines  and  often  almost  in  identical  terms. 
Apart  from  arrays  of  names  and  verbiage,  they 
were  simpler  documents  than  any  recent  charters. 
The  monopoly,  their  raison  d'Stre,  the  "sole 
privilege  to  pass  and  trade "  to  certain  places 
is  the  leading  provision  in  all.  The  necessary 
powers  for  securing  the  enjoyment  of  that 
privilege  of  trade  and  of  the  assigned  territory 
are  given,  and  this  carried  a  right  to  exact 
customs  duties  from  traders  not  members  of  the 
company.  A  governor  and  court  of  directors 
were  usually  instituted,  and  empowered  to 
make  laws,  levy  fines,  and  imprison.  In  some 
cases  full  jurisdiction  of  life  and  death  is  con- 
ferred, together  with  the  power  to  declare  martial 
law ;  in  others  power  to  make  peace  or  war  with 
heathen  natives  is  also  delegated  ;  in  one  case 
(the  Amazon  Company)  we  find  mention  of 
* '  all  customary  privileges  for  sending  ships,  men, 
ammunition,  armour,  and  other  things."  Pro- 
visions regulating  the  admission  of  members  are 
usual,  and  the  term  of  duration  is  commonly 
limited  to  a  moderate  period,  though  in  the  case 
of  the  Royal  African  Company  it  was  for  1000 
years.  Briefly,  the  old  charters  regarded  two 
things  :  1st,  the  monopoly  of  trade ;  2d,  security 
against  intruders  or  foreign  foes.  They  were 
somewhat  vague  in  language,  and  left  each 
company  to  work  out  its  own  development 
according  to  circumstances.  No  kind  of  super- 
vision by  the  supreme  government  was  sug- 
gested ;  but  in  some  cases  a  right  of  interference 
was  preserved  by  the  curious  legal  fiction  of 
making  the  area  of  the  grant  a  part  of  an 
English  borough. 

It  was  a  part  of  the  policy  of  the  companies 
to  induce  settlers  to  go  out  to  their  lands,  and 
to  keep  these  settlers  in  a  kind  of  tutelage  ;  if 
this  was  necessary  to  their  first  success,  it  was 
also  essentially  the  cause  of  their  troubles. 
The  government  of  a  few  individuals  who 
while  attracting  free  settlers  directed  every- 
thing avowedly  for  their  own  profit,  and  denied 
the  right  of  those  settlers  to  enjoy  the  fruit  of 
their  own  industry,  was  clearly  indefensible. 
The  operations  of  aU  the  companies  which  made 
something  of  a  permanent  start,  such  as  those 
of  Virginia  and  Bermuda,  were  very  early  dis- 
turbed by  complaints  of  their  monopoly.  De- 
privation of  profits  bred  discontent ;  discontent 
proved  difficult  to  handle.  The  domain  of  the 
company  often  became  a  scene  of  confusion  ; 
and  discredit  was  cast  not  only  on  its  monopoly, 
but  upon  its  power  to  govern.  It  was  this  con- 
dition of  affairs  which  Adam  Smith  reprobated  ; 
but  the  real  root  of  the  evil  here  was  the  exclu- 
sive privilege  operating  injuriously  to  others  of  , 
the  same  race  and  ambition. 

Government  in  the  proper  sense  did  not 
greatly  enter  into  the  schemes  of  any  companies- 


COLONIES  :    GOVERNMENT  OF,  BY  COMPANIES 


331 


In  most  cases  the  disputes  just  referred  to  began 
so  early  in  their  history,  and  became  so  serious, 
that  all  future  responsibility  for  the  government 
really  rested  with  the  crown,  which  gradually 
absorbed  the  area  of  its  own  grant.  Such  was 
the  case  of  the  Virginia  Company  in  1624, 
some  eight  years  after  it  was  incorporated  ;  the 
question  of  reform  was  mooted  by  the  proposal 
to  renew  the  charter  for  trade  only,  ' '  but  not 
for  the  government  of  the  country,  of  which 
the  king  will  himself  take  care."  In  1631 
this  plan  took  final  shape,  the  protests  of  the 
"adventurers"  delayed  it,  but  they  could  not 
stifle  the  voices  of  dissatisfied  Englishmen  ;  the 
administration  of  the  company's  territory  fell 
in  to  the  crown,  and  the  company  paid  the 
charges. 

In  one  notable  instance,  under  a  special  set 
of  circumstances,  a  government  of  remarkable 
power  and  energy  grew  up  almost  against 
the  will  of  the  administrators.  The  British 
East  India  Company  started  with  no  ambitious 
scheme  of  government ;  they  were  content  to 
have  established  their  factories  on  the  coasts  of 
the  Carnatic  and  Bengal,  provided  they  could 
oust  theu'  foreign  European  rivals  from  the 
trade.  The  intrigues  of  the  French  forced  them 
to  fight,  first  for  their  existence,  aftenvards  for 
quiet  possession  ;  the  flame  of  war  once  lighted 
was  not  easily  quenched  ;  the  brand  had  fallen 
amongst  a  restless  and  inflammable  people  ;  the 
small  band  of  the  company's  servants  had  to 
choose  between  conquest  and  death.  The  man 
for  the  hour  was  at  hand  ;  success  followed 
Clive's  arms,  and  a  British  company  became  the 
lords  of  a  vast  empire.  In  this  case  the  climate 
and  distance  had  confined  the  numbers  of  ad- 
venturers of  British  race  to  but  few  besides 
the  company's  own  servants  or  licensees  ;  the 
directors  were  hardly  hampered  by  internal  dis- 
content, and  the  objects  of  their  earlier  adminis- 
tration were  a  people  who  expected  to  be  ruled. 

It  would  have  been  a  strain  on  any  nation 
to  support  the  continued  wars  which  for  nearly 
half  a  century  taxed  the  resources  of  the  great 
East  India  Company ;  it  was  natural  that 
support  from  the  government  should  be  asked 
for,  and  that  its  enjoyment  should  be  accom- 
panied with  some  measure  of  control.  Never- 
theless the  government  of  India,  even  after 
the  institution  of  the  Board  of  Control  in  1784, 
was  in  reality  the  government  of  the  company  ; 
and  that  it  was  enlightened  and  careful,  that 
it  gradually  handled  with  success  the  most 
diflicult  problems  which  confronted  it,  that  it 
swept  away  gi-eat  national  evils  such  as  child- 
murder  and  thuggism  ;  in  short,  that  it  was 
conducted  by  a  peculiarly  able  set  of  English- 
men on  the  lines  most  approved  at  home,  will 
hardly  be  denied.  The  rule  of  the  company 
came  abruptly  to  an  end  in  1858,  not  so  much 
because  it  was  proved  a  failure,  as  because  a 
gi*eater  crisis  than  ever  had  arisen,    and  the 


interests  of  all  classes  in  this  country  had  be- 
come bound  up  with  the  possession  of  India, 
so  that  the  sense  of  national  responsibility  waa 
stronger  than  before. 

What  the  East  India  Company  did  in  the 
old  world  the  Hudson's  Bay  Company  partly 
accomplished  under  quieter  conditions  in  North 
America,  laying  the  foundations  of  two  great 
provinces  of  the  Canadian  dominion.  The  same 
thing  might  have  been  done  by  many  of  the 
old  companies  had  conditions  been  equal. 
Indeed,  as  Mr.  Merivale  suggests  of  the 
Dutch  India  companies,  the  government  of  a 
company  in  those  days  was  likely  to  be  more 
generally  beneficial  than  that  of  a  nation.  There 
was  greater  regularity  and  economy  of  adminis- 
tration ;  a  sharp  check  was  kept  over  employes  ; 
if  the  court  of  directors  itself  wished  to  tyran- 
nise or  squeeze,  it  at  least  kept  its  subordinates 
in  order.  It  is  true  that  Adam  Smith  draws 
an  exactly  opposite  picture  ;  but  it  will  be  ad- 
mitted by  all  who  read  history  fairly  that  this 
great  man  was  blinded  by  his  hatred  of  mono- 
polies of  all  kinds,  and  failed  to  give  credit  even 
where  credit  was  due. 

The  weak  point  of  a  company's  government 
was  apt  to  be  in  its  external  relations.  On  the 
one  hand  was  the  fear  of  embroiling  itself  and 
its  nation  ;  on  the  other  the  reluctance  to 
throw  away  money.  This  is  excellently  illus- 
trated by  the  later  history  of  the  Dutch  West 
India  Company  in  Demerara  and  Essequibo. 
The  Spaniards  were  constantly  encroaching 
without  warrant  on  the  limits  of  the  Dutch 
colony ;  the  Dutch  governors  were  eager  to 
drive  them  ofi"  once  for  all ;  but  the  company, 
partly  actuated  by  its  anxiety  not  to  cause  a 
national  breach,  partly  avowing  the  need  of 
economy,  declined  to  take  a  step  which  might 
have  saved  endless  trouble  afterwards. 

The  fact  is  that  to  govern  with  capacity  a 
company  must  first  be  rich.  It  is  chiefly  this 
which  Mr.  Merivale  has  in  mind  when  he  states 
that  the  prosperity  of  companies  declined  as  soon 
as  they  substituted  empire  for  trade.  Sovereignty 
brought  large  establishments  and  lavish  expendi- 
ture. Because  the  means  failed  it  is  not  a  fair 
inference  that  the  administration  of  trading  com- 
panies is  inherently  rotten.  The  monopoly  ot 
the  old  companies  produced  factitious  prosperity; 
this  led  them  on  to  extravagance  ;  and  in  but 
few  cases  could  they  withstand  the  simultaneous 
undermining  of  their  monopoly  and  the  unex- 
pected strain  of  then*  own  engagements. 

The  Sierra  Leone  Company  at  the  beginning 
of  this  centmy  is  hardly  a  fair  example  of  the 
trading  company.  Its  operations  were  mixed 
up  with  philanthropic  interference,  which  is 
proverbially  unbusiness-like.  And  after  all, 
its  government  was  hardly  less  successful  than 
that  of  the  West  African  colonies  under  the 
British  crown. 

The  Sierra  Leone  Company  was  the  last  of  the 


332 


COLONIES:   GOVERNMENT  OF,  BY  COMPANIES 


older  attempts  to  make  a  trading  company  self- 
administering.  The  charter  of  the  Falkland 
Islands  Company  was  purely  a  trading  charter. 
A  colonial  government  had  been  established 
before  Mr.  Lafone  obtained  his  grant.  No  posi- 
tive monopoly  was  granted  by  the  charter  ; 
the  company  was  empowered  to  carry  on  opera- 
tions for  taming  wild  cattle  and  breeding  stock, 
for  establishing  whale  and  seal  fisheries,  to 
enter  into  any  sort  of  trade  with  the  islands 
generally,  and  to  contract  for  the  performance 
of  any  services  either  to  the  government  or 
individuals.  These  objects  were  not  such  as  to 
demand  a  charter,  the  only  practical  aim  of 
which  appears  to  have  been  to  give  prestige  ; 
the  effect,  however,  has  been  to  create  a  mono- 
poly in  that  distant  colony  which  is  bitterly 
assailed  by  the  few  independent  islanders. 

It  would  not  be  right  to  omit  all  mention  of 
the  Sombrero  Phosphates  Company,  holding 
the  island  of  Sombrero  in  the  West  Indies 
under  a  lease  which  makes  the  lessees  responsible 
for  the  maintenance  of  order  amongst  their 
employes  and  any  other  inhabitants,  and  so 
far  creates  a  small  dependent  government. 

But  broadly  speaking,  except  that  the  East 
India  Company  lived  on,  ever  approximating  to 
state  government,  it  may  be  said  that  colonisa- 
tion by  chartered  companies  dropped  into  abey- 
ance in  the  18th  century,  and  that  after  a  lapse 
of  nearly  a  hundred  years  the  system  suddenly 
burst  again  into  life  in  the  charter  of  the  British 
North  Borneo  Company. 

This  charter  was  the  first,  and  the  example, 
of  the  modern  grants.  It  was  the  result  of  a 
number  of  concessions  in  the  same  district  com- 
ing into  the  hands  of  one  man  and  forming  a 
responsibility  which  he  could  not  bear  alone. 
The  revival  of  the  idea  of  a  chartered  company 
was  not  unnatural,  in  view  of  the  extent  and 
delicacy  of  the  interests  concerned.  But  the 
precise  stipulations  of  the  new  charter  gave  it  a 
stamp  widely  different  from  that  of  the  old 
grants. 

The  German  New  Guinea  Company  was  the 
next  in  the  field.  And  the  Royal  Niger  Com- 
pany, the  Imperial  British  East  Africa  Com- 
pany, and  the  British  South  Africa  Company, 
all  received  charters  on  the  new  British  model 
within  the  space  of  three  and  a  half  years  ;  all 
three  absorbing  individual  and  competing  in- 
terests which  the  government  of  Great  Britain 
was  disinclined  to  support.  The  German  East 
African  Company  followed  in  the  steps  of  the 
British  Company  of  similar  title. 

Modem  philanthropy  and  respect  of  human 
life,  the  natural  timidity  of  governments,  and 
the  special  caution  which  characterises  that  of 
Great ,  Britain,  have  laid  an  indelible  mark  on 
the  new  British  charters.  There  is,  of  course, 
no  exclusive  enjoyment  of  trade  ;  on  the  con- 
trary, monopolies  are  carefully  prohibited  ;  but 
there  is  the  exclusive  right  to  grant  concessions 


within  the  territory  assigned,  and  to  deal  with 
it  for  the  company's  advantage  ;  power  is  also 
taken  for  the  establishment  of  any  kind  of 
business.  At  every  point  the  control  of  the 
crown,  through  one  of  the  principal  secretaries 
of  state,  is  jealously  reserved  ;  without  reference 
to  him  no  transfer  of  territory  can  be  made,  no 
dealings  with  native  or  foreign  powers  are  final. 
The  discouragement  of  all  slavery  and  of  the 
liquor  traffic  is  specially  enjoined  ;  interference 
with  native  religions  is  forbidden  ;  considera- 
tion of  the  customs  of  natives  is  required  in  the 
administration  of  justice. 

As  already  suggested,  it  is  in  these  precau- 
tions that  the  real  difference  between  the  older 
and  modern  grants  lies.  It  is  nothing  more 
than  the  difference  of  the  spirit  of  their  age. 
Both  contemplate  the  necessity  of  administra- 
tion, and  make  some  sort  of  provision  for  it. 
But  in  the  older  cases  a  free  hand  is  left  to  the 
directors  ;  in  the  modern  every  precaution  is 
taken  against  collision  with  foreign  states  or 
oppression  of  native  races.  There  is  no  founda- 
tion for  any  attempt  to  differentiate  ancient 
and  modern  chartered  companies  by  the  extent 
of  their  administrative  purpose.  This  has 
always  been  the  creature  of  circumstance,  and 
it  may  be  that  when  the  history  of  existing 
companies  some  day  comes  to  be  written,  one 
or  more  may  be  found  to  have  rivalled  the 
success  of  the  British  East  India  Company. 

A  real  difference  in  regard  to  method  of 
government  is  found  between  the  British  and 
Dutch  companies  on  one  side,  and  the  French 
and  German  companies  on  the  other.  The  dis- 
tinction applies  alike  to  old  and  modem  charters. 
The  Britons  and  the  Dutch  are  above  all  things 
traders,  and  traders  who  rely  on  their  own 
resources  ;  their  charters  are  for  trade,  and  the 
companies  are  left  to  stand  or  fall  by  them- 
selves ;  intervention  of  the  national  government 
closes  the  company's  rule.  The  French  and 
Germans  carry  with  them  their  fatherland  ;  the 
imperial  power  must  be  close  behind  them  ; 
the  sovereignty  of  their  companies  is  the  dele- 
gated sovereignty  of  the  supreme  government ; 
the  administration  of  justice  and  certain  execu- 
tive functions  rest  directly  with  the  govern- 
ment ;  and  all  foreign  relations  are  controlled 
by  it.  The  German  New  Guinea  Company 
and  the  German  East  African  Company  are 
veiled  forms  of  the  German  government,  hence 
the  warships  and  bombardments  which  mark 
their  operations. 

The  obvious  result  is  that  the  progress  of  the 
aided  companies  is  at  first  more  obtrusive ; 
avowed  dominion  by  the  national  government 
must  come  more  rapidly  ;  and,  in  the  case  of 
nations  like  the  Germans  and  French  whoae 
policy  is  exclusive,  this  involves  restrictions 
affecting  the  world.  On  the  other  hand  the 
real  grip  of  a  district,  which  is  the  foundation 
of  good  administration,  may  never  come  by  this 


COLONIES:  SYSTEMS  OF  COLONISATION 


333 


method.  By  the  British  plan  the  ground  is 
carefully  prepared  for  empire  first ;  if  the  pro- 
ject is  successful,  there  is  little  question  that 
colonial  government  will  take  firm  root,  when 
Its  time  comes  at  last. 

If  we  have  dealt  chiefly  with  British  com- 
panies it  is  that  in  British  hands  the  chartered 
company  has  been  most  widely  and  successfully 
used.  In  its  present  form  the  British  chartered 
company  is  shorn  of  every  objectionable  feature. 
It  may  be  a  great  pioneer  of  trade  and  confer 
lasting  blessing  on  unopened  districts.  It  may 
keep  open  tracts  of  land  which  would  other- 
wise be  closed  by  a  selfish  policy.  But  the 
government  which  encourages  fresh  companies 
must  be  prepared  eventually  to  administer  a 
new  territory  ;  and  the  real  question  of  policy 
is  brought  down  to  this — whether,  while  there 
is  yet  room  for  expansion,  a  living  empire  must 
be  a  growing  emphe. 

[The  locus  dassicus  on  the  subject  of  government 
by  companies  is  Adam  Smith's  excellent  chapter 
bk.  iv.  oh.  vii.  and  esp.  pt.  ii.,  where  his  dis- 
tinction between  **  regulated  "  and  "joint-stock" 
companies  is  worth  noting.  See  also  Sir  G.  C. 
Lewis's  essay  on  The  Government  of  Dependencies, 
circap.  143. — Merivale's  Colonisation  andColonies, 
pp.  50-60  (ed.  1861).— T^Ae  Calendars  of  State 
Papers  {Colonial)  (1574-1674,  3  vols.)  are  a  mine 
of  history,  and  Mr.  Sainsbury 's  prefaces  are  useful. 
— Sir  W.  Kaye's  History  of  the  East  India  Company 
is  one  amongst  many  works  on  that  subject.  A 
sketch  of  the  Dutch  West  India  Company  is  found 
in  Motley's  United  Netherlands.  References  to 
other  special  companies  are  scattered  ;  but  for  the 
Hudson's  Bay  Company  consult  Pari.  Paper  547  of 
1842  ;  and  for  recent  charters  the  London  Gazette 
of  8th  November  1881  (British  N.  Borneo),  13th 
July  1886  (Royal  Niger),  7th  September  1888 
(Imp.  Brit.  E.  African  Co.),  20th  December  1889 
(Brit.  S.  African  Co.)] 

[See  African  Companies,  Early  ;  African 
Companies,  Recent  ;  East  India  Companies, 
British.]  c.  a.  h. 

Systems  of  Colonisation.  In  its  economic 
or  industrial  aspect,  colonisation  must  be 
deemed  the  outcome  of  modern  necessities 
and  the  offspring  of  modern  instincts.  The 
settlement  of  colonies  took  place,  indeed,  in 
early  times,  but  it  proceeded  usually  in  ways 
and  from  causes  other  than  those  recognised 
by  modern  systems.  With  the  Phcenicians, 
colonies  were  little  else  than  trading  stations  ; 
to  the  Greeks  they  represented  more,  being 
founded  oftentimes  in  response  to  political 
exigencies  ;  the  Roman  colonies,  united  to  the 
mother  state  by  a  common  bond  of  citizen- 
ship, while  at  times  little  more  than  military 
settlements,  were  at  times  again  a  means  of 
relieving  distress  or  discontent.  Nor  was  there 
any  sign  of  conscious  colonisation  even  at 
the  close  of  the  Middle  Ages,  when  the  dis- 
covery of  America  threw  open  a  new  world  to 
Em-ope.  About  that  time  two  chief  motives 
led  to  settlements  beyond  the  borders  of  the 


country  or  city  whose  citizens  formed  the  new 
inhabitants.  1.  The  desire  to  form  trading 
stations,  as,  for  instance,  in  the  cases  of  Venice 
and  Genoa  in  the  Mediterranean,  of  Spain  and 
Portugal  in  the  new  world,  and  afterwards 
in  the  case  of  companies,  such  as  the  East 
India  Companies.  2.  The  desire  for  adventure 
resulting  at  times  in  settlement.  During  the 
IGth  and  17th  centuries,  the  first  of  these  ob- 
jects met  with  encouragement  from  the  new 
school  of  statesmen  as  Lord  Bui-ghley  and 
Oliver  Cromwell  in  England,  Richelieu  and 
Colbert  in  France.  In  the  case  of  the  former 
country,  too,  political  conditions  and  love  of 
adventm-e  combined  to  add  tlie  notion  of  settle- 
ment to  that  of  trade.  There  was,  however, 
no  conscious  regulation  of  the  new  settlements 
with  a  view  to  their  rapid  industrial  develop- 
ment. Colonisation,  in  its  true  sense,  was  un- 
known, whether  the  system  adopted  was  pro- 
prietary or  more  immediately  dependent  on 
the  crown.  The  growth  of  a  system  of  colonisa- 
tion may  be  best  traced  in  the  history  of  the 
British  colonies.  Here,  indeed,  relations  of  the 
colony  to  the  mother  country  were  fully  recog- 
nised, especially  by  such  jueasures  as  the 
Navigation  Acts  {q.v.)  The  system  thus 
inaugurated  was  that  of  political  freedom,  but 
commercial  restraint  for  the  advantage  of  the 
mother  country.  An  attempt  to  interl'ere  with 
the  former  led  to  the  loss  of  the  American 
colonies,  and  in  consequence  to  a  change  of 
policy.  The  colonies  were  governed  more  from 
home,  but  every  encouragement  was  offered  to 
their  commercial  development,  as  the  effect  of 
the  trade  restrictions  (differential)  imposed  on 
both  sides  was  to  confine  colonial  products  to 
the  most  important  market  in  the  world,  though 
this  might  have  the  effect  of  limiting  the 
sources  from  which  England  might  derive 
her  supplies  of  raw  material.  Thus  matters 
stood  at  the  beginning  of  the  19th  century. 
In  reality  there  were  four  points  on  which  a 
decision  had  to  be  arrived  at : — 1.  The  position 
of  the  colony  as  an  outlet  for  the  rapidly  in- 
creasing home  population.  2.  The  settlement 
of  this  population  so  as  to  promote  best  the 
development  of  the  colony.  3.  In  consequence, 
the  political  relations  of  the  two  countries.  4. 
The  commercial  relations  of  the  two  countries. 

The  first  two  of  these  are  those  which  relate 
most  closely  to  the  subject  of  colonisation,  the 
others  being  in  part  their  consequence,  and  from 
their  nature  involving  a  consideration  of  general 
administrative  and  commercial  policy. 

The  colonies  were  supplied  with  immigrants 
from  home,  but  these  being  in  general  either 
convicts  or  paupers  (cp.  Wakefield,  Art  oj 
Colonisation,  Letter  xxi.)  were  of  doubtful  ad- 
vantage. In  the  next  place,  the  new  popula- 
tion, enticed  by  the  offer  of  free  grants  of  land, 
spread  themselves  over  a  larger  surface  than 
they  had  capital   to  cultivate.     In  1829   the 


334 


COLONIES:   SYSTEMS  OF  COLONISATION— COLQUHOUN 


system  of  free  grants  was  opposed  by  Edward 
Gibbon  Wakefield  {Letter  from  Sydney,  by  R. 
Gouger)  and  in  1830  the  Colonisation  Society 
was  formed.  Its  members  attacked  the  system 
of  transportation,  and  their  accusations  were 
confirmed  by  the  report  of  the  select  committee 
in  1838,  soon  followed  by  the  cessation  of 
transportation. 

Meantime  the  efforts  of  "Wakefield  were  con- 
centrated on  the  second  of  the  two  questions. 
Labour  was  needed  on  the  land.  It  must  be 
restrained  from  undue  diffusion.  "When  the 
need  of  labour  had  been  felt  at  a  much  earlier 
date  in  the  American  colonies  it  had  been  met, 
in  the  southern  states  at  least,  by  the  employ- 
ment of  slaves.  This  remedy  was  out  of  the 
question.  Now  "Wakefield  proposed  to  cope 
with  the  matter  by  a  reconstruction  of  the 
system  according  to  which  the  public  lands  were 
disposed  of.  Free  grants  were  to  be  abolished 
and  the  land  to  be  sold  at  a  price  determined 
according  to  the  circumstances  of  the  case.  It 
was  further  proposed  to  apply  the  proceeds  to 
the  promotion  of  immigration,  and  also  to  the 
improvement  of  the  means  of  communication  (cp. 
Eeign  of  Victoria,  vol.  ii.  pp.  405-408).  The 
important  principle  was  that  of  the  sale  of  land 
at  a  sufficient  price.  So  far  as  the  substitution 
of  "sale"  for  "free  grant"  was  concerned,  it  was 
adopted  by  the  instruction  of  1831,  with  refer- 
ence to  Australia  (Grey,  Colonial  Policy,  letter 
vii.),  advocated  in  the  Durham  report  and  given 
fuU  efi'ect  to  by  the  Australian  Land  Act  of  1842. 
But  when  it  was  attempted  to  put  the  plan 
more  fully  into  practice,  a  difficulty  occurred  in 
the  interpretation  of  the  term  "sufficient." 
This  was  shown  in  the  history  of  the  efforts  of 
the  South  Australian  Company  (cp.  "Wakefield, 
Art  of  Colonisation,  letter  ix.  and  also  despatch 
by  Sir  George  Gipps,  Pari.  Papers,  1843,  No. 
323). 

The  efibrts  of  "Wakefield  were  in  fact  directed 
to  the  discovery  of  means  whereby  capital  and 
labour  might  be  introduced  into  the  colony  in 
such  a  manner  and  in  such  proportions  as  to 
lead  to  its  more  stable  development.  For  the 
fullest  accounts  of  his  system,  see  The  Art  of 
Colonisation,  by  E.  G.  "Wakefield  ;  Lectures  on 
Colonisation,  by  Herman  Merivale ;  Colonisation 
avec  les  peuples  modemes,  par  P.  Leroy  Beaulieu. 
The  two  latter  works  are  extremely  critical  in 
nature,  though  perhaps  the  most  searching  criti- 
cism of  all  is  to  be  found  in  the  above-quoted 
despatch  from  Sir  George  Gipps. 

It  remains  to  consider  the  effect  of  colonisa- 
tion on  the  home  country.  Its  condition  may 
be  affected  directly  or  indirectly — directly  by 
the  loss  it  sustains  of  population  and  capital, 
indirectly  by  the  consequences  involved  in  the 
development  of  a  colonial  trade.  The  question 
of  emigration  has  attracted  and  continues  still 
to  attract  a  considerable  amount  of  attention. 
"While  there  must  be  considerable  difference  of 


opinion  as  to  the  benefit  it  confers,  the  three 
following  propositions  may  be  regarded  as  estab- 
lished. 1.  It  cannot  be  a  permanent  safeguard 
against  over-population.  2.  Unless  concurrent 
with  an  increase  of  prudence  in  marriage  and  a 
rise  in  the  standard  of  comfort,  it  can  ameliorate 
but  little  the  condition  of  the  working  classes 
from  whose  number  the  emigrants  are  theoreti- 
cally drawn.  3.  It  is  highly  beneficial  in  reliev- 
ing the  congestion  which  from  many  incidental 
causes  has  taken  place  in  particular  districts. 

The  exportation  of  capital,  implying  as  it 
does  the  employment  of  such  capital  in  circum- 
stances more  favourable  than  would  have  been 
the  case  at  home,  prevents  the  rate  of  interest, 
from  falling.  (For  this  and  for  its  other  effects 
see  Merivale,  Colonisation,  Lecture  vi.) 

The  development  of  the  colonial  trade  which 
involves  the  same  better  distribution  of  energy, 
has  in  consequence  a  beneficial  eff'ect  on  the 
condition  of  the  people  in  the  home  country 
(see  Colonial  Policy). 

[Works  cited  in  text,  and  more  particularly,  H. 
Merivale,  Lectures  on  Colonisation.  —  P.  Leroy 
Beaulieu,  Colonisation  chez  les  peuples  modemes  ; 
Roscher,  Kolonien,  Kolonialpolitik  und  Auswan- 
derung. — Colonel  Torrens,  Colonisation  of  South 
Australia.  ]  *  e.  o.  k.  a. 

COLQUHOUN,  Patrick  (bom  1745,  died 
1820),  lord  provost  of  Glasgow,  police  magis- 
trate in  London,  in  the  course  of  an  active  life 
contributed  to  social  science  some  thirty  publi- 
cations ;  among  which  may  be  distinguished : 
(1)  Treatise  on  the  Police  of  the  Metropolis, 
1795  ;  (2)  Treatise  on  Indigence,  1806  ;  (3) 
Treatise  on  the  Population,  Wealth,  Power, 
and  Resources  of  the  British  Empire  .  .  ., 
1814.  Sir  R.  Giffen,  in  his  Growth  of  Capital 
(p.  101),  utilises  Colquhoun's  estimates  of 
national  wealth  ;  and,  while  admitting  that 
"many  of  his  details  are  fanciful,"  considers 
that  "he  was  most  unjustly  decried  by 
M'CuUoch"  {Ihid.  p.  50).  Colquhoun  himself 
confesses  that  his  statistics  are  not  accurate : 
"all  that  is  attainable  is  approximating  facts," 
he  pleads.  His  general  remarks  are  often 
sound  ;  for  instance,  advocating  savings  banks, 
"The  great  desideratum  in  political  economy 
is  to  lead  the  poor  by  gentle  and  practicable 
means  into  the  way  of  bettering  themselves." 
He  has  just  views  on  the  education  of  the  poor 
{Indigence,  ch.  v.),  and  on  the  growth  of  the 
population  {Wealth,  Power,  and  Resources,  ch. 
i.)  On  currency  he  is  less  happy  (Letters  to 
Dr.  Boase,  Brit.  Mus.  AddU.  MS.,  29,281). 

[In  a  Biographical  Sketch  ...  by  'larp6s 
(Colquhoun's  son-in-law,  Dr.  Yeats)  there  is  a 
catalogue  of  Colquhoun's  publications.  It  does 
not  include  Considerations  on  the  means  o/ 
affording  prqfttaMe  employmemi  to  the  redund- 
ant population  of  Oreai,  Britain  and  Ireland, 
published  anonymously  1818  (Lowndes).] 

F.  Y.  E. 


COLTON— COMBINATION 


335 


COLTON,  Rev.  Calvin,  born  in  Massa- 
Dliusetts  1789,  died  in  Georgia  1857.  At 
first  a  Presbyterian  clergyman,  he  soon  entered 
the  ministry  of  the  Protestant  Episcopal  Church. 
This  he  relinquished  for  journalism,  and  in 
1852  became  professor  of  political  economy  at 
Trinity  College,  Hartford,  Conn.  He  advocated 
very  strongly  the  policy  of  protection  to  home 
industries^  and  was  a  devoted  follower  of  Henry 
Clay.  He  wrote  works  on  travel,  and  on  religious 
and  political  subjects.  Among  his  economic 
works  are  The  Crisis  of  the  Country,  1840. — 
The  Junius  Tracts,  1843-44.— TAe  Rights  of 
Labour,  New  York,  1846,  pp.  96  ;  and  a  more 
extensive  work.  Public  Economy  for  the  United 
States,  New  York,  1848,  pp.  536.  He  edited 
the  works  of  Henry  Clay,  and  in  all  his  economic 
writings  dwells  principally  upon  the  theme  of 
protection.  d.  e..  d. 

COL  WELL,  Stephen,  born  in  Virginia  1800  ; 
entered  on  the  practice  of  law  in  his  native 
state ;  early  removed  to  Pittsburg,  and  re- 
linquished his  profession  to  become  an  iron 
merchant  in  Philadelphia,  where  he  lived  the 
remainder  of  his  life  ;  died  1872.  He  devoted 
much  time  to  the  study  of  political  economy, 
wrote  largely  for  the  periodicals  of  the  day,  and 
associated  himself  with  the  protective  party. 
Among  his  more  extended  writings  may  be  men- 
tioned The  Relative  Position  in  our  Industry  of 
Foreign  Camonerce,  Domestic  Production,  and 
Internal  Trade,  Philadelphia,  1850,  8vo,  pp. 
50  ;  and  an  American  edition  of  Frederick 
List's  National  System  of  Political  Economy, 
Philadelphia,  1856,  pp.  497,  for  which  he  wrote 
a  preliminary  essay,  pp.  Ixxxiv.  His  best 
known  work  is  The  Ways  and  Means  of  Com- 
mercial Payment,  Philadelphia,  1858,  in  which 
he  attempts  a  full  analysis  of  the  credit  system, 
with  its  various  modes  of  adjustment ;  he  argues 
that  a  mistake  has  been  made  in  previous 
analyses  in  not  making  a  radical  distinction 
between  money  of  the  precious  metals  and 
forms  of  credit ;  the  historical  inquiry  into  the 
growth  of  the  credit  system  is  of  considerable 
value,  and  the  whole  work  exhibits  independ- 
ence of  thought  ;  he  did  not  accept  the  view 
that  the  quantity  of  money  is  the  controlling 
factor  in  determining  prices.  His  other  writ- 
ings of  economic  interest  are.  The  Claims  of 
Labour,  and  their  Precedence  to  the  Claims  of 
Free  Trade,  pp.  52,  1861. — Gold,  Banks,  and 
Taxation,  pp.  68,  1864  ;  and  State  and  NatioTial 
Systems  of  Banks,  Expansion  of  the  Currency,  the 
Advance  of  Gold,  and  the  Defects  of  the  Internal 
Revenue  Bill  of  June  1864,  8vo,  1864.  At 
the  close  of  the  civil  war  in  1865  he  was  ap- 
pointed a  member  of  the  revenue  commission, 
and  in  1866  made  a  valuable  report  on  taxa- 
tion. In  this  document  Colwell's  special  reports 
are  upon  The  Influence  of  Duplication  of  Taxes 
upon  American  Industry ;  upon  Relations  of 
Foreign  Trade  to  Domestic  Industry  and  Internal 


Revenue  ;  upon  Iron  and  Steel ;  and  upon  TFool 
and  Woollens.  He  also  elsewhere  made  reports 
upon  High  Prices  and  their  Relations  with  Cur- 
rency and  Taxation,  1866. — Over -Importations 
and  Relief,  1866. — Financial  Suggestions  and 
Remarks,  1867,  pp.  19.  See  if emoir  by  Henry 
C.  Carey,  Philadelphia,  1871,  pp.  35,  in  which 
(p.  32)  will  be  found  a  list  of  writings,  thirty- 
two  in  number.  d.  e.  d. 

COMBINATION.  Combinations  for  the 
purpose  of  controlling  the  production,  exchange, 
and  distribution  of  wealth,  have  assumed  so 
many  forms  that  it  is  only  possible  here  to  give 
an  outline  of  the  subject^ — the  reader  being 
referred  to  other  pages  for  a  detailed  examin- 
ation of  each  class. 

I.  Production.  Some  forms  of  wealth  can 
only  be  produced  by  the  assistance  of  large 
capital,  and  in  some  industries  production  on 
a  large  scale  is  distinctly  economical  (Mill's 
Polit.  Econ.,  bk.  i.  ch.  ix.)  Hence  capitalists 
have  united  in  various  combinations  recognised 
by  law : — 

(1)  Partnership.  Where  two  or  more  persons 
agree  to  combine  property,  labour,  or  skiU  in 
business,  and  to  share  the  profits  between  them. 

(2)  Company.  Where  a  number  of  persons 
are  incorporated  into  a  company  either  under 
act  of  parliament  or  by  charter  from  the  crown, 
the  liability  of  members  being  either  limited 
or  unlimited  (see  Companies). 

Combinations  of  producers  have  also  been 
formed  with  the  object  of  controlling  the  pro- 
duction of  some  one  or  more  commodities  so  as 
to  secure  if  possible  a  monopoly  of  production. 
The  following  types  of  this  method  may  be 
mentioned : — 

(1)  Pools.  Where  a  joint  committee  of  dele- 
gates from  several  producing  establishments 
control  the  production  (see  Pools). 

(2)  Syndicates.  Where  one  firm  or  company 
agrees  to  take  all  the  produce  of  other  firms  in 
the  same  business  at  fixed  prices :  the  amount 
of  the  produce  being  often  limited  by  agreement. 
The  copper  syndicate  formed  by  the  Soci6t6 
Industrielle  et  Commerciale  des  Mdtaux  de  Paris 
is  the  most  famous  of  this  class. 

(3)  Trusts.  Where  the  stockholders  in 
several  corporations  transfer  their  shares  to 
trustees,  who  become  registered  in  their  places 
as  owners  of  the  stock  and  so  obtain  complete 
control  of  the  management.  Usually  the  share- 
holders receive  ti-ust  certificates  in  exchange  for 
their  shares.  The  complete  legality  of  such  a 
proceeding  has  been  maintained  (Polit.  Sci, 
Quarterly,  Dec.  1888),  but  in  at  least  one 
American  case  it  has  been  held  that  a  corpor- 
ation whose  members  enter  into  such  a  trust 
forfeits  its  corporate  character  (see  Trusts). 

Companies  are  sometimes  formed  with  the 
object  of  establishing  a  monopoly  of  production, 
by  buying  up  the  business  of  all  persona 
engaged  in  the  trade.       The  Salt  Union  which 


336 


COMBINATION— COMBINATION  LAWS 


has  purchased  many  of  the  salt  properties  in 
England  and  Ireland  is  an  example  of  this  class. 
Various  forms  of  combinations  are  found  to 
exist  between  sellers  and  buyers  : — 

(1)  Wholesale  firms  are  frequently  bound  by 
agreement  with  their  customers  (retail  dealers) 
not  to  sell  except  to  retail  firms. 

(2)  Distributors  or  intermediate  dealers,  often 
combine  to  buy  at  a  low  price  from  producers 
and  to  sell  at  a  high  price  to  consumers.  The 
milk  exchange  of  New  York  bought  milk  at 
two  to  three  and  a  half  cents  per  quart  and 
sold  it  as  high  as  seven  or  ten  cents. 

(3)  Combinations  or  agreements  between 
seller  and  buyer  that  the  latter  will  sell  again 
only  at  a  certain  price  are  very  numerous  in 
America,  though  such  agreements  have  been 
declared  illegal. 

In  a  separate  class  may  be  placed  the  com- 
binations entered  into  by  carrying  companies 
either  to  secure  if  possible  a  monopoly  of  trafiic 
or  to  prevent  competition  by  agreeing  on  a 
scale  of  rates  and  charges. 

[For  examples  of  these  various  forms  of  com- 
binations see  Report  of  Committee  of  State  of 
New  York  upon  Trusts,  1888. — Report  of  Com- 
mittee of  Canadian  House  of  Commons  on  Com- 
binations regarding  manufactVA-e  or  sale  of  Pro- 
ducts, 1888. — Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics, 
1889,  Boston,  vol.  iii.  No.  2. — Political  Science 
Quarterly,  1888.  New  York,  vol.  iii.  Nos.  2,  3.— 
Sidgwick,  Polit.  Econ.,  bk.  iii.  oh.  x.,  and  Marshall, 
Principles  of  Economics,  bk.  v.  ch.  viii.,  discuss 
the  theoretic  aspects  of  monopolies. — Cournot's 
treatment  of  the  abstract  theory  of  monopoly 
{Recherches,  ch.  v.  Du  Monopole)  has  influenced 
most  subsequent  writers.  Much  light  is  thrown 
both  on  the  theory  and  facts  of  the  subject  by  the 
following:  Hadley,  Railway  Transportation. — C. 
W.  Baker,  Monopolies  and  the  People.] 

II.  Distribution.  In  all  the  leading  indus- 
tries the  employers  and  the  employed  have 
formed  their  respective  associations  for  the  pro- 
tection of  their  own  interests.  The  terms  upon 
which  the  labourer  is  to  give  his  services  are 
not  arranged  by  him  and  his  employer  individu- 
ally, but  by  the  respective  associations  to  which 
they  belong.  Mill,  regarding  wages  as  paid  out 
of  capital,  did  not  think  that  combinations  of 
working  men  could  raise  wages  without  adding 
to  capital ;  but  more  recent  economists  look  on 
wages  as  a  share  of  the  produce,  and  admit  that 
by  combination  wages  may  be  raised  (Sidgwick's 
Polit.  Econ.,  bk.  ii.  ch.  x.  ;  Marshall's  Econ- 
omics of  Industry,  London,  1879  ;  and  The 
Principles  of  Economics,  1891  ;  Walker  on 
JFages.     See  Trade  Unions). 

Combinations  on  the  part  of  labourers  to 
obtain  higher  wages  or  shorter  hours  of  labour 
are  not  illegal,  but  it  seems  that  a  combination 
of  tenants  to  obtain  a  reduction  of  rent  may, 
under  certain  circumstances,  amount  to  an  illegal 


conspiracy. 

III.  Prodttction  and  Distribution. 


In 


order  to  avoid  the  conflicts  that  arise  between 
employers  and  employed  difierent  forms  of  "  pro- 
fit sharing  "  have  been  tried  (see  Co-partner- 
ship, App.),  the  employer  agreeing  to  handover 
to  the  workers,  in  addition  to  their  wages,  a 
share  of  the  profits  (see  Profit  Sharing). 

IV.  Distribution  and  Consumption.  In 
order  to  secure  to  consumers  the  profits  made 
by  producers,  various  forms  of  co-operation  have 
been  introduced  in.  which  the  capital  is  sub- 
scribed by  the  consumers.  This  idea  has  been 
specially  successful  in  saving  to  the  consumer  the  _i 
profits  of  the  retail  dealer  by  the  establishment 
of  co-operative  stores,  and  there  is  a  growing 
tendency  to  apply  the  same  principle  to  actual 
production  (see  Co-operation).       j.  e.  c.  m. 

COMBINATION  LAWS.  The  object  of  the 
series  of  statutes  known  as  the  combination 
laws  was  to  enforce  the  provisions  of  the  statutes 
of  labourers  of  Edw.  III.  and  of  Elizabeth  which 
authorised  the  justices  in  quarter  sessions  to 
fix  wages.  One  of  the  first  acts,  3  Hen.  VI. 
c.  1,  after  reciting  that  the  yearly  confeder- 
acies of  the  masons  tended  to  destroy  the  force 
of  the  statutes  of  labourers,  enacted  that  such 
meetings  should  not  be  held  under  pain  of  im  ■ 
prisonment.  In  1548  a  more  general  statute 
was  passed » (2  &  3  Ed.  VI.  c.  15)  which  pro- 
hibited all  conspiracies  and  covenants  not  to 
make  or  do  their  work  but  at  a  certain  price, 
under  penalty,  on  a  third  conviction,  of  the 
pillory  and  loss  of  an  ear.  In  subsequent  years 
the  following  acts  relating  to  particular  trades 
were  passed  prohibiting  combinations  for  rais- 
ing wages  or  reducing  the  hours  of  labour  in 
the  trade,  viz.  7  Geo.  I.  c.  13  (journeymen 
tailors)  ;  12  Geo.  I.  c.  34  (wool  trade)  ;  22  Geo. 
II.  c.  27  (hatters)  ;  17  Geo.  III.  c.  55  (sHk 
weavers)  ;  and  36  Geo.  III.  c.  Ill  (paper  trade). 

In  1799  a  general  act  was  passed,  but  it  was 
repealed  and  replaced  in  the  following  year  by 
40  Geo.  III.  c.  60,  which  prohibited  all  com- 
binations for  obtaining  an  advance  in  wages  oi 
lessening  the  hours  of  work.  This  act,  pays 
Mr.  Justice  Stephen  (History  of  the  CHmvnal 
Law  of  England,  London,  1883,  vol.  iii.  p. 
208),  "applies  in  the  most  detailed,  specific, 
uncompromising  way  the  principle  upon  which 
all  the  earlier  legislation  had  depended.  ...  I 
should  not  describe  it  as  a  system  specially 
adapted  and  designed  to  protect  freedom  of 
trade.  The  only  freedom  for  which  it  seems 
to  me  to  have  been  specially  solicitous  is  the 
freedom  of  the  employers  from  coercion  by 
their  men." 

The  first  attempt  to  modify  this  system  of 
legislation  was  the  5  Geo.  IV.  c.  95,  which 
repealed  all  the  previous  statutes  so  far  as  they 
related  to  combinations  of  workmen,  and  declared 
that  persons  joining  combinations  of  workmen 
for  obtaining  an  advance  in  wages  or  lessening 
the  hours  of  labour,  or  for  other  specified  pur- 
poses, should  not  be  liable  to  any  prosecution  foi 


COMBINATION  LAWS— COMFORT 


337 


conspiracy.  The  act  was  considered  to  have  en- 
couraged combinations  for  obj  ectionable  purposes, 
and  in  the  following  year  (1825)  it  was  repealed 
and  replaced  by  the  6  Geo.  IV.  c.  129.  This 
new  act,  whilst  it  repealed  the  previous  statutes, 
did  not  in  express  terms  legalise  combinations 
of  workmen — the  legality  of  such  combinations 
was  left  to  be  dealt  with  by  the  common  law — 
it  simply  rendered  men  liable  to  punishment 
for  the  use  of  threats,  intimidation,  molestation, 
and  obstruction  directed  towards  the  attainment 
of  the  objects  of  trade  unions.  A  few  altera- 
tions in  the  act  were  made  by  22  Vict.  c.  34. 
The  recommendations  of  the  royal  commission 
of  1867  on  trade  unions  led  to  the  repeal  of 
the  6  Geo,  IV.  c.  129,  and  the  22  Vict.  c.  34, 
by  the  38  &  39  Vict.  c.  31,  and  the  38  &  39 
Vict.  c.  32,  which  declared  that  the  purposes 
of  a  trade  union  were  not  to  be  deemed  un- 
lawful by  reason  merely  that  they  were  in  restraint 
of  trade,  and  carefully  defined  what  acts  should 
be  deemed  criminal  oflFences.  The  protection 
afforded  by  these  acts  was  greatly  diminished 
by  the  gi-adual  extension  of  the  common  law 
docti'ine  of  conspiracy,  and  at  length,  in  1875, 
the  act  was  repealed  and  replaced  by  the  Con- 
spiracy and  Protection  Act,  38  &  39  Vict.  c.  86 
(CoNSPiiiACY  ;  Common  Law,  Doctrine  of). 

[The  followiug  writings  set  forth  the  sequence 
and  import  of  these  laws  :  G.  Howell,  Handbook 
of  the  Labour  Laws. — Jevons,  State  in  Relation  to 
Labour. — J.  E.  Davis,  Labour  and  Labour  Laws. 
— Report  on  Strikes  and  Lockouts  of  1888  by  the 
Labour  Correspondent  of  the  Board  of  Trade, 
Parliamentary  Papers,  1889,  C  5809.] 

J.  E.  c.  M. 

COMFORT,  Standard  of.  This  expression, 
together  with  the  synonymous  "  standard  of 
living,"  has  been  generally  employed  by 
economists  in  connection  with  the  question  of 
Population  (g'.u)  Among  the  "preventive 
remedies "  of  over-population  described  by 
Malthus  (g'.v.)  in  his  essay  is  included 
"moral  restraint,"  and  this  is  defined  (ch.  ii.) 
as  a  **  restraint  from  marriage  from  prudential 
motives."  By  this  is  meant  the  fear  of  los- 
ing, as  the  consequence  of  entering  upon  the 
responsibilities  of  the  married  state,  the  com- 
mand of  adequate  means  of  subsistence.  The 
means,  which  will  be  regarded  as  adequate,  will 
vary  according  to  the  conception  formed  by  the 
individual,  or  the  class  to  which  he  or  she 
belongs,  of  the  elements  which  make  up  sub- 
sistence ;  and  it  is  this  conception  which  is 
implied  in  the  tenn  **  standard  of  comfort,"  or 
*'  standard  of  living."  It  may,  therefore,  vary 
from  age  to  age,  from  country  to  country,  from 
class  to  class,  and  even  fi*om  individual  to 
individual.  The  term  may  be  analysed  in 
different  ways.  We  may  regard  the  constitu- 
ent elements  of  subsistence  as  consisting  of 
(1)  food,  (2)  clothes,  (3)  shelter,  etc. ;  or  we 
may,    using    a    cross-division,    consider    with 

VOL.  L 


Senior  {Political  Economy,  p.  36)  that  the 
range  of  man's  desires  rises  in  an  ascending 
scale  from  (1)  necessaries  to  (2)  decencies  and 
(3)  luxuries.  And  hence  the  term  has  some- 
times been  employed  in  a  narrower,  and 
sometimes  in  a  wider  sense.  In  an  earlier  and 
less  advanced  stage  of  civilisation  the  proportion 
assigned  to  the  element  of  necessaries  in  the 
conception  formed  by  classes  and  by  individuals 
of  their  standard  of  comfort  is  greater  than  it 
is  at  a  later  stage,  and  among  these  necessaries 
the  supply  of  food  is  accorded  the  most  pro- 
minent place.  And  therefore  the  question  of 
population  has  very  generally  been  considered 
either  solely  or  chiefly  with  reference  to  food, 
and  it  has  also  been  argued  by  M'^Cullocii 
and  others  that  the  habitual  use  of  a  cheap 
staple  article  of  food  by  a  nation  may  lead  to 
inconvenience  and  danger,  because  in  the  event  of 
a  scarcity  or  famine  of  that  food,  there  would 
be  no  cheaper  food  on  which  to  fall  back,  and 
the  standard  of  comfort  would  not  permit  of 
temporary  contraction.  It  has  been  said  that 
' '  you  may  take  from  an  Englishman,  but  you 
cannot  take  from  an  Irishman."  If  a  famine 
of  wheat  should  occur,  the  Englishman  could 
fall  back  on  some  cheaper  food  ;  but  experience 
has  shown  more  than  once  that  the  Irishman  has 
nothing  on  which  to  fall  back  if  tlie  potato 
fails.  But  General  Walker  lias  pointed  out 
(  Wages  Question,  ch.  vii. )  that,  so  far  as  regards 
the  temporary  contraction  of  the  standard  of 
comfort,  this  argument  does  not  appear  to  take 
suflicient  account  of  the  fact  that  there  are  other 
constituent  elements  of  the  standard  besides 
food,  and  that  therefore  the  habitual  use  of  a 
cheap  food  may  allow  of  greater  expenditure  in 
other  directions,  which  may  be  curtailed,  should 
food  become  scarce,  and  its  price  advance.  A 
similar  failure  to  realise  the  elastic  comprehen- 
siveness of  the  term  "  standard  of  comfort "  has 
been  shown  (cp.  Sidgwick,  Principles  of  Political 
Economy,  bk.  i.  ch.  vi.  §  3)  to  attach  to 
another  line  of  reasoning  in  wliich  it  has  been 
introduced.  Modern  socialist  writers  (see 
Socialism),  such  as  Rodbertus  and  Lassalle, 
have  spoken  of  an  ''iron  and  cruel  law"  of  wages, 
which  is  always  forcing  wages  down  to  the  level 
of  a  bare  subsistence.  For,  if  they  rise  above 
this  level,  there  is  a  tendency  to  an  increase 
of  population,  and  the  greater  competition  for 
employment,  which  is  consequent  upon  this, 
tends  in  its  turn  to  occasion  a  decline  of  wages. 
This  law  is  undoubtedly  based  on  the  concep- 
tion of  a  standard  of  living  or  comfort,  which 
will  be  maintained  in  such  a  way  that,  if  the 
earnings  of  man  and  woman  rise  above  the 
amount  sufficient  to  secure  this  standard,  popu- 
lation will  increase,  and,  if  they  fall  below,  it 
will  decrease.  But  the  conception  is  often, 
though  it  is  not  always,  interpreted  by  socialist 
writers  in  a  narrow  sense  as  referring  to  the 
bare  necessaries  of  life,  and  not  more  widely  as 

z 


338 


COMFORT— COMMERCE 


including  its  decencies  and  luxuries.  It  is  used 
as  if  the  standard  of  comfort  were  limited  to 
physical  needs,  and  did  not  comprehend  moral 
requirements.  As  a  matter  of  fact  it  consists 
of  the  necessaries,  decencies,  and  luxuries  of 
life  ;  and  the  desire  to  retain  command  over  the 
possession  of  the  two  last  may  become  more 
powerful  even  than  the  want  of  the  first  as 
a  restraint  on  the  increase  of  population.  The 
nature  of  all  three  may  undergo  considerable 
change  and  exhibit  great  variety.  The  house, 
which  would  now  be  a  decency  in  England, 
would  have  been  thought  a  luxury  two  or  three 
centuries  ago.  The  clothes,  which  would  be 
deemed  extravagant  to-day,  except  in  theatrical 
performances,  would  then  have  been  considered 
necessary  articles  of  apparel.  The  tobacco, 
which  is  regarded  as  a  decency  in  Turkey,  is 
still  perhaps  a  luxury  in  England,  and  the  wine, 
which  is  a  decency  in  England,  is  a  prohibited 
luxury  in  Turkey.  And  so  the  standard  of 
comfort  varies  in  different  ages,  countries,  and 
classes  ;  and  in  the  case  of  the  lower  as  of  the 
higher  ranks  of  society  it  may  advance  from 
time  to  time.  The  origin  of  the  socialist  law 
of  wages  has  been  ascribed  to  Ricardo's  {q.v.) 
theory  of  the  natural  price  of  labour,  but 
Ricardo's  own  language  is  sufficiently  elastic 
and  comprehensive.  "It  is  not  to  be  under- 
stood," he  says  (ch.  v.)  "that  the  natural  price 
of  labour,  estimated  even  in  food  and  necessaries, 
is  absolutely  fixed  and  constant.  It  varies  at 
different  times  in  the  same  country,  and  very 
materially  differs  in  different  countries.  It 
essentially  depends  on  the  habits  and  customs 
of  the  people."  And  again  he  remarks,  "The 
friends  of  humanity  cannot  but  wish  that  in  all 
countries  the  labouring  classes  should  have  a 
taste  for  comforts  and  enjoyments,  and  that  they 
should  be  stimulated  by  all  legal  means  in  their 
exertions  to  procure  them."  The  effects  of  the 
standard  of  comfort  on  the  movement  of  popu- 
lation are  of  course  not  immediate  ;  and  the 
consequences  of  an  alteration  in  it  take  some 
time  to  make  their  influence  felt.  And  hence 
J.  S.  MiU  has  argued  (bk.  ii.  ch.  xiii.  §  4)  that, 
"when  the  object  is  to  raise  the  permanent 
condition  of  a  people,  small  means  do  not 
merely  produce  small  effects,  they  produce  no 
effect  at  all.  Unless  comfort  can  be  made  as 
habitual  to  a  whole  generation  as  indigence  is 
now,  nothing  is  accomplished."  In  a  similar 
way  General  Walker  has  shown  {Wages 
QiLcstion,  ch.  iv.)  that,  if  through  some  sudden 
mischance  wages  sustain  a  serious  fall,  a  positive 
"  degradation  "  of  labour  may  follow,  and  the 
labourer  may  have  no  power  or  strength  to 
maintain  his  old  standard  of  comfort  without 
external  assistance. 

It  should  be  noted  that  some  ambiguity 
may  arise  regarding  the  unit  selected  for  con- 
sideration in  connection  with  the  standard  of 
comfort.     The   term   may  sometimes   refer  to 


a  single  individual,  whether  male  or  female, 
and  sometimes  to  a  family  as  a  whole.  In 
the  discussion  of  questions  of  population  the 
conditions,  which  are  necessary  in  order  to 
maintain  the  requisite  supply  of  labour,  are 
generally  present  to  the  mind  of  the  writer ;  and 
then  the  standard  of  comfort  must  be  under- 
stood as  referring  to  the  family  as  the  unit 
rather  than  the  individual,  for  the  wages  of  the 
labourers  must  be  such  as  to  enable  them  to  live 
themselves,  and  to  maintain  their  wives,  and 
bring  up  their  children,  according  to  the 
standard  of  comfort,  which  they  consider 
necessary  for  a  family  in  their  rank  of  life. 
But  the  earnings  possibly  of  the  wife,  and 
possibly  also  of  the  children,  may  be  called  in  to 
assist  those  of  the  man,  and  so  from  the  point 
of  view  both  of  income  and  expenditure  the 
family  is  treated  as  the  unit.  There  are 
however,  other  cases  in  which  shorter  periods 
of  time  are  in  view  than  those  sufficient  to  allow 
of  the  standard  of  comfort  producing  its  full 
influence  on  the  movement  of  population,  and 
then  the  term  is  often  employed  with  reference 
to  the  individual  rather  than  the  family.  An 
example  of  this  may  be  found  in  the  comparison 
made  between  the  earnings  of  men  and  of 
women  (cp.  Females  and  Children,  Earnings 
OF  ;  see  also  Davies,  D.) 

In  addition  to  the  books  mentioned  above, 
some  typical  budgets  of  working  men,  showing 
the  chief  items  of  their  expenditure,  and  the 
proportionate  amounts  spent  on  the  different 
items,  have  been  compiled  abroad,  especially  by 
Dr.  Engel  and  M.  Le  Play,  and  more  recently 
in  our  own  country  by  the  Board  of  Trade. 

L.  L.  p. 

COMMANDITE,  Sooi^fix^  en.  Form  of 
joint  stock  company.  Code  de  Commerce,  liv.  i. 
tit.  iii.  §§  23-28.  The  managing  partners  are 
liable  without  limit ;  the  investing  partners  are 
regarded  as  simple  lenders  to  the  undertaking, 
and  their  liability  is  limited  to  their  investment. 
Something  equivalent  (joint -stock  company 
limited,  the  liability  of  whose  directors  is  un- 
limited) is  legalised  by  the  Companies  Act 
1867,  §§  4-8  ;  and  it  would  appear  desirable  in 
the  interests  of  careful  management  that  in- 
vestors should  encourage  the  adoption  of  this 
form  of  joint-stock  company.  a.  d. 

COMMERCE.  Trade  in  its  most  extended 
form.  "Commerce"  and  "trade"  are  words 
which  are  used  almost  synonymously.  But 
commerce  may  be  regarded  as  national,  that  is  as 
covering  commercial  dealings  between  nations  ; 
and  trade  refers  more  distinctly  to  special  in- 
dustries and  to  internal  mercantile  intercourse. 
It  will  therefore  be  proper,  keeping  to  the 
limits  thus  set  down,  to  furnish  under  the  head 
of  commerce  a  summary  of  the  external  com- 
mercial relations  of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland, 
of  her  colonies,  and  finally  of  the  world.  The 
figures,  as  we  shaU  see,  are  not  only  interestmg 


COMMERCE 


339 


in  themselves,  but  will  serve  to  illustrate  some 
economic  truths  as  an  appeal  to  actual  fact 
alone  is  able  to  do.  It  is  marvellous  how  the 
commerce  of  the  world  may  almost  be  said  to 
be  the  creation  of  the  past  hundred  years. 
The  close  of  the  twenty-five  years  of  war  that 
followed  the  French  Revolution  found  the 
external  commerce  of  the  world  mainly  confined 
to  luxuries,  wines  and  spirits,  tobacco,  tea,  and 
so  on — the  rigidly  protective  policy  of  the  lead- 
ing nations  of  the  earth,  added  to  their  hostility, 
keeping  down  the  national  interchanges  to  high- 
priced  goods  only. 

In  1820,  five  years  after  the  overthrow  of 
the  first  Napoleon,  the  imports  and  exports 
combined  (they  were  then  "official  values," 
not  "declared  values"  as  we  have  them  now) 
(Official  ;  Declared  and  Real  Values)  of 
the  United  Kingdom  were  only  £79,500,000,  or 
only  about  £3  :  15s.  per  head  of  the  population 
then  existing,  whereas  in  1912  they  reached 
£1,344,000,000,  or  £29  :  3  :  8  per  head.  Dur- 
ing the  same  period  the  commercial  intercourse 
between  Great  Britain  and  her  colonies  has 
been  almost  wholly  created,  and  amongst 
foreign  countries  the  movement  is  upon  the 
average  very  considerable.  Steam  carriage,  the 
freedom  from  protracted  wars,  the  growth  of 
population,  colonisation,  and  electricity  have 
been  the  main  elements  in  that  development  of 
commerce.  In  1854  the  "official  values  "  were 
discarded  in  the  imports  for  computed  values  and 
in  the  exports  for  declared  values,  and  from  1871 
the  values  of  the  imports  have  also  been  declared. 
The  following  figures  give  the  imports  and 
exports  at  intervals  since  1855  : — 


Year. 

Imports. 

Exports.                         1 

United 
Kingdom. 

United 
Kingdom 
Produce. 

Foreign, 

etc., 
Produce. 

Total 
Exports. 

1855 
1800 
1870 
1880 
1885 
1887 
1890 
1908 
1912 

&l/,3,5/,Z,850 
210,530,873 
303,257,/,93 
/,11,229,565 
370,967,955 
362,227,56/, 
1^20,885,695 
592,953,/t87 
7l,k,6U0,631 

£95,688,085 
135,891,227 
199,586,822 
223,060,446 
213,044,500 
221,414,186 
263,531,585 
377,103,824 
487,223,439 

£21,003,215 
28,630,124 
44,493,755 
63,354,020 
58,359,194 
59,348,975 
64,349,091 
79,623,697 

111,737,691 

£116,691,300 
164,521,851 
244,134,73s 
286,414,466 
271,403,694 
2S0,7C3,lta 
327,880,676 
456,727,521 
598,961,130 

The  highest  cash  value  of  the  imports  was 
in  1912,  when  they  reached  £744,641,000,  and 
the  highest  value  of  the  exports  was  also  in 
1912,  when  the  total  was  £598,961,000.  The 
increase  indicated  up  to  1872  has  since  in  a 
measure  fallen  off",  and  it  was  not  till  1899 
that  great  progress  was  again  recorded.  Since 
that  date  the  progress  has  continued.  But  it 
is  well  worthy  of  remark  that  these  are  values 
only,  and  in  nowise  show  the  volume  of 
merchandise  moved.  Now  there  have  latterly 
been  compiled  many  statistics  to  show  that  the 
prices  of  commodities  have  largely  fallen  since 
1872,  when  measured  by  a  gold  standard  ;  and 
the  tabular  statistics  supplied  by  Sir  R.  H. 


Inglis  Palgrave  to  the  Royal  Commission  on 
the  Depression  in  Trade  in  1886  are  conclusive 
on  this  point.  It  was  therein  shown  that,  as 
compared  with  1865-69,  prices  in  1885  fell,  on 
average,  20  per  cent,  and  as  compared  with 
1872  the  drop  was  30  per  cent.  From  this 
drop  no  important  recovery  has  occurred  up  to 
quite  recently  (1912).  Hence  it  appears  that 
this  country's  Foreign  commerce  is  in  bulk  about 
30  per  cent  larger  than  in  1872.  Indirectly 
the  shipping  tonnage  entered  and  cleared  with 
cargoes  only  at  the  ports  of  the  United  Kingdom 
is  an  illustration  of  this  expansion. 


Ports  of  United  Kingdom. 

Entered. 

Cleared. 

In  1872 

Tons. 

17,905,940 
76,191,000 

Tons. 

19,248,352 
76,266,000 

In  1912 

Thus  it  is  right  to  assume  that  notwithstanding 
that  values  are,  as  already  stated,  not  as  high  as 
might  liave  been  expected  owing  to  depreciation 
in  prices,  the  actual  commercial  intercourse  of 
the  United  Kingdom  has  largely  increased. 

In  1912,  36  per  cent  of  the  imports  consisted 
of  food  and  drink,  35  per  cent  of  raw  materials 
and  articles  mainly  unmanufactured  (of  which 
49  per  cent  was  for  textile  manufacture),  24 
per  cent  of  manufactured  goods,  2  per  cent  of 
metals  and  minerals,  1-|  per  cent  of  chemicals 
and  dyeing  materials,  leaving  1^  per  cent  to 
be  classed  as  miscellaneous  goods,  including 
tobacco.  In  the  same  year,  of  the  United 
Kingdom  exports,  as  much  as  38  per  cent 
consisted  of  textiles,  including  yarns,  21  per 
cent  of  metals  and  machinery,  8  per  cent  of 
coal,  3  per  cent  of  apparel,  6  per  cent  of  food 
and  drink,  4  per  cent  of  chemicals,  etc.,  1  per 
cent  of  earthenware,  china  and  glass,  |  per  cent 
of  paper,  over  1  per  cent  of  leather,  nearly  1 
per  cent  of  arms  and  ammunition,  etc.,  nearly 
2  per  cent  of  ships,  and  2  per  cent  of  rail- 
way carriages,  motor  cars,  carts,  etc.,  leaving 
12  per  cent  of  miscellaneous  exports.  These 
are  the  returns  for  1912,  excluding  precious 
metals.  In  the  same  year  the  imports  of 
gold  reached  £52,688,881,  and  the  exports 
£46,538,469,  while  the  imports  of  silver  were 
£16,778,304,  and  the  exports  £18,333,019. 
Combined  with  the  former,  the  following  con- 
trast is  presented  : — 


United  Kingdom,  1912. 

Imports. 

Exports. 

Merchandise        

£744,640,000 
69,467,000 

£814,107,000 

£598,961,000 
64,871,000 

£663,832,000 
150,275,000 

£814,107,000 

Precious  metals  

Excess  of  imports  

This  excess  of  imports  is  a  very  striking  feature, 
and  it  continues.  In  1900  the  excess  was  over 
£176,000,000;  in  1890,  over  £101, 000,000;  in 


340 


COMMERCE 


1880,  £121,000,000  ;  in  1870,  £69,000,000. 
How  can  this  constant  influx,  averaging  over 
£130, 000, 000  annually  since  1880,  be  accounted 
for  ?  The  figures  fui-nished  officially  are  ad- 
mittedly defective  on  some  points.  The  imports 
of  precious  stones  are  to  a  large  extent  want- 
ing ;  exports  of  ships  are  included  in  1899  and 
subsequently,  but  not  before.  It  is  probable 
that  if  we  added  £10,000,000  on  each  side  for 
missing  items,  we  should  be  within  the  mark. 
But  this  does  not  help  us  to  an  answer  to  the 
question,  How  is  the  discrepancy  between  our 
imports  and  exports  to  be  accounted  for  ?  In 
the  first  place,  these  imports  are  valued  plus 
the  charges  for  shipment  to  our  ports,  while  the 
exports  are  returned  minus  those  charges.  Let 
us  take  9  per  cent  as  this  addition  to  the  exports 
(the  reason  of  this  rate  will  appear  later)  as 
representing  the  earnings  of  British  shipping 
engaged  in  this  commerce  ;  and  add  another 
4  per  cent  for  the  earnings  of  British  shipping 
carrying  goods  wholly  for  foreign  countries  or 
our  colonies,  s,nd  a  total  of  some  £72,000,000 
results,  wliich  may  fairly  be  set  towards  filling 
up  this  discrepancy.  There  still  remains  much 
to  be  accounted  for.  The  interest  remitted 
home  for  investments  abroad  supplies  in  great 
measure  the  solution.  An  estimate  in  the 
Bankers'  Magazine  of  1880  of  the  amount  of 
interest  accruing  annually  upon  British  invest- 
ments abroad,  reached  a  total  of  £70,000,000 
aterling.  The  income  from  abroad  has  since 
increased  ;  some  foreign  holdings  may  be 
smaller  but  colonial  are  certainly  larger,  and 
the  estimate  for  1911-12  in  the  Keport  of  the 
Inland  Revenue  is  over  £103,894,000.  The 
following  rough  balance-sheet  may,  therefore, 
be  made  respecting  the  commercial  relations  of 
the  United  Kingdom  in  1912  : — 

Liabilities. 

Imports  (as  stated)    £814,000,000 

„       (not  stated) 10,000,000 

DiflFerence  may,  between  the  foregoing 
amount  and  that  stated  per  contra, 
possibly  be  an  increase  in  foreign  in- 
vestments        40,000,000 

£864,000,000 

Assets. 

Exports  (as  stated)   £664,000,000 

„        (not  stated) 10,000,000 

Earnings  of  British  shipping 86,000,000 

Interest  on  foreign  investments   104,000,000 

£864,000,000 


This  is  to  be  understood  only  as  a  rough 
approximation  ;  it  shows,  however,  that  but  for 
a  further  investment  of  capital  abroad  the 
country  would  have  had  the  call  of  a  still  larger 
volume  of  imports. 

The  commerce  of  the  British  Empire  may 
thus  be  stated,  the  figures  including  the  precious 
metals,  which  in  some  colonies  may  to  a  large 
extent  be  ranked  as  merchandise. 


Imports. 

Exports.        ( 

1912. 

1912.           I 

United  Kingdom 

£814,364,000 

£664,143,000 

Asiatic  Possessions 

209,636,000 

235,183,000 

Australasian  „ 

88,075,000 

100,267,000 

African          ,, 

59,088,000 

77,659,000 

N.  American ,, 

117,723,000 

67,277,000 

S.  American  ,, 

2,900,000 

3,639,000 

W.  Indian      ,. 

11,211,000 

9,952,000 

European       „ 

2,616,000 

988,000 

£1,805,613,000 

£1,159,108,000 

If  to  this  total  be  added  the  return  of  the 
remaining  countries  of  the  world,  we  obtain  the 
following  grand  total : — 


Imports. 

Exports. 

British  Empire .... 
Europe 

£1,805,613,000 
1,952,082,000 
208,851,000 
196,916,000 
535,386,000 
112,428,000 

£1,159,108,000 
1,599,659,000 
150,292,000 
177,501,000 
681,525,000 
112,871,000 

Russia  and  Turkey 
Asia 

America      . ,   ... 

World's  Commerce 

£4,310,266,000 

£3,980,456,000 

These  figures  are  the  latest  returns  available, 
though  not  all  for  the  same  year,  and  it  will  be 
seen  that  the  exports  grew  to  the  extent  of 
£829,810,000  in  value  by  the  time  they  became 
imports.  T^his  difference  was  equal  to  over  8 
per  cent  on  the  exports,  or  to  nearly  4  per  cent 
on  the  combined  total  of  imports  and  exports. 
In  this  way  we  arrive  at  some  notion  of  the 
earnings  and  profitableness  of  commerce,  and 
the  worth  and  value  of  the  world's  shipping 
industry.  Thus  the  world  invariably  appears 
to  import  more  than  it  exports,  and  it  is  far  from 
indicating  any  loss  of  purchasing  power  that 
there  should  be  this  discrepancy  between  imports 
and  exports.  Taking  the  population  concerned 
as  1,623,000,000,  this  trade  represents  imports 
per  head  to  the  extent  of  £2  :  13  : 1,  and  exports 
to  the  extent  of  £2  :  9s.  per  annum.  These 
averages,  however,  are  reduced  by  the  vast 
populations  of  Asiatic  countries  like  China, 
where  the  imports  are  not  quite  3s.  per  head 
and  the  exports  but  little  over  2s.  In  Europe 
(apart  from  Russia  and  Turkey  and  the  British 
Isles)  the  imports  average  nearly  £8  per  head, 
and  the  exports  about  £6  ;  in  America  (North 
and  South,  excluding  Canada)  imports  are 
nearly  £4,  and  exports  nearly  £5  per  head. 

The  exports  from  Australia  to  Great  Britain 
average  some  £8  per  head  of  the  population  of 
the  Colony  ;  from  New  Zealand,  over  £14  per 
head  ;  from  the  South  African  Union,  over  £8 
per  head  ;  from  Canada,  over  £4  per  head. 

[The  theory  of  excess  of  imports  is  well  stated  by 
Sir  R.  Giflfen  in  Essays  on  Finance,  There  is  a  full 
enumeration  of  the  exports  other  than  commodities, 
"  invisible  exports,"  by  which  imports  are  balanced 
in  Bastable's  International  Trade ;  the  heads  of 
British  commerce  are  given  by  Sir  Rawson  Rawson. 
His  statement  of  the  growth  of  tonnage  and  the 
conclusions  built  on  it  are  striking  (see  also 
Goschen,  Foreign  Exchanges).     For  further  details 


COMMEEGE,  BRITISH 


341 


see  the  Statistical  Abstract  and  the  Parliamentary 
Papers  relating  to  trade  and  commerce,  passim.] 

COMMERCE,  British  (History  of).  The 
earliest  trade  of  the  British  Isles  consisted  in 
the  exchange  of  tin  with  the  Gauls,  and  perhaps 
also  with  Phoenician  traders. 

Under  Roman  rule  the  agricultural  and 
mineral  resources  of  Britain  were  more  fully 
developed.  Corn  was  exported  in  large  quanti- 
ties. Tin,  copper,  lead,  and  iron  were  extracted, 
but  there  is  little  evidence  that  these  articles 
were  exported.  London,  as  a  centre  of  com- 
merce, dates  at  least  from  Roman  times  (Tac. 
Ann.  xiv.  33).  It  was  certainly  the  principal 
port  for  trading  with  Gaul. 

The  English  conquest  which  swept  away  the 
remams  of  the  system  established  by  Roman 
administrators,  broke  off  active  commercial  rela- 
tions with  the  continent ;  even  the  materials 
for  any  notice  of  commerce  during  the  early 
Anglo-Saxon  period  are  wanting.  Towards  the 
end  of  the  8th  century  traces  of  a  revival  appear — 
due  to  the  influence  of  the  Christian  Church. 
The  letter  of  protection  for  English  pilgi-ims 
given  to  Offa  of  Mercia  by  Charlemagne  (796), 
which  refers  to  trade  carried  on  by  them,  has 
even  been  called  "the  first  English  commercial 
treaty."  There  is  no  evidence  as  to  the  com- 
modities exported,  but  it  may  be  inferred  that 
raw  wool  had  now  become  a  leading  article  of 
trade  to  the  Netherlands.  Commerce  was 
mainly  in  the  hands  of  foreigners.  The 
settlement  of  German  merchants,  which  after- 
wards became  the  London  Hanse  (see  Adven- 
ruRERs,  Merchant),  existed  tejnp.  EtheLred  II. 
(979-1016),  and  some  aliens  were  probably 
resident  before  that  reign.  The  often-quoted 
law  of  Athelstane  (925-40),  that  a  merchant 
who  had  made  three  sea- voyages  should  be  of 
right  a  thane,  is  a  proof  of  the  small  number 
as  weU  as  of  the  importance  of  such  native 
traders.  There  is  evidence  that  Bristol  was  the 
seat  of  a  considerable  trade  in  slaves  with  the 
Danish  settlements  in  Ireland.  The  constant 
intercourse  between  England  and  Normandy 
also  restored  in  some  degree  the  older  trade  with 
northern  France. 

The  "Colloquies"  of  .ffilfric  (11th  century) 
tell  us  what  the  commodities  imported  were. 
A  merchant  being  asked  what  he  brings,  replies, 
"skins,  silks,  costly  gems  and  gold,  various 
garments,  pigments,  wine,  oil,  ivory,  orichalcum 
(brass),  copper,  tin,  silver,  glass,  and  such  like," 
hence  it  appears  that  articles  of  luxury  were 
the  principal  imports.  During  the  whole 
Old  English  period  commerce  was  little  de- 
veloped (see  City,  Medieval).  The  so-called 
Anglo-Saxon  "laws"  bear  the  impress  of  this 
state  of  things.  Beyond  a  few  trite  rules  no 
commercial  policy  is  discernible.  The  customs 
of  a  town  regulate  trade  in  it.  There  is  no 
general  commercial  law.  Any  settled  and 
definite}  policy  as  "mercantilism"  or  "protec- 


tion" is  not  to  be  expected.  At  most,  the 
rules  bearing  on  the  subject  reflect  the  eco- 
nomic prejudices  current  among  the  classes 
who  had  the  framing  of  law  and  usage  in  their 
hands. 

The  commercial  position  of  England  in  the 
12th  century  is  better  known.  Tlie  communi- 
cation -^vith  Normandy  increased  by  the  Con- 
quest (1066).  In  the  middle  of  the  century 
mention  is  made  of  the  import  of  silver  in  ex- 
change for  meat,  fish,  cattle,  and  wool,  all 
being  sent  to  the  manufactm-ing  districts  of  the 
low  countries.  The  vigorous  rule  of  Henry  II. 
(1154-1189)  assisted  the  revival  of  trade.  His 
possession  of  Guienne  gave  new  opportunities 
for  traflic  in  import  of  wine  and  salt  thence. 
Rouen  was  particularly  favoured,  being  granted 
a  monopoly  of  trade  with  Ireland,  and  freedom 
of  commerce  in  London.  The  foundations  of 
the  future  prosperity  of  many  English  towns  were 
now  laid.  London  was  the  scat  of  trade  in  such 
Eastern  luxuries  as  were  then  becoming  known 
through  the  influence  of  the  Crusades  (see  Crus- 
ades, Economic  effects  of).  Bristol  and 
Chester  had  whatever  Irish  trade  existed,  and 
both  these  towns  imported  French  wines.  Hull 
was  one  of  the  ports  whence  avooI  went  abroad, 
and  the  trade  with  Norway  was  carried  on  through 
Grimsby.  Exeter  exported  the  tin  of  Cornwall, 
obtaining  wine  and  salt  in  return.  A  further 
proof  of  the  growth  of  the  English  towns  i8 
found  in  the  establishment,  in  most  of  them,  of 
.Merchant  Guilds  (see  Gilds).  Corn  was  some- 
times exported,  but  not  without  a  royal  licence 
(as  in  1181,  see  Corn  Lav^^s).  A  particular 
import — woad  used  for  dyeing — seems  to  show 
that  a  native  woollen  manufacture  existed, 
though  all  finer  cloth  came  from  Flanders. 

The  development  of  commerce  from  the 
reign  of  Henry  III.  (1216)  can  be  traced  by 
the  attempts  at  legislation  scattered  through 
the  early  parts  of  the  statute-book.  The  in- 
creased number  of  foreign  merchants  in  England 
is  a  good  indication  of  larger  trade  relations. 
The  provisions  of  the  great  Charter,  securing 
them  liberty  in  time  of  peace  and  reciprocity  oi 
treatment  in  war,  must  have  been  called  forth 
by  the  importance  of  their  interests.  Many 
cases  of  special  privileges  occur ;  as  those 
gi-anted  to  Venetian  merchants  and  to  German 
cities  ;  first,  to  Cologne,  the  principal  town  of 
western  Germany,  later  to  Liibeck,  chief  city  of 
the  eastern  Hanse.  French  cities  (e.g.  Amiens, 
1237)  also  obtained  special  favours,  mainly 
consisting  in  relaxation  of  restraints  on  trade 
imposed  by  customs  and  ordinances  of  English 
towns.  All  legislation  was  not  so  generous  in 
character.  The  export  of  wool  and  import  of 
cloth  were  prohibited  1261  ;  "prohibitions  re- 
peated 1271."  In  1275  foreigners  were  ordered 
fco  sell  their  goods  and  depart  within  forty 
days,  probably  to  hinder  Forestallers  (q.v.) 
Much  indeed  of  mediaeval  legislation  was  in  the 


342 


COMMERCE,  BRITISH 


interest  of  tli(3  consumer  rather  than,  as  in  later 
times,  of  the  producer. 

Besides  the  general  effect  on  commerce  pro- 
duced by  the  policy  and  constitutional  legisla- 
tion of  Edward  I.,  he  dealt  in  some  cases  directly 
with  matters  affecting  trade.  The  Statute  of 
Merchants  (1283)  gave  greater  security  to  foreign 
as  well  as  native  traders  for  recovery  of  debts, 
while  the  Charta  Mercatoria  (ISOd), — which  by 
its  enumeration  of  the  various  nationalities 
affected  shows  the  extent  of  the  body  of  foreign 
traders,  confirmed  and  extended  privileges  which 
aliens  had  gradually  obtained.  Full  security 
was  given  to  all  foreigners  to  come  and  go  free 
from  any  personal  duty  ;  they  were  allowed  to 
sell  by  wholesale  to  any  native  or  alien,  and 
to  retail  spices  and  mercery  ;  any  article  might 
be  exported,  on  paying  the  duty  (except  wine, 
for  which  a  licence  was  required),  to  countries 
at  peace  with  England.  All  restrictions  on 
residence  were  removed,  the  export  of  wool 
on  which  duty  had  once  been  paid  was  legalised. 
It  might  also  be  moved  from  one  part  of  the 
country  to  another  (see  Board  of  Trade). 
In  this  period  there  is  a  close  connection  be- 
tween politics  and  commerce.  Edward  I.  used 
the  English  supply  of  superior  kinds  of  wool  as 
a  means  of  securing  aid  from  the  Flemings. 
According  to  the  requirements  of  the  moment 
its  export  was  either  forbidden,  heavily  taxed, 
or  freely  permitted.  The  first  prohibition 
of  the  export  of  gold  is  found  1307  ;  soon 
afterwards  the  Staple  (q.v.)  comes  into 
notice.  We  cannot  trace  here  the  various 
changes  of  the  system,  but  it  tended  directly 
to  limit  trade  to  the  staple  towns,  and  by 
enabling  the  course  of  every  transaction  to  be 
more  easily  watched,  made  it  possible  to  enforce 
the  statutes  which  forbade  foreigners  to  take 
their  money  out  of  the  kingdom,  or,  in  a  milder 
form,  required  one  half  of  it  to  be  expended  on 
native  commodities. 

The  exports  during  the  13  th  and  14  th  cen- 
turies included  wool,  sent  largely  to  Flanders, 
hides,  tin,  and  fish.  Coal  was  exported  to 
France  from  Newcastle  in  the  14th  century. 
Lead  and  iron  were  also  at  times  exported,  and 
in  good  seasons  corn.  The  imports  comprised 
iron  from  Spain,  linen  and  fine  cloth  from 
Flanders,  wine  and  salt  from  Gascony,  silks, 
fruits,  spices,  and  Greek  wines  brought  by  the 
Italian  fleets,  which,  after  1317,  regularly 
visited  England.  Furs,  pitch,  and  timber 
came  from  the  north  of  Europe  through  the 
traders  of  the  Hanse  towns ;  in  times  of  scarcity 
com  was  imported.  The  trade  with  Bordeaux 
was  very  active,  and  mainly  carried  on  by 
English  ships  from  London,  Bristol,  Dover, 
and  Hull ;  they  took  out  wool,  herrings,  lead, 
copper,  and  tin,  and  pilgrims  as  passengers ;  they 
returned  laden  with  wine  and  wheat.  In  1350, 
141  ships  carried  13,429  tuns  of  wine  from 
Bordeaux  to  England. 


The  difficulty  of  getting  precise  amounts  of  the 
commodities  traded  in  during  the  earlier  periods 
has  led  historians  to  quote  gladly  the  exports 
and  imports  as  given  in  the  custom  accounts  for 
1354.  The  former  comprise  31,651^  sacks 
and  3036  cwt.  of  wool,  sheepskins,  hides, 
4774|-  pieces  of  coarse  cloth,  and  8061^  pieces 
of  worsted,  representing  a  total  value  of 
£212,338  :5s.,  of  which  nearly  £82,000  went 
in  duties.  The  imports  were  1831  pieces  of 
fine  cloth,  397f  cwt.  of  wax,  1829^  tuns  of 
wine,  with  linen,  mercery,  and  grocery,  the 
whole  valued  at  £38,383:16:10,  paying 
nearly  £600  duty.  These  figures,  however, 
though  instructive  as  showing  the  amounts  of 
commerce  in  certain  articles,  and  illustrating 
the  great  predominance  of  export  duties  in  early 
times,  are  yet  very  incomplete,  e.g.  there  is 
no  account  of  the  large  export  of  minerals. 
More  detailed  returns  of  the  customs  of  the 
port  of  London  during  the  14th  century  show 
extraordinary  fluctuations  from  year  to  year. 

The  mechanism  of  commercial  transactions 
became  much  more  refined  during  the  period 
under  consideration.  Though  the  earliest 
dealers  in  money  and  exchange,  the  Jews, 
were  expelled  by  Edward  I.  (1290),  their  place 
was  speedily  taken  by  Italians,  who  supplied 
the  funds  needed  by  the  English  kings  for  their 
French  wars,  and  developed  the  employment  of 
the  Bill  of  Exchange  {q.v.)  Even  in  the  ab- 
sence of  direct  evidence  it  is  probable  that  the 
stringent  regulations  as  to  export  of  money 
were  evaded  by  the  use  of  these  instruments, 
supplemented  by  smuggling,  which  the  small 
size  of  all  the  vessels  employed  in  trade  rendered 
very  easy. 

The  trade  of  Ireland  and  Scotland,  up  to  the 
end  of  the  14th  century,  was  not  important. 
Bristol  received  the  raw  produce  of  Ireland, 
principally  com  and  skins  ;  there  was  also 
some  direct  trade  with  Bordeaux.  Scottish 
wool  was  exported  from  Berwick,  and  the 
produce  of  the  fisheries  found  its  way  both  to 
England  and  the  Continent. 

At  the  opening  of  the  15th  century  British 
trade,  in  its  mediaeval  form,  had  attained  a 
high  development,  and  was  increasing  in 
volume.  Italian  merchants  were  accorded  full 
privileges  by  Henry  IV.  (1409),  and  even 
allowed  to  engage  in  the  carrying  trade  con- 
trary to  the  policy  of  the  early  Navigation 
Laws  e.g.  that  of  Richard  II.  (1381).  The 
remarkable  poem  called  a  Libel  of  English 
Policy  (1436)  gives  a  full  account  of  commod- 
ities exchanged  between  the  countries  of 
western  Europe.  Spanish  goods — fruit,  oil, 
soap,  wax,  and  iron — reached  England  by  way 
of  Bruges.  The  Portuguese  trade,  a  direct  one 
supplied  similar  wares  with  the  addition  of 
hides  and  salt.  Of  Italian  traders  the  Genoese 
brought  alum,  spices,  and  gold  to  meet  the 
balance  due  by  them  for  the  export  of  wool  and 


COMMERCE,  BRITISH 


343 


cloth  from  England.  The  Venetians  supplied 
articles  of  luxury  and  were  regarded  with  dis- 
favour as  leading  the  nation  to  engage  in  "un- 
productive" consumption.  Wine  and  salt 
came  from  France,  as  formerly,  but,  in  conse- 
quence of  the  continual  wars,  through  Brittany, 
then  practically  independent.  Trade  with 
Flanders  consisted  in  the  exchange  of  raw 
materials  for  manufactures,  but  the  growth  of 
a  feeling  in  favour  of  native  industry  is  shown 
by  the  writer,  who  advocates  a  decided  national 
policy,  holding  that  England  by  her  power 
over  the  supply  of  raw  wool,  and  by  her  posses- 
sion of  Calais,  which  gave  her  command  of  the 
Channel,  could  compel  Spain  and  the  Nether- 
lands to  support  her  against  France. 

One  of  the  best  indications  of  the  growth  of 
commerce  is  the  increasing  number  of  wealthy 
native  merchants.  Though  some  are  mentioned 
in  the  13th  century,  and  the  names  of  De  la 
Pole  and  Whittington  were  remarkable  in  the 
14th,  it  is  not  till  the  15th  century  that 
they  become  numerous, — at  London,  Cotton, 
Smith,  and  BuUayn ;  at  Hull  Taverner  is  noticed 
as  trading  with  Italy  and  enjoying  special 
freedom  by  royal  licence  ;  Thornton  at  New- 
castle ;  the  Jays,  Sturmy,  and  notably  the 
Cannynges  at  Bristol.  William  Cannynge  the 
younger  is  said  to  have  had  one  ship  of  900 
tons,  and  to  have  employed  800  men  and  ten 
ships  with  an  aggregate  tonnage  of  2853  tons. 

In  the  15th  century  the  society  of  Adven- 
turers, Merchant  {q.v.)  was  first  chartered 
(1406),  though  a  greater  antiquity  is  claimed 
for  it.  This  body,  trading  with  the  Nether- 
lands, Germany,  and  the  Baltic  coast,  interfered 
with  the  previous  monopoly  of  the  Teutonic 
Hanse,  which,  however,  still  retained  its  privi- 
leges and  factory  at  London.  The  fact  that  the 
Hanse  trade  supplied  much  needed  and  desired 
commodities — timber  for  ships  and  bows,  iron, 
flax,  and  hemp,  besides  furs  and  Rhenish  wine 
— ^undoubtedly  led  to  this  favour. 

Another  noteworthy  feature  is  the  increased 
number  of  Commercial  Treaties  {q.v.)  stipu- 
lating for  reciprocal  concessions  to  subjects  of 
the  contracting  parties.  Engagements  of  this 
kind  were  formed  with  Venice,  the  Hanse  towns, 
Brittany,  Castile,  the  Netherlands,  and  Den- 
mark, the  most  remarkable  being  those  of 
Utrecht  with  the  Hanse  in  1474,  and  the 
Intercursus  Magmus  (1496)  which  reopened  the 
Netherlands  trade  after  a  suspension  of  two 


The  prejudice  against  foreign  traders  became 
very  strong  during  the  latter  part  of  this 
century,  and  was  still  more  intense  in  the  next. 
English  commerce  had  reached  a  turning-point ; 
instead  of  simply  supplying  other  countries  with 
raw  materials  and  taking  in  exchange  finished 
articles,  it  was  sought  to  preserve  the  home 
market  for  native  produce  and  to  place  the 
carrying  trade,  so  far  as  English  Imports  and 


exports  were  concerned,  in  the  hands  of  English 
merchants.  The  woollen  manufacture,  which 
had  always  existed  in  a  rude  form  and  had  been 
improved  by  Flemish  immigi'ants  in  the  12th 
and  14th  centuries,  was  now  in  a  position  to 
export  the  coarser  kinds  of  cloth.  The  com- 
mercial history  of  the  time  is  powerfully  affected 
by  a  movement  towards  what  would  now  be 
called  ' '  protection. "  Not  to  mention  jnany  minor 
acts  dealing  with  special  cases,  there  is  the 
well-known  statute  of  1463  (3  Ed.  IV.  c.  iv.) 
prohibiting,  by  enumeration,  the  import  of 
almost  all  wrought  goods,  "that  the  English 
artificers  may  have  employment "  ;  and  though 
the  statute  was  limited  to  the  king's  reign,  it 
was  in  fact  re-enacted  in  that  of  Richard  III., 
and  regarded  so  late  as  the  18  th  century  as 
"the  wisest  piece  of  commercial  legislation." 
The  ideas  of  aiding  the  defence  of  the  kingdom, 
as  in  the  laws  of  1408  and  1483,  requiring  the 
import  of  bowstaves  by  the  Veiietian  traders, 
and  of  securing  an  abundance  of  commodities 
specially  needed  for  the  welfare  of  the  people, 
were  still  prominent  in  the  minds  of  statesmen. 

These  tendencies  of  English  commercial  policy 
were  supported  by  changes  in  the  outside  world. 
The  fall  of  the  Greek  empire  (1453)  and  the 
later  conquest  of  Egypt  (1517),  involving  the 
decline  of  Italian  commerce,  altered  the  balance 
of  commercial  as  of  political  power.  The  con- 
solidation of  the  French  and  Spanish  monarchies 
changed  the  older  lines  of  English  trade  with 
those  countries,  and  the  opening  up  of  the  New 
World  of  America  and  India  had  a  still  greater 
effect.  The  trade  with  the  Mediterranean, 
formerly  in  the  hands  of  the  Italians,  was  now 
so  important  as  to  lead  to  the  appointment  of  a 
consul  at  Pisa,  1485  (confirmed  1490),  and 
after  the  discovery  of  the  Cape  passage  to  India 
(1497),  English  trade  with  Portugal  rapidly 
increased.  The  Guinea  traffic  was  opened  1530, 
the  North  Sea  voyage  to  Russia  discovered 
1553.  The  Levant  commerce  commenced  1550, 
the  first  Levant  or  Turkey  Company  {q.v.) 
was  chartered  1581.  Ten  years  later  the  first 
voyage  to  India  was  made,  and  1600  the  founda- 
tion of  the  East  India  Companies  {q.v.) 
was  laid. 

The  movement  of  English  commerce  is  shown 
by  the  average  amounts  of  imports  and  exports 
during  the  reign  of  Henry  VIII.,  which  fairly 
represent  the  first  half  of  the  16th  century ; 
as  estimated  by  Schanz,  they  are  as  follows  : — 
Imports,  10,060  tuns  of  wine  ;  3028  cwt.  wax, 
making  with  other  imports  a  total  real  value  of 
£402,092,  but  officially  estimated  at  £284,360. 
Exports,  98,132  pieces  of  cloth  ;  5785  sacks  of 
wool;  14,056  hides;  4387  pieces  of  worsted; 
8931  cwt.  of  tin,  with  other  exports  giving  a 
total  estimated  value  of  £427,830,  officially 
stated  at  £293,287.  Comparing  these  figures 
with  the  returns  for  1354  given  above,  the 
growth  of  the  woollen  industry  is  evident— uv 


344 


COMMERCE,  BRITISH 


stead  of  unwrought  wool  it  is  cloth  that  is 
exported.  Even  in  Flemish  markets  English 
competition  was  beginning  to  be  felt  during 
the  15th  century,  while  the  wider  field  that 
the  Italian  and  Levant  trade  offered  proved  a 
further  encouragement.  The  development  of 
English  export  trade  was  aided  by  the  monetary 
revolution  of  the  16th  century.  For  a  thousand 
years  there,  had  been  no  considerable  addition 
to  the  amount  of  money  in  circulation,  which  at 
times  had  been  even  reduced.  England  had 
kept  up  its  stock  of  money  by  trade  with  Flanders 
and  the  Italian  cities,  but  the  discovery  of  the 
mines  of  Mexico  and  Peru  led  to  a  continuous 
flow  of  bullion  through  Spain  to  the  commercial 
centres  of  the  Low  Countries,  where  the  rapid 
rise  in  prices  stimulated  the  already -growing 
import  of  English  products,  since  there  was  no 
rise  of  prices  in  England  till  1670.  The  revolt 
of  the  Netherlands  gave  a  further  opportunity 
to  English  traders.  The  capture  of  Antwerp 
(1585)  was  a  severe  blow  to  its  trade,  most  of 
which  passed  to  Amsterdam  and  London,  which 
during  the  preceding  eighty  years  had  been 
gradually  gaining  at  the  expense  of  other 
English  ports.  A  large  body  of  Flemish 
weavers  emigrated  to  the  eastern  counties  and 
increased  the  power  of  that  district  to  produce 
for  export.  The  closing  of  the  London  settle- 
ment of  the  Hanse  (decreed  1552,  finally  carried 
out  1598),  removing  as  it  did  the  last  trace  of 
a  time  when  the  commerce  of  England  was  con- 
ducted by  foreigners,  is  a  significant  mark  of 
the  opening  of  a  new  period. 

The  17th  century  is  pre-eminently  the  period 
of  the  Mercantile  System  {q.v.)  The  tend- 
encies which  had  been  shown  under  the  Tudors, 
and  even  earlier,  to  advance  native  industries  by 
excluding  foreign  rivalry,  now  took  the  direction 
of  encouraging  exports,  more  especially  of  imi- 
tating the  commercial  development  of  Holland 
by  securing  markets  and  the  Carrying  Trade 
{q.v.)  The  commerce  of  this  period  was  mainly 
carried  on  by  companies,  either  joint  stock  or 
regulated,  possessing  in  some  cases  monopolies  of 
commerce  with  particular  countries — the  East 
India  Companies  of  eastern  traffic,  the  Merchant 
Adventurers  of  the  German  trade.  There  was  a 
steady  advance  in  business  transacted,  as  the 
following  short  table  proves. 


Year. 

Imports. 

Exports. 

Total. 

1613 

£2,141,151 

£2,487,435 

U,628,586 

1622 

2,619,315 

2,320,436 

U,9S9,751 

1662 

4,016,019 

2,022,812 

6,038,831 

1669 

4,196,139 

2,063,274 

6,259,m 

1699 

5,640,506 

6,788,166 

12,1^8,672 

1703 

4,526,579 

6,644,103 

11,170,682 

Making  due  allowance  for  errors  in  the  returns 
for  each  year,  taken  as  they  are  from  different 
sources,  the  general  fact  of  increasing  commer- 
cial relations  is  plain.  In  addition  to  older 
lines  of  traffic,   all  still  open,  there  was  the 


East  India  trade  at  the  commencement  of  the 
century,  and  later  the  important  trade  to  the 
American  "Plantations."  At  first  the  energy 
and  superior  resources  of  the  Dutch  enabled 
them  to  secure  the  greater  part  of  the  additional 
commerce  of  Europe.  The  pamphlet  writers  of 
the  period  are  agreed  on  the  point,  and  they 
are  probably  correct.  Notwithstanding  this 
relative  inferiority,  the  commerce  of  England 
was  certainly  prospering.  The  woollen  industry, 
now  established  as  the  leading  manufacture, 
was  increasing  its  export.  Indian  trade  replaced 
the  older  commerce  with  Italy  in  supplying 
Eastern  products,  but  the  trade  with  the  Medi- 
terranean, now  carried  on  by  the  Levant  Com- 
pany, retained  much  of  its  importance.  Sugar, 
tobacco,  and  such  rude  products  as  timber 
and  hides,  were  imported  from  the  American 
colonies  in  large  quantities.  In  spite  of  national 
jealousy  and  wars,  the  direct  trade  with  Holland 
was  large ;  English  goods  being  stored  at  Amster- 
dam to  be  reshipped  in  the  cheaper  Dutch  vessels. 
The  Navigation  Laws  (see  Navigation  Acts), 
sought  to  destroy  the  advantage  of  these  rivals, 
and  are  generally  held  to  have  so  far  succeeded. 
A  further  instance  of  the  same  spirit  is  found  in 
the  complete  prohibition  of  French  goods  (1678); 
and,  though^the  measure  expired  at  the  death  of 
Charles  II.,  it  was  practically  re-enacted  after 
the  Revolution.  In  other  respects  the  policy  of 
protection  was  developed,  the  export  duty  on 
wool  replaced  by  a  prohibition,  and  various 
foreign  products,  which  might  compete  with  Eng- 
lish goods  were  either  excluded  or  heavily  taxed. 
Trade  with  Ireland  and  the  colonies  was  sub- 
jected to  restrictions  with  the  double  object  of 
securing  a  market  for  home  manufactures  and 
a  cheap  supply  of  raw  materials  for  native 
workers.  In  another  direction,  however,  com- 
merce was  freed  from  restraint.  The  privileges 
of  the  companies  were  closely  questioned  and 
the  monopoly  of  the  Merchant  Adventurers  was 
removed.  The  old  *  *  Statutes  of  Employment, " 
prescribing  the  expenditure  of  money  within  the 
country,  became  obsolete,  and  the  export  of 
buUion  was  legalised  (1663),  a  reform  in  which 
the  advocates  of  the  East  India  Company  took  a 
prominent  part,  since  this  trade  was  carried  on 
by  the  export  of  silver  to  the  East,  where  it 
was  specially  prized. 

By  the  end  of  the  century  the  exports  to 
Holland  had  probably  reached  their  highest 
point.  In  1703  they  amounted  to  £2,417,890 
(i.e.  over  36  per  cent  of  the  total),  more  than 
half  (£1, 339, 526)  being  woollen  goods.  Trade 
with  France  was  only  possible  by  means  of 
smuggling  ;  the  Methuen  treaty  with  Portugal 
(1703)  being  expressly  designed  to  give  the 
wines  of  that  country  an  advantage  over  com- 
petitors, of  which  the  chief  was  France.  The 
attempt  to  negotiate  an  Anglo-French  com- 
mercial treaty  (1714)  was  a  failure,  and  the 
privileges  given  to  England  by  the  treaty  of 


/ 


COMMERCE,  BRITISH 


345 


Utrecht  (1713)  caused  a  development  of  the 
South  Sea  trade,  ending  in  the  terrible  crisis 
of  1720-21.  During  the  first  half  of  the 
18th  century  the  most  noteworthy  feature  of 
commerce  was  the  growth  of  colonial  trade. 
In  1704  the  combined  imports  and  exports  in 
the  ''colony"  trade  were  less  than  £1,300,000, 
or  about  one-ninth  of  the  whole.  Between  1760 
and  1770  the  colonial  trade  was  one- third  of  a 
traffic  which  had  doubled  in  amount ;  in  the 
export  trade  the  increased  proportion  was  still 
greater. 

Among  new  articles  of  export  may  be  noticed 
hardware  from  Birmingham  and  Sheffield,  and 
cotton ;  the  latter,  though  steadily  gi'owing,  only 
amounted  in  value  to  about  £200,000  in  1764, 
while  the  export  of  woollen  goods  was  about 
£4,000,000. 

The  period  1750-70  fitly  covers  the  com- 
mencement of  the  economic  movement  which 
has  been  happily  called  the  Industrial  Re- 
volution {q.v.)  A  series  of  inventions  altered 
the  whole  method  of  production,  and  the  im- 
I)rovement  in  transport  made  exchange  easier. 
As  a  consequence  foreign  trade,  in  spite  of  the 
political  hindrances  arising  from  protrac-ted  war, 
increased  at  a  greater  speed.  The  official  values 
of  imports  and  exports  are  not  too  inaccurate  to 
bring  this  out  clearly. 

Imports  and  Exports  at  intervals  often  years  1770-lSlO. 


Year. 

Imports. 

Exports. 

Total. 

1770 
1780 
1790 
1800 
1810 

£11,002,000 

9,95(5,000 

16,398,000 

28,258,000 

39,302,000 

£12,142,000 
11,363,000 
17,636,000 
34,382,000 
48,439,000 

£3S,1U,000 
21,319,000 
3lt,0Sh,000 
62,61,0,000 
87,7U1,000 

The  cotton  industry  shows  the  largest  in- 
crease. In  1790  the  value  exported  was 
£1,662,369  ;  1800  it  reached  £5,406,501  ; 
1810,  £18,951,994.  The  woollen  export  ad- 
vanced from  about  £6,000,000  in  1800  to  over 
£9,000,000  in  1815.  There  was  also  an  in- 
crease in  exports  of  hardware,  earthenware,  and 
silks. 

During  this  remarkable  development  there 
was  no  relaxation  of  the  Protective  System. 
An  exception  must,  however,  be  made  for 
the  early  administration  of  the  second  Pitt 
(1784-92),  when  the  customs  laws  were  consoli- 
dated and  the  Eden  treaty  negotiated  with  France 
(see  Commercial  Treaties).  The  break-down 
of  the  colonial  system  by  the  establishment  of 
the  independence  of  the  United  States  did  not 
reduce  the  American  demand  for  English  goods. 
On  the  contrary  the  exports  thither  increased 
from  about  £2,000,000  in  1772  to  £3,500,000 
in  1793  and  £7,000,000  in  1798. 

The  peace  of  1815  may  be  regarded  as  closing 
the  period  of  English  commerce  which  opened 
with  the  I7th  century  ;  since  then  the  modern 
system  of  foreign  trade  has  arisen  (see  Com- 
merce). 


The  great  commercial  development  of  Eng- 
land has  naturally  led  to  the  formation  of 
theories  as  to  the  causes  which  have  produced 
it.  The  principal  are :  (1)  The  mercantile 
theory,  predominant  in  the  writers  of  the  l7th 
and  first  half  of  the  18  th  centuries,  which  ex- 
plains the  growth  of  English  commerce  by 
reference  to  the  wise  regulations  and  restrictions 
imposed  by  the  state.  (2)  The  view  of  Adam 
Smith  and  the  English  economists  which 
ascribes  the  supremacy  of  England  to  its  compar- 
ative freedom  from  restraints.  (3)  The  doctrine 
of  List  who  regards  the  present  gi'catness  of 
English  industry  and  commerce  as  largely  due 
to  the  advantages  given  by  the  earlier  system 
of  regulation  and  restraint.  The  influence  of 
this  theory  may  be  traced  in  most  recent  works 
on  economic  history. 

[Anderson,  Historical  and  Chronological  Deduc- 
tion of  the  Origin  of  Commerce,  2  vols,  fol.,  London, 
1764. — Macpherson,  Annals  of  Commerce,  4  vols. 
4to,  London,  1805.  Based  on  Anderson  for  the 
period  1492-1760  ;  the  earlier  part  and  the  conclu- 
sion to  1800  by  Macpherson  solely. — G.  L.  Craik, 
The  History  of  British  Commerce,  3  vols.  l2mo, 
London,  1844.  Compiled  from  preceding. — W.  S. 
Lindsay,  History  of  Merchant  Shipping  and 
Ancient  Commerce,  4  vols.  8vo,  London,  1874-76. 
Notices  of  Commerce  in  vols,  i,  and  ii. — W.  Cun- 
ningham, Growth  of  English  Industry  and  Com- 
merce, 2d  ed.  8vo,  vol.  i.,  Cambridge,  1890. — For  the 
mediaeval  period,  W.  Von  Ochenkowski,  Englands 
Wirthschaftliche  Entwickelung  im  Ausgange  des 
Mittelalters,^^.  168-253,  8vo,  Jena,  1879,  and  W. 
J,  Ashley,  English  Economic  History  and  Theory, 
vol.  i.  pp.  102  seq.  are  useful. — G.  Schauz,  Englische 
Handelspolitik,  2  vols.  8vo,  Leipzig,  1881,  is  a 
thorough  study  of  the  later  mediaeval  period  of 
English  commerce  and  specially  of  the  earlier 
Tudors. — J.  E.  T.  Rogers,  History  of  Agricul- 
ture and  Prices,  6  vols.  8vo,  Oxford,  1866-88, 
devotes  special  chapters  to  foreign  trade  (vol.  i. 
ch.  viii.,  vol.  iv.  ch.  iv.,  vol.  v.  ch.  v.) — Leone 
Levi,  History  of  British  Commerce,  1763-1878,  2d 
ed.  1880,  has  collected  evidence  on  the  growth  of 
commerce  in  the  18th  century. — Hubert  Hall,  A 
History  of  the  Custom  Revenue  of  England,  2  vols. 
8vo,  1885,  illustrates  the  course  and  methods  of  the 
mediasval  trade  of  England. — H.  de  B.  Gibbius, 
History  of  Comvierce  in  Europe,  cr.  8vo,  London, 
1891,  bk.  ii.  ch.  vii.,  bk,  iii.  chs.  iii.  andvi.,  and 
Industrial  History  of  England,  cr.  8vo,  London, 
1890,  period  iv.  ch.  ii.,  gives  a  good  brief  account 
of  the  growth  of  foreign  trade.  For  legislation, 
charters,  and  diplomatic  documents,  the  sources 
are :  The  Statutes  of  Vie  Realm,  9  vols,  folio, 
London,  1810-22,  and  Rymer,  Foedera,  17  vols, 
fol.  London,  1704-1717. 

Among  the  innumerable  pamphlets  on  the  dif- 
ferent aspects  of  English  commerce,  the  following 
give  a  view  of  its  state  at  diflereut  times, — Sir  W. 
Raleigh,  Observations  touching  Trade  and  Com- 
merce with  the  Hollanders,  Works,  vol.  ii.  Lon- 
don, 1751. — J.  R.,  The  Trade's  Increase,  1615. — 
L.  Roberts,  The  Merchant's  Map  of  Commerce, 
1638.— Sir  J.  Child,  A  New  Discourse  of  Trade. 
2d  ed.  1690. — Davenant,  Discourses  on  the  Revemies 


346 


COMMERCIAL  INSTRUMENT— COMMERCIAL  LAW 


and  the  Trade  of  England,  part  ii.  Works,  vol.  i. 
ed.  1771. — De  Foe,  A  Plan  of  the  English  Com- 
merce, 1728.]  c.  F.  B. 

COMMERCIAL  INSTRUMENT.  An  in- 
strument embodying  a  contract  the  benefit  of 
which  passes  to  every  owner  of  the  instrument. 
Where  such  an  instrument  is  by  cufitom 
transferable-  by  delivery,  with  or  without 
indorsement,  and  is  also  capable  of  being  sued 
upon  by  the  person  holding  it  for  the  time 
being,  there  it  is  entitled  to  the  name  of  a 
negotiable  instrument  and  the  property  in  it 
passes  to  a  bond  fide  transferee  for  value,  not- 
withstanding any  defect  in  the  title  of  the 
transferor.  Bills  of  exchange,  cheques,  and 
promissory  notes,  are  generally  negotiable,  but 
if  they  are  payable  to  order  an  endorsement  is 
required  as  well  as  delivery,  if  they  are  payable 
to  bearer  mere  delivery  is  sufficient.  A  hond 
fide  owner  for  value  can  claim  payment  of  such 
an  instrument  if  the  chain  of  indorsements  is 
complete,  though  one  of  the  indorsers  was  not 
entitled  to  negotiate.  A  forged  indorsement 
interrupts  the  chain,  and  a  banker  paying  a 
bill  having  a  forged  indorsement  cannot,  as  a 
general  rule,  debit  the  acceptor  or  the  drawer 
with  the  amount  of  the  biU.  It  is,  however, 
provided,  by  way  of  exception  to  the  rule  just 
stated,  that,  where  a  cheque,  payable  to  order, 
has  been  paid  in  good  faith  and  in  the  ordinary 
course  of  business,  the  banker  is  deemed  to  have 
paid  it  in  due  course,  notwithstanding  any 
forgery  in  the  indorsement  (Bill  of  Exchange 
Act,  §  60).  A  bill  of  exchange,  promissory 
note,  or  cheque  is  not  negotiable  if  it  contains 
words  indicating  an  intention  that  it  should 
not  be  transferable  {Ihid.  §  8,  sub-§  1),  and  it 
ceases  to  be  negotiable  if  its  further  negotiation 
is  prohibited  by  a  restrictive  indorsement  {Ihid. 
§§  37  and  36).  Over-due  bills  are  not  negoti- 
able {Ihid.  §  36,  sub-§  2).  If  a  cheque  is 
crossed  with  the  words  "not  negotiable"  it 
ceases  to  be  a  negotiable  instrument,  but  it 
remains  transferable.  A  person  taking  such  a 
cheque,  though  payable  to  bearer,  cannot  claim 
payment  if  any  of  the  holders  through  whose 
hands  it  has  passed  took  it  without  a  sufficient 
title. 

A  debenture,  though  expressed  to  be  payable 
to  bearer,  is  not  necessarily  a  negotiable  instru- 
ment (Crouch  V.  Credit  Foncier,  Law  Reports, 
8  Queen's  Bench,  374),  but  bonds  or  debentures 
maybe  made  negotiable  by  statute — for  instance, 
a  statute  of  George  III.  made  East  India  Bonds 
negotiable  like  promissory  notes — and  as  pro- 
missory notes  can  now  be  issued  under  seal, 
debentures  must  be  considered  negotiable  if 
they  have  otherwise  the  characteristics  of 
promissory  notes. 

Foreign  government  bonds  payable  to  bearer 
are  generally  considered  negotiable  by  the  law 
of  the  country  in  which  they  are  issued,  and  are 
treated   as   such   by   the   custom  of  bankers. 


brokers,  and  dealers  ;  if  this  is  the  :ase 
negotialsility  is  also  recognised  in  English 
courts  (Gorgier  v.  Mieville,  3  Barnewall,  and 
CressweU  45  ;  Goodwin  v.  Robarts,  1  Appeal 
Cases,  476).  The  same  may  be  said  with 
regard  to  share-certificates  issued  to  bearer  and 
other  similar  securities,  but  where  share- 
certificates  are  not  issued  to  bearer  they  will,  as 
a  general  rule,  not  be  negotiable ;  thus  American 
railway  shares  are  generally  transferred  by  an 
indorsement  appointing  the  indorsee  attorney  to 
effect  the  transfer  in  the  company's  books.  It 
has  become  the  custom  for  registered  share- 
holders of  such  shares  who  wish  to  sell  them  to 
indorse  the  same  in  blank,  and,  according  to 
the  custom  of  the  London  stock  exchange, 
shares  thus  indorsed  in  blank  pass  from  hand 
to  hand,  until  a  buyer  wishes  to  become 
registered  as  owner  of  the  shares.  Shares 
indorsed  in  blank  in  this  manner  are  not 
negotiable,  and  a  hand,  fide  purchaser  for  value 
taking  them  from  a  thief  acquires  no  title 
(Williams  v.  Colonial  Bank,  Law  Reports,  38 
Chancery  Division,  388,  affirmed  by  House  of 
Lords  15  Appeal  Cases,  267). 

Documents  of  title  relating  to  goods  such  as 
bills  of  lading  and  dock  warrants  are  com- 
mercial instruments,  without  being  negotiable 
in  the  strict  sense ;  if  a  document  of  this  nature 
is  stolen,  a  hond  fide  holder  for  value  taking 
from  the  thief  acquires  no  right  to  the  goods  ; 
he  is,  however,  protected  against  vendor's  lien 
and  stoppage  in  transitu.  The  Factors'  Act, 
1889,  provides  that  if  a  mercantile  agent  is, 
with  the  consent  of  the  owner,  in  possession  of 
documents  of  title  to  goods,  any  sale  or  pledge 
of  the  goods  made  by  him  is  valid,  unless  the 
person  taking  under  the  sale  or  pledge  had 
notice  that  it  was  unauthorised  ;  in  the  absence 
of  evidence  to  the  contrary  the  consent  is  to  be 
presumed.  No  such  simple  rule  exists  in  the 
case  of  negotiable  instruments.  Bankers  fre- 
quently make  advances  to  customers  on  the 
security  of  such  instruments,  knowing  that  they 
macy  not  be  the  borrower's  property,  but  assum- 
ing that  he  has  authority  to  pledge  them. 
Where  a  money  dealer  obtained  such  an  ad- 
vance, the  House  of  Lords  held  that  the  banker 
ought  to  have  made  special  inquiries  as  to  the 
extent  of  the  authority  (Earl  Sheffield  v.  Lon- 
don Joint  Stock  Bank,  Law  Reports,  13  Appeal 
Cases,  333),  but  a  similar  decision  of  the  Court 
of  Appeal  in  the  case  of  a  stockbroker  (Law 
Reports  [91]  1  Chancery,  270)  was  overruled  by 
the  House  of  Lords  {Times  newspaper,  5th 
April  1892).  The  question  depends  on  the 
particular  facts  of  each  case.  E.  s. 

COMMERCIAL  LAW.  The  body  of  legal 
rules  that  fall  under  the  phrase  "commercial 
law  "  may  be  divided  into  four  classes.  (1)  In- 
ternational rules  that  govern  the  commercial 
intercourse  of  states.  A  very  considerable  por- 
tion  of  international   law   is   concerned   witb 


COMMERCIAL  LAW— COMMERCIAL  ROUTES 


347 


commerce,  e.g.  the  rights  of  aliens,  the  position 
of  consuls,  freedom  of  navigation,  carriage  of 
contraband  of  war,  breaking  blockades,  and  the 
seizure  of  private  property  by  belligerents.  (2) 
Municipal  laws  of  a  political  nature  affecting 
the  commerce  of  a  state,  such  as  laws  imposing 
restraints  on  or  encouraging  foreign  trade,  laws 
relating  to  conveniences  for  navigation,  laws 
regulating  carriage  by  sea  or  land,  laws  encour- 
aging particular  trades,  and  laws  preventing 
monopolies.  (3)  Municipal  laws  relating  to 
the  private  interests  of  trade  such  as  the  law 
of  contracts  generally,  and  of  special  mercantile 
contracts  in  particular,  including  the  law  relat- 
ing to  the  instruments  of  commerce.  (4)  The 
remedies  to  be  pm-sued  for  injuries  to  commercial 
rights, 

No  attempt  has  as  yet  been  made  by  the 
state  in  England  to  separate  commercial  law 
from  the  general  body  of  the  law,  and  only  one 
text  writer  has  endeavoured  to  do  so  on  any 
adequate  scale  (see  Treatise  on  the  Laws  of  Com- 
merce and  Manufactures  and  the  Contracts  relat- 
ing thereto,  by  J.  Chitty,  London,  1820). 
Several  continental  states,  on  the  other  hand, 
(e.g.  France),  have  also  a  special  commercial 
code  administered  usually  by  special  commercial 
tribunals.  1 

[The  sources  of  commercial  law  may  be  classified 
as  follows  : — 

a.  Roman  law,  which  furnished  to  the  early 
English  judges  many  rules  which  they  aj^plied  to 
personal  property. 

h.  The  maritime  codes  of  the  commercial  com- 
munities of  Europe.  The  most  important  of  these 
codes  were  the  Consolato  del  Mare,  the  Ordinance 
of  Wisby,  the  laws  of  Oleron,  and  the  Ordinance 
of  Louis  XIV.  See  Pardessus,  Collections  des  lois 
viaritimes  anterieures  au  xviile.  siecle,  Paris, 
1828-1845. — Warnkdnig,  Flandrische  staats-und 
Recht-geschichte,  vol.  1. — Gapitula  et  ordinationes 
maritinwe  civitatis  Amalfitana;,  Vienna,  1844. 

c.  The  customs  of  merchants  which  came  to  be 
enforced  if  implied  in  contracts  between  mer- 
chants. 

d.  Statutory  enactments.  The  great  charter 
protected  foreign  traders  ;  bankruptcy  laws  were 
passed  under  Elizabeth ;  monopolies  were  pro- 
hibited and  the  law  relating  thereto  was  settled 
in  the  time  of  James  I. 

e.  The  decisions  of  the  courts.  To  Lord  Chief 
Justices  Holt  and  Mansfield,  and  to  Lord  Stowell 
is  mainly  due  the  development  of  the  principles  of 
commercial  law. 

Treatises  relating  to  early  commercial  law  :  Con- 
suetudo  vel  Lex  Mercatoria,  by  Gerard  Malynes, 
London,  1622. — Lex  Mercatoria,  by  G.  Jacobs, 
London,  1718. — Lex  Mercatoria  Redimva,  by  W. 
Beawes,  London,  1751. 

Modern   treatises :    Smith's    Mercantile    Law, 


1  The  commercial  code  in  France  has  been  considered 
to  have  exercised  a  great  influence  on  traders  by  com- 
pelling attention  to  the  mode  in  which  they  are  conduct- 
ing their  business.  Recent  modifications  may  endanger 
this.    See  Code  Napoleon. 


London,  1890. — 0.  Tudor,  Leading  Cases  on  Mer- 
cantile and  Maritime  Law,  London,  1884.] 

J.  E.  C.  M. 

COMMERCIAL  ROUTES,  History  of. 

A.  Ancieiit  History. — Ancient  commerce  is 
remarkable  for  concentration  ;  it  affected  a 
comparatively  small  portion  of  the  earth's  sur- 
face. The  earliest  peoples  who  rose  to  promin- 
ence and  prosperity,  the  Chinese,  the  Egyptians, 
and  the  Aryan  inhabitants  of  India,  were  mainly 
occupied  in  agriculture  and  domestic  manufac- 
tures. None  of  them  possessed  the  enterprising 
spirit  which  leads  to  external  trade.  The 
Chinese  especially  displayed  that  aversion  to 
intercourse  with  foreigners  which  has  charac- 
terised them  to  the  present  day.  What  trade 
existed  in  early  days  was  conducted  overland. 
The  Arabs  with  their  camels  are  the  earliest 
known  merchants.  Their  caravans  conveyed 
the  most  valued  commodities  between  Egyjit 
and  the  populous  districts  of  Central  Asia  and 
Hindostan. 

The  Phoenicians,  the  advanced  outpost  of  the 
Semitic  race  on  tlie  Mediterranean,  whose  forests 
gave  a  plentiful  supply  of  timber  for  the  con- 
struction of  ships,  made  the  first  attempt  to 
conduct  commercial  enterprise  by  sea.  Under 
the  successive  headships  of  Sidon  and  Tyre,  the 
Phoenicians  undertook  the  trade  between  east 
and  west.  Their  colonies,  originally  commercial 
factories  for  the  collection  of  goods,  gradually 
spread  over  all  the  coasts  of  the  Mediterranean, 
while  Cyprus,  Malta,  and  Sardinia  furnished 
them  with  convenient  harbours  in  the  middle 
of  that  sea.  For  more  than  four  centuries  they 
monopolised  the  maritime  commerce  of  the 
world.  They  collected  and  exchanged  gold  and 
precious  stones  from  Asia,  corn  and  linen  from 
Egypt,  frankincense  and  other  spices  from 
Arabia,  wines  from  Italy  and  Greece,  and  the 
slaves  of  Africa.  Gradually  bolder  traders  over- 
stepped the  limits  of  the  Mediterranean.  In- 
stead of  merely  receiving  eastern  goods  from 
Arab  caravans,  they  crossed  the  isthmus  of 
Suez  and  voyaged  from  the  Red  Sea  to  the  Pers- 
ian Gulf  and  the  coast  of  India.  Westward 
they  passed  the  Pillars  of  Hercules  and  founded 
a  colony  at  Cadiz,  whence  they  journeyed  round 
the  African  coast  as  far  as  the  Canaries,  and 
sought  the  highly-valued  tin  from  the  Tin- 
Islands,  identified  by  some  with  the  Scilly  Isles. 

Few  geographical  discoveries  of  first-rate  im- 
portance were  made  in  ancient  times  after  the 
Phoenicians.  Their  most  notable  rivals  were 
the  Greeks  ;  first  Miletus  and  the  Ionian  cities 
of  Asia  Minor,  and,  after  the  Persian  conquest, 
Athens  and  Corinth.  But  the  Greeks  did 
little  more  than  compete  with  the  Phoenicians 
on  the  old  routes.  Their  colonies  extended 
from  the  ^gean  to  Italy,  Sicily,  and  the  coasts 
of  Africa  and  Gaul.  Their  greatest  traveller, 
Pytheas,  perhaps  penetrated  further  westward 
than  Phoenician  merchants  had  been  before.   The 


348 


COMMERCIAL  ROUTES 


most  notable  achievements  of  Greek  commerce 
were  the  opening  up  of  the  Black  Sea  trade 
and  the  improved  intercourse  with  Central  Asia 
and  India,  which  followed  the  conquests  of 
Alexander.  The  Greeks  succeeded,  however, 
in  distancing  their  older  rivals ;  the  political 
annihilation  of  Tyre  left  the  maintenance  of 
Phoenician  reputation  and  interests  to  its  great- 
est colony,  Carthage.  But  the  Carthaginians, 
though  they  checked  the  advance  of  Greek 
colonisation,  and  almost  monopolised  the  trade 
with  Spain,  were  unable  to  recover  the  eastern 
trade  of  the  mother  city.  Their  maritime 
ascendency  was  almost  wholly  confined  to  the 
western  part  of  the  Mediterranean. 

Carthage  and  Greece  succumbed  in  turn  to 
Rome.  But  the  Romans  never  were  a  mercantile 
people.  Their  original  occupations  were  agri- 
culture and  war,  and  they  learned  no  new  ones. 
Trade  they  always  left  to  foreigners,  as  in  their 
decline  they  entrusted  the  defence  of  the  empire 
to  the  barbarians.  Roman  colonies,  in  contrast 
to  those  of  the  Greeks  and  Phoenicians,  were 
military  strongholds.  The  extension  of  the 
Roman  empire  increased  geographical  knowledge, 
and  facilitated  commercial  intercourse.  The 
growing  population  and  wealth  of  the  capital 
made  the  supply  of  its  wants  a  lucrative  and 
OBcessary  business.  But  Rome  lived  on  the 
spoils  of  the  provinces.  It  could  never  be  a  great 
mart ;  it  had  hardly  any  products  of  its  own  to 
exchange  for  the  imports  which  it  received.  The 
chief  commercial  cities  in  the  Roman  period  were 
Palmyra,  Ephesus,  Alexandria,  in  the  east, 
Marseilles  and  Cadiz  in  the  west.  Maritime 
enterprise  was  checked  rather  than  encouraged 
in  the  Roman  period.  It  was  no  longer  neces- 
sary to  pass  the  straits  of  Gibraltar  when  inter- 
course with  Britain  could  be  conducted  through 
Gaul  and  across  the  Channel.  The  Romans  were 
great  makers  of  roads,  and  overland  trade  became 
more  usual  and  important  than  in  the  days  of 
Phoenician  and  Greek  ascendency.  The  gradual 
disruption  of  the  empire  by  German  invaders 
proved  a  direct  blow  to  commerce,  the  extent 
and  security  of  which  had  been  seriously  dimin- 
ished by  the  5th  century  a.d. 

B.  The  Middle  Ages.—'YYiQ  fall  of  Rome  led 
to  a  separation  between  east  and  west  unknown 
in  earlier  times.  Western  Europe  was  occupied 
for  centuries  with  almost  incessant  wars.  The 
invasion  of  the  Germans  was  followed  by  the 
advance  of  the  Slavs,  who  spread  over  the  whole 
of  northern  Germany,  and  of  the  Huns,  whose 
attack  was  still  more  destructive,  though  ulti- 
mately less  successful.  The  Germans,  who 
succeeded  in  keeping  the  upper  hand  in  the 
west,  were  not  a  town-loving  people.  Like  the 
early  Romans,  they  devoted  themselves  to  arms 
and  agi-iculture.  The  social  system  they  de- 
veloped in  contact  with  Roman  influences  was 
Feudalism  {q.v.),  by  which  the  occupants  of 
the  soil  were  bound  to  render  military  or  agi'i- 


cultural  services,  Nations  were  non-existent ; 
international  trade  unknown.  Maritime  enter- 
prise partook  of  the  prevalent  military  character. 
The  sailors  of  the  early  Middle  Ages  were  the 
hardy  Northmen,  whose  aims  were  plunder  and 
conquest,  not  a  peaceful  exchange  of  commodi- 
ties. The  temporary  union  of  western  Christen* 
dom  under  Charles  the  Great  promised  to  revive 
commercial  intercourse,  but  his  empire  broke 
up  under  his  sons.  Trade  relapsed  again  into 
insignificance. 

Meanwhile  the  East  had  a  separate  life  of  its 
own.  Roman  law  and  traditions  were  pre- 
served at  Constantinople,  which  for  a  time  took 
the  place  of  Rome  as  the  great  receptacle  of  im- 
ported commodities,  Greek  merchants  brought 
thither  the  products  of  Asia  and  Africa  from 
Syria  and  Egypt,  and  those  of  eastern  Europe 
from  the  shores  of  the  Black  Sea.  But  the 
trade  of  Constantinople  suffered  from  the  short- 
sighted regulations  of  an  arbitrary  government, 
and  was  soon  seriously  curtailed  by  Arab  con- 
quests. Under  the  mighty  impulse  given  by 
the  teaching  of  Mohammed,  the  Arabs  reduced 
in  rapid  succession  the  interior  of  Asia,  the 
northern  shores  of  Africa,  and  distant  Spain. 
Everywhere  they  carried  with  them  their  Koran 
and  their  trade.  The  Arabs,  the  earliest,  be- 
came in  the  early  Middle  Ages  the  greatest 
merchants  in  the  then  world.  The  chief  centres 
of  their  trade  were  Mecca,  Bagdad,  Damascus, 
and  Alexandria.  There  they  collected  and  ex- 
changed the  products  of  China,  of  India,  and  of 
northern  Africa.  Arab  ships  traversed  the  Red 
Sea  and  the  Persian  Gulf,  where  their  most 
notable  ports  were  Yemen,  Aden,  and  Basra. 
But  maritime  enterprise  had  been  prohibited  by 
Omar  ;  it  was  never  regarded  with  favour  by 
the  caliphs.  The  chief  routes  of  Arab  commerce 
were  overland ;  their  caravans  journeyed  through 
Central  Asia  and  the  north  of  Africa.  At 
Trebizond  they  collected  the  products  of  the 
Black  Sea  and  eastern  Europe,  and  thus  diverted 
much  of  the  trade  which  would  othenvise  have 
gone  to  Constantinople.  Spain  alone  of  the 
Arab  conquests  was  compelled,  from  its  position, 
to  use  the  sea  as  a  means  of  transit.  For  some 
time  Spanish  Arabs  and  Moors  monopolised  the 
trade  of  the  western  Mediterranean.  Their 
most  important  harbours  were  Cadiz,  Malaga, 
and  Almeria. 

The  Crusades  (v.  Crusades,  Economic  effect  of) 
— the  most  important  event  in  mediaeval  history 
— ^had  the  effect  of  reuniting  the  east  and  west, 
which  had  been  severed  since  the  irruption  of 
the  Germans,  and  of  reviving  the  supreme  mari- 
time importance  of  the  Mediterranean,  Con- 
stantinople declined ;  the  great  Italian  republics, 
— Venice,  Pisa,  and  Genoa, — founded  factories 
in  Greece,  on  the  coasts  of  Syria,  and  the  Black 
Sea.  There  they  collected  oriental  product? 
brought  by  Arab  caravans,  and  thence  conveyed 
them  to  western  Europe.     From  Italy  the  chie/ 


-COMMERCIAL  ROUTES 


349 


commercial  routes  ran  overland  to  southern  Ger- 
many. From  Venice  the  most  frequented  road 
proceeded  by  Verona  and  across  the  Brenner  to 
Ulm,  Augsburg,  and  Ratisbon.  From  Genoa 
and  Pisa  merchants  travelled  to  Lake  Gomo  and 
across  the  St.  Gothard  to  Lucerne  and  Stras- 
burg.  All  the  goods  not  retained  by  the  south 
German  towns  passed  on  to  Bruges,  the  great 
emporium  of  the  Middle  Ages,  where  the  pro- 
ducts of  the  north  were  exchanged  for  those  of 
the  south  and  east.  The  only  serious  com- 
petitors of  the  Italian  towns  for  the  Levant 
trade  were  the  bold  sailors  of  Catalonia,  but 
their  mai'ket  was  limited  to  the  Spanish  king- 
doms and  the  south  of  France. 

The  chief  carriers  of  goods  in  Europe  at  this 
date  were  the  Germans.  While  trade  between 
Italy  and  Flanders  founded  the  prosperity  and 
political  importance  of  the  great  towns  of 
southern  Germany,  their  fellow-countrymen  in 
the  north  found  another  means  of  acquiring 
wealth.  The  famous  Hanseatic  League  {q.v.), 
formed  13th  century,  undertook  the  task  of 
conducting  commerce  between  the  east  and 
west  of  northern  Europe.  Their  leading  towns, 
Liibeck  and  Hamburg,  commanded  the  land 
route  connecting  the  Baltic  with  the  North  Sea. 
The  task  of  defending  their  trade  against  the 
aggressions  of  the  Scandinavian  peoples,  who 
could  block  the  maritime  entrances  to  the 
Baltic,  forced  on  the  north  German  towns  a  unity 
and  an  organisation  to  which  the  less  threatened 
cities  of  the  south  never  attained.  The  chief 
depots  of  the  Hanse  towns  were  at  Novgorod, 
Wisby,  Bergen,  London,  and  Bruges.  At 
Bruges  they  met  the  southern  merchants,  and 
received  from  them  the  products  of  their  native 
industry  and  those  which  they  brought  from 
Italy.  The  nations  who  in  later  times  won 
maritime  supremacy  had  not  yet  turned  their 
attention  to  mercantile  adventure.  England 
was  mainly  an  agricultural  country  ;  its  chief 
product,  wool,  was  exported  to  be  made  up  by 
Flemish  looms.  The  people  of  Holland  and  the 
adjacent  provinces  procured  a  scanty  subsistence 
by  fishing  and  cultivating  the  soil.  France,  not 
yet  emerged  from  the  condition  of  feudalism, 
found  its  energies  absorbed  in  internal  struggles 
and  the  great  war  vath.  England.  Its  oldest 
port,  Marseilles,'  had  lost  the  importance  it  had 
once  possessed,  and  did  not  recover  any  notable 
share  in  the  Mediterranean  trade  till  the 
15th  century. 

C.  Modem  History. — It  is  no  arbitrary  choice 
which  has  fixed  on  the  fall  of  Constantinople  as 
the  dividing  line  between  mediaeval  and  modem 
times.  The  Turkish  conquests  threatened  to 
bring  about  the  same  result  as  had  been  achieved 
by  the  German  migrations  of  the  5th  century — 
to  break  off  once  more  the  connection  between 
Asia  and  western  Europe.  One  after  another 
the  Italian  factories  in  Greece  and  Asia  Minor 
were  taken  and  destroyed.     The  closing  of  the 


Levant  was  not  completed  until  the  conquest  ol 
Egypt  by  Selim  I.  in  1519,  but,  for  seventy 
years  before,  eastern  trade  had  gradually  been 
becoming  more  diflScult  and  precarious.  The 
great  problem  created  by  these  conditions  was 
the  discovery  of  another  route  to  the  east.  It 
is  true  that  the  chief  instrument  of  maritime 
discovery,  the  compass,  had  been  invented  some 
time  before,  and  the  Portuguese  had  already 
commenced  theii*  famous  voyages  along  the 
western  coast  of  Africa.  They  had  discovered 
Madeira  1419,  they  found  the  first  of  the  Azores 
1447,  they  reached  the  Cape  de  Verd  islands 
1456.  But  it  was  the  Turkish  conquests  which 
gave  the  great  impulse  to  maritime  enterprise 
outside  the  Mediterranean.  Bartholomew  Diaz 
commanded,  1486,  an  exploring  expedition, 
which  had  passed  the  mouth  of  the  Congo  when 
a  storm  blew  the  ships  out  to  sea.  "When  calms 
returned  they  steered  westwards ;  at  last,  suspect- 
ing that  they  had  missed  the  southern  point  of 
the  continent,  they  turned  northwards  and 
found  themselves  in  Algoa  Bay.  Compelled  to 
return  by  his  sailors,  Diaz  left  the  completion 
of  his  work  to  Vasco  da  Gama,  who,  starting 
Jidy  1497,  found  his  way  round  the  Cape  of 
Good  Hope  to  India.  The  Portuguese  were  not 
slow  to  profit  by  his  great  discovery  ;  for  nearly 
a  century  they  monopolised  the  trade  between 
India  and  Europe.  The  great  Albuquerque 
made  himself  master  of  the  Red  Sea  and  the 
Persian  Gulf,  and  thus  closed  the  ancient  routes 
to  the  Mediterranean.  He  also  gave  a  capital 
to  the  Portuguese  settlements  by  the  capture  of 
Goa  on  the  Malabar  coast.  The  trade  of  Portu- 
gal soon  extended  to  the  islands  of  the  eastern 
Archipelago,  and  even  to  China  and  Japan. 

Meanwhile,  the  Spaniards  had  also  attempted 
to  solve  the  great  problem  of  the  age,  Christo- 
pher Columbus,  a  Genoese  by  bu'th,  had  con- 
ceived the  scheme  of  reaching  India  by  sailing 
westwards.  Under  the  patronage  of  Isabella  of 
Castile  he  set  out  on  Ids  great  expedition  of 
1492,  which  resulted  in  the  discovery  of  America. 
Ignorant  of  the  existence  of  this  intervening 
continent,  his  contemporaries,  believing  he  had 
really  reached  India,  gave  the  islands  where  he 
first  landed  the  name  of  the  West  Indies,  which 
they  have  kept  ever  since.  Columbus  himself 
believed  that  the  islands  connected  with  Asia 
*'  stretched  out  so  far  to  the  eastward  that  their 
distance  from  Europe  could  not  be  great. "  The 
exact  position  of  America  was  not  appreciated 
until  1513,  when  Balboa  crossed  the  Isthmus 
of  Darien  and  discovered  the  Pacific,  of  which 
he  took  formal  possession  in  the  name  of  the 
Spanish  crown. 

There  is  no  need  to  speak  of  the  further  pro- 
gress of  discovery,  of  the  conquest  of  Mexico 
and  Peru,  of  the  famous  papal  buU  which 
divided  the  world  between  Spain  and  Portugal, 
and  which  enabled  the  latter  to  claim  possession 
of  Brazil  (Bull  of  Borgia,  q.v.)    It  is  sufficient 


350 


COMMERCIAL  ROUTES 


to  point  out  here  that  these  discoveries  revolu- 
tionised the  commercial  routes  of  the  world. 
The  Mediterranean  lost  its  importance,  the 
Italian  cities  were  ruined.  Ti-ade  lost  its  old 
unity  and  concentration,  and  fell  into  the 
hands  of  new  peoples.  The  Portuguese  and 
Spaniards  preserved  the  ascendency  which  their 
precedence  in  the  work  of  discovery  assured 
them.  The  great  routes  of  commerce  ran  to 
the  west  and  to  the  east.  But  the  central 
point  to  which  trade  converged  was  still  the 
Netherlands.  Antwerp,  at  that  time  a  posses- 
sion of  the  Spanish  king,  took  the  place  which 
Bruges  had  lost  owing  to  the  sUting  up  of  its 
canal  and  the  increased  size  of  vessels  necessary 
for  oceanic  trade.  The  overland  routes  in 
southern  Germany  ceased  to  be  employed  for 
anything  beyond  local  exchange.  The  Baltic 
was  no  longer  a  great  commercial  highway,  and 
the  Hanse  Towns  steadily  declined  until  their 
league  perished  in  the  turmoil  of  the  Thirty 
Years'  War  (see  Hanseatio  League). 

But  the  later  part  of  the  16th  century  wit- 
nessed another  great  mercantile  revolution. 
Antwerp  was  ruined  by  the  reckless  oppression 
of  Alva  and  the  long  war  which  followed  the 
revolt  of  the  Netherlands.  Two  countries, 
England  and  Holland,  hitherto  unknown  in 
the  history  of  commerce,  began  to  pose  as  the 
maritime  rivals  of  Spain  and  Portugal.  The 
trade  which  Antwerp  lost  was  gradually  diverted 
to  London  and  Amsterdam.  Philip  II.  annexed, 
1580,  Portugal  and  its  dependencies  to  the 
Spanish  crown.  The  defeat  of  the  Spanish 
Armada,  1588,  annihilated  the  maritime  ascend- 
ency of  Spain.  These  events  led  to  the  collapse 
of  the  monopoly  of  the  eastern  trade  so  long 
preserved  by  Lisbon.  The  Dutch  were  the  first 
to  seize  the  opportunity  thus  ofiered.  Dutch 
vessels  first  reached  an  Indian  port  1595  ; 
within  a  few  years  Dutch  settlements  were 
formed  in  Java  and  Sumatra.  The  great  Dutch 
East  India  Company  was  formed  1602  ;  it 
founded  a  capital  for  its  vast  possessipns  at 
Batavia  1618.  England  was  not  slow  to  follow 
in  the  footsteps  of  the  Dutch,  and  in  1600  the 
first  of  the  English  East  India  Companies  {q.  v. ), 
received  its  charter.  Though  the  massacre  of 
Amboyna  excluded  them  from  the  spice  trade, 
the  English  succeeded  in  establishing  a  lucrative 
commerce  with  Hindostan.  From  this  time  the 
eastern  trade  was  open  to  every  European 
country;  France,  Sweden,  Denmark,  endeavoured 
to  obtain  a  share  in  it.  But  these  countries 
each  entrusted  the  trade  to  an  exclusive  com- 
pany, and  thus  checked  the  progress  which 
private  enterprise  might  have  effected. 

Meanwhile  the  decline  of  Spain  led  to  a 
similar  extension  of  western  commerce.  John 
Cabot  had  discovered,  1496,  Newfoundland  for 
Henry  VII. ;  Jacques  Cartier  sailed,  1534,  up 
the  St.  Lawrence  and  gave  the  name  of  New 
France  to  what  is  now  the  province  of  Quebec. 


But  it  was  not  till  the  17th  century  that  the 
Spanish  ascendency  in  America  was  seriously 
threatened.  Quebec  was  founded,  1603,  as  the 
capital  of  the  great  French  colony  of  Canada  ; 
by  the  end  of  the  century  the  French  had  also 
established  themselves  in  Louisiana  at  the 
mouth  of  the  Mississippi.  Between  Canada 
and  the  Spanish  settlement  in  Florida  the  whole 
of  the  western  coast  was  successively  occupied 
by  the  English,  who  absorbed  the  Dutch  pro- 
vince of  the  New  Netherlands,  and  the  Swedish 
colony  on  the  Delaware.  At  the  same  time 
France,  England,  and  Spain  shared  the  West 
Indian  islands  among  them,  and  their  incessant 
rivalry  proved  the  cause  of  numerous  wars.  The 
Dutch  for  a  time  took  Brazil  from  the  Portu- 
guese, but  they  abandoned  it,  1661,  and  from 
this  time  confined  their  attention  mainly  to 
the  eastern  trade,  their  control  over  which  was 
strengthened  by  the  establishment  of  a  colony 
at  the  Cape  of  Good  Hope.  The  loss  of  their 
position  in  America  was  fatal  to  the  commercial 
greatness  of  the  Dutch.  The  eastern  trade, 
trammelled  by  the  system  of  exclusive  com- 
panies, made  comparatively  little  progress,  while 
the  commerce  with  America,  where  the  European 
settlements  were  real  colonies  instead  of  mere 
mercantile  d^ppots,  became  every  year  more  im- 
portant and  lucrative.  In  America,  too,  unlike 
the  East  Indies,  trade  was  open  to  any  subject 
of  the  colonising  countries. 

It  is  impossible  and  unnecessary  to  trace  here 
the  history  of  European  colonies  in  the  18th 
century.  Its  main  characteristic  is  the  steady 
growth  of  the  colonial  power  of  England  at  the 
expense  of  France  and  Spain.  In  the  history 
of  commercial  routes  it  is  only  important  to 
remember  that  each  country  set  itself  to  mono- 
polise the  trade  with  its  own  colonies.  It  was 
the  age  of  the  Mercantile  System  {q.v.),  and 
colonies  were  regarded  as  one  of  the  chief 
means  by  which  a  country  could  secure  for  itself 
a  favourable  balance  of  trade.  Thus  the  inter- 
colonial trade  was  of  small  proportions,  and 
was  of  the  character  of  a  smuggling  trade, 
carried  on  in  defiance  of  restrictive  laws.  The 
attempt  to  enforce  these  laws,  which  regarded 
colonies  as  existing  merely  for  the  benefit  of  the 
mother-country,  led,  quite  as  much  as  the  stamp 
act  or  the  tea  duty,  to  the  revolt  of  the  American 
colonies. 

From  the  15th  to  the  18th  centuries,  there- 
fore, an  enormous  extension  of  European  com- 
merce was  effected  by  the  opening  up  of  the 
Atlantic  and  Pacific.  The  old  routes  of  the 
Middle  Ages  were  abandoned,  the  Italian  and 
German  cities  lost  their  mercantile  importance, 
trade  followed  a  vast  number  of  complicated 
routes  across  the  ocean.  But  of  this  trade  the 
Atlantic  coasts  of  Europe  were  still  the  centre, 
and  as  long  as  the  system  of  mocopoly  was  up- 
held, this  condition  of  things  would  be  main- 
tained.     But  in  the  later  part  of  the  18tb 


COMMERCIAL  SCIENCE— COMMERCIAL  SYSTEM 


351 


century  a  fatal  blow  was  dealt  to  the  old  colonial 
system  by  the  American  revolt  and  the  French 
Revolution.  From  this  time  it  became  impos- 
sible to  treat  colonies  merely  as  markets  for  the 
goods  of  the  motlier  country.  Former  restrict- 
tions  were  disregarded  or  abolished,  a  new  era 
of  colonial  independence  and  self-government 
set  in,  completed  when  England,  raised  through 
the  results  of  the  revolutionary  wars  to  being 
beyond  all  question  the  greatest  of  colonial 
powers,  adopted  a  policy  of  free  trade.  From 
this  time  the  trade  of  the  world  has  lost  even 
the  semblance  of  unity  which  was  preserved  as 
long  as  the  routes  from  the  colonies  led  of  neces- 
sity to  the  mother  country  in  Europe. 

Great  commercial  changes  have  taken  place 
within  the  last  century  which  must  be  briefly 
alluded  to.  First,  the  rapid  and  almost  un- 
paralleled development  of  Australia  and  New 
Zealand.  In  the  18  th  century  Australia  was 
only  known  as  a  convict  settlement,  whereas 
Sydney  and  Melbourne  are  now  among  the 
greatest  ports  of  the  world.  Second,  the 
opening  of  the  Suez  Canal,  effected  primarily 
by  French  enterprise  and  capital,  but  of  which 
the  chief  benefit  has  hitherto  been  reaped  by 
England.  It  is  not  too  much  to  say  that  the 
•Suez  Canal  has  revolutionised  the  commercial 
routes  to  the  east.  It  has  restored  much  of 
their  old  importance  to  the  Mediterranean  and 
the  Red  Sea.  It  has  effected  at  least  a  partial 
revival  of  the  commercial  prosperity  of  Italy 
and  Egypt.  The  overland  route  to  Brindisi 
has  taken  the  place  of  the  old  roads  through 
southern  Germany  to  Venice  and  Genoa.  Tiio 
return  of  eastern  trade  to  its  medieval  direction 
has  been  one  of  the  most  notable  events  of  19th 
century  history.  Its  political  consequences 
have  been  still  more  far-reaching.  Third,  the 
development  of  the  great  trans-continental  rail- 
ways of  Canada,  the  United  States  of  America, 
and  Siberia,  and  the  improved  railway  communi- 
cation of  the  Near  East.  Lastly,  the  opening  of 
the  Panama  Canal,  the  results  of  which  belong 
to  the  domain  rather  of  the  future  than  of  history . 

[Adolf  Beer,  Allgemeine  Oeschichte  des  Welt- 
handels  (Vienna,  1860,  2  vols.)  —  Movers,  Das 
phonizische  Alterthum,  Bd.  iii.  (Berlin,  1856). — 
Grote,  History  of  Chreece. — Mommsen,  Rdmische 
Geschichte. — Sartorius,  Oeschichte  des  hanseatis- 
chen  Bundes. — Ritter,  Oeschichte  der  Erdkunde 
und  der  Entdeckungen  (Berlin,  1861). — Peschel, 
Oeschichte  des  Zeitalters  der  Entdeckungen  (1858). 
— Macpherson,  Annuls  of  Commerce  (4  vols.,  Lon- 
don, 1805). — E.  J.  Payne,  History  of  European 
CbZom'es  (London,  1877).]  R.L. 

COMMERCIAL  SCIENCE  {Handel^issen- 
schaft).  Strictly  speaking  the  term  commercial 
science  should  be  applied  to  that  branch  of 
political  economy  which  treats  of  the  increase 
of  wealth  and  the  economy  of  labour  by  the 
operations  of  commerce,  it  being  assumed  that 
the  state  does  not  interfere,  and  that  every 
individual  is  instigated  by  economic  motives,  and 


by  economic  motives  alone.  In  this  way  a  dis> 
tinction  may  be  clearly  drawn  between  Stoats- 
vyissenschaft  and  Handelswissenschaft.  But  in 
practice  this  subject  of  commerce  has  been 
treated  much  more  from  the  view  of  an  art  than 
of  a  science  (e.g.  cp.  Traits  theorique  et  pratique 
des  operations  commerciales  et  financikres,  by 
N.  Merten ;  Handelswissenschaft,  by  C.  F. 
Findeisen.  In  the  former  of  these  two  works 
the  theoretical  treatment  is  really  confined  to 
that  part  of  the  subject  concerned  with  banking 
and  exchange  operations,  while  the  latter  is 
practical  in  nearly  every  sense).  Viewed  in  this 
way  commerce  is  treated  with  reference  to  the 
facts  of  business,  and  thus  affords  a  continued 
series  of  illustrations  of  many  points  in  ordinary 
economic  theory.  Thus  exchange  is  viewed 
with  a  special  regard  to  the  various  classes  of 
middlemen  and  the  services  rendered  by  each 
to  the  rapid  circulation  of  the  commodities. 
Again,  instead  of  speaking  of  a  producer  or  a 
seller  without  explanation,  an  attempt  is  made 
to  classify  producers  or  sellers  in  their  various 
actual  forms,  whether  as  individual  operators,  as 
partners  in  a  firm,  or  as  members  of  a  company. 
The  function  of  each  is  described.  As  there  is 
considerable  approximation  to  the  .character  of 
a  handbook  of  commerce,  a  certain  attention  is  of 
necessity  paid  to  the  legal  standing  and  obliga- 
tions of  the  various  parties  involved.  The 
intensely  practical  nature  of  this  treatment  is, 
however,  relieved  when  we  come  to  questions  of 
money  and  exchange,  for  here  the  theoretical 
principles  are  clearly  and  definitely  laid  down. 
This  latter  branch  of  the  subject  it  is  which  has 
attracted  most  attention  of  recent  years  both  on 
the  Continent  and  in  England,  as  we  may  see 
from  the  labours  of  such  writers,  for  instance,  as 
Jevons  {Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finxtnce), 
Giffen,  Goschen,  R.  H.  Inglis  Palgrave,  Ellis, 
Bagehot,  J.  G.  Courcelle-Seneuil,  and  others. 

E.  c.  K.  G. 
COMMERCIAL  SYSTEM.  The  fourth  book 
of  the  Wealth  of  Nations  is  devoted  to  an  ex- 
amination of  "systems  of  political  economy," 
considered,  as  Adam  Smith  explains,  as  a  branch 
of  the  science  of  a  statesman  or  legislator.  With 
his  accustomed  sense  of  the  due  proportion  of 
theory  to  historical  facts,  the  writer  devotes 
almost  the  whole  of  the  book  to  an  examination 
of  the  commercial  or  mercantile  system  which 
had  reached  its  fuU  maturity  as  part  of  the 
policy  of  Europe,  whilst  the  agricultural  system 
of  his  friend  Quesnay  is  dismissed  in  a  single 
chapter  on  the  ground  that  it  "at  present  ex- 
ists only  in  the  speculations  of  a  few  men  of 
great  learning  and  ingenuity  in  France."  Any 
account  of  the  commercial  system  by  a  modem 
writer  must  be  in  the  main  a  repetition  of 
Adam  Smith  with  indications  of  the  principal 
criticisms  to  which  his  work  has  been  subjected. 
The  chief  fault  to  be  found  with  Adam  Smith's 
treatment,  as  a  whole,  is  that  he  was  so  much 


352 


COMMERCIAL  SYSTEM 


concerned  to  destroy  the  system  as  part  of  the 
practical  policy  of  the  day  and  as  altogether 
unfitted  for  the  stage  of  industrial  development 
already  attained,  that  he  sometimes  overlooks 
and  sometimes  mistakes  the  conditions  under 
which  the  system  arose,  and  under  which  it 
answered  the  wants  of  the  time.  Subsequent 
writers  (in  Germany,  e.g.  List,  Schanz,  Roscher, 
and  in  this  country  W.  Cunningham)  have 
shown  that  the  mercantilists  at  any  rate  as 
represented  by  their  chief  writers,  were  not 
guilty  of  the  childish  sophism  that  money  only 
was  wealth  and  that  the  only  thing  at  which 
the  commercial  legislator  should  aim  was  the 
acquisition  by  the  country  of  the  greatest  possible 
sum  of  money  by  its  foreign  trades.  In  many 
respects  they  regarded  a  favourable  balance  of 
trade  merely  as  a  good  symptom  of  other  more 
important  national  interests,  such  as  the  full 
employment  of  labour  and  capital  at  home,  a 
point  on  which  Adam  Smith  himself  lays  much 
stress  in  his  second  book.  In  other  aspects  of 
their  system,  the  political  power  of  the  nation 
was  considered  as  fundamental,  as  in  the  navi- 
gation laws,  of  which  again,  including  the 
motives  at  their  basis,  Adam  Smith  strongly 
approves  (compare  Seeley's  Expansion  of  Eng- 
land). At  the  same  time,  however,  it  must  be 
admitted  that  before  the  last  quarter  of  the 
18  th  century  the  system  had  ripened  to  decay, 
the  ideas  which  had  given  it  vitality  at  an 
earlier  stage  had  been  lost  sight  of,  and  the 
mere  symptom,  i.e.  the  favourable  balance,  had 
come  to  be  considered  as  itself  the  essence  of 
well-being. 

The  following  is  a  brief  critical  summary  of 
Adam  Smith's  treatment  as  given  in  book  iv. 
of  the  Wealth  of  Nations.  He  begins  by  an 
explanation  of  the  true  functions  of  money  in 
trade,  and  its  relation  to  other  forms  of  wealth, 
and  shows  that  no  particular  political  attention 
should  be  directed  towards  the  accumulation  of 
money,  either  on  account  of  its  durability  or 
because  it  is  thought  to  be  useful  in  foreign 
wars.  The  argument  is  decisive  against  the 
case  as  it  is  represented ;  but  it  may  be  objected 
that  if  we  substitute  for  durability  the  idea  of 
a  store  of  value,  and  if  we  remember  that  at 
the  end  of  the  17th  century  Pope's  father,  on 
retiring  from  business,  carried  his  wealth  in 
actual  guineas,  and  recall  the  graphic  accoimt  of 
Pepys  hiding  his  money,  we  may  arrive  at  a 
juster  view  of  this  mercantilist  point.  And 
the  further  we  go  back  towards  the  mediaeval 
period,  this  peculiar  importance  of  money  as 
a  store  of  value  becomes  more  prominent. 
Again,  as  regards  the  foreign  wars,  there  was 
a  close  connection  between  the  balance  of  trade 
and  the  balance  of  power,  and  even  in  our  own 
day  we  find  Bismarck  and  other  foreign  states- 
men attaching  importance  to  a  full  supply  of 
gold  in  their  ' '  war  chests. "  The  ostensible  object 
of  the  mercantilists  being  to  obtain  a  favourable 


balance  (see  Balance  of  Teade,  History  of) 
we  have  next  to  consider  the  methods  by  which 
this  end  was  promoted.  Speaking  generally, 
the  aim  of  their  policy  was  to  diminish  as  much 
as  possible  the  importation  of  foreign  goods  for 
home  consumption  and  to  increase  as  much  as 
possible  the  exportation  of  the  produce  of 
domestic  industry.  The  restraints  on  importa- 
tion were  of  two  kinds :  (1)  restraints  on  any 
foreign  goods  which  could  be  produced  at  home 
from  whatever  country  they  were  imported ;  and 
(2)  special  restraints  on  imports  from  countries 
with  which  the  balance  of  trade  was  generally 
unfavourable.  As  regards  (1)  Adam  Smith 
gives  the  most  general  arguments  in  favour  of 
free  trade  as  against  prohibition  (see  Free 
Trade).  The  principal  point  to  observe  is  that 
Adam  Smith  was  not  in  a  position  to  state  the 
free  trade  theory  with  the  dogmatic  simplicity 
of  some  modern  writers,  as  he  was  obliged  to  take 
into  account  the  opinions  expressed  in  book 
ii.,  on  the  comparative  advantages  of  employ- 
ing capital  in  different  ways,  e.g.  the  superiority 
of  home  to  foreign  trade  and  of  agiiculture  to 
manufactures,  especially  as  regards  the  labour 
of  a  country.  If  from  this  point  of  view  his 
case  is  not  so  strongly  put  as  at  present,  on 
the  other  h^-nd  logically  we  must  take  into 
account  his  optimistic  views  on  nature  and 
his  references  to  the  ''invisible  hand,"  which 
directs  private  interest  so  as  to  increase  the  public 
good.  The  dangers  of  prophecy  are  incidentally 
illustrated  in  the  assertion  that  even  the  free 
importation  of  foreign  com  could  very  little 
aflfect  the  interest  of  the  farmers  of  Great 
Britain,  and  the  free  importation  of  cattle  or 
meat  still  less.  The  chapter  is  also  noteworthy 
for  the  famous  exceptions  to  free  trade,  ad- 
mitted by  Adam  Smith  as  generally  advan- 
tageous or  at  least  worthy  of  deliberation,  and 
in  which  the  older  and  more  rational  mer- 
cantilists would  recognise  much  of  their  own 
teaching.  Thus  on  the  ground  that  defence 
is  of  much  more  importance  than  opulence, 
* '  the  act  of  navigation  "  is  described  as  '  *  perhaps 
the  wisest  of  all  the  commercial  regulations  of 
England."  The  taxation  of  foreign  commodi- 
ties which  come  into  competition  with  those 
which  are  produced  and  taxed  at  home  is  ap- 
proved, though  the  possible  extension  of  the 
doctrine  to  substitutes,  and  to  the  general  as 
distinct  from  the  special  taxes  of  the  foreigner, 
so  far  as  it  is  taken  account  of,  is  repudiated. 
The  cases  worthy  of  deliberation  are  retaliation 
with  the  view  of  obtaining  better  terms  for  oui 
exports  and  the  regard  for  vested  interests  on  the 
ground  of  humanity.  (2)  The  restraints  upon 
imports  from  countries  with  which  we  have  an 
unfavourable  balance  are  much  more  strongly 
condemned.  It  was  easy  to  show  that  even 
on  mercantilist  principles,  that  is,  taking  the 
favourable  balance  as  fundamental,  the  rest  of 
the  world  should  be  considered  simply  as  one 


COMMERCIAL  SYSTEM 


353 


great  market,  and  that  we  should  buy  in  the 
cheapest  and  sell  in  the  dearest  country,  inde- 
pendently of  the  particular  balance.  Simple, 
however,  as  this  doctrine  seems,  it  is  still  often 
lost  sight  of,  and  forgetful  of  the  indirect  settle- 
ment of  international  debts,  so-called  fair  trade 
writers  compare  the  exports  and  imports  between 
two  particular  countries,  e.g.  France  and  Eng- 
land. Adam  Smith  at  this  stage  shows  clearly 
that  it  is  for  the  interest  of  a  nation  to  have 
rich  neighbours,  and  that  anything  which  injures 
a  foreign  nation  indirectly  injures  the  home 
country.  He  points  out  also  that  the  '*  favour- 
able balance  of  the  annual  produce  and  the 
consumption  "  is  very  dilferent  from  the  balance 
of  trade  and  "necessarily  occasions  the  pro- 
sperity or  decay  of  every  nation,"  to  which  the 
mercantilists  might  rejoin  that  the  one  balance 
properly  understood,  i.e.  as  referring  to  a  grow- 
ing export  trade  compared  with  consumption  of 
foreign  luxuries,  is  one  of  the  best  signs  of  the 
other  balance. 

Passing  now  to  encouragements  given  to  ex- 
ports, we  notice  first  of  all  (1 )  drawbacks.  These, 
as  the  name  suggests,  are  duties  drawn  back  on 
exportation  or  re-exportation,  and  as  they  tend 
to  restore  the  natural  course  of  trade,  they  are 
strongly  approved  of  by  Adam  Smith.  The 
chief  dangers  of  drawbacks  are  that  the  com- 
modity may  be  re-imported  and  the  revenue 
suffer  from  smuggling,  and  that,  as  abundant 
proof  has  been  given  lately,  the  drawback  may 
really  be  a  bounty  in  disguise  (see  Drawbacks  ; 
Bounties).  (2)  Bounties  are  next  examined, 
and  receive  the  strongest  condemnation  of  any 
expedient  of  the  mercantile  system  (see  Boun- 
ties). Incidentally  the  whole  subject  of  the 
Corn  Laws  is  examined  and  it  will  be  seen  from 
the  different  species  of  laws  discussed  that  the 
commercial  system  as  a  whole  was  much  more 
varied  in  its  aims  than  is  generally  supposed. 
The  laws,  for  example,  against  engrossing  and 
forestalling  were  plainly  drawn  up  in  the  inter- 
ests of  the  consumer,  and  the  same  object  was 
apparent  in  the  attempt  to  abolish  the  middle- 
men and,  to  quote  a  favourite  position  of  Adam 
Smith,  to  bring  the  produce  as  near  as  possible 
to  the  consumer.  (3)  The  next  expedient  of 
the  system  to  encourage  exports  was  the  negotia- 
tion of  treaties  of  commerce  giving  special  ad- 
vantages to  those  countries  with  which  we  had 
or  were  supposed  to  have  a  favourable  balance. 
Again  it  may  be  said  that  Adam  Smith  takes  a 
rather  narrow  view  of  the  real  objects  of  many 
of  these  treaties.  The  reader  may  compare 
List's  account,  in  National  Systems  of  Political 
Economy,  of  the  celebrated  Methuen  treaty  with 
Portugal.  In  recent  times  much  controversy 
has  taken  place  on  the  advantages  and  disad- 
vantages of  commercial  treaties  ;  they  were 
approved  of  by  Cobden,  and  have  been  adopted 
to  a  large  extent  practically  even  by  this  country, 
but  they  are  objected  to  by  extreme  free  traders 
VOL.  I. 


(see  Commercial  Treaties).  (4)  The  last 
device  of  the  system  to  encourage  exportation 
was  the  monopoly,  total  or  partial,  of  the  colonial 
trade.  This  question  is  discussed  by  Adam 
Smith  at  great  length,  as  Avas  only  natural,  since 
his  work  appeared  in  the  same  year  as  the  de- 
claration of  American  independence.  The 
argument,  however,  of  the  chapter  is  involved 
and  rather  obscure.  The  principal  difficulty  is 
caused  by  the  constant  reference  to  the  wiiter's 
peculiar  views  on  the  relative  advantages  of 
employing  capital  in  different  ways — such  as 
that  the  near  trade  is  more  advantageous  than 
the  distant.  It  is  noteworthy  also  that  one  of 
the  cardinal  objections  of  Adam  Smith  to  this 
monopoly  is  that  thereby  the  general  rate  of 
profits  in  the  country  is  raised,  and  that  this 
element  in  the  cost  of  production  being  increased, 
we  are  undersold  in  other  commodities,  thus 
sacrificing  an  absolute  for  a  relative  advantage. 
If  a  country  is  so  wealthy  that  it  is  naturally 
exporting  capital,  this  argument  falls  to  the 
ground.  Another  objection  to  Adam  Smith's 
line  of  treatment  is  that  perhaps  he  does  not 
pay  sufficient  attention  to  the  idea  of  political 
power  historically  involved  in  the  acquisition 
or  colonisation  of  new  territory.  Although 
the  East  India  Company  was  never  a  com- 
mercial success,  it  laid  the  foundation  of  our 
Indian  empire.  At  the  same  time,  howevei, 
he  was  the  first  to  propose  a  wide-reaching 
scheme  of  what  would  now  be  called  imperial 
federation. 

There  remain  to  be  noticed  two  other  expedi- 
ents of  the  mercantile  system.  As  regards  raw 
materials  and  the  instruments  of  manufactures, 
the  usual  policy,  described  above,  was  appar- 
ently reversed  and  importation  was  encouraged 
and  exportation  discouraged  or  prohibited. 
The  explanation  is  to  be  found  in  the  idea  that 
if  raw  material  were  worked  up  before  being 
exported  it  would  be  more  valuable,  and  that  a 
nation  should  keep  for  its  own  benefit  any 
peculiar  advantages  of  production.  The  history 
of  the  woollen  trade  is  most  instructive  on  this 
point.  Wool  in  the  early  Middle  Ages  was  the 
principal  export  and  source  of  England's  supply 
of  money,  whilst  later  on  the  export  was  for- 
bidden and  the  prohibition  was  extended  to 
sheep.  As  regards  "instruments  "  of  production, 
the  living  instrument — the  artisan,  was  placed 
under  the  same  restrictions  as  dead  capital. 
The  idea  that  the  exportation  of  raw  material 
and  instruments  shall  be  discouraged  has  re- 
cently been  revived  in  this  country  as  regards 
our  coal  supplies,  and  one  of  the  favourite  modern 
protectionist  arguments  is  that  for  the  higher 
forms  of  work  a  nation  should  rely  on  its  own 
members  and  not  let  them  become  mere  "hewers 
of  wood  and  drawers  of  water. " 

[The  principal  interest  of  the  mercantile  system 
is  historical,  though  many  of  its  expedients  are  still 
advocated  under  the  name  of  fair  trade.     Besides 

2  A 


354 


COMJ^IEKCIAL  TREATIES 


the  work*  alluded  to,  the  reader  may  consult  the 
books  mentioned  under  the  particular  articles 
referred  to,  e.g.  Free  Trade,  Bounties,  etc.] 

J.  s.  N. 
COMMERCIAL  TREATIES.  Treaties  of 
commerce  seem  to  have  been  of  very  early 
origin.  Sir  H.  Maine  (Village  Communities 
p.  192)  has  pointed  out  the  close  conneotion  in 
the  most  rudimentary  societies  between  neutral- 
ity and  markets  ;  and  in  times  when  the  same 
word  (e.g.  hostis)  was  often  used  both  for 
enemy  and  stranger,  it  is  plain  that  commerce 
was  hardly  possible  without  some  more  or  less 
formal  agreement.  The  earliest  commercial 
treaty  extant  was  that  made  between  Rome  and 
Carthage,  B.C.  508  (cp.  Macpherson's  Anrials  of 
Commerce,  vol.  i.  p.  60).  [iii.  22,  23  Poly  bins.] 
The  earliest  treaty  that  occurs  in  the  history 
of  England  is  that  between  Charlemagne  and 
Offa,  A.D.  796.  Throughout  the  mediaeval 
period  the  foreigner  was  regarded  as  a  highly 
suspicious  character.  In  Saxon  times  foreign 
traders  were  only  allowed  to  come  to  the  country 
on  the  occasion  of  four  great  fairs,  knd  were 
obliged  to  leave  the  kingdom  within  forty  days. 
Attempts  were  made  to  keep  in  force  this  forty- 
days  regulation  down  to  the  time  of  the  Tudors 
(cp.  Schanz,  op.  cit.  inf.  vol.  i.  p.  380).  For  a 
considerable  period  aliens  were  liable  for  the 
debts  contracted  by  members  of  the  same  town 
or  country,  and  even  for  crimes  the  same  mutual 
obligation  prevailed.  One  of  the  clauses  of 
Magna  Charta  (§  41)  refers  to  the  protection 
given  to  foreign  merchants.  More  than  a  hun- 
dred years  later  (1325)  it  was  stipulated  by 
Edward  II.  that  the  merchants  of  Venice  should 
have  power  to  come  to  England  for  ten  years 
with  liberty  to  sell  their  merchandise  and  to 
return  home  in  safety  "without  having  either 
their  persons  or  goods  i^opped  on  account  of 
other  people's  crimes  or  debts."  It  may  be 
said  generally  that  the  principal  object  of  com- 
mercial treaties  for  many  centuries  was  simply 
to  afford  security  to  traders.  In  process  of  time, 
however,  as  the  mercantile  system  (see  Balance 
OF  Trade  ;  Commercial  System)  was  de- 
veloped and  this  rudimentary  security  had  been 
attained,  commercial  treaties  became  the  great 
agents  by  which  a  nation  tried  to  secure  for 
itself  the  advantages  supposed  to  foUow  from 
this  system.  Treaties  of  this  kind  were  severely 
attacked  by  Adam  Smith  (  Wealth  of  Nations, 
bk.  iv.  ch.  vi.),  who  takes  as  his  principal  example 
the  famous  Methuen  Treaty  concluded  with 
Portugal  in  1703.  The  reader,  however,  should 
compare  with  Adam  Smith's  remarks  the  account 
of  the  benefits  conferred  by  this  treaty  upon 
English  traders  as  stated  by  List  {National 
System  of  Political  Economy,  p.  62,  Eng.  trans.) 
The  root  idea  of  modern  commercial  treaties 
is  reciprocity.  A  list  of  the  treaties  of  com- 
merce and  navigation  still  in  force  between  the 
United  Kingdom  and  foreign  countries  is  to  be 


found  in  Leone  Levi's  History  of  British  Com- 
merce, 2d  ed.  p.  565.  The  treaty  which  has 
excited  most  controversy  is  that  negotiated 
with  France  by  Richard  Cobden  in  1860  (cp. 
Finance  and  Politics,  by  Lord  Buxton,  vol. 
i.  ch.  xi.  ;  and  Lord  Morley's  Life  of  Cobden, 
vol.  ii.  ch.  xi.)  In  the  negotiations  of  the 
treaty  the  emperor  of  the  French,  by  whom 
alone  the  matter  on  the  French  side  was  practi- 
cally settled,  was  influenced  largely  by  purely 
political  considerations.  It  was,  however,  in  this 
treaty  that  the  notion  of  the  reciprocal  advan- 
tages rather  than  the  balance  of  losses  by  mutual 
concessions  first  found  due  prominence.  The 
principal  provisions  were  as  follows:  On  the  side 
of  France  prohibitive  duties  were  to  give  way  to 
protective  duties  of  moderate  amount.  On  all 
the  staples  and  material  articles  of  British  manu- 
facture— woollen,  cotton,  silk,  flax,  jute,  hemp, 
hair,  and  manufactures  of  iron  and  other  metals, 
tools  and  machinery,  manufactures  of  leather, 
wood,  glass  and  earthenware,  as  well  as  on 
yarns,  coal  and  coke,  and  other  raw  materials, 
etc. — the  duties  were  to  be  so  much  reduced 
that  the  maximum  ad  valorem  charge  was  not 
to  exceed  30  per  cent,  which  was  to  be  reduced 
within  three  years  to  25  per  cent,  and  the 
duties,  when  practicable,  were  to  be  changed 
into  specific  duties.  Thirty  per  cent  was  to 
be  the  maximum,  but  the  actual  amount  of 
duty  to  be  paid  on  each  article  was  left  to  separ- 
ate negotiation,  and  in  the  result  in  most  cases 
it  was  fixed  much  below  the  maximum.  Accord- 
ing to  Cobden  the  average  did  not  actually 
exceed  15  per  cent.  (Buxton,  Finan/ie  and 
Politics,  vol.  i.  p.  230.)  England,  on  her  part, 
engaged  to  abolish  at  once  all  the  remaining 
import  duties  on  manufactured  goods.  She 
agreed  not  to  levy  a  duty  on,  or  prohibit  the  ex- 
port of,  coal ;  and — the  most  important  practical 
concession  to  France — she  agi^eed  to  make 
great  reductions  on  wine  and  brandy  ;  other 
nations,  however,  being  of  course  placed  on  the 
same  footing.  Both  parties  engaged  to  insert 
in  the  treaty  a  "most  favoured  nation  clause." 
The  treaty  was  to  remain  in  force  for  ten  years 
and  then  to  continue  from  year  to  year  unless 
"  denounced  "  by  either  party,  in  which  case, 
unless  definitely  renewed,  it  would  lapse  in  twelve 
months.  In  1 8  7  2  the  treaty  was  ' '  denounced  " 
by  France  at  the  instance  of  Thiers,  the  govern- 
ment being  in  great  financial  difficulties  at  the 
time  owing  to  the  German  indemnity.  The  treaty 
was,  however,  renewed  next  year.  After  a  series 
of  attempts  for  a  definite  rcmewal  on  an  improved 
basis  from  the  free  trade  point  of  \dew,  the  treaty 
was  practically  abandoned  in  1882,  when  as  a 
substitute  the  French  government  passed  a  law, 
giving  to  England  the  be'-nefits  of  the  "most 
favoured  nation  "  treatment.  France  was  thus 
left  free  to  raise  the  duties  on  any  article  at 
once,  and  by  simple  repeal  of  the  law  to  treat 
England  less  advantageously  than  other  nations. 


COMMERCIAL  TREATIES— COMMISSIONS  OF  ENQUIRY 


355 


The  French  treaty  of  1860  has  been  described 
at  some  length,  because  in  connection  with  it 
the  whole  question  of  the  principles  of  com- 
mercial treaties  has  been  raised  and  discussed. 
The  principal  arguments  for  and  against  may 
be  enumerated  under  five  headings. 

(1)  The  opponents  of  commercial  treaties 
appeal  to  their  failure  in  the  past  to  secure  the 
advantages  for  which  they  were  ostensibly 
negotiated.  So  long  as  the  Navigation  Acts 
remained  in  force,  they  naturally  gave  rise  to 
retaliation  by  other  nations,  and  the  retalia- 
tion was  met  by  reciprocity  treaties  with  various 
countries  on  various  conditions.  The  complica- 
tions which  ensued  were  so  great  that  they  had 
much  to  do  with  the  ultimate  repeal  of  the  acts. 
This  is  only  one  example  of  the  alleged  failure 
of  treaties  in  the  past,  but  it  is  maintained  that 
on  the  whole  they  have  produced  more  harm 
than  good.  To  this  it  is  replied  by  the  ad- 
vocates of  the  system  that  the  old  ideas  on 
which  such  treaties  were  based  were  economi- 
cally unsound,  being  survivals  of  the  mercantile 
system  ;  but  that  the  French  treaty  and  others 
drawn  on  similar  lines  have  proved  beneficial 
in  recent  times,  and  that  the  appeal  to  the 
past  can  only  be  fairly  made  when  all  the 
circumstances  of  the  case  are  considered. 

(2)  It  is  objected  to  commercial  treaties  that, 
in  appearance  at  least,  if  not  in  reality,  they 
are  opposed  to  the  principles  of  free  trade. 
Even  although  no  diff'erential  duties  are  imposed, 
and  all  nations  are  ostensibly  treated  with 
equal  favour,  still  it  is  said  that  if  a  free  trade 
nation  arranges  its  tariff  out  of  consideration 
to  the  revenue  of  another  country,  so  far  that 
nation  is  "favoured"  relatively  to  others,  and 
that  this  amounts  to  an  infringement  of  free- 
trade  principles.  To  this  it  is  replied  that 
commercial  treaties  afford  a  middle  way  between 
protection  and  free  trade,  and  that  if  other 
nations,  by  means  of  a  treaty,  are  brought  to 
see  the  advantages  of  a  reduction  of  tariff's,  they 
may  ultimately  follow  the  example  of  England 
(Most  Favoui;ed  Nation  Clause),  repeal 
many  of  these  duties  altogether,  and  eventu- 
ally adopt  free  trade.  Such  was  the  opinion 
of  Cobden,  and  it  is  supported  by  Lord  Morley, 
Cliffe  Leslie,  and  many  other  free-traders. 

(3)  It  is  alleged  that  it  may  prove  incon- 
venient to  a  government  to  have  its  hands 
tied  for  a  definite  term  of  years  on  fiscal  matters, 
as  England  was  bound,  for  example,  not  to  in- 
crease the  wine  duties  nor  to  impose  an 
export  duty  on  coal.  To  this  it  is  replied 
that  the  fixity  of  a  tariff  is  advantageous  for  the 
stability  of  trade. 

(4)  This  reply  leads  to  the  further  objection 
that,  as  the  time  of  the  treaty  approaches  ful- 
filment, there  will  be  a  great  disturbance  in 
trade  whilst  the  new  negotiations  are  in  pro- 
gress, and  again  an  appeal  is  made  to  the 
experience  with  France  after  the  first  ten  years 


had  been  completed.  The  obvious  answer  is 
that  the  disturbance  is  only  temporary,  and  in 
any  case  that  a  treaty  subject  to  the  possible 
failure  of  renewal  is  better  than  none  at  all,  so 
far  as  the  convenience  of  traders  is  concerned. 

(6)  The  objection  made  by  the  extreme 
advocates  of  free  trade,  which,  if  valid,  would 
be  the  strongest  possible,  is  that  there  is  really 
no  use  in  such  treaties  ;  that  a  nation  should 
rely  simply  upon  free  imports  to  fight  foreign 
tariffs,  and  that  the  exports  can  be  left  to 
take  care  of  themselves.  Suppose,  it  is  said, 
that  England  of  her  own  accord,  and  without 
any  equivalent  treaty,  reduces  the  duties  on 
French  wines  and  silks,  and  thus  encourages 
importation  ;  still  these  imports  must  in  the 
end,  directly  or  indirectly,  be  paid  for  by 
exports  ;  if  France  excludes  our  goods  directly, 
then  she  must  accept  payment  from  other 
nations  which  do  accept  our  goods.  The  best 
answer  to  this  argument  is  perhaps  that  given 
by  Lord  IVlorley  {Life  of  Cobden,  vol.  ii.  p. 
343).  "The  decisive  consideration  is  that  we 
can  only  procure  imports  from  other  countries 
on  the  cheapest  possible  terms  on  condition 
that  the  producers  in  those  countries  are  able 
to  receive  our  exports  on  the  cheajtest  possible 
terms."  This  opinion  may  also  be  supported 
by  the  authority  of  Adam  Smith,  who  always 
maintained  that  the  near  trade  was  more 
advantageous  than  the  remote,  and  the  direct 
than  the  roundabout  trade. 

[See  Tariff  Reform  Movement,  App. — Schanz, 
Englische  Handels-Politik,  Leij^zig,  ISSl.  —  Adam 
Smith,  M'Culloch's  edition  (1872),  Note  on  Com- 
mercial Treaties. — Cliffe  Leslie,  Essays  on  Fi- 
nancial Reform,  Cobden  Club,  1872. — List, 
National  System  of  Political  Economy. — Morley's 
Life  of  Cobden. — Sir  Thomas  Farrer,  Free  Trade 
versus  Fair  Trade. — Four  Letters  on  Commercial 
Treaties  (Cobden  Club),  1870.— Mallet's  Free 
Exchange,  1891.]  J.  s.  N. 

COMMISSARY.  See  Succession  (Scots 
Law). 

COMMISSION  AGENT.  A  person  entrusted 
by  a  principal  with  the  sale  or  purchase  of 
goods  and  receiving  a  commission  for  his  re- 
muneration. Commission  agents  generally  sell 
or  buy  in  their  own  name,  and  therefore  deal  as 
principals  with  the  buyers  or  sellers  ;  but,  as 
regards  the  mutual  relations  between  them  and 
their  principals,  they  are  bound  b}'  the  ordinary 
rules  of  the  law  of  agency.  e.  s. 

COMMISSIONS  OF  ENQUIRY.  It  has  long 
been  the  practice  in  the  United  Kingdom  to 
appoint,  under  a  royal  warrant,  commissions  to 
institute  enquiries,  to  collect  information,  and 
to  report  concerning  matters  of  special  public 
interest  as  to  which  it  is  felt  to  be  necessary  to 
obtain  the  assistance  of  well-informed  persona 
whose  services  are  not  ordinarily  at  the  disposal 
of  the  government.  The  scope  of  such  enquiries 
is  carefully  defined  in  the  waiTant  constitut- 
ing the  commission,   usually  described  as  the 


356 


COMMISSIONS  OF  ENQUIRY— COMMISSIONS,  JUDICIAL 


"reference,"  and  the  commission  is  invested 
with  power  to  summon  witnesses  and  to  call 
for  such  records,  books,  and  papers  as  in  its 
judgment  may  serve  to  throw  light  on  the 
subject  of  the  enquiry.  The  first  person  named 
in  the  reference  is  usually  considered  to  be 
nominated  as  the  chairman  of  the  committee, 
and  a  secretary,  not  himself  a  member  bf  the 
commission,  is  also  appointed.  The  commission 
itself  decides  the  course  which  its  proceedings 
shall  take.  It  frequently  arranges,  in  the  first 
instance,  for  the  issue  of  such  circular  letters  as 
may  appear  calculated  to  elicit  general  informa- 
tion, and  it  then  proceeds  to  hear  oral  evidence. 
The  first  witnesses  called  are  ordinarily  those 
government  officers  who,  from  the  position  they 
occupy,  may  be  presumed  to  have  a  special 
knowledge  of  the  subject  in  hand.  The  examin- 
ation in  chief  is  conducted  by  the  chairman,  each 
member  of  the  commission  in  turn  having  an 
opportunity  of  questioning  the  witness.  In  some 
cases,  additional  or  assistant  commissioners  are 
appointed  to  prosecute  subordinate  enquiries  in 
distant  places  and  even  in  foreign  countries. 
These  usually  receive  payment  for  their  services, 
as  does  also  the  secretary,  unless  he  be  in  the 
permanent  employment  of  the  government,  in 
which  case  it  is  customary  to  award  him  a 
bonus  when  the  work  of  the  commission  is  at 
an  end.  The  commissioners  themselves  are 
ordinarily  unpaid.  When  the  commission  has 
obtained  all  the  evidence  it  considers  necessary, 
it  prepares  and  presents  its  report,  which,  with 
an  exact  transcript  of  the  evidence  and  the 
documents  forthcoming  in  the  course  of  the 
enquiry,  are  then  laid  before  both  houses  of 
parliament  and  sold  to  the  public.  Commis- 
sions of  enquiry  obtain  and  arrange  in  a  con- 
venient form  a  vast  amount  of  information  of 
great  value,  and  in  this  their  main  utility  exists. 
Parliamentary  and  political  reasons  frequently 
prevent  the  carrying  out  of  the  recommenda- 
tions of  commissions,  it  being  impossible  to 
dissociate  from  the  government  of  the  day  the 
final  responsibility  for  any  action  taken  on  the 
basis  of  their  reports. 

The  following  are  among  the  principal  com- 
missions of  enquiry  appointed  since  1830,  to 
consider  subjects  of  economic  interest : — 

1832.  Poor  Laws. 

1833.  Employment  of  Children  in  Factories. 
1836.  Irish  Railways. 

1840.  Employment  of  Children  in  Mines. 

1843.  Scotch  Poor  Laws. 

1843.  Irish  Land  Laws. 

1853.  Shipping  Dues. 

1855.  Decimal  Coinage. 

1863.  Fisheries. 

1866.  Duration  of  Coal  Supply. 

1867.  Trades  Unions. 

1868.  International  Coinage. 

1875.  Labour  Laws. 

1876.  Factory  and  Workshops  Acts. 
1881.  Agricultural  Interests. 


1885.  Housing  of  the  Working  Classes. 

1886.  Depressions  of  Trade  and  Industry. 

1887.  Gold  and  Silver. 
1891.  Labour. 

1905.  Poor  Laws  and  Relief  of  Distress,    t.h.e. 

COMMISSIONS,  Judicial.  The  general 
tendency  of  English  legislation  has  been  to 
reserve  all  judicial  business  for  the  courts  of 
justice.  But  in  modern  times  certain  import 
ant  functions  of  a  judicial  character  have  been 
entrusted  to  commissions  differing  in  many  re- 
spects from  the  ordinary  courts.  The  motives 
for  establishing  such  commissions  instead  of 
increasing  the  regular  judicial  staff  have  been 
various.  A  particular  class  of  cases  may  de- 
mand such  a  technical  knowledge  of  subjects 
not  legal  as  cannot  reasonably  be  expected  from 
a  professional  judge.  Thus  the  class  of  cases 
which  comes  before  the  Railway  Commission 
requires  an  exceptional  acquaintance  with  the 
principles  of  railway  organisation  and  manage- 
ment. Or  again,  the  judicial  function  to  be 
performed  may  be  one  which  the  law  has  never 
contemplated,  and  for  which  the  principles  of 
jurisprudence  afford  no  guidance.  Thus  the 
principal  function  of  the  Irish  Land  Commission 
and  the  Scotch  Crofters'  Commission  is  to  set 
aside  existing  contracts  of  land-tenure  and  to 
determine  what  is  called  a  "fair  rent."  In 
these  cases  the  function  of  the  commissions  is 
rather  political  than  legal ;  it  is  to  reduce  that 
resistance  to  the  fulfilment  of  legal  obligations 
which  is  never  recognised  by  a  jurist,  although 
it  may  sometimes  be  troublesome  to  a  states- 
man. 

Commissions  such  as  these  differ  from  normal 
courts  of  justice  principally  in  three  respects — 
(a)  jurisdiction ;  (b)  composition  ;  (c)  procedure. 

(a)  Jurisdiction. — Whilst  an  ordinary  court 
of  justice  has  usually  jurisdiction  to  deal  with 
many  kinds  of  cases,  a  judicial  commission  is 
commonly  confined  to  dealing  with  cases  of  a 
particular  class.  Thus  the  main  function  of 
the  Railway  Commission  is  to  ensure  impartial 
treatment  of  all  persons  or  corporations  using 
a  railway,  and  to  arbitrate  in  disputes  between 
railway  companies  or  canal  companies.  The 
main  function  of  the  Irish  Land  Commission 
and  of  the  analogous  commission  in  Scotland  is 
to  deal  with  disputes  between  landlord  and 
tenant. 

(b)  Composition. — In  the  United  Kingdom, 
at  all  events,  it  is  the  uniform  practice  to  select 
the  judges  exclusively  from  the  legal  profession. 
But  judicial  commissions  usually  include  other 
persons  as  well  as  professional  lawyers.  Thus 
the  Railway  Commission,  as  originally  consti- 
tuted (Regulation  of  Railways  Act,  1873,  36  & 
37  Vict.  c.  48),  consisted  of  three  commis- 
sioners, of  whom  one  was  to  be  of  experience 
in  law,  another  of  experience  in  railway  business. 
As  recently  remodelled  (Railway  and  Canal 
Traffic  Act,   1888,   51  &  52  Vict.  c.  25),  the 


COMMISSIONS,  JUDICIAL— COMMODITY 


357 


Railway  Commission  consists  of  two  appointed 
commissioners,  including  one  of  railway  experi- 
ence and  three  ex-officio  commissioners,  namely, 
a  judge  of  a  superior  court  in  England,  in  Scot- 
land, and  in  Ireland  respectively.  The  Irish 
Land  Commission  (Land  Law  Ireland  Act,  1881, 
44  &  45  Vict.  c.  49)  consists  of  three  commis- 
sioners, one  of  whom  must  be  a  barrister  of 
ten  years'  standing,  and  holds  office  for  life, 
whilst  the  other  two  need  not  be  lawyers,  and 
are  appointed  for  a  term  of  seven  years.  This 
commission,  however,  delegates  most  of  its  work 
to  sub-commissions.  Barristers,  solicitors,  and 
persons  possessing  a  practical  acquaintance  with 
the  value  of  land  in  Ireland  are  competent 
to  be  appointed  to  the  office  of  assistant-com- 
missioner. The  Crofters'  Commission  consists 
of  three  persons,  of  whom  one  must  be  an  advo- 
cate of  ten  years'  standing. 

(c)  Procedure. —  The  procedure  of  such  a 
judicial  commission  as  above  described  is  wholly 
determined  either  by  the  statutes  under  which 
it  acts  or  by  rules  drawn  up  by  itself.  There 
is  no  implied  adoption  of  any  system  of  pro- 
cedure followed  in  any  of  the  regular  courts. 
At  least  such  adoption  is  limited  to  one  or  two 
equitable  principles,  such  as  that  of  hearing 
both  parties  to  a  dispute,  which  we  hardly  re- 
gard as  technical.  Appeals  to  a  superior  court 
on  questions  of  fact  are  not  allowed,  since  this 
would  defeat  the  purpose  of  instituting  such 
commissions  ;  but  appeals  on  questions  of  law 
are  in  some  cases  permitted.  Such  commissions 
as  above  described  are  for  some  purposes  a  neces- 
sity of  the  body  politic.  But  their  unnecessary 
multiplication  would  be  a  great  evil.  A  tri- 
bunal established  to  deal  with  a  special  class  of 
cases  is  often  the  readiest  instrument  of  injustice 
or  oppression.  Everybody  is  interested  in  the 
impartiality  of  a  court  before  which  he  may 
appear  as  defendant.  But  many  unfortunately 
will  applaud  j)artiality  in  a  court  where  defend- 
ants belong  exclusively  to  an  unpopular  class 
like  landlords  or  railway  companies.  As  com- 
pared Avitli  judges  who  are  also  jurists,  judges 
who  have  had  no  legal  discipline  are  less  likely 
to  deal  with  causes  in  a  severely  judicial  spirit, 
to  consider  sufficiently  the  consequences  of 
making  a  precedent,  or  to  uphold  that  stringency 
of  procedure  which,  tedious  as  it  may  seem,  is 
the  best  safeguard  against  passion  or  careless- 
ness. Hitherto  the  predominance  of  the  regular 
courts  of  justice  has  protected  us  from  most  of 
the  evils  which  might  have  been  feared  from 
commissions  armed  with  judicial  power.  But 
the  multiplication  of  extraordinary  tribunals 
and  of  special  procedures  would  break  dowoi 
this  predominance,  and  with  it  the  old  English 
principle  of  submitting  to  a  regular  court  for 
adjudication  in  the  regular  way  every  question 
which  can  be  formulated  in  terms  of  law — a 
principle  always  precious  and  always  difficult 
to  maintain,  but  in  an  age  of  popular  govern- 


ment especially  invaluable  and  yet  especially 
liable  to  be  overthrown. 

[For  further  particulars  respecting  the  Rail- 
way Commission  see  the  Acts  36  &  37  Vict, 
c.  48,  and  51  &  52  Vict.  c.  25,  and  the  Acts 
therein  referred  to ;  also  the  report  of  the 
joint-committee  of  Lords  and  Commons  on  rail- 
way amalgamation,  1872  ;  and  the  text-books 
on  the  law  relating  to  railways. 

Respecting  the  Irish  Land  Commission,  see 
the  Act  44  &  45  Vict.  c.  49  and  the  amending 
Acts.  See  also  the  rules  issued  by  the  Irish 
Land  Commission,  especially  those  of  October 
1881. 

Respecting  the  Crofters'  Commission  see  the 
Act  49  &  50  Vict.  c.  29  and  the  amending  Act.] 

F.  c.  M. 

COMMISSIONER.     See  Factor. 

COMMISSIONERS  OF  SEQUESTRATED 
ESTATE.     See  Bankruptcy,  Scotland. 

COMMITTEE  (with  reference  to  cases  of 
lunacy).  A  person  charged  to  represent  the 
interests  of  a  lunatic,  either  as  committee  of 
his  person  or  as  committee  of  his  estate.  Com- 
mittees are  appointed  for  those  lunatics  only 
whose  mental  incapacity  has  been  established 
by  the  inquisition  of  one  of  the  masters  in 
lunacy,  either  with  or  without  the  assistance 
of  a  jury.  The  same  person  is  frequently 
appointed  in  both  capacities,  i.e.  as  committee 
of  the  person  and  of  the  estate  of  a  lunatic. 
The  administration  of  the  property  of  a  lunatic 
so  found  by  inquisition  is  to  a  gi-eat  extent 
imder  the  control  of  the  lunacy  authorities. 

COMMITTEE  OF  INSPECTION  (bank- 
ruptcy). A  committee  consisting  of  not  less 
than  three  and  not  more  than  five  persons, 
selected  from  the  creditors  of  an  insolvent 
debtor  at  the  first  or  any  subsequent  meeting 
of  creditors,  for  the  purpose  of  superintending 
the  administration  of  the  bankrupt's  property 
by  the  trustee.  The  trustee  cannot  exercise 
certain  powers  without  the  permission  of  the 
committee  of  inspection,  and  tlie  committee  can 
take  the  initiative  in  certain  other  proceedings. 
The  appointment  of  a  committee  of  inspection 
is  not  compulsory,  and  the  act  provides  that  in 
the  absence  of  such  a  committee  the  Board  of 
Trade  is  to  exercise  its  functions.  [See  Bank- 
ruptcy Act,  1883,  46  &  47  Vict.  c.  52,  specially 
§§  22,  57,  58  (2),  64,  74  (4),  89  (1),  also 
Bankruptcy  Act,  1890,  53  &  54  Vict.  c.  71, 
R  51  Y,.  s 

COMMODATU]\L  A  term  of  Roman  law 
used  to  express  the  loan  of  a  thing  which  had 
to  be  returned  in  specie  {i.e.  in  the  same  kind). 

COMMODITY.  The  idea  of  something  com- 
modious  in  the  way  of  usefulness  is  never  absent 
from  the  use  of  this  word  in  an  economic  sense, 
but  to  this  meaning  a  very  wide  interpretation 
is  given  by  some  economic  writers,  while  others 
are  disposed  to  restrict  its  application  much 


358 


COMMON  ASSURANCE— COMMONS 


more  closely.  A.  Smith  (  Wealth  of  Nations, 
bk.  iii.  ch.  iii.)  defines  the  difference  be- 
tween productive  and  unproductive  labour  as 
that  which  does  or  "does  not  fix  and  realise 
itself  in  any  permanent  subject  or  vendible  com- 
modity which  endures  after  that  labour  is  past, 
and  for  which  an  equal  amount  of  labouf  could 
aftei-wards  be  procured."  Ricardo  (ch.  i.  §  1) 
uses  the  word  in  a  somewhat  different  manner. 
"  If  a  commodity  were  in  no  way  useful,  in 
other  words,  if  it  could  in  no  way  contribute  to 
our  gratification,  it  would  be  destitute  of  ex- 
changeable value,"  and  includes  among  "the 
mass  of  commodities,"  "rare  statues  and  pic- 
tures, scarce  books  and  coins,  wines  of  a  peculiar 
quality."  With  J.  S.  Mill  {Principles  of  Politi- 
cal Economy,  bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.  §  3),  while  other 
considerations  come  in,  the  word  is  employed 
mainly  in  the  same  sense  as  by  Ricardo. 
Mill  speaks  of  the  product  of  labour  as  "utili- 
ties," among  which  he  would  class  not  only  the 
labour  of  the  physician  and  the  teacher,  but 
that  of  the  musical  performer  and  the  actor. 
This  idea  is  further  developed  by  H.  Sidgwick 
(Principles  of  Political  Economy,  bk.  i.  ch. 
iv.)  who  proposes  to  extend  the  terms  "produce" 
and  "commodities  "  so  as  to  include  "consum- 
able services,"  such  as  the  utilities  developed 
by  "literary,  artistic,  and  scientific  culture." 
In  this  view  E.  Cannan  {Elementary  Political 
Economy,  pt.  ii.  §  2)  includes  "services  which 
do  not  involve  the  production  of  a  useful 
material  object "  among  "commodities."  The 
difficulty  of  exact  definition  of  "productive" 
and  "unproductive"  labour  has  led  to  this 
extension  of  the  use  of  the  term  "commodity." 
The  examples  from  the  authors  cited  above 
sufiiciently  explain  this  gradual  development. 
The  original  use  was  wide,  e.g.  "Tickling 
commodity,  the  bias  of  the  world"  {Kin^  John), 
and  elsewhere  in  Shakespeare  frequently  (Tt^eZ/'^A 
Night,  Henry  IV.,  etc.) 

COMMON  ASSURANCE.  The  legal  evi- 
dences of  the  transfer  of  real  property.  These 
have  been  called  "common"  assurances  as  op- 
posed to  special  methods  of  transfer  such  as 
fines  or  recoveries. 

[Stephen's  Gommentaries,  bk.  ii.  pt.  i.  c.  xv.] 

J.  E,  c.  M. 

COMMON  EMPLOYMENT,  Doctrine  of. 
"  A  servant,  when  he  engages  to  serve  a  master, 
undertakes,  as  between  himself  and  his  master, 
to  run  all  the  ordinary  risks  of  the  service,  in- 
cluding the  risk  of  negligence  upon  the  part  of 
a  fellow-servant  when  he  is  acting  in  the  dis- 
charge of  his  duty  as  servant  of  him  who  is  the 
common  master  of  both."  This  extract  from 
the  judgment  of  Earle,  C.-J.,  in  Tunney  v. 
Midland  Railway  Co.  (L.R.  1  C.P.  at  p.  290) 
may  be  taken  as  a  judicial  statement  of  the 
doctrine  of  common  employment  first  suggested 
in  1837  in  Priestley  v.  Fowler  (3  M.  &  W.  1), 
and  afterwards  adopted  by  the  House  of  Lords. 


In  the  earlier  cases  various  reasons  were  given 
in  support  of  the  doctrine,  but  in  the  later  cases 
the  tendency  is  to  base  the  rule  upon  an  implied 
contract  entered  into  by  the  servant  with  his 
master  that  the  latter  should  not  be  under  any 
necessity  to  indemnify  him  from  the  negligence 
of  a  fellow -servant.  In  order  to  establish 
common  employment  it  is  not  necessary  that 
the  servants  should  be  employed  about  the  same 
kind  of  work  ;  it  is  sufficient  that  they  are  en- 
gaged under  the  same  employer  for  the  purposes 
of  the  same  business,  however  difierent  in  detaO 
those  purposes  may  be.  The  relative  rank  of 
the  servants  is  immaterial,  and  a  stranger  who 
voluntarily  gives  help  is  for  the  time  regarded 
as  a  servant. 

The  legal  effects  of  the  doctrine  have  been  to 
some  extent  modified  by  the  43  &  44  Vict.  c.  42 
Under  that  act  a  workman  is  entitled  to  com 
pensation  for  injuries  resulting  from  the  negli 
gence  of  a  fellow-servant  acting  as  a  super^ 
intendent  or  imder  orders  issued  by  the  master, 
Special  provision  is  made  for  railway  servants 
who  may  claim  damages  from  their  employer 
for  the  negligence  of  their  fellow-servants  in 
charge  of  any  signal,  points,  locomotive  engine, 
or  train  upon  a  railway.  An  employer  is  also 
made  liable^to  his  servants  for  any  defect  in  the 
condition  of  the  ways,  works,  machinery,  or 
plant  connected  with  his  business.  The  right 
to  claim  compensation  is,  however,  burdened 
Avith  numerous  onerous  conditions. 

[Addison  on  Torts,  by  H.  Smith,  London,  1887. 
— Treatise  on  the  Principles  of  Obligations  arising 
from  Civil  Wrongs  in  the  Common  Law,  by  F. 
Pollock,  London,  1887.  As  to  liability  of  em- 
ployers in  foreign  countries,  see  Pari.  Pap.  Com- 
mercial, 1886,  No.  21. — Harvard  Law  Review, 
December  1888.  On  the  subject  generally,  see 
Essays  in  Jurisprudence,  by  F.  Pollock,  London, 
1882.— Parliamentary  Papers,  H.  C,  1876,  No. 
372  ;  1877,  No.  285.— Report  of  Select  Committee, 
1886,  No.  192.]  J.E.C.M. 

COMMON  GOOD  (Scotland).  Property  be- 
longing to  a  municipal  corporation,  administered 
by  the  magistrates.  A.  D. 

COMMONS.  Upon  the  origin  of  rights  of 
common  there  are  two  main  theories.  The 
legal  theory,  in  its  crudest  form,  traces  the 
primitive  form  of  property  to  individual  owner- 
ship, and  regards  rights  of  common  as  being 
based  upon  the  grant  or  the  sufferance  of  an 
individual  owner.  The  historical  theory  traces 
the  natural  or  original  form  of  property  to 
common  ownership,  and  sees  in  rights  of 
common  the  survivals  of  an  era  before  the  evolu- 
tion of  individual  ownership.  So  far  as  the 
soil  of  England  is  concerned,  the  balance  of 
probability  appears  to  be  in  favour  of  the 
view  that  the  legal  theory,  with  certain  modi- 
fications, approximates  most  closely  to  the 
truth.  The  question  may  have  more  than 
antiquarian  importance,  because  it  has  a  direct 
bearing  upon  that  theory  of  the  nation  alisatior 


COMMONS 


359 


of  the  land  which  assumes  as  its  basis  the 
original  common  ownership  of  the  soil.  If  the 
historical  theory  is  correct,  rights  of  common 
represent  all  that  the  encroachments  of  indi- 
vidual owners  failed  to  absorb  ;  if  the  legal 
theory. is  coiTCct,  rights  of  common  represent 
the  encroachments  of  servile  tenants  upon  the 
possessions  of  individual  owners.  The  essence 
of  the  Mark  system  or  Teutonic  village  com- 
munity of  freemen  is  that  the  territory  of  the 
mark,  or  the  soil  occupied  by  the  agi-arian 
association,  was  owned  by  the  community  by 
which  it  was  cultivated,  or  by  the  tribe  or 
nation  of  which  the  community  formed  a  part. 
Community  of  occupation  and  co-tillage  are 
characteristic  features  of  the  Anglo-Saxon  sys- 
tem of  farming  in  the  dawn  of  agricultural  history 
(see  Agriculture  in  England).  Writers  like 
Maurer,  Kemble,  Freeman,  Nasse,  and  others, 
have  therefore  argued  or  assumed  that  the 
mark  system  existed  in  this  country  in  its  pure 
form,  and  their  contentions  are  supported  by 
the  researches  of  Sir  H.  Maine  into  the  village 
community  (see  Digby,  History  of  the  Law  of 
Real  Property,  and  Joshua  Williams,  Rights  of 
Commons).  If  this  historical  view  is  correct, 
then  the  manorial  system  is  an  encroachment 
upon  the  mark  system,  the  "land-law  of  the 
noble  "  superseded  the  "  land-law  of  the  people," 
the  mark  of  independent  freemen  was  degraded 
into  the  manor  of  serfs  and  semi-servile  tenants, 
and  commons  are  a  survival  of  the  primitive 
form  of  property  which  existed  in  this  country. 
This  view  is  taken  by  Elton  {Tenures  of  Kent), 
who  dates  the  encroachments  of  individual  upon 
common  ownership,  and  of  the  manor  upon  the 
mark,  from  the  reign  of  Edward  the  Confessor. 
But  it  is  doubtful  whether  the  mark  as  a  system 
of  land  ownership  ever  existed  in  this  country. 
As  a  unit  of  local  administration  it  is  assumed 
by  Stubbs  {Constitutional  History,  vol.  i.  83-86), 
but  even  this  assumption  is  open  to  question 
(see  Lodge's  Anglo-Saxon  Law,  p.  82).  Al- 
though, as  a  means  of  farming,  the  mark  system 
indisputably  prevailed  and  regulated  the  agii- 
culture  of  the  country  till  the  present  century, 
Seebohm  {Village  Community)  has  shown  good 
reason  to  doubt  whether  the  partners  of  the 
association  were  ever  in  this  country  the 
independent  owners  of  the  land  they  tilled, 
and  whether  they  were  not  always  tenants 
tilling  soil  over  which  they  enjoyed  regulated 
customary  rights,  but  of  which  they  were  not 
the  owners.  He  proves  beyond  all  question 
that  in  many  cases  the  land  was  in  Anglo- 
Saxon  times  owned  by  individuals  and  culti- 
vated by  communities  who  held  under  their 
lords  by  semi-servile  tenure.  These  estates 
readily  adapted  themselves  with  the  slightest 
possible  changes  to  the  Norman  system  of 
manors.  Thus  modified,  the  legal  theory  is  I 
probably  most  near  the  truth.  According  to  I 
Blackstone  {Commentaries,   11.    92)   and   Coke  | 


{Complete  Copyholder,  p.  8,  etc.),  rights  of 
common  existed  subsequently  to  manors,  and 
originated  in  the  grant  or  the  sufferance  of  the 
lord.  And  this  is  the  legal  basis  upon  which 
common  rights  rest.  As  a  question  of  fact  it 
may  still  be  disputed  whether  rights  of  common 
over  the  wastes  of  a  manor  are  exercised  by  the 
association  of  farmers  in  virtue  of  their  former 
ownership  of  the  soil,  or  by  the  gi-ant  or  suff"er- 
ance  of  the  individual  owner,  whose  tenants 
they  are.  But  there  can  be  no  dispute  that 
since  the  Norman  Conquest  such  rights  are 
legally  of  the  nature  of  exceptional  rights 
granted  over  land  by  its  real  owner  to  his 
tenants.  They  are  of  four  kinds  :  (1)  Append- 
ant, i.e.  attached  or  incident  to  the  ten- 
ancies of  freeholders ;  (2)  appurtenant,  i.e. 
enjoyed  by  strangers  In  respect  of  land  not 
belonging  to  the  manorial  estate  ;  (3)  in  gross, 
irrespective  of  land  at  all;  {^)  customary,  i.e. 
enjoyed  by  copyholders.  Such  rights  differ  not 
only  in  origin  but  in  kind.  Thus  there  may  be 
commons  of  pasture,  of  piscary  (fishing),  of  tur- 
bary (turf- cutting),  of  estovers  (cutting  or  taking 
wood). 

The  later  history  of  commons  is  a  history 
on  the  one  side  of  attempts  to  extinguish  the 
rights  enjoyed,  and  on  the  other  of  efforts  to 
resist  such  encroachments.  At  first  no  public 
rights  were  recognised  ;  resistance  was  made  if 
at  all,  in  the  interests  only  of  the  commoners. 
Opposition  to  the  enclosure  of  commons  entered 
upon  a  new  phase  in  1845  (Gen.  Inclosure  Act, 
8  &  9  Vict.  e.  148),  when  the  necessity  of  pre- 
serving commons  as  places  of  recreation  or  as 
breathing  spaces  in  crowded  districts  was 
recognised.  Considering  the  untempered  con- 
demnation which  has  been  passed  on  the 
Inclosure  Acts  by  popular  speakers  and  writers 
in  recent  years,  it  is  amusing  to  contrast 
Bentham's  opinion  that  "the  tendency  of  the 
General  Inclosure  Bill  seems  alike  favom-able 
to  the  interests  of  the  rich  and  poor."  .  .  . 
"  It  effects  the  raising  of  the  wages  of  labour  " 
(Poor  Bill  introduced  by  Mr.  Pitt,  Works,  vol. 
viii.  p.  449).  Miss  Martineau  in  her  illustrations 
of  political  economy  is  equally  partial  to  enclos- 
ures. We  may  therefore  distinguish  between 
(A)  commoners'  opposition  up  to  1845,  and  (B) 
public  opposition  after  1845.  (A)  Legislation 
to  limit  and  restrain  the  rights  of  lords  of 
manors  to  enclose  their  wastes  begins  with  the 
statute  of  Merton  (1235)  and  the  statute  of 
Westminster  (1285),  which  protected  respec- 
tively commons  appendant  and  commons  ap- 
purtenant. Down  to  the  year  1800  commons 
could  only  be  enclosed  by  means  of  private  acta 
of  parliament.  But  under  the  pressure  of  in- 
creasing population  it  was  necessary  to  utilise 
every  available  acre.  In  1801,  through  the 
exertions  of  Young  and  Sir  J.  Sinclair,  an  In- 
closure Act  was  passed  (41  Geo.  III.  c.  109) 
which  incorporated  the  provisions  generally  in 


360 


COMMONS— COMMUNE 


eluded  in  the  special  acts,  and  regulated,  and 
at  the  same  time  facilitated,  the  enclosure  of 
land.  The  following  statistics  of  enclosures 
illustrate  the  extent  to  which  agriculture  pro- 
gressed in  the  latter  half  of  the  18th  century. 
Between  1700  and  1845  there  were  3835  en- 
closure acts  and  7,572,664  acres  enclosefl,  the 
total  area  of  Great  Britain  being  56,786,199 
acres,  and  the  cultivated  area  about  32,500,000. 
Of  this  total  number  3209  acts  were  passed  in 
the  reign  of  George  III.  and  6,288,910  acres  en- 
closed. (B)  Signs  of  the  change  of  policy  which 
protects  open  spaces  are  previously  seen  in  18th 
century  tracts  (e.g.  Inquiry  into  the  Influence 
of  Enclosures  on  Population  (1786),  or  Ad- 
vantages and  Disadvantages  of  Inclosing  (1772)), 
and  in  the  debates  upon  the  Inclosure  Bill  of 
1836  (see  Hansard  35,  1226  and  1271).  But 
the  new  policy  received  full  expression  in  1845, 
when  the  General  Inclosure  Act  was  passed 
(8  &  9  Vict.  c.  148).  It  was  primarily  passed 
to  facilitate  the  enclosure  of  commons  and 
wastes  which  impeded  the  productive  employ- 
ment of  land,  and  for  this  object  it  appointed 
commissioners  who  were  to  decide  whether  or  not 
enclosures  were  expedient.  But  it  protects  com- 
mons within  a  certain  distance  of  London  or 
large  towns  from  enclosures,  requires  the  appro- 
priation of  allotments  for  the  exercise  and  re- 
creation of  the  neighbourhood,  and  declares 
that  no  village  greens  shall  be  enclosed.  But 
it  was  felt  that  the  commissioners  did  not 
sufficiently  protect  the  public.  And  in  this 
direction  legislation  has  since  that  time  ad- 
vanced. The  public  and  not  the  landlord  is 
now  treated  as  the  real  owner.  The  Metropolitan 
Commons  Act,  1866,  was  passed  in  this  spirit. 
In  1869  a  committee  of  the  House  of  Commons 
reported  on  metropolitan  commons,  and  sug- 
gested various  alterations  in  the  existing  law  of 
enclosures.  Many  of  their  suggestions  were 
embodied  in  the  Inclosure  Act  of  1876.  The 
preamble  of  this  act  shows  how  completely  the 
spirit  of  legislation  was  changed.  It  expressly 
forbids  the  commissioners  to  sanction  any  en- 
closures unless  they  are  satisfied  that  such 
enclosures  will  benefit  not  only  private  interests 
but  the  neighbourhood.  Clauses  in  the  act 
also  provide  for  the  management,  protection, 
and  preservation  of  commons.  Commons  may 
now  be  enclosed  in  one  of  three  ways — (i.)  they 
may  be  appropriated  by  railway  companies 
under  the  powers  of  their  acts  ;  (ii.)  they  may 
be  enclosed  under  the  Inclosure  Act ;  (iii.)  they 
may  be  enclosed  by  an  individual  owner  who 
claims  to  be  legally  entitled  to  enclose. 

[For  works  relating  to  the  subject  of  enclosures 
see,  in  addition  to  those  quoted  in  the  text, 
Fitzherbert  on  Surveying  (1523). — Tusser's  Com- 
parison between  Champion  Country  and  Several 
(E.  E.  Text  Society). — Lee's  Regulated  Inclosure 
(1556). — Lawrence's  Duty  of  a  Land  Steward 
^1727).— Young's  Enclosure  of  Wastes  (1801).— 


Reports  of  the  Board  of  Agriculture,  1793 
1813. — Elton's  Commons  and  Waste  Lands. — 
Woolrych's  Rights  of  Commons. — Scruttou's  Com- 
mons and  Common  Fields.  ]  r.  e.  p. 

COMMONTY  (Scotch).  Common  or  waste,' 
over  which  there  are  rights  of  common,    a.  d. 

COMMUNE.  When  a  group  of  families 
forming  a  tribe  cease  to  lead  a  wandering  life 
and  settle  down  in  a  fixed  place  of  abode,  the 
commune  springs  into  being.  At  present,  in 
India  the  village  communities  are  considered 
as  composed  of  families  descended  from  a 
common  ancestor. 

The  commune  is  society's  primary  organic 
cell.  A  collection  of  communes  united  under 
the  rule  of  a  sovereign  power  forms  the  state. 
Primitively  in  all  countries  the  commune  was 
a  political  body  where  autonomy  reigned,  and 
which  itself  regulated  all  the  local  intereats  of 
its  inhabitants.  We  see  this  in  the  Anglo- 
Saxon  Tunscip,  in  the  Toumship  of  New 
England,  in  the  Germanic  Gemeinde,  in 
the  Gemeente  of  the  Netherlands,  in  the 
Gommunaut^s  of  the  Neo-latin  peoples,  in  the 
Russian  3fir,  in  the  Javanese  Dessa,  in  the 
Indies,  and  in  Japan,  China,  and  Arabia,  or  in 
other  words,  in  all  climates  and  amongst  all 
races.  As  the  families  living  on  the  communal 
land  have  common  interests  to  be  considered 
and  provided  and  legislated  for,  it  necessarily 
follows  that  the  commune  becomes  a  sort  of 
institution  of  the  economic  order.  This  is 
clearly  apparent  in  following  the  birth  and 
development  of  the  New  England  townships. 

As  soon  as  a  planiation  is  formed,  the  heads 
of  the  different  families  meet  together  in  the 
spring-time,  every  year,  in  a  town-meeting,  to 
consult  respecting  public  interests,  and  to 
appoint  the  various  functionaries  to  fulfil  the 
same :  Churchwardens  for  the  supervision  of 
matters  connected  with  the  church  ;  overseers 
of  the  poor  to  distribute  succour  to  the  needy  ; 
highway  surveyors  to  maintain  the  roads  in 
good  order ;  fence  viewers  to  overlook  the 
hedges,  gates,  and  enclosures  generally ;  wardens 
for  the  repression  of  drunkenness,  cruelty  to 
animals ;  constables  or  police  for  the  maintenance 
of  general  order  ;  and  school  trustees  or  school- 
board  officers  to  attend  to  the  schools  and 
appoint  competent  masters  and  mistresses. 
Everywhere,  too,  at  the  commencement,  as  I 
have  shown  in  my  book  Primitive  Property, 
the  commune  reserved  the  greater  portion  of 
its  land  as  common  pasture  ground  (commons), 
where  all  the  inhabitants  had  the  right  to  send 
their  cattle  to  graze,  and  the  remainder  was 
periodically  divided  up  between  all  the  families 
of  the  commune,  with  the  exception  of  the 
little  plot  surrounding  each  dwelling,  which 
was  the  private  property  of  the  owner.  Accord- 
ing to  Caesar  and  Tacitus,  this  was  the  agrarian 
system  which  existed  among  the  Germanic 
races,  and  it  may  still  be  found  at  the  preseni 


COMM  U  N  E— COMMUNICATION 


361 


day,  with  precisely  the  same  distinctive  charac- 
teristics, in  the  Russian  Mir  and  in  the  Javanese 
Dessa.  If  one  be  desirous  of  studying  the 
working  and  results  of  this  system  on  a  small 
scale,  one  may  do  so  in  the  allmends  of 
Switzerland  and  southern  Germany.  The  level 
land  lying  along  the  shore  of  the  lake  of  Brienz, 
between  Interlaken  and  Bonigen,  is  the  all- 
mend  of  this  latter  village.  It  is  divided  into 
small  plots  where  vegetables  and  fruit-trees  are 
cultivated.  Each  of  these  plots  is  owned  by 
the  head  of  a  family  for  his  life.  The  com- 
munal allmend  comprises  forests,  which 
supply  the  inhabitants  with  wood  for  firing  and 
building  purposes,  pasturage  where  their  cattle 
can  graze  in  summer,  and  arable  land  whence 
they  can  procure  a  portion  of  their  sustenance. 
The  commune  is  thus  a  sort  of  hive  which 
furnishes  each  family  with  supplies,  and  thus 
attaches  it  to  the  soil  of  the  Alma  Mater. 

At  the  present  day,  owing  to  the  growing 
exigencies  of  civilisation,  the  commune  is  step 
by  step  recovering  the  economic  status  it  pos- 
sessed at  the  outset.  This  is  plainly  observable 
in  countries  where  civilisation  is  the  most 
advanced,  in  the  United  States  and  Scotland, 
for  instance.  The  city  of  Glasgow  may  be 
mentioned  as  an  example.  The  city  here 
not  only  opens  schools  for  the  entire  popu- 
lation but  also  supplies  the  drinking  water, 
the  gas,  lights  at  its  own  expense  the  common 
staircases  of  large  lodging-houses,  lets  out 
heating  apparatus,  stoves,  and  fixtures,  at 
a  low  rental  ;  it  considers  tramways  to  be 
a  part  of  the  street,  and  allows  them  to 
be  worked  by  a  company  only  on  the  fixed 
condition  that  the  price  shall  not  exceed  a 
penny  a  mile,  and  that  morning  and  evening 
cars  be  run  for  workmen  at  half-price.  The 
local  sanitary  legislation  is  also  thoroughly 
perfected.  There  is  complete  municipalisation 
of  markets  and  slaughter-houses  ;  the  city  also 
entered  upon  a  scheme  of  wholesale  demolition 
of  slums  and  overcrowded  districts,  in  view  of 
better  housing  of  the  poor,  and  now  it  is  build- 
ing houses  on  sites  it  has  cleared,  and  wiU  then 
enter  upon  the  functions  of  house  landlord  ;  it 
has  also  opened  a  series  of  common  lodging- 
houses,  having  accommodation  for  2000  persons 
nightly,  and  has  established  a  magnificent 
system  of  baths,  swimming-baths,  and  wash- 
houses  ;  it  maintains  a  corps  of  lady  inspectors 
who  go  about  among  poor  families  to  inculcate 
domestic  cleanliness  ;  it  has  entered  upon  the 
general  laundry  business,  and  is  serving  families 
at  the  current  prices.  Museums  of  all  sorts, 
parks,  playgrounds,  and  public  libraries  have 
been  opened  to  foster  the  progress  of  civilisation. 

It  may  be  seen,  in  fact,  in  all  parts  of  the 
world  that  the  old  "commune"  notion  is  gain- 
ing ground  more  or  less  rapidly,  and  the 
socialistic  ideal  of  the  state  as  a  providential 
power  doing  its  best  to  remedy  the  results  of 


social  inequality,  is  little  by  little  forcing  itself 
upon  the  world.  Attention  can  only  be  drawn 
here  to  this  fact.  Its  advantages  and  dis- 
advantages must  be  elsewhere  discussed.  One 
thing,  however,  appears  probable,  that  in  the 
future  organisation  of  society,  communes  will,  as 
at  its  outset,  play  an  important  economic  part. 

[E.  de  Laveleye,  Primitive  Property,  trans. 
1878.]  E.  de  L. 

COMMUNE  OF  PARIS,  1871.  It  is  widely 
believed  in  England  that  the  Commune  of  1871 
was  primarily  a  communist  institution .  In  deny- 
ing this  the  better  informed  are  apt  to  merely 
explain  the  true  meaning  of  the  word  Commune 
(q.v.),  and  leave  the  impression  that  the  estab- 
lishment of  the  Commune  was  only  an  extreme 
application  of  the  principle  of  local  self-govern- 
ment (e.g'.  P.  G.  Hamerton,  French  and  English, 
1889,  p.  xii.  n.)  This  is  nearly  as  incorrect  a» 
the  more  common  belief.  It  is  quite  true  that 
adherents  of  the  Commune  are  not  properly 
called  "communists,"  the  French  word  being 
not  communistes  but  commun/iux  or  commun- 
ards, but  it  is  not  the  case  that  the  Commune 
movement  was  a  purely  political  aft'air.  Local 
and  temporary  circumstances  made  its  short- 
lived success  possible,  but  any  real  strength 
which  it  possessed  was  entirely  contributed  by 
the  partisans  of  a  social  or  economic  revolution. 
About  one-third  of  the  members  of  the  council 
of  the  Commune  were  connected  with  the  Intek- 
NATIONAL  {q.v.)  The  chief  economic  measure, 
passed  by  it  or  recommended  by  its  committee 
on  labour  and  exchange,  which  was  entirely 
composed  of  socialists,  provided  for  the  remission 
of  house  rents  for  the  period  covered  by  the 
siege,  the  gratuitous  return  of  all  articles  under 
£1  in  value  pawned  at  the  Mont  de  Piete,  the 
establishment  of  a  list  fixing  the  wages  of 
labourers  in  communal  contracts,  and  the  trans- 
ference of  Avorkshops  abandoned  by  their  owners 
to  associations  of  workmen  (y.  Anarchism). 

[Lissagaray,  Histoire  de  la  Commune  de  1871, 
Bruxelles,  1876. — J.  Leighton,  Paris  under  the 
Commune,  1871. — P.  Delion,  Les  memhres  de  la 
commune  etdu  comitS  central,  1871. — G.  de  Mol- 
inari,  Les  Clubs  rouges  pendant  le  Siege,  1871. 
— E.  de  Laveleye,  Le  Socialisvie  Contemporain, 
Bruxelles,  1881,  pp.  273,  279-282,  309,  310.— B. 
Malon,  Histoire  du  Socialisme,  1883.]  E.  c. 

COMMUNICATION,  Means  of.  Modem 
facilities  for  communication  between  one  district 
and  another  are  so  complete  generally  that  the 
fact  that  these  facilities  are  comparatively  recent 
is  not  unfrequently  forgotten.  Their  economic 
value  is  so  great  that  it  is  scarcely  possible  to 
over-estimate  it.  A  reference  to  the  condition 
of  matters  before  present  facilities  existed  in 
England  will  enable  this  to  be  better  understood. 
Porter,  in  his  Progress  of  the  Nation,  written 
1842,  makes  the  following  observations  on  a  part 
of  Sussex  now  practically  included  among  the 
suburban  districts  of  the  metropolis,  and  acces 


362 


COMMUNIO— COMMUNISM 


/ 


sible,  when  Porter  wrote,  within  four  hours  of 
London.  "  An  inhabitant  of  Horsham,  in 
Sussex,  lately  living,  remembers,  when  a  boy, 
to  have  heard  from  a  person  whose  father  carried 
on  the  business  of  a  butcher  in  that  town,  that 
in  his  time  the  only  means  of  reaching  the 
metropolis  was  either  by  going  on  foot  or  riding 
on  horseback,  the  latter  of  which  undertakings 
was  not  practicable  at  all  periods  of  the  year, 
nor  in  every  state  of  the  weather  ;  that  the  roads 
were  not  at  any  time  in  such  a  condition  as  to 
admit  of  sheep  or  cattle  being  driven  upon  them 
to  the  London  markets,  and  that  for  this  reason 
the  farmers  were  prevented  sending  thither  the 
produce  of  their  land,  the  immediate  neighbour- 
hood being,  in  fact,  their  only  market.  Under 
these  circumstances,  a  quarter  of  a  fat  ox  was 
commonly  sold  for  about  15s.,  and  the  price  of 
mutton  throughout  the  year  was  only  five 
farthings  the  pound."  This  illustration,  as 
every  one  can  supply  the  present  condition  of 
matters  for  himself,  shows  the  effect  of  improved 
internal  communication  within  a  recent  period 
and  a  restricted  area.  Mr.  E.  Atkinson  has  in 
his  publications.  The  Relative  StreTigth  and 
Weakness  of  Nations,  etc.,  recorded  the  corre- 
sponding but  even  greater  effect  of  similar 
facilities  in  the  United  States  of  America — 
"The  wages  for  one  day's  work  of  an  average 
mechanic  in  the  far  East  will  pay  for  moving  a 
year's  subsistence  of  bread  and  meat  a  thousand 
miles  or  more  from  the  distant  West."  These 
instances  of  results  from  improvements  of  means 
of  communication  illustrate  comparatively  recent 
changes,  brought  about  by  their  means,  in  pro- 
duction, price,  etc.  Further  development  ^vill, 
no  doubt,  be  as  active  a  factor  in  the  future  as 
it  has  been  in  the  past.  The  main  part  of  the 
comforts  and  conveniences  of  life,  the  whole 
work  of  commerce,  to  refer  to  no  other  points, 
depend  on  the  power  of  ready  communication, 
which,  in  its  turn,  depends  almost  as  much  on 
the  absence  of  obstruction  on  the  part  of  govern- 
ments for  fiscal  and  other  purposes,  as  on  the 
extension  of  mechanical  facilities  (see  Rail- 
ways ;  Canals  ;  Tkanspoet,  Cost  op  Inland). 
[Many  economic  problems  presented  by  modern 
means  of  communication,  including  remarks  on 
their  utility  to  the  community  and  the  measure- 
ment in  money  of  that  utility,  are  discussed  with 
great  originality  by  Dupuit  in  the  Dictionnaire 
de  VLcon.  Politique,  under  the  heads  Routes  et 
Chemins,  Voies  de  Communications,  abridged  from 
certain  longer  memoirs  to  which  reference  will  be 
found  under  Dupuit.] 

COMMUNIO.  An  expression  of  Roman  law 
applied  collectively  to  a  number  of  persons 
jointly  interested  in  some  property  or  under- 
taking. If  the  joint  interest  arises  by  contract, 
the  Roman  writers  speak  of  societas  (partner- 
ship) ;  if  it  is  created  by  accident  (as  for  instance 
in  the  case  of  joint  heirs)  the  expression  corn- 
mv/nio  incidens  is  used  by  later  writers,   e.  s. 


COMMUNISM  is  the  theory  which  teaches 
that  the  labour  and  the  income  of  society 
should  be  distributed  equally  among  all  its 
members  by  some  constituted  authority.  For 
an  example  of  what  communists  mean  by  equal 
division  of  labour  and  income  the  following 
explanation  may  suffice  : — "Here  equality  must 
be  measured  by  the  capacity  of  the  worker 
and  the  need  of  the  consumer,  not  by  the 
intensity  of  the  labour  and  the  quantity  of 
things  consumed.  A  man  endowed  with  a 
certain  degree  of  strength,  when  he  lifts  a 
weight  of  ten  pounds,  labours  as  much  as 
another  man  with  five  times  the  strength  when 
he  lifts  fifty  pounds.  He  who,  to  satisfy  a 
burning  thirst,  swallows  a  pitcher  of  water, 
enjoys  no  more  than  his  comrade  who,  but 
slightly  thirsty,  sips  a  cupful.  The  aim  of  the 
communism  in  question  is  equality  of  pains  and 
pleasures,  not  of  consumable  things  and  workers' 
tasks "  (Buonarroti,  Conspiration  de  Babeuf, 
i.  297).     (See  Buonarroti.) 

As  communism  involves  the  conception  of 
society  as  an  industrial  association  for  the  pro- 
duction of  wealth,  it  is  of  modern  origin.  That 
conception  certainly  played  no  part  in  the  in- 
stitutions attributed  to  Minos  and  Lycurgus, 
nor  in  those  suggested  by  Plato  in  the  Republic. 
The  equal  distribution  of  wealth  among  a 
governing  class  was  then  upheld  as  desirable 
wholly  from  a  moral  and  political,  not  at  aU 
from  an  economic,  point  of  view  ;  equality  of 
distribution,  and,  still  more,  equality  of  labour, 
among  the  whole  population,  would  have  been 
utterly  abhorrent  to  the  minds  of  Greek  states- 
men and  philosophers,  if  they  had  been  able  to 
conceive  the  idea.  The  practice  of  the  earliest 
Christians  described  in  Acts  ii.  44,  45  ;  iv.  34, 
V.  8,  has  generally  been  considered  as  com- 
munistic, but  all  that  is  actually  said  is  that  a 
number  of  persons  sold  their  property  and  gave  \ 
the  proceeds  to  be  distributed  among  their 
poorer  fellows,  who  doubtless  treated  what  they 
received  as  income  ;  in  this  there  would  have 
been  no  communism  even  if  the  gifts  had  been 
compulsory,  and  Peter's  words  to  Ananias  show 
that  they  were  not.  The  first  exposition  of 
communism  is  to  be  found  in  Sir  Thomas 
More's  Utopia  (see  More,  Sir  T.)  published  at 
Lou  vain  in  1516.  Written  in  Latin,  the  Utopia 
was  accessible  to  all  the  learned  world  of 
the  time  ;  at  first  in  the  original,  and  after- 
wards in  translations,  it  has  had  an  enormous 
number  of  readers.  After  a  severe  criticism  of 
capital  punishment  for  theft,  of  the  habit  of 
maintaining  a  multitude  of  idle  followers,  and 
of  the  extension  of  pasture  at  the  expense  of 
arable  land.  More  enters  on  the  description 
of  a  nation  numbering  apparently  three  or 
four  million  souls,  living  a  simple  life  with- 
out private  property,  under  elected  officers 
who  fix  the  duration  of  requisite  labour 
and  generally  direct  production.     Distribution 


COMMUNISM 


363 


is  supposed  to  effect  itself  without  difficulty, 
as  the  impossibility  of  ostentation  and  the 
general  \bundance  prevent  any  one  from  de- 
manding more  than  his  fair  share  :  "  It  is  the 
fear  of  want  that  makes  any  of  the  whole  race 
of  animals  either  gi"eedy  or  ravenous. "  Division 
of  labour  exists,  but,  agricultural  labour  being  a 
"hard  course  of  life,"  every  one  must  take  his 
turn  in  the  fields.  The  institution  of  marriage 
is  only  slightly  modified,  but  the  adoption  of 
children  is  largely  practised  in  order  to  keep 
all  the  families  nearly  equal  in  size.  Increase 
of  population,  if  there  is  any,  is  dealt  with  by 
emigration.  There  is  a  small  class  of  unen- 
franchised persons  or  slaves,  consisting  of  con- 
victs condemned  to  hard  labour,  prisoners  taken 
in  battle,  and  foreigners  who  have  entered  the 
service  of  the  Utopians  voluntarily.  As  a  sub- 
stitute for  the  stimulus  to  industry  provided 
by  self-interest  when  private  property  is  estab- 
lished, the  fact  that  "  all  men  live  iu  full  view  " 
is  put  forward. 

It  is  highly  improbable  that  More  considered 
his  book  as  anything  more  than  a  picture  of  an 
entirely  ideal  state  of  society,  towards  which 
some  approximation  might  possibly  be  made  in 
certain  particulars.  Not  until  the  era  of  the 
French  Revolution  did  a  communist  organisa- 
tion of  society  come  to  be  thought  of  as  some- 
thing to  be  actively  striven  for,  and  completely 
realised  at  no  distant  date.  The  Civitas  Solis 
(1620)  of  Campanella  {q.v.),  a  work  of  small 
merit  and  importance  (for  a  translation,  see 
Ideal  Commonwealths,  in  Morley's  Universal 
Library),  is  far  less  practical  than  the  Utopia. 
The  immediate  precursors  of  the  communism  of 
the  Revolution  were  Morelly  and  Mably, 
writers  who,  in  accordance  with  the  fashion  of 
their  day,  placed  their  Utopias  in  "the  state  of 
nature."  Morelly  {q.v.),  in  his  Code  de  la 
Nature  (1755),  taught  that  man  naturally  pos- 
sesses every  virtue,  and  is  only  depraved  by  bad 
institutions,  the  chief  of  which  is  private  pro- 
perty. Every  one  would  be  industrious,  he 
thought,  if  it  were  not  that  some  are  deterred 
from  labour  by  the  enervation  of  riches,  and 
others  by  the  desperation  of  poverty.  He  de- 
clared, therefore,  that  it  would  be  "in  con- 
formity with  the  intentions  of  nature,"  if  every 
citizen  contributed  to  the  resources  of  the  state, 
in  accordance  with  his  strength,  talents,  and  age, 
and  in  return  were  whoUy  maintained  at  the 
public  expense.  Every  one  was  to  engage  in 
agriculture  between  the  ages  of  20  and  25. 
Celibacy  was  not  to  be  allowed.  Mably  {q.v.), 
who  was  a  brother  of  Condillac  {q.v.),  in 
Letters  I.  and  II.  o^  Doutes  proposes  aiix  philo- 
sophes  economistes  sur  I'ordre  naturel  et  essentiel 
des  socUtis  politiques  (1768),  endeavoured  to 
show,  in  opposition  to  Merciee  de  la  Riviere 
{q.v.),  that  private  property  in  land  is  not  the 
natural  and  necessary  basis  of  society.  On  the 
contrary,  he  said,  society  could  exist,  without 


property,  as  is  proved  by  the  cases  of  Sparta,  the 
Jesuits  in  Paraguay,  and  the  monastic  orders ; 
while  the  establishment  of  property  in  land  and 
inequality  of  condition,  has  been  the  great 
source  of  avarice,  ambition,  and  vanity.  In 
his  Train  de  la  Legislation  (1776),  Book  I.,  he 
maintained  the  same  views,  and  incidentally 
described  the  communist  arrangements  which 
nature,  as  he  thought,  dictated  to  primitive 
man;  he  imagines  "the  citizens  distributed 
into  different  classes,  the  more  robust  are 
appointed  to  cultivate  the  earth,  the  rest  work 
at  the  rough  handicrafts  with  which  society 
cannot  dispense."  "To  exclude  idleness,  all 
that  was  necessary  was  to  encourage  labour  by 
passing  laws  which  should  awaken  in  the  citizens 
the  natural  instinct  which  induces  us  to  seek 
the  esteem  of  our  fellows,  and  to  fear  their 
contempt."  But  it  was  undesirable,  he  ad- 
mitted frankly,  to  try  to  restore  the  lost  con- 
dition of  natural  equality.  The  rich  would 
resist  any  such  attempt,  and  it  is  doubtful  if 
the  poor  would  support  it,  and  still  more  doubt- 
ful if  they  "could  adopt  the  feelings  which 
would  be  in  harmony  with  their  new  position," 
if  the  attempt  were  successful. 

The  Revolution  in  France  was  economic  aa 
well  as  political.  It  made  the  people  far  more 
equal  in  wealth  than  before.  But  a  mere  re- 
distribution of  property,  even  when  it  makes 
wealth  more  equal,  is  not  a  communist  measure, 
and  need  not  tend  in  a  communist  direction. 
The  creation  of  a  gi-eat  number  of  small  free- 
holders, which  was  greatly  p'romoted  by  the 
Revolution,  is  considered  to  have  strengthened 
the  institution  of  separate  property.  Though 
there  was  a  large  class  which  desired  to  reduce 
or  destroy  the  inequality  between  rich  and  poor, 
there  were  but  few  who  saw  that  the  only  way 
to  create  and  maintain  equality  in  wealth  was 
to  establish  complete  communism,  and  were  at 
the  same  time  convinced  of  the  practicability  of 
such  a  change.  Babeuf  {q.v.)  and  his  fellow- 
conspirators  of  1796,  who  called  themselves 
the  "Equals,"  were  the  most  remarkable  repre- 
sentatives of  this  small  party.  How  far  the 
Equals  had  actually  thought  out  a  scheme  of 
communism  is  not  very  easy  to  decide,  since 
the  history  of  their  conspiracy,  written  by  their 
ablest  member,  Philippe  Buonarroti,  was  not 
published  till  1828.  Buonarroti  admits  that 
he  describes  their  economic  plans  almost  en- 
tirely from  memory  ;  he  has  probably  added 
many  ideas  which  belong  in  reality  to  a  later 
date  than  1796.  In  the  Babouvist  Utopia,  aa 
described  by  Buonarroti,  every  one  is  allotted  two 
different  occupations,  the  one  light  and  the 
other  hard.  To  give  variety  and  change  of 
scene,  all  are  employed  by  turns  in  the  trans- 
port and  postal  services.  Those  who  will  not 
work  are  treated  as  thieves  are  treated  under 
the  system  of  private  property.  Education, 
carried  on  in  vast  boarding-schools,  subordinates 


364 


COMMUNISM 


family  affection  to  patriotism.  The  increase  of 
population  is  stimulated  to  the  utmost.  Dis- 
tribution is  ruled  by  the  principle  of  strict 
equality  of  pains  and  pleasures.  The  transi- 
tion to  this  state  of  things  was  to  be  effected  by 
establishing  at  once  the  skeleton  of  a  great 
national  community,  which  would  rapidly  ac- 
quire all  property  by  means  of  free  gifts  and 
escheats,  bequest  and  inheritance  being  totally 
abolished.  For  the  existing  generation  ad- 
hesion to  the  community  would  be  voluntary. 
Whether  the  heads  of  the  Babouvist  conspii-acy 
desired  to  carry  out  some  such  scheme  as  this 
or  not,  their  immediate  object  was  to  over- 
throw the  Directory,  and  for  this  purpose 
appeals  to  the  love  of  plunder,  in  which  they 
dealt  very  freely,  were  likely  to  be  more  useful 
than  elaborate  schemes  of  orderly  communism. 
After  the  discovery  and  defeat  of  the  plot,  and 
the  execution  of  Babeuf  (May  1797),  the 
revolutionary  spirit  slumbered  for  a  time,  and 
communism,  which  was  as  yet  nothing  more 
than  an  incidental  outcome  of  the  desire  for 
destruction,  slumbered  also.  The  schemes  of 
Saint-Simon  {q.v.)  and  Foueier  (g-.i?.),  which 
soon  began  to  occupy  the  attention  of  those 
who  were  inclined  to  wish  for  social  reorganisa- 
tion, though  they  involve  distribution  by  con- 
stituted authority,  cannot  properly  be  con- 
sidered communistic,  as  they  lack  the  essential 
characteristic  of  communism  in  not  being 
founded  on  the  principle  of  equality.  Buon- 
arroti's book,  printed  at  Brussels  in  1828,  but 
not  much  read  in  France  till  some  time  after- 
wards, revived  to  some  extent  the  idea  of  com- 
munist equality,  and  led  to  the  publication 
(1837-40)  of  the  Moniteur  rdpublieain,  the 
Homme  lihre,  and  a  number  of  other  short-lived 
and  bloodthirsty  communist  newspapers.  The 
insignificance  of  the  Babouvist  party  was  shown 
in  the  futile  insurrection  of  12th  May  1839, 
when  the  followers  of  Armand  Barb^s,  Martin 
Bernard,  and  Louis  Auguste  Blanqui,  to  the 
number  of  three  or  four  hundred,  obtained 
possession  of  the  H6tel  de  ViUe  for  a  few  hours. 
In  the  next  year  merely  destructive  communism 
was  practically  superseded  in  France  by  "  Icar- 
ianism,"  the  creation  of  Cabet  (q.v.),  thought 
out  in  England,  where  Robert  Owen  {q.v.) 
was  the  chief  teacher  of  communism. 

Owen's  communism  was  very  different  from 
that  of  Babeuf,  Buonarroti,  and  their  followers. 
It  had  its  origin  not  in  politics  and  a  worship 
of  the  abstract  principle  of  equality,  but  in 
practical  philanthropy.  The  primary  object  of 
Owen  was  not  to  destroy  the  existing  state  of 
society,  but  to  substitute  for  it  a  new  state,  the 
superiority  of  which  he  considered  he  had  proved. 
Assistant  master  in  an  elementary  school  at  the 
age  of  seven,  draper's  apprentice  at  ten,  mule 
machine  maker  at  eighteen,  manager  of  an  im- 
portant cotton  spinning  factory  at  nineteen, 
and  successful  in  each  capacity,  he  had  every 


claim  to  be  considered  "a  practical  man,"  and 
it  was  entirely  through  his  own  experience  that 
he  arrived  at  his  schemes  of  social  regeneration. 
The  good  effects  of  his  treatment  of  the  factory 
hands  when  manager  and  part-proprietor  ol 
mills  in  Manchester  (1790-97)  and  New  Lanark 
(1797-1828)  established  in  his  mind  a  theory 
that  heredity  is  of  very  small  importance  as 
regards  character,  and  that  "it  is  impossible 
that  any  human  being  can  form  his  own  quali- 
ties or  character,"  which  are  really  formed 
by  education  and  surroundings.  This  theory, 
if  admitted,  is  obviously  an  excellent  basis  for 
communism.  By  its  denial  of  moral  responsi- 
bility it  overthrows  the  common  argument  that 
poverty  is  generally  "deserved,"  and  that 
private  property  is  therefore  just.  Further,  it 
avoids  the  error  of  confounding  wealth  or 
material  welfare  with  happiness,  and  it  was 
suitable  to  a  time  when  the  desirability  of 
making  elementary  education  more  general  was 
beginning  to  dawn  on  the  public  mind.  So 
Owen  developed  from  the  philanthropist  manu- 
facturer into  the  communist  projector.  In 
March  1817  he  submitted  to  the  House  of 
Commons'  committee,  then  considering  the  poor 
law,  a  report  which  he  had  drawn  up  for  the 
**  Associatioft  for  the  relief  of  the  manufacturing 
and  labouring  poor."  In  this  he  proposed  that 
the  unemployed  poor  should  be  formed  into 
communities  of  about  one  thousand  persons,  who 
should  be  provided  with  land  and  other  requi- 
sites of  production  by  the  state,  and  support 
themselves  by  agriculture  and  manufactures. 
He  says  nothing  in  the  report  itself  about  the 
principle  on  which  distribution  within  the  com- 
munities should  be  effected,  but  in  a  letter  to 
the  newspapers  of  30th  July  1817,  he  argues 
that  men  will  be  as  industrious  "in  a  com- 
munity of  mutual  and  combined  interests  as 
when  employed  for  their  individual  gain.  .  .  . 
Wherever  the  experiment  has  been  tried,  the 
labour  of  each  has  been  exerted  cheerfully." 
When  working  by  the  day,  he  adds,  the  worker 
has  no  interest  in  his  work,  and  when  he  works 
by  the  piece  he  is  apt  to  overwork  himself. 
"When  employed  with  others  in  a  community 
of  interests  both  these  extremes  are  avoided  ; 
the  labour  becomes  temperate  but  effective, 
and  may  be  easily  regulated  and  superintended. 
Besides,  the  principles  and  practices  are  now 
quite  obvious  by  which  any  inclinations  from 
the  most  indolent  to  the  most  industrious  may  M 
be  given  to  the  rising  generation."  The  scheme  'M 
was  wonderfully  well  received ;  the  Morning 
Post  of  9th  August  1817  declared  that  the 
"appeal,  founded  as  it  is  upon  genuine  reason, 
virtue,  and  humanity,  cannot  possibly  fail  of 
success."  But  Owen,  over-elated  with  appro- 
bation, went  out  of  his  way  to  declare  at  a 
public  meeting  on  21st  August  that  the  only 
reason  his  plans  had  not  been  adopted  centu- 
ries ago  was  the  errors  of  religion,  which  had 


COMMUNISM 


365 


created  enough  bigotry  and  fanaticism  to  wreck 
not  only  a  community  but  Paradise  itself.  This 
incident,  which  Owen  grotesquely  persisted  in 
believing  to  be  the  most  important  event  in  the 
history  of  mankind,  alienated  much  sympathy. 
Nevertheless  in  1819  a  committee  (appointed 
by  public  meeting),  of  which  the  Duke  of  Kent, 
Ricardo,  Torrens,  and  Sir  R.  Peel  the  elder 
were  members,  recommended  the  establishment 
of  an  experimental  community  by  means  of 
capital  to  be  provided  by  a  joint-stock  company 
and  on  the  principles  of  private  property,  com- 
munist distribution  being  strictly  excluded. 
Nothing  came  of  this,  as  subscriptions  could  not 
be  obtained.  In  1825  Abram  Combe,  a  tanner 
of  Edinburgh  and  disciple  of  Owen,  in  con- 
junction with  Mr.  A.  J.  Hamilton  of  Dalzell, 
obtained  300  acres  of  land  and  built  a  common 
dwelling-house  for  100  families  at  Orbiston  near 
Glasgow.  About  300  persons  willing  to  form  a 
community  were  easily  collected.  Till  a  new 
generation  fit  for  equality  had  grown  up,  it  was 
proposed  to  distribute  the  income  of  the 
community  according  to  the  estimated  value 
of  the  produce  of  each  individual's  labour. 
Combe  died  in  August  1827,  and  the  whole 
undertaking  immediately  collapsed.  Mean- 
while Owen  was  trying  to  establish  a  similar 
community  in  America.  He  bought,  in  1825, 
the  village  of  Harmony,  Indiana,  from  the 
Harmony  Society  or  Rappists,  who  wished  to 
remove.  He  called  the  place  New  Harmony, 
and  invited  the  "industrious  and  well  disposed" 
of  aU  nations  and  creeds  to  come  and  form  a 
"  preliminary  society."  Eight  or  nine  hundred 
persons  came,  and  the  preliminary  society,  in 
wliich  members  were  remunerated  according  to 
the  amount  of  their  services,  was  soon  super- 
seded (January  1826)  by  the  definitive  "com- 
munity of  equality,"  in  which  equality  (modi- 
fied by  difierences  of  need)  was  alone  to  regulate 
distribution.  But  the  miscellaneous  collection 
of  individuals  who  had  assembled  in  answer  to 
Owen's  comprehensive  invitation  never  became 
united  by  any  feeling  of  common  interest,  so 
that  by  November  1826  the  official  newspaper 
of  New  Harmony,  edited  by  Owen's  sons,  had  to 
admit  that  ' '  New  Hamiony  is  not  now  a  com- 
munity." Attempts  were  made  to  form  several 
smaller  communities  out  of  the  ruins,  but 
these  all  failed,  and  very  soon  scarcely  a  trace 
of  Owen's  scheme  remained  in  America.  In 
England  from  1827  to  1832  the  Owen- 
ites  founded  several  hundred  "co-operative 
societies."  These  consisted  of  persons  who 
collected  a  small  common  capital  by  subscrip- 
tions and  opened  a  shop,  in  the  hope  of  accumu- 
lating from  the  profits  of  the  business  an 
amount  sufficient  for  the  establishment  of  a 
communist  village.  The  system  of  sharing 
profits  with  customers  which  made  co-operative 
societies  successful  at  a  later  date  had  not  yet 
been  discovered,  and  the  Owenite  societies  failed, 


and  were  soon  almost  entirely  forgotten.  Owen 
himself  continued  a  firm  believer  in  the  speedy 
advent  of  "a  new  system  of  society."  His 
Labour  Exchange  of  1833  (see  Labour  Ex- 
change) was  intended  to  be  in  some  way  an 
intermediate  step.  "The  Association  of  all 
Classes  of  all  Nations"  and  "The  National 
Community  Friendly  Society  "  Avere  founded  in 
1835,  the  first  to  propagate  his  principles,  and 
the  second  to  promote  the  establishment  of 
communities  founded  upon  them.  The  two 
organisations  were  amalgamated  in  1839  under 
the  title  of  "The  Universal  Society  of  Rational 
Religionists."  The  chief  product  of  the 
labours  of  these  bodies  was  the  "  Queen  wood 
community,"  a  communist  farm  at  Tytherley 
in  Hampshire,  of  which  Owen  was  persuaded  to 
take  charge  in  1 8  4 1 .  The  experiment  attracted 
much  attention,  and  its  failure,  which  occurred 
a  few  months  after  Owen's  arrival,  seems  to 
have  been  the  death-blow  of  Owenism. 

Etienne  Cabet  (q.v.),  French  advocate  and 
deputy  was  condemned  in  1834  to  five  years'  exile 
in  consequence  of  his  violent  opposition  to  Louis 
Philippe's  government.  He  spent  the  five  years 
in  England,  and  after  studying  More's  Utopia, 
and  no  doubt  submitting  to  some  extent  to 
Owenite  influence,  began  to  doubt  whether  the 
political  revolution  for  which  he  had  hitherto 
been  striving  was  all  that  was  required  for  his 
country.  He  returned  to  France  in  1839  a 
thorough  communist,  and  in  1840  published 
his  Voyage  en  Icaric.  Though  provided  with 
a  hero  and  heroine,  and  a  somewhat  thin  thread 
of  romance,  in  order  if  possible  to  attract  the 
frivolous  as  well  as  the  serious  reader,  this  work, 
like  the  Utopia,  consists  chiefly  of  a  description 
of  an  imaginary  state  where  communism  is 
established.  But  while  More's  ideal  state  is 
totally  detached  from  ordinary  life,  Cabet's  is 
described  as  having  grown,  in  less  than  half 
a  century,  out  of  a  state  in  which  all  the  evils 
of  private  property  were  rampant.  Icaria  is 
France  in  1890,  as  Cabet  thought  it  should  and 
might  be.  Unlike  the  Babouvists,  however,  he 
saw  that  the  change  could  only  be  carried  out 
by  pacific  measures.  "Communism,"  he  says, 
"intended  for  the  happiness  of  all  men,  must 
not  begin  by  throwing  a  large  party  into 
despair"  {Voyage,  p.  562,  ed.  1845).  "Com- 
munism cannot  be  established  and  consolidated 
except  by  the  power  of  almost  unanimous  public 
opinion  {Ibid.  p.  515)."  It  has  been  objected 
that  the  transition  to  communism  in  Icaria  is 
made  to  begin  with  a  bloody  revolution,  but 
this  revolution  is  apparently  considered  neces- 
sary in  order  to  overthrow  a  very  odious  politi- 
cal tyranny.  Democracy  once  established,  the 
change  to  communism  is  carried  out  peaceably 
enough,  it  being  an  indispensable  condition  that 
the  rich  and  the  owners  of  property,  great  and 
smaU,  should  not  have  their  habits  and  pre- 
judices wounded  {Ihid.  p.  343).     In  his  account 


366 


COMMUNISM 


of  the  details  of  the  transitory  r6gime,  Cabet 
adopts  much  of  the  scheme  propounded  by 
Buonarroti.  In  the  completed  Icaria,  the 
distribution  of  wealth  is  regulated  by  the 
principle  of  equality  interpreted  to  mean  an 
extraordinary,  and  most  people  would  think 
a  very  oppressive,  uniformity.  Every  one  is 
allowed,  so  far  as  possible,  to  choose  his  occupa- 
tion, and  the  stimulus  to  industry  is  provided 
by  regarding  the  idle  man  as  a  thief.  Marriage, 
and  family  life  are  strictly  maintained.  Great 
importance  is  attached  to  education.  The  in- 
crease of  population  is  not  thought  to  require 
any  checks. 

For  some  of  the  French  communists  of  the 
time,  Icarianism  was  far  too  moderate  a 
doctrine.  They  objected  to  the  condemnation 
of  violence  and  to  the  maintenance  of  marriage 
and  the  family.  But  the  protests  of  Theodore 
Dezamy  and  others  were  of  no  avail  against  the 
wide  circulation  of  Cabet's  writings,  and  the 
Icarian  school  was  soon  supposed  to  number  its 
adherents  among  working  men  by  the  hundred 
thousand.  Warned  no  doubt  by  Owen's  numer- 
ous failures,  Cabet  at  first  advocated  only 
attempts  to  convert  whole  nations  to  com- 
munism, and  deprecated  the  foundation  of 
small  communist  societies,  which  "would  do 
but  little  good  if  they  succeeded,  and  much 
harm  if  they  failed,  as  they  were  nearly  sure  to 
do"  {Voyage,  p.  564).  Yet,  urged  on  to  some 
kind  of  action  both  by  friends  and  enemies,  he 
became  himself  the  founder  of  such  a  society. 
After  a  consultation  with  Owen,  he  bought 
some  delusive  rights  over  a  million  acres  in  the 
north-east  of  Texas.  On  3d  February  1848, 
eighty-nine  chosen  men  were  despatched  from 
Havre  as  the  "  first  advance  guard "  of  the 
multitudes  who  were  expected  to  follow  and 
establish  an  Icaria  in  America.  Three  weeks 
later  Louis  Philippe  fell,  and  great  numbers  who 
had  before  been  willing  to  emigrate  now  desired  to 
remain  in  France  and  promote  Icarianism  in  the 
new  Republic,  so  that  only  about  four  hundred 
persons  followed  the  "advance  guard."  When 
they  arrived  at  New  Orleans  the  advance  guard 
had  already  abandoned  the  land  in  Texas, 
which  was  altogether  unsuitable.  Eventually 
about  280  of  the  colonists  established  them- 
selves as  a  communist  society  at  Nauvoo, 
Illinois,  a  settlement  from  which  the  Mormons 
had  just  retired.  This  community  prospered 
fairly  for  some  time,  and  increased,  under 
Cabet's  leadership,  till  it  numbered  some  600 
members.  On  Cabet's  expulsion  in  1856,  180 
of  the  members  left  with  him  and  established 
a  community  at  Cheltenham,  near  St.  Louis, 
which  lasted  till  1864.  The  original  com- 
munity removed  from  Nauvoo  to  Icaria,  Adams 
County,  Iowa,  in  1860.  Its  expulsion  of 
Cabet  had  alienated  sympathy  in  France,  and 
it  became  surrounded  by  various  difficulties. 
After  the  war  its  position  gradually  improved, 


but  in  1877  there  was  another  schism  ;  the 
conservatives  or  old  party  became  "the  Ne\» 
Icarian  Community,"  and  the  young  party 
"the  Icarian  Community,"  each  numbering 
thirty  or  forty  persons.  The  old  domain  was 
divided  between  the  two  new  communities,  but 
in  1883  the  "Icarian  Community"  decided  to 
remove  to  Icaria-Speranza,  near  Cloverdale  in 
California.  (Albert  Shaw,  Icaria;  a  Chapter 
in  the  History  of  Communism,  1884.) 

The  Icarian  communities  may  be  regarded  as 
relics  of  a  movement  the  history  of  which  is 
nearly  confined  to  the  first  half  of  the  nineteenth 
century.  From  1848  socialism,  of  which  the 
fundamental  principle  is  that  the  whole  income 
of  society  should  be  received  by  labour,  not 
that  it  should  be  divided  equally,  has  taken 
the  place  of  communism.  "The  proposal  to 
organise  society  on  a  communistic  plan  ...  is 
one  of  which  the  serious  interest  has  now  passed 
away"  (Sidgwick,  Pol.  Econ.,  III.  vii.  §  3). 
But  wholly  apart  from  the  history  of  the 
advocacy  of  that  proposal,  there  have  been 
innumerable  cases  where  the  principles  of  equal 
labour  and  equal  distribution  have  been  recog- 
nised and  acted  on  (for  a  considerable  list,  see 
Roscher,  Pol.  Econ.,  §  Ixxxi.  notes).  Religious 
societies,  such  as  the  Essenes,  Anabaptists, 
Dunkers,  Moravians  or  United  Brethren, 
the  monastic  orders,  and  the  six  societies 
described  in  Nordhoff's  Communistic  Societies 
of  the  United  States  (1875),  have  always 
been  prone  to  adopt  a  communist  organisation, 
whether  from  asceticism,  or  unselfishness,  oi'  a 
desire  to  minimise  communication  with  the 
world.  Of  these  bodies  the  American  societies 
are  far  the  most  important  from  an  economic 
point  of  view,  as  their  industrial  character  is 
not  by  any  means  wholly  subordinate  to  their  re- 
ligion. In  1874  they  consisted  of  about  seventy 
communities,  with  a  total  jiopulation  of  5258. 
The  Shakers  (58  communities  or  "families," 
population  2415,  founded  in  1792)  and  the 
Rappists  or  Harmonists  of  Economy  (pop.  110, 
founded  1805)  were  celibate,  the  Separatists  of 
Zoar  (pop.  300,  founded  1842)  and  the  Aurora 
and  Bethel  communes  (pop.  600,  founded  1844) 
maintained  the  institutions  of  marriage  and  the 
family,  while  the  Perfectionists  of  Oneida  and 
Wallingford,  followers  of  Mr.  J.  H.  Noyes 
(pop.  283,  founded  1849),  practised  an  elabor- 
ate system  of  polygamy  and  polyandry.  This 
was  abandoned  in  1879,  and  the  society  was 
converted  into  a  joint-stock  company  in  1880. 
Most  of  the  communities  were  well  off,  and  all 
were  able  to  secure  efficient  but  not  exhausting 
labour  from  their  members.  The  population  in 
general  was  declining,  chiefly  in  consequence  of 
the  superior  attractions  presented  to  the  young 
people,  native  and  adopted,  by  the  more  excit- 
ing existence  of  the  outside  world.  All  the 
societies  except  the  Shakers  and  the  Perfection- 
ists had  German  founders. 


COMMUNISM— COMPAGNONNAGES 


367 


Communist  elements,  the  importance  of 
which  seems  to  be  growing,  are  present  in  the 
state  provision  of  such  things  as  roads,  drains, 
lamps,  parks,  schools,  and  libraries,  which  are 
maintained  by  taxes  and  rates  levied  in  the 
main  according  to  the  ability  of  the  contributor 
to  pay,  and  are  used  in  common,  or  equally,  or 
according  to  need.  The  English  poor  law  is 
communistic  as  regards  the  contributions  levied 
under  it,  but  the  comparison  which  used  to  be 
frequently  made  between  the  workhouse  and  a 
communist  society  is  misleading,  as  the  paupers 
have  not  the  direction  of  their  collective  in- 
dustry, and  are  not  in  the  least  affected  by  the 
increase  or  diminution  of  its  produce. 

The  criticism  of  communism  by  economists 
begins  (not  to  include  Hume's  Essays,  II.  p. 
270)  with  Malthus's  remarks  on  the  schemes 
of  Owen  and  Spence  {q.v.)  in  the  5th  edition 
of  his  Essaij  on  Population  (1817).  He  gives 
"two  decisive  arguments  against  communism: 
(1)  the  absence  of  "  those  stimulants  to  exertion 
which  can  alone  overcome  the  natural  indolence 
of  man  "  ;  and  (2)  the  absence  of  checks  to  the 
increase  of  population  which  would  be  brought 
about  by  the  removal  of  "the  laws  of  private 
property  and  the  moral  obligation  imposed  on 
every  man  by  the  commands  of  God  and  nature 
to  support  his  own  children"  (ii.  276,  277). 
These  two  arguments  have  been  very  generally 
repeated  by  later  writers  down  to  the  present 
time  (e.g.  Sidgwick,  Pol.  Econ.,  III.  vii.  §  3), 
and  very  little  has  been  added  to  them.  J.  S. 
Mill  {Pol.  Econ.,  II.  i.  §  3)  rejected  them  both, 
urging  that  both  supervision  and  individual 
self-interest  in  the  efficiency  of  labour  would  be 
more  complete  in  a  communist  society  than  is 
at  present  the  case  as  regards  the  great  mass  of 
labour,  and  that  excessive  increase  of  popula- 
tion would  be  more  likely  to  be  repressed  by 
public  opinion  in  a  communist  society,  where  it 
would  cause  "immediate  and  unmistakable 
inconvenience  to  every  individual  in  the  associa- 
tion." MlII's  position  as  to  the  stimulus  to 
industry  has  been  strengthened  by  the  support 
which  many  economists  have  given  to  co-oper- 
ative production,  in  which  the  stimulus  is  col- 
lective and  not  individual,  since  each  man's 
labour  is  supposed  to  be  made  more  efficient 
than  under  the  ordinary  system  by  the  desire 
of  each  that  the  product  of  the  labour  of  all 
may  be  great.  No  one  need  look  to  political 
economy  to  prove  or  disprove  the  advantage  of 
communism  in  the  abstract.  It  is  generally 
recognised  that  a  society  is  likely  to  be  happier 
the  more  equally  the  produce  of  its  labour  is 
divided  (Sidgwick,  Pol.  Econ.,  III.  vii.  §  1  ;  cp. 
Jevons's  Theory,  ch.  iii.),  but  the  remaining 
economic  question,  "Can  any  kind  of  govern- 
ment organise  labour  and  production  so  as  to 
supply  the  wants  of  society  (given  the  admitted 
advantage  of  equality)  as  well,  on  the  whole,  as 
they  can  be  supplied  by  the  system  of  private 


property  and  competition  ? "  is  one  as  to  which 
opinions  may  legitimately  differ,  and  to  which 
the  true  answer  is  probably  different  at  different 
times  and  places. 

For  the  "communists"  of  Paris  in  1871,  see 
Commune  of  Paris.  (See  also  Anarchism  ; 
Babeuf  ;  Brissot  de  AVarville  ;  Christ- 
ian Socialism;  Co-orERATiON  ;  Property; 
Proudhon  ;  Socialism  ;  and  Art.  in  App.) 

[A.  Sudre,  Histoire  du  Communisme,  3™®  ed. 
1850. — B.  Malon,  Histoire  du  S'ocialisme,  1883. — 
E.  Fleury,  Babeuf  et  le  Socialisvie  en  1796,  2™« 
ed.  1851. — L.  vou  Stein,  Geschichte  der  Socialen 
Betoegung  im  Frankreich,  1850. — R.  Owen,  Life 
written  by  Himself,  vol,  1.  1857  ;  vol.  i.  A.  (con- 
tinuation of  appendices)  1858. — R.  Dale  Owen, 
Threading  my  Way,  1874. — A.  J.  Booth,  Robert 
Owen,  1869. — M.  Hennell,  Ov.tline  of  the  various 
social  Systems  and  Communities  which  have  been 
founded  on  the  Principle  of  Co-operation,  1844. — 
G.  J.  Holyoake,  History  of  Co-operation  in  England, 
vol.  i.  1875  ;  vol.  ii.  1879.— J.  H.  Noyes,  History 
of  American  Socialisms,  1870. — A.  Shaw,  Icaria, 
1884. — Encyclopcedia  Britannica,  9th  ed.  Art. 
"Oneida,"  by  W.  A.  Hinds  (a  member  of  the 
community),  1884.  —  Nordhoff,  Covimunistic 
Societies  of  the  United  States,  1875.]  e.g. 

[Among  English  economic  writers  J.  S.  Mill 
(Principles  of  Political  Economy,  bk.  ii.  ch. 
ii.  §  2)  makes  the  characteristic  of  commun- 
ism "absolute  equality  in  the  distribution  of 
the  physical  means  of  life  and  employment." 
H.  Sidgwick  again  {Principles  of  Political 
Economy,  bk.  iii.  ch.  vii.  §  3)  restricts  Com- 
munism and  Socialism  to  systems  which  in- 
volve either  the  almost  entire  abolition  of 
private  property,  or  its  restrictions  to  con- 
sumers' wealth.] 

COMPAGNONNAGES.  These  were  associa- 
tions of  itinerant  workmen  in  Italy,  France, 
and  England,  formed  with  the  purpose  of  pro- 
viding members  with  food,  lodging,  and  em- 
ployment;  differing  from  the  craft -guilds  in 
that  the  latter  were  local,  while  the  compag- 
nonnage  was  a  widespread  organisation  with 
local  branches.  A  house  of  refuge,  presided 
over  by  an  officer  called  the  "mother"  of  the 
lodge,  was  maintained  in  every  town.  Here 
board  and  lodging  were  provided  for  members 
of  the  society.  Membership  was  tested  by 
secret  signs  and  passwords.  Such  employment 
as  was  to  be  found  in  the  place  was  distributed 
to  members  in  rotation,  the  last  comers  having 
a  prior  claim  to  those  who  had  already  had 
work  in  the  town.  The  origin  of  the  compag- 
nonnages  is  involved  in  legend,  but  they  appear 
to  have  started  in  Italy,  and  to  have  spread 
thence  through  France  during  the  12th  century 
into  England.  In  France  they  were  closely 
connected  with  the  order  of  the  Knights  of  the 
Temple.  They  were  divided  into  three  main 
branches  under  the  names  of  "  Enfants  do 
Salomon,"  "Enfants  de  maitre  Jacques,"  and 
"Enfants  du  pere  Soubise."     The  two  formei 


368 


COMPANIES 


divisions  contained  men  of  various  trades,  but 
the  last  was  composed  of  thatchers  and  plas- 
terers only.  The  rivalry  which  existed  between 
these  divisions  gave  rise  to  sanguinary  conflicts, 
and  the  compagnonnages,  originally  useful  in 
protecting  workmen  against  seignorial  oppres- 
sion, tended  to  assume  the  character  of  secret 
societies,  and  to  become  sources  of  riot  aad  dis- 
order. They  were  the  object  of  much  repressive 
legislation  from  the  16th  to  the  18th  century, 
and  in  France  were  finally  abolished  in  1791. 

[Block,  Dictionnaire  gin^ral  de  la  Politique, 
1873. — Dictionnaire  de  VEconomie  Politique,l852. 
— Nouveau  Dictionnaire  d'^conomie  Politique, 
1890.]  A.  H. 

COMPANIES. 

Companies,  English  and  Scotch  Law,  p.  368 ;  Increase 
of,  p.  369 ;  Influence  on  Business,  p.  370 ;  Companies, 
City  of  London,  p.  371 ;  Companies,  Staple,  p.  373 ; 
Companies,  Trading,  p.  375  (see  Foreign  Trade,  Regul- 
ation of). 

Companies.  English  and  Scotch  Law. 
The  primary  idea  of  partnership  is  the  associa- 
tion of  persons,  mutually  acquainted,  for  the 
purpose  of  commercial  enterprise,  that  is,  to  gain 
something.  Mutual  acquaintance  and  mutual 
choice  and  confidence  result  in  personal  relations 
between  the  partners  ;  one  can  bind  his  fellows 
in  the  way  of  the  partnership  business  ;  when 
one  dies  or  when  his  circumstances  undergo  a 
material  change,  the  remaining  partners  can 
withdraw  their  confidence  or  resist  the  introduc- 
tion of  his  representatives  or  assignees  whom 
they  may  not  know,  and  the  continuance  of  the 
partnership  then  becomes  impossible.  As  the 
outside  world  looks  to  the  partners  themselves, 
when  they  are  known,  or  even  when  only  some 
of  them  are  known,  credit  is  given  to  them  and 
they  are  all  either  directly  or  ultimately  liable 
to  the  creditors  of  the  firm.  Joint-stock  com- 
panies as  usually  formed  are  built  up  by  stated 
contributions  from  those  who  form  them  ;  the 
element  of  mutual  personal  choice  disappears  ; 
the  shares  are  transferable  ;  the  management  is 
carried  on  by  the  officials  of  the  company  to  the 
exclusion  of  the  individual  shareholders  as  such. 
The  transition  from  simple  partnership  to  joint- 
stock  companies  was  hampered  in  England  by 
the  persistent  application  by  the  courts,  to  all 
forms  of  association,  of  those  principles  which 
are  applicable  in  fact  only  to  simple  partnerships 
founded  on  mutual  personal  choice.  In  Scot- 
Land  the  transition  was  at  first  rendered  easy  by 
a  diff"erent  set  of  principles  borrowed  from  Con- 
tinental and  Roman  law.  The  Scottish  com- 
mon law  recognises  even  in  simple  partnership 
a  separate  quasi-personality,  in  virtue  of  which 
it  can  sue  and  be  sued  by  even  its  own  partners, 
can  enter  as  a  partner  into  other  partnerships, 
and  is  primarily  liable  for  all_  the  debts  of  the 
joint  undertaking.  Primarily  only,  however  ; 
ultimately  the  partners  are  liable  for  all  the 
debts  of  the  firm.     A  natural  outcome  of  this 


doctrine  of  separate  quasi-personality,  which 
was  at  the  beginning  of  last  century  more 
broadly  stated  as  a  doctrine  of  separate  person- 
ality, was  that  where  a  joint-stock  companj 
took  care  not  to  introduce  the  names  of  its 
partners  into  its  collective  name,  but  used  a 
descriptive  name  of  its  own  (compare  the  French 
Sociiti  anonyme),  the  creditors  of  the  concern 
were  held  to  have  given  credit  not  to  any  in- 
dividual partners,  but  to  the  separate  entity 
which  had  been  created  by  their  joint  con- 
tributions. Accordingly  it  was  decided  in 
1727  that  the  partners  of  the  Arran  Fishing 
Company  were  not  personally  liable  beyond 
their  shares  in  the  company.  Thus  the  Scot- 
tish law  was  at  that  early  date  within  easy 
reach  of  the  principle  of  joint-stock  companies 
with  limited  liability. 

The  Scottish  lawyers  of  the  day  appear  to 
have  considered  that  to  obtain  a  royal  charter 
was  a  superfluous  though  dignified  measure  ; 
they  explain  that  such  a  charter  n»eeded  no 
legislative  sanction,  such  as  is  necessary  where 
monopolies  are  to  be  conferred,  because  the 
powers  conferred  were  already  in  accord  with  the 
common  law  ;  there  might,  however,  be  an  ad- 
vantage in  the  explicit  limitation  of  liability 
which  was  set  forth  in  the  charter.  In  England 
the  current?  idea  of  the  time  was  that  limited 
liability  companies  were,  generally,  contrary  to 
public  policy ;  and  English  ideas  began  to  affect 
the  Scotch  legal  mind.  In  Scotch  legal  procedure 
it  became  customary  and  then  necessary  to  add 
to  the  name  of  a  company  the  names  of  at  least 
three  of  its  partners  as  such  ;  confusion  was 
introduced  by  the  Scotch  use  of  the  word 
"company"  to  mean  simple  personal  partner- 
ship as  well  as  joint-stock  company.  In  the 
leading  case  (1778)  of  the  banking  firm  Douglas, 
Heron,  and  Co.,  generally  known  as  the  Douglas 
Bank  or  the  Ayr  Bank,  it  was  decided  that  the 
liability  of  the  partners  was  not  limited,  appar- 
ently because  of  the  ^emi-personal  name  of  the 
firm  ;  this  shook  the  confidence  of  Scotch  in- 
vestors in  all  joint-stock  companies  ;  next  the 
Bubble  Act,  passed  in  1719  after  the  South 
Sea  crash,  prohibiting  companies  from  acting 
as  corporate  bodies  with  transferable  shares, 
was  unearthed  and  then  believed  to  apply  to 
Scotland ;  and  the  Act  7  Geo.  IV.  c.  67,  empower- 
ing private  banking  companies  to  sue  and  be  sued 
in  the  name  of  their  principal  officer  on  certain 
conditions,  was  believed  to  confirm  by  implica- 
tion the  view  that  joint-stock  companies  were 
no  more  than  simple  partnerships,  and  that 
consequently  liability  could  only  be  limited  by 
special  and  separate  contracts  with  creditors. 
But  even  in  Scotland,  and  even  at  that  time, 
there  was  a  doubt  as  to  how  things  stood  when 
the  partners  of  a  joint -stock  company  were 
known  ;  and  in  extensive  undertakings  above 
the  rank  of  ordinary  commercial  partnerships 
a  favourite  expedient  was  to  obtain   a   ro-yal 


COMPANIES 


369 


charter  which  placed  the  question  beyond 
doubt  by  the  creation  of  a  mercantile  corpora- 
tion. Such  a  corporation  was  a  distinct 
individual,  with  its  own  estate  and  liabilities, 
a  corporate  name,  and  its  own  seal ;  it  could 
sue  and  be  sued,  and  was  managed  by  its  own 
officials  to  the  exclusion  of  the  shareholders  : 
it  could  hold  lands  without  the  intervention 
of  trustees  ;  it  had  perpetual  succession  and 
transferable  shares,  could  make  bye-laws,  and 
could  not  be  dissolved  except  by  surrendering 
its  charter ;  and  when  its  property  was  ex- 
hausted, its  creditors  had  no  other  funds  to 
look  to  for  payment  of  its  liabilir-ics. 

Even  with  regard  to  chartered  companies  in 
Scotland  the  legislature  (6  Geo.  IV.  c.  91, 
1825)  empowered  the  crown  to  insert  in  charters 
a  condition  of  unlimited  liability  ;  and  in  the 
charters  of  the  National  (1825)  and  Commercial 
(1831)  Banks  the  liability  is  stated  not  to  be 
limited  by  the  charters.  An  act  of  1837  re- 
pealed this  ;  and  from  that  date,  before  whicli 
the  circumstances  in  England  and  in  Scotland 
had,  so  far  as  regards  the  powers  of  joint-stock 
companies  and  the  liabilities  of  their  share- 
holders, become  practically  the  same,  a  long 
course  of  legislation  has  step  by  step  evolved  lor 
the  whole  United  Kingdom  the  principle  oi' 
registered  joint-stock  companies  either  with  or 
without  limited  liability  (see  Companies,  In- 
crease of)  ;  the  governing  statute  now  being 
the  Companies  Act  1862,  upon  which  attend  a 
number  of  supplementary  statutes  bearing  the 
same  name  in  successive  years  :  the  whole  now 
forming  a  mass  of  legislation  sorely  in  need  of 
consolidation. 

Where  a  proposed  company  tends  to  invade 
the  privileges  of  the  public,  legislative  sanction 
is  necessary  for  its  formation  with  the  desired 
powers  ;  for  example,  companies  having  mono- 
polies such  as  the  Bank  of  England  and  the 
Bank  of  Scotland,  upon  which  a  monopoly  of 
Scottish  banking  was  conferred  for  twenty-one 
years,  both  of  which  have  charters  following 
upon  statutes.  Railway  companies  and  others 
having  aggi-essive  powers  are  formed  directly  by 
private  acts  of  parliament ;  and  for  companies  of 
this  order  a  considerable  measure  of  uniformity 
in  administration  is  secured  through  the  opera- 
tion of  the  various  general  Clauses  Consolidation 
Acts  of  1845,  and  amending  statutes.      A.  d. 

COMPANIES,  Increase  of.  The  marvel- 
lous expansion  of  joint-stock  enterprise  during 
recent  years  may  be  clearly  seen  from  the 
following  figures,  which  show  the  respective 
numbers  of  limited  companies  registered  in  each 
successive  year  since  1863.  They  are  taken  from 
the  last  return  issued  by  the  Registrar  of  Joint- 
Stock  Companies,  and  do  not  include  companies 
incorporated  under  special  Acts  of  Parliament — 
as,  for  instance.  Railway  and  Canal  Companies 
— but  only  such  companies  as  were  incorporated 
under  the  Companies'  Acts. 
VOL   I. 


•6 
c 

-a 

q 

1 

'6 

1 

a 

1 

^3 

1 

» 

OQ 

^ 

m 

OQ 

*-* 

1S63 

689 

24 

20 

1877 

80S 

83 

47 

186U 

893 

17 

34 

1878 

72(5 

61 

28 

1865 

902 

29 

42 

1870 

876 

58 

34 

7S66 

656 

33 

37 

1880 

1074 

65 

31 

1S67 

412 

14 

14 

1881 

1394 

72 

29 

1S6S 

392 

20 

13 

188-2 

1393 

95 

38 

1869 

417 

13 

11 

1883 

1416 

108 

106 

1870 

518 

12 

15 

188h 

1282 

107 

54 

1871 

668 

42 

31 

1885 

1257 

73 

52 

1872 

912 

81 

27 

issa 

1647 

87 

51 

1873 

lOGl 

62 

42 

1887 

1808 

91 

46 

187k 

1076 

63 

18 

1888 

2278 

120 

67 

1875 

1035 

45 

24 

188!) 

2455 

133 

70 

1876 

831 

64 

29 

1890 

2769 

145 

91 

[See  Companies,  Increase  op,  Aiij^.] 
The  figures  for  1891  showed  a  large  falling 
off,  which  was  continued  by  the  effects  of 
the  financial  difficulties  in  South  America 
and  the  Baring  crisis  ;  but  there  can  be  no 
doubt  that  these  were  merely  temporary 
hindrances,  and  that  a  tendency  so  marked 
must  continue  to  exist  and  will  even  increase 
in  intensity.  It  cannot  be  disputed  that  the 
expansion  of  joint-stock  enterprise  will  pro- 
duce considerable  economic  changes  ;  these 
changes  depend  on  certain  characteristics  of 
joint-stock  as  distinguished  from  private  imder- 
takings,  the  most  important  of  which  are  the 
following :  (1)  A  company  is  an  artificial  unit 
created  by  law,  inaccessible  to  several  of  the 
motives  and  independent  of  several  of  the  inci- 
dents to  which  a  single  trader  or  a  private 
partnership  is  subject.  The  failure  of  a  com- 
pany does  not  in  itself  affect  the  mercantile 
standing  of  any  person,  and  there  may  be  there 
fore  more  temptation  to  enter  on  risky  enter- 
prises ;  on  the  other  hand,  the  freedom  from 
any  ties  of  personal  friendship  or  moral  obliga- 
tion makes  it  easier  to  conduct  business  on 
strict  rules  (e.g.  in  the  gi-anting  of  credits). 
A  private  ti'ading  concern  generally  depends  on 
the  continuation  of  one  or  more  lives,  and  also 
on  the  continued  wish  of  a  limited  number 
of  individuals  to  carry  it  on  ;  a  company  is 
generally  formed  for  an  indefinite  time,  and 
has  a  much  greater  chance  of  continued  ex- 
istence. No  one  would  enter  into  a  transac- 
tion with  a  private  firm,  involving  the  continu- 
ance of  its  solvency  for  a  long  number  of  years 
as,  for  instance,  when  a  life  policy  is  taken 
out  which  may  not  become  payable  for  eighty 
years  or  more.  (2)  The  persons  engaged  in 
the  management  of  a  company  are  not  so 
directly  interested  in  its  success  as  the  partners 
of  a  private  firm.  It  may  happen,  and  has 
happened,  that  directors  or  managers  have 
actually  had  interests  hostile  to  the  company 
over  which  they  were  placed,  through  being 
more  largely  benefited  by  the  success  of  com- 
peting undertakings,  or  through  having  sold 
shares  in  the  hope  of  repurchasing  them  at  a 
cheaper   price.      They   may   also    for  various 


370 


COMPANIES 


reasons  be  desirous  of  creating  a  momentary 
advance  in  the  price  of  the  shares,  and  with  that 
view  enter  into  transactions  showing  large 
profits  on  paper,  but  seriously  compromising 
the  continued  prosperity  of  the  undertaking. 
(3)  Joint-stock  enterprise  favours  the  creation 
of  businesses  carried  on  on  a  large  scale*,  and 
renders  the  existence  of  smaller  establishments 
more  difficult.  (4)  The  greater  publicity  of 
business  transactions  and  of  their  results  is 
another  of  the  leading  characteristics  of  joint- 
stock  companies. 

The  expansion  of  joint-stock  enterprise,  and 
the  gradual  absorption  of  private  trading  con- 
cerns, will  probably  produce  the  following 
results  :  (1)  The  profits  of  private  traders  will 
be  diminished — ^because  the  expenses  of  man- 
agement must  necessarily  be  much  smaller  in 
proportion  in  the  larger  establishments,  the 
existence  of  which  will  be  facilitated  by  joint- 
stock  enterprise,  than  in  the  smaller  undertak- 
ings carried  on  by  individuals,  and  because  the 
former  class  will  therefore  be  able  to  outbid  the 
latter  class  until  their  own  level  of  minimum 
profits  has  been  reached.  (2)  Numerous  oppor- 
tunities will  be  created  for  employment  with  a 
fixed  income.  The  small  tradesman  who  now 
has  some  chance  of  acquiring  wealth,  but  who 
runs  a  constant  risk  of  being  deserted  by  his 
customers,  will  become  a  clerk  in  a  large  estab- 
lishment and  thus  acquire  a  more  modest,  but 
much  less  precarious  source  of  income.  (3) 
The  man  of  real  talent  will  have  a  better 
opportunity  of  acquiring  a  proper  position, 
because  he  will  not  disappear  in  the  crowd,  but 
rise  from  step  to  step  in  the  establishment  in 
which  he  works.  (4)  The  expansion  of  joint- 
stock  enterprise  will  facilitate  the  introduction 
of  improvements  and  inventions,  as  the  proba- 
bility of  the  presence  of  inventive  persons  is 
much  greater  in  large  than  in  small  establish- 
ments, and  as  large  establishments  are  in  a 
better  position  to  try  experiments  which  may 
prove  costly  and  unsuccessful.  (5)  As  regards 
the  relations  between  employers  and  workmen, 
the  further  development  of  joint-stock  enterprise 
will  probably  prove  beneficial.  The  decrease 
in  the  number  and  the  increase  in  the  size  of 
industrial  establishments  will  facilitate  com- 
binations between  employers  as  well  as  between 
workmen ;  but  this  fact  will  also  facilitate 
negotiations,  and  the  contest  will  lose  much  of 
its  bitterness  when  the  workmen  are  no  longer 
opposed  to  private  individuals  whose  wealth 
and  manner  of  living  is  conspicuously  before 
their  eyes,  but  on  receiving  their  wages  from 
impersonal  companies,  the  profits  of  which  are 
ascertainable  by  everybody.  The  publicity  of 
profits  will  also  facilitate  profit-sharing  arrange- 
ments. 

It  will  thus  be  seen  that  the  gradual  sub-, 
stitution  of  joint-stock  in  the  place  of  private 
enterprise  will   in   all   probability  lead   to   a 


general  levelling  of  profits  and  incomes,  and 
will  at  the  same  time  in  many  ways  facilitate 
the  general  production  of  wealth  ;  but  some  of 
the  above  mentioned  facts  will,  on  the  other 
hand,  tend  to  increase  the  motives  and  oppor- 
tunities for  unsound  trading.  It  is  clearly 
within  the  province  of  legislation  to  counteract 
these  motives  and  opportunities,  but  it  is 
difficult  to  devise  efficient  means  for  that 
purpose.  It  has  been  proposed  to  introduce 
a  system  of  registration  requiring — in  imitation 
of  the  provisions  on  that  subject  which  are 
in  force  in  some  continental  countries — -an 
investigation  of  the  circumstances  attending 
the  formation  of  a  company  and  the  sub- 
scription of  a  certain  part  of  its  capital, 
previously  to  the  issue  of  the  final  certificate 
of  incorporation  ;  and  the  existing  law  has 
some  stringent  provisions  with  regard  to  the 
liabilities  of  the  promoters  and  directors  of 
companies  for  statements  or  omissions  in 
prospectuses  ;  but  the  object  of  provisions  of 
that  sort  is  more  the  protection  of  investors 
than  the  prevention  of  unsound  trading  ;  they 
may,  in  fact,  even  increase  unsound  trading 
by  preventing  prudent  and  solvent  persons 
from  joining  the  boards  of  new  companies. 
Unsound  trading — that  is,  trading  without  a 
chance  of  profit,  or  with  overwhelming  chances 
of  loss — cannot  be  entirely  prevented,  but 
the  legislature  might,  by  insuring  its  detection, 
or  by  removing  its  inducements,  succeed  in  re- 
stricting it  as  much  as  possible.  Compulsory 
yearly  balance  sheets,  and  a  compulsory  yearly 
valuation  of  the  assets  by  independent  pro- 
fessional auditors  would  do  much  in  that 
direction.  A  more  active  participation  of  the 
shareholders  in  the  meetings  of  the  company 
would  also  act  as  an  efficient  check  on  directors 
and  managers  ;  but  legislation  is  powerless  in 
that  respect.  If  the  principle  of  reserve 
liability  (the  liability  to  pay  an  additional 
amount  on  each  share  in  the  case  of  a  winding 
up)  was  made  compulsory  generally,  share- 
holders would  possibly  become  more  watchful ; 
and,  as  in  any  case  stock  exchange  gambling 
in  the  shares  of  companies  would  become  im- 
possible if  such  a  measure  were  adopted,  as 
it  would  take  away  the  possibility  of  obtaining 
loans  on  the  shares,  one  of  the  chief  motives  of 
unsound  management  would  in  this  way  be 
removed.  There  are  many  other  means  by 
which  the  dangers  pointed  out  above  may  be 
counteracted  in  a  certain  measure,  and  the 
attention  of  legislators  may  be  usefully  directed 
to  a  subject  the  importance  of  which  will,  if 
the  present  tendency  continues,  become  more 
conspicuous  every  year.  e.  s, 

COMPANIES.  Their  Influence  on  Busi- 
NESS.  In  the  marvellous  industrial  develop- 
ment of  the  past  half  century,  joint-stock 
companies  have  played  a  most  important  part. 
Their  influence  is  not  to  he  measured  merely  by 


COMPANIES 


371 


the  magnitude  of  the  capital  that  has  been  em- 
barked in  them,  enormous  although  that  has 
been.  As  to  the  amount  of  that  capital,  un- 
fortunately no  exact  statistics  are  available. 
From  parliamentary  returns  it  appears  that 
from  the  commencement  of  the  Companies  Act, 
1862,  to  the  31st  December  1890,  there  had 
been  registered  in  the  United  Kingdom,  com- 
panies with  an  aggregate  nominal  share  capital 
of  about  £3,970,000,000.  Of  these  companies, 
however,  a  multitude  never  got  beyond  the 
registration  stage,  which  is  only  the  preliminary 
to  an  appeal  to  the  public  for  capital.  Others 
again,  which  it  was  attempted  to  float,  failed  to 
meet  with  support  ;  while  many  that  were 
constituted  had  to  be  content  with  a  smaller 
capital  than  was  at  first  intended.  Besides,  in 
the  great  majority  of  cases  the  nominal  capital 
is  greatly  in  excess  of  the  paid-up  or  working 
capital.  The  amount  of  proposed  capital  thus 
affords  no  guide  to  the  amount  of  capital  actu- 
ally invested  and  used  in  business.  According, 
however,  to  the  calculations  of  the  registrar 
of  joint-stock  companies,  the  paid-up  share 
capital  of  the  registered  joint-stock  companies 
of  the  United  Kingdom  carrying  on  business  on 
the  30th  of  April  last  was  £775,000,000  ;  if  to 
that  be  added  the  capital  raised  by  debentures, 
mortgages,  etc.,  it  is  probably  not  over  the 
mark  to  estimate  that  the  capital  embarked 
by  our  joint-stock  companies  thus  exceeded 
£1,000,000,000.  But,  as  has  been  said,  it  is 
not  so  much  the  magnitude  of  the  capital  of  the 
joint-stock  companies  as  the  way  in  which  it 
has  been  employed  that  has  influenced  business. 
Joint-stock  capital  is  essentially  more  venture- 
some than  that  of  individual  traders.  The 
limitation  of  liability  has  enabled  risks  to  be 
run  and  experiments  to  be  made  which  would 
never  have  been  ventured  upon  had  it  been 
necessary  for  those  by  whom  they  were  under- 
taken to  stake  their  whole  fortune  upon  the 
result.  Hence  it  is  that  the  companies  have 
to  a  large  extent  acted  as  the  pioneers  and 
promoters  of  private  enterprise.  They  have 
exploited  all  manner  of  new  inventions,  that 
otherwise  might  have  fallen  still  -  born,  they 
have  opened  up  new  territories,  have  developed 
transit  facilities  all  over  the  world,  and  girded 
the  earth  with  the  meshes  of  the  electric  tele- 
graph. Thus  they  have  not  only  opened  up 
new  fields  for  trade,  they  have  also  afforded  the 
physical  means  by  which  these  maybe  exploited  ; 
and  further  to  some  extent,  by  means  of  banks, 
finance  houses,  and  similar  institutions,  pro- 
vided traders  with  the  requisite  capital.  In 
these  ways  they  have  given  an  impulse  to 
business  far  beyond  the  extent  of  their  own 
operations.  To  them  also  another  feature  of 
recent  times,  the  now  decided  tendency  to  a 
lower  level  of  the  prices  of  commodities  in 
general,  is  in  no  small  measure  due.  Supplies 
of  commodities   have   been   increased   by    the 


enlargement  of  the  area  of  production  ;  cost  oi 
transit  has  been  reduced :  and,  by  steam  and 
telegraph,  markets  have  been  brought  into  such 
close  contact  that  the  former  need  for  large 
stocks  of  goods  has  been  reduced  to  a  minimum. 
Further,  a  lower  standard  of  profits  has  been 
established.  Shareholders  whose  sm-plus  capital 
is  invested  in  an  undertaking  are  naturally  con- 
tent with  a  smaller  return  than  the  individual 
trader  who  derives  his  whole  income  from  a 
similar  business  ;  while  the  publication  of 
their  accounts  by  trading  companies,  and  the 
great  mobility  of  capital  under  the  joint-stock 
system,  ensure  that  whenever  on  any  business 
a  high  rate  of  profit  is  being  earned  new  capital 
will  flow  into  it,  and,  by  creating  keener  com- 
petition cause  profits  to  be  curtailed.  The  flow 
of  money  into  business  too  has  been  made 
somewhat  more  direct.  In  the  collection  and 
distribution  of  the  surplus  capital  of  the  country 
the  banks  do  not  play  quite  so  great  a  part  as 
they  previously  did.  Some  portion  of  what 
would  formerly  have  been  deposited  with  them, 
and  by  them  lent  out  to  traders,  now  goes 
direct  into  the  hands  of  the  companies,  and  this 
no  doubt  is  one  amongst  other  causes  that  have 
in  recent  years  led  to  a  continuous  decrease  in 
the  amount  of  bills  negotiated,  notwithstand- 
ing the  enormous  increase  in  the  volume  of 
business.  Such  are  some  of  the  influences 
which  joint-stock  companies  have  exercised 
upon  business.  That  their  influence  has  not 
been  altogether  for  good  is  notorious.  Through 
them  hundreds  of  millions  have  been  wasted  on 
chimerical  enterprises,  or  gone  into  the  pockets 
of  fraudulent  promoters ;  and  shareholders  have 
suffered  grievously  through  the  ineptitude  or 
extravagance  of  the  management.  The  question 
of  comparative  losses  and  gains,  however,  lies 
beyond  the  scope  of  these  remarks. 

[Compare  Adam  Smith,  Wealth  of  Natioyis,  bk. 
v.  ch.  i. — J.  S.  Mill,  Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  i.  eh.  ix. 
§§  1,  2.]  E.  J. 

COMPANIES  (City  of  London).  The  city 
companies  formerly  constituted  the  administra- 
tive machinery  by  means  of  which  the  munici- 
pality of  London  exercised  a  minute  supervision 
over  trade  and  manufacture  ;  while,  on  the 
other  hand,  freedom  of  one  of  the  companies  was 
a  necessary  qualification  for  the  civic  franchise. 
Though  their  trade  functions  have  with  very 
few  exceptions  (vide  infra)  long  since  become 
obsolete,  they  still  form  an  integral  part  of 
the  London  municipality,  and  they  administer 
great  revenues.  The  companies,  therefore,  are 
the  most  important  survival  of  the  industrial 
and  municipal  system  of  the  Middle  Ages. 
It  has  been  argued  that  some  of  the  guilds, 
which  became  later  the  chartered  companies, 
must  have  existed  in  Anglo-Saxon  times,  but 
there  is  no  documentary  evidence  in  support 
of  this  contention.  The  Pepperers,  the  Gold- 
smiths, and  others,  were  amongst  the  adulterin'; 


372 


COMPANIES 


guilds  amerced  in  the  reign  of  Henry  II.,  and 
the  Guildhall  is  mentioned  circa  1212.  During 
the  13th  century  the  influence  of  the  city  guilds 
increased,  and  gradually  freedom  of  a  guild 
and  the  civic  franchise  became  practically 
convertible  terms.  Edward  III.  incorporated 
many  of  the  trading  fraternities,  and  hftnself 
became  a  member  of  the  Linen-Armourers.  In 
1377  there  were  no  less  than  forty -eight  of 
these  fraternities.  In  the  same  year  the  right 
of  election  of  the  city  officers  was  transferred 
from  the  wards  to  the  companies,  but  this 
arrangement  led  to  tumults  and  discontent 
amongst  the  citizens,  and  "the  approved  and 
established  practice  of  ancient  and  praise- 
worthy usage  "  was  restored  {Liber  Albus,  37). 
The  Grocers,  originally  founded  by  twenty-two 
pepperers  of  Soper  Lane  (now  Queen  Street), 
were  apparently  the  most  powerful  of  the 
companies  at  this  time.  There  were  complaints 
of  their  monopolising  tendencies  in  1363,  but 
in  1385  and  the  two  following  years  they  were 
able  to  return  Sir  Nicholas  Brembre  to  the 
mayoralty  "  be  strong  hand  of  certayne  craftes  " 
(Heath,  Account  of  the  Grocers,  443  ;  Aungier, 
Groniques  de  London,  xvii.  ;  Bot.  Pari.,  II. 
278;  Herbert,  Livery  Gompanies,  i.,  38).  The 
companies'  charters  were  inquired  into  by  the 
commission  of  Richard  II.  (1389),  but  they 
were  confirmed  and  extended  in  subsequent 
reigns.  It  is  evident  that  in  the  16th 
century  trade  and  industry  had  outgrown  the 
regulations  of  the  Middle  Ages,  and  the  ex- 
clusive privileges  of  the  companies  demanded 
some  relaxation.  But  new  companies  continued 
to  be  incorporated  till  the  reign  of  Charles  II. 
At  the  Reformation  their  trust  estates,  which 
were  charged  with  the  support  of  chantries, 
obits,  and  lamps,  were  vested  in  the  Crown 
(37  Henry  VIII.  c.  4  ;  1  Edward  VI.  c.  14, 
§  6).  They  were  afterwards  allowed  to  purchase 
these  confiscated  lands  in  the  reigns  of  Edward 
VI.  and  James  I.  The  terms  of  the  grants 
then  made  have  since  been  held  by  the  court 
of  Chancery  to  have  vested  in  the  companies 
the  same  absolute  property  in  these  lands 
which  the  act  of  Edward  VI.  vested  in  the 
crown.  "They  have  thus  been,  since  the 
Reformation,  in  the  eye  of  the  law,  the  corporate 
property  of  the  companies,  free  from  any  trust. 
But  these  crown  grants  may  be  reasonably 
taken  to  have  been  made  in  the  expectation 
that  the  income  would  continue  to  be  in  great 
part  applied  to  charitable  uses"  (Liv.  Comp. 
Gam.,  i.  40,  and  infra). 

The  seizure  of  the  chauntry  estates  was 
followed  by  a  statute  (2  &  3  Edward  VI.) 
which  licensed  all  manner  of  workmen  con- 
nected with  the  building  of  houses,  etc.,  to 
exercise  their  occupations  in  cities  and  towns 
corporate,  though  they  were  not  free  of  the 
corporations.  This  act  was  afterwards  re- 
pealed, and  the  position  of  the  companies  was 


strengthened  by  subsequent  legislation  {v.  Ap- 
prenticeship, Statute  of).  The  charters  ol 
James  I.  constituted  "courts  of  assistants," 
the  first  legal  appointment  of  which  was  made 
by  Mary  on  the  formation  of  the  Stationers' 
Company  (Herbert,  Liv.  Gomp.,  i.  118),  foi 
the  government  of  the  companies.  The  system 
of  forced  loans  from  the  companies,  which  was 
extensively  practised  by  Henry  VI II.,  was 
continued  in  the  following  reigns  by  precepts 
from  the  lord  mayor,  and  during  the  civil 
wars  there  were  periodical  payments  of  large 
sums  of  money.  In  1652,  a  committee  was 
appointed  to  ascertain  the  validity  of  the 
charters  of  different  existing  corporations, 
when  the  Grocers'  charter  was  called  for.  But 
Cromwell  granted  them  a  new  charter,  enabling 
them  to  make  bye-laws  for  their  own  govern- 
ment, and  conferring  on  them  the  power  of 
levying  a  fine  of  £30  on  each  member  at  his 
admission.  At  the  Great  Fire  (1666)  many 
of  the  companies'  halls  were  destroyed,  and 
important  documents  and  deeds  were  burnt. 
When  Charles  II.  made  himself  Master  of 
the  Corporations  in  1684  by  action  of  quo 
warranto,  the  companies  surrendered  their 
charters,  but  they  were  restored  at  the 
Revolution  <1 688). 

The  city  companies  have  several  times  in 
this  century  been  made  the  subject  of  public 
inquiry  {v.  Municipal  Corporations  Commission, 
1833;  Charity  Commissioners*  Reports;  Educa- 
tional Endowments  Committee  of  the  London 
School  Board,  1876-79  ;  Livery  Companies 
Commission,  1880-84),  and  their  present  posi- 
tion may  be  thus  briefly  summarised.  The 
extensive  powers  which  they  formerly  enjoyed, 
in  the  control  of  the  London  trades,  have  long 
since  been  repealed  by  statute  or  fallen  into 
disuse.  But  some  of  the  companies  still  enjoy 
exclusive  trade  privileges  {v.  Apothecaries'  Act, 
1815  ;  Apothecaries'  Act  Amendment  Act 
1874,  41  Geo.  III.  c.  69,  §  13  ;  and  the 
Copyright  Act,  1842).  There  are  at  present 
twelve  "great  companies"  and  sixty  minor 
companies.  The  civic  precedence  of  the  former, 
— mercers,  grocers,  drapers,  fishmongers,  gold- 
smiths, skinners,  merchant  taylors,  haber- 
dashers, salters,  ironmongers,  vintners,  and  cloth- 
workers,  dates  from  the  reign  of  Edward  III., 
and  Sir  R.  Wilmot  (1742)  was  the  first  lord 
mayor  who  did  not  belong  to  one  of  the  twelve 
great  companies.  Membership  was  probably 
never  confined  to  the  craft  or  the  trade  which 
the  company  represented.  It  is  obtained  by 
apprenticeship,  real  or  colom-able,  patrimony, 
redemption,  or  election  honoris  causd.  Though 
there  are  now  few  freewomen  of  the  companies, 
sisters  were  formerly  admitted  on  the  same 
terms  as  men,  and  attended  the  banquets 
and  entertainments.  There  are  three  gi'adea 
of  membership  :  the  court,  or  governing 
body,  self- elective  ;  the  "livery,"  limited  ir 


COMPANIES 


373 


numbers ;  and  the  simple  freemen.  The 
courts,  consisting  of  the  master,  wardens,  and 
assistants,  have  the  entire  control  of  the 
companies'  affairs,  the  appointment  of  the 
staff,  the  management  of  corporate  property, 
the  administration  of  charitable  trusts,  the 
admission  to  freedom,  livery,  and  court,  etc. 
Members  of  the  companies  are  entitled,  in  case  of 
poverty,  to  admission  to  almshouses,  pensions,  or 
other  charitable  reliefs.  Till  1835  the  freedom 
of  the  city  could  be  obtained  only  through  a  liv- 
ery company,  but  in  that  year  the  municipality 
decided  to  confer  it  irrespective  of  the  com- 
panies on  certain  terms  through  the  city 
chamberlain.  But  the  "common  hall,"  in 
conjunction  with  the  court  of  aldermen,  still 
chooses  the  lord  mayor.  The  companies' 
estates  lie  in  the  city  of  London,  in  various  parts 
of  England,  and  in  Ulster,  where  they  were 
compelled  to  purchase  and  colonise  certain  lands 
in  1609.  The  capital  value  of  their  property 
was  estimated  at  not  less  than  £15,000,000,  and 
the  total  income  thence  arising,  in  1879  or 
1880,  at  from  £750,000  to  £800,000.  The 
accuracy,  however,  of  these  figures  was  disputed. 
Their  income  falls  into  two  divisions  :  (1)  Cor- 
porate Income,  i.e.  income  which  is  at  the 
absolute  disposal  of  the  companies,  estimated 
at  £550,000  to  £600,000  per  annum  (1879  or 
1880) ;  and  (2)  Trust  Income,  i.e.  income  which 
the  companies  or  their  courts  are  bound  to 
apply  in  accordance  with  {a)  the  wills  of 
founders,  (h)  acts  of  parliament,  (c)  the  decrees 
of  the  Court  of  Chancery,  and  {d)  schemes 
framed  by  the  charity  commissioners,  and  by 
the  commissioners  of  endowed  schools.  The 
companies'  corporate  income  is  expended  in 
maintenance,  entertainments,  and  benevolent 
objects  :  such  as  the  relief  of  poor  members  ; 
education,  exhibitions  at  Oxford  and  Cambridge, 
University  and  King's  Colleges,  London,  the 
companies'  schools,  the  London  school  board, 
Girton  and  Newnham  Colleges,  etc.  ;  technical 
education,  the  Yorkshire  College,  Leeds,  the 
technical  schools  at  Huddersfield,  Bradford, 
etc,  in  connection  Avith  the  City  and  Guilds  of 
London  Institute,  the  Technical  College  in 
Finsbury,  and  the  Central  Institution  in  South 
Kensington  ;  and  in  the  support  of  some  of  the 
London  hospitals.  The  Companies'  trust 
income  is  expended  in  the  relief  of  poor 
members,  almshouses,  etc.,  education,  and  on 
charitable  objects  of  a  general  kind.  It 
appeared  (1884)  that  about  half  of  the  total 
income  of  the  companies  was  devoted,  either 
under  the  terms  of  benefactions  or  voluntarily, 
to  public  or  benevolent  objects.  But  "the 
majority  of  the  commissioners  were  of  opinion 
that  the  law  of  trusts  in  its  application  to  the 
increment  of  the  companies'  city  house-property 
had  promoted  the  increase  of  the  companies' 
corporate  estate  at  the  expense  of  their  trust 
estate"  {Liv.  Camp.  Com.,  i.  42).      The  com- 


missioners proposed  various  measures  of  reform, 
the  most  important  of  which  were  the  restraint 
of  alienation,  by  the  application  to  the  com- 
panies of  §  94  of  the  Municipal  Corporations 
Act,  1835  (5  &  6  Will.  IV.  c.  76),  the 
publication  of  accounts,  and  the  appointment 
of  a  commission  to  undertake  (i)  the  allocation 
of  a  portion  of  the  corporate  incomes  of  the 
companies  to  objects  of  acknowledged  public 
utility  ;  (ii)  the  better  application  of  the  trust 
incomes  of  the  companies  ;  and  (iii),  should  it 
prove  practicable,  the  reorganisation  of  the 
companies.  It  may  be  pointed  out  that  the 
companies  were  formerly  bound  to  contribute 
to  various  public  works.  Amongst  these  may 
be  mentioned  the  employment  of  the  poor, 
military  and  naval  armaments,  the  provision 
of  coal  and  corn,  and  the  protection  of  the 
city. 

[The  materials  for  the  history  of  the  city 
companies  are  extensive ;  see  especially  Riley, 
Munimenta  GUdhallce  Londoniensis.  —  Riley, 
Memoi-ials. — Croniques  de  London,  ed.  Aungier 
(Camd.  Soc.) — Liber  de  Antiquis  Legibus  (ed. 
Stapletou  (Camd.  Soc.)  —  Herbert,  Hist,  of  ilw 
Ttvelve  Great  Livery  CojnjMiiies. — Heath,  Account 
of  the  Grocers.  —  Norton,  Commentaries  on  the 
Hist,  of  Lond. — C.  M.  Clode,  Memorials  of  the 
Merchant  Taylors,  1875.  —  Gross,  Gild  Mer- 
chant.— Cunningham,  Growth  of  English  Industry 
and  Commerce.  —  Loftie,  Hist,  of  Lond.  —  Rot. 
Pari.,  Municipal  Corporations  Commission  (1835- 
37). — Livery  Companies  Commission  (1884).] 

W.  A.  S.  H. 

COMPANIES,  Staple.  It  is  by  no  means 
difficult  to  understand  the  cause  which  led 
merchants  trading  independently  to  form  them- 
selves into  companies  for  certain  purposes. 
The  dangers  of  travel,  the  difficulties  arising 
in  the  places  where  they  desired  to  trade, 
made  combination  almost  a  matter  of  necessity. 
To  satisfy  those  needs  leagues  such  as  the 
Hanseatio  League  {q.v.)  were  formed  ;  but 
when  formed,  other  reasons  led  to  the  in- 
troduction of  an  organisation  much  closer 
and  more  complete  than  was  necessary  for  the 
two  foregoing  ends.  In  the  first  place, 
combinations  were  more  natural  to  the  time 
than  competition,  and,  as  in  the  case  of  in- 
dustry the  Gild  {q.v.),  so  in  the  case  of  com- 
merce, the  company,  became  the  cential  feature. 
Further  than  this,  the  formation  of  the  com- 
pany, following  closely  one  of  the  primary 
causes  of  the  guild,  was  answerable  for  its  mem- 
bers. The  sovereign  made  certain  concessions 
to  foreign  merchants  trading  in  his  countr}^, 
and  they  combined  to  accept  these  concessions 
and  to  regulate  their  conduct  and  their  members 
by  them.  Of  such  organisations  the  institutions 
of  the  Hanse  furnish  many  examples,  the 
Steelyard  (q.v.)  in  London  being  one  of  the 
most  prominent  among  them.  But  in  the  case 
of  our  own  country,  not  only  did  the  king  ordei 
the  comings  and  goings  of  the  merchant  strangers, 


374 


COMPANIES 


as  to  his  own  dominions,  but  it  was  only  by 
his  permission  and  under  his  direction  that  the 
English  merchant  could  trade  abroad  with  any 
certain  hope  of  government  support  should  he 
suffer  wrong  from  foreign  powers.  In  this  con- 
nection it  is  that  we  are  forced  to  consider  the 
institution  of  the  Staple.  Individuals  *  had 
traded  and  formed  bands  for  the  occasion,  but 
the  organisation  of  the  staple  first  secured  to 
the  English  trader  a  firm  and  steady  footing. 

The  Staple  was  an  organisation  whereby  aU 
or  the  chief  articles  of  export  were  ordered  to 
be  sent  for  foreign  sale  to  certain  fixed  places 
on  the  continent  (Schanz,  vol.  i.  p.  329).  Dif- 
ferent staple  towns  might  be  assigned  for  the 
sale  of  different  commodities.  There  is  a  variety 
of  testimony  as  to  the  first  introduction  of  this 
system  ;  it  is  traced  back  by  some  to  1248,  but 
while  there  is  no  certain  authority  for  assigning 
it  to  so  early  a  date,  there  is  no  doubt  that  the 
system  of  the  staple  was  fuUy  recognised  in  the 
reign  of  Edward  I.  In  the  reign  of  Edward 
III.  it  becomes  of  the  highest  political  import- 
ance. To  a  large  extent  indeed  it  must  be 
viewed  as  a  political  institution.  It  was  in- 
troduced by  the  government  and  used  by  it  for 
certain  ends  of  its  own.  In  the  first  place  the 
institution  of  the  staple  in  any  town  was  a 
bribe  to  tlie  sovereign  within  whose  domains 
that  town  lay.  In  the  second  place,  it  provided 
an  easy  means  for  the  collection  of  the  export 
duties  levied  on  commodities  sent  out  of  the 
kingdom.  It  may  weU  be  asked  how  far  it 
aided  English  trade.  Foreign  traders  indeed 
were  permitted  to  enter  into  the  staple  organisa- 
tion on  equal  terms  with  English.  But  though 
this  was  the  case,  the  exceptional  rights  of 
jurisdiction  and  privileges  granted  to  the  com- 
pany of  the  staple  encouraged  the  English  ex- 
porter to  send  his  commodities  abroad  now  that 
that  could  be  done  with  every  security  and  under 
favourable  conditions.  It  may  have  assisted 
the  development  of  trade  among  foreigners,  but 
it  certainly  increased  the  traffic  of  the  English 
on  the  continent.  Each  concession  promised 
to  the  English  king  by  foreign  princes  to  induce 
him  to  establish  the  staple  within  their  particu- 
lar boundaries  meant  a  corresponding  advantage 
to  the  traders  who  were  included  in  the  staple, 
and  most  of  these  were  English.  The  organisa- 
tion of  the  staple  was  effective.  The  merchants 
of  the  staple  elected  their  mayor,  who  exercised 
great  power.  He  dealt  speedy  justice  according 
to  the  Law  Merchant  {q.v.)  ;  he  rdgiilated 
prices  ;  and  it  was  his  function  to  arrange  the 
various  dues  which  had  to  be  paid,  and  to  see 
that  there  was  necessary  accommodation  pro- 
vided for  storing  goods,  etc. 

But  while  the  staple  was  the  institution  on 
the  maintenance  of  which  the  well-being  of  the 
English  trade  of  the  13th  and  14th  centuries 
chiefly  depended,  the  commercial  necessities  of 
later  years   brought   into  prominence  traders 


whose  main  purpose  it  was  to  exercise  their  func- 
tions outside  the  staple  towns.  The  staple  had 
been  useful,  but  it  neither  directly  supported  the 
interests  of  the  English  trader  as  distinct  from 
the  foreigner  nor  did  it  provide  means  whereby 
the  trade  might  be  extended  into  new  countries. 
This  was  the  work  of  other  and  chiefly  of  ono 
other  organisation.  Already  in  the  1 4th  century 
there  were  separate  bands  of  merchants  trading 
outside  the  staple.  These  were  the  merchant 
venturers  of  different  cities.  But  though  they 
were  termed  companies  of  merchant  venturers, 
it  must  not  be  supposed  that  they  were  in  any 
kind  of  partnership,  or  that  the  bond  existing 
between  them  was  of  any  very  stringent  nature. 
There  were  companies  of  merchant  venturers  in 
York,  Newcastle,  Bristol,  etc.,  and  they  were 
engaged  in  the  most  different  directions.  Some 
were  adventurers  to  Iceland,  some  to  Prussia, 
others  into  the  southern  countries.  But  the 
importance  of  these  various  bodies  trading  to 
various  parts  was  thrown  into  the  shade  by  the 
pre-eminence  accorded  to  those  engaged  in  the 
trade  between  England  and  the  Netherlands. 
It  was  to  them  that  the  name  of  merchant  ad- 
venturer particularly  attaches  (v.  Adven- 
turers, Merchant).  There  is  considerable 
doubt  as  to  their  origin.  Most  probably  their 
history  may  be  traced  back  (Wheeler,  Treatise 
of  Commerce)  to  the  grant  of  privileges  made 
by  the  Duke  of  Brabant  to  the  English  mer- 
chants trading  in  his  domain.  Thereby  they 
became  entitled  to  appear  on  equal  terms  before 
the  tribunals  of  the  land  in  the  case  of  quarrel 
with  natives,  while  special  rights  of  jurisdiction 
were  gi-anted  to  them  for  settling  disputes 
among  themselves.  This  particular  jurisdiction, 
according  to  Schanz,  was  the  bond  of  union 
ultimately  developed.  It  is  probable  also  that 
prominent  among  the  English  traders  was  the 
brotherhood  of  St.  Thomas  of  Canterbury,  and 
that  grants  made  in  common  to  the  English 
were  appropriated  gi-adually  by  this  society. 
But  as  yet  there  was  no  sign  of  any  close  union. 
At  this  time  the  connection  of  the  merchant 
venturers  in  Flanders  and  the  Netherlands  with 
the  organisation  of  the  staple  was  very  close 
indeed — so  close  that  the  mayor  of  the  staple 
exercised  a  supervision  over  the  traders  in  towns 
other  than  the  staple.  But  when  the  staple 
was  fixed  at  Calais,  and  when  the  cloth  trade 
with  Antwerp  grew  into  sudden  importance,  as 
in  the  beginning  of  the  15th  century,  such 
relations  were  impossible.  In  1407  the  right 
was  granted  to  the  traders  in  the  Netherlands  to 
assemble  and  elect  a  governor  who  might  regu- 
late such  matters  as  were  common  to  them  all. 
This  was  the  second  stage  in  the  history  of  the 
merchant  adventurers.  The  first  marked  their 
origin,  the  second  their  separation  from  the 
staple.  But  of  any  formal  incorporation  there 
Avas  no  mention.  That  such  was  as  yet  the  case 
is  contradicted,  Schanz  thinks,  by  the  fact  that 


COMPANIES— COMPENSATION 


375 


the  various  members  belonged  in  England  to 
various  companies.  But  this  continued  in  after 
times,  when  the  merchant  adventurers  had  long 
won  the  grants  they  sought.  The  third  period 
in  their  history  was  under  the  Tudors. 

Henry  VII.  was  well  aware  of  the  import- 
ance of  trade  between  the  Netherlands  and 
England.  The  conduct  of  that  trade  was 
chiefly  in  the  hands  of  the  London  merchants, 
who  did  all  they  could  to  exclude  others  from 
participating  with  them  in  its  benefits.  This 
they  hoped  to  effect  by  demanding  from  each 
newcomer  a  certain  and  not  insignificant  sum 
to  pay  for  the  costs  of  the  governors  or  consuls, 
and  to  serve  as  insurance  or  surety  money. 
That  such  an  attempt  could  be  made  marks,  of 
course,  the  growth  which  had  taken  place  in 
the  cori)orate  direction.  Hitherto  nothing  had 
been  done  to  recognise  the  legality  of  such 
growth,  but  it  was  recognised  at  length  when 
Henry  VII.,  to  set  at  rest  all  doubt  and  to 
prevent  all  extortion,  decreed  that  every  mer- 
chant should  be  free  to  trade  to  the  Nether- 
lands undisturbed  on  payment  of  a  certain  sum, 
much  less  than  that  which  had  been  demanded, 
to  the  body  of  the  merchant  adventurers.  From 
this  moment  their  energies,  both  in  the  cause  of 
trade  and  of  monopoly,  were  redoubled.  On  the 
whole  they  met  with  support  from  Henry  VII. 
and  Henry  VIII.,  who  could  not  fail  to  under- 
stand their  importance.  In  their  great  struggle 
with  the  staplers,  though  no  definite  grant  gave 
victory  to  either  side,  they  were  enabled  to 
snatch  the  substantial  fruits  of  victory  by 
gradual  encroachment.  As  a  matter  of  fact 
the  organisation  of  the  staple  had  become  anti- 
quated. The  new  trade  was  not  such  that  it 
could  be  directed  in  regular  channels  and  re- 
stricted to  particular  places  ;  thus,  when  the 
staple  lost  its  rights  over  the  country  beyond 
the  towns  of  the  staple,  assert  them  though  it 
might  within  these  towns,  it  had  lost  far  more 
than  it  retained.  The  traders  of  the  staple 
had  to  pay  their  dues  to  the  merchant  adven- 
turers when  they  traded  outside  the  particular 
towns  assigned  to  them. 

The  encouragement  given  to  the  younger 
corporation  was  wise  ;  by  it  trade  was  taken 
out  of  the  hands  of  the  foreigners  and  placed 
in  those  of  the  English.  Thus,  indeed,  it  is 
that  the  policy  of  this  society  was  a  part  of 
that  great  policy  of  adventure  which  marked 
the  end  of  the  15th  and  the  whole  of  the 
16th  centur3\  And  as  the  organisation  of 
the  merchant  adventurers  grew  more  rigid 
it  lost  its  mobility,  and  in  its  turn  it  had 
to  see  much  trade  fall  into  the  hands  of 
new  companies.  The  company  of  the  merchant 
adventurers  consisted  of  traders  engaged  in 
individual  enterprises  but  united  for  purposes 
of  jurisdiction  and  having  rights  of  monopoly. 
But  now  new  countries  were  about  to  be 
opened  up,  and  new  bands  of  traders  appear, 


having  common  interest  in  the  ventures  they 
were  undertaking.  They  grew  into  importance 
during  the  reign  of  Elizabeth,  from  whom, 
by  the  wise  advice  of  Lord  Burghley,  they 
met  with  support.  The  queen  and  her  minister 
themselves  were  often  sharers  in  the  ventures. 
There  was  something  else  done  for  them  besides 
this.  The  originators  of  the  expeditions,  and 
thus  the  principal  venturers  therein,  in  return 
for  their  toil  and  their  risk  were  granted  rights 
of  monopolising  the  trade  in  the  region  to 
which  they  were  setting  sail.  They  did  not 
form  company  partnerships  in  the  ordinary 
sense  of  the  words,  they  had  monopoly 
rights,  and  each  expedition  was  separate  and 
distinct  in  which  the  original  grantees  and 
their  friends  made  venture ;  but  gradually 
these  expeditions  became  regular,  and  in  like 
manner  it  would  appear  the  amount  of  each 
man's  venture  became  fixed  by  custom.  This 
process  may  be  traced  in  the  history  of  the 
East  India  Company  {q.v.),  founded  1599,  in 
its  development  from  the  IjEVANT  Company 
(g-.v.),  founded  1592.  Among  other  companies 
may  be  mentioned.  Company  of  Merchants 
trading  to  Spain,  Russia  Company,  African 
Companies,  Eastland  Company,  Company  of 
Cathay,  Turkey  Company,  Hamburg  Company. 
In  due  time  the  policy  of  granting  monopolies 
])oth  to  these  companies  as  also  to  the  merchant 
adventurers  became  a  matter  of  much  debate 
{v.  pamphlets  by  Lewis,  Roberts,  Brent,  and 
Parker),  and  in  1672  the  rights  gi-anted  and 
hitherto  continued  were  curtailed  by  act  of 
parliament  (14  C.  II.  c.  7). 

[Schanz,  Englische  Handelspolitik.  —  Ochen- 
kowski,  Engl,  toirthsch.  Entioickelung. — Wlieeler, 
Treatise  of  Commerce. — Paraplilets  by  Misselden 
and  Malynes.  There  is  a  spirited  but  insufficient 
description  of  the  growth  and  importance  of  these 
companies,  both  Staple  and  Merchant  Adventurers, 
in  Richard  Jones's  works,  edited  by  Whewell.] 

B.  c.  K.  G. 

COMPANIES,  TRADING.  See  Foreign 
Trade,  Regulation  of. 

COMPENSATION.  1.  Forlandtakencmnp^il- 
sorily. — Where  land  is  taken  under  the  authority 
of  the  state  for  public  undertakings  the  amount 
of  compensation  to  be  paid  to  the  owner  is,  il 
the  parties  cannot  agi-ee,  determined  by  justices, 
arbitrators,  a  jury,  or  a  surveyor  appointed  by 
the  justices,  under  the  Lands  Clauses  Con- 
solidation  Act  of  1845  (8  &  9  Vict.  c.  18).  The 
act  does  not  prescribe  the  measure  of  compen- 
sation, though  it  directs  that  regard  must  be 
had  to  damage  sustained  by  reason  of  the  sever- 
ance of  lands  or  other  injury  done  to  other 
lands  not  taken;  In  the  case  of  freeholds  thirty 
to  thirty- three  years'  purchase  is  usually  allowed, 
and  in  the  case  of  leaseholds  such  a  sum  as 
would  at  the  expiration  of  the  term  repay  a 
purchaser  his  original  outlay  and  compound 
interest  thereon.     Other  items  that  enter  into 


376 


COMPENSATION— COMPETITION 


the  amount  payable  are  injury  to  severed  lands, 
value  of  fixtures,  loss  on  sale  of  stock,  costs  of 
removal,  and  value  of  goodwill.  Ten  per  cent 
is  added  to  the  value  of  the  land  for  compulsory 
sale.  Probable  increase  in  value  may  be  taken 
into  account,  but  no  deduction  is  made  in  respect 
of  the  probable  increased  value  of  the  lands  not 
taken  arising  from  the  work  in  question.  In 
the  case  of  land  taken  under  the  Artisans'  and 
Labourers'  Dwelling  Improvement  Acts,  1875- 
82,  the  compensation  is  to  be  based  on  the 
principles  laid  down  in  the  acts,  and  no  addi- 
tional allowance  is  to  be  made  for  compulsory 
purchase  (see  Compulsory  Taking  of  Land). 

[Law  of  Compensation,  by  E.  Lloyd,  London, 
1882.] 

2.  For  Tenants'  Improvement.  At  common 
law  a  landlord  was  not  bound  on  the  termina- 
tion of  a  tenancy  to  compensate  a  tenant  for 
improvements,  but  in  particular  localities  "cus- 
toms of  the  country "  arose  under  which  the 
landlord  compensates  an  outgoing  tenant  for 
certain  improvements,  such  as  building,  drain- 
ing, manuring,  or  preparing  land  for  crops. 
These  "customs  of  the  country,"  though  most 
variable  and  based  on  no  uniform  principle, 
came  to  be  enforced  as  part  of  the  contract  of 
tenancy.  For  lists  of  improvements  for  which 
allowances  are  made,  see  Woodfall's  Landlord 
and  Tenant,  1889.  In  1875  an  act  (38  &  39 
Vict.  c.  92),  was  passed  with  the  object  of 
introducing  a  general  law  of  compensation  for 
England  and  Wales.  Though  based  on  the 
Report  of  the  Central  Chambers  of  Agriculture, 
1875,  its  permissive  character  rendered  the  act 
largely  inoperative.  The  royal  commission  on 
agiiculture  in  1882  reported  in  favour  of  mak- 
ing the  principles  of  the  act  compulsory.  In 
1883  a  new  act  (46  &  47  Vict.  c.  61)  was  passed, 
under  which  an  outgoing  tenant  can  claim  com- 
pensation equivalent  to  the  Value  of  the  follow- 
ing improvements  to  an  incoming  tenant : — (1) 
for  buildings,  ensilage,  pasture,  osier-beds, 
water  meadows,  irrigation  works,  gardens,  roads, 
bridges,  water-courses,  fencing,  hop-planting, 
fruit- planting,  warping,  and  embankments,  pro- 
vided the  improvement  is  made  with  the  con- 
sent of  the  landlord  ;  (2)  for  drainage,  provided 
notice  of  the  improvement  be  given  to  the  land- 
lord ;  (3)  for  boning,  chalking,  clay-burning, 
claying,  liming,  marling,  artificial  manure,  and 
consumption  of  feeding  stuff  not  produced  on 
the  holding.  The  act  only  applies  to  agricul- 
tural holdings,  and  affords  no  protection  to  a 
tenant  against  the  practical  confiscation  of  his 
improvements  by  additions  to  his  rent.  As  to 
compensation  for  tenants'  improvements,  or  for 
disturbance,  in  Ireland,  see  33  &  34  Vict.  c.  46, 
44  &  45  Vict.  c.  49.     (Small  Holdings,  App.) 

[The  economic  aspects  of  such  compensation  are 
discussed  in  Sidgwick's  Political  Economy,  bk.  ill. 
ch.  4. — English  Land  and  English  Landlords, 
G.  B.  Brodrick,   London,  1881. — Tenant's  Gain 


not  Landlord's  Loss,  J.  H.  Nicholson,  Edinburgh, 
1883.] 

3.  Land  Nationalisation.  Some  writers  ad- 
mit that  if  land  were  nationalised  landlords 
should  receive  compensation  ;  others  deny  this 
on  the  ground  either  that  the  land  is  the  pro- 
perty of  the  people,  or  that  private  property  is 
injurious  to  the  state.  But  property  is  the 
creation  of  law,  and  in  no  sense  can  it  be  said 
that  the  land  "belongs  to  the  people."  Even 
assuming  that  it  would  be  expedient  to  abolish 
private  property,  on  the  erroneous  idea  that 
ownership  was  injurious  to  the  state,  com- 
pensation should  equally  be  given. 

[See  Land  Nationalisation,  by  A.  E.  Wallace, 
London,  1882. — Progress  and  Poverty,  by  H. 
George,  London,  1881.  —  Social  Statics,  by  H. 
Spencer,  London.]  j.  E.  c.  M. 

COMPETITION  and  CUSTOM.  Wealth 
having  been  produced,  is  forthwith — or  even  in 
the  act  of  production — distributed  amongst 
those  who  have  been  concerned  in  its  production, 
and  the  share  of  the  product  which  falls  to  the 
lot  of  each  of  these  is  determined  in  the 
absence  of  disturbing  causes  by  competition. 
Competition  has  been  defined  as  the  free  action 
of  individual  self-interest  —  that  is  to  say, 
supposing  a  given  amount  of  wealth  to  be 
divided  amongst  four  persons,  the  proportion 
of  it  which  each  gets  will  depend  on  the  extent 
to  which  he  is  superior  to  the  others  in  the 
qualities  necessary  to  the  struggle,  the  strongest 
for  this  purpose  getting  most  and  the  weakest 
least.  But  competition  is  more  clearly  seen  in 
its  results.  1.  Granting  that  every  man  seeks 
to  increase  his  pleasures  and  reduce  his  pains, 
i.e.  to  secure  an  increase  of  pleasure  for  a  given 
amount  of  exertion,  or  a  given  amount  of 
pleasure  for  a  smaller  amount  of  exertion,  we 
see  that  every  man  will  set  himself  to  procure 
the  necessaries  and  comforts  of  life  at  a  minimum 
of  sacrifice  ;  no  one  will  work  harder  for  a  given 
result  than  he  need.  The  same  holds  good 
when  division  of  labour  and  exchange  appear. 
Every  man  will  now  strive  to  exchange  the  pro- 
ducts of  his  labour  for  as  much  as  possible  ol 
the  products  of  the  labour  of  others,  for  by  so 
doing  he  will  increase  the  amount  of  necessaries 
and  comforts  which  his  labour  commands. 
When  this  process  has  become  general  the  re- 
sult will  be  that  similar  exchanges  will  take 
place  on  similar  terms.  This  is  commonly  ex- 
pressed by  saying  that  there  can  only  be  one 
price  at  one  time  for  the  same  unit  of  the  same 
quality  of  the  same  article  in  the  same  market 
(see  Market).  Thus  a  quartern  loaf  of  house- 
hold bread  may  be  assumed  to  be  at  the  same 
price  on  the  same  day  all  over  Oxford,  but  may 
be  at  a  different  price  in  Bristol,  Norwich,  and 
Durham ;  a  quarter  of  wheat  of  the  same  quality 
to  sell  for  the  same  sum  all  over  England  ;  an 
ounce  of  silver  all  over  the  civilised  world.  These 
are  the  results  of  "commercial"  competition. 


COMPETITION 


377 


2.  Granting  that  all  are  striving  for  a  maximum 
return  to  their  exertions,  producers  will  betake 
themselves  to  those  forms  of  production  which 
offer  such  a  return,  whether  immediately  or  by 
means  of  exchange.  Labourers  will  go  where 
wages  are  highest ;  manufacturers  will  embark 
in  those  industries  which  give  the  largest  pro- 
fits ;  capitalists  will  lend  their  savings  to  those 
who  can  be  trusted  to  pay  the  highest  interest. 
But  in  time  all  these  inequalities  will  vanish. 
If  occupation  A,  for  example,  is  crowded  because 
of  the  high  return  which  exertion  commands  in 
it,  occupation  B  will  be  comparatively  de.s^.rted, 
with  the  result  that  the  products  of  B  will  rise 
in  value  as  compared  with  those  of  A,  and  the 
rewards  of  those  engaged  -will  rise  and  fall  pro- 
portionately. Ultimately  an  equality  will  be 
arrived  at — that  is  to  say,  that  whether  by 
wages,  profits,  or  interest,  equal  efforts  and 
sacrifices  will  secure  an  equal  real  reward,  how- 
ever dissimilar  the  services  by  which  they  are 
represented,  or  the  money  -  payment  in  which 
their  reward  is  given.  This  is  popularly  ex- 
pressed by  saying  that  "in  the  long  run  wages 
and  profits  tend  to  an  equality,"  and  is  the 
result  of  "  industrial "  competition. 

Thus  far  the  working  and  results  of  competi- 
tion have  been  described  in  an  "economic" 
world,  among  a  people,  that  is,  who  were  actu- 
ated by  economic  motives  and  no  other.  It  is 
commonly  brought  into  relation  with  the  facts 
of  life  by  saying  that  it  is  a  "  tendency."  This 
may  mean  one  of  two  things— (1)  In  the  eco- 
nomic world,  as  we  see,  competition  is  complete 
and  its  results  are  patent.  The  possibility,  the 
vision,  of  a  gi-eater  reward  for  his  exertions  will 
make  a  man  shift  his  wares  from  one  market  to 
another,  and  the  same  prospect  will  lead  him 
to  shift  himself  and  his  capital  from  one  under- 
taking or  calling  to  another  so  soon  as  may  be  ; 
with  him  no  other  motive  can  or  does  interfere. 
Competition  m  actual  life  is  a  tendency  in  so 
far  as  men  in  the  absence  of  any  counterbalanc- 
ing motive  are  swayed  by  self-interest.  The 
expression  does  not  imply  that  self-interest  is 
more  than  one  motive  out  of  many,  but  it  is 
the  motive  to  which  alone  economists  attend, 
(2)  It  is  sometimes  assumed  that  competition  is 
a  tendency  in  the  sense  that  it  is  a  force  of 
gi'adually  increasing  strength  in  determining 
distribution.  How  far  competition  is  a  tendency 
in  this  latter  sense  is  a  matter  of  considerable 
dispute.  It  would  be  quite  impossible  to  dis- 
cuss the  relative  strength  at  any  moment  of  the 
various  motives  which  influence  human  action, 
as,  e.g.  to  show  the  comparative  force  of  patriot- 
ism and  self-interest  in  the  average  man  in  two 
successive  generations.  But  taking  the  material 
world  and  the  distribution  of  wealth  in  it,  we 
may  have  definite  forces  at  work  which  are,  so 
to  say,  rivals  of  competition  in  this  field. 

1.  Early  in  the  centmy  it  was  taken  for 
granted  that  the  only  serious  hindrance  in  the 


way  of  perfect  competition  was  custom.  Custom, 
i.e.  the  doing  a  thing  because  others  have  done 
it,  has  at  all  times  been  a  powerful  influence  in 
the  world.  It  is  seen  in  both  the  spheres  of 
competition.  Custom  may  fix  prices  year  after 
year  ;  custom  determines  a  man's  walk  in  life, 
the  employment  of  labour  and  capital,  often  to 
the  exclusion  of  any  other  motive.  ' '  Heralds 
in  Sparta,"  says  Herodotus  (vi.  60),  "are  not 
so  made  on  account  of  any  special  clearness  of 
voice,  but  son  succeeds  father."  The  younger 
sons  of  the  peasant  owner  in  Auvergne  leave 
their  native  mountains  to  work  in  Paris  and 
elsewhere,  not  because  wages  are  higher,  but 
because  it  is  the  tradition  to  do  so  in  order  to 
avoid  breaking  up  the  family  estate.  It  may 
be  strongly  argued  that  custom  is  losing  strength. 
It  is  still  powerful  in  the  East,  more  powerful 
in  Asia  than  in  Europe,  in  Europe  than  in 
America  ;  it  was  stronger  and  extended  over  a 
wider  area  a  century  ago  than  now  ;  the  pro- 
fessions, etc.  in  which  it  still  lingers  among 
ourselves  are  gradually  shaking  it  off ;  its  dis- 
appearance as  a  factor  in  exchange  would  be  an 
additional  illustration  of  the  transition  from 
status  to  contract,  whicli  is  said  to  characterise 
the  modern  as  distinguished  from  the  ancient 
or  mediaeval  world. 

2.  Combination  is  commonly  said  to  be  an 
obstacle  or  interruption  to  competition,  and  if 
competition  be  defined  as  the  action  of  indi- 
vidual self-interest,  it  is,  at  first  sight,  incon- 
sistent with  combination.  Thus,  e.g.  if  com- 
petition in  the  above  sense  is  thorough-going, 
every  workman  will  make  his  own  terms  v/ith 
his  master,  will  compete  against  his  fellow- 
workmen  for  employment,  will  stand  or  fall  by 
his  own  individual  strength.  The  labour' 
market  will  exhibit  the  spectacle  of  a  three- 
fold struggle,  viz.  of  master  against  master 
for  workmen,  of  workman  against  workman  for 
employment,  and  of  master  against  workman 
to  settle  the  rate  of  wages.  Remove  either  of 
these  by  combination  of  workmen  in  trades- 
unions  or  of  masters  in  associations,  and  com- 
petition is  p7-o  tanto  diminished.  So,  too,  in 
exchange  ;  here  it  is  the  struggle  to  sell  and 
the  struggle  to  buy,  and  the  struggle  between 
buyers  and  sellers  which  settles  the  price.  A 
combination  of  buyers  or  sellers,  a  "ring"  of 
any  kind,  diminishes  the  competition.  In 
Michigan,  e.g.  the  sellers  of  salt,  by  an  agi-ee- 
ment  to  sell  through  a  joint  agent  only  and  at 
uniform  rates,  put  an  end  to  all  competition 
amongst  themselves.  On  the  other  hand  it 
may  be  urged  (a)  that  although  in  both  of  these 
cases  competition  is  in  one  direction  weakened, 
in  another  it  is  strengthened.  The  competition 
among  sellers  in  the  labour  or  the  salt  market 
is  suspended  only  to  increase  their  strength  in 
competing  with  buyers,  to  enable  their  self- 
interest  to  act  with  greater  force  ;  the  struggle 
is    more    severe    as    being   between   organised 


378 


COMPETITIOiN 


bodies  rather  than  between  isolated  individuals ; 
(b)  that  all  combination  is  really  in  the  end 
dictated  by  self-interest,  and  that  no  one  who 
joins  a  combination  does  so  with  the  idea  that 
his  own  interest  will  suffer,  but  rather  that  the 
interests  of  the  individuals  are  bound  up  with 
the  interest  of  the  body  to  which  they  belong. 

3.  A  third  rival  of  competition  is  socialism. 
In  competition,  as  we  have  seen,  every  man  is 
left  to  secure  for  himself  what  he  can  of  the 
wealth  which  he  has  helped  to  produce.  Social- 
ism would  substitute  for  this  "scramble"  an 
orderly  distribution  by  the  state.  So  far  as  we 
are  concerned  with  it  here,  socialism  would  not 
directly  affect  production,  but  taking  wealth 
when  produced,  the  state  would  distribute  it  by 
some  one  of  its  organs.  The  principle  of  dis- 
tribution is  immaterial  to  our  subject ;  whether 
the  state  proceed  on  some  real  or  supposed 
ground  of  equity,  distribute  according  to  deserts 
or  according  to  needs,  it  will  equally  put  an  end 
to  competition. 

For  Adam  Smith  the  end  of  the  statesman  is 
to  secure  that  all  distribution  proceeds  on  com- 
petitive principles ;  the  removal  of  all  hindrances 
and  obstacles  to  the  free  play  of  individual  self- 
interest  is  the  general  lesson  of  the  Wealth  of 
Nations;  whilst  at  the  same  time  the  writer 
shows  that  the  results  of  competition  are  but 
seldom  seen  in  their  fulness.  For  Ricardo  com- 
petition is  a  postulate  ;  his  conclusions  uniformly 
depend  on  the  assumption  that  all  men  know 
and  seek  their  own  interest  without  let  or 
hindrance.  Mill  assumes  competition  in  part, 
and  in  part  treats  it  as  a  growing  force  ;  much 
of  his  reasoning,  like  that  of  Ricardo,  starts 
from  the  hypothesis  that  competition  is  uni- 
versal ;  much  again  of  his  treatise  is  devoted  to 
showing  its  limitations  in  practice.  Cairnes 
has  pointed  out  that  these  limitations  are  far 
more  effective  than  was  supposed  in  his  theory 
of  mutually  exclusive,  or,  as  he  calls  them, 
"non-competing,"  groups  of  producers,  but  his 
conclusions  have  perhaps  no  claim  to  finality. 
Cliffe  Leslie  again  showed,  by  some  remark- 
able instances,  first,  how  much  more  lasting  is 
custom  than  was  once  thought,  and  how  much 
a  man's  actions  are  determined  by  his  sur- 
roundings, rather  than  by  simple  motives  such 
as  self-interest ;  and  secondly,  that  the  areas 
over  which  anything  like  equality  in  prices  can 
be  traced  are  very  small,  and  that  so  far  the 
tendency  has  been  for  fresh  inequalities  to  arise 
as  fast  as  the  old  are  obliterated. 

[See  Adam  Smith,  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk,  1. 
ch.  X.  ;  pt.  11.  bk.  Iv.  eh.  i.-vill. — Mill,  Principles 
of  Political  Economy,  bk.  11.  ch.  Iv. — Cairnes, 
Sovie  Leading  Principles  of  Political  EconoTtiy 
newly  Expounded.  —  Cliffe  Leslie,  Essays  in  Pol- 
itical and  Moral  Philosophy,  xv.  xvll.  xxi. — 
Sldgwlck,  The  Principles  of  Political  Economy, 
Introd.  i.  HI. — F.  "Walker,  Political  Economy,  bk. 
ill.  ch.  i.]  L.  u.  P. 


COMPETITION  AND  Regulation.  Where 
one  man  vies  with  another  for  the  advan- 
tage of  dealing  with  a  third  party,  there  is  com- 
petition. Simple  examples  are  :  the  public  at  an 
auction  bidding  against  each  other ;  a  shopkeeper 
lowering  his  prices  to  attract  custom.  The  action 
of  a  competitor  is  less  simple  when,  changing  his 
occupation,  he  enters  the  trade  of  those  with 
whom  he  competes.  "  The  operation  of  compe- 
tition ...  by  which  the  terms  of  similar 
exchanges  are  kept  approximately  similar 
should  be  carefuUy  distinguished  from  that 
other  action  of  competition  by  which  certain 
inequalities  in  the  remuneration  of  dissimila/r 
services  tend  to  be  continually  removed" 
(Sidgwick's  Political  Economy,  Introd.  ch.  Hi. 
§  3).  These  varieties  of  competition  are  distin- 
guished by  Cairnes  as  "commercial"  and 
"industrial"  competition  {Leading  Principles, 
part  i.  ch.  iii.)  The  simpler  process  may  be 
illustrated  by  the  action  of  physical  forces 
tending  to  equilibrium.  Jevons  compares  the 
equations  of  "final  utility"  which  determine 
market  prices  to  the  differential  equations 
which  determine  the  equilibrium  of  a  mechan- 
ical system  {Theory  of  Political  Economy,  ch. 
iv.)  The  analogies  of  exact  science,  the  formiilae 
of  Jevons  and  Walras,  are  less  helpful  when  we 
regard  competitors  as  balancing  the  total  utilities 
of  different  occupations.  The  equation  of 
"net  advantages,"  to  ufse  Prof.  Marshall's 
phrase  (see  Principles  of  Economics)  in  different 
trades  is  not  very  analogous  to  any  theorem  in 
mathematical  physics. 

Competition  is  contrasted  with  monopoly  and 
combination  ;  with  governmental  regulation, 
charity,  and  custom.  The  preferability  of 
competition  to  these  regimes  is  debated  on 
grounds  which  may  be  distinguished  as  trans- 
cendental and  utilitarian. 

(1)  Competition  is  advocated  as  natural  in  an 
optimistic  sense  ;  as  consonant  with  justice  and 
abstract  right.  But  {a)  those  who  with  Burke 
maintain  that  the  "laws  of  commerce  are  the 
laws  of  nature,  and  therefore  the  laws  of  God," 
employ  an  argument  from  design  which  few 
now  accept.  And  (p)  the  other  metaphysical 
reasons  presuppose  an  unreal  freedom  of  compe- 
tition. Actually,  competitors  do  not  start 
fair ;  inheritance  and  other  causes  favour 
some  ;  want  of  capital,  education,  opportunity, 
handicap  many  (Wagner,  Lehrhuch  der  Pol. 
Oekon.,  §  100  et  seq.)  Society  is  stratified  in 
"non- competing  groups"  (Cau-nes,  Leading 
Principles,  ch.  iii.  ;  Mill,  bk.  ii.  ch.  xiv.  §  2). 
Where  mobility  of  labour  from  one  group  to 
another  does  not  exist,  there  is  no  presumption 
that  competition,  thus  hampered,  effects  an 
equitable  distribution.  Even  if  perfect  equality 
of  opportunity  were  attainable,  natural  ability 
would  still  constitute  a  non-competing  group. 
Is  it  clear  then  that  competition  between  work- 
men is  "the  only  way  to  equity,  and  that  anj 


COMPETITION 


379 


interference  with  it  must  involve  injustice  ? " 
(Danson,  Wealth  of  Households,  par.  811). 
Rather  the  coincidence  of  competition  with 
justice  is  "a  perfectly  a  priori  assumption, 
an  unproved  supposition  "  (Wagner,  loc.  cit. ) 

(2)  Rejecting  the  "metaphysical  incubus" 
of  abstract  principles  and  rights  (Jevons,  State 
in  Relation  to  Labour,  ch.  i.),  let  us  weigh  the 
utility  of  competition.  Its  tendency  to  equal 
distribution  of  wealth  deserves  place  under  this 
head  (cp.  Bentham,  Principles  of  the  Civil 
Code,  pt.  i.  ch.  vi.  ;  J.  S.  Mill,  Utilitarianism, 
p.  93).  Also,  in  this  regime,  more  than  any 
other,  each  individual  is  stimulated  by  self- 
interest  to  do  his  best  for  the  supply  of  others' 
wants.  "  The  difficulty  of  finding  any  adequate 
substitute  for  it  (the  motive  of  self-interest)  is 
an  almost  invincible  obstacle  in  the  way  of 
reconstructing  society  on  any  but  its  present 
individualistic  basis"  (Sidgwick).  However, 
"trusts"  and  other  modern  forms  of  monopoly 
are  less  blamed  for  inefficiency  than  for  im- 
moderate charges  and  gains  (C.  W.  Baker,  Mono- 
polies and  the  People,  1889). 

Competition  is  an  almost  ineradicable  gi'owth 
of  self-interested  human  nature.  "  Expellas 
furca,  tamen  usque  recurret."  Combinations 
resisting  the  tendency  of  this  force  are  liable  to 
disruption.  Professor  Marshall  says  arbi- 
trators "must  not  set  up  arrangements  widely 
different  from  those  which  would  have  been 
brought  about  by  competition."  They  should 
follow  the  example  of  Rennie,  who,  when  he 
had  to  construct  a  breakwater,  first  ascertained 
"the  slope  at  which  the  natural  action  of  the 
waves  would  arrange  a  bank,"  and  then  "let 
stones  into  the  water  so  as  to  form  such  a  slope  " 
{Economics  of  Industry,  bk.  iii.  ch.  viii.  §  2). 

Again,  competition  has  the  advantage  of 
tending  to  a  definite  determinate  adjustment ; 
affording  a  simple  intelligible  rule,  laissezfaire. 
Whereas  the  bargain  between  combinations  is 
indeterminate  ;  or  only  determinable  by  some 
extra -economic  principle  not  commanding 
general  assent  (Sidg^vick,  Political  Economy, 
bk.  ii.  ch.  X.  §  2  ;  Menger,  Grundsdtze,  ch. 
iv.  ;  Edgeworth,  Mathematical  Psychics,  pp. 
20-56).  Jevons  says  {Scientific  Primer,  ch. 
vii.),  "there  is  no  way  of  deciding  what  is  a 
fair  day's  wages"  outside  competition.  It  is 
difficult  even  to  imagine  upon  what  other  prin- 
ciple certain  complicated  transactions  of  modern 
trade  and  industry  could  be  regulated. 

Again,  competition  is  a  struggle  for  life 
which  results  in  the  survival  of  the  fittest. 
However,  the  "  selection  "  is  not  "  natural,"  but 
artificial ;  so  far  as  the  competitors  do  not  start 
fair  (Wagner,  Lehrhuch,  §  135  ;  above  (1,  h)). 
Nor  is  the  "fitness"  which  economical  com- 
petition tests  of  the  highest  order.  Success  may 
be  due  to  cleverness  in  attracting  business,  or  to 
a  lower  standard  of  comfort.  That  a  degraded 
standard  may  result  from  unrestricted  competi- 


tion is  shown  in  Booth's  Life  and  Labour  of  the 
People  in  London.  Mere  survival,  adaptation  to 
"being"  rather  than  "well-being,  "is  not  an  ideal. 
(Sidgwick,  Theory  of  Evolution,  "Mind,"  vol.  i.) 

Against  the  advantages  of  the  "  struggle  for 
life  "  should  also  be  set  the  allegation  of  trade- 
unionists  that  in  imregulated  competition  men 
injure  themselves  by  over-exertion  (Report  of 
Trades- Union  Commission,  1867),  the  infantile 
mortality,  and  other  evils  ascribed  to  the  un- 
restricted employment  of  mothers  (Jevons's 
State  in  Relation  to  Labour,  ch.  iii.). 

Further  objections  to  competition  are  that  it 
defeats  itself  when  the  successful  competitor, 
having  crushed  out  his  rivals,  becomes  a  mono- 
polist (see  Hadley,  Railway  Transportatio^n ; 
Foxwell,  "Des  Monopoles,"  ^cfwe  d'l^conomie 
Politique,  1889).  Again  competition  involves 
much  waste  of  effort  in  advertising  and  search 
for  employment ; — much  waste  of  capital,  as 
when  two  railways  are  made  where  one  would 
be  sufficient.  Again  there  are  many  arrange- 
ments which  it  is  the  interest  of  all  combined 
to  adopt,  but  of  each  acting  in  competition  to 
violate  ;  e.g.  Sunday  rest,  or  early  closing  of 
shops.  Other  disadvantages  are  stated  by 
Professor  Sidgwick  with  special  reference  to 
governmental  regulation  {Political  Eco7iomy, 
bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.) 

The  case  for  interference  is  prima  fade 
stronger  with  respect  to  foreign  trade  ;  where 
the  object  of  government  is  not  the  interest  of 
all  parties  concerned,  but  only  of  their  own 
country.  List  maintains  that  the  freedom  of 
trade  advocated  by  Adam  Smith  is  best  for  the 
world  as  a  whole ;  but  that  for  particular 
countries  it  is  better  to  develop  their  own  manu- 
factures by  protection  {Das  nationale  System 
der  Polit.  OeJcon.) 

So  far,  on  the  supposition  that  all  parties  are 
intelligent  enough  to  know  their  own  interest, 
and  free  to  make  their  own  terms.  The  case 
for  interference  is  stronger  where  those  condi- 
tions are  wanting.  The  plea  of  ignorance  is 
urged  ' '  in  those  special  cases  where  it  is  impos- 
sible, or  at  least  difficult,  for  the  buyer  of 
goods  to  verify  their  character  for  himself" 
(Jevons,  op.  cit.  ;  Say,  Cours,  4"ie  Partie,  ch.  x.) 
Want  of  freedom  is  more  difficult  to  define 
scientifically.  Absolutely  free  competition  no- 
where exists  (above  (1,  b)).  Suppose  as  much 
mobility  of  labour  to  exist  as  in  the  case  of  Irish 
cottier-tenants  before  1881,  or  the  "sweated" 
workers  in  East  London  ;  if  the  terms  estab- 
lished by  the  play  of  supply  and  demand  are 
not  favourable  to  those  classes,  shall  we  say  that 
they  are  not  free,  or  only  not  fortunate  ? 

The  general  presumption  in  favour  of  compe- 
tition may  be  outweighed  in  particular  cases  by 
the  disadvantages  which  have  been  noticed. 
The  balance  of  contemporary  opinion  seema 
inclining  to  the  position  thus  indicated  by 
Professor  Sidgwick.      "It  does  not  appear  tc 


380 


COMPLEMENTARY  GOODS— COMPULSORY  PILOTAGE 


me  that  the  answer  ...  in  concrete  cases  can 
reasonably  be  decided  by  any  broad  general 
formula  ;  but  rather  that  every  case  must  be 
dealt  with  on  its  own  merits,  after  carefully 
weighing  the  advantages  and  drawbacks  of 
intervention.  The  expediency  of  such  interfer- 
ence in  any  particular  case  can  only  be  decided 
by  the  light  of  experience  after  a  careful  balance 
of  conflicting  considerations." 

[The  authorities  on  this  subject  are  innumerable. 
Prof.  Marshall's  Principles  of  Economics  may  be 
specially  mentionad  as  showing  (1)  how  deeply 
ingrained  in  our  nature  is  the  principle  of  com- 
petition, which  makes  itself  felt  even  in  institutions 
which  seem  to  be  only  regulated  by  custom  (2)  how 
far  from  ideally  perfect  is  the  sys^Qmoi  laissez-faire, 
since  it  is  theoretically  possible  that  governmental 
interposition  should  effect  an  increase  of  wealtli 
(bk.  V.  Doctrine  of  Maximum  Satisfaction). — The 
views  of  the  older  authorities  are  considered,  and 
some  new  lights  are  imparted  in  Prof.  Marshall's 
Address  On  smiu  aspects  of  Competition  to  section 
P  of  the  British  Association,  1890.]  P.  T.  E. 

COMPLEMENTARY  GOODS.  This  ex- 
pression is  used  by  the  Austrian  economist 
Menger  {Volkswirthschaft,  1871,  pp.  11,  etc.) 
who  describes  goods  as  of  first,  second,  or  higher 
rank  in  order  of  production.  In  the  production 
of  bread,  for  example,  the  bread  itself  would  be 
of  the  first  rank,  flour,  salt,  yeast,  the  services 
of  a  baker  and  his  bakery,  etc.,  would  be  goods 
of  the  second  rank  ;  grain,  mill,  and  miller's 
work  would  be  goods  of  the  third  rank,  and  so 
on.  In  such  cases  the  separate  goods  of  each 
remoter  rank  must  be  combined,  if  they  are  to 
produce  the  goods  of  the  rank  nearer  the  actual 
consumption  ;  they  are  complementary  parts  of 
a  total.  This  conception  becomes  of  special 
interest  when  the  value  of  the  complementary 
goods  is  considered  for  each  separately ;  and 
this  question  has  been  carefully  treated  by 
Wieser  {der  Natilrliche  Werth,  1889,  p.  101, 
etc.)  and  Bohm-Bawerk  {Positive  Theorie  des 
Kapitales,  1889,  p.  179,  etc.,  English  transla- 
tion (1891),  pp.  165,  etc.)  The  discussion  in 
J.  S.  Mill  {Political  Economy,  iii.  xvi.)  of  some 
peculiar  cases  of  value  (joint  cost  of  production) 
followed  up  by  Jevons  {Political  Economy,  3d 
ed.  p.  197)  is  in  many  ways  closely  analogous. 
(See  also  Quart.  Journal,  of  Economics,  April 
1889,  p.  338.)     (See  Consumees'  Goods.) 

J.  B. 

COMPOSITION.     See  Bankruptcy. 

COMPOUND  INTEREST.  Interest  that 
arises  from  adding  to  the  principal  the  interest 
as  it  becomes  due  and  then  considering  the  sum 
that  accrues  at  the  end  of  each  stated  time  as  a 
new  principal.  For  short  periods  of  time  the 
compound  interest  of  any  sum  differs  but  little 
from  its  simple  interest,  but  if  compound  in- 
terest is  allowed  to  accumulate  for  a  number  of 
years,  the  increase  is  very  great.  Any  sum  placed 
out  at  5  per  cent  compound  interest  will  double 
itself  in  14;^  years.     Hence  at  5  per  cent  com- 


pound interest  £1  would  in  14|-  years  amount 
to  £2  ;  in  28|  years  to  £4  ;  and  in  213|  years  to 
£32,768.  At  simple  interest  the  £1  in  213| 
years  would  increase  to  £11  :  13  :  9  only. 

J.  E.  c.  M. 

COMPROMISE  (Scots  law).  An  actual  ad- 
justment of  disputed  claims  by  mutual  con- 
cession. A.  D. 

COMPTES,  Chambre  des.  In  the  reign  of 
Philip  IV.,  the  Cour  du  Roy,  the  chief  organ 
of  the  central  administration  in  mediaeval 
France  was  subdivided  into  three  bodies,  for 
the  separate  functions  of  administration,  justice, 
and  finance.  These  bodies  were  the  conseil  du 
roy,  corresponding  to  the  concilium  ordi- 
TMrivmi  in  England  ;  the  parlement  de  Paris, 
corresponding  to  our  courts  of  king's  bench 
and  common  pleas ;  and  the  chamhre  des 
comptes,  corresponding  to  our  Exchequer.  The 
chamhre  des  comptes  originally  followed  the 
king,  but  was  fixed  at  Paris  by  an  edict  of 
1319.  Its  chief  functions  were  to  audit  the 
accounts  of  the  local  haillis  and  seneschaux,  to 
receive  payments  from  the  royal  domain  and 
direct  taxes,  and  to  decide  judicial  questions 
arising  from  these  payments.  Originally  it 
had  some  voice  in  settling  the  amount  and 
incidence  o:f  taxation,  but  its  administrative 
functions  were  gradually  curtailed  by  the 
growing  omnipotence  of  the  controller-general 
and  the  royal  councU.  In  the  14  th  century 
the  chamhre  des  comptes  was  a  more  important 
body  than  the  parliament  of  Paris,  and  in 
1339,  when  Philip  VI.  went  to  Flanders,  he 
left  the  chief  authority  in  its  hands.  But  by 
the  18  th  century  it  had  sunk  into  comparative 
insignificance,  and  is  rarely  heard  of.  The 
audit  of  accounts,  which  remained  its  chief 
function,  had  become  a  mere  formality,  and 
was  often  fifty  years  behindhand.  But  it  must 
stiU  have  possessed  some  means  of  enriching 
its  members,  for  its  seats  sold  for  a  higher 
price  than  those  in  the  other  cours  souveraimes. 
The  office  of  conseiller  in  the  chamhre  des 
comptes  was  sold  under  Louis  XV.  for  150,000 
livres  ;  whereas  the  highest  price  in  this  century 
for  a  seat  in  the  parliament  was  60,000  livres, 
and  in  the  cour  des  aides  45,000.  The  chamhre 
des  comptes  was  suppressed  by  a  law  of  7  th 
September  1790,  at  which  time  it  contained 
289  officers. 

[Gasquet,  Precis  des  Institutions  Politiqu^s  et 
Sociales  de  VAncienne  France,  Paris,  1885  ; 
Cheruel,  Dictionnaire  Historique  des  Institutions 
de  la  France,  Paris,  1884.]  R.  l. 

COMPULSORY  PILOTAGE.  By  the  Mer- 
chant Shipping  Act  of  1854  (17  &  18  Vict, 
c.  104),  the  master  of  a  vessel,  when  entering  oi 
leaving  certain  harbours  and  districts,  such  as 
t'he  ports  of  London,  of  Liverpool,  and  of  Kings- 
ton-upon-Hull,  the  Trinity  House  outport  dis- 
tricts, or  the  Tyne  or  Falmouth  district,  is  re- 
quired to  take  on  board  a  qualified  pilot,  and 


COMPULSORY  PREFERENCE— COMTE 


381 


to  hand  over  to  him  the  navigation  of  the 
vessel.  So  long  as  the  master  and  crew 
obey  the  orders  of  such  pilot,  the  owners  are 
not  liable  for  any  damage  occasioned  by  the 
fault  or  incapacity  of  the  pilot.  Compulsory 
pilotage  is  based  on  the  principle  that  the  state 
is  justified  in  interfering  to  protect  ships  and 
their  cargoes  from  injury  by  other  vessels  owing 
to  an  inadequate  knowledge  of  the  dangers  of 
navigation  in  specified  ports  and  harbours  and 
districts.  The  object  aimed  at  is  not  so  much 
to  secure  the  safety  of  the  vessel  that  is  com- 
pelled to  take  the  pilot  on  board  as  to  prevent 
such  vessel  from  damaging  other  vessels.  The 
risk  of  collision  is  reduced  and  property  at  sea 
is  rendered  more  secure. 

[Maude  and  Pollock's  Merchant  Shi2)ping,  Lon- 
don, 1886.]  J.  E.  c.  M. 

COMPULSORY  PREFERENCE  or  ''Pre- 
ferential Payments."  In  the  distribution  of  the 
property  of  a  bankrupt  and  of  the  assets  of  a 
company  being  wound  up  the  following  debts 
are  to  be  paid  before  all  others,  except  funeral 
and  testamentary  expenses,  viz.  one  year's 
rates  and  taxes  ;  four  months'  salaries  of  clerks 
up  to  £50,  and  two  months'  wages  of  labourers 
or  workmen  up  to  £25.  These  debts  rank 
equally  between  themselves  (51  &  52  Vict. 
c.  62 ;  52  &  53  Vict.  c.  60).  J.  e.  c.  m. 

COMPULSORY  TAKING  OF  LAND.  The 
right  of  the  state  to  take  land  for  public  pur- 
poses, subject  to  the  obligation  of  making  com- 
pensation, has  been  recognised  by  all  modern 
legal  systems.  This  right,  which  is  sometimes 
called  doviinium  eminens  or  eminent  domain, 
may  be  exercised  by  the  state  itself  or  by 
individuals  acting  under  the  authority  of  the 
state.  The  object  for  which  land  may  be  taken 
compulsorily  is  stated  to  be  "  public  utility. " 
Government  would  be  impossible  if  the  state 
had  not  power  to  take  land  for  the  buildings 
and  fortifications  necessary  to  its  existence, 
whilst  the  production  of  wealth  would  be  greatly 
retarded  if  land  was  not  obtainable  for  the 
construction  of  works  of  transportation  and 
communication.  Public  utility  is  apparent  in 
such  cases.  There  is,  however,  great  difficulty 
in  defining  "public  utility,"  as  it  must  vary 
in  different  countries  owing  to  variations  in 
material  surroundings.  Randolph  suggests  (Law 
Quarterly  Review,  vol.  iii.  p.  320)  that  under- 
takings should  only  be  held  to  be  of  a  public 
nature  where  they  are  such  as  the  state  itself 
or  its  subordinate  political  corporations  might 
properly  engage  in,  and  he  condemns  the  acts 
passed  in  the  New  England  states  to  authorise 
the  taking  of  land  for  the  erection  and  mainten- 
ance of  water  power.  In  the  United  States  a 
corporation  taking  land  compulsorily  ipso  facto 
becomes  liable  to  make  compensation,  since  the 
written  constitution  recognises  the  right  to 
compensation  ;  in  other  countries  provision  for 
compensation  is  made  by  statute.     Tlie  Code 


Napoleon  by  art  545  declares,  "that  no  one  is 
obliged  to  transfer  his  property  unless  it  be  for 
the  public  utility  and  in  consideration  of  a  just 
and  previous  indemnity."  In  the  colonies,  e.g. 
in  New  South  Wales,  provision  has  been  made 
for  resuming  land  for  certain  specified  public 
purposes,  and  the  land  grants  usually  contain  a 
clause  relating  to  resumption.  But  in  England, 
though  the  Lands  Clauses  Consolidation  Acts 
provide  machinery  for  determining  the  amount 
of  compensation  to  be  paid  where  land  is  taken, 
no  general  law  has  ever  been  passed  to  define 
when  land  may  be  taken.  Eacli  taking  of  land 
must  be  authorised  by  special  act  of  parliament. 
The  Crofters  Act,  however,  gives  under  certain 
conditions  power  to  the  crofter  commissioners 
to  enlarge  crofter  holdings. 

English  statutes  on  the  compulsory  taking  of 
land  fall  into  three  classes:  (1)  Where  compul- 
sory powers  have  been  conferred  on  public  bodies 
for  specified  purposes,  subject  to  a  scheme  being 
approved  by  a  government  department  and  to 
confirmation  by  statute.  The  Artisan  Dwellings 
Acts,  1868-1882;  33  &  34  Vict.  c.  75  (school 
sites) ;  44  &  45  Vict.  c.  20  (post-office  sites) ;  and 
various  statutes  relating  to  improvements  in  Lon- 
don came  under  tliis  class.  (2)  Where  the  statute 
gives  a  particular  corporation,  such  as  a  railway 
company,  power  to  talve  land.  (3)  The  Crofters 
Act  1886,  enabling  a  coniinission  to  enlarge 
crofters'  holdings,  Small  Holdings  Act,  1907. 

[Principles  of  the  Lata  of  Compensation,  C.  A. 
Cripps,  London,  1884. — Law  of  Compensation, 
by  Lloyd,  London,  1882.]  J.  e.  c.  m. 

COMTE,  AuGUSTE,  the  founder  o{  Positivisme, 
was  born  at  Montpellier  1798,  and  died  at  Paris, 
1857.  After  studying  hard,  especially  mathe- 
matics, he  was  received,  the  fom-th  on  the  list, 
at  the  Ecole  Polytechnique.  Insubordination 
led  to  his  expulsion  from  the  school,  and  he 
found  himself  without  position  or  means.  After 
some  fruitless  efforts  he  attached  himself,  1818, 
to  Saint-Simon,  whose  secretary  he  became, 
succeeding  in  this  office  to  the  historian 
Augustin  Thierry  ;  but,  in  1824,  in  connection 
with  the  bringing  out  of  the  CaMchisme  des 
industriels,  in  which  the  Syst^nu  de  politique 
positive,  due  entirely  to  the  pen  of  Comte, 
appeared,  thwe  arose  a  disagreement  between 
the  master  and  the  scholar,  and  Comte  could 
no  longer  content  himself  with  the  position  of 
disciple  ;  he  desired  to  be  master  in  his  turn. 
The  idiosyncrasies  of  these  two  personalities, 
to  neither  of  which  energy  can  be  denied,  were 
certain,  sooner  or  later,  to  lead  to  a  separation. 
Comte  married  soon  after,  but  overwork  and  the 
burden  of  worries  which  his  disposition  magnified 
to  a  remarkable  degree,  brought  on  a  serious 
derangement  of  the  brain.  This  attack  was 
successfully  overcome  by  care  and  nursing,  but 
it  would  perhaps  be  rash  to  affirm  that  the  cure 
was  complete. 

On  his  return  to  ordinary  life,  after  a  treatment 
for  this  serious  malady  which  lasted  nine  months, 


382 


COMTE 


A.  Comte  found  himseli  afresh  in  face  of  the 
most  pressing  monetary  difficulties.  However, 
he  obtained  in  time  the  position  of  assistant  to 
one  of  the  professors  at  the  ^cole  Polytechnique, 
and  the  post  of  examiner  to  the  same  school. 
He  joined  to  this  a  place  as  usher  in  a  private 
institution,  and,  thanks  to  the  moderation  of 
his  requirements,  was  able  to  employ  himself 
quietly  with  his  favourite  occupations.  It  was 
at  this  date  that  he  composed  the  great  work 
we  shall  speak  of  later  on,  and  which,  as  we 
shall  proceed  to  shew,  deals  rather  with  philo- 
sophy than  with  economics. 

With  a  little  prudence  and  care  he  would 
have  been  able,  in  this  manner,  to  continue 
the  labours  which  he  had  most  at  heart. 
Unfortunately,  a  professorship  of  algebraical 
analysis  which  he  sought  for  was  given  to 
Sturm.  He  made  an  enemy  of  Arago,  who 
had  been  the  cause  of  this  appointment.  His 
temper  set  the  backs  of  the  whole  council  of  the 
school  up  against  him,  and  he  was  removed 
from  his  post  of  examiner,  and  in  consequence 
from  that  of  assistant  lecturer.  It  should  be 
stated  that  he  had  fulfilled  both  these  duties  in 
the  most  complete  and  conscientious  manner, 
besides  having,  from  1830  to  1848,  given  to 
the  Association  Polytechnique  gratuitously,  and 
without  a  single  omission,  a  course  of  lectures 
on  astronomy. 

Deprived  of  his  regular  resources,  separated 
by  mutual  consent  from  his  wife,  he  had  to  de- 
pend for  the  means  of  existence  on  the  purses 
of  his  friends  and  disciples.  It  is  to  be  re- 
gretted that  he,  we  may  almost  say,  demanded 
this  help,  with  some  persistence  and  even  with 
hauteur.  He  held  that  he  had  a  right  to  these 
subsidies  in  retiu-n  for  the  services  which,  as 
a  philosopher,  he  rendered  to  civilisation. — It 
was  a  debt  the  repayment  of  which  he  claimed 
rather  than  assistance  which  he  solicited  (see 
his  Lettres  a  J.  S.  Mill). 

His  great  work,  on  which  he  had  laboured 
for  twenty  years,  his  Cours  de  Philosophie  Posi- 
tive (6  vols,  in  8vo)  appeared  1839-42. 

The  fundamental  idea  to  which  Comte  has 
given  the  name  of  positivism  is,  that  **  we  know 
nothing  but  phenomena,  and  that  the  knowledge 
we  have  of  these  is  relative  and  not  absolute. 
We  know  neither  the  essence  nor  the  real  mode 
by  which  any  fact  is  produced  ;  we  only  know 
the  relations  of  the  succession  or  the  similarity  of 
facts  one  to  another.  These  relations  are  con- 
stant, that  is  to  say,  always  the  same  under  the 
same  circumstances.  The  constant  resemblances 
which  bind  phenomena  together,  and  the  con- 
stant successions  which  unite  them  under  the 
titles  of  antecedents  and  consequences,  are  what 
are  termed  their  laws.  The  laws  of  phenomena 
are  all  that  we  can  know  of  them.  Their  essen- 
tial natures  and  their  causes  are  unknown  to  us, 
and  remain  impenetrable." 

He   supported   this   doctrine   by   a   historic 


theory  which  he  called  the  Three  Stages  {Thiorie 
des  trois  4tats) — the  theological  stage,  including 
fetichism,  polytheism,  and  monotheism  ;  the 
metaphysical  stage ;  finally,  the  positive  or 
scientific  stage.  It  will  be  seen  that  in  all  this 
we  are  rather  at  a  distance  from  the  domain  of 
economics.  Hence  we  must  pause  here  in  our 
exposition  of  the  doctrines  of  Auguste  Comte, 
contenting  ourselves  with  reminding  our  readers 
that,  after  1845,  his  mind  underwent  a  trans- 
formation at  which  many  of  his  disciples  were 
justly  astonished,  and  in  which  the  majority 
of  them  declined  to  follow  him.  He,  who 
previously  had  refused  adherence  to  any  form 
of  worship,  instituted  one  of  which  he  made 
himself  the  high  priest,  and  which,  in  its  philo- 
sophy, borrows  from  pantheism,  if  not  from 
fetichism.  In  his  eyes,  to  quote  o'nly  one  ex- 
ample, it  is  due  "  to  pay  honour  to  the  planets, 
especially  to  the  sun  and  moon. "  He  rearranged, 
rather  let  us  say  he  reconstructed,  his  Syst^me  de 
politique  positive,  adding,  as  a  sub -title,  ou 
Traiti  de  Sociologie  in^titVAint  la  Peligion  de 
V Humanity  (1851  in  8vo),  he  then  composed  a 
Catdchisme  Positiviste,  and  finally  a  Calendrier 
Positiviste,  in  which  he  instituted  saints  and  sub- 
saints,  supplementary  ones,  selected  from  all 
countries  ajid  from  aU  periods  of  time.  He  even 
went  further  than  this  ;  he  established  sacra- 
ments, and  under  his  title  of  pontifex  proceeded 
to  administer  them — the  last  wanderings  of  a 
mind  elevated  in  some  respects,  but  ill-balanced 
and  driven  out  of  its  right  course  by  many  freaks 
of  temperament,  particularly  by  pride.  Apart 
from  his  theosophy  A.  Comte  has  had  and  still 
has  many  distinguished  disciples  in  France  and 
abroad.  He  may  be  said  even  to  have  founded 
a  school.  We  may  quote  among  his  disciples 
who  are  dead  Littre,  John  Stuart  Mill,  and 
Grote  the  historian.  a.  c.  f. 

COMTE,  Aug.,  and  English  Political 
Economy.  Comte's  importance  for  the  history 
of  English  political  economy  is  due  first,  and 
chiefly,  to  his  influence  on  John  Stuart  Mill. 
About  1830  Mill,  dissatisfied  with  the  views  of 
his  father  and  Bentham,  was  reading  eagerly 
the  tracts  of  the  St.  Simonians,  including,  at 
that  time,  one  by  Comte,  which  promulgated 
the  law  of  the  three  stages  of  the  evolution  of 
science.  In  1839,  when  Mill  was  planning  his 
Logic,  he  took  up  the  study  of  the  Philosophie 
Positive.  The  conception  of  the  inverse  deduc- 
tive method,  described  afterwards  in  the  Logic 
as  the  proper  method  of  historical  and  statistical 
inquiries  (bk.  vi.  ch.  ix.,  x.),  was  (he  teUs  us, 
Autoh.,  210)  derived  wholly  from  Comte.  The 
two  men  corresponded  with  each  other  on 
cordial  terms  (1841-46),  though  they  never 
met.  This  correspondence,  so  far  as  published 
(Lettres  d' Auguste  Comte  d  John  Stuart  Mill, 
Paris  1877),  shows  that  Mill  had  substan- 
tially accepted  the  law  of  the  three  stages, 
and  had  been  strongly  impressed  with  Comte's 


COMTE 


383 


idea  of  a  master-science  of  sociology,  dealing 
both  with  the  present  order,  or  statics,  of 
society  and  with  its  evolution,  or  dynamics. 
The  idea  was  not  new.  It  may  be  traced  to 
Aristotle,  and  among  economists  Comte  allowed 
that  Adam  Smith  possessed  it,  while  J.  B.  Say 
had  discussed  it  with  Comte  himself  {Lcttres, 
p.  255).  But  Comte's  exposition  of  it  was 
original  and  striking.  He  gave  Mill  also  a 
wider  conception  of  what  was  meant  by  the 
general  interests  of  humanity,  embracing  'past, 
present,  and  future  human  beings  as  members 
of  one  body  (Aug.  Comte  and  Positivism,  1865, 
p.  135).  Comte,  too,  first  drew  Mill's  attention 
to  the  importance  of  the  working  classes  as  an 
element  in  all  social  movements  ;  Comte  had 
thought  at  one  time  of  writing  a  special  book 
on  industrial  life.  He  brought  Mill  to  admit 
that  in  the  universal  consensus  or  solidarity  of 
the  phenomena  of  society  no  parts  could  be 
called  independent  of  the  others,  and  that  the 
way  to  study  the  whole  body  of  them  was  not 
(as  Mill  had  said  in  1830  in  Unsettled  Ques- 
tions, publ.  1844,  e.g.  p.  146)  Bentham's  a 
priori  method  of  deduction  from  known  prin- 
ciples, but  Comte's  own  method  of  first  gener- 
alising from  history  and  then  verifying  by 
deduction  from  known  principles.  We  must 
learn  to  "  predict  the  past "  before  we  can  know 
the  present.  The  **  limited  and  temporary  value 
of  the  old  political  economy"  {Autoh.,  p.  166) 
Mill  learned  not  from  Comte  but  from  the  St. 
Simonians.  Comte  soon  found  Mill  was  going 
on  a  way  of  his  own,  and  had  no  intention  of 
making  his  projected  book  on  political  econ- 
omy a  mere  stalking  horse  for  positivism 
{Lettres,  p.  254).  Mill  still  upheld  the  need 
of  studying  political  economy  by  the  a  priori, 
as  distinguished  from  the  inverse  deductive 
method,  though  he  thought  himself  bound  to 
show  the  modifications  of  a  priori  results  in 
actual  societies.  Political  economy  must,  pro- 
visionally, be  a  separate  study.  In  the  details 
of  MiU's  Principles  of  Political  Economy  (publ. 
1848)  Comte's  influence  is  therefore  not  marked, 
though  it  was  working,  with  other  causes,  to 
change  Mill's  views  on  the  possibilities  of  human 
nature  and  the  final  constitution  of  society. 
After  their  correspondence.  Mill  recoiled  from 
the  object  of  his  first  attraction,  though,  for 
the  sake  of  the  public,  he  refrained  from  open 
criticism  {Aug.  Comte  and  Pos.,  p.  3).  He 
found  in  Comte  too  little  heed  for  individuality 
and  liberty.  He  agreed  with  Comte  in  ap- 
preciating the  proletariat,  deploring  the  exist- 
ence of  an  idle  class,  and  of  labourers  degraded  by 
minute  division  of  labour  ;  he  admired  his  idea 
that  possessors  of  wealth  should  regard  them- 
selves as  public  functionaries.  But  he  refused 
to  place  the  supreme  government  in  the  hands 
of  the  wealthiest  capitalists,  or  to  trust  to  the 
moral  influence  of  a  body  of  philosopher  priests, 
for  the  securing  of  a  fair  and  generous  distribu- 


tion of  wealth.  Though  he  regarded  distribu- 
tion as  being,  unlike  production,  under  no 
"necessities  of  nature"  {Autoh.,  p.  247)  but 
under  laws  of  arbitrary  human  institution  only, 
Mill  sought  for  progress  by  associations  and  by 
democratic  government  and  legislation  as  well 
as  by  moral  and  intellectual  improvement  among 
people  and  rulers.  Comte's  social  statics  seem 
to  Mill  his  weakest  point.  On  the  position  of 
women,  for  example,  the  two  authors  are  irre- 
concilable. Finally,  Comte  was  nothing  if 
not  systematic  ;  Mill  was  essentially  eclectic. 
Otherwise  the  influence  of  Comte  might  have 
had  the  same  effect  on  him  as  on  Harriet 
Martineau,  who  abandoned  all  distinctly  econ- 
omical work  when  she  gave  up  the  particular 
economic  doctrines  she  had  herself  helped  to 
popularize. 

If  in  England  the  application  of  the  "his- 
torical method  "  to  economics  was  (as  is  some- 
times said)  suggested  by  Comte  rather  than 
by  English  or  by  German  writers,  it  was  not, 
at  least,  through  Mill's  precept  or  Mill's  ex- 
ample. Cliffe  Leslie's  indebtedness  to  Comte  is 
not  clearly  acknowledged  by  the  former  [Essays, 
1879,  pp.  241,  411).  Sir  Henry  Maine  and 
Professor  Thorold  Rogers  seem  free  of  all  debt 
to  him.  The  controversy  between  Cairnes  and 
Mr.  Frederick  Harrison  on  "Comte  and  Politi- 
cal Economy  "  (see  Fortnightly  Review,  May  and 
July  1870,  Cairnes,  Essays  in  Political  Economy, 
etc.),  served  to  make  the  issue  clearer :  Can 
there  be  a  political  economy  as  a  study  distinct 
from  general  sociology  ?  But  it  was  after 
Prof.  J.  K.  Ingram's  address  to  the  British 
Association  (in  1878),  which  put  the  Comtian 
criticisms  in  a  broadly  intelligible  form,  that 
the  historical  economists  obtained  recognition  in 
this  country  as  a  distinct  school.  Prof.  Ingi-am 
has  since  followed  up  the  attack  by  a  History 
of  Political  Economy  (1888).  Hitherto,  both 
in  this  country  and  in  America,  the  tendency  of 
this  movement  has  rather  been  to  attract  the 
attention  of  historians  to  the  importance  of  the 
economic  element  in  history,  than  to  draw 
away  any  considerable  number  of  economists 
from  the  study  of  economic  theory  (see  His- 
torical Method  ;  Positivism,  etc.)     j.  b. 

COMTE,  Chakles,  born  at  Sainte  Eminie 
(Lozere),  1782,  died  at  Paris,  1837.  His  father, 
a  warm  partizan  of  the  Revolution,  gave  Comte 
a  rigid  training  which  influenced  him  all  his 
life.  To  this  may  be  ascribed  his  vote  in  1804 
against  the  establishment  of  the  empire,  and 
the  vote  was  nominative  and  signed  with  his 
name.  Comte  had  to  pay  the  penalty  of  his 
courage.  As  a  consequence  he  devoted  himself 
to  the  study  of  law,  and  founded,  June  1814,  a 
periodical  Le  Censeur  (7  vols,  in  8vo).  Charles 
Dunoyer  joined  him  in  this.  The  two  edited 
this  organ,  established  in  support  of  law  and 
liberty,  and  hence  as  hostile  to  the  legitimist 
reaction  as  to  the  pretended  liberal  empire,     h 


384 


COMTE— CONCILIATION 


pamphlet  on  the  subject  of  the  day,  energetic- 
ally written  and  frankly  brisk  in  style,  De 
Vimpossibilit6  d'6tahlir  une  monarchic  constitu- 
Hormelle  sous  un  chef  militaire  et  particulUre- 
ment  sous  NapoUon,  brought  on  them  a  prosecu- 
tion which  did  great  honour  to  their  spirit. 
The  terreur  blanche  obliged  them,  towawis  the 
end  of  the  year  1815,  to  suspend  their  journal, 
which  they  did  not  resume  till  1817,  under  the 
title  of  Le  Censeur  Europ4en  (12  vols,  in  8vo), 
with  the  motto  Paix  et  libcrU.  In  the  interval 
(1815-17)  Comte,  probably  incited  by  Dunoyer, 
took  up  the  study  of  political  economy,  associ- 
ating himself  in  this  with  J.  B.  Say,  whose 
son-in-law  he  shortly  became.  Notwithstanding 
private  and  public  persecution  and  prosecution, 
the  Censeur  Europ6en  was  able  to  hold  on  its 
existence  to  the  date  of  the  assassination  of  the 
Due  de  Berry  (13th  February  1820).  This  sad 
event  rendered  the  maintenance  of  the  contest 
impossible,  and  the  editors  were  compelled,  in 
face  of  a  sentence  which  condemned  them  to 
imprisonment  and  a  heavy  fine,  to  abandon  their 
straightforward  and  courageous  publication. 

Comte  preferred  exile  to  prison.  He  went 
first  to  Geneva  and  then  to  Lausanne,  where 
he  was  appointed  professor  in  natural  law  {la 
morale).  The  Sainte- Alliance  was  alarmed  at 
this  series  of  lectures  given  by  so  able  a  professor, 
and  demanded  his  expulsion.  The  Canton  de 
Vaud  desired  to  resist,  but  Comte,  in  order  to 
avoid  bringing  anxiety,  perhaps  even  worse,  on 
the  territory  which  had  befriended  him,  retreated 
to  England  while  waiting  the  reversal  of  his 
sentence.  He  was,  however,  unable  to  defend 
his  case,  as  the  government  refused  to  allow  the 
registration  of  his  notice  of  appeal.  He  then 
pursued  his  economic  studies,  and  published. 
May  1826,  his  Traiti  de  legislation  or  exposition 
of  the  general  laws  by  following  which  states 
prosper,  perish,  or  remain  stationary  (4  vols,  in 
Svo),  a  work  as  much  economic  as  judicial  in 
tone,  but  which  approaches  in  character  closer 
to  the  Esprit  des  Lois  than  to  a  treatise  on 
political  economy.  The  author  shows  himself 
throughout  a  worthy  disciple  of  the  master 
whose  daughter  he  had  married.  We  may  add 
that  the  Acaddmie  Fran^aise,  in  1828  (under 
the  Restauration)  awarded  Comte  the  grand  prix 
Monty  on  as  the  author  of  the  work  of  the  greatest 
service  to  morals. 

Less  even  than  Dunoyer  did  he  know  how  to 
lend  himself  to  half  measures,  to  accept  compro- 
mises. Thus  in  1830,  being  named  p/oeureur 
du  roi  for  the  tribunal  of  the  Seine,  after  having 
been  elected  Depute  de  la  Sarthe,  Comle  could 
not  remain  long  in  possession  of  this  office,  and 
returned  to  the  labour  of  his  choice — scientific 
study.  The  Acad6mie  des  Sciences  morales  et 
politiques  was  re-established  by  royal  ordinance 
26th  October  1832  ;  he  joined  it  and  became 
himself  the  first  perpetual  secreta  rj-.  In  this 
capacity  he  delivered  the  ^loge  on  Garat,  and 


composed  that  on  Malthus  which  death  hindered 
him  from  reading.  In  1834  he  published  hia 
Traits  de  la  proprUte  (2  vols.  8vo),  a  work^,  this 
time,  exclusively  economic,  and  the  scientific  im- 
portance of  which  is  in  no  way  behind  his  Traiti 
de  Ugislation.  The  following  year  a  second 
edition  of  the  work  last  named  appeared.  Al- 
though Comte  had  experienced  a  disappointment 
in  seeing  Rossi  preferred  to  him  for  the  chair  of 
political  economy  at  the  ColUge  de  France, 
vacant  through  the  death  of  his  father-in-law, 
the  nobleness  of  his  nature  kept  him  from  bear- 
ing any  grudge  against  his  successful  competitor, 
and,  though  he  had  been  ill  for  four  months,  he 
caused  himself  to  be  carried  into  the  Institute 
the  17th  December  1836  to  vote  in  his  favour 
as  a  candidate  for  election  to  the  Academic  des 
Sciences  morales  et  politiques.  Some  months 
after  he  expired.  Mignet,  the  second  perpetual 
secretary  of  that  academy,  read,  30th  May  1846, 
at  a  solemn  meeting  of  that  body,  a  notice  of 
Charles  Comte  in  which  full  justice  was  done 
to  the  lofty  character  of  this  illustrious  thinker. 

A.  G.  f. 

CONCESSION.  A  term  not  used  in  English 
law,  but  the  word,  or  some  similar  word,  is 
used  in  many  foreign  countries  to  denote  the 
permission,  given  by  the  government  to  the 
undertaking  of  certain  works,  or  to  the  forma- 
tion of  certain  societies  or  companies,  in  the 
cases  in  which  such  permission  is  necessary. 
This  term  has  been  current  in  France  especially 
for  the  last  three  centuries  or  so  in  the  sense 
of  a  right  of  property,  privilege,  or  monopoly 
granted  by  government — to  individuals  or  groups 
of  individuals, — in  land,  mines,  public  works, 
performance  of  stage-plays,  and  generally  speak- 
ing in  anything  that  can  be  monopolised.  At 
present  it  is  used  most  often  of  mines,  as 
in  the  case  of  the  ruby  mines  of  Upper  Bur- 
mah ;  tramways  passim ;  railways,  as  in  France, 
where  the  "concession"  is  terminable,  and 
rights  revert  to  the  state  ;  trading  privileges 
including  especially  exemption  from  duties,  as 
in  the  Russian  "concession"  to  the  Anglo- 
Siberian  Company  ;  and  banks,  as  in  the  case 
of  the  Imperial  Bank  of  Persia.  "Concess- 
ions "  of  the  nature  of  patents  or  monopolies 
have  been  recently  (1889-90)  granted  by  the 
Boer  government  in  the  Transvaal  so  lavishly 
and  at  such  inadequate  fees  as  to  cause  great 
public  discontent ;  they  include  cordage,  paper, 
paints,  ropes,  furniture,  matches,  electric 
lighting,  and  jam.  The  expediency  of  raising 
revenue  in  such  a  way  will  be  discussed  under 
Monopolies  ;  Patent.  j.  b. 

CONCILIATION,  Boards  of.  These  boards 
are  established  in  difierent  industries  with 
the  object  of  preventing  and  adjusting  in- 
dustrial disputes  between  employers  and  em- 
ployed. They  consist  of  representatives  of 
masters  and  of  men  engaged  in  the  industries, 
with    which  they   are    concerned,    who    meet 


CONCOURSE— CONDITIONING 


385 


together  to  endeavour  to  settle  by  discussion 
and  mutual  agreement  any  disputes  which  may 
arise.  A  typical  illustration  of  their  constitu- 
tion and  working  may  be  found  in  the  board 
established  in  1869  in  the  manufactured  iron 
trade  of  the  north  of  England.  Here  the  men 
belonging  to  the  different  works  select  in  each 
case  by  ballot  a  delegate,  and  the  employers 
belonging  to  a  single  firm  are  similarly  repre- 
sented by  a  single  delegate.  The  members  of 
the  board  thus  constituted  elect  a  president, 
together  Avith  one  secretary,  from  among  the 
delegates  of  the  masters,  and  a  vice-president, 
together  with  a  second  secretary,  from  among 
the  delegates  of  the  men.  They  also  elect  a 
standing  committee,  as  it  is  called,  consisting 
of  five  representatives  of  the  men,  and  ten  repre- 
sentatives of  the  masters  (five  of  whom  alone  are 
able  to  discuss  or  vote  on  any  question)  ;  and  of 
this  committee  the  president  and  vice-president 
are  ex  officio  members,  without  enjoying  any 
power  of  voting.  The  standing  committee 
meets  every  month  or,  if  occasion  demands, 
more  frequently,  and  the  board  itself  meets 
twice  a  year  and  at  other  times  when  sum- 
moned by  the  committee.  In  the  first  iiistance 
all  questions  are  laid  before  the  committee. 
They  are  submitted  in  writing  to  the  secretaries 
seven  days  before  the  meeting ;  the  written 
reply  of  the  other  side  is  usually  placed  before 
the  same  meeting,  and  an  agreement  of  sub- 
mission signed  by  the  parties  concerned.  If 
the  standing  committee  cannot  arrive  at  an 
agreement,  the  referee,  who  is  a  permanent 
official,  is  called  in  and  can  take  evidence  ;  and 
in  this  way  all  questions  may  be  settled,  except 
a  general  advance  or  reduction  in  wages,  or  the 
appointment  of  an  arbitrator  (see  Arbitration 
BETWEEN  Employers  and  Employed).  These 
questions  the  board  alone  can  decide,  and  it 
also  determines  matters  referred  to  it  from  the 
standing  committee,  selecting  an  arbitrator  if  it 
cannot  itself  arrive  at  an  agreement.  The  ne- 
cessary expenses  of  the  board  are  defrayed  by 
the  subtraction  of  a  penny  every  fortnight  from 
the  wages  of  every  workman  earning  upwards 
of  half-a-crown  a  day,  and  by  requiring  each 
firm  to  pay  an  amount  equal  to  that  thus  sub- 
tracted. Similar  boards  have  been  established 
in  the  Nottingham  hosiery  trade,  the  boot  and 
shoe  trade,  etc.  ;  in  the  coal  and  iron  and  steel 
trades  in  connection  with  sliding  scales  (see 
Sliding  Scale).  The  constitution  of  these 
boards  is,  with  some  diff"erences  of  detail,  similar 
to  that  described,  which  is  based  on  the  model 
of  the  French  Conseils  de  Prud'hommes  (q.v.) 
The  cotton-spinning,  engineering,  ship-wrights, 
building  trades,  and  the  railway  companies 
follow  somewhat  different  systems.  The  ad- 
vantage of  this  method  of  adjusting  industrial 
disputes  over  that  of  arbitration  is  chiefly  that 
the  decision  is  attained  by  friendly  and  informal 
•liscussion  and  mutual  concession,  and  there- 
VOL    I. 


fore  is  more  likely  to  be  faithfully  observed, 
and  less  calculated  to  leave  behind  a  feeling  of 
irritation.  L.  L.  p. 

District  boards  have  been  formed  to  deal 
with  disputes  occurring  in  any  trade  in  the 
district  with  which  they  are  connected,  the 
first  having  been  established  in  London  in 
1890.  In  1896  the  Conciliation  Act  was  passed 
giving  power  to  the  Board  of  Trade  to  take  steps 
to  arrange  actual  disputes  or  to  form  concilia- 
tion boards  where  required,  etc.  Many  volun- 
tary boards  appeal  to  the  Board  of  Trade  to 
assist  in  the  settlement  of  dillerences.  There 
has  been  no  legislative  compulsion  connected 
with  conciliation  hitherto  though  there  is  a 
body  of  opinion  in  favour  of  it.  There  are 
about  200  boards  of  conciliation  and  arbitra- 
tion in  the  United  Kingdom  dealing  with  about 
1500  cases  annually.  [See  Ann.  Repts.  of 
Labour  Dept.  of  Bd.  of  Trade  on  Strikes  and 
Lock-Outs  ;  Laboiir  Gazette  (monthly  journal)  ; 
Hept.  on  Rules  of  Voluntary  Conciliation  and 
Arbitration  Boai\ls  ;  Repts.  of  the  Bd.  of  Trade 
on  proceedings  under  the  Conciliation  Act,  1896  ; 
N.  P.  Oilman,  Methods  of  Industrial  Peace 
(1904)  ;  A.  0.  Pigou,  Principles  and  Methods 
of  Industrial  Peace  (1905)  ;  also  Engineering 
Trades  Industrial  Treaty,  App.] 

CONCOURSE  (Scots  law).  Concurrence  or 
consent,  e.g.  concourse  of  the  lord  advocate  to 
criminal  prosecutions  by  private  persons,    A.  d. 

CONCURRENCE  (Scotland).  Backing  a 
warrant  by  a  J.  P.  ^  A.  D. 

CONDILLAC,  Etienne  Bonnot  de  (1714- 
1780),  Abbe  of  Mureaux,  younger  brother  of 
Mably,  born  at  Grenoble,  died  at  Flux  near 
Beaugency.  As  a  philosopher  of  the  school  of  the 
sensationalists,  he  published  much-valued  works 
based  on  that  system.  As  an  economist  he  pub- 
lished, 1776,  Le  Commerce  et  le  Gouvernement 
consid4r6s  relativement  I'un  a  I'autre,  described 
by  Jevons  as  ' '  original  and  profound. "  He  sup- 
ports the  doctrines  of  the  physiocrats,  except  in 
regard  to  industry,  which  he  considers  as  pro- 
ductive. This  work  is  reproduced  in  Mdanges 
d'economie  politique  {Collection  des  principaux 
<:conomistes,  Guillaumin,  1847).  A.  c.  f. 

CONDITIONING.  In  textile  industries, 
mainly  in  the  silk  trade,  "conditioning "  covers 
the  process  of  determining  the  quality,  net 
weight,  and  description  of  raw  material,  or  of 
yarns,  etc.  ;  a  conditioning-house  is  an  establish- 
ment where  at  fixed  charges  such  material  maybe 
prepared  and  arranged,  and  an  official  warranty 
as  to  condition  obtained.  Conditioning-houses 
and  boards  exist  in  most  textile  manufacturing 
districts  on  the  continent.  In  some  places,  such 
as  Lyons,  they  are  public  establishments,  that 
at  Lyons  dating  from  1779  ;  while  in  others 
they  are  houses  provided  by  committees  of  the 
merchants  themselves,  and  their  verdict  as  to 
weight  and  quality  is  accepted  as  conclusive ;  but 
they  are,  as  yet,  scarcely  known  in  the  United 

2  c 


386 


CONDITIONING— CONDORCET 


Kingdom,  and  the  advantages  they  offer  have 
not  "been  properly  recognised.  The  only  con- 
ditioning-house in  London  of  which  there  is 
record — it  is  possibly  the  only  house  of  this 
nature  in  the  United  Kingdom — is  the  Trade 
Silk  Condition  Company,  Limited,  of  Worship 
Street,  E.C.,  which  publishes  a  scale  of  cfiarges 
arranged  under  the  following  heads : — Condi- 
tioning ;  Weighing  ;  Boiling-off  and  Washing  ; 
Assay  of  Size  ;  Assay  of  Spin  and  Throw,  or 
Elasticity  and  Tenacity  ;  directions  being  given 
under  each  head.  This  house  has  been  in 
operation  for  many  years,  and  not  only  fur- 
nishes the  weight  of  the  raw  silk  when  freed 
from  moisture  and  the  numerous  impurities  to 
be  found  in  the  bales,  but  tests  it  in  various 
ways,  and  by  so  doing  places  upon  the  tested 
article  an  unbiassed  official  stamp,  which  inter- 
ested vendors  and  purchasers  themselves  could 
hardly  do.  It  also  carries  its  operations  further, 
as  the  raw  material  is  duly  prepared  for  manu- 
facture. In  the  same  establishment  wool  can 
by  arrangement  be  conditioned.  It  will  be 
gathered  from  this  that  conditioning  partakes 
of  the  nature  of  Sampling  and  Grading,  terms 
employed  in  various  other  trades,  operations 
which  will  be  found  dealt  with  under  those 
heads. 

Some  few  years  ago  a  small  establishment  for 
conditioning  silk  was  started  in  Manchester, 
but  it  has  either  ceased  to  exist  or  to  carry 
on  operations  as  a  separate  undertaking.  The 
Bradford  chamber  of  commerce,  amongst  others, 
has  for  a  considerable  time  past  advocated  the 
establishment  of  a  conditioning- house  in  connec- 
tion with  the  wool  trade  of  that  district,  such 
an  undertaking  to  be  conducted  by  the  corpora- 
tion of  Bradford.  Parliamentary  powers  were 
duly  obtained  some  years  ago,  but  this  condi- 
tioning-house is  not  yet  established,  although 
there  are  some  prospects  of  a  start  being  made 
in  respect  to  it.  Such  an  official  undertaking 
might  well  become  a  decided  success,  and  the 
Bradford  standard  be  recognised  throughout 
the  entire  Yorkshire  woollen  and  worsted  dis- 
tricts. It  is  evident  that  such  establishments 
are  to  the  advantage  of  the  manufacturers  of 
high  quality  goods,  and  enable  them  the  better 
to  draw  the  line  between  genuine  and  counter- 
feit materials.  In  this  way,  French,  Italian, 
and  other  continental  silk  manufacturing  dis- 
tricts have  long  recognised  the  advantages 
afforded,  and  it  remains  to  be  seen  whether, 
if  the  Bradford  corporation  take  the  affair  up 
in  earnest,  the  conditioning-house  will  not  soon 
become  a  recognised  necessity  of  the  textile 
industries  in  this  country. 

[See  for  conditioning  at  Lyons  article  on  "  Con- 
dition "  in  the  Nouveau  Diciionnaire  d'£conomie 
Politique  and  Monographie  de  la  Condition  des 
soies  de  Lyon,  par  Adrien  Perret,  Lyon,  1878.] 

CONDORCET,  Marie  Caritat,  Marquis 
de  (1743-1794),  bom  at  Ribemond  near  Saint 


Quentin,  died  at  Bourg-la-Reine.  He  won  his 
first  laurels  as  a  mathematician,  and  showed 
in  this  study  qualities  which  astonished  the 
most  distinguished  savants  of  his  time.  When 
he  was  twenty  the  Academie  des  Sciences  con- 
sidered an  £ssai  sur  le  Calcul  Integral,  from 
his  pen,  worthy  to  appear  in  the  collection  of 
their  memoirs,  and,  in  1769,  the  same  learned 
body  received  him  into  their  number,  appointing 
him,  in  1773,  their  perpetual  secretary.  He 
soon  won  the  friendship  of  Turgot,  by  whom 
his  attention  was  turned  towards  political 
economy.  Under  the  inspiration  of  Turgot  he 
wrote  various  articles  or  works,  among  others 
Les  Rifiexions  d'un  Ldboureur  de  Picardie  d 
M.  N.  .  .  .  auteur  prohibitif,  d,  Paris,  1775  ; 
and  Les  Reflexions  sur  le  commerce  des  bleds, 
1776,  two  writings  directed  against  M.  Necker, 
that  auteur  prohihitif  who  had  brought  out, 
May  1775,  his  work  Sur  la  legislation  et  le 
commerce  des  grains.  The  Academie  Fran^aise 
admitted  him,  1782,  among  its  members. 
Condorcet's  activity  did  not  slacken  up  to  the 
first  days  of  the  Revolution  ;  in  1781  he  pub- 
lished the  R&fUodons  sur  Vesclavage  des  nkgres 
(there  is  no  need  to  say  that  he  was  an  aboli- 
tionist), then,  in  1785,  his  Essais  sur  Vapplica- 
Hon  de  I'analyse  d  la  probability  des  decisions 
rendues  d  la  plurality  des  voix  (in  8vo)  ;  in  1786, 
La  vie  de  Turgot  (in  8vo)  ;  about  1787,  De 
I'influence  de  la  Revolution  d'Am4rique  sur 
VEurope,  dedicated  to  Lafayette,  which  indi- 
cates the  course  of  events  at  that  time ;  in  1788, 
Essai  sur  la  constitution,  et  les  fonctions  des  as- 
semblies provinciales ;  in  1789,  Banque  Na- 
tionale  (in  4to)  ;  and  in  1790,  La  fixation  de 
Vimpdt  (in.  8vo).  He  did  not  belong  to  the 
Assemblee  constituante  but  was  member  of 
the  Assemblee  legislative  and  of  the  Convention 
which  succeeded  it.  We  shall  not  attempt  to 
sketch  out  his  career,  which  was  frankly  that 
of  a  republican,  but  a  friend  of  law  and  liberty 
during  the  Revolution.  It  may  suffice  to  say 
that  his  pen  was  never  inactive  and  was 
vigorously  supported  by  his  eloquent  words. 
Proscribed  as  a  Girondin,  he  was  sheltered  for 
eight  months  by  a  devoted  woman.  It  was 
then  that  he  wrote  his  Esquisse  d'un  tableau 
historiqu£  des  progr^s  de  l' esprit  humain,  1794, 
an  eloquent  tribute  to  the  doctrine  of  the  in- 
definite perfectibility  of  man. 

Learning  that  the  penalty  of  death  had  been 
pronounced  against  those  who  received  the  Gir- 
ondins  into  their  houses,  he  departed,  not 
heeding  the  prayers  of  his  courageous  hostess, 
and  wandered  for  several  days.  Entering  a 
tavern  at  Clamart  to  appease  his  hunger,  he 
was  arrested  by  order  of  a  member  of  the  re- 
volutionary committee,  and  thrown  into  a  prison, 
where  he  was  found  dead  the  next  day  when 
sought  for  to  be  brought  before  his  accusers. 
He  had,  it  was  believed,  taken  his  life  with  a 
poison  which  he  carried   on  him.     Quick   in 


CONDUITT— CONJUNCTUR 


38? 


intelligence,  vigorous  in  mind,  passionately 
loving  what  was  right,  his  was  one  of  the 
worthiest  and  purest  natures  concerned  in  the 
first  French  Revolution.  A.  c.  f. 

[For  a  criticism  of  the  Esquisse,  see  Malthus, 
Essay  on  Population,  bk.  iii.  ch.  i.  (Bonar, 
Malthus  and  His  Work,  bk.  i.  chs.  i.  and  ii.) 
Condorcet's  application  of  the  theory  of  probabili- 
ties to  the  estimation  of  evidence  in  his  ESsais 
sur  V application  de  V analyse  d  la  probdbilite  des 
decisions  vendues  d  la  pluralite  des  voiz  .  .  .  above 
noticed,  claims  the  attention  of  the  statistician. 
A  very  unfavourable  verdict  is  pronounced  on 
this  part  of  Condorcet's  work  by  Todhunter  in 
his  Theory  of  Probability.] 

CONDUITT,  John  (1688-1737),  married 
Newton's  niece,  and  succeeded  Newton  as 
master  of  the  mint.  His  principal  work,  Ob- 
servations upon  the  Present  State  of  our  Gold 
and  Silver  Coins,  1730  (published  1774),  is 
supposed  to  represent  Newton's  views.  It  con- 
tains a  luminous  statement  of  the  principle, 
that  in  order  to  keep  silver  in  circulation,  the 
"  rate  at  which  gold  shall  be  current "  should  be 
the  same  as  in  neighbouring  countries.  Con- 
duitt  is  referred  to  in  Boulter's  letters  in 
connection  with  the  Irish  coinage.  He  was  a 
member  of  parliament,  and  a  fellow  of  the 
Royal  Society,  to  which,  in  1718,  he  contributed 
a  learned  paper  on  "The  Situation  of  the 
Ancient  Carteia." 

[Brewster,  Memoirs  of  Sir  Isaac  Newton.  — 
Jevons,  Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finance. 
— De  Morgan,  Newton,  his  friend  and  his  niece.] 

CONFIDENT  PERSON.  See  Bankruptcy 
IN  Scotland. 

CONFIRMATION  OF  EXECUTOR  (Scots 
law).     Proving  a  will  as  executor.  a.  d. 

CONFLICT  OF  LAWS.  One  of  the  numer- 
ous titles  applied  to  the  principles  that  are 
followed,  or  which  theorists  think  ought  to  be 
followed,  in  determining  whether  a  domestic  or 
a  foreign  law  ought  to  be  applied  to  a  given  set 
of  circumstances.  It  is  a  well-settled  principle 
that  within  its  own  territory  a  state  is  entitled 
to  enforce  its  own  laws.  But  in  many  cases  it 
would  be  inexpedient  or  unjust  to  do  so.  The 
property  in  question  may  be  situated  abroad, 
the  contract  to  be  enforced  may  have  been 
entered  into  in  one  country  by  persons  of  dif- 
ferent domiciles  with  reference  to  performance 
in  another  country,  or  the  document  to  be  in- 
terpreted may  be  expressed  in  the  technical 
language  of  foreign  law.  Hence  every  state 
finds  it  necessary  to  apply  in  certain  cases  the 
legal  rules  of  other  states.  Though  each  state 
decides  for  itself  when  and  how  a  foreign  law 
shall  be  applied,  there  is  a  tendency  to  adopt  a 
common  practice.  The  law  of  the  place  where 
real  property  is  situated  governs  all  questions 
as  to  the  tenure,  title,  and  descent  of  such  pro- 
perty, but  in  some  countries  it  is  held  that  a 
deed  or  will  relating  to  real  property  is  sufficient 


if  in  accordance  with  the  law  of  the  place  where 
it  was  made.  On  the  other  hand,  movable 
property  is,  as  regards  succession  or  transfer  on 
death  or  marriage,  governed  by  the  lex  domicilii, 
the  lex  situs  only  applying  in  the  case  of  title 
to  a  particular  chattel.  Contracts  valid  by  the 
law  of  the  place  where  made  are  valid  every- 
where, but  everything  that  relates  to  their  exe- 
cution is  subject  to  the  law  of  the  place  where 
the  contract  is  to  be  carried  out.  Proceedings 
in  courts  of  justice  are  regulated  by  the  lex 
fori. 

[Private  International  Lata,  by  J.  Westlake, 
Q.C.,  London,  1880.— See  also  Holland's  Juris- 
prudence for  the  different  principles  recommended 
by  theorists,  and  for  a  list  of  the  chief  writers  on 
the  subject,  and  art.  in  Law  Quarterly  Review, 
vol.  vi.  No.  21,  by  A.  V.  Dicey  on  "Private 
International  Law  as  a  Branch  of  the  Law  of 
England."]  j.  e.  c.  m. 

It  frequently  happens  in  the  course  of 
judicial  proceedings,  that  the  court  has  to 
decide  whether  its  own  ordinary  law  has  to 
be  applied  to  the  matter  coming  before  it,  or 
whether  some  other  system  of  law  has  to  be 
applied  ;  this  may  happen  when  the  parties 
reside  in  different  localities,  when  the  subject 
matter  of  the  action  is  situated  in  a  place  where 
another  system  of  law  is  administered,  or  when 
the  events  or  acts  which  form  the  foundation 
of  the  proceedings  have  taken  place  in  a  locality 
governed  by  another  system  of  law.  The  rules 
of  law  which  determine  questions  of  this  sort 
are  generally  classed  under  the  head  of  conflict 
of  laws  ;  and  the  branch  of  law  to  which  they 
belong  is  called  Private  International  Law  (see 
International  Law,  Private)  ;  but  these 
rules,  though  based  on  the  same  principles  in 
most  countries,  always  form  part  of  the  muni- 
cipal law,  and  are  not,  strictly  speaking,  inter- 
national rules.  E.  s. 

CONFUSIO.  A  tenn  of  Roman  law  mean- 
ing— (1)  the  intermingling  of  things  in  such  a 
manner  as  to  render  the  separation  of  one  of 
the  component  parts  impossible  {e.g.  the  pour- 
ing together  of  two  separate  quantities  of  liquid) ; 
(2)  the  extinction  of  a  smaller  right  by  being 
merged  into  a  larger  right  {e.g.  a  pawnee  acquires 
the  absolute  property  in  the  pawned  object). 

E.  S. 

CONJUNCTUR.  Recent  German  economists 
use  this  word  to  denote  the  conditions  and 
opportunities  of  success  which  a  man  does 
not  owe  to  his  owti  efforts,  but  receives  as  a  gift 
of  fortune.  For  example,  inherited  wealth,  in- 
fluential parentage,  and  even  nationality  and 
education,  give  a  good  start  in  life  which  would 
be  described  as  due  to  Conjunctur.  It  is  per- 
haps most  often  used  of  the  happy  concurrence 
of  circumstances  by  which  the  speculator  is 
enabled  to  realise  a  fortune  without  labour  but 
at  the  same  time  without  breach  of  the  rules 
of  competition.     Modem  socialists,  even  of  the 


388 


CONQUEST— CONSCRIPTION 


moderate  schools,  contend  that  in  modern 
society  ConjuTictur  and  not  skill  or  industry  is 
the  maker  of  fortunes  ;  and  they  would  restrict 
the  influence  of  Gonjunctur  by  alterations  in 
the  tenure  of  property  and  the  conduct  of  busi- 
ness (see  Socialism).  , 

[For  a  discussion  of  the  "  Wesen  und  Wirkung 
der  Conjuuctur,"  see  A.  Wagner,  Volkswirth- 
schaftsleh/re,  Leipzig,  1879  {Grundlegung ,  p.  98, 
seq.) — See  also  Marshall,  Principles  of  Economics 
(1890),  pp.  656,  692  n.]  J.  b. 

CONQUEST.  The  appropriation  of  the  pro- 
perty in  and  of  the  sovereignty  over  a  part  or  the 
whole  of  an  enemy's  country  by  force  of  arms. 
Though  the  title  is  usually  regulated  by  the 
terms  of  a  treaty  of  peace,  the  conquest  is  com- 
plete from  the  time  the  conqueror  proves  his 
ability  to  maintain,  and  his  intention  to  retain, 
the  territory  as  part  of  his  own  state.  As  a 
rule,  the  inhabitants  retain  their  rights,  except 
in  so  far  as  they  are  necessarily  altered  by  the 
fact  of  conquest.  Allegiance  to  the  former 
sovereign  is  dissolved,  but  consent  is  necessary 
before  allegiance  is  acquired  by  the  new  sove- 
reign. Usually  a  limited  time  is  given  within 
which  the  inhabitants  must  transfer  their  allegi- 
ance or  leave  the  territory.  In  return  for 
allegiance  the  rights  of  citizenship  are  acquired. 
Municipal  laws,  including  the  rights  of  property, 
remain  unchanged,  except  in  so  far  as  they  are 
necessarily  altered  by  the  political  institutions, 
or  are  in  conflict  with  the  laws  of  the  new  state. 
A  country  conquered  by  England  becomes  a 
dominion  of  the  crown,  and  the  crown  may 
determine  the  form  of  government. 

[Hall's  International  Law,  Oxford,  1890. — Max 
Wirth,  Grundzuge  der  Nat.  Oekoii,.^  considers 
"  Conquest "  as  a  form  of  "  highly  ski  lied  labour."] 

J.  E.  0.  M. 
CONRING,  Hermann  (1606-1681),  was  one 
of  the  most  eminent  of  the  polyhistors  of  the 
I7th  century.  The  estimation  in  which  he  was 
held  in  his  own  time  is  sufliciently  proved  by 
his  epitaph,  written  by  Meibomius — "Juris 
naturalis  gentium  publici  doctor,  philosophise 
omnis  peritissimus  practicse  et  theoreticse,  philo- 
logus  insignis,  orator,  poeta,  medicus,  theologus. 
Multos  putas  hie  conditos.  Unus  est,  Herm. 
Conringius,  saeculi  miraculum."  He  was  born 
in  East  Friesland,  and  studied  medicine  at 
Helmstadt,  where  he  was  afterwards  professor 
in  that  faculty  ;  he  was  also  for  some  time 
court  physician  to  Christina  of  Sweden.  He 
early  accepted  und  zealously  propagated  the 
Harveian  doctrine  of  the  circulation  of  the  blood. 
His  principal  field  of  distinction  lay,  however, 
in  politics  and  jurisprudence.  He  was  among 
the  first  who  formed  a  comprehensive  conception 
of  a  science  of  political  economy  ;  he  explains 
his  ideal  of  it  in  his  dedication  of  a  new  edition 
of  the  principal  writings  of  Bodin,  adding  that 
such  a  body  of  doctrine,  **  Eam  artem  [Chre- 
matisticam]   in   justam    aliquam   et  integram 


methodum  redactam  non  esse,"  though  manj 
scattered  contributions  to  it  might  be  found  in 
various  writers.  He  himself  hoped  to  realise 
this  scheme ;  he  produced,  however,  only  a 
number  of  separate  writings  on  special  heads : 
De  re  nummaria,  1662  ;  De  Vectigalibus  and 
De  Aerario,  1663  ;  De  importandis  et  exportan- 
dis  and  Dc  commercio  et  mercatura,  1665  ;  De 
contrihutionibus,  1669.  His  historical  import- 
ance lies  not  so  much  in  the  complete  treatment 
of  economic  questions  as  in  the  awakening  and 
stimulating  influence  which  he  exercised  both 
by  his  books  and  his  personal  teaching.  In  his 
great  statistical  work,  Examen  rerumpuhlicarum 
totius  orbis,  he  gives  but  little  numerical  detail, 
as  was  natural  at  his  period,  but  has  many  just 
historical  and  political  views  (Roscher,  Gesch. 
der  Nat.  OeJc.  in  Deutschland,  p.  264). 

J.  K.  I. 

CONSCRIPTION.  Compulsory  military  ser- 
vice. In  modem  times  introduced  by  Napoleon 
I.,  followed  by  Prussia,  and  since  1870  adopted 
by  all  the  great  continental  powers.  On  the 
continent  every  male  citizen  capable  of  bearing 
arms  becomes  liable  to  military  service  on  com- 
pleting his  twentieth  or  twenty-first  year,  but 
in  some  countries  service  can  be  avoided  by  a 
money  payftient  or  by  passing  an  examination. 
The  period  of  active  service  varies  from  one  to 
four  years.  The  liability  to  serve  is  universal, 
e.g.  in  Prussia  and  in  France  ;  but  in  some 
countries,  e.g.  in  Russia,  the  number  from  whom 
full  service  is  required  is  fixed  every  year.  After 
completing  the  period  of  active  service  the  men 
pass  into  the  reserve,  and  are  liable  to  be  called 
upon  in  the  event  of  an  outbreak  of  hostilities. 
In  Holland  and  Belgium,  though  the  army  is 
based  on  conscription,  the  greater  part  of  the 
forces  is  formed  of  volunteers.  Switzerland 
maintains  no  standing  army,  but  every  citizen 
is  liable  to  serve,  and  the  troops  are  called  out 
for  a  few  weeks'  training  in  the  year. 

The  social  and  economic  efi'ects  of  the  military 
systems  of  Europe  have  been  discussed  by  Cliffe 
Leslie  [Essays  in  Political  and  Moral  Philosophy , 
Dublin,  1879).  Whilst  admitting  that  the 
training  of  a  soldier  tends  to  make  the  workman 
more  efficient,  he  points  out  that  even  a  three 
years'  system  postpones  to  a  late  period  the 
productive  use  of  a  part  of  the  productive  power 
of  the  country,  whilst  a  longer  period  unfits  the 
greater  number  of  men  for  industrial  pursuits. 
Adam  Smith  {Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  v.  ch.  i.) 
thought  that  the  progress  of  manufactures  and 
improvement  in  the  art  of  war  would  tend  to 
make  the  soldier's  a  separate  trade,  but  the 
tendency  has  been  in  recent  years  to  make  the 
army  a  national  one.  Whilst  therefore  a  war 
between  two  states  in  which  all  the  citizens  are 
soldiers  implies  that  the  industrial  population 
are  fighting  in  the  ranks,  it  must  not  be  for- 
gotten  that  wars  are  of  much  shorter  duration  1 
now  than  in  former  times.     It  is  very  difficuH 


CONSEILS  DE  PRUD'HOMMES— CONSOLIDATED  FUND 


38S 


to  make  any  comparison  between  the  relative 
cost  of  armies.  The  most  recent  information 
will  be  found  in  Major-General  Brackenbury's 
Eviderice  before  the  Select  Committee  on  Army 
and  Navy  JEstimates,  1887,  Appendix  to  First 
Report,  and  in  the  Journal  of  the  Statistical 
Society,  March  1891,  **  Statistics  of  the  Defence 
Expenditure  of  the  chief  Military  and  Naval 
Powers,"  by  Sir  Charles  Dilke.  Germany,  -vv^ith 
compulsory  service  and  an  expenditure  of 
£60,000,000,  can  put  over  4,000,000  troops  in 
the  field  in  time  of  war ;  England,  with  voluntary 
enlistment  and  an  expenditure  of  £28,000,000, 
can  only  put  275,000.  The  ditierence  arises 
from  the  greater  cost  of  living  in  England,  the 
higher  rate  of  pay,  and  the  large  number  of 
foreign  dependencies  to  be  garrisoned  (see 
Defence,  Cost  of).  j.  e.  c.  m. 

CONSEILS  DE  PRUD'HOMMES.  These 
councils  are  found  on  the  continent  in  France 
and  in  Belgium,  and  have  for  their  object  the 
adjustment  of  industrial  disputes  by  a  rapid  and 
inexpensive  method.  They  are  said  to  have 
originated  in  the  experts  ox prudlwmmes  selected 
by  the  mediaeval  guilds  to  settle  disputes  between 
manufacturers  and  merchants  at  the  diiTerent 
markets  and  fairs  about  the  genuineness  of  goods 
and  other  such  matters.  They  were  abolished 
before  or  during  the  Revolution,  but  were  re- 
established at  Lyons  some  ten  years  later,  and 
subsequently  in  other  French  towns.  They  con- 
sist of  representatives  elected  in  equal  numbers 
by  masters  and  men,  and  the  election  is  con- 
ducted by  the  maire  and  prifet  of  the  particular 
town  or  district.  In  Paris  there  are  four  such 
conseils  to  deal  with  the  many  trades  and  indus- 
tries there  found.  The  conseil  thus  elected  lasts 
for  three  years,  and  is  divided  into  two  bureaux 
or  committees.  The  bureau  particulier,  con- 
sisting of  one  master  and  one  man,  sits  daily, 
and  the  bureau  g^n^ral,  consisting  of  at  least  five 
members,  meets  weekly.  Disputants  are  first 
invited  to  come  before  the  bureau  particulier  and 
to  explain  their  differences,  and  arrive,  if  pos- 
sible, at  an  amicable  settlement.  Should  this 
attempt  fail,  they  are  formally  summoned  before 
the  bureau  g6niral,  which  disposes  authorita- 
tively of  the  matter  in  the  same  way  as  an 
English  arbitrator  (see  Arbitration  between 
Employers  and  Employed).  Appeal  from  the 
decision  of  the  bureau  general  lies,  however,  to 
the  tribunals  of  commerce  and  the  ordinary 
civil  courts,  but  such  appeals  are  apparently 
seldom  made.  Petitions  for  the  establishment 
of  the  conseils  are  addressed  to  the  minister  of 
commerce.  Statistics  of  these  French  conseils 
show  that  previously  to  the  Franco -German 
war  the  number  of  cases  brought  before  them 
had  grown  to  a  maximum  of  some  45,000  in 
the  year  1868,  and  that  after  experiencing  a 
temporary  decrease  during  the  war  until  they 
had  fallen  to  some  30,000  in  1873,  in  1880 
they  had  risen  again  to  some  40,000.     Of  these 


some  60  per  cent  related  to  wages — but  not 
to  their  regulation  for  the  future,  simply  to 
the  determination  of  disputes  as  to  the  past ; 
some  13  per  cent  arose  about  dismissals  ;  some 
10  per  cent  were  concerned  with  alleged  mis- 
behaviour ;  some  5  per  cent  with  questions  of  ap- 
prenticeship ;  and  some  13  per  cent  with  various 
other  matters.  The  majority  of  cases  were 
settled  by  the  bureau  particulier,  but  a  large 
proportion  were  adjusted  outside  the  conseils 
altogether.  In  Belgium  there  are  similar  con- 
seils to  those  in  France,  and  a  proposal  has  more 
than  once  been  made  to  establish  something 
after  their  pattern  in  England.  An  act,  which 
has  proved  inoperative,  was  passed  with  this 
object  in  1867  (30  &  31  Vict.  c.  105). 

[For  an  account  of  these  councils  see  Price's  In- 
dustrial Peace,  ch.  iii. — Jevons's  Stale  in  Relation 
to  Labour,  ch.  vii. — an  article  on  "Conseils  de 
Prud'hommes,"  by  W.  H.  S.  Aubrey  in  the  Contem- 
porary Review,  April  1883 — and  a  paper  on  "The 
Strikes  of  the  past  Ten  Years"  by  G.  P.  Bevan  in  tlie 
StatisticalJournal  for  March  1880,  vol.  xliii.  pp. 
35  to  64.— Parly.  Papers,  c.  5896-17  and  c.  6206- 

18.]  L.L.P. 

CONSIDERATION.  A  consideration  in 
*'  value  "  is  not  necessary  to  a  contract  in  Scot- 
land either  by  deed  or  not  by  deed.         a.  d. 

CONSIGNEE.  A  person  to  whom  goods  are 
shipped.  A  person  whose  orders  the  master  of 
a  vessel  is  to  follow,  by  virtue  of  the  clauses  of 
a  charter  party,  is  called  the  consignee  of  the 
vgssbI 

CONSOLIDATED  FUND.  The  division  oi 
the  British  revenue  between  the  Consolidated 
Fund  and  Annual  Supply  will  be  best  under- 
stood from  the  following  oflicial  statement  de- 
rived from  Public  Income  and  Expenditure, 
Returns  ordered  House  of  Commons  24th  July 
1866,  pt.  ii.  p.  611. 

"  From  the  period  of  the  establishment  of  a 
systematic  parliamentary  control  over  the  ex- 
penditure of  the  public  moneys,  that  portion  of 
the  total  issues  from  the  exchequer  during  the 
financial  year,  which  is  more  strictly  called  the 
public  expenditure,  has  always  been  divided 
into  two  separate  and  distinct  general  heads. 
The  first  of  these  is  composed  of  the  more  per- 
manent charges  which  have  been  authorised  by 
parliament  to  be  paid  from  time  to  time  when 
due,  the  mode  and  period  of  payment  being 
under  the  directions  of  the  treasury.  The  second 
head  consists  of  the  charges  annually  gi'anted 
by  parliament,  and  thus  brought  periodically 
under  its  immediate  cognisance  and  control. 
Since  the  establishment  of  the  consolidated 
fund  in  1786,  these  two  heads  of  public  ex- 
penditure have  been  known  as  the  consolidated 
fund  charges  and  the  annual  supply  charges, 
so  designated  from  the  funds  out  of  which  they 
are  respectively  payable. 

The  consolidated  fund  charges  have  beer 
usually  subdivided  into — 


390 


CONSOLIDATIO— CONSPIKACY 


The  annual  charges  of  public  debt. 

Civil  list. 

Annuities  and  pensions. 

Salaries  and  allowances  of  certain  independent 
offices. 

Courts  of  justice. 

At  this  date  [1866]  diplomatic  salaries  and 
pensions  (now  included  among  annual  sup- 
ply charges). 

Miscellaneous  charges. 
The  general  heads  of  the  supply  charges  are — 

The  classilied  miscellaneous  civil  services. 

Payments  out  of  gross  revenue ;  or,  since  1854, 
the  charges  of  collection  and  management 
of  revenue. 

Army,  navy,  and  ordnance  services. 
The  other  issues  from  the  exchequer,  consist- 
ing of — 

Advances  by  way  of  loan. 

Sinking  fund  and  other  payments  for  the 
reduction  of  the  national  debt  have  formed  part 
of  the  consolidated  fund  charges,  or  the  annual 
supply  charges,  according  to  the  parliamentary 
enactments  by  which  these  issues  have  been 
authorised  "  (Public  Income  and  Expenditure,  or 
Return  ordered  24th  July  1866,  pt.  ii.  p.  611). 

In  explanation  of  this  arrangement,  A.  Todd 
I'emarks — 

"'Formerly,'  that  is  after  'the  old  system 
of  retaining  public  money  at  the  exchequer  it- 
self was  'abolished,'  'the  proceeds  of  parlia- 
mentary taxes  constituted  separate  and  distinct 
funds '  ;  but  by  the  Act  27  Geo.  III.  c.  13,  §  47, 
it  was  directed  that  the  various  duties  and  taxes 
should  be  carried  to  and  constitute  a  fund,  to  be 
called  'The  Consolidated  Fund.'"  (These  per- 
manent grants  out  of  the  consolidated  fund  are 
recapitulated  above  in  the  extract  given  from  the 
Report  on  Public  Moneys.)  Todd  continues : 
"These  charges  are  made  payable  out  of  the 
consolidated  fund  by  permanent  statutes,  from 
year  to  year,  without  any  renewal  of  parlia- 
mentary authority.  The  principle  of  not  sub- 
jecting to  the  uncertainty  of  an  annual  vote 
the  provision  for  the  security  of  the  public 
creditor,  the  dignity  of  the  crown,  annuities 
and  pensions  to  royal  and  distinguished  persons, 
the  salaries  of  judges  and  other  officers  in  whose 
official  character  independence  is  an  essential 
element,  compensation  for  rights  surrendered, 
and  like  charges,  is  one  the  soundness  of  which 
is  generally  admitted." 

(Alpheus  Todd,  On  Parliamentary  Government 
in  England,  vol.  i.  pp.  733,  737,  2nd  edition.) 

Todd  further  raises  a  question  whether  in 
certain  cases  amounts  may  not  have  been  carried 
to  the  consolidated  fund  which  should  have 
been  voted  as  part  of  annual  supply,  but  those 
who  are  conversant  with  the  practice  of  the 
House  of  Commons  in  •  the  discussion  of  the 
annual  votes  will  agree  that  little  would  bo 
gained  in  the  way  of  real  economy  by  this 
course  being  pursued. 


CONSOLIDATIO.  In  Roman  law  this 
expression  was  used  for  the  extinction  of  a 
usufruct  in  consequence  of  the  usufructuary 
becoming  the  owner  of  the  property  to  which  it 
referred.  It  is  also  a  technical  term  used  by 
writers  on  feudal  law,  and  is  by  them  applied 
to  the  termination  of  a  vassal's  right  by  sur- 
render, escheat,  or  some  other  cause  which 
restored  the  beneficial  rights  of  ownership  to  the 
lord.  E.  s. 

CONSOLS.  A  stock  exchange  abbreviation  for 
"consolidated  annuities,"  originally  applied  to 
the  3  per  cent  consolidated  annuities  of  1751 
(25  Geo.  II.  c.  27)  which  bore  interest  payable 
on  6th  January  and  6th  July.  These  3  per 
cents  were  converted  in  1888  into  stock  bearing 
interest  at  2|  per  cent  till  1903,  and  after 
that  date  at  2^  per  cent  till  1923.  The 
amount  of  these  consols  when  jBrst  issued 
in  exchange  for  pre-existing  securities  was 
£9,137,812,  but  they  were  afterwards  in- 
creased to  about  £400,000,000  :  by  1888  they 
had  been  reduced  by  purchase  in  the  market 
and  by  conversions  into  terminable  annuities 
to  £322,681,000.  In  1889  Mr.  Goschen  com- 
pleted the  redemption  of  this  enormous  amount 
of  stock,  and  these  3  per  cents,  which  for  up- 
wards of  a  century  were  reckoned  as  the  standard 
security  of  the  London  market,  will  soon  be 
unknown  there.  They  are  now  only  a  matter 
of  history.  The  3  per  cent  reduced  annuities, 
although  a  similar,  and  at  first  a  larger,  issue, 
were  never  designated  consols. 

But  the  familiar  term  "  consols  "  has  recently 
been  applied  to  a  number  of  other  investments. 
There  are  New  Zealand  5  per  cent  consols.  Cape 
of  Good  Hope  4  per  cent  consols,  and  other 
government  securities,  which  are  currently 
designated  consols  by  dealers  upon  the  exchange 
simply  because  the  word  is  more  readily  spoken 
and  written  than  consolidated  stock.  It  is  also 
at  times  applied  to  other  consolidated  stocks 
than  those  issued  by  governments  (see  Con- 
version OF  British  National  Debt). 

CONSPIRACY,  Common-Law  Doctrine  of. 
Though  there  were  some  dicta  to  the  effect 
that  a  combination  for  the  purpose  of  raising 
wages  would  be  unlawful,  no  case  of  a  convic- 
tion for  such  an  offence  occurred  until  the  year 
1825.  Mr.  Justice  Stephen  is  therefore  led  to 
conclude  that  up  to  that  year  an  agreement  to 
combine  to  raise  or  depress  the  rate  of  wages 
was  not  an  indictable  offence  apart  from  statute. 
The  opposite  view  was  entertained  by  many 
persons  and  was  enforced  by  the  courts.  ' '  Read- 
ing Sir  W.  Erie's  summing-up  in  this  case  (R.  v. 
Rowlands,  2  Den.  Cr.  Ca.  364)  and  his  memo- 
randum on  trade  unions  together,  it  seems  that 
his  view  of  the  subject  of  conspiracies  in  restraint 
of  trade  was  this — at  common  law  all  combina- 
tions of  workmen  to  affect  the  rate  of  wages 
were  illegal.  A  limited  exception  Avas  intro- 
duced by  the  6  Geo.   IV.   c.    129.      But  the 


CONSTITUTUM  DEBITI— CONSULAR  REPORTS 


391 


ordinary  operations  of  a  strike  which  do  not  fall 
definitely  within  those  narrow  exceptions  are 
still  illegal  conspiracies."  This  view  was  en- 
forced in  subsequent  cases,  but  by  the  22  Vict. 
c.  34,  workmen  were  not  to  be  considered  guUty 
of  ** molestation"  or  "obstruction"  under  the 
act  of  1825  by  reason  of  entering  into  agree- 
ments for  the  purpose  of  fixing  wages  or  the 
hours  of  labour.  A  commission,  issued  in  18b7, 
recommended  a  relaxation  of  the  law,  and  the 
38  &  39  Vict.  c.  31  legalised  trade  unions, 
whilst  the  38  &  39  Vict.  c.  32  amended  the 
law  relating  to  "molestation."  The  decision 
in  1872  in  the  gas  stokers'  case  to  the  eftect 
that  a  strike  might,  under  certain  circumstances, 
amount  to  a  conspiracy  at  common  law  to 
molest,  injure,  or  impoverish  an  individual,  or 
to  prevent  him  carrying  on  his  business,  led  to 
the  passing  of  38  &  39  Vict.  c.  86,  which  en- 
acted that  an  agi*eement  by  two  or  more  persons 
to  do  any  act  in  furtherance  of  a  trade  dispute 
should  not  be  indictable  as  a  conspiracy  if  such 
act  committed  by  one  person  should  not  be 
punishable  as  a  crime. 

[Sir  W.  Erie,  TJie  Law  relating  to  Trade  Unions, 
Loudon,  1869.— K.  S.  Wright,  The  Laio  of  Crim- 
inal Conspiracies,  London,  1873. — Roscoe's  Digest 
of  the  Law  of  Evidence  in  Criminal  Cases,  titles 
"Conspiracy"  and  "Conspiracy  in  Restraint  of 
Trade,"  London,  1884. — Sir  J.  F.  Stephen,  Histmy 
of  the  Criminal  Law,  London,  1883.]   J.  E.  c.  M. 

CONSTITUTUM  DEBITI.  An  informal 
promise  to  pay.  Such  a  promise  gave  a  right 
of  action  in  Roman  law,  by  virtue  of  the  prae- 
torian edict,  quite  independently  of  the  cause 
of  the  promise.  It  was  frequently  used,  in  the 
place  of  a  regular  contract  of  suretyship,  for  the 
purpose  of  guaranteeing  another  person's  debt 
{constitutum  debiti  alieni).  e.  s. 

CONSTITUTUM  POSSESSORIUM.  An  ex- 
pression used  by  mediaeval  -WTiters  on  Roman 
law  to  express  the  fictitious  delivery  which  takes 
place  when  the  owner  of  a  thing  transfers  the 
property  to  another,  and  contracts  to  retain  the 
possession  as  bailee  for  the  new  owner,     e.  s. 

CONSUL.  Consuls  are  commercial  agents 
appointed  to  reside  in  foreign  countries  for  the 
purpose  of  protecting  the  individual  interests 
of  traders,  travellers,  and  mariners  belonging  to 
the  state  which  appoints  them.  A  consul  is 
not  a  diplomatic  agent,  and  he  is  not  therefore 
authorised,  except  in  special  cases,  to  make  any 
representations  to  the  government  of  the  state 
in  which  he  acts.  He  is  not  entitled  to  ex- 
emption from  local  jurisdiction,  but  enjoys 
certain  specific  privileges  essential  to  the  dis- 
charge of  his  duties,  such  as  exemption  from  per- 
sonal taxes  and  the  inviolability  of  the  papers 
of  the  consulate.  The  most  important  duties  of 
consuls  will  be  found  in  Hall's  International  Law 
(Oxford,  1880),  and  in  the  authorities  there 
quoted.  In  eastern  countries  such  as  Turkey, 
China,  and  Japan,  the  subjects  of  western  states 


are  not  liable  to  the  local  courts,  and  jurisdiction 
is  by  treaty  exercised  by  consular  courts.  (See 
Consular  Reports  ;  also  Consuls  and  Con- 
sular Reports,  Appendix.) 

[Phillimore's  International  Laiv,  ii.  §  272. — 
Calvo's  Droit  International,  §§  495-99. — Hand- 
huch  des  Volkerrechts  herausgegeben  von  Dr.  Franz 
von  Holtzendorff,  vol.  iii.,  Berlin,  1887.]    J.  E.c.m. 

CONSULAR  REPORTS.  The  ability  of  the 
various  representatives  of  the  United  Kingdom 
in  foreign  countries  to  supply  information  of 
great  value  to  the  trading  community  at  home 
has  long  been  recognised,  and  every  secretary 
of  embassy  or  legation,  and  every  paid  consular 
oflicer  is  therefore  required  to  furnish  an  annual 
report  on  the  trade,  commerce,  and  navigation 
of  the  country  or  district,  as  the  case  may  be, 
in  which  he  is  stationed.  Secretaries  of  em- 
bassies or  legations  are  also  required  to  report 
annually  on  the  finances  of  the  countries  in 
which  they  act.  Reports  on  special  subjects 
are  occasionally  called  for,  and  information  on 
commercial  or  industrial  topics  of  special  interest 
is  frequently  sent  home  by  diplomatic  and  con- 
sular officers  on  their  own  motion.  These 
reports  are  published  by  the  foreign  office,  and 
sold  in  three  regular  and  several  minor  series. 

1.  The  general  series  entitled ' '  Reports  on  Sub- 
jects of  Commercial  and  General  Interest  by  Her 
Majesty's  Representatives  La  Foreign  Countries. " 

2.  The  diplomatic  trade  series,  being  *  *  Reports 
by  the  Secretaries  of  Embassy  or  Legation  on 
the  Manufactures,  Commerce,  etc.,  of  the 
Countries  in  which  they  Reside." 

3.  The  consular  trade  series,  being  "Reports 
by  Her  Majesty's  Consuls  on  the  Trade  of  the 
Countries  in  which  they  Reside." 

Reports  from  China,  Japan,  and  Siam  appear 
in  three  minor  and  separate  series,  each  headed 
by  the  name  of  the  country. 

In  the  course  of  the  year  1886  some  atten- 
tion was  given  to  the  possibility  of  rendering 
these  reports  of  greater  practical  value  to  the 
commercial  classes,  it  being  the  opinion  of 
many  that  foreign  traders  were  better  served  in 
this  respect  than  those  of  the  United  Kingdom. 
Some  evidence  to  this  effect  was  given  before 
the  royal  commission  on  the  depression  of  trade 
and  industry,  who  referred  to  the  subject  in  their 
report.  It  cannot  be  said  that  this  contention 
was  established,  but  the  result  of  the  investiga- 
tion made  by  that  commission  and  the  foreign 
office  was  to  efiect  some  substantial  improve- 
ments. It  was  arranged  that  the  reports  should 
be  more  promptly  published,  that  the  importance 
of  procuring  full  information  regarding  the 
industry  and  the  condition  of  the  working 
classes  should  not  be  lost  sight  of,  and  that 
samples  of  the  manufactured  goods  chiefly  in 
demand  in  the  countries  in  which  consuls 
resided  should  be  sent  home  with  the  reports. 
The  reports  are  now  utilised  by  the  Board  of 
Trade  Journal. 


392 


CONSUMABLES— CONSUMERS'  RENT 


[The  General  Consular  Instructiorts  and  the 
Correspondence  respecting  the  Question  of 
Diplomatic  and  Consular  Assistance  to  British 
Trade  Abroad,  published  in  1886  (c.  4779), 
contain  much  information  on  this  subject.  An 
Index  to  the  Eeports  published  from  1886  to 
1890  is  also  available  (c.  6374).]  t.  h.  e. 

CONSUMABLES.     See  Consumptibles. 

CONSUMERS'  GOODS  (or  Consumption 
Goods)  include  all  those  desirable  things  which 
directly  satisfy  human  needs  and  desires,  e.g. 
food  and  clothing.  Those  desirable  things 
which  are  only  useful  indirectly  as  a  means 
towards  the  production  of  consumers'  goods — 
as,  for  example,  machines  and  the  raw  materials 
of  manufacture — are  by  contrast  spoken  of  as 
Producers'  Goods  (or  Production  Goods).  This 
distinction  has  been  carried  further  by  Professor 
Menger  and  the  Austrian  school  of  economists, 
who  divide  goods  into  successive  orders  :  goods 
of  the  first  order,  consisting  of  consumption  goods 
as  above  defined  ;  goods  of  the  second  order,  of 
those  things  which  contribute  immediately 
towards  the  production  of  goods  of  the  first 
order,  e.g.  sewing  machines  ;  goods  of  the 
third  order,  of  those  things  which  contribute 
similarly  towards  the  production  of  goods  of  the 
second  order,  e.g.  machinery  used  in  the  manu- 
facture of  sewing  machines  ;  and  so  on.  In 
many  cases  it  is  impossible  to  draw  a  hard  and 
fast  lino  between  goods  of  different  orders,  or 
even  between  consumers'  goods  and  producers' 
goods  ;  but  this  does  not  destroy  the  import- 
ance of  the  distinctions  indicated.  It  may  be 
observed  that  while  some  things  are  in  their 
very  nature  consumers'  goods  or  producers'  goods 
as  the  case  may  be,  e.g.  ball  dresses  and  sewing 
machines,  others  cannot  be  classified  until  the 
use  to  which  they  are  put  is  known.  For 
example,  a  horse  may  be  used  as  a  pleasure 
horse  or  for  work  on  a  farm  ;  or,  indeed,  some- 
times for  the  one  purpose  and  sometimes  for  the 
other.  A  thing  may  even  belong  to  several 
orders  of  goods  at  the  same  time ;  as,  for  example, 
a  furnace  which,  while  working  machinery  of 
various  kinds,  also  serves  to  warm  a  neighbouring 
club-room  or  workmen's  common  room. 

[Marshall,  Principles  of  JSconomics  (2nd  ed.), 
bk.  ii.  ch.  iii.  §  1  ;  and  Sidgwick,  Principles  of 
Political  Economy,  bk.  i.  ch.  iii.  §  4  (see  Comple- 
mentary Goods).]  j.  n.  k. 

CONSUMERS'  RENT.  A  term  introduced 
into  the  nomenclature  of  political  economy  by 
Professor  Marshall,  to  designate  the  diff"erence 
between  the  price  that  a  purchaser  actually  pays 
for  a  given  commodity  and  the  price  that  he 
would  be  willing  to  pay  rather  than  go  without 
it.  While  the  former  can  never  exceed  the 
latter,  it  is  clear  that,  as  regards  a  large  portion 
of  each  individual's  expenditure,  the  latter 
must  exceed  the  former.  This  is  proved  by  the 
fact  that  although  a  rise  in  the  price  of  a  com- 
modity may  lead  a  purchaser  to  buy  less  of  it, 


he  wiU  not  usually  give  up  buying  it  altogethei 
unless  the  rise  in  price  is  very  considerable. 
Consumers'  rent  thus  measures  the  surplus 
satisfaction  that  a  consumer  derives  from  the 
purchase  of  a  commodity  over  and  above  the 
satisfaction  that  he  sacrifices  in  paying  away 
its  price.  In  illustration,  we  may  suppose  the 
case  of  a  man  who,  if  the  price  of  coals  were  £10 
a  ton,  would  just  be  induced  to  buy  one  ton 
annually  ;  who  would  just  be  induced  to  buy 
two  tons  if  the  price  were  £7,  three  tons  if  it 
were  £5,  four  tons  if  were  £3,  five  tons  if  it 
were  £2,  six  tons  if  it  were  £1  :  10s.  ;  and  who 
— the  price  being  actually  £1 — does  as  a  matter 
of  fact  buy  seven  tons.  The  fact  that  for  one 
ton  he  would  be  willing  to  give  £10  shows  that 
the  satisfaction  he  derives  from  that  one  ton  is 
economically  measured  by  £1 0.  Hence  the  pur- 
chase of  it  for  £1  yields  a  surplus  satisfaction 
that  is  measured  by  £9  ;  it  yields,  in  other 
words,  a  consumers'  rent  of  £9.  Similarly  the 
surplus  satisfaction  yielded  by  the  whole  amount 
of  coal  that  he  buys  is  measured  by  the  differ- 
ence between  his  actual  expenditure  on  coal  (£7) 
and  the  sum  of  the  prices  that  he  would  just  be 
willing  to  give  for  each  successive  ton,  i.e. 
£29  :  10s.  In  other  words,  the  whole  consumers' 
rent  that  h^  derives  from  buying  coal  at  £1  a 
ton  is  £22  :  10s. 

The  term  Consumers'  Bent  is  seen  to  be  em- 
ployed analogically :  agricultural  rent  is  the 
excess  of  the  value  of  the  total  produce  obtained 
from  a  given  piece  of  land  over  what  is  required 
to  remunerate  the  farmer  for  the  outlay  involved 
in  raising  the  produce  ;  consumers'  rent  is  the 
excess  of  the  money  equivalent  of  the  satisfac- 
tion derived  by  an  individual  from  the  total 
amount  of  a  commodity  that  he  purchases,  as 
measured  by  the  total  price  that  he  would,  if 
necessary,  be  willing  to  give  for  it,  over  the  out- 
lay actually  incurred. 

Since  the  amount  of  satisfaction  yielded  to 
different  purchasers  by  the  same  expenditure 
may  be  very  different,  it  follows  that  a  given 
consumers'  rent  may  represent  varying  amounts 
of  surplus  satisfaction.  In  particular,  the 
utilities  of  two  commodities  cannot  be  regarded 
as  even  approximately  represented  by  their 
money  measures,  when  one  of  the  commodities 
is  consumed  chiefly  by  the  rich  and  the  other 
chiefly  by  the  poor.  Professor  Marshall  points 
out  accordingly  that  the  practical  usefulness  of 
e,stimates  of  consumers'  rents  is  limited  to  those 
cases  in  which  the  prices  taken  into  consid- 
eration are  those  paid  in  markets  where  the 
average  wealth  of  the  purchasers  is  equal. 

The  working  out  of  problems  that  relate  to 
consumers'  rent  is  much  facilitated  by  the  em- 
ployment of  diagrammatic  methods.  The  use 
of  diagrams  also  indicates  clearly  the  analogy 
between  consumers'  rent  and  rent  in  the  ordin- 
ary sense. 

[The  above  account  of  consumers'  rent  is  taken 


CONSUMPTIBLES— CONSUMPTION 


from  a  paper  by  Professor  Marshall,  on  the  Pure 
Theory  of  {Domestic)  Values,  printed  for  private 
circulation  in  1879,  and  from  the  same  author's 
Principles  of  Economics.  For  further  explanation 
and  for  illustration  of  the  uses  to  which  the  con- 
ception of  consumers'  rent  may  be  put  in  economic 
discussions,  and  the  limitations  with  which  they 
must  be  received,  see  the  last-named  work,  bk. 
iii.  ch.  iv.,  and  bk.  v.  chs.  vii.  and  viii.] 

J.  K  K. 

CONSUMPTIBLES.  A  Term  employed 
BY  THE  Schoolmen.  The  schoolmen  based  a 
theory  of  interest  on  the  distinction  between 
"consumable"  and  "durable"  goods.  In  the 
case  of  the  former,  the  use  of  which  is  insepar- 
able from  and  transferred  with  the  article  itself, 
interest  was  in  their  eyes  wrong.  The  transfer 
of  a  consumptible,  e.g.  corn  and  wine,  carries 
with  it  the  right  to  consume.  So  to  require  the 
thing  back,  and  also  something  for  its  use,  is 
to  charge  two  prices  for  it,  one,  a  fair  and 
proper  equivalent,  the  other  an  extortion  (see 
Fungibles), 

[Aquinas,  Summa  Theologice,  II.  ii.  Q.  78,  Art. 
1. — Bohm-Bawerk,  Capital  and  Interest  (Eng. 
trans.),  vol.  i.  ch.  i.  p.  22.]  l.  r.  p. 

Consumptibles.  The  end  of  all  produc- 
tion is  consumption,  and  consumptibles  are 
the  individual  material  objects  destined  for,  or 
capable  of,  consumption.  This  may  follow  after 
and  extend  over  a  longer  or  shorter  period. 
The  loaf  which  is  eaten  on  the  day  of  baking, 
the  Suez  Canal  which  will  last,  it  is  hoped,  for 
centuries,  are  both  consumptibles  ;  they  have 
this  in  common  that  they  are  destined  to  be 
consumed,  and  their  destination  is  proved  by 
the  fact.  But  it  is  not  necessary  that  the  pro- 
cess even  of  consumption  should  begin  at  once 
on  the  completion  of  production.  Consump- 
tibles may  be  in  stock  an  unlimited  period 
before  consumption  begins  without  forfeiting 
the  title.  Thus  the  term  covers  the  whole 
range  of  production,  and  includes  all  the  pro- 
ducts of  industry.  But  it  includes  also  a  large 
number  of  other  things.  The  gifts  of  nature, 
fruits,  metals,  animals,  and  also  the  forces  of 
nature  are  all  to  be  classed  under  the  head  of 
consumptibles.  In  some  such  cases  the  process 
even  of  consumption  may  not  begin  for  centuries, 
and  may  continue  for  centuries  more. 

Cousumptible  and  kindred  terms  would  be  by 
some  restricted  to  articles  that  are  desired  for 
their  own  sake  which  are  ends  in  themselves  ; 
goods  of  the  first  order,  in  Menger's  phrase.  In 
this  sense  a  loaf  is  consumed,  but  not  a  machine. 
"  Used  up  "  has  been  proposed  as  a  more  general 
term  than  consumed.  Another  distinction  is 
between  commodities  which  in  order  to  be  useful 
must  be  used  up,  and  those  which,  though  in  fact 
they  do  wear  away,  do  not  confer  utility  by  being 
used  up.  A  loaf  belongs  to  the  former  class,  the 
Suez  Canal  to  the  latter. 

CONSUMPTION.  Some  economists  have 
proposed  to   place   consumption  on   the  same 


footing  as  production,  distribution,  and  exchange 
as  a  special  department  of  economics.  Since  in 
England,  however,  this  has  not  been  attempted 
in  the  standard  text-books,  it  seems  best  to 
indicate  the  various  problems  in  the  accepted 
divisions  of  the  subject  which  would  naturally 
fall  under  a  department  of  consumption.  It 
will  be  found  that  to  a  great  extent  the  prob- 
lems of  the  new  department  have  been  already 
investigated  under  other  names. 

(1)  First  of  all  come  questions  of  definition  and 
the  explanation  of  the  fundamental  ideas  at  the 
basis  of  consumption,  generally  treated  by  English 
writers  in  connection  with  production.  ' '  Con- 
sumption," says  Adam  Smith,  "is  the  sole  end 
and  purpose  of  all  production,  and  the  interest 
of  the  producer  ought  to  be  attended  to  only 
so  far  as  it  may  be  necessary  for  promoting  that 
of  the  consumer."  Later  criticism  has  throAvn 
doubt  on  the  possibility  of  making  such  a  sharp 
distinction  between  the  interests  of  producers 
and  consumers.  Apart  from  women  who  are 
largely  employed  in  domestic  duties,  and  old 
men,  invalids,  and  children,  the  number  of 
those  returned  in  the  census  of  any  civilised 
country  as  "unoccupied"  is  extremely  small, 
and  thus  the  great  majority  of  the  adult  males 
are  both  producers  and  consumers.  Accordingly 
the  conditions  as  regards  health,  variety,  moral 
and  intellectual  efiects  on  the  worker  of  the 
work  done,  etc.,  are  of  co-ordinate  importance 
with  the  amount  and  quality  of  the  definite 
commodities  consumed.  These  questions  are 
often  discussed  under  the  "disadvantages"  of 
Division  of  Labour  {q.v.),  and  sometimes 
under  the  effects  of  machinery. 

The  principal  idea  in  consumption  is  utility, 
taken  in  the  wide  sense  in  which  the  term  is 
used  in  ethics  (utilitarianism)  ;  the  character- 
istics of  which  were  first  analysed  by  Bentham. 
From  the  consumer's  point  of  view  the  chief 
attribute  of  wealth  is  simply  its  utility — "its 
power  or  capacity,"  in  Mill's  language,  "to 
satisfy  a  desire  or  serve  a  purpose."  From 
this  standpoint  the  fact  that  wealth  requires 
land,  labour,  and  capital  for  its  production,  that 
it  may  be  distributed  in  difiFerent  ways  according 
to  the  laws  of  the  state  or  so-called  natural 
economic  laws,  and  that  it  may  be  exchanged, 
are  of  secondary  importance.  The  consumer 
looks  primarily  to  utility.  Thus  if  by  some 
discovery  of  natural  sources  any  commodity 
became  so  abundant  as  to  lose  altogether  its 
exchange  value,  this  would  to  the  consumer  be 
the  best  thing  possible.  Professor  Jevons  was 
the  first  to  give  full  importance  to  utility  as  the 
foundation  of  consumption,  and  in  this  way  the 
basis  of  economic  science  in  general  {Theory  of 
Political  Economy).  Previous  writers,  as  Mill, 
had  been  content  with  indicating  broadly  that 
utility  was  one  requisite  of  exchange  value.  By 
the  distinction  between  final  and  total  utility 
(see  Utility),  Jevons  threw  a  new  light  on  the 


394 


CONSUMPTION 


whole  subject.  The  utility  obtained  by  the 
consumption  of  successive  portions  of  any  com- 
modity is  beyond  a  certain  point  subject  to  a 
species  of  diminishing  return.  The  total  utility 
of  the  things  necessary  to  preserve  life  is  very 
great,  but  the  final  utility  of  the  last  mouthful 
of  bread  and  butter  eaten  by  a  well-fed  labourer 
may  be  very  small.  The  art  of  consumption, 
even  without  considering  the  limited  powers  of 
acquisition  by  an  individual,  consists  in  know- 
ing when  to  leave  off  in  one  thing  and  to  begin 
another.  The  ideal  is  reached  when  the  final 
utilities  of  all  the  articles  consumed  are  just 
equal.  If  everything  were  to  be  had  in  perfect 
abundance  consumption  would  in  each  case  be 
carried  on  until  the  zero  point  was  reached,  and 
further  consumption  would  involve  harmful  ex- 
cess or  negative  utility. 

(2)  The  relation  of  consumption  to  production 
may  next  be  noticed.  The  object  of  consump- 
tion is  to  obtain  utility,  but  in  general  this  can 
only  be  done  by  the  destruction,  at  a  more  or 
less  rapid  rate,  of  the  thing  used.  To  replace 
this  destruction,  when  the  natural  supplies  are 
limited,  is  the  object  of  production.  This  leads 
to  the  distinction  between  productive  and  un- 
productive consumption.  The  former  may  be 
defined  strictly  as  that  part  of  the  producer's 
consumption  which  is  necessary  to  keep  up  or 
increase  his  efficiency,  whilst  the  remainder  is 
unproductive.  Thus  it  is  impossible  to  separate 
the  individuals  who  compose  an  industrial 
society  into  distinct  classes  of  productive  and 
unproductive  consumers,  for  the  great  majority 
are  both,  though  in  different  degrees. 

Apart  from  this  most  general  relation  of 
consumption  to  production,  we  may  consider 
the  former  as  a  stimulus  to  the  latter.  This  is 
the  principal  point  overlooked  in  Mill's  unfor- 
tunately-worded proposition  that  demand  for 
commodities  is  not  demand  for  labour.  It  is 
the  growth  in  the  intensity  and  variety  of  the 
demands  of  consumers  which  is  the  mainspring 
of  the  increase  of  production,  and  thus  of  the 
employment  of  labour.  This  point  has  been 
forcibly  illustrated  by  Adam  Smith  in  his 
historical  survey  of  the  way  in  which  the 
commerce  of  the  towns  contributed  to  the 
improvement  of  the  country  ( Wealth  of 
NatioTis,  bk.  iii.  ch.  iv.)  Mill  himself  also 
observes  (Political  Economy,  bk.  i.  ch.  xiv.) 
that  amongst  the  means  of  increasing  the 
industrial  activity  of  oriental  nations  must  be 
reckoned  "the  growth  of  mental  activity 
making  the  people  alive  to  new  objects  of 
desire. " 

(3)  Although  in  one  way  consumption 
through  demand  determines  production,  in 
another  way  production  through  the  conditions 
of  supply  determines  consumption.  For  the 
means  at  the  disposal  of  any  individual  are 
limited,  and  in  many  cases  give  little  surplus 
above  what  is  requii-ed  for  the  barest  neces- 


saries, and  it  follows  that  the  price  of  tht 
article  is  as  important  as  its  utility  in  deter- 
mining the  quantity  consumed.  The  funda- 
mental law  of  demand  is  that  with  every  fall  in 
price  per  unit,  other  things  remaining  the 
same,  the  number  of  imits  demanded  increases. 
The  consumer  will  aim  at  obtaining  the  maxi- 
mum utility  from  the  expenditure  of  the  money 
at  his  command,  and,  to  put  the  matter  in  the 
simplest  form,  a  peck  of  apples  may  be  of  more 
use  than  a  single  pineapple.  But  the  price  of 
any  article,  not  actually  subject  to  natural  or 
artificial  scarcity  or  monopoly,  depends  normally 
upon  Cost  of  Production  {q.v.)  Thus  cost  of 
production  has  an  equal  reciprocal  influence  on 
consumption.  This  is  well  illustrated  in  the 
case  of  food.  The  introduction  of  a  cheaper 
means  of  subsistence  often  leads  to  the  partial, 
or  even  total  abandonment  of  a  more  costly, 
though  in  other  respects  superior  national  food, 
as,  for  example,  was  the  case  with  the  potato 
in  Ireland.  Again  in  the  matter  of  clothing, 
the  cheapness  of  the  commodities  produced  on 
a  large  scale  has  driven  out  of  use  various 
home-made  articles,  e.g.  stockings.  The  total 
result  of  this  substitution  of  cheap  and  inferior 
articles  may  contribute  towards  lowering  the 
standard  of  comfort  of  the  mass  of  the  people, 
and  in  this  way  the  effect  of  production  upon 
consumption  may  be  most  important. 

(4)  The  connection  between  the  distribution 
and  the  consumption  of  wealth  is  obviously  of 
the  closest  kind,  for  the  kind  of  articles 
selected  by  the  consumer  will  depend  upon  the 
amount  of  his  income.  If  aU  incomes  were  at 
the  same  level  of  moderate  competence  there 
would  be  no  scope  for  the  higher  forms  of 
luxuries,  which  require  exclusive  use  for  their 
enjoyment.  Accordingly  we  find  that  socialists 
who  aim  at  comparative  equality  of  incomes 
lay  great  stress  on  all  forms  of  social  enjoyment, 
e.g.  theatres,  picture-galleries,  music,  etc. 
Again,  historically,  we  find  that  the  forms  of 
wealth  at  different  times  have  been  largely 
determined  by  its  distribution.  The  produc- 
tion of  works  of  art  in  mediaeval  Italy,  and 
game  preserving  in  England,  are  examples  of 
the  mode  in  which  consumption  varies  with  the 
interests  of  dominant  classes. 

(5)  The  question  of  consumption  may  next 
be  considered  from  the  point  of  view  of  govern- 
mental control  or  laissez-faire.  In  former 
times  almost  every  government  thought  it  a 
most  important  part  of  its  duty  to  lay  down 
what  various  classes,  or  even  individuals,  might 
or  might  not  consume,  and  we  find  sumptuary 
laws  of  the  most  detailed  kind.  In  mediaeval 
England,  for  example,  both  clothing  and  food 
were  subject  to  the  strictest  regulations.  A 
person  must  be  of  a  certain  social  standing  to 
be  entitled  to  wear  silk,  or  to  eat  more  than 
three  courses  at  a  meal.  In  oriental  countries 
this  idea  has  reached  its  fuU  development  in 


CONSUMPTION 


395 


the  caste  system.  In  modern  times  in  progres- 
sive societies  the  tendency  has  been  in  con- 
sumption, as  in  production,  to  rely  more  and 
more  upon  laissez-faire,  although  public  opinion, 
distributed  through  different  social  orders, 
still  exercises  considerable  influence,  especially 
in  matters  of  dress,  houses,  furniture,  etc.  In 
some  respects,  however,  the  government  stjU 
exercises  a  direct  or  indirect  control  over  con- 
sumption, and  it  is  held  to  be  justified  in  doing 
so  in  cases  where  the  consumer  is  not  the  best 
judge  of  his  own  real  interests,  or  of  the  real 
value  of  the  article  consumed.  Thus  in  most 
countries  the  sale  of  intoxicants  and  the  pre- 
scription of  medicines  have  been  placed  under 
legal  restraint.  At  the  same  time  also  laws 
with  detailed  provisions  have  been  enacted 
against  various  forms  of  adulteration  and 
fraud.  The  interests  of  consumers  who  are 
considered  unfit  to  judge  for  themselves,  e.g. 
children,  have  been  specially  considered.  In- 
directly government  influences  consumption 
mainly  by  taxation,  and  some  taxes  are  advo- 
cated principally  for  their  social  eff"ects  (see 
Taxation). 

If  the  department  of  consumption  ever 
assumes  in  the  text-books  a  position  of  co- 
ordinate importance  with  the  other  depart- 
ments, it  might  well  be  made  to  embrace 
various  other  topics  at  present  scattered 
through  ditlerent  parts  of  economics. 

Such,  for  example,  is  the  question  of  the 
poor  and  poor-laws  (see  Charity,  State), 
the  advisability  of  protecting  the  limited 
natural  resources  of  a  nation,  the  necessity  of 
considering  the  ultimate  social  effect  of  certain 
forms  of  trade  which,  for  the  time  being,  may 
be  profitable  (see  Free  Trade),  and  various 
questions  on  the  distribution  and  inheritance 
of  wealth,  e.g.  the  eff'ects  on  national  consump- 
tion of  a  system  of  peasant  proprietary. 

(6)  Lastly,  the  light  thrown  by  the  study  of 
consumption  upon  social  progress  may  be  con- 
sidered. Consumption  being  largely  deter- 
mined by  distribution,  is  itself  in  turn  one  of 
the  best  signs  of  the  way  in  which  the  national 
wealth  is  distributed.  Statistics  as  to  the 
consumption  per  head  of  various  articles  in 
diff"erent  nations,  or  in  the  same  nation  at 
diff"erent  times,  often  give  the  best  evidence 
available  on  the  wealth  of  various  classes.  In 
making  such  comparisons,  however,  regard 
must  always  be  paid  to  a  possible  change  or 
difference  in  tastes  and  habits,  and  also  to  the 
cost  of  the  various  articles  considered,  whether 
influenced  by  natural  or  governmental  causes, 
and  to  the  use  of  substitutes.  A  relative 
falling-off"  in  the  rate  of  the  consumption  of 
008*66  may  be  due  to  an  increase  in  the  use  of 
cocoa,  and  a  decrease  in  the  use  of  intoxicants 
may  be  ascribed,  not  to  diminished  consuming 
power,  but  to  higher  moral  development.  But 
when  proper  precautions  are  taken,  statistics  of 


consumption  furnish  a  good  outline  of  the 
material  life  of  the  mass  of  the  people.  The 
mere  fact,  for  example,  that  so  many  articles 
are  continuously  produced  on  a  larger  scale 
shows,  not  only  that  they  are  consumed  in 
increasing  qua  titles,  but  also  that  larger 
numbers  of  people  are  able  to  purchase  them, 
and  thus  the  contention  of  the  socialists  that, 
through  production  on  a  large  scale,  wealth  is 
being  concentrated  in  a  few  hands,  is  shoAvn  to 
be  an  error,  because  the  articles  produced  can 
only  be  consumed  when  spread  over  a  wide 
area.  In  making  comparisons  of  national 
progress  from  the  consumer's  standpoint,  it 
would  be  most  useful  if  index  numbers  based  on 
the  average  consuming  power  of  various  classes 
were  constructed  (see  Index  Numbers). 

[The  subject  of  consumption  is  specially  treated 
in  Koscher's  Political  Economy,  and  in  Schonberg's 
Handbook,  by  Professor  Lexis.  A  useful  develop- 
ment of  Jevons's  theory  is  given  in  Mr.  Wicksteed's 
Alphabet  of  Economic  Science  ;  and  in  Mr.  J.  N. 
Keynes'  Scope  and  Method  of  Political  Economy, 
at  p.  101  et  seq.,  there  is  an  interesting  discussion 
of  the  question  whether  the  consumption  of  wealth 
should  or  should  not  be  regarded  as  constituting 
a  distinct  department  of  political  economy  ;  with 
notices  of  numerous  economists  who  have  adopted 
this  arrangement.]  J.  s.  N. 

CONSUMPTION,  Taxes  on.  The  provision 
of  an  adequate  revenue  for  the  purposes  of  govern- 
ment has  from  the  earliest  times  been  effected, 
in  part,  by  means  of  taxes  on  consumable 
articles.  Adam  Smith  (  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk. 
V.  ch.  ii.  art.  iv.)  ascribes  the  invention  of 
such  taxes  to  "the  impossibility  of  taxing  the 
people  in  proportion  to  their  revenue  by  any 
capitation,"  but  it  would  appear  that  the  failure 
of  direct  imposts  in  mediaeval  times  resulted  in 
an  increase  and  extension  of  a  previously  exist- 
ing method  of  raising  revenue,  rather  than  in 
the  institution  of  a  system  which  is,  in  its 
essence,  that  of  contribution  in  kind.  Taxes 
on  consumable  commodities  have  been  com- 
mended by  economists  on  the  gi'ound  of  their 
convenience,  it  having  been  found  possible  by 
means  of  such  taxes  ' '  to  raise  a  considerable  re- 
venue .  .  .  the  payments  of  which  by  con- 
sumers are  made  in  insensible  portions,  where 
it  would  have  been  impossible  to  collect  the 
same  amount  by  direct  taxation  at  comparatively 
long  intervals.  Taxation  is  in  this  respect  like 
bleeding"  (Professor  Nicholson,  Encyclopedia 
Britannica,  9th  ed.,  art.  "Taxation").  It  has 
also  been  urged  in  favour  of  this  system  of 
taxation  that  it  may  be  assessed  so  as  to  leave 
no  doubt  concerning  what  ought  to  be  paid,  or 
when  it  ought  to  be  paid,  and  Montesquieu 
{Esprit  des  Lois,  liv.  xii.  cap.  vii.)  says  in 
favour  of  taxes  on  commodities  that  they  "are 
felt  the  least  by  the  people  because  no  formal 
demand  is  made  for  them.  They  can  be  so 
wisely  contrived  that  the  people  shall  scarcely 
know   that   they   pay   them."     On  the   othei 


396 


CONSUMPTION— CONTIN^I^ONTP  A.BANT^^ 


hand,  while  Ricardo  affirms  that  a  tax  on 
necessaries  will  not  be  borne  by  the  working 
classes  {Principles  of  Political  Economy,  ch. 
xvi.),  Adam  Smith  distinguishes  between  the 
eflfect  of  taxes  on  necessaries  and  on  luxuries, 
observing  {Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  v.  ch.  ii. 
art.  iv.)  that  in  the  former  case  the  tflx  will 
eventually  be  shifted  to  other  shoulders  than 
those  of  the  immediate  consumer.  M'Culloch 
adds  that  the  process  by  which  this  is  brought 
about  is  slow  and  difficult,  and  that  "there  is 
in  most  cases  a  great  risk  in  imposing  or  in- 
creasing taxes  on  necessaries,  lest  the  wages  of 
labour  should  not  sustain  a  corresponding  rise, 
and  the  condition  of  the  labourers  be  in  conse- 
quence depressed."  Professor  Sidgwick  empha- 
sises the  fact  that  the  taxation  of  commodities 
is  "incompatible  with  any  very  exact  equalisa- 
tion of  the  burden  of  taxation,"  but  he  adds 
that  the  system  has  "  the  merit  of  avoiding  the 
worst  inequalities  which  taxation  proportioned 
to  income  would  cause  .  .  .  since  it  enables 
those  persons  whose  needs  are  greatest  to  diminish 
their  share  of  taxation  by  abstinence  from  cus- 
tomary luxuries  "  {Principles  of  Political  Econ- 
omy,  1883,  pp.  565,  566). 

It  is  generally  believed,  with  Adam  Smith, 
that  taxes  on  commodities  take  out  or  keep  out 
of  the  pockets  of  the  people  more  than  almost 
any  other  taxes,  in  proportion  to  what  they 
bring  in  to  the  state,  although  it  may  be 
doubted  whether,  under  a  well-ordered  tariff  and 
modern  administration,  any  serious  ^  objection 
arises  under  this  head  (see  Cost  of  Collection 
OF  Taxes). 

Taxes  on  commodities  have  also  been  resorted 
to  for  other  purposes  than  the  provision  of 
revenue,  e.g.  the  discouragement  of  the  con- 
sumption of  intoxicating  liquors,  and  the  pro- 
tection or  encouragement  of  home  industries  by 
means  of  the  imposition  of  duties  either  on  im- 
ported foreign  manufactures  or  on  raw  materials 
sent  abroad  (see  Protection).  Such  taxes 
may  be  levied  either  by  the  collection  of  a  duty 
from  the  importer,  producer,  or  manufacturer, 
in  which  case  it  is  usual  where  the  duty  is  at 
all  heavy  to  permit  the  dutiable  articles  to  be 
warehoused  under  the  supervision  of  the  revenue 
officers  until  such  time  as  delivery  for  consump- 
tion takes  place,  or  by  the  collection  of  an 
annual  licence  duty  from  the  person  using  the 
article,  as  in  the  case  of  carriages  and  guns. 
The  imposition  of  a  licence  duty  in  respect  of 
the  manufacture  of  or  dealing  in  certain  articles 
has  practically  the  same  effect  as  a  duty  on  the 
articles  themselves. 

As  to  the  incidence  of  duties  on  commodities, 
the  summary  of  opinion  given  by  Professor 
Nicholson  in  the  article  above  referred  to  may 
be  cited :  **  Where  production  takes  place  under 
free  competition,  the  tax  will,  owing  to  the 
tendency  of  profits  to  equality,  be  transferred 
to    the    consumer,    but  when    the    article    is 


practically  monopolised,  a  tax  must  fall  on  the 
monopolist."  For  a  more  minute  discussion  of 
these  cases,  see  Pantaleoni,  Theoria  della  pres- 
sione  tributaria,  and  Cournot,  Eecherches,  ch.  vi. 

The  majority  of  the  leading  treatises  on  political 
economy  specifically  deal  with  this  subject  (see 
also  Custom,  Customs  Duties  ;  Excise),    t.  h.  b. 

CONTINUATION  or  CONTANGO.  Under 
the  word  Backwardation  {q.v.)  the  process 
by  which  a  person  who,  being  unable  to  deliver 
stock  which  he  has  sold,  borrows  it,  has  been 
already  described.  In  the  same  way,  one  who 
has  bought  stock  or  shares  which  he  cannot  pay 
for  is  obliged  to  borrow  the  money,  and  this  he 
can  often  do  from  the  person  who  has  sold  the 
stock  or  securities  in  question.  But  the  seller 
charges  him  a  "  contango."  Under  normal  cir- 
cumstances the  contango,  or  rate  of  continuation, 
somewhat  exceeds  the  ordinary  rate  of  interest 
at  which  money  can  be  borrowed  from  the 
banks,  for  the  banks  do  not  lend  to  the  full 
market- value  of  the  securities  lodged  with  them, 
whereas  one  who  "contangoes"  retains  securi- 
ties to  the  bare  amount  of  his  loan,  and  has  no 
claim  until  the  next  settling  day  against  the 
person  whom  he  trusted  to  fulfil  the  bargain. 
A  great  deal  of  business  is  done  by  money- 
dealers,  wfio  borrow  at  a  low  rate  and  re-lend 
on  the  stock  exchange  in  this  way.  A.  E. 

CONTINENTAL  SYSTEM.  The  great  war 
from  1803  to  1814  was  primarily  a  duel  be- 
tween France  and  England,  in  which  the  other 
powers  of  Europe  were  engaged,  sometimes  on 
one  side,  sometimes  on  the  other.  But  thei 
war  had  this  peculiar  characteristic,  thati 
neither  of  the  two  chief  belligerents  could 
attack  each  other  directly.  The  battle  of 
Austerlitz  annihilated  the  coalition  which  Pitt 
had  formed,  and  secured  the  supremacy  of  ^ 
Napoleon  on  the  mainland.  Almost  at  the 
same  time  Nelson's  victory  at  Trafalgar 
destroyed  the  naval  power  of  France,  and  put 
an  end  to  all  ideas  of  invading  England.  Thus 
the  two  states  were  forced  to  fall  back  upon 
indirect  modes  of  warfare,  and  each  sought  to 
cripple  the  other's  commerce.  The  measures 
adopted  by  Napoleon  for  this  purpose  in  his 
famous  decrees  from  Berlin  and  Milan  have 
received  the  name  of  the  "  continental  system." 
England  retaliated  by  a  series  of  orders  in, 
council,  of  which  the  two  most  important  were 
issued  in  1807. 

There  was  no  novelty  in  the  questions  raised  i 
or  the  means  adopted  in  this  war,  except  the 
vast  scale  on  which  mercantile  hostilities  were ' 
carried  on.  In  all  the  wars  of  the  18th 
century  England  had  sought  to  cut  off  France 
from  commerce  with  its  colonies.  The  result 
had  been  to  throw  this  trade  into  the  hands  oi 
neutral  powers.  To  prevent  this,  England  had  j 
laid  down  the  rule  of  1756,  that  a  neutral  had  J 
no  right  to  relieve  a  belligerent  by  carrying  on  , 
a  trade  in  time  of  war,  from  which  it  would  be 


nc-bTiTTriNENTAL  SYSTEM 


397 


excluded  during  peace.  The  harshness  with 
which  England  employed  its  maritime  ascend- 
ency to  enforce  this  rule  induced  the  states  of 
northern  Europe  to  conclude  an  Armed  Neu- 
trality {q.v.)  in  1780,  and  again  in  1800.  The 
principles  which  they  asserted  were  that  ' '  free 
ships  make  free  goods,"  that  a  neutral  may 
Carry  any  commodities,  except  such  as  are  con- 
traband of  war,  and  that  a  blockade  can  only 
be  respected  when  it  is  effectual. 

The  essential  difficulty  of  measures  against 
the  commerce  of  an  enemy  was  that  they 
must  necessarily  affect  the  interests  of  neiitral 
states.  This  difficulty  became  very  prominent 
in  the  war  with  Napoleon.  On  IGth  ]\Iay 
1806,  the  Whig  ministry  in  England  notified 
to  the  ministers  of  neutral  powers  that  the 
whole  coast  from  the  Elbe  to  Brest  was  block- 
aded against  the  introduction  of  contraband  of 
war  or  of  goods  belonging  to  the  enemies  of 
England,  while  the  coast  from  Ostend  to  the 
Seine  was  subject  to  a  rigorous  blockade.  This 
measure  gave  Napoleon  a  pretext  for  issuing 
the  Berlin  decree  on  21st  November  1806. 
The  preamble  asserted  that  England  had 
violated  the  law  of  nations  :  (1)  by  extending 
to  private  property  on  sea  a  right  of  capture 
which  on  land  only  applies  to  property  of  the 
state  ;  (2)  by  extending  to  unfortified  towns 
and  ports  a  right  of  blockade  which  is  only 
applicable  to  fbrtilied  places  ;  (3)  by  declaring 
blockaded  places  before  which  there  is  not  a 
single  vessel,  and  "places  which  all  the  united 
forces  would  be  incapable  of  blockading,  such 
as  entire  coasts  and  a  whole  emi)ire."  On  tlieso 
grounds  he  decrees  that — (1)  the  British  Islands 
are  in  a  state  of  blockade  ;  (2)  all  commerce 
with  them  is  prohibited  ;  (3)  every  English  sub- 
ject in  countries  occupied  by  French  troops,  or 
those  of  their  allies,  will  be  made  prisoners  of 
war  ;  (4)  all  property  of  an  English  subject  is 
lawful  prize  ;  (5)  all  merchandise  belonging  to 
England,  or  obtained  from  her  manufactories  or 
colonies,  is  lawful  prize  ;  (6)  no  ship  coming 
direct  from  England  or  English  colonies  shall 
be  received  in  any  port. 

This  measure  went  far  beyond  anything 
which  England  had  ever  attempted,  and  was 
the  more  preposterous  as  France  had  no  naval 
power  by  which  it  could  be  enforced.  Probably 
the  wisest  course  for  England  would  have  been 
to  leave  France  to  meet  the  discontent  of  her 
subjects  and  allies,  and  the  hostility  of  neutral 
states,  of  which  the  United  States  were  the 
most  important.  In  that  case  the  Berlin 
decree  would  almost  certainly  have  been  a  dead 
letter.  But  if  the  continental  system  owed  its 
origin  to  the  action  of  France,  it  owed  its 
efficiency  to  the  action  of  England.  Without 
waiting  to  see  what  attitude  would  be  assumed 
;  by  neutrals,  the  Whig  government  issued  an 
:i  order  in  council  on  7th  January  1807.  After 
:'       reciting  the  purport  of  the  Berlin  decree,  it 


ordered  that  no  vessel  should  be  allowed  to 
trade  between  one  port  and  another  belonging 
to  France  or  her  allies  ;  that  neutral  vessels 
attempting  such  a  voyage  should  be  warned  by 
English  men-of-war  and  privateers  ;  and  that 
if  they  disregarded  the  warning,  they  should 
be  captured  as  lawful  prize.  This  order  failed 
in  its  avowed  object  of  compelling  France  to 
withdraw  the  decree,  or  inducing  neutral  states 
to  insist  on  its  withdrawal.  On  the  contrary 
English  goods  in  the  north  of  Europe  were 
rigorously  confiscated  by  French  troops.  Mean- 
Avhile  the  Whig  ministry  fell,  and  the  Tories, 
who  succeeded  to  office  under  the  duke  of  Port- 
land, issued  a  second  and  far  more  stringent 
order  in  council,  on  11th  November  1807. 
This  decreed  that  all  ports  belonging  to  France 
or  her  allies,  or  to  any  country  from  which  the 
British  flag  was  excluded,  should  be  regarded 
as  in  a  state  of  blockade  ;  that  all  trade  in 
articles  produced  in  such  countries  should  be 
condemned  as  unlawful ;  and  that  every  vessel 
trading  from  or  to  such  countries,  or  carrying 
theh'  produce,  should  be  captured  as  lawful 
prize. 

Napoleon  promptly  answered  this  order  by 
the  Milan  decree,  17th  December  1807.  Its 
chief  provisions  were  as  follows  : — Every  slnp 
of  any  nation  which  submits  to  the  order  of 
11th  November  is  declared  denationalised,  and 
considered  as  British  property  ;  (2)  the  British 
Isles  are  declared  in  a  state  of  blockade  "by 
sea  as  well  as  by  land."  Every  ship  going  to 
or  from  a  port  of  England  or  English  colonies 
is  declared  to  be  good  prize  ;  (3)  these  measures 
shall  ' '  continue  to  be  in  force  until  the  British 
government  returns  to  the  principles  of  the  law 
of  nations,  which  regulates  the  relations  of 
civilised  states  in  time  of  war." 

Thus  the  continental  system,  carried  to  its 
logical  extreme  by  both  the  two  gieat  belliger- 
ents, threatened  to  pvit  a  stop  to  the  commerce 
of  the  whole  world.  It  was  of  course  im- 
possible to  enforce  with  absolute  strictness 
the  provisions  either  of  Napoleon's  decrees 
or  of  the  English  orders.  A  vast  system  of 
smuggling  was  the  inevitable  result,  and  goods 
were  carried  to  the  blockaded  ports,  though  their 
price  was  necessarily  enhanced  by  the  compara- 
tive scantiness  of  the  supply,  and  by  the  risks 
run  in  conducting  the  trade.  Perhaps  the 
most  curious  thing  is  that  this  smuggling  was 
connived  at,  and  made  a  source  of  revenue,  by 
the  two  states  who  were  responsible  for  the 
prohibitions.  Both  England  and  France  issued 
licenses  for  the  evasion  of  their  respective 
decrees.  Napoleon  is  said  to  have  amassed  by 
their  sale  the  sum  of  400,000,000  francs; 
while  in  England  the  number  of  commercial 
licenses  mounted  from  791  in  1805  to  18,356 
ia  1810. 

Although  thus  limited  by  licensed  and  un- 
licensed evasions,  the  results  of  the  continental 


398 


CONTINENTAL  SYSTEM— CONTRABAND 


system  can  hardly  be  over-estimated.  It  was 
a  principal  cause  of  the  ultimate  fall  of 
Napoleon.  To  render  the  system  efficient  and 
complete  he  must  make  himself  master  of  the 
whole  of  Europe.  This  impelled  him  to  those 
enterprises  in  Portugal  and  Spain,  and  especi- 
ally to  the  great  expedition  to  Russia, 'which 
contributed  essentially  to  ruin  his  power.  And 
again  the  sufferings  caused  among  the  peoples 
of  Europe  by  the  scarcity  and  dearness  of  com- 
modities which  they  had  learnt  to  regard  as 
necessaries  excited  a  discontent  against  French 
domination  which  had  not  existed  at  the  begin- 
ning of  the  revolutionary  conquests.  The 
French  had  always  professed  to  be  the  enemies 
of  dynasties  but  the  friends  of  the  people,  and 
their  professions  had  long  been  believed.  The 
continental  system  destroyed  that  belief,  and 
the  Napoleonic  empire  fell  before  the  popular 
hostility  which  his  measures  against  England 
had  excited. 

With  regard  to  England,  the  policy  or  im- 
policy of  the  orders  in  council  was  hotly  debated 
at  the  time,  and  can  hardly  yet  be  regarded  as 
a  matter  on  which  opinion  is  absolutely  formed. 
That  they  did  in  the  end  serve  their  purpose  as 
measures  of  hostility  against  Napoleon  is 
absolutely  demonstrable.  But  they  did  this  at 
considerable  cost.  In  the  first  place  they 
inflicted  enormous  hardships  upon  English 
manufacturers,  who  were  to  a  great  extent 
deprived  of  the  market  for  their  produce.  No 
doubt  these  hardships  were  lessened  by  the 
system  of  licenses,  but  this  in  itself  is  indefens- 
ible on  any  principles  of  commercial  morality. 
The  almost  unanimous  petitions  from  the  chief 
manufacturing  towns  prove  that  they  had  un- 
doubted grievances  to  complain  of,  and  that 
these  were,  to  a  great  extent,  due  to  the  policy 
of  the  government. 

But  the  most  harmful  result  to  England  was 
undoubtedly  the  quarrel  with  the  United 
States.  It  was  inevitable  that  the  enmity  of 
neutrals  should  be  directed  less  against  the 
state  which  originated  the  continental  system 
than  against  that  which  had  the  power  to 
enforce  it.  In  1808  Congress  passed  an  act  of 
embargo,  prohibiting  aU  intercourse  with  Eng- 
land and  France  as  long  as  the  two  countries 
maintained  their  decrees.  In  the  hope  of  con- 
ciliating the  last  great  power  which  was  not 
hostile,  England  modified  the  orders  in  council 
in  April  1809,  by  opening  to  American  vessels 
the  Baltic,  the  North  Sea,  part  of  Italy,  and 
the  foreign  possessions  of  the  Dutch.  But  the 
quarrel  was  not  healed,  and  it  was  further 
aggravated  by  disputes  arising  from  the  English 
claim  to  search  American  vessels  for  deserters 
from  the  navy.  To  make  matters  worse, 
Napoleon  offered  to  withdraw  his  decrees,  on 
condition  that  England  should  revoke  the 
orders  in  council  and  abandon  ''the  new  prin- 
ciples of  blockade  which  they  had  laid  down. " 


To  this  the  English  ministers  would  not  agree, 
and  at  the  end  of  1810  the  American  ambas- 
sador quitted  England. 

The  loss  of  the  American  market,  and  the 
prospect  of  a  quarrel  with  the  United  States, 
increased  the  ill-feeling  in  England  against  the 
orders.  The  Whigs,  who  were  responsible  for 
the  policy  in  its  origin,  now  turned  round  and 
denounced  it.  At  last,  in  1812,  Brougham 
carried  a  motion  in  the  Commons  for  an  inquiry 
before  a  committee  of  the  whole  house.  The 
evidence  was  almost  conclusive,  and  after  a 
one-sided  debate,  the  government  avoided  a 
division  by  announcing  that  the  orders  would 
be  abandoned.  They  were  repealed  by  an  order 
of  23rd  June  1812.  But  it  was  too  late  to 
avoid  the  war  with  America,  which  lasted  for 
two  years  with  little  credit  to  either  country, 
and  was  terminated  by  the  treaty  of  Ghent  in 
1814.  (See  Blockade  ;  International  Law  ; 
Paper  Blockade.) 

[The  Berlin  and  Milan  decrees  will  be  found 
in  the  Moniteur :  the  orders  in  council  in  the 
London  Gazette.  They  are  quoted  in  extenso 
by  Leone  Levi,  History  of  British  Commerce, 
part  ii.  oh.  iv.,  Appendix.  —  See  also  Alison, 
History  of  Europe,  vol.  viii.  ch.  1. — Life  and 
Tim^  of  l^ord  Brougham,  by  himself,  vol.  ii.  ch 
X.,  and  Speeches,  vol.  i. — Spencer  Walpole,  Life  of 
the  Right  Hon.  Spencer  Perceval,  vol.  ii.  ch.  viii.— 
For  the  fullest  criticism  of  the  policy  of  the  orders 
in  council,  see  Hansard,  Parliamentary  Debates, 
sub.  ann.,  1812.]  R.  l. 

CONTRABAND.  A  term  used  to  denote 
articles  in  which  trade  is  carried  on  contrary  to 
the  provisions  of  (a)  international  law  and 
comity,  (&)  the  revenue  laws  of  a  nation. 

(a)  It  has  been  generally  admitted  amongst 
civilised  nations  that  the  subjects  of  a  neutral 
power  are  entitled  to  continue  to  trade  with 
those  of  powers  at  war  with  each  other  without 
rendering  their  goods  liable  to  capture  and  for- 
feiture. In  order  to  enable  this  right  to  be 
exercised  without  detriment  to  the  position  of 
the  belligerents,  international  jurists  have 
endeavoured,  with  some  limited  success,  to 
lay  down  the  rules  which  should  be  observed 
in  trade  so  carried  on,  and  those  rules  have 
frequently  been  embodied  in  treaties.  It  is 
now  well  established  that  the  carriage  and  sale 
to  a  belligerent  of  instruments  and  materials 
which  are,  by  their  own  nature,  fit  to  be  used 
in  war,  are  inconsistent  with  neutrality.  "If," 
says  Lord  Grenville  {Letters  of  Sulpicius,  p.  26), 
"  I  have  wrested  my  enemy's  sword  from  his 
hands,  the  bystander  who  furnishes  him  with  a 
fresh  weapon  can  have  no  pretence  to  be  con- 
sidered as  a  neutral  in  the  contest."  All  such 
instruments  or  materials  are  therefore  regarded 
as  contraband,  or  merces  banno  interdicta,  and 
they  are  liable  to  seizure  and  forfeiture  if  cap- 
tured in  course  of  conveyance  to  a  belligerent. 
Another  class  of  articles  is  said  to  be  ancipitis 
usits,  i.e.  of  variable  application,  being  of  snch 


CONTEABAND— CONTRACT 


399 


a  character  that  it  cannot  be  exactly  determined 
whether  they  are  intended  for  belligerent  or  for 
ordinary  commercial  purposes.  Amongst  these 
articles  are  coal,  naval  stores,  timber,  and  tar. 
The  decision  whether  articles  of  this  class  are  to 
be  deemed  contraband  will  rest  with  the  court 
before  which  the  goods  are  brought,  when  regarfi" 
should  be  had  to  the  destination  of  the  ship, 
the  purposes  for  which  the  goods  are  intended, 
the  position  and  cliaracter  of  the  war,  and  the 
regulations  and  treaty  obligations  laid  down  or 
accepted  by  the  belligerent.  Even,  however, 
if  articles  of  this  class  are  held  to  be  contra- 
band, they  are  not  ordinarily  subject  to  seizure, 
but  merely  to  the  right  of  pre-emption,  under 
which  their  full  value,  with,  in  some  cases,  the 
ordinary  mercantile  profit,  is  paid  for  the 
articles  if  the  belligerent  desires  to  retain  them. 
This  right  is  described  by  Sir  Robert  Phillimore 
as  "a  fair  compromise  between  the  right  of  the 
belligerent  to  seize,  and  the  claim  of  the  neutral 
to  export  his  native  commodities,  though  imme- 
diately subservient  to  the  purposes  of  hostility" 
{Commentaries  upon  International  Law,  vol.  iii. 
2nd  edition,  p.  451).  Within  these  limitations  as 
to  commodities,  and  subject  to  absolute  prohibi- 
tion of  commerce  with  besieged  and  blockaded 
places,  "it  cannot  be  too  emphatically  declared 
that  it  is  the  unquestionable  right  of  the  neutral 
to  carry  on  a  general  trade  with  the  belligerents" 
(ihid.  p.  387). 

{h)  The  term  "  contraband  "  is  also  applied  to 
goods  in  respect  of  which  the  requirements  of 
the  revenue  laws  of  a  country  have  not  been 
complied  with,  and  which  are  liable  to  seizure 
hereunder.  Section  177  of  the  Customs  Laws 
Consolidation  Act,  1886(39&40  Vict.  c.  36), 
provides  that  goods  unshipped  without  payment 
of  duty,  prohibited  goods  (whether  imported  or 
shipped  for  exportation),  goods  illegally  removed 
from  a  warehouse,  goods  concealed  on  board  a 
ship  or  boat,  and  goods  packed  therewith  for 
the  purpose  of  concealing  them — are  all  liable 
to  forfeiture,  and  a  similar  provision  is  enacted 
(§  179)  in  respect  of  prohibited  goods  found  on 
board  or  attached  to  any  vessel  or  boat  found 
on  arriving  within  the  United  Kingdom,  or 
within  three  leagues  thereof.  The  seizures  may 
be  disposed  of  as  the  commissioners  of  customs 
direct.  The  excise  acts  contain  similar  enact- 
ments with  respect  to  excisable  commodities. 

In  1911  the  customs  officers  made  6630 
seizures,  amounting  in  the  aggregate  to  1 0 , 6 4 9  tb 
of  tobacco  and  cigars,  and  143  gallons  of  spirits. 
The  produce  of  these  seizures  is,  as  a  general  rule, 
sold,  if  a  price  over  and  above  the  duty  can  be 
obtained,  and  the  articles  are  legally  saleable. 

[Phillimore's  Commentaries  on  International 
Law. — Wheaton's  Elements  of  International  Law. 
— Hall's  International  Law,  2nd  ed.,  1884,  pp. 
598-637. — As  to  offences  against  the  revenue  laws 
see  the  annual  reports  of  the  commissioners  of 
customs  and  inland  revenue.]  T.  H.  e. 


CONTRACT.  The  origin  of  contracts  must 
be  co-eval  \vith  the  first  commencement  of  econo- 
mic relations  among  mankind.  The  simplest 
actions  of  daily  life,  even  amongst  the  least  civil- 
ised communities,  are  really  forms  of  contract. 
Exchange  and  barter,  the  earliest  and  crudest 
outcome  of  the  law  of  supply  and  demand,  is 
essentially  a  contract.  The  man  who  can  make 
a  rude  plough  finds  himself,  by  the  possession  of 
that  faculty,  independent  of  the  necessity  of  en- 
gaging directly  in  agricultural  pursuits  to  obtain 
a  share  of  the  fruits  of  the  earth.  This  element- 
ary example  will  suffice  to  demonstrate  the 
primary  bearing  of  the  doctrine  of  contracts  on 
economic  questions.  For  even  in  this  there  is 
traceable  one  of  the  great  and  fundamental 
principles  of  contract  in  its  relation  to  political 
economy,  namely,  the  power  it  bestows  of  ob- 
taining at  once  a  personal  benefit,  through 
entering  into  an  engagement  ultimately  to 
discharge  the  original  obligation.  In  more 
advanced  conditions  of  society,  the  principle 
assumes  more  extended  development ;  land- 
owners lease  land  to  farmers  possessing  skill 
and  capacity  requisite  to  till  that  land  to  ad- 
vantage, capitalists  advance  money  to  merchants 
to  be  employed  in  trade  to  produce  profits  ex- 
ceeding the  rate  of  interest  demanded,  but  the 
principle  is  still  the  same.  It  is  obvious  that 
to  induce  a  man  to  entrust  liis  property  to 
another,  to  part  with  his  present  enjoyment 
and  use  of  it  for  the  sake  of  future  advantage, 
the  certainty  of  that  future  advantage  must  be 
secured  to  him,  he  must  have  a  hold  over  the 
person  to  whom  he  has  entrusted  it,  he  must, 
to  carry  on  his  business  and  arrange  fresh  com- 
binations, be  able  to  reckon  with  confidence  upon 
the  return  to  him  of  his  capital,  together  with 
the  increment  which  is  the  result  of  its  tempor- 
ary alienation.  It  is  the  establisliment  of  this 
confidence,  the  basis  of  any  system  of  credit, 
which  is  the  aim  and  object  of  the  law  of  con- 
tracts. The  methods  by  which  the  law  seeks 
to  attain  this  security  are  various.  For  two 
objects,  apt  to  clash,  have  to  be  borne  in  mind. 
On  the  one  hand,  that  of  ensuring  performance 
of,  inspiring  confidence  in,  the  fulfilment  of  the 
contract ;  on  the  other,  that  of  encouraging  the 
freedom  of  contract  by  attaching  thereto  such 
safeguards  that  persons  may  readily  bind  them- 
selves, knowing  that  the  law  will  protect  them, 
and  that  precautionary  measures  exist  which 
will  prevent  undue  advantage  being  taken  of 
ignorance,  necessity,  inadvertence,  want  of 
proper  advice,  or  lapse  of  time  ;  and  that  fraud, 
if  it  exists,  will  invalidate  any  contract,  how- 
ever formal  and  solemn.  To  turn  to  concrete 
examples.  Among  the  first  class,  or  what  may 
be  termed  the  promisee's  safeguards,  may  be 
enumerated  the  rules  by  which  money  due  or 
liquidated  demands  under  a  contract  can  be 
recovered  by  speedy  and  economical  process, 
such  as  that  provided  by  Order  XIV.  of  the 


400 


CONTRACT 


rules  of  the  Supreme  Court,  which  practically 
casts  the  onus  of  proving  non-liability  on  the 
defendant,  and  the  procedure  which  amerces 
damages,  assumed  to  be  commensurate  with  the 
injury  directly  or  reasonably  referable  to  the 
breach  of  the  contract,  or  where  such  damages 
afford  no  sufficient  reparation,  specific  perform- 
ance of  the  contract  itself.  The  other  class, 
which  may  be  termed  the  promisor's  protection, 
comprises  enactments,  such  as  the  statute  of 
limitations,  which  requires  that  actions  on  con- 
tracts should  be  brought  within  such  period  as 
to  render  it  probable  that  witnesses  who  can 
speak  to  what  really  took  place  may  be  still 
available ;  the  statute  of  Frauds,  rendering 
writing  necessary  for  proof  of  contracts  attaining 
a  certain  degree  of  importance  or  extending  over 
a  specified  period  ;  the  whole  doctrine  of  the 
limitation  of  the  contractual  powers  of  infants 
and  married  women,  the  equitable  rules  which 
will  in  fitting  cases  set  aside  or  modify  un- 
conscionable bargains  with  reversioners  or  per- 
sons whose  immediate  and  pressing  needs  impair 
their  liberty  of  action,  and  finally  the  great 
principle  that  fraud  invalidates  everything. 

In  certain  exceptional  cases  the  legislature 
goes  even  further  than  this,  and  adopts  a  course 
which  must  always  be  open  to  criticism  and 
discussion.  It  passes  an  act  to  benefit  a  par- 
ticular class,  such  for  instance  as  the  Agricultural 
Holdings  Act  of  1883,  or  the  Ground  Game  Act 
of  1880,  and  then  provides  that  it  shall  not  be 
competent  for  any  member  of  the  class  intended 
to  be  benefited  to  contract  himself  out  of  the 
act.  How  far  this  interference  with  freedom 
of  contract  is  justified  must  always  be  an  open 
question.  It  is  never  permissible  save  in  the 
interest  of  a  class  admittedly  improvident  or 
prone  to  sacrifice  future  advantage  for  imme- 
diate gratification,  such  for  example  as  sailors. 
But  e"vien  in  such  cases,  members  of  the  class 
intended  to  be  benefited  must  occasionally  lose 
good  opportunities  by  reason  of  the  fetters  so 
imposed  on  their  contracting  powers.  Take 
the  case  of  a  farmer  willing  to  take  a  farm  at  a 
lower  rent  if  he  could  renounce  the  benefit  of 
the  Ground  Game  Act,  having  no  inclination  to 
avail  himself  of  the  sporting  reservation  it 
ensures  him,  and  possessing  a  well-founded  con- 
fidence that  his  landlord,  from  his  own  tastes 
and  interests,  to  say  nothing  of  his  regard  for 
an  obligation  assumed,  would  never  permit 
ground  game  to  increase  to  the  prejudice  of  the 
tenant's  occupation  of  the  farm.  It  certainly 
seems  hard  that  the  parties  should  not  be  per- 
mitted to  regulate  their  relations  in  accordance 
with  their  own  wishes  and  their  mutual  interests. 
But  the  justification  of  such  measures  is  to  be 
found,  if  at  all,  in  the  general  interest  of  the 
community  and  the  welfare  of  the  class  specially 
concerned,  and  for  one  case  where  the  rule  might 
probably  be  relaxed  with  advantage,  there  would 
be  many  where  the  deviation  would  produce 


ultimate  disadvantage  to  one  party.  Some 
instances  of  legislative  interference  with  freedom 
of  contract  seem,  however,  to  be  entirely  bene- 
ficial, such  for  instance  as  the  Truck  Acts,  and 
the  legislation  respecting  the  employment  of 
women  and  children  in  mines  and  factories, 
(see  Children's  Labour,  and  Factory  Acts.) 
An  interference  with  contracts,  frequently  un 
justifiable,  is  that  of  ex  post  facto  legislation, 
enactments  which  set  aside  or  modify  existing 
contracts,  not  on  the  gi'ound  of  any  inherent 
disability  or  irregularity  existing  at  the  time 
the  contract  was  entered  into,  not  on  any  sugges- 
tion that  the  parties  were  not  of  competent  and 
freely  consenting  mind  when  they  contracted, 
or  that  the  contract  was  in  any  way  tainted 
with  fraud,  but  on  the  plea  that  since  that  date 
circumstances  have  altered,  that  something  has 
supervened  which  renders  it  equitable  or  desir- 
able that  its  terms  should  be  reconsidered  or 
readjusted  without  the  consent  of  at  least  one 
of  the  parties  thereto.  Whether  such  circum- 
stances exist  or  not  in  any  particular  case,  or 
whatever  estimate  may  be  made  of  the  justice 
or  the  policy  of  such  a  measure,  appears  alto- 
gether outside  the  economic  questions  involved. 
If  good  is  done  in  any  particular  case,  the  benefit 
is  immeasiirably  outweighed  by  the  danger  of 
the  precedent,  by  the  general  sense  of  insecurity 
induced,  and  the  shock  to  confidence  in  the 
sanctity  of  contract  occasioned  thereby.  In- 
stances are  not  far  to  seek.  Irish  rents  in  recent 
times,  and  commercial  obligations  in  France 
during  the  stress  of  the  Franco-German  war,  have 
been  the  subject  of  this  sort  oi  ex  post  facto  legisla- 
tion, and  however  widely  opinions  may  difler  as 
to  the  degree  of  justification  afforded  in  each 
case  by  the  exigencies  of  the  situation,  the  pre- 
cedent cannot  from  an  economic  point  of  view 
be  regarded  as  otherwise  than  dangerous.  Such 
legislation  has  been  likened  to  a  convulsion  of 
nature  which  by  destroying  the  subject  matter 
of  a  contract  renders  the  fulfilment  thereof  im- 
possible and  takes  away  in  ordinary  cases  any 
right  to  damages  for  the  breach  ;  and  the  simile 
indicates  the  legal  attitude  towards  exceptional 
measures  of  this  nature.  A  question  of  mixed 
economics  and  law  in  relation  to  contract  which 
is  at  present  taking  definite  and  practical  form 
is  how  far  the  law  will  intervene  to  limit  com- 
binations which,  having  as  their  objects  the 
attainment  of  complete  or  partial  monopolies 
and  the  elimination  of  healthy  competition,  may 
tend  to  enhance  the  price  of  articles  of  daily  ne* 
cessity,  to  the  benefit  of  the  few  and  the  prejudice 
of  the  many.  Contracts  made  with  a  view  to 
such  an  end  may  be  declared  void  as  between 
the  parties  both  in  this  country  and  in  America, 
but  community  of  interest  secures  adherence  to . 
the  terms  of  such  contracts  and  the  remedy,  if  I 
any,  must  be  brought  to  bear  from  outside. 
As  stated  by  Lord  Coleridge  in  the  recent  case 
of  the   Mogul   Steamship  Company,   Limited, 


CONTRACT,  LAW  OF 


401 


t;.  M'Gregor,  Gow,  and  Co.,  21,  Q.B.D.,  544, 
in  a  judgment  affirmed  by  the  H.  of  L.  (92) 
Appeal  Cases  25,  the  line  which  separates  the 
reasonable  selfishness  of  traders  from  wrong  and 
malice  is  one  difficult  to  draw  in  words.  But 
the  law  of  conspiracy  is  very  untrammelled  and 
general  in  its  operation,  embracing  in  its  wides^ 
definition  any  combination  of  two  or  more  per- 
sons for  the  accomplishment  of  anything  which 
in  the  opinion  of  the  court  is  detrimental  to  the 
public  welfare,  and  it  will  probably  come  to  be 
judicially  settled  before  long  how  far  salt  unions, 
flour  and  coal  unions,  and  the  whole  develop- 
ment of  the  ring  system,  fall  within  the  scope 
of  the  criminal  law  under  this  head. 

The  intervention  of  bankruptcy  law  to  pre- 
clude the  full  enforcement  of  contracts  stands  on 
a  different  footing  (see  Bankruptcy  Law).  The 
possibility  of  bankruptcy  is  always  a  remote 
potential  incident  of  every  contract,  from  the 
inception  of  which  it  must  be  taken  to  have 
been  in  the  contemplation  of  the  parties  and 
accepted  by  them ;  moreover,  the  obloquy  and 
disabilities  involved  by  becoming  bankrupt, 
coupled  with  the  necessary  surrender  of  all 
existing,  and  until  discharge,  all  accruing, 
property  constitute  a  sufficient  deterrent  and 
punishment  to  warrant  an  interference  which 
is  after  all  more  in  tlie  interest  of  the  body 
of  creditors  than  of  the  bankrupt. 

Confidence  in  the  fulfilment  of  contracts 
renders  possible  the  replacement  of  a  very  large 
proportion  of  the  circulating  medium  of  a 
country  by  the  employment  of  paper  to  re- 
present the  gold  or  silver  which  would  otherv/ise 
be  required.  Bank-notes  are  merely  contracts 
to  pay,  yet  the  firm  belief  in  the  validity  of  the 
contract  supports  a  circulation  adequate  for  the 
wants  of  the  country,  with  the  assistance  only 
of  coin  representing  a  comparatively  small  pro- 
portion of  the  outstanding  liability,  and  so 
with  bills  and  promissory  notes  ;  though  only 
contracts,  yet,  backed  by  the  credit  of  the 
parties  to  them,  they  take,  during  their  currency, 
the  place  of  coin. 

So  again,  the  entire  fabric  of  legitimate  co- 
operation and  combination,  of  partnerships,  the 
utilisation  of  capital  and  organisation  of  labour, 
would  be  impossible  were  it  not  for  the  doctrine 
of  contracts  and  its  practical  availability.  A 
firm  of  contractors,  themselves  bound  by  con- 
tract to  unite  their  energies  and  capital,  or 
deriving  that  capital  from  others  by  means  of 
conti'act,  undertake  under  contract  important 
works  for  a  body  of  persons  who  again,  as  a 
company,  combine  their  capital  under  the 
provisions  of  a  contract  of  association,  the 
contractors  make  subcontracts  with  managers, 
foremen,  and  workmen  for  their  respective 
services,  with  producers,  carriers,  shipowners, 
j  and  manufacturers  for  the  supply  and  carriage 
I  of  the  requisite  materials  and  plant,  other 
con  traces  are  entered  into  with  landowners 
VOL.  I. 


for  the  site  to  be  occupied,  and  so  by  the 
intervention  of  a  series  of  contracts,  an  enter- 
prise is  carried  through  which  would  be 
absolutely  impossible  without  such  machinery. 
Employment  is  found  directly  or  indirectly  for 
a  large  number  of  persons,  and  money  is  put 
into  circulation  through  the  most  remunerative 
and  beneficial  channels. 

As  we  have  seen  that  the  principle  of  contract 
helped  to  supply  the  simplest  wants  of  early 
economic  society,  so  it  keeps  pace  and  expands 
with  the  increasing  needs  of  advancing  civilisa- 
tion. By  an  inherent  power  of  development, 
without  any  moving  cause  other  than  men's 
recognition  of  its  necessity  and  appreciation  of 
its  efficacy,  it  rises  to  every  fresh  occasion,  and 
almost  insensibly  permeates  daily  life  to  the 
welfare  and  progress  of  society  at  large.  ^ 

[Addison  on  Contracts. — Chitty  on  Contracts. — 
Pollock's  Law  of  Contracts. — Anson  on  Contracts.'\ 

J.  R.  p. 

Contract,  Law  of.  A  contract  is  a  legally 
binding  promise  made  by  one  or  more  persons 
to  another  person  or  other  persons,  to  do  some 
act,  to  forbear  from  some  act,  or  to  suffer 
some  act  to  be  done,  for  the  benefit  of  such 
other  person  or  persons.  Such  a  promise, 
whether  legally  binding  or  not,  is  called  an 
agreement,  and  an  agreement  becomes  a  contract 
if  the  following  requirements  are  complied  with  : 

(1)  the  promise  must  be  intended  to  create  a 
legal  relation  between  the  parties  (e.g.  a  promise 
to  dine  at  a  friend's  house  is  not  a  contract)  ; 

(2)  the  parties  must  be  capable  of  contracting 
(e.g.  the  agi-eements  of  infants  and  lunatics  are 
mostly  invalid,  and  a  married  woman  having 
no  separate  estate  is  incapable  of  contracting)  ; 

(3)  the  contents  of  the  agreement  must  have 
been  submitted  by  the  one  side  to  the  other 
(otfer),  and  must  have  been  assented  to  by  the 
latter  in  an  unambiguous  and  unqualified 
manner  (acceptance)  ;  (4)  the  agreement  must 
not  be  entered  into  for  an  unlawful  or  immoral 
object  {e.g.  an  agreement  not  to  exercise  a  certain 
trade  without  any  limit  as  to  space  is  invalid, 
as  being  in  general  restraint  of  trade,  and  there- 
fore against  public  policy;  an  agreement  to 
commit  an  indictable  offence  is  similarly  void, 
and  there  are  numerous  other  instances)  ;  (5) 
the  contract  must  either  be  made  by  deed  {i.e. 
signed,  sealed,  and  delivered  by  the  promising 
party  or  parties),  or  it  must  be  supported  by  a 
"valuable  consideration." 

A  contract  made  by  deed  is  called  a  contract 
under  seal  or  a  specialty  ;  contracts  not  made 
by  deed  are  called  simple  contracts  or  parol 
contracts.  A  valuable  consideration  may  consist 
in  a  benefit  accruing  to  the  promising  party  or 
in  a  sacrifice  made  by  the  party  to  whom  the 
promise  is  made,  in  exchange  for  the  promise. 

1  Montesquieu's  story  of  the  Troglodytes  forcibly  illus- 
trates the  dissolution  of  society  through  breach  of  con- 
tract. 

2  D 


402 


CONTRACT,  LAW  OF— CONTRIBUTION 


If,  for  instance,  A  by  contract  under  seal  pro- 
mises to  B  to  pay  liim  £500  on  a  given  day  by 
way  of  gift,  B  will  succeed  in  an  action  against 
A  if  A  fails  to  pay  at  such  date.  If,  on  the  other 
hand,  the  same  promise  be  made  by  writing 
without  seal,  1>  has  no  remedy  in  case  of  non- 
performance. I  f,  however,  A,  by  word  of  mouth, 
promises  B  to  pay  him  £500  in  two  days  in 
consideration  of  B  lending  him  a  book  for  two 
hours,  there  will  be  an  enforceable  contract,  as 
the  adequacy  of  the  consideration  is  not  inquired 
into  except  in  so  far  as  it  might  be  evidence 
of  fraud. 

An  agreement  which  satisfies  the  above-men- 
tioned requirements  is  called  a  contract ;  if, 
on  the  other  hand,  any  one  of  the  requirements 
is  not  complied  with,  the  transaction  remains 
without  any  legal  efiect,  and  the  agreement  is 
called  "void."  Void  agreements  must  be 
distinguished  from  unenforceable  and  voidable 
contracts. 

Certain  classes  of  contracts  are  not  enforce- 
able in  the  absence  of  written  evidence  as  to 
their  contents,  the  following  being  the  most 
important : — 

(1)  Under  §  4  of  the  Statute  of  Frauds 
(29  Car.  II.  c.  3). 

(a)  Contracts  by  which  an  executor  or 
administrator  assumes  personal  liability  for 
debts  owing  to  the  estate  administered  by  him. 
(b)  Contracts  of  guarantee,  (c)  Contracts  made 
in  consideration  of  marriage,  (d)  Contracts  for 
the  sale  or  purchase  of  land  or  of  any  interest  in 
land,  (e)  Contracts  not  to  be  performed  within 
a  year  from  the  date  on  which  they  are  made. 

(2)  Under  §  1 7  of  the  same  statute. 
Contracts  for  the  sale  of  goods  at  the  price  of 

£10  or  at  any  higher  price,  unless  the  goods 
have  been  partly  accepted  and  received  by  the 
buyer,  or  have  been  partly  paid  for  by  the  same. 

(3^  Contracts  arising  on  bills  of  exchange. 

(4)  Contracts  of  marine  insurance,  etc. 

The  requirement  of  writing  in  these  cases 
does  not  affect  the  validity  of  the  contract ; 
only  so  long  as  no  written  evidence  exists  the 
contract  cannot  be  proved  in  a  court  of  law  ; 
but  written  evidence  dated  from  a  time  sub- 
sequent to  the  date  of  the  contract,  if  otherwise 
in  order,  is  quite  sufficient. 

A  "  voidable  "  contract  is  one  which  may  be 
rescinded  by  one  of  the  parties,  unless  such 
party,  after  having  become  aware  of  the  circum- 
stances which  make  the  continuance  of  the 
contract  depend  on  his  option,  by  his  conduct 
or  by  express  words  shows  that  he  intends  to 
abide  by  the  agreement.  Thus,  for  instance,  a 
contract  induced  by  fraud  or  undue  influence  is 
voidable  at  the  option  of  the  defrauded  or  intimi- 
dated party. 

The  usual  remedy  for  breach  of  contract  is 
an  action  for  damages  ;  the  party  who  suffers 
loss  in  consequence  of  such  breach  is  entitled  to 
receive  compensation  in  money  from  the  party 


who  failed  to  perform  the  contract.  He  is  *'  as 
far  as  money  can  do  it  to  be  placed  in  the  same 
situation  as  if  the  contract  had  been  performed." 
The  causal  connection  between  the  non-perform- 
ance and  the  loss  must,  however,  not  be  too 
remote,  and  the  loss  must  be  of  such  a  descrip- 
tion as  might  reasonably  have  been  contemplated 
by  the  parties  when  entering  into  the  contract. 
Thus  a  person  who  sends  some  machinery  for 
repair  through  a  carrier  who  fails  to  deliver  it 
in  proper  time  cannot  claim  compensation  for 
the  loss  of  trade  arising  through  the  delay  in 
the  receipt  of  the  repaired  machinery.  If, 
however,  a  carrier  undertakes  to  cany  goods 
which  to  his  knowledge  were  meant  to  be  sold 
at  a  particular  time,  he  is  liable  for  the  damage 
done  by  loss  of  market  arising  from  a  delayed 
delivery.  In  actions  for  non-payment  of  a  debt 
nothing  more  than  the  sum  due  could  be 
recovered  formerly,  unless  there  was  an  express 
promise  to  pay  interest ;  it  is  now  provided  by 
3  &  4  William  IV.  c.  42,  §§  28,  29  that  in 
the  case  of  a  debt  payable  by  virtue  of  a  written 
instrument  interest  at  the  current  rate  may  be 
allowed  by  way  of  damages. 

The  practice  of  the  Court  of  Chancery  has 
provided  a  remedy,  in  cases  where  money  is  no 
adequate  Compensation  for  a  breach  of  contract 
in  the  shape  of  an  order  for  specific  performance. 
This  remedy  is,  however,  available  only  to  a 
very    limited    extent,    the    most    conspicuous 
instances  being  contracts  for  the  sale  of  land, 
and   even   in   the   case  of  a  contract   which, 
according  to  the  nature  of  its  subject  matter, . 
might  be  specifically  enforced,  the  court  will  not  j 
grant  a  decree  unless  certain  requirements  are 
complied  with,  one  of  the  requirements  being 
valuable  consideration,  which  for  the  purpose  of  ' 
specific  enforcement  must  exist  in  a  contract 
under  seal  as  well  as  in  a  simple  contract,  e.  s. 

CONTRACT  NOTE.  The  writing  on  these 
documents  is  a  short  and  formal  announcement 
that  a  stockbroker  has  bought  or  sold  for  his 
principal  a  given  amount  of  stock,  bonds,  or 
shares  at  specified  prices,  to  which  is  added 
brokerage  and  a  stamp,  which  Mr.  Goschen 
raised  to  6d.,  on  each  contract  note  for  more 
than  £100,  but  which,  before  1888,  used  always 
to  be  Id.  Contracts  do  not  pass  between 
members  of  the  stock  exchange.  It  is  a  rule 
that  every  bargain  between  members  should  be 
checked  by  1 1  a.  m.  on  the  following  day  ;  and 
the  committee  will  not  listen  to  any  dispute  if 
this  be  neglected.  A.  e. 

CONTRACTORS.  Persons  who  are  parties 
to  a  contract.  The  name  is  more  specially 
applied  to  persons  who  make  it  a  regular 
business  to  undertake  large  works  (e.g.  the 
construction  of  railways,  bridges,  or  buildings) 
for  sums  fixed  beforehand.  e.  s. 

CONTRACTUS  TRINUS.  See  Eck,  Johann. 

CONTRIBUTION,  CONTRIBUTORY.  Sec 
Company. 


CONVENTION  OF  ROYAL  BURGHS— CONVENTIONAL  TARIFF   403 


CONVENTION  OF  ROYAL  BURGHS  OF 
SCOTLAND.  This  municipal  federation  origin- 
ated in  the  court  or  parliament  of  four  burghs, 
which  consisted  of  representatives  from  Edin- 
burgh, Stirling,  Berwick,  and  Roxburgh.  In 
1368  Lanark  and  Linlithgow  were  substituted 
for  Berwick  and  Roxburgh.  In  the  13th  aid 
14th  centuries  this  court,  with  the  chamber- 
lain of  Scotland  as  presiding  officer,  exercised 
a  general  supervision  over  the  burghs  of  the 
kingdom,  legislating  for  them,  and  acting  as 
their  high  court  of  appeal.  The  transition 
from  the  old  parliament  or  court  of  four 
burghs  to  the  modem  convention  of  royal 
burghs  seems  to  have  taken  place  gradually 
during  the  15th  century.  Already,  in  1405, 
the  process  of  transformation  is  j)erceptible. 
In  this  year  the  court  of  four  burghs  enacted 
that  two  or  three  burgesses  from  each  of  the 
king's  burghs,  south  of  the  Spey,  should 
assemble  annually  to  treat  and  ordain  con- 
cerning all  things  that  relate  to  the  well-being, 
liberties,  and  court  of  the  king's  burghs. 
The  name  "  convention  "  gradually  superseded 
"court"  and  "parliament"  in  the  first  half 
of  the  16th  century. 

The  most  important  member  of  the  league 
was  Edinburgh,  which  sent  two  commissioners 
to  the  meetings  of  the  convention,  while  the 
other  royal  burghs  usually  sent  only  one. 
Edinburgh  was  also  generally  selected  as  the 
seat  of  the  convention.  But  the  place  and 
time  of  meeting  varied.  As  a  rule,  the  com- 
missioners assembled  annually.  The  presiding 
officer,  elected  at  each  session,  was  called  the 
moderator.  He  was  generally  the  commissioner 
of  the  town  where  the  meeting  was  held,  or,  if 
there  were  two  commissioners,  the  senior  dele- 
gate. A  committee  of  representatives  of  various 
burghs  was  often  appointed  to  transact  urgent 
business  while  the  convention  was  not  sitting. 

The  chief  function  of  the  convention  was 
the  supervision  of  trade,  domestic  and  foreign. 
It  made  regulations  concerning  markets,  tolls, 
fisheries,  manufactures,  customs -duties,  ship- 
ping, imports  and  exports,  etc.  It  negotiated 
commercial  treaties  with  continental  states  and 
cities.  It  exercised  control  over  Scotch 
merchants  in  France,  Flanders,  and  other 
countries  of  Europe.  The  chief  foreign  trade 
of  Scotland  was  carried  on  Avith  the  Nether- 
lands, and  was  monopolised  by  the  royal 
burghs.  This  trade  was  regulated  through 
"the  conservator  of  the  Scotch  privileges  in 
the  Netherlands."  He  was  elected  by  the 
convention,  though  the  king  sometimes  claimed 
and  exercised  the  right  of  appointment.  The 
conservator  lived  in  the  Scotch  staple -town, 
usually  Campvere  (the  modern  Vere  in  the 
province  of  Zealand),  where  the  royal  burghs 
enjoyed  important  privileges.  He  had  general 
charge  of  Scotch  merchants  and  factors  in  the 
Netlierlands,  and  was  the  judge  of  the  con- 


servatory court,  which  tried  all  civil  and 
criminal  cases  concerning  Scotsmen.  The 
"lord"  conservator  was  himself  guided  by 
the  instructions  and  orders  of  the  convention. 
At  Campvere  there  was,  moreover,  a  "con- 
sergerie,"  where  the  Scotch  merchants  lodged 
and  took  their  meals.  The  master  of  the  con- 
sergerie  was  expected  to  enforce  many  minute  re- 
gulations, some  of  which  were  peculiar.  In  the 
staple-town  we  also  find  a  Scotch  school,  kirk, 
and  prison-house.  The  convention  carefully 
regulated  everything  relating  to  these  various 
institutions,  including  even  the  wearing  apparel 
of  merchants  and  the  price  of  their  meals. 

Besides  the  supervision  of  commerce,  this 
powerful  organisation  exercised  important  func- 
tions in  connection  with  national  taxation. 
It  apportioned  public  taxes  among  the  burghs. 
It  also  sometimes  made  loans  and  grants  of 
money  to  the  king. 

A  third  important  function  of  the  convention 
was  the  oversight  of  the  internal  administration 
of  royal  burghs.  It  took  cognisance  of  weights 
and  measures  ;  altered  the  "setts"  or  written 
constitutions  of  towns  ;  decided  controversies 
between  burghs,  or  between  burghs  and  their 
magistrates ;  and  regulated  the  election  of 
municipal  officers,  the  qualifications  of  burgess- 
ship,  the  finances,  etc.,  of  towns.  It  also 
often  appropriated  money  for  the  repair  of 
harbours,  and  for  the  general  improvement  of 
particular  burghs. 

The  federation  is  still  in  existence,  but  its 
most  important  functions  have  been  absorbed 
by  parliament.  Its  meetings  are  held  annually 
at  Edinburgh,  which  is  represented  by  two 
commissioners  and  two  assessors,  while  the 
other  burghs  send  one  commissioner  and  one 
assessor.  The  larger  towns  have  cause  for 
complaint  owing  to  the  inequality  of  repre- 
sentation. The  convention  now  merely  makes 
suggestions  and  recommendations  concerning 
commerce  and  municipal  affairs,  for  the  purpose 
of  influencing  public  opinion  and  parliamentary 
action.  It  used  to  exert  great  influence  upon 
national  legislation. 

[This  account  is  based  upon  the  Acts  of  the 
Parliament  of  Scotland  (12  vols.,  1814-1875), 
and  especially  upon  the  Records  of  the  Convention 
of  Royal  Burghs,  edited  by  J.  D.  Marwick  (6 
vols.,  Edinburgh,  1866-90).  These  Records  form 
a  rich,  unworked  mine  of  information  for  historians 
and  economists.  There  is  no  good  history  of  the 
convention.  —  John  Mackay 's  Convention  of  the 
Royal  Burghs  of  Scotland  to  1707  (Edinburgh, 
1884)  is  a  very  brief  and  fragmentary  account. 
The  subject  is  worthy  of  more  attention  than  it 
has  thus  far  received.]  c.  or. 

CONVENTIONAL  TARIFF.  This  term  is 
applicable  to  regulations,  of  a  more  or  lesa 
arbitrary  or  empirical  kind,  giving  a  fixed 
value  of  conversion  from  one  currency  to 
another,  in  which  the  exact  intrinsic  value  or 


404       CONVENTIONAL  VALUE— CONVERSION  OF  NATIONAL  DEBT 


unit  par  of  excliange  is  disregarded.  Thus,  the 
English  sovereign  in  Portugal  has  a  legal  con- 
ventional tariff  value  of  53^  pence  per  milreis 
of  her  own  gold  coinage,  although  the  pure  gold 
value  of  the  latter  is  only  53*284  pence.  Then 
again,  in  international  postal  conventions 
between  England  and  a  gi-eat  group  of  other 
countries,  similar  fractional  differences  are 
allowed  to  be,  so  to  speak,  glossed  over.  For 
example,  ten  centimes  and  one  penny  are  to  an 
enormous  extent  taken  as  identical.  But  one 
penny,  as  the  two  hundred  and  fortieth  part 
of  a  gold  sovereign,  has  about  '00417  of  its 
value,  whilst  ten  centimes  have  only  about 
•00396.  This  is  tantamount  to  depreciating 
English  currency  to  the  extent  of  more  than  5 
per  cent  of  its  real  value.  In  the  practical 
result,  the  British  public  has  been  unduly 
generous  and  quixotically  lavish  in  letting 
itself  be  mulcted  in  this  way  by  conventional 
tariffs.  The  extent  of  this  may  best  be  under- 
stood if  attention  be  given  to  the  fact  that 
hundreds  of  millions  sterling,  by  way  of  loans 
to  foreigners,  have  been  advanced,  in  which  a 
conventional  tariff  has  been  used,  either  of 
25,  instead  of  25-2215,  francs,  to  the  sovereign, 
or  of  48,  instead  of  49-316,  pence  to  the 
dollar.  F.  H. 

CONVENTIONAL  VALX7E.  A  term  some- 
times used  as  equivalent  to  Official  or  De- 
clared Value  {q.v.),  for  the  Board  of  Trade  and 
customs  returns.  The  values  of  goods  imported 
and  exported  were,  down  to  1870,  computed  at 
prices  ascertained  in  1694,  as  a  conventional 
method  of  bringing  them  all  together  into 
money  totals.  Thus,  e.g.,  "eggs"  were  on 
importation  calculated  at  a  uniform  value  of 
9d.  a  great  hundred,  though  in  the  mean- 
time the  prices  had  risen  to  6s.  ;  and  cottons  on 
exportation  at  Is.  6d.  per  yard,  though  they 
had  fallen  to  4^d.  French  values  are  re-adjusted 
every  year,  and  those  so  obtained  are  conven- 
tionally used  in  all  publications  during  the 
progress  of  the  year,  but  corrected  for  the 
annual  records.  S.  Bo. 

CONVERSION  OF  BRITISH  NATIONAL 
DEBT.  The  form  in  which  the  British 
National  Debt  has  been  held  has  frequently 
been  modified.  The  improved  condition  of  the 
public  credit  has  from  time  to  time  enabled  the 
government  to  make  arrangements  for  the  pay- 
ment of  a  lower  rate  of  interest,  an  object  which 
is  accomplished  either  by  the  issue  to  the 
holders  of  the  stock  to  be  converted  of  another 
stock  bearing  a  different  rate  of  interest,  or  by 
the  repayment  of  the  capital  value  of  the  stock 
out  of  moneys  borrowed  for  the  purpose.  In 
the  one  case  the  stockholder  remains  unchanged, 
although  the  nominal  amount  of  his  holding, 
and  the  interest  paid  upon  it  may  be  varied. 
In  the  other,  the  place  of  the  original  stock- 
holder is  taken  by  one  who  is  ready  to  accept 
less  favourable  terms  for  himself, 


Operations  of  this  character  have  not  been 
infrequent.  The  first  conversion  of  the  British 
National  Debt  was  carried  into  effect  in  1711, 
when  a  mass  of  floating  obligations  was  con- 
vertedinto  £9,177,968  of  South  Sea  Company's 
stock  bearing  6  per  cent  interest.  In  1760, 
Mr.  Pelham  converted  £54,413,433,  4  per  cent 
stock  into  the  same  amount  of  new  stock 
eventually  to  bear  3  per  cent  interest  only.  In 
1817  the  Irish  debt,  of  £103,033,750,  was  con- 
verted into  the  debt  of  the  United  Kingdom. 
Inl822,Mr.Vansittartconverted£149,627,867, 
5  per  cent  stock  into  £157,109,217,  4  per 
cent  stock.  In  1824,  Mr.  Robinson  converted 
£70,098,935,  4  per  cent  stock  into  3^  per 
cent  stock  of  the  same  amount.  In  1830, 
Mr.  Goulburn  converted  £150,790,176,  4  per 
cent  stock  partly  into  5  per  cent  stock  at  the 
price  of  70,  but  almost  wholly  into  3-^  per  cent 
stock  at  par.  In  1834,  Lord  Althorp  convert- 
ed £6,489,190,  4  per  cent  stock  into  an  equal 
amount  of  3|  per  cents.  In  1844,  Mr.  Goul- 
burn succeeded  in  converting  £248,757,311, 
3^  per  cent  stock  into  a  new  stock  to  carry  3| 
per  cent  for  ten  years  and  3  per  cent  for  twenty 
years.  In  1853,  Mr.  Gladstone  arranged  for  the 
conversion  of  £3, 063, 906,  3  per  cent  stocks.  In 
1883  a  sum  of  £70,241,908,  3  per  cents  was 
converted  into  terminable  annuities,  and 
in  1884,  Mr.  Childers  converted  £23,362,596, 
3  per  cent  stocks  into  2|  per  cents  at  102,  and 
2^  per  cents  at  108. 

For  some  time  prior  to  1888,  the  price  of  the 
leading  marketable  securities,  including  British 
government  stocks  not  redeemable  at  any  early 
period,  had  made  it  evident  that  the  state  of 
the  public  credit  rendered  it  unnecessary  that 
so  much  as  3  per  cent  interest  on  the  funded 
debt  should  be  paid.  On  the  9  th  March  of 
that  year  Mr.  Goschen  submitted  a  scheme  for 
the  conversion  of  the  three  per  cent  stocks  then 
existing — consols,  reduced  threes,  and  new 
threes — into  a  single  stock  to  bear  interest, 
payable  quarterly,  at  the  rate  of  3  per  cent  for 
the  year  ending  the  5th  April  1889,  2|  per  cent 
for  the  following  fourteen  years  ending  the  5th 
April  1903,  and  2|  per  cent  for  the  next  suc- 
ceeding twenty  years  ending  the  5th  April  1923, 
and  thenceforward  until  it  should  be  redeemed. 
The  new  stock  was  to  be  called  "Two-and- 
three  -  quarters  per  cent  consolidated  stock " 
until  the  5th  April  1903,  and  "Two-and-a-half 
per  cent  consolidated  stock "  thereafter.  An 
equivalent  amount  of  the  new  stock  was  offered 
in  exchange  for  the  stock  to  be  converted,  and 
any  increase  in  the  nominal  amount  of  the  debt 
was  thus  avoided,  but  an  important  difference 
in  the  position  of  the  three  old  stocks  as 
respects  redemption  rendered  a  different  modus 
operandi  and  some  variation  of  terms  essential. 
The  new  3  per  cent  stocks  had  been  redeemable 
at  any  time  since  the  5th  January  1873,  and 
Mr.  Goschen  proposed  to  assume  consent  to  the 


CONVERSION  OF  BRITISH  NATIONAL  DEBT 


406 


conversion  unless  the  holders  formally  dis- 
eented,  in  which  case  they  were  to  be  paid  off 
at  par  in  one  sum,  or  in  such  proportions  and 
in  such  order  and  manner  as  the  treasury 
might  direct.  The  amount  of  stock  to 
which  this  arrangement  was  applicable  was 
£166,399,043. 

The  position  of  the  holders  of  consols  and 
reduced  threes  was  a  better  one,  for  they 
possessed  a  right  to  twelve  months'  notice  before 
their  stock  could  be  redeemed.  In  their  case 
it  was  considered  that  assent  to  conversion 
could  not  properly  be  assumed  in  the  absence 
of  a  formal  acceptance  of  the  altered  terras,  and 
in  order  therefore  to  encourage  holders  to  give 
such  assent  and  to  forego  their  privilege  of 
notice,  a  bonus  of  5s.  per  cent  was  to  be  given 
to  those  who  agreed  to  the  conversion  within 
certain  specified  periods.  The  amount  of  the 
stocks  to  which  this  arrangement  applied  was 
in  the  aggi-egate  £391,593,466,  of  which 
£322,681,033  was  in  consols,  and  £68,912,433 
in  reduced  threes.  The  former  amount  was 
subsequently  increased  by  £34,625,778,  created 
in  lieu  of  the  remaining  sums  to  be  paid  in 
respect  of  a  terminable  annuity  into  which 
certain  stocks  belonging  to  suitors  of  the 
supreme  court  had  been  converted. 

In  order  to  compensate  stockbrokers,  bankers, 
solicitors,  and  other  recognised  agents  for  tlie 
trouble  to  which  the  offer  made  to  holders  of 
consols  and  reduced  threes  would  put  them, 
the  treasury  were  to  be  empowered  to  pay  a 
commission  of  Is.  6d.  per  cent  on  the  stock 
converted. 

The  proposals  made  by  Mr.  Goschen  were 
favourably  received  both  in  parliament  and  in 
financial  circles,  and  a  bill  embodying  them 
received  the  royal  assent  on  the  27th  March 
1888.  It  speedily  became  evident  that  the 
scheme  would  be  successful.  The  simplicity 
of  the  terms  proposed  had  undoubtedly  much 
to  do  with  the  success  of  the  operation,  to- 
gether with  an  impression  current  among 
business  men  that  such  a  conversion  was 
certain  to  be  carried  through.  By  the  29th 
March,  the  holders  of  new  threes  who  had  ex- 
pressed dissent  represented  not  more  than  some 
£400,000  out  of  £166,000,000,  whilst  assents 
on  the  part  of  the  holders  of  consols  and  re- 
duced threes  to  the  extent  of  £297,406,173, 
or  nearly  76  per  cent  of  the  whole,  were  re- 
ceived by  the  26  th  April,  an  additional 
£70,861,170,  or  18  per  cent,  being  converted 
between  that  date  and  the  1st  June.  On  the 
5th  November  1888,  new  stock  to  the  extent 
of  £549,094,011  had  been  accepted  and 
£1,199,102  old  stock  had  been  paid  off",  leav- 
ing a  balance  of  £42,325,173  still  to  be  dealt 
with. 

The  operations  undertaken  for  the  conversion 
and  failing  this  the  redemption,  of  this  remanet 
may  be  thus  summarised  :  I 


Stock  redeemed  by  the  action  of  the 

ordinary  Sinking  Funds £1,356,461 

Paid  off  under  discount     6,128,006 

Stock    acquired    by   National    Debt 

Commissioners  and  converted  8,164,312 

Stock  temporarily  converted  into  a  3 

per  cent  Book  Debt  6,376,143 

Stock  automatically  converted 8,426,141 

Paid  away  or  claimed  in  cash 11,874,110 


£42,325,173 


The  final  results  of  the  whole  series  of  opera- 
tions were  as  follows  : — 


Stock  dealt  with. 

1   Per 

Amount.       |  ^ent. 

Converted  into  new  stock  ... 
Paid  off  in  money       

£565,684,4651  95  71 
19,354,253|     3-3 

5,785,689     I'O 

£590,824,407100-0 

Converted  into  a  temporary 
"Book  Debt"         

Net  amountof  stock  dealtwith 

The  cost  of  the  operations  was  as  follows  : — 

Bonus  to  redemptioners     £958,528 

Commission  to  agents   234,073 

Remuneration  to  Banks  of  Eng- 
land and  Ireland   116,054 

Dividend  paid  in  advance 1,715,815 

£3,024,470 

T\\e  saving  in  interest  on  the  National  Debt 
exceeded  a  million  in  1889-90  ;  for  the  following 
thirteen  years  it  was  about  £1,400, 000  per  ann. , 
an  amount  doubled  after  1903-4  when  consols 
became  a  2^  per  cent  Stock  redeemable  1923. 

[Hansard's  Debates,  vol.  cccxxiii.  pp.  709  and 
1813  ;  vol.  cccxxiv.  p.  118.— The  Acts  51  Vict, 
c.  2,  51  &  52  Vict.  c.  15,  &  52  Vict.  c.  i.—Parlio- 
mentary  Papers,  Nos.  c.  5584,  283  of  1889  and 
153  of  1890. — Also,  for  a  detailed  account  of  tlu) 
operations.  Conversion  and  Redemption,  by  E.  W. 
Hamilton,  London,  1889.]  T,  H.  e. 

CONVERSION,  COLONIAL  AND  FOR- 
EIGN STOCKS.  In  its  financial  aspect  "con- 
version "  is  a  term  generally  applied  to  con- 
solidations and  simplifications  of  securities  or 
to  reconstructions  of  a  national  currency,  like 
that  carried  out  by  Germany  in  1873.  It  is 
intended  to  confine  these  remarks  to  the  most 
important  conversions  of  colonial  and  foreign 
stocks.  (For  the  conversion  of  the  British 
National  Debt  see  separate  article.) 

Colonial  Stocks. 

Canada. — In  1860  Canada  effected  an  im- 
portant conversion  of  her  6,  5,  and  4^  per  cent 
debentures  into  5  per  cent  consols  or  bonds, 
redeemable  in  1885,  when  the  holders  were 
offered  4  per  cent  inscribed  stock,  and  most  of 
them  accepted  the  offer. 

Cape  of  Good  Hope. — This  colony  has  effected 
various  conversions  of  debt,  that  of  1872  con 


406 


CONVERSION,  COLONIAL  AND  FOREIGN  STOCKS 


verting  the  securities  of  the  Cape  Railway  into 
government  4^  per  cent  consolidated  debentures 
and  that  of  1886,  offering  the  holders  of  the 
entire  debt  bearing  6,  5,  42",  and  4  per  cent, 
the  option  of  converting  into  4  per  cent  inscribed 
stock.  This  offer  applied  to  £13,343,100  in 
bonds  and  was  largely  carried  into  effect. 

India. — In  1874  there  was  a  partial  conver- 
sion of  the  old  10\  per  cent  stock  of  1833.  In 
1880  India  5  per  cent  stock  was  converted  into 
4  per  cent  stock.  In  1887  India  4  per  cent 
stock  was  offered  the  option  of  converting  into 
3^  per  cent  stock,  when  £48,215,673  accepted 
the  terms  offered.  Since  then  there  have  been 
some  conversions  into  3  per  cent  stock. 

New  Zealand. — This  colony  effected  import- 
ant conversions  of  debt,  in  1868,  when  Ncav 
Zealand  5  per  cent  consols  were  issued,  and  in 
1885  and  1886,when  loans  of  about£14,000,000 
were  allowed  to  convert  into  4  per  cent  inscribed 
stock,  the  holders  mostly  availing  themselves  of 
the  option. 

Jamaica,  Mauritius,  and  Natal  have  likewise 
effected  conversions  of  debt. 

Foreign  Stocks. 

In  1869  Austria  compulsorily  converted  all 
her  issues  into  internal  5  per  cent  rentes,  where- 
upon the  Council  of  Foreign  Bondholders  issued 
"Anglo-Austrian  bondholders'  certificates"  to 
cover  the  loss  entailed.  These  were  redeemed 
at  £5  each  in  1871.  In  1888  there  was  a 
partial  conversion  into  4  per  cent  gold  rente, 
which  will  probably  be  carried  further. 

Egypt  has  also  effected  many  consolidations 
of  this  nature,  but  the  unification  carried  out 
in  1877  was  by  far  the  most  important  of  them. 
All  the  then  existing  loans  of  Egypt,  many  of 
them  carrying  high  rates  of  interest  and  sinking 
fund,  were  converted  into  38^  per  cent  5  per 
cent  preference  stock,  and  61i  per  cent  unified 
stock,  which  was  to  bear  up  to  7  per  cent 
interest.  But  in  reality  it  has  borne  4  per  cent 
interest.  At  the  same  time  the  Khedive's 
private  loans  were  converted  into  Daira  Sanieh 
debt.  These  conversions  were  the  result  of  Mr. 
Goschen's  mission  in  1876,  which  proved  the 
financial  salvation  of  Egypt. 

French  debt  conversions  have  been  numerous, 
one  of  the  latest  being  in  1883  of  the  5  per  cent 
national  loans  into  new  4^  per  cent  rente  to  the 
amount  of  £271,591,430"  This  stock  may  be 
again  converted  from  1893.  In  1878  new  3 
per  cents  were  issued  in  conversion  of  some 
railway  stocks  ;  in  1883  this  stock  was  added 
to  by  conversion  of  the  savings  banks'  deposits. 
Altogether  about  £75,000,000  was  so  dealt 
with. 

Mexico  has  made  many  conversions,  with  and 
without  the  consent  of  her  creditors.  The  last, 
in  1886,  whereby  the  entire  foreign  debts  were 
exchanged  for  consolidated  debt  of  1886,  bear- 
ing 1  per  cent  rising  to  3  per  cent  interest,  was 


the  result  of  protracted  negotiations  following 
on  the  practical  repudiation  of  1866. 

Peru,  to  go  no  farther  back,  effected  partial 
conversions  in  1852,  1862,  1865,  and  1872, 
and  it  is  evident,  that  before  Peru  ceases  to  be 
classed  amongst  the  list  of  defaulters,  a  further 
consolidation  and  reduction  of  debt  will  have  to 
be  carried  into  effect. 

Russia  has  carried  out  a  number  of  conver 
sions,  partly  of  internal  debt.  But  her  latest 
conversion,  that  of  1889,  is  to  exchange  the  5 
per  cent  railway  loans  of  1870,  1872,  1873,  and 
1884  into  £49,120,783  of  4  per  cent  bonds. 

Spain  effected  her  first  conversion  of  foreign 
debt  in  1834,  and  from  that  time  up  to  the 
consolidation  and  conversion  of  1881-82  her 
arrangements  with  her  creditors  were  numerous. 
By  the  last  arrangement  all  her  outstanding 
loans  were  exchanged  for  4  per  cent  external 
and  internal  stock,  with  a  large  reduction  in  the 
nominal  capital  of  the  debt. 

Turkey  in  1865  converted  her  many  internal 
debts  into  a  general  debt  bearing  5  per  cent 
interest.  In  1882  all  the  loans  upon  which 
Turkey  w^as  in  default  were  converted  into  four 
series  of  1  per  cent  bonds  amounting  in  all  to 
£91,842,000. 

The  Uniljed  States  in  1871  and  1873  con- 
verted 6  per  cents  into  a  5  per  cent  funded 
loan  for  $500,000,000.  In  1876  a  further 
$300,000,000  in  4^  per  cents  were  issued  for 
conversion  purposes  ;  and  in  1877-78  another 
1739,000,000  were  issued  in  exchange  for  6 
and  5  per  cent  bonds.  In  1881  the  5  per 
cents  of  1871-73  were  renewed  at  3^  per  cent, 
and  in  1882  they  were  converted  into  3  per 
cents,  which  have  since  been  entirely  redeemed. 

There  is  hardly  a  foreign  country  of  any 
standing  which  has  not  carried  out  similar 
operations,  the  main  object  in  all  being  to  pay 
lower  rates  of  interest  upon  their  obligations. 
It  is  not  too  much  to  say  that  if  all  the  govern- 
ment debts  of  the  civilised  world  carried  interest 
now  at  the  rates  originally  contracted  for,  their 
burdens  in  interest  would  quite  double  what 
they  now  are.  It  is  evident  too,  that  many 
further  conversions  to  lower  rates  of  interest 
will  be  effected  in  the  near  future. 

CONVERSION  OF  ARABLE  LAND  INTO 
PASTURE  IN  ENGLAND.— Historically,  two 
epochs  stand  out  in  which  tillage  has  been  on 
a  large  scale  converted  to  pasture  in  England  : 
(1)  1400-1580  ;  (2)  1878  to  present  time. 

(1)  So  long  as  self-sufiicing  farming  was  prac- 
tised or  feudalism  prevailed,  little  or  no  attention 
was  paid  to  the  nature  of  the  soil  or  climate. 
Whatever  corn  was  requii-ed  for  the  support  of 
isolated  villages,  organised  as  separate  com- 
munities complete  in  themselves,  was  necessarily 
grown  upon  the  spot,  and  land  was  valued  less 
for  the  rents  it  produced  than  for  the  men  it 
supported.  Divisions  into  arable  and  pasture 
were    therefore    dictated    by   social    exigencies 


CONVERSION— CONVERTIBILITY  OF  BANK  NOTES 


407 


instead  of  natural  advantages.  At  the  end  of 
the  14th  century  farming  for  profit  was  intro- 
duced, and  gradually  tillage  was  superseded  as 
the  staple  agricultural  industry ;  pasture  became 
the  rule,  and  wool  the  source  of  the  farmer's 
wealth.  This  change  was,  in  the  first  instance, 
due  to  social  causes.  The  Black  Death  {q.v.\ 
depopulated  rural  districts.  Landlords  were  de- 
prived of  their  quit-rents,  and  holdings  thrown 
upon  their  hands.  There  was  plenty  of  land,  but 
few  to  work  it ;  little  money  was  forthcoming 
to  pay  for  labour  even  when  it  was  available. 
In  this  crisis  landlords  adopted  one  of  three 
courses  :  (a)  they  offered  stock  and  land  leases 
(Rogers,  Agriculture  and  Prices,  i.  p.  24)  ;  {h) 
they  exacted  the  labour  services,  which  had  now 
become  exceptionally  valuable  ;  (c)  they  laid 
down  their  land  to  pasture,  and  enclosed  vast 
tracts  as  sheep-runs.  From  these  courses 
followed  important  results.  From  (a)  sprang 
the  class  of  tenant  farmers ;  from  Qj)  the 
Peasants'  Revolt  of  1381  and  the  effort  to 
destroy  the  manorial  muniment  rooms  (Denton, 
Fifteenth  Century)  ;  from  (c)  the  acceleration 
in  the  break-up  of  the  old  manorial  and  common- 
farm  system,  as  a  more  profitable  method  was 
discovered  of  employing  land.  If  this  last 
course  was  adopted  upon  lands  depopulated  by 
the  Black  Death,  no  social  grievance  was  caused. 
If  the  change  simply  meant  the  conversion  of 
common  farms  into  enclosures  on  which  corn  and 
cattle  could  be  conveniently  raised,  it  consti- 
tuted an  advance  in  agricultural  science,  and 
displaced  little  or  no  labour.  But,  as  a  rule, 
the  change  meant  that  landlords  withdrew  tlieir 
demesnes  from  the  common  farms,  ceased  to 
employ  labour,  enclosed  an  undue  share  of  the 
wastes,  deprived  copyholders  and  tenants  of  the 
means  of  cultivating  their  own  holdings,  and 
threw  the  new  enclosures  into  vast  sheep-walks. 
Thus  the  change  caused  a  large  amount  of 
agrarian  distress  and  social  discontent  [Libelle  of 
English  Polycye  ;  Denton,  Fifteenth  Century  ; 
More's  Utopia,  p.  41  (English  Reprints,  1869)  ; 
Dialogue  betioeen  Cardinal  Pole  and  Thomas 
LupsetjlEi.  E.  T.  S. ;  Supplication  of  Poor  Covimons, 
E.  E.  T.  S. ;  F.  W.  Russell,  Rett's  Rebellion,  etc.] 
When  once  the  tendency  began,  it  was  accelerated 
by  the  dissolution  of  the  monasteries  and  the 
high  profits  of  the  rising  wool  trade,  and  con- 
tinued to  develop  in  spite  of  the  prohibitions  of 
the  legislature  {e.g.  6  Hen.  VIII.  c.  5 ;  7  Hen. 
VIIL  c.  1 ;  25  Hen.  VIIL  c.  13  ;  27  Hen.  VIII. 
c.  22).  England  in  fact  became  a  gi-ass-grow- 
ing,  wool-producing,  pasture  country  until  the 
pressure  of  population  at  the  close  of  the  18th 
century  reversed  the  agricultural  policy. 

(2)  War  prices  of  corn  (1797-1815)  en- 
couraged farmers  to  plough  up  land  for  corn. 
But  the  preponderance  of  pasture  over  arable 
land  continued  after  the  change  had  been  long 
in  progress.  Of  this  fact  two  inquiries  give 
sufficient   proof.       Mr.    Comber   (Inquiry  into 


the  State  of  National  Subsistence,  1808)  calcu* 
lates  the  arable  land  and  gai-dens  of  England 
and  Wales  at  11,588,000  acres,  the  lands  de- 
pastured by  cattle  at  17,479,000  acres,  and  the 
commons  and  cultivated  wastes  at  6,473,000 
acres.  Mr.  Couling  (Select  Committee  on 
Emigration,  1827)  calculated  in  that  year  the 
arable  land  and  gardens  of  England  and  Wales 
at  11,143,370  acres,  the  meadows,  pastures, 
and  marshes  at  17,605,630  ;  the  unculti- 
vated improvable  wastes  at  3,984,000  acres. 
Temporarily  checked  from  1815  to  1850,  the 
tide  set  subsequently  in  the  direction  of  the 
conversion  of  pasture  into  arable  land.  In 
1874  there  were  13,900,000  acres  of  land  in 
England  and  Wales  under  corn  crops,  green 
crops,  or  rotation  grasses,  as  against  12,071,691 
acres  under  permanent  pasture.  In  1875  there 
were  13,980,000  acres  of  land  under  corn  crops, 
etc.,  against  12,202,596  acres  of  pasture. 
Thus,  as  compared  with  1808  or  1827,  the 
arable  land  exceeded  the  pasture  by  one  and 
three  quarter  million  acres,  instead  of  the 
pasture  exceeding  the  arable  land  and  gardens 
by  six  and  a  half  million  acres.  The  pre 
ponderance  of  arable  land  over  pasture  ceased 
to  increase  after  1878.  In  1879  and  1880  the 
area  of  arable  land  was  13,480,500  acres  and 
13,210,600  acres,  and  the  area  of  pasture  land 
was  13,007,400  and  13,267,600  acres.  Thus, 
by  1880,  the  tide  had  commenced  to  turn.  In 
1888  and  1889,  the  area  of  pasture  land  ex- 
ceeded the  arable  land.  In  1888  the  arable 
land  was  12,715,800  acres,  the  permanent 
pasture,  14,554,500.  In  1912  the  arable  land 
was  14,660,300  acres,  the  permanent  pasture, 
17,335,700  acres.  e.  e.  p. 

CONVERTIBILITY  OF  BANK  NOTES. 
The  convertibility  of  bank  notes  into  specie  on 
demand  is  an  essential  condition  of  a  sound  cur- 
rency. It  has  been  held,  and  it  would  appear 
difficult  to  controvert  the  statement,  that  im- 
mediate convertibility  on  demand  is  a  complete 
safeguard  against  over-issue,  for  if  a  redundant 
note  were  in  circulation  the  provision  that  it 
would  be  immediately  paid  on  demand  would 
appear  sufficient  to  ensure  that  such  a  note, 
when  redundant,  should  immediately  be  with- 
drawn. But,  according  to  the  currency  prin- 
ciple supported  by  Sir  R.  Peel  (see  Currency 
Doctrine),  the  question  of  convertibility  might 
depend  on  other  considerations.  "The  real 
question  to  be  solved  is,  how  to  regulate  the 
quantity  of  the  paper  circulation,  so  as  to  keep 
its  value  identical  with  what  the  value  of  the 
metallic  currency  should  be  "  (speech  of  Sir  R. 
Peel,  House  of  Commons,  May  20,  1844). 
"Convertibility  alone  will  not  ensure  this. 
Convertibility  provides,  indeed,  the  means  ot 
taking  out  of  circulation  a  quantity  of  paper 
already  in  excess ;  but  it  imposes  a  very 
imperfect  check  on  putting  too  much  paper 
into  circulation."     Sir  R.  Peel  did  not  attempt 


408 


CONVEYANCE— COOPER 


to  reconcile  the  latter  half  of  this  sentence 
with  the  former,  for  it  is  difficult  to  under- 
stand how  paper  substituted  for  money  can 
remain  in  excess  of  the  wants  of  the  country 
when  the  means  of  taking  this  excess  out  of 
circulation  have  been  provided.  Real  converti- 
bi]ity,  that  is  to  say  the  means  of  obtaining 
specie  for  notes  whenever  required,  appears  an 
ample  safeguard  against  over -issue  of  notes. 
Bank  notes,  however,  play  a  very  different  part 
in  the  financial  system  of  the  country  from  what 
they  did  at  the  commencement  of  this  century 
(see  Bank  Note  ;  Currency  Doctrine.) 

[Tooke  and  Newmarch's  History  of  Prices  is  a 
perfect  mine  of  information  on  the  subject. — 
Fullerton,  On  the  Regulation  of  Currencies. — 
James  Wilson,  On  Capital,  Currency,  and  Bank- 
ing, and  the  writings  of  Huskisson,  Ricardo,  Sir 
W.  Clay,  Colonel  Torrens,  Walker  on  Money."] 

CONVEYANCE.  (1)  The  transfer  of  the 
ownership  of  property.  (2)  The  instrument  by 
which  the  transfer  is  effected.  A  conveyance, 
to  be  effectual,  must  be  embodied  in  a  deed 
(which  is  a  document  signed,  sealed,  and  de- 
livered by  the  parties  in  the  presence  of  a  wit- 
ness). The  conveyance  of  property  need  not 
necessarily  have  the  effect  of  transferring  the 
beneficial  rights  of  ownership  ;  in  the  case  of  a 
mortgage,  for  instance,  the  legal  estate — i.e. 
the  formal  right  of  ownership — is  vested  in  the 
mortgagee,  but  the  mortgagor,  as  a  general  rule, 
remains  in  possession  and  in  the  full  enjoyment 
of  an  owner's  material  right — excepting,  how- 
ever, the  right  of  alienation.  The  methods  of 
conveyancing  have  been  considerably  simplified 
within  the  last  two  generations,  and  even  within 
the  last  decade.  A  modern  conveyance  begins 
with  the  date  and  the  names  of  the  parties  ; 
then  follow  the  recitals,  which  in  the  first  place 
explain  the  title,  and  in  the  second  place  state 
the  nature  of  the  transaction  which  has  caused 
the  conveyance  to  be  effected  (each  recital  be- 
ginning with  the  word  "whereas  ") ;  these  being 
finished,  the  so-called  "  Testatum  "  ("  Now  this 
indenture  witnesseth  ")  introduces  the  effective 
part  of  the  conveyance,  beginning  with  the 
statement  of  the  consideration  and  the  acknow- 
ledgment of  the  same,  then  proceeding  with  the 
"operative  words"  {e.g.  "the  vendor  conveys," 
etc.),  and  afterwards  describing  the  "  parcel " — 
i.e.  the  property  which  is  the  object  of  the 
conveyance;  by  the  "habendum"  the  nature 
of  the  estate  which  is  conveyed  is  explained 
(whether  in  fee  simple,  for  life,  upon  trust,  etc. ) ; 
and  finally  the  "  covenants  "  contain  the  mutual 
promises  concerning  the  property  or  the  adjoin- 
ing property.  Many  of  the  alienating  owner's 
covenants  have  been  rendered  unnecessary  by 
the  Conveyancing  Act  of  1881,  the  addition  of 
certain  expressions  to  the  operative  words  im- 
plying a  number  of  covenants  which  formerly 
had  to  be  set  out  at  great  length.  It  is  un- 
necessary to  mention  that  the  description  of  a 


conveyance  as  given  here  is  liable  to  a  great 
many  variations  according  to  the  circumstances 
of  the  case.  A  conveyance  on  sale  is  liable  to 
a  stamp  duty  of  5s.  for  every  £50.  E.s. 

COOLIE  SYSTEM.  By  this  system  a  mi- 
gration of  labourers  from  India,  China,  and  the 
South  Pacific,  to  other  tropical  countries  under 
European  government,  is  placed  under  state 
regulation.  The  movement  began  (1834)  when 
the  freed  negroes  largely  declined  plantation 
work.  The  management  being  at  first  in 
private  hands,  unpleasant  rumours  called  for 
government  intervention,  and  now  the  egress 
from  India  is  strictly  controlled  (acts  of  1864 
andl869),  the  termsof  engagement  are  regulated, 
and  the  colonial  governments  held  responsible 
for  their  execution.  Commissions  of  inquiry 
were  issued  for  Demerara  (1870)  and  Mauritius 
(1875).  The  French  government  on  their  part 
undertake  inspection  in  their  colonies.  The 
movement  from  China  is  regulated  by  a  conven- 
tion (1866)  between  the  governments  of  China, 
Great  Britain,  and  France. 

The  chief  colonies  employing  coolie  labour 
are  Demerara  (one-third  of  population),  Trinidad 
(two  thousand  a  year),  Mauritius  (five-sevenths 
of  population),  Natal  (one-fifteenth),  Queensland 
(chiefly  from  the  Pacific  Islands),  and  the 
Straits.  Outside  the  British  empire,  Cuba, 
Peru,  Tahiti,  and  the  French  sugar  islands. 

The  system  is  interesting — (1)  as  showing 
the  beginnings  of  a  movement  from  the  two 
great  centres  of  population  in  Asia,  the  dimen- 
sions of  which  cannot  be  foreseen  ;  and  (2)  as 
an  instance  of  non-economic  considerations  in- 
ducing state  interference  with  private  enter- 
prise, for  the  protection  of  labour  against  the 
individual's  ignorance  of  the  value  of  his  labour 
and  his  acceptance  of  a  standard  of  living  de- 
termined by  the  offers  of  competing  capitalists. 

[Comhill  Magazine,  1867.— Jenkins,  The  Coolie, 
London,  1871,  an  adverse  report. — Histories  of 
the  colonies  above  mentioned.]  a.  o. 

COOPER,  Thomas  (1759-1840),  was  born  in 
London  and  admitted  to  the  bar,  became  a 
Radical,  was  involved  in  political  troubles,  and 
finally  followed  his  friend  Priestley  to  the  United 
States,  where  again  he  took  an  active  part  in 
political  affairs.  In  1 820  he  became  president  of 
Columbia  College  in  Columbia,  South  Carolina, 
and  held  that  place  till  1834. 

In  addition  to  pamphlets,  he  wrote  Lectures  on 
the  Elements  of  Political  Econoviy,  Columbia, 
1826,  and  a  Manual  of  Political  Economy 
(Washington,  1834),  both  good  text -books  in 
their  day,  expounding  the  doctrines  of  Adam 
Smith  and  Ricardo.  F.  W.  T. 

COOPER,  Thomas  (1805-1892)  imprisoned 
in  early  life  as  a  chartist  (see  Chartism),  was 
among  the  last  survivors,  as  he  had  been  one 
of  the  most  sincere  of  the  leaders  in  that 
movement. 


CO-OPERATION 


409 


CO-OPERATION 

Co-operative  Associations,  p.  409 ;  Co-operative  Farming, 
p.  413 ;  Co-operative  Workshops,  p.  415 ;  Co-operation, 
Partial  (Oldham  Cotton  Spinning  Companies),  p.  417  ; 
Co-operation,  Social  Aspects  of,  p.  418. 

Co-operative  Associations.  The  term 
co-operation  has  been  employed  by  economisii 
in  two  senses,  (a)  as  indicating  certain  broadly 
marked  phenomena  connected  with  the  auto- 
matic development  of  human  communities,  of 
which  what  is  most  widely  known  as  division 
of  labour  is  an  instance  ;  and  (b)  as  indicating 
the  deliberate  association  of  individuals  to  form 
trading  bodies  on  certain  specific  principles  for 
their  common  advantage.  The  latter  use  of 
the  term  is  the  more  common  of  the  two,  outside 
text  books  on  economics. 

(a)  The  simplest  conceivable  case  of  co- 
operation is  when  two  men  combine  to  move 
a  weight  too  heavy  for  either  to  deal  with 
singly.  In  this  case  two  similar  forces  are 
integrated.  Co-operation  of  this  kind  is  only 
r  of  limited  application,  I'or  the  number  of  men 
whose  power  can  be  brought  to  bear  on  even  a 
large  object  at  suitable  points  is  comparatively 
small,  unless  some  form  of  machinery  is  used. 
But  the  labour  of  men  may  also  be  combined 
by  their  performing  different  tasks  simultane- 
ously, in  order  to  produce  a  joint  result, 
and  as  soon  as  this  is  recognised  the  growth 
and  organisation  of  the  community  become 
capable  of  much  more  rapid  progress  than 
before.  A  maker  of  bows  can  do  his  work 
without  assistance,  but  his  labour  will  be  more 
efficient  if  he  can  send  out  some  one  to  collect 
suitable  pieces  of  wood  for  him.  A  skilful 
smith  could,  at  a  pinch,  make  a  simple  bit  of 
ironwork  by  his  own  unaided  exertions,  but  his 
trouble  is  enormously  lightened  if  he  has  an 
assistant  to  blow  his  bellows.  The  case  of  the 
smith  is  typical  of  all  operations  which  requu-e 
two  or  more  series  of  acts  to  be  performed  more 
or  less  simultaneously — in  this  case,  blowing  to 
keep  the  fire  hot,  and  hammering.  If  the 
piece  of  ironwoi-k  to  be  executed  is  at  all  large, 
an  assistant  becomes  indispensable.  The  thing 
could  not  be  done  at  all  without  him.  Suppos- 
ing he  gets  a  third  man  to  sharpen  or  polish 
such  articles  as  he  and  his  companion  have 
been  making,  the  efficiency  of  the  whole  group 
is  much  increased.  The  constitution  of  this 
group  of  artificers  illustrates  the  principle  of 
division  of  labour,  as  Adam  Smith  called  it. 
Modern  economists  have  adopted  the  more 
accurate  expression  division  of  employment,  but 
Smith's  description  of  the  principle  as  illus- 
trated in  pin-making  is  still  the  classical  de- 
scription in  the  English  language  (see  Wealth  of 
Nations,  bk.  i.  ch.  i.),  though  he  left  it  to  his 
successors,  e.g.  Babbage,  to  point  out  some  of 
the  most  important  advantages  of  the  division 
of  labour. 

What  is   called   civilised   society   has   only 


become  possible  because  this  principle  of  division 
of  employment  has  been  carried  out  to  the  full 
extent  admitted  of  by  the  progress  of  scientific 
knowledge.  For  an  analysis  of  the  reasons  why 
it  has  so  greatly  increased  the  efficiency  of 
labour,  reference  may  be  made  to  Mill,  bk.  i. 
ch.  viii. ;  Sidgwick,  bk.  i.  ch.  iv. ;  Marshall's 
Econoviics  of  Industry,  bk.  i.  ch.  vii.  viii. 
(see  Division  of  Labour).  Division  of  em- 
ployment implies,  however,  specialisation  of 
employment,  a  result  which  is  not  without 
disadvantages.  When  there  exist  large  bodies 
of  men  who  can  only  perform  some  special  kind 
of  skilled  labour,  portions  of  these  bodies  are 
from  time  to  time  in  danger  of  becoming 
redundant,  and  consequently  of  losing  their 
means  of  subsistence.  This  evil  result  may 
be  produced  by  climatic  influences,  by  a  mis- 
calculation as  to  the  requkements  of  the  com- 
munity, or  in  modern  times  of  the  communities 
supplied,  by  changes  of  fashion,  or  by  new  inven- 
tions. The  latter  cause  is  much  less  injurious 
to  the  men  than  it  used  to  be,  as  the  process  of 
improvement,  though  constant,  is  only  gradual. 
The  violent  disturbance  of  the  labour  market 
which  followed  the  first  introduction  of  steam 
machinery  and  of  the  factory  system  is  not 
likely  to  occur  again.  The  other  three  causes 
are  still  active  and  produce  serious  effects.  It 
is  to  be  observed  that  specialisation  of  emjjloy- 
ment  is,  from  the  nature  of  the  work  to  be  done, 
much  less  extensively  carried  out  in  agriculture 
than  in  manufacturing. 

The  mode  in  which  the  co-operation  of  indi- 
viduals in  modern  society  occurs  presents  other 
aspects  besides  division  or  specialisation  of 
employment.  It  is  marked,  as  is  well  known, 
by  the  association  of  larger  and  larger  bodies  of 
men  acting  under  a  single  firm  or  company. 
Provided  the  management  is  good  a  large  busi- 
ness can  be  conducted  more  economically  than 
a  small  one, — that  is,  the  labour  of  those  con- 
cerned is  more  efficient  in  the  former  than  in 
the  latter  case.  Of  late  years  this  tendency 
has  taken  the  form  of  the  amalgamation  under 
one  management  of  several  works  engaged 
in  producing  the  same  article.  Another  very 
important  feature  of  the  modern  conditions  of 
industrial  life  is  the  high  degree  of  dependence 
of  each  industry  for  its  prosperity  on  the  pros- 
perity of  other  industries.  Any  influence  tend- 
ing to  increase  the  activity  of  one  trade  tends 
to  make  several  other  trades  more  active,  and 
generally  the  efficiency  of  labour  in  all  trades 
is  increased  to  some  extent.  Conversely  depres- 
sion in  one  trade  produces  depression  in  others. 
A  high  degree  of  economic  efficiency  arising 
from  a  high  degree  of  industrial  organisation 
necessarily  carries  with  it  a  liability  to  frequent 
derangement  of  that  organisation,  the  parts 
forming  the  industrial  organism  becoming  mora 
mutually  dependent  in  proportion  as  differenti- 
ation is  carried  further. 


410 


CO-OPERATIVE  ASSOCIATIONS 


(b)  Co-operation  in  the  sense  of  an  associa- 
tion of  individuals  for  certain  specific  business 
purposes  is  of  two  kinds :  associations  of  con- 
sumers, and  associations  of  producers. 

Associations  of  consumers  arose  from  the 
desire  of  individuals  in  the  possession  of  small 
incomes  to  obtain  the  commodities  they  require 
for  daily  use  at  wholesale  prices.  In  1844 
twenty-eight  workmen  of  Rochdale  subscribed 
a  fund  to  be  used  in  the  purchase  of  flour, 
sugar,  and  other  articles,  which  were  bought 
retail  by  the  subscribers  at  the  ordinary  prices 
of  the  district,  the  excess  realised  being  periodic- 
ally divided  among  the  members  after  all  costs 
had  been  met.  The  experiment  was  thoroughly 
successful  and  has  been  widely  imitated.  Shops 
worked  on  this  principle  are  now  well  known  as 
co-operative  stores.  Those  carried  on  by  work- 
men, which  are  now  very  numerous,  have  in 
some  cases  adhered  to  the  lines  on  which  they 
were  started,  which  included  the  division  of 
part  of  the  profits  among  the  persons  employed 
in  the  store,  and  the  setting  aside  of  another 
part  for  educational  purposes,  but  in  some 
cases  these  latter  practices  have  been  dropped, 
the  whole  surplus  being  divided  among  the 
members  of  the  store.  The  encouragement  to 
thrift  has  been  very  great.  The  profits  being 
at  the  disposal  of  the  members  only  at  fixed 
intervals,  and  in  appreciably  large  amounts,  are 
less  likely  to  be  dissipated.  The  stores  also 
afford  direct  facilities  for  investment.  As  a 
working  man  co-operator  said,  "We  may  al- 
most eat  and  drink  ourselves  into  a  house." 
The  enormous  institutions  started  in  London  by 
members  of  the  middle  classes  have  been  highly 
successful,  but  are  not  co-operative  in  the  special 
sense  in  which  the  word  is  used  by  those  to 
whom  "co-operation"  is  a  species  of  religion. 
These  great  stores  sell  their  goods  at  the  lowest 
price  they  can,  which  is,  of  course,  an  excellent 
thing,  and  just  what  is  wanted  by  the  classes  for 
whose  benefit  these  stores  are  intended,  but  the 
persons  employed  in  them  have  no  share  in  the 
profits.  The  consumers,  as  such,  have  no  share 
in  the  profits.  It  is  this  feature  in  their  or- 
ganisation which  leads  "  co-operators  "  in  the 
more  special  sense  of  the  term,  to  deny  that  these 
stores  are  truly  co-operative.  Useful  as  they  are 
they  are  less  interesting  to  the  economist  than 
the  real  co-operative  associations,  from  the 
growth  of  which  great  and  salutary  changes  in 
the  structure  of  society  are  looked  for  by  those 
who  are  best  acquainted  with  the  subject. 
Many  of  them  have  become  merely  large 
shops  differing  hardly  at  all  from  big  com- 
mercial concerns. 

Co  -  operative  Societies.  —  The  associations 
which  are  conducted  in  the  United  Kingdom, 
either  theoretically  or  in  fact,  oii  true  co-opera- 
tive principles,  are  of  two  kinds,  distributive 
and  manufacturing.  The  origin  of  distri- 
butive  societies  has  already  been  referred  to, 


and  it  is  not  necessary  to  go  at  length  into  the 
history  of  the  movement  which,  from  such 
small  beginnings,  has  achieved  the  remarkable 
results  now  apparent.  The  manufacturing 
and  industrial  side  of  the  movement  has 
not  yet  attained  its  proper  development  in 
the  United  Kingdom.  Subjoined  are  tables 
which  will  furnish  a  general  idea  of  the 
present  magnitude  of  this  movement,  from 
which  so  much  is  hoped  by  thoughtful  students 
of  sociology.  The  figures  of  which  these  tables 
are  a  condensation,  will  be  found  in  full  in  the 
Report  of  the  Central  Co-operative  Board  to 
the  Plymouth  Congress,  1910. 

The  following  is  a  statement  of  the  number 
of  co-operative  societies  existing  in  the  United 
Kingdom  at  the  end  of  1909,  and  of  certain 
particulars  regarding  their  business  ;  arranged 

(A)  with  reference  to  geographical  divisions  ; 

(B)  according  to  the  special  functions  they 
perform. 


Sections. 

1  No.  of 
Socie- 
ties. 

No.  of 
Mem- 
bers. 

Share 
Capital. 

Irish  ...... 

23 

i      223 

145 

475 

294 

223 

81 

97 

9,335 

311,437 

304,589 

l,0fff,186 

405,129 

370,381 

98,711 

78,525 

£52,111 

3,344,188 

4,687,461 

16,388,278 

5,245,820 

2,742,394 

813,707 

862,005 

Midland.     .»    . 

Northern    .     . 
North  Western 
Sco'etish      .    . 
Southern     .    . 
South  Western 

• 

Total     .... 

1561 

2,585,293 

34,135,964 

Sections. 

Invest- 
ments. 

Received 
for  goods 
sold  '09. 

Net  profit 
in  '09. 

Irish 

£27,601 
1,823,913 
2,915,667 
11,895,699 
5,636,759 
1,270,307 
414,765 
472,251 

£280,942 

7,529,806 

10,769,530 

54,925,533 

22,714,409 

7,978,530 

1,769,508 

2,884,006 

£20,716 

883,620 

1,872,510 

5,134,424 

2,852,785 

619,297 

220,415 

407,356 

Midland     .    . 
Northern   .     . 
North  Western 
Scottish     .     . 
Southern   .     . 
South  Western 
Western     .    . 

Total    .... 

24,456,962 

108,852,264 

12,011,123 

1 


Sections. 

No.  of 

Socie- 
ties. 

No.  of 
Mem- 
bers. 

Share 
Capital. 

Distributive  .  .  . 
Productive .... 

Supply 

Special 

English  Wholesale 

Distributive     .    . 

Productive  .  .  . 
Scottish  Wholesale 

Distributive     .    . 

Productive  .    .    . 

1430 

119 

4 

6 

1 
1 

2,469,039 

31,806 

81,755 

1,254 

1,163 
276 

£ 
30,804,246 
858,039 
378,792 
26,644 

1,657,305 
410,938 

Total     .... 

1561 

2,585,293 

34,135,964 

CO-OPEEATIVE  ASSOCIATIONS 


411 


Sections. 

Invest- 
ments 

Received 
for  goods 
sold  '09 

Net  profit 
iu'09 

Distributive .  .  . 
Productive  .  .  . 
Supply  .... 
Special  .... 
English  Wholesale 

Distributive  .     . 

Productive  .  . 
Scottish  Wholesale 

Distributive  .     . 

Productive     .    . 

£ 

20,405,988 

452,448 

148,733 

290,644 

1,487,094 
1,672,055 

£ 

70,315,078 

3,142,047 

2,104,618 

157,447 

19,469,782 
6,206,156 

5,090,421 
2,366,715 

£ 

10,847,945 

184,159 

52,006. 

4,257 

429,208 
201,310 

232,493 
59,745 

Total  .... 

24,456,962 

108,852,264 

12,011,123 

Statement  showing  the  above  items  at  the  end  of 
the  undermentioned  years. 


Yrs. 

Socie- 
ties. 

Mem- 
bers. 

Share 
Capital. 

Trade. 

Prolits. 

1861 
1871 
1881 
1890 
1909 

746 
1230 
1554 
1561 

48,184 

262,188 

642,783 

1,117,085 

2,585,293 

£ 

333,290 

2,305,951 

6,937,284 

12,2(51,952 

34,135,964 

£ 

1,512,117 

9,437,471 

24,926,005 

43,215,710 

108,852,264 

£ 

670,721 

1,970,576 

4,170, OlitS 

12,011,123 

It  will  be  at  once  seen  from  a  glance  at  the 
totals  given  in  these  tables  that,  taken  as  a 
whole,  the  societies  to  which  they  refer  are  in  a 
highly  satisfactory  condition.  The  net  profit 
of  £12,011,123  shown  at  the  end  of  1909  is 
very  large  relatively  to  the  share  capital,  and 
the  investments  amounted  at  that  time  to 
over  £24,456,000.  The  value  of  stock,  land, 
buildings,  etc.  was,  we  may  observe,  over 
£28,286,948.  ■ 

The  strength  of  the  movement  lies,  in  the 
northern  and  north-western  districts  of  England 
and  in  Scotland.  Manchester  is,  indeed,  the 
headquarters  of  co-operation,  for  it  is  there  that 
the  English  Wholesale  Society,  whicli  is  com- 
monly called  "The  Wholesale,"  has  its  chief 
office ;  but  the  great  societies  of  Rochdale, 
Leeds,  Halifax,  Huddersfield,  Burnley,  Accring- 
ton,  Bolton,  and  Bradford  each  contribute  a 
very  large  quota  to  the  total  business  done.  In 
the  midland,  southern,  and  western  districts 
co-operation  is  very  imperfectly  developed,  but 
great,  and  to  a  large  extent  successful,  efforts 
are  being  made  to  improve  matters  in  this  respect, 
especially  in  London. 

One  fact  which  should  be  noted  was  the  small 
volume  of  co-operative  production  twenty  years 
ago — meaning  by  co-operative  production,  in 
the  full  sense,  a  system  in  which  the  wage- 
earners,  as  such,  share  in  the  profits.  This 
feature  was  a  source  of  keen  regret  and  dis- 
appointment to  zealous  co-operators.  The 
report  of  the  Committee  on  Production  to  the 
Ipswich  Congress,  1889,  was  in  many  respects 
hopeful,  and  some  progress  has  been  made 
since  then,  but  the  obstacles  to  success  in  this 
department  of  co-operation  are,  and  always 
have  been,  much  greater  than  in  the  distributive 


department.  The  difficulty  which  impressed 
the  Ipswich  Committee  most  was  to  get  pro 
ductive  societies  to  abstain  from  competing 
with  each  other,  as  will  be  seen  from  the 
following  extracts  from  their  report :  "As  we 
have  before  stated  in  our  reports,  we  have  to 
admit  that  in  the  multiplication  of  these  very 
small  societies,  each  struggling  for  a  separate  life, 
there  is  the  possibility  of  great  difficulty  in  the 
future.  We  have  to  regret  that  our  attempts 
to  bring  these  societies  into  federation  with  each 
other  have  entirely  failed,  owing  in  a  great 
measure  to  petty  jealousies  which  seem  insepar- 
able from  such  associations.  In  the  view  of 
this  committee  it  is  a  matter  for  serious  con- 
sideration how  far  the  formation  of  these  small 
and  isolated  societies  should  be  encouraged, 
unless  there  is  some  guarantee  that  they  will 
act  in  co-operation  with  each  other."  And  in 
concluding  the  report,  the  committee  observe, 
"that  there  still  exists  among  co-operative 
societies  and  their  members  a  deplorable  amount 
of  disloyalty  towards  the  efforts  of  those  societies 
which  are  honestly  striving  to  work  out  this 
difficult  problem  of  co-operative  production." 
These  severe  expressions  are  quoted  partly  in 
order  to  explain  the  comparative  I'ailure  of  pro- 
ductive co-operation  at  first,  and  partly  to 
show  that  the  leaders  of  the  co  -  operative 
movement  were  men  who  looked  facts  in  the 
face,  and  did  not  seek  to  disguise  them  under  a 
cloud  of  words.  This  is  an  attitude  of  mind 
^\hich  is  favourable  to  the  ultimate  success  of 
the  movement.  It  might  almost  be  said  that 
it  is  a  guarantee  of  it,  for  the  principle  of  pro- 
ductive co-operation  is  a  sound  one,  though  its 
practice  requires  tiie  prevalence  of  a  higher  level 
of  education,  both  moral  and  mental,  than  at 
present  exists  in  the  majority  of  co-operators. 
That  a  greater  approximation  towards  the  prin- 
ciple is  possible  may  perliaps  be  inferred  from 
the  fact  that,  besides  the  W^holesale's  boot 
and  shoe  works  at  Leicester,  there  are  four 
corn-milling  societies,  each  of  which  soid  over 
£100,000  of  goods  in  1909,  wliile  one  of  these, 
the  Halifax  Flour  Mills,  sold  over  £446,000 
worth,  and  had  £228,400  of  investments  at 
the  end  of  1909.  Flour  mills  are  still,  as  they 
were  twenty  years  ago,  the  most  successful 
branch  of  the  movement ;  their  sales  in  1909 
were  £1,106,000,  out  of  a  total  of  £2,287,000. 
In  Scotland  bakeries  do  the  largest  business. 
Co-operative  farming  has  so  far  answered  less 
well  in  the  United  Kingdom  (see  Co-operative 
Farming),  though  something  in  this  direction 
has  been  done  in  Scotland,  and  butter-making 
on  the  co-operative  plan  has  been  commenced 
in  Ireland  through  the  exertions  of  Canon  Bagot 
and  the  Hon.  H.  C.  Plunkett.  As  will  be  seen 
below,  co-operative  farming  is  far  from  being  a 
failure  on  the  continent. 

It  has   already  been  said  that  co-operative 
manufacturing  encounters  much  greater  diifi- 


412 


CO-OPERATIVE  ASSOCIATIONS 


eulties  than  co-operative  distribution.  The 
nature  of  the  difficulties  has  been  described  as 
they  present  themselves  practically  to  the  able 
and  energetic  men  who  are  trying  year  by  year 
to  overcome  them.  They  can  only  be  got  rid 
of  by  degrees,  for  they  are  the  result  of  tlje  low 
state  of  general  education.  Professor  Marshall 
has  pointed  out  in  The  Econcytnics  of  Industry, 
and  also  in  his  address  to  the  Ipswich  Congress 
(1889),  that  higher  mental  qualities  are  needed 
for  carrying  on  a  large  manufacturing  concern 
than  in  conducting  a  successful  shop.  At 
present  workmen  have  not  realised  that  good 
management  must  be  paid  for  and  is  worth 
paying  for  (compare  Walker,  The  Wages  Ques- 
tion, ch.  XV.,  Co-operation :  getting  rid  of  the 
entrepreneur).  Their  attitude  in  regard  to  this 
subject  is  shown  by  the  remark  attributed  to 
one  who  is  now  a  Cabinet  Minister,  that  "he 
had  never  seen  a  man  who  was  worth  more  than 
£5  0  0  a  year. "  It  is  not  suggested  that  managers 
of  co-operative  societies  ought  to  be  paid  at  this 
or  any  other  specific  rate  in  all  cases,  but  until 
workmen  generally  realise  that  there  are  men 
whose  worth  for  special  purposes  is,  in  the 
present  state  of  society,  £500,  and  even  more 
than  £5000  per  annum,  they  will  never  under- 
stand why  co-operative  manufacturing  fails  to 
succeed  in  competing  with  its  capitalist  rivals. 
Still  the  obvious  success  of  the  Halifax  Flour 
Mills  is  evidence  that  in  one  branch  of  trade, 
at  any  rate,  co-operators  can  adapt  themselves 
to  the  industrial  requirements  of  the  time  if 
they  take  the  proper  means. 

The  plain  fact  is  that  co-operative  manufac- 
turing is  still  in  the  experimental  stage.  Pro- 
gress has  been  made  since  1889  when,  at  the 
annual  Co-operative  Congress,  held  at  Ipswich 
in  that  year,  there  was  an  interesting  dis- 
cussion on  the  question  whether  small  produc- 
tive societies  should  be  encouraged  to  continue 
to  work  independently  of  the  Wholesale,  or 
whether  the  Wholesale  should  undertake  the 
work  itself.  The  discussion  ostensibly  related 
to  the  best  means  of  establishing  Profit- sharing 
{q.v.)  in  production,  and  the  chief  charge  brought 
against  the  Wholesale  was  that  it  did  not  share 
profits  with  its  workers,  that,  like  some  of  the 
original  societies,  it  had  degenerated  into  "  joint- 
stockism."  The  latter  principle  did  not  seem 
to  be  wholly  approved  even  by  the  advocates  of 
production  by  the  Wholesale  Society,  but  Mr. 
Benjamin  Jones,  of  the  Wholesale,  in  the  course 
of  a  paper  read  to  the  congress,  pointed  out  that 
at  Oldham,  where  many  mills  are  owned  by 
workmen,  "  joint- stockism  "  had  led  to  the  same 
results  as  "  profit-sharing"  was  intended  to  lead 
to  by  making  workmen  well  off.  The  whole  dis- 
cussion, which  ended  in  the  approval  by  the 
congress  of  production  carried  on  by  societies  in- 
dependent of  the  Wholesale,  but  "  federalised, " 
was  a  very  business-like  one.  There  are,  of 
course,  numerous  differences  of  opinion  on  minor 


technical  points  in  relation  to  distributive  co- 
operation, the  most  important  of  which  is  the 
question  how  far  credit  should  be  allowed  to 
members  of  stores.  The  balance  of  opinion  is, 
it  need  hardly  be  said,  against  the  giving  of 
credit. 

Co  -  operation  abroad  can  only  be  briefly 
touched  on  here.  A  good  deal  of  valuable  in- 
formation on  the  subject  will  be  found  in  a 
paper  by  Mr.  Vaughan  Nash  on  ' '  Co-operation 
in  relation  to  International  Commerce,"  read 
before  the  Ipswich  Congress.  Mr.  Nash  had  a 
special  object  in  writing  this  paper,  namely,  to 
urge  on  co-operators  in  different  countries  the 
advantage  that  would  result  from  their  working 
together  more  than  at  present,  but  it  furnished 
a  useful  rdsumA  of  the  position  of  co-operation 
in  foreign  countries  in  1888.  During  the  last 
twenty  years  a  considerable  change  has  taken 
place  in  the  attitude  of  the  continental  socialist 
co-operators.  For  many  years  they  despised 
co-operation  among  consumers,  as  being  a 
"bourgeois  institution"  and  a  support  to 
*'  capitalism."  They  have  discovered  that,  even 
from  their  point  of  view,  co-operation  among 
consumers  has  merits.  This  was  perceived  first 
in  Belgium  and  later  in  other  places.  At  the 
International  Co-operative  Alliance,  which  held 
its  meeting  in  Hamburg  in  1910,  a  body  of 
socialists  who  had  been  attending  the  Socialist 
Congress  at  Copenhagen  were  present  in  order 
to  cement  an  alliance  between  Socialism  and 
Co-operation,  on  equal  terms.  The  free  develop- 
ment of  co-operation  is  now  recognised  as  a 
good  thing  by  the  socialist  leaders  of  the 
Continental  Countries.  In  two  important, 
respects  these  countries  are  still  in  a  decidedly 
more  advanced  condition  than  the  united  King- 
dom, namely,  in  regard  to  agriculture  and 
banking.  In  France,  Austria,  Germany,  Den- 
mark, Italy,  Switzerland,  and  Sweden,  there 
exist  powerful  organisations  of  peasant  pro- 
prietors for  the  joint  purchase  or  hire  of  farming 
implements  and  other  requirements,  for  acquiring 
and  working  dairies,  for  the  joint  sale  of  pro- 
duce and  for  obtaining  credit.  Long  ago 
Denmark  possessed  a  most  highly  organised 
system  of  agricultural  co-operation,  and  it  is 
owing  to  this  that  the  export  of  Danish  butter 
has  so  much  increased  of  late.  Co-operative 
dairies  seem  to  succeed  in  most  countries,  includ- 
ing the  United  States,  where  ' '  creameries  "  are 
an  important  feature.  There  can  be  little  doubt 
that  the  system  of  popular  banks  with  which 
the  name  of  Schulze-Delitsch  is  associated  has 
been  of  great  service  to  agricultural  co-operation 
in  Germany,  and  a  modification  of  the  same  plan 
devised  by  Signer  Luzzati  was  many  years  ago 
introduced  into  Italy  {v.  Banks,  Popular). 
These  loan  societies  are  closely  connected  with 
the  farming  societies,  being  in  fact  chiefly  com- 
posed of  the  same  individuals.  They  coiuraet 
loans  on  the  guarantee  of  all  the  members  and 


CO-OPERATIVE  FARMING 


413 


make  advances  to  members  at  a  slightly  higher 
rate  than  that  at  which  they  borrow,  but  still 
much  below  the  terras  at  which  the  individual 
members  could  raise  money  themselves.  As 
regards  the  joint  sale  of  agricultural  produce 
the  system  is  less  developed  than  in  other 
respects,  and,  generally,  distributive  co-operation 
is  too  much  neglected  on  the  continen^t,  except 
in  Switzerland  and  Holland,  and  to  some 
extent  in  Belgium.  As  is  well  known,  there 
are  co-operative  workshops  in  France  of  old 
standing,  the  most  famous  being  those  with 
which  the  names  of  Godin  at  Guise  and  Leclairo 
at  Paris  are  associated  (v.  CiT]5  OirvmfeRE  ; 
Familist^he).  These  two  experiments  in 
profit-sharing  have  realised  a  remarkable  degree 
of  success.  It  had  always  been  feared,  even 
by  friends  of  co-operation,  that  such  institutions 
were  dependent  on  the  lives  of  the  individuals 
who  started  them,  but  so  far  these  unfavourable 
anticipations  have  been  agreeably  disappointed. 
For  a  description  of  the  very  successful  work 
carried  out  by  the  late  M.  Godin  see  tlie  trans- 
lation of  the  pamphlet  Twenty-eight  Years  of 
Co-partnership  at  Guise,  published  by  the 
Labour  Co-partnership  Association,  6  Blooms- 
bury  Square,  London,  W.C,  The  Right  Hon. 
T.  Burt,  in  the  preface,  bespeaks  "the  careful 
attention  of  co-operators,  of  trade  unionists, 
of  liberal-minded  employers  "  to  this  interesting 
history. 

"Russia,"  says  Mr.  Nash,  "is  by  far  the 
most  co-operative  country  in  Europe,  but  its 
vDlage  communities,  or  mirs,  are  beginning  to 
show  sigTis  of  dissolution,  and  its  artels,  being 
nomadic  and  shifting,  have  but  little  bearing 
on  the  question  of  international  co-operation." 
The  Artel  (g-.u)  is  a  species  of  workmen's  society 
which  is  found  in  all  branches  of  industry  in 
Russia,  the  members  of  which  jointly  execute 
pieces  of  work,  especially  buildings,  railways, 
and  bridges. 

As  regards  the  United  States,  we  have  already 
mentioned  the  existence  of  creameries  as  the 
most  important  feature  from  a  co-operative  point 
of  view,  but  there  are  also  some  co-operative 
workshops.  There  were  also  many  co-operative 
stores  before  the  Civil  War,  but  their  progi-ess 
since  then  has  been  very  slow.  In  the  British 
colonies  there  is  very  little  co-operation  of  any 
kind.  w.  H. 

Co-operative  Farming.  The  application 
of  co-operation  to  agriculture  was  one  of  the 
earliest  aims  of  the  founders  of  co-operation, 
and  formed  a  part  of  almost  all  the  plans  of 
Robert  Owen  and  his  followers.  The  best 
known  experiment  in  the  pioneer  period  was 
that  of  Rathlahine  (sometimes  called  Rala- 
hine),  in  County  Clare,  Ireland,  in  1831-33. 
Mr.  E.  T.  Craig,  a  disciple  of  Robert  Owen, 
was  invited  by  Mr.  J.  Scott  Vandeleur,  an 
Irish  landlord,  to  form  a  society  based  on 
the   co-partnership   of   landlord   and   tenant. 


The  farm  was  618  acres  in  extent,  half  of 
it  under  tillage.  The  labourers  at  the  outset 
numbered  twenty -eight  men,  twelve  women, 
and  fifty -two  children.  Subsequent  admis- 
sions to  membership  were  by  ballot.  Mr. 
Vandeleur,  the  landlord,  was  president  and  re  • 
served  to  himself  a  power  of  veto,  as  well  as 
the  right  to  discharge  labourers  during  the  first 
year.  He  also  stipulated  for  the  exclusion  of 
intoxicants.  The  labourers  elected  a  committee 
who  met  nightly  to  arrange  the  farm  work. 
At  the  year's  end  the  landlord  received  his  rent 
of  £900  in  kind,  taking  the  risks  of  variations 
in  value.  The  rest  of  the  produce,  which  was 
not  consumed  by  the  members  and  charged  to 
them,  was  sold  for  common  account.  The 
first  profits  were  appropriated  to  enhancing 
wages  twenty  and  twenty-five  per  cent.  The 
surplus  beyond  was  devoted  to  a  fund  to  pay 
out  the  landlord.  The  experiment  was  success- 
ful commercially.  It  also  restored  peace  on 
the  estate  and  established  harmony  in  the 
relations  of  the  landlord  and  his  people.  But 
it  was  brought  to  a  sudden  end  in  1833  by 
the  flight  of  Mr.  Vandeleur,  who  had  ruined 
himself  by  gambling  (see  Co-operative  Agri- 
culture by  Wm.  Pare,  Longmans,  1870  ;  and 
History  of  Ealaliine,  by  E.  T.  Craig  ;  Triibner 
and  Co.,  1882).  About  the  same  time,  1829, 
Mr.  "Wm.  Gurdon  leased  a  farm  at  Assington, 
Suffolk,  to  a  body  of  his  labourers  who  formed 
themselves  into  a  voluntary  co-operative  society, 
based  on  a  plan  of  dividing  equally  the  produce 
of  the  farm.  He  lent  them  capital  without 
interest.  The  experiment  was  very  successful, 
the  labourers  repaying  the  loan  capital  and 
making  large  profits  for  themselves.  This 
success  led  to  the  leasing  of  a  second  farm  to 
labourers  in  1853,  to  be  worked  on  the  same 
lines.  This  also  was  very  successful,  yielding 
a  profit  to  the  labourers  of  £3674  up  to  1879. 
In  1883  the  association  had  to  ask  for  help 
from  outside  sympathisers,  in  consequence  of 
continued  agricultural  depression.  The  land 
being  stiff  clay,  almost  all  under  tillage,  is 
suitable  for  little  else  but  wheat-growing,  and 
the  co-operative  labourers  were  unable  to  make 
a  profit  on  wheat-growing  after  1879.  In  1884 
a  co-operative  society  was  formed  to  continue 
the  farm,  the  labourers'  capital  being  augmented 
by  subscriptions  of  co-operative  societies  and 
friends.  This  society,  the  Assington  Agri- 
cultural Association,  at  present  shows  an 
annual  loss  of  about  £1  per  acre.  The  No.  1 
farm  established  in  1829  is  still  being  worked 
by  the  labourers'  society,  but  no  accounts  are 
published. 

In  1829  Lord  Wallscourt  commenced  an 
Irish  experiment,  and  reported  in  1846  that, 
after  seventeen  years'  trial,  the  venture  had 
-answered  beyond  his  hopes  ;  he  had  been  able 
to  travel  abroad  a  year  at  a  time,  and  on  his 
return  always  found  the  farm  had  prospered. 


414 


CO-OPERATIVE  FARMING 


He  divided  profits  with  his  labourers,  reckoning 
every  £5  of  their  wages  as  being  equal  to  £100 
of  his  own  capital.  (See  Professor  F.  W. 
Newman's  Lectures  ov,  Political  Economy,  p. 
338,  Chapman,  1851.) 

After  the  pioneer  periods  of  Robert  Owen 
and  the  Christian  socialists,  the  co-operative 
movement,  advancing  on  the  line  of  least 
resistance,  left  farming  experiments — as  it  left 
productive  efforts — almost  neglected,  and  at- 
tended almost  exclusively  to  the  development 
of  the  simple  stores  system.  But  from  time  to 
time,  during  the  thirty  years  which  followed 
the  establishment  of  the  Rochdale  Pioneers 
Society  in  1844,  co-operative  farming  experi- 
ments were  made  by  advanced  co-operators. 
Mr.  Walter  Morrison,  M.P.,  established  a 
co-operative  farm  in  the  Midlands,  giving  the 
labourers  a  share  in  the  profits  and  management. 
The  experiment  was  partially  successful,  paying 
five  per  cent  interest,  but  in  other  respects  was 
not  considered  suflSciently  hopeful  to  render  it 
worth  while  to  persevere.  Lord  George  Manners 
adopted  profit-sharing  Math  his  labourers  upon 
a  farm  at  Cheveley,  Newmarket.  He  told  the 
writer  of  this  article  that  the  experiment  was 
so  successful  as  to  yield  him  ten  per  cent  on 
his  capital,  and  permit  of  £3  per  worker  being 
paid  as  dividend  on  labour.  To  stimulate 
thrift  Lord  G.  Manners  adopted  the  plan  of 
paying  the  labourers'  dividends  into  the  post 
office  savings  bank,  and  "handing  the  pass- 
books to  their  wives  " — a  device  which  he  said 
answered  perfectly.  It  was  his  intention  to 
form  a  more  complete  co-operative  society  to 
work  the  farm,  but  his  death  brought  this 
interesting  and  successful  effort  to  a  close. 
More  recently  Mr.  Bolton  King  established  two 
co-operative  farms  at  his  residence  near 
Leamington.  The  rules  were  very  generous  to 
the  labourers,  leaving  them  with  full  powers 
over  both  the  land  and  the  landlord's  capital 
without  the  checks  which  in  other  cases  have 
naturally  been  provided.  The  result  was  not 
successful.  Equally  unsuccessful  was  an  at- 
tempt by  Mr.  William  Lawson  at  Aspatria 
near  Carlisle,  described  by  him  in  a  work 
called  Five  Years  of  Gentleman  Farming,  edited 
by  G.  J.  Holyoake.  Mr.  William  Lawson,  a 
brother  of  Sir  Wilfrid  Lawson,  gave  time  and 
money  freely  to  his  effort,  but  he  adopted 
methods  of  farming  which  were  condemned  as 
impracticable  by  the  Royal  Agricultural  Society's 
Commissioners  on  steam  ploughing,  and  the 
failure  can  scarcely  therefore  be  imputed  to  the 
co-operative  arrangements  (vide  Jourtial  of  the 
Hoyal  Agricultural  Society  of  England). 

Recently  the  opinion  in  favour  of  co-opera- 
tive farming  has  received  a  great  impetus, 
and  many  co-operative  societies  have  taken 
farms  to  work  as  part  of  their  enterprise. 
The  report  of  the  Central  Co-operative  Board 
for  1910  gives  a  list  of  ninety-one  known  co 


operative  farms  of  which  the  following  is 
summary : — 


•ssot: 

^OOSrH  0«-H  to 

: 

•* 

■^UOJ<I 

£ 
1113 

1225 
436 

2574 
808 

S 

s 

£ 

4862 

2999 

1652 

1544 

506 

305 

165 

of 

•pauMO 
uo  :jseja:jni 

£ 
2054 
1872 
1716 

770 
1063 

448 
22 

^ 

i 

•pa^saAui 

£ 
52,735 
73,055 
52,542 
20,375 
30,090 
20,148 
750 

1 
< 

rt<  <M  OO  00  O  -*  O 
rH  >0  iC  Tf  ±- O  O 
O  t-j  OO  .O  CO  i-H  C^ 

f 

i- 

o 

t-rH«OrH-*(M      • 

i 

CO 

Number 
of  Co- 
operative 
Farms. 

^««^r-c,^ 

M 

s 

"^3 
ja  S  o 

PI 

Midland    .    . 
Northern  .     . 
North-western 
Scotland    .     . 
Southern  .    . 
South-West   , 
West     .     .    . 

J 

•go 

1" 

m 

I 

The  two  last  on  the  list  are  farms  worked 
by  separate  farming  societies,  all  the  others  are 
farms  attached  to  stores.  The  large  amount  of 
capital  invested  is  due  to  the  freeholds  having 
been  frequently  bought  by  co-operative  societies 
as  investments  for  their  surplus  capital.  The 
totals  show  that  over  ten  thousand  acres  are 
now  farmed  co-operatively  and  over  a  quarter 
of  a  million  of  capital  is  invested  in  the  farms. 
The  results  vary  very  greatly,  the  losses  on 
balance  nearly  equalling  the  piofits. 

Simultaneously  with  this  development  of 
farming  enterprise  inside  the  co-operative  move- 
ment, a  considerable  number  of  profit-sharing 
and  co-operative  experiments  have  been  set 
on  foot  by  landowners  and  farmers,  like  Earl 
Spencer,  Mr.  Boyd  Kinnear,  and  Lord  Wantage. 
The  latter  was  stated  to  have  taken  20,000  acres 
of  land  into  his  own  hands  and  adopted  a  plan  of 
working  it  upon  a  system  of  association  with 
the  labourers  which  paid  him  good  interest  and 
yielded  them  about  £2  each  of  dividend  on 
labour.  The  results  were  described  in  glowing 
terms  by  the  Daily  News  commissioner,  whose 
letters  have  been  published  in  book  form  (see 
Life  in  our  Villages,  Cassell  and  Co . ,  1 8 9 1 ).  In 
part  iv.  of  volume  ii.  3rd  series  of  the  Journal 
of  the  Royal  Agricultural  Society  (31st  December 
1891)  Mr.  Albert  Grey  reported  a  most  success- 
ful effort  at  co-operative  farming  carried  out  by 
him   in   Northumberland,  on  the   large   scale 


CO-OPERATIVE   WORKSHOPS 


415 


of  3765  acres,  of  which  1290  are  permanent 
pasture  and  2475  arable.  In  1886  he  com- 
menced on  the  Home  Farm  at  Hawick,  and  in 
the  next  four  years  was  able  to  pay  the  labourers 
three  annual  bonuses  of  6d.  in  the  £  on  their 
wages.  The  same  year  he  applied  the  profit- 
sharing  plan  to  the  East  Learmonth  farm  of 
821  acres,  of  which  all  is  arable  but  122  acres. 
In  the  case  of  this  farm  the  outgoing  tenant 
had  refused  to  continue  his  tenancy  unless  he 
were  allowed  a  reduction  of  20  per  cent  in  his 
rent.  Mr.  Grey  had  been  able  to  earn  the  old 
rent  under  the  profit-sharing  arrangement  and 
also  interest  on  capital.  In  addition  he  had 
paid  the  labourers  three  annual  bonuses,  viz. 
one  of  Is.  in  the  £,  one  of  Is  l|d.,  and  one  of 
Is.  3d.  Mr.  Grey  adopted  the  formula  for 
division  of  profits  carried  out  by  M.  Godin  of 
Guise  in  his  celebrated  co-operative  workshops 
(see  CiTt  OuvRifeRE).  Interest  on  capital 
ranks  as  equivalent  to  wages  of  labour  for  a 
pro  rata  division  of  profits  (see  Co-operative 
Traveller  Abroad,  Labour  Association,  London, 
1888).  On  the  additional  area  of  land  which 
Mr.  Grey  placed  under  the  profit  -  sharing 
system  in  1888,  he  was  sanguine  of  making  a 
profit,  and  his  whole  paper  was  filled  with  in- 
teresting details  of  economies  effected  and 
improvements  obtained  by  the  reconciliation  of 
interests  of  employer,  managers,  and  labourers. 
]\Ir.  Albert  Grey  subsecpiently  became  Earl 
Grey,  taking  an  active  part  in  public  life  as 
Governor  General  of  Canada  and  in  other 
capacities  which  absorbed  his  time  and  attention. 
In  view  of  the  recent  revival  in  agricultural 
prosperity  it  seems  evident  that  the  time  is 
ripe  for  the  application  of  co-operation  to  farm- 
ing, and  it  only  requires  the  evidence  of  a  few 
successes  on  a  considerable  scale  to  bring  about 
a  great  extension  of  the  movement.         e.  o.  g. 

It  has  been  proposed  (1911)  by  the  Board 
of  Agriculture,  to  spend  £20,000  through  the 
County  Councils  on  behalf  of  Agricultural 
Co-operation. 

Co-operative  Workshops.  In  the  article 
on  Co-operative  Associations  the  general 
fact  is  stated  that  productive  co-operation  has 
developed  much  more  slowly  than  distributive 
co-operation.  Forty  yeai's  ago  the  failures  of 
co-operative  workshops  were  so  numerous  that 
many  writers  held  that  co-operation  had  been 
proved  to  be  inaj^plicable  to  manufacturing. 
Professor  Beesly,  in  a  pamphlet  on  The  Social 
Future  of  the  Working  Class  (Reeves  and 
Turner),  1868,  stated  :  "I  believe  there  is  not 
in  England  at  the  present  moment  a  single 
co-operative  society  in  which  workmen  divide 
the  profits  irrespective  of  their  being  share- 
holders," and  he  concluded  that  "we  must  look 
for  improvement  not  to  this  or  that  new-fangled 
industrial  system,  but  to  the  creation  of  a. 
moral  and  religious  influence  which  may  bend 
all   in    obedience   to    duty.     When   we   have 


created  such  an  influence  we  shall  find  that  it 
will  act  more  certainly  and  eflectually  on  a 
small  body  of  capitalists  than  it  would  on  a 
loose  multitudinous  mob  of  co-operative  share- 
holders." So  far  as  this  was  a  statement  of 
facts  it  was  too  sweeping.  Mr.  J.  S.  Mill, 
Professor  Fawcett,  and  other  economists  could 
see  even  then  some  favourable  features  in  the 
struggling  experimental  attempts  at  workshop 
co-operation.  Upon  these  and  upon  confidence 
in  general  principles  they  based  very  hopeful 
forecasts  of  the  future,  and  the  latest  facts  and 
figures  seem  to  justify  their  views. 

Comparing  the  returns  issued  by  the  Co- 
operative Union  for  1909  with  those  issued  for 
1889,  the  following  figures  show  that  progress 
is  becoming  more  rapid  as  the  feeling  grows 
that   the    initial   diflaculties    have    been    over- 


1889. 

1909. 

Number  of  Co-operative 

Workshops  . 

106 

121 

Number  of  Members 

25,728 

31,806 

Share  Capital 

£714,189 

£858,039 

Loan  Capital  . 

£274,784 

£3,877,654 

Reserve  Funds 

£28,46',) 

£151,291 

Total  Funds   . 

£1,017,442 

£2,886,984 

Sales        .... 

£2,308,028 

£11,714,918 

Profits     .... 

£118,355 

£445,214 

Losses     .... 

£5,581 

£6,218 

Net  Gain 

£112,774 

£438,996 

if  a  coniimrison  is  made  between  the  latest  figures 
for  1909  and  those  for  1889,  it  will  be  found 
that  the  percentages  of  increase  in  20  years 
have  been  as  follows — in  number  of  workshops, 
14*15  percent;  in  members,  23-62  per  cent; 
in  share  capital,  24*34  per  cent  ;  in  business, 
407*57  per  cent;  and  in  profits,  276*16  per 
cent.  These  figures  show  that  whilst  there 
has  been  an  increase  of  new  societies  (possessing 
of  course  fewer  members  than  the  older  ones), 
the  established  societies  have  increased  their 
capital,  and  have  even  more  rapidly  gained  in 
trade  and  in  the  power  to  make  profits.  If  a 
further  comparison  is  made  of  the  growth  of  the 
co-operative  workshops  as  compared  with  the 
growth  of  the  co-operative  movement  generally, 
it  will  be  seen  that  the  productive  side  of  co- 
operation is  now  distinctly  vigorous  and  is 
probably  absorbing  the  most  energetic  and  cap- 
able co-operators.  The  following  were  the  per- 
centages of  increase  of  the  co-operative  movement 
in  1890  over  1888 — in  number  of  societies, 
3*48  per  cent;  in  members,  12*55  per  cent  ; 
in  share  capital,  17*97  per  cent  ;  in  business, 
17*59  per  cent;  and  in  profits,  22*13  per 
cent. 

Two  kinds  of  workshops  are  included  in  the 
figures  quoted  above  from  the  annual  returns 
of  the  Co-operative  Union,  viz.  workshops  which 
divide  their  profits  only  between  capital  and 
custom,  and  workshops  which  admit  labour  also 
into  partnership.     Repeated   resolutions   have 


416 


CO-OPERATIVE  WORKSHOPS 


been  passed  by  large  majorities  of  delegates  at 
annual  co-operative  congresses  affirming  that 
the  true  principle  of  co-operation  in  production 
requires  the  co-partnership  of  labour.  But  the 
Central  Co-operative  Board,  which  is  the  execu- 
tive of  the  movement,  is  reluctant  to  exclude 
from  recognition  the  large  workshops  which 
belong  to  the  Co-operative  Wholesale  Society, 
and  those  corn  mills  belonging  to  stores  which 
violate  the  principle  laid  down  by  congress. 
The  burning  question  of  the  movement  has 
been  whether  the  inclusion  of  the  worker  to 
share  in  profits  and  mabagement  is  essential  or 
not.  As  the  promoters  of  industrial  co-operation 
are  generally  agreed  that  nothing  short  of  the 
partnership  of  labour  with  capital  will  finally 
reconcile  the  two  interests  and  end  conflict, 
public  interest  naturally  centres  most  around 
the  workshops  in  which  co-partnership  exists. 
According  to  the  annual  reports  and  other  pub- 
lications of  the  Labour  Co-partnership  Associa- 
tion (of  6  Bloomsbury  Square,  London)  the 
co-operative  workshops  which  recognise  the 
principle  of  profit-sharing  with  labour  now 
number  one  hundred  and  twelve,  and  are 
therefore  in  a  majority.  Eight  or  nine  of  them 
have  beeii  in  existence  over  forty  years.  They 
are  established  in  almost  all  parts  of  the  kingdom 
and  in  about  forty  different  trades.  The  number 
of  workers  employed  is  between  four  thousand 
and  five  thousand.  The  Labour  Co-partnership 
Association,  which  devotes  itself  especially  to 
the  establishment  and  welfare  of  these  profit- 
sharing  societies,  holds  exhibitions  of  their  pro- 
ductions, and  the  goods  shown  are  said  to  be 
very  excellent  and  tasteful.  The  practicability  of 
successful  manufacturing  on  co-partnership  lines 
may  therefore  be  considered  to  be  established. 

The  absence  of  strikes  seems  to  be  satisfac- 
torily assured.  Where  strikes  have  been  made 
public  in  connection  with  "  co-operative  "  work- 
shops they  have  been  in  factories  which  exclude 
the  workers  from  participation.  Only  one  small 
conflict  is  known  to  have  occurred  at  a  profit- 
sharing  workshop,  and  that  was  promptly 
settled. 

The  amelioration  of  the  social  position  of  the 
workers  cannot  be  wholly  stated  in  figures. 
The  addition  to  the  wages  in  the  shape  of 
"bonus"  or  "dividend  on  labour"  varies  very 
greatly,  but  appears  to  average  ll|d.  in  the  £, 
or  rather  under  5  per  cent  on  wages.  But 
only  a  portion  of  the  effect  of  profit-sharing  can 
be  seen  in  this  item.  It  is  stated  by  Mr.  Joseph 
Greenwood,  the  late  manager  of  the  Hebden 
Bridge  Fustian  Manufacturing  Society  in  York- 
shire, that  whilst  profit-sharing  with  them  added 
only  9d.  in  the  £  to  wages,  the  average -income 
of  their  workers  (men,  women,  and  children) 
had  been  increased  in  twenty  years  from  about 
12s.  6d.  per  week  up  to  over  l7s.  per  week,  the 
chief  increase  being  due  to  regularity  of  employ- 
ment and  saving  of  lost  time.      Fustian  cutting 


was  originally  a  sweated  industry,  but  the 
society  at  Hebden  Bridge  now  employs  296 
workers,  all  of  whom  are  shareholders.  They 
own  £9132  of  the  capital  stock,  which  amounts 
in  all  to  £29,615.  That  the  condition  of 
these  workers  must  have  been  greatly  im- 
proved beyond  the  amount  of  "bonus"  dis- 
tributed is  evident  from  the  fact  that  the  latter 
has  only  totalled  about  one-third  of  the  sums 
invested  by  the  workers  in  their  society.  The 
Labour  Co-partnership  Association,  moreover, 
adds  that  the  societies  which  have  been  formed 
in  recent  years  since  it  has  been  at  work  have 
almost  all  been  induced  to  adopt  rules  which 
make  provision  for  many  excellent  common 
funds.  Thus  the  Leicester  Co-operative  Boot 
and  Shoe  Manufacturing  Society  when  dividing 
£240  of  surplus  profits  (realized  during  a 
quarter-year)  apportioned  the  sum  thus :  to 
reserve  £40  ;  to  the  workers  (lO^d.  in  the  £  on 
wages),  £80  ;  to  the  committee  (who  are  nearly 
all  workers  in  the  factory),  £24  ;  to  the  educa- 
tional fund,  £10  ;  to  the  provident  fund,  £20  ; 
to  the  special  service  fund  for  rewarding  inven- 
tions and  economies,  £6  ;  to  capital  (in  addi 
tion  to  6  per  cent),  £20  ;  to  customers  (2|d. 
in  the  £  on^  purchases)^  £40.  In  this  case  the 
lO^d.  "  dividend  on  wages  "  fonned  but  a  third 
portion  of  the  whole  benefits. 

The  increase  in  the  productiveness  of  labour 
under  co-partnership  rules  seems  very  clear. 
The  Agricultural  and  Horticultural  Association 
commenced  some  years  ago  to  manufacture 
oilcake  for  cattle,  putting  down  machinery 
calculated  to  produce  35  tons  per  week  and 
subsequently  adding  other  machinery  calculated 
to  produce  60  tons  per  week.  At  first  the  new 
employes,  unfamiliar  with  the  profit-sharing 
system  of  the  Association,  only  produced  21  to 
26  tons  off  the  first  machinery  and  about  48 
tons  off  the  second.  But,  under  the  stimulus 
of  "bonus  "  the  first  set  of  machinery  now  pro- 
duces 57  tons  per  week  and  the  second  set 
produces  about  76  tons  per  week.  The  differ- 
ence in  output  converted  a  loss  into  a  profit  for 
the  Association,  whilst  the  average  remunera- 
tion of  the  workers  (men  and  youths)  went  up 
from  £1:0:7  per  week  to  £1  :  6  :  8. 

The  result  upon  the  position  of  capital  in 
these  workshops  has  been  to  substitute  a  safe 
and  steady  reasonable  dividend  for  a  higher 
but  fluctuating  one.  As  the  societies  attain 
success  they  decrease  the  dividends  on  capital 
instead  of  increasing  them.  Several  leading 
workshops  have  recently  done  so,  including  the 
Hebden  Bridge  Fustian,  Leicester  Hosiery, 
Manchester  Printing,  Edinburgh  Printing,  and 
Paisley  Shawl  Manufacturing.  The  majorit;y 
of  shareholders,  being  customers  and  workers, 
attach  most  importance  to  the  dividends  on 
custom  and  on  wages,  and  decrease  the  dividend 
or  interest  on  capital  to  increase  these.  But 
this  does  not  appear  to  check  the  inflow  of  in 


CO-OPERATION,  PARTIAL 


417 


vestments,  as  the  dividend  or  interest  on  capital 
is  a  first  charge  on  the  whole  profits.  These 
being  swelled  by  the  stimulus  given  to  custom 
and  zeal  of  the  workers,  the  dividend  on  capital 
assumes  almost  the  sate  position  of  a  first  mort- 
gage, and  5  per  cent  is  found  amply  suffici6at 
to  attract  funds.  E.  o.  G. 

Co-operation,  Partial  (Oldham  Cotton- 
Spinning  Companies).  The  term  "partial 
co-operation "  is  ap[)lied  by  Prof.  Marshall 
{Principles  of  Economics,  vol.  i.  p.  364,  2nd 
edition)  to  such  partial  applications  of  the 
co-operative  principle  to  production  as  (a) 
profit-  or  profit-and-loss  sharing  (see  Profit- 
Sharing),  {h)  the  Leicester  boot  works  and 
other  similar  productive  establishments  owned 
by  the  main  body  of  co-operative  stores 
through  their  agents  the  wholesale  (see  Co- 
operation and  Co-operative  Workshops), 
and  (c)  certain  joint -stock  cotton -spinning 
companies  in  Oldham  and  its  neighbourhood. 
These  last  are  owned  by  combinations  of  small 
capitalists,  among  whom  are  many  workpeo]jle 
with  a  special  knowledge  of  the  cotton  industry, 
though  few  of  the  companies'  employes  can 
describe  themselves  as  "their  own  masters." 
It  is  customary,  but  incorrect,  to  call  these 
concerns  "co-operative  mills,"  and  to  say  that 
many  of  them  are  owned  by  the  working  classes. 
It  is,  however,  true  that  the  foundation  of  a 
number  of  the  Oldham  "  Limiteds  "  was  due 
to  an  attempt  by  working  men  to  a]tply  the 
co-operative  principle  to  production.  The  early 
history  of  the  Sun  Mill  Company  is  typical  of 
the  whole  movement  in  its  initial  stages,  and 
throws  much  light  on  the  difficulties  attending 
even  a  partial  application  of  such  a  principle 
to  a  highly  organised  industry. 

The  "Oldham  Building  and  Manufacturing 
Society,"  the  first  of  its  kind  registered  under 
the  Joint- Stock  Companies  Act,  was  founded  in 
1858  :  capital  £1000  in  £5  shares.  The  pro- 
moters were  members  of  the  Oldham  Industrial 
Co-operative  Society.  Calls  on  shares  were  to 
be  3d,  weekly,  and  the  directors  were  paid  6d.  a 
week  for  their  services.  Several  months  elapsed 
before  all  the  shares  were  taken  up,  and  a 
longer  delay  occurred  before  the  society's 
business,  weaving,  could  begin.  At  the  end  of 
the  first  quarter's  working,  a  dividend  of  7|- 
per  cent  was  paid,  but  afterwards  the  looms 
were  run  at  a  loss.  The  difficulty  of  disposing 
of  the  manufactured  goods,  disputes  among  the 
directors,  and  between  the  shareholders  and 
non- shareholders  employed  by  the  company, 
and  above  all  the  unsuitability  of  the  climate  for 
weaving  led  to  this  result.  It  became  necessary 
to  make  a  radical  change  in  the  scheme,  and 
accordingly  the  promoters  decided  to  increase 
the  capital  to  £14,870,  and  build  premises  for 
cotton  -  carding  and  spinning.  The  engines 
were  "  christened  "  in  1863,  and  under  the  new 
name  of  the  "Sun  Mill  Company,"  business 
VOL.  I. 


was  carried  on  through  the  period  of  the  Cotton 
Famine  (see  Cotton  Famine)  eventually  with 
considerable  profit.  But,  in  1867,  Mr. 
Gladstone,  visiting  Oldham,  was  officially 
informed  that  out  of  more  than  a  thousand 
shareholders,  only  four  were  also  the  company's 
employes,  and  that  it  was  difficult  to  persuade 
workpeople  to  buy  shares.  In  1868,  in  order 
to  ensure  loyalty  to  the  company's  interests  on 
the  part  of  its  principal  servants,  their  salaries 
were  reduced,  and  instead  a  bonus — a  percentage, 
— was  given  on  all  profits  over  10  per  cent  on  the 
capital.  The  directors  at  one  time  desired  to 
extend  this  system  of  profit-sharing  to  the 
operatives,  but  were  strenuously  opposed  by 
the  principal  servants,  and  eventually,  as  the 
bonus  was  found  not  to  have  the  desired  ellect, 
the  directors  went  back  to  the  old  arrangement 
of  fixed  salaries.  Since  then  the  history  of 
the  concern,  which  in  its  early  years  had  shown 
"much  experimental  enterprise  but  a  w^ant  of 
judgment  as  to  consequences,"  chiefly  deals 
with  the  struggles  of  a  young  business  to  extend 
its  connection.  During  the  twenty  years 
1858-1877  £8  :  10s.  was  paid  in  dividends  on 
the  £5  share. 

[^The  Sun  Mill  Company,  Limited  ;  its  com- 
mercial and  social  history,  by  William  Marcroft, 
Oldham,  1877.  The  same  writer,  in  a  pamphlet 
entitled  A  Co-operative  Village,  and  published 
at  Oldham  in  1878,  propounds  a  scheme  of 
partial  co-operation  by  which  a  small  settle- 
ment could  attain  a  kind  of  "industrial 
independence."] 

It  was  hoped  that  the  Limited  Liability  Act 
(see  Limited  Liability  Acts)  would  encourage 
the  labouring  classes  to  invest  their  savings  in 
manufacturing  ventures  ;  in  Oldham  and  its 
neighbourhood  the  example  set  by  the  promoters 
of  the  Sun  Mill  Company  was  in  several  cases 
followed  by  working  men.  But  the  movement 
soon  passed  out  of  their  hands,  and  losing  its 
co-operative  aspect,  degenerated  into  a  system 
of  company  promoting  by  outside  speculators. 
Owing  to  the  presence  of  great  machinery  works 
in  the  town  a  factory  could  be  built  there  and 
fitted  up  with  the  newest  machinery  at  the 
smallest  possible  cost.  As  a  rule  the  buildings 
were  mere  "shells,"  so  arranged  as  to  hold  mules 
with  a  very  large  number  of  spindles.  During 
the  fifteen  years  after  the  passing  of  the  above- 
mentioned  act  the  total  number  of  spindles  in 
Oldham,  then  as  now  the  headquarters  of 
cotton-spinning,  was  nearly  doubled.  In  1886, 
according  to  the  official  list,  seventy-seven  mills 
(average  age  nine  years)  contained  5,166,922 
spindles,  whose  balance-sheet  value  was  over 
five  million  pounds  ;  at  present  there  are  more 
than  a  hundred,  whose  shares  are  quoted  in  the 
official  list.  The  majority  have  at  one  time  or 
other  paid  very  large  dividends. 

Of  late  the  Oldham  "Limiteds"  (see  Mr. 
Albert   Simpson's   "statement  respecting   the 

2  B 


418 


CO-OPERATION,  SOCIAL  ASPECTS  OF 


Cotton  Mills  of  Oldham,  and  the  working  of 
the  Limited  Liability  Act  in  connection  with 
them,"  handed  in  to  the  Labour  Commission, 
group  C,  10th  July  1891)  have  been  charged 
with  omitting  to  write  off  enough  per  annum 
for  depreciation,  so  that  their  large  dividends 
are,  in  part  at  least,  paid  out  of  capital.  In 
many  cases  there  is  evidence  to  warrant  such 
a  criticism  ;  out  of  a  hundred  and  ten  concerns 
the  shares  of  sixty -seven,  many  of  which 
pay  large  dividends,  are  at  a  discount.  The 
appointment  of  government  auditors  under  the 
Limited  Liability  Act  has  been  suggested  as  a 
remedy. 

Again,  it  is  certain  that  "  divi-hunting  "  has 
forced  many  of  them  into  rash  speculation,  and 
led  to  a  serious  loss  of  financial  vitality. 
During  1890,  to  defeat  attempts  to  "corner" 
cotton  at  Liverpool,  many  of  their  "buyers" 
bought  cotton  "to  arrive"  throughout  the  year  ; 
and,  as  a  consequence  of  the  sharp  fall  in  1891, 
the  legitimate  profits  of  cotton-spinning  were 
swallowed  up  by  the  losses  due  to  cotton 
speculation.  Workpeople  are  not  disposed  to 
risk  their  savings  in  this  manner,  and  though, 
in  the  case  of  the  older  and  more  stable  concerns, 
conducting  their  business  on  sound  principles, 
and  setting  aside  a  yearly  sum  to  pay  for 
renewal  of  machinery,  etc.,  a  small  percentage 
of  the  shareholders  are  retired  workmen,  and  a 
few  even  employes  of  the  company  in  which 
they  hold  shares,  generally  speaking,  the 
Oldham  "Liraiteds"  are  not  even  "partially 
co-operative."  E.  b.  o. 

Social  Aspects  of  Co-operation.  The 
statistical  information  conveyed  in  the  ofl&cial 
reports  of  the  Kegistrar  of  Friendly  Societies 
and  of  the  United  Board  of  the  Co-operative 
Union,  whilst  it  furnishes  very  complete  parti- 
culars as  to  the  financial  side  of  the  co-operative 
movement,  affords  no  sufficient  criterion  as  to 
the  social  side.  That  provision  is  made  for 
the  social  and  educational  development  of  co- 
operators  may,  however,  be  gleaned  from  those 
sources.  Thus  in  the  year  1909  the  sum  of 
£91,070  is  stated  to  have  been  applied  by  co- 
operative societies  to  educational  purposes, 
whilst  the  sum  of  £10,580  :  8  :  11  was  voted 
to  the  maintenance  of  the  Co-operative  Union, 
whose  work  is  entirely  of  an  educational  char- 
acteiL  The  money  spent  upon  education  goes 
sometimes  to  lectures  and  classes,  but  more 
often  to  keep  up  reading-rooms  and  libraries, 
which  in  the  northern  counties  are  usually  to  be 
found  in  connection  with  the  stores.  Social 
gatherings  and  entertainments  also  come  in  for 
a  share  of  the  educational  grants.  In  addition 
to  supporting  university  extension  lectures  in 
several  centres,  co-operators  have  founded  two 
scholarships  at  Oxford,  the  Hughes  and  the 
ISTeale,  to  commemorate  the  services  rendered 
to  the  movement  by  Mr.  Thomas  Hughes  and 
Mr.  E.  Vansittart  Neala     Tlie  development  of 


the  social  side  of  the  co-operative  movement  is 
promoted  by  an  effective  system  of  district  and 
sectional  organisation.  Delegates  are  periodic- 
ally brought  together  by  this  means  to  discuss 
the  welfare  of  their  movement,  and  much  pro- 
pagandist work  is  done.  Once  a  year  the  Co- 
operative Congress  is  held,  at  which  co-operators 
meet  from  all  parts  of  the  United  Kingdom. 
"The  annual  congress  is  composed  of  delegates 
from  societies  in  union,  each  society  being 
entitled  to  send  one  delegate  for  each  annual 
subscription  of  1 000  d.  or  fractional  part  thereof. 
Business  of  the  congi-ess  :  There  is  first  the 
inaugural  address,  then  the  report  of  the  Central 
Co-operative  Board,  the  election  of  scrutineers, 
of  the  voting  for  the  new  central  board,  and  the 
discussion  of  papers  and  proposals  bearing  on 
co-operation  "  (Acland  and  Jones,  Working  Men 
Co-operators,  p.  111).  Co-operators  recognise 
that  their  business  system  depends  largely  upon 
the  progress  of  mutual  improvement  amongst 
their  members,  and  they  are  constantly  urging 
that  more  attention  should  be  paid  to  the 
special  training  of  co-operatoiis.  "We  regret 
to  find  that  educational  grants  do  not  keep 
pace  with  the  general  growth  of  the  societies. 
Our  opinion  is  that  it  will  pay  every  society  to 
devote  at  l&st  2^  per  cent  of  its  net  profits 
to  education,  and  that  though  societies  may 
and  do  succeed  without  this,  yet  it  is  because 
the  older  generation  still  lives  and  guides  them, 
but  when  the  day  arrives  that  they  no  longer 
take  part  in  their  management,  the  societies 
will  run  a  great  risk  of  suffering  thereby  "  {Co- 
operative Wholesale  Societies'  Almanac,  1883, 
quoted  in  Working  Men  Co-operators).  It  is, 
however,  by  the  daily  routine  of  co-operative 
transactions  that  the  social  life  of  the  movement 
is  chiefly  fostered.  To  regard  the  mechanism 
of  the  movement  as  simply  an  adaptation  of 
"shopping"  is  to  completely  misapprehend  its 
character.  Equally  erroneous  is  the  superficial 
estimate  of  the  store  system  as  a  form  of 
"joint-stockism."  The  store,  it  is  true,  con- 
tains the  stock-in-trade  of  the  shop,  but  its 
social  significance  lies  in  its  being  the  centre  of 
a  consumer's  league,  the  organised  expression 
of  a  social  standard  of  requirements.  As  a 
domestic  dep&t  or  repository,  the  store  has 
played  an  important  part  in  the  growth  of 
neighbourly  feeling.  By  affording  opportunities 
for  social  thrift  as  well  as  consumption,  it  enters 
into  the  everyday  economy  of  families  connected 
with  it,  in  many  instances  supplying  the  house 
itself,  as  well  as  the  furniture,  clothing,  and 
food  requirements  of  the  inmates.  The  Women's 
Guild  recognises  the  influence  of  women  in  the 
co-operative  movement,  for  though  only  estab- 
lished a  few  years,  it  has  done  much  to  educate 
them  in  the  responsibilities  of  organised  pur- 
chasing. 

The  constitution  of  the  co-operative  society 
is,  after  all,  the  best  guarantee  of  its  social 


CO-OPERATION,  SOCIAL  ASPECTS  OF 


419 


character.  If  that  constitution  were  of  a  merely 
joint-stock  character,  as  is  so  commonly  alleged 
by  critics  of  co-operation,  we  should  expect  to 
find  people  going  into  the  movement  for  the 
acquisition  of  shares,  and  using  their  position 
to  enhance  the  value  of,  and  increase  the  return 
upon,  their  holdings.  This,  however,  does  not 
happen.  The  shares  in  a  store  yield  a  stereo- 
typed return  of  5  per  cent,  sometimes  less,  and 
there  is  never  a  market,  in  the  recognised  sense  of 
the  term,  for  co-operative  shares.  When  shares 
change  hands  they  do  so  usually  at  par.  The 
share  list  is  never  closed  to  new  comers.  ' '  This 
open  democracy  of  a  million  souls,"  to  quote 
Miss  Potter  (Mrs.  Sydney  Webb)  in  The  Co- 
operative Movement  in  Great  Britain,  is  open 
to  all  comers.  The  holder  of  the  maximum 
allowed  by  law  (£200)  has  just  as  much  power 
as,  and  no  more  than  the  shareholder  witli  two 
or  three  pounds.  Thus  Ave  lind  none  of  the 
characteristics  usually  associated  Avith  the  joint- 
stock  system  in  co-operation.  Instead  of  a 
trading  concern  in  which  the  lion's  share  in 
the  direction  of  the  revenue  goes  to  the  large 
stockholder,  the  power  is  equally  apportioned 
to  all  the  members,  and  the  dividend  is  pro- 
portioned to  the  use  made  of  the  store  (dividend 
on  Purchases.) 

Just  as  individuals  have  formed  societies  for 
distribution  and  saving  on  a  mutual  basis,  so 
the  societies  themselves  have  united  in  order  to 
perfect  and  consolidate  the  co-operative  system. 

The  English  Co-operative  Wholesale  Society, 
enrolled  in  1863,  has  grown  into  an  organisation 
of  enormous  power  ;  the  notable  point  in  this 
connection,  which  is  dealt  with  very  fully  in 
Miss  Potter's  book,  being  the  social  influence 
which  this  great  federal  institution,  in  common 
with  its  sister  society  in  Scotland,  has  exerted. 
These  federal  institutions,  while  allowing  free 
play  to  local  activity,  keep  up  a  constant 
healthy  circulation  of  ideas  and  commodities 
between  the  societies  federated.  Villagers  and 
townsmen  gather  at  the  delegate  meetings  to 
transact  the  aftairs  of  "the  Wholesale."  The 
best  experience  and  information  of  the  central 
institution  is  placed  at  the  service  of  the  most 
insignificant  society.  Just  as  the  trade  union 
and  the  friendly  society  have  passed  through  the 
stages  of  scattered  and  isolated  local  effort  into 
national  associations,  so  has  co-operation  ;  and 
to  the  federal  development  of  the  movement 
may  be  ascribed  much  of  the  steady  and  uniform 
rise  in  the  standard  of  requirements  noticeable 
in  the  co-operative  movement  (see  Miss  Potter's 
book).  Nowhere  can  this  be  more  clearly  per- 
ceived than  in  those  districts  where  the  stores 
have  remained  outside  the  federal  body.  The 
county  of  Forfar,  for  instance,  has  held  aloof 
almost  entirely  from  the  Scottish  Wholesale 
Society,  and  inquiries  made  throughout  the  dis- 
trict show  that  co-operation  has  stood  still  in 
consequence  during  the  past  thirty  years,  each 


society  in  its  own  rut,  whilst  the  standard  of  de- 
mand is  lower  than  within  the  federation.  The 
federal  principle  has  been  largely  applied  to  the 
business  of  corn-milling,  the  price  of  bread  in 
districts  where  co-operation  is  strong  being  fre- 
quently set  by  the  joint  agency  of  the  mill  and 
the  store.  It  happens  also,  frequently,  that 
instead  of  the  store  taking  the  current  prices 
of  the  neighbourhood  for  its  goods,  it  has  come 
to  set  them  for  the  district.  Productive  de- 
partments have  been  established  on  a  large 
scale  in  connection  with  the  two  wholesale 
societies,  and  production  is  now  carried  on  in 
many  directions  for  use  direct  and  not  for  profit, 
none  of  the  commodities  of  the  wholesales  being 
sold  outside  the  circle  of  the  stores. 

The  Co-operative  Wholesale  Society  Ltd. 
gives  its  name  to  the  Bank  of  the  Association. 
The  Head  Office  is  in  ]\lanchester.  It  was 
established  in  1873.  The  Bank  had  in  1910 
a  paid-up  capital  of  £1,709,657,  Loan  Capital 
£3,091,174,  deposits,  etc,  £1,650,532  and 
1160  Shareholders. 

It  is  frecj^uently  stated  in  detraction  of  the 
co-operative  movement  that  so  far  from  being 
a  social  organisation  it  is  mainly  composed  of 
self-seeking  persons,  devoid  of  public  spirit, 
and  intent  upon  personal  acquisition.  The 
advocates  of  co-operation  do  not,  however,  claim 
that  their  system  is  regenerative,  though  they 
maintain,  as  it  would  seem  with  reason,  that 
the  advantage  of  the  individual  can  only  be 
secured  by  the  welfare  of  those  associated  with 
him.  Seeing  that  the  co-operative  body  now 
numbers  two  and  a  half  millions  of  associates, 
it  would  appear  that  a  considerable  number  of 
those  enrolled  must  contribute  their  quota  of 
public  work.  Otherwise  instead  of  continually 
increasing  prosperity  we  should  find  corrupt 
and  self-centred  societies  partaking  of  the  pro- 
pensities of  members  whose  only  thought  was 
for  themselves.  But  little  inquiry  is  necessary  to 
show  that  in  this  movement  a  large  and  increas- 
ing body  of  enthusiastic  and  efficient  persons  are 
continually  devoting  themselves  to  the  fui'ther- 
ance  of  its  principles.  In  no  other  movement  is 
there  so  much  hard  and  thankless  voluntary  Avork 
done  for  the  love  of  the  thing  as  in  co-operation. 

Profit-sharing  industrial  partnership  has 
recently  developed  greatly  in  the  form  of 
Co-partnership  (see  Appendix).  This  is 
largely  due  to  the  late  Sir  George  Livesey  of 
the  South  Metropolitan  Gas  Comj)any.  The 
basis  of  the  system  is  a  bonus  on  salaries  and 
wages,  and  the  objects  are  to  give  all  officers 
and  workmen  an  inducement  beyond  their 
salaries  and  wages  to  take  an  interest  in  their 
work  and  the  welfare  of  the  company  which 
employs  them  besides  the  opportunity  of  be- 
coming shareholders  in  that  company,  and  thus, 
by  becoming  OAvners  of  property,  to  improve 
permanently  their  position  in  life.  The  co- 
partnership bonus  is  calculated  annually  on  the 


420 


COPARCENERS— COPLESTON 


salary  or  wages  for  twelve  months.  The  offer 
to  be  made  to  every  oflBcial  and  workman  of  the 
company  in  regular  employment,  the  condition 
of  acceptance  being  the  willingness  to  sign  an 
agreement,  which  agreement  binds  the  company 
to  provide  work  for  twelve  months.  The  prin- 
ciple is  already  adopted  by  twenty-six  gas  com- 
panies of  the  United  Kingdom,  with  capitals  of 
nearly  forty- five  millions,  and  many  other  firms. 
[Acland  and  Jones,  Working  Men  Co-operators. 
— Beatrice  Potter,  The  Co-operative  Movement  in 
Great  Britain, — Annual  Report  of  the  Co-opera- 
tive Union. — Annual  Report  of  the  Registrar  of 
Friendly  Societies. — Sedley  Taylor,  Profit  Sharing. 
— Co-partnership,  pub.  by  Co-partnership  Pub- 
lishers Ltd.,  6  Bloomsbury  Sq.,  London.]    v.  N. 

COPARCENERS.  Persons  to  whom  lands 
of  inheritance  descend  jointly.  For  instance 
at  common  law,  when  an  ancestor  dies  seised  of 
land  in  fee  simple  or  in  fee  tail,  and  his  next 
heirs  are  two  or  more  females,  they  will  take 
an  equal  interest  in  the  land.  Under  the  custom 
of  Gavelkind  {q.v.),  which  prevails  in  Kent, 
lands  descend  to  all  the  males  in  equal  degree. 
Coparceners  take  a  distinct  share  in  the  land 
and  can  compel  partition. 

[Stephen's  Commentaries,  bk.  ii.  pt.  1.] 

J.  B.  C.  M. 

The  real  property  of  a  person  dying  intestate 
generally  goes  to  one  heir  ;  but  in  some  cases 
several  persons  are  coheirs,  and  are  then  said 
to  take  as  coparceners.  This  occurs  (1)  at 
common  law  when  the  persons  entitled  by 
descent  are  females  (the  rule  of  primogeniture 
applying  to  males  only)  ;  (2)  in  the  case  of 
lands  held  under  the  custom  of  gavelkind,  the 
males  of  the  same  degree  of  relationship  (in  so 
far  as  they  are  otherwise  entitled)  take  as  copar- 
ceners. There  is  no  right  of  survivorship 
between  coparceners — a  circumstance  which  dis- 
tinguishes the  tenancy  of  coparceners  from  joint- 
tenancy  (cp.  Joint- Ovmership).  E.  s. 

COPERNICUS,  NicoLAUs(1473-1643).  This 
great  man  has  a  place  in  the  history  of  political 
economy  in  virtue  of  his  tract  Monetae  Cudendoe 
Ratio,  wiitten  in  1526  by  desire  of  Sigismund  I., 
king  of  Poland,  as  a  re-statement  of  the  prin- 
ciples previously  explained  by  the  author  at  the 
Prussian  Landtag  of  1522  as  those  on  which  the 
reform  of  the  currency  should  be  based.  The 
conditions  on  which  he  insists  are — strict  in- 
tegrity in  the  weight  and  quality  of  the  coin, 
the  charge  of  a  seigniorage  just  sufficient  to  defray 
the  cost  of  mintage,  and  a  unity  of  the  monetary 
system  throughout  the  entire  state.  There  is, 
with  much  that  is  sound,  some  admixture  of 
error  in  the  tract.  It  was  first  published  by 
Benkowski  in  1861  and  afterwards,  in  conjunc- 
tion with  the  treatise  of  Oresme,  in  1864  by 
Wolowski  (Roscher,  Oesch.  der  Nai.  Oek.  in 
Deutschland,  p.  111).  J.  K.  i. 

COPLESTON,  Edward  (1776-1849),  born 
at  Offwell  in  Devonshire,  educated  at  Oxford, 


he  became  provost  of  Oriel,  1814.  He  waa 
the  champion  of  Oxford  University  against 
the  attacks  made  against  it  in  the  early 
numbers  of  the  Edinburgh  Review ;  and  it 
was  as  "one  of  his  constituents,"  that  he 
wrote  his  chief  economical  treatise,  his  two 
"  Letters  to  the  Right  Hon.  Robert  Peel,  M.P. 
for  University  of  Oxford,  on  the  pernicious 
eff'ects  of  a  variable  Standard  of  Value,  especi- 
ally as  it  regards  the  condition  of  the  Lower 
Orders  and  the  Poor  Laws"  (1819).  He  be- 
came Dean  of  Chester  in  1826,  and  succeeded 
Sumner  as  Dean  of  St.  Paul's  and  Bishop  of 
Llandaff  in  1827.  He  was  an  occasional  writer 
for  the  Quarterly  Review  (see  list  of  his  works 
in  Memoir,  pp.  346-7).  Though  chiefly  known 
as  a  theologian  and  ecclesiastic,  he  took  part  in 
the  economical  and  political  controversies  of  his 
day  ;  his  Oxford  Prize  Essay  (1796)  on  "Agri- 
culture" shows  that  his  attention  was  early 
directed  to  the  topics  afterwards  treated  in  his 
"  Letters  to  Sir  Robert  Peel." 

In  the  first  of  these  Letters  (which  bears  the 
motto  "  laissez-nous  faire  ")  he  states  the  doc- 
trine of  currency  which  (he  says),  though  "only 
a  question  of  simple  arithmetic,"  yet  affects 
"all  the  most  valuable  interests  of  life."  He 
gives  illustrations,  from  English  history,  of  what 
has  happily  been  called  by  some  later  writei-s 
the  "secular"  depreciation  of  the  currency  (or 
its  depreciation  over  a  long  period  of  time),  and 
points  out  how  very  gradually  and  unequally 
prices  adapt  themselves  to  the  change.  As  in 
retail  dealings  and  in  transactions  between 
non-commercial  people  competition  acts  much 
less  promptly  and  effectively  than  in  dealings 
between  merchants,  so  its  efficacy  is  very 
imperfect  in  case  of  the  agricultural  labourers, 
as  distinguished  from  the  mechanics  of  the 
cities  ;  they  are  quite  unable  to  make  their 
wages  keep  pace  with  any  depreciation  of  money 
or  rise  in  the  price  of  food.  "At  no  period  of 
our  history  till  the  present  was  the  condition  of 
the  labourer  so  bad  as  in  the  time  of  Elizabeth. " 
Rather  than  raise  the  labourer's  wages,  the 
farmer  will  let  him  "come  on  the  poor  rates." 
Now  the  causes  of  depreciation  may  be  the 
natural  progress  of  trade  and  the  discovery  of 
mines  ;  the  distress  is  in  that  case  unavoidable, 
and  every  civilised  nation  will  at  one  time  or 
other  pass  through  the  experience.  But  th* 
depreciation  may  be  due  to  artificial  and  pre- 
ventible  causes  ;  and  this  is  our  own  case,  in 
1819.  We  have  ourselves  to  blame  ;  and  we 
ought  to  apply  the  cure.  We  should  restore 
our  ciurency  to  its  old  basis,  and  put  an  end  to 
the  suspension  of  cash  payments.  Copleston 
throughout  follows  the  leading  of  Ricardo, 
Huskisson,  and  Canning  against  Bosanquet, 
Vansittart,  and  the  opponents  of  the  bullion 
committee. 

In  the  second  Letter  he  discusses  what 
steps    should    be    taken    to    secure    that   the 


COPPER  MONEY 


421 


return  to  a  more  normal  currency  and  low 
prices  shall  be  as  far  as  possible  equable  in  its 
effects  on  all  classes.  The  new  corn  law  was 
meant  to  give  to  the  agriculturists  the  supposed 
advantages  secured  to  commercial  men  by- 
restriction  ;  but  it  would  \)9  better,  he  thinKs, 
to  dispense  with  both  of  them  and  return  to 
our  normal  condition.  Then  he  goes  at  some 
length  into  the  question  of  the  relief  of  the 
poor,  discussing  what  government  can  and  can- 
not do  in  this  matter,  what  our  own  govern- 
ment had  done,  and,  finally,  what  it  ought  to 
do.  He  considers  that  Malthus  (whom  he 
otherwise  warmly  praises)  has  not  done  full 
justice  to  the  English  Poor  Law.  Till  lately, 
according  to  Copleston,  this  law  was  so  well  ad- 
ministered as  to  preserve  life  without  encourag- 
ing the  propagation  of  it.  An  historical  review 
of  the  legislation  in  regard  to  the  poor  in  England 
is  made  to  support  his  view  that  depreciation  of 
the  cun-ency  has  been  a  potent  cause  of  distress 
to  the  poor,  and  unfair  gain  to  their  employers. 
His  own  recommendations  are  stricter  than  his 
criticisms  of  Malthus  might  have  led  his  reader 
to  expect.  "  Legal  relief  is  necessarily  of  itself 
encroaching  and  unsatiable."  He  appeals  to 
employers  to  raise  wages  without  waiting  till 
they  are  compelled  ;  but  (he  believes)  in  any 
case  the  march  of  events  will  so  lessen  poverty 
that  it  will  not  be  true  of  England  as  of  India 
and  China  that  its  only  source  of  wealth  is  its 
"redundant  supply  of  human  labour." 

Copleston's  article  in  the  Quarterly  Revicia 
(for  April  1822),  on  the  state  of  tlie  currency, 
would  lead  him  to  be  classed  among  the  ultra- 
buUionists,  who  attributed  more  influence  to 
the  suspension  of  cash  payments  than  the  facts 
would  justify.  It  is  criticised  by  Tooke  in  his 
TJioughts  and  Details  on  High  and  Low  Prices, 
(part  i.  pp.  19,  43,  seq.,  1823)  ;  and  Ricardo 
includes  him  among  the  adversaries  who  ' '  put 
sentiments  in  my  mouth  that  I  never  uttered  " 
(letter  to  Malthus,  16th  Dec.  1822).  But, 
like  many  other  of  the  minor  economists,  he 
did  service  by  drawing  attention  to  particular 
points  that  had  been  comparatively  neglected 
by  the  more  prominent  writers. 

[W.  J,  Copleston,  Memoir  of  E.  Copleston, 
Bishop  of  Llandaff,  vnth  Selections  from  his 
Diary  and  Correspondence  (London  1851). — See 
also  Mozley,  Reminiscences  of  Oriel  College,  1883.] 

J.  B. 

COPPER  MONEY  (England).  This  metal 
was  first  used  for  coinage  in  England  in  the 
reign  of  James  I.,  when,  under  the  authority 
of  a  patent  granted  by  the  king.  Lord  Har- 
rington of  Exton  caused  copper  Farthings  to  be 
struck  and  put  into  circulation.  These  pieces, 
known  as  "Harrington  tokens,"  weighed  only 
six  grains. 

Copper  Halfpence  were  first  issued  in  the 
reign  of  Charles  II.,  and 

Copper  Pence  in  that  of  George  III.  (1797). 


Copper  Twopences  were  issued  at  the  same 
time  as  the  first  coinage  of  pence,  but  they  were 
found  to  be  inconveniently  large  and  heavy 
(2  oz.),  and  their  coinage  was  not  continued. 

Copper  Half -far  things  for  circulation  in  Eng- 
land were  first  coined  in  the  year  1843.  The 
last  issue  of  coins  of  this  denomination  bears 
the  date  1856. 

The  following  is  a  list  of  the  denominations 
of  copper  coins  issued  for  circulation  in  England 
since  the  reign  of  James  I.  : — 


James  I. 
Charles  I. 
Cromwell. 
Charles  II. 
William  &  Mary. 
William  III. 
Anne. 
George  I. 

George  II. 
George  III. 


Farthing. 

Farthing. 

Farthing. 

Halfpenny,  Farthing. 

Halfpenny,  Faithing. 

Halfpenny,  Farthing. 

P'arthing. 

Halfpenny  (125  grs.),    Farthing  (62-5 
grs.) 

Halfpenny  (152  grs.),  Farthing,  (76grs.) 

(1770)— Halfpenny  (152  grs.),  P\arthiiig 
(76  grs.) 

(1797)— Twopence   (S75    grs.),    Penny 
(437-5  grs.) 

(1799>— Halfpenny  (194*5  grs.),  Farth- 
ing (972  grs.) 

(1806)— Penny  (291-7  grs.),  Halfpenny 
(145-8  grs.).  Farthing  (72*9  grs.) 
George  IV.  Penny  (291-7  grs.).  Halfpenny  (145-8 

grs.),  Farthing  (72-9  grs.) 
William  IV.  Penny  (291-7  grs.).   Halfpenny  (145-8 

grs.),  Farthing  (72-9  grs.) 
Victoria.  Penny  (291-7  grs.),   Halfpenny  (145-8 

grs.),    Fartliing  (72-9  grs.),    Half- 
farthing  (2(5-5  grs.) 

In  1860  copper  was  superseded  by  bronze  for 
the  manufacture  of  pence,  halfpence,  and 
larthings ;  the  old  copper  pieces  being  demone- 
tised by  royal  proclamation  of  the  13th  May 
1869.  They  were,  however,  exchanged  at  the 
Mint  for  their  full  nominal  value  until  the 
year  1873. 

The  weights  of  the  bronze  coins  are  as 
follows : — 

Penny,  145-83  grs. 

Halfpenny,  87-5  grs. 

Farthing,  43-75  grs. 

Farthings  made  of  tin  were  struck  in  the 
reigns  of  Charles  II.,  James  II.,  and  William 
&  Mary  ;  halfpence  also  were  made  of  that 
metal  in  the  tAvo  last-named  reigns.    F.  E.  A. 

COPPER  MONEY  (Sweden).  {Copper 
plates  or  blocks  itscd  as  money  in  Sweden. )  From 
1644  to  1776  there  was  in  Sweden  a  cumber- 
some form  of  copper  currency.  It  consisted  of 
thick  square  plates  (pUtar)  of  pure  copper  of 
various  dimensions  and  weights,  the  largest 
weighing  as  much  as  17  kilogrammes  (or  37^ 
lbs.  av.)  The  nominal  value  in  silver  dalers, 
with  the  year  of  its  issue,  etc.,  was  stamped  in 
the  corners  and  in  the  centre  of  each  plate.  The 
reason  which  led  to  the  adoption  of  this  form 
of  currency  was  a  desire  to  benefit  the  native 
copper  mines,  a  feeling  analogous  to  that 
which  at  the  present  date  (1891)  has  greatly 
promoted  the  coinage  of  silver  money  in  the 
United  States. 


422 


COPYHOLD— COPYRIGHT 


By  the  law  of  1644  one  skeppund  of  copper 
(170  kilogrammes  or  374|  lbs.  av.)was  coined 
into  a  number  of  platar  equal  in  total  nominal 
value  to  69  silver  dalers.  In  the  hope,  however, 
of  adding  to  the  wealth  of  the  nation,  laws  were 
passed  in  1674  and  1715  which  directed  that 
the  stamps  on  the  blocks  should  be  altered  so 
as  to  cause  them  to  pass  at  a  higher  nominal 
value  than  before,  the  number  of  silver  dalers 
represented  by  a  skeppund  of  copper  being 
increased  in  1674  to  100,  and  in  1716  to  180. 
The  latter  rate  was  maintained  until  1776, 
when,  by  a  new  coinage  law,  the  pldtar  were 
demonetised,  and  ceased  to  form  any  part  of 
the  Swedish  currency. 

After  1715  one  plat  was  reckoned  as  equal 
to  two  silver  dalers,  or  f  of  a  Rixdaler.  This 
would  be  equivalent  to  2f  crowns  of  the  present 
gold  standard,  which  are  equal  in  sterling  to 
2s.  ll^d.  The  weight  of  one  plat  at  the 
valuation  of  1715-1776  would  therefore  be  (170 
kilogrammes-T-90)  1*88  kilogrammes  or  4  lbs. 
2  oz.  av.,  while  the  nominal  value  of  the 
largest  plate,  weighing  17  kilogrammes  (37^ 
lbs.  av.),  would  be  eighteen  sUver  dalers,  equal 
to  twenty-four  of  the  present  gold  crowns, 
which  amount  in  sterling  to  £1  :  6  :  5. 

For  a  long  time  these  blocks  of  copper  formed 
the  chief  medium  of  exchange  in  Sweden 
(so  far  as  metal  was  concerned),  and  as  they 
were  very  unwieldy,  merchants  were  often 
obliged  to  obtain  a  wheelbarrow  when  they 
had  to  pay  or  receive  any  large  sum  of  money. 
The  inconvenience  of  employing  this  form  of 
money  appears  to  have  led  to  its  disuse. 

In  Italy,  Mommsen  (^Hist.  of  Rome,  vol.  i. 
p.  458,  ed.  1864)  says,  ''there  seems  from  the 
first  to  have  been  a  fixed  ratio  for  the  relative 
value  of  copper  and  silver  (250  "1)."        P.  E.  A. 

COPYHOLD.  Land  forming  part  of  a  manor 
and  subject  to  certain  burdens  in  favour  of  the 
lord.  Among  these  the  fine  payable  on  aliena- 
tion and  the  "  heriot "  are  the  most  prominent. 
The  right  of  heriot  entitles  the  lord  to  take  the 
best  beast,  and  in  some  cases  the  most  valuable 
chattel  on  the  holding,  when  the  tenant  dies. 
The  tenants'  rights  are  derived  from  "the 
custom  of  the  manor,"  the  lord  being  still 
looked  upon  as  the  feudal  possessor  of  the  land, 
hence  he  is  entitled  to  all  mines  and  minerals 
under  the  land,  and  to  all  timber  growing  upon 
it.  The  transfer  of  copyhold  lands  is  still 
effected  in  the  mediaeval  forms.  The  new 
tenant  is  admitted  in  the  lord's  court — the 
court  baron — and  his  admittance  entered  on 
the  court  roll,  the  copy  of  which  is  evidence  of 
his  title — hence  the  expression  "copyhold." 
A  series  of  copyhold  enfranchisement  acts  were 
passed  between  1841  and  1894.  The  last  (1894) 
repealed  former  acts  and  consolidated  and  im- 
proved the  law.  It  deals  with  both  voluntary 
and  compulsory  enfranchisement  with  the  con- 
sent of  the  Board  of  Agriculture.     Either  lord 


•'or  tenant  may  compel  enfranchisement  on  con^ 
dition  of  bearing  the  expenses.  Every  facility  is 
now  given  to  enable  both  lord  and  tenant  to  put 
an  end  to  their  obsolete  relation,  and  copyholds 
will,  no  doubt,  soon  disappear  altogether,  e.  s. 
COPYRIGHT.  Copyright  may  be  defined 
as  the  sole  and  exclusive  privilege  of  multiply- 
ing copies  of  an  original  work  of  art  or  literary 
composition.  Under  the  Tudors  monopolies  for 
printing  special  classes  of  books  were  often 
granted  by  the  crown,  but  it  was  not  until  8 
Anne  c.  19  that  a  law  was  passed  conferring 
copyright  after  publication.  Copyright  is  now 
governed  by  5  &  6  Vict.  c.  45  and  subsequent 
amending  acts,  the  last  of  which  (1911)  extends 
to  the  British  Dominions.  It  brings  all  copy- 
right under  statutory  law.  It  simplifies  the  law 
and  makes  it  more  favourable  to  the  author. 

(1)  Literary  Copyright.  Original  books,  includ- 
ing pamphlets,  lectures,  sheets  of  music,  reproduc- 
tions of  music  by  mechanical  methods,  musical 
"records,"  maps,  charts,  plans,  translations,  etc., 
are  protected  for  the  author's  life  and  for  fifty 
years  after ;  except  that  if,  after  the  author's  death, 
a  work  is  unfairly  withheld  or  the  price  unduly 
raised,  a  special  license  may  be  granted  for  its 
publication  or  performance  on  reasonable  terms. 
Libellous  and,  immoral  publications  are  not  pro- 
tected by  copyright.  Newspapers  under  some 
circumstances  may  be  within  the  acts.  The  first 
publication  of  the  work  must  be  within  the  United 
Kingdom  or  such  part  of  the  British  Empire  to 
which  the  law  applies.  Aliens  resident  in  such 
parts  of  the  Empire  enjoy  the  same  protection. 

(2)  Dramatic  Copyright.  Plays  and  musical 
compositions  are  protected  for  the  same  period  as 
books,  but  the  time  runs  from  the  publication 
or  representation,  whichever  happens  first.  To 
dramatise  a  copyright  book  is  an  infringement. 

(3)  Works  of  Art.  By  the  act  of  1911  works 
of  art  were  included  for  the  first  time  in  the  same 
arrangement  as  literary  works. 

(4)  Designs.  Original  designs  used  in  manu- 
facture for  fabrics,  etc.,  may  be  registered  and 
protected  under  the  Patents  and  Designs  Act  1907, 
and  the  Trade-Marks  Act,  1905. 

(5)  Copyright  in  Foreign  Countries.  See 
Colles  and  Hardy,  Playright  and  Copyright  in 
all  Countries,  London,  190G  ;  Copinger,  Law  of 
Copyright  in  Works  of  Literature  and  Art,  ed. 
J.  M.  Easton,  1904.  In  the  United  States  the 
act  of  1909  protects  literary,  artistic,  and  musical 
productions,  for  twenty-eight  years,  with  a  renewal 
for  a  further  period  of  twenty-eight  years  to  the 
author  or  his  heirs.  Aliens  can  enjoy  this  protection 
if  resident  in  the  United  States  when  the  work  is 
first  published,  or  if  the  foreign  states  to  which  they 
belong  grant  certain  copyright  protection  to  subjects 
of  the  States.  The  "  manufacture  "  clause  (act  of 
1891)  requires,  with  a  view  to  protecting  native 
typographers,  that  a  book  published  in  the  United 
States  should  be  printed  there.  The  law  of  1909 
left  this  unaltered  except  in  the  case  of  books 
originally  published  in  a  foreign  language. 

(6)  International  Copyright.  By  an  act  of 
1844  authors  of  foreign  nationality  could  be  pro- 
tected by   British   copyright  provided   (1)  they 


COQUELIN— CORN  LAWS 


423 


complied  with  certain  formalities,  such  as  the 
registration  of  their  works  in  England  within  a 
year  of  the  date  of  publication  abroad,  and  (2)  that 
reciprocal  protection  is  given  to  British  authors  in 
the  countries  of  which  they  are  subjects.  It  did 
not,  however,  confer  on  any  foreign  author  rig^ats 
greater  than  those  he  enjoyed  in  his  own  country. 
The  system  was  improved  by  the  International 
Copyright  Act,  1886,  and  by  the  "Bern  Conven- 
tion," 1887,  entered  into  by  the  British  Empire, 
Belgium,  France,  Germany,  Italy,  Spain,  Switzer- 
land, Norway,  Japan  and  others.  British  authors 
are  protected  abroad  by  the  arrangement  under 
which  each  country  enters  into  the  Convention. 
Austria- Hungary  arranged  a  separate  convention 
with  England  in  1893.  The  International  Con- 
vention at  Berlin,  1908,  made  recommendations 
simplifying  the  law  still  further. 

(7)  Basis  of  Copyright. — Blackstone  (2  Com. 
p.  405),  and  other  writers  (Copinger  on  Copyright) 
adopting  Locke's  view  of  occupancy,  incline  to 
base  the  right  of  an  author  to  the  exclusive  use 
of  works  composed  by  him  on  occupancy  founded 
on  personal  labour.  But  it  is  difficult  to  see  how, 
without  great  straining  of  language,  a  title  which 
the  Romans  applied  to  material  things  can  be  made 
to  embrace  the  right  of  an  author  to  his  ideas  em- 
bodied in  outward  form.  Judicial  decisions  incline 
to  the  economic  view  that  a  manuscript  having 
value  was  a  form  of  wealth,  and  should  be  pro- 
tected like  other  property,  Millar  v.  Taylor  (4  Burr, 
2362),  Donaldson  v.  Becket  (4  Burr,  2408),  Jetfries 
V.  Boosy  (4  H.  L.  C.  867).  Spencer  [Social  Statics, 
c.  xi.  §  1)  holds  that  "a  man  may  claim  the  ex- 
clusive use  of  his  original  ideas  without  overstep- 
ping the  boundaries  of  equal  freedom,  it  follows 
that  he  has  a  right  to  claim  them,  or  in  other 
words,  such  ideas  are  his  property." 

See  Report  of  Royal  Commission  on  Copyright 
Laws  and  Minutes  of  Evidence,  1878. — See  also 
Scrutton,  The  Law  of  Copyright,  1896. — Shortt, 
The  Laio  relating  to  works  of  Literature  and  Art, 
1884. — MacGillivray,  A  Treatise  on  the  Law  of 
Copyright,  1902. — Winslow,  The  Law  of  Artistic 
Copyright,  1889. — Cohen,  Law  of  Copyright,1896. 
— Edmunds,  Copyright  in  Designs,  1908. — Knox 
and  Hind,  Copyright  in  Designs,  1899. — Briggs, 
Law  of  Liter  national  Copyright,  1906. 

COQUELIN,  Charles  (1805-1852),  born  at 
Dunkirk,  died  at  Paris.  Beginning  life  in 
business  (1839-44),  he  published  a  Trait6  de  la 
filature  du  lin  (Paris,  1845).  Soon  after, 
having  joined  the  free  traders  in  their  campaign 
in  favour  of  customs  reforms,  he  wrote  in  the 
Hevue  des  deux  mondes,  also  in  the  Journal  des 
economistes,  to  which  he  contributed  many 
articles,  much  noticed  and  justly  valued  at  the 
time,  on  banks,  commercial  companies,  railways, 
canals,  conversion  of  the  rente,  the  corn  laws, 
the  circulating  medium,  liberty  in  commercial 
matters,  etc.  He  superintended  up  to  his  death 
the  publication  of  the  Dictionnaire  de  Veconomie 
politique  of  Guillaumin  (1852-53).  His  principal 
work,  Du  cridit  et  des  banques  (Paris,  1848,  1st 
ed. ;  1859,  2nd  ed.),  still  remains,  though  some 
of  the  details  are  out  of  date,  one  of  the  ablest 


arguments  in  favour  of  freedom  for  institutions 
of  credit  and  circulation.  a.  c.  f. 

CORBET,  Thomas  ;  wrote— 

An  Inquiry  into  the  Causes  and  Modes  of  the 
Wealth  of  Individuals,  or  the  Principles  of  Trade 
and  Speculation  Explained  (London,  1841 )  sm.  8vo. 

The  author,  claiming  for  himself  only  that 
degree  of  originality  which  Newton  evinced  when 
he  explained  the  most  ordinary  transactions,  such 
as  plumbing  and  weighing,  assigns  as  the  "  dis- 
tinguishing principle  of  trade "  though  "  not 
noticed  by  Adam  Smith  " — to  buy  and  sell  always 
at  the  market  price.  "  Many  other  principles," 
as  the  author  says,  "will  be  found  to  be  as  novel." 

F.  Y.  E. 

CORBETTA,  Eugenio,  author  of  Conferenze 
popolari  di  economia  pubblica  e  sociale,  Milano, 
1872,  Dumolard.  m.  p. 

CORN  LAWS.  A  corn  law  is  an  expedient 
adopted  by  the  legislature,  with  the  object  of 
securing  a  higher  price  for  the  cultivator,  and 
a  higher  rent  for  the  landowner.  It  takes 
two  forms.  One,  and  the  most  familiar,  is  a 
tax  or  prohibition  on  importation.  The  other 
is  a  bounty  on  exportation.  The  first  corn  law 
of  the  former  kind  in  the  English  statute  book 
is  one  enacted  3  &  4  Edward  IV.  The  only  law 
of  the  latter  kind  is  the  famous  Bounty  Act 
of  William  and  Mary,  enacted  in  1689  (1  W. 
and  M.,  s.  1,  c.  12).  The  act  was  extended 
to  Scotland  by  5  Anne  c.  8,  and  Avas  slightly 
modified  by  13  Geo.  III.  c.  43. 

Acts  of  the  sovereign,  probably  by  the  advice 
of  the  council,  prohibiting  the  export  of  corn, 
with  the  view  of  distressing  the  king's  enemies 
or  of  preventing  scarcity  at  home,  are  of  early 
and  frequent  occurrence  in  English  history. 
But  they  are  temporary,  the  expedients  of 
military  policy,  or  of  a  feeling  that  it  was  the 
first  duty  of  a  sovereign  to  assist  in  procuring 
plenty  at  home,  and  were  not  intended  to  pro- 
mote the  interest  of  either  cultivators  or  land- 
lords. These  restraints  were  constantly  en- 
forced by  severe  and  even  savage  penalties. 

The  preamble  of  the  petition  on  which  the 
act  of  Edward  IV.  is  founded  (Rolls  of  Parlia- 
ment, V.  p.  504),  asserts  that  "husbandmen 
and  occupiers  in  husbandry  are  sore  hurt  by  the 
bringing  of  corn  out  of  other  lands  and  partes 
when  corns  of  the  growing  of  the  said  realm 
have  been  of  easy  price."  Imports  of  wheat, 
rye,  and  barley  are  prohibited,  unless  the 
prices  of  these  three  kinds  of  gi-ain  are  at  6s. 
8d.,  4s.,  and  3s.  respectively  the  quarter.  The 
corn  thus  imported  is  to  be  forfeited,  half  to  go 
to  the  king,  half  to  the  informer.  Prize  of 
war,  however,  apparently  (for  the  language  of 
the  petition  is  not  very  clear),  is  exempt  from 
these  provisions. 

The  year  in  which  this  act  was  passed  was 
one  of  very  low  prices,  for  wheat  was  only 
3s.  lO^d.,  rye  2s.  lOd.,  barley  2s.  4^d.  the 
quarter.  During  the  period  before  1542,  when 
prices  began  to  rise  permanently,  Le.  for  eighty 


I 


424 


CORN  LAWS 


years  (1462-1542),  prices  for  twenty-three  years 
only  were  above  the  rates,  sometimes  only 
slightly,  so  that  one  could  hardly  say  that  the 
act  was  very  effectual  in  promoting  its  avowed 
object.  Besides,  for  a  very  long  time,  acts  of 
parliament  were  very  imperfectly  obeyed,  per- 
haps hardly  known  to  exist ;  and  governments, 
even  in  the  most  despotic  times,  were  very 
much  alarmed  at  any  discontent  which  might 
arise  in  case  the  price  of  food  was  artificially 
heightened.  There  are  numerous  statutes  pro- 
hibiting the  exportation  of  corn  in  times  of  real 
or  apprehended  scarcity. 

Imported  corn,  like  every  other  foreign 
commodity,  was  made  liable  to  the  charges 
which  were  imposed  by  Cecil  {see  Book  of 
Rates) — the  constant  subject  of  quarrel  be- 
tween the  early  Stuarts  and  their  parliaments. 
Here,  however,  the  maximum  price  at  which 
imported  wheat  was  freed  from  customs  duty 
was  48s.  a  quarter.  The  average  price  of  wheat 
during  the  17th  century  was  41s.  and  nearly 
the  whole  century  was  a  period  of  exceeding 
suffering  to  the  poorer  or  labouring  classes. 

The  real  commencement  of  the  system  of 
imposing  a  scale  of  charges  on  imported  corn, 
with  a  view  to  heightening  prices  and  there- 
after rents,  was  the  sliding  scale  of  22  Charles 

II.  c.  13.  Under  this  law  a  duty  of  16s. 
a  quarter  was  imposed  on  wheat  as  long  as  it 
was  at  and  below  53s.  4d.  and  of  8s.  when  the 
price  was  between  53s.  4d.  and  80s.  Other 
kinds  of  grain  were  similarly  treated,  for  16s. 
was  to  be  exacted  when  rye  was  below  40s. 
barley  and  malt  when  below  32s.  and  peas  and 
beans  below  40s.  Oats,  when  at  1 6s.  and  under, 
were  to  pay  5s.  4d.  There  was  as  yet  no 
malt,  but  only  a  beer  duty.  Now  during  the 
17th  century,  the  average  price  of  wheat  was 
41s.,  of  barley  21s.  ll|d.,  of  malt  23s.  7|d., 
of  peas  23s.  2|d.,  of  beans  23s.  l^d.,  and  of 
oats  14s.  7|d.  I  have  not  found  the  price  of 
rye  in  sufficient  frequency  to  justify  an  average. 
But  the  above  figures  prove  that  the  intention 
of  the  act  was  to  put  a  prohibition  on  the 
importation  of  food.  It  is  true  that  when 
scarcities  came,  as  in  the  seven  years'  dearth  at 
the  end  of  the  17th  century,  in  1709-10,  in 
1756,  and  on  some  other  occasions,  the  act 
was  suspended  for  a  period,  and,  as  Adam  Smith 
says,  "  the  necessity  for  these  temporary  statutes 
sufficiently  demonstrates  the  impropriety  of  this 
general  one."  The  act  remained  in  existence 
as  the  ordinary  corn  law  for  more  than  a 
century,  for  it  was  changed  only  by  13  Geo. 

III.  c.  43. 

The  sliding  scale  act  of  Charles  II.  was,  as 
far  as  the  realisation  of  its  objects  are  con- 
cerned, a  total  failure.  The  price  of  wheat  was 
generally  low  to  the  end  of  the  century,  for 
during  the  forty  years  1663-1702  inclusive  the 
average  is  38s.  lOd.,  this  period  including  the 
so-called  seven  dear  years  1692-1698  inclusive. 


Besides,  the  act  was  suspended  as  soon  as  it 
really  came  into  operation.  With  rare  ex- 
ceptions too  the  harvests  were  exceedingly 
abundant  well  into  the  third  quarter  of  the 
18th  century,  average  prices  being  constantly 
less  than  half  the  average  rate  of  the  17th 
century.  For  this  result  there  were  two 
dominant  causes.  The  first  was  the  extra- 
ordinary geniality  of  the  seasons.  The  second 
was  the  gradual  adoption  of  the  new  agriculture, 
the  substitution  to  a  great  extent  of  the  four- 
course  for  the  three-course  system  of  cultivation, 
the  spread  of  turnip  and  artificial  grass  culture, 
and  the  great  increase  as  a  consequence  of  live 
stock.  The  development  of  English  industry 
and  manufactures  was  remarkable,  and  was  due 
in  great  measure  to  the  plenty  which  prevailed. 
We  shall  see  presently  what  bounties  did. 

When  prices  occasionally  rose  to  what,  till 
recent  years,  we  should  call  moderate  rates,  say 
50s.  a  quarter,  there  were  great  discontents 
and  occasionally  serious  bread  riots.  The  act 
of  Charles  does  not  appear  to  have  been  blamed 
for  these  disagreeable  experiences,  for  the 
calamity  was  generally  assigned  to  the  acts  oi 
the  com  dealers,  who  were  branded  with  the 
names  of  forestallers  and  regraters,  and  looked 
on  generally  as  pubKc  enemies.  {See  Fore- 
stallers AND  Regraters.)  The  government 
were  exceedingly  alarmed  at  these  symptoms, 
and  did  their  best  to  keep  the  ports  open 
for  foreign  food.  At  last  by  13  Geo.  III. 
foreign  corn  could  be  imported  at  nominal 
duties  when  wheat  was  over  48s.,  rye,  beans, 
and  peas  32s.,  barley,  here,  and  bigg  24s.,  and 
oats  16s.,  the  rate  on  wheat  being  6d.  a 
quarter,  on  rye,  etc.  3d.,  on  barley,  etc.  and 
oats  2d.,  and  the  whole  duty  might  be  drawn 
back,  if  re-exported  in  six  months.  In  1791 
the  corn  laws  were  consolidated  but  not  materi- 
ally changed.  During  the  great  continental 
wars  prices  were  all  that  the  farmers  and  land- 
owners could  desire. 

But  in  1813,  after  the  retreat  from  Moscow, 
the  domination  of  Napoleon  came  to  an  end, 
and  with  it  his  anti-commercial  decrees.  Large 
quantities  of  foreign  corn  came  into  England 
and  prices  fell.  In  1815,  therefore,  another 
act  was  passed  (55  Geo.  III.  c.  26).  Under 
this  act  no  foreign  corn  could  be  taken  out  of 
bond  unless  when  the  following  prices  were 
reached — ^wheat  80s.,  rye,  peas,  and  beans  53s., 
barley,  here,  and  bigg  40s.,  and  oats  26s., 
some  favour  being  shown  to  the  produce  of 
Canada.  It  was  supposed  that  this  enactment 
would  raise  prices,  but  they  continued  provok- 
ingly  low,  and  in  consequence  there  occurred 
what  was  called  agricultural  distress.  By  3 
Geo.  IV.  c.  60,  a  new  scale  of  maxima  was 
adopted  of  70s.,  46s,,  35s.,  and  25s.  Certain 
modifications  were  made  between  this  date  and 
1846,  when  the  corn  laws  were  abolished,  the 
measure  to  take  final  effect  in  1849.     Only  b 


CORN  LAWS 


426 


shilling  duty  was  left,  which  was  abolished 
twenty  years  later  by  Mr.  Lowe. 

The  bounty  on  exported  corn,  as  is  stated 
above,  was  granted  in  1689.  The  corn  law  of 
Charles  IL  had  been  a  failure.  It  did  no  good 
in  cheap  years,  it  was  dangerous  in  dear  times, 
and  had  to  be  suspended.  The  bounty  was 
far  more  plausible,  and,  at  first  sight,  far  more 
defensible.  It  stimulated  corn  growing,  and 
to  stimulate  corn  growing  was  to  provide  more 
abundant,  j)erhaps  cheaper  food.  The  bounty 
too  seemed  3o  small,  especiall.F  when  compared 
with  the  duties  on  imports  under  the  act  of 
Charles.  EngHsh  agriculture  was  in  a  deplor- 
able condition  in  1689.  It  was  affirmed  by  the 
closest  and  most  intelligent  observer  of  the 
time,  Gregory  King,  that  the  average  rate  of 
corn  production  in  England  was,  one  kind  with 
the  other,  not  above  fourteen  bushels  to  the 
acre,  and  the  bounty  would  mend  this  serious 
deficiency  of  enterprise.  State-aided  industry 
was  a  superstition  of  the  time  ;  the  grant  of 
the  bounty  by  parliament  seems  to  have 
excited — and  I  jiave  read  much  that  was  written 
at  the  time  -neither  criticism  nor  opposition. 

The  bounty  was  not  to  be  given  when  the 
price  of  wheat  reached  48s.,  of  rye  32s.,  of 
barley  and  malt  24s.  a  quarter.  When  the 
prices  were  below  this  amount,  the  payments 
on  exportation  were  5s.  on  wheat,  3s.  6d.  on 
rye,  2s  6d.  on  barley  and  malt.  After  the 
Scottish  union  oats  were  included  and  here,  and 
2s.  6d.  was  to  be  paid  on  these,  15s.  on  oat- 
meal. By  13  Geo.  III.  c.  43  the  maximum 
price  of  wheat  was  made  44s.  and  5s.,  rye  28s. 
and  3s.,  barley,  malt,  and  here  22s.  and  2s.  6d., 
oats  2s.,  oatmeal  2s.  6d.  But  after  1773  it 
was  rarely  that  prices  were  low  enough  to 
admit  a  bounty,  and  very  soon  the  bounty  was 
practically  suspended.  The  form,  however, 
survived  during  the  continental  war. 

The  sliding  scale  of  import  duties  had  no 
effect  on  agriculture,  and  till  the  last  thirty 
years  of  its  existence  only  a  fitful  effect  on 
prices.  It  did  not  encourage  cultivation,  because 
the  best  hopes  of  farmer  and  landlord  seemed 
to  lie  in  scarcity.  Its  effect  was  that  it 
destroyed  or  weakened  the  foreign  market,  by 
rendering  it  uncertain,  and  that  it  prevented 
the  exchange  of  British  manufactures  against 
foreign  grain.  It  deluded  the  farmer  by  the 
excessive  range  of  variation  in  prices  which  it 
caused,  and  it  was  a  serious  injury,  for  the 
same  reason,  to  the  mass  of  the  people.  Hence 
there  were  people  who  denounced  the  sliding 
scale,  but  thinking  that  British  agriculture 
could  not  prosper  without  some  assistance, 
advocated  a  fixed  duty.  This  was  the  policy 
of  the  Whigs.  The  advocates  of  free  trade 
answered  that  a  fixed  duty  was  a  fixed  wrong, 
and  this  criticism  was  accepted  and  endorsed 
by  parliament. 

But  the  operation  of  the  bounty  was  very 


different.  It  cannot  be  doubted — the  writei 
has,  for  the  first  time,  collected  the  evidence — ■ 
that  the  bounty  stimulated  corn-growing,  en- 
closures, and  to  a  very  limited  extent  arable 
agriculture.  But  this  advantage,  such  as  it 
was,  was  countervailed  by  mischievous  conse- 
quences. In  the  first  place,  it  discouraged  the 
spread  of  the  new  agriculture,  i.e.  in  general 
terms,  the  substitution  of  the  four-course  for 
the  three-course  system,  and  the  abandonment 
of  bare  fallows  for  turnip  and  artificial  grass 
culture,  and  with  this  the  increase  and  improve- 
ment of  cattle  and  sheep  raising.  The  legisla- 
ture encouraged  only  one  branch  of  agriculture, 
corn  raising,  and  by  implication  discouraged 
the  other  branches.  In  the  next  place,  men 
gambled  for  the  bounty.  It  was  reckoned  that 
in  average  cheap  years,  only  a  thirty-third  of 
the  crop  won  the  bounty,  but  it  obviously 
affected  the  whole  crop  which  was  raised.  In 
just  the  same  way,  in  modern  times,  the  beet- 
root crop,  favoured  by  continental  governments, 
is  the  most  unsatisfactory  and  disappointing 
industry  on  the  continent. 

In  the  next  place,  for  a  long  time,  as  no  rule 
as  to  quality  was  established,  the  bounty  was 
favourable  on  corn  which  was  below  the  aver- 
age quality.  The  contrast  between  minimum 
and  maximum  prices  of  grain  on  the  London 
Corn  Exchange  is  extraordinary,  constantly 
being  thirty  to  forty  per  cent,  for  so  gi-eat  an 
interest  was  created  by  the  bounty  that  it  has 
been  possible  to  collect,  from  the  days  of  the 
great  famine  of  1709-10,  accurate  accounts  of 
weekly  London  prices  from  the  newspapers.  At 
last  the  legislature  required  the  city  of  London 
to  furnish  a  return  of  prices  and  quantities,  and 
established  a  system  of  averages.  But  the 
most  important  action  which  parliament  took 
was  in  1770,  when  returns  of  corn  prices  were 
required  from  every  county  weekly,  which 
were  published  in  the  London  Gazette.  These 
returns  disclose  the  fact  that,  though  by  this 
time  the  effect  of  the  bounty  was  much  dimin- 
ished, the  price  of  corn  in  the  inland  counties, 
i.e.  those  who  had  no  access  or  no  easy  access 
to  the  ports,  was  fully  5s.  a  quarter  higher  than 
it  was  in  the  maritime  counties  or  from  fifteen 
to  twenty  per  cent  dearer.  The  whole  country 
paid  the  tax,  and  some  parts  of  it  had  to  pay 
all  the  more  for  food.  The  officials  too,  who 
made  the  returns,  were  constantly  charged  with 
stating  that  prices  were  far  lower  than  experi- 
ence justified. 

There  was  considerable  difference  of  opinion 
about  the  operation  of  the  bounty.  Arthur 
Young,  who  had  only  the  interests  of  progress- 
ive agriculture  at  heart,  believed  that  it  and 
the  sliding  scale  were  important  stimulants  to 
agriculture.  Smith,  as  might  be  expected, 
though  he  was  not  possessed  of  the  facts  which 
prices  disclose,  denied  that  the  effect  was  any- 
thing but  mischievous.      Tooke,   perhaps  the 


426 


CORN  RENTS 


last  considerable  economist  who  handled  the 
question,  declares  that  in  the  absence  of  accur- 
ate information  on  the  effects  of  it,  he  is  unable 
to  determine  whether  the  good  was  greater  than 
the  evil.  On  this,  the  evidence  of  facts,. of 
which  a  summary  has  been  given,  is  conclusive. 

J.  T.  R. 

CORN  RENTS.  During  the  latter  half  of 
the  16th  century  rents  were  very  slow  to  im- 
prove. In  Stafford's  famous  pamphlet,  at  one 
time  ascribed  to  Shakespeare,  the  complaints 
of  the  landlord  are  loud.  Prices  had  trebled 
and  rents  were  stationary.  The  explanation 
is,  that  everything  needed  for  agriculture, 
except  labour,  had  increased  near  threefold  in 
price,  and  the  margin  from  which  rent  could 
be  paid  was  therefore  not  increased.  The 
Oxford  and  Cambridge  colleges,  the  schools 
of  Winchester  and  Eton,  were  greatly  im- 
poverished, and  apparently  found  it  difficult  to 
live.  Their  tenants  too  were  all  on  customary 
rents. 

In  this  crisis  parliament,  at  the  instance  of 
Burleigh  or  Sir  Thomas  Smith,  for  the  credit  is 
divided,  came  to  the  rescue  by  the  act  of  1576, 
18  Eliz.  c.  6,  under  which  the  colleges  and 
the  two  schools  were  empowered  in  the  grant 
of  fresh  leases  to  reserve  one-third  of  the  old 
rent  in  produce  or  in  money  at  the  maximum 
prices  of  wheat  and  malt,  in  the  markets  of 
Oxford,  Cambridge,  Winchester,  and  Windsor. 
I  have  found  that  the  produce  rent,  at 
fictitious  prices,  had  been  for  some  time 
customary  at  King's  College,  Cambridge,  before 
the  act  was  passed  ;  and  the  hint  probably 
came  to  Burleigh  or  Smith  from  this  practice. 
Thus  the  college  demanded  that  the  lessee 
should  supply  so  many  quarters  of  wheat  and 
malt  at  6s.  8d.  and  4s.  though  the  market  price 
might  be  treble  these  amounts,  and  sheep  at  2s. 
when  the  lowest  price  was  6s.  8d.  The  Cam- 
bridge colleges  clung  to  this  system  despite 
the  act  till  the  end  of  the  century.  The 
reason,  I  believe,  was  that  domestic  grinding 
and  baking  were  customary  at  Cambridge, 
while  at  Oxford  purchases  were  made  from 
the  common  baker  or  brewer.  The  local 
custom  was  dropped  at  last,  it  appears,  because 
these  covenants  did  not  secure  high  quality. 

The  act  did  not  prejudice  existing  leases. 
Hence  it  is  some  time  before  the  returns  of 
corn  prices  appear.  The  earliest  which  I  have 
found  in  Oxford  is  in  1582.  The  practice  of 
Eton  long  continued  to  be  that  of  King's 
College,  and  Winchester  appears  to  have 
adopted  the  change  slowly,  for  the  accounts  of 
this  school  have,  it  seems,  been  lost  up  to  the 
time  of  the  Long  Parliament.  The  rent  days 
at  Oxford  on  which  the  market  returns  are 
given  are  rarely  more  than  two.  New  College 
alone  having  occasionally  a  third.  At  King's 
College  they  were  thirteen,  but  one  seldom  finds 
the  whole.     At  St.  John's  they  are   six,   and 


these  are  always  found.  At  Winchester  there 
were  also  six,  at  Eton  seven,  though  at  last 
Eton  only  has  two.  Winchester  has  oc- 
casionally oat  rents. 

These  com  prices  are  of  the  greatest  value  in 
the  history  of  agricultural  prices,  which  indeed 
could  not,  since  the  Reformation,  have  easily 
been  constructed  without  them.  In  the  early 
part  of  the  18th  century  Fleetwood,  after- 
wards bishop  of  St.  Asaph,  and  previously 
fellow  of  Eton,  extracted  the  Eton  prices,  and 
published  them  in  his  Chronicon  Preciosum. 
This  gave  the  hint  to  parliament,  which, 
during  the  18th  and  19th  centuries,  occasionally 
called  on  the  Eton  authorities  to  return  their 
corn  prices.  These  were  published  in  parlia- 
mentary papers.  The  writer  of  this  article 
was  the  first  to  collect  the  Oxford,  Cambridge, 
and  Winchester  prices,  as  well  as  those  of  Eton, 
from  the  original  records.  It  is  probable  that 
no  other  country  could  supply  such  a  series,  but 
from  casual  and  broken  notices  of  French  com 
prices,  it  is  plain  that  generally  they  are  not 
very  different  in  amount,  money  and  measures 
being  duly  interpreted,  from  those  which  pre- 
vailed in  Southern  England.  j.  t.  r. 

CORN  RETURNS.  By  the  Corn  Returns 
Act  1882  (^5  &  46  Vict.  c.  37)  which  consoli- 
dated and  amended  the  5  &  6  Vict,  c.  14  and 
the  27  &  28  Vict.  c.  87,  the  buyers  of  corn  in 
certain  towns  named  by  order  in  council,  are 
required  to  make  to  the  inspectors  of  corn  re- 
turns, weekly  returns  of  the  amount  of  each  sort 
of  British  corn  bought  by  them,  and  the  weight 
and  the  price  thereof.  Such  returns  are  to  be 
made  in  not  less  than  150  and  in  not  more  than 
200  towns.  The  inspectors  are  to  forward  to  the 
Board  of  Trade  weekly  summaries  of  these  re- 
turns, and  from  these  summaries  the  Board  of 
Trade  computes  the  weekly,  quarterly,  and  yearly 
average  prices  of  each  sort  of  corn.  These  aver- 
ages are  computed  by  dividing  the  total  prices 
by  the  total  quantities.  On  these  averages  de- 
pends the  yearly  amount  payable  to  owners  of 
tithe  rent  charges  (see  Tithe).         j.  e.  c.  m. 

CORNAGE.  A  monetary  payment  called 
cornage  was  a  frequent  incident  of  the  tenure 
of  land  in  the  counties  of  Cumberland,  Durham, 
Northumberland,  and  Westmoreland.  Little- 
ton explains  cornage  tenure  to  be  the  tenure  of 
land  by  the  service  of  blowing  a  horn  to  give 
notice  of  the  incursions  of  the  Scotch ;  and  this 
explanation  has  been  often  repeated,  but  is 
certainly  incorrect.  The  true  explanation  is 
that  in  lands  held  by  cornage  tenure  the  tenant 
paid  to  the  lord  a  small  sum  of  money  for  every 
homed  beast  in  his  possession,  or  a  fixed  sum 
as  a  composition.  The  payment  was  an  incident 
of  both  free  and  unfree  tenures,  and  in  the 
latter  case  was  paid  by  all  the  tenants  together. 
In  the  manor  of  Easington  in  Durham  it  was 
fixed  at  30s.  a  year  from  a  very  early  period, 
and  in  most  cases  the  amount  paid  bears  na 


CORNER  —CORPORATION 


427 


relation  to  the  actual  number  of  cattle  on  the 
land.  But  a  charter  of  Henry  I.,  in  granting 
the  cornage  of  Borton  to  the  monks  of  Durham, 
estimates  its  amount  as  twopence  from  each 
animal.  For  similar  payments  in  other  covn- 
tries  than  England  see  Ducange,  Glossarium, 
s.v.  In  England  cornage  seems  to  be  confined 
to  the  four  counties  named,  where  it  is  also 
known  as  "horngeld"  or  "hornbield."  It 
perhaps  points  to  an  early  payment  of  rent  in 
cattle.  Servile  tenants  owing  cornage  were 
often  also  bound  to  provide  the  lord  with  a 
milch-cow  or  its  value. 

[Littleton's  Tenures  1481.  The  Boldon  Book, 
edited  for  the  Surtees  Society  by  the  Rev.  William 
Greenvvell  (see  esp.  "Glossary,"  5.1;.)]       c.  G.  c. 

CORNER  ON  Stock  Exchange.  A  specu- 
lator is  said  to  have  got  into  a  corner  when  he 
cannot  deliver  the  securities  or  other  articles 
which  he  has  sold  for  delivery  at  a  given  date 
(y.  Backwardation  and  Bear).  a.  e. 

The  word  is  an  Americanism  now  acclimat- 
ised here,  signifying  a  condition  of  a  market  in 
which  speculators  of  one  class  are  placed  at  the 
mercy  of  their  opponents.  It  is  a  term  even 
more  extensively  used  in  the  produce  markets, 
in  the  corn  trade,  and  so  forth,  than  upon  the 
stock  exchange.  As  a  rule,  the  speculators 
**  cornered  "  are  those  who  have  sold  what  they 
did  not  possess  in  the  expectation  of  being  able 
to  buy  upon  lower  terms.  In  many  cases  such 
sales  have  extended  to  a  larger  amount  than 
there  are  goods  of  the  class,  or  securities,  upon 
the  market  or  in  existence,  and  if  the  buyers 
are  strong  enough  to  demand  a  delivery  of  what 
has  been  sold  it  is  evident  that  the  sellers 
must  at  last  apply  to  those  to  whom  they  have 
sold  to  let  them  off  tlieir  bargains.  The 
result  is  that  the  buyers  may  then  demand 
their  own  terms  to  cancel  the  transaction.  In 
America,  where  gambling  in  produce  is  carried 
to  enormous  lengths,  these  "corners"  are 
frequent.  A  "corner"  may  be  said  to  differ 
from  a  "rig"  in  that  the  latter  more  often  is 
applied  to  a  transaction  such  as  the  recent 
French  operation  in  copper.  In  that  case  an 
effort  was  made  to  secure  the  entire  production 
of  the  world,  amounting  to  upwards  of  200,000 
tons  annually,  and  to  sell  it  only  at  an  advance 
of  about  100  per  cent,  all  consumers  of  copper 
being  compelled  to  purchase  from  the  syndicate. 
The  result  proved  disastrous.  The  French 
Society  des  Mitaux  * '  rigged  "  the  market  for 
upwards  of  a  year,  but  it  may  also  be  said  that 
they  "cornered"  those  who  had  speculatively 
sold  copper  for  forward  delivery  in  October 
1887,  the  price  advancing  from  under  £40  per 
ton  early  in  that  month  up  to  nearly  £90  in 
January  1888  {see  Cartel  ;  Combination). 

CORNIANI,  Giambattista  (1742-1813) 
born  at  Orgi  Nuovi,  in  the  province  of  Brescia, 
wrote  mjlessione  sulle  Monete,  in  1796  (pub- 
lished in  Verona  for  the  first  time,  and  repub- 


lished in  1804  by  Custodi)  on  the  genera\ 
effects  depending  on  the  quantity  of  coin  which 
circulates  in  a  country,  and  two  other  essays, 
entitled  Discorsi  due  delta  Legislazione  relativa- 
mente  all'  AgricoUura,  read  in  1777  before  the 
academy  of  Brescia  on  rural  legislation,  and 
also  published  by  Custodi,  whose  personal 
friend  he  was.  Corniani,  although  an  indif- 
ferent economist,  was  a  distinguished  man  of 
letters.  m.  p. 

CORPORATION,  Municipal.  A  body  of 
persons  incorporated  for  the  purpose  of  promot- 
ing the  good  government  of  a  town. 

By  the  Municipal  Corporation  Act  1835  (5  & 
6  Will.  IV.  c.  76)  the  greater  number  of  muni- 
cipal corporations  were  reformed  and  their  con- 
stitution placed  upon  a  uniform  basis.  That 
act  and  subsequent  acts  have  been  consolidated 
by  the  Municipal  Corporations  Act  1882  (45 
&  46  Vict.  c.  50). 

The  government  of  a  municipal  corporation 
is  entrusted  to  a  mayor  and  a  certain  number  of 
aldermen  and  councillors  who  constitute  the 
"council."  The  council  is  elected  by  the  bur- 
gesses ;  the  aldermen  and  mayor  by  the  council. 
The  qualification  of  a  burgess  consists  in  (1)  being 
of  full  age  ;  (2)  having  occupied  a  building  in 
the  borough  for  twelve  months ;  (3)  being  rated 
to  relief  of  the  poor  and  having  paid  his  rate : 
(4)  not  having  received  parochial  relief;  and  (5) 
residing  witliin  seven  miles  of  the  borough. 

The  rents,  profits,  and  interest  of  all  corpor- 
ate property  is  paid  into  a  borough  fund,  and 
out  of  such  fund  the  expenditure  is  defrayed. 
Any  deficiency  is  made  up  by  a  borough  rate. 

The  consent  of  the  Treasury  is  required  to 
enable  a  corporation  to  acquire  or  dispose  of 
land,  but  it  may,  subject  to  certam  restrictions, 
make  leases  not  exceeding  thirty-one  years. 

The  chief  powers  enjoyed  by  municipal  cor- 
porations are  :  the  administration  of  all  town 
property  ;  paving,  lighting,  and  the  cleansing 
and  maintenance  of  thoroughfares  ;  the  making 
of  sewers ;  the  establishment  of  public  buildings  ; 
appointment  and  supervision  of  the  police  ;  the 
administration  of  special  trusts  ;  and  the  super- 
intendence of  education  where  there  is  no  school- 
board. 

Special  powers  are  enjoyed  for  the  purpose  of 
removing  unhealthy  areas  and  erecting  work- 
men's dwellings. 

By  the  Local  Government  Act  1888  boroughs 
are  divided  into  four  classes  :  (1)  those  under 
10,000  inhabitants  ;  (2)  those  over  10,000  but 
without  quarter-sessions  ;  (3)  those  over  10,000 
but  with  quarter-sessions  ;  and  (4)  sixty-one 
named  boroughs  each  with  a  population  of 
50,000,  on  the  1st  June  1888. 

The  first  three  classes  form  part  of  the 
county  in  which  they  are  situate.  Class  1  is 
practically  incorporated  with  the  county.  In 
class  2  the  right  of  the  borough  justices  to 
grant  licences  is  withdrawn.     In  class  3   the 


428 


CORPORATION— CORPORATIONS  OF  ARTS  AND  TRADES 


boroughs  are  permitted  to  continue  to  manage 
minor  business.  Class  4  is  invested  with  all 
the  powers  of  a  county  council.  A  county 
borough  is  entitled  to  share  in  the  local  taxation 
account ;  the  amount  depending  on  an  adjust- 
ment to  be  made  between  the  county  and*  the 
borough  ;  and  all  boroughs  are  to  receive  from 
the  county  council  grants  in  aid  of  the  salaries 
of  certain  officers,  and  of  county  lunatics. 

Any  deficiency  of  income  is  met  by  borough  or 
police  rates.  As  a  sanitary  authority  a  borough 
may  also  levy  general  district  rates  and  private 
improvement  rates.  Money  may  be  borrowed 
with  the  assent  of  the  local  government  board. 

[C.  Gross,  The  Gild  Merchant,  Oxford,  1890. 
— J.  S.  Vine,  English  Municipal  Institutions, 
London,  1879. — 0.  N.  Bazalgette  and  G.  Hum- 
phreys, Local  and  Municipal  Government,  Lon- 
don, 1888. — J.  M.  Lely,  Municipal  Corporations, 
London,  1882.]  j.e.  c.  M. 

CORPORATION,  Aggregate.  An  associa- 
tion of  persons  which  the  law  regards  as  capable 
of  possessing  rights,  and  of  being  subject  to 
duties.  The  existence  of  a  corporation  depends 
in  English  law  on  one  of  five  things,  viz.  ^1^ 
common  law,  (2)  prescription,  (3)  statute,  (4) 
charter,  or  (5)  implication  (see  Grant  On  Cor- 
porations) ;  but  practically  all  corporations  may 
be  traced  to  charters  granted  by  the  crown  or 
to  acts  of  parliament.  The  early  corporations 
were  generally  ecclesiastical  or  municipal  bodies, 
though  some  were  formed  for  charitable  or 
educational  purposes.  Trading  corporations 
are  more  modern.  At  first  they  were,  and 
sometimes  are,  incorporated  by  charter  (see 
Charter)  or  by  special  act  of  parliament,  but 
in  1844  persons  were  allowed  to  form  a  com- 
pany by  means  of  a  certificate  of  incorporation. 
Each  member  of  a  company  so  incorporated  was 
liable  for  the  debts  of  the  company,  but  in 
1855  an  act  (18  &  19  Vict.  c.  133)  was  passed 
which  authorised  the  formation  of  companies 
in  which  the  liability  of  each  member  is  limited 
to  the  amount  of  shares  held  by  him.  This 
principle  has  been  developed  by  subsequent 
legislation,  and  the  "company"  is  to  a  large 
extent  taking  the  place  of  the  "partnership." 
Apart  from  the  limitation  of  liability,  a  com- 
pany possesses  a  great  practical  advantage  over 
the  partnership,  inasmuch  as  the  death  of  a 
partner  usually  dissolves  the  partnership,  where- 
as the  death  of  a  member  of  a  company  does 
not  afi'ect  its  existence.  A  further  important 
distinction  between  these  two  modes  of  conduct- 
ing business  is  that  one  partner  can  as  a  rule 
withdraw  his  capital,  whereas  a  shareholder 
cannot  do  so  unless  the  company  is  wound  up. 

J.  E.  c.  M. 

CORPORATION,  Sole,  is  a  name  under 
which  each  successive  holder  of  any  public  office 
is  described  in  his  capacity  of  owner  of  any  pro- 
perty attached  to  such  office  (e.g,  the  rector  of 
a  parish  as  owner  of  the  glebe).  e.  s. 


CORPORATIONS  OF  ARTS  AND  TRADED 

England,  p.  428 :  France,  p.  430 ;  Germany,  p.  431. 

The  constitution  of  manufacturing  industi'y 
in  the  Middle  Ages  was  everywhere  in  Europe 
characterised  by  the  system  of  Guilds,  or 
corporations  of  arts  and  trades.  These  diff"ered 
more  or  less  in  the  different  countries.  In 
England,  where  the  state  was  consolidated 
and  a  strong  central  power  established  at  an 
earlier  period  than  in  France  or  Germany, 
trade  was  earlier  and  more  completely  controlled 
by  the  government,  and  the  state  regulations 
relating  to  it  more  energetically  and  systematic- 
ally carried  into  effect.  The  guilds  were  not 
as  widely  diffused  in  England,  nor  had  they  as 
great  a  degree  of  autonomy,  as  elsewhere.  But 
in  their  aims  and  operations,  wherever  they 
existed,  there  was  a  remarkable  general  similar- 
ity, so  that  a  statement  of  these  for  England 
will  apply  in  a  great  degree  to  the  other  coun- 
tries which  have  been  named.  The  same  re- 
mark may  be  made  respecting  the  history  of 
these  institutions.  A  survey  of  their  rise, 
progress,  and  decline  in  England,  France,  and 
Germany  respectively,  will  show  that  in  their 
development  and  downfall  identical  social 
causes  were  everywhere  in  operation. 

England. — Already,  in  the  Anglo-Saxon 
times,  religious  and  social  guilds  had  existed 
for  the  performance  of  pious  offices  and  for 
mutual  help  and  solace,  and  frith-guilds  for 
joint  action  in  personal  defence  and  for  preser- 
vation of  the  peace.  The  latter  rose  naturally 
in  a  society  where  the  state  was  not  strong 
enough  to  provide  adequately  for  the  legal 
protection  of  its  members.  But  the  merchant 
guilds,  which  are  found  in  the  Norman  period 
in  many  English  towns,  though  they  may  have 
been  suggested  by  these  earlier  associations, 
had  quite  different  aims.  The  merchant  guild 
(or  "hanse"  as  it  was  sometimes  called)  was  a 
society  "formed  primarily  for  the  purpose  of 
obtaining  and  maintaining  the  privilege  of 
carrying  on  trade  "  in  a  town.  This  privilege 
implied  the  restriction  of  that  trade  to  the 
guild  brethren,  who  had  also  defined  rights  of 
traffic  with  other  towns.  Any  one,  not  a 
member  of  the  guild,  trading  in  the  town,  was 
subject  to  fines.  An  entrance  fee  had  to  be 
paid  on  admission  to  the  guild,  and  probably 
annual  dues  to  the  common  fund,  -which  were 
spent  in  festivities  or  religious  offerings,  or  in 
relieving  the  poorer  brethren.  Rules  for  the 
conduct  of  buying  and  selling  in  the  town,  and 
for  the  enforcement  of  commercial  morality, 
were  framed  by  the  guild,  and  binding  on  its 
members.  Admission  to  the  merchant  guilds 
seems  to  have  been  open  only  to  those  inhabit- 
ants of  the  town  who  were  full  burgesses  by 
virtue  of  holding  land  within  the  town  bound- 
aries.  Each  guild  had  for  its  head  a  president 
caUed  an  alderman,  with  two  or  more  assistant? 


II 


CORPORATIONS  OF  ARTS  AND  TRADES— ENGLAND 


42S 


known  as  wardens  ;  and  there  was  a  council  of 
twelve  or  twenty-four. 

The  earliest  distinct  mention  of  a  merchant 
guild  is  in  the  year  1093,  but  they  may  have 
existed  before  the  Conquest.  The  charters 
granted  by  Henry  II.  to  a  number  of  the 
leading  English  towns  recognise  the  existence 
in  them  of  guilds  merchant.  The  craft  guilds 
appear  somewhat  later ;  they  are  found  in 
some  places  early  in  the  12th  century,  and  in 
the  13th  we  hear  of  them  in  most  of  the 
industrial  towns.  Their  origin  has  been  vari- 
ously explained.  Some  have  regarded  them  as 
the  descendants  of  the  collegia  of  the  Roman 
artisans.  But  the  latter  organisations,  at  least 
under  the  later  empire,  were  not  free  associa- 
tions, but  were  imposed  by  the  government  on 
the  working  classes  ;  and  it  is  not  likely  that 
they  had  a  continuous  existence  from  the  5  th 
to  the  12th  century.  Others  suppose  the  craft 
guilds  to  have  arisen  out  of  organisations,  under 
seigniorial  regulations,  of  artisan  serfs  on  the 
lands  of  monasteries  and  great  nobles.  But 
this  is  a  mere  hypothesis,  so  far  as  England  is 
concerned,  and  for  France  and  Germany  it  has 
been  made  probable  only  in  some  special  cases. 
Brentano,  again,  has  put  forward  the  view  that 
the  craft  guilds  were  formed  in  consequence  of 
the  expulsion  of  the  petty  artisans  from  the 
merchant  guilds,  the  craftsmen  combining  for 
mutual  protection  against  the  old  burgliers. 
An  obstinate  struggle  does  seem  to  have  taken 
place  in  Germany  and  the  Netherlands  between 
a  burgher  oligarchy  which  had  got  possession 
of  the  municipal  government  and  the  members 
of  the  craft  guilds  ;  but  there  is  no  evidence 
of  any  such  contest  in  England.  These  guilds 
seem  to  have  everywhere  arisen  spontaneously 
out  of  the  social  conditions  of  the  Middle  Ages, 
and  to  have  been  at  first  simply  private  associa- 
tions for  the  general  advancement  of  the  in- 
terests of  the  artisans,  as  the  merchant  guilds 
had  been  for  promoting  those  of  the  traders. 

The  earliest  English  craft  guilds  that  came 
into  notice  were  those  of  weavers  and  fullers 
of  woollen  cloth.  "We  hear  of  them  in  1130  as 
making  an  annual  payment  to  the  king  for  the 
royal  licence,  without  which  they  were  treated 
as  ''adulterine"  and  fined.  The  royal  charter 
forbade  any  one  in  the  town  to  which  it  related 
to  follow  a  craft  unless  he  was  a  member  of  the 
corresponding  guild,  and  conferred  on  the  guild 
the  right  of  exercising  a  certain  supervision  over 
its  members.  Of  the  powers  thus  bestowed  the 
municipal  authorities  were  often  jealous,  and 
we  find  those  of  London  offering  King  John  a 
money  payment  on  condition  of  his  abolishing 
the  weavers'  guild.  The  exclusive  right  to 
engage   in  trade  which  had  belonged  to  the 

(merchant  guilds  brought  these  last  into  collision 
with  the  craftsmen,  who  sometimes  sold  the 
wares  they  produced  dii'ectly  to  their  customers  ; 
and  the  craftsmen  ultimately  gained  the  rights 


of  burgesses,  though  we  cannot  trace  the  history 
of  the  change.  The  monopoly  of  the  burgesses 
was  probably  lost  before  the  end  of  the  13th 
century ;  in  any  case  the  statute  of  1335, 
establishing  the  freedom  of  buying  and  selling, 
must  have  abolished  it.  This  amounted  practi- 
cally to  a  dissolution  of  the  merchant  guilds, 
which  survived  only  as  social  and  religious  clubs, 
or  as  a  machinery  for  the  discharge  of  certain 
functions  of  the  municipal  government,  especi- 
ally for  admission  of  apprentices  to  the  freedom 
of  the  city.  The  bye-laws  of  the  several  craft- 
guilds  made  it  a  requisite  for  admission  to  a 
trade  to  have  served  an  apprenticeship  of  a 
certain  duration,  the  term  being  usually  seven 
years.  They  also  prescribed  the  proper  treat- 
ment of  apprentices  by  the  master,  and  some- 
times limited  the  number  which  a  master  was 
allowed  to  have.  They  fixed  the  conditions 
which  must  be  satisfied  before  setting  up  as  a 
master,  and  regulated  the  processes  of  mann- 
factm-e  with  a  view  to  the  production  of  good 
and  solid  work.  They  exercised  a  general  sur- 
veillance over  the  moral  conduct  of  their  mem- 
bers. Violations  of  the  rules  were  punished  by 
fines,  and,  in  case  of  repeated  oifences,  by  expul- 
sion from  the  trade.  The  guilds  further  per- 
formed in  some  degree  the  functions  of  friendly 
societies,  and  practised  common  festivities  and 
religious  observances. 

These  bodies  have  sometimes  been  represented 
as  issuing  the  regulations  and  exercising  the 
jurisdiction  we  have  described  quite  independ- 
ently of  the  city  authorities,  whilst  others 
consider  them  to  have  been  no  more  than  the 
mechanism  through  which  the  municipality 
superintended  manufacture,  the  officers  of  the 
guilds  merely  bringing  offenders  before  the 
municipal  courts.  The  truth  seems  to  lie 
between  these  two  views.  The  town  magis- 
trates could  issue  regulations  binding  on  the 
crafts  ;  but  the  guild  rules  were  in  fact  gener- 
ally drawn  up  by  the  craftsmen  themselves 
and  submitted  to  the  magistrates,  who  usually 
sanctioned  them  as  of  course  and,  though  some- 
times taking  causes  into  their  own  hands, 
commonly  left  the  supervision  of  the  manufac- 
ture and  the  decision  of  minor  questions  to  the 
masters,  bailiffs,  or  overseers  of  the  trades. 
The  extent  of  the  jurisdiction  of  the  guilds  was 
probably  different  in  different  places.  The 
kings,  from  Edward  I.  onward,  favoured  the 
craft  guilds  as  a  useful  counterpoise  to  the  urban 
magnates,  and  as  a  serviceable  auxiliary  for  police 
purposes.  And  the  municipal  authorities  them- 
selves became  friendly  to  them  as  subserving  the 
latter  object.  Indeed  before  the  end  of  the 
reign  of  Edward  III.,  citizenship  was  bound  up 
with  the  membership  of  one  of  the  guilds,  and 
it  was  natural  that  the  jealousy  between  them 
and  the  town  governments  should  disappear. 

In  the  time  of  Edward  III.  there  were  aa 
many  as  forty  distinct  companies  or  crafts  in 


430 


CORPORATIONS  OF  ARTS  AND  TRADES— FRANCE 


London,  and  at  the  end  of  the  century  not 
fewer  than  sixty  ;  in  towns  of  the  second  rank 
their  number  increased  more  slowly.  In  the 
first  half  of  the  14th  century  the  guild  system 
was  at  its  maximum  of  efficiency.  It  continued 
to  extend  itself  to  new  centres  for  two  hundred 
years  afterwards.  But  under  the  Tudors  the 
direct  control  and  superintendence  of  industry 
was  more  and  more  taken  into  the  hands  of  the 
central  government,  and  the  regulations  of 
crafts  and  trades  were  incorporated  into  the 
public  law  of  the  realm.  The  act  5  Eliz. 
c.  4  (1562),  commonly  called  the  Statute  of 
Apprentices,  adopting  what  had  been  the  ordin- 
ary bye-law  of  the  corporations,  required  a 
seven  years'  apprenticeship  in  all  trades  carried 
on  in  market  towns.  It  provided  that  when 
there  were,  in  certain  specified  trades,  three 
apprentices  in  a  workshop,  at  least  one  journey- 
man should  be  employed,  and  for  every  addi- 
tional apprentice  another  journeyman.  It  also 
contained  enactments  respecting  the  hours  of 
labour  and  the  annual  fixing  of  the  rate  of 
wages  by  the  justices  of  the  peace.  This  statute 
was  held  not  to  apply  to  trades  established  at 
a  la-ter  period,  or  to  places  which  only  obtained 
corporate  privileges  after  1562  ;  and  thus  some 
of  the  most  important  manufactures  of  Eng- 
land were  never  subject  to  it.  In  Scotland  no 
such  law  existed,  and  Adam  Smith  says  that 
"  he  knew  of  no  country  in  Europe  in  which 
corporation  rules  were  so  little  oppressive." 

The  increasing  application  of  great  capitals 
to  industry,  and  the  substitution  of  the  factory 
for  the  workshop,  tended  to  make  the  old  trade 
rules  obsolete  ;  and  the  guild  spirit  became  at 
the  same  time  more  narrow  and  selfish.  In  the 
18  th  century  any  statutes  which  gave  coercive 
power  to  the  guilds,  though  not  formally  re- 
pealed, were  in  a  great  degree  allowed  to  fall 
into  desuetude,  and  the  importance  of  these 
institutions  practically  disappeared.  They 
were  discredited  in  principle  by  the  polemic 
directed  against  them  in  the  Wealth  of  Nations. 
Adam  Smith  condemned  "the  exclusive  privi- 
leges of  corporations,  statutes  of  apprentice- 
ship, and  all  those  which  restrain  in  particular 
employments  the  competition  to  a  smaller 
number  than  would  otherwise  go  into  them," 
as  "encroachments  on  natural  liberty,"  as 
raising  the  market  prices  of  the  wares  produced 
above  their  natural  price,  and  as  obstructing 
the  free  circulation  of  labour  fi'om  one  employ- 
ment to  another.  Smith  held  that  a  long,  or 
indeed  any  fixed,  term  of  apprenticeship  was 
altogether  unnecessary  ;  but  he  certainly  ex- 
aggerates the  facility  with  which  handicrafts 
can  be  thoroughly  learned.  He  also  thought  it 
a  mere  pretence  that  corporations  are  required 
for  the  better  government  of  trade.  After 
several  partial  enactments  of  a  liberal  tendency, 
the  apprentices'  act  of  Elizabeth  was  repealed 
in  1814  (54   Geo.   III.  c.   96),   and  the  trade 


privileges  of  the  guilds  formally  abolishfcd  in 
1835  (5  &  6  Will.  IV.  c.  76).  Partly  as 
a  result  of  the  legal  destruction  of  the  old 
system,  a  new  legislation  has  been  introduced 
for  the  protection  of  the  working  classes  by 
provisions  for  the  healthy  conduct  of  manu- 
facturing production,  and  the  limitation  and 
regulation  of  the  labour  of  women  and  children. 
France. — In  France  the  name  jurande  was 
given  to  the  office  of  those  who  were  appointed 
to  watch  over  the  execution  of  the  trade 
regulations  and  the  conservation  of  the  interests 
of  the  several  crafts.  These  Juris  corresponded 
pretty  nearly  to  the  English  wardens.  Those 
only  who  were  admitted  as  mattres  could  carry 
on  a  manufacture  on  their  own  account.  The 
production  of  a  chef-d'oeuvre  (masterpiece)  was 
commonly  required  for  admission  to  the 
maUrise,  and  it  was  the  business  of  the  jur^  to 
pass  judgment  on  its  execution.  The  journey- 
men (compagnons)  had  been  apprentices  to  the 
trade,  and  expected  in  time  to  be  themselves 
mattres.  The  relations  of  the  three  classes 
were  substantially  the  same  as  in  England. 
Powerful  corporations  existed  from  early  times 
in  Paris.  The  Parisian  marchands  de  I'eau 
(nautcB  Pari^iMci)  dominated  the  commerce  of 
Paris.  The  provost  of  this  body  was  the  head 
of  the  municipal  magistracy.  The  corporations 
of  goldsmiths  and  of  money-changers  were  also 
very  ancient.  The  documents  relating  to  the 
trade  corporations  of  the  metropolis  begin  to  be 
numerous  in  the  time  of  Philip  Augustus.  The 
trade  statutes  and  customs  of  the  city  of  Paris 
in  the  13  th  century  are  preserved  in  the  collec- 
tion made  by  £tienne  Boyleau  (seeBoiLEAU,  E.), 
appointed  provost  of  the  city  by  Louis  IX.  about 
1260.  The  kings,  who  at  first  were  hostile  to 
the  claims  of  the  corporations,  from  the  begin- 
ning of  the  15th  century  favoured  them,  both 
as  useful  instruments  of  police  and  as  a  source 
of  fiscal  aids.  But  they  also  sought,  though 
often  with  but  little  success,  to  temper  their 
exclusiveness,  repress  their  exactions,  and 
adapt  their  regulations  from  time  to  time  to 
the  development  of  new  branches  of  industry 
and  new  methods  of  production,  whilst  on  the 
other  hand  they  insisted  on  their  royal  right  of 
issuing  letters  of  maitrise,  and  of  supervising 
the  guilds.  Louis  XI.  in  1467  armed  the 
trades,  forming  them  into  banners  and  com- 
panies, bound  by  an  oath  of  fidelity  to  the 
crown.  An  edict  of  Henry  III.  (1581)  gave  to 
the  institution  of  corporations  the  extent  of 
a  national  system,  and  placed  all  the  trades  of 
the  kingdom  under  a  general  law.  The  edict 
at  the  same  time  corrected  prevalent  abuses. 
It  mentions  in  particular  the  heavy  expenses  to 
which  artisans  were  subjected  in  order  to 
obtain  the  maUrise,  the  masterpiece  which  they 
had  to  produce  sometimes  absorbing  the  work 
of  more  than  a  year,  and  candidates  being 
expected  to  regale  the  jur6s  with  banquets  and 


CORPORATIONS  OF  ARTS  AND  TRADES— GERMANY 


431 


conciliate  them  by  gifts.  The  crown,  by  this 
act,  may  be  said  to  have  taken  possession  of 
the  police  of  mannfacturmg  industry  through- 
out the  realm.  But,  owing  to  the  opposition 
of  the  guilds  and  of  the  civic  authorities,  Vhe 
provisions  of  the  edict  were  very  imperfectly 
carried  into  effect,  and  a  law  of  Henry  IV. 
(1597)  was  not  much  more  successful. 

In  the  last  states-general  (1614)  the  tiers  etat 
brought  forward  a  strong  protest  against  the 
prevailing  evils,  and  prayed  for  the  suppression 
of  all  guilds  created  since  1576,  and  the  open- 
ing of  crafts  to  all  persons  without  exception, 
subject  only  to  visitation  by  state  inspectors. 
But  the  government  did  not  respond  to  this 
appeal.  The  industrial  policy  of  Colbert  recog- 
nised the  guilds,  but  only  as  organs  of  the  state, 
subject  to  its  control  and  direction  ;  he  revised 
the  statutes  of  the  existing  bodies,  and  founded 
many  new  ones,  and  regulated  their  whole  pro- 
ceedings (1673-74).  But  though  eminently 
successful  in  his  own  hands,  his  general  system, 
as  carried  out  by  his  unintelligent  and  feeble 
successors,  tended  rather  to  impede  than  to 
promote  industry.  While  the  guilds  were  not 
duly  controlled,  they  were  subjected  to  exorbit- 
ant charges,  and  were  thus  forced  to  impose 
extravagant  dues  on  then-  members,  and  to 
insist  more  strongly  on  their  monopoly.  There 
were  endless  prosecutions  of  indi\ddual  artisans, 
and  conflicts  as  to  the  limits  of  the  several 
industrial  professions,  as  well  as  struggles  for 
precedence  between  them,  and  these  tended  to 
bring  the  whole  system  into  disrepute.  The 
body  of  laws  relating  to  them,  however,  remained 
essentially  unaltered  till  1776,  when  Turgot 
proposed  to  Louis  XVI.  the  entire  abolition 
(except  in  a  few  trades  for  special  reasons)  of 
the  jurandes  and  niattrises,  and  the  establish- 
ment of  absolute  liberty  of  manufacture.  In 
an  elaborate  report  which,  according  to  his 
custom,  he  prefixed  to  the  ordinance,  he  main- 
tained that  * '  the  right  to  work  is  the  sacred 
and  inalienable  property  of  the  poor  man,"  and 
that  "all  sound  principles  were  violated  by  the 
accepted  doctrine  that  it  was  a  royal  right, 
which  the  prince  might  sell  and  the  subjects 
must  buy."  The  ordinance  was  carried  against 
the  will  of  the  parliament  in  a  lit  de  justice, 
but  its  execution  was  strongly  opposed  by  in- 
terested parties,  and,  after  the  fall  of  the 
minister,  the  old  system  was  introduced  again, 
though  with  some  liberal  reforms.  This  state 
of  things  lasted  until  the  constituent  assembly 
in  1791  abolished  the  corporations  and  pro- 
claimed the  complete  liberty  of  industry.  With 
some  fluctuations  this  policy  has,  on  the  whole, 
been  maintained  up  to  the  present  time. 

Germany. — The  German  Ziinfte  were  in  their 
aims  and  constitution  essentially  similar  to  the 
English  guilds  and  the  French  corporations. 
The  Emperor  Henry  I.  had  required  all  artisans 
to  settle  in  towns,  and  the  handicrafts  were 


long  held  to  be  the  special  right  of  urban  com- 
munities. The  Ziinfte  are  first  found  in  the 
12th  century  in  particular  cities  and  to^vns. 
They  gradually  gained  influence  in  the  civic  ad- 
ministration, and  on  the  other  hand  strengthened 
the  cities  against  the  nobility.  At  first  purely 
private  associations,  they  came  to  be  recognised 
as  organs  of  the  state,  and  exercised  certain 
magisterial  functions.  In  the  13th  and  14th 
centuries  they  extended  to  many  additional 
cities,  and  in  the  15th  century  there  was  a  com- 
plete guild  organisation  of  the  trades  through- 
out Germany.  The  rules  of  the  system  were 
rigorously  carried  out.  What  was  known  as  the 
Ziinftzwang  was  strictly  enforced,  that  is,  the 
requirement  that  every  artisan  should  belong  to 
one  of  the  corporations.  The  boundaries  of  trades 
were  precisely  fixed,  so  that  a  member  of  one 
could  not  do  work  which  properly  belonged  to 
another,  however  cognate  the  occupations  might 
be.  The  Ziinfte  in  different  places  were  bound 
together  and  kept  in  touch  with  each  other 
through  the  institution  of  the  Wanderjahr. 

In  the  17th  century  the  decline  of  these 
corporations  began.  The  growth  of  the  arts, 
the  rise  of  new  crafts  outside  the  Ziinfte,  and 
the  extension  of  manufacture  on  the  great  scale 
made  it  impossible  to  maintain  the  old  restric- 
tions on  processes  of  production  ;  and  the  open- 
ing of  distant  markets  and  the  development  of 
speculative  production  required  a  new  trade 
rigime.  At  the  same  time  the  central  govern- 
ments, in  the  spirit  of  the  mercantile  system, 
assumed  more  and  more  the  direct  control  of  the 
whole  field  of  national  industry.  As  the  Ziinfte 
increasingly  failed  to  serve  real  public  ends, 
they  were  more  and  more  governed  by  a  spirit 
of  selfish  exclusiveness,  and  were  worked  in  the 
interest  of  a  few  privileged  families.  For  those 
who  were  not  sons  of  masters  it  became  almost 
impossible  to  obtain  admission  except  by  mar- 
riage with  the  daughter  or  widow  of  a  master. 
The  reception  of  apprentices  was  made  difficult 
by  the  imposition  of  conditions  and  charges,  the 
qualifications  required  of  journeymen  (Gesellen) 
were  enhanced  by  lengthening  of  the  wander- 
period  and  the  time  of  probation.  The  educa- 
tion of  apprentices  was  neglected,  and  there 
was  little  care  for  the  condition  and  treatment  of 
the  journeymen.  But  the  ZUvfte  still  retained 
their  powers,  and  it  was  only  late  in  the  18th 
century  that  they  were  seriously  attacked. 
They  had  then  to  ^sustain  the  same  assaults  of 
economic  theory  which  were  directed  against 
the  English  guilds  and  the  French  corporations. 
Schlettwein,  a  German  follower  of  the  Physio- 
crats {q.v.),  denounced  the  whole  system  and 
demanded  freedom  of  industry.  But  the  legisla- 
tive overthrow  of  these  institutions  belongs  to 
the  19th  century,  and  was  not  completed  in  all 
the  states  before  the  middle  of  its  sixth  decade. 
The  Stein-Hardenberg  legislation  of  1808-10 
and  the  law  of  1811  established  the  liberty  of 


432 


coRTi— corv:6e 


Tianiifaoture  in  Prussia,  which  had  been  previ- 
ously introduced  in  the  provinces  \thich  formed 
pai  t  of  the  confederation  of  the  Rhine.  The 
principle  of  freedom  was  embodied  in  the  general 
ordinance  (Gewerbeordnung)  of  1845,  but  the 
revolutionary  period  which  followed  prevented 
the  fair  trial  of  this  ordinance,  and  the  com- 
plaints against  it  led  to  a  modification  of  its 
provisions  and  a  partial  return  to  the  old  order 
of  things  in  the  ordinances  of  1849.  In  1861 
and  1865  changes  were  again  made  in  a  liberal 
direction,  but  the  law  of  1849  remained  sub- 
stantially in  force  in  Prussia.  In  most  of  the 
other  states,  between  1860  and  1864,  the  prin- 
ciple of  industrial  liberty  was  introduced.  All 
these  local  laws  were  in  1869  merged  in  the 
uniform  code  of  the  North  German  Confedera- 
tion, which  has  since  become  that  of  the  empire. 
By  this  code  the  exclusive  rights  of  Zilnfte  or 
mercantile  corporations,  the  distinction  between 
city  and  country  with  respect  to  manufacture, 
the  necessity  of  a  proof  of  capacity  before  enter- 
ing any  craft  or  trade,  the  limitation  of  each 
artisan  to  one  branch  of  production,  and  all 
restrictions  as  to  modes  of  production,  have  been 
abolished,  and  it  is  left  open  to  every  subject  of 
the  empire  to  carry  on  any  industrial  profession, 
and  to  take  apprentices  and  employ  journeymen 
in  such  numbers  as  he  may  find  expedient, 
subject  only  to  sanitary  and  other  police  regula- 
tions and  to  such  fiscal  obligations  as  may  be 
imposed  by  the  laws. 

Adam  Smith  and  other  economists  have 
dwelt  too  exclusively  on  the  evils  and  abuses  of 
these  institutions,  and  have  left  out  of  account 
the  social  necessities  out  of  which  they  arose, 
and  the  not  inconsiderable  advantages  which 
they  possessed.  There  has  of  late  been  a  feeling 
in  France  and  Germany  that  with  the  abolition 
of  the  restrictions  enforced  by  the  corporations, 
there  was  a  real  loss  of  moral  and  social,  as 
well  as  of  some  economic,  benefits.  In  Prussia 
several  efforts  have  been  made  to  restore  them 
on  a  free  basis ;  and  it  is  understood  that  further 
steps  of  the  same  kind  are  now  likely  to  be 
taken  by  the  German  governments,  whose  object 
is  thus  to  establish  a  sort  of  police  of  the  in- 
dustrial world  and  solve  a  part  of  the  great  pro- 
blem of  the  organisation  of  labour.  It  seems, 
however,  extremely  questionable  whether  these 
institutions  could  be  usefully  revived  ;  and  the 
good  ends  which  some  have  hoped  to  attain 
through  their  instrumentality  must  probably 
be  effected  by  other  means  better  adapted  to 
existing  conditions. 

[The  best  book  on  guilds  merchant  is  Gross's 
Oild  Merchant,  1890. — On  English  guilds,  the 
student  should  first  read  Breutano's  Essay  on  the 
History  and  Development  of  Gilds,  prefixed  4o 
Toulmin  Smith's  English  Gilds,  1870.  With  it 
may  usefully  be  compared  Ochenkowski's  Englands 
wirthschaftliche  Entwickelung  im  Ausgange  des 
Mittelaltera,  1879,  and  Cunningham,   Growth  of 


English  Industry  and  Commerce. — In  Ashley's 
English  Economic  History  and  Theory,  vol.  i. 
1888,  will  be  found  a  clear  accouut  of  the  origin 
and  early  history  of  the  guilds,  founded  on  a  study 
of  the  sources.  Seligman's  Two  Chapters  on  the 
MedicevaZ  Guilds  of  England  (Amer.  Econ.  Assoc, 
vol.  ii. )  may  also  be  recommended.  For  the  French 
and  German  guilds,  see  the  article  "Gewerbe"  by 
Schonberg  in  his  Handhuch  der  politischen  Oeko- 
r^07?^^g,  3rd  ed.  1890.  Art.  " Maitrise," Encydopidie 
of  Diderot  and  D'Alembert.  — The  early  Parisian 
trade  rules  may  be  seen  in  ]^tienne  Boyleau'a 
Mglements  des  Arts  et  MStiers,  published  for  the 
first  time  by  Depping,  1837.]  J.  K.  i. 

CORTI,  Adolfo.  Author  of  Elementi  della 
sdenza  del  Commercio,  Pa  via,  1829.        m.  p. 

CORVAIA,  Baron,  a  socialist,  caused  a  book 
to  be  written  by  Michele  Parma,  proposing  the 
foundation  of  a  national  bank  intended  to 
redeem  the  lower  classes  from  the  oppression  of 
capitalists.  This  bank  was  to  be  connected 
with  a  savings  bank,  and  was  designed  to 
eliminate  usury.  The  treatise.  La  Ban^ocrazia, 
0  il  gran  lihro  sociale,  novella  sistema  finanziario 
was  published  at  Milan  in  1840,  and  was  trans- 
lated into^  German.  m.  p. 

CORVEE.  In  the  strict  sense  of  ihe  term, 
Corvie  is  used  to  signify  a  tax  levied  by  the 
state  on  the  labouring  classes,  and  paid  by  them 
in  a  certain  number  of  days  of  labour,  either 
wholly  unremunerated  or  remunerated  at  a  rate 
less  than  the  ordinary  rate  of  wages.  In  par- 
ticular such  a  system  of  taxation  has  very 
generally  been  applied  in  many  countries  to  the 
construction  and  maintenance  of  roads  and 
bridges,  each  locality  being  compelled  to  defray 
the  cost  of  such  works  by  contributions  of 
laboiu"  from  its  inhabitants.  In  England  the 
common  law  threw  upon  the  occupiers  of  land 
in  each  parish  the  duty  of  keeping  the  roads  in 
repair.  It  is  not  easy  to  say  exactly  how  this 
duty  was  originally  carried  out,  but  it  may 
fairly  be  presumed  that  the  statute  2  &  3 
Philip  and  Mary,  c.  8,  which  is  the  first  of  the 
many  highway  acts,  did  little  more  than  de- 
clare the  system  in  use.  Under  this  act  each 
parish  is  to  appoint  surveyors  of  highways  to 
oversee  the  repair  of  the  roads  in  that  district. 
Labour  required  for  this  purpose  is  to  be  dis- 
tributed by  the  inhabitants  in  the  following 
proportions.  Every  occupier  of  land  is  to  send 
for  every  ploughland  occupied  by  him  a  cart 
with  horses  and  two  able  men  with  them,  and 
every  householder,  cottager,  or  labourer,  unless 
he  be  a  yearly  hired  servant,  is  to  work  himself 
or  by  a  substitute  on  such  days  as  the  surveyors 
shall  appoint  for  the  repairing  of  the  roads. 
These  days  under  the  act  of  Philip  and  Mary 
were  to  be  four  in  number,  but  the  act  5  Eliz. 
c.  13  extended  the  number  to  six,  which  were 
all  to  be  before  Midsummer  day.  Fines  for 
non-attendance  on  the  days  fixed  were  to  form 
a  fund  for  the  repair  of  the  roads.  The  first 
step  towards  the  abolition  of  this  form  of  taxa- 


COh'^QLOl'GORVETTO 


433 


tion  was  taken  by  the  act  15  Charles  11,  c.  1, 
the  first  of  the  turnpike  acts,  which  applies 
the  system  of  tolls  to  the  counties  of  Hertford, 
Cambridge,  and  Huntingdon,  through  which  ran 
the  great  road  to  York  and  the  north.  Sta^te 
labour,  as  corv6e  was  called  in  England,  had 
already  been  found  inadequate  to  keep  in  proper 
repair  many  of  the  great  ways  of  communication, 
and  the  bad  state  of  the  chief  roads  was  a 
frequent  subject  of  complaints  and  petitions  to 
parliament  about  this  time.  The  system  of 
turnpikes  was  accordingly  extended  by  degrees 
to  the  whole  of  England,  and  in  many  cases  its 
introduction  gave  rise  to  great  discontent  and 
serious  local  riots  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  the 
inhabitants  were  thus  set  free  from  statute 
labour.  However,  many  of  the  roads  in  the 
country,  including  almost  all  purely  local  ones, 
were  not  turnpike  roads,  but  remained  subject 
to  the  provisions  of  the  various  highway  acts 
which  were  enacted  from  time  to  time.  But 
even  for  the  repair  of  these  statute  labour  was 
beginning  to  be  found  insufficient.  The  act  3 
&  4  William  and  Mary,  c.  12  gives  to  the 
justices  of  the  peace  power  to  levy  a  rate  in 
cases  where  the  six  days  of  forced  labour  should 
be  found  to  be  insufficient,  and  after  various 
changes  had  been  introduced  by  subsequent 
acts,  statute  labour  was  finally  abolished  by 
the  act  5  and  6  William  lY.  c.  50,  which 
substituted  for  it  the  system  of  highway  boards 
and  rates  now  in  existence. 

It  would  not  appear  that  in  England  this 
limited  application  of  corvee  was  ever  unpopular. 
In  France,  however,  where  the  corv6c  originally 
existed  only  in  certain  disti-icts,  its  extension 
to  the  whole  of  the  country,  effected  by  M.  Orry, 
controller-general  of  finance  in  1737,  gave  rise 
to  much  discontent.  The  burden  on  the  peasant 
was  heavier,  and  the  peasant  was  less  able  to  bear 
it,  than  in  England.  In  1758  M.  de  BouUogne, 
then  controller-general,  estimates  the  annual 
value  of  the  labour  so  contributed  at  1,200,000 
livres,  probably  a  modest  estimate.  Certainly 
the  burden  on  the  peasant  was  much  heavier. 
Necker  estimates  the  cost  to  the  peasants  of  the 
services  rendered  in  Berry  alone  at  624,000 
livres.  These  consisted  not  only  of  the  labour 
of  the  peasant  himself ;  beyond  this  he  was 
compelled  to  bring  with  him  any  beasts  of 
draught  or  burden,  and  any  vehicle,  that  he 
possessed.  Nor  was  it  only  for  the  repair  of 
the  roads  that  corvie  was  imposed  upon  him. 
In  De  Tocqueville's  Ancien  Mgiinie,  p.  444, 
will  be  found  an  account  of  the  various  public 
services  carried  out  by  means  of  corvee,  and 
Turgot's  Lettre  au  Controleur  Gdndral  sur 
I'abolition  de  la  corvee  pour  les  transports  mili- 
taires  gives  a  vivid  picture  of  the  wastefulness 
and  inconvenience  involved  in  that  particular 
application  of  forced  labour. 

A  good  account  of  the  inadequacy  of  corvie 
as  applied  to  the  construction  and  maintenance 
VOL.  I. 


of  the  roads  is  given  in  Diderot's  IhicydopMie, 
but  the  most  effectual  indictment  of  this  tax  ia 
to  be  found  in  Turgot's  M^moire  au  roi  sur  un 
projet  d'^dit  tendant  a  supprimer  la  corv4e,  with 
the  accompanying  criticisms  of  M.  de  Miromes- 
nil  and  Turgot's  often  rather  contemptuous 
replies  (see  vol.  ii.  p.  237  of  Turgot's  collected 
works).  This,  with  the  curious  Frocks  verbal  du 
lit  de  justice  tenu  d  Versailles  le  12  Mars  1776, 
will  give  a  good  idea  of  the  arguments  used 
both  by  Turgot  and  his  opponents  on  this 
question. 

The  abolition  of  corvie  by  this  edict  was, 
however,  only  temporary.  Turgot's  successor 
Calonne  at  once  restored  it,  and  though  again 
abolished  in  the  early  days  of  the  Revolution, 
the  reactionary  policy  of  the  Directoiro  once 
more  reinstated  it  under  the  name  of  Prestation 
by  the  decree  of  4  Thermidor,  an  x.  At  the 
present  day  the  repair  of  the  communal  roads 
of  France  is  carried  out  under  this  system. 
By  the  laws  of  the  28th  July  1824  and  the  21st 
May  1836  the  municipal  councils  may  call  upon 
every  male  citizen  between  certain  ages  to  give 
three  days'  labour  yearly  for  this  pur]^)ose,  and 
may  exact  the  same  time  from  every  beast  of 
draught  or  burden  and  vehicle  within  the  com- 
mune. A  money  payment  in  lieu  of  labour 
may  be  made  at  discretion. 

For  an  account  of  the  use  of  corvee  in  Egypt, 
see  the  Times,  14th  September  1888.  The 
construction  of  the  Suez  Canal  during  its  early 
stages  was  carried  out  under  a  system  of  forced 
labour  on  a  very  large  scale.  In  most  countries, 
however,  taxes  of  the  nature  of  corv4e  are  now 
disused,  unless  the  Conscription  {q.v.)  is  re- 
garded as  an  exception  to  this  rule. 

In  mediaeval  societies  payments  in  labour  to  in- 
dividuals, especiallyin  lieu  of  rent,  were  common, 
and  in  France  were  termed  corv6es  personnelles. 
The  nature  of  these  and  their  economic  bearings 
will,  however,  be  most  fitly  treated  of  under 
Manor  and  Feudalism  {q.v.) 

[CEuvres  de  Turgot,  nouvelle  Edition,  par  MM, 
Eugene  Daire  et  Hippolyte  Dussard,  precedee  par 
une  notice  sur  la  vie  et  les  ouvrages  de  Turgot,  par 
M.  Eugene  Daire,  1844. — M.  Necker,  De  Vad.- 
ministration  des  Finances  de  la  France,  1784. — 
Collection  de  comptes  rendus  Pieces  authentiques 
etats  et  tableaux  depuis  1758  jusqioen  1787  con- 
cernant  les  Finances  de  France,  1788. — Diderot 
et  D'Alembert,  Encyclopedic,  1772.  — De  Tocque- 
ville,  Vancien  Regime  et  la  Revolution,  1857. — 
De  Tocqueville,  Histoire  Philosophique  du  regne 
de  Louis  XV.,  1847. — Larou.sse,  Dictionnaire 
Universel,  1866.  —  Penny  Cyclopoedia,  articles 
"Turnpike"  and  "Highway,"  1833. — Stephen's 
New  Commentaries  on  the  Laws  of  England, 
1886. — Comyns'  Digest  of  the  Laws  of  England, 
1822.]  c,  G.  c. 

CORYETTO,  Louis-Emmanuel,  Comte  de 
CoRVETTO  (1766-1821),  born  and  died  at  Genoa, 
early  distinguished  himself  in  law  and  politics 
in  his  native  city,  and  was  made  a  director  of 

2  F 


434 


COSHERY— OTJ5T.T5.  BOOK 


the  Bank  of  St.  George  there  in  1802.  Bona- 
parte created  him  councillor  of  state  in  1805, 
and  transferred  him  to  Paris,  where  he  helped 
to  draft  the  Oode  de  Commerce  and  the  Code 
Penal.  In  1811  he  became  inspector-general 
of  state  prisons,  was  retained  in  the  ^state 
councU  by  Louis  XVIII.,  made  president  of  the 
section  of  finance,  and  (27th  Sept.  1815  to 
7th  Dec.  1818)  minister  of  finance.  The 
economic  interest  of  his  career  centres  in  this 
last  office.  Upon  Corvette  devolved  the  problem 
of  freeing  the  teri'itory  by  meeting  the  war  in- 
demnity of  700  million  francs  (£28,000,000), 
in  addition  to  claims  of  1400  million  francs 
(£56,000,000),  for  requisitions  made  during 
the  war.  Though  the  latter  claims  were  cut 
down  to  240  millions  (£9,600,000),  Corvetto 
was  obliged  to  issue  large  amounts  of  stock, 
and  to  seek  the  aid  of  Messrs.  Hope  and 
Baring  ;  but  the  circumstances  under  which 
the  loans  were  floated,  and  the  action  of  the 
government  in  inflating  the  price  of  the  stock 
by  large  purchases,  led  "Wellington  to  describe 
the  Paris  money-market  as  the  scene  of  such 
speculation  as  had  not  been  equalled  since  the 
days  of  Law.  Corvetto  justified  his  action  on 
the  ground  that  it  was  patriotic  to  pay  the  state 
debts  as  cheaply  as  possible  and  to  maintain  its 
credit.  His  conduct  has  been  severely  criticised 
by  M.  Leon  Say,  who  argues  that  the  interven- 
tion of  the  government  in  such  speculations 
can  have  but  a  momentary  efiect  upon  prices, 
apart  from  other  and  pernicious  consequences. 
The  intentions  of  Corvetto  were  good  :  his 
example  was  dangerous. 

[L.  Say  :  Les  interventions  du  Trisor  d  la  Bourse 
depuis  cent  ans.  (Annales  de  Tj^cole  libre  des 
Sciences  politiques  1^^^  ann6e  1886,  pp.  12-24). — 
Baron  G.  de  Nervo  :  Le  comte  Corvetto,  Paris, 
1869.]  H.  H. 

COSHERY.  In  the  Middle  Ages  social  and 
political  relations  in  Ireland  were  regulated  by 
the  clan  system.  There  was  no  private  pro- 
perty in  land  :  the  clansmen  being  co- pro- 
prietors with  the  chief.  But  although  the 
chief  was  not  lord  of  the  land,  he  had  large 
customary  rights  over  the  property  of  his 
dependents.  One  of  the  most  important  of 
these  was  coshery,  an  old  custom  which  allowed 
him  to  take  the  houses  and  provisions  of  his 
clansmen  for  the  use  of  himself  and  his  followers. 
The  English  invaders  of  Ireland  based  upon 
this  right  the  practice  of  coigns  and  livery, 
by  which  they  extorted  from  the  Irish  free 
quarters  and  provisions  for  their  soldiers.  After 
the  Cromwellian  settlement  many  of  the  dis- 
possessed chiefs  lived  for  years  at  the  expense 
of  their  former  dependents,  and  various  statutes 
were  passed  to  prohibit  this  custom  of  coshery. 

E.  L. 

COST  (Comparative  and  Relative).  The 
doctrine  of  comparative  cost  is  the  basis  of  the 
theory  of  international  trade.      It  is  held  that 


the  labour  and  capital  of  a  country  naturally 
flow  into  those  departments  of  production  in 
which  it  has  the  greatest  comparative  advan- 
tage, or  in  which  the  comparative  cost  is  least. 
Thus,  at  the  time  of  the  gold  discoveries  in 
Australia,  although  the  absolute  real  cost 
(reckoned  in  days'  labour)  of  producing  various 
articles,  was  less  than  in  other  countries,  their 
cost,  compared  with  gold,  was  greater,  and  con- 
sequently they  were  imported  in  exchange  for 
the  gold.  The  theory  rests  on  the  assumption 
that  labour  and  capital  only  move  with  diffi- 
culty from  one  country  to  another. 

[Cairnes's  Principles  of  Political  Economy, 
newly  Expounded. — Professor  Bastable's  Theory 
of  Foreign  Trade.  —  Coumot's  TMorie  des 
Michesses.] 

Relative  cost  is  a  term  used  in  the  theory  of 
value.  The  normal  value  of  freely  produced 
commodities  is  said  to  depend  upon  the  relative 
cost  of  production,  that  is,  relatively  to  that 
of  other  things,  value  always  expressing  a  rela- 
tion of  one  commodity  to  others  (see  Cost  of 
Production).  j.  s.  n. 

COST,  IN  THE  Sense  of  Price.  Cost  is 
sometimes  used  to  signify  price,  meaning  by 
this  money  value  at  the  moment.  J.  S.  Mill 
says  (Principles  of  Pol.  Econ.  bk.  iii.  ch.  iii. 
§  I.),  "Adam  Smith  and  Ricardo  have  called 
that  value  of  a  thing  which  is  proportional  to 
its  cost  of  production  its  natural  value  (or  its 
natural  price).  They  meant  by  this  the  point 
about  which  the  value  oscUlates,  and  to  which 
it  always  tends  to  return — the  centre  value  to- 
wards which,  as  Adam  Smith  expresses  it,  the 
market  value  of  a  thing  is  constantly  gravitating ; 
and  any  deviation  from  which  is  but  a  tempor- 
ary irregularity,  which,  the  moment  it  exists, 
sets  forces  in  motion  tending  to  correct  it." 
The  cost  of  a  thing  is  thus  taken  to  be  indi- 
cated by  its  price,  in  the  sense  in  which  a 
purchaser  uses  the  word  as  equivalent  to  the 
maker's  price  at  the  time.  ' '  In  common  speech, " 
as  Prof.  F.  A.  Walker  says,  "the  word  price  brings 
up  the  idea  of  money  value. "  The  "  cost "  may 
diflPer  greatly  from  the  "price"  which  a  thing 
may  ultimately  fetch,  as  it  may  from  its  "value," 
but  when  used  in  the  sense  indicated  above,  the 
expression  refers  to  the  price  at  the  moment. 
The  essential  distinctions  (1)  between  normal 
and  market  value  ;  (2)  cost,  in  the  sense  of 
real  cost,  and  expenses  are  treated  elsewhere. 
See  Value  ;  Cost,  Comparative  and  Rela- 
tive ;  Cost  of  Production. 

COST  BOOK.  The  book  which  contains 
the  names  of  the  shareholders  and  the  number 
of  shares  held  by  each,  and  particulars  of  all 
transactions  in  a  partnership  formed  for  work- 
ing a  mine.  Mining  regulations  differ  in  vari- 
ous parts  of  the  United  Kingdom.  In  Devon 
and  Cornwall  a  licence  is  first  obtained  to  try 
for  ores ;  and  if  the  metal  is  found,  a  lease  is  then 
granted  for  a  number  of  years.     The  mine  is 


/ 


COST  OF  COLLECTION  OF  TAXES 


435 


managed  by  an  agent  who  is  appointed  by  and 
works  under  the  direction  of  the  shareholders. 
A  shareholder  cannot  bind  the  other  share- 
holders by  any  contract  except  for  necessaries 
required  for  the  due  working  of  the  mine  accord- 
ing to  the  usual  custom  of  the  district.  The 
agent  has  no  power  to  make  the  shareholders 
liable  for  money  lent  or  upon  bills  of  exchange. 

[M'Swinney,  On  Mines,  1884.]       J.  E.  c.  M. 

COST  OF  COLLECTION  OF  TAXES.  One 
of  the  maxims  or  principles  of  taxation  enunci- 
ated by  Adam  Smith,  and  Avhich,  as  Mill  ob- 
serves, "may  be  said  to  have  become  classical," 
is  that  "  every  tax  ought  to  be  so  contrived  as 
both  to  take  out  and  to  keep  out  of  the  pockets 
of  the  people  as  little  as  possible  over  and  above 
what  it  brings  to  the  public  treasury  of  the 
state "  ( Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  v.  ch.  ii.  pt. 
ii.)  Smith  cites  four  ways  in  which  a  tax  may 
offend  against  this  principle.  The  cost  of  collec- 
tion may  be  excessive  ;  the  regulations  and 
procedure  which  a  tax  necessitates  may  be  such 
as  to  obstruct,  and  even  to  divert,  industry  ;  it 
may,  by  holding  out  inducements  to  evasion, 
require  the  levy  of  penalties  and  forfeitures ;  and, 
finally,  it  may  cause  annoyance  and  vexation  to 
the  taxpayer  from  which  he  would  gladly  pay 
to  be  free.  Fawcett  adds  a  fifth  ground  of 
complaint,  viz.  that  the  price  to  the  consumer 
of  a  taxed  commodity  may  be  unduly  enhanced. 

The  scheme  of  taxation  existing  in  the  United 
Kingdom  has  not  hitherto  been  generally  open 
to  objection  on  any  of  the  grounds  mentioned 
by  Smith.  Its  revenue  has  been  collected  at  a 
low  cost,  amounting  to  little  more  than  2^  per 
cent  of  the  amount  collected. 

Dowell  {History  of  Taxation  and  Taxes,  2nd 
ed.,  vol.  ii.  p.  529)  describes  the  causes  which 
brought  about  this  result.  ' '  The  reform  of  the 
tariff,  diminished  smuggling,  and  the  consequent 
reduction  in  the  customs  establishment  and 
abolition  of  the  preventive  coast  guard  ;  an 
equalised  spirit  duty  throughout  the  kingdom 
and  diminished  illicit  distillation ;  the  con- 
solidation of  the  numerous  revenue  boards  and 
establishments  ;  the  abolition  of  the  taxes  on 
manufactures  ;  increased  facilities  of  communi- 
cation by  railroad,  letter  post,  and  telegraph  ; 
the  abolition  of  the  pernicious  system  of 
appointments  to  offices  through  parliamentary 
influence  ;  and  improved  education,  .  .  .  re- 
duced the  percentage  by  half  in  the  sixty  years." 

The  system  of  taxation  of  the  United 
Kingdom  has  been  greatly  altered  by  the 
Finance  Act  of  1910,  the  following  taxes  hav- 
ing been  introduced  or  increased  ; — the  duties 
on  increment  value  and  site  value  of  land,  on 
undeveloped  land,  mineral  rights  duty,  provi- 
sions as  to  total  and  site  value  of  land,  pro- 
visions for  periodical  valuation  of  undeveloped 
land,  duty  on  site  value,  duties  on  excise  liquor 
licenses,  valuation  of  licensed  premises,  further 
rates  of  estate  duty  and  settlement  estate  duty, 


with  power  to  transfer  land  in  satisfaction  of 
estate  duty,  settlement  estate  duty,  or  succes- 
sion duty,  super-tax  on  incomes  over  £5000. 
Special  provisions  as  to  assessment  of  super-tax, 
increase  in  some  instances  of  the  stamp  duty 
on  leases  and  on  marketable  securities,  and 
additional  customs  and  excise  duties  on  spirits. 
The  Budget  of  1914  proposes  several  alterations 
in  the  income  tax,  and  the  imposing  the  super- 
tax on  incomes  over  £3000.  These  alterations 
have  caused  an  increase  in  the  cost  of  collecting 
the  Inland  Revenue.  In  reading  the  figures  in 
the  table  given  below  (p.  436)  we  must  bear  in 
mind  that  in  1909-10  the  excise  formerly  in- 
cluded with  the  inland  revenue  was  transferred 
to  the  customs. 

The  effect,  on  the  cost  of  collection,  of  the 
limitation  of  the  indirect  taxes  to  a  small  num- 
ber of  commodities,  aided  doubtless  by  greatly 
reformed  administration,  is  very  marked.  In 
1775,  when  "heavy  duties  were  already  imposed 
upon  many  of  the  mast  important  articles  of 
consumption,"  and  "almost  all  our  most  im- 
portant manufactures  were  taxed,"  the  net 
revenue  of  the  customs  amounted  to  two  millions 
and  a  half,  levied  at  an  expense  of  more  than 
10  per  cent  in  salaries  and  other  incidents,  and 
more  than  20  or  30  per  cent  if  the  perquisites 
then  exacted  by  custom-house  officers  are  in- 
cluded (  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  v.  ch.  ii.  art.  iv.) 
In  1816,  "  with  everything  taxed  that  could  be 
taxed,"  the  net  amount  received  from  customs 
duties  cost  more  than  14^  per  cent  to  collect. 
In  1825  this  rate  had  fallen  to  less  than  8  per 
cent,  in  1843  it  was  5^  per  cent,  and  in  1909 
a  little  over  3  per  cent. 

The  earlier  economists  concluded,  from  the 
facts  of  which  they  were  cognisant,  that  the  cost 
of  collecting  taxes  on  commodities  was  nuich  in 
excess  of  that  of  collecting  direct  taxes.  The 
operation  of  the  various  causes  above  enumerated 
has,  however,  tended  to  equalise  that  cost,  and 
the  same  tendency  is  observable  in  other 
countries.  Thus  in  1841  the  cost  of  collecting 
the  customs  duties  was  5*33  per  cent,  and  in 
the  case  of  excise  6-37  per  cent  as  compared 
with  2-16  per  cent  for  stamps,  and  4-13  per 
cent  for  assessed  taxes  (Bohn,  Cyclopcedia  of 
Political  Knowledge,  1849,  art.  "Taxation"). 
In  1909  the  cost  of  the  customs  had  been  re- 
duced to  3 '12  per  cent,  and  that  of  the  inland 
revenue  (excise,  stamps,  and  taxes)  was  2*61 
per  cent.  The  cost  of  collecting  direct  taxes 
in  France  before  the  Revolution  was  (Roscher, 
Finanzwissenschaft,  bk.  iii.  §  91)  6  per  cent  as 
against  14  per  cent  in  the  case  of  indirect  taxes, 
but  in  1881  the  duties  on  commodities  cost 
only  5  "13  per  cent  to  collect,  and  the  direct 
taxes  3*5  per  cent.  In  Prussia  the  cost  of  the 
direct  taxes  rose  from  4  per  cent  in  1861  to  7 
per  cent  in  1883-84,  that  of  indirect  imposts 
fell  during  the  same  period  from  1 2  to  9  per  cent. 

In  the  United  Kingdom  it  may  be  said  that 


436 


COST  OF  COLLECTION  OF  TAXES 


the  cliancellor  of  fhe  exchequer  need  not  now 
concern  himself  with  any  considerations  as  to 
the  direct  cost  of  collection  when  increasing  or 
diminishing  the  burden  of  taxation,  so  long  as  he 
is  content  to  alter  and  adapt  existing  taxes  and 
not  to  impose  new  ones.  The  expense  of  collect- 
ing the  considerable  additions  made  to  the  stamp 
duties  previous  to  1890  probably  did  not  cause 
an  extra  expenditure  on  the  part  of  the  state  of 
so  much  as  1  per  cent  on  the  amount  received. 

The  customs  and  excise  duties  in  1892  cost 
the  state  something  over  4  per  cent  to  collect, 
as  compared  with  3*5  per  cent  for  taxes  and 
1*3  per  cent  for  stamps.  The  proportions 
probably  remain  much  the  same.  In  the 
latter  case  it  is  to  be  observed  that  much  of 
the  business  performed  in  connection  with  their 
collection  is  met  by  the  individual  taxpayer, 
who  is  frequently  compelled  to  employ  solicitors 
•  and  agents  for  the  preparation  of  the  accounts 
requii'ed  in  connection  with  the  death  duties, 
and  to  enlist  similar  services  in  making  payment 
of  many  of  the  stamp  duties  on  deeds.  In  the 
case  of  the  stamp  duties  levied  in  connection 
with  stock  exchange  and  other  commercial 
transactions,  expense  and  labour  devolve  upon 
bankers,  brokers,  and  others,  the  cost  of  which 
cannot  be  precisely  estimated,  but  which  in  the 
aggregate  must  be  considerable.  The  cost  of 
the  collection  of  the  income-tax  is  comparatively 
low  by  reason  of  the  great  ease  with  which  much 
of  the  revenue  under  that  head  is  obtained.  The 
deduction  of  the  tax  from  dividends  payable  out 
of  the  public  funds  and  other  similar  incomes 
is  a  simple  matter,  and  it  may  be  taken  that  one- 
third  of  the  tax  costs  less  than  2^  per  cent  to  col- 
lect, which  would  bring  up  the  cost  of  the  remain- 
ing two-thirds  of  the  tax  to  about  the  same  point 
as  in  the  case  of  the  indirect  taxes,  viz.  4  per  cent. 

The  small  stamp  duties  on  such  documents  as 
receipts  and  cheques  are  collected  at  an  excep- 
tionally  low  cost,  whether  the  charges  defrayed 
by  the  state  or  by  the  individual  taxpayer  be 
taken  into  consideration. 

It  remains  to  consider  the  ground  of  objection 
under  this  head  against  taxes  on  commodities, 
viz.  that  a  dealer  makes  an  additional  profit 
by  reason  of  their  existence.  Fawcett  was  of 
opinion  {Manual  of  Political  Economy,  5th  ed., 
p.  554)  that  the  retailer  is  able  to  obtain  "the 
ordinary  trade  profit"  on  the  amount  of  the 
duty,  and  assuming  this  profit  to  be  20  per  cent, 
he  estimated  that  the  consumer  would  pay  at 
least  this  amount  more  than  the  revenue  would 
receive.  This,  he  says,  ''is  the  most  serious 
objection  which  can  be  urged  against  taxes  on 
commodities,"  It  may,  however,  be  doubted 
whether  this  proposition  is  clearly  established, 
the  fact  that  the  price  of  an  article  is  augmented 
by  the  imposition  of  a  tax  will  not  of  itself  be 
sufficient  to  enable  the  trader  to  secure  the  same 
rate  of  profit  on  the  enhanced  price  as  that 
which  he  Avould  obtain  on  the  price  of  the  article 


calculated  duty  free,  as  for  many  commercial 
purposes  it  usually  is.  It  is  probable  that  the 
only  circumstances  connected  with  the  existence 
of  a  tax  on  commodities  which  will  affect  the 
amount  of  a  trader's  profit  are  either  that  the 
tax  is  collected,  and  its  evasion  prevented,  in 
such  a  manner  as  to  increase  the  labour  and 
skill  necessary  to  prepare  the  commodity  for 
sale,  or  else  that  the  tax  is  so  an'anged  as  to 
render  the  employment  of  additional  capital 
requisite.  In  so  far  as  the  taxation  of  com- 
modities in  the  United  Kingdom  is  concerned, 
the  direct  cost  attending  their  collection,  whether 
paid  by  the  state  or  by  the  trader,  has  been  very 
low,  and,  as  has  been  shown  above,  it  does  not 
differ  materially  from  that  of  other  taxes.  The 
necessity  for  the  employment  of  additional 
capital  in  consequence  of  the  manufacturer  or 
dealer  being  required  to  pay  over  the  duty  prior 
to  the  delivery  of  the  commodity  for  consump- 
tion, has  been  very  much  reduced  by  the  estab- 
lishment of  bonded  warehouses,  in  Avhich  articles 
can  be  stored  without  payment  of  duty  until 
the  time  approaches  when  they  are  to  be  taken 
into  consumption. 

"The  English  customs  system  is  remarkable 
for  its  vigorous  adherence  to  the  principle  of 
purely  financial  duties."  See  Prof.  Bastable, 
Public  Finance,  1903,  bk.  iv.  ch.  vii.  §  3. 

The  following  table  shows  the  actual  gross 
receipt  of  duty  by  the  inland  revenue  depart- 
ment, and  the  percentage  of  the  cost  of  collec- 
tion in  the  years  specified  : — 


Year. 

Total  Gross 
Receipt  by  In- 
land Revenue 

Department. 

Net  Charges 
of  Collec- 
tion. 

Percentage 

of  Charges 

of  Collection 

to  Gross 

Receipt. 

£ 

£ 

1847 

32,812,000 

1,451,000 

4-42 

1850 

33,363,000 

1,358,000 

4-07 

1860 

44,141,000 

1,608,000 

3-64 

1870 

40,588,000 

1,610,000 

3-97 

1880 

49,817,000 

1,831,000 

3-67 

1890-91 

•    58,780,000 

1,875,000 

3-19 

1900-01 

90,467,000 

2,177,000 

2-40 

1908-09 

98,979,000 

2,588,000 

2-60 

1909-10 

47,494,000 

1,644,000 

3-46 

1910-11 

107,570,000 

2,128,000 

1-98 

1911-12 

86,631,000 

2,044,000 

2-35 

1912-13 

87,703,245 

2,230,000 

2-54 

The  following  table  is  extracted  from  the 
reports  of  the  commissioners  of  customs  for  the 
purpose  of  illustrating  the  decline  which  has 
taken  place  in  the  cost  of  the  collection  of  the 
duties  under  their  control.  It  is,  however,  clear 
from  the  observations  contained  in  the  29th 
report  of  the  commissioners  (1885),  that  the 
system  of  calculation  adopted  wasunduly  favour- 
able, and  it  has  since  been  abandoned.  Tl^e  real 
cost  is  probably  about  1  per  cent  in  excess  of 
that  shown  in  the  table. 


w''*^' 


COST  OF  PRODUCTION 


r 

I 

Percentage  of 

Year. 

Gross  Receipt. 

Cost  of  Col- 
lection. 

£ 

1847 

21,824,000 

5-97 

1850 

22,194.000 

5-78 

1860 

23,517,000 

3-27 

1870 

22,575,000 

3-55 

1874 

22,867,000 

3-47 

1875* 

22,042,849 

4-36 

1880 

21,884,105 

4-44 

1890 

22,670.425 

3-95 

1900 

28,151.410 

3-13 

1909 

83.263,703 

3-12 

*  The  cost  of  the  collection  of  the  excise  and 
customs  duties  has  ceased  to  be  published  since 
the  alteration  referred  to  above  was  made  in  1909- 
1910.  T.  TT.  E. 

COST   OF    LABOUR.      See  Cost  of  Tro- 

DUCTION. 

COST  OF  PRODUCTION.  The  real  cost  of 
production  of  any  commodity  is  held  to  be  the 
"sum  of  the  efforts  and  abstinences"  requisite 
to  make  it  ready  for  consumption,  and  the  act 
of  production  is  not  said  to  be  completed  until 
the  commodity  is  in  the  hands  of  the  consumer 
or  until  (as  Mill  phrases  it)  it  has  received  the 
utility  of  being  in  the  place  where  it  is  wanted. 
In  a  modern  industrial  society,  mth  a  complex 
system  of  division  of  labour  and  with  raw 
material  and  other  requisites  of  production  drawn 
from  all  parts  of  the  world,  it  is  clear  that  in 
most  cases  the  series  of  efforts  of  all  kinds,  taking 
into  consideration  those  which  are  indirect  as 
well  as  those  which  are  direct,  would  be  practic- 
ally infinite.  This  difficulty,  however,  may  be 
overcome  as  in  other  sciences  by  neglecting 
quantities  below  a  certain  magnitude.  But 
even  after  the  mental  elements  in  real  cost  have 
been  reduced  to  a  minimum  in  number  in  this 
way,  it  is  found  that  the  analysis  cannot  for 
most  purposes,  practical  or  scientific,  be  carried 
so  far,  and  we  must  attempt  to  arrive  at  some 
common  measure  by  which  the  summation  may 
be  effected  and  a  comparison  made.  This  leads 
to  the  position  emphasised  by  Mill  (bk.  iii.  ch. 
iv.  §  1),  "If  we  consider  as  the  producer  the 
capitalist  who  makes  the  advances,  the  word 
labour  may  be  replaced  by  the  word  wages  ; 
what  the  produce  costs  to  him  is  the  wages 
which  he  has  had  to  pay."  After  making 
allowance  for  the  partial  error  concerning  wages 
implied  in  the  word  "advances"  (see  Wages  ; 
Wages  Fund),  we  arrive  at  the  distinction  which 
is  expressed  by  the  phrase  ^^  expenses  of  produc- 
tion" (adopted  by  Prof.  Marshall  in  his  Eco- 
nomics  of  Industry)  as  contrasted  with  the  real 
cost  in  the  sense  defined  above.  That  is  to  say, 
we  are  to  consider  only  the  money  measures  of 
these  various  efforts  of  labour,  and  it  is  left  to 
the  theory  of  wages  and  profits  to  explain  how 


the  nominal  or  money  expenses  tend  to  become 
proportioned  to  the  real  cost.  We  assume  then 
that  in  any  industrial  society  there  is  at  any 
time  a  certain  general  rate  of  wages  which  is 
necessary  that  labour  may  be  forthcoming  and 
a  certain  general  rate  of  profits  which  is  neces- 
sary for  the  creation  and  application  of  the 
requisite  auxiliary  and  sustaining  capital.  The 
forces,  whether  "  natural "  or  due  to  the  "  policy 
of  Europe,"  to  adopt  Adam  Smith's  language, 
which  are  the  efficient  causes  of  variations  in 
these  rates,  or  which  account  for  the  actual 
rates  at  any  time,  are  estimated  in  considering 
the  distribution  of  the  wealth  of  the  society, 
and  it  only  leads  to  confusion  in  considering 
cost  as  affecting  value  to  repeat  the  analysis  at 
the  later  stage.  It  may  then  be  taken  for 
granted  that  in  any  modern  industrial  society 
no  article  will  continue  to  be  produced  which 
does  not  yield  the  wages  and  profits  which  will 
satisfy  the  labourers  and  capitalists  concerned. 
It  must  be  added,  however,  as  is  shown  also  in 
the  theory  of  wages  and  profits,  that  there  are 
various  natural  and  artificial  causes  of  difference 
in  the  returns  in  different  employments  even  in 
"  the  same  neiglibourhood  "  (Adam  Smith),  and 
with  what  would  now  be  termed  perfect  mobility 
of  labour  and  capital.  These  causes  of  differ- 
ence must  be  allowed  for  in  addition  to  the 
general  rates,  and  we  may  then  assume  that  in 
any  industrial  society  there  are  at  any  time 
determinate  rates  of  wages  and  profits  requisite 
to  bring  into  play  particular  kinds  of  labour  and 
capital. 

At  this  jjoint  the  fundamental  law  of  cost 
(or  rather  expenses)  of  production  may  be  thus 
stated  : — 2Vie  normal  selling  price  of  any  article 
tends  to  he  such  as  to  yield  the  wages,  interest, 
and  profits  involved  in  the  expenses  of  production. 
If  the  price  is  above  this  rate,  labour  and  capital 
are  attracted  to  the  industry,  the  supply  is  in- 
creased, and  the  price  falls  ;  whilst  conversely, 
if  the  remuneration  is  not  so  high,  labour  and 
capital  are  repelled  and  the  price  rises.  But  it 
must  be  observed  that  in  any  established  in- 
dustry, owing  to  the  want  of  perfect  mobility  of 
labour  and  capital,  the  effect  of  a  fall  in  price  due 
to  a  lessened  demand  for  the  product  on  the  part 
of  other  industrial  gi-oups  may  be  to  cause  a 
quasi-permanent  fall  in  the  rates  of  wages  and 
profits  in  that  industry  ;  and  thus  lower  for  a 
considerable  time  the  expenses  of  production 
(see  Wages).  If,  however,  we  assume  that 
mobility  is  perfect,  or  allow  time  for  the  full 
effect  of  the  forces  which  determine  wages  and 
profits,  the  normal  expenses  of  production  are 
given  in  the  law  as  stated.  The  argument  in- 
volved in  this  analysis  will  be  found  to  coincide 
with  the  ideas  implied  in  the  popular  usage  of 
the  phrase  "cost  of  production."  This  is  best 
seen  from  considering  a  new  industry.  The 
maker  of  a  new  article  will  expect  to  obtain 
from  the  selling  price   a   sufficient   return  to 


438 


COST  OF  PRODUCTION 


attract  the  labour  which  he  requires,  and  to 
give  besides  a  fair  amount  of  profit.  Otherwise 
he  will  not  continue  to  make  the  article,  whilst 
conversely,  if  the  price  is  higher  than  this 
normal  rate,  the  industry  will  rapidly  spread 
until  through  competition  the  price  falls. 

We  may  now  carry  the  analysis  a  step  further 
and  consider  the  causes  of  variation  in  the 
"  cost  price  "  of  articles,  to  adopt  a  useful  popu- 
lar phrase.  It  must  be  assumed  once  for  all 
that  price  will  vary  exactly  with  or  exactly 
measure  value,  in  other  words  that  the  causes 
of  purely  monetary  variations  may  be  neglected. 
It  would  be  as  absurd  to  repeat  at  this  stage  the 
theory  of  Money  and  Prices  {q.v.),  as  at  an 
earlier  stage  to  bring  in  the  theory  of  wages  and 
profits.  To  make  the  assumption  quite  clear, 
let  it  be  supposed  then  that  so  far  as  the  causes 
affecting  the  general  level  of  prices  are  con- 
cerned, there  would  be  no  variation  in  the  prices 
of  particular  articles. 

"With  this  hypothesis  it  wiU  be  seen  that  a 
rise  in  the  general  rate  of  wages,  reckoned  in 
money,  wiU  so  far  raise  the  normal  price  of  the 
articles  on  which  the  labour  is  employed.  It  is 
not  necessary  here  to  inquire  in  detail  how  such 
arise  might  take  place ;  it  might  be  at  the  expense 
of  profits,  or  be  caused  by  a  lessened  amount  of 
unproductive  consumption  on  the  part  of  govern- 
ments, municipalities,  or  individuals,  or  it  might 
be  due  to  increased  cost  of  living  caused  by 
natural  or  artificial  causes.  It  is  sufficient  to 
assume  that  a  general  rise  occurs  as  described. 
There  is  in  this  case  no  necessity  a  priori  for  a 
corresponding  rise  in  the  rate  of  profit,  and  in 
fact  that  rate  may  decline.  It  follows,  then, 
that  so  far  the  cost  price  of  things  made  by  the 
direct  employment  of  labour  will  tend  to  rise 
relatively  to  those  in  the  production  of  which 
there  is  much  fixed  capital  and  a  longer  time 
involved.  Thus  a  general  rise  in  wages  may 
disturb  relative  prices,  considered  as  dependent 
on  cost  of  production.  Similarly  a  rise  in 
general  profits  would  disturb  relative  prices, 
acting  of  course  in  an  opposite  direction.  Con- 
versely a  fall  in  general  wages  or  profits  would 
also  disturb  prices  mutatis  mutandis. 

It  may  next  be  noted  that  any  change  in  the 
quantity  of  labour  or  capital  employed  will  so 
far  affect  relative  prices,  as  is  best  illustrated 
by  the  effects  of  the  adoption  of  labour-saving 
machinery.  Ricardo  (and  to  some  extent  Mill) 
appears  to  lay  too  much  stress  on  the  quantity 
of  labour,  and  in  this  way  to  fall  into  the 
paradox,  true  only  under  extreme  hypo- 
thetical conditions,  that  movements  in  the 
general  rate  of  wages  cannot  affect  relative 
values. 

Variations  in  the  relative  rates  of  wages  and 
profits  requisite  for  the  normal  support  of  any 
industry,  naturally  cause  corresponding  differ- 
ences in  the  normal  cost  price.  This  is  too 
obvious  to  require  amplification. 


Besides  labour  and  capital  in  the  ordinary 
sense  of  the  terms,  raw  material  is  required. 
This  raw  material,  however,  is  itself  the  product 
of  labour  and  capital,  and  so  far  would  come 
under  the  analysis  just  given.  But  since 
Ricardo  gave  such  prominence  to  the  economic 
theory  of  rent,  the  text-books  have  emphasised 
the  fact  that  raw  material  is  more  directly  de- 
pendent upon  natural  sources  of  supply,  and 
that  these  sources  of  supply  may  be  exploited 
at  unequal  costs.  This  leads  to  the  position 
that  when  there  is  a  difference  in  the  cost  of 
producing  the  various  parts  of  the  normal  supply, 
the  normal  price  must  be  such  as  to  give  a  fair 
return  to  that  portion  produced  under  most  un- 
favourable circumstances.  If  it  falls  below, 
the  supply  from  that  source  would  be  discon- 
tinued until  the  price  rises,  whUst  if  the  price 
is  above  this  limit  resort  will  be  made  to  in- 
ferior sources  until  the  *'  source  on  the  margin  " 
again  just  determines  the  normal  cost.  If, 
however,  the  worst  land  or  mine  (or  the  like) 
just  pays  the  expenses  of  working  at  the  price, 
the  better  sources  will  give  more  than  the 
ordinary  return.  This  difference  constitutes 
economic  rent  (see  Rent).  According  to  this 
view  it  is  oljvious  that  economic  rent  cannot 
enter  into  the  cost  of  production,  in  other  words, 
price  determines  rent  not  rent  price. 

Although  economic  rent,  under  the  simple 
hypothetical  conditions  laid  down  in  the  theory, 
does  not  enter  into  cost  price,  the  payment  of 
rent  under  actual  conditions  may  affect  this 
price  in  several  ways.  The  object  of  the  land- 
owner is  to  obtain  a  maximum  net  return  when 
the  land  is  let,  and  it  is  possible  that  under  a 
system  of  cultivating  ownership  more  labour 
and  capital  would  be  devoted  to  land  than  it 
would  pay  the  landowner  to  sanction  in  the 
case  of  a  tenant.  Many  great  improvements, 
for  example,  have  been  effected  by  English 
landowners  with  a  very  small  return,  and  the 
consequent  increase  in  the  supply  must  have 
affected  the  price,  whilst  a  farmer  farming  for 
profit  and  paying  rent  would  have  invested 
much  less  in  the  land.  Peasant  proprietors, 
again,  notoriously  cultivate  their  land  beyond 
the  point  at  which  it  would  yield  a  rent,  and 
the  produce  is  consequently  somewhat  cheaper. 
On  the  other  hand,  the  kind  of  produce  may 
be  determined  partly  by  the  convenience  of  the 
landlord  {e.g.  large  grazing  farms  or  deer  forests 
as  against  arable  or  crofts),  and  the  consequent 
effect  on  the  supply  operates  on  the  price.  If 
we  consider  the  case  of  a  new  kind  of  produce 
introduced  into  a  fully  cultivated  country,  the 
grower  would  naturally  consider  the  rent  which 
he  must  pay  for  the  necessary  land  as  part  of 
the  cost  of  production.  In  some  cases  also 
there  is  in  rent  an  element  of  monopoly,  and  in 
all  cases  it  is  difficult  to  separate  purely  economic 
rent  from  profit  rent.  This  point  has  been 
pushed  to  an  extreme  by  M.  Leroy-Beaulieu  in 


COST,  RELATIVE— COTTON  FAMINE 


439 


his  Ripartition  des  Eichesses,  which  is  much 
criticised  by  Prof.  "Walker  in  his  work  Land 
and  its  Rent.  On  the  whole  it  may  be  said  that 
economic  rent,  if  it  can  be  actually  separated 
from  the  other  elements  in  cost  according-  to 
the  hypothesis  assumed,  does  not  enter  into 
cost,  but  that  practically  other  factors  are 
closely  combined  with  it  to  form  rent  in  the 
popular  acceptation  of  the  term,  and  that,  in  this 
-  sense,  rent  often  does  form  part  of  the  cost 
(compare  Prof.  Marshall's  Economics  of  In- 
dustry). 

To  complete  the  enumeration  of  the  elements 
in  cost  of  production,  reference  must  be  made  to 
the  effect  of  taxes  (see  Taxation)  and  to  the 
manner  in  which  cost  operates  when  combined 
\vith  a  complete  or  partial  monopoly  (see 
Monopoly). 

The  doctrine  of  comparative  cost  as  deter- 
mining the  course  of  international  trade  and 
the  limits  of  international  values,  originally 
enounced  by  Ricardo,  and  developed  by  J.  S. 
Mill,  Cairnes,  and  recently  by  Prof.  Bastable,  is 
properly  treated  under  the  headings  named 
(see  Difficulty  of  Attainment  ;  Interna- 
tional TiiADE  ;  Value).  It  may  simply  be 
noted  here  that  in  the  statement  of  the  theory 
cost  is  taken  in  the  sense  of  real  cost,  as,  owing 
to  the  absence  of  mobility  of  labour  and  capital 
between  different  countries,  there  is  not  the 
same  correspondence  between  real  cost  and 
expenses  as  may  be  assumed  in  the  same  in- 
dustrial area. 

The  most  recent  criticism  of  the  generally 
accepted  theory  of  cost  of  production  described 
above,  as  embracing  wages  and  profits,  is  the 
attempt  of  Prof.  Walker  to  place  profits  on  the 
same  footing  as  economic  rent,  and  thus  to  ex- 
clude it  from  cost  of  production  in  the  same 
way  as  rent  is  excluded  (see  Profit). 

[Cost  of  production  forms  such  an  important 
part  of  the  general  theory  of  Economics,  that  it  is 
fully  treated  in  all  systematic  works,  and  it  is  not 
necessary  to  refer  to  monographs  on  the  question.] 

J,  s.  N. 

COST,  RELATIVE.  See  Cost,  Compara- 
tive. 

COTTIERS.  Under  the  Stuarts  the  clan 
system  of  joint  occupation  of  land,  based  upon 
the  customs  of  gavelkind  and  tanistry,  was 
abolished  in  Ireland.  In  its  place  was  intro- 
duced the  English  system  of  private  ownership 
by  landlords.  The  landlords  let  their  lands 
to  tenants  at  a  rack-rent.  But  these  tenants 
were  not  capitalist  farmers,  as  in  England,  but 
labourers  who  cultivated  a  small  holding  by 
their  own  labour  and  that  of  their  families. 
This  system  of  peasant-tenants,  or  cottiers,  has 
been  extremely  disastrous  in  its  results.  Owing 
to  excessive  competition  for  land — resulting 
from  the  absence  of  alternative  occupations — 
the  tenants  were  in  the  habit  of  offering  more 
rent  than  they  could  possibly  pay,  and  thus 


scraped  a  miserable  existence  from  the  soil, 
while  owing  ever -increasing  arrears  to  the 
landlord.  In  the  early  part  of  last  century 
Swift  records  that  ''it  is  the  usual  practice  of 
the  Irish  tenant  rather  than  want  land  to  offer 
more  for  a  farm  than  he  knoweth  he  can  ever 
be  able  to  pay :  and  in  that  case  he  groweth 
desperate  and  payeth  nothing  at  all."  The 
inevitable  result  of  the  cottier  tenure  under 
these  conditions — aggravated  by  absenteeism 
and  the  consequent  presence  of  middlemen — 
was  a  distressed  peasantry  and  a  wretched 
system  of  agriculture.  These  evils  have  led  in 
the  present  day  to  the  Irish  land  acts  of  1870 
and  1881. 

[Lecky,  History  of  England  in  the  Eighteenth 
Century,  vol.  i.  p.  240  seq. — J.  S.  Mill,  Political 
Economy,  bk.  ii. — J.  E.  Cairnes,  Political  Essays  ; 
Fragments  on  Ireland,  essay  iv.  ]  R.  L. 

COTTON  FAMINE  (1861-65).  Some  of  the 
most  serious  economic  disturbances  of  modern 
times  arose  out  of  the  great  civil  war  in  the 
United  States,  occurring  between  1861  and 
1865.  Amongst  these,  the  most  prominent, 
so  far  as  its  influence  upon  the  interests  of  the 
United  Kingdom  is  concerned,  was  the  almost 
complete  extinction  for  four  years  of  the  chief 
source  of  supply  of  cotton,  the  raw  material  of 
the  largest  textile  industry  of  this  country. 
In  the  month  of  July  1861  the  United  States 
government  established  a  blockade  of  the 
southern  ports,  and,  from  that  time  the 
American  cotton  field  was  practically  closed  for 
four  years.  Fortunately  the  crop  of  1860-61, 
the  largest  ever  grown  up  to  that  time,  had 
already  been  shipped,  and  stocks  in  the  con- 
suming countries  had  been  abundantly  re- 
plenished. The  existence  of  these  stocks,  and 
the  doubts,  then  widely  entertained,  of  a  long 
continuance  of  the  war,  kept  prices  of  cotton 
comparatively  low  until  nearly  the  end  of  1861. 
With  the  opening  of  1862,  however,  a  period 
of  scarcity  and  abnormally  high  prices  began, 
which  has  been  fitly  named  the  "cotton 
famine."  The  immediate  and  most  striking 
commercial  results  of  the  famine  were  the 
gi-adual  establishment  of  new  and  extended 
sources  of  cotton  supply,  and  the  diminished 
use  of  cotton  fabrics,  accompanied  by  an  en- 
larged consumption  of  woollen  and  linen  goods. 
At  the  same  time  an  industrial  disturbance  was 
occasioned  in  Lancashire,  Cheshire,  Derbyshire, 
and  in  the  neighbourhood  of  Glasgow,  which 
stands  out  very  prominently  in  the  history  of 
those  years.  An  excellent  and  very  full  record 
of  the  painful  consequences  of  the  famine  upon 
the  manufacturing  population,  and  of  the  meas- 
ures taken  to  mitigate  them,  is  given  in  Dr. 
Watt's  Facts  of  the  Cotton  Famine.  Its  direct 
commercial  effects  upon  the  cotton  trade  are 
stated  in  a  paper  read  before  the  Manchester 
Statistical  Society  in  April  1869,  by  Mr.  Elijah 
Helm,  and  entitled  "A  Review  of  the  Cottou 


440 


COTTON  FAMINE 


Trade  of  the  United  Kingdom  during  the  Seven 
Years  1862-68." 

When  the  civil  war  began  the  English 
cotton  industry  had  for  more  than  a  year  been 
in  the  enjoyment  of  unusual  prosperity.  Prices 
of  the  raw  material  were  lower  than  they^had 
been  since  1856,  and  to  this  advantage  was 
added  a  good  general  demand,  home  and 
foreign,  for  cotton  manufactures.  The  work- 
people had  been  well  employed  at  very  high 
wages,  and  the  profits  of  spinners  and  manu- 
facturers had  put  them  into  a  comparatively 
strong  position.  Those  engaged  in  the  industry 
were,  therefore,  well  prepared,  for  a  time  at 
least,  to  battle  with  the  difficulties  which  were 
in  store.  This  fact,  together  with  the  pre- 
vailing opinion  that  the  war  could  not  last 
long,  explains  to  some  extent  the  courage  with 
which  the  threatened  disaster  was  at  first  faced, 
and  the  refusal  of  external  aid  which  was  offered 
very  early.  Towards  the  close  of  1861,  how- 
ever, the  advancing  price  of  cotton,  and  the 
absence  of  a  corresponding  rise  in  the  markets 
for  cotton  goods,  which  had  previously  been 
supplied  very  freely,  if  not  too  abundantly, 
began  to  tell  upon  the  activity  of  the  industry, 
and  as  winter  approached  it  was  found  that 
the  number  of  people  applying  for  relief  to  the 
guardians  of  the  poor  in  Lancashire  was  steadily 
increasing.  It  was  then  realised  that  the  cotton 
manufacturing  districts  had  to  face  a  public 
danger  of  great  magnitude,  which  would  require 
much  endurance,  co-operation,  and  effort,  if  it 
was  to  be  successfully  averted.  The  rapidly 
increasing  number  of  applicants  for  pauper 
relief  told  a  story  the  significance  of  which 
the  employers  were  well  able  to  interpret.  It 
meant  that  the  various  reservoirs  into  which 
the  savings  of  their  workpeople  had  percolated 
were  beginning  to  run  dry.  The  funds  of  the 
savings  banks,  the  co-operative  and  friendly 
societies,  and  the  trade  xinions  had  been  heavily 
drawn  upon,  and  their  subscriptions  had  rapidly 
fallen  off.  Private  and  public  appeals  for  help 
multiplied,  and  at  length  relief  committees 
were  established  in  nearly  every  cotton  manu- 
facturing town  or  village.  These  formed  the 
machinery  of  distribution,  by  means  of  which 
an  untold  amount  of  local  and  national  assist- 
ance was  brought  home  to  thousands  of  work- 
people who  were  thrown  out  of  employment. 
Suggestions  were  often  made  during  the  winter 
of  1861-62  that  an  appeal  for  national  assistance 
should  be  made,  but  they  were  at  first  dis- 
couraged from  a  feeling  of  self-respect ;  but  in 
the  spring  of  1862  a  fund  for  relieving  distress 
in  the  manufacturing  districts  was  started  at 
the  London  Mansion  House,  which  before  its 
close  reached  the  sum  of  £528,336.  This 
fund  together  with  other  contributions  was 
dispensed  through  the  instrumentality  of  the 
central  committee  in  Manchester,  the  president 
of  which  was  the  then  Earl  of  Derby ;  the  active, 


energising,  and  organising  instrument  being  the 
late  Sir  James  Kay -Shuttle  worth,  who  occupied 
the  position  of  vice-president.  But  besides  the 
national,  colonial,  and  other  contributions  which 
were  forwarded  through  the  Mansion  House, 
large  local  gifts  in  money  and  in  other  forms 
were  made,  and  the  spinners  and  manufacturers 
and  other  local  employers  freely  gave  their 
labour  (besides  contributing  abundantly  in  the 
shape  of  money)  in  the  work  of  distributing 
help  to  their  poorer  neighbours  by  means  of 
"  relief  tickets, "  and  of  clothing  and  household 
supplies,  of  which  large  quantities  were  liber- 
ally forwarded  from  many  parts  of  the  country. 
Towards  the  close  of  1862  Mr  Cobden,  who  was 
a  member  of  the  Manchester  committee,  taking 
a  very  serious  view  of  the  crisis,  advocated  an 
appeal  for  extended  help.  He  accepted  an 
estimate  of  the  loss  of  wages  occasioned  by 
the  want  of  cotton  at  more  than  £7,000,000 
per  annum,  which  he  said  meant  a  loss  to 
Lancashire  of  about  £10,000,000.  He  added 
that  from  facts  which  had  come  within  his  own 
knowledge  he  had  arrived  at  the  conclusion 
that  the  whole  mass  of  the  working  population 
had  been  brought  down  "to  one  sad  level  of 
destitution."  He  urged,  therefore,  in  view  of 
the  fact  that  the  shopkeeping  portion  of  the 
community  was  fast  sinking  into  poverty,  that 
an  earnest  appeal  should  be  made  for  more 
liberal  contributions.  This  appeal  did  much 
to  increase  the  funds  at  the  disposal  of  the 
committee.  As  time  went  on  the  sufferings 
both  of  the  workpeople  and  their  employers 
greatly  increased.  Poor  rates  and  other 
assessments  became  heavier,  and  the  burden  of 
the  famine  fell  upon  all  classes.  The  distress 
was  extreme  and  widespread.  Emigration  had 
been  often  suggested,  and  in  April  1863  an 
"Emigrants'  Aid  Society"  was  formed.  By 
means  of  its  funds  more  than  1000  persons 
were  sent  to  new  lands.  In  that  year  the 
number  of  emigrant  spinners  was  2086,  whilst 
in  1861  it  was  only  123.  Many  more  left 
their  homes  in  the  cotton  manufacturing  dis- 
tricts, whose  occupations  were  not  specified. 
On  the  whole,  however,  the  prominent  fact  of 
the  cotton  famine,  so  far  as  the  working  popu- 
lation is  concerned,  is  that  it  was  kept  at  home. 
The  opportunity  was  used  by  local  authorities 
to  employ  by  means  of  borrowed  funds  the  dis- 
employed  population  in  the  paving  and  sewer- 
ing of  streets,  and  in  other  improvements,  the 
advantage  of  which  is  now  observable  in  the 
generally  clean  and  sanitary  condition  of  the 
streets  in  most  Lancashire  towns  and  villages. 
The  impetus  given  to  the  linen  industry  by  the 
cotton  famine  may  be  inferred  from  the  fact 
that  whilst  there  were,  in  1858,  only  91,646 
acres  under  fiax  in  Ireland,  the  area  had  in- 
creased in  1864  to  301,942  acres. 

The  following  figures,  taken  from  the  trans- 
actions of  the  Manchester  Statistical  Society 


COTTON  LISTS— COULISSE 


441 


(1868-69),  show  the  average  yearly  exports  of 
cotton,  linen,  and  woollen  piece  goods  during 
the  seven  years  preceding  the  cotton  famine, 
and  the  seven  years  which  include  that  occur- 
rence, and  during  which  the  three  trades  xare 
influenced  by  it : — 

Exports  of  Cotton  Piece  Goods. 
Yards. 

1855-61   2,311,234,538 

1862-68 2,219,011,153 

Decrease  92,223,385 

or  3  "9  per  cent. 

Ex2)orts  of  Linm  Piece  Goods. 
Yards. 

1855-61  131,238,504 

1862-68  210,304,491 

Increase  79,065,987 

or  60*2  per  cent. 

Woollen  Piece  Goods. 

Yards. 

1855-61   168,747,893 

1862-68  245,091,834 

Increase  76,343,941 

or  45  "2  per  cent. 
[Arnold's  History  of  the  Cotton  Famine.'] 

K.  H. 

COTTON  LISTS.  In  the  cotton  industry 
the  wages  of  spinners  and  weavers  are  regulated 
by  rates  or  "prices"  framed  by  committees 
representing  associations  of  employers  and 
employed.  A  certain  rate  of  wages  is  taken 
as  a  standard,  and  the  object  of  the  list  is  to 
adjust  wages  to  the  very  varying  conditions 
under  which  the  trade  is  carried  on.  In  the 
spinning  lists  wages  depend  on  (1)  the  amount 
of  yarn  spun  ;  (2)  the  size  of  the  spinning 
mule  ;  (3)  the  fineness  of  the  yarn  ;  and  (4)  the 
twist  in  the  thread.  Any  advantage  arising 
from  improved  machineiy  is  divided  between 
the  employer  and  the  employed,  and  any  extra 
work  not  coming  within  the  normal  duties  of 
the  spinner  is  j^aid  ibr  separately.  In  the 
weaving  list  the  elements  taken  into  account 
are  (1)  the  fineness  of  the  yarn  ;  (2)  the  close- 
ness of  the  threads  ;  (3)  the  width  of  the  cloth  ; 
and  (4)  the  length  of  the  cloth.  Neither  in 
the  spinning  nor  in  the  weaving  list  is  the  price 
of  the  raw  material  or  the  price  of  the  finished 
product  taken  into  account.  Adjustments 
take  place  from  time  to  time  by  adding  or  sub- 
tracting a  certain  percentage  from  the  standard 
rate. 

[See  Reports  on  the  Regulation  of  Wages  in  the 
Cotton  Industry :  (1)  Spinning ;  (2)  Weaving, 
published  by  the  British  Association  for  the 
Advancement  of  Science,  1887.]  J.  E.  c.  M. 

COTTON,  Sir  Robert  Bruce  (1570-1631) ; 
the  founder  of  the  celebrated  library  ;  was 
not  a  mere  antiquary,  but  one  who  applied 
the  lessons  of  the  past  to  practical  problems. 


Such  is  the  character  of  his  speech  at  the 
council  table,  "Touching  the  Alteration  of  the 
Coyne. "  By  numerous  precedents.  Cotton  shows 
the  danger  of  tampering  with  the  purity  of 
coin.  The  parity  to  be  maintained  between 
the  valuation  of  gold  and  silver,  that  the  mint- 
age may  be  reduced  to  some  proportion  of 
neighbour  parts,  is  also  inculcated.  Among  the 
"divers  choice  pieces  of  that  renowned  an- 
tiquary" which  have  been  preserved,  may  be 
noticed  here — 21ic  Manner  and  Meanes  how  th^ 
Kings  of  England  ham  Supported  their  Estate, 
in  Cottoni  Posthuma,  1651. 

[M'Culloch,  Collection  of  Tracts  on  Money. — 
Jevons,  Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finance, 
p.  347. — Edwards's  Lives  of  the  Founders  of  the 
British  Museum.']  F.  Y.  v.. 

COULISSE.  The  name  given  to  the  unofficial 
market  on  the  Paris  bourse  and  supposed  to 
have  its  origin  in  tlie  word  coulisse  or  sliding 
bar  which  formed  a  passage  for  the  agents  de 
change,  outside  which  speculators  used  to 
congregate  to  transact  business.  This  irregular 
market  in  time  organised  itself  in  a  separate 
building  until  the  licensed  brokers  (see  Change, 
Agents  de)  in  1859  instituted  proceedings 
to  defend  tlieu"  monopoly,  and  a  number  of 
oifenders  were  condemned  to  heavy  penalties. 
The  coulisse,  however,  altliough  disorganised 
could  not  be  suppressed,  and  the  agents  de 
change  eventually  submitted  to  tolerate  it  as  a 
lesser  evil  than  an  increase  in  the  number  of 
their  own  offices,  with  which  they  were  menaced. 
It  now  forms  two  groups,  each  with  its  own 
dii-ecting  committee  Avhicli  decides  on  tlv. 
admission  of  members  and  draws  up  a  daily 
price  list  of  the  business  done.  One  grouj' 
deals  exclusively  in  French  rentes,  but  three  pei- 
cents  only  ;  the  other  in  stocks  and  shares, 
principally  foreign,  the  number  of  which  is 
limited  by  tacit  agi'eement  with  the  syndicai 
chamber  of  agents  de  change,  French  banks 
and  railways  being  among  those  excluded. 
The  coulisse  docs  not  buy  or  sell  for  money  ; 
it  has  only  one  account  day  monthly,  and  its 
rates  of  brokerage  are  lower  than  those  of  the 
licensed  brokers.  Most  of  the  speculative 
transactions  with  London  and  the  continental 
bourses,  are  executed  in  the  coulisse,  and  for 
convenience  prices  of  certain  foreign  govertiment 
stocks  are  quoted  in  fractions  instead  of  in 
decimals  as  on  the  official  market.  Its  members 
have  no  common  fund  as  a  guarantee  towards 
the  public,  and  contracts  with  them  cannot  be 
enforced  by  law  excepting  for  stocks  and  shares 
not  dealt  in  on  the  ofticial  market,  and  con- 
sequently not  comprised  in  the  monopoly  of  the 
agents  de  change.  The  number  of  coulissiers 
syndicated  is  nearly  two  hundred,  but  in  addition 
a  certain  number  not  "on  the  sheet,"  as  it  is 
called,  are  recognised.  They  are  not  bound  by 
the  strict  rules  of  the  agents  de  change,  whc 


442 


COUNCIL  BILLS 


are  forbidden  to  operate  on  their  own  account. 
Business  in  the  coulisse  commences  half  an  hour 
earlier  than  in  the  parquet  or  regular  market, 
and  governs  in  a  great  measure  the  opening 
prices  on  the  latter.  The  coulisse  for  rentes 
meets  in  the  bourse  itself  near  the  railed  .en- 
closure called  the  corheille  reserved  for  the 
agents  de  change  ;  the  other  is  dispersed  in 
groups  inside  or  around  the  building,  but 
always  in  the  same  places.  The  agents  de  change 
recently  adopted  measures  to  defend  their  mono- 
poly, and,  May  1892,  reduced  the  number  of 
foreign  funds,  dealings  in  which  by  the  coulisse 
were  tolerated,  and  interdicted  quotations  of 
prices  on  the  coulisse  before  or  after  the  business 
hours  of  the  official  market.  t.  l. 

COUNCIL  BILLS  (India  Council  Drawings). 
Bills,  or  cabled  instructions,  issued  by  the 
India  Council  in  London  on  the  treasuries  of 
Calcutta,  Bombay,  or  Madras,  as  desired,  and 
sold  through  the  Bank  of  England  to  bankers 
or  merchants  requiring  to  remit  to  India.  It 
was  not  till  after  the  Imperial  government 
superseded  the  East  India  Company,  that  India 
Council  bills  were  first  offered  for  public  com- 
petition in  London.  The  Indian  government 
found  that  it  was  necessary  to  make  large  pay- 
ments annually  in  this  country  for  interest  upon 
its  sterling  debt  and  for  salaries,  pensions,  and 
materials — payments  which  could  hardly  have 
been  made  by  remittances  in  money,  and  for 
which  therefore  it  was  necessary  either  to  secure 
"exchange"  operations,  or  to  obtain  funds  in 
London  by  additional  borrowings.  The  latter 
method  was  first  resorted  to.  Between  1857 
and  1862  the  sterling  debt  raised  by  India  was 
increased  from  £4,000,000  to  £35,000,000,  and 
for  the  time  the  necessity  to  remit  to  London 
was  obviated.  Indeed  the  Indian  government 
was,  on  balance,  compelled  to  remit  extensively 
to  the  East.  At  that  time,  too,  the  external 
trade  of  India  did  not  present  the  remarkable 
features  now  disclosed.  The  exports  of  mer- 
chandise were  mostly  somewhat  larger  than  the 
imports,  but  the  movement  of  specie  was  suffi- 
cient to  counterbalance  this  difference,  and, 
including  specie,  there  was,  in  each  of  the  seven 
years  1st  May  1855  to  30th  April  1862,  a 
balance  of  imports  over  exports.  Then  came 
the  American  "War  and  India's  opportimity, 
when  Lancashire  had  nothing  but  Indian  cotton 
to  exist  upon  ;  and  in  the  four  years  1862-1865 
the  exports  of  India  averaged  £13,500,000  a 
year  more  than  the  imports,  specie  included. 
From  that  date  Indian  exports  have  constantly 
exceeded  the  imports,  and  that  in  spite  of  the 
very  large  amount  of  silver  sent  thither  from 
Europe.  Indeed  in  the  past  twenty  years  that 
excess  of  exports  has  in  value  averaged  quite 
£15,000,000  sterling  annually.  Hence  mer- 
chants have  had  on  balance  constantly  to  remit 
very  large  sums  to  India  in  payment  for  goods, 
sums  quite  equal  to  the  amount  of  the  govern- 


ment remittances  homeward.  Hence  there 
arose  the  possibility  that  the  government  and 
the  merchants  should  balance  each  other's  com- 
mitments by  paying  them,  thus  obviating  cash 
shipments  out  and  home  by  a  simple  exchange 
operation.  The  India  Council  drawings  consti- 
tute therefore  a  method  whereby  the  Anglo- 
Indian  merchants,  or  rather  the  bankers  on 
their  behalf,  provide  the  cash  to  cover  the  Indian 
government's  requirements  in  this  country, 
while  the  government  in  India  provides  the 
cash  requisite  to  cover  the  merchants'  payments 
on  the  other  side. 

In  1861-62  there  was  a  stoppage  of  the  heavy 
Indian  loans  issued  in  London,  and  the  Indian 
government  in  consequence  had  a  balance  ol 
payments  to  make  in  England  for  which  the 
Secretary  of  State  for  India  drew  bills  to  an 
amount  of  1,20,03,592  rupees,  obtaining  for 
these  in  London  £1,193,729,  the  average  rate 
being  Is.  lid. -867  per  rupee.  Thenceforward 
the  India  Council  drawings  increased  rapidly. 
In  1862-63  the  bills  drawn  by  the  India  Council 
realised  £6,641,576,  and  in  the  following  year 
£8,979,521.  In  the  next  five  years  they  aver- 
aged about  £6,000,000  per  annum  ;  and  in  the 
five  years  1st  April  1871  to  31st  March  1876, 
these  drawings  realised  an  average  of  over 
£12,000,000  sterling  annually.  In  the  next 
five  years  the  depreciation  in  silver  became  dis- 
tinctly pronounced  (see  Table  on  next  page) ;  but 
the  India  Council  drawings  increased  until,  in 
1879-80,  bills  were  allotted  to  the  extent  of 
18,35,00,000  rupees,  realising  £15,261,810. 
In  the  financial  year  ended  31st  March  1882, 
the  total  issued  was  22,21,09,350  rupees,  thp 
sum  received  in  respect  to  those  drawings  being 
£18,412,429.  In  the  twenty-seven  years 
ended  March  1889,  the  total  drawings  were 
357,47,59,165  rupees,  realising  £303,269,974, 
or  an  average  of  close  upon  Is.  8d.  per  rupee. 

Time  was  when  these  India  Coimcil  drawings 
consisted  wholly  of  bills  which  were  offered 
weekly  on  Wednesday  by  the  Bank  of  England. 
Gradually  the  character  of  merchants'  opera- 
tions changed,  and  the  establishment  of  tele- 
graphic communication  with  India  worked  a 
revolution.  The  bill  became  too  slow  in  its 
operation,  and  the  Indian  government  found 
that  a  higher  price  was  being  paid  for  cabled 
payments  than  for  its  bills.  In  January  1882 
it  was  decided  to  sell  telegraphic  transfers  as 
well  as  bills,  so  as  to  obtain  the  additional 
price  which  remitters  were  prepared  to  pay  for 
the  advantage  given  by  the  more  expeditious 
means  of  remittance.  From  the  first,  these 
telegraphic  transfers  were  largely  purchased. 
In  1892  the  continued  fall  in  the  gold  price 
of  silver  compelled  the  Indian  Government  to 
consider  closing  the  Indian  mints  to  the  free 
coinage  of  silver,  though  they  might  be  used 
by  the  Government  for  the  coinage  of  rupees 
in  exchange  for  gold  at  the  ratio  of  16  pence 


COUNTERVAILING  DUTY— COUNTY  COUNCIL 


443 


the  rupee.  (See  Rupee.)  This  arrangement 
lia3  continued  ever  since.  At  first  the  value 
of  the  rupee  stood  at  about  13  pence.  It  has 
since  reached  and  often  exceeds  the  required 
rate  of  16  pence.  The  Bank  of  England  now 
announce  the  amounts  to  be  offered  the  following 
week,  the  amounts  sold,  and  the  rates  realised  ; 
these  details  are  published  regularly  in  the 
money  market  intelligence  of  the  newspapers. 


Official 
Years 
ended. 

Amount  of 

Sums  re- 
ceived in 

Average 
Rate 

Bills  drawn. 

respect  of 

obtained 

Bills  drawn. 

per  Rupee. 
is.  ll'867d. 

'Ch 

/'1862       . 

Rs.  1,20,03,592 

£1,193,729 

a, 

1863       . 

6,66,37,287  1     6,641,576 

11-920 

18(54       . 

9,01,41,740 

8,979,521 

11-007 

^ 

1865       . 

6,82,45,100 

6,789,473 

11-876 

o 

M 

V18()6       . 

7,04,71,747 

6,998,890 

11S35 

/1867      . 

5,84,14,133 

5,013,746 

11-06U 

18(58       . 

4,28,18,177 

4,137,285 

11-190 

186!)       . 

3,83,40,000 

3,705.741 

11-197 

1870       . 

7,20,00,000 

6,980,122 

11-267 

1S71       . 

9,00,85,000 

8,443,509 

10-U95 

1S7L'       . 

10,70,00,000 

10,310,339 

11  -lae 

1873       . 

14,70,25,000 

13,939,095 

10-751, 

1874      . 

14,26,57,000 

13,285,678 

10-361 

1875       . 

11,74,37,000 

1(1,841,615 

10-156 

1876       . 

13,75,00,000 

12,389,913 

9-625 

1877       . 

14,85,75,1'J2 

12,695,799 

8 -508 

1878       . 

11,69,85,000 

10,134,455 

8-791 

187!)       . 

1(5,91,23,612 

13,948,565 

7 -79/, 

P 

1880      . 

18,35,00,000 

15,261,810 

7-961 

3 

1881       . 

18,32,77,000 

15,239,677 

7-956 

S^ 

1882      . 

22,21,09,360 

18,412,429 

7-895 

s 

1883       . 

18,58,56,593 

15,120,521 

7-525 

CO 

1S84      . 

21,62,15,462 

17,599,805 

7-536 

1885       . 

17,10,22,119 

13,758,909 

7-308 

1886      . 

13,53,2o,c69 

10,292,692 

6-25 U 

1887      . 

16,70,03,150 

12,13(5,279 

5-ltUl 

1888      . 

21,85,76  993 

15,389,388 

U-897 

1889       . 

20,84,17,211 

14,223,433 

U-379 

1890       . 

22,41,86,638 

15,474,496 

U-566 

1895       . 

31,15,70,798 

17,006,993 

1-10 

1900      . 

27,96,27,9-13 

18,722,564 

k-07 

1905      . 

3(5,53,57,363 

24,425,558 

U-05 

1910      . 

38,68,06,214 

25,851,367 

h-ok 

1911       . 

40,39,09,748 

27,058,550 

U-075 

1912       . 

38.47,49,178 

25,743,710 

U-006 

,1913       . 

42.2(),  19,009 

28.305.827 

1,-075 

COUNTERVAILING  DUTY.  A  duty  or 
surtax  imposed  on  imported  goods  in  order 
to  place  them  on  an  equal  footing  with  articles 
of  the  same  class  manufactured  at  home,  and 
liable  to  excise  or  other  inland  revenue  duties. 

The  duties  of  this  character  which  are 
levied  in  the  United  Kingdom  are  intended  to 
be  the  exact  equivalent  of  the  cost  to  the  home 
producer  of  the  duties  levied  upon  his  products. 
Thus,  whilst  British  spirits  are  chargeable  with 
the  duty  of  10s.  6d.  per  proof  gallon,  imported 
spirits  are  subject  to  a  customs  duty  of  10s.  lOd. , 
the  additional  4d.  being  imposed  in  respect  of 
the  loss  and  hindrance  caused  to  the  home 
producer  by  the  regulations  of  the  excise 
department.  An  interesting  account  of  the 
negotiations  which  led  to  the  increase  of  the 
countervailing  duty  from  2d.,  at  which  it  was 
fixed  by  the  Commercial  Treaty  with  France  in 
1860,  to  5d.,  and  to  its  subsequent  reduction 
to  4d.,  is  to  be  found  in  the  twenty-eighth 
report  of  the  Commissioners  of  Inland  Revenue 
(p.  11).     Imported  articles  in  the  manufacture 


of  which  spirits  are  used  are,  in  the  like  manner, 
subjected  to  countervailing  duties,  amongst  the 
principal  of  these  being  liqueurs,  perfumed  spirits, 
chloroform,  and  transparent  soap.  On  imported 
methylated  spirits,  w^hich  are  not  chargeable 
with  duty  if  prepared  according  to  the  pre- 
scribed regulations,  the  countervailing  duty 
of  4d.  is  alone  levied.  In  the  case  of  imported 
beer,  the  customs  duty  is  6s.  6d.  per  barrel  of 
thirty-six  gallons,  at  the  standard  gravity  of 
1055  degrees,  the  corresponding  charge  on 
British  beer  being  6s.  3d.  On  imported  playing 
cards,  the  stamp  duty  per  dozen  packs  is  3s.  9d. 
as  against  3s.  in  the  case  of  cards  manufactured 
at  home.  In  all  these  instances,  the  counter- 
vailing duty  is  estimated  to  be  no  higher  than 
is  necessary  to  place  home  and  foreign  producers 
on  an  equal  footing  as  regards  the  real  burden 
of  the  home  duty.  If,  in  any  case,  the  counter- 
vailing duty  were  in  excess  of  the  amount 
requisite  for  this  purpose,  it  would  become 
protective  in  character. 

The  term  is  also  applied  to  a  duty  imposed 
on  imported  articles,  the  manufacturers  of 
which  receive  a  bounty  in  respect  of  them. 
Thus  Sir  Thomas  Farrer  discusses  the  proposal 
to  impose  a  countervailing  duty  on  ' '  bounty 
for  sugars,"  and  arrives  at  the  conclusion  that 
it  would  be  impossible  to  fix  the  amount  of 
such  a  duty,  that  it  would  be  contrary  to  treaty 
stipulations,  and  that  its  effect  would  be  to 
raise  the  price  of  a  necessary  article  {Free  Trade 
versus  Fair  Trade,  p.  262).  (See  also  remarks 
made  by  Ricardo  in  Letters  of  liicardo  to 
Malthus,  "  If  I  could  convince  myself  that  any 
part  of  the  price  of  corn  was  owing  to  taxation, 
I  should  be  in  favour  of  a  protecting  duty  to 
that  amount,"  p.  64.) 

For  a  complete  list  of  the  countervailing 
duties  levied  in  the  United  Kingdom,  see  the 
Statistical  Abstract,  1891.  T.  H.  e. 

COUNTY  BOROUGH.  All  boroughs  having 
a  population  of  over  50,000,  together  with  some 
old  county  boroughs,  were,  by  the  Local  Govern- 
ment Act  of  1888,  created  county  boroughs  so 
as  to  exclude  them  from  the  administrative 
business  of  the  adjoining  county.  Retaining 
all  their  powers  as  municipal  corporations,  these 
boroughs  exercise  all  the  chief  powers  of  county 
councils,  whilst  as  district  authorities  they  ex- 
ercise powers  in  rega,rd  to  infant  life  protection, 
mad  dogs,  petroleum,  habitual  drunkards,  and 
slaughter  houses  (see  Coeporation  Muni- 
cipal, and  County  Council).         j.  e.  c.  m. 

COUNTY  COUNCIL.  County  councils  were 
established  by  the  Local  Government  Act  1888. 
England  and  Wales  are  now  divided  into  sixty- 
two  administrative  counties.  The  council 
consists  of  elected  councillors  and  nominated 
aldermen.  All  persons  enrolled  as  county 
electors  possessing  property  to  the  amount  of 
£1000  in  a  county  of  four  or  more  divisions,  or 
of  £500  in  a  smaller  county,  or  are  rated  to  the 


444 


COUNTY  RATE— COURCY 


poor  at  £30  per  annum  in  a  larger  or  £16  in  a 
smaller  county  ;  all  persons  entitled  to  be  so 
enrolled  except  in  respect  of  residence,  but  who 
are  resident  within  15  miles  of  the  county  and 
have  the  above-mentioned  property  qualifica- 
tion ;  persons  without  property  qualification  but 
who  are  entitled  to  elect  to  the  office  of  county 
councillor  and  reside  within  the  county,  peers 
owning  property  in  the  county,  and  persons 
registered  as  parliamentary  voters  in  respect 
of  ownership  of  property  in  the  county,  are 
qualified  to  be  county  councillors.  The  occu- 
pation as  owner  or  tenant  of  a  building  of  any 
value,  provided  the  owner  or  tenant  has  been 
in  occupation  for  twelve  months  and  has  paid 
the  poor  rate  and  county  rate,  qualifies  a 
person  to  be  an  elector,  unless  he  is  an  alien, 
or  has  received  parish  relief,  or  is  disentitled 
under  some  Act  of  Parliament,  as  the  Felony  Act, 
during  the  qualifying  period.  The  aldermen, 
who  are  one-third  in  number  of  the  number  of 
councillors,  one-sixth  in  London,  are  chosen  by 
the  council.  County  councillors  hold  office  for 
three  years  and  retire  together,  aldermen  for 
six  years,  one-half  retiring  every  third  year. 

The  jurisdiction  of  the  county  councils  extends 
over: — county  and  police  rates ;  duties  on  licenses 
for  carriages,  armorial  bearings,  guns,  dogs,  game; 
supervision  of  county  treasurer ;  management  of 
county  halls  ;  licensing  of  theatres,  houses  for 
music  and  dancing,  and  racecourses  ;  pauper 
lunatic  asylums ;  reformatory  and  industrial 
schools  ;  bridges  and  main  roads  ;  fees  of  in- 
spectors, analysts,  etc.  ;  coroner's  salary,  fees, 
and  district ;  parliamentary  polling  districts  and 
registration ;  contagious  diseases  of  animals ;  in- 
jurious insects  ;  weights  and  measures  ;  sale  of 
food  and  drugs  ;  acquiring  land  for  small  hold- 
ings and  allotments  ;  exercising  powers  under 
the  housing  acts  ;  enforcement  of  the  River 
Pollution  Prevention  Act  1876  ;  wild  birds 
protection  ;  licensing  of  magazines  and  factories 
of  explosives ;  formation  and  regulation  of  fishery 
districts  ;  deciding  claims  for  compensation  for 
damage  by  riot ;  local  education  (Acts  of  1902 
and  1903)  ;  and  recent  acts  have  in  minor 
matters  extended  their  jurisdiction. 

Certain  counties  possess  special  powers.  For 
instance,  London  and  the  metropolitan  counties 
license  music  halls  and  racecourses,  whilst  the 
Yorkshire  councils  have  power  to  make  rules 
subject  to  confirmation  of  the  lord  chancellor 
as  to  the  registration  of  deeds.  Some  of  the 
general  powers  of  county  councils  can  only  be 
exercised  with  the  assent  of  some  department 
of  state,  whilst  the  control  of  the  police  is  vested 
in  a  joint  committee  composed  of  an  equal 
number  of  magistrates  and  members  of  the 
council.  The  London  Metropolitan  Police  are, 
however,  under  the  control  of  the  Home  Secre- 
tary. The  revenue  of  the  county  councils  is  de- 
rived from  four  sources:  (1)  The  exchequer  con- 
tributions, i.e.  (a)  one-half  the  net  proceeds  of 


the  probate,  etc.,  duty;  (&)  1^  per  cent  of  the 
net  capital  value  of  personal  property  on  which 
estate  duty  is  imposed  in  the  place  of  probate 
duty,  and  a  further  contribution  from  estate 
duty  in  aid  of  rates  on  agricultural  land  ;  (c)  the 
proceeds  of  the  local  taxation  licenses ;  (c^)  certain 
duties  imposed  on  spirits  and  beer.  (2)  Income 
from  property  belonging  to  the  council.  (3)  Fees. 
(4)  County  rates  (see  County  Rate). 

Powers  of  borrowing  for  specified  purposes  and 
with  the  consent  of  the  local  government  board 
on  the  security  of  the  council's  revenue,  for  any 
period  not  exceeding  thirty  years,  have  been 
conferred  on  the  county  councils. 

The  county  of  London  succeeded  to  tlie  duties 
and  liabilities  of  the  metropolitan  board  of  works. 

[A.  Pilling,  Handbook  for  Council  Authorities, 
London,  1889. — A.  Macmorran,  The  Local  Gov- 
ernment Act,  1888,  London,  1888.]     j.  e,  c.  m. 

COUNTY  RATE.  Moneys  required  by  a 
county  council  over  and  above  exchequer  con- 
tributions, income  of  the  council,  and  fees,  are 
raised  by  a  rate.  The  basis  of  this  rate  is  de- 
termined in  the  first  instance  by  a  committee 
of  the  council,  who  estimate  the  net  rateable 
value  of  each  parish.  The  council  may  alter  such 
basis,  and  any  person  may  appeal  to  quarter- 
sessions  against  the  basis,  on  the  ground  that  his 
parish  is  treated  unfairly.  The  1 5  &  1 6  Vict.  c.  81 , 
§  2,  directs  the  "basis  to  be  founded  and  pre- 
pared rateably  and  equally  according  to  the  full 
and  fair  annual  value  of  the  property."  On  this 
basis  the  county  council  rates  each  parish  at  so 
much  in  the  pound,  and  serves  a  notice  on  the 
guardians  of  the  parish  requiring  them  to  pay  the 
same.  Usually  the  poor-law  valuations  are  fol- 
lowed ;  but  some  county  councils  adopt  the  as- 
sessment to  income  tax,  schedule  A,  others  form 
a  special  valuation  of  their  own.        j.  e.  c.  m. 

COUPON".  A  certificate  entitling  the  bearer 
to  payment  of  interest  on  a  government  or 
other  public  security  at  the  time  and  for  the 
period  stated  on  its  face.  These  certificates  are 
printed  on  the  same  sheet  as  the  instrument 
certifying  the  principal  security,  each  of  them 
as  it  falls  due  being  detached  by  the  holder 
and  encashed  by  him.  The  original  coupons 
do  not  always  cover  the  whole  period  of  the 
currency  of  the  security,  in  which  case  there  is 
often  a  so-called  "talon'  which  entitles  the 
holder,  when  all  coupons  are  used,  to  obtain  a 
new  coupon -sheet.  In  other  cases  the  principal 
document  must  be  presented  in  order  to  have  a 
new  series  of  coupons  attached  to  it.        E.  s. 

COUROY,  Alfred  de  (1816-1888),  born  at 
Brest,  died  at  Montmorency.  At  the  age  of 
seventeen  he  entered  the  employment  of  the 
"  Compagnie  d'assurances  generales,  Paris,"  the 
manager  of  which  he  afterwards  became.  He 
translated  the  Thiorie  des  annuit^s  viag^res  et 
des  assurances  sur  la  vie,  by  Feancis  BAiLY(g'.'2;.) 
(2  vols,  in  8vo).  He  was  the  author  of  many 
works  on  questions  connected  with  insurance 


COURNOT 


44{ 


and  similar  subjects.  Among  the  more  import- 
ant of  these  are  Essai  sur  les  lois  du  hasard 
(in  32mo,  1862),  Un  Examen  de  la  loi  d,u  S4 
■juillet  1867,  sur  les  socUles  anonymes  (in  18 mo), 
Un  Pr6cis  de  V assurance  sur  la  vie  (in  ISino, 
1870),  Cominentaire  dcs  polices  fran^uises 
d' assurance  maritime  (in  18mo,  1874)  ;  finally, 
Le  Droit  et  les  OuvTiers  (in  8vo,  1886).  His 
principal  claim  to  notice,  however,  was  the 
establishment  in  1870  of  a  "caisse  de  prevoy- 
ance  "  for  the  employees  of  his  company,  based 
on  the  individual  subscriptions  of  each.  Many 
other  associations  have  folloAved  the  lead  thus 
given,  to  the  ad^•antage  both  of  employers  and 
employed.  A  law  proposed  by  the  French 
senate,  but  not,  at  the  date  of  wiiting,  ratified 
by  the  chamber  of  deputies,  proposes  to  apply 
the  same  system  to  government  officials.  De 
Courcy's  honest  and  laborious  life  was  devoted 
to  the  improvement  of  the  condition  of  the 
humble  ;  during  his  last  years  he  established 
the  Society  de  secours  aux  families  dcs  marins 
fran<^ais  naufragis.  His  authority  on  all  ques- 
tions of  maritime  risk  was  reckoned  the  highest 
that  had  ever  been  known  in  Paris.      A.  C.  f. 

COURNOT,  Antoine  Augustin,  eminent 
mathematician  and  philosopher  (1801-1877), 
deserves  notice  as  the  first  who  successfully 
applied  mathematics  to  political  economy. 
His  success  was  signal.  His  Rccherches  sur  Jcs 
Princijycs  Matheinatiqncs  de  la  Thearie  dcs  Hi  ch- 
esses, published  1838,  is  still  the  best  state- 
ment in  mathematical  form  of  some  of  the 
highest  generalisations  in  economic  science. 
This  work  may  be  summarised  under  three 
headings :  pure  theory  of  price,  abstract  pro- 
positions on  taxation,  and  miscellaneous  applica- 
tions of  mathematical  reasoning. 

I.  Cournot  appears  to  have  been  the  first  to 
represent  by  means  of  an  equation,  or  curve,  the 
relation  between  the  price  of  a  commodity  and 
the  quantity  saleable  at  that  price  in  a  market 
consisting  of  purchasers  competing  with  each 
other.  Let  D  stand  for  quantity  demanded, 
and  p  for  corresponding  price.  Then  the  law 
of  demand  is  expressed  by  the  equation  D  =  F 
(p),  or  the  con'esponding  curve  whose  ordinate 
is  D  and  abscissa  p  (ch.  iv.)  How  much 
logomachy  is  saved  by  this  appropriate  concep- 
tion !  How  difficult  it  is  in  words  to  distinguish 
between  what  has  been  called  a  "rise"  of 
demand  occasioned  by  a  change  in  the  form  of 
the  function  F,  or  displacement  of  the  curve, 
and  an  "  extension  "  of  demand  due  to  a  change 
of  the  variable  p,  a  movement  along  the  curve. 
The  price  for  which  the  total  value  is  greatest, 
is  found  by  making  the  expression  D  x  ^  or  F 
(p)xp  a.  maximum.  The  price  thus  determined 
is  that  which  a  monopolist  would  fix,  on  the 
supposition  that  the  expenses  of  production  are 
either  zero,  or  a  fixed  charge  independent  of 
quantity  produced,  as  in  the  ease  of  a  "  mineral 
soiu'ce."     Otherwise,  the  expression  to  be  maxi- 


mised must  be  diminished  by  the  cost  of  pro- 
duction. This  cost  is  to  be  regarded  as  a 
function  of  the  quantity  produced,  say  0  (D). 
The  relation  of  cost  to  product  may  be  graphic- 
ally illustrated  by  the  curve  p  =  (p'(D)  ;  where 
p,  the  price,  as  before  is  the  abscissa,  and  i^'(D) 
represents  the  cost  of  producing  the  last  unit 
of  the  quantity  produced.  In  the  most  general 
and  important  case,  the  function  (p'(D)  increases 
with  the  variable  D  agi-eeably  to  the  law  of 
diminishing  returns. 

After  analysing  the  operation  of  monopoly, 
Cournot  advances  from  the  simple  to  the  com- 
plex by  introducing  a  second  proprietor  (ch. 
vii.)  He  argues,  by  reasoning  which  has  been 
traversed  by  M.  Bertrand  (Journal  des  Savants 
for  1883  ;  cp.  Prof.  Marshall,  Principles  oj 
Economies,  bk.  v.  chap.  viii.  §  2,  note,  2nd  ed.), 
that  with  the  division  of  the  proprietorship, 
the  price  diminishes.  There  is,  however,  one 
curious  exception  to  this  rule.  Suppose  two 
commodities  have  no  other  use  biit  to  enter  into 
the  formation  of  a  certain  compound  commodity 
in  the  fixed  proportions  m^ :  m^ .  And  let  the 
"sources"  from  which  the  component  commo- 
dities are  derived  be  initially  in  the  hands  of  a 
single  monopolist ;  but  afterwards  let  each  of 
the  two  sources  pass  into  the  hands  of  an  inde- 
pendent proprietor.  AVhat  effect  on  the  price 
of  the  compound  will  be  produced  by  this 
breaking  down  of  monopoly  ?  Common  sense 
would  probably  reply  that  the  price  would  be 
lowered  by  increase  of  competition.  But 
Cournot's  reasoning  concludes  that  the  price  will 
be  raised  by  the  separation  of  the  proprietor- 
ship (art.  57).  Cournot  gives  the  imaginary 
instance  of  zinc  and  copper  having  no  other  use 
but  to  make  brass.  The  following  would  be  a 
more  important  example.  If  a  railway  and 
line  of  steamers  have  no  other  use  except  to 
form  part  of  a  certain  through  journey  ;  then 
primd  facie,  and  in  the  abstract,  it  is  more 
advantageous  for  the  public  that  the  two  should 
be  in  the  hands  of  a  single  monopolist  than 
that  they  should  be  owned  by  two  competing 
companies,  each  seeking  independently  to  obtain 
for  itself  the  maximum  net  profit.  This  theorem 
exhibits  the  power  of  Cournot's  methods  in  a 
very  striking  light. 

When  by  the  multiplication  of  producers, 
monopoly  becomes  "extinct,"  the  equation  for 
determining  price  assumes  a  certain  simplicity. 
It  becomes  of  the  form  Q,{p)  =  F(p)  ;  where 
D  =  F(p)  is  as  before  the  demand  curve  ;  and 
I)  =  Q(p)  is  a  curve  expressing  the  quantity 
that  would  be  offered  at  any  assigned  price. 
The  function  U  is  compounded  out  of  the 
functions  expressing  the  cost  of  production  to 
each  producer,  in  such  wise  as  to  bring  out 
very  clearly  the  principle  that  the  price  is 
equal  to  the  cost  of  production  of  the  last  unit 
produced.  In  symbols  j9  =  ^'^(0^)  ;  where  p  is 
the  price,   D^  is  the  quantity  of  commodity 


446 


COURNOT 


supplied  by  any  one  producer,  and  0'^  a  function 
representing  the  cost  to  that  producer  of  the 
last  unit  produced.  It  is  to  be  observed,  that 
cost  of  production  as  used  by  Cournot  must  be 
interpreted  as  expense,  exclusive  of  the  remunera- 
tion to  the  entrepreneur  for  his  own  labour. 
Cournot  does  not  take  into  account  what  Jevons 
calls  the  "final  disutility"  of  labour,  any  more 
than  he  has  expounded  the  theory  of  final  utility 
in  the  case  of  the  consumer. 

II.  The  formulae  which  take  account  of  cost 
are  well  adapted  to  investigate  the  effect  of  a 
tax  which  may  be  regarded  as  an  increase  in 
cost  of  production.  Cournot  has  discussed  a 
variety  of  taxes,  including  "negative  taxes," 
or  bounties  ;  on  the  supposition  either  of  mono- 
poly, or  a  regime  of  perfect  competition.  The 
following  appear  to  be  the  most  striking 
theorems. 

If  a  tax  of  so  much  per  unit  of  commodity  is 
imposed  on  a  monopolised  article,  the  conse- 
quent rise  in  price  may  be  greater,  equal  to,  or 
less  than,  the  tax.  The  loss  to  the  monopolist 
is  greater  than  the  gain  to  the  treasury  (arts. 
33,  38). 

If  a  similar  tax  be  imposed  under  a  regime 
of  competition,  the  rise  in  price  will  be  less 
than  the  tax.  There  is  no  general  relation 
between  the  loss  to  the  producer  and  the  gain 
to  the  treasury  (arts.  51,  52). 

Converse  propositions  are  true  of  bounties. 
Similar  conclusions  are  deducible  with  respect 
to  an  ad  valorem  tax  and  a  tithe  (chaps,  vi.  and 
vii.)  There  are  also  some  interesting  theorems 
as  to  the  effect  of  taxing  one  of  two  commodities 
employed  m  a  fixed  proportion  in  the  "joint 
production"  of  a  certain  compound,  and  not 
useful  for  any  other  purpose  (art.  62). 

The  most  remarkable  results  obtained  by 
Cournot's  method  are  those  which  relate  to  a 
tax  on  the  importation  or  exportation  of  a  com- 
modity subject  to  the  law  of  diminishing  returns. 
Cournot  finds  that  the  price  in  the  importing 
country  may  possibly  be  lowered  by  the  im- 
position of  the  tax  (art.  70).  This  paradoxical 
conclusion  appears  to  the  present  writer  to  be 
due  to  a  flaw  in  the  mathematical  reasoning. 
Equations  (6)  chap.  x.  appear  not  to  be  legiti- 
mately deduced.  The  following  is  another 
argument  unexpectedly  favourable  to  protection. 
Suppose  a  restriction  of  trade  in  respect  of  a 
certain  commodity  between  two  localities  is 
removed.  Cournot  concludes  that  neither  the 
quantity  nor  the  total  value  of  that  commodity 
is  necessarily  increased  by  freedom  of  trade. 

III.  Among  miscellaneous  topics  treated 
mathematically  there  occurs  first  variation  in 
general  prices.  Comparing  ratios  to  differences 
upon  the  principle  which  is  at  the  foundation 
of  logarithms,  Cournot  illustrates  the  change 
in  the  value  of  money  in  relation  to  other  com- 
modities by  the  motion  of  one  body  relative  to 
a  set  of  other  bodies.     He  compares  the  move- 


ment of  general  prices  caused  by  a  change  on 
the  part  of  money  to  the  apparent  motion  ol 
the  stars  due  to  the  revolution  of  the  earth 
(chap,  ii.)  It  will  be  seen  that  Cournot's 
measure  of  the  variation  in  the  value  of  money 
is  of  the  nature  of  a  mere  type,  or  simple  aver- 
age as  distinguished  from  a  "weighted"  index 
number  (see  Index  Numbers). 

The  next  topic  to  be  noticed  is  Cournot's 
mathematical  treatment  of  the  foreign  ex- 
changes (chap,  iii.)  We  may  say  with  Jevons 
of  this  investigation  that  it  is  "highly  ingeni- 
ous, if  not  particularly  useful. " 

It  remains  to  speak  of  Cournot's  theory  of 
"social  revenue"  (chap,  xi.)  He  well  defines 
the  national  income  so  as  to  include  the  wages 
of  so-called  "unproductive"  labourers.  He 
gives  formulae  for  the  "real  gain"  and  "real 
loss  "  in  revenue  which  are  very  similar  to  the 
methods  by  which  statisticians  would  now  esti- 
mate a  change  in  the  "volume  of  trade."  In 
the  definition  of  "real  gain  and  loss"  abstrac- 
tion is  made  of  the  detriment  suffered  by  those 
consumers  who  are  deterred  by  a  rise  of  price 
from  purchasing  and  the  converse  advantage 
accruing  to  those  who  are  induced  by  a  lower 
price  to  become  purchasers.  The  peculiarity  of 
this  definition  permits  the  truth,  while  it 
diminishes  the  importance,  of  Cournot's  para- 
doxical conclusion  that,  when  a  restriction  of 
trade  in  respect  of  a  certain  commodity  between 
two  localities  is  removed,  the  importing  country 
suffers  a  "real  loss"  (art.  89).  Cournot  him- 
self points  out  the  limitations  of  his  theorj' 
He  does  not  pretend  to  treat  the  question  "au 
point  de  vue  de  I'homme  d'Etat."  But  he  adds 
with  modest  confidence,  in  words  applicable  to 
his  whole  book  and  the  mathematical  method 
in  general : 

"  II  y  aurait  toujours  de  I'avantage  h,  eclaircir 
en  quelques  lignes,  k  la  faveur  de  signes  precis, 
et  d'une  m6thode  d'argumentation  plus  rigour- 
euse,  les  difficult^s  soulevees  par  des  volumes  de 
controverse. " 

The  main  outlines  of  Cournot's  system  have 
been  presented  by  their  author  in  a  form  divested 
of  mathematical  symbol,  or  rather  in  two  such 
forms,  in  two  works  dated  1863  and  1876  re- 
spectively. Of  these  versions  the  latter  seems 
best  to  preserve  the  elegance  of  the  original  in- 
vestigation. Both  paraphrases  are  accompanied 
with  some  additional  and  valuable  matter. 
Particular  attention  may  be  called  to  the  cri- 
ticism of  Mill's  theory  of  international  trade, 
and  to  the  remarks  on  "economic  optimism." 
Some  of  these  reflections  may  be  found  in  an 
earlier  work  treating  of  the  relation  between  the 
first  principles  of  the  different  sciences. 

Yet  another  debt  of  gratitude  is  owed  by  poli- 
tical economists  to  Cournot.  In  his  masterly 
work  on  chances  he  has  pointed  out  the  bearing 
of  the  calculus  of  probabilities  on  statistics. 

F.  Y.  E. 


COURT— COURT  ROLLS 


447 


The  following  are  the  works  of  Cournot  which 
wholly  or  in  part  relate  to  political  economy  : 

Recherches  sur  les  Principes  MatMmatiques  de 
la  Theorie  des  Richesses  (1838). — Exposition  (^e  la 
Theorie  des  Chances  et  des  Prohdbilites  (1843). — 
TraiU  de  V Enchainertxent  des  Idees  Fondamentales 
dans  les  Sciences  et  dans  VHistoire  (1861). — Prin- 
cipes  de  la  Them'ie  des  Richesses  (1863). — Revue 
Sominaire  des  Doctrines  Economiques  (1876). 

COURT,  PiETER  DE  LA  (1618-1685),  born  at 
Leyden  where  he  succeeded  his  father  as  a  cloth- 
manufacturer  after  having  studied  law.  He 
emigrated  to  Antwerp,  1672,  being  an  adherent 
of  the  pensionary  of  Holland,  John  de  Witt, 
murdered  that  year.  In  1673  he  settled  at 
Amsterdam,  where  he  resided  until  his  death. 
His  principal  works,  all  of  a  polemical  character, 
are : — 

Het  Welvaaren  der  Stadt  Leyden  [The  Wel- 
fare of  the  City  of  Leyden),  edited  for  the  first 
time,  1845,  by  B.  W.  Uittewaall,  under  the  title 
Proeve  uit  een  onuitgegeven  staathuishondkundig 
geschrift  {Specimen  of  an  unedited  economical 
Work). — Intrest  van  Holland  of  te  Gronden  van 
Hollands  Welvaren  ungaaewezen  door  v.  d.  H. — ■ 
(Van  den  Hove  de  la  Coiu-t),  [Interest  of  Hol- 
land, or  Grounds  of  Holland's  welfare  explained 
by  V.  D.  H. ),  Amsterdam,  1662,  translated  into 
German  1665  (twice)  and  1668.  The  second 
edition  of  the  same  work  was  entitled  Aanwij- 
sing  der  heilsame  politike  gronden  en  3Iaxim-en 
van  de  Republike  van  Holland  en  West-  Vriesland, 
door  V.  d.  H. — {Explanations  of  the  wholesome 
political  doctrines  and  maxims  of  the  Rejmhlic  of 
Holland  and  West-Friesland,  by  v.  d.  H.),  Am- 
Bterdam,  1669,  translated  into  German,  1670  ; 
into  French,  1709,  under  the  title  Alemoires  de 
Jean  de  Witt ;  into  English,  1743,  under  the  title 
Political  Maxims  of  the  State  of  Holland,  etc.  by 
John  de  Witt,  Pensionary  of  Holland,  etc.  London, 
printed  for  T.  Nourse  at  the  Lamb,  without 
Temple  Bar.  The  fact  is,  that  John  de  Witt 
added  only  some  remarks,  and  wrote  the  chapters 
5  and  6  of  part  iii.,  as  is  now  placed  beyond 
doubt.  De  la  Court  was  a  free-trader  by  con- 
viction, but  principally  for  the  merchants'  sake. 
Monopolies,  especially  those  of  the  Indian  Com- 
panies, he  eagerly  opposed.  Industry  too  should 
be  free  in  developing  itself — guilds  hinder  im- 
provement ;  governmental  rules,  prescribing  the 
mode  of  producing  and  the  quality  of  merchandise, 
give  no  security  as  to  adulterations,  and  cannot 
have  any  salutary  efiect,  the  consumer  being  the 
only  person  who  can  judge  of  what  he  wants. 

A.  F.  V.  L. 

COURT  ROLLS,  MANORIAL  ACCOUNTS 
and  EXTENTS.  Among  the  mediaeval  docu- 
ments most  valuable  for  the  purposes  of 
economic  history,  must  be  placed  those  which 
illustrate  the  manorial  system.  These  may  be 
classified  under  the  three  heads  specified  above. 

I.  Court  Rolls.  The  practice  of  enrolling 
the  business  done  in  the  king's  court  seems  to 
have  been  begun  near  the  end  of  Henry  II. 's 
reign.  The  earliest  extant  roll  is  one  of  1194, 
and  from  that  date  onwards  there  is  a  fairly 


continuous  series  of  these  rolls  at  the  Public 
Record  Office.  Some  of  the  entries  on  them  are  of 
interest  to  the  student  of  economic  history  ;  but 
the  rolls  that  are  likely  to  interest  him  moro 
are  the  rolls  of  local,  usually  manorial,  courts. 
Such  rolls,  not  being  public  documents,  must  be 
sought  in  the  libraries  and  muniment  rooms  of 
cathedrals,  colleges,  and  landlords ;  but  the 
Record  Office  has  a  fine  collection  of  rolls 
concerning  manors  which  at  one  time  or 
another  came  into  the  hands  of  the  king.  A 
few  lords  of  manors  had  begun  to  keep  rolls 
before  1250,  many  before  1300  ;  but  rolls  of 
the  13th  century  are  not  now  very  common. 
They  are  of  gi-eat  value  as  evidence  of  the 
condition  of  the  peasantry,  the  terms  on  which 
they  held  their  lands,  and  the  mode  in  which 
justice  was  done  between  and  upon  them.  The 
entries  fall  into  three  main  classes  :  (1)  cases  of 
litigation  between  the  tenants ;  (2)  the  punish- 
ment of  petty  offences,  either  against  the 
manorial  custom  or  against  the  general  law  ; 
(3)  the  transfer  of  the  customary  tenements  by 
surrender  and  admittance,  for  the  villain  or 
customary  lands  of  the  manor  could  not  be 
alienated  %vithout  being  given  up  into  the  hands 
of  the  lord,  who  thereupon  admitted  the  new 
tenant.  In  the  earlier  ages,  entries  of  the  two 
former  classes  prevail  ;  in  later  times,  the  court 
almost  ceases  to  exercise  a  contentious  jurisdic- 
tion, and  the  court  roll  becomes  little  more  than 
a  register  of  the  titles  of  the  copyholders. 
The  copyholders,  as  in  the  15th  century  the 
customary  tenants  or  tenants  in  villainage  came 
to  be  called,  acquired  this  name  because  copies 
of  the  entries  on  the  court  rolls  concerning 
their  lands  served  them  as  title-deeds.  From 
the  older  rolls  a  great  deal  may  be  learnt  about 
villainage,  the  common  field  system  and  the 
state  of  agriculture.  It  may  safely  be  said 
that  we  never  shall  know  how  far  the  tenure  of 
the  mediaeval  peasant  was  precarious  until  these 
documents  have  been  examined.  Rolls  of 
municipal  courts,  and  of  the  courts  which  ad- 
ministered "the  law  merchant"  in  fairs  and 
markets,  illustrate  another  side  of  economic 
history,  the  condition  of  trade,  the  nature  of 
merchant  guilds  and  trade  guilds,  the  treatment 
of  foreigners  and  to-\vn  life  in  general.  W^e  have 
some  rolls  of  this  class  even  from  the  thirteenth 
century.  As  yet  hardly  a  beginning  has  been 
made  towards  publishing  the  court  rolls  ;  but 
the  Selden  Society's  volume  for  1889  contains 
a  selection  of  entries  from  certain  rolls  of  the 
13th  century  which  may  be  considered  as 
typical. 

II.  Manorial  Accounts.  The  accounts  of 
the  manorial  officers,  bailiffs,  and  reeves,  are 
scarcely  of  such  general  interest  as  the  court 
rolls  and  extents,  but  they  afford  excellent 
materials  for  the  history  of  prices,  and  have  been 
largely  used  by  Professor  Thorold  Rogers. 
They  have  not  been  printed,  at  least  on  any 


448 


COURTEN— COURTS  OF  LAW 


large  scale,  and  must  be  souglit  in  tlie  Public 
Record  Office  and  private  muniment  rooms.  A 
yery  full  and  very  early  set  of  accounts  relating 
to  the  Bishop  of  Winchester's  manors  is  in  the 
possession  of  the  Ecclesiastical  Commissioners. 
It  goes  back  as  far  as  John's  reign. 

III.  Manorial  Extents.  The  "extent" of 
a  manor  is  a  description  of  it  which  generally 
gives  the  names  of  the  tenants,  the  size  of  their 
holdings,  the  legal  character  of  their  tenure,  the 
amount  and  nature  of  their  rents  and  services, 
whether  rendered  in  money,  in  produce,  or  in 
labour.  Generally  the  extent  is  the  result  of  a 
sworn  verdict  returned  by  a  jury  of  tenants  to 
a  set  of  interrogatories  addressed  to  them  by  the 
lord's  steward.  To  *  *  extend  "  (extendere)  a  manor 
is  to  obtain  by  this  process  a  full  statement 
and  valuation  of  all  the  lord's  rights.  On  the 
continent,  the  practice  of  making  such  manorial 
registers  can  be  traced  to  very  remote  times  and 
possibly  is  of  Roman  origin.  The  most  famous 
of  these  very  ancient  registers  is  that  of  the 
Abbey  of  S.  Germain  des  Pres,  made  in  the  time 
of  Charles  the  Great  (published  1844  by  B. 
Guerard  under  the  title  Polyptyque  de  I'dbhi 
Irminon  ;  the  first  volume  of  a  new  edition  by 
Auguste  Longnon  appeared  in  1886).  The 
England  of  the  days  before  the  Conquest  has 
apparently  left  us  nothing  at  all  comparable 
with  this.  But  the  "extent"  comes  in  with 
the  Conqueror,  and  is  at  once  applied  to 
England  on  a  vast  scale  ;  Domesday  Book  is  an 
extent  of  the  realm  made  on  the  king's  behalf 
by  local  juries.  Gradually  the  lords  of  manors, 
especially  the  religious  houses,  followed  the 
example  thus  set.  We  have  a  few  extents 
from  the  12th,  many  from  the  13th  century. 
Some  have  been  printed ;  some  believed  to  be  of 
almost  equal  value  still  lie  in  manuscript. 

[Among  published  extents  are  the  Boldon  Book, 
a  survey  of  the  Palatinate  of  Durham,  printed  as 
an  appendix  to  the  official  edition  of  Domesday, 
and  again  by  the  Surtees  Society. — The  Glastonbury 
Inquisitions  (Koxburghe  Club). — The  Cartulary  of 
Burton  Abbey  (Salt  Society). — The  Black  Book  of 
Peterborough. — The  Domesday  of  St.  Paul's. — the 
Register  of  Worcester  Priory. — The  Cartulary  of 
Battle  Abbey  (all  for  the  Camden  Society). — The 
Cartulary  of  Gloucester  Abbey,  and  the  Cartulary 
of  Ramsey  Abbey  (both  in  the  Rolls'  series). — The 
Hundred  Rolls,  published  by  the  Record  Com- 
missioners, give  very  valuable  extents  of  manors 
in  Cambridgeshire,  and  some  other  counties.] 

P.  w.  M. 
COURTElsT,    Sir    William    (1572-1636). 
See  Interlopers. 

COURTIER  (Broker).  See  Change, 
Agents  de. 

COURTS  OF  LAW  (England).  The  princi- 
pal courts  in  England  are  the  County  Courts  ; 
the  Supreme  Court  of  Judicature ;  and  the 
House  of  Lords.  The  jurisdiction  of  the  County 
Courts  is  in  most  cases  limited  by  the  amount 
or  value  ot   the  claims  brought  forward,   the 


limit  varying  according  to  the  subject  matter  of 
the  action,  but  some  matters  cannot  be  taken 
before  a  County  Court,  while  in  others  their 
jurisdiction  is  unlimited,  as  for  instance  in 
bankruptcy  proceedings.  England  and  Wales 
are  for  County  Court  purposes  divided  into  five 
hundred  districts.  The  districts  are  grouped 
together  into  fifty-nine  circuits,  one  judge  being 
as  a  rule  appointed  to  each  circuit.  The  county 
courts  have  no  criminal  business.  The  various 
statutes  relating  to  these  courts,  which  were 
first  established  in  1846,  have  been  consolidated 
by  the  County  Courts  Act,  1888  (61  &  52  Vict. 
c.  43).  The  Supreme  Court  of  Judicature  con- 
sists of  Her  Majesty's  High  Court  and  Her 
Majesty's  Court  of  Appeal.  The  High  Court 
has  taken  the  place  {a)  of  the  Courts  of  Queen's 
Bench,  Common  Pleas,  and  Exchequer  now 
united  in  the  Queen's  Bench  Division  ;  (h)  of 
the  High  Court  of  Chancery  now  transformed 
into  the  Chancery  Division  ;  (c)  the  Courts  of 
Probate  and  of  Divorce  and  Matrimonial  Causes 
and  the  High  Court  of  Admiralty  now  merged 
in  the  Probate,  Divorce,  and  Admiralty  Division. 
The  London  Bankruptcy  Court  has  also  been 
absorbed  by  the  High  Court,  the  London  bank- 
ruptcy work  being,  at  present,  allotted  to  the 
Queen's  Bench  Division.  The  High  Court  has 
original  jurisdiction  in  aU  civil  matters  which 
may  be  brought  before  an  English  tribunal,  but 
a  plaintiff  instituting  proceedings  in  the  High 
Court  for  which  a  County  Court  would  have 
been  competent  has  to  submit  to  unpleasant 
consequences  as  regards  costs.  The  active 
judges  of  the  High  Court  are  the  Lord  Chief 
Justice,  the  President  of  the  Probate,  etc 
Division  and  twenty  puisne  judges  (fourteen 
in  the  Queen's  Bench  Division,  five  in  the 
Chancery  Division,  and  one  in  the  Probate, 
Divorce,  and  Admiralty  Division).  The  judges 
as  a  rule  sit  alone,  but  some  matters  in  the 
Queen's  Bench  Division  {e.g.  appeals  from 
County  Courts)  are  heard  by  divisional  courts 
consisting  of  two,  and  in  exceptional  cases  even 
of  three  judges.  In  Admiralty  proceedings  the 
judge  has  frequently  the  assistance  of  two 
nautical  assessors.  The  courts  of  assize,  sitting 
periodically  in  the  provinces,  are  now  considered 
as  belonging  to  the  High  Court ;  the  matters 
coming  before  these  courts  are  generally  tried 
by  judges  of  the  Queen's  Bench  Division,  but 
they  act  as  judges  of  assize  by  virtue  of  a  special 
commission  issued  separately  on  each  occasion. 
For  the  purpose  of  the  assizes  England  and 
Wales  are  subdivided  into  seven  circuits.  There 
are  also  district  registries  in  the  provinces  at- 
tached to  the  High  Court  in  which  all  pre- 
liminary steps  may  be  taken.  In  London  these 
preliminary  proceedings  take  place  partly  in  the 
central  office,  partly  in  the  judge's  chambers. 
Criminal  causes  are  tried  at  the  assizes  and  also 
(exceptionally)  by  the  Queen's  Bench  Division. 
Five  judges  of  the  latter  division  form  the  Court 


COURTS 


449 


of  Crown  Cases  Reserved,  hearing  appeals  on 
points  of  criminal  law  reserved  by  judges  of 
assize,  and  in  cases  of  particular  importance  all 
the  Queen's  Bench  judges  sit  together  for  that 
purpose.  The  Court  of  Appeal  hears  appeals 
from  the  High  Court.  It  is  composed  of  four 
ex-offido  judges  :  the  Lord  Chancellor,  the  Lord 
Chief  Justice,  the  Master  of  the  Rolls,  and  the 
President  of  the  Probate,  Divorce,  and  Admiralty 
Division,  and  of  five  ordinary  judges  (called 
Lords  Justices  of  Appeal).  As  a  general  rule, 
three  judges  of  the  Court  of  Appeal  sit  together ; 
in  particularly  important  cases  the  court  is 
sometimes  composed  of  six  judges.  The  Supreme 
Court  has  been  created  by  the  Supreme  Court 
of  Judicature  Act  1873  (36  &  37  Vict.  c.  QQ), 
and  its  constitution  has  been  modified  by  a 
number  of  subsequent  acts.  The  House  of 
Lords  hears  appeals  from  the  English  Court  of 
Appeal,  and  from  the  corresponding  com'ts  in 
Scotland  and  Ireland.  There  are  four  salaried 
judges  forming  part  of  that  tribunal  who  are 
called  lords  of  appeal  in  ordinary,  and  who 
enjoy  all  the  privileges  of  the  peerage  during 
their  lifetime  (Appellate  Jm-isdiction  Act,  1887). 
Besides  these,  the  Lord  Chancellor  and  such 
peers  as  have  held  any  high  judicial  office  take 
part  in  the  judicial  proceedings  of  the  House. 
It  ought  to  be  mentioned  that  the  same  lords 
and  a  few  other  members  of  the  Privy  Council 
form  the  Judicial  Committee  of  the  Privy 
Council,  a  tribunal  hearing  appeals  from  the 
ecclesiastical  courts  and  from  the  highest  courts 
of  appeal  in  India  and  the  colonics  and  de- 
pendencies. In  addition  to  the  courts  which 
we  have  enumerated,  there  are  a  number  of  courts 
of  exclusively  criminal  jurisdiction  (such  as  the 
Central  Criminal  Court  at  the  Old  Bailey,  the 
courts  of  quarter  session  and  of  petty  session, 
the  stipendiary  magistrates*  courts,  etc.),  and 
others  of  purely  local  importance  (as  the  Lord 
Mayor's  Coui't  in  the  city  of  London,  the  Liver- 
pool Court  of  Passage,  etc.).  e.  s. 

COURTS  (Ireland).  The  courts  in 
Ireland  are,  on  the  whole,  organised  on  the 
same  system  as  the  English  courts.  There  is 
a  Supreme  Court  consisting  of  the  High  Court 
and  the  Court  of  Appeal,  the  former  consisting 
of  the  Chancery,  Queen's  Bench,  and  Probate 
Divisions.  The  Chancery  Division  has  taken 
over  the  jurisdiction  of  the  former  Landed 
Estates  Court  (40  &  41  Vict.  c.  57  ;  50  Vict. 
c.  6).  There  is  a  Court  of  Bankruptcy  which 
remains  distinct  from  the  High  Court,  and  local 
bankruptcy  courts  have  been  constituted  by  an 
act  passed  in  1888  (51  &  52  Vict.  c.  44). 
The  courts  corresponding  to  English  county 
courts  are  called  Civil  Bill  Courts  and  are  held 
before  the  chairman  of  Quarter  Sessions  or  the 
recorder  as  the  case  may  be.  The  chairmen  of 
Quarter  Sessions  are  now  called  "  County  Court 
judges  and  chairmen  of  Quarter  Sessions,"  and 
are  appointed  by  the  Lord  Lieutenant.  They 
VOL.  1. 


must  be  baiTisters  of  ten  years'  standing  (14 
&  15  Vict.  c.  57  ;  40  &  41  Vict.  c.  56). 
The  Lord  Lieutenant  is  also  empowered  to 
appoint  stipendiary  magistrates,  having  all  the 
powers  of  justices  of  the  peace  in  counties  and 
boroughs  (6  &  7  William  IV.  c.  13  ;  3  & 
4  Vict.  c.  108).  The  inspector -general  ot 
constabulary,  his  deputy,  and  assistants,  have 
power  to  act  as  justices  of  the  peace  throughout 
Ireland  (2  &  3  Vict.  c.  75  ;  9  &  10  Vict. 
c.  97).  The  jurisdiction  and  constitution 
of  the  courts  of  Quarter  Sessions  and  Petty 
Sessions  is  similar  to  that  of  the  corresponding 
courts  in  England.  The  Land  Commission 
constituted  under  the  Land  Law  (Ireland) 
Act  of  1881  (44  &  45  Vict.  c.  49)  and  the 
Purchase  of  Land  Act  1885  (48  &  49  Vict, 
c.  73)  has  quasi-judicial  functions  in  con- 
nection with  the  caiTying  out  of  these  statutes. 

E.  s. 

COURTS  (Scotland).  The  principal  courts 
in  Scotland  are  (1)  the  Sheriff  Courts,  (2)  the 
High  Court  of  Justiciary,  (3)  the  Court  of 
Session. 

Courts  are  also  held  by  justices  of  the  peace 
and  magistrates  of  burghs,  but  these  are  not  of 
the  same  importance  as  the  corresponding 
courts  in  England,  as  a  great  part  of  the  juris- 
diction exercised  by  the  justices  in  England  is 
in  Scotland  entrusted  to  the  sheriffs.  In  the 
burghs  of  Edinburgh,  Glasgow,  and  Aberdeen, 
the  magistrates  (who  are  salaried  officials)  have 
the  powers  of  a  sheriff,  and  occupy,  in  fact, 
exactly  the  same  position  within  their  re- 
spective burglis  as  slierilfs  within  their  re- 
spective counties. 

(1)  A  Sheriff  Court  exists  for  each  county 
and  has  an  extensive  civil  and  criminal  juris- 
diction (including  bankruptcy  jurisdiction);  it  is 
presided  over  by  the  sheriff  principal  (formerly 
called  sheriff  depute)  or  by  the  sheriff  substitute  ; 
juries  act  in  criminal  trials  only,  and  even  in 
criminal  trials  the  sherifi"  is  frequently  com- 
petent to  act  without  a  jury.  The  sheriff 
principal  and  sheriff  substitute  are  both  salaried 
judges  and  must  be  trained  lawyers.  An  appeal 
lies  from  the  sheriff  substitute  to  the  slaeriff 
principal,  and  from  the  sheriff  principal  to  the 
Comi;  of  Session. 

(2)  The  High  Court  of  Justiciary  is  the 
supreme  criminal  court  for  Scotland.  The 
judges  of  this  court  are  called  "lords  com- 
missioners of  justiciary "  ;  they  hold  sittings 
with  juries  both  in  Edinburgh  and  in  the 
larger  provincial  towns  (Circuit  Courts).  Since 
1887  every  judge  of  the  Court  of  Session  is  one 
of  the  lords  commissioners  of  justiciary.  The 
lord  president  of  the  Court  of  Session,  as 
president  of  the  High  Court  of  Justiciary,  has 
the  title  of  "  lord  justice  general." 

(3)  Before  the  Court  of  Session,  actions  which 
the  sheriff  is  not  competent  to  try  must  be 
brought  in  the  first  instance;   and   as  regards 

2  G 


450 


COVERTURE— COXE 


all  other  actions,  it  has  a  concurrent  jurisdiction 
with  the  Sheriff  Court.  Its  judges  are  called 
*'  Senators  of  the  College  of  Justice,"  or  **  Lords 
of  Council  and  Session " ;  the  presiding  judge 
has  the  title  "lord  president,"  and  the  judge 
next  to  him  in  rank  is  called  "lord  justice 
clerk."  The  court  is  divided  into  (a)  the  Inner 
House  consisting  of  two  divisions,  presided  over 
respectively  by  the  "lord  president"  and  the 
"  lord  justice  clerk,"  four  judges  sitting  in  each 
division,  three  forming  a  quorum  ;  and  (6)  the 
Outer  House  consisting  of  five  judges  who  are 
called  "  lords  ordinary."  Actions  are  generally 
brought,  in  the  first  instance,  before  one  of  the 
lords  ordinary,  and  may  then  go  to  one  of  the 
divisions  of  the  Inner  House  by  way  of  appeal, 
but  certain  matters  (including  appeals  from  the 
Sheriff  Courts)  must  go  at  once  to  the  Inner 
House.  Actions  of  a  certain  description  coming 
before  the  Court  of  Session  are  tried  with  a 
jury,  but,  on  the  whole,  the  trial  by  jury  of  civil 
actions  is  not  nearly  as  frequent  in  Scotland  as 
it  is  in  England.  e.  s. 

The  Court  of  Session  is  the  superior  court 
in  Scotland :  a  court  both  of  law  and  equity. 
Appeals  lie  from  the  Court  of  Session  to  the 
House  of  Lords. 

In  respect  of  the  administration  of  estates 
the  court  has  the  fuU  powers  of  a  court  of  equity, 
but  in  practice  the  court  interferes  as  little  as 
possible  with  executors  or  with  the  trustees 
under  a  settlement ;  and  when  it  is  necessary 
for  the  court  to  do  so,  or  to  direct  the  adminis- 
tration, it  appoints  judicial  factors,  independent 
administrators,  who  give  security,  are  paid  a 
commission,  and  report  periodically.        A.  D. 

COVERTURE.  A  legal  term  used  to  denote 
marriage  ;  a  married  woman  being  said  to  be 
"under  coverture."  At  common  law  coverture 
merged  the  wife's  personality  in  that  of  her 
husband,  and  the  result  was  that  her  property 
was  governed  by  the  following  rules.  (1)  All 
freeholds  of  which  she  was  seised  at  the  time  of 
marriage  or  afterwards  vested  in  her  and  the 
husband  jointly  during  their  joint  lives,  he 
being  entitled  to  the  control  and  management 
and  to  the  profits,  but  only  able  to  alienate 
with  the  wife's  consent.  On  the  death  of  the 
wife,  the  husband,  under  certain  circumstances, 
took  a  life  interest  in  her  heritable  freeholds. 
(2)  All  chattels  real  vested  in  the  husband,  so 
that  he  could  alienate  them  during  his  life  ;  but 
if  she  survived  him,  and  he  had  not  alienated 
them,  they  vested  in  her.  (3)  Chattels  personal 
vested  in  the  husband  absolutely,  but  if  they 
were  choses  in  action  his  title  only  became  com- 
plete when  he  reduced  them  into  possession. 

The  above  rights  of  the  husband  were  modi- 
fied by  the  equitable  doctrine,  that  if  he  re- 
quired the  aid  of  a  court  of  equity  to  enable 
him  to  acquire  the  property,  such  aid  was  only 
given  on  tlie  condition  that  he  settled  a  portion 
of  the  property  on  the  wife  and  children.     By 


the  Married  Woman's  Property  Act  of  1870  (33 
&  34  Vict.  c.  93)  certain  descriptions  of  property 
which  at  common  law  would  have  vested  in  the 
husband  were  declared  to  be  separate  estate, 
and  by  the  Act  of  1882  (45  k  46  Vict.  c.  75) 
every  woman  married  on  or  after  1st  January 
1883  is  enabled  to  acquire,  hold,  and  dispose  of 
property  as  if  she  were  unmarried.  The  result 
is  that  the  wife's  personality  no  longer  merges 
in  that  of  her  husband,  though  in  some  respects 
she  does  not  possess  the  same  status  as  a  single 
woman. 

[Macqueen's  Law  of  Husband  and  Wife,  3rd 
ed.,  London,  1885.]  j.  e.  c.  m. 

COWELL,  John  Welsford,  author  of 
Letters  to  the  Bight  Hon.  F.  T.  Baring  on  the  In- 
stitution of  a  Safe  and  Profitdble  Paper  Currency, 
1843 — an  automatic  arrangement  for  maintain- 
ing a  gold  reserve,  the  third  (or  some  definite) 
part  of  the  outstanding  notes  payable  on  demand. 
This  idea  is  reproduced  in  Further  Letters  on 
Currency  .  .  .,  1858.  Cowell  contributed,  as 
assistant  commissioner,  to  the  evidence  col- 
lected by  the  poor  law  commissioners,  1834. 

F.  Y.  E. 
COWRIE.  A  shell  found  on  the  shores  of 
the  Maldive  and  Laccadive  Islands,  and  used  as 
small  change  in  Siam,  parts  of  India,  and  on 
the  west  coast  of  Africa.  In  Guinea  2000 
cowries  =  1  macuta,  or  ten-cent  silver  piece, 
which  is  valued  at  4  "Od.  f.  e.  a. 

COXE,  Tench  (1755-1824),  born  in  Phila- 
delphia, Pennsylvania.  Having  entered  on  a 
mercantile  life  he  became  assistant  secretary 
of  the  treasury  in  1790,  and  commissioner 
of  the  revenue  1792-97.  He  early  devoted 
much  attention  to  economic  subjects,  and  in 
1787  wrote  An  Inquiry  into  the  Principles  on 
which  a  Commercial  System  for  the  United  States 
of  America  should  be  foumded;  to  which  are 
added  some  Political  Observations  connected  with 
the  Subject,  Philadelphia,  1787,  pp.  52.  This 
favoured  the  prohibition  of  the  coasting  trade 
to  foreign  shipping  ;  the  importation  of  foreign 
goods  in  the  bottoms  only  of  the  country  produc- 
ing them,  and  in  other  respects  was  influenced  by 
the  commercial  policy  of  England  at  that  time. 
Coxe  also  demanded  special  encouragement  to 
manufactures  and  the  exemption  of  raw  materials 
from  tariff  duties.  In  1792  he  published  an 
Examination  of  Lord  Sheffield's  Observations  on 
the  Commerce  of  the  United  Provinces,  to  prove 
that  Lord  Shefiield  was  wrong  in  his  gloomy 
prophecies  for  the  future  of  the  new  republic. 
These  two  articles  with  others  and  additional 
matter  may  be  found  in  a  View  of  the  United 
States  of  America,  in  a  series  of  papers,  written 
at  various  times  between  the  years  1787  and  1794,; 
interspersed  with  authentic  documents  ;  the  whole 
tending  to  exhibit  the  progress  and  present  state 
of  civil  and  religious  liberty,  population,  agri- 
culture, exports,  imports,  fisheries,  navigation, 
ship-building,   manufactures,   and  general  im- 


CEADOCKE— CREDIT 


451 


provements,  Philadelphia,  1794,  pp.  513.  He 
laboured  energetically  for  the  establishment  of 
cotton  manufactures,  and  is  said  to  have  b'^en 
the  first  to  attempt  to  bring  an  Arkwright 
machine  to  the  United  States.  Among  his 
other  writings  are  Thoughts  on  Naval  Power  and 
the  encouragement  of  Commerce  and  Manufactures, 
1806  ;  Memoir  on  Cultivation,  Trade,  and  Manu- 
facture of  Cotton,  1807  ;  On  the  Navigation  Act, 
1809  ;  and  in  particular  A  Statement  of  the  Arts 
and  Manufactures  of  the  United  States  of  America, 
for  the  year  1810,  Philadelphia,  1814.  This 
latter  was  prepared  under  the  direction  of  the 
government  for  the  census  of  1810,  and  repre- 
sents the  first  extended  attempt  to  make  an 
industrial  census  of  the  country.  The  first 
part  of  this  is  descriptive,  and  the  remainder 
statistical.  As  a  statistical  inquiry,  it  is  almost 
a  failure  as  measured  by  modern  standards. 
His  official  papers,  1790-97,  may  be  found 
in  American  State  Papers,  Finance,  vol.  i. 

D.  E.  D. 

CRADOCKE,  Francis,  author  of  An  Ex- 
pedient for  taking  away  all  Impositions  and  for 
raising  a  Revenue  without  Taxes,  1660  ;  and  of 
Wealth  Discovered  .  .  .  1661.  The  author 
proposes  a  land  bank  with  *'  imaginary  money," 
as  "a  discovery  of  richer  mines  than  any  the 
king  of  Spain  is  owner  of."  This  projector  was 
added  (along  with  Petty)  to  the  king's  council 
on  trade  (  Wealth  Discovered,  flyleaf. ) 

[Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  vol.  ii.  p.  485.] 

F.  Y.  E. 

CRAFT  GUILDS.  See  Corporations  of 
Arts  and  Trades. 

CRAIG,  John,  of  Glasgow,  author  of  Ele- 
ments of  Political  Science,  1814  ;  and  Re- 
marks on  soine  Fundamental  Doctrines  in 
Political  Economy,  1821.  All  Craig's  re- 
marks are  not  so  erroneous  as  his  doctrine  that 
**  value  in  use  must  be  very  accurately  measured 
by  value  in  exchange. "  f.  y.  e. 

CREDIT.  The  fundamental  notion  in  credit, 
as  the  name  itself  implies,  is  trust  or  confidence, 
but  this  characteristic  obviously  needs  limita- 
tion ;  for  the  buyer  of  an  article  must  always 
repose  some  confidence  in  the  dealer  even  when 
the  transaction  is  for  cash,  and  the  practical 
rule  is  caveat  emptor.  There  emerges  then  as 
the  second  principal  characteristic  the  idea  of 
deferred  payment,  taking  payment  in  the  widest 
sense  of  the  term.  A  credit  transaction  involves 
time  before  it  is  completed,  that  is  to  say,  a 
commodity,  or  the  use  of  a  commodity  for  a 
time,  or  service  of  some  kind  is  rendered  now, 
whilst  the  reciprocal  service  or  commodity  is 
given  after  a  specified  interval.  Some  writers 
have  regarded  this  time  element  as  really  the 
primary  characteristic,  because  in  some  species 
of  credit  transactions  there  is  practically  perfect 
security,  and  thus  no  demand  on  the  confidence 
of  the  person  who  makes  the  advance.  It  is 
certainly  useful  to  emphasise  the  time  in  some 


In  this  way,  for  example,  we  understand 
how  the  ecclesiastical  economists  of  the  Middle 
Ages  thought  it  sinful  to  demand  or  receive  a 
reward  on  account  of  deferred  payment,  because 
they  conceived  that  time  in  itself  had  no  value, 
whilst  a  modern  writer  who  looks  on  time  aa 
fundamental  in  the  accumulation  and  use  of 
capital,  has  no  difficulty  in  giving  moral 
approval  to  the  reward  for  Abstinence  {q.v.) 
Historically,  however,  and  to  a  very  great  ex- 
tent in  the  modern  world,  confidence  or  trust 
is  certainly  of  the  essence,  and  not  merely  an 
accident,  of  credit. 

Much  controversy  has  taken  place  as  to  the 
distinction  between  capital,  in  the  sense  of  pro- 
duction capital  (see  Capital),  and  credit.  The 
individual  merchant  or  manufacturer  regards 
his  credit  as  one  of  the  principal  requisites  in 
carrying  on  his  business.  A  manufacturer  with 
good  credit  can  at  once  expand  his  business  to 
meet  a  growing  demand,  whilst  his  inferior  in 
mercantile  standing  must  proceed  more  slowly. 
It  thus  appears  that,  from  the  individual  point  of 
view,  it  is  naturally  regarded  as  giving  increased 
productive  power.  Then,  as  so  often  happens 
in  economics,  a  simple  summation  is  made  of 
the  advantages  of  individuals,  and  credit  comes 
to  be  regarded  as  part  of  the  national  (produc- 
tion) capital,  just  in  the  same  way  as  a  national 
protectionist  policy  is  fallaciously  constructed 
from  considering  the  gains  to  particular  pro- 
tected industries.  It  is  evident,  however,  that 
in  its  simplest  form,  so  far  as  production  is  con- 
cerned, credit  cannot  directly  increase  the  actual 
means  of  production  which  are  potentially  at 
the  service  of  a  nation,  but  can  only  transfer 
the  right  to  use  these  means  from  one  member 
of  the  community  to  another.  Credit  supplies 
in  fact  (as  pointed  out  above)  a  species  of  medium 
of  exchange,  and  logically  the  mere  exchange  of 
products  or  instruments  is  quite  different  from 
the  actual  increase  of  commodities.  Thus, 
credit  in  the  ordinary  sense  of  the  term  cannot 
be  considered  as  part  of  the  national  (production) 
capital. 

But  although  a  sharp  distinction  may  be 
drawn  logically  between  exchange  and  produc- 
tion, it  is  obvious  that  in  a  modern  industrial 
society  exchange  is  practically  a  necessary  part 
of  production.  For  without  exchange  division 
of  labour,  which  is  fundamental  in  production, 
could  not  be  carried  out,  and  without  credit 
exchange  itself,  in  the  present  state  of  society, 
could  not  be  effected  sufficiently  for  division  of 
labour.  Accordingly,  so  far  a  well  organised 
system  of  credit  may  be  regarded  as  one  of  the 
productive  forces  of  industry.  This  is  well  illus- 
trated by  the  occurrence  of  commercial  crises, 
which  for  the  time  being  through  the  collapse  of 
credit  place  a  check  on  the  production  of  the 
nation.  Bagehot  very  justly  ascribed  a  large  part 
of  our  commercial  supremacy  over  continental 
nations  to  the  superior  organisation  of  our  credit 


452 


CREDIT 


At  the  same  time,  however,  it  seems  useful  to 
retain  the  old  distinction  so  sharply  emphasised 
by  Ricardo,  M'Culloch,  Mill,  etc.,  between  the 
actual  material  (production)  capital  and  the 
mere  transference  of  the  right  to  use  that 
capital.  If  this  is  done,  it  will  stiU  be, open 
to  the  economist  to  point  out  the  different 
methods  by  which  indirectly  credit  tends  to 
increase  production  and  also  the  accumulation 
of  capital  (in  the  narrower  sense).  (1)  By 
means  of  credit  capital  finds  its  way  into  the 
hands  of  those  who  can  use  it  to  most  advan- 
tage, as  is  shown  in  the  increased  discount  of 
bills  when  a  trade  begins  to  flourish.  Again 
many  large  undertakings  would  be  impossible 
without  credit,  e.g.  the  construction  of  rail- 
ways, the  improvement  of  lands  by  funds 
obtained  on  mortgage,  etc.  The  return  for 
the  funds  immediately  advanced  must  from 
the  nature  of  the  case  be  deferred.  We  may 
go  further  and  say  that  as  soon  as  we  pass 
from  the  simplest  stage  of  society  in  which  the 
individual  provides  for  his  own  wants,  this 
deferred  element  which  is  the  basis  of  credit 
comes  to  the  front.  The  landowner  must  give 
credit  to  the  mAtayer  and  also  to  the  farmer, 
and  similarly  at  every  stage  of  a  manufacture 
credit  is  given  before  the  finished  product  is 
available  to  meet  the  cost  of  production.  (2) 
By  means  of  credit  also  the  amount  of  national 
capital  available  for  production  is  increased. 
Those  whose  savings  would  be  too  small  {e.g. 
the  working  classes)  if  used  alone,  and  those 
{e.g.  the  professional  classes)  who  cannot  use 
their  wealth  in  material  production,  are  enabled 
by  credit  institutions  and  all  kinds  of  joint- 
stock  associations  to  add  to  the  means  of  pro- 
duction. In  former  times,  as  Adam  Smith 
points  out,  almost  the  only  means  of  employing 
possible  surplus  wealth  was  by  keeping  large 
numbers  of  retainers  who  were  for  the  most 
part  unproductive  consumers. 

The  effects  of  competition  in  increasing  the 
efficiency  of  production  in  spite  of  the  defects 
of  the  entrepreTieur  system,  have  often  been 
pointed  out  {e.g.  by  Walker),  and  even  the 
socialists  often  allow  that  from  the  production 
point  of  view  simply  the  regime  of  competition 
is  perhaps  superior  to  that  of  organised  state 
control.  But  credit  is  evidently  essential  to 
the  full  development  of  competition,  and  the 
growth  of  credit  is  historically  one  of  the  most 
marked  characteristics  of  the  progress  of  society 
from  status  to  contract.  In  nearly  all  contracts 
there  is  a  deferred  element  on  one  side  at  least, 
in  other  words  nearly  all  contracts  involve 
credit,  and  thus  again,  indirectly  at  least, 
credit,  by  giving  play  to  freedom  of  contract 
and  competition,  increases  production. 

Even  taking  the  comparatively  narrow  view 
of  Mill  on  the  relations  of  capital  to  industry, 
we  learn  that  although  industry  is  limited  by 
capital  it  seldom  comes  up  to  that  limit,  and 


we  may  add  the  more  perfect  the  credit  organisa- 
tion the  greater  the  mobility  of  capital,  and  the 
nearer  it  approaches  to  the  limit.  And  when 
we  take  the  wider  definitions  of  capital  (see 
Capital),  now  generally  accepted,  it  seems 
possible  to  include  certain  species  of  credit 
directly  under  capital.  An  effective  system  of 
banking  certainly  increases  the  revenue  not 
only  of  bankers  but  of  the  nation  at  large, 
and  the  "bank  money"  of  the  money  market 
is  to  a  great  extent  purely  the  creation  of 
credit,  and  is  as  efficient  as  actual  coin.  It 
may  of  course  be  said  that  it  is  only  "repre- 
sentative" money,  but  it  is  the  result  of 
highly -skilled  labour  and  of  reservation  for 
future  needs  which  are  the  general  character- 
istics of  capital.  Thus  John  Law  {q.v.)  in  his 
famous  system  was  guilty  not  of  a  direct 
fallacy,  but  rather  of  exaggerating  a  truth 
from  the  theoretical  standpoint ;  and  prac- 
tically, as  he  himself  pointed  out,  he  failed  by 
trying  to  compress  within  too  short  a  time 
what  must  take  generations  for  its  develop- 
ment. Credit  effects  a  very  great  economy  of 
the  national  resources,  and  thus  may  fairly 
come  under  revenue  capital.  Nor  does  this 
view  appear  to  clash  with  popular  usage,  for 
we  find  in  estimates  of  national  capital  that 
account  is  generally  taken  of  the  capital  of 
banks  and  insurance  societies  and  the  like, 
although  strictly,  and  taking  only  material 
(production)  capital,  this  would  involve  count- 
ing the  same  elements  twice  over. 

[Besides  the  treatment  of  credit  in  the  text-books, 
the  reader  may  consult  the  masterly  work  of  Knies 
{Der  Credit),  which  gives  a  critical  historical  sur- 
vey as  well  as  an  original  view  of  the  theory,  and 
the  article  by  Wagner  in  Schdnberg's  HandMch, 
which,  more  Oemianico,  gives  a  complete  biblio- 
graphy up  to  date.  For  the  views  of  Mr. 
Macleod  on  credit  see  his  works.]  J.  8.  N. 

CREDIT.  Influence  on  Prices.  Credit 
supplies  the  means  whereby  the  transfer  of 
wealth  from  one  person  to  another  is  effected  for 
a  period  of  time,  at  the  end  of  which  it  is  restored 
to  its  owner.  Having  given  this  very  general 
description  of  credit,  it  is  necessary  to  be  more 
specific.  Thus,  credit  may  be  given  in  the 
form  of  commodities  transferred  by  a  tradesman 
to  a  customer,  and  paid  for  in  money  after  an 
interval.  In -this  case,  the  "consideration"  for 
the  credit  given  is  sometimes  not  mentioned, 
but  as  a  matter  of  fact  it  is  obtained  by  the 
tradesman  in  the  form  of  an  addition  to  the 
price.  Sometimes  it  is  expressly  understood 
that  when  goods  are  sold,  some  rate  of  interest 
on  the  cash  price  will  be  charged  if  they  are  not 
paid  for  at  once.  This  form  of  credit,  however, 
is  of  little  importance  from  an  economic  point 
of  view,  though  it  is  of  importance  in  other 
ways.  The  only  prices  it  affects  are  retail 
prices. 

The  credit  given  in  wholesale  transactions  is 


CREDIT 


453 


of  much  greater  interest  to  the  economist.  It 
is  a  powerful  agent  for  influencing  prices,  since 
it  gives  rise  to  what  are  known  as  bills  of  ex- 
change (see  Bill  Broking  ;  Bill  of  Ex- 
change), with  all  the  consequences  which 
their  use  brings  with  it.  In  this  case,  how- 
ever, the  credit  is  given,  or  at  any  rate  is 
supposed  to  be  given,  as  the  result  of  a  trans- 
action in  commodities,  that  is  in  real  articles  of 
definite  value  such  as  actual  bales  of  cotton,  or 
cotton  cloth,  pigs  of  iron,  or  other  goods.  The 
biU  is  drawn  by  the  seller  on  the  buyer,  and 
the  buyer  "meets"  it  in  three,  four,  or  six 
months'  time  according  to  the  nature  of  the 
bill.  He  gets  the  money,  however,  at  once, 
by  "discounting"  the  bill  with  his  banker, 
who  keeps  it  until  it  is  due  ;  or  the  drawer  may 
discount  it  with  a  bill-broker  if  he  has  facilities 
for  such  an  operation,  who  in  his  turn  may  sell 
it  to  a  banker,  or  employ  it  as  a  "security  bill " 
in  his  business.  When  any  particular  trade 
is  active  and  profitable,  bills  arising  out  of  it 
appear  in  increased  numbers.  They  not  only 
enable  the  drawer  to  use  the  money  due  to  him 
for  a  sale  at  once,  and  set  the  drawer  free  from 
the  immediate  need  of  finding  money  to  pay  for 
what  he  has  bought,  but  they  may  also  be  used 
as  a  basis  for  a  temporary  increase  of  the  credit 
commanded  by  the  person  who  discounted  them. 
Bill-brokers  sometimes  pledge  bills  they  have 
bought  with  bankers,  as  security  for  a  short  loan, 
and  this  leads  to  the  consideration  of  another 
form  of  credit,  which  is  even  more  effective 
than  bills  as  an  instrument  for  raising  prices. 

Bankers  Advances. — Many  people  suppose 
that  a  banker's  "  deposits  "  are  solely  the  result 
of  the  paying  in  of  money  to  the  customer's 
account.  As  regards  private  individuals  this  is 
so  in  the  main  (see  Deposits),  but  a  consider- 
able part  of  a  business  man's  deposit  is  the 
result  of  advances  made  to  him,  usually  but  not 
always  on  security.  A  successful  manufacturer 
or  merchant  has  no  difficulty  in  getting  such 
advances  except  in  times  of  abnomial  pressure 
in  the  money  market,  sometimes  as  an  "over- 
draft," though  this  mode  of  giving  credit  is 
rarely  adopted  by  banks  in  the  metropolis,  but 
usually  as  a  loan,  provided  he  can  satisfy  his 
banker  that  the  operation  he  wants  the  money 
for  is  a  sound  one.  In  times  of  great  trade 
activity  a  gi-eat  deal  of  the  money  in  the  hands 
of  bankers  is  placed  at  the  disposal  of  enterpris- 
ing men  of  business,  and  in  these  circumstances 
prices  generally  are  apt  to  rise  very  rapidly, 
especially  if  the  men  to  whom  the  advances  are 
made  are  engaged  in  one  or  two  of  the  leading 
trades  of  the  country.  A  considerable  rise  in 
the  price  of  coal  and  iron  is  sure  to  produce  a 
rise  in  most  other  articles  of  commerce,  and 
during  the  middle  stages  of  a  general  rise  in 
prices,  money  is  lent  freely,  and  under  these 
circumstances  the  economic  organism  is  in  a 
state  of  the  highest  efficiency.     Credit  is  then 


at  its  mouxmvwm,  and  exercises  its  fuUest  effect 
on  prices.  Later  on,  when  prices  have  risen 
very  much,  bankers  become  aware  that  the 
total  volume  of  their  customers'  obligations  ia 
larger  than  is  quite  safe,  and  they  therefore 
make  advances  with  more  caution. 

Bank  Notes. — It  used  to  be  thought  that 
bank  notes  were  the  most  powerful  of  all  agents 
for  raising  prices,  but  that  idea  has  long  been 
abandoned,  though  it  has  been  true  where  the 
notes  are  inconvertible.  All  authorities  are 
now  agreed  that  convertible  notes  cannot  be 
over-issued.  Inconvertible  notes  can  be  and 
have  been  over-issued,  but  they  cannot  be  kept 
in  circulation  at  par  unless  their  issue  is  care- 
fully restricted  to  meet  the  actual  needs  of  the 
commercial  community,  as  was  done  with  con- 
summate skill  by  the  Bank  of  France  after  the 
war  of  1870.  An  excessive  issue  of  inconvertible 
notes  may  raise  prices  enormously.  Theoreti- 
cally the  rise  will  be  equal  in  all  articles,  but 
in  practice  some  commodities  are  usually  affected 
more  than  others.  One  peculiarity  of  an  exces- 
sive note  issue  is  that  it  operates  primarily  on 
retail  prices  instead  of  on  wholesale  prices  as 
an  expansion  of  banking  credit  does.  In  some 
countries — in  Scotland,  for  instance — convertible 
notes  are  an  important  part  of  the  machinery 
by  which  the  business  of  bankers  is  carried  on. 
A  person  in  a  small  way  of  business,  for  whom  an 
account  is  opened  by  a  Scotch  bank,  may  take  a 
large  part  of  what  he  requires  in  the  bank's  own 
notes,  which  thus  practically  take  the  place  of 
Cheques.  The  system  works  well  in  Scotland, 
and  it  is  quite  probable  that  it  would  also  work 
in  England,  though  it  is  questionable  whether 
it  is  absolutely  needed,  as  owing  to  the  great 
extension  of  the  cheque  system  any  person  who 
has  a  good  business,  however  small,  can  obtain 
the  support  of  a  banker.  In  any  case  a  sound, 
that  is  a  convertible,  bank  note  issue  cannot  be 
nearly  as  effective  an  agent  for  facilitating  the 
expansion  of  business  as  the  system  of  advances.. 
or  "book  credits,"  as  Mill  called  them.  Such 
credits  are  capable  of  expansion,  limited  only 
by  bankers'  opinion  of  the  solvency  of  their 
customers.  That  opinion  may  at  times  be 
wrong,  and  then  too  much  money  is  lent  to  the 
wi'ong  people,  prices  are  forced  up  too  high,  and 
a  commercial  crisis  ensues. 

Cheques. — The  cheque  system  is  a  necessary 
part  of  the  banking  system,  and  cheques  are 
not,  in  the  first  instance,  a  form  of  credit  at  aU. 
If  a  bank's  customer  merely  draws  against  cash 
actually  deposited  by  him,  it  is  obvious  that 
the  cheques  he  draws  to  pay  debts  or  to  provide 
himself  with  cash  for  daily  use  are  not  credit 
instruments,  except  to  a  very  limited  extent. 
Even  when  a  cheque  is  drawn  against  an  ad- 
vance gi-anted  to  the  customer  by  the  bank,  it 
is  not  the  cheque  which  is  the  instrument  of 
credit  but  the  advance  itself.  But  when,  as  is 
occasionally   the   case,    cheques   pass   through 


454 


CREDIT— CREDIT  FONCIER  OF  FRANCE 


several  hands  before  being  pi-esented  to  the 
bank  on  which  they  are  drawn,  they  become 
instruments  of  credit,  taking  the  place  of  coin 
or  notes  in  the  district  where  they  circulate. 
In  England,  where  a  large  proportion  of  people 
have  banking  accounts,  cheques  do  not  circulate 
long  in  this  way,  for  they  almost  immedilitely 
reach  the  hands  of  some  person  who  pays  them 
into  a  bank,  by  whom  they  are  "cleared"  in 
the  usual  manner,  but  there  is  reason  to  think 
that  in  countries  where  banking  is  less  developed 
than  in  the  United  Kingdom,  cheques  on  banks 
of  great  reputation  are  made  to  do  a  good  deal 
of  work  as  an  aid  to  the  coin  and  note  circula- 
tion. Cheques  on  London  banks  given  to  hotel- 
keepers  on  the  Continent  often  "remain  out" 
for  months,  and  when  finally  cleared  are  covered 
with  the  endorsements  of  the  persons  and  firms 
through  whose  hands  they  have  passed.  Such 
cheques  have,  during  the  period  in  question, 
formed  a  real  addition  to  the  circulation  of  the 
districts  they  have  traversed. 

Foreign  Cheques. — During  the  last  ten  or 
twelve  years  there  has  been  an  important  ex- 
tension of  the  cheque  system  in  connection  with 
foreign  trade,  cheques  drawn  in  Berlin  and 
Paris  on  a  London  banking  house  having  be- 
come negotiable  instruments  payable  at  sight, 
just  like  a  cheque  drawn  in  Manchester  on  a 
London  bank,  so  close  are  the  relations  between 
these  twj  great  capitals  and  London.  A  still 
more  remarkable  feature  of  modern  business  is 
the  use  of  "telegraphic  transfers,"  which  are 
largely  used  in  trade  with  India  and  the  United 
States.  They  are  of  course  merely  orders  sent 
by  bankers  to  their  agents  in  foreign  cities  to 
pay  specific  sums  over  to  certain  persons,  but 
they  greatly  facilitate  the  operations  of  mer- 
chants and  bankers. 

Among  the  arrangements  which  have  faciK- 
tated  the  extension  of  credit  must  be  included 
the  clearing  houses  established  in  London,  Man- 
chester and  New  York  (see  Clearing  Houses  ; 
Clearing  House,  the  London  Bankers',  App. ) 

[Ricardo,  Works  (M'Culloch),  ch.  xxvii. — Mill, 
Political  Economy,  bk.  iii.  ch.  xi.  xii.  and  xiii. — 
F.  A.  Walker,  Money,  pts.  ii.  and  iii. — Bagehot, 
Lombard  Street^  passim. — Adam  Smith,  bk.  ii. 
ch.  ii.]  w.  H. 

CRl^DIT  FONCIER  OF  FRANCE.  This 
institution  is  intended  to  enable  house  and 
landowners  to  raise  money  on  mortgage  at  a 
low  rate  of  interest,  with  facility  of  repayment 
by  an  annuity  including  redemption  of  the 
capital.  The  foundation  of  the  Credit  Foncier 
was  due  to  the  economist  M.  Wolowski.  It 
dates  from  1852,  but  had  been  preceded  in 
1820  by  a  mortgage  bank  called  the  Caisse 
HypotMcairCf  which,  after  a  struggling  exist- 
ence, was  finally  liquidated  in  1846.  The  new 
establishment  was  created  under  governmental 
patronage,  and  invested  with  special  privileges 
which   constituted  a  virtual   monopoly.     The 


original  idea  was  to  found  a  number  of  mort- 
gage banks,  each  with  its  operations  confined 
to  a  prescribed  region.  Three  only  were 
organised,  those  of  Paris,  Nevers,  and  Mar- 
seilles ;  the  last  two  were  afterwards  absorbed 
by  the  first,  the  operations  of  which  were  then 
extended  to  the  whole  of  France.  They  were 
styled  Banques  Fonci^res  with  the  name  of  their 
locality.  On  their  amalgamation  the  subsist- 
ing one  was  at  first  called  the  Banque  Foncihre 
de  France,  but  on  representations  by  the  Bank 
of  France,  which  feared  a  confusion  from  the 
similarity  of  names,  the  title  was  changed  to 
that  of  Credit  Foncier  de  France.  The  opera- 
tions of  this  establishment  were  at  first  re- 
stricted to  loans  on  houses  and  rural  property, 
with  or  without  redemption  by  a  sinking  fund. 
They  were  extended  in  1858  to  loans  for  drain- 
age ;  in  1860  to  Algeria,  and  in  1860  the 
Cridit  Foncier  was  authorised  to  lend  to  towns 
and  departments  for  public  works  and  improve- 
ments. This  last  exteusion  contributed  in  a 
great  measure  to  the  vast  public  works  com- 
menced under  the  empire  and  since  continued. 
The  Grddit  Foncier  was  also  empowered  in  1860 
to  make  advances  in  the  form  of  discounts  to 
the  Sous-Comptoir  des  Entrepreneurs,  a  con- 
tractors' bank,  which  lends  on  mortgage  to 
builders  after  their  work  has  reached  a  certain 
stage,  and  whUe  in  progress  ;  the  Crddit  Foncier 
itself  only  granting  loans  on  houses  when  ready 
for  occupation.  When  the  buildings  are 
finished  the  bills  discounted  by  the  Sov^- 
Comptoir,  and  rediscounted  by  the  Credit 
Foncier,  are  cancelled  by  a  regular  mortgage  to 
the  latter  company.  The  CrSdit  Foncier  patron- 
ised in  1861  the  formation  of  the  Crddit  Agricole, 
instituted  to  make  advances  to  agriculture 
not  authorised  by  its  own  statutes,  and  which 
it  assisted  in  a  similar  manner  by  rediscounts. 
This  involved  the  Cridit  Foncier  in  difiiculties 
in  1876,  the  Credit  Agricole  having  impru- 
dently taken  in  nearly  seven  millions  sterling 
of  treasury  bills  of  the  Egyptian  floating  debt, 
and  passed  them  on  to  the  Credit  Foncier.  The 
Egyptian  government  having  made  default,  the 
Cr&dit  Agricole  had  to  go  intd  liquidation,  and 
was  merged  in  the  Credit  Foncier,  shareholders 
receiving  a  part  of  their  capital  in  new  Credit 
Foncier  shares.  The  Credit  Foncier  absorbed 
in  1882  a  rival  mortgage  bank,  the  Banque 
Hypothicaire,  which  had  been  founded  on  the  ex- 
piration of  the  exclusive  privilege  (granted  for 
twenty-five  years)  of  the  former.  This  led  to  a 
further  creation  of  shares,  and  as  the  business 
of  the  Credit  Foncier  increased,  new  capital  was 
raised,  the  right  of  issue  of  mortgage  and  com- 
munal bonds  being  limited  to  twenty  times  the 
share  capital,  the  amount  of  which  then  rose  to 
£6,820,000,  with  a  limit  of  £8,000,000.  The 
government  exercises  a  direct  control  over  the 
Cridit  Foncier  by  appointing  the  governor  and 
two  deputy-governors.     Decisions  of  the  elected 


CREDIT,  LETTER  OF— CRISES,  COMMERCIAL  AND  FINANCIAL      458 


board  of  directors  must  be  approved  by  the 
governor.  The  Credit  Fonder  enjoys  the  special 
privilege  of  issuing  bonds  which,  in  addition  to 
the  fixed  interest,  give  a  right  to  drawings  ior 
prizes.  Each  issue  of  bonds  with  alottery  requires, 
however,  a  special  authorisation  by  the  govern- 
ment. The  Credit  Fonder  can  only  lend  on  first 
mortgage,  and  to  the  amount  of  one-half  the  estim- 
ated value  of  houses  and  farms,  and  one-third  of 
that  of  vineyards,  woods,  and  other  plantations. 
The  share  capital  is  now  (1914)  £10,000,000 
divided  into  500,000  shares  of  £20  ;  this  may 
be  raised  to  £12,000,000  when  the  bonds  in 
circulation  amount  to  twenty  times  the  share 
capital ;  the  increase  may  be  made  in  one  or  in 
two  operations.  The  rate  of  interest  on  the 
loans  may  not  exceed  by  more  than  60  centimes 
per  cent  the  rate  of  the  return  (interest,  lottery- 
fees,  and  other  charges)  from  the  bonds  in  circu- 
lation at  the  time  Avhen  the  rate  of  interest  on 
the  loans  is  fixed.  The  rate  of  interest  now 
(July  1914)  on  tlie  mortgage  loans  is  4 '85  per 
cent,  without  commission.  The  annual  payment 
(interest  and  sinking  fund)  is  12 '7  4  per  cent 
for  a  loan  to  be  redeemed  in  ten  years  ;  7  '87  per 
cent  in  twenty  years;  5-33  per  cent  in  fifty 
«  years,  and  4 '99  per  cent  in  seventy-five  years. 
The  rates  for  loans  to  the  departments,  com- 
munes, and  local  bodies  is  now  4  '30  per  cent. 
The  total  amount  of  the  mortgage  loans  granted 
since  the  origin  of  the  CrMit  Fonder  (1852)  to 
31st  December  1913  was  £267,112,247;  of 
this  £32,792,993  has  been  paid  off  in  annual 
sums,  £131, 401, 465  has  been  paid  off'  at  earlier 
dates  than  the  time  fixed,  and  £102,917,789 
remains  outstanding.  The  mortgage  loans 
issued  in  Paris  and  in  the  department  of  Seine 
amounted  to  £154,097,492,  and  in  the  other  de- 
partments, Algiers  and  Tunis,  to  £113,014,754. 
The  communal  and  departmental  loans  issued, 
1860-1913,  amounted  to£187,198,535,  of  which 
there  still  remained  to  be  redeemed  (31st  Dec. 
1913)  £94,705,378.  The  nominal  value  of 
the  bonds  in  circulation  at  that  date  was 
£218,641,540  ;  the  balance  in  circulation, 
£178,732,795.  The  charter  of  the  Cr6dit 
Fancier  was  extended  for  ninety -nine  years  from 
1881. 

[C.  Gide,  Prindpes  D' Economic  Politique,  Paris, 
1889;  A.  Courtois,  Histoire  des  Banques  en  France, 
Paris,  1881  ;  A  Hi  story  of  Banking  in  all  the 
Leading  Nations,  New  York,  1896.  Economiste 
Frangais  and  Monde  Economique,  2Mssim.  T.  L. 
CREDIT,  Letter  of.  A  letter  addressed  to 
a  banker,  or  some  other  person  or  firm,  con- 
taining a  request  to  make  payments  or  give 
acceptances  to  a  third  person  or  firm  for  account 
of  the  writer  or  -writers  of  the  letter.  Some- 
times the  letter,  instead  of  being  addressed  to 
I  one  particular  person  or  firm,  is  directed  to  a 
number  of  banks,  with  an  indication  that  all 
payments  must  be  indorsed  on  it  by  the  parties 
eff"ecting  them,   so  as  to   show  what  amount 


remains  unused.  A  letter  of  this  kind  is  called 
a  circular  letter  of  credit.  Circular  letters  ol 
credit  are  also  issued  in  the  form  of  a  request 
to  the  banks  to  whom  they  are  addressed  to 
purchase  the  holder's  drafts  on  the  bank  who 
issued  the  letter,  such  drafts  to  be  drawn  on 
the  forms  which  are  handed  to  the  holders  of 
the  letter  of  credit,  each  of  these  forms  being 
marked  with  a  fixed  amount.  Another  class  of 
letters  of  credit — commonly  called  confirmed 
letters  of  credit — is  much  used  in  mercantile 
transactions  with  foreign  countries.  These 
letters  are  addressed  to  the  person  to  whom 
the  credit  is  granted,  and  contain  an  authority 
to  issue  drafts  up  to  a  certain  amount  on  the 
writer  or  writers  ;  and  also  an  undertaking,  not 
only  as  against  the  drawer,  but  also  as  against  aU 
bona  fide  holders,  to  accept  such  drafts,  pro- 
vided they  are  issued  within  a  certain  time. 
If  the  credit  is  given  for  the  purchase  of  goods 
there  is  a  further  condition  added,  according  to 
which  shipping  documents  of  a  value  corre- 
sponding to  the  amount  of  the  drafts  must 
accompany  or  precede  them.  e.  s. 

CRIMINAL  PROSECUTION  in  Scotland  is 
conducted  by  public  prosecutors,  and  private 
prosecution,  which  cannot  take  place  without 
the  "concourse"  or  concurrence  of  the  lord 
advocate,  is  almost  unknown.  When  a  crime 
has  been  committed,  all  who  are  supposed  to 
be  able  to  give  evidence  are  called  to  testify 
before  a  magistrate  in  private  :  the  suspected 
person  may  also  make  a  declaration,  which  may 
at  once  be  satisfactory  and  entitle  him  to  libera- 
tion ;  if  not,  he  is  at  once,  or  after  further 
examination,  committed  for  trial  before  a  jury 
of  fifteen,  who  acquit,  condemn,  or  find  "not 
proven,"  by  a  majority. 

CRISES,  Commercial  and  Financial. 
Times  of  difficulty  in  commercial  matters  are, 
when  pressure  becomes  acute,  termed  crises. 
The  crises  of  1857  and  1866  will  be  described 
in  some  detail.  The  most  important  ones 
which  have  occurred  since  the  end  of  the  last 
century  likewise  deserve  notice  ;  those  earlier 
than  that  date,  though  historically  of  interest, 
exhibit  features  which  have  little  in  common 
with  the  methods  of  conducting  financial  and 
commercial  business  at  the  present  day.  The 
crisis  of  1792-93,  of  which  Macpherson  {Annuls 
of  Commerce,  vol.  iv.  p.  266)  was  the  his- 
torian, is  described  by  him  as  having  followed 
heavy  investments  "in  machinery  and  in  land 
navigation."  The  number  of  bankruptcies  was 
unprecedented.  "Many  houses  of  the  most 
extensive  dealings  and  most  established  credit 
failed  ;  and  their  fall  involved  vast  numbers  of 
their  correspondents  and  connections  in  all 
parts  of  the  country."  The  usual  features  of 
a  panic  followed.  Temporary  loans  became 
almost  unattainable;  hoarding  followed.  "It 
was  impossible  to  raise  any  money  upon  the 
security  of  machinery  or  shares  of  canals,  loi 


456 


CRISES,  COMMERCIAL  AND  FINANCIAL 


the  value  of  such  property  seemed  to  be  anni- 
hilated in  the  gloomy  apprehensions  of  the 
sinking  state  of  the  country,  its  commerce  and 
manufactures  ;  and  those  who  had  any  money, 
not  knowing  with  whom  they  could  place  it 
with  safety,  kept  it  unemployed  and  locked  up 
in  their  coffers."  At  a  meeting  of  some  of  the 
principal  merchants  and  traders  in  the  city 
(23rd  April  1793)  the  government  was  asked  to 
assist  business  houses  of  real  substantial  stand- 
ing by  advances  of  exchequer  bills.  To  this 
Mr.  Pitt,  then  prime  minister,  agreed :  the 
result  entirely  justified  his  resolution.  "The 
very  first  intimation  of  the  intention  of  the 
legislature  to  support  the  merchants  operated 
all  over  the  country  like  a  charm,  and  in  a 
great  degree  superseded  the  necessity  of  the 
relief  by  an  almost  instantaneous  restoration  of 
mutual  confidence."  A  similar  plan  to  that 
adopted  in  London  was  pursued  in  Liverpool, 
and  parliament  authorised  the  corporation  of 
Liverpool  to  issue  negotiable  notes  to  the 
amount  of  £200,000  in  support  of  the  credit 
of  individuals.  Tooke  mentions  {History  of 
Prices,  vol.  iv.  p.  272)  that  in  1792,  although 
the  bank  rate  of  discount  was  not  reduced 
below  5  per  cent,  the  market  rate  had  fallen 
to,  or  below,  3  per  cent  per  annum,  and  the  3 
pel  cent  consols  had  reached  97^  in  the  March 
of  that  year.  "  This  comparatively  low  rate  of 
interest  had  been,  in  some  degree,  both  a  cause 
and  an  eff'ect  of  the  great  extension  of  the 
country  bank  system,  which  about  that  time 
took  place."  Too  heavy  advances  on  insufll- 
cient  or  inconvertible  securities,  and  an  over- 
stimulated  spirit  of  mercantile  enterprise,  appear 
to  have  been  the  causes  of  this  crisis. 

During  the  year  1796,  and  at  the  commence- 
ment of  1797,  a  severe  pressure  in  the  money 
market,  extensive  failures  of  banks  in  the 
north  of  England,  and  great  mercantile  dis- 
credit prevailed.  The  difficulties  experienced 
were  very  great.  At  a  meeting  held  in  the 
city,  2nd  April  1796,  resolutions  respecting  the 
"alarming  scarcity  of  money"  were  passed, 
and  affirming  "that  this  scarcity  proceeds 
chiefly,  if  not  entirely,  from  an  increase  of  the 
commerce  of  the  country,  and  from  the  great 
diminution  of  mercantile  discount  which  the 
Bank  of  England  has  thought  proper  to  intro- 
duce in  the  conduct  of  that  establishment 
during  the  last  three  months."  A  plan  was 
drawn  up  for  a  board  to  be  constituted  by  act 
of  parliament  for  the  support  of  credit.  They 
were  to  issue  promissory  notes,  payable  six 
months  after  date,  bearing  interest  at  the  rate 
of  £1  :  18s.  per  cent  per  annum,  upon  receiving 
the  value  in  gold  and  silver.  Bank  of  England 
notes,  or  in  bills  of  exchange  not  having  more 
than  three  months  to  run  (Tooke,  History  of 
Prices,  vol.  i.  p.  201).  This  proposal  was  not 
carried  out.  The  pressure  was  aggi-avated  to  a 
great  extent  by  alarms  prevalent  at  the  time. 


The  next  serious  crisis,  taken  in  chronologi- 
cal order,  took  place  in  1810-11.  A  careful 
history  of  the  events  which  led  to  this  disturb- 
ance is  found  in  Tooke  {History  of  Prices,  vol.  i. 
p.  303).  A  great  advance,  and  an  enormously 
high  range  of  prices  in  this  country,  in  1808, 
while  on  the  continent  they  were  low,  through 
the  operation  of  the  same  causes  which  made 
tuem  high  here  (see  Continental  System),  in- 
duced merchants  to  make  great  efforts  to  over- 
come or  elude  the  obstacles  to  trade.  Heavy 
importations  took  place,  a  great  fall  of  prices 
followed,  so  great  that  in  many  instances  the 
importer,  after  paying  for  the  enormous  charges 
on  importation,  was  left  with  nothing  whatever 
to  meet  the  previous  cost.  Simultaneously  a 
total  stop  was  put  to  the  exports  from  this 
country  to  the  Baltic.  Here,  as  Tooke  remarks, 
all  the  incidents  which  lead  to  a  severe  crisis 
were  present.  "So  many  circumstances,  on  so 
large  a  scale,  combining  in  the  same  direction, 
the  fall  of  prices,  the  reduction  of  private  paper, 
and  the  destruction  of  credit,  were  greater  and 
more  rapid  than  were  before,  or  have  since  been 
known  to  have  occurred  within  so  short  a  space 
of  time."  In  August  1810  several  failures 
of  banks,  and  of  important  business  houses 
were  reported  (monthly  Commercial  Report,  1st 
August  1810).  It  is  stated — "speculations  in 
Spanish  wool,  an  article  which  has  fallen  about 
50  per  cent,  are  considered  as  the  origin  of 
those  unlooked-for  disasters.  Five  Manchester 
houses  have  stopped  payment  in  the  city,  and 
we  are  sorry  to  add,  have  involved  numerous 
industrious  persons,  both  in  town  and  country, 
in  their  ruin.  The  demands  upon  the  five 
houses  are  said  to  amount  to  two  millions  ;  but 
it  is  supposed  that  their  real  property  will  ulti- 
mately cover  all  deficiencies.  Speculative  ex- 
ports to  South  America  are  the  rock  upon  which 
these  houses  have  split.  In  consequence  of 
these  unexpected  events,  public  credit  is  at  the 
present  moment  as  low  as  ever  it  has  been  in  the 
memory  of  man."  The  report  continues,  1st 
December  1810 — "A  numerical  evidence  of  the 
present  state  of  trade  may  be  deduced  from  the 
number  of  bankruptcies  in  the  London  Gazette. 
They  amounted — 

This  month  in  1810  to  273 
The  same  month  1809  „  130 
„  „         1808  „  100 

1807,,    97 
1806  „     65 
1805  „    87 
1804  „     60 
besides   stoppages   and  compositions   equal  in 
number  to  half  the  traders   in  the  kingdom ! 
These  failures   throughout   the  kingdom  have 
wonderfully  afffected  the  manufacture  of  every 
description  of  goods  ;   and  a  general  want  of 
confidence  exists  between  the  manufacturer  and 
the   export    merchant"   (1st    January   1811). 
"  In  our  last  report  we  stated  the  vast  increase 


CRISES,  COMMERCIAL  AND  FINANCIAL 


457 


of  bankruptcies  within  the  last  month  compared 
with  similar  months  for  seven  years  back  ;  and 
we  regret  to  say  that  they  still  continue  to  in- 
crease in  number,  and  that  confidence  in  tae 
mercantile  world  seems  nearly  at  an  end.  .  .  . 
In  Lancashire  the  cotton  manufacturers  appear, 
by  the  late  gazettes,  as  well  as  by  private  in- 
formation, to  be  gi'eatly  distressed,  and  business 
quite  at  a  stand.  In  Manchester  and  other 
places  houses  stop  not  only  every  day  but 
every  hour.  Cotton  wool  is  in  no  demand  at 
any  price,  and  no  export  of  the  manufactured 
goods,  except  a  few  fine  sorts  to  Rio,  etc.  The 
trade  of  Birmingham,  Sheffield,  etc.,  quite  at  a 
stand,  and  no  orders  for  execution  there,  except 
a  few  for  our  home  consumption."  A  reference 
to  the  parliamentary  debates  in  the  spring  of 
1811  will  show  that  this  is  no  exaggerated  de- 
scription. A  select  committee  of  the  House  of 
Commons  made  inquiries  into  the  state  of  com- 
mercial credit,  and  reported  that  the  statements 
as  to  the  great  embarrassment  and  distress  were 
founded  on  fact,  and  that  it  "had  arisen  out  of 
great  and  extensive  speculations,  which  com- 
menced upon  the  opening  of  the  South  American 
market  in  the  Brazils  and  elsewhere,  to  the 
adventures  of  British  merchants."  The  chan- 
cellor of  the  exchequer  (Hon.  S.  Perceval)  re- 
ferred to  the  subject  in  his  speech  during  the 
debate  on  the  Commercial  Credit  Bill  ;  and  after 
mentioning  the  report  of  the  select  committee, 
he  continued,  "the  distress,  originating  with  the 
merchant,  and  disabling  him  from  paying  the 
manufacturer,  was  felt  most  severely  by  the 
manufacturer  and  those  employed  by  him.  All 
the  principal  manufacturers  had  been  compelled 
to  contract,  and  some  wholly  to  suspend,  their 
works.  It  appeared  by  the  report  that  there 
was  scarcely  a  cotton  manufacturer  in  the  king- 
dom who  had  not  diminished  by  one  half  the 
number  of  persons  employed  in  his  mills  ;  and 
that  many  of  the  smaller  manufacturers  had  dis- 
charged their  people  altogether."  Those  em- 
ployed by  the  manufacturers  who  still  carried  on 
business  were  retained  at  lower  wages,  and  ' '  the 
most  calamitous  distress  "  is  described  as  prevail- 
ing in  many  of  the  manufacturers'  districts.  The 
commercial  troubles  of  the  time  were  not  con- 
fined to  the  United  Kingdom  ;  the  condition  of 
trade  in  the  United  States  was  fully  as  bad. 
Tooke  quotes  a  letter  from  New  York,  dated 
11th  February  1811,  which  states  that :  "  Such 
times  for  money  were  never  known,  and  all  con- 
fidence among  merchants  is  totally,  and  indeed 
very  justly,  destroyed."  This  crisis  appears  to 
have  been  one  of  great  severity  ;  in  reference  to 
it  and  to  the  further  and  even  heavier  troubles 
of  1825  the  very  artificial  conditions  of  business 
induced  by  the  restrictions  on  trade  imposed  by 
the  great  war  waged  at  the  commencement  of 
the  century  in  Europe,  must  be  borne  in  mind. 
i  Tooke  gives  (History  of  Prices,  vol.  i.  pp.  308- 
I         314)  many  details  of  the  heavy  charges  which 


had  to  be  paid  by  merchants.  Thus  the  freight 
and  insurance  on  hemp  from  the  Baltic  to  London 
was,  1809,  in  some  instances  from  £40  to  £50 
per  ton.  The  charge  of  conveyance  of  silk  from 
Italy  to  Havre  amounted  nearly  to  £150  per  bale 
of  240  lb.  The  following  cases  referred  to, 
occurring  between  1809  and  1812,  are  even 
more  extraordinary.  "The  charges  of  freights 
and  French  licence  on  a  vessel  of  little  more  than 
100  tons  burden,  have  been  known  to  amount 
to  £50,000  for  the  voyage  merely  from  Calais 
to  London  and  back  ;  this  made  the  proportion 
of  freight  on  indigo  amount  to  4  s.  6d.  per 
pound.  A  ship,  of  which  the  whole  cost  and 
outfit  did  not  amount  to  £4000,  earned  a  gross 
freight  of  £80,000  on  a  voyage  from  Bordeaux 
to  London  and  back."  Tooke  says  of  this 
period  (jfftstory  of  Prices,  vol.  iv.  p.  273),  "the 
commercial  distress  and  banking  discredit  of 
1810-11  nearly  equalled,  in  point  of  intensity, 
those  of  1792  and  1825  ;  and  the  losses  caused 
by  the  fall  of  prices  in  1810  were,  I  am  inclined 
to  think,  gi'eater  than  they  had  been  at  any 
former  period.  In  the  stiU  more  violent  fluc- 
tuation of  prices  which  took  place  between 
1812  and  the  close  of  1815,  it  is  possible  that 
the  losses  were  greater  ;  but  there  was  not  then 
any  such  sudden  and  extensive  revulsion  of 
credit  and  commercial  distress  as  occuiTed  in 
1810-11." 

The  next  serious  crisis  occun-ed  in  1825, 
one  of  the  most  severe  through  which  the 
commercial  and  banking  systems  of  the  country 
had  ever  passed.  At  this  date  speculation  ran 
very  high,  for  the  most  part  in  loans  and  min- 
ing adventures,  and  other  investments  abroad. 
The  foreign  exchanges  were  so  much  depressed 
as  to  be  the  cause  of  a  nearly  continuous  drain 
on  the  bullion  of  the  bank.  This  foreign  drain, 
Tooke  remarks,  was  not  counteracted  by  any 
operation  of  the  bank ;  it  was  suffered,  he 
observed,  to  run  its  course,  till  it  ceased  of  its 
own  accord,  that  is  by  simple  eflSux,  towards 
the  close  of  the  summer.  Many  and  heavy 
banking  failures,  and  a  state  of  commercial  dis- 
credit, preceded  and  formed  the  earlier  stage  of 
the  panic.  The  tendency  to  speculation,  and 
the  undue  extension  of  credit,  was  preceded, 
probably  caused,  and  certainly  favoured  and 
promoted,  by  the  Ioav  rate  of  interest  which 
had  existed  for  some  time  previously  ;  and  this 
low  rate  of  interest  was  apparently  prolonged 
by  the  operations  of  the  Bank  of  England. 
Facility  of  banking  accommodation  which  had 
existed  for  some  time  previously,  favoured  un- 
due extension  of  credit. 

This  gradually  led  on  to  the  great  diflaculties 
of  the  year. 

In  the  summer  of  1822  the  bank  reduced  its 
rate  of  discount  from  6  to  4  per  cent.  The 
course  of  the  rate  of  interest  is  marked  by  the 
following  statement  of  the  price  of  the  3  pel 
cent  public  funds. 


458 


CRISES,  COMMERCIAL  AND  FINANCIAL 


1823. 

3rd  April    . 

73h 

,j 

1st  July      . 

80| 

J, 

3rd  October 

82i 

1824. 

1st  January 

86 

)} 

2nd  April    . 

94^ 

28th  „        . 

97|  (the  highest) 

f) 

November   . 

96i 

1825. 

January 

94i 

1826. 

14tli  February 

.      73|  (the  lowest) 

The  great  severity  of  the  pressure  extended 
over  a  very  short  time,  hardly  more  than 
three  weeks.  Some  banking  failures,  princi- 
pally in  the  provinces,  in  the  month  of  Decem- 
ber, were  followed  by  the  failure  of  several 
banks  in  London.  A  severe  drain  on  the 
resources  of  the  bank  of  England  took  place — 
"the  lowest  amount  of  the  bank  treasure  was 
on  the  24th  of  December,  viz., 


Coin 
Bullion 


£426,000 
601,000 


£1,027,000 
"The  accidental  discovery,  for  such  it  was 
said  by  Mr.  Harman,  in  his  evidence  in  1832 
(Bank  Charter  Report,  1832)  to  have  been,  of 
an  amount  of  £1  notes  which  had  been  put 
away  in  the  bank  was,  doubtless,  a  fortunate 
circumstance  ;  for,  although  the  sum  was  not 
large  (between  £700,000  and  £800,000),  it 
«erved  to  meet  the  peculiar  difficulty  of  that 
time,  which  consisted  in  an  extensive  discredit 
of  the  small  note  country  circulation.  And  it 
is  probable  that  it  had  an  immediate  and  very 
great  effect  in  stopping  the  demand  from  the 
provinces  for  gold  "  (Tooke,  History  of  Prices, 
vol.  iv.  p.  343).  Though  the  period  of  pres- 
sure in  1825  was  so  short,  it  had  been  preceded 
by  considerable  and  extravagant  speculations 
in  foreign  loans  and  shares  of  companies, 
mining  and  commercial.  Besides  several  min- 
ing companies  for  operation  in  Mexico,  Chili, 
Brazil,  Peru,  and  the  provinces  of  Rio  de  la 
Plata,  "so  great  was  the  rage  for  speculation 
that,  in  the  course  of  a  very  few  weeks,  in  the 
early  part  of  the  year  (1824),  the  following 
undertakings,  among  others,  were  brought  for- 
ward in  London,  and  found  subscriptions  court- 
ing their  acceptance : — The  Alliance  Fire  and 
Life  Insurance  Company,  with  a  capital 
of  £4,000,000;  the  Palladium  Fire  and 
Life  Insurance  Company,  with  a  capital  of 
£2,000,000  ;  the  British  Annuity  Company, 
whose  capital  was  £3, 000,000;  theMetropolitan 
Investment  Company,  with  a  capital  of 
£1,000,000  ;  the  Thames  and  Isis  Navigation 
Company,  with  a  capital  of  £120,000  ;  an  Ale 
Brewery  Association,  with  a  capital  of  £200,000  ; 
a  company  for  obtaining  from  government  a 
gi-ant  of  a  million  of  acres  in  New  South 
Wales,  and  for  improving  the  growth  of  wool ; 
an  association  for  the  cutting  a  canal  across  the 
Isthmus  of  Darien"  [a  curious  anticipation  of 
the   attempt   made  to  join  the  Atlantic  and 


Pacific  oceans  by  the  recent  Panama  canal]. 
More  than  thirty  private  acts  were  brought 
forward  in  the  House  of  Commons  to  give  effect 
to  these  projects.  "  In  all  these  speculations, 
only  a  small  instalment,  seldom  exceeding  five 
per  cent,  was  paid  at  first ;  so  that  a  very 
moderate  rise  on  the  prices  of  the  shares 
produced  a  large  profit  on  the  sum  actually 
invested."  Tooke  describes  the  spirit  of  specu- 
lation aroused  as  follows.  "This  possibility  of 
enormous  profit  by  risking  a  small  sum  was 
a  bait  too  tempting  to  be  resisted ;  all  the 
gambling  propensities  of  human  nature  were 
constantly  solicited  into  action  ;  and  crowds  of 
individuals  of  every  description — the  credulous 
and  the  suspicious,  the  crafty  and  the  bold,  the 
raw  and  the  experienced,  the  intelligent  and  the 
ignorant ;  princes,  nobles,  politicians,  placemen, 
patriots,  lawyers,  physicians,  divines,  philo- 
sophers, poets,  intermingled  with  women  of  all 
ranks  and  degrees  (spinsters,  wives,  and  widows) 
— hastened  to  venture  some  portion  of  their 
property  in  schemes  of  which  scarcely  anything 
was  known  except  the  names." 

The  extent  of  the  speculative  rise  in  prices  is 
well  shown  by  the  following  instances  of  the 
upward  movement  in  market  prices  of  five  of 
the  principal  mining  companies. 

lOth  December  1824.        11th  January  1825. 

£/£,£/            &  &  & 

Anglo-Mexican    100  sh.  10  pd.  33  pr.     158  115  125 

Brazilian    .     .     100        10        10s,  dis.  66  70  44  pr. 

Columbian .     .     100        10         19  pr.      82  62  59 
Real  del  Monte   400        70       550—1350 

United  Mexican    40        10         35  —    155  115  125 

The  recoil  from  these  speculations  was  inevit- 
able. The  country  banks,  whose  advances  and 
whose  issues  of  notes  had  both  exceeded  the 
limit  of  prudence,  were  among  the  principal 
sufferers.  Several  London  banks  likewise  failed. 
A  remark  made  by  Mr.  Huskisson,  "that  we 
were  within  a  few  hours  of  a  state  of  barter," 
has  often  been  quoted  as  showing  the  severity 
of  the  trial  th>  country  passed  through.  The 
turning  point  appears  to  have  been  in  the  week 
ending  Saturday  1 7th  December  1825.  On  that 
day,  according  to  a  statement  made  by  Mr. 
Richards,  then  deputy  governor  of  the  bank, 
"whether  from  fatigue,  or  whether  from  being 
satisfied,  the  public  mind  had  yielded  to  cir- 
cumstances, and  the  tide  turned  at  the  moment 
on  that  Saturday  night."     The  greater  part  of 

1826  was  a  time  of  considerable  depression,  but  by 

1827  the  trade  and  manufactures  of  the  country 
had  resumed  their  usual  and  steady  course. 

The  monetary  disturbances  of  1836-37  are  not 
included  by  Tooke  among  the  memorable  com- 
mercial crises  (History  of  Prices,  iv.  p.  269). 
"  It  was  confined  in  a  great  measure  to  two 
branches  of  trade,  the  American  and  East  Indian 
including  China.  The  bank  raised  its  rate  of 
discount  to  5  per  cent,  and  laid  some  restric- 
tion upon  the  bills  of  the  American  houses,  who 
were  notoriously  overtrading.     But  for  purposes 


CRISES,  COMMEECIAL  AND  FINANCIAL 


459 


of  trade  generally  there  was  no  want  of  accom- 
modation ;  and  the  utmost  rate  that  was  heard 
of  was  6  and  7  per  cent  for  fair  commercial  bills 
of  moderate  length.  And,  with  the  exception 
above  mentioned,  there  was  depression  in  the 
prices  of  produce. "  The  derangement  of  trade 
in  1836-37,  as  well  as  that  of  1839,  appears  to 
have  been  but  slight. 

Of  a  far  different  character  was  the  crisis 
of  the  year  1847.  As  was  the  case  before 
the  crisis  of  1825  came  on,  a  considerable 
period  of  speculative  activity,  fostered  by  a 
low  rate  for  money,  preceded  this  crisis  also. 
Another  circumstance  has  to  be  noticed.  The 
bank  act  of  Sir  R.  Peel  came  into  operation 
2nd  September  1844.  The  automatic  arrange- 
ment for  the  management  of  the  note  circulation 
which  that  act  introduced  took  away  from  the 
directors  alike  any  power  or  any  responsibility 
for  the  "regulation  of  the  currency"  so  far  as 
this  consisted  of  their  notes.  This  responsi- 
bility being  removed,  the  old  arrangement  by 
which  a  fixed  or  nearly  fixed  rate  of  discount 
was  usually  charged  passed  away  as  well.  The 
demand  for  money  being  extremely  slack  at  the 
time,  a  charge  of  4  per  cent,  as  their  rate  then 
was,  had  kept  the  bank  entirely  out  of  the 
market.  On  5th  September  1844  the  rate  was 
lowered  to  2|  per  cent  for  first-class  bills,  with 
not  more  than  ninety-five  days  to  run,  and  to 
3  per  cent  for  notes.  13th  March  1845,  the 
rate  was  placed  at  2^  per  cent,  both  for  bills 
and  notes,  a  lower  rate  than  had  ever  been  pre- 
viously charged.  The  published  rate  was  also 
for  the  first  time  stated  (March  1845)  to  be  the 
minimum  rate,  and  this  form  of  announcement 
has  been  continued  ever  since.  The  fact  that 
the  bank  competed  now,  practically  for  the  first 
time,  Avith  the  bill  brokers  in  the  open  market 
was  a  very  important  factor.  The  bank  soon 
became  a  large  holder  of  commercial  bills,  and 
exercised  a  gi-eat  influence  accordingly.  ^lean- 
while  several  other  causes  had  contributed  to 
the  stringency  of  affairs  which  deserve  attention. 
Such  causes  are  usually  to  be  traced  to  reasons 
which  have  been  in  existence  for  some  time 
previously.  Previously,  both  in  1 8  2  5  and  1847, 
considerable  reductions  had  been  made  in  the 
interest  paid  on  the  public  funds.  This  had  in 
1825  the  eff"ect  of  turning  people's  minds  to 
foreign  investments.  In  1847  speculation  was 
chiefly  directed  to  the  development  of  railways 
and  other  improvements  at  home.  "In  social 
and  financial  interest  and  importance  railways 
far  surpass  the  other  agencies  of  transport.  The 
creation  of  the  present  century,  they  have  con- 

Itributed  largely  to  promote  its  special  character- 
istics." Prof.  Bastable,  Public  Finance,  London, 
1892,  bk.  ii.  ch.  iii.  §  12.  Up  to  1846  their 
progress  had  been  slow. 
The  amounts  which  parliament  had  authorised 
railway  companies  to  raise  are  given  in  Porter's 


Railway  Capital 

Yearly 
Average. 

£ 

£ 

In  four  years  1826-29 

3,267,000 

817,000 

,,        „       1830-33 

8,629,000 

2,157,000 

„       1834-37 

43,522,000 

10,880,000 

„         „        1838-41 

14,458,000 

3,614,000 

In  two  years  1842-43 

9,173,000 

4,586,0U0 

lu  one  year     1844 

17,870,000 

17,870,000 

„       1845 

60,824,000 

60,824,000 

„       1846 

132,096,000 

132,096,000 

The  enormous  increase  in  this  class  of  expendi- 
ture, after  1841-43,  explains  of  itself  gi'eat  part 
of  the  monetary  difficulties  which  succeeded. 
Tooke  gives  (^History  of  Prices,  vol.  iv.  p.  314) 
an  estimate  of  the  actual  outlay  on  labour  and 
materials  of  railways  about  this  period  which  is 
very  instructive. 

Estimated  Outlay  on  Labour  and  Materials 
(Railways). 

1841  .         .         .  £1,176,000 

1842  .         .         .  2,384,000 

1843  .         .         .  3,548,000 

1844  .         .         .  4,880,000 

1845  .         .         .  11,280,000 

1846  .         .         .  29,188,000 
1847,  first  half-year  20,560,000 

After  an  outlay  which  in  the  first  half  of 
1847  had  been  nearly  two-thirds  of  the  whole 
of  that  in  1846,  this  class  of  expenditure  was 
sharply  arrested.  The  eff"ect  of  these  diff"erent 
operations — (1)  a  sudden  immensely  increased 
outlay  of  capital  on  fixed  investments  ;  then 
(2)  an  even  more  sudden  and  sharp  stop  put  to 
this  outlay — on  the  business  of  the  country  may 
be  well  understood.  Meanwhile,  simultaneously 
with  this  double  derangement  to  the  ordinary 
course  of  transactions,  a  wild  speculation  in  rail- 
way stocks  went  on. 

Some  idea  of  this  may  be  obtained  from  a  very 
careful  paper  read  before  a  meeting  of  the  Sta- 
tistical Society,  January  1847,  by  Mr.  Dawson. 

"Between  March  and  September  1845  joint- 
stock  speculations  for  the  immediate  investment 
of  capital  were  set  on  foot,  involving  a  larger 
aggregate  amount  than  had  ever  before  been  so 
involved  in  this  country.  The  amount  to  raise 
which,  for  railways  alone,  the  sanction  of  parlia- 
ment was  actually  applied  for  in  the  following 
session,  exceeded  £340,000,000  sterling.  And 
if  we  include  all  the  new  schemes  in  which  scrip, 
or  letters  of  allotment,  were  actually  selling  in 
the  market  at  a  premium  in  July,  August,  and 
September  1845,  the  amount  cannot  be  esti- 
mated at  less  than  £500,000,000. 

"Many  of  the  schemes  of  1845  reached  a  high 
premium  within  a  few  weeks  after  their  issue  ; 
and  all  those  first  in  the  market,  and  having 
any  substantial  merit,  were  raised  considerably 
above  their  true  value.  For  instance,  the 
Leeds  and  Thirsk  Railway — £50  shares,  with 
only  a  deposit  of  £2  :  10s.  paid — were  selling  in 
March  at  £3  :  10s.,  in  September  at  £23  :  15s., 
and  in  November  at  £4  :  15s.  per  share.    Again, 


460 


CRISES,  COMMERCIAL  AND  FINANCIAL 


the  Bolton,  Wigan,  and  Liverpool — £40  shares 
with  £4  paid — were  selling  in  January  1845 
at  £4  :  10s.  ;  in  September  at  £42  :  15s.  ;  and 
in  December,  when  £9  had  been  paid,  at  £20 
per  share.  If  we  assume  an  average  premium 
of  £10  per  cent  upon  the  schemes  then  in  the 
market,  the  property  temporarily  created  by 
these  speculations  (and  the  repeated  purchase 
and  sale  of  which,  on  commission,  furnished 
profitable  employment  to  some  thousands  of 
brokers)  must  have  been  at  least  £50,000,000. 

"And  to  this  there  is  to  be  added  an  increased 
value,  during  the  same  period,  of  the  shares  in 
the  established  lines  of  railway.     For  instance  : 

"The  Midland  stock— amount  £4,180,000 
— was  selling  in  January  1845  at  114  per  cent, 
and  in  July  at  188  per  cent ;  showing  a  rise 
of  74  per  cent,  and  an  increase  in  the  aggre- 
gate value  of  the  stock  of  £3,098,000. 

"The  Great  Western — share  capital  issued 
£8,100,000— £100  shares  selling  in  January 
1845  at  £156  ;  and  in  July  at  £228  ;  and 
(allowing  for  a  call  at  £5  per  share  in  the 
interim),  showing  a  rise  of  67  per  cent,  and  an 
increase  in  the  aggregate  value  of  the  shares  of 
£5,467,000. 

"The  Manchester  and  Leeds — share  capital 
£4,660,000 — £100  shares  selling  in  January 
1845  at  £126  ;  and  in  August  at  £215  ;  show- 
ing a  rise  of  89  per  cent,  and  an  increased 
value  in  the  aggregate  of  £4,147,000. 

"The  average  increase  in  the  value  of  £100 
shares  in  these  three  lines  was  £76  ;  and  the 
total  increase  of  value  in  August  and  September 
was  upwards  of  £12,000,000." 

Mr.  Dawson  continues:  "  It  will  be  seen,  on 
reference  to  the  tables,  that  during  those 
months  in  which  the  purchases  and  sales  of 
railway  property  were  most  numerous  and 
extensive,  while  everybody,  was  buying  and 
selling  shares,  and  the  current  rate  of  interest 
was  only  2^  per  cent,  that  portion  of  the 
circulating  medium  which  consisted  of  Bank  of 
England  notes  was  but  very  slightly,  if  at  all, 
increased ;  and  that  it  reached  its  greatest 
amount  when  the  prices  of  shares  were  lowest — 
when  the  number  and  amount  of  current 
transactions  were  reduced  to  the  lowest  point 
by  discredit,  and  when  the  current  rate  of 
interest  for  first-class  bills  had  risen  from  2-J-  to 
4^  per  cent." 

These  last  remarks  of  Mr.  Dawson's  refer  to 
an  important  point  connected  with  this  crisis — 
the  first  authoritative  suspension  of  the  bank 
act  of  1844,  and  also,  incidentally,  to  the 
question  of  the  connection  between  the  circula- 
lation  of  notes  and  periods  of  commercial  crisis. 
Reference  will  be  made  to  this  further  on. 
Meanwhile  other  complications  occurred. 

The  failure  of  the  potato  crop  in  1846 
caused  the  need  for  a  heavy  importation  of 
corn.  "The  price  of  corn  was  very  high  in 
1847,  the  average  in  May  being  92s.  lOd.  per 


quarter,  but  the  imports  rose  in  proportion. 
In  the  three  years  from  1845  to  1847  they 
were  as  follows : 


1845 

1846 

1847 

Wheat   

Cwts. 

8,777,140 

945,864 

241,667 

Cwts. 
6  207  894 

Cwts. 
11  fin  sn?i 

Wheatmeal  and  Flour 
Maize 

3,190,4291   6,329,058 
18,024,883  lift  'ifi'i  lO'l 

r '    '     1 

The  corn  merchants,  who  for  some  time  had 
great  difficulty  in  obtaining  advances  upon 
cargoes  in  consequence  of  the  high  rate  of  dis- 
count, lost  immense  sums  from  the  great  fall 
in  prices  which  took  place,  owing  to  the  pro- 
spect of  an  abundant  harvest.  And  the  result 
was  the  failure  of  many  houses  in  the  com 
trade,  which  became  the  signal  for  other  heavy 
bankruptcies.  Several  banks  succumbed,  and 
credit  was  severely  shaken"  (L.  Levi,  History 
of  British  ComTnerce,  p.  310). 

The  fluctuations  in  the  rate  charged  by  the 
bank  were  very  considerable,  and  were  the  more 
noticed  at  the  time  as  nothing  exactly  similar 
had  ever  occurred  before. 

On  1st  January  1847  the  notice  of  27th 
August  1846,  fixing  the  minimum  rate  at  3 
per  cent  per  annum  on  95  days  bills,  was  still 
in  force. 

1847.      Per  cent. 
14th  Jan.       3^  minimum  on  95  days  bills. 
21st     „         4 

8th  April     5  ,, 

15th     ,,        5    omitting  all  stipulation  as  to  the 
term  of  the  paper. 
2nd  Aug.     5    on  1  month  bills ;  5^  on  2  months ; 

6  per  cent  above  2  months. 
5th     ,,        5^  minimum  rate. 
2Qd  Sept.     5    on  loans  till  14th  Oct. 
23rd    ,,        5^  on  2  months  bills  ;  6  per  cent  on 
3  months, 
1st  Oct.       5^  on  everything  falling  due  before 
14th  Oct.,  and  total  refusal  to 
advance  on  public  securities. 
25th   „         8    minimum  rate  under  authority  oi 
the  government  letter  of  this  date. 
22nd  Nov.     7    minimum  rate. 

2nd  Dec.      6 
23rd    ,,        5  „ 

1848. 
27th  Jan.      4  ,, 

The  announcement  of  1st. October  that  no 
advances  would  be  made  on  public  securities 
produced  (see  Economist,  9th  October  1847)  a 
severe  panic  on  the  stock  exchange.  There 
was  no  failure  of  a  bank,  however,  except 
that  of  Cockbums  and  Co.  of  Whitehall,  tiU 
13th  October,  when  Knapp  and  Co.  of  Ai3ing- 
don  suspended  payment.  On  18th  October 
the  Royal  Bank  of  Liverpool  stopped  ;  before 
23rd  October  other  important  banking  failures 
took  place  at  Liverpool,  Manchester,  Newcastle, 
and  in  the  West  of  England.  3  per  cent  consols, 
which  had  stood  at  84^  on  5th  October,  were 


CRISES,  COMMERCIAL  AND  FINANCIAL 


461 


by  this  time  77|,  the  lowest  point,  and  a  total 
suspension  of  all  business  and  all  payments  was 
imminent.  The  reserve  of  the  bank  was  reduced 
to  a  very  low  ebb. 


1847. 

Reserve  of  Specie 

16th  Oct. 

.      £3,070,000 

23rd    „ 

1,990,000 

30t]i    „         . 

1,600,000 

Meanwhile  the  anxiety  and  alarm  prevailing 
were  causing  a  general  hoarding  of  coin  and 
bank  notes,  and  it  really  appeared  not  unlikely 
that  the  banking  department  of  the  Bank  of 
England  might  be  compelled  to  stop  payment 
while  there  was  more  than  £6,000,000  of  specie 
in  the  issue  department.  The  chancellor  of  the 
exchequer  (Sir  C.  Wood,  afterwards  Lord  Halifax) 
was  urged  by  many  deputations  and  remon- 
strances to  relax  the  bank  act,  but  he  declined. 
At  last,  on  22nd  or  23rd  October,  some  of  the 
leading  city  bankers  had  an  interview  with 
the  prime  minister  (Lord  John,  afterwards  Earl 
Russell),  and  on  their  explaining  the  necessities 
of  the  position,  the  desired  relaxation  was  given. 
The  official  letter  (25th  October)  recommended 
"the  directors  of  the  Bank  of  England,  in  the 
present  emergency,  to  enlarge  the  amount  of 
their  discounts  and  advances,  upon  approved 
security."  A  high  rate,  8  per  cent,  was  to  be 
charged,  to  keep  these  operations  within  reason- 
able limits  ;  a  bill  of  indemnity  was  promised  if 
the  arrangement  led  to  a  breach  of  the  law. 
The  extra  profit  derived  was  to  be  for  the  bene- 
fit of  the  public.  No  really  adequate  reason 
has  ever  been  given  for  this  last  stipulation, 
unless  it  is  supposed  to  have  been  made  to  pre- 
vent the  bank  from  maintaining  the  extra  rate 
unduly  long. 

The  effect  of  the  government  letter  in  allay- 
ing the  panic  was  complete.  When  anxiety  as 
to  obtaining  bank  notes  or  gold  was  removed, 
the  immediate  pressure  shortly  disappeared. 
Speaking  in  the  House  of  Commons,  during  the 
debate  of  30th  November  on  this  subject,  the 
chancellor  of  the  exchequer  (Sir  C.  Wood) 
stated  that  the  tenor  of  the  remarks  made  by 
those  who  applied  to  him  was  **  Let  us  have 
notes"  .  .  .  **We  don't  mean  indeed  to  take 
the  notes,  because  we  shall  not  want  them  ; 
only  tell  us  that  we  can  get  them,  and  this  will 
at  once  restore  confidence." 

The  space  which  can  be  allowed  here  to  this 
subject  does  not  permit  further  details  being 
given.  It  should  be  observed  that  the  earlier 
crises  than  the  last  one  mentioned  here,  that  of 
1847,  weie  all  so  greatly  influenced  by  the 
highly  artificial  condition  both  of  trade  and 
credit,  caused  by  the  terrible  wars  of  the  com- 
mencement of  the  century,  that  the  lessons  to 
be  drawn  from  them  are,  comparatively  speaking, 
inapplicable  to  the  business  circumstances  of 
the  present  time.  The  commercial  histories  of 
that  period,  including  the  admirable  one  con- 


tained in  Tooke  and  Newmarch's  History  oj 
Prices,  are  fuU  of  remarks  on  the  questions  how 
far  the  crises  were  brought  on,  or  increased  in 
severity,  by  the  issues  of  notes  made  by  the 
country  bankers  at  that  period.  That  those 
banks  em^iloyed  their  own  credit  frequently 
unwisely  there  is  no  doubt,  and  equally  that 
they  frequently  gave  credit  unwisely  to  traders 
on  inadequate  security.  Notes  were  at  that 
date  the  recognised  medium  in  which  advances 
were  made  ;  and  that  there  was  by  all  banks, 
including  the  Bank  of  England,  at  times  an 
over-issue  of  the  circulating  medium  may  be 
conceded.  It  is,  however,  matter  for  fair  dis- 
cussion whether  any  statesman  nowadays  would 
have  arranged  the  bank  act  of  1844  on  the 
principles  of  Peel,  or  whether  it  is  advisable  to 
concentrate  the  whole  of  the  issues  on  one  bank, 
however  powerful  and  well-organised. 

Commercial  crises  may  take  place  without  any 
reference  to  the  circulating  medium,  as  has  been 
exemplified  in  Hamburg  and  elsewhere.  They 
can  only  be  averted  or  mitigated  by  the  judg- 
ment of  those  with  whom  the  guidance  of  com- 
mercial affairs  and  of  the  banking  institutions 
of  the  country  rests  at  the  time. 

[The  periodicity  of  crises  has  frequently  been 
noticed.  Mr.  Wm.  Langton,  in  his  paper  "  Ob- 
servations on  a  Table  showing  the  Balance  of  Ac- 
count between  the  Mercantile  Public  and  the  Bank 
of  England,"  Trarisactions  of  Manchester  Statis- 
tical Society,  1857-58  (reprinted  also  in  the 
Transactions,  1875-76,  Appendix),  has  made 
valuable  remarks  on  the  subject. — Mr.  John  Mills 
("Paper  on  Credit  Cycles,"  Transactions  of  the 
Manchester  Statistical  Society,  18(37-68),  has  shown 
the  connection  between  these  periods  and  the  vari- 
ations of  personal  feeling. — Also  paper  by  H. 
Chubb  [Statistical  Society  Journal,  June  1872), 
"Bank  Act  and  Crisis  of  1866.— Prof.  Jevons 
{Investigations  in  Currency  and  Finance,  pp.  153, 
203-8),  has  shown,  with  his  customary  ingenuity  of 
research,  that  the  period  of  credit  cycles  and  of  the 
solar  cycles  of  maximum  intensity  coiTespond 
with  considerable  exactness.  The  frequent  recur- 
rence of  periods  of  excitement  and  depression  in 
monetary  and  commercial  matters  is  likewise  re- 
ferred to  by  Mr.  James  Wilson,  Fluctuations  oJ 
Currency,  Commerce,  and  Mamifacture,  referable 
to  the  Corn  Laws.  We  must  be  careful  not  to 
yield  to  the  belief  that  post  hoc  is  identical  with 
propter  hoc  in  these  matters  ;  but  this  subject  is 
eminently  one  in  which  careful  historical  investi- 
gation may  be  expected  to  produce  useful  and 
practical  results.  For  earlier  history,  Macpherson, 
Annals  of  Cominerce  (4  vols.  London,  1805). — 
Anderson,  Origin  of  Commerce  (4  vols.  London, 
1801). —  Select  Tracts  on  Commerce  and  Early 
Tracts  on  Commerce,  reprinted  and  edited  by 
J.  R.  M'Culloch,  1856-1859,  may  also  be  con- 
sulted.— Max  Wirth,  Geschichte  der  Handelskrisen, 
Frankfurt  am  Main,  1891. — D.  Morier  Evans, 
Commercial  Crisis,  1847-48  (published  1848).— 
D.  Morier  Evans,  Commercial  Crisis,  1857-58 
(published  1859). — C.  Juglar,  Des  Crises  Com- 
merciales,  Paris,  1889.] 


462 


CRISES,   1857-1866-1890 


CRISES,  1857-1866-1890.  The  early  panics 
of  the  present  century  having  been  described 
above,  our  attention  will  be  confined  here  par- 
ticularly to  the  events  of  1857,  1866,  and  1890. 

One  of  the  most  remarkable  and  instructive 
facts  is  negative,  viz.  that  there  has  been  really 
no  panic  in  England  since  1866.  The*  differ- 
ence between  the  events  of  that  year  and  what 
occurred  in  1890  will  be  explained  later  on. 
It  was  formerly  regarded  as  almost  a  law  of 
nature  that  a  crisis  should  arise  every  ten  years 
or  thereabouts,  and  the  years  1825,  '37,  '47,  '57, 
and  '  6  6  confirmed  this  impression.  But  since  the 
last  date,  with  the  exception  of  some  alarm  in 
1878  (when  the  City  of  Glasgow  and  the  West 
of  England  Banks  collapsed  under  circumstances 
calculated  to  cause  such  disquietude  as  would  in 
former  times  have  caused  alarm  if  not  panic), 
though  there  have  been  many  changes  in  busi- 
ness, and  a  huge  development  of  trade,  we  had 
no  crisis  until  November  1890.  This  last  crisis 
differed  much  from  previous  disturbances  of 
credit.  In  former  times  alarm  was  diffused 
over  the  whole  kingdom  ;  London  was  drained 
of  its  reserves  to  fill  up  the  wants  of  the  country, 
and  the  imprudences  of  banks  having  caused  or 
aggravated  alarms,  there  was  a  general  uneasi- 
ness in  the  banking  world  and  a  consequent 
increased  holding  of  cash,  and  an  indisposition 
to  grant  assistance  to  the  trading  world.  But, 
on  this  last  occasion  there  was  no  general 
alarm  in  the  country.  Banks  outside  London 
were  hardly  sensible  of  the  crisis,  and  even  in 
London  there  was  no  panic  except  in  Capel 
Court.  No  bank  failed  in  town  or  country, 
and  no  suspicion  of  danger  to  banks  seems  to 
have  existed  amongst  their  customers.  Some 
great  issuing  houses  lost  their  position,  and 
narrowly  escaped  suspension.  Enormous  losses 
fell  on  the  public,  but  not  on  banks,  except 
indirectly.  It  was  not  a  panic  as  involving 
general  alarm  amongst  the  public,  but  a  crisis 
in  special  directions,  which  might  easily  have 
extended,  so  as  to  have  caused  such  a  panic  as 
never  yet  has  occurred  in  any  country.  The 
danger  was  prodigious,  but  it  was  averted. 

In  former  crises  the  danger  was  not  averted, 
and  things  were  allowed  to  drift,  so  that  great 
houses  and  banks  failed,  and  general  alarm 
ensued.  In  this  case,  no  great  house  suspended, 
though  Barings,  one  of  the  greatest  of  all,  went 
into  liquidation.  Instead  of  a  huge  lock  up  of 
mercantile  capital  in  unpaid  documents,  busi- 
ness was  carried  on  without  any  serious  incon- 
venience to  any  one  ;  and  it  may  be  fairly  said 
that,  for  all  practical  purposes,  nothing  was 
known  of  the  crisis  in  the  country  at  large, 
until  all  was  over. 

In  some  respects  all  crises  are  alike,  inas- 
much as  all  such  events  arise  from  what 
is  called  an  "abuse  of  credit."  But  that 
abuse  may  take  various  forms.  Sometimes 
the  vagaries  of  banks  in  lending  enormous  sums 


without  any  security  that  can  be  realised,  have 
caused  the  trouble.  At  other  times,  as  for 
instance  in  the  case  just  referred  to,  great 
investments  by  the  public  in  stocks  which  are 
worthless,  or  much  depreciated,  have  had  a 
similar  effect  in  arousing  exaggerated  alarms. 
The  causes  varying,  the  results  also  vary  much. 

Of  course,  if  the  errors  of  banks  start  the 
anxiety,  it  is  natural  that  other  banks  should 
feel  the  effects  more  than  merchants  who  have 
nothing  to  do  with  the  matter,  except  that 
they  suffer  for  the  mistakes  of  others.  If,  on 
the  other  hand,  as  in  1890,  mercantile  impru- 
dence originated  the  mischief,  then,  most  natu- 
rally, mercantile  credit  is  affected  more  than 
that  of  banks,  who  may  suffer,  but  not 
deservedly. 

A  glance  at  the  peculiar  features  of  the 
several  crises  above  mentioned  will  illustrate 
what  has  been  here  stated,  and  will  bring  out 
more  clearly  those  resemblances  and  differ- 
ences which  tend  to  throw  light  on  the  whole 
subject. 

It  is  not  very  easy  to  define  how  far  credit 
may  extend  safely,  but  it  is  very  clear  that 
during  the  years  1855  and  1856  the  extension 
of  credit  was  enormous  and  dangerous.  It  has 
been  somelJimes  asserted,  though  there  is  no 
way  of  testing  the  truth  of  the  assertion,  that 
during  the  years  in  question  there  were  as  many 
bills  offered  for  discount  in  Lombard  Street  as 
there  are  now,  though  the  real  volume  of  trade 
has  vastly  increased  since  1857,  the  total  of  the 
imports  and  exports  being  unitedly  £311,764,000 
in  1856,  and  £748,944,000  in  1890.  In  those 
times  it  was  a  common  thing  for  banks  in 
manufacturing  districts  to  send  great  masses  of 
bills  to  London  for  rediscount,  i.e.  bills  taken 
by  the  banks,  but  which  they  were  unable  to 
hold  to  maturity  from  their  own  resources. 
The  amount  of  this  business  in  1856  and  1857 
was  enormous,  and  even  after  the  panic  of  that 
year,  when  many  bills  came  to  an  end  by  failures 
of  traders  and  of  bankers,  the  amount  of  redis- 
counts by  banks  continued  to  be  very  large. 
But,  at  this  moment,  that  business  has  almost 
come  tc  an  end.  It  was  much  reduced  after 
1866,  and  it  is  now  confined  within  narrow 
and  perfectly  legitimate  limits.  In  fact  most 
of  the  banks  which  in  1857  were  borrowers  in 
London  are  now  large  depositors  there. 

Those  who  are  too  young  to  remember  1857 
would  not  find  it  easy  to  imagine  the  condition 
of  things  which  then  existed.  The  reserve  of 
the  Bank  of  England  may  be  said  to  have  been 
continually  at  danger  point  (the  amounts  in 
the  autumn  of  1857  are  given  in  the  table  that 
follows),  although  the  daily  transactions  in 
Lombard  Street  were  large  and  important. 
The  demands  were  often  heavy,  as  we  have 
said,  but  the  reserve  was  miserably  small.  It 
was  a  common  thing  for  the  largest  operators  in 
bills  to  keep  practically  no  reserve  whatever, 


CKISES,  1857-1866-1890 


463 


and  to  depend  on  application  to  the  Bank  of 
England  for  the  supply  of  their  wants.  The 
average  rate  of  interest  paid  on  loans  and  dis- 
counts was  very  high,  and  though  it  is  true  that 
no  prudent  trader  was  ever  killed  by  interest 
paid  on  borrowed  money,  it  is  clear  that  in  a 
condition  of  things  when  traders  generally  were 
large  borrowers,  the  existence  of  a  very  high 
rate  of  discount  was  one  of  those  circumstances 
which  combined  to  create  an  electrical  and  ex- 
citable condition  in  men's  minds,  so  that  alarm 
and  panic  were  very  liable  to  supervene. 

The  immediate  cause  of  panic  is  of  course  the 
fear  on  the  part  of  borrowers  that  they  will  not 
be  able  to  secure  what  they  need,  accompanied 
by  a  fear  on  the  part  of  lenders  of  giving  what, 
in  ordinary  times,  they  would  grant  with 
pleasure.  This  fear  arises  in  different  ways  on 
different  occasions.  It  may  be  caused  by  heavy 
failures  making  even  the  solvent  anxious  as 
to  their  future,  for  all  traders  have  payments 
for  which  they  must  provide.  Or  it  may  arise 
from  the  condition  of  the  Bank  of  England,  as 
her  accounts  are  periodically  published,  and 
are  supposed  to  tell  all  the  world  what  may  be 
expected  as  to  borrowing  and  lending.  How- 
ever small  may  be  the  reserve  kept  by  other 
operators,  "the  bank "  is  expected  to  be  ready  for 
every  emergency,  and  if  her  reserve  should  be 
depleted,  every  one  gets  alarmed  and  desires  to 
provide  without  delay  against  a  very  uncertain 
future.  So  it  comes  about  that  adverse  ex- 
changes combine  with  internal  alarms  to  reduce 
the  surplus  notes  of  the  bank,  and  this  condi- 
tion adds  to  the  demands  upon  her  just  when 
she  is  least  able  to  meet  them.  Under  our 
system,  however  great  the  pressure,  she  cannot 
take  a  sovereign  from  her  issue  department. 
The  gold  held  there  is  as  sacred  as  if  deposited 
at  Westminster  in  the  custody  of  the  govern- 
ment. The  bank,  therefore,  raises  the  rate  of 
interest,  so  as  if  possible  to  attract  gold  from 
other  countries.  That  movement  cannot  oper- 
ate at  once,  but  the  fact  of  her  taking  such 
action  is  quickly  effective  in  increasing  alarms 
outside.  Demands  increase  still  more,  so  that 
the  bank  has  recourse  to  restrictions  in  one 
form  or  another — restrictions  which  only 
aggravate  panic,  until  at  last  the  bank  must 
either  collapse  as  a  bank,  and  cease  to  make 
advances,  or  must  obtain  extraordinary  powers, 
so  that  she  may  allay  alarm  by  a  greater 
freedom  in  her  operations. 

So  marked  has  been  the  influence  of  these 
considerations  during  recent  panics,  that  some 
writers  have  been  disposed  to  attribute  our 
present  liability  to  these  alarms  to  the  change 
made  in  our  currency  laws  in  1844,  when  the 
two  departments  of  the  bank  were  separated, 
and  the  old  elasticity  of  the  issues  of  the  bank 
was  replaced  by  a  hard  and  fast  limit  depend- 
ent on  supplies  of  bullion.  But  the  answer  to 
tnia  suggestion  is  very  simple,  viz.  that  our 


panics  before  1844  were  probably  far  more 
severe  than  those  which  have  occurred  since, 
and  that  for  forty-six  years  since  1866,  with 
the  same  law,  we  have  had  no  proper  panic. 
In  1837  the  bank  was  very  nearly  denuded  of 
gold,  her  issue  of  notes  not  being  restricted, 
whereas  since  1844  she  has  never  been  deprived 
of  a  large  reserve  in  the  issue  department,  a 
reserve  not  available  without  special  authority 
from  government,  but  still  a  reserve  which  is 
available,  and  has  been  found  ample  for  every 
emergency  of  modern  times.  Alike  in  1847, 
1857,  and  1866,  a  letter  from  the  chancellor 
dissipated  the  panic  as  by  the  wand  of  a 
magician.  Once  remove  the  fear  of  a  complete 
break-down,  and  panic  passes  away  far  more 
quickly  than  it  arose.  It  is  astonishing  how 
soon  all  real  alarm  disappears,  and  business 
resumes  an  ordinary  course.  High  rates  of 
discount  may  prevail  for  some  time,  but,  sooner 
or  later,  they  too  disappear,  and  "  confidence  is 
restored, "  until  a  renewal  of  commercial  blunders 
or  follies  brings  about  a  renewal  of  discredit 
and  consequent  alarm. 

The  following  table  shows  the  rapid  change 
which  arises  as  soon  as  the  panic  has  subsided : — 

000  omitted  in  cols.  2  and  3.   Figures  from  nearest  return, 


1 

2 

3 

4 

Gold 

Rate  of 

Tear  and  Month.;: 

Bullion 

Reserve 

Discount 

in  Bank. 

of  Notes. 

per  cent. 
5h 

September  4, 1847 

£7,374 

£4190 

October  2,         „ 

7,117 

3409 

6 

November  6,    „ 

7,248 

2030 

8 

December  4,     „ 

9,111 

5583 

6 

January  1,     1848 

10,444 

7866 

5 

Septembers,  1857 

10,836 

6065 

54 

October  3, 

10,078 

4606 

5i 

November  4,    „ 

7,947 

2155 

8 

„        11,    „ 

6,666 

957 

10 

„        18,    „ 

6,079 

11481 

10 

„       25,    „ 

6,784 

1918 

lO 

December  2,     „ 

6,896 

2268 

10 

January  6,     1858 

12,113 

7089 

8 

March  7,    1866 

13,151 

7416 

7 

April  4,        „ 

13,486 

6153 

6 

May  2, 

12,712 

4839 

6 

June  6,         „ 

12,620 

2167 

10 

July  4, 

14,148 

3336 

10 

August  1,     „ 

12,932 

2412 

102 

1  £2,000,000  was,  under  authority  of  Treasury  letter, 
12th  November  1857,  added  to  the  securities  in  the 
issue  department,  in  the  returns  from  18th  November 
to  23rd  December  1857,  both  inclusive.  The  strict 
limits  of  the  Act  of  1844  were  only  exceeded  in  the 
returns  of  18th  and  25th  November  1857.  They  were  not 
exceeded  in  1847  and  in  1866.  Tradition,  founded  on  a 
statement  made  by  the  late  Mr.  William  Newmarch, 
reports  that  they  would  have  been  exceeded  in  1S66  had 
not  the  banks  in  the  city  repaid  to  the  Bank  of  England 
every  evening,  during  the  worst  of  the  crisis,  the  notes 
which  they  had  drawn  out  in  the  day. 

S  Reduced  to  8  per  cent  16th  August. 


464 


CRISES,  185V-1866-1890 


So  far  the  features  of  both  the  panics  now 
under  consideration  are  very  similar.  The 
difference  is  more  one  of  detail  than  of  principle. 
In  both  there  was  the  high  rate  of  discount 
following  adverse  exchanges,  and  great  demands 
for  accommodation  by  traders.  In  both  there 
was  the  depletion,  more  or  less  rapid,  "of  the 
bank  reserve,  and  finally  the  heavy  failures  and 
the  consequent  alarms,  ending  in  a  sort  of 
"stampede"  or  "sauve  qui  peut,"  if  one  may 
use  such  expressions  in  this  place.  In  neither 
case  did  a  single  solvent  firm  succumb,  though 
in  both  cases,  and  especially  in  1857,  more  than 
one  solvent  house  escaped  as  by  a  sort  of 
miracle. 

Of  course  the  panic  of  1866  was  marked  by 
the  great  failure  of  the  almost  historic  house  of 
Overend,  Gumey,  &  Co.,  and  by  that  memor- 
able "Black  Friday,"  when  it  seemed  likely 
that  confidence  might  be  utterly  lost,  whereas 
in  fact  it  was  maintained  in  a  truly  astonish- 
ing way.  Lombard  Street  was  given  over 
to  an  excited  crowd  who  did  not,  however, 
withdraw  their  deposits,  if  they  had  any,  and 
the  day  passed  off  with  most  trifling  results 
as  compared  with  the  fears  that  pervaded  the 
minds  of  many  experienced  persons.  But  the 
panic  of  1857  was  in  one  way  more  striking  and 
more  serious  than  that  of  1866,  inasmuch  as  it 
was  as  widespread  in  America  as  it  was  in  the 
United  Kingdom,  and  in  fact  began  in  New 
York.  But  these  differences  are  not  of  first-rate 
importance.  The  grand  distinction  between 
the  two  panics  is  that  already  mentioned,  viz. 
that  in  the  former  no  warning  was  taken,  and 
the  panic  was  followed  in  a  few  years  by  another 
equally  severe,  while,  in  the  latter  case,  the 
lesson  seemed  to  have  been  taken  to  heart,  the 
excessive  credit  was  cut  down,  and  the  era 
of  panics  seemed  to  have  passed  away.  Why 
this  should  be  so  is  not  very  clear.  Some  say 
that  the  disappearance  of  Overend,  Gurney,  & 
Co.,  and  their  friends  is  one  great  cause  of 
the  change.  Without  refusing  to  give  some 
weight  to  this  fact,  it  is  difficult  to  suppose 
that  this  can  be  the  only  cause  of  so  remarkable 
a  contrast.  It  seems  more  rational  to  say  that 
the  tremendous  lessons  of  1857  and  1866  were 
not  lost  on  the  financial  or  the  mercantile  world, 
and  that,  as  a  result,  credit  has  been  maintained 
on  a  far  sounder  footing  than  in  former  years. 

This  confidence  in  our  present  position  was, 
it  is  true,  somewhat  rudely  shaken  during  the 
year  1890.  As  already  stated,  although  we 
were  not  visited  by  an  old-fashioned  panic,  the 
events  of  1890  bore  no  small  resemblance  to 
those  of  former  years,  and,  but  for  much  judg- 
ment and  skill  displayed  by  the  directors  of 
the  Bank  of  England,  the  crisis  of  1890  might 
have  easily  ended  in  failures  and  panic  far  more 
serious  than  those  of  any  former  years.  It  is 
probably  quite  true  that  the  tremendous  lessons 
of  1857  and  1866  were  not  lost  on  the  financial 


or  the  mercantile  world,  and  that  credit  was 
maintained  on  a  comparatively  sound  footing 
for  many  years.  There  has  been  abundance 
of  enterprise  since  1866,  but  those  who  have 
been  familiar  with  the  money  market  for  thirty 
years  will,  we  think,  agi-ee  that  a  much  larger 
proportion  of  business  is  now  transacted  on  a 
cash  basis,  and  without  recourse  to  credit,  than 
was  possible  a  quarter  of  a  century  ago.  But 
though  this  is  so,  and,  in  ordinary  business, 
there  may  be  less  danger  of  "abuse  of  credit" 
than  there  was  when  the  country  was  much 
less  "  capitalised "  than  it  now  is,  the  very 
abundance  of  means  may  have  given  rise  to 
an  inclination  towards  excessive  confidence,  as 
if  the  capital  available  for  loans  of  all  kinds 
had  no  limit.  This  feeling  may  also  have  been 
intensified  by  the  great  accumulation  of  capital 
in  the  hands  of  "trusts"  or  "investment  com- 
panies" eager  for  profit,  and  not  always  so 
much  alive  as  are  individuals  to  the  danger  of 
great  mistakes. 

But,  probably,  the  most  important  distinction 
which  marked  the  position  of  1890  as  compared 
with  1857  and  1866  will  be  found  in  the  con- 
dition of  the  Bank  of  England.  When  alarm 
began  at  the  latter  end  of- October  1857,  the 
reserve  of  the  bank  was  under  £5,000,000, 
and  at  the  end  of  April  1866  it  was  under 
£6,000,000.  In  one  day  in  1866  £4,000,000 
left  the  bank  in  notes  and  coin,  in  consequence 
of  the  failure  of  Overend,  Gurney,  &  Co. 
Such  a  position  was  dangerous,  and  the  publi- 
cation of  such  returns,  combined  with  the  rais- 
ing of  the  rate  of  discount  to  nine  and  ten  per 
cent,  was  sure  to  aggravate  alarms.  But  in 
1890  the  reserve  stood  at  £14,500,000  when  it 
became  known  that  the  great  house  of  Baring 
had  gone  into  liquidation,  and  that  its  liabili- 
ties would  be  paid  by  the  bank.  The  position 
of  the  bank  being  so  strong,  and  it  being  known 
or  rumoured  that  the  action  of  the  bank  was 
approved  and  supported  by  the  government, 
panic  did  not  arise,  except  as  to  the  price  of 
securities  directly  affected  by  this  great  failure, 
or  by  failures  in  America,  and  no  mercantile 
disaster  of  the  least  consequence  occurred,  nor 
was  the  rate  of  interest  charged  on  discounts 
excessive.  In  fact,  there  was  no  general  dis- 
credit. Of  course  there  was  uneasiness,  it  being 
known  that  other  houses  must  have  lost  heavily 
through  South  American  complications,  but 
banking  and  other  business  went  on  as  usual, 
and  prices  of  produce  were  not  seriously  affected. 

There  were  none  of  the  usual  symptoms  of 
panic,  except  in  the  Stock  Exchange,  and  the 
contrast  to  those  who  had  lived  through  1857 
and  1866  was  very  remarkable.  In  those  years 
people  feared  that  the  bank  would  be  unable, 
without  an  increased  power  of  issue,  to  deal 
with  the  emergency,  and  it  was  never  absolutely 
certain  when,  if  at  all,  the  government  would 
i  come  to  the  aid  of  the  bank.     In  1890,  thanks 


CRISES,  1857-1866-1890 


465 


to  the  forethought  of  the  bank  in  providing 
herself  with  an  addition  to  her  bullion  by  a 
loan,  her  position  was  so  strong  at  the  critical 
moment  as  to  prevent  the  occurrence  of  any 
general  alarm.  Men  did  not  rush  to  supply 
themselves  with  money  one  day,  in  fear  that 
they  might  find  it  difficult  to  procure  it  on  the 
following  day,  but  attended  to  their  businesses 
without  excessive  anxiety  as  to  the  supplies  of 
capital.  Caution  prevailed,  but  not  panic,  and 
the  distinction  is  a  very  clear  one.^ 

As  to  the  effects  of  crises  and  panics,  there  is 
perhaps  but  little  to  be  said.  It  has  been  already 
pointed  out  that  trading  people  soon  recover 
their  spirits  and  their  confidence  when  the  panic 
is  once  well  over.  So  it  comes  to  pass  that 
prices  which,  before  and  during  panics,  have 
been  in  some  instances  severely  depressed,  quickly 
rise  to  their  former  level,  and  men  cease  to  con- 
sider the  money  market  in  their  dealings,  being 
no  longer  afraid  of  monetary  trouble  as  to  the 
discount  of  bills,  or  otherwise.  The  statistics 
of  our  trade  seem  to  confirm  this  view.  Spite 
of  panics,  our  aggi-egate  trade  has  gone  on  in- 
creasing, with  fluctuations  no  doubt,  but  not 
with  fluctuations  which  seem  to  point  to  panic 
as  the  great  disturber  of  our  commerce.  We 
have  had  divers  "depressions"  in  trade,  often 
very  difficult  to  account  for,  and  they  are  gener- 
ally followed  by  improvement  and  even  specu- 
lation, often  little  expected,  and  arising  no  one 
knows  why.  But  certainly,  in  recent  years, 
neither  depressions  nor  elevations  can  be  traced 
to  the  eff'ects  of  panic.  Vast  changes  have 
taken  place,  thanks  to  "many  inventions,"  and 
prices  have  fluctuated  beyond  all  precedent 
without  any  very  marked  oscillations  in  credit. 
The  supply  of  loanable  capital  since  1866  has 
been,  on  an  average  of  years,  ample,  and  this 
has  no  doubt  lessened  the  tendency  to  panic 
amongst  traders  generally.  But  there  have 
been  these  great  fluctuations  although  the 
money  market  has  been  so  stable,  and  this 
recent  experience  tends  to  confirm  the  opinion 

1  The  contrast  of  the  three  great  crises  with  reference 
to  the  reserves  of  the  bank  in  its  banking  department, 
is  shown  by  the  following  Table. 


Notes  in  reserve  in  the  Banking  Department  of 

the  Bank  of  England. 

1857. 

1806. 

1890. 

£ 

£ 

£ 

Oct.   3 

4,606,000 

April  11 

6,317,000 

Oct.  15 

10,275,000 

.,    10 

4,024,000 

„     25 

5,844,000 

„     29 

10,600,000 

..    17 

3,217,000 

May     9 

4,950,000 

Nov.  12 

10,024,000 

„    24 

3,485,000 

„      16 

730,000 

„     19 

13,378,000 

»    31 

2,258,000 

„      23 

830,000 

„     26 

15,309,000 

Nov.  4 

2,155,000 

„      .30 

415,000 

Dec.  10 

15,904,000 

»    11 

957,000 

June    6 

2,167,000 

,.     17 

15,797,000 

„    18 

1,148,000 

„     20 

4,067,000 

„     24 

14,205,000 

„    25 

1,918,000 

July    4 

3,335,000 

Dec.  2 

2,268,000 

„      18 

2,498,000 

,.     9 

3,900,000 

Aug.    1 

2,412,000 

»    16 

5,757,000 

„      15 

3,611,000 

»    23 

7,426,000 

„      29 

5,833,000 

[For  returns  from  18th  November  to  23rd  December 
1857,  see  note  1,  p.  463.] 

VOL.  I. 


that  we  should  not  attribute  much  permanent 
effect  to  the  panics  of  former  periods.  No  one  is 
likely  to  forget  the  temporary  effects  of  a  panic 
if  he  has  lived  through  one,  but,  as  to  perman- 
ent results,  panics  are  probably  not  important. 

But  panics  in  the  United  States  have  been  very 
severe.  The  sharpest  were  in  1837,  1857,  1873, 
1893  and  1907.  The  closing  months  of  1907 
were  marked  by  an  outburst  of  widespread  and  un- 
reasoning alarm,  and  by  the  suspension  of  cash 
payments  by  many  of  the  16,000  banks  of  the 
country.  Cash  could  not  be  obtained,  and  the  use 
of  an  emergency  currency  of  cheques  guaranteed 
by  the  Clearing  Houses,  estimated  at  upwards  of 
£100,000,000,  was  required.  The  crisis  beganin 
New  York  connected  with  two  of  the  National 
Banks  and  continued  with  two  of  the  Trust  com- 
panies. (-fifeo^.i/bwrTi.,  London,  1908, "The  Ameri- 
(3a.n  Crisis  of  1907";  Quart.  Journ.  of  Econ.^ 
U.S.A.,  1908,  "Hoarding  in  the  Panic  of  1907.") 

It  is  interesting  to  observe  that  countries 
where  panics  are  rare,  as  France  and  Germany, 
do  not  appear  to  make  greater  commercial  pro- 
gress than  England  and  the  States,  where  panics 
have  been,  comparatively,  not  infrequent. 

In  fact,  in  countries  of  great  enterprise,  and 
where  credit  attains  a  great  development,  it  is 
obvious  that  there  must  be  a  danger  of  undue 
expansion  followed  by  excessive  alarms.  Such 
people  use  up  their  means  too  closely,  no  doubt, 
but,  on  the  other  hand,  they  do  far  more  busi- 
ness and  acquire  far  larger  profits  from  their 
enterprise  than  can  be  secured  by  people  who 
are  no  doubt  more  prudent,  but  are  less  ener- 
getic. The  very  prudent  nations  escape  panic, 
but  they  at  the  same  time  must  accept  a  smaller 
return  on  their  capital.  They  no  doubt  keep 
larger  reserves  than  less  cautious  traders,  but 
such  reserves  are  expensive  to  maintain,  and  it 
may  be  well  doubted  whether  in  the  long  run  more 
is  not  gained  by  the  more  enterprising  peoples, 
even  though  they  may  subject  themselves  to  oc- 
casional alarms  of  a  serious  and  painful  nature. 

The  general  result  seems  to  be  that,  however 
remarkable  the  phenomena  of  crises  may  be, 
they  are  not  of  great  permanent  importance, 
nor  are  they  to  be  regarded  as  an  inevitable 
consequence  of  an  active  and  enterprising  con- 
duct of  business.  They  are  really  spasmodic 
symptoms,  and  not  symptoms  of  any  serious  and 
continuous  disease  which  has  to  be  brought 
under  some  legislative  remedy.  They  illustrate 
the  results  of  a  temporary  suspension  of  the 
laws  which  regulate  the  ordinary  currency  of  a 
nation  when  confidence  between  man  and  man 
is  lost,  but  events  so  exceptional  defy  regula- 
tion, and  the  cure  for  such  evils  will  probably  be 
found  rather  in  the  practical  good  sense  of  men 
of  business  than  in  any  expedients  invented 
by  ingenious  law  makers. 

It  has,  however,  been  suggested  that  some 
kinds  of  legislation  may  aggravate  panic  ;  as, 
for  instance,  the  law  of  the  United  States  of 

2  H 


466 


CRISES,  PERIODICITY  OF 


America  as  to  banlc  reserves,  and  our  own  law 
as  to  the  issues  of  the  Bank  of  England.  We 
certainly  think  that  the  experiences  of  1847, 
1857  and  1866  (to  say  nothing  of  1890),  show 
that  such  a  law  as  ours,  which  gives  no  power 
of  expansion  to  the  bank,  as  such,  no  matter 
how  grave  may  be  the  emergency,  is  one  of 
very  doubtful  wisdom.  It  would,  we  believe, 
be  far  more  reasonable  to  adopt  something  like 
the  plan  adopted  by  the  German  Bank  law  of 
1875,  whereby  the  bank  can  issue  beyond  the 
usual  limit  on  paying  at  the  rate  of  5  per  cent 
per  annum  to  the  government  on  all  extra- 
ordinary issue,  as  a  sort  of  penalty — an  arrange- 
ment which  ensures  a  reasonable  charge  to  the 
public  on  such  extra  issues,  and  thus  compels 
contraction  of  obligations  by  a  sort  of  automatic 
process.  Panic  is  thus  avoided,  while  a  whole- 
some warning  is  extended  to  the  trading  world, 
and  the  money  market  is  brought  under  the 
rule  of  law,  and  is  not,  as  with  us,  dependent 
in  the  worst  times  on  the  caprice  of  a  Chan- 
cellor of  the  Exchequer,  who  may  be  a  man 
ignorant  of  the  dangers  and  difficulties  of  com- 
merce, or  who  only  knows  them  vaguely,  as  set 
forth  in  the  books  of  mere  theorists.      w.  f. 

CRISES,  Periodicity  of.  In  the  world  of 
physics  the  idea  of  "periodicity"  of  "cycles" 
is  familiar.  The  twenty-eight  years  period  of 
the  sun  is  a  simple  illustration  of  a  regular 
cycle. 

The  recurrence  of  commercial  crises  over  a 
century,  at  intervals  of  ten  or  twelve  years,  has 
been  frequently  noticed  by  economists,  and  the 
suggestion  made  that  possibly  the  physical  law 
which,  every  ten  or  eleven  years,  brings  good 
vintage  years  to  Europe  and  droughts  to  India, 
may  control  the  commercial  fortunes  of  men. 
An  enumeration  of  recorded  years  of  acute  com- 
mercial distress— 1753,  1763,  1772-73,  1783, 
1793,  1815,  1825,  1836-39,  1847,  1857,  1866, 
1878, 1890 — suggests  periodicity.  Duringthese 
140  years  trade  and  banking  have  been  carried 
on  in  war  and  peace,  with  a  silver  standard,  with 
a  gold  standard,  under  a  suspension  of  cash  pay- 
ments, in  times  of  plenty,  and  in  times  of  want ; 
but  the  fatal  years  have  come  round  with  a 
considerable  approach  to  cyclical  regularity. 
While  admitting  that  the  commercial  crises 
to  which  this  generation  has  been  exposed  have 
been  less  acute  than  those  which  afflicted  the 
close  of  the  last  and  the  beginning  of  the 
present  century,  the  fact  of  their  recurrence 
in  something  like  periodicity  remains — a  fact 
which  it  is  easier  to  record  than  to  explain. 
Space  only  permits  a  statement  of  some  of  the 
more  important  crises,  with  a  reference  to  works 
from  which  fuller  information  may  be  derived. 

To  commence  with  the  beginning  of  this 
century,  the  question  of  the  periodicity  of  cycles 
is  discussed  by  Henry  Thornton,  whose  well- 
known  sagacity  caused  him  to  be  greatly  con- 
sulted on  financial  questions  by  William  Pitt, 


in  his  work,  An  Enquiry  into  the  Effects  of  the 
Paper  Credit  of  Great  Britain,  1802.  Thornton 
speaks  of  the  crisis  of  1793  as  the  first  material 
one  of  the  kind  which  had  for  a  long  time 
happened.  He  points  out  that  the  panic  greatly 
abated,  and  mercantile  credit  began  to  be  re- 
stored, so  soon  as  the  intention  to  issue  ex- 
chequer bills  was  announced.  He  also  mentions 
as  worthy  of  notice  that,  though  the  failures 
had  originated  in  an  extraordinary  demand  for 
gold,  it  was  not  any  supply  of  gold  which 
eflfected  the  cure,  but  the  idea  of  general  solvency 
which  was  created  by  the  promised  issue  of 
exchequer  bills  (pp.  49-51).  He  further  men- 
tions (p.  152)  that  the  fluctuation  in  the  balance 
of  trade  with  foreign  countries  which  we  ex- 
perience had  also  become  larger  than  heretofore, 
in  consequence  of  the  greater  extent  of  our 
population  and  commerce.  "The  scale  of  all 
things  having  increased,  the  scale  of  this  balance 
may  have  increased  also  in  a  degree  unexpected 
by  the  bank." 

Tooke,  in  his  History  of  Prices,  vol.  i.  p.  176, 
gives  a  clear  account  of  the  progress  of  events 
leading  up  to  the  disasters  of  1793.  Tooke 
states  that  immediately  preceding  that  crisis 
a  great  revulsion  and  derangement  of  commercial 
credit  had  occurred,  due  to  a  pre-existing  and 
undue  extension  of  credit  and  paper  circulation. 

In  vol.  ii.  p.  5,  in  discussing  the  causes  which 
led  to  the  discredit  of  1816,  he  explains  that 
the  speculation  in  exported  commodities,  which 
had  its  first  rise  in  the  prospect  of  the  down- 
fall of  the  power  of  Napoleon  I.  in  Europe, 
reached  its  height  in  the  spring  of  1814,  and 
that  the  tardy  discovery  that  the  effective  de- 
mand of  the  continent  had  been  over-rated  pre- 
cipitated the  crisis  of  1815-16. 

The  causes  of  the  crisis  of  1825  are  discussed 
by  Tooke  (vol.  ii.  pp.  149-159).  In  1822,  the 
British  5  per  cent  had  been  reduced  to  4  per 
cent  ;  this  had  led  to  a  general  restlessness 
among  those  whose  incomes  were  reduced,  and 
a  readiness  to  invest  in  foreign  loans,  the 
principal  borrowing  states  being  South  Ameri- 
can. The  South  American  loans  ultimately 
entailed  a  loss  of  nearly  the  whole  of  the  sums 
subscribed.  The  exaggerated  views  of  coming 
prosperity  allowed  full  scope  for  an  undue 
enlargement  and  abuse  of  credit. 

The  panic  of  1836  is  fully  described  by  Tooke 
(vol.  ii.  p.  274).  It  is  noticeable  that  whereas 
the  disasters  in  1825  were  principally  due  to 
foreign  speculations,  those  of  1835  were  due  to 
home  speculations,  an  undue  extension  of  credit 
arising  from  gambling  in  shares  of  railways, 
joint-stock  banks,  etc. 

In  vol.  iv.,  speaking  of  the  crisis  of  1847, 
Tooke  says :  "In  August  1845  the  specula- 
tion assumed  all  the  apparent  characteristics  of  a 
mania.  Symptoms  of  an  approaching  revulsion 
were,  however,  then  clearly  discernible." 

It  is  noteworthy  that  the  gradual  develop- ; 


CRISES,  PERIODICITY  OF— CROME 


467 


ment  and  overgrowth  of  credit  indicated  by 
Langton,  Jevons,  and  Mills,  are  clearly  stated 
by  Tooke. 

A  variety  of  causes  brought  about  the  serious 
crash  in  1847 — railway  calls  in  excess  of  the 
means  of  the  country,  high  price  of  corn,  etc. ; 
but  the  evidence  of  a  culmination  of  previously 
developing  causes  is  as  clear  on  this  occasion  as 
on  the  others  which  have  preceded  and  followed 
that  date. 

Mr.  William  Langton,  of  Manchester,  speak- 
ing of  periodicity  says  (2Vansactions  of  the 
Manchester  Statistical  Society,  December  1857)  : 
"These  disturbances  are  the  accompaniment  of 
another  wave  which  appears  to  have  a  decennial 
period,  and  in  the  generation  of  which  moral 
causes  have  no  doubt  an  important  part.  The 
prompting  cause  of  these  convulsive  movements 
appears  to  lie  in  the  inordinate  use  of  credit." 

The  doctrine  of  periodicity  was  held  strongly 
by  Professor  Jevons,  who  carried  his  investiga- 
tions into  the  subject  over  a  great  length  of 
time,  and  with  his  noted  ability.  In  a  com- 
munication on  the  study  of  periodic  fluctuations, 
British  Association  1862  (Cambridge),  Jevons 
says,  "There  is  a  periodic  tendency  to  com- 
mercial distress  and  difficulty  during  these 
months  (October  and  November).  It  is  when 
great  irregular  fluctuations  aggravate  this  dis- 
tress, as  in  the  years  1836-39,  1847,  1857,  that 
disastrous  breaches  of  commercial  credit  occur." 
In  elucidation  of  Jevons's  allusion  to  "great 
irregular  fluctuations,"  a  quotation  from  his 
paper  on  "The  frequent  pressure  in  the  money 
market,"  Journal  of  the  Statistical  Society  of 
London,  1866,  vol.  xxix.  p.  235,  may  be  useful. 
"  These  changes  arise  from  deficient  or  excessive 
harvests,  from  sudden  changes  of  supply  or 
demand  in  any  of  our  great  staple  articles,  from 
periods  of  excessive  investment  or  speculation, 
from  wars  and  political  disturbances,  or  other 
fortuitous  occurrences  which  we  cannot  calculate 
upon,  and  allow  for. "  Still  further  developing 
the  notion  of  periodicity,  Jevons  {Political 
Econx)my,  1878,  Science  Primers)  says,  "Good 
vintage  j'ears  on  the  continent  of  Europe,  and 
drougnts  in  India,  recur  every  ten  or  eleven 
years,  and  it  seems  probable  that  commercial 
crises  are  connected  with  a  periodic  variation 
of  weather  aff'ecting  all  parts  of  the  earth,  and 
probably  arising  from  increased  waves  of  heat 
received  from  the  sun  at  average  intervals  of 
ten  years  and  a  fraction." 

The  influence  of  solar  radiation,  and  the 
possibility  of  a  relation  between  the  sim-spot 
period  and  the  price  of  corn  and  other  events, 
formed  a  subject  of  inquiry  suited  to  the  exact 
and  scientific  mind  of  Jevons,  For  this  the 
reader  may  be  referred  to  his  Investigations  in 
I  Currency  and  Finance,  in  which  his  detached 
I  papers  are  collected,  and  Letters  and  Journal  of 
W.  S.  Jevons. 

The  invention  of  the  term  "credit  cycle"  may 


be  traced  to  Mr.  John  Mills  of  Manchester 
(Paper  on  "Credit  Cycles  and  the  Origin  of 
Commercial  Panics,"  Transactions  of  the  Man- 
chester Statistical  Society,  December  1867). 
Mr.  Mills  discussed  the  pathology  of  crises  ; 
and  after  alluding  to  "the  occult  forces  which 
swell  or  diminish  the  volume  of  transactions 
through  a  procession  of  years,"  thus  spoke  of 
periodicity.  "It  is  an  unquestionable  fact 
that  about  every  ten  years  there  occurs  a  vast 
and  sudden  increase  of  demand  in  the  loan 
market  followed  by  a  great  revulsion  and  a 
temporary  destruction  of  credit. 

"  The  periodicity  of  commercial  crises  is  at 
any  rate  a  fact.  The  decades  interposed  between 
the  great  commercial  crises  are  normal  cycles  of 
development  of  credit  under  certain  existing 
conditions  ;  that  during  each  of  these  decades 
commercial  credit  runs  through  the  mutations 
of  a  life,  having  its  infancy,  growth  to  maturity, 
diseased  overgrowth,  and  death  by  collapse." 

Mr.  Mills  enters  into  a  minute  examination  of 
the  life-history  of  a  credit  cycle  in  a  communica- 
tion made  to  the  Manchester  Statistical  Society, 
Transactions  1871.  Four  years  earlier,  in  his 
paper  read  before  the  Manchester  Statistical 
Society  in  1867,  Mr.  Mills  had  discussed  the 
possibility  of  finding  remedies  for  the  periodic 
recurrence  of  commercial  panics,  in  seeking  for 
which  he  laid  stress  on  the  increased  spread  of 
information.  Mr.  Mills's  anticipation  appears 
to  have  been  verified  in  some  measure  by  the 
course  of  events. 

[Max  Wirth,  Geschichte  der  Handelskrisen, 
1883. — Clement  Juglar,  Des  Crises  Commerciales 
et  de  leur  retour  periodique  en  France,  en  Angle- 
terre,  et  aux  ^tats-Unis,  1889.]  g.  h.  p. 

CROMBIE,  Alexander  (1762-1842),  born 
at  Aberdeen,  was  for  some  time  Presbyterian 
minister,  and  then  schoolmaster,  in  London. 
He  was  known  for  his  writings  on  etymology 
and  syntax,  especially  for  his  Gymnasium,  a 
book  of  exercises  in  Latin  composition  ;  but 
he  wrote  also  on  theology,  philosophy,  and 
political  economy.  Apart  from  his  books,  he 
seems  to  have  had  a  wide  personal  influence. 
Major  Torrens  dedicated  to  Dr.  Crombie  his 
Fssay  on  Money  and  Paper  Currency  (1812), 
and  speaks  of  him  with  great  deference  in  the 
Essay  on  the  External  Corn  Trade  (1815).  In 
1813  Crombie  published,  in  the  Pamphleteer 
(vol.  X.)  a  Letter  to  David  Ricardo  containing 
an  analysis  of  his  pamphlet  on  the  Depreciation 
of  Bank  Notes  ;  but  Ricardo  did  not  regard 
him  as  a  perfectly  faithful  exponent  of  his 
views.  Crombie's  Letters  on  the  Agricultural 
Interest  (1816)  would  seem  to  have  been  the 
last  of  his  economical  writings. 

.  [Ricardo's  letters  to  Malthus,  1887,  Clar.  Press, 
p.  82,  s7/i»  dato  21st  April  1815.]  J.  b. 

CROME,  August  Friedrich  Wilhelm 
(1753-1833),  a  distinguished  German  statisti 


468 


3R0SS  DRAWING— CROWN,  ENGLISH 


cian  and  economist,  was  bom  at  Sengwarden, 
in  the  territory  of  Kniphausen.  He  studied 
theology  at  Halle,  and  was  for  some  time 
instructor  of  the  hereditary  prince  of  Dessau. 
From  1787  to  1831,  he  filled  the  chair  of 
statistics  and  cameral  science  at  Giessen,  Ho 
is  called  by  Roscher  the  ''Haupt-theoretiker 
des  Rheinbundes,"  having  persistently  defended 
that  confederation,  and  maintained  it  to  be  "a 
liberation  for  Germany,  alike  beneficent  to 
rulers  and  to  the  people."  He  expected  that 
under  its  influence  a  better  national  economy 
would  be  introduced,  founded  on  the  principles 
of  Adam  Smith,  "as  improved  by  Soden, 
Huf eland  and  Jakob. "  In  Deutschland' s  Krise 
und  Errettung  im  April  und  Mai  1813,  which 
appeared  immediately  after  the  battle  of  Liitzen, 
just  when  the  national  rising  against  Napoleon 
was  coming  to  a  head,  he  attempted  to  show 
by  statistical  reasonings  the  madness  of  oppos- 
ing the  "great  hero,"  as  certain  to  lead  to  the 
ruin  of  the  fatherland.  This  publication  raised 
a  storm  which  was  only  partially  appeased  by 
his  treatise  Ueber  Deutschland' s  und  Europa's 
Stoats-  und  National-  Interesse  bei  und  nach  dem 
Congresse  zu  Wien,  1814.  His  other  principal 
works  were,  Europa's  Produkte,  1782  ;  Ghriisse 
und  Bevolkerung  der  Eur  op.  Staaten,  1785; 
Ueber  die  Culturverhdltnisse  der  Europ.  Staaten, 
1792  ;  and  Geographische  Statistische  Darstel- 
lung  der  Staatskrdfte  von  den  sdmmtlichen  zu 
dem  deutschen  Staatenbunde  gehorigen  Ldndern, 
1820-1828.  He  translated  into  German  (1795) 
the  treatise  entitled  Govemx)  della  Toscana  sotto 
il  regno  di  Leopoldo  11. ,  1790,  which  was  the 
work  of  that  prince  himself.  Crome  undertook 
the  translation  by  Leopold's  desire,  and,  in  the 
comments  which  he  added,  he  appears  as  an 
advocate  of  an  enlightened  and  reforming  ab- 
solutism, such  as  that  of  which  the  book  is  a 
history.  He  was  also  author  of  an  autobio- 
graphy. (See  Roscher,  Geschichte  der  Natumal- 
Oekon.  in  Deutschland,  p.  649).  J.  k.  i. 

CROSS  DRAWING.  Another  term  for  the 
making  of  an  Accommodation  Bill  {q.v.) 
When  such  an  instrument  has  been  wilfully 
put  into  circulation  by  a  fraudulent  trader,  as 
if  founded  on  a  real  transaction,  the  nicest 
penetration  and  judgment  of  experienced  busi- 
ness men,  such  as  bill-brokers  and  bankers,  will 
sometimes  be  put  to  the  test  to  discover  the 
true  origin  and  character  of  the  instrument. 
Bills  of  this  description  are  sometimes  termed 
"Wind  Bills,"  or  "Kites,"  from  their  want  of 
substantial  basis. 

[Hutchison,  The  Practice  of  Banking,  vol.  i. 
p.  125.] 

CROSSED  CHEQUE.  The  crossing  of 
cheques  is  now  regulated  by  §§  76  to  82  of 
the  Bills  of  Exchange  Act  1882  (see  Cheques, 
Law^  of). 

CROAVN  DEBTS.  Debts  due  from  a  subject 
to  the  crown  have  priority  over  all  other  debts. 


and  may  be  recovered  by  the  summary  process; 
known  as  an  extent.  Every  person  who  has 
money  belonging  to  the  crown  is  a  crown  debtor. 
Formerly,  in  order  to  enjoy  priority,  a  crown 
debt  required  to  be  a  debt  of  record  or  to  be 
secured  by  deed,  but  since  the  32  &  33  Vict.  c. 
4  6 ,  which  abolished  the  priority  of  specialty  debts, 
any  crown  debt  takes  priority  to  all  others. 
Crown  debts  do  not  affect  land  until  a  writ  oi 
execution  has  been  issued  and  registered. 

[Elphinstone  and  Clark's  Law  of  Judgments  and 
Searches,  London,  1887. — Prerogatives  of  the 
Crown,  by  J.  CMtty,  London,  1820.] 

J.  E.  c.  M. 

CROWN  (English).  Gold  coin  (Henry  VIII. 
to  Charles  II.) 


..^ 

Val^eingold 

Reign. 

Year. 

Rat- 
ing. 

Fine- 
ness. 

916-6  fine,  at 
£3  :  17  :  10^ 

Henry  VIII, 

tS 

an  oz. 

1627 

5/ 

57-25 

916-6 

9/3^ 

Edward  VI. 

1549 

.')/ 

42-25 

883-3 

6/2| 

James  I. 

1605 

5/ 

38-725 

916-6 

" 

1605 
(Thistle 
Crown) 

4/ 

31-00 

» 

5/Oi 

»» 

1612 

5/6 

38-725 

„ 

6/3i 

»i          » 

1612 
(Thistle 
Crown) 

4/4| 

31-00 

5/Oi 

„ 

1619 

5/ 

38-725 

jj 

6/3^ 

Charles  I. 

1627 

5/ 

35-12 

»' 

5/8^ 

Also  doable  crowns  (James  I.  to  Charles  II.)  and  half 
crowns  in  proportion. 

Silver  coin  (Henry  VI  IL  to  present  time). 


if 

Value  in 

Reign. 

Year. 

Rat- 
ing. 

1 

Fine- 
ness. 

silver  925 
fine,  at 

^ 

|5s.  6d.anoz.| 

Henry  VIII. 

1542 
(as  a  kind 
of  medal) 

5/ 

480-00 

925 

6/6 

Edward  VI. 

1551 
(for    cir- 
culation) 

5/ 

480-00 

»» 

5/6 

Elizabeth 

1601 

6/ 

464-50 

5/3| 

George  III. 

1817 
(and 

subse- 

8/ 

436-36 

»» 

5/or5-81fr8. 

quently) 

Also  half-crowns  in  proportion.  A  crown  in  white 
metal  was  struck  in  the  reign  of  James  I.,  but  only  a 
few  were  issued. 

Crown  {Scandinavian).  The  standard  of 
value,  but  not  a  coin,  6-22278  grains  of  fine 
gold.     Value,  Is.  l-215d.,  1-389  franc. 


Standard  Gold  Coins. 

Denomination. 

Weight. 

Fine- 
ness. 

Value  in 
gold  916-6 

fine  at 

£3:17:10^ 

an  oz. 

Value  in 

gold 

francs 

(900  fine). 

Twenty  crowns  . 
Ten  crowns 

gr. 
138-264 
69-132 

900 
900 

s.    d. 
22    Oi 
11    Oi 

francs. 
27-78 
13-89 

CROWN  LANDS— CRUSADES 


469 


Silver  Token  Coins. 


Value  in 

Value  in 

Fine- 

silver  925 

standard 

Denomination. 

Weight. 

fine  at 

silver 

5s.  6d.  an 
oz. 

francs 
(900  fine). 

francs. 

gr. 

s.    d. 

Double-crowns  . 

231-485 

800 

2    H 

2-67 

Cromis 

115-7425 

800 

1    1| 

1-33 

Half-crowns    (or 

50  ore  pieces)  . 

77-162 

600 

6| 

0-67 

Forty  ore    . 

61-727 

600 

5^ 

0-53 

Twenty-five  ore  . 

37-346 

600 

3J 

0-32 

Ten  ore       . 

22-376 

400 

u 

0-13 

CROWN  LANDS.  In  Saxon  times  tlie 
king  owned  three  kinds  of  property  in  land  : 
(1)  private  estate  which  he  could  dispose  of  by 
will ;  (2)  demesne  lands  that  could  be  alienated 
only  by  consent  of  the  witan ;  (3)  certain 
rights  over  his  folkland.  The  folkland  tended 
to  become  merged  in  the  royal  demesne 
(Stubbs's  ConstitutioTial  History,  i.  ch.  vi.  §  59  ; 
c.  vii.  §  75),  a  process  that  was  completed  by 
the  Norman  Conquest  {Ih.  ch.  ix.  §  95). 

From  Domesday  we  learn  that  the  income 
from  royal  lands  amounted  to  £20,000  (Pear- 
son's Early  and  Middle  Ages,  i.  385).  An 
important  portion  of  the  royal  demesne  con- 
sisted of  forests  which  were  exempt  from  the 
ordinary  law,  and  subject  to  royal  regulations 
of  great  severity  (Pearson's  Hist.  Maps,  pp.  44- 
48;  Ellis's  Intr.  i.  103-116).  The  crown 
was  supposed  to  defray  the  expenses  of  the 
household,  of  the  administration  of  justice,  and 
of  the  military  forces.  Though  the  crown 
revenue  was  greatly  diminished  by  the  loss  of 
the  French  possessions,  it  was  increased  by 
marriages  and  by  the  dissolution  of  the  monas- 
teries. The  alienation  of  the  crown  lands  to 
favourites  led  to  the  attempts  of  the  barons  to 
limit  the  king's  power  of  giving  (Stubbs,  ch.  xvii. 
p.  284),  and  to  the  passing  of  various  statutes 
with  the  same  object. 

By  the  1  Anne,  c.  1,  §§  5-8  ;  10  Geo.  IV.  c.  50, 
§  127 ;  and  1  &  2  Vict.  c.  2,  §§  1,  2,  the  right  of 
alienation  was  limited  to  leases  for  lives  or  a  term 
of  years.  By  the  last-mentioned  act  the  crown 
surrendered  its  hereditary  revenues  (see  Rogers's 
Economic  Interpretation  of  History,  Oxford,  1888, 
ch.  xix.)  The  management  of  the  crown  lands  is 
entrusted  to  the  Commissioners  of  Woods,  and  is 
governed  by  a  series  of  statutes  enumerated  in 
The  Chronological  Tahle  and  Index  of  the  Statutes, 
10th  ed.,  Loudon,  1887.  See  also  The  Landed 
Interest,  ch.  x.,  by  J.  Caird,  London,  1878. 

The  crown,  it  is  said  (Chitty,  Prerogatives  of 
tJie  Crown,  ch.  xi.,  London,  1820),  is  owner  of  the 
foreshore  between  high  and  low  water  mark  in 
ordinary  tides,  imless  a  grant  in  private  ownership 
can  be  proved,  but  Moore,  in  his  History  of  the 
Foreshore,  London,  1888,  maintains  that  the 
theory  of  the  crown's  ownership  of  the  jus  priv- 
atum of  the  foreshore  did  not  exist  until  the  reign 
of  Elizabeth,  and  that  its  origin  is  due  to  success- 
ful attempts  to  extend  the  prerogative.     See  also 


Hall's  Rights  of  the  Crown  and  the  Privileges  oj 
the  Subject  in  the  Seashore,  by  R.  L.  Loveland, 
2nd  ed.,  London.  Some  ^vriters  also  maintain 
that  the  crown  owns  all  land  imder  the  marginal 
seas  to  the  distance  of  a  marine  league,  a  view 
taken  by  a  minority  of  the  court  in  R.  v.  Keyn, 
L.R.,  2  Ex.,  D.  63  ;  but  others  deny  such  a  right, 
conceding  only  a  right  of  jurisdiction  (see  Hall's 
International  Law,  Oxford,  1880). 

Forfeited  estates  formerly  vested  in  the  crown 
(see  33  &  34  Vict.  c.  23),  and  the  crown  is 
owner  of  considerable  private  property  in  land. 
In  theory,  state  lands  in  our  colonies  are  vested 
in  the  crown,  but  control  over  them  is  vested  in 
the  colonial  legislatures.  All  crown  lands,  in- 
cluding all  private  lands  not  disposed  of,  descend 
with  the  crown.  J.  e.  c.  m. 

CRUMPE,  Samuel  (1766-1796),  Irish  physi- 
cian, deserved  the  prize  awarded  by  the  Royal 
Irish  Academy  to  his  essay  On  tlie  best  riieans 
of  providing  Employment  for  the  People,  The 
causes  of  Irish  distress  are  ably  analysed. 
Among  the  remedies  is  a  bounty  on  the  exporta- 
tion of  corn  (p.  241).  The  author  is  prepared 
to  prohibit  the  export  of  wool  (p.  303). 

F.  Y.  E. 

[Dr.  Crumpe's  prize  essay  is  described  as  "  an 
excellent  treatise  "  ;  Malthus,  Essay  on  Popula- 
tion, bk.  iv.  ch.  xi.  note.] 

CRUSADE.  A  Portuguese  gold  coin,  bearing 
the  design  of  a  cross.  It  was  current  in  England 
in  Queen  Mary's  reign,  and  was  valued  at  6s.  8d. 

F.  E.  A. 

CRUSADES,  Economic  Effects  of.  The 
crusades  cover  a  long  period  of  time,  from  the 
11th  to  the  13th  century,  and  their  early 
triumphs  were  followed  by  complete  and  dis- 
astrous failure.  This  long  duel  between  the 
west  and  the  east,  between  Christianity  and 
Islam,  exercised  the  most  profound  influence 
upon  Europe :  upon  the  position  of  popes, 
emperors,  and  kings  ;  upon  the  relations  be- 
tween church  and  state  ;  upon  the  progress  of 
literature,  education,  and  art.  To  the  crusades 
are  due  the  breaking  up  of  classes  and  the  rise 
of  nations.  No  less  marked  Avas  their  influence 
upon  the  economic  conditions  of  mediaeval 
Europe.  The  fall  of  the  western  empire  and 
the  triumph  of  the  Teutonic  invaders  had 
resulted  in  the  complete  separation  of  the  east 
from  the  west,  and  in  the  annihilation  of  that 
maritime  commerce  which  had  been  first  in- 
augurated by  the  Phoenicians  and  developed  by 
the  Greeks.  So  completely  had  naval  enter- 
prise been  neglected  that  the  early  crusadera 
had  no  alternative  but  to  march  overland  to 
Constantinople  and  to  cross  the  Hellespont  into 
Asia.  The  first  result  of  the  crusades  was  to 
revive  maritime  trade  in  those  countries  whose 
geographical  position  fitted  them  for  this, 
especially  in  the  Italian  coast  towns  and  such 
cities  as  Marseilles  and  Barcelona.  By  the 
13th  century  the  Mediterranean  had  become 
once   more   the   centre   of  a  world- em bracinij 


470 


CRUSADES— CULTUKli: 


commerce  ;  from  its  shores  the  products  of  the 
east  were  carried  overland  to  the  centre  of 
Europe,  thence  to  England  and  even  to  the 
Baltic  coasts.  The  route  by  the  Caspian  and 
southern  Russia,  through  which  a  scanty  trade 
between  Asia  and  Europe  had  been  conducted 
in  the  dark  ages,  was  henceforth  almost  entirely 
neglected. 

Next  to  the  development  of  trade  due  to  the 
crusading  movements  must  be  ranked  the 
advance  of  industry.  The  products  of  the  east 
had  to  be  purchased  by  those  of  Europe  ;  thus 
an  enormous  stimulus  was  given  to  manufactures 
and  agriculture.  And  not  only  were  the  old 
industries  developed,  but  many  new  ones  were 
actually  introduced  from  the  east.  From 
Greece  came  the  manufacture  of  silk  and  the 
cultivation  of  the  mulberry.  From  Tyre  the 
Venetians  learnt  the  art  of  making  glass,  an 
industry  which  they  retain  still,  long  after  the 
days  of  their  decline.  The  crusaders  introduced 
from  Africa  the  cultivation  of  maize  and  the 
sugar-cane.  In  Damascus  they  learnt  notable 
improvements  in  the  working  of  metals,  and 
the  making  of  cloth. 

The  increase  of  trade  and  manufactures  led 
to  the  growth  and  rise  of  towns,  one  of  the 
most  important  results  of  the  crusades.  The 
greatest  immediate  profit  was  reaped  by  the 
Italian  cities,  Venice,  Pisa,  Genoa,  Amalfi,  etc. 
Increase  of  trade  and  manufactures  also  brought 
wealth  to  the  German  towns  in  the  valleys  of 
the  Danube  and  the  Rhine,  to  the  communes 
of  France,  to  the  trading  and  manufacturing 
cities  of  Flanders,  finally  to  the  north  German 
towns,  which  formed  the  famous  Hanseatio 
League  {q.v.)  The  traders  required  protection 
from  lawless  oppression  and  from  piracy.  This 
was  acquired  in  the  north  by  combination,  in 
the  south  by  the  promulgation  of  the  earliest 
codes  of  maritime  law,  and  generally  by  the 
acquisition  of  municipal  privileges  and  inde- 
pendence. The  crusades  owed  their  origin  to 
the  spirit  of  religion  and  of  chivalry.  They 
gave  the  popes  a  vast  increase  of  secular 
authority  ;  they  led  to  the  institution  of  reli- 
gious orders,  like  the  Franciscans,  Dominicans, 
and  Carthusians  ;  and  of  the  military  orders 
of  the  Templars,  Hospitallers,  and  Teutonic 
Knights.  But  their  ultimate  results  were  fatal 
to  the  interests  which  they  at  first  promoted. 
The  contact  with  the  east  gave  the  first  stimu- 
lus to  the  freedom  of  thought  which  was 
destined  to  destroy  the  superstitions  on  which 
rested  the  religious  unity  of  Europe.  The  rise 
of  the  burgher  class  was  followed  by  the  rise  of 
the  spirit  of  nationality — both  fatal  to  the  class 
institutions  of  feudalism  and  chivalry.  The 
nobles  who  fought  in  the  crusades  were  com- 
pelled to  find  money  by  the  sale  of  privileges 
to  the  towns,  of  their  lands  to  the  highest 
bidder,  of  freedom  to  their  serfs.  The  social 
changes  thus  produced  destroyed  the  mediaeval 


system,  and  gave  rise  to  those  industrial  rela- 
tions which  have  been  the  dominant  influence 
in  Europe  ever  since. 

[Heeren,  Versuch  einer  Entwickelung  der  Folgen 
der  Kreuzziige  fur  Europa  (1808). — Adolf  Beer, 
Geschichte  des  ,  Welthandels  (1860). — Blanqui, 
Histoire  de  VEconomie  Politique  en  Europe. — 
Guizot,  History  of  Civilisation  in  Europe. — • 
Ranke,  Weltgeschichte,  viii.]  b.  l. 

CULPA.  An  expression  of  Roman  law  ex- 
pressing the  want  of  proper  diligence.  The 
Roman  jurists  distinguished  between  culpa  levis 
and  culpa  lata,  and  mediaeval  writers  introduced 
a  third  degree  of  culpa  which  they  called  culpa 
levissima.  Culpa  lata,  i.e.  gross  negligence,  was 
treated  nearly  in  the  same  way  as  unlawful 
intention  (dolus).  In  some  contractual  and 
other  relations  there  was  no  absolute  standard 
for  the  degree  of  diligence  required  ;  the  persona 
concerned  had  to  give  the  same  amount  of  care 
as  they  were  accustomed  to  give  to  their  own 
affairs.  The  omission  of  this  degree  of  diligence 
is  called  culpa  in  concreto  by  mediaeval  writers. 

E.  s. 

CULPEPER,  Sir  Thomas,  the  elder  (1578- 
1662),  author  of  ^  Tract  against  the  high  rate 
of  Usurie,^lQ2\,  which,  "presented  to  the 
high  court  of  parliament,"  conduced  to  the 
reduction  of  the  legal  rate  of  interest  from 
ten  to  eight  per  cent  in  1624.  The  tract  was 
reprinted  with  additions  in  1641.  The  author 
meanwhile  "set  forth  another  treatise  to 
evince  the  necessity  of  reducing  money  from 
eight  to  six"  (preface  to  the  Discourse  of  Sir 
Thomas  Culpeper  the  younger),  namely  A 
TroAt  against  the  high  rate  of  Usurie,  1640 
(Brit.  Mus.,  1093  b.  98).  The  two  treatises 
were  reprinted  together,  with  a  preface,  by 
Sir  Thomas  Culpeper  the  younger,  1688. 

F.  Y.  E. 

CULPEPER,  Sir  Thomas,  the  younger 
(1626-1697),  a  worthy  son  of  the  elder  knight, 
assailed  usury  in  a  Discourse  dated  1688. 
Thomas  Manley,  gent.,  answered  this  discourse, 
maintaining  that  "as  it  is  the  scarcity  of 
money  (and  many  borrowers)  that  maketh  the 
high  rates  of  interest,  ...  so  the  plenty  of 
money  and  few  borrowers  will  make  the  rates 
low."  Culpeper  retorted  with  The  necessity  of 
abating  Usury  reasserted,  1670.  Some  other 
publications  on  the  same  subject  are  ascribed  to 
Culpeper  (Wood's  Athen.  Oxen.,  ch.  iv.  p.  447). 

F.  Y.  E. 

CULTURE,  Large  and  Small.  The 
question  of  large  or  small  holdings  may  be 
ta-eated  morally,  socially,  and  economically. 
Here  it  will  mainly  be  discussed  in  the  latter 
aspect  It  is  the  physical  formation  of  a 
country  which  chiefly  determines  the  size  of 
holdings.  It  may  be  laid  down  as  an  axiom 
that,  where  the  soil  and  climate  are  specially 
adapted  for  cereals  and  sheep,  and  where  the 
physical  configuration  of  the  country  admits  of 


CULTURE 


4^1 


large  enclosures,  there  large  holdings  are  the  most 
productive.  On  the  other  hand,  where  districts 
are  hilly,  the  soil  rocky,  the  surface  broken, 
or  where  soil  and  climate  are  specially  favour- 
able to  permanent  grass,  there  small  holdings 
are  best.  It  follows  that,  as  a  rule,  grass 
counties  have  most,  and  corn  counties  have 
fewest,  small  holdings.  But  there  are  excep- 
tions. Near  large  towns,  small  holdings  will 
necessarily  pay  best.  A  small  holding  is  a 
relative  term.  It  differs  in  size  when  the 
holding  is  a  market  garden,  a  grass  farm,  or 
an  arable  land.  A  man  may  make  his  living 
off  a  very  small  tract  of  market-garden  land, 
or  off  5  acres  of  gi-ass.  It  is  doubtful  whether 
an  arable  farmer,  solely  dependent  upon  the 
produce  of  the  soil,  and  not  engaged  in  any  other 
profitable  occupation,  can  live  on  less  than  40 
acres.  All  holdings  may  be  considered  small 
which  are  50  acres  or  under.  In  England  there 
were,  in  1887,  294,729  small  holdings,  aggre- 
gating 3,559,000  acres.  (See  Major  Craigie  on 
"Agricultural  Holdings,"  Journ.  Stat.  Soc, 
1887.)  In  1913  there  were  249,773  small 
holdings  aggregating  3,581,375  acres,  the  de- 
crease in  number  being  among  holdings  not 
over  20  acres  {Agric.  Stat.  Pt.  I.,  1914),  In 
England,  small  holdings  tend  to  increase. 
This  increase  arises  from  the  fall  in  the  price  of 
cereals,  the  diminished  cajjital  of  large  farmers, 
the  growing  number  of  men  who  combine  farm- 
ing with  other  avocations,  and  also  recently 
from  encouragement  by  county  councils,  etc. 
Grain,  meat,  and  wool  can  be  produced  more 
economically  upon  large  farms,  Avhile  pork, 
poultry,  eggs,  vegetables,  are  best  suited  for 
small  holdings.  Fruit-farming  is  not  profit- 
able for  small  farmers,  because  the  initial  out- 
lay is  large,  the  crops  precarious,  and  the 
profits  unreliable.  In  dairying  small  farmers 
enjoy  no  advantage  over  large.  But  in 
pigs,  poultry,  calf-rearing,  vegetables,  where 
minute  care  and  attention  secure  safe  and 
quick  returns,  small  farms  are  economically 
preferable  to  large,  and  chiefly  for  these 
reasons.  While  labour  has  increased  in  price 
and  deteriorated  in  quality,  small  farmers 
hire  no  labourers  and  employ  the  best  that  is 
procurable — their  own.  Again,  the  depression 
in  prices  has  most  particularly  affected  the 
produce  of  large  farms,  and  has  fallen  com- 
paratively lightly  on  the  produce  of  small 
holdings,  which  is  also  of  a  more  varied  kind. 
The  eggs  of  large  farmers  are  in  one  basket, 
and  the  bottom  has  either  fallen  out  or  is 
rickety.  The  eggs  of  small  farmers  are  stored 
in  several  baskets  and  the  bottoms  are  re- 
latively secure.  Again,  small  farmers,  selling 
direct  to  consumers,  not  only  feel  the  fall  of 
prices  less,  but  eliminate  the  profits  of  middle- 
men. Lastly,  small  farmers  are  under  fewer 
temptations  to  extravagance.  They  are  more 
frugal  and  more  industrious.     They  are  sparing 


of  everything  except  their  labour,  prodigal  of 
nothing  but  themselves.  Employing  no  hired 
labour,  practising  mixed  husbandry,  rearing 
stock  instead  of  feeding  them,  often  enjoying 
common  rights,  doing  the  work  of  two  labourers 
and  eating  the  food  of  one,  small  farmers  weather 
storms  which  wreck  their  richer  brethren.  But 
it  is  a  false  argument  that  small  farmers  are 
necessarily  more  profitable  to  the  community 
than  large  farmers,  because  the  former  pay 
higher  rents.  They  undoubtedly  pay  higher 
rents  ;  but  they  do  so  because  the  competi- 
tion for  holdings  of  this  class  is  especially 
keen,  because  the  expenses  ol"  buildings,  ap- 
proaches, hedges,  and  repairs  are  far  heavier 
on  small  than  on  large  farms,  and  because  the 
land  devoted  to  small  farms  is,  as  compared 
with  ordinary  agricultural  land,  what  may  be 
called  accommodation  land.  In  point  of  material 
comfort,  wage-earning  labourers  in  constant 
employment  are  better  off  than  small  farmers, 
whether  they  own  or  occupy  the  soil.  It 
cannot,  for  instance,  be  questioned  that  the 
English  agricultural  labourer  is  better  housed, 
better  fed,  and  better  clothed  than  the  French 
peasant  proprietor.  Wherever  a  peasant  pro- 
prietary prevails,  except  under  most  favourable 
conditions,  the  rural  populations  live  hard, 
fare  hard,  and  are  on  the  border-line  of  starva- 
tion. In  point  of  production,  the  product  per 
acre  in  England  exceeds  that  of  any  country  on 
the  continent  except  East  Flanders.  In  point 
of  agricultural  science,  English  farming  is, 
speaking  generally,  more  advanced  than  in 
countries  where  the  small  culture  of  peasant 
proprietors  prevails.  Belgium  affords  a  notice- 
able example  of  the  stagnation  which  is  pro- 
duced by  the  multiplication  of  small  cultivators. 
Seventy-five  years  ago  the  agriculture  of  Belgium 
was  the  first  in  Europe.  Since  then  the  size  of 
the  farms  has  decreased,  and  the  number  of 
small  farmers  continuously  increased.  Enter- 
prise and  experiment  diminished  with  the  ex- 
tension of  la  petite  culture.  Farming  has  rather 
retrograded  than  advanced  ;  the  stock,  and 
especially  the  sheep,  have  decreased  ;  the  small 
farmer  only  raises,  and  only  eats,  pork.  In 
point  of  pauperism,  rural  England  has  fewer 
paupers  than  countries  where  small  culture  is 
the  rule.  In  Prussia  the  number  of  peasant 
heads  of  families  exempted  from  direct  taxa- 
tion because  their  earnings  are  less  than  £25  a 
year,  amounted  in  1888  to  nearly  1\  millions. 
In  France  3  millions  out  of  the  7  million 
proprietors  are  unable  to  contribute  largely  to 
state  objects  by  reason  of  poverty.  In  point 
of  encumbrances,  the  soil  of  England  is  less 
burdened  with  mortgages  than  the  land  of 
countries  farmed  by  small  cultivating  owners. 
In  France,  for  example,  the  real  owners  of  the 
soil  are  local  money-lenders,  and  in  some  de- 
partments 80  per  cent  of  the  land  is  said  to  be 
mortgaged.     Small  culture  cannot  be  regarded 


472 


CUM  DIVIDEND— CURRENCY  DOCTRINE  OR  PRINCIPLE 


as  an  agiicultural  panacea.  It  can  only  thrive 
in  England  under  the  economic  conditions 
mentioned  above.  (See  Agricultuhal  Hold- 
ings Acts.     Appendix.) 

[Reports  to  the  Royal  Commission  on  Agricul- 
ture, 1881  and  1882,  especially  those  of  the  late 
Mr.  Jenkins. — James  Howard,  Continental  Farm- 
ing and  Peasantry  (1870). — Lady  Verney,  Cottier 
Owners,  etc.  (1885). — W.  Beauclerk,  Rural  Italy 
(1888).— J.  S.  Mill,  Princ.  of  Pol.  Econ.']     b.  e.  p. 

CUM  DIVIDEND.  On  the  London  stock 
exchange  it  is  always  understood  that  a  share 
sold  includes  also  the  dividend  which  may  have 
accrued  upon  it  since  the  previous  distribution, 
unless  the  bargain  is  made  specifically  Ex  Divi- 
dend {q.v.)  On  Indian  rupee  paper,  exchequer 
bills,  and  corporation  bonds,  however,  the  bar- 
gains are  done  **  clean,"  or  exclusive  of  dividend, 
which  the  buyer  has  to  pay  to  the  seller  at  the 
conventional  rate,  according  to  the  number  of 
days  since  the  previous  distribution  of  dividend. 

A.  E. 

CURATOR  BONIS.  A  guardian  appointed 
by  a  Scotch  court  to  manage  the  estates  of  a 
minor  or  of  a  lunatic.  His  functions  are  to 
realise  and  protect  the  estate.  He  has  no 
charge  of  the  ward's  person,  except  in  so  far  as 
it  is  his  duty  to  see  the  ward  properly  educated. 

[Erskine's  Principles  of  the  Law  of  Scotland, 

1880.]  J.B.C.  M. 

CURRENCY.  This  word  is  sometimes  em- 
ployed in  the  sense  of  circulating  medium, 
sometimes  in  the  sense  of  standard  of  value. 
Adam  Smith  says  (book  iv.  ch.  iii.),  in  the  weU- 
known  Digression  concerning  Banks  of  Deposit, 
particularly  concerning  that  of  Amsterdam, 
"The  currency  of  a  great  state,  such  as  France 
or  England,  generally  consists  almost  entirely 
of  its  own  coin."  Here  a  standard  of  value  is 
referred  to,  and  the  constancy  of  the  "Bank 
Money  "  of  the  bank  of  Amsterdam  is  mentioned 
as  one  of  its  advantages.  Adam  Smith's  com- 
parison of  the  currency  to  the  road  which  con- 
veys the  produce  of  a  country  to  market  (  Wealth 
of  Nations,  book  ii.  ch.  ii.),  and  J.  S.  Mill's  de- 
scription of  it  as  "a  machinery  for  doing  quickly 
and  commodiously  what  would  be  done,  though 
less  quickly  and  commodiously,  without  it" 
{Principles  of  Political  Economy,  book  iii.  ch.  vii. 
§  3),  illustrate  the  services  which  the  currency 
performs.  An  ideally  perfect  system  of  currency, 
to  be  based  on  a  system  of  tabulatory  prices,  is 
dealt  with  by  Jevons,  Investigations  in  Currency 
and  Finance.  Some  idea  of  the  same  kind 
appears  to  have  passed  before  the  mind  of  D. 
Ricardo,  Proposals  for  an  Economical  and  Secure 
Currency  (Ricardo's  Works,  2nd  ed.  p.  397). 
His  definition  of  a  perfect  currency  is  as  follows  : 
"A  currency  may  be  considered  as  perfect  of 
which  the  standard  is  invariable,  which  always 
conforms  to  that  standard,  and  in  the  use  of 
which  the  utmost  economy  is  practised."  A 
tabular  standard   of  value   was   suggested   by 


Joseph  Lowe  to  give  a  steady  value  to  money 
contracts  through  reference  to  the  prices  of 
different  articles.  A  similar  method  was  recom- 
mended by  G.  Poulett  Scrope,  whose  remark, 
"  without .  stability  of  value  money  is  a  mere 
fraud,"  goes  to  the  root  of  the  matter.  The 
subject  had  also  been  considered  by  G.  R.  Porter. 
Mr.  Giffen  has  more  recently  carried  on  the  in- 
vestigation. The  idea  of  a  standard  of  value 
to  remain  as  far  as  possible  constant,  is  included 
in  the  principle  on  which  Corn  Rents  {q.v.)  are 
based  (see  also  Circulating  Medium  ;  Index 
Numbers,  etc.) 

[Jevons,  Investigations  in  Currency  and  Fin- 
ance.— Ricardo's  Works,  ed.  M'Culloch. — Joseph 
Lowe,  The  Present  State  of  England  in  regard  to 
Agriculture,  Trade,  and  Finance,  1822. — G. 
Poulett  Scrope,  Principles  of  Political  Economy, 
1833.— Porter,  Progress  of  the  Nation,  1815.] 

CURRENCY  DOCTRINE  or  PRINCIPLE. 
A  name  given  to  a  doctrine  or  opinion  which 
supplies  the  basis  for  the  method  adopted  by 
Sir  R.  Peel  when  regulating  the  paper  currency 
by  the  Bank  Act  of  1844.  It  appears  to  have 
been  first  used  by  Mr.  G.  W.  Norman,  who,  in 
his  evidence  before  the  House  of  Commons 
Committeemen  Banks  of  Issue,  1840,  Q.  2018, 
sppaking  of  the  circulation,  referred  to  "cur- 
rency principles,  according  to  which  it  would 
increase  or  decrease  with  increase  or  decrease  of 
bullion."  The  evidence  of  Mr.  Gilbart,  before 
the  same  committee,  1841,  showed  that  he 
understood  the  term  in  a  similar  sense.  Q.  932, 
"I  mean  by  the  phrase  'currency  principles,'  a 
bank  which  shall  do  nothing  else  but  issue 
notes  for  gold,  and  gold  for  notes  ; "  and  Q. 
933,  "I  do  not  at  all  admit  that  those  are 
the  correct  principles  upon  which  the  currency 
should  be  administered. "  Mr.  T.  Tooke,  History 
of  Prices,  vol.  iv.  p.  167,  and  passim,  agrees 
with  Mr.  Gilbart.  The  controversy  was  con- 
tinued by  others,  among  whom  may  be  cited 
Mr.  Jones  Loyd  (Lord  Overstone),  who,  in  his 
writings  and  in  his  evidence  before  the  Select 
Committee,  H.  of  C,  1840,  and  also  before  the 
Select  Committee  on  Bank  Acts,  H.  of  C,  1857, 
expressed  the  same  opinion,  Q.  648,  1857, 
"The  paper  notes  or  certificates  ought  to  be 
preserved  at  their  proper  value  by  making  them, 
under  all  circumstances,  conform  in  amount  to 
the  coins  or  metallic  circulation  which  they 
represent."  Sir  R.  Peel  employed  the  same 
opinion  as  the  basis  of  the  argument,  on  which 
he  founded  the  reasons  for  the  changes  which 
he  introduced  in  the  banking  system  of  the 
country,  through  the  Bank  Acts  of  1844-45 
(see  speech  in  H.  of  C.  on  Bank  Charter,  6th 
May  1844).  The  principles  and  the  methods 
of  actiou  which  Sir  R.  Peel  supported  on  that 
occasion,  were  in  opposition,  as  he  admitted, 
to  "the  high  authority  of  Adam  Smith  and 
of  Ricardo,"  who  held  that  freedom  of  com* 
petition  and  immediate  convertibility  into  coir 


CURVES 


473 


at  the  will  of  the  holder,  coupled,  it  should  be 
understood,  with  such  provisions  as  would  secure 
the  holder  from  loss  under  any  circumstances, 
would  prevent  the  notes  of  banks  from  being 
issued  in  excess.  Sir  R.  Peel  might  have  added 
that  this  opinion  of  his  own  was  also  in 
opposition  to  that  of  Mr.  Huskisson.  Sir  R. 
Peel  referred  in  the  speech  quoted  above  to  the 
Bullion  Committee  Report  (q.v.)  which,  it 
should  be  pointed  out,  was  made  during  the 
period  of  suspension  of  specie  payments,  and 
recommended  a  return  to  payments  in  specie 
as  a  cure  for  the  evils  deprecated.  Sir  R.  Peel 
was  by  far  the  most  powerful  supporter  of  this 
doctrine,  which  is  of  importance  as  laying  down 
a  principle  unknown  before — namely  that  it  is 
essential  that  the  bank  notes  circulating  in  a 
country  should  always  conform  in  amount  to 
the  metallic  circulation  which  they  represent, 
see  above  —  the  result  of  the  acceptance  of 
which  has  been  the  separation  of  the  banking 
department  from  the  issue  department  of  the 
Bank  of  England  (see  Bank  of  England). 
The  doctrine  has  never,  it  should  be  mentioned, 
found  general  acceptance  with  economists.  It 
marks  the  diiference  between  those  who  regard 
bank  notes  as  ''money,"  and  those  who  con- 
sider them,  in  the  words  of  Huskisson,  as  "cir- 
culating credit,"  and  a  "substitute  for  money 
in  the  transactions  of  tlie  community  "  (Huskis- 
son on  the  Deprcciatiov,  vftJic  Curmiqi).  While 
insisting,  and  properly,  on  adeipiate  security 
being  given  for  the  bank  note,  the  currency 
doctrine  leaves  out  of  sight  the  operation  of  all 
other  instruments  of  credit,  e<[ually  effective  in 
their  way,  as  bank  notes,  on  price  and  the  move- 
ments of  commodities. 

[See  books  referred  to  under  Bullion  Com- 
mittee.— Evidence  before  Committee  on  Banks  of 
Issue,  House  of  Commons,  1840-41. —  Committee 
on  Bank  Acts,  House  of  Commons,  1857. — Tracts 
and  other  publications  on  "  Metallic  and  Paper 
Currency,"  printed  by  Lord  Overstone,  1837-57. — 
Speeches  of  Sir  R.  Peel  on  "Bank  Charter,"  House 
of  Commons,  May  6,  20,  etc.,  1844,  etc.] 

CURVES  are  amongst  the  most  useful  appli- 
ances which  mathematics  lends  to  the  social 
sciences.  The  curves  most  frequently  employed 
in  this  way  are  plane  curves  :  such  as  AB  in 
the  annexed  figures  ;  referred  to  rectangular 
axes  OX  and  OY  in  such  wise  that  the  curve 
represents  the  interdei)endence  of  two  variable 
quantities  Ox  and  Oy,  the  change  in  one  of  the 
variables  Oy  which  attends  a  change  in  the 
other  variable  O^-.  Two  species  of  curve  may 
be  distinguished :  (1)  where  the  quantitative 
relation  between  the  variables  is  not  supposed 
to  be  numerically  ascertained,  the  datum  being 
of  an  indefinite  character,  as  that  0*;  continu- 
ally increases  with  the  decrease  of  Oy  ;  and  (2) 
where  the  curve  is  the  record  of  statistical 
observations, 

(1)  The  lirst  kind  of  curve  is  used  in  abstract 


economics  ;  where  the  data  are  in  general  quan- 
titative indeed  but  not  numerical,  e.g.  that  the 
demand  for  a  commodity  increases  as  its  price 
decreases.  Jevons's  hope  of  obtaining  demand 
curves  by  statistical  observation  {Theory,  Intro- 
duction, p.  23,  2nd  ed.),  may  appear  chimerical. 
There  is  one  datum  of  the  kind  indicated  which 
curves  are  specially  adapted  to  represent,  the 
property  of  increase  at  a  decreasing  rate,  which 
is  at  the  root  of  the  two  most  exact  theories  in 
political  economy,  viz.  the  law  of  rent  and  the 
law  of  final  utility.  This  important  relation  is 
simply  expressed  by  means  of  a  curve  concave 
towards  the  axis  OX  such  as  AB  in  Fig.  1. 
In  this  case  the  quantity  represented  by  the 

Y 


line  0^  continually  increases  with  the  increase 
of  0*-,  but  the  rate  of  increase  continually 
decreases.     The  same  idea  may  be  expressed  by 


a  descending  curve  such  as  AB  in  Fig.  2,  if 
one  quantity  is  represented  by  the  area  con- 
tained between  the  right  lines  OY,  Ox,  xp, 
and  the  curve  AB.  This  quantity  continually 
increases  with  the  increase  of  Ox,  but  at  a 
decreasing  rate.  To  represent  such  relations 
curves  appear  a  more  potent  aid  than  ordinary 
language,  and  perhaps  even  than  algebraic 
symbols.  Diagi-ams  are  preferred  before  sym- 
bols by  Prof.  Marshall  (Principles  of  Economics, 
preface  to  first  edition).  "The  use  of  the 
latter   [diagrams]   requires   no    special   know- 


474 


CURVES— CUSTOM  :    CUSTOMS  DUTIES 


ledge,  and  they  often  express  the  conditions  of 
economic  life  more  accurately  as  well  as  more 
easily  than  do  mathematical  symbols." 

It  may  be  observed,  however,  that,  as  com- 
pared with  Functions  {q.v.),  curves  have  a  some- 
what limited  use.  They  are  almost  restricted 
to  the  simple  case  of  two  variables.  Thus  in 
the  theory  of  rent,  a  curve  happily  represents 
the  returns  yielded  by  successive  applications 
of  doses  of  outlay,  as  in  Jevons's  illustration 
{Theory  of  Political  Economy,  ch.  vi.)  Or, 
according  to  a  construction  which  De  Quincey 
appears  to  have  been  the  iirst  to  use,  the  success- 
ive parts  of  one  co-ordinate  Ox  may  represent 
qualities  of  land  (arranged  in  a  descending 
order),  while  the  corresponding  values  of  Oy 
stand  for  the  returns  made  to  equal  capitals 
applied  to  each  portion  of  land  (cp.  Prof. 
Marshall,  Frinci2)les  of  Economics,  p.  483,  2nd 
ed.)  But,  when  it  is  attempted  to  combine  these 
two  constructions,  as  the  present  writer  has  done 
(British  Association  Report  for  1886),  the  un- 
familiar ideas  of  solids  and  surfaces  are  intro- 
duced ;  and  clearness  is  sacrificed.  To  take 
another  example  (the  Demand  Curves,  q.v.) 
so  much  extolled  by  recent  economists,  are 
available  only  on  the  hypothesis  that,  while 
the  price  of  the  article  under  consideration 
varies,  the  prices  of  all  other  articles  remain 
constant  (Auspitz  und  Lieben  Theorie  der 
Freise).  But  this  is  a  somewhat  narrow  hypo- 
thesis, excluding  the  important  cases  of  "com- 
peting" and  "completing"  commodities  (ibid.), 
as  we  may  call  those  articles  which  are  related 
either  on  the  one  hand,  as  beef  and  mutton, 
or  on  the  other  hand,  as  tea  and  sugar.  In 
such  cases  a  symbolic  expression  representing 
the  advantage  of  the  consumer  as  a  function  of 
his  purchases  is  much  more  helpful  than  a 
curve.  Again,  in  the  theory  of  distribution 
the  profits  of  the  entrepreneur,  depending  on 
the  one  hand  on  the  sales  of  finished  products, 
and  on  the  other  hand  on  the  expenses  of  pro- 
duction, wages,  interest  and  rent,  and  so  forth, 
is  better  represented  by  a  function  of  several 
variables  than  by  a  curve.  A  curve  may  be 
best  adapted  to  the  Ricardian  first  approxima- 
tion that  the  profits  on  successive  doses  of 
capital  are  equal.  But  it  is  not  so  easy  to 
represent  geometrically  the  modifications  of 
this  conception  which  a  nearer  view  requires — 
that  the  profits  of  an  entrepreneur  are  not 
proportional  to  the  amount  of  capital  em- 
ployed, that  the  wages  of  a  labourer  are  in  a 
certain  sense  just  equal  to  the  product  of  his 
labour  (Marshall,  Principles  of  Economics,  2nd 
ed.  vol.  i.  p.  566).  Such  theories  appear  to  the 
present  writer  to  flow  more  naturally  from  the 
analytical  calculus  of  maxima  and  minima  than 
from  any  use  of  curves.  For  further  observa- 
tions as  to  the  use  of  curves  in  economics,  see 
Functions  and  Mathematical  Method. 
(2)    Of  the   curves   obtained   by  statistical 


observation  it  suffices  here  to  remark  that  they 
are  for  the  most  part  derived  from  a  discontinu- 
ous set  of  points,  such  as  p,  q,  r,  s,  in  Fig.  3  (or 
set  of  right  lines  joining  those  points).     Here 


Fig.  3. 
P. 


X4. 


the  lengths  ^a-j  qx^  rx^  sx^  etc.,  represent  the 
quantities  of  some  variable  under  observation 
at  finite  (not  infinitesimal)  intervals  of  time, 
space,  or  other  variable.  Cases  in  which  the 
registration  is  continuous,  as  in  some  meteoro- 
logical observations,  are  rare  in  social  statistics. 
(As  to  the  use  of  curves  in  statistics  see  the 
Geaphical  Method  and  Statistics.) 

y.  F.  Y.  E. 

CUSTODI,  Pietro  (1771-1846),  born  near 
Novara.  He  was  by  profession  a  lawyer,  but 
soon  entered  into  journalism  and  directed  the 
paper  Ainico  dclla  lihcrta  Italiana.  He  be- 
came privy  councillor  and  baron.  The  History 
of  Milan  by  Pietro  Verri  was  continued  by 
Custodi ;  as  an  economist  he  is  widely  known 
as  the  editor  of  a  collection  of  the  princi]5al 
Italian  economists  in  fifty  volumes.         M.  p. 

CUSTODIA.  An  expression  of  Roman  law 
denoting  a  special  duty  of  taking  care  of  a 
bailed  object  (see  Bailee).  e.  s. 

CUSTOM  —  Customs  Duties.  Duties 
charged  by  law  upon  commodities  imported 
into  or  exported  from  a  country.  The  duties 
of  customs  "  seem  to  have  been  called  customs, 
as  denoting  customary  payments  which  had 
been  in  use  from  time  immemorial ;  they 
appear  to  have  been  originally  considered  as 
taxes  upon  the  profits  of  merchants  "  (  Wealth 
of  Nations,  bk.  v.  chap.  ii.  art.  iv.)  As  early 
as  1336,  however,  complaints  were  made  by  the 
producers  of  wool,  at  that  time  the  most  im- 
portant dutiable  article,  that  the  intended 
special  taxation  of  merchants  was  not  effected  by 
customs  duties,  and  from  1344,  when  the  price 
of  wool  ceased  to  be  fixed  by  law,  such  duties 
were  for  a  long  period  supported  by  merchants, 
and  opposed  by  the  agricultural  classes.  In 
1490,  a  "retaliatory"  and  additional  duty  im- 
posed on  malmsey  wine  imported  from  Crete 
"until  the  Venetians  should  abate  their  new 
impositions, "  was  the  first  step  in  the  long  series 
of  duties  imposed  for  other  than  revenue  pur- 
poses, and  eventually  mainly  for  the  protection 
and  encouragement  of  home   industries.      In 


CUSTOM:    CUSTOMS  DUTIES 


475 


1815  when,  as  Mr.  Dowell  says,  *  *  taxation  reached 
its  zenith,"  the  public  demand  that  the  enor- 
mous necessities  of  the  government  should  be 
met  as  far  as  possible  by  the  imposition  of  pro- 
tective tariffs  had  resulted  in  a  customs  system 
of  the  most  complicated  and  onerous  description, 
and  even  when  the  burdens  of  Avar  diminished, 
the  reductions  effected  in  the  customs  duties 
were  small  as  compared  with  the  diminution  of 
the  direct  taxes.  In  1842  Sir  Robert  Peel 
carried  his  first  gi-eat  measure  of  tariff  reform, 
his  policy  being  to  utilise  the  direct  taxes,  and 
especially  the  income-tax,  in  order  to  remove 
the  comparatively  unproductive  duties  with 
which  traders  were  met  in  every  direction.  In 
that  year  some  750  articles  out  of  about  1200 
were  removed  from  the  tariff,  the  loss  to  the 
revenue  being  not  more  than  £1,200,000. 
Three  years  later.  Peel  effected  a  further  revision, 
abolishing  the  duties  on  more  than  400  articles, 
principally  raw  materials,  and  repealing  all  ex- 
port duties,  at  an  aggregate  loss  of  £3,500,000. 
In  1846  the  duties  on  corn  and  some  other 
articles  of  food  were  discarded  at  a  cost  of 
£750,000.  In  1853  Mr.  Gladstone  took  a 
fui'ther  step  in  the  same  direction,  and,  by  the 
same  means  as  his  predecessor.  In  1860  he 
proposed  further  reductions  of  import  duties, 
and  took  what  has  been  described  as  "  the  final 
step  in  the  reform  of  one  of  the  most  compre- 
hensive and  complicated  lists  of  prohibition  and 
commercial  restrictions,  in  the  form  of  frontier 
or  port  duties,  that  ever  hindered  the  develop- 
ment of  the  trade  and  manufactures  of  a  nation." 
This  final  step  involved  a  loss  of  revenue  of 
£2,250,000. 

The  following  table  shows  the  net  produce  of 
customs  duties  in  the  United  Kingdom  in  each 
tenth  year  from  1837  to  1907  inclusive  : — 


1837 

£22,063,000 

1877 

£20,099,000 

1847 

21,656,000 

1887 

19,631,000 

1857 

23,276,000 

1897 

20,618,000 

1867 

22,655,000 

1907 

32,181,000 

The  following  table  shows  in  detail  the  net  pro- 
duce of  the  customs  duties  for  1912-13  : — 
Chicory!         .         .        £46,000 
Cocoa     V        .         .         332,000 
Coffee    J         .         .         170,000 
Tea         .         .  .     6,152,000 


Total  duties  on  imported 
non-alcoholic  beverages     . 
Spkits    .         .         .  £4,167,000 
Wine     .         .         .      1,110,000 
Foreign  Beer  .         .  27,000 


1,700,000 


Total  duties  on  imported 

alcoholic  beverages 

5,304,000 

Sugar  

3,052,000 

Dried  Fruits 

465,000 

Tobacco  and  Snuff 

17,254,000 

Motor  Spirit 

722,000 

Other  Receipts 

20,000 

£33,517,000 

In  1909  the  Excise  department,  formerly 
under  the  control  of  the  Inland  Revenue,  was 
amalgamated  with  the  Customs.  The  two  de- 
partments, though  nominally  independent,  had 
always  worked  in  close  relationship  and  trans- 
acted much  of  each  other's  business,  many  of  the 
duties  collected  by  each  being  interdependent  or 
countervailing.  Both  included  duties  on  beer, 
chicory,  spirits  and  tobacco.  The  arbitrary  dis- 
tinction between  customs  and  excise  in  the  public 
accounts  was  therefore  of  little  value  for  eco- 
nomic purposes.  The  two  departments  now  work 
together  as  the  Board  of  Customs  and  Excise. 

The  department  performs  many  functions 
other  than  the  collection  of  revenue.  It  is 
responsible,  inter  alia,  for  the  measurement  of 
the  tonnage  of  vessels,  the  registration  of  ships, 
the  collection  of  light  dues,  the  receipt  of  wreck, 
the  settlement  of  salvage  claims,  the  mainten- 
ance of  fisheries  conventions,  the  observance 
of  quarantine  regulations,  the  examination  of 
merchandise  marks,  the  collection  of  statistics 
(import  and  export,  etc.),  the  prevention  of 
the  importation  of  injurious  literature,  lottery 
advertisements,  etc.,  the  enrolment  and  pay- 
ment of  men  for  the  Royal  Naval  Reserve.  It 
undertakes  work  in  connection  with  the  Old 
Age  Pensions  and  the  National  Insurance  Act 
(1911).  Under  the  latter  it  investigates  various 
claims  and  questions  and  transmits  the  informa- 
tion collected  to  the  Insurance  Commissioners, 
distributes  Insurance  literature,  and  in  seaport 
towns  gives  information  as  to  the  Seamen's 
National  Insurance  Society.  Under  the  Sale 
of  Food  and  Drugs,  and  similar  Acts,  the  de- 
partment is  entrusted  with  such  duties  as  the 
examination  of  imported  tea  and  the  disposal 
of  all  declared  unfit  for  human  use,  and  the 
prosecution  for  illegal  importations  of  adulter- 
ated or  impoverished  butter  or  milk.  A  number 
of  foreign  reprints  of  English  books  also  are 
annually  confiscated  at  tlie  ports  of  entry  by 
this  department  (Copyright  Act,  1911). 

An  important  feature  of  any  well-organised 
customs  system  is  that  by  which  dutiable  articles 
are  allowed  to  be  deposited  in  warehouses 
under  bond  for  the  due  payment  of  the  duties 
when  delivered  for  consumption  (see  Bonded 
Warehouses).  The  earlier  economists  strongly 
advocated  the  maintenance  of  such  warehouses, 
mainly  on  the  gi'ound  that  the  consumer  escapes 
charges  for  interest  on  the  duties  paid  by  the 
merchant,  but  it  is  now  evident  that  the  system 
is  of  gi-eat  and  very  varied  utility.  Not  only 
is  the  payment  of  duty  deferred,  but  it  is  not 
exacted  at  all  on  the  waste  occasioned  by  natural 
causes,  and  by  the  various  operations  allowed  to 
be  effected  under  supervision  in  bonded  ware- 
houses, prior  to  duty  being  charged.  Bonded 
goods  may  be  removed  from  warehouse  to  ware- 
house, or  they  may  be  re-exported  or  transhipped 
free  of  duty,  which  is  in  fact  only  paid  when 
the  goods  are  to  be  taken  into  consumption. 


476 


CUSTOM— CUSTOM :    HABIT 


The  incidence  of  customs  duties,  like  those  of 
other  taxes  on  commodities  cannot  be  accurately 
determined  without  taking  into  consideration 
the  various  conditions  attending  the  production 
and  supply  of  the  article  taxed,  and  its  relation 
to  the  requirements  of  the  consumer,  and  even 
when  the  incidence  of  such  duties  has  been 
established,  their  effect  in  restricting  interna- 
tional trade,  or  in  diverting  it  from  the  channels 
in  which  it  would  naturally  flow,  must  be  ascer- 
tained before  it  can  be  seen  whether  the  direct 
and  indirect  cost  of  the  duties  outweigh  their 
advantages.  It  is  usually  considered  that  the 
burden  of  customs  duties  will  fall  eventually  upon 
the  consumer,  whether  they  are  charged  on  the 
export  or  on  the  import  of  the  dutiable  article, 
but  in  the  case  of  export  duties  it  usually 
happens  that  the  restriction  of  trade  in  the 
dutiable  article,  or  its  diversion  to  other  markets, 
diminishes  the  profit  of  the  home  producers  and 
distributors  to  an  extent  far  beyond  the  yield  of 
the  duty,  and  in  the  case  of  import  duties  it  has 
been  considered  that  some  portion  of  the  burden 
will  at  times  be  borne  by  the  merchant  by  whom 
the  duties  are  advanced,  his  ability  to  transfer 
it  to  the  consumer  being  by  no  means  absolute. 
(See  Cost  of  Collection  of  Taxes.) 

[Annual  Reports  of  the  Commissioners  of  Cus- 
toms. — Ham's  Customs  Year  Book.  — Dowell's 
History  of  Taxation  and  Taxes  in  England. — 
Hall's  History  of  the  Customs  Revenue.]  t.  h.  b. 

CUSTOM  (Habit)— ITS  Place  in  Eco- 
nomics. When  the  two  are  distinguished,  habit 
is  an  unwritten  law  or  tradition  of  our  indi- 
vidual selves,  custom  is  so  for  a  society  of 
men.  Every  custom  has  thus  begun  in  some 
habit ;  and  both  custom  and  habit  have  a 
power  analogous  to  vis  inertice  as  defined  in 
Newton's  First  Law  of  Motion.  Men  continue 
in  a  state  of  rest  or  of  uniform  motion  in  a 
straight  line,  except  in  so  far  as  they  are  led  to 
change  that  state  by  force  impressed  on  them. 
"Where  actions  are  determined  by  the  necessity 
of  physical,  physiological,  or  even  of  ethical 
laws,  they  are  not  said  to  be  done  by  habit  or 
custom,  the  latter  words  being  confined  to  such 
actions  as  are  more  evidently  modifiable  by 
human  caprice.  They  are  not  used  of  nature 
but  of  second  nature. 

In  men  more  than  in  other  animals  habits 
become  customs,  social  functions  creating  social 
structures.  The  knowledge  of  the  past  is  pre- 
served, and  in  the  case  of  scientific  discoveries 
and  mechanical  inventions,  for  example,  one 
generation  of  learners  can  begin  at  the  point 
where  the  preceding  left  off,  and  convert  into 
habit  and  custom  what  was  at  first  a  con- 
scious efl'ort  and  deliberate  act  of  wiU.  It  is 
an  essential  condition  of  a  skilled,  i.e.  of  nearly 
every  industry  that  practice  makes  perfect ; 
and  the  standard  of  perfection  becomes  higher  if 
the  skill  can  be  transmitted  by  teaching,  and 
need  not  be  acquired  by  each  individual  ab  initio, 


unaided.  This  applies  even  to  the  art  of  walk- 
ing upright  and  the  perception  of  distance  by 
vision.  The  most  familiar  economical  examples 
are  those  given  by  Adam  Smith  in  his  first 
chapters  (see  Division  of  Labour).  To  his 
already  old  text  must  be  added  the  equally  old 
commentary  that  the  bent  and  fitness  of  the 
individuals  must  be  consulted.  Some  are  born 
to  use  tools  ;  others  can  make  better  use  of  their 
eyes  or  voice  than  of  their  hands,  etc.  Where- 
ever  the  bent  lies,  habit  will  be  acquired  fastest 
when  the  bent  is  followed.  In  the  present 
condition  of  the  working  classes  in  Europe  the 
sons  are  as  a  rule  brought  up  to  their  father's 
trade ;  yet,  owing  to  the  frequent  changes 
caused  in  a  trade  by  new  inventions,  this 
practice  can  hardly  lead  to  the  growth  of  castes 
(see  Caste)  such  as  prevail  in  the  East.  But 
even  in  our  own  country  custom  may  often 
make  a  long  stand  against  new  inventions, 
to  the  great  detriment  of  economy,  e.g.  in 
retention  of  fallows  and  opposition  to  reaping 
machines. 

In  the  more  complicated  economical  relations, 
where  distribution  is  concerned,  custom  as  else- 
where may  be  both  a  strength  and  a  weakness, 
to  those  bound  by  it.  It  may  become  an  instru. 
ment  aiding  progress ;  or  it  may  become  a  fetter. 
Customary  rates  of  wages  may  be  rates  that 
neither  fall  so  low  nor  rise  so  high  as  the  rates 
that  would  be  fixed  by  competition  in  open 
market,  and  so  it  is  with  customary  rents  and 
customary  prices.  What  has  always  been  paid  j 
acquires  an  apparent  justification  from  usage 
and  this  is  found  in  the  case  of  taxes,  as 
appears  in  the  very  name  Customs,  where 
novelty  and  unpopularity  as  a  rule  go  together. 
The  times  and  ways  of  payment  are  largely 
fixed  by  custom  more  than  by  conscious  regard 
to  expediency.  Wages,  for  example,  are  paid 
in  the  case  of  London  workmen  by  the  week, 
of  many  Scotch  workmen  by  the'  fortnight,  of 
domestic  servants  by  the  month,  of  many  farm 
servants  by  the  year. 

When  wages  have  been  raised  by  a  temporary 
cause,  they  may  be  maintained  by  custom,  in 
the  sense  that  the  labourers'  standard  of  living 
may  be  permanently  raised.  This  result  can 
hardly  be  secured  without  some  form  of  com- 
bined action  among  the  labourers.  Combina- 
tion implies  criticism  and  initiative,  and  seems 
a  necessary  aid  if  custom  is  to  be  a  strength 
instead  of  a  weakness. 

It  is  only  roughly  true  that  men  are  eman- 
cipated from  custom  in  proportion  to  their 
education.  They  are  seldom  removed  by  it 
from  the  influence  of  fashion  (see  Fashion), 
which  is  simply  a  form  of  custom  where  the 
capriciousness  of  the  unwritten  law  is  not  con- 
cealed, and  where  the  matters  concerned  are. 
supposed  to  be  beyond  exact  utilitarian  calcu- 
lation. Fashion  often  determines  not  only 
what  men  eat  and  wear,  but  where  they  buy 


CUSTOM:    HABIT— DAIRE 


477 


and  even  to  some  extent  what  they  pay. 
The  goodwill  of  a  business  is  simply  this 
fashion  considered  from  the  purveyor's  point 
of  view.  Thomas  Telford  the  engineer  formed 
part  of  the  goodwill  of  the  Salopian  coffee- 
house at  Charing  Cross  (see  Smiles'  Life  of 
Telford).  It  is  perhaps  the  tendency  of  an 
active  commercial  community  to  go  from  the 
one  extreme,  of  regard  for  custom,  to  the  other, 
regard  for  mere  cheapness  as  measured  by  price 
without  due  account  of  quality.  Modern  im- 
provements, such  as  railways,  and  telegraphs, 
and  co-operative  stores,  play  a  great  part  in 
breaking  down  custom  and  causing  a  rough 
equality  even  in  retail  prices.  In  the  whole- 
sale markets,  where  both  sellers  and  buyers 
are  alive  to  their  commercial  interests,  the 
power  of  custom  is  a  smaller  factor  than  in 
retail  dealings.  But  in  the  stock  markets  and 
elsewhere  it  is  still  a  factor  (see  e.g.  Babbage, 
Mach.  avd  Manuf,  3rd  ed.  ch.  xv.  p.  145; — 
Ellis,  "Influence  of  Opinion  on  Markets," 
Economic  Journal,  March  1892,  pp.  109  seq.) 
It  may  be  doubted  if  customary  profit  is  so 
tangible  a  conception  as  it  seemed  to  Adam 
Smith  ;  yet  in  recent  Continental  Usury  Laws 
it  figures  still  very  largely,  as  it  did  in  the 
Middle  Ages.  Where  instead  of  prices  or  profits 
conditions  of  bargaining  are  concerned,  it  is 
not  only  a  factor  but  the  main  factor,  for 
commercial  law  is  simply  the  customs  of  mer- 
chants to  which  the  state  now  gives  legal  eifect. 
There  is  a  sense  in  which  nearly  all  statute  law 
is  custom,  defined,  and  made  consistent  and  it 
may  be  imposed  on  an  unwilling  minority,  as 
in  the  Factory  Acts,  q.v.  To  make  custom 
our  friend  for  life  we  bind  him  under  penalties. 
If  prices  are  affected  by  custom,  still  more 
is  the  currency  itself.  Custom  prevents  our 
adoption  of  a  decimal  currency.  No  money  is 
3urrency  if  it  falls  under  suspicion,  even  ground- 
lessly,  like  Wood's  pence  under  Swift's  attacks, 
and  is  refused  in  ordinary  transactions.  Money 
is  unlike  aU  other  tools  in  depending  almost 
entirely  on  custom,  instead  of  mechanical  fitness, 
for  its  eflSciency.  The  general  outward  char- 
acter of  European  coins  has  accordingly  changed 
only  by  a  seiies  of  variations  which  were,  each. 


very  slight  indeed  at  the  time  of  their  intro- 
duction. To  be  current,  a  coin  needs  to  have 
a  familiar  look  and  resemble  its  predecessors  in 
almost  all  respects.  In  paper  money  too,  as 
in  Scotch  one  pound  and  English  five -pound 
notes,  custom  is  essential  to  currency.  Some- 
what analogous  is  the  recognition  of  articles  as 
good  because  of  a  well-known  trade  mark. 

There  are  many  instances  of  the  power  of 
custom  in  political  history.  Good  statesman- 
ship is  averse  to  an  absolutely  new  departui-e, 
and  makes  only  such  changes  as  at  least  seem 
to  be  an  outgi'owth  of  old  customs,  and  a  return 
to  some  old  Magna  Charta  instead  of  a  new 
institution.  There  is  no  contradiction  between 
custom  and  reflection.  If  the  former  by  itself 
is  inertia,  the  latter  by  itself  is  insubstantial, 
and  its  product  ephemeral,  like  a  learning  that 
dispenses  with  memory  and  history,  and  trusts 
to  unassisted  original  study.  Though,  especially 
in  matters  economical,  deliberate  reflection  and 
calculation  will  inevitably  subject  all  customs 
and  customary  institutions  to  the  test  of  criti- 
cism, yet  any  new  order  will  be  built  up  out 
of  the  materials  of  the  old,  and  -will  only  itself 
be  permanent  by  becoming  customary. 

[For  the  influence  of  custom  on  Prices,  Wages, 
Rent,  etc.,  see  Rlcliard  Joues,  Political  Economy , 
ed.  Whewell,  1859.  Distribution  of  Wealth  (1831). 
—J.  S.  Mill,  Polit.  Econ.,  ii.,  iv.  (1848).— T.  E. 
Cliffe  Leslie,  Essays  in  Pol.  and  Moral  Philosophy, 
2nd  ed.  1888. — On  the  emancipation  of  modern 
industry  from  mediaeval  custom,  etc.,  see  Cobden, 
Engl.,  Irel.,  and  America. — On  custom  and  the 
currency,  see  Jevons,  Money,  ch.  viii.  p.  78,  and 
in  relation  to  the  morphology  of  coins,  see  C.  F. 
Keary,  Numismatic  Chronicle,  v.  165-98,  vi.  41- 
95. — On  custom  and  habit  in  general  see  Rumelin, 
Reden  und  Aufsdtze  (1881),  ii.  pp.  148  seq..  Das 
Wesen  der  Gewohnheit,  and  compare  Hegel,  Rechts- 
philosophie,  §  151. — On  custom  as  standard  of 
living,  see  Malthus,  Essay  on  Pop.,  i.,  ii.,  iv., 
viii.  —  On  fashion,  see  Hermann,  Staatswirth- 
schaftliche  Untersuchungen  (2nd  ed.  1870),  pp.  99, 
100. — On  custom  as  Status  in  distinction  from 
Contract,  see  Maine,  Ancient  Law,  passim. — On 
goodwill,  etc.,  see  Schaffle,  Die  nationalokono- 
mische  Theorie  der  ausschliessenden  Absatzver- 
hdltnisse  (Tiibingen)  1867.]  J.  b. 


DAIRE,  EuGfeNE,  born  in  Paris  1798,  died 
there  1847.  He  commenced  life  as  a  collector 
of  the  contributions  directes,  a  direct  tax  on  in- 
dividuals imposed  on  their  incomes,  at  Arpajon 
(Seine -et-Oise),  but  was  dismissed  from  his 
employment  after  the  revolution  of  1830,  on 
account  of  the  opinions  held  by  a  relation  of  his, 
which  he  himself,  however,  did  not  share.  He 
was  afterwards  restored  to  his  post  at  the  request 
of  the  inhabitants  of  the  place.  In  1839  he 
resigned  his  office,  desiring  to  apply  himself  to 
economic    study.       After    some    preliminary 


attempts  he  discovered  the  direction  in  which  his 
true  vocation  lay,  and  devoted  himself  to  pre- 
paring the  collection  of  the  works  of  the  principal 
economists,  published  by  Messrs.  Guillaumin. 
Of  the  fifteen  volumes  of  this  collection  he  edited 
six  :  Les  J^conomistes  financiers  du  XVIIIe  siecle 
(Vaubanj  Boisguillebert,  J.  Law,  Melon,  and 
Dutot),  Les  Physiocrates  (Quesnay,  Dupont  de 
Nemours,  Mercier  de  la  Riviere,  Abbe  Baudeau, 
and  Le  Trosne),  the  (Euwes  de  Turgot,  the 
(Euvres  diverses  de  J.  B.  Say,  the  first  volume 
of  M^latiges  (David  Hume,  V.  de  Forbonnais, 


478 


DALBIAC— DAMAGES 


Condillac,  Condorcet,  Lavoisier,  and  Franklin). 
Daire  wrote,  in  these  volumes,  a  special  notice  of 
each  author.  Some  of  these  are  of  great  value, 
for  example,  those  of  Law  and  Turgot.  Equally 
important  is  his  introductory  exposition  of  "  the 
theories  of  the  Physiocrats,"  which  gained  him 
a  prize  of  1500  fr.  (£60)  from  the  Academy  of 
Moral  and  Political  Science.  The  news  of  this 
success  only  reached  him  on  his  deathbed.  An 
able  financier  and  a  distinguished  economist, 
Daire  was  too  early  lost  to  the  science,  of 
which,  had  his  life  been  spared,  he  might  have 
been  a  distinguished  expositor.  A.  c.  f. 

DALBIAC,  General  Sir  James  Charles 
(1776-1848),  served  with  distinction  in  the 
Peninsular  War,  was  Tory  member  for  Ripon 
1835-37.  He  published,  in  1841  (London),  A 
few  words  on  the  com  laws,  wherein  are  hroiight 
under  consideration  certain  of  the  statements 
which  are  to  he  found  in  the  Srd  ed.  of  Mr. 
M'GullocKs  pamphlet  on  the  same  subject.  See 
M'Culloch,  Liter,  of  Pol.  Eeon.,  p.  80.  He 
wrote  also  a  Military  Catechism  for  the  use  of 
young  Officers  and  non-commissioned  Offi/xrs  of 
Cavalry  (1817). 

To  the  same  author  is  perhaps  to  be  attributed 
the  following  tract  ascribed  on  the  title  page  to 
"J.  a.  Dalbiac,  of  Buckham  Hall,  Uckfield  " 
(Sussex).  Proofs  of  existing  agricultural  dis- 
tress, and  an  endeavour  to  show  the  necessity  of 
permanent  and  efficient  protection  to  agriculture 
by  permanent  and  efficient  legislative  enactments 
(Lewes,  1820).  The  writer  employs  the  form 
of  a  dialogue  between  a  farmer  and  a  manu- 
facturer. He  argues  in  the  spuit  of  Western, 
whose  "Resolutions"  of  March  1816  he  quotes 
in  his  appendix.  j.  b. 

DALRYMPLE,  Sir  John,  4th  baronet  (1726- 
1810),  was  the  eldest  son  of  Sir  William 
Dalrymple  of  Cranstoun.  He  was  educated 
at  Edinburgh  and  at  Cambridge,  and  became 
an  advocate  at  the  Scottish  bar  in  1748.  From 
1776  to  1807  he  was  one  of  the  barons  of  the 
exchequer.  In  1757  he  published  an  Ussay 
towards  a  General  History  of  Feudal  Property 
in  England  (4th  and  enlarged  edition,  1759, 
8vo),  praised  by  Hume  (J.  H.  Burton,  Life, 
ii.  37).  Part  of  this  work  was  revised  by 
Montesquieu.  Dalrymple  printed  in  1764  Con- 
siderations on  the  Polity  of  Entails  (2nd  ed.  1765, 
8vo),  a  very  able  defence.  His  Memoirs  of 
Great  Britain  and  Ireland,  1681-92  (3  vols.  4to, 
1771-88,  new  ed.  1790,  3  vols.  8vo),  largely 
based  upon  unpublished  documents,  is  chiefly 
interesting  from  a  biographical  and  anecdotal 
point  of  view.  He  received  a  visit  from  Dr. 
Johnson  at  Cranstoun  in  1773  (Boswell,  Life, 
1887,  V.  pp.  401-404).  He  was  given  to 
chemical  and  industrial  experiments,  and  in 
1798  interested  himself  in  teaching  the  making 
of  soap  from  herrings.  He  was  succeeded  in 
the  baronetcy  by  his  fourth  son,  who  became 
eiglith  earl  of  Stair  in  1840. 


His  economic  writings  are  : 

An  Appeal  to  Facts  in  a  Letter  to  Earl  Temple, 
London,  1763,  4to  (includes  an  account  of  the 
money  raised  on  loan  for  the  public  service  from 
1755  to  1762). — The  Question  considered:  Whetlier 
wool  should  be  allowed  to  he  reported  when  the 
price  is  low  at  home  on  paying  a  duty  to  the  public  ? 
London,  1781  (2nd  ed.  1782,  answered  by  Rev.  N. 
Forster  and  two  anonymous  pamphleteers.  The 
author  gives  various  reasons  why  it  should  be 
permitted). — Address  and  Proposals  on  the  subject 
of  the  coal,  tar,  and  iron  branches  of  trade,  London, 
1784,  8vo  (written  to  attract  the  attention  of 
speculators  to  the  coal,  ironstone,  and  limestone  on 
his  estate  in  Edinburgh). — Address  to  the  Land- 
holders of  England  upon  the  interest  which  they 
have  in  the  state  of  the  distillery  laws,  London, 
1786,  8vo  (proposes  a  tax  on  stills). 

[Dictionary  of  Nat.  Biogr.,  xiii.  424-425  : 
M'Culloch,  Literature  of  Political  Economy,  1845]. 

H.  K.  T. 

DAMAGES.  The  technical  name  for  a  sum 
of  money  claimed  by  a  person  who  has  suffered 
injury  or  loss  by  reason  of  a  breach  of  contract 
or  of  another's  wrongful  act  or  omission.  In 
actions  for  damages  it  belongs  to  the  province 
of  the  jury  to  assess  the  amount,  but  there  are 
certain  established  rules,  according  to  which 
they  ought  to  find,  and  which  the  judge  ought 
to  explain  to  them,  e.g.  the  rule  relating  to 
remoteness  of  damage,  according  to  which  the 
loss  for  which  compensation  is  claimed  must 
be  something  immediately  connected  with  the 
breach  of  contract  or  wrongful  act  or  omission, 
and  must  be  such  as  the  defendant  would 
reasonably  have  contemplated  as  the  result  of 
such  breach,  act,  or  omission.  The  non-receipt 
of  money  promised  to  be  paid  on  a  certain  date 
may  prevent  the  promisee  from  making  a  pro- 
fitable investment,  or  may  even,  through  caus- 
ing his  insolvency,  bring  about  the  ruin  of  his 
prospects  ;  but  these  are  not  the  ordinary 
results  of  the  non-payment  of  a  debt,  and  no 
damages  can  therefore  be  claimed  beyond  the 
amount  of  the  debt  with  interest.  In  a  case  of 
breach  of  contract  for  the  sale  of  goods,  the 
measure  of  damages  is  the  difference  between 
the  price  named  in  the  contract  and  the  market 
value  of  the  like  goods  at  the  time  when  the 
contract  was  broken.  As  a  general  rule, 
damages  are  not  awarded  as  a  compensation  for 
injuries  which  do  not  result  in  a  pecuniary  loss, 
but  in  exceptional  cases  it  is  admissible  to 
compensate  the  plaintiff"  for  wounded  feelings 
or  bodUy  pain,  e.g.  in  actions  for  breach  of' 
promise  to  marry,  in  actions  for  defamation , 
(libel  or  slander),  in  actions  for  assault,  etc. 

In  some  cases  the  conduct  of  the  defendant 
may  be  such  as  to  make  it  permissible  for  the , 
jury  to  award  damages  in  excess  of  the  amount  j 
which  would  be  sufficient  to  compensate  thai 
plaintiff"  for  the  injury  suff"ered  by  him,  e.g. 
trespass  of  a  particularly  insulting  character, 
seduction    under    aggravating    circumstances. 


I 


DAMAGES— DAMNUM  EMERGENS 


479 


In  such  a  case  the  damages  are  said  to  be 
"exemplary"  or  "vindictive."  On  the  other 
hand  the  damages  may  be  so  small  that  they 
could  not  reasonably  be  looked  upon  as  com- 
pensation for  any  injiiry.  Damages  of  the 
latter  kind,  which  in  technical  language  are 
called  "nominal  damages,"  may  occur  in  two 
classes  of  oases  :—(l)  When  the  plaintiflTs  in- 
tention is  not  so  much  to  obtain  compensation, 
as  to  make  use  of  an  action  for  damages  as  a 
convenient  mode  of  procedure  for  asserting  a 
right,  e.g.  action  of  trespass  for  the  purpose  of 
establishing  a  title  to  lands ;  (2)  When  the 
plaintiff,  though  technically  in  the  right,  ought 
not,  according  to  the  opinion  of  the  jury,  to 
succeed  in  the  action,  e.g.  in  action  for  defama- 
tion when  the  defendant  through  flaws  in  the 
evidence,  has  failed  to  establish  his  plea  of 
justification,  but  has  convinced  the  jury  that 
the  plaintiff's  character  is  worthless.  The 
expression  "  ordinary  damages  "  is  used  in  con- 
tradistinction to  "nominal"  or  "exemplary" 
damages.  In  certain  cases  it  is  recognised  by 
the  law  that  the  requirements  of  the  plaintiff 
cannot  be  adequately  satisfied  by  damages,  and 
Specific  Performance  {q.v.)  is  decreed,  e.  s. 
DAMAGES,  Measure  of.  Damages  are  the 
pscuniary  satisfaction  which  a  plaintiff  may 
obtain  by  success  in  an  action.  The  rules  by 
which  such  satisfaction  is  measured  form  a 
branch    of    law    known    as    the    Measure    of 


[See  as  to  English  Law,  Damages,  by  J.  D. 
Mayne  and  L.  Smith,  London,  1884  ;  and  as  to 
American  Law,  The  Measure  of  Damages,  by  T. 
Sedgwick,  New  York,  1874.]  j.  e.  c.  m. 

DAMETH,  Henri  (1812-1884),  born  at 
Paray-le-Monial  (Sa6ne-et- Loire),  died  at 
Geneva.  He  was  in  early  life  a  devoted  fol- 
lower of  Fourier  {q.v.),  but  became,  through 
conscientious  study,  one  of  the  most  ardent 
popularisers  of  economic  science.  He  published 
in  1842  a  work  entitled  Defense  du  FourUrisme, 
1  vol.  in  18mo ;  then  in  1849,  Un  Tnimoire 
sur  lafoTidation  des  citis  industrielles  dites  ciUs 
de  V  Union,  in  8vo;  after  this  he  filled,  from 
1850  to  1855,  the  position  of  editor-in-chief  to 
the  Avenir  de  Nice.  Becoming  convinced  of 
the  soundness  of  economic  theory  he  shook 
himself  clear  of  the  doctrines  of  Fourier,  and 
published:  Le  Juste  et  V Utile,  1859,  1  vol.  in 
8vo  ;  L'J^cononiie  politique  et  le  spiritu/ilisme, 
1862,  1  vol.  in  8vo;  Introduction  d  Vitude  de 
Veconomie  politique,  1865,  1  vol.  in  8vo;  Les 
Banques  publiques  d' Amission,  1866,  1  vol.  in 
8vo  (in  this  he  supported  the  freedom  of  banks)  ; 
Le  mouvement  socialiste  et  Viconomie  politique, 
1869,  1  vol.  in  18mo ;  La  question  sodale,  1871, 
1  vol.  in  12mo ;  and  finally  Les  Bases  naturelles 
de  I'iconomie  sodale,  1872,  1  vol.  in  18mo. 
He  lectured  with  success,  in  1864,  on  political 
economy  at  Lyons,  in  connection  with  the 
chamber  of  commerce  of  that  city,  and  at  the 


Academy  of  Geneva,  from  1865.  His  works 
are  lucid  in  style  and  temperate  in  tone.  He 
assisted  MM.  Victor  Philippe,  Jean  Tisseur,  and 
Alph.  Courtois  in  founding  the  Society  of  Politi- 
cal Economy  at  Lyons  (1866).  a.  c.  f. 

DAMNUM  EMERGENS,  i.e.  the  loss  or 
injury  resulting  to  one  person  in  consequence 
of  his  having  made  a  loan  to  another,  was 
usually  regarded  by  canonists  and  theologians 
in  the  later  middle  ages  as  justifying  a  demand 
for  Interest  (in  the  original  and  limited  sense 
of  that  word,  q.v.)  The  doctrine  of  compensa- 
tion to  the  creditor  arose  out  of  an  obscure 
passage  in  the  Roman  law  ;  and  the  sharp  dis- 
tinction between  damnum  emergens  and  Lucrum 
Cessans  {q.v.),  which  was  for  a  long  time 
rigidly  observed  by  writers  on  the  subject  seems 
to  have  been  first  drawn  by  the  greatest  of  the 
mediaevaf  glossators,  Accursius.  But  while  the 
civil  law  recognised  both  these  reasons  as  justi- 
fying a  demand  for  compensation,  Aquinas  and 
many  of  the  schoolmen  accepted  only  damnum 
emergens.  Until  the  end  of  the  middle  ages, 
moreover,  the  principle  was  maintained  that 
compensation  was  only  due  when  the  period  for 
which  the  loan  was  originally  made  had  expired, 
and  the  debtor  showed  culpable  neglect  in  ful- 
filling his  obligations.  The  theoretical  distinc- 
tion between  usury  and  interest  tended,  how- 
ever, to  disappear,  owing  to  (1)  the  concession, 
which  even  Aquinas  made,  that  such  a  recom- 
pense could  be  justly  bargained  for  at  the  time 
of  making  the  loan,  (2)  the  concession  that  the 
payment  might  take  the  form  of  a  certain 
percentage  for  each  period  of  delay,  and  (3) 
the  practice  of  making  the  original  term,  during 
which  no  payment  for  the  use  of  the  money  was 
required,  so  short  that  the  loan  came  to  bear  in- 
terest almost  from  the  first.  The  final  step  was 
taken  when  some  of  the  Protestant  theologians, 
especially  Melanchthon,  and  many  of  the  later 
Roman  Catholic  canonists,  especially  Navarrus, 
recognised  the  justice  of  contracting  to  receive 
interest  even  before  there  had  been  any  delay, 
i.e.  from  the  time  the  loan  was  contracted.  As 
by  this  time  lucrum  cessans  had  also  cojne  to 
be  accepted  as  a  sufficient  cause  for  the  payment 
of  interest,  it  was  possible  to  meet  all  the 
necessities  of  the  growing  trade  of  the  period 
without  a  violent  breach  with  the  doctrine  of 
usury. 

A  characteristic  example  of  the  transitional 
literature  of  the  16th  century  is  The  Arraignment 
and  Conviction  of  Usury  by  Miles  Mosse,  London, 
1595.  He  sums  up  the  matter  as  follows  :  "  There 
are  two  manifest  and  essential  differences  between 
Usury  and  Interest,  which  do  so  distinguish  the 
one  from  the  other,  as  that  they  cannot  possibly 
be  confounded.  One  difference  is  this  :  Usury  is 
an  overplus  or  gain  taken  more  than  was  lent ; 
Interest  is  never  gain  or  overplus  above  the  princi- 
pal, but  a  recompense  demanded  and  due  for  the 
damage  that  is  taken  or  the  gain  that  is  hindered 
through   lending.      Another   difference  is    this : 


480 


DAMNUM  FATALE— DANGEUL 


Usury  accrueth  and  groweth  due  by  lending,  from 
the  day  of  borrowing,  unto  the  appointed  time  of 
payment ;  Interest  is  never  due  but  from  the 
appointed  day  of  payment  forward,  and  for  so 
long  as  I  forbear  my  goods  after  the  day  in  which 
I  did  covenant  to  receive  them  again,"    w.  J.  a. 

[By  far  the  best  treatment  of  the  subject  is  to 
be  found  in  Endemann,  Studien  in  der  Momanisch- 
hanonistischen  Wirthschafts-  und  Rechtslehre,  vol. 
ii.  (1883)  ch.  viii.  §§  1-3.  For  the  views  of  the 
Reformers,  see  also  Schmoller,  Zur  Geschichte  der 
national6kon.Ansichtenin  Deutschland,  etc.  1861, 
p.  98  [reprinted  from  Zeitschr.  /.  d.  ges.  Staats- 
wissenschaft,  Bd.  xvi.  ]  The  subject  is  also  slightly 
touched  in  F.  X.  Funk,  Zins  u.  Wucher,  1868, 
and  Geschichte  des  Kirchlichen  Zinsverbotes,  1876. 
For  brief  accounts  in  English,  see  Ashley,  JSco- 
nomic  History,  vol.  i.  part  i.  (1888),  and  Bohm- 
Bawerk,  Capital  and  Interest,  tr.  Smart,  1890.] 

DAMNUM  FATALE  (Scot.)  Loss  arising 
from  inevitable  accident  beyond  prevention  by 
human  prudence.  a.  t). 

DANEGELD.  This  is  the  first  money  tax 
of  which  we  have  any  record  in  English  history. 
Ethelred  IL  levied  two  shillings  on  every  hide 
of  land  to  provide  a  fund  for  buying  off  the 
Danes.  His  successors,  even  the  Danish  kings, 
retained  this  as  an  annual  tax,  long  after  the 
original  pretext  had  disappeared.  Edward  the 
Confessor  is  said  to  have  abolished  the  Dane- 
geld,  but  William  L  again  exacted  it,  though 
at  three  times  the  original  rate,  viz.  six  shillings 
for  every  hide.  But  under  the  Norman  kings 
it  was  an  occasional  instead  of  an  annual  tax. 
That  tlie  impost  was  unpopular  is  proved  by 
the  assertion  of  Henry  of  Huntingdon  tliat 
Stephen,  on  his  accession,  promised  to  abolish 
it.  The  promise  was  not  kept,  and  the  Dane- 
geld  was  regularly  collected  in  the  first  seven 
years  of  Henry  IL's  reign.  By  this  time  the 
tax  had  become  a  fixed  sum  from  each  county, 
and  any  surplus  went  into  th.e  pockets  of  the 
sherifis  who  collected  it.  In  1163  Henry  IL 
proposed  to  take  the  tax  out  of  the  hands  of 
the  sherifis,  and  to  bring  it  direct  into  the 
exchequer.  The  proposal  was  opposed  by 
Becket,  and  from  this  time  the  term  Danegeld 
disappears  from  the  Pipe  Kolls.  It  has  often 
been  asserted  that  Becket's  opposition  led  to 
the  abolition  of  the  tax,  but  this  is  an  error. 
The  two  shillings  from  the  hide  were  frequently 
levied  in  the  later  years  of  Henry  II.  under  the 
name  of  hydagium.  They  were  collected  under 
Kichard  I.  in  1194,  and  in  1198  were  raised  to 
five  shillings  on  the  hide  or  carucate.  Dane- 
geld and  hydagium  are  merely  two  names  for 
the  same  tax,  which  was  collected  from  all  free 
tenants,  whether  holding  by  knight-service  or 
by  socage. 

[Dialogus  de  Scaccario,  i.  11. — Stubbs,  Consti- 
tutional History,  vol.  i.]  b.  l. 

DANGEUL,  Makquis  de  Pltjmart  (fl. 
1750),  was  born  at  Mans,  and  became  a 
commissioner  of  the  Cour  des  Comptes.     He  was 


a  relative  of  Forbonnais,  and,  like  him,  devoted 
himself  to  the  study  of  the  works  of  the  Spanish 
mercantilists.  He  translated  one  of  these : 
Le  Ritahlissement  des  manufactures  et  du  com- 
merce d'Espagne,  traduit  de  Vespagnx)l  de  Bernard 
de  Ulloa,  1763.  After  this,  at  the  suggestion 
of  Gournay,  he,  as  Turgot  did,  made  himself 
acquainted  with  the  works  of  Josiah  Tucker, 
and  following  Tucker  in  the  lines  of  free  trade 
and  development  of  commercial  enterprise,  he 
wrote  his  book  Remarques  sur  les  avantages  et 
les  disavantages  de  la  France  et  de  la  Grande 
Bretagne  par  rapport  au  Commerce  et  aux  autres 
Sources  de  la  Puissance  des  J^tats.  Traduit  de 
VAnglois  du  Chevalier  John  Nickolls,  Leyde  et 
Paris,  Estienne,  1754.  This  work  is  pseudony- 
mous ;  the  author  admits  that  he  borrowed  the 
title  and  the  introductory  sections  from  Tucker's 
Brief  Essay  on  Trade  (1750).  In  it  he  expresses 
his  regret  at  the  want  of  interest  in  economic 
questions  in  France  (p.  49),  he  states  the  diffi- 
cult problems  of  agricultural  and  financial  policy 
in  which  his  country  was  involved  ;  he  describes 
the  strength  of  the  leisured  and  the  wants  of 
the  labouring  classes  ("p.  60),  the  efi'ects  of 
unequal  taxation  (p.  43),  and  the  absenteeism 
of  the  nobles  (p.  64),  the  centralisation  of 
government,  the  multitude  of  holidays,  and  the 
low  standard  of  the  working  classes  (p.  26). 
On  the  other  hand  he  praises  English  husbandry 
as  being  the  time  mine  of  riches  (p.  101),  and 
shows  the  practical  and  theoretic  literary  interest 
taken  in  English  trade  (p.  152).  Dangeul,  how- 
ever, condemns,  like  Tucker,  the  monopoly  of 
the  home  trade,  exercised  in  England,  by  cor- 
porations and  companies  (pp.  205-216),  as  being 
opposed  to  the  interests  of  the  population  and 
its  growth.  According  to  both,  competition, 
entirely  unfettered,  is  most  advantageous  for 
a  nation's  trade,  as  it  diminishes  the  profits  of 
dealers  (p.  253)  and  assists  the  introduction  of 
machinery  in  manufactures.  Dangeul  is  an 
admirer  of  Decker's  Proposal  for  a  single  tax  on 
luxmies  in  lieu  of  duties  and  excises  (p.  404)  ; 
he  also  differs  from  Forbonnais  in  one  very 
important  point  of  taxation :  he  proposes  to 
exempt  the  absolute  necessaries  of  life,  con- 
sidering that  the  taxation  of  these  extinguishes 
the  spirit  of  private  property  among  the  poor 
(pp.  407-409).  In  1756  he  wrote  anonymously, 
Examen  de  la  conduite  de  la  Grande  Bretagne  d 
Vusa^e  de  la  Hollande  depuis  la  naissance  de 
la  ripuUique,  Paris  et  La  Haye,  1756.  The 
writings  of  Dangeul  are  interesting  in  so  far^^ 
as  they  are  evidence  of  the  practical  influence] 
of  the  now  undeservedly  neglected  Dean  of] 
Gloucester,  Josiah  Tucker,  the  spiritual  father] 
of  Gournay,  Dangeul,  Turgot,  and  also  of  Adai 
Smith. 

[See  Querard,  La  France  littiraire,  t.  vii.  p.  21 J 
— M'Culloch,  Literature  of  Political  Economy, 
62. — Morellet,  MSmoii'es  (inSdits),  1823,  t.  i.  pp. 
37-38. — Tucker,  Instructions  for  Travellers,  1757,- 


DARG— DARWINISM 


481 


p.  9. — Quesnay,  Oeuvres,  ed.  Oncken,  pp.  148, 
206  note  2,  p.  230  note  2,  approving  quotation  by 
Voltaire,  Dictionnaire  Philosophiqibe,  1765,  art. 
Agriculture,  Oeuvres  Completes,  1875,  ch.  xvii. 
p.  83. — Le  Blanc,  Discours  politiques  de  M.  Hume, 
Dresde,  1755,  t.  i.  p.  21 ;  t.  ii.  p.  271.]        8.  b. 

DARG.  A  Scottish  term  for  a  day's  work. 
Cottars  were  formerly  bound  to  give  the  labour 
of  a  certain  number  of  days  to  their  superior  in 
lieu  of  rent :  these  days  were  called  darg-days, 
i.e.  days  of  work. 

[Scottish  Dictionary  (Supplement),  by  John 
Jamieson,  Edinburgh,  1825.]  J.  B.  C.  M. 

DARIC.  Ancient  Persian  coin  of  approxi- 
mately pure  gold,  first  sti'uck  about  1516  B.C. 
by  Darius  I.,  bearing  the  effigy  of  the  king  as 
an  archer,  but  with  no  inscription.  Double 
darics,  struck  about  the  time  of  the  fall  of  the 
empire,  bear  Greek  letters  or  symbols,   f.  e.  a. 

DARIEN  COMPANY.  The  originator  of 
this  disastrous  enterprise  was  "William  Paterson, 
the  founder  of  the  Bank  of  England.  His  idea 
was  to  found  a  company  for  colonising  the 
Isthmus  of  Darien,  and  conducting  overland 
the  trade  between  the  Atlantic  and  Pacific. 
By  this  means,  he  thought,  the  whole  commerce 
between  Europe  and  Asia  might  be  diverted 
from  the  route  round  the  Cape,  and  Scotland 
might  supplant  Holland  as  the  great  emporium 
for  the  wealth  of  the  East.  Without  divulging 
the  details  of  his  scheme,  he  succeeded  in 
exciting  the  speculative  interest  of  his  country- 
men, and  a  bill  to  establish  the  new  company 
was  carried  through  the  Scotch  Parliament  and 
received  the  sanction  of  the  Lord  High  Commis- 
sioner on  26tli  June  1695.  The  "Company 
of  Scotland  trading  to  Africa  and  the  Inrlies," 
was  authorised  to  seize  unoccupied  territories 
in  Asia,  Africa,  and  America,  to  plant  colonies, 
construct  forts,  wage  war  and  conclude  treaties  ; 
while  the  king  was  pledged  to  obtain  reparation 
from  any  foreign  state  which  molested  the 
company.  The  company  received  a  monopoly 
of  the  trade  with  Asia,  Africa,  and  America  for 
thirty-one  years,  and  for  twenty-one  years  their 
imports,  except  sugar  and  tobacco,  were  to  be 
free  from  all  duties.  Scotchmen  hastened  to 
invest  their  scanty  savings  in  the  new  venture, 
and  £220,000  was  actually  contributed  towards 
a  nominal  capital  of  £400,000.  But  Scotland 
was  then  a  poor  country,  and  the  financial 
success  of  the  scheme  could  only  be  secured  by 
English  support. 

The  hostility  of  England,  in  those  days  of 
commercial  jealousy,  was  from  the  first  a 
certainty.  A  new  trading  colony  would 
certainly  lead  to  war  with  the  country  whose 
monopoly  was  attacked,  and  the  burden  of  such 
a  war  must  fall  upon  England,  as  Scotland  had 
neither  army,  nor  navy,  nor  military  revenue. 
England  would  never  go  to  war  to  secure  to 
Scotland  trading  privileges  which  would  be 
injurious  to  herself.  The  English  Parliament 
VOL.  L 


protested  against  the  scheme,  and  William  III. 
recalled  the  commissioner  who  had  given  the 
royal  sanction  to  the  act.  No  English  capital 
was  subscribed,  and  it  was  even  proposed  to 
prosecute  the  directors  of  the  company. 

But  English  opposition,  ascribed  to  national 
jealousy,  only  increased  the  obstinate  determina- 
tion of  the  Scotch  to  carry  out  the  enterprise. 
In  1698  some  1200  colonists,  including  Paterson 
and  his  wife,  sailed  from  Leith  to  Darien, 
where  they  took  formal  possession  of  the 
country  under  the  name  of  New  Caledonia, 
concluded  treaties  with  native  chieftains, 
established  a  representative  parliament,  and 
began  to  fortify  New  Edinburgh  as  their  capital. 
The  enterprise  was  almost  insane  in  its  rashness. 
The  isthmus  had  been  discovered  and  crossed 
by  Spaniards  nearly  two  centuries  before,  and 
they  had  only  failed  to  settle  there  because  it 
was  too  unhealthy  for  Europeans  to  live  there. 
But  Spain  would  never  tolerate  foreign  intruders 
in  the  heart  of  her  American  provinces,  and  an 
expedition  was  being  fitted  out  to  expel  the 
settlers  when  disease  compelled  the  decimated 
remnant  to  sail  to  New  York.  Before  this 
terrible  news  reached  Scotland  a  second  expedi- 
tion had  sailed  to  Darien,  where  they  arrived  four 
months  after  the  departure  of  the  first  colonists, 
to  find  New  Edinburgh  a  deserted  ruin.  With 
the  courage  of  despair  the  new  settlers  landed, 
but  their  fate  was  already  sealed  by  dissensions 
and  disease,  when  the  arrival  of  a  Spanish  fleet 
compelled  the  survivors  to  surrender  and  return 
homewards.  The  ill-feeling  which  this  ill- 
starred  undertaking  excited  between  England 
and  Scotland,  and  the  risk  of  similar  misunder- 
standings of  the  same  nature,  gave  an  impulse 
to  the  projects  of  a  legislative  union  between 
the  two  counti'ies  which  was  finally  effected 
in  1707. 

[The  best  modern  narrative  of  the  Darien  Ex- 
pedition is  to  be  found  in  Macaulay's  History  oj 
England,  vol.  iv.]  R.  L. 

DARWINISM  is  a  name  sometimes  given  to 
the  theory  put  forward  in  Darwin's  Origin  of 
Species  that  the  struggle  for  existence  among 
plants  and  animals  results  in  natural  selection 
or  survival  of  the  fittest  varieties.  This 
theory  is  sometimes  spoken  of  (e.g.  in  Maine's 
Popular  Government,  p.  37)  as  if  it  had  been 
anticipated  in  Malthus's  doctrine  of  population. 
But  Malthus,  though  he  insists  on  the  fact  of 
the  struggle  for  existence  among  mankind,  had 
no  notion  of  its  altering  or  improving  the 
human  race  by  causing  the  fittest  varieties  to 
survive.  Darwin  {Life  and  Letters,  vol.  i.  p. 
83),  says  that  the  idea  of  natural  selection 
occurred  to  him  on  reading  Malthus's  Essay, 
not  that  he  found  it  there. 

Mr.  Herbert  Spencer  and  some  writers  who 
have  followed  him  have  used  the  theory  as  an 
argument  against  state  interference  with  private 
property   and   industrial   competition.      They 

2i 


482 


DATE  OF  DRAWING— DAVANZATI 


urge  that  if  the  state  interferes  with  the  struggle 
for  existence  it  will  hinder  natural  selection, 
and  thus  obstruct  the  evolution  of  a  superior 
race;  "Now  more  than  ever  before,"  Mr. 
Spencer  asserts,  "people  are  doing  all  they  can 
to  further  survival  of  the  unfittest "  {Man  versus 
the  State,  p.  69).  The  socialist  meets  this 
argument  by  pointing  out  that  "survival  of 
the  fittest "  means  survival  of  those  who  are 
fittest  to  undergo  a  particular  struggle,  not 
those  who  are  the  absolutely  best,  and  if  the 
struggle  is  abolished  it  will  not  matter  whether 
people  are  fit  for  it  or  not  (Sidney  Webb, 
Contemporary  Review,  Dec.  1889,  pp.  868,  869). 
Prof.  Huxley  says  :  "  It  is  an  error  to  imagine 
that  evolution  signifies  a  constant  tendency 
to  increased  perfection"  {Nineteenth  Century, 
Feb.  1888,  p.  163),  and  even  if  it  were  uni- 
versally admitted  that  the  absolutely  best 
individuals  of  each  generation  do  come  to  the 
top  in  industrial  competition,  it  might  still  be 
questioned  whether  this  results  in  the  survival 
of  the  best  families.  Mr.  Francis  Galton  urges 
very  strongly  that  the  Malthusian  advice  to 
delay  the  period  of  marriage  is  likely  "to 
bring  utter  ruin  upon  the  breed  of  any  country 
where  it  is  followed  by  the  prudent,  while  the 
imprudent  are  left  free  to  disregard  it "  {Heredi- 
tary Genius,  p.  356).  Now  the  wealthier  and 
therefore  presumably  "fitter"  individuals 
certainly  marry  later  than  the  poorer  (see 
Marriage-Eate),  and  it  cannot  be  said  to  be 
proved  that  the  greater  mortality  among  the 
poor  is — or  would  be  if  there  were  no  state 
interference — sufficient  to  counterbalance  their 
earlier  marriages  and  so  to  make  them  less  eflec- 
tive  continuers  of  the  race  than  the  wealthy. 

The  subject  has  not  been  much  discussed  by 
economists  of  any  school,  because  the  analogy 
between  industrial  competition  and  the  struggle 
for  existence  among  the  lower  animals  is  too 
imperfect  to  be  of  much  service.  It  is  contrary 
to  sound  economic  traditions  to  look  upon  com- 
petition as  a  "private  war"  (Maine,  Popular 
Government,  p.  50),  and  on  an  improvement  in 
the  powers  of  labour  as  "sharpening  our  claws 
that  we  may  fight  our  neighbours  the  more 
fiercely  "  (Kitchie,  Darwinism  and  Politics,  p. 
31).  Competition  is  not  a  struggle  for  a  pre- 
existing determinate  quantity  of  wealth,  in 
which  each  man's  gain  is  so  much  subtracted 
from  the  possible  gains  of  all  the  rest.  Though 
the  success  of  one  producer  often  damages  other 
producers  of  the  same  commodity,  it  almost 
always  benefits  the  community  at  large,  and 
makes  it  not  more  difficult  but  easier  to  obtain 
the  means  of  existence.  Thus  it  happens  that 
in  countries  where  the  industrial  powers  are 
most  highly  developed,  individuals  who  have 
naturally  the  least  industrial  power,  e.g.  the 
blind,  deaf  and  dumb,  and  paralytic,  find  it 
easier  to  make  a  living  than  they  do  in  more 
backward  countries. 


There  is  a  curious  anticipation  of  Mr.  Herbert 
Spencer's  theory  in  Joseph  Townsend's  Disserta- 
tion on  the  Poor  Laws  (1786).  "By  establishing 
a  community  of  goods,  or  rather  by  giving  to  the 
idle  and  vicious  t\i&  first  claim  upon  the  produce 
of  the  earth,  many  of  the  more  prudent,  careful, 
and  industrious  citizens  are  straitened  in  their 
circumstances  and  restrained  from  marriage.  The 
farmer  breeds  only  from  the  best  of  all  his  cattle  ; 
but  our  laws  choose  rather  to  preserve  the  worst, 
and  seem  to  be  anxious  lest  the  breed  should  fail  " 
(p.  426  in  Overstone's  Select  Tracts,  "  Miscel- 
laneous"). B.C. 

DATE  OF  DRAWING.  As  a  general  rule 
a  bill  of  exchange  is  dated  ;  the  absence  of  a 
date  does  not,  however,  according  to  the  law  of 
the  United  Kingdom,  make  a  bill  invalid  (Bill 
of  Exchange  Act  §  3  [4a]  ).  The  holder  may,  in 
such  a  case,  insert  the  true  date  of  drawing,  and 
the  bill  is  then  payable  accordingly  {ibid.  §  12), 
the  date  appearing  on  the  face  of  the  bill  being 
presumed  to  be  the  true  date  of  drawing  until 
the  contrary  is  proved  ;  a  holder  in  due  course 
has,  in  any  case,  the  same  rights  as  if  the  true 
date  had  been  inserted  {ibid.  §  13).  According 
to  continental  law  the  date  is  an  essential  re- 
quirement, and  an  undated  document  is  not 
available  as  a  bill  of  exchange  (German  Codes,  4 
[6]  ;  French  Code  de  Commerce,  §  110  ;  Italian 
bodice  di  Commercio,  §  251).  If  a  bill  is  to 
operate  as  from  a  date  previous  to  the  actual 
issue,  it  may,  according  to  the  law  of  the  United 
Kingdom,  be  dated  accordingly  (ante  -  dated), 
and  if  its  operation  is  to  begin  as  from  a  subse- 
quent date,  that  date  may  be  inserted — the  bill 
is  then  said  to  be  post-dated.  It  thus  becomes 
possible  to  evade  the  stamp  duty  by  post-dating 
a  biU  payable  on  demand,  which  has  the  same 
effect  as  if  the  bill  had  been  drawn  from  the 
right  date  payable  on  the  date  which  appears  as 
the  date  of  issue — in  which  case  an  ad  valorem 
stamp  duty  would  have  been  payable.  The 
holder  of  a  post-dated  bill  cannot,  of  course, 
present  it  for  acceptance  before  the  date  appear- 
ing on  its  face.  If  a  bill  is  drawn  from  a 
country  in  which  the  Greek  calendar  is  used, 
the  date  of  issue  must  be  taken  as  the  date 
according  to  the  Greek  calendar.  Thus  a  bill 
drawn  in  St.  Petersburg  on  the  1st  November  is 
treated  as  drawn  on  13th  November  according 
to  our  computation.  It  is,  however,  customary 
to  insert  the  two  dates  thus :  St.  Petersburg , 
1/13  November.  E.  s. 

DAVACH.     Ancient  measurement  of  land,  ■ 
N.E.     Scotland ;     equal     (average)     to     four 
"ploughgates,"  which  amount  to  416  Scotch 
acres,  or  528-5  imperial  acres. 

[Cosmo  Innes,  Scotch  Legal  Antiquities.']  a.  d. 

DAVANZATI,  Bernardo  (1529-1606),  bom 
in  Florence.  This  name  will  always  be  famous 
in  the  history  of  Italian  literature,  because, 
writing  in  prose,  he  attained  to  the  same 
vigour  and  precision  that  Dante  displayed  in 
poetry.     The  writings  of  Davanzati  are  stUl 


DAVANZATI— DAVENANT 


483 


models  of  style.  He  undertook  to  translate 
Tacitus  and  to  surpass  him  in  conciseness,  and 
asserts  that,  on  an  average,  a  hundred  Italian 
words  are  required  where  Tacitus  needs  a  hun- 
dred and  eight  Latin  ones,  and  a  French  trans- 
lation a  hundred  and  sixty.  Besides  his  trans- 
lation of  Tacitus,  a  history  of  the  Reformation 
in  England  under  Henry  VIII.,  and  minor 
academic  essays,  two  economic  writings,  for 
which  he  merits  here  a  mention,  are  extant. 
These  are  his  Lezione  delle  moTiete,  1582,  and  his 
Notizia  dei  cambj,  published  in  1588,  and  in- 
chided  in  Custodi's  Scrittori  Classici.  To  judge 
him  correctly  it  must  be  considered  that  he  was 
a  contemporary  of  Scakuffi  (1582),  of  Jean 
BoDiN  (1578),  and  of  William  Stafford 
(1581),  men  who  wrote  their  books  half  a  cen- 
tury before  Petty  and  Locke  were  born  (Petty, 
1623-1687  ;  Locke,  1632-1704).  Davanzati  be- 
gins by  showing  how  "barter  is  a  necessary  com- 
plement of  division  of  labour  amongst  men  and 
amongst  nations";  he  then  passes  on  to  show 
how  there  is  easily  a  "want  of  coincidence  in 
barter,"  which  calls  for  a  "medium  of  ex- 
change" ;  and  this  must  be  capable  of  "subdivi- 
sion," and  be  a  "  store  of  value."  He  then  goes 
off  upon  a  historical  digression  on  currencies,  and 
on  returning  from  tlience  recognises  in  money  "a 
common  measure  of  value."  This  leads  him  to 
a  dissertation  on  the  causes  of  value  in  general, 
in  which  respect  his  remarks  are  also  worth 
mentioning,  because  he  has  clearly  shown  that 
utility  and  value  are  "accidents  of  things" 
and  functions  of  the  "quantity  in  which  they 
exist."  Proceeding  to  examples,  he  remarks 
"that  one  single  egg  was  more  worth  to  Count 
Ugolino  in  his  tower  than  all  the  gold  of  the 
world,"  but  that,  on  the  other  hand,  "ten 
thousand  grains  of  corn  are  only  worth  one  of 
gold  in  the  market,"  and  that  "water,  however 
necessary  for  life,  is  worth  nothing,  because 
superabundant."  In  the  siege  of  Casilino  "a 
rat  was  sold  for  200  florins,  and  the  price 
could  not  be  called  exaggerated,  because  next 
day  the  man  who  sold  it  was  starved  and  the 
man  who  bought  it  was  still  alive."  Returning 
to  his  argument,  he  says  aU  the  money  in  a 
country  is  worth  all  the  goods,  because  the  one 
exchanges  for  the  other  and  nobody  wants 
money  for  its  own  sake.  Davanzati  does  not 
know  anything  about  the  rapidity  of  circulation 
of  money,  and  only  says  every  country  needs  a 
different  quantity  of  money,  as  different  human 
frames  need  different  quantities  of  blood.  The 
rest  of  his  treatise  is  directed  against  artificial 
deterioration  of  money.  The  mint  ought  to 
coin  money  gratuitously  for  everybody  ;  and 
the  fear  that,  if  the  coins  are  too  good,  they 
should  be  exported  is  simply  illusory,  because 
they  must  have  been  paid  for  by  the  exporter. 
Davanzati  insists  particularly  on  the  injury  the 
defrauding  government  is  the  first  to  experience 
when  it  tampers  with  the  coin.     In  his  essay 


on  exchanges  Davanzati  goes  minutely  into  the 
mechanism  of  exchanges,  but  he  evidently  does 
not  suspect  the  causes  of  the  phenomenon  noi 
its  limits.  Davanzati  was  by  profession  a  mer- 
chant, and  lived  a  part  of  his  life  in  France. 

[For  a  criticism  of  Davanzati,  see  Travers  Twiss, 
View  of  the  Progress  of  Pol.  Econ.,  1847.  Lec- 
ture i.j  M.  P. 

DAVENANT,  Charles,  LL.D.  (1656- 
1714),  economist  and  politician,  son  of  Sir 
William  Davenaut,  the  poet,  was  born  in 
London.  He  way  educated  at  Cheam  Grammar 
School,  Surrey,  and  in  1671  matriculated  at 
Balliol  College,  Oxford,  but  did  not  then 
proceed  to  a  degree.  After  composing,  at  the 
age  of  nineteen,  a  tragedy  under  the  title  of 
"Circe,"  which  had  some  slight  success,  he 
turned  his  attention  to  the  law,  and  appears 
to  have  taken  the  degree  of  LL.D.,  but  at 
what  university  is  uncertain.  He  held  the 
office  of  commissioner  of  excise  from  1683  to 
1689,  and  represented  St.  Ives,  Cornwall,  in 
the  first  parliament  of  James  11.  His  first 
work  of  economic  interest.  Ways  and  Means  of 
supplying  the  War,  was  published  in  1695.  In 
it  he  strongly  objected  to  meeting  war  expenses 
by  borrowing  money,  and  advocated  an  excise 
as  the  best  and  fairest  tax.  He  sat  again  in 
parliament,  this  time  for  Great  Bedwin,  in 
1698,  continuing  to  write  on  economic  and 
political  subjects.  Under  William  III.  he  did 
not  hold  office,  and  criticised  the  financial 
policy  of  the  government  with  some  bitterness  ; 
but,  on  the  accession  of  Queen  Anne,  he  returned 
to  official  life  as  secretary  to  the  commission 
appointed  to  treat  for  the  union  with  Scotland. 
In  1705  he  was  appointed  inspector -general 
of  exports  and  imports,  which  office  he  held 
until  his  death. 

As  an  economist,  Davenant  must  on  the 
whole  be  classed  as  an  adherent  of  the  mercantile 
theory.  In  opposition  to  the  bullionists  he 
points  out  that  an  energetic  people  with  good 
seaports  and  a  soil  fertile  in  variety  of  com- 
modities, can  easily  exchange  its  products  for 
as  much  gold  and  silver  as  it  may  require. 
"M(5ney,"  he  says,  "is  the  servant  of  trade — 
at  bottom  no  more  than  the  counters  with 
which  men  in  their  dealings  have  been  ac- 
customed to  reckon."  He  seems  to  have  con- 
sidered, however,  that  the  possessors  of  money 
in  specie  were  in  a  position  of  advantage 
compared  with  the  possessors,  and  would-be 
sellers  of  commodities.  "  Those  who  stand 
possessed  of  the  ready  money  have,  in  all 
times  and  all  countries,  given  the  law." 
Especially  is  this  the  case  with  perishable 
commodities,  and  articles  of  luxury,  which 
should  not  be  bought  by  any  nation  to  a 
large  amount,  except  for  the  purpose  of  being 
re-sold.  On  the  last  ground  he  strongly 
supported  the  East  India  Company  in  the 
controversies  which  raged  about  1697  on  the 


484 


DAVENANT— DAVIES 


subject  of  the  importation  of  East  India  goods, 
and  opposed  the  act  which  was  passed  in  the 
supposed  interest  of.  English  manufacturers, 
forbidding  the  wearing  or  use  of  Indian  silks 
and  muslins.  Such  a  measure  would  only 
benefit  the  French  sUk  trade  and  encourage 
smuggling.  "The  natural  way  of  promoting 
the  woollen  manufacture  is  not  to  force  its 
consumption  at  home,  but  by  wholesome  laws 
to  contrive  that  it  may  be  wrought  cheaply  in 
England,  which  will  enable  us  to  command  the 
markets  abroad."  Europe  was  foolish  enough 
to  be  ready  to  pay  for  luxuries  from  India  ; 
much  wealth  could  be  gained  by  the  nation 
which  would  act  as  the  go-between  ;  and  for 
England  to  refuse  to  reap  the  harvest  would 
be  merely  to  leave  it  to  the  Dutch. 

In  his  earlier  economic  period  Davenant 
shows  distinct  tendencies  towards  what  might 
almost  be  called  a  free- trade  position.  "  Trade 
is  in  its  nature  free,  finds  its  own  channel,  and 
best  directeth  its  own  course,  and  all  laws  to  give 
it  rules  and  directions,  and  to  limit  and  circum- 
scribe it,  may  serve  the  particular  ends  of 
private  men,  but  are  seldom  advantageous  to 
the  public.  .  .  .  The  various  products  of 
different  soils  and  countries  is  an  indication 
that  Providence  intended  they  should  be  helpful 
to  each  other."  In  the  works,  however,  which 
he  published  after  his  return  to  official  employ- 
ment, he  did  not  venture  to  disturb  current 
economic  ideas,  devoting  himself  to  carrying  on 
the  statistical  work  of  Sir  "William  Petty  and 
Mr.  Gregory  King,  and  attempting  by  an 
elaborate  investigation  to  ascertain  the  precise 
position  of  England  in  regard  to  the  balance 
of  trade  (see  Balance  of  Trade,  History  of 
THE  Theory),  His  views  on  taxation  have 
been  already  alluded  to.  He  thought  that 
the  incidence  of  taxation  should  be  proportional 
to  the  tax-payer's  ability  to  pay,  and  that 
taxes  should  bear  chiefly  on  consumers 
of  luxuries.  He  thought  that  "all  taxes 
whatsoever  were,  in  their  last  resort,  a  charge 
upon  land."  Trade  with  uncivilised  countries 
such  as  Africa  was,  he  thought,  best  carried 
on  by  a  monopolistic  corporation  (see  Foreign 
Trade,  Regulation  of).  As  regards  the 
labour  question,  he  strongly  advocated  the 
compulsory  employment  of  the  able-bodied  poor 
in  manufactures,  as  a  means  to  cheap  production 
and  the  consequent  command  of  foreign  markets. 
Davenant's  chief  works  were — 

An  Essay  on  the  Wai/s  and  Means  of  Supplying 
the  War,  London,  1695. — An  Essay  on  the  East 
India  Trade,  London,  1697. — Two  Discourses  on 
the  Public  Revenues  and  Trade  of  England, 
London,  1698. — An  Essay  on  the  probable  means 
of  making  the  people  gainers  in  the  balance  of 
Trade,  London,  1699. — A  Discourse  on  Grants 
and  Resumptions. — Essays  on  the  Balance  of 
Power,  London,  1701. — A  Picture  of  a  modern 
Whig,  London,  1701. — Essays  on  Peace  at  Home 
and  War  Abroad,  London,  1704..— Reflections  on 


the  Constitution  and  Management  of  the  Trade  to 
Africa,  London,  1709. — Two  Reports  to  the  Com' 
missioners  for  taking  the  Public  Accounts,  London, 
1712  and  1715.  A  collected  edition  of  his  works, 
edited  by  Sir  C.  Whitworth,  was  published  at 
London  in  1771. 

[Stephen's  Dictionary  of  Nationxd  Biography, 
London,  1888. — Conrad,  Handworterbttch  der 
Staatswissenschaften,  Jena,  1888. — Gnillaumin 
and  Coquelin,  Dictionnaire  d'jSconomie  Politique, 
Paris,  1858,  and  heading  "East  India  Trade"  in 
British  Museum  Catalogue.]  a.  h. 

Davenant  is  perhaps  best  known  to  most  readers 
by  his  employment  of  the  estimate  made  by 
Greqoby  King  (q.v.)  of  the  effect  of  deficiency 
in  supply  on  augmentation  of  price.  The  passage 
in  which  this  is  mentioned  is  as  follows  : 

"  It  is  observed  that  but  one  -  tenth  the  defect 
in  the  harvest  may  raise  the  price  three-tenths, 
and  when  we  have  but  half  our  crop  of  wheat, 
which  now  and  then  happens,  the  remainder  is 
spun  out  by  thrift  and  good  management,  and 
eked  out  by  the  use  of  other  grain  ;  but  this  will 
not  do  for  above  one  year,  and  would  be  a  small 
help  in  the  succession  of  two  or  three  unseasonable 
harvests.  For  the  scarcity  even  of  one  year  is 
very  destructive,  in  which  many  of  the  poorest 
sort  perish,  either  for  want  of  sufficient  food  or 
by  unwholesome  diet. 

"  We  take  it  that  a  defect  in  the  harvest  may 
raise  the  price  of  c6rn  in  the  following  propor- 
tions : — 


Defect. 

1  tenth  \ 

2  tenths  I 

3  tenths  Vraises  the  price- 

4  tenths  I 

5  tenths y 


Above  the 
common  rate. 
3  tenths 
8  tenths 
1*6  tenths 
2-8  tenths 
4 '5  tenths 


So  that  when  corn  rises  to  treble  the  common 
rate,  it  may  be  presumed  that  we  want  above  one- 
third  of  the  common .  produce  ;  and  if  we  should 
want  five-tenths  or  half  the  common  produce,  the 
price  would  rise  to  near  five  times  the  common 
rate"  {D'Avenant,  vol.  ii.  pp.  224,  225). 

DAVIES,  David,  D.D.  (d.  1819?),  gradu- 
ated at  Oxford,  and  was  appointed  rector  of 
Barkham,  Berkshire.  When  in  1775  and  1785 
parliament  ordered  returns  to  be  made  of  the 
poor  rates  throughout  the  kingdom,  no  inquiry 
was  thought  necessary  as  regards  the  actual  cir- 
cumstances of  poor  families.  To  remedy  this 
omission,  Davies  collected  budgets  of  labouring 
families  in  his  own  parish  about  Easter  1787. 
Of  these  accounts  an  abstract  was  printed  ; 
many  copies  were  distributed  with  the  help 
of  friends  throughout  England,  Wales,  and 
Scotland.  The  valuable  information  collected^ 
in  this  manner  is  tabulated  in  the  following 
work,  and  furnishes  minute  particulars  as  to* 
the  wages,  food,  etc.,  of  agi'icultural  labourers. 
The  author  offers  various  suggestions  for  the 
encouragement  of  thrift,  with  recommendations 
for  rating  wages  by  statute  and  according  to 
the  price  of  bread. 

TJie  Case  of  Labourers  in  Husbandry  stated  and 


DAVILA— DAYS  OF  GRACE 


48fi 


considered,  in  three  parts :  Part  I.  A  View  of 
their  Distressed  Condition.  Part  II.  The  Princi- 
pal Causes  of  their  Growing  Distress  and  Nuniher, 
and  of  the  Consequent  Increase  of  the  Poor-Rate. 
Part  III.  Means  of  Relief  Proposed.  With  an 
Appendix  containing  a  collection  of  accounts 
showing  the  earnings  and  expenses  of  Labouring 
families  in  different  parts  of  the  Kingdom.  Bath, 
1795,  4to. 

[M'Culloch,  Literature  of  Political  Economy, 
1845,  p.  285.— Sir  F.  M.  Eden,  State  of  the  Poor, 
1797,  vol.  iii. — A.  Toynbee,  Industrial  Revolu- 
tion.'] H.  R.  T. 

DAVILA,  EL  Padre  Batjtista  (17th  cen- 
tury). In  his  Resumen  de  los  medios  prdcticos 
para  el  general  alivio  de  la  Monarquia  (A 
short  account  of  the  practical  means  of  the 
general  Relief  of  the  Monarchy),  printed  in 
1651,  Davila  advocates  a  single  and  progressive 
poll-tax.  He  thus  aims  to  remedy  the  fright- 
ful state  to  which  Spain  had  been  brought  by 
the  bad  administration  of  the  **  Rentas  Reales  " 
and  by  the  vexatious  exactions  and  dishonesty 
of  the  collectors.  He  also  deals  with  the  pro- 
blem of  the  debased  currency. 

[Colmeiro's  Biblioteca  de  los  Economistas  Es- 
pailoles  aud  Historia  de  la  Economia  Politica  en 
Esparla  (vol.  11.  pp.  494,  575,  576).]         e.  ca. 

DAVILA  Y  LUGO,  Don  Francisco  (17th 
century).  Davila's  Desengafios  y  Replicas  a  las 
Proposiciones  de  Gerardo  Basso  (Disproof  of  and 
Reply  to  the  proposals  of  G.  B.),  Madrid  1632, 
is  addressed  to  Philip  IV.,  and  strongly  remon- 
strates against  the  adoption  of  a  plan  suggested 
by  a  Milanese  writer,  Gerardo  Basso,  Avho  in  his 
Arbitrios  y  Disaursos  Politicos  (Madrid,  1627) 
had  suggested  the  recoinage  of  the  existing 
Vellon,  debased  small  coins  of  silver  and  copper, 
which  made  up  almost  the  whole  of  the  existing 
currency  in  Spain.  This  recoinage  was  to  be 
effected  at  the  joint  cost  of  the  state  and  of  the 
public,  and  reissued  at  a  nominal  value  gi-eatly 
superior  to  the  intrinsic  value.  Davila  explains 
the  objections  to  the  tampering  with  the  value 
of  the  currency  and  insists  that  the  latter  must 
be  brought  into  strict  correspondence  with  the 
currency  of  the  neighbouring  states.  All 
monetary  exchanges  ought  to  be  regulated 
according  to  a  book  of  rates,  which  he  con- 
siders that  he  alone  is  qualified  to  compile,  and 
which  must  be  based  on  the  real  metallic 
correspondence  betAveen  the  national  and  foreign 
coins  in  circulation. 

[Colmeiro's  Biblioteca  de  los  Economistas  Es- 
pafioles.]  E.  ca. 

DAY,  DAY  WORK,  AND  DIET.  A  term 
given  by  the  court  at  the  prayer  of  the  demand- 
ant or  plaintiff,  especially  at  the  Exchequer  for 
accountants  of  the  crown  to  render  their 
accounts  (Dialogus,  ii.  4).  Also  Days  of  grace 
were  certain  days  allowed  to  the  acceptor  of  a 
bill  or  to  the  maker  of  a  note  in  which  to  make 
payment  in  extension  of  the  term  specified  in 
the  bill  or  note.     They  were  so  called  because 


at  first  allowed  only  as  a  matter  of  favour, 
perhaps  originally  through  the  mediation  of  the 
church,  but  this  custom  of  the  merchants  has 
long  been  recognised  by  the  law.  Also  a  year- 
and-a-day. 

In  another  sense,  one  day's  entertainment  or 
reception  in  lieu  of  service  and  rent,  as  in 
Domesday  Book,  where  many  such  fee-farm  rents 
are  mentioned  usually  reserved  to  the  king  in 
so  many  days'  or  nights'  provision,  e.g.  "so 
much  honey  as  was  sufficient  for  the  king's 
family  for  half  a  day,  and  as  much  as  was  enough 
for  a  whole  day  "  (Spelm.  Domesday). 

Also  an  allowance  or  diet  for  officers  of  state 
calculated  according  to  the  expenses  of  a  day's 
journey  or  sojourn.  A  table  of  diets  for  the 
sheriffs  of  the  English  counties  according  to  the 
number  of  days'  journeys  completed  in  attending 
at  the  exchequer  at  AVestminster  or  at  York  is 
preserved  in  an  ancient  record  (Red  Book  of 
Exch^qiLer,  fol.  14).  Especially  used  of  ambassa- 
dors or  other  agents  of  the  crown  (Audit  Office 
Declared  Accts.,  "Ambassadors,"  "Agents"). 
Also  of  soldiers,  labourers,  etc.  paid  by  the 
crown  (Q.  R.  Wardrobe  Accounts,  "Army,"  etc.) 
Diet  is  also  used  of  a  day's  journey,  formerly 
calculated  as  twenty  miles,  jn-esumably  for  a 
horseman. 

Also  in  agriculture  of  the  day's  work  of  one 
ploughman  or  cart,  namely  one  "journey" 
(Jotirn4e).  Hence  sometimes  used  as  a  specific 
quantity  in  grants  of  land  (Cart.  Reading,  fol. 
90d.)  The  extent  of  land  ploughed  in  a  day 
was  variously  computed,  but  was  commonly  fixed 
at  four  perches.  In  another  sense  a  day-work 
was  a  recognised  proedial  service  rendered  by  the 
villeins  in  most  manors  to  the  lord,  and  thess 
"opera  diurna"  are  enumerated  in  many  cus- 
tumals,  and  often  in  connection  with  an  allow- 
ance of  food — "  Et  debent  facere  LX  opera 
diurna,  ut  supra,  in  gardino,  vel  alibi,  ut  supra, 
capiendo  LXV  panes,  ut  supra."  (Cust.  of 
Battle,  p.  10). 

[Spelman,  Gloss. — Cowel,  Interpr.  — Nordeu's 
Surveyors'  Dialogue. — Notes  and  Queries  (3rd 
series),  iii.  512. — Custumal  of  Battle  Abbey 
(Camden  See.)]  h.  na. 

DAYS  OF  GRACE.  These  are  the  days 
which,  in  the  case  of  bills  of  exchange,  not 
being  payable  on  demand,  are  added  to  the 
time  of  payment  appearing  on  the  face  of  the 
instrument.  According  to  the  law  of  the 
United  Kingdom  there  are  three  such  days  of 
grace  (see  Bill  of  Exchange,  Law  of)  ;  but 
a  bill  may  (by  the  use  of  the  words  "  without 
grace "  or  some  similar  expression)  stipulate 
that  the  day  appearing  on  its  face  is  to  be  the 
final  due  date.  In  most  continental  countries 
"days  of  grace,"  in  the  sense  indicated  above, 
do  not  exist ;  the  holder  may  take  out  protest 
without  waiting  for  any  additional  days  ;  but 
he  does  not  lose  his  right  of  recourse,  if  the 
presentation  or  protest  is  deferred  for  a  certain 


486 


DEAD  FREIGHT— DEALER 


time  (two  days  according  to  tlie  German  and 
Italian  codes,  §§41  and  296  ;  one  day  accord- 
ing to  the  French  code,  §  162).  These  ad- 
ditional days,  which  may  be  called  "days  of 
grace  at  the  holder's  option  "  are  convenient,  as 
they  enable  the  holder  to  exercise  some  leniency 
in  favour  of  acceptors  who,  by  reason  of  some 
accident,  are  not  in  possession  of  liquid  funds 
on  the  exact  day  ;  but  the  English  days  of 
grace  have  no  practical  object  whatever,  and 
only  add  an  unnecessary  complication  in  the 
computation  of  the  time  of  payment.       E.  s. 

DEAD  FREIGHT.  Compensation  paid  by 
the  freighter  of  a  whole  ship  for  space  remaining 
unoccupied  when  the  cargo  is  not  a  full  one. 

A.  D. 

DEADLY,  Warrandice  Against  All 
(Scot.)  Warranty  against  all  mortals  {contra 
omnes  mortales).     (See  Warrandice.)     a.  d. 

DEAD  RENT.  A  rent  reserved  in  a  mining 
lease  and  payable  whether  the  mine  be  worked 
or  not.  The  object  of  such  reservation  is  to 
secure  the  working  of  the  mine.  In  some 
leases  the  dead  rent  and  the  royalty  (see 
Royalty)  are  made  payable  cumulatively ;  in 
others  the  dead  rent  merges  in  the  royalty 
actually  paid  (The  Law  of  Mines,  by  R.  F. 
MacSwinney,  London,  1884). 

[As  regards  the  amount  and  economic  effects  of 
dead  rents,  see  Mining  Royalties,  by  W.  R.  Sorley, 
London,  1889,  and  The  Reports  of  the  Royal  Com- 
mission on  Mining  Royalties,  c.  6195  of  1890,  c. 
6331  and  c.  6529  of  1891.]  j.  e.  c.  m. 

DEAD'S  PART  (Scot.)  The  portion  of  a 
man's  free  movable  estate  which  he  is  at 
liberty  at  common  law  to  bequeath  by  will ; 
that  is,  if  he  have  neither  wife  nor  child,  the 
whole  ;  if  he  have  either  wife  or  child,  one 
half ;  if  he  have  both  wife  and  child,  one 
third.  In  other  words,  the  wife  is  entitled  to 
one  equal  share ;  the  child  or  the  children 
jointly  to  another  equal  share  ;  the  testator  is 
limited  to  one  equal  share,  the  deceased's 
share,  or  "dead's  part."  This  common-law 
scheme  of  distribution  may  be  modified  by 
ante-nuptial  contract  of  marriage  (see  Mar- 
riage Settlement),  or,  after  the  marriage, 
by  formal  renunciation  of  their  legal  rights  by 
the  wife  or  children  respectively.  a.  d. 

DEADWEIGHT  ANNUITY.  A  terminable 
annuity  the  creation  of  which  was  sanctioned 
in  1822,  in  lieu  of  certain  naval  and  military 
pensions  payable  out  of  the  public  funds.  The 
phrase  was  originally  employed  by  Cobbett. 

The  distressed  condition  of  agriculture  in 
1822  led  Lord  Londonderry's  government  to 
propose  various  measures  for  the  lessening  of 
the  public  burdens.  Amongst  them  was  a 
scheme  for  the  creation  of  an  annuity  of 
£2,800,000,  for  a  period  of  forty-five  years,  in 
lieu  of  the  "dead  expense"  or  "dead  weight" 
of  the  naval  and  military  pensions  and  half- 
pay  amounting  altogether  to  about  £5,000,000 


a  year,  which  had  arisen  out  of  the  recent  wars. 
It  was  claimed  that  the  government  were  justified 
in  distributing  this  charge  equally  over  a  period 
of  years,  instead  of  awaiting  the  gradual  extinc- 
tion of  the  burden  by  the  death  of  the  pen- 
sioners. The  scheme  was  opposed  by  Ricardo, 
amongst  others,  on  the  ground  that  it  was  a 
covert  attack  upon  the  sinking  fund,  and  a 
relieving  of  the  then  taxpayers  at  the  expense 
of  posterity,  but  it  eventually  became  law  (3 
Geo.  IV.  c.  51).  In  1823,  the  Bank  of  Eng- 
land agreed  to  purchase  £585,740,  part  of  the 
proposed  annuity,  paying  for  it  the  sum  of 
£13,089,419,  spread  over  the  six  years  1823-28 
(4  Geo.  IV.  c.  22),  but  this  was  the  only  sale 
efiected,  and  the  original  act  was  repealed  in 
1828  (9  Geo.  IV.  c.  79)  on  the  unanimous  re- 
commendation of  the  House  of  Commons  ;  thus 
the  whole  of  the  annuity,  except  the  £585,740 
per  annum  sold  to  the  Bank  of  England,  was 
cancelled.  In  July  1839  the  Bank  of  England 
invited  tenders  for  the  purchase  of  their  annuity, 
with  a  view  to  counteract  a  long- continued  drain 
upon  the  stock  of  bullion,  but  the  biddings  fell 
short  of  the  minimum  advertised  price,  and  the 
annuity  continued  to  be  paid  to  the  Bank  until 
1867,  when  it  expired. 

[In  addition  to  the  Acts  above  named,  Hansard, 
2nd  Series,  vol.  vii.  pp.  164,  280,  316,  737,  1319, 
1396,  vol.  xix.  p.  646  ;  Tooke's  History  of  Prices, 
vol.  iii.  88,  100-1,  vol.  iv.  333  ;  and  the  Report  of 
the  Select  Committee  on  Banks  of  Issue  (No.  602 
of  1840),  may  be  consulted.]  t.  h.  e. 

DEALER  (Stock  Exchange).  A  dealer  is 
a  man  who,  in  concert  with  others,  makes  what 
is  called  a  market.  He  stands  ready  to  buy  or 
sell  certain  stocks,  or  shares,  or  bonds  and. 
when  a  stockbroker  approaches  him  with  a 
demand  for  a  quotation,  the  dealer  (or  jobber, 
as  he  is  still  called  in  and  about  the  stock  ex- 
change) replies  by  mentioning  two  prices,  the 
lower  being  that  at  which  he  will  buy,  and  the 
higher  that  at  which  he  will  sell.  For  instance, 
when  quoting  the  price  of  consols,  he  offers  to 
buy  each  £100  stock  at  98,  or  to  sell  at  98' 
There  is  no  legal  obligation  upon  him  to  quote 
prices  or  to  deal  after  quotation,  but  it  is  part 
of  the  etiquette  of  the  stock  exchange,  which 
is  quite  as  much  a  club  as  a  market,  that  the 
dealer  should  follow  up  his  quotation  by  buying 
or  selling  as  the  case  may  be  up  to  the  value 
of  £1000.  Indeed,  were  a  jobber  to  give  a 
quotation  and  then  refuse  to  deal  at  either 
price  named  in  the  quotation,  he  would  fall  into 
disrepute,  and  perhaps  be  reported  to  the  Stock 
Exchange  Committee  for  General  Purposes.  In 
theory  the  dealer  is  supposed  to  be  ignorant 
of  and  indiflFerent  to  the  desire  of  the  broker 
who  accosts  him — that  is,  he  is  supposed  to  be 
ready  to  sell  or  to  buy — but  in  practice  a 
shifty  dealer  will  try  to  delay  giving  his  quota- 
tion until  he  has  discovered,  or  thinks  he  has 
discovered,  the  intentions  of  the  person  who 


DEALER— DEARNESS 


487 


has  come  to  him.  If  he  thinks  that  the  latter 
wishes  to  buy  he  raises  his  selling  price  ;  if  he 
has  reason  to  believe  that  the  party  wishes  to 
sell,  he  quotes  as  low  a  buying  price  as  possible, 
unless  the  state  of  his  book  makes  it  his  interest 
to  deal  freely.  Dealers  sometimes  transact 
business  among  themselves,  for  at  the  end  of 
a  day  it  may  happen  that  dealer  A  has  con- 
tracted to  buy  more  stock  than  he  can  pay  for, 
while  dealer  B  has,  on  the  other  hand,  con- 
tracted to  sell  more  of  the  same  stock  than  he 
can  possibly  deliver.  Then  A  and  B  come 
together,  and  each  relieves  the  pressure  upon 
the  other  dealer's  "book."  In  short,  they 
institute  a  kind  of  clearing-house  among  them- 
selves, writing  off  liabilities  to  sell  against 
liabilities  to  buy.  It  need  not  be  said  that  the 
dealers  who  compose  a  market  have  many 
opportunities  for  discovering  facts  which  may 
lead  them  to  a  correct  conclusion  as  to  the  drift 
of  prices  in  the  market.  At  the  end  of  one 
week  they  will  discover  that  the  public  has  been 
absorbing  a  certain  stock  so  freely  as  to  limit 
the  supply  on  the  market.  A  week  or  two  later 
they  will  have  found  that  the  tide  has  turned, 
and  once  again  they  are  enabled  to  take  measures. 
The  dealer  is  a  product  of  division  of  labour. 
He  gives  his  time  and  attention  exclusively 
to  the  consideration  of  one  or  two  securities,  and 
gradually  accumulates  in  his  own  mind  a  record 
of  the  forces  which  go  to  raise  or  depress  that 
group  of  securities  in  the  market.  He  also 
preserves  a  kind  of  continuity,  and  acts  as  the 
middle  link  between  the  buyer  of  a  stock  who 
may  be  at  Penzance,  and  the  seller  who  may  be 
at  Middlesbrough.  If  it  were  not  for  the  dealer 
or  jobber,  a  man  with  stocks  or  shares  to  sell 
would  have  to  run  about,  or  employ  a  broker 
to  run  about,  from  place  to  place,  ofiering  these 
shares  and  remaining,  perhaps,  in  the  dark  as 
to  what  is  a  good  average  market  price.  Thus 
the  dealer  forms  the  nucleus  of  a  perpetual  fair, 
and  whereas  a  horse  fair,  for  example,  is  often 
only  an  annual  function,  persons  in  the  neigh- 
bourhood of  the  town  in  which  it  is  held  being 
almost  compelled  to  keep  their  cattle  until  a 
fair  takes  place,  the  attendance  of  a  concourse 
of  dealers  on  the  stock  exchange  makes  it 
always  possible  to  buy  or  sell  the  stocks  in 
which  they  are  concerned.  In  active  times  the 
price  quoted  by  a  dealer  is  usually  more  "close  " 
— that  is,  the  interval  between  the  buying  and 
selling  quotation  is  narrow — whereas  in  dull 
times  the  dealer  hesitates  to  offer  anything 
like  a  middling  quotation  for  fear  of  inability  to 
cover  or  "undo"  his  bargain  by  a  resale  or  a 
repurchase  at  such  a  price  as  would  leave  the 
dealer  a  turn  or  profit.  A.  E. 

DEARNESS,  Artificial.  When  action  is 
consciously  and  deliberately  directed  to  enhance 
the  price  of  some  commodity  in  some  market 
above  the  competitive  level,  any  resulting 
deamess  may  be  called  artificial. 


We  are  not  here  to  consider  natural  mono- 
polies, for  the  deamess  produced  by  these  may 
be  regarded  as  in  a  sense  normal ;  and  the  end 
of  the  monopolist  is  not  dearness,  but  high  net 
profit,  which  may  in  some  circumstances  be 
produced  by  cheapness. 

Nor  can  we  conveniently  consider  under  this 
head  such  artificial  monopolies  as  copyright  in 
books,  or  works  of  art,  or  patents  for  inventions. 
Dearness  so  produced  is  in  a  sense  artificial,  as 
deliberately  created  by  the  state.  But  the 
price  of  such  things  is  not  on  the  average 
higher  than  is  necessary  to  induce  the  author 
or  the  inventor  to  work  for  the  community. 

The  protection  of  home  products  by  duties 
on  imports  may  produce  artificial  dearness,  but 
is  more  conveniently  considered  separately 
under  the  head  Protection. 

The  cases  in  which  demand  can  be  artificially 
created  are  not  important.  Laws  such  as  the 
English  law  in  the  reign  of  Elizabeth  for  the 
eating  of  fish  on  Wednesdays  and  Fridays,  and 
the  charitable  endeavoui'S  of  leaders  of  fashion 
to  foster  local  manufactures,  e.g.  Irish  poplins, 
have  had  this  end  and  possibly  this  effect. 
The  eflect  of  false  rumours  is  generally  transi- 
tory and  followed  by  an  equivalent  or  greater 
reaction.  But  the  issue  of  misleading  reports 
and  fraudulent  balance  sheets  may  maintain 
the  shares  of  banks  and  companies  at  an 
artificial  level  for  years,  as  in  the  case  of  the 
city  of  Glasgow  Bank  (1878).  Again  a  govern- 
ment may  use  its  power  as  a  purchaser  to  en- 
hance the  price  of  commodities  for  the  benefit 
of  a  section  of  its  subjects,  or  for  the  profit  of 
influential  persons.  The  laws  passed  in  1878 
and  1890,  to  regulate  the  purchase  of  silver  for 
currency  purposes  in  the  United  States,  had 
this  effect  if  not  this  object. 

Artificial  dearness  can  only  be  permanent 
when  the  individual,  or  association,  or  public 
authority  engaged  in  enhancing  the  price  has 
either  practical  control  over  the  most  important 
of  all  possible  sources  of  supply,  and  thus  can 
limit  the  output,  or  has  absolute  control  over 
the  market  of  demand. 

Thus  the  East  India  Company  and,  in  later 
days,  the  Indian  government,  had  practical 
control  over  the  sources  of  supply  of  a  specially 
high  quality  of  opium.  We  are  told  that  the 
Company  used  this  power  in  a  very  arbitrary 
way  to  limit  the  supply  of  their  opium  (Adam 
Smith,  bk.  iv.  ch.  vii.).  And  the  Indian 
government  placed  this  restriction  on  a  regular 
basis  with  such  profitable  results  that  a  mono- 
poly revenue  of  some  seven  millions  sterling 
was  drawn  from  this  source  (see  Opium).  But 
the  market  was  not  under  English  control,  and 
a  war  with  China  was  necessary  in  order  to 
maintain  it.  The  rate  of  profit  also  diminished 
through  increased  consumption  of  Chinese 
opium,  which,  although  inferior,  was  a  com- 
peting substitute. 


488 


DEARNESS 


The  Dutch  East  India  Company  had  long 
after  1607  sovereign  control  over  the  Molucca 
Islands,  once  almost  the  only  sources  of  supply 
for  certain  highly  valued  spices.  Discovering 
by  experience  that  a  small  increase  of  supply 
creates  a  more  than  proportional  fall  in  the 
price  of  such  commodities,-  they  rigorously 
limited  the  supply  by  destroying  a  part  of  the 
plants  in  their  own  islands,  and  by  extirpating 
as  far  as  possible  the  clove  and  the  nutmeg  in 
the  islands  where  they  had  no  settlements  (Adam 
Smith,  I.e.)  In  abundant  seasons  they  also 
destroyed  a  large  part  of  their  own  produce. 
In  modern  times  the  monopoly  of  the  spice 
trade  is  no  longer  in  the  hands  of  any  nation. 

Mines  and  salt  mines  have  been  commonly 
regarded  in  Europe  as  state  monopolies.  Until 
modern  times  the  price  has  been  thus  main- 
tained at  an  artificial  level.  Where  the  whole 
sources  of  supply  are,  as  in  this  case,  col- 
lected in  one  hand  and  foreign  competition 
is  excluded,  it  is  not  necessary  to  restrict  the 
output.  The  price  can  be  fixed,  and  the 
demand  at  that  price  will  determine  the  output. 

Somewhat  similar  are  the  state  monopolies 
of  matches,  tobacco,  etc.  which  exist  in  France 
and  other  European  countries.  They  are 
highly  profitable  to  the  state,  but  the  consumer 
has  to  put  up  with  inferior  quality.  More 
convenient  in  the  latter  respect  are  customs  duties, 
supplemented  by  equivalent  excise,  or  levied 
on  commodities  not  produced  at  home.  These 
also  produce  artificial  dearness  for  the  profit  of 
the  state.  But  the  rate  of  taxation  does  not 
measure  the  increase  in  price.  It  may  be  less 
or  more  according  to  the  law  which  the  produc- 
tion of  the  commodity  obeys  (see  Diminishing 
Returns,  and  iNCREAsiNa  Returns).  Ex- 
port duties  can  only  be  levied  with  permanent 
advantage  to  the  state  when  a  country  has 
a  natural  monopoly  of  a  commodity,  or  pro- 
duces it  under  exceptional  advantages.  So 
with  English  wool  in  the  thirteenth  and  four- 
teenth centuries.  Such  duties  result  in  artificial 
dearness  of  the  commodity,  which  is  generally 
accompanied  by  a  reduced  demand  and  may 
ultimately  destroy  the  trade.  A  bounty  on 
exports  has  the  opposite  efiect,  and  raises  the 
price  for  a  time  at  least  to  the  home  consumer. 

A  trading  body,  not  fortified  in  a  monopoly 
by  the  power  of  a  state,  can  rarely  obtain  such 
control  over  all  the  sources  of  supply  of  any 
commodity  in  any  market,  as  may  be  possessed 
by  a  public  authority  or  a  chartered  company. 
The  attempt  has  been  made  in  recent  times  by 
great  associations  of  capitalists,  trading  and  pro- 
ducing bodies  known  as  syndicates  and  trusts. 
The  Standard  Oil  Trust  in  the  United  States  was 
formed  in  1881,  to  control  three-quarters  of  the 
total  petroleum  refining  power  of  the  States,  and 
exercised  also,  as  it  is  alleged,  influence  over  the 
output  of  crude  petroleum,  and  the  carrying 
corporations.      It   is   not   suggested  that  the  I 


trust  enhanced  the  price  of  refined  petroleum 
above  its  previous  level,  but  the  considerable 
profits  of  the  trust  suggest  that  it  partly 
prevented  a  natural  decline.  The  Sugar  Re- 
fining Company,  which  united  under  one 
control  the  chief  sugar  refining  establishments 
in  the  States,  is  admitted  to  have  raised  the 
price  of  refined  sugar  two  cents  a  pound.  But 
in  spite  of  their  overwhelming  power,  neither 
of  these  two  great  associations  was  able  to 
control  the  whole  of  the  producing  power  and 
effectually  keep  down  the  output.  Though 
protected  in  their  own  country  they  could  not 
control  the  foreign  trade,  and  there  remained 
even  at  home  a  smaU  body  of  outside  com- 
petitors and  a  vast  power  of  potential 
competition  which  might  at  any  time,  if 
tempted  by  exaggerated  •profits,  have  come  into 
the  field.  In  the  case  of  the  Cotton  Bagging 
Trust,  a  syndicate  of  consumers,  known  as  the 
Farmers'  Alliance,  was  formed  in  opposition. 
The  moderation  with  which  trusts  have  been 
generally  conducted  has  not  saved  them  from 
unpopularity.  In  some  States  such  combina- 
tions have  been  pronounced  illegal,  and  attempts 
have  been  made  to  crush  them  by  legislation. 

One  of  the  best  conceived  of  such  schemes 
was  the  English  Salt  Union  formed  in  1888,  to 
controlthesupply  of  salt  from  the  English  mines. 
The  effect  of  their  action  was  immediately  seen 
in  the  decline  of  English  exports  of  salt  from 
898,000  tons  in  1888  to  667,000  tons  in  1889, 
with  a  rise  in  values  from  £486,000  to 
£539,000,  thus  illustrating  a  well-known  law 
which  is  the  strength  of  those  who  attempt  to 
forestall  necessaries.  In  September  1888  the 
price  of  lump  salt  delivered  free  in  Cambridge 
was  26s.  a  ton,  in  July  1889,  48s.,  July  1890, 
52s.,  July  1891,  36s.  The  company  paid  in 
the  first  year  10  per  cent  on  its  ordinary 
shares,  in  1890,  7  per  cent,  and  in  the  first 
half  of  1891,  5  per  cent  only.  The  7  per  cent 
preference  shares  in  October  1891  stood  at  a 
discount.  Excellent  as  are  the  sources  of 
supply  controlled  by  this  company,  necessary 
and  universal  as  is  the  use  of  salt,  its  bulk 
comparatively  small  and  the  burden  per  head 
light,  the  rise  in  price  cannot  fail  to  affie.ct  the 
export  trade,  and  the  greater  the  rise  in  price 
the  greater  the  inducement  to  competition, 
which  for  the  great  export  trade  is  serious  and 
even  in  England  may  become  active.  The 
difficulties  of  a  trust  increase  with  its  success 
and  with  the  duration  of  its  success  (on  the 
whole  subject,  see  a  Foreign  Office  Report, 
1890,  c.  5896-32). 

Even  more  hopeless  is  the  task  when  the 
attempt  is  made  to  enhance  price  over  a  con- 
siderable period,  with  no  control  over  the 
output,  by  buying  up  the  stock  in  the 
market.  The  copper  syndicate  started  in  , 
France  towards  the  end  of  1887,  with  a  capital 
of  4  millions  sterling,  and  the  resources  of  the 


DEARNESS 


488 


Comptoir  d'Escompte  at  its  back.  Copper  was 
then  and  had  long  stood  at  about  £40  a  ton. 
Demand  for  copper  was  reviving.  The  opera- 
tions of  the  syndicate  raised  copper  to  £85  in 
January  1888,  and  to  £99  a  ton  in  September 
of  the  same  year.  They  had  contracts  with  all 
chief  copper-producing  companies  binding  the 
syndicate  to  take  over  all  their  copper  up  to  a 
certain  amount  at  a  certain  price.  But  they 
had  not  the  power  to  keep  down  the  output, 
which  increased  from  224,000  tons  in  1887  to 
262,000  tons  in  1888. 

During  the  period  the  visible  supply  in- 
creased from  45,000  tons  to  118,000  tons. 
Meanwhile  consumers  were  minimising  their 
purchases.  Copper  is  not  a  necessary  of  life, 
and  in  March  1889,  when  the  resources  of  the 
society  and  of  the  Comptoir  d'Escompte  were 
exhausted,  the  society  itself  held  130,000  tons. 

In  April  1889  the  price  of  copper  was  back 
at  £40.  As  a  speculative  venture  the  syndicate 
had  very  favourable  prospects.  But  its  ill- 
regulated  attempt  to  artificially  enhance  and 
maintain  the  price  failed,  through  want  of 
power  to  keep  down  the  output  in  proportion 
to  the  reduced  consumption. 

In  the  middle  ages  local  markets  were 
sometimes  so  far  isolated  by  difficulties  of 
communication  and  carriage  that  a  very  con- 
siderable difference  in  price  would  be  long  in 
attracting  supplies  from  other  markets.  Such 
exceptional  markets  may  occasionally  have 
been  looted  by  speculators,  whose  resources 
were  large  in  proportion  to  the  market.  In 
dealing  with  necessaries,  it  would  be  enough 
to  buy  up  a  large  part  of  the  available 
supply,  to  withhold,  export  at  a  loss,  or  even 
destroy  a  part,  in  order  to  realise  substantial 
profits  (see  Jevons,  Theory  of  Political  Econ- 
omy, 1879,  167  seq.,  and  the  estimate  there 
quoted,  which,  though  resting  on  an  insufficient 
inductive  basis,  is  the  guess  of  a  shrewd  man  of 
much  experience).  Such  events  may  have 
occurred  to  justify  the  popular  hatred  of 
FoRESTALLERS  AND  Regrators  and  Accajpa- 
reurs,  and  the  legislation  on  the  subject  from  the 
lex  Julia  de  Annona  downwards.  But  the 
enterprise  could  rarely  be  attempted  with 
success,  and  Adam  Smith  (bk.  iv.  ch.  v.)  did 
good  service  in  pointing  out  the  useful  function 
of  corn  dealers  as  mitigating  the  severity  of  a 
scarcity,  and  in  condemning  all  such  legislation. 
It  is  very  difficult  to  believe  that  a  pacte  de 
Famine,  in  eighteenth-century  France,  can  have 
been  successful,  unless  by  the  aid  of  legislation 
restrictive  of  trade. 

The  modern  market  for  necessaries  is  co- 
extensive with  the  world.  The  modetn 
harvest  continues  from  January  to  December. 
No  combination  of  capitalists  has  yet  arisen 
which  could  even  threaten  an  artificial 
scarcity  of  food,  unless  in  a  strictly  protected 
country,  or  a  country  where  modem  means  of 


communication  have  not  been  developed.  On 
the  other  hand,  to  produce  in  a  sensitive  market 
a  transitory  enhancement  of  price  does  not  re- 
quire great  resources.  The  device  is  familiar 
on  the  stock  exchange  and  the  produce  market. 
But  to  make  this  manoeuvre  profitable  the  in- 
fluence of  example  is  necessary.  When  a  lead- 
ing financier  buys  largely,  small  speculators 
rush  in  to  profit  by  the  boom,  and  the  master 
may  unload  at  the  expense  of  his  imitators. 
If  this  expectation  is  not  fulfilled  the  market 
must  be  depresued  by  the  operator's  sales,  as 
much  as  it  was  raised  by  his  purchases.  On 
the  whole,  such  fluctuations  tend  to  depress 
average  prices  by  discouraging  legitimate  pur- 
chase for  consumption  or  investment,  though 
they  may  be  profitable  to  individuals. 

At  an  exceptional  conjuncture,  when  the 
supply  of  some  necessary  runs  low,  the  action 
of  some  corner  or  ring  may  stimulate  normal 
demand  into  frenzy.  This  was  the  case  in  New 
York  in  September  1869,  when  £22,000,000 
sterling  in  gold  were  locked  up  in  the  treasury 
and  the  available  market  supply  fell  to£  3,000,000 
sterling.  The  currency  being  inconvertible, 
this  supply  might  have  been  sufficient  for  nor- 
mal needs.  But  it  was  easy  for  a  few  specula- 
tors to  control  the  whole,  and  exact  a  ruinous 
price  from  purchasers  whose  needs  were  pressing. 
A  ring  was  formed  and  in  one  day  the  premium 
on  gold  was  forced  from  40  to  60  per  cent. 
The  excitement  was  so  gieat  and  the  dealings 
so  large  that  the  gold  clearing-house  was  un- 
equal to  the  strain.  The  further  rise  of  gold 
was  only  stopped  by  government  sales  of  gold. 
It  is,  however,  easier  to  create  such  movements 
than  to  profit  by  them.  The  means  taken  on 
this  occasion  by  the  conspirators  to  protect 
themselves  are  said  to  have  been  outside  the 
limits  of  legitimate  trade. 

When  speculators  are  rashly  bearing  a 
stock  of  which  the  real  supply  is  small,  a 
corner  may  sometimes  be  formed  to  lock  up  the 
whole,  and  prices  are  then  forced  up  to  an 
abnormal  level,  for  the  bears  cannot  find  stock 
to  deliver  on  settling  day  (see  Backwarda- 
tion ;  Corner  ;  Ring). 

The  so-called  cotton  corner  of  1889,  on  the 
collapse  of  which  (September  30th)  "Septem- 
bers "  fell  thirty  points  in  one  day,  was  rather 
a  case  of  exaggerated  speculation  for  the  rise 
than  a  genuine  case  of  artificial  dearness. 

The  mutual  relations  of  individuals  are 
becoming  less  important  to  economics  than  the 
mutual  relations  of  great  associations.  The 
labour  market  has  been  lately  swayed  by  great 
combinations,  not  unlilce  those  which  attempt 
to  control  the  production  of  commodities.  The 
object  of  their  action  is  to  enhance  the  rate  of 
wages,  and  in  so  far  any  dearness  of  labour 
produced  may  be  termed  artificial.  But  bar- 
gaining is  one  of  the  normal  functions  of  the 
economic  man,  and  the  desire  to  obtain  the 


490 


DEARTH— DEATH  DUTIES 


best  terms  possible  one  of  the  ordinary  forces 
that  determine  prices.  It  seems  best  therefore 
to  confine  the  term,  in  the  labour  market,  to 
any  dearness  that  may  be  produced  by  the 
exclusion  of  certain  men  from  certain  labour 
markets,  by  limitation  of  apprenticeship,  or 
by  intimidation  of  outside  competition!  The 
attempt  is  subject  to  the  difficulties  already 
mentioned.  The  greater  the  artificial  en- 
hancement of  price  the  greater  the  attraction 
to  outside  competition,  whether  of  man  with 
man,  or  producer  with  producer,  or  port  with 
port,  or  country  with  country. 

The  various  modes  in  which  it  has  been 
attempted  to  enhance  price  artificially  have 
been  surveyed,  according  as  the  enhancement 
has  been  permanent,  temporary,  or  what  may 
be  called  momentary.  The  success  of  the 
attempt  depends  upon  the  nature  of  the  com- 
modity dealt  with,  the  extent  of  the  market  of 
supply,  and  of  demand,  and  the  character  of 
the  resources  commanded.  Price  may  be 
momentarily  enhanced  by  taking  advantage  of 
peculiar  circumstances  of  the  market.  It  may 
be  temporarily  enhanced  by  buying  up  the 
stock,  but  such  attempts  cannot  be  successful 
unless  it  is  possible  to  exclude  extraneous 
supplies,  or  unless  such  supplies  are  by  the 
circumstances  of  the  case  excluded.  If  this  be 
so,  in  the  case  of  necessaries  there  is  hardly 
any  limit  to  the  possible  enhancement  of  price. 
In  other  commodities  consumption  is  minimised 
and  substitutes  employed.  Permanent  enhance- 
ment requires  either  a  practical  monopoly  of  the 
sources  of  supply,  which  is  apt  to  break  down 
if  the  strain  be  severe,  or  such  command  over 
a  market  of  demand  as  only  a  government  can 
exercise.  The  safeguard  of  the  community 
against  the  tyranny  of  great  capitals  rests  in 
the  practical  difficulty  of  keeping  great  voluntary 
combinations  together,  and  of  finding  a  com- 
modity indispensable,  without  substitutes,  of 
which  the  sources  of  supply  are  absolutely 
limited. 

[Adam  Smith,  bk.  iv.  ch.  v. — Cournot,  Prin- 
cipes  Mathimatiques,  ch.  i.  §  2. — John  Stuart 
Mill,  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  bk.  iv. 
ch.  ii.  §  5. — Roscher,  Political  Economy,  bk.  ii. 
ch.  ii.  §  108. — Sidgwick,  Principles  of  Political 
Economy,  bk.  ii.  ch.  ii.  §  4,  §  7  ;  bk.  ii.  ch.  x. 
See  also  Corner  ;  Customs  ;  Excise  ;  Porestal- 
LERS  AND  Reqrators  ;  MONOPOLIES  ;  Protection  ; 
Ring  ;  Syndicate  ;  Trade  Unions  ;  Trusts.] 

S.  M.  L. 

DEARTH.     See  Famine. 

DEATH  DUTIES.  The  collection  of  a  tax 
on  the  occasion  of  the  transference  of  property 
from  the  dead  to  the  living  has  been  made 
a  means  of  raising  public  revenue  from  very 
early  times.  Adam  Smith  cites  as  examples 
the  vicesima  hereditatum  of  the  Romans, 
the  duties  payable  by  heirs  under  the  feudal 
law,  and  the  Dutch  tax  on  successions.  Duties 
of  this  class  now  rank,  with  common  consent, 


amongst  the  most  legitimate  and  least  detri- 
mental to  individual  interests  of  all  descriptions 
of  taxation. 

Adam  Smith  discusses  the  arguments  for  and 
against  these  duties  at  considerable  length 
(  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  v.  ch.  iii. ),  and  points 
out  that  they  are,  or  may  be  made,  "perfectly 
clear  and  certain,"  "the  time  of  payment  is 
.  .  .  sufficiently  convenient,"  and  "they  are 
levied  at  very  little  expense."  On  the  other 
hand  he  considered  them  unequal,  on  the 
ground  that  the  frequency  of  transference  was 
not  always  the  same  in  property  of  equal  value, 
and  he  also  thought  that  so  far  as  they  diminish 
the  capital  value  of  property  they  "tend  to 
diminish  the  funds  destined  for  the  maintenance 
of  productive  labour."  The  latter  point  was 
emphasised  by  Fawcett  (Manual  Polit.  Econ., 
bk.  iv.  ch.  ii.),  but  MUl  (Principles,  bk.  v. 
ch.  ii.  §  7)  attached  no  importance  to  the 
objection  in  a  wealthy  country.  He  considered 
that  "the  amount  which  would  be  derived 
from  a  very  high  legacy  duty  in  each  year 
is  but  a  small  proportion  of  the  annual  increase 
of  capital  in  such  a  country  ;  and  its  abstrac- 
tion would  but  make  room  for  saving  to  an 
equivalent  amount."  Prof.  Sidgwick  adopts 
a  similar  view,  and  says  that  the  bad  efiect 
of  such  duties  "is  not  at  all  likely  to  be  at 
all  equal  in  proportion  to  the  similar  efiect 
that  would  be  produced  by  extra  taxes  on 
income  ;  in  fact,  the  limits  of  taxation  on  in- 
heritances will  be  practically  determined  for 
the  financier  rather  by  the  danger  of  evasion 
through  donMiones  inter  vivos  than  by  the 
danger  of  checking  industry  and  thrift." 
(Principles,  bk.  iii.  ch.  viii.  §  11). 

Mill  regarded  legacy  and  inheritance  duties 
as  taxes  in  respect  of  which  it  was  both  ex- 
pedient and  just  that  the  principle  of  gradua- 
tion should  be  adopted  (Principles,  bk.  v.  ch. 
ii.  §  3),  but  Prof.  Nicholson  contests  this  view 
and  expresses  the  opinion  that  "graduated 
taxation,  even  in  the  modified  form  proposed 
by  Mill,  would  tend  to  check  production  on 
a  large  scale"  (Encyclopaedia  Britannica,  art. 
"  Taxation  ").  The  levy  of  a  larger  percentage 
on  a  larger  sum  has,  however,  received  distinct 
recognition  in  the  scale  of  death  duties  in  force 
in  the  United  Kingdom. 

Prof.  Nicholson  (ibidem)  says  that  "it  is 
obvious  as  regards  incidence  that  taxes  of 
this  class  are  the  most  direct  of  all  taxes,  in 
the  sense  that  they  cannot  be  transferred  to 
other  persons  by  the  beneficiaries  "  ;  to  which 
he  adds,  that  the  principal  difficulties  connected 
with  them  arise  in  connection  with  the  canon 
of  equality  of  taxation. 

The  death  duties  levied  in  the  United 
Kingdom  date  from  the  year  1694,  when  a 
fixed  duty  of  5s.  each  was  imposed  on  all  pro- 
bates of  wUls  and  letters  of  administration. 
This  duty  was  increased  four  years  later  to  10s., 


DEATH  DUTIES 


491 


but  in  both  cases  the  charge  was  more  analogous 
to  the  stamp  duties  levied  on  instruments  of 
a  legal  character  than  to  the  death  duties  as  we 
now  know  them.  In  1779  Lord  North,  taking 
note  of  the  observations  of  Adam  Smith, 
proposed  that  the  charges  should  vary  accord- 
ing to  the  amount  of  the  estate,  the  maximum 
duty  to  be  a  fixed  sum  £2  :  10s.  on  each  estate 
of  £300  and  upwards.  In  the  following  year 
these  charges  were  supplemented  by  a  graduated 
duty  on  receipts  given  for  legacies.  Frequent 
changes  in  the  scale  of  probate  duties  were 
made  between  1779  and  1815,  the  maximum 
charge  being  gi-adually  augmented,  and  in  the 
latter  year  a  distinction  was  drawn  between  the 
duties  levied  on  testate  and  intestate  estates. 
During  the  same  period  the  legacy  duties  were 
also  increased,  and  their  payment  made  more 
secure.  The  most  important  alterations  were 
those  proposed  by  Pitt  in  1796,  when  executors 
were  made  responsible  for  the  payment  of  the 
duty,  and  the  charge  was  levied  at  different 
rates  varying  according  to  the  consanguinity  of 
the  legatee  to  the  testator.  These  rates  were 
enlarged  in  1804  and  again  in  1805.  No  com- 
plete record  of  the  yield  of  the  death  duties 
exists  prior  to  the  year  last  named,  but  they 
then  produced  £495,000,  a  sum  which  had  in- 
creased to £882,000  in  1810,  and  to £1,298,000 
in  1815. 

In  1842  the  Irish  probate  duties  were 
brought  up  to  the  level  of  those  levied  in 
Great  Britain,  but,  with  this  exception,  the 
death  duties  remained  unaltered  for  thirty-eiglit 
years.  The  amount  they  produced,  however, 
steadily  increased,  rising  from  £1,696,000  in 
1820,  to  £2,189,000  in  1830,  £2,192,000  in 
1840,  and  to  £2,343,000  in  1850. 

In  1796,  Pitt  had  endeavoured  unsuccess- 
fully to  obtain  a  tax  on  successions  to  landed 
property,  analogous  to  that  on  legacies  of 
personal  estate,  and  it  was  reserved  for  Mr. 
Gladstone,  in  1853,  to  bring  within  the  scope 
of  the  duties  all  successions  to  property,  by 
reason  of  death,  whether  the  property  was 
real  or  personal,  and  whatever  the  nature  of 
the  title  to  receive  it.  Mr.  Gladstone  found 
it  essential  to  make  considerable  differences 
between  the  new  duties  and  the  old  ones, 
alike  in  the  amount  to  be  paid  and  the  manner 
of  payment,  and  his  estimate  of  the  produce 
of  the  duties  he  imposed  proved  excessive, 
their  yield  never  having  amounted  to  one-half 
of  the  sum,  £2,000,000,  which  he  thought 
they  would  realise.  Some  slight  modifications 
of  the  death  duties  were  made  in  1859  and  in 
1864,  and  six  years  later  Mr.  Lowe  proposed, 
but  without  success,  to  so  rearrange  them  as 
to  secure  an  additional  £1,020,000  a  year,  but 
it  was  not  until  1880  that  any  substantial 
changes  were  made.  Meanwhile  the  aggregate 
.produce  had  risen  from  £2,547,000  in  1853 
ito  £3,564,000  in  1860,  £4,953,000,  in  1870, 


and  to  £6,400,000  in  1879,  figures  which 
strikingly  exemplify  the  growth  of  the  national 
wealth. 

In  1880,  Sir  Stafford  Northcote  revised  the 
scale  of  probate  duties,  and  a  year  later  Mr. 
Gladstone  followed  his  example  and,  at  the 
same  time,  abolished  the  distinction  between 
the  duties  payable  in  respect  of  testate  and  in- 
testate successions,  transferred  the  duty  from  the 
probate  or  letters  of  administration  themselves 
to  a  detailed  affidavit  of  value  to  be  lodged 
with  the  application  for  representation,  and  re- 
pealed the  1  per  cent  legacy  or  succession  duty 
payable  by  direct  lineals  wherever  the  increased 
probate  duty  was  paid.  On  the  same  occasion 
Mr.  Gladstone  afforded  relief  to  small  estates 
not  exceeding  £300,  alike  in  the  amount  to 
be  paid  and  the  mode  of  payment,  whilst  a 
new  duty,  styled  the  "account  duty,"  was 
imposed  as  an  equivalent  to  the  probate  duty 
in  certain  circumstances  in  which  the  pa3rnient 
of  the  latter  was  avoided.  The  yield  in  the 
year  1880-81,  under  Sir  Stafford  Northcote's 
scheme,  was  £6,826,000,  and  in  1882-83, 
when  Mr.  Gladstone's  proposals  first  took  full 
effect,  the  receipts  were  £7,438,000.  Five 
years  later  the  produce  had  risen  to  £8,242,000. 
In  1888  Mr.  Goschen  proposed  that  the  ex- 
chequer should  surrender  one  moiety  of  the 
probate  duty  for  the  benefit  of  various  local 
authorities,  and  he  accompanied  this  proposal 
by  an  addition  of  a  ^  per  cent  to  the  1  per  cent 
rate  of  succession  duty  and  of  l^-  per  cent  to 
the  higher  rates.  In  1889  he  imposed  a  new 
duty,  analogous  to  the  probate  and  succession 
duties,  which  was  termed  the  "estate  duty"  by 
reason  of  its  limitation  to  estates  or  successions 
of  £10,000  and  upwards. 

In  1894  Sir  William  Harcourt  in  his  Budget 
of  that  year,  rearranged  the  system  of  the  Death 
Duties  into  which  he  introduced  the  principle 
of  graduation.  A  new  estate  duty  was  imposed 
to  take  the  place  of  probate  and  account  duty 
and  of  the  former  estate  duty.  The  new  duty 
was  levied  on  the  principal  value  of  all  settled 
property  passing  at  death,  at  rates  varying  from 
1  per  cent  on  property  from  £100  to  £500  in 
value,  to  8  per  cent  on  estates  valued  at  over 
£1,000,000.  The  net  produce  of  this  tax  in 
1901-2  amounted  to  £13,908,490,  legacy  duty 
yielded  £3,133,588,  and  other  duties,  including 
succession  duty,  £1,308,136,  brought  up  the 
total  proceedsofthedeath  duties  to  £18,513,714. 
In  1907  Mr.  Asquith raised  the  Estate  Duties,  and 
in  1910  Mr.  Lloyd  George  passed  his  Finance  Act, 
by  which  the  rates  were  considerably  increased. 
The  Act  of  1914  proposes  still  further  changes. 

It  will  now  be  convenient  to  describe,  undei 
their  respective  heads,  the  death  duties  at 
present  levied  in  the  United  Kingdom. 

(1)  Estate  Duty.— This  duty,  imposed  by 
Sir  William  Harcourt,  as  stated  above,  took 
the  place  of  the  Probate,  Administrative  and 


492 


DEATH   DUTIES 


Inventory  Duties,  the  Account  Duty  and  Estate 
Duty,  which  had  been  in  force  up  to  that  time. 
It  requires  that  prior  to  the  issue  of  any  grant 
of  probate  or  letters  of  administration  of  the 
estate  of  any  deceased  person,  the  applicant 
should  deliver  an  affidavit  containing  detailed 
particulars  of  the  value  and  description  of  all 
the  property  belonging  to  the  deceased  which 
the  executor  or  administrator  has  the  right  to 
recover  virtute  officii.  All  property  must  be 
included,  whether  real  or  personal,  settled  or 
not  settled.  Leaseholds  are  personal  property 
and  should  also  be  entered  in  the  affidavit. 
Debts  payable  out  of  the  estate,  together  with 
reasonable  funeral  expenses,  may  be  deducted 
from  the  assets,  and  the  duty  is  charged  upon 
the  principal  amount  of  the  estate  according  to 
the  following  scale  imposed  by  Mr.  Lloyd 
George's  Budget,  1910. 


1 

Principal  Value  of  the  Estate. 

Rate  of 
Duty. 

Above         £100  and  not  above         £500 

£1  per  cent 

500      „            „            1,000 

2         „ 

1,000       „            „             5,000 

3 

5,000       „            „           10,000 

4 

10,000      „            „           20,000 

5 

20,000      „            „           40,000 

6 

40,000      „            „           70,000 

7 

70,000       „            „         100,000 

^         '■ 

100,000      „            „         150,000 

9 

150,000       „            „         200,000 

10 

200,000       „            „         400,000 

11 

400,000       „            „         600,000 

12 

600,000      „            „         800,000 

13 

800,000       „            „       1,000,000 

14 

1,000,000 

15 

The  duty  is  denoted  by  means  of  a  stamp  on 
the  affidavit,  and  provision  is  made  for  the 
delivery  of  a  "corrective  affidavit"  where  an 
adjustment  of  the  duty  originally  paid  is  found 
necessary.  In  the  case  of  small  estates  not 
exceeding  the  gross  value  of  £300  a  fixed  duty 
of  30s.,  and  of  estates  between  £300  and  £500 
gross  value  50s.,  may  be  paid,  the  grant  of 
representation  being  obtained  through  the 
agency  of  the  officers  of  inland  revenue  on 
payment  of  a  fee  of  158.  in  lieu  of  the  fees 
ordinarily  charged  in  the  Probate  Division  of 
the  High  Court.  In  Scotland,  where  the  pro- 
cedure at  death  differs  from  that  in  force  in 
England  and  Ireland,  the  duty  is  payable  on 
the  inventory  which  is  required  to  be  exhibited 
in  that  country — where  property  is  situated  in 
more  than  one  of  the  three  kingdoms,  arrange- 
ments are  made  by  which  one  grant  of  repre- 
sentation suffices. 

Among  other  alterations  introduced  by  the 
Budget  of  1910  was  the  Increment  Value  Duty. 
This,  after  April  30,  1909,  is  leviable  at  the 
rate  of  £1  for  every  complete  £5  of  the  in- 
creased value  of  the  land,  when,  on  the  occasion 
of  any  transfer  or  sale,  and  at  the  death  of  the 
owner,  the  property  is  valued  for  Estate  Duty. 
For  details   see   the   Finance  Act,  1910.     It 


further  enacted  that  Real  Property  may  be 
transferred  as  payment  of  Estate  Duty,  Settle- 
ment Estate  Duty,  or  Succession  Duty  ;  that 
gifts  of  over  £100  made  during  the  last  three 
years  of  life,  with  the  exception  of  gifts  for 
public  or  charitable  purposes,  in  consideration 
of  marriage,  or  as  part  of  reasonable  norma 
expenditure,  are  regarded  as  property  passing 
at  death  and  taxed  accordingly.  Settlement 
Estate  Duty  was  raised  from  1  to  2  per  cent. 

The  Estate  Duty  produced  the  sura  of 
£14,231,000  in  the  year  1908-9.  Taken  as  a 
whole  they  form  the  most  important  branch  of 
the  death  duties — more  than  77  per  cent  of 
the  total.  The  yield  exceeded  £500,000  for 
the  first  time  in  1814,  £1,000,000  in  1837, 
£1,500,000  in  1863,  £2,000,000  in  1872, 
£4,000,000  in  1883,  £10,000,000  in  1895, 
£12,000,000  in  1900.  The  produce  for  1908-9 
represented  the  duty  levied  at  the  rates  imposed 
by  the  Act  of  1907;  in  1912-13  it  was 
£20,046,347,  the  large  increase  resulting  from 
the  Act  of  1 9 1 0.  The  estates  upon  which  the  duty 
was  collected  may  be  classified  thus  (1913)  : — 


Net  Value  of  Estate. 

=1 

Value. 

Not  above  £1000    .        .        .        . 
Above£1000Mnclnotabove  £100,000 
Above  £100,000      .        .        .        . 

48,179 

22,316 

293 

£ 
19,906,000 
174,914,000 
84,442,000 

70,788 

279,252,000 

(2)  Legacy  Ihity. — This  duty,  originally  a 
stamp  duty  on  receipts,  is  now  more  fitly 
described  as  "a  tax  upon  movable  property  ; 
its  incidence  depends  upon  the  domicile  of  the 
deceased  owner,  and  its  amount  upon  the  value 
of  the  bequest  or  succession,  and  upon  the 
degree  of  consanguinity  existing  between  the 


1  per  cent 
1        „ 


10 


deceased  and  the  legatee."     It  is 
(1914)  at  the  following  rates  : — 

Husband  or  wife      .... 
Lineal  issue  or  lineal  ancestor  . 
Brothers  and  sisters  and   their   de- 
scendants     

Uncles  and  aunts,  all  other  relations 

and  any  other  person  . 
The  1  per  cent  duty  is  not  levied  when  the 
principal  value  of  the  property  is  less  than 
£15,000,  or  when  the  value  of  the  legacy  or 
Succession  does  not  exceed  £1000  (£2000  in 
the  case  of  widow  or  child  of  deceased),  what- 
ever may  be  its  principal  value.  The  duty  is 
payable  when  the  legatee  comes  into  the  posses- 
sion of  his  legacy,  and  owing  to  the  complexity 
of  the  manner  in  which  property  may  be  dis- 
posed of  by  a  testator,  the  rules  for  its  assess 
ment  are  of  an  exceedingly  complicated  char 
acter.  The  duty  is  paid  in  money,  althoug' 
a  stamp  is  impressed  on  certain  forms  of  ai 
count  in  order  to  denote  the  discharge  of  the 


DEATH  DUTIES— DEATH-RATE 


498 


liability.     There  are  some  exemptions  in  favour 
of  the  Royal  Family,  learned  societies,  etc. 

The  legacy  duty  produced  £3,336,000  in 
1908-9,  and  it  then  comprised  nearly  18  per  cent 
of  the  total  yield  of  the  death  duties.  The  receipts 
amounted  to  £546,000  in  1809,  £1,070,000  in 
1822,  £2,935,000  in  1877,  £2,731,000  in 
1895-6,  and  £3,909,000  in  1907-8.  This  last- 
named  sum  was  not  exceeded  until  the  figures 
increased  considerably  under  the  present  scale 
of  rates  (1914),  being  £4,506,923  in  1912-13. 

Considerable  difficulties  arise  in  the  collection 
of  the  legacy  duty  by  reason  of  the  length  of 
time  which  may  elapse  between  the  death  of  a 
testator  and  the  receipt  of  a  legacy.  But  these 
difficulties  cannot  well  be  avoided  if  a  consan- 
guinity scale  is  maintained,  and  the  retention 
of  such  a  scale  is  now  almost  universally  sup- 
ported by  public  opinion.  All  present  and 
future  claims  for  legacy  duty  under  a  will  may 
be  compounded  for  by  agreement,  but  this 
course  is  not  adopted  to  any  large  extent. 

(3)  Siiccession  Duty.  —  This  duty  supple- 
ments and  completes  the  duty  on  legacies.  It 
charges  "  all  successions  to  property,  real  as 
well  as  personal,  whether  the  title  be  under 
settlement  or  will,  by  descent,  intestacy,  or  sur- 
vivorship." The  rate  payable  depends  on  the 
consanguinity  of  the  person  from  whom  the 
succession  is  derived.  Where  Estate  Duty 
is  not  payable  the  following  is  the  scale  : — 
Lineal  issue  or  lineal  ancestor.  .  .  l^V  per  cent 
Brothers  and  sisters  and  their  descendants  4^!-  ,, 
Uncles  and  aunts                ,,                ,,  Oj        ,, 

Great  uncles  and  aunts      „                ,,  V:V        ,, 

Any  other  x^erson 11  i        ,, 

The  capital  sura  upon  wliich  these  rates  of 
duty  are  calculated  is  ordinarily  arrived  at  by 
ascertaining  the  net  annual  value  of  the  suc- 
cession after  deduction  of  necessary  outgoings, 
and  by  calculating  the  worth  of  an  annuity  for 
an  amount  equal  to  such  net  annual  value,  for 
the  life  of  the  successor,  according  to  the 
annuity  tables  set  out  in  a  schedule  to  the  Act 
16  and  17  Vict.  cap.  51.  Thus  if  the  annual 
income  of  an  estate  be  £350,  and  the  necessary 
outgoings  £50,  the  successor  being  thirty-five 
years  of  age,  the  duty  is  calculated  on  £4725, 
that  being  the  assumed  value  of  an  annuity  of 
£300  at  that  age.  The  amount  so  assessed 
is  payable  either  by  eight  equal  half-yearly 
instalments,  the  first  being  due  twelve  months 
after  the  succession  opens,  or,  as  an  alternative, 
by  three  annual  instalments  of  one-eighth  of  the 
duty  and  by  a  fourth  instalment  equal  to  the 
amount  of  the  remaining  five-eightha.  Like 
the  legacy  duty,  the  succession  duty  is  payable 
in  money,  although  a  stamp  is  impressed  on  the 
account  required  to  be  brought  in.  Certain 
small  successions  are  exempt  and  provision  is 
made  to  prevent  the  charge  of  both  legacy  and 
succession  duty  on  the  same  succession. 

The  succession  duty  produced  £565,000  in 
1858-59,   and  twenty  years  later  the  produce 


was  £725,000.  In  1890-91  it  was  £1,209,000, 
and  £1,309,000  in  1901-2,  the  maximum 
amount  reached.  Since  that  date  it  has  fallen, 
and  was  only  £767,039  in  1912-13. 

The  succession  duty  has  been  criticised  on 
the  ground  that  the  charges  it  imposes  on  real 
property  are  less  than  tlie  corresponding  ones 
on  personal  estate.  Tliis  inequality  was  to 
some  extent  redressed  by  the  legislation  of 
1888,  but  the  manner  in  which  the  duty  is 
assessed  and  paid  still  favour  settled  personalty 
and,  to  a  greater  extent,  realty.  The  inequality 
is,  however,  defended  by  reference  to  the  excep- 
tional pressure  of  the  income  tax  on  landed 
property,  and  to  the  incidence  of  local  and 
imperial  taxation  generally. 

[Wallace,  Epitome  of  the  Death  Duties,  1886. — 
Trevor,  Digest  of  Taxes  on  Successions,  4th  ed. 
1881. — Hanson,  Probate,  Legacy,  and  Succession 
Duty  Acts,  3rd  ed.  1876. — Hanson,  Revenue  Acts 
of  1881,  1883. — M'Culloch,  Treatise  on  Succession 
to  Property  vacant  by  Death. — Thring,  Introduction 
to  the  Succession  Duty  Act,  1853. — Archbold,  Suc- 
cession Duty  Act  of  1853, 1854. — Griffith,  Digest  of 
the  Stamp  Duties,  9th  ed.  1886. — Harris,  English 
Death  Dxcties,  1890. — Buxton  and  Barnes,  Hand- 
hook  to  the  Death  Duties,  1890. — Dowell,  History 
of  Taxation  and  Taxes  in  England. — Hansard, 
Debates,  Reports  of  the,  Covimissioners  of  Inland 
Revenue. — Finance  (1909-10)  Act.^       t.  h.  b. 

DEATH-RATE 

Analysis  of  Contents.— Definition  and  division  of  the 
subject.  I.  Duath-rate  as  a  factor  in  the  natural 
increase  of  population,  p.  493.  II.  The  causes  ol 
variation  in  death-rate ;  (a)  such  causes  as  age  and 
sex;  Qj)  such  as  vice,  unhealthy  occupations,  indi- 
gence, insanitary  residences,  p.  494.  III.  Death-rate, 
as  indicating  (by  its  decline)  national  prosperity,  p. 
497.     IV.  In  relation  to  insurance,  p.  497. 

I.  Death-kate  may  be  defined  as  the  ratio 
between  the  number  of  persons  dying,  out  of  a 
certain  population,  in  a  unit  of  time,  generally 
a  year,  and  the  number  of  the  population.  But 
as  the  number  of  the  population  cannot  be 
supposed  constant  for  any  considerable  time, 
there  is  some  difficulty  in  rendering  precise 
the  conception  which  has  been  indicated.  To 
remove  the  diflSculty  completely  the  use  of  the 
differential  calculus  would  be  required,  but  it 
is  not  necessary  to  call  in  that  aid  except  for 
certain  actuarial  calculations.  For  the  less 
technical  inquiries  which  are  the  object  of 
this  article  the  general  idea  which  the  definition 
above  given  conveys  is  sufficiently  clear. 

The  death-rate  is  the  most  important  ratio  or 
coefficient  in  vital  statistics.  While  co-ordinate 
with  birth-rate  as  a  factor  in  the  natural  in- 
crease of  population,  death-rate  is  more  import- 
ant than  Birth-rate  {q.v.)  on  the  following 
grounds.  The  investigation  of  the  causes  which 
affect  death-rate  is  more  directly  connected  with 
a  practical  art,  that  of  preventing  disease. 
Again  birth-rate  by  its  variation  gives  a  more 
equivocal  sign  of  national  prosperity  or  the 
reverse,  than  death-rate.     A  rise  in  birth-rate 


494 


DEATH-RATE 


may  be  due  to  increased  improvidence  or  illegi- 
timacy, as  well  as  to  material  prosperity ; 
whereas  a  fall  in  death-rate  can  hardly  admit 
of  any  other  than  a  favourable  construction. 
Again  the  chance  of  death  is  an  object  of  wider 
and  deeper  interest  than  any  other  dat^mi  in 
vital  statistics  ;  and  a  great  practical  business, 
that  of  insurance,  is  based  on  these  probabilities. 
These  points  of  comparison  being  taken  as 
headings  ;  it  may  first  (I.)  be  observed  that  the 
natural  increase,  being  the  difference  between 
birth-rate  and  death-rate,  is  not  necessarily  small 
where  death-rate  is  large,  or  large  where  death- 
rate  is  small.  Thus  the  death-rate  for  Russia 
in  recent  years,  35  "7  per  mille  (Marshall,  Prin- 
ciples of  Economics,  bk.  iv.  ch.  iv.  and  authori- 
ties there  cited),  exceeds  the  average  of  Europe, 
28  per  mille,  by  a  fourth,  yet  the  natural  increase 
for  Russia,  13  per  mille,  is  above  the  average 
for  Europe.  Again  the  death-rate  for  England 
is  below,  the  natural  increase  above,  the  average 
for  Europe. 

Other  examples  are  given  in  the  article  on 
Birth-rate  ;  where  it  was  pointed  out  that 
large  birth-rates  are  frequently  attended  by, 
but  do  not  cause,  large  death-rates. 

II.  The  question  there  raised  is  to  be  more 
fully  considered  here  under  the  head  of  causes 
of  variation  in  death-rates,  (a)  One  such  cause 
is  difference  of  age.  If  the  population  of  any 
country  is  divided  into  groups  of  different  ages, 
the  death-rates  for  the  different  groups  differ 
enormously.  Thus  (according  to  the  English 
Life-Table,  No.  III.,  which  may  be  regarded 
as  a  standard)  the  mortality  for  infants  under 
one  year  old  is  m  England  165-6  per  1000 
(Vital  Statistics,  Selections  from  the  writings  of 
William  Farr,  by  Noel  A.  Humphreys,  p. 
491),  while  it  is  only  5*2  per  1000  at  the  age- 
period  10-15  (ibid.  p.  487),  After  that  period 
the  death-rate  increases  with  the  age.  At  the 
period  75-85  it  has  become  140  per  1000,  and 
is  still  greater  at  later  ages  ;  the  death-rate  of 
second  childhood  equals  that  of  infancy.  The 
general  law  is  happily  indicated  by  Addison  in 
his  Vision  of  Mirza  {Spectator,  No.  159,  1st 
September  1711),  where  the  human  race  is 
imagined  passing  over  the  flood  of  eternity  by 
a  bridge,  supported  on  as  many  arches  as  there 
are  years  in  man's  life.  "  Hidden  pitfalls  were 
set  very  thick  at  the  entrance  of  the  bridge,  so 
that  throngs  of  people  no  sooner  broke  through 
the  cloud  but  many  of  them  fell  into  them. 
They  grew  thinner  towards  the  middle,  but 
multiplied  and  lay  closer  together  towards  the 
end  of  the  arches." 

It  follows  from  this  law  that  in  a  population 
where  there  is  a  particularly  large  proportion 
of  infants  or  old  persons  the  general  death-rate, 
the  mortality  "at  all  ages,"  as  it  is  called,  is 
apt  to  be  high.  Now  in  an  increasing  popula- 
tion, as  compared  with  a  stationary  one,  the 
number  of  births  continually  augmenting,  the 


number  of  infants  is  particularly  large.  Henca 
it  is  plausibly  argued  that  an  increasing  popula- 
tion, just  because  it  is  increasing,  will  have  a 
high  death-rate  ;  that  high  birth-rates,  per  se, 
make  high  death-rates  ;  other  things,  and  in 
particular  the  mortality  at  each  age-period, 
being  supposed  the  same. 

But  here,  as  so  frequently  in  statistics,  first 
appearances  are  fallacious.  It  is  true,  no  doubt, 
that  in  an  increasing  population  there  is  a  par- 
ticularly large  proportion  of  infants  subject  to 
a  high  mortality.  But  it  is  also  true  that,  in 
such  a  population,  the  proportion  of  persons  at 
those  advanced  ages  at  which  the  mortality  is 
high  is  apt  to  be  particularly  small  as  compared 
with  the  numbers  in  the  period  of  healthy 
adolescence  (Farr,  Vital  Statistics,  "Deaths." 
Humphreys  "On  the  Value  of  Death-rates," 
Journal  of  the  Statistical  Society,  1874,  vol. 
xxxvii.) 

From  these  considerations  it  appears  that 
great  care  must  be  exercised  in  allowing  for  the 
influence  of  age  on  mortality  before  drawing 
inferences  from  the  death-rate  as  to  the  sanitary 
condition  of  a  population.  To  take  an  extreme 
instance,  suppose  that  the  death-rate  for  the 
inmates  of  a  prison  were  the  same  as  that  for 
the  general  population,  this  at  first  sight  might 
appear  a  satisfactory  state  of  things.  But 
when  it  is  considered  that  the  prison  population 
consists  of  adults,  a  class  of  which  the  mortality 
under  ordinary  conditions  might  be  expected 
to  be  half  that  of  the  general  population,  the 
conclusion  becomes  very  different. 

To  take  a  less  simple  case.  The  death-rate 
in  many  towns  is  particularly  high.  But  it 
has  been  argued  that  this  is  not  an  unfavour- 
able symptom,  for  that  it  is  due  to  the  presence 
of  a  great  number  of  infants.  But  the  truth 
is,  that  the  inference  from  the  high  death- 
rates  becomes  d  fortiori  unfavourable  when 
proper  account  is  taken  of  the  ages  of  the  urban 
population. 

A  usual  method  of  exhibiting  such  conclu- 
sions is  to  construct  what  is  called  a  "normal" 
death-rate  for  any  group  under  consideration  ; 
by  supposing  the  persons  at  each  period  of  age 
in  that  particular  population  to  be  affected 
with  the  mortality  prevalent  at  that  age  in 
the  general  population  (or  any  other  popula- 
tion taken  as  standard).  Thus  in  the  case  of 
three  counties  containing  large  towns,  instanced 
by  Mr.  Humphreys  in  his  instructive  paper 
above  cited,  the  actual  death-rate  was  26-5.1 
But  the  normal  death-rate,  or  that  which 
might  have  been  expected,  if  the  mortality  at 
each  age  was  the  same  as  for  the  general  popu- 
lation, was  only  22.2.1  ^^go  the  actual  death- 
rate  for  three  rural  counties  was  19  ;  while  the, 
normal  death-rate  was  23-8.  The  two  pairs  oU 
figures,  whether  compared  with  each  other  or| 

1  Taking  the  simple  average  of  the  death-rates  given 
for  each  of  the  three  counties. 


DEATH-EATE 


496 


with  the  standard  death-rate  for  a  stationary 
population,  which  Mr.  Humphreys  gives  as 
24*47,  show  that  the  unfavourable  inference 
concerning  the  urban  as  compared  with  the 
rural  counties  is  stronger  than  at  first  sight 
appears.  The  original  figures,  26 '5  and  19, 
differ  only  by  7  "5.  But  we  may  regard  the 
excess  of  the  mortality  in  the  urban  over  the 
rural  counties  as  virtually  nine  ;  if  we  take 
into  account  that  the  former  normally  would 
have  been  less  by  nearly  two  than  the  latter. 

A  more  exact  method  of  drawing  such  com- 
parisons is  to  express  the  mortality  of  each 
section  as  a  ratio  of  its  actual  to  its  normal 
mortality.  This  plan  is  adopted  by  Mr. 
Humphreys  in  his  article  on  "Class  Mortality 
Statistics,"  in  the  Journal  of  the  Statistical 
Society  for  1887.  T^ie  following  figures  (ex- 
tracted from  Mr.  Humphreys'  Table  IV.,  loc. 
cit.,  p.  281)  relate  to  the  mortality  in  two 
classes  of  the  Dublin  population  : 


Description  of 
Class. 

Recorded 
death-rate 
per  1000. 

standard 
death-rate 
according 
to  English 
Life-table. 

Coefficient  of 
comparative 
mortality. 

Professional 

Class  . 
General  Service 

Class  . 

19-8 
36-8 

25-2 
21-3 

632 
1659 

The  first  column  gives  the  actually  observed 
mortality  at  all  ages  for  the  more  and  less 
favoured  class.  The  second  column  gives  the 
corresponding  normal  mortalities  (obtained  on 
the  hypothesis  that  the  numbers  at  each  age 
were  those  observed  for  Dublin,  and  the  mort- 
ality at  each  age  that  observed  for  England). 
The  third  column  gives  the  coefl[icients  express- 
ing the  force  of  mortality ;  being  each  the 
ratio  of  normal  to  actual  mortality,  multiplied 
by  1000,  or  expressed  as  a  per  mille.  It  will 
be  observed  that  the  evidence  of  diff'erence  in 
healthiness  afforded  by  the  first  column  be- 
comes d  fortiori  in  the  third  column.  The 
mortality  of  the  "general  service"  class 
appears  to  be  nearly  twice  as  great,  and  is 
nearly  three  times  as  great  as  that  of  the  pro- 
fessional class. 

The  cause  of  variations  in  death-rate  which 
has  been  considered,  namely  diff'erence  of  age, 
may  be  placed  in  a  category  of  causes  which 
are  of  practical  importance,  largely  on  the 
ground  that  it  is  necessary  to  allow  for  their 
action  in  order  to  estimate  the  effect  of  another 
class  of  causes  which  it  is  more  within  the  scope 
of  human  art  to  alleviate.  This  distinction  is 
nearly  identical  with  Dr.  Farr's  of  "causes 
inherent  in  the  population,  and  causes  outside 
the  population"  {Vital  Statistics,  p.  159  ei 
seq.)  Another  cause  belonging  to  the  first 
category  is  sex.     The  full  effect  of  this  cause 


may  be  seen  on  inspection  of  a  life-table.  At 
the  early  ages  the  difference  between  the  mort- 
ality of  the  two  sexes  is  marked.  At  the  zero- 
point  of  age  it  appears  that  the  proportion  of 
male  to  female  still-born  children  is  139  :  100. 
For  the  period  0-5  the  proportion  of  mortality 
is  72  :  62  (according  to  Dr.  Farr's  Life-Table  for 
England  and  Wales).  At  the  age  of  adoles- 
cence female  mortality  gains  upon  male  ;  but 
again  lags  behind  at  later  ages.  The  disturbing 
effect  which  this  cause  exercises  on  inferences 
drawn  from  the  general  death-rate  is  not  so  con- 
siderable as  the  effect  of  age.  Mr.  Humphreys 
in  his  paper  "On  the  Value  of  Death-rates" 
already  referred  to  (Journal  of  Stat.  Soc, 
xxxvii.  p.  444),  contrasting  the  English  towns 
which  have  the  greatest  and  the  least  pro- 
portion of  male  to  female  inhabitants,  argues 
that  the  extreme  perturbation  of  the  general 
death-rates  which  may  be  expected  from  this 
cause  is  not  more  than  two  per  mille. 

Here  may  be  mentioned  the  effect  on  mortal- 
ity of  the  variations  of  the  seasons.  Of  the 
four  quarters  of  the  year  the  first  is  the  most 
fatal ;  next  comes  the  fourth  ;  the  mortality  of 
the  second  quarter  is  for  this  country  on  an 
average  in  excess,  but  occasionally  below,  that 
of  the  third  quarter  (Reports  of  the  Registrar- 
General,  tables  showing  death-rates  in  each 
quarter  of  the  years  since  1838).  A  very 
elegant  graphical  representation  of  such  vicissi- 
tudes is  given  by  M.  Levasseur  (after  M. 
Janssens)  for  Belgian  infants,  in  the  Jubilee 
volume  of  the  Statistical  Society,  1885,  p.  232. 
Quetelet's  investigations  of  seasonal  mortality 
in  Belgium  are  particularly  instructive  {Physique 
Sociale,  liv.  ii.  ch.  v.  §  8).  He  shows  that  the 
curve  of  death-rate  at  different  seasons  varies 
for  different  ages  ;  and  that  very  generally  it 
presents  two  maxima,  one  in  winter  the  other 
in  summer.  Besides  the  obvious  importance 
attaching  to  such  observations,  they  are  valu- 
able as  enabling  us  to  avoid  perplexity  in 
investigating  other  causes.  The  Registrar- 
General,  in  the  investigation  which  will  be 
presently  noticed  concerning  the  death-rate  in 
different  occupations,  has  very  properly  selected 
the  samples  (of  deaths)  on  which  his  conclusion 
is  based  from  all  seasons  indifferently  {Supple- 
ment to  the  45th  Report  of  the  Registrar-General, 
p.  29).  A  sophist  by  taking  the  samples  for 
one  occupation  from  a  healthy  season,  and  for 
another  occupation  from  an  unhealthy  season, 
might  have  brought  out  almost  any  conclusion 
which  he  wanted. 

Other  causes,  not  admitting  of  such  exact 
measurement,  are  race  and  climate  (including 
properties  of  soil,  water,  etc.) 

Also  it  may  be  expected  that  the  mortality 
of  unmarried  persons  will,  ceteris  paribus,  be 
particularly  large.  The  married  have  the 
advantage  at  almost  all  ages,  as  is  shown  by  Dr. 
Farr  {Vital  Statistics,  p.  441,  and  references 


496 


DEATH-EATE 


tihere  given).  But  it  is  a  nice  question  whether 
celibacy  can  be  regarded  as  a  cause  of  high 
death-rate.  The  high  death-rate  attending 
celibacy  may  be  a  case  of  post  hoc  not  propter 
hoc ;  the  finest  individuals  being  selected  for 
marriage  ;  while  "men  with  a  weak  constitu- 
tion, ill-health,  or  any  great  infirmity  of  Hody  or 
mind  will  not  often  wish  to  marry,  or  will  be 
rejected  "  (Darwin,  Descent  of  Man,  pt.  i.  ch.  v.) 

(h)  The  causes  which  have  been  mentioned 
require  to  be  taken  account  of  by  those  who 
would  avoid  perplexity  in  investigating  another 
set  of  causes  which  are  perhaps  of  more  direct 
practical  interest :  as  being  capable  of  remedy 
by  human  eff'ort.  This  second  category  of 
causes  may  be  divided  under  four  heads :  (1) 
vice,  (2)  unhealthy  occupations,  (3)  indigence, 
and  (4)  insanitary  residences, — agencies  which 
are  apt  to  be  entangled  with  each  other  as 
well  as  with  the  first  set  of  causes. 

(1)  There  is  much  truth  as  well  as  exaggera- 
tion in  Siissmilch's  dictum  ascribing  the  chief 
differences  in  mortality  to  "  the  manner  of  life, 
.  the  moral  circumstances,  virtue  and  vice,  indol- 
ence and  industry."  One  example  is  the  great 
mortality  of  illegitimate  children.  Dr.  Farr 
cites  instances  in  which  the  death-rate  of 
illegitimate  infants  is  double  that  of  the  legiti- 
mate {Vital  Statistics,  p.  198).  A  similar 
excess  of  mortality  among  illegitimate  children 
is  shown  by  Quetelet  {Physique  Sociale,  bk.  ii. 
ch.  vii.  §  2),  Wappaeus  {Bevolkerungs  Statistik, 
pt.  i.  p.  214),  and  other  continental  statisticians. 
The  vice  of  drunkenness  is  also  conspicuously 
fatal.  On  this  subject  some  of  the  most  recent 
observations  together  with  a  reference  to  the 
best  authorities  will  be  found  in  the  Report  on 
the  connection  of  disease  with  habits  of  intemper- 
ance by  the  collective  investigation  of  the  British 
Medical  Association,  edited  by  Isambard  Owen. 
Among  the  earlier  authorities  may  be  mentioned 
Neison,  who  in  his  Contributions  to  Vital 
Statistics  fully  proves  the  connection  between 
deep  drinking  and  high  death-rate  ;  bringing 
out  the  remarkable  fact  that  spirits  are  more 
fatal  than  malt  liquors  {Contributions  to  Vital 
Statistics,  p.  218).  Another  authority  particu- 
larly free  from  suspicion  is  the  Eegistrar 
General,  whose  statistics  with  respect  to 
occupations  (Supplements  to  Reports  for  1865, 
1875,  and  1885)  point  unmistakably  to  a 
connection  between  drink  and  death.  The 
mortality  of  hotel-keepers  and  theii-  servants  is 
appalling,  about  three  times  as  great  as  that  of 
the  most  healthy  classes.  Among  the  diseases 
to  which  the  classes  mentioned  and  several 
others  succumb,  "alcoholism  "  plays  a  large  part 
(Supplement  to  Report  for  1885,  p.  xxx.  et  seq.) 

At  this  point,  however,  the  action  of  the 
cause  which  has  been  considered  is  intermixed 
with  that  which  we  have  distinguished  as  cause 
(2),  unhealthy  occupations.  It  is  difficult  to 
pronounce  with  respect  to  the  mortality  in  some 


occupations  how  much  thereof  is  occasioned  by 
unresisted  temptation  to  drink,  how  much  ia 
due  to  other  circumstances.  Thus  in  the  case 
of  drivers  ("Cab,  Omnibus,  Service,"  loc.  cit.), 
the  bill  of  mortality  due  to  "  alcoholism  "  is  par- 
ticularly large ;  but  the  same  class  also  succumb 
in  numbers  to  phthisis  and  diseases  of  the 
respiratory  system,  which  may  no  doubt  be 
connected  with  the  exposure  incident  to  the 
occupations  in  question. 

(2)  The  observations  referred  to  prove  the 
influence  of  occupation  on  health  in  many  cases 
to  be  real  and  considerable.  The  number  of 
deaths  observed  in  188 1-82 — more  than  400, 000  ; 
the  scrupulosity  above  noticed  with  which  these 
samples  have  been  selected  impartially  from 
healthy  and  unhealthy  seasons ;  the  allow- 
ance for  the  effect  of  ag^  (expressed  in  the  last 
column  of  table  J,  Supplement  to  the  45th  Report 
1885,  p.  xxvi.),  are  very  convincing.  The  sus- 
picion of  accident  is  precluded  by  the  general 
agreement  between  the  statistics  for  1861-62, 
1871,  and  1880-82.  The  same  occupations 
constantly  come  out  low  or  high  in  the  scale  of 
mortality.  At  one  end  of  the  scale  are  clergy- 
men with  a  co-efficient  of  death-rate  or  '  *  compara- 
tive mortality  figure"  556,  gardeners  and 
farmers  with  co-efficients  respectively  599  and 
681,  with  at  the  other  end  of  the  scale  hotel- 
keepers  and  their  servants,  for  whom  the  corre- 
sponding figures  are  respectively  1521  and  2205, 
also  chimney-sweeps,  workers  in  earthenware 
(1742),  and  the  residual  class  of  general  labourer 
(2020).  (See  J.  T.  Arlidge,  M.D.,  The  Hygiene, 
Diseases,  and  MortalUy  of  Occupations,  1892.) 

(3)  In  the  last  case  and  probably  some 
others,  a  further  cause — indigence,  comes  into 
play.  The  term  indigence  must  be  construed 
strictly  as  want  of  necessaries,  "inadequate 
warmth  and  food"  (Farr).  Mere  absence  of 
riches  is  not  fatal  to  life,  as  Nelson's  statistics 
with  respect  to  members  of  friendly  societies  show 
{Contributions  to  Vital  Statistics ;  cp.  Wappaeus, 
Bevolkerungs  Statistik,  pt.  i.  p.  201).  The  very 
different  consequences  of  actual  indigence  may 
be  traced  in  certain  statistics  of  class  mortality 
among  the  population  of  Dublin  compiled  by 
Dr.  Grimshaw,  and  discussed  by  Mr.  Humphreys 
in  a  paper  already  referred  to  {Journal  of  the 
Statistical  Society  1887,  vol.  50).  In  the  same 
paper  reference  is  made  to  the  observations  made 
by  Mr.  Ansell  and  Hodgson  and  others,  proving 
that  the  more  favoured  classes  enjoy  greater  vital- 
ity. Especially  with  respect  to  infant  mortality 
is  the  poverty  of  the  poor  his  curse.  The  death- 
rate  for  infants  under  5,  in  the  "  general  service  " 
class  of  the  Dublin  population,  was  110  pei 
mille,  in  the  "professional "  class  22  per  mille 
{ibid.  p.  282).  So  the  mortality  of  peers'  and 
clergymen's  children  is  three  times  less  than 
the  mortality  of  infants  of  the  same  age  in 
large  towns  (Farr,  Vital  Statistics,  p.  159). 
These  conclusions  are  confirmed  by  numerous 


DEATH-RATE 


497 


observations  on  the  comparative  death-rate  in 
the  poorer  and  more  flourishing  parts  of  towns  ; 
some  of  which  are  cited  by  Wappaeus  {Bevollc- 
erungs  Statlstik,  pt.  i.  p.  200). 

(4)  Here,  and  indeed  generally,  mere  indi- 
gence, the  want  of  necessaries,  is  aggravated  by 
a  fourth  cause,  insanitary  conditions  of  resid- 
ence, or,  m  Dr.  Farr's  more  exact  language, 
"exposure  to  poisonous  effluvia  and  destructive 
agencies. "  The  interaction  of  these  two  causes 
is  very  strikingly  exhibited  in  an  article  in  the 
GiomaledegliEconomisti,  "  NuovaPolitica  Sani- 
taria, in  Italia  "  (March  1891)  ;  where  it  is  con- 
tended that  the  sanitary  measures  carried  out 
in  Italy  defeated  their  own  end.  For  the  tax- 
payer, deprived  by  the  burden  of  taxation  of  the 
necessaries  of  life,  becomes  thereby  more  exposed 
to  the  shafts  of  disease.  In  our  terminology 
cause  (4)  might  be  reduced,  and  yet  the  effect 
would  be  more  fatal  if  concurrently  cause  (3) 
were  aggravated. 

The  nature  and  variety  of  insanitary  condi- 
tions are  ably  discussed  by  Dr.  Farr  (Vital 
Statistics).  A  vast  mass  of  experience  as  to 
the  evil  effect  of  crowding  is  summed  up  by 
him  in  the  simple  formula  that  the  mortality 
of  districts  is  as  the  twelfth  root  of  their  densi- 
ties  {Vital   Statistics,   p.    175).       In  symbols 

m  _  /D\ -12. 

— >  —  (  ^  j  The   fact   that  in  an  earlier 

paper  the  sicdh  root  was  proposed,  and  that  in 
the  formula  the  index  '12  does  not  signify  the 
twelfth,  but  rather  the  eighth  or  ninth  root, 
is  not  suggestive  of  extreme  precision.  At 
any  rate  the  law  makes  no  claim  to  be  more 
than  empirical.  It  is  not  fulfilled  by  the 
experience  of  the  crowded  Peabody  Buildings  ; 
where  the  mortality  is  less  than  for  London 
generally  (Newholme,  Journal  of  the  Statistical 
Society,  1891).  It  is  interesting  to  inquire 
whether  the  causes  of  death  which  admit  of 
reduction  are  being  reduced  by  science  ;  or : — 

III.  More  generally,  and  without  reference 
to  causation,  whether  a  decline  of  death-rate 
attends  the  progress  of  civilisation.  The  most 
extended  series  of  observations  is  that  which 
the  Swedish  census  presents  (quoted  in  the 
25th  vol.  of  the  Journal  of  the  Statistical 
Society,  and  by  Wappaeus,  op.  cit.,  p.  229). 
Looking  at  these  we  may  now  say  with  even 
more  truth  than  Malthus  said  :  "The  gradual 
diminution  of  mortality  since  the  middle  of 
last  century  is  very  striking."  According  to 
Dr.  Farr  "  the  mortality  of  the  city  of  London 
was  at  the  rate  of  80  per  1000  in  the  latter 
half  of  the  17th  century,  50  in  the  18th, 
against  24  in  the  present  day"  {Vital  Statistics, 
p.  131)  ;  14-7,  Kept.  Registrar-General,  1908. 

On  the  other  hand  the  returns  for  France 

and  Russia,   extending  over  a  long  period  of 

years,   which  Wappaeus  adduces  {loc.  cit.),  do 

not  show  a  marked  decline.     And  it  is  remark- 

VOL.  L 


able  that  the  death-rate  for  England  and  Wales 
has  remained  virtually  unaltered  for  the  greater 
part  of  the  time  over  which  the  record  extends, 
from  1841  to  1871.  Since  that  period  indeed 
a  decline  has  set  in,  ascribed  by  some  to  im- 
proved sanitation. 

There  is  some  difficulty  in  estimating  the 
gain  which  has  been  made  in  recent  years, 
owing  to  the  circumstance  that  while  the  death- 
rates  at  some  (the  earlier)  ages  decreased,  at 
other  (later)  ages  the  death-rates  increased. 
Such  at  least  was  the  relation  when  the  stat- 
istics bearing  on  this  point  were  first  discussed 
by  Mr.  Humphreys  in  his  valuable  paper  in  the 
Journxil  of  the  Statistical  Society  ior  1883  ;  since 
that  date  the  gain  in  vitality  at  diflferent  ages 
may  have  become  more  uniform  (cp.  Report  of 
the  Registrar-General  for  1885,  Supplement). 

IV.  The  significance  of  the  recent  change  in 
death-rates  may  best  be  appreciated  by  glancing 
at  that  aspect  of  the  subject  which  in  the 
arrangement  here  adopted  has  been  placed 
last ;  namely,  that  which  relates  to  life  insur- 
ance. The  business  of  insurance  is  beyond  the 
scope  of  this  article.  But  the  theory  of  life- 
tables  on  which  that  business  rests  must  be 
understood  in  order  to  make  a  right  use  of 
mortality  statistics,  even  for  the  general  pur- 
poses here  contemplated. 

The  simplest  view  of  the  matter  is  that 
according  to  which  a  population  is  regarded  as 
"stationary" — a  steady  influx  of  life  through 
the  channel  of  birth,  a  steady  efflux  at  each 
age,  at  a  rate  proper  to  each  age.  To  compare 
the  vitality  of  two  populations  thus  conceived, 
there  are  available  several  measures  besides  the 
common  death-rate  hitherto  considered.  One 
consists  of  that  age  which  is  such  that  just  as 
many  persons  die  before  it  as  live  after  it  ;  the 
"  equation  of  life  "  as  it  is  called.  For  instance 
in  the  life-table  constructed  for  the  healthy 
districts  of  England  and  Wales  by  Dr.  Farr, 
this  meridian  point  is  at  the  age  58  nearly.  It 
is  an  even  chance  that  a  new-born  infant  will, 
or  will  not  survive  that  age.  Similarly  may 
be  determined  the  age  to  which  it  is  an  even 
chance  that  a  person  aged  10  or  20  years  will 
live.  Thus  Mr.  Neison  finds  that  for  males 
aged  10  in  the  rural  districts  of  England  and 
Wales,  the  equation  of  life  is  58*375  years; 
in  the  city  districts  the  corresponding  figure  is 
61*743  {Contributions  to  Vital  Statistics,  p. 
100).  This  eminent  statistician  holds  that 
* '  the  equation  of  life  .  .  .  appears  to  be  the 
best  mode  to  determine  the  comparative  value 
of  Hfe  in  different  classes  or  different  districts  " 
in  certain  cases  {ibid.)  at  least. 

Another  measure  of  vitality,  however,  has 
obtained  more  vogue,  namely,  the  average  dura- 
tion or  so-called  "expectation"  of  life,  or 
"mean  after- time"  as  Dr.  Farr  proposed  to 
call  it.  For  instance,  the  mean  after-time  foi 
males  at  birth,  according  to  the  English  life 

2  K 


498 


DEATH-RATE— DEBASEMENT  OF  COIN 


table  No.  3,  is  44*4  years  ;  at  the  age  of  11  (the 
prospect  of  living  having  improved  for  those 
who  have  cleared  the  dangers  of  infancy)  the 
mean  after-time  is  51  years  nearly. 

The  following  is  an  instructive  exapple 
of  the  uses  to  which  this  co-efficient  lends  it- 
self. Observing  the  age  at  which  a  number  of 
sovereigns  or  other  notables,  as  popes,  during 
a  series  of  generations  had  acceded,  we  can 
compare  the  average  length  of  their  reigns 
with  the  average  length  of  life  deducible  from 
a  standard  life-table  ;  and  thus  ascertain  that 
the  lives  of  men  are  lengthened  "with  the 
process  of  the  suns." 

This  example  illustrates  what  is  implied  in 
the  idea  of  an  average  duration,  the  putting 
together  and  treating  as  commensurate  quanti- 
ties the  lives  lived  by  different  persons.  In 
fact,  actuaries  often  consider  not  so  much  the 
mean  life  as  the  sum  of  lives,  the  "years  lived  " 
by  a  whole  population.  It  is  thus  that  the 
gain  in  vitality  referred  to  under  the  last  head- 
ing is  measured.  Considering  the  infants  bom 
in  any  one  year  in  England  and  Wales  number- 
ing say  859,000,  the  registrar-general  calculated 
that  the  years  to  be  lived  by  this  generation 
will,  in  vu'tue  of  the  change  in  death-rates  at 
various  ages  which  have  occurred  during  recent 
years,  be  more  numerous  by  some  two  million 
years  of  life  (Report  of  the  Eegistrar-General 
for  1885,  Supplement;  cp.  Humphreys,  Journal 
of  the  Statistical  Society,  1883).  Of  the  millions 
of  lives  thus  yearly  gained,  by  far  the  greater 
part  are  lived  at  the  ages  25  to  60,  which  are 
most  "careful,"  most  conducive  to  the  defence 
and  enrichment  of  our  country. 

So  far  with  reference  to  a  stationary  popula- 
tion, abstracting  the  fact  that  the  actual  popula- 
tion is  continually  increasing.  But  the  logic  of 
the  subject  and  its  fallacies  would  be  imperfectly 
treated  without  noticing  the  modifications  which 
this  fact  introduces.  In  a  stationary  population 
it  is  evident  that  the  mean  duration,  or  "  ex- 
pectation," of  life  is  identical  with  the  mean  age 
at  death  ;  and  a  little  attention  will  show  that 
each  of  these  co-efficients  is  identical  with  an- 
other measure  with  which  we  are  here  more 
particularly  concerned,  namely,  the  number  of 
persons  out  of  whom  one  dies  per  annum,  the 
inverse  death-rate  as  we  may  call  it.  But  when 
population  increases  these  identities  are  broken 
up.  The  inverse  death-rate  becomes  a  little 
greater,  the  mean  age  at  death  becomes  much 
less  than  in  a  stationary  population.  Thus  the 
mean  expectation  of  life  being,  in  Dr.  Farr's 
time,  41  for  England  and  Wales,  the  inverse 
death-rate  was  1  in  43  ;  the  mean  age  at  death 
about  29.  The  neglect  of  these  distinctions 
has  proved  fatal  to  the  work  of  amateurs  who 
have  attempted  to  use  measures  of  mortality 
more  delicate  than  the  common  death-rate  "at 
all  ages."  The  indications  given  by  this  last 
are  less  fallacious,  as  has  been  shown  above 


(under  the  heading  of  age  and  sex),  than  might 
have  been  supposed.  Yet  it  is  desirable  to 
supplement  if  possible  this  rough  measure  by 
arranging  our  observations  in  the  form  of  a 
Life- Table. 

[The  authorities  on  this  subject  are  almost  as 
numerous  as  the  writers  on  statistics.  As  a  lucid 
statement  of  the  principal  facts  for  the  leading 
nations  of  the  world  the  Confronti  Internazionali 
per  gli  anni  1865-83,  issued  by  the  Ministero  di 
Agricultura,  Industria,  e  Commercio,  Rome,  may 
be  specially  mentioned.  Works  which  instruc- 
tively place  a  number  of  facts  in  the  light  of 
theory  are  : — Quetelet's  Physique  Sociale. — Wap- 
paeus,  Bevulkerungs  Statistik. — Mayr's  Gesetzmas- 
sigkeit  in  Gesellschaftsleben. — Haushofer's  Lehr- 
und  Handbv/ih  der  Statistik. — Westergaard's 
Theorie  der  Statistik,  and  other  books  cited  in  the 
text.  For  some  of  the  finer  logical  points  which 
have  been  touched,  Dr.  Farr's  Vital  Statistics, 
edited  by  Mr.  Noel  Humphreys,  should  be  studied ; 
and  Mr.  Humphreys'  own  papers  in  the  Journal 
of  the  Statistical  Society  for  1874, 1883,  and  1887.] 

F.  Y.  E. 

DEBASEMENT  OF  COIN,  History  of 
THE.  Coins  may  be  debased  in  three  ways — 
(1)  a  debasement  in  total  weight ;  (2)  a  debase- 
ment in  fineness  ;  (3)  a  debasement  by  increas- 
ing the  rating  or  nominal  value,  the  coins 
continuing  at  the  same  standard  weight  and 
fineness.  The  effect  of  the  last  may  also  be 
brought  about  unintentionally  by  a  fall  in  the 
value  of  the  precious  metals,  and  herein  lies 
the  secret  of  much  of  the  debasement  of  the 
middle  ages. 

The  first  historically  recorded  debasement  is 
that  effected  at  Athens  by  Solon  (b.c.  594)  to 
redeem  the  poorer  citizens  from  debt.  By  his 
advice  the  weight  of  metal  in  the  silver  drachma 
or  standard  Athenian  coin  was  reduced  more 
than  25  per  cent,  thus  enabling  100  drachmae 
to  be  coined  out  of  the  mina  or  unit  of  weight 
instead  of  only  73  as  previously  (Plutarch, 
Solon,  c.  15).  Creditors  were  compelled  to 
take  these  light  coins  as  full  payment,  and 
were  thus  obviously  defrauded  ;  but  perhaps 
in  this  case  the  end  may  have  justified  the 
means  (Grote,  Hist,  of  Greece,  pt.  ii.  ch.  xi.  ; 
Boeckh,  Metrologie,  ch.  ix.)  It  must  be  ad- 
mitted too  that,  as  a  rule,  the  Greek  states 
were  not  often  to  blame  in  this  respect,  partly 
perhaps  because  their  philosophers  inculcated 
sound  principles  (Lenormant,  Gontemp.  Hev. 
Feb.  1879),  but  more  probably  owing  to  their 
small  size.  This  naturally  caused  a  large  pro- 
portion of  their  money  transactions  to  be  inter- 
national, and  in  foreign  trade  coins  can  onlj 
be  exchanged  for  their  value  as  bullion  whatever 
their  rating  as  legal  tender  within  the  issuing 
state  ;  debasements  therefore  would  be  avoided 
for  mere  convenience  where  the  foreign  trade 
was  of  primary  importance. 

In  the  large  and  constantly  growing  Roman 
state  no  considerations  of  this  sort  existed,  nor, 


DEBASEMENT  OF  COIN 


499 


as  far  as  we  know,  was  the  subject  of  money  at 
all  adequately  studied  ;  on  the  contrary,  a  con- 
tinuous series  of  debasements  lends  colour  to 
the  opposite  view.  The  history  of  these  is  pro- 
fessedly given  by  Pliny  (xxxiii.  13),  but  the 
evidence  of  actual  coins  that  have  been  dis- 
covered makes  it  probable  that  his  account  is 
incomplete.  According  to  his  view  the  Roman 
coinage,  wliich  originally  had  the  "as"  or  pound 
of  copper  for  the  unit  of  value,  remained  un- 
changed till  the  First  Punic  War.  The  coined 
"as"  was  then  reduced  suddenly  to  2  uncice  or 
ounces,  that  is,  to  ^th  of  its  former  weight. 
About  this  time  10  asses  made  a  denarius  and  22- 
a  sestertius  ;  but  during  the  Second  Punic  War 
the  unit  was  further  reduced  50  per  cent,  and 
asses  were  coined  weighing  only  1  oz.,  16  of 
which  made  a  denarius  and  4  a  sestertius. 
Finally,  by  the  Papirian  law,  B.C.  191,  the 
"as"  was  made  to  weigh  only  ^  oz.,  but  it  is 
hardly  necessary  to  regard  this  as  a  debasement 
of  the  standard,  for  by  this  time  silver  was 
also  largely  current.  The  silver,  however,  was 
in  its  turn  debased,  and  the  denarius,  which 
had  weighed  jK^d  of  a  lb.,  was  reduced  to  ^th. 
In  B.C.  91  a  plated  coinage  was  issued,  but  was 
soon  withdrawn.  The  denarius,  however,  con- 
tinued to  fall,  and  under  Nero  weighed  only 
^ig^th  of  the  lb.  In  the  same  reign  the  gold 
aurei,  which  had  originally  been  coined  at  40 
to  the  pound,  had  become  debased  12  per  cent. 
Under  Alexander  Severus  these  coins  got  the 
name  of  solidus,  corrupted  afterwards  into  the 
French  "sou."  Constantine  fixed  them  at  72 
to  the  pound,  but  the  mere  name  gives  a 
measure  of  their  subsequent  debasement  in  the 
West.  In  the  Byzantine  empire,  on  the  con- 
trary, this  standard  was  long  preserved,  and 
seems  to  have  still  existed  in  1204  when  the 
Crusaders  captured  Constantinople. 

In  the  dark  ages  gold  again  fell  into  disuse, 
and  endless  variations  took  place  in  the  silver 
standards  set  up  by  the  numerous  barbarian 
rulers.  The  first  monarch  with  the  power  and 
the  will  to  alter  this  was  Charlemagne.  He 
introduced  a  silver  solidus  -^^th  of  a  lb.  in 
weight  and  divided  into  12  denarii,  but  his 
death  in  814  cut  short  the  attempt  to  get  it 
uniformly  adopted  throughout  his  empire.  Its 
use,  however,  gradually  spread,  and  ia  England, 
since  the  conquest,  has  formed  the  basis  of  our 
monetary  system.  Charlemagne's  liber,  solidus, 
and  denarius  are  the  origin  of  the  £  s.  d.  we 
still  use,  and  WiUiam  the  Conqueror's  only 
coin,  the  silver  penny,  really  did  weigh  -g-^Tj-^ii 
of  the  lb.  This,  the  so-called  Tower  pound,  was 
I  oz.  lighter  than  the  Frank  pound,  but  the 
English  standard  of  fineness  (11  oz.  2  dwt.  of 
pure  silver  to  18  dwt.  of  alloy)  was  very  high. 

The  history  of  the  English  debasements  does 
not  begin  till  1300,  when  Edward  I.  reduced 
the  weight  by  cutting  the  pound  into  243 
pence.     This  bad  example  was  soon  followed  ; 


by  1344  the  number  had  increased  to  266,  and 
in  1352  it  rose  to  300.  Early  in  the  next  cen 
tury  the  pound  weight  of  silver  was  valued  at 
£1^  or  360  pence,  which  by  the  reign  of 
Edward  IV.  became  450.  In  1526  Henry 
VIII.  abolished  the  Tower  pound  as  the  unit 
of  weight  and  substituted  the  French  pound 
troy,  weighing  |  oz.  more  ;  he,  however,  con- 
tinued to  reduce  the  weight  of  the  penny,  540 
being  coined  out  of  the  new  pound,  equivalent 
to  506|-  out  of  the  old.  Further,  he  was  the 
first  king  to  tamper  with  the  fineness.  This 
began  in  1543,  when  he  increased  the  amount 
of  alloy  in  the  pound  from  18  dwt.  to  2  oz,, 
following  this  up  by  an  issue  of  coins  in  1545 
containing  50  per  cent  of  alloy.  Under 
Edward  VI.  the  money  became  still  worse,  and 
in  1550  the  greatest  amount  of  debasement 
ever  known  in  England  was  attained,  when  a 
pound  of  metal  containing  no  more  than  3  oz. 
of  pure  silver  was  coined  into  as  many  as  864 
pence.  This  lasted  only  two  years.  In  1552 
an  improvement  began,  which,  though  not 
completed  till  the  great  recoinage  by  Elizabeth 
in  1560  (Froude,  Hist,  of  Eng.,  vol.  vii.  ch.  vi.), 
in  the  end  reduced  the  number  of  pence  cut  from 
the  pound  to  720,  and  restored  the  standard 
English  coins  to  their  old  degree  of  fineness. 
The  latter  has  been  maintained  ever  since,  but  it 
was  not  till  1600  that  the  weight  was  definitely 
settled.  Silver  was  then  coined  at  744  pence 
to  the  pound,  and  this  continued  in  spite  of  some 
famous  proposals  for  debasement  (Macaulay, 
Hist,  of  Eng.,  ch.  xxi.)  so  long  as  silver  re- 
mained the  standard.  Ever  since  the  14th  cen- 
tury gold  has  been  coined  in  England,  but  for 
the  greater  part  of  the  time  only  as  a  subsidiary 
coinage.  It  is  consequently  unnecessary  to 
discuss  the  numerous  debasements  and  changes 
of  rating  to  which  the  earlier  coins  were  sub- 
jected in  the  endeavour,  usually  a  fruitless  one, 
to  preserve  a  proper  proportion  between  the  two 
precious  metals.  England,  however,  by  the  end 
of  the  17th  century  had  become  so  rich,  and 
gold  so  much  used,  that  it  gi-adually  assumed 
the  superior  position.  In  1717  a  recoinage  took 
place  in  which  the  change  was  legally  recog- 
nised, and  ever  since  our  standard  coinage  has 
been  gold.  When,  therefore,  in  1816,  the  silver 
puund  was  ordered  to  be  cut  in  792  pence,  no 
debasement,  properly  speaking,  occurred,  as  the 
object  was  to  make  the  coins  tokens.  Since 
gold  has  been  the  standard,  there  has  been  no 
intentional  debasement,  but  a  gi-eat  recoinage 
was  necessitated  in  1774.  The  present  money 
system  is  regulated  by  the  Coinage  Act  1870, 
33  &  34  Vict.  c.  10. 

In  Scotland  the  system  of  coinage  was  orig- 
inally borrowed  from  that  of  England,  and 
the  two  remained  identical  as  late  as  1355,  in 
which  year  Edward  III.  intentionally  debased 
the  English  silver  in  imitation  of  David  II. 
Subsequently,  however,  the  Scotch  kings,  under 


500 


DEBASEMENT  OF  COIN 


the  influence  of  French  ideas,  so  multiplied 
their  debasements  that  they  left  the  English 
far  behind.  By  1 3  9  0  English  money  was  worth 
twice  as  much  Scotch,  and  the  latter  eventually 
ceased  to  be  current  by  tale  in  England.  .  In 
1600  £36  Scotch  were  coined  from  the  pound 
of  silver  as  compared  with  62s.  English.  The 
greatest  debasement  in  fineness  occurred  be- 
tween 1576  and  1579,  but  the  amount  of  alloy 
in  the  pound  never  rose  above  4  oz.  The  two 
coinages  were  again  assimilated  at  the  union  in 
1707. 

In  Ireland  regular  coinages  were  first  intro- 
duced by  John  in  1177,  and  regular  debasements 
by  Edward  III.  By  1465  the  Irish  shilling 
was  worth  only  9d.  English.  Three  years  later 
960  pence  were  coined  from  the  pound  and  a 
reaction  set  in,  but  in  1520  the  coius  were 
again  so  bad  that  payment  by  weight  became 
general.  As  in  England  Henry  VIII.  debased 
the  fineness,  and  even  Elizabeth  transferred 
Edward  VI. 's  worst  debasements  to  Ireland 
when  she  restored  the  English  coinage  ;  James 
I.  attempted  to  restore  the  old  Irish  fineness 
(9  oz.  silver  to  3  oz.  alloy)  and  decried  Eliza- 
beth's shillings  to  2d,,  but  the  bad  money 
drove  out  the  good.  Complaints  of  scarcity 
became  constant,  and  in  1651  aU  sorts  of  tokens 
and  foreign  coins  were  in  circulation.  In  1689 
James  II.  raised  the  rating  of  all  coins  8^  per 
cent,  as  a  war  measure  against  William  III., 
and  this  remained  permanently  in  force  till 
1825.  It,  however,  failed  to  bring  in  the 
necessary  funds,  and  in  1690  he  issued  a  coin- 
age of  old  guns,  broken  bells,  nails  and  pewter 
pots.  In  the  next  century  there  was  little 
improvement,  but  much  dissatisfaction ;  the 
case  of  Wood's  copper  coinage  is  the  most 
famous.  In  1804  twenty-one  shillings  of  the 
best  Irish  silver  were  not  worth  nine  English  ; 
in  fact,  the  debasements  only  terminated  when 
the  Irish  and  English  coinages  were  assimilated 
in  1825.  On  the  continent  France  may  be 
taken  as  the  typical  country,  and  there  the 
debasements  were  far  worse  than  in  England, 
as  no  central  power  was  for  a  long  time 
developed.  In  1315  thirty-one  barons  claimed 
the  right  of  coinage  besides  the  king,  and 
mutual  rates  of  exchange  were  arranged  for 
their  coins.  Dante  has  (Par.  xix.)  singled  out 
Philip  le  Bel  as  the  typical  false  moneyer, 
but  many  other  sovereigns  were  quite  as  bad. 
The  standard  which  the  people  always  claimed 
was  that  of  St.  Louis,  who  in  1226  cut  the 
marc  of  8  oz.  into  58  solidi  or  sous,  but  un- 
fortunately this  was  afterwards  very  rarely 
attained.  During  the  long  wars  with  England 
the  country  practically  became  bankrupt,  and 
the  kings  dealt  recklessly  with  the  coinage. 
In  1360,  when  John  was  captive,  the  silver 
marc  was  once  rated  at  240  sous,  but  this  was 
only  a  temporary  measure,  and  before  the  end 
of  the  year  the  marc  had  again  fallen  to  100 


sous.  In  1454,  when  the  English  were  finally; 
expelled,  the  marc  was  coined  into  175  sous, 
but  quieter  times  only  brought  more  regular 
debasements.  In  1575  the  sou  had  become  so 
small  that  silver  livres,  worth  20  sous  each,  took 
their  place  as  the  ordinary  money  of  account. 
17j  of  these,  equivalent  to  345  sous,  were 
coined  from  the  marc.  They  soon,  however, 
sank  in  value,  each  Bourbon  king  in  succession 
reducing  the  weight  till  1789,  when  as  many 
as  52  were  coined  from  the  marc.  In  other 
words  a  livre  of  this  date  weighed  only  ^^  of 
the  liber  of  Charlemagne  though  bearing  the 
same  name.  During  the  Revolution  even  the 
name  was  discarded  and  the  synonym  "franc" 
substituted.  In  all  other  countries  the  history 
has  been  the  same.  In  modem  Germany  the 
mark  is  only  worth  a  shilling.  In  Spain  the 
maravedi,  originally  a  gold  coin  worth  14 
shillings,  is  now  a  small  copper  coin  not  worth 
a  farthing.  In  Portugal  the  reis,  too  small  at 
last  for  use,  are  calculated  in  hundreds.  No 
country,  however,  has  been  worse  than  France. 

[A  fairly  full  general  outline  of  the  debasements  in 
classical  British  and  French  coins  maybe  found  in 
Macleod's  Diet,  of  Pol.  Econ.,  vol.  i.,  "Coinage." 
For  France  the  standard  book  is  Le  Blanc's  TraiU 
Historique  des  Monnoyes  de  France  ;  for  England 
Lord  Liverpool's  Coins  of  the  Realm. — Conigliani, 
Note  historichi  sulla  Questione  giuridica  dei  paga- 
menti  monetarii  (1891). — Galiani,  Delia  Moneteb^ 
bk.  ii.  vi.  iii.  ii. — Adam  Smith,  Wealth  of  Nations^ 
i.  xi. — Del  Mar,  Money  in  Ancient  Countries 
(1885).]  w.  J.  c. 

Debasement  of  coin  "in  its  proper  sense 
means  a  reduction  of  fineness,"  according  to 
an  authority  quoted  by  Prof.  Walker  {Money, 
p.  187).  In  a  wider  sense  the  term  denotes 
also,  the  reduction  of  the  quantity  of  pure  metal 
in  the  coin  by  diminishing  its  weight  whUe 
preserving  its  customary  fineness  ;  whether  that 
diminution  is  effected  at  the  mint,  or  after 
mintage  by  abrasion,  clipping,  or  sweatiag. 
For  example,  Henry  VIII.  practised  debasement 
proper  when,  by  introducing  an  increased  pro- 
portion of  alloy,  he  lowered  the  fineness  of  silver 
to  nearly  a  third  of  what  it  had  long  been 
before  he  began  tampering  with  it.  Debasement 
in  the  wider  sense  was  committed  by  Edward 
VI.  when  he  "not  only  continued  the  issue  of 
base  money  commenced  by  Henry,  but  lowered 
the  quantity  of  mixed  metal"  in  each  coin 
(Rogers's  History  of  Agriculture  and  Prices,  vol. 
iv.  p.  734).  (See  Alloy.)  Another  example 
of  the  less  specific  sense  is  afforded  by  the 
"debased  state  of  the  currency,"  "previous  to 
the  recoinage  of  1696,"  to  use  Ricardo's  words 
{Reply  to  Bosanquet,  p.  96).  Elsewhere 
Ricardo  speaks  of  the  metallic  cun-ency  being 
"debased  by  wearing  or  clipping."  {High 
Price  of  Bullion,  p.  26).  The  term  is  to  be 
taken  in  its  wider  sense  in  Ricardo's  important 
proposition  :   ' '  However  debased  a  coinage  may 


DEBENTUEE 


501 


become,  it  will  preserve  its  mint  value,  that  is 
to  say  it  \\ill  pass  in  circulation  for  the  intrinsic 
value  of  the  bullion  which  it  ought  to  contain, 
provided  it  be  not  in  too  great  abundance " ; 
and  provided  that,  as  Prof.  Walker  adds,  it  is 
not  discredited  (Ricardo,  Political  Economy,  ch. 
xxvii.  ;  Reply  to  Bosanquet,  ch.  vi.  ;  AValker, 
Money,  p.  199).  The  first  of  these  conditions 
is  not  likely  to  be  fulfilled  in  the  case  of  de- 
basement proper.  Governments  which  debase 
are  likely  to  over-issue.  Striking  instances  of 
this  abuse  are  given  by  Rogers  in  his  Historical 
Gleanings  (i.  pp.  95-97  quoted  by  Prof.  Walker, 
loc.  cit.)  F.  Y.  E. 

DEBENTURE.  The  word  "debenture" 
has  been  judicially  defined  as  "a  document 
which  either  creates  a  debt  or  acknowledges 
it "  (Justice  Chitty  in  Levy  v.  Abercorris  Slate 
and  Slab  Company,  37  Chancery  Division,  on 
p.  264)  ;  every  document  which  answers  that 
description  is  a  debenture,  and  the  use  of  the 
word  in  itself  confers  no  rights  whatever  on  the 
holder.  It  is  very  important  that  this  should 
be  generally  understood,  as  there  is  a  vague 
belief  in  the  minds  of  many  persons  that  a 
debenture  must  always  be  secured  by  a  charge 
on  some  property,  or  at  least  entitle  the  holder 
to  priority  over  other  creditors.  There  are 
certain  classes  of  debentures,  issued  by  virtue  of 
certain  acts  of  parliament,  which  confer  special 
privileges  on  the  holders  (as,  for  instance,  the 
mortgage  debentures  issued  under  the  Land 
Debentures  Acts  of  1865  and  1870,  as  to  which 
see  Mortgage  Banks,  or  the  debentures  issued 
by  local  authorities  under  the  Local  Loans  Act, 
1875,  as  to  which  see  Loans,  Local)  ;  but, 
speaking  generally,  the  rights  of  the  holders  of 
any  particular  issue  of  debentures  must  be 
ascertained  from  the  instrument  or  trust-deed 
or  other  document  referred  to  in  the  same. 
Debentures  issued  by  foreign  or  colonial  govern- 
ments or  municipalities,  as  a  general  rule,  do 
not  confer  any  special  privileges  on  the  holders  ; 
they  are  simply  promises  to  pay  the  principal 
sum  on  a  given  date  and  interest  at  a  certain 
rate  in  the  meantime.  Debentures  of  companies 
registered  under  the  Companies  Acts,  on  the 
other  hand,  are  now  mostly  secured  by  a  mort- 
gage of  some  particular  property,  or  by  a  charge 
on  the  whole  undertaking.  The  latter  is  called 
a  "floating  charge"  and  does  not  prevent  the 
company  from  disposing  of  its  property  by  sale 
or  mortgage  in  the  ordinary  course  of  business, 
but  it  is  generally  provided  that  as  soon  as 
default  is  made  in  the  payment  of  interest  or 
principal,  or  as  soon  as  the  winding-up  of  the 
company  is  ordered  or  resolved  upon,  the  de- 
benture holders  may  enforce  their  secm"ity, 
which  thus  attaches  to  the  whole  of  the  com- 
pany's property  existing  at  that  moment,  but 
subject  to  any  mortgages  or  charges  created  for 
the  purposes  of  the  company's  business  while  it 
was  a  going  concern.     If  any  property  is  to 


serve  as  a  secm-ity  for  debentures  in  a  way  which 
makes  it  impossible  for  the  company  to  alienate 
it  at  any  time,  there  must  be  a  regular  mortgage 
of  such  property  to  trustees  acting  for  the 
debentm-e  holders  by  a  separate  trust-deed.  A 
trust-deed  by  which  movable  goods  are  mort- 
gaged must  be  registered  as  a  bill  of  sale,  but 
a  debenture  issued  by  an  incorporated  company 
which  contains  a  charge  on  such  goods  need  not 
be  so  registered  (see  Bill  of  Sale).  Deben- 
tures containing  a  charge  or  mortgage  are  some- 
times called  mortgage  debentures. 

It  should  be  pointed  out  that  the  law  of  most 
foreign  countries  does  not  recognise  mortgages 
of  immovable  property  unless  they  be  registered 
according  to  the  law  of  the  place,  and  also  that 
according  to  most  systems  of  foreign  law,  mov- 
able property  cannot  be  charged  in  favour  of  a 
creditor  Avhile  remaining  in  the  debtor's  posses- 
sion. Holders  of  debentures  secured  by  foreign 
property  should  remember  these  facts  and  not 
be  surprised  if,  in  trying  to  realise  their  security 
abroad,  they  find  themselves  in  conflict  with 
foreign  mortgagees  or  judgment  creditors  or  a 
foreign  trustee  in  bankruptcy ;  and  when 
trustees  are  acting  for  the  debenture  holders, 
they  should  be  careful  to  perfect  their  security 
as  much  as  possible,  by  complying  with  the 
formalities  required  by  the  law  of  the  place 
where  the  property  is  situate. 

The  special  acts  of  British  railway  companies 
generally  incorporate  the  provisions  of  the  Com- 
panies Clauses  Act,  1845,  with  respect  to  tlie 
issue  of  debentures  (§§  38-55),  but  these  pro- 
visions leave  a  wide  margin  as  to  the  rights  of 
debenture  holders,  which  mainly  depend  on  tlie 
special  act,  authorising  a  particular  issue,  or  on 
the  conditions  attached  to  it  by  the  company. 

A  debenture  must  always  be  repayable  at 
some  time  ;  a  fixed  date  may  be  appointed  for 
that  purpose,  or  the  gradual  repayment  of  the 
debentures  of  a  particular  issue  by  yearly  draw- 
ings, or  in  a  certain  order  of  succession,  may 
be  provided  for.  In  many  cases  the  company 
or  corporation  issuing  debentures  reserves  the 
right  of  redeeming  the  same  before  the  date 
fixed  for  repayment,  either  on  the  happening 
of  a  given  event  (e.g.  the  sale  of  the  property) 
or  entirely  at  the  borrower's  option.  There  are 
also  so-called  "perpetual  debentures,"  Avhich 
are  usually  made  payable  only  in  the  event  of 
winding-up  or  default  on  the  part  of  the 
borrower  in  the  paying  the  interest. 

Debentures  may  be  issued  to  bearer  or  to  the 
registered  holder,  or  they  may  be  transferable 
by  indorsement.  Debentures  to  bearer  pi'ima 
facie  are  not  "negotiable  instruments"  (see 
Commercial  Instrument).  The  question  in 
each  case  turns  upon  the  conditions  of  the  par- 
ticular issue  and  on  the  usage  of  the  stock 
exchange. 

As  debentures  to  bearer  are  now  subject  to  a 
stamp  duty  of  20s.  per  £100,  which  must  b« 


502 


DEBENTURE  STOCK 


paid  by  the  borrower,  whilst  the  stamp  duty 
payable  on  the  transfer  of  a  registered  debenture 
is  payable  by  the  transferor,  companies  have  of 
late  years  preferred  to  issue  registered  deben- 
tures. 

[As  to  debentures  issued  by  companies  under 
the  Companies  Acts,  see  Lindley  on  Company 
Law. — Palmer,  Company  Precedents. — Buckley  on 
the  Companies  Acts.  As  to  debentures  issued  by 
railway  companies,  see  Hodges  on  Railways. — 
Brown  and  Theobald  on  Railway  Companies. 
As  to  the  negotiability  of  debentures,  see  also 
Chalmers,  Bills  of  Exchange,  4th  ed.  p.  319.] 

B.  s. 

DEBENTURE  STOCK.  No  general  defini- 
tion can  be  given  of  this  term,  as  a  distinction 
must  be  drawn  between  two  different  kinds  of 
debenture  stock. 

(a)  Debenture  stock  issued  by  companies 
incorporated  under  the  Companies  Acts  differs 
from  debentures  in  form  but  not  in  substance. 
A  debenture  is  an  instrument  embodying  the 
contract  between  the  company  and  the  holder, 
and  generally  creating  a  charge  on  property. 
"Debenture  stock,"  on  the  other  hand,  is  only 
a  name  for  the  debt  which  it  represents,  which 
debt  is  created  and  secured  by  a  trust  deed 
between  the  company  and  the  persons  who  act 
as  trustees  for  the  holders  of  debenture  stock. 
By  the  effect  of  this  deed  the  holders  of  deben- 
ture stock  are,  as  a  rule,  placed  in  the  same 
position  as  the  holders  of  debentures  secured  in 
the  usual  form,  and  in  cases  where  a  general 
charge  is  to  be  given,  it  is  usual  for  companies 
to  issue  debentures  for  the  amount  of  the 
debenture  stock  to  be  held  by  the  trustees  as  a 
collateral  security  for  the  payment  of  the 
debenture  stock  and  the  interest  thereon. 

Debenture  stock  of  this  kind  usually  takes 
the  form  of  so-called  "perpetual  debenture 
stock,"  that  is  to  say,  the  holders  are  not 
entitled  to  claim  repayment  of  ,the  principal 
sum  until  the  winding-up  of  the  company,  or 
until  default  has  been  made  in  the  payment  of 
the  interest ;  but  it  also  frequently  happens 
that  a  date  is  fixed  for  repayment ;  any  of  the 
ways  in  which  redemption  or  repayment  may 
be  provided  for  in  the  case  of  a  Debenture 
{q.v.)  is  also  permissible  in  the  case  of  deben- 
ture stock. 

Each  individual  holder  of  debenture  stock 
receives  a  certificate  stating  that  he  is  the 
holder  of  a  certain  amount  of  stock,  and  that 
the  redemption  of  the  said  stock  and  the  pay- 
ment of  the  interest  thereon  is  secured  by  a 
deed  dated  from  a  certain  date,  and  made 
between  certain  parties.  Stock  certificates  may 
be  issued  to  bearer,  but  this  is  of  rare  occur- 
rence, the  rule  being  that  the  names  of  the 
stockholders  are  registered.  In  such  a  case  it 
may  be  provided  that  any  portion  of  the  stock 
may  be  transferred,  or  fractions  of  one  pound 
may  be  excluded,  or  it  may  be  stipulated  that 


all  sums  transferred  must  be  multiples  of  £5 
or  of  £10,  or  of  any  other  sum.  The  possibil- 
ity of  transferring  any  portions  of  the  stock  is 
one  of  the  advantages  of  debenture  stock  as 
compared  with  debentures,  and  probably  one 
of  the  principal  reasons  why  the  issue  of 
debenture  stock  by  companies  has  become  so 
popular  within  the  last  few  years.  Debenture 
stock  certificates  to  bearer  are  subject  to  an  ad 
valorem  stamp  duty  payable  by  the  company. 
See  the  books  on  companies  quoted  s.v.  De- 
benture. 

(&)  Debenture  stock  issued  by  a  British 
railway  company  or  other  company  obtaining 
a  special  act  incorporating  the  Companies 
Clauses  Act,  1863,  is  with  the  interest  thereon 
a  charge  on  the  undertaking  of  the  company, 
and  the  interest  of  such  debenture  stock  has 
priority  over  the  dividends  or  interest  on  any 
ordinary  shares  or  stocks.  If  any  interest 
remains  unpaid  for  thirty  days  after  the  date 
on  which  it  is  payable,  stockholders  whose 
total  holding  amounts  to  a  certain  sum,  may 
obtain  the  appointment  in  England  or  Ireland 
of  a  receiver,  and  in  Scotland  of  a  judicial  factor, 
and  any  stockholder  may  also  recover  the 
arrears  by  action  against  the  company.  The 
stockholders  are  not  under  any  circumstances 
entitled  to  claim  repayment  of  the  principal 
sum  paid  up  in  respect  of  the  debenture  stock, 
and  they  cannot,  under  any  circumstances, 
become  entitled  to  the  possession  of  any  part 
of  the  property  of  the  company.  On  the  other 
hand  it  is  not  in  the  power  of  the  company  to 
redeem  the  stock,  unless  they  obtain  a  special 
act  of  parliament  for  that  purpose. 

It  has  been  said  that  "debenture  stock  of 
this  kind  is  nothing  but  preference  stock  with 
a  special  preference"  (Court  of  Appeal  in 
Attree  v.  Hawe,  9  Chancery  Division,  on  p. 
349),  but  this  statement  was  made  with  refer- 
ence to  a  special  point,  and  was  not  intended 
to  convey  the  meaning  that  there  is  no  essential 
difference  between  debenture  stock  and  prefer- 
ence stock.  This  has  been  pointed  out  by  Mr. 
Justice  Chitty  {in  re  Bodman,  Law  Reports 
(1891),  3  Chancery,  on  p.  138);  he  says: 
"the  holder  of  debenture  stock  is  a  creditor 
of  the  company  with  a  security  in  the  assets 
of  the  company  .  .  .  debenture  stock  is  bor- 
rowed money  capitalised  for  purposes  of  con- 
venience." The  fact  that  debenture  stock 
issued  by  a  British  railway  company,  or  other 
similar  company,  is  never  repayable,  while  the 
debenture  stock  of  a  company  incorporated 
under  the  Companies  Acts  must  always  be 
repayable,  though  not  necessarily  on  a  fixed 
date,  constitutes  a  material  difference.  Stock 
of  the  first  kind  is  in  the  nature  of  a  perpetual 
annuity,  whereas  stock  of  the  second  kind  is  a 
debt  secured  in  the  same  way  as  a  debt  for 
which  debentures  are  issued. 

The   holders   of  British   railway  debenture 


DEBIT— DEBT 


503 


stock  receive  certificates  registered  in  their 
respective  names,  and  transfers  are  made  in 
the  same  way  as  the  transfer  of  ordinary  rail- 
way stock.  See  the  books  on  railway  companies 
quoted,  s.v.  Debenture,  also  Lindley  on  Com- 
pany Taio.  E.  s, 

DEBIT.  That  side  of  an  account  on  which 
everything  in  the  nature  of  a  debt  is  entered. 
The  word  is  also  used  to  denote  the  entries 
so  made,  i.e.  a  debt.  J.  e.  c.  m. 

DEBITUM  FUNDI  (Scot.)  "A  debt  owed 
by  the  land  itself,"  in  whosesoever  hands  it 
may  be  ;  a  real  burden  or  lien  preferable  to  all 
rights  of  the  proprietor,  and  enforceable  not 
only  against  the  vassal  himself,  but  also  by  a 
"real  action"  against  the  lands  themselves. 
By  law  the  feu-duties  and  some  other  feudal 
duties  due  to  the  superior,  are  in  this  category ; 
and  by  agreement,  "annual  rents,"  debts 
secured  on  land,  reserved  burdens,  and  the  like 
may  be  made  debita  fundi,  and  may  by  regis- 
tration secure  a  preference  postponed  to  the 
superior's  rights  (see  Poinding  of  the  Ground). 

A,  D. 

DfiBOUCHl^S,  Thi5orie  des,  generally  re- 
garded as  the  main  original  contribution  of 
J.  B.  Say  to  economic  science.  This  theory  of 
outlets  or  of  vent  affirms  that  a  general  glut  or 
general  over-production  is  impossible.  If  all 
products  could  be  had  for  nothing,  men  would 
everywhere  spring  into  existence  to  consume 
them.  Products  are  bought  with  other  pro- 
ducts. Therefore  each  product  is  more  in 
demand  as  other  products  increase  and  bid 
against  it.  In  other  words,  as  the  same  pro- 
duct constitutes  the  producer's  demand  and  the 
consumer's  supply,  a  general  excess  of  supply 
over  the  general  demand  is  absurd.  Moreover, 
human  desires  expand  indefinitely.  So  long  as 
these  are  unsatisfied  there  can  be  no  over-pro- 
duction except  from  lack  of  purchasing  power 
arising  from  under-production  on  the  part  of 
the  would-be  purchasers. 

Hence  it  is  concluded  that  to  maximise  pro- 
duction is  the  interest  of  all ;  that  industry  is 
solidaire  ;  and  that  cosmopolitanism  in  com- 
merce is  true  wisdom,  imports  stimulating  the 
sale  of  indigenous  products.  This  theory,  Say 
predicted,  "wiU  change  the  politics  of  the 
world"  {Traitd,  5th  ed.  1826,  I.  ciii.) 

The  theory  was  resisted  by  Malthus  and 
SiSMONDi  {q.v.),  but  was  supported  by  James 
Mill  and  Ricardo,  whose  friendship  grew  out  of 
this  agreement,  as  we  learn  from  J.  S.  Mill 
{Principles,  1875  ed.,  III.  xiv.)  The  last- 
mentioned  writer's  examination  of  the  theory, 
though  enforcing  the  strength  of  the  main  posi- 
tion, leaves  still  something  to  be  desired. 
Arguments  are  used  which  take  no  account  of  i 
the  relativity  of  demand  to  price,  the  imperfec- 
tion of  the  world  market,  or  the  element  of 
time  necessary  to  create  new  habits  of  produc- 
tion  or  consumption   or  to  raise   up   a   new 


generation  of  consumers.  The  case  is,  however, 
conclusive  against  those  whose  view  involves 
the  fallacy  of  a  general  fall  of  values,  or  who 
mistake  the  phenomenon  of  a  commercial  crisis, 
in  times  of  contracting  credit,  for  over-pro- 
duction. The  remedy,  says  J.  S.  Mill,  for 
"what  may  be  indiscriminately  called  a  glut 
of  commodities  or  a  dearth  of  money,  is  not  a 
diminution  of  supply,  but  the  restoration  of 
confidence." 

[For  modern  opposition  to  Say's  theory,  see 
Uriel  H.  Crocker,  Excessive  Saving,  Boston, 
U.S.A.,  1884,  and  in  Harvard  Quarterly  Journal 
of  Economics,  April  1887  and  April  1892.— Ed- 
ward F.  Sweet,  "  Over-Production,"  Chicago  Times, 
26th  April  1880. — Mummery  and  Hobson,  Physi- 
ology of  Industry,  1889. — See  also  Report  of  tlie 
Royal  Commission  on  the  Depression  of  Trade  and 
Industry,  1885,  and  for  alterations  in  price  and 
standard  of  value,  Appendix  B,  by  R.  H.  Inglis 
Palgrave.]  H.  H. 

DE  BROUCKERE,  Charles,  born  at 
Bruges  in  1796,  died  at  Brussels  in  1860.  One 
of  the  most  eminent  and  honest  of  Belgian 
politicians.  He  served  from  1815  to  1820  with 
the  army  of  the  Low  Countries,  and  after  this 
engaged  in  the  business  of  banking.  He  then 
commenced  his  political  career  as  a  deputy  in 
the  second  oliamber  of  the  states  -  general,  in 
which  he  sat  among  the  opposition.  After  the 
Belgian  revolution  of  September  1830,  he  was 
appointed  a  member  of  the  national  congress, 
resisted  the  republican  party,  declared  himself 
in  favour  of  a  monarchy  and  of  the  exclusion 
of  the  family  of  Orange-Nassau  from  the  throne. 
In  conformity  with  these  views  he  voted  for  the 
Duke  of  Nemours,  in  opposition  to  the  Prince 
of  Saxe  -  Coburg ;  but  when  the  latter  was 
elected  king,  and  reigned  as  Leopold  I.,  he 
supported  him  warmly,  first  directing  the 
finances,  and  then  acting  as  minister  of  war. 
After  holding  other  offices,  he  returned,  for  a 
period  of  eight  years,  to  private  life,  engaged  in 
business,  was  appointed,  in  1847,  burgomaster 
of  the  city  of  Brussels,  which  office  is  considered 
equal  to  the  j)ositiou  of  a  minister  of  state.  He 
was  also  elected  a  member  of  the  chamber  of 
representatives,  and  held  both  these  posts  till 
his  death.  Besides  this  he  lectured  on  economic 
science,  on  which  his  views  were  so  liberal  that 
they  included  free  trade.  His  only  work  in 
economics  is  called  Principcs  g6n6raux  d'eco- 
nomie  politique,  1851,  1  vol.  in  18mo,  an  able 
though  a  short  production.  a.  c.  f. 


DEBT. 

Debt,  p.  503. 

Debt,  Imprisonment  for,  p.  504. 
Debtor  and  Creditor,  Law  of,  p.  505. 
Debtor's  Summons,  p.  500. 

Debt.  A  "debt"  may  be  defined  as  an  ob- 
ligation to  pay  a  sum  certain  in  money,  with  or 
without  interest.     But  it  is  to  be  noted  that, 


504 


DEBT— DEBT,  IMPRISONMENT  FOR 


by  English  law,  when  goods  are  sold,  or  work 
and  materials  are  supplied  without  any  stipula- 
tion as  to  price,  there  is  an  implied  obligation 
to  pay  a  reasonable  price  for  them.  If  the 
parties  differ,  the  amount  payable  can  onl^  be 
ascertained  by  litigation,  which  in  substance, 
though  not  in  form,  resembles  an  action  for 


Putting  aside  recognisances,  and  statutory 
penalties,  recoverable  by  civil  process,  debts 
may  be  divided  into  three  classes,  namely, 
judgment  debts,  specialty  debts,  and  simple 
contract  debts.  When,  by  the  judgment  of  a 
court  of  competent  jurisdiction,  a  person  is 
ordered  to  pay  money,  the  judgment  creditor 
may  usually  enforce  his  rights  either  by  the 
process  of  the  court  which  gave  the  judgment, 
or  by  bringing  an  action  on  the  judgment  as  if 
it  were  an  ordinary  debt. 

A  specialty  debt  is  a  debt  created  by  an 
instrument  under  seal.  Formerly  specialty 
debts  had  priority  over  simple  contract  debts, 
but  recent  legislation  has  now  practically  effaced 
this  distinction,  and  the  main  difference  between 
the  two  classes  of  debts  consist  in  this  ;  (a)  a 
specialty  debt  may  in  general  be  created  without 
consideration,  as  for  example  by  a  voluntary 
bond,  and  (&)  the  period  of  limitation  for  a 
specialty  debt  is  twenty  years,  while  in  the 
case  of  a  simple  contract  debt  it  is  six  years. 

Any  debt,  other  than  a  judgment  or  specialty 
debt,  whether  evidenced  by  writing  or  not,  is 
called  a  simple  contract  debt.  It  is  to  be  noted 
that  the  term  applies  not  only  to  obligations  to 
pay  arising  from  agreement  between  the  parties, 
but  to  cases  where  the  law  implies  such  an 
obligation  apart  from  agreement.  These  quasi- 
contracts,  as  they  are  sometimes  called,  fall 
chiefly  under  two  heads.  First,  when  a  person 
is  compelled  to  discharge  the  liabilities  of 
another,  he  becomes  the  creditor  of  that  other 
person  for  the  money  so  paid.  For  instance,  if 
one  of  two  sureties  pays  the  whole  debt  due 
from  the  principal  debtor,  he  can  recover  the 
proportionate  share  from  the  other  surety  as  a 
debt.  Secondly,  when  a  person  has  wrongfully 
received  money,  the  party  entitled  to  it  can 
generally  recover  it  as  a  debt.  For  instance,  if 
an  account  by  mistake  be  paid  twice  over,  the 
second  payment  can  be  recovered  as  a  debt  due 
from  the  person  who  received  it. 

As  a  general  rule  debts  do  not,  according  to 
English  law,  carry  interest.  The  obligation  to 
pay  interest  arises  only  (a)  by  agreement,  or  (&) 
by  mercantile  usage,  as  in  the  case  of  debts 
secured  by  bills  or  notes,  or  (c)  by  statute. 
Scotch  law  is  more  favourable  to  claims  for 
interest,  see  Interest  (see  also  Debtor  and 
Creditor,  Law  of  ;  Receipt).  m.  d,  c. 

Debt,  Imprisonment  for.  Most  civilised 
countries  have  now  got  rid  of  imprisonment  for 
debt.  It  was  abolished  in  France  in  1867,  in 
Belgium  in  1871,  in  Switzerland  and  Norway 


in  1874,  in  Italy  in  1877,  and  in  Scotland  in 
1880.  But  in  England  the  system  is  in  full 
force.  It  is  true  that  in  1869  a  statute  was 
passed  bearing  the  title  "An  Act  for  the  Aboli- 
tion of  Imprisonment  for  Debt,  for  the  Punish- 
ment of  Fraudulent  Debtors,  and  for  other 
purposes  "  (32  &  33  Vict.  c.  62),  but  it  appears 
from  the  county  court  returns  of  1889  that 
during  the  preceding  year  201,335  applica- 
tions were  made  to  commit  judgment  debtors 
to  prison,  54,995  warrants  of  committal  were 
issued,  and  6429  debtors  went  to  prison. 
The  fact  is  the  act  in  question  merely 
regulates  imprisonment  for  debt,  but  in  no 
wise  abolishes  it  (see  §  5).  Imprisonment  on 
mesne  process  has  been  abolished,  but  when  a 
suitor  has  recovered  judgment  for  debt,  damages, 
or  costs,  he  has  two  courses  open  to  him.  He 
may  proceed  either  against  the  property  or 
against  the  person  of  his  debtor.  If  he  elects 
to  proceed  against  his  person  he  takes  out  what 
is  called  a  "judgment-summons"  calling  on 
the  debtor  to  appear  before  the  court  on  a  day 
named,  to  be  examined  as  to  his  means,  and  to 
show  cause  why  he  should  not  be  committed  to 
prison  for  having  neglected  or  refused  to  pay 
the  sum  specified  in  the  judgment  or  order. 
The  summons  may  be  taken  out  in  the  county 
court,  whether  the  judgment  be  in  that  court 
or  the  high  court.  At  the  hearing,  if  the  creditor 
proves,  or  the  debtor  admits,  liiat  the  latter 
either  has  or  has  had  since  the  judgment  the 
means  of  satisfying  it,  the  court  may  order  him 
to  be  committed  to  gaol  for  a  period  not  exceed- 
ing six  weeks.  The  imprisonment  does  not 
operate  as  a  satisfaction  of  the  debt,  but  on  the 
other  hand  the  debtor  cannot  be  twice  im- 
prisoned for  the  same  sum  of  money.  The 
debtor  can  at  any  time  obtain  his  release  by 
paying  the  debt  and  costs.  While  in  prison 
the  debtor,  like  any  other  prisoner,  is  kept 
there  at  the  public  expense.  Execution  against 
the  person  therefore  differs  from  execution 
against  property,  for  in  the  latter  case  the 
creditor  has  to  pay  the  costs  of  the  execution  if 
they  cannot  be  recovered  from  the  property  of 
the  debtor.  When  a  judgment  is  ordered  to 
be  paid  by  instalments,  default  in  paying  any 
instalment  constitutes  a  ground  for  committal. 
Suppose  then  a  debt  of  £2  is  ordered  to  be  paid 
by  instalments  of  4s.  a  month,  a  common  order 
in  the  county  courts.  Theoretically  for  this 
debt  of  £2  the  debtor  might  be  committed  ten 
times  for  periods  of  six  weeks  each.  Practi- 
cally the  discretion  vested  in  the  court  would 
prevent  so  harsh  an  application  of  the  law.  It 
has  recently  been  held  that  a  married  woman 
cannot  be  committed  for  non-payment  of  a 
judgment  debt,  for  under  the  Married  Women's 
Property  Act,  1882,  the  contracts  of  a  married 
woman  do  not  bind  her  personally,  but  merely 
bind  her  available  separate  estate  if  any.  By 
one  of  the  eccentricities  of  modern  legislation  a 


DEBT,  IMPRISONMENT  FOR— DEBTOH  AND  CREDITOR,  LAW  OF     505 


married  woman,  who  has  a  husband  to  rely  on, 
is  thus  put  in  a  more  favourable  position  than  a 
single  woman  or  widow  who  has  no  one  to  help 
her.  From  the  figures  cited  above  it  appears 
that  not  more  than  3  per  cent  of  the  applica- 
tions to  commit  result  in  the  actual  imprison- 
ment of  the  debtor.  This  result  is  due  to  a 
peculiar  mode  of  administering  the  act  of  1869 
adopted  by  most  of  the  county  courts,  namely 
the  system  of  suspended  orders.  It  can  best 
be  illustrated  by  an  example.  Suppose  a  work- 
man whose  standing  wages  are  2ys.  a  week  is 
summoned  for  non-payment  of  a  judgment  debt 
of  £2  which  is  three  months  old.  It  is  clear 
that  since  the  date  of  the  judgment  he  has  had 
more  than  £2  wherewith  he  could  have  paid 
the  debt,  but  on  the  other  hand  he  probably 
cannot  pay  £2  forthwith.  The  creditor  is 
entitled  to  his  order  of  committal,  but  he  has 
no  desire  that  his  debtor  should  go  to  prison. 
His  only  wish  is  to  get  his  money.  The  court 
therefore  makes  an  order  committing  the  debtor, 
but  directs  that  the  waiTant  of  an'est  shall  not 
issue  as  long  as  the  debtor  pays  a  certain 
weekly  or  monthly  instalment  into  court,  say 
5s.  a  month.  This  mode  of  enforcing  the  act 
was  probably  not  contemplated  by  the  legisla- 
ture, but  after  being  questioned  by  the  court  of 
appeal,  its  validity  has  been  finally  affirmed  by 
the  House  of  Lords. 

The  policy  of  the  act  of  1869  is  defended  on  the 
ground  that  without  it  debts  would  be  practi- 
cally unrecoverable  from  the  working  classes, 
who  as  a  rule  have  little  or  no  property  avail- 
able for  seizure  under  an  execution.  Against 
this  argument  it  is  urged  that  imprisonment 
for  debt  encourages  a  system  of  factitious  credit 
which  is  injurious  alike  to  debtors  and  creditors. 
All  sound  credit  should  rest  on  one  of  two 
bases,  namely  property  or  character.  If  a  man 
has  neither  property  nor  character  it  is  better 
that  he  should  not  be  able  to  obtain  credit  by 
what  is  practically  a  mortgage  of  his  body. 
The  recovery  of  debt  by  means  of  imprisoning 
the  debtor  is  usually  a  tedious  and  expensive 
process.  The  creditor  is  for  a  long  time  kept 
out  of  his  money,  and  the  impecunious  debtor 
has  heavy  costs  to  pay  in  addition  to  the  debt. 
The  tradesmen  who  deal  with  the  poor  no 
doubt  fix  their  prices  with  reference  to  the 
difficulty  in  recovering  the  money,  and  the 
result  of  the  present  system  is  to  raise  normal 
prices  as  regards  the  honest  poor  who  pay  their 
way.  The  question  of  imprisonment  for  debt 
was  inquired  into  by  a  select  committee  of  the 
House  of  Commons  in  1873,  who  reported 
strongly  against  the  existing  procedure,  and 
suggested  various  amendments  in  the  law,  but 
no  action  has  hitherto  been  taken  on  their 
report.  It  is  to  be  noted  that  under  the  Bank- 
ruptcy Act  of  1883  a  debtor  can  file  his  own 
petition,  and  that  as  soon  as  a  receiving  order 
is   made   against  him   he   is   protected    from 


proceedings  under  §  5  of  the  Debtors  Act 
1869.  The  same  result  follows  if  an  adminis- 
tration order  is  made  by  a  county  court  in  the 
case  of  a  small  debtor,  whose  total  liabilities 
do  not  exceed  £50. 

[See  the  subject  further  discussed  in  Glasson's 
Ilistoire  du  Droit  de  V Angleterre,  vol.  vi.  §  296, 
and  Fortnightly  Review,  September  18S8.] 

M.  D.  C. 

Debtor  and  Creditor,  Law  of.  The 
salient  points  of  the  English  law  of  debtor  and 
creditor  may  be  noted  under  two  heads,  firstly, 
the  rights  and  obligations  of  creditors  and  their 
debtors  ;  and  secondly,  the  means  for  enforcing 
those  rights  and  obligations. 

When  a  debt  becomes  due,  it  is  the  duty  of 
the  debtor  to  pay  it  without  waiting  for  any 
demand.  Hence  it  has  been  held  that  an 
action  may  be  maintained  on  a  promissory  note 
payable  on  demand,  without  showing  any 
presentment  to  the  maker.  The  control  of 
the  courts  over  costs  prevents  this  rule  from 
working  any  practical  injustice.  If  no  place 
of  payment  has  been  fixed  either  by  custom  or 
agreement,  it  is  in  general  the  duty  of  the 
debtor  to  seek  out  his  creditor  for  the  purpose 
of  paying  him,  imless  the  latter  be  "beyond 
the  seas,"  that  is  to  say  out  of  England. 

In  most  continental  countries  a  creditor  is 
entitled  to  draw  a  bill  on  his  debtor  for  the 
amount  of  his  debt,  but  in  England  the  obliga- 
tion to  accept  or  pay  a  bill  of  exchange  only 
arises  from  agreement  between  the  parties.  It 
is  to  be  noted  that  when  a  man  has  an  account 
at  a  bank,  the  banker  is  not  a  trustee  of  his  cus- 
tomer's funds,  but  the  relationship  between  them 
is  simply  that  of  debtor  and  creditor,  with  a 
superadded  implied  obligation  on  the  part  of 
the  banker  to  honour  his  customer's  cheques 
to  the  extent  of  the  balance  to  his  credit. 

A  creditor  is  not  bound  to  give  change  to  his 
debtor.  It  is  the  duty  of  the  latter  to  tender 
the  exact  amount  of  his  debt  in  legal  currency 
as  defined  by  the  Coinage  Act,  1870  (see  Legal 
Tender).  Hence  it  follows  that  the  creditor, 
apart  from  agreement,  is  not  bound  to  take  a 
cheque  or  other  negotiable  instrument  in  pay- 
ment of  his  debt.  Bank  of  England  notes  are 
legal  tender,  except  when  tendered  by  the  bank 
itself. 

By  th'e  common  law  the  relationship  of 
debtor  and  creditor  is  regarded  as  a  strictly 
personal  one.  Hence,  as  a  general  rule,  if  a 
third  person  voluntarily  pays  the  creditor 
without  the  debtor's  consent  or  subsequent  rati- 
fication, the  payment  is  ineffectual.  It  neither 
liberates  the  debtor  nor  creates  any  obligation 
against  him.  The  law  merchant  has  intro- 
j  duced  certain  exceptions,  as,  for  instance,  the 
payment  for  honour  of  a  bill  of  exchange. 
These  exceptions  are  doubtless  borrowed  from 
countries  where  the  rule  of  the  civil  law  pre- 
i  vails,  according  to  which  debitorem  ignarwm^ 


506 


DEBTOR'S  SUMMONS— DEBTS,  PUBLIC 


sive  etiam'  invitum,  solvendo  liberare  possumus. 
In  accordance  with  the  principle  that  the  obli- 
gation created  by  a  debt  is  a  personal  one,  the 
common  law  did  not  recognise  the  assignment 
of  debts  ;  but  now  by  §  25  of  the  Judicature 
Act,  1873,  when  a  debt  is  assigned  absolutely, 
by  writing  under  the  hand  of  the  assignor, 
and  notice  in  writing  is  given  to  the  debtor, 
the  assignee  is  entitled  to  receive  the  debt  or 
to  sue  for  it  in  his  own  name. 

In  coimtries  which  follow  the  civil  law, 
mutual  debts  extinguish  each  other  by  what  is 
known  as  **  compensation,"  but  English  law 
acknowledges  no  such  rule.  If  parties  who 
have  cross  accounts  choose  to  strike  a  balance, 
the  balance  is  recoverable  as  a  debt,  but  that 
is  by  virtue  of  the  agreement.  Agam  by 
virtue  of  the  Judicature  Act  1873,  any  claim 
may  now  be  answered  by  any  cross-claim  that 
the  defendant  may  have  ;  for  instance,  a  claim 
for  rent  may  be  met  by  a  counter-claim  for 
damages  for  trespass,  but  it  is  purely  optional 
with  the  debtor  whether  he  sets  it  up  or  not. 

There  is  yet  another  rule  which  seems 
peculiar  to  the  English  common  law.  It  has 
been  held  that  where  there  is  an  undisputed 
debt,  payment  of  a  lesser  sum  cannot  discharge 
the  debt,  even  though  the  lesser  sum  be 
accepted  by  the  creditor  in  satisfaction  of  the 
whole.  The  alleged  reason  is  that  there  is 
no  consideration  for  the  abandonment  of  the 
balance.  The  courts,  feeling  the  hardship  of 
the  rule,  have  narrowed  its  application  as  much 
as  possible,  and  have  confined  it  to  money  pay- 
ments. For  instance,  if  a  creditor,  to  whom 
£100  is  owing,  agrees  to  take  from  his  debtor 
the  promissory  note  of  a  third  person  for  £50 
in  satisfaction  of  the  debt,  the  debt  is  dis- 
charged ;  and  it  has  even  been  held,  in  a  case 
of  somewhat  doubtful  authority,  that  the 
debtors'  own  cheque  may  have  the  same 
effect,  though  a  payment  by  him  in  cash  would 
not. 

Passing  now  from  the  creditor's  rights  to  his 
remedies  for  enforcing  them,  the  ordinary  mode 
of  enforcing  a  debt  is  by  action.  If,  however, 
the  debtor  has  committed  one  of  the  overt  acts 
of  insolvency  known  as  "acts  of  bankruptcy," 
proceedings  in  bankruptcy  may  be  taken  against 
him.  A  corporation  or  company  under,  the 
Joint  Stock  Companies  Acts  cannot  be  pro- 
ceeded against  in  bankruptcy,  but  if  it  be 
unable  to  pay  its  debts,  the  creditor  may 
petition  to  have  it  wound  up.  In  the  case  of 
an  ordinary  debtor,  if  the  debt  do  not  exceed 
£50,  the  creditor  may  sue  for  it  in  the  county 
court,  where  the  procedure  is  cheap  and  summary. 
If  the  debt  exceeds  £50  but  does  not  exceed 
£100,  the  action  must  be  commenced  in  the 
high  court,  but  either  party  can  apply  to  have 
it  removed  into  the  county  court.  If  the  debt 
exceeds  £100  the  high  court  is  the  only  court 
competent    to    adjudicate   on   it,    unless    the 


cause  of  action  has  arisen  within  the  jurisdic- 
tion of  one  of  the  few  local  inferior  courts,  such 
as  the  Mayor's  Court  of  London,  which  have 
unlimited  pecuniary  jurisdiction  within  certain 
local  limits.  When  the  creditor  has  obtained 
judgment  he  may  enforce  his  rights  in  three 
different  ways.  First  he  may  under  certain 
conditions  proceed  against  the  person  of  his 
debtor  (see  Debt,  Imprisonment  for). 
Secondly,  he  may  proceed  to  realise  his  debt 
from  the  property  of  his  debtor  by  means  of 
execution  against  that  property,  and  thirdly, 
he  may  by  the  assistance  of  the  court  attach 
any  debt  owing  by  a  third  person  to  his  debtor. 

M.  D.  c. 

Debtor's  Summons.  Under  the  Bank- 
ruptcy Act  1869,  bankruptcy  proceedings  were 
commonly  initiated  by  what  was  known  as  a 
"debtor's  summons."  Any  creditor  for  £50  or 
upwards  could  take  out  a  summons  in  the 
bankruptcy  court,  calling  on  his  debtor  to  pay 
the  sum  due  within  seven  or  twenty-one  days, 
according  as  the  debtor  was  a  trader  or  a  non- 
trader.  If,  subject  to  certain  qualifications,  the 
debt  was  not  then  paid,  an  act  of  bankruptcy 
was  deemed  to  have  been  committed,  on  which 
a  petition  might  be  presented.  The  system 
was  grossly  abused,  and  a  select  committee  of 
the  House  of  Commons  in  1880  recommended 
its  abolition.  The  Bankruptcy  Act  1883  gave 
effect  to  this  recommendation,  and  substituted 
the  procedure  by  "  bankruptcy  notice  "  founded 
on  the  final  judgment  of  a  court  of  justice,  on 
which  no  stay  of  execution  had  been  granted, 
thus  eliminating  all  questions  as  to  really 
disputed  debts. 

A  debtor's  summons  must  be  distinguished 
from  a  judgment -summons,  under  which  a 
creditor,  who  has  obtained  judgment,  seeks  to 
enforce  execution  against  the  person  of  his 
debtor  (see  Debt,  Imprisonment  for). 

m.  d.  c. 

DEBTS,  Public.  In  primitive  society,  where 
commerce  is  small  and  manufactures  are  scanty, 
the  tendency  of  both  sovereign  and  subjects  is 
to  hoard  rather  than  to  invest  the  surplus  pro- 
ducts not  immediately  consumable.  The  ele- 
mentary state  of  credit  and  the  difiiculties  in 
the  way  of  the  exchange  of  commodities  impel 
both  public  authorities  and  individual  members 
of  the  community  to  make  provision  against 
special  contingencies,  and  when  such  provision 
fails,  force  is  resorted  to  in  order  that  collective 
and  private  wants  may  be  satisfied.  As,  how- 
ever, commerce  and  manufactures  expand,  con- 
sumption becomes  easier  and  more  attractive 
both  to  sovereign  and  people,  and  the  means  of, 
and  inducement  to,  profitable  investment  in- 
crease. Under  these  conditions  there  is  a  grow- 
ing disinclination  to  do  more  than  provide  for  the 
current  expenses  of  the  government,  and  when 
extraordinary  exigencies  arise,  extraordinary 
measures  for  raising  the  funds  have  to  be  resorted 


DEBTS,  PUBLIC 


507 


to.  These  measures  are  rendered  the  more  easy 
by  reason  of  the  expansion  of  credit  and  exchange 
to  which  they  are  in  a  great  degree  due.  Hence 
Adam  Smith,  who  treats  this  phase  of  the  sub- 
ject at  some  length,  remarks  (  Wealth  of  Nations, 
bk.  V.  ch.  iii.)  :  **The  same  commercial  state 
of  society  .  .  .  produces  in  the  subjects  both 
an  ability  and  an  inclination  to  lend.  If  it 
commonly  brings  along  with  it  the  necessity  of 
bon'owing,  it  likewise  brings  with  it  the  facility 
of  doing  so  ; "  whilst  Prof.  Adams,  in  whose 
work  on  Public  Debts  the  most  complete  presen- 
tation of  the  economic  aspects  of  the  subject  of 
this  article  is  to  be  found,  observes  that  "the 
funding  system  seems  to  be  capable  of  wide 
acceptance  only  among  people  whose  labour  is 
of  a  high  grade  of  efficiency  and  who  have 
developed  for  themselves  representative  govern- 
ment." 

At  the  outset,  borrowing  by  the  state,  even 
when  incurred  for  extraordinary  purposes  such 
as  war,  took  the  form  of  a  mere  anticipation  of 
revenue  rather  than  of  permanent  indebtedness. 
In  the  United  Kingdom,  in  the  reign  of  William 
III.  and  the  earlier  part  of  that  of  Queen  Anne, 
various  loans  were  raised  on  the  assumption 
that  they  would  be  discharged  out  of  the  pro- 
ceeds of  taxes  which  were  at  the  same  time 
imposed  for  periods  varying  from  5  to  10  years, 
and  it  has  been  and  is  still  the  constant  practice 
of  the  government  to  borrow  in  anticipation  of 
revenue,  it  being  practically  impossible  so  to 
adjust  the  collection  of  taxes  as  to  meet  at  the 
due  dates  throughout  the  year  the  payments 
requiring  to  be  made  from  the  Exchequer.  The 
limits  within  which  loans  can  be  contracted 
under  such  conditions  are,  however,  necessarily 
narrow  ;  in  our  own  country  the  increasing 
requirements  of  the  government  soon  led  to  the 
adoption  of  a  less  onerous  system,  and,  as  Adam 
Smith  points  out,  "  taxes  which  before  had  been 
anticipated  only  for  a  short  term  of  years  were 
rendered  perpetual  as  a  fund  for  paying,  not  the 
capital,  but  the  interest  only  of  the  money 
which  had  been  borrowed  upon  them  by  difier- 
ent  successive  anticipations. "  When  this  point 
has  been  reached  the  funding  system  may  be 
said  to  attain  its  full  development. 

Two  of  the  principal  causes  which  have  led 
to  public  borrowing  have  already  been  alluded 
to — temporary  necessity  and  special  emergency. 
A  third  remains — the  construction  of  public 
works,  in  some  instances  the  most  potent  of 
all.  When  capital  is  required  to  be  expended  in 
order  to  provide  works  which  will  be  a  source 
of  benefit  and  profit  to  the  community  over  a 
long  period  of  years,  the  taxpayers  of  a  single 
year  are  unwilling,  and  indeed  unable,  to  bear 
the  whole  of  the  burden,  and  in  proportion  as 
the  conception  of  the  province  of  the  state  is 
enlarged,  the  public  debt  incurred  in  order  to 
provide  the  capital  requisite  for  its  undertakings 
is  necessarily  augmented. 


Economists  have  discussed  in  considerable 
detail  the  advantages  and  disadvantages  of 
public  borrowing,  as  compared  with  the  only 
alternative  possible  under  a  constitutional 
government — the  increase  of  taxation.  It  is 
urged  on  the  one  side  that  a  public  debt  affords 
a  convenient  form  of  investment,  especially  to 
those  investors  who,  desiring  full  security  for 
their  investment  rather  than  a  high  rate  of 
interest,  are  anxious  to  obtain  a  public  guar- 
antee. It  has  also  been  shown  that  a  public 
debt  may  be  made  the  means  of  materially 
assisting  the  establishment  and  provision  of 
banking  facilities  ;  and,  as  an  argument  against 
the  repayment  of  an  existing  debt,  it  has  been 
contended  that  its  pressure  "is  necessarily 
decreased  from  year  to  year  by  the  gradual 
depreciation  in  the  value  of  the  monetary  unit 
in  which  all  obligations  are  expressed,"  and 
that  even  when  this  cause  is  not  operative  "  all 
the  practical  effects  of  debt  reduction  may  be 
realised  through  the  natural  growth  and  prosper- 
ity of  the  nation."  None  of  these  considera- 
tions, however,  appears  to  outweigh  the  dis- 
advantages of  public  indebtedness  j5g?'  se,  even 
when  it  takes  the  most  convenient  form  which 
can  be  devised  ;  but  they  require  to  be  taken 
into  account  in  determining  whether  the  crea- 
tion or  maintenance  of  a  public  debt  is  prefer- 
able to  the  retention  of  existing  taxes  or  the 
imposition  of  new  ones. 

The  weight  of  the  intrinsic  objections  to 
public  borrowing  depends  to  a  considerable 
extent  upon  the  purposes  for  which  debt  is  con- 
tracted. In  this  connection  it  is  to  be  noted 
that  many  of  the  objections  to  the  funding 
system  which  are  pointed  out  by  Adam  Smith 
and  other  early  economists,  and  their  predic- 
tions of  its  disastrous  consequences,  proceed  on 
the  assumption  that  the  contraction  of  debt  by 
the  state  implies  the  destruction  of  capital,  and 
not  its  profitable  investment.  Even,  however, 
when  borrowing  is  resorted  to  in  order  to  pro- 
vide funds  for  the  purposes  of  war,  it  may  well 
be  that  the  net  result  to  a  nation  may  be 
entirely  favourable,  for,  as  M'Culloch  elo- 
quently observes,  "  the  integi-ity  and  increase  of 
our  dominions,  the  protection  of  our  rights  and 
liberties,  and  our  triumphs  by  land  and  sea,  are 
the  real  equivalents  of  the  public  debt  and  of 
all  the  blood  and  treasure  we  have  spent  in 
warlike  enterprise,  and  they  are  quite  as  ample 
and  conduce  as  much  to  our  prosperity  as  a 
nation  as  if  they  had  been  realised  in  an  increase 
of  population  and  wealth  ;  no  sacrifices  can  be 
too  great  that  are  required  to  preserve  national 
security  and  independence,  and  a  loan  expended 
on  armies  or  fleets  employed  for  such  a  purpose 
is  quite  as  well  and  profitably  employed  as  if 
it  had  been  laid  out  on  agriculture,  or  in  pro- 
moting manufactures  or  trade." 

Prof.  Adams,  in  the  work  above  referred  to, 
discusses  the  objections  to  public  debts  under 


508 


DEBTS,  PUBLIC 


the  three  heads  of  their  political,  social,  and 
industrial  effects.  Under  the  first  he  points 
out  that  the  result  of  borrowing  is  to  conceal 
from  the  nation  the  full  effects  of  the  policy 
and  course  of  action  pursued  by  the  government, 
an  argument  which  in  a  somewhat  different 
form  is  urged  by  Adam  Smith,  who  regarded 
the  borrowing  of  money  as  the  removal  of  an 
adequate  check  on  the  undertaking  and  continu- 
ance of  war.  It  may,  however,  be  observed 
that  if  borrowing  be  not  resorted  to,  the  diffi- 
culty of  providing  funds  by  reason  of  the 
impatience  of  the  taxpayer  may  easily  prevent, 
under  a  democratic  system  of  government,  the 
adoption  of  a  policy  in  all  respects  advantageous. 
A  further  political  objection  presents  itself  in 
the  case  of  weak  states,  the  autonomy  of  which 
may  be  endangered  by  the  contraction  of  foreign 
loans.  Under  the  head  of  social  effects,,  the 
same  writer  exj)resses  the  opinion  that  public 
debts  "exert  a  social  influence  in  rendering 
permanent  such  class  relations  as  spring  from 
disparity  of  possessions,  and  they  introduce 
conflicting  interests  between  citizens."  It  is, 
however,  to  be  doubted  whether  this  result  of 
the  creation  of  debt  is  long  maintained  when 
it  takes  an  extremely  mobile  form,  as  in  our 
own  country. 

The  industrial  effects  of  borrowing  are  those 
which  will  ordinarily  have  the  gi-eatest  influ- 
ence in  determining  whether  a  public  loan 
should  be  contracted,  and  on  this  point  Prof. 
Adams  may  again  be  cited.  "Public  loans 
influence  industrial  affairs  through  the  medium 
of  capita^.,  but  the  character  of  this  influence 
depends  upon  the  nature  of  the  loan,  upon  the 
conditions  under  which  it  is  contracted,  and 
upon  the  fund  of  capital  from  which  it  is  filled. 
So  long  as  the  placement  of  a  debt  by  the  state 
does  not  affect  the  market  quotations  of  com- 
modities, the  full  extent  of  its  influence  is  to 
divert  capital,  which  might  otherwise  have  gone 
to  extend  existing  industries,  to  the  purposes 
of  the  government.  But  the  moment  the  state 
offers  unusual  inducements  the  price  of  com- 
modities is  thereby  affected.  Future  loans 
must  therefore  be  contracted  on  a  rising  market, 
and  by  taking  this  step  the  government  enters 
upon  a  policy  which  contains  the  germ  of  indus- 
trial disturbance  and  social  injustice.  ...  At 
the  same  time  there  is  a  wide  margin  between 
a  slight  increase  of  the  normal  rate  of  interest 
and  an  offer  of  excessive  inducements  ;  and 
although  the  industrial  and  financial  principles 
.are  the  same  in  either  case  the  practical  results 
may  be  very  different.  It  is  therefore,  impos- 
sible, to  determine  how  far  a  government  is 
justified  in  raising  the  rate  on  public  bonds, 
unless  the  probable  results  of  this  method  of 
securing  money  be  compared  with  what  must 
follow  frojn  running  the  taxing  machinery  at 
a  higher  rate  of  speed."  M'CuUoch  arrived 
at  substantial! v  the  same  conclusion.      "The 


policy  of  raising  the  supplies  for  a   war   by 
means  of  a  loan  or  by  an  equivalent  increase  oi 
taxation,  cannot  be  decided  on  general  prin- 
ciples, but  must  always  be  determined  by  refer- 
ence to  the  state  of  the  country  at  the  time. 
Whenever    there    is   no    risk    of    prejudicing 
industry    by    increasing    taxation,    that    plan 
should  be  preferred,  and  although  a  loan  should 
be  required  to  obviate   too  rapid  an  increase 
of  taxation,  the  inconveniences  attending  the 
accumulation  of  debt  are  so  very  gi-eat,  that     | 
every   practicable   effort   should    be   made    to     I 
raise  the  revenue  to  the  highest  limit  to  which    m 
it  can  be  safely  carried,  and  to  make  it  defray    ^ 
a  part,  at  least,  if  not  the  whole,  of  the  extra- 
ordinary expenditure." 

As  to  the  manner  in  which  public  debts  J 
should  be  contracted,  there  is  now  but  little  m 
difference  of  opinion  amongst  economists.  It 
is  an  axiom  that  "floating  debts  should  be 
sparingly  used,"  by  reason  of  the  disturbing 
influence  which  they  exercise  upon  the  money 
market,  and  vice  versa,  by  reason  of  the  difficul- 
ties which  a  government  may  experience  in 
keeping  such  debts  on  foot.  It  is  also  agreed 
that  whenever  a  debt  is  large  enough,  it  should 
take  a  varied  form  in  order  ta  suit  the  varying 
requirements  of  investors.  On  this  point, 
however,  it  is  to  be  observed  that  it  is  essential 
that  each  class  of  debt  should  be  large  enough 
to  be  readily  marketable  if  it  is  of  a  negotiable 
character.  The  question  of  whether  stock 
should  be  issued  at  par  with  interest  at  the 
full  current  rate  at  which  the  money  can  be 
borrowed,  or  at  a  discount  at  a  lower  rate  of 
interest,  has  been  the  subject  of  considerable 
discussion,  and  it  cannot  be  said  that  any 
general  rule  has  been  laid  down.  Many 
investors  are  very  willing  to  accept  a  low  rate 
of  interest  for  their  money  if  they  see  in  front 
of  them  an  increment  of  value,  and  it  may  be 
important  to  the  borrowing  power  to  satisfy  its 
present  requirements  at  as  low  an  immediate 
charge  as  possible.  There  can  be  no  doubt, 
however,  that  the  system  has  frequently 
resulted  adversely  to  the  state.  M'CuUoch 
(Dictionary  of  Commerce,  art.  "  Funds  ")  states 
that  "in  consequence  of  the  prevalence  of  the 
practice,  the  principal  of  the  debt  now  existing 
amounts  to  nearly  two-fifths  more  than  the 
sum  actually  advanced  to  the  lenders, "  and  the 
balance  of  opinion  is  now  distinctly  in  favour 
of  the  issue  of  stock  at  par,  wherever  possible. 
The  course  pursued  by  the  British  municipal 
corporations  confirms  this  conclusion. 

Many  of  the  considerations  presented  with 
regard  to  the  advantages  and  disadvantages  of 
borrowing  as  compared  with  the  imposition  of  \ 
taxation  apply  equally  to  the  repayment  of 
debt.  It  is  probable  that  the  evil  effects  of  an 
ill-devised  system  of  taxation  altogether  out- 
weigh the  consequences  of  the  existence  of  debt, 
and  that  surplus  revenue  may  be  much  more 


DEBTS,  PUBLIC 


509 


wisely  devoted  to  the  revision  of  the  former 
than  the  repayment  of  the  latter.  When, 
however,  this  has  been  accomplished  the  gradual 
liquidation  of  the  debt  increases  the  financial 
strength  of  a  country  and  its  ability  to  meet 
future  contingencies  when  they  arise.  This 
object  requires  therefore  to  be  kept  in  view  in 
determining  the  mode  in  which  public  debt  is 
contracted,  and  it  is  usually  accomplished  by 
the  periodical  drawing  of  bonds,  or  as  in  our 
own  case  by  the  conversion  of  debt  into  termin- 
able annuities.  This  latter  course  is  materially 
assisted  by  the  constant  growth  of  the  funds 
coming  under  the  control  of  the  government  in 
the  shape  of  savings  bank  deposits  or  moneys 
in  Chancery,  which  can  safely  be  made  the 
subject  of  financial  operations  of  the  character 
referred  to.  In  many  instances,  however,  and 
especially  in  the  loans  of  local  authorities, 
repayment  is  agreed  to  be  made  en  bloc  at  a 
given  date,  the  necessary  funds  for  the  purpose 
being  accumulated  in  the  interim.  The  rate 
at  which  a  public  debt  should  be  repaid,  and 
the  period  during  which  it  should  subsist  must 
be  determined  by  the  general  considerations 
above  summarised,  but  in  the  case  of  loans 
contracted  for  the  construction  of  public  works, 
especially  by  local  authorities,  it  is  obvious  that 
regard  must  be  had  to  the  character  of  the 
works  and  the  length  of  time  during  which 
their  full  utility  is  likely  to  endure. 

[Nearly  all  the  general  treatises  on  Political 
Economy  refer  to  this  subject.  In  addition, 
Adams  ou  Public  Debts,  London,  1888. — Leroy- 
Beaulieu,  Traite  de  la  Science  des  Finances.  — Fenn 
on  TJie  Funds,  London,  14th  ed.,  1889,  and  the 
articles  "  Funding  System  "  and  "  National  Debt  " 
in  the  8th  and  9th  editions  of  the  Encyclopaedia 
Britannica  may  be  consulted. — C.  F.  Bastable, 
Public  Finance,  London,  1903.  See  also  An- 
nuity; Conversion;  Funding  System;  National 
Debt  ;  and  Sinking  Fund.]  t.  h.  e. 

DEBT,  Public,  Statement  of  (Government 
indebtedness).  In  the  following  tables  a  state- 
ment is  given  of  the  national  debts — (1st)  of 
Great  Britain  and  her  Colonies,  and  (2nd)  of  all 
the  foreign  countries  of  the  world  which  have 
created  such  liabilities.  It  is  impossible  to 
bring  all  the  statements  down  to  a  fixed  date  ; 
but  the  returns  are  all  comprised  within  the 
years  1911-1912  and  £8,815,930,670,  which 
is  the  total  of  the  two  tables,  may  be  stated  to 
closely  represent  the  national  indebtedness  of 
■the  world  at  the  close  of  1912.  Side  by  side 
will  be  found  the  population  of  these  countries 
at  the  same  date  as  nearly  as  possible,  and  a 
statement  of  the  debt  per  head.  But  any  bald 
statement  of  the  capital  is  misleading.  Where 
a  debt  carries  6  per  cent  interest  it  is  a  far 
greater  burden  than  where  it  carries  only  2\ 
per  cent,  as  in  the  case  of  Great  Britain  and 
some  Canadian  stock  ;  and  the  interest  is 
therefore  added  as  a  guide  to  what  the  burden 


of  the  debt  really  amounts  to.  But  even  the 
interest  is  not  a  guide  to  the  burden  of  a 
country's  national  debt.  By  many  countries 
large  sums  have  been  raised  for  the  construc- 
tion of  railways,  and  some  of  these  public  works 
make  a  return  sufficient  to  cover  the  interest  on 
the  national  debt.  The  endeavour  has  been 
made  in  cases  where  the  figures  are  available  to 
show  what  portion  of  the  interest  has  been  made 
good  by  the  earnings  of  reproductive  works, 
and  the  net  burden  met  out  of  national  taxation. 
It  would  occupy  far  too  much  space  to  describe 
the  results  indicated.  They  must  be  allowed 
to  speak  for  themselves.  In  dealing  with 
foreign  nations,  especially  with  the  Continent 
of  Europe,  it  has  been  found  impossible  in  some 
instances  to  separate  the  Revenue  from  Public 
works  from  that  obtained  from  State  Domains, 
Forests,  etc.  In  some  cases  inconvertible  paper 
currencies  are  included  in  the  total  debts. 
Amongst  the  debts  have  been  included  the 
amounts  raised  by  separate  states — such  as 
those  comprising  the  United  States  and  the 
German  Empire  —  but  not  county  or  city 
indebtedness  of  any  description. 

As  compared  Avith  a  previous  estimate  made  in 
1892  (see  art.  in  First  Edition,  1894),  when  the 
debts  were  found  to  aggregate £6,505,375,562 
the  increase  is  shown  to  be  £2,310, 5:35, 108, 
A  comparison  of  the  following  tables  with  those 
given  in  the  first  edition  of  this  Dictionary  will 
show  that  almost  all  countries  have  increased 
their  debts.  In  the  ten  years  1882  to  1892, 
the  national  debts  of  the  world  increased  by 
£1,111,000,000.  Between  1872  and  1882  the 
increase  was  only  £789,000,000,  between  1862 
and  1872  it  was  £2,000,000,000.  There  were 
three  great  wars  between  1862  and  1872,  while 
between  1892  and  1912  several  leading  countries 
have  been  engaged  in  serious  warfare,  which  has 
added  greatly  to  their  indebtedness. 

[Statistical  Abstract  of  the  Principal  and  other 
Foreign  Countries.  Secretary  of  Legation  Reports. 
— Almanack  de  Ootha,  1892. — The  Statesman's 
Year  Book,  1892.— Fenn  on  The  Funds,  1889  and 
1892. — Annual  General  Report  of  the  Corpora- 
tion of  Foreign  Bondholders. — The  Victorian 
Year  Book,  1890-91.— T'Ae  Seven  Colonies  of 
Australasia,  1892  (Sydney). — The  Year  Book  of 
Canada.  — Generally  the  official  statistics  of 
foreign  countries.] 

DEBT^,  Great  Britain  and  Ireland. 
Public,  pp.  510,  511.  Local,  pp.  512,  513. 
England  a7id  Wales. — Side  by  side  with  the 
national  debt  of  the  United  Kingdom  a  very 
large  amount  of  debt  has  been  contracted  by 
the  local  authorities,  which  should  not  be  lost 
sight  of  in  any  estimate  of  the  public  indebted- 
ness of  the  country. 

For  outstanding  loans  of  local  authorities  in 
England  and  Wales  at  the  end  of  the  financial 
years  1874-5,  1886-7,  1898-9,  and  1910-11,  see 
next  page. 


510 


DEBTS,  PUBLIC 


Revenue 
from 

Country. 

Population 

Debt 

Debt  per 

Debt 

Invested 

Net  Burden 

(1911). 

(1912). 

Head. 

Charge. 

Funds,  Re- 

of Interest.! 

productive 

• 

Works,  etc.t 

British  Empire 

No. 

£ 

£    s.    d. 

£ 

£ 

£ 

United  Kingdom    . 

45,662,646 

724,806,000 

15  15    3 

24,500,000 

260,582* 

24,2.39,418 

Colonies  and  Possessions 

British  India  .... 

244,221,377 

303,680,788 

1    U    6 

9,884,000 

19,871,777 

nil 

Straits  Settlements  (includ- 

ing Labuan) 

722,075 

6,913,852 

9  13    5 

94,147 

large 

a 

Ceylon 

4,106,350 

6,130,727 

1    9  10 

288,875 

606,828 

nil 

Mauritius        .... 

375,481 

1,290,691 

3    5    1 

a 

large 

a 

Seychelles       .        .        .        . 

22,691 

13,875 

0  n  2 

a 

a 

a 

Hong-Kong     .... 

456,739 

1,485,733 

3    5    0 

a 

large 

a 

Commonwealth  of  Australia 

New  South  Wales 

1,646,734 

100,052,635 

60  lU  11 

3,867,017 

3.290,720 

576,297 

Victoria       .        .        .        . 

1,315,551 

60,737,216 

U6    3    0 

2,207,232 

1,158,757 

1,048,475 

South  Australia  . 

408,558 

29,440.113 

72    3    1 

a 

large 

a 

Western  Australia 

282,114 

26,283,523 

93    k    1 

1,101,561 

1,896,579c 

Tasmania    .        .        .        . 

191,211 

11,302,411 

59    3    5 

414,2o5 

large 

Queensland. 

605,813 

47,068,186 

77  13    h 

1,724,3046 

1,117,683 

606,621 

New  Zealand 

1,008,468 

90,060,763 

89    6  11 

2,656,344 

1,197,895 

1,458,440 

Fiji 

139,541 

82,815 

0  11  10 

a 

a 

a 

Union  of  South  Africa    . 

5,973,394 

117,260,534 

19  12    7 

3,970,472?; 

a 

a 

Swaziland    .... 

99,959 

100,000 

10    0 

3,500& 

a 

% 

Nyasaland  .... 

970,430 

60,000 

0    10 

a 

a 

a 

Uganda        .... 

2,843,325 

295,000 

0    2    0 

Or 

a 

a 

East  Africa .... 

2,402,863 

250,000 

0    2    1 

a 

a 

a 

South  Nigeria      . 

7,857,983 

8,267,665 

110 

228,042 

26,271 

201,771 

Gold  Coast  .... 

1,501,793 

2,469,118 

1  12  10 

a 

a 

a 

Sierra  Leone 

1,403,132 

1,248,048 

0  17    9 

61,336 

.. 

Dominion  of  Canada 

7,204,838 

99,331,136 

13  15    9 

2,684,681 

a 

a 

Newfoundland     . 

238,670 

5,650,713 

23  12  10 

a 

a 

a 

West  India  Islands 

Bahamas      .... 

55,944 

47,223 

0  16    9 

a 

a 

a 

Jamaica       .        .        .        . 

831,383 

3,843,074 

U  12    5 

245,535 

a 

a 

St.  Lucia     .... 

48,637 

142,230 

2  17  11 

a 

a 

a 

St.  Vincent. 

41,877 

50 

a 

a 

a 

Barbados     .... 

171,982 

436,900 

2  10    9 

a 

a 

a 

Grenada       .... 

66,750 

123,670 

1  17    0 

a 

a 

a 

Leeward  Islands 

127,304 

266,850 

2    2    6 

a 

a 

a 

Trinidad  and  Tobago  . 

833,552 

1,045,093 

3    2    2 

a 

a 

a 

Bermuda     .        .        .        . 

18,994 

45,500 

2    5    0 

a 

a 

a 

British  Honduras 

40,458 

194,541 

U  17    6 

a 

a 

a 

British  Guiana    . 

296,041 

884,615 

2  19    2 

a 

a 

a 

Malta 

211,564 

79,081 

0    7    5 

22,5966 

a 

a 

Cyprus    

Total  British  Empire      . 

273,964 

269,227 

0  19    6 

a 

a 

a 

417,559,646  d 

1,658,011,443 

3  19    5 

*  England  also  receives  about  £1,400,000  annually  from  her  Suez  Canal  Shares. 

t  Approximate  figures  only.  a  Information  unobtainable.  b  Interest  only. 

c  Gross  returns  from  railways.  d  Population  of  the  whole  British  Empire. 

Note.— It  is  very  difficult  to  state  the  exact  sinking  fund  of  the  Home  National  Debt.  Nominally  £1,000,000 
was  so  applied  in  1914.  But  a  considerable  portion  of  the  annual  chargelou  the  Terminable  Annuities  is  in  reality 
sinking  fund,  and  out  of  a  total  charge  of  £24,500,000  some  £2,000,000  may  be  applied  to  reduction  of  capital. 


Year. 

Amount  of  loans  outstanding. 

1874-75 

£92,820,100 

1886-87 

186,343,678 

1898-99 

275,327,374 

1910-11 

540,211,480 

The  liabilities  of  local  authorities  in  respect 
of  their  outstanding  loans  had  thus  increased 
by  £447,391,380,  or  480-6  per  cent  in  1910-11 
as  compared  with  1874-75.  Of  this  increase 
£93^523,578  falls  in  the  twelve  years  from 
1874-75  to  1886-87,  £88,983,696  in  the  twelve 
years  1886-87  to  1898-99,  and  £264,884,106 
in  the  twelve  years  1898-99  to  1910-11.     The 


loans  raised  during  the  thirty-six  years  amounted 
to  over  £500,000,000.  A  considerable  part  has 
been  repaid  in  that  time.  It  should  be  remem- 
bered that  the  above  loans  have  been  incurred 
for  purposes  of  public  utility,  as  harbours,  docks, 
piers,  waterworks,  gasworks,  and  markets,  from 
which  considerable  revenue  is  derived.  Others, 
such  as  those  incurred  for  schools,  though  not 
yielding  an  immediate  return,  have  been  raised 
for  highly  useful  purposes.  The  proportion 
which  the  local  indebtedness  bears  to  the  rate- 
able value  of  the  several  districts  in  respect  of 
which  it  has  been  incurred  varies  greatly  in 


DEBTS,  PUBLIC 


511 


Debts  of  Foreign  Countries. 


Country. 

Population 
(1911). 

Public  Debt 
(1912). 

Debt  per 
Head 
(1912). 

Interest, 

Debt 

Charge, 

etc.  (1912). 

Income  from 

Invested 
Funds,  Repro- 
ductive Works, 
etc.t 

Net  Burden 
of  Interest.! 

European 

No. 

£ 

£    s.   d. 

£ 

£ 

£ 

Austria    .... 

29,003,000 

519,631,229 

11    0    U 

20,278,487 

7,700,000 

12,578,487 

Hungary. 

21,239,619 

274,702,000 

12  18    8 

12,210,259 

25,000,000 

nil 

Belgium  .... 

7,571,387 

162,385,545 

21    8  11 

7,642,435 

entirely  covereil 

nil 

Denmark. 

2,800,000 

19,716,996 

7    0    8 

4,554,673 

560,000 

4,000,000 

France     .... 

39,601,509 

1,071,848,000 

27    1    U 

50,824,000 

2,700,000 

Germany,  Empire  . 

64,925,993 

242,743,000 

3  lU    9 

11,825,400 

large 

Prussia 

40,165,219 

471,443,702 

11  17    3 

20,517,457 

large 

Bavaria 

6,887,291 

114,299.000 

16  12  10 

847,427 

1,500,000  e 

.. 

Saxony. 

4,806,661 

43,445,000 

9    0    9 

1,939,475 

large 

.. 

Wiirtemberg 

2,437,574 

31,240,000 

12    8    0 

1,368,750 

large 

Baden  .... 

2,142,833 

28,384,000 

13    h  10 

1,685,302 

1,490,000 

Minor  States 

3,899,561 

75,407,000 

19    6    5 

a 

large 

Greece      .... 

2,800,000 

42,827,021 

15    5    9 

1,536,457 

300,000 

1,200,000 

Italy         .        .        .        . 

34,687,000 

537,174,000 

15    9    9 

18,043,000 

2,275,000 

16,000,000 

Luxemburg     . 

259,891 

973,145 

3    7    2 

439,725 

large 

Montenegro     . 

516,000 

390,000 

0  15    1 

a 

a 

Netherlands     . 

6,114,302 

96,954,638 

15  17    1 

3,153,614 

470,000 

2,800,000 

Portugal  .... 

5,958,643 

188,986,980 

31  Ik    5 

6,915,603 

3,200,000 

3,700.000 

Roumania 

7,248,061 

65,991,727 

9     12 

3,976,198 

1,155,000 

2,800,000 

S-irvia      .... 

2,911,701 

26,362,240 

9    10 

1,295,782 

750,000 

500  000 

Spain       .... 

19,588,688 

409,250,978 

20  17    9 

16.420,594 

916,000 

15,500,000 

Sweden    .... 

5,604,192 

33,478,180 

5  19    5 

i;615,223 

covered 

nil 

Norway    .... 

2,439,300 

20,156,000 

8    5    2 

950,681 

1,700,000 

ml 

Switzerland     . 

3,781,430 

9,313,700 

2    9    3 

251,885 

266,160 

nil 

Russia      .... 

167,920,000 

945,553,000 

5  12    6 

42,611,000 

100,000,000 

nil 

Finland 

3,140,000 

7,053,539 

2    h    8 

338,964 

2,238,000 

nil 

Turkey     .... 

21,273,900 

128,834,486 

6    10 

Bulgaria     and     Eastern 

Roumelia 
1                Total  European     . 

4,337,516 

24,407,976 

5  12    3 

1,605,880 

a 

a 

514,061,380 

5,592,953,082 

American 

United  States  . 
Separate  States    . 

95,656,000 1 

573,674,774 
96,326,800 

5  11  11 
10     1 

10,252,800 
a 

10,745,000 
a 

a 

Argentine  Confederation 

7,171,910 

109,282,923 

15    U    9 

6,654,501 

a 

a 

Bolivia     .... 

2,267,935 

784,008 

0    6  10 

136,989 

a 

a 

Brazil       .... 

24,308,219 

136,271,000 

5  12    0 

6,336,000 

a 

a 

Chili         .... 

3,505,317 

42,183,952 

12    0    8 

2,307,117 

a 

a 

Colombia 

5,472,604 

5,602,686 

10    5 

a 

a 

a 

Costa  Rica 

399,424 

3,433  110 

8  12    1 

159,386 

a 

a 

Cuba        .... 

2,382,990 

13,524,000 

5  13    6 

622,000 

a 

a 

Ecuador  .... 

1,500,000 

4,513,579 

3    0    2 

a 

a 

a 

Guatemala 

1,991,261 

3,523,222 

1  15    U 

a 

a 

a 

Haiti        .... 

2,500.000 

7,976,000 

3    3    9 

576,493 

a 

a 

Honduras 

566,017 

23,271,656 

Ul    2    k 

a 

a 

a 

Mexico     .... 

15,115,612 

46,174,065 

3    11 

2,557,935 

a 

a 

Paraguay 

800,000 

2,204,770 

2  15    1 

a 

a 

a 

Peru         .... 

4,906,900 

10,920,083 

2    h    6 

218,754 

a 

a 

Salvador  .... 

1,200,000 

3,543,297 

2  18    k 

a 

a 

a 

San  Domingo  . 

600,000 

3,643,743 

6    15 

296,553 

a 

a 

Uruguay  .... 

1,225,914 

28,054,796 

22  17    8 

1,638.731 

a 

a 

Venezuela 

Total  American    . 

2,755,685 

7,192,560 

2  12    2 

215,776 1 

a 

a 

174,325,788 

1,122,101,024 

.. 

.. 

.. 

Asiatic 

China       .... 

325,000,000 

74,446,750 

0    h    6 

3,852,554 1 

o 

a 

Japan       .... 

52,312,068 

254,593,000 

U  17    3 

16,459,658 

a 

a 

Siam        .... 

Total  Asiatic 

8,117,953 

8,000,000 

10    0 

a 

large 

a 

385,430,021 

837,039,750 

.. 

African 

Congo  (Belgian) 

15,000,000 

11,149,888 

0  Ih  10 

430,000  t 

a 

a 

Egypt      .... 

11,287,359 

94,350,000 

8    7    2 

4,028,000 

4,700,000 

Liberia     .... 
Total  African 
Total  Foreign 

1,500,000 

325,483 

0    h    k 

a 

a 

a 

27,787,359 

105,825,371 

.. 

.. 

1,101,604,548 

7,157,919,227 

t  Approximate  figures  only. 


o  Information  unobtainable. 


e  Against  Railway  Debt  only. 


512 


DEBTS,  PUBLIC— LOCAL 


different  localities.  The  annual  rateable  value 
of  England  and  Wales  for  the  purposes  of  the 
poor-rate,  according  to  the  valuation  lists  in 
force  at  Lady-day  1913,  was  £221,011,832. 

The  relative  proportions  which  the  debts  of 
local  authorities  bore  to  the  national  debts  at 
the  end  of  the  financial  years  1874-75  and 
1910-11  are  shown  by  the  following  figures. 


Years. 

National  Debt. 

Local  Debt. 

Proportion  of 
Local  Debt  to 
National  Debt. 

1874-5 
1910-11 

£ 
768,945,757 
733,072,610 

£ 

92,820,100 

540,211,480 

per  cent. 
12 
73 

The  following  statement  shows,  so  far  as  it 
has  been  found  practicable  to  apportion  them, 
the  amounts  outstanding  in  respect  of  the 
principal  purposes  for  which  the  loans  of  the 
local  authorities  had  been  raised. 

Loans  outstanding  {England  and  Wales), 

year  1910-11. 

Local  Authorities. 


Administration  of  Justice 
Baths,  Washhouses,  aud  Open  Bath- 
ing Places  .... 
Cemeteries    ..... 
Education  (Schools,  Appliances,  etc) 

(1)  Elementary  Education 

(2)  Higher  Education 
Electric  Lighting  .... 
Fire  Engines,  Stations,  Appliances 

Gasworks 

Harbours,  Docks,  Piers,  Canals,  and 

Quays       .         .         .         .         . 

Highways,  Bridges,  and  Ferries 

Hospitals 

Housing  of  the  Working  Classes     . 

Lighting  Highways,  etc. 

Lunatic  Asylums  .... 

Markets        ..... 

Parks,  Pleasure-grounds,  and  open 
spaces      ..... 

Police  Stations  and  Gaols 

Poor  Relief  (Workhouses,  In- 
firmaries, Offices,  etc.) 

Private  Street  Works  and  other 
works  of  private  improvement     . 

Sewerage  and  Sewage  Disposal 

Small  Holdings  and  Allotments 

Tramways  and  Light  Railways 

Unemployed  Workmen  Act,  1905  . 

Valuation     ..... 

Waterworks  .... 

Other  Works  and  Purposes  (includ- 
ing destruction  of  house  refuse)  . 

Unapportioned  Loans    . 

Total    . 


£940,301 

3,235,704 
3,028,622 

41,370,651 
6,099,671 

29,681,430 
1,925,249 

23,119,160 

72,304,050 
.59,502,561 

5,841,792 

10,880,962 

189,670 

10,885,767 

7,329,207 

8,574,665 
1,877,266 

12,283,844 

1,336,435 

42,322,260 

1,853,139 

36,419,547 

28,028 

1,424 

128,687,495 

26,598,708 
3,893,872 

£540,211,480 

Amount  remaining  at  the  end  of  the  year  1910- 
1911,  in  sinking  funds  and  similar  funds,  towards 
the  repayment  of  the  part  of  the  total  entered  in 
column  4,  which  is  repayable  by  means  of  those 
funds £21,595,096 

The  local  taxation  returns  from   which  these 


figures  are  obtained  relate  to  the  accounts  of  the 
local  authorities  of  England  and  Wales.  These 
authorities  are  very  numerous. 

During  the  year  1910-11  the  accounts  of  the 
following  local  authorities  were  audited  by  district 
auditors  :  62  County  Councils  ;  29  Metropolitan 
Borough  Councils  with  the  Corporation  of  London  ; 
the  Managers  of  the  MetropoHtan  Asylum  District ; 
the  Metropolitan  Police  Authority  ;  1136  Town 
Councils ;  666  Rural  District  Councils ;  7073 
Parish  Councils  and  Parish  Meetings  ;  Overseers 
of  the  Poor  for  about  14,553  Parishes  ;  653  Boards 
of  Guardians  ;  56  Authorities  for  the  Management 
of  Harbours,  Docks,  Piers,  Canals,  and  Quays  (in- 
cludmg  the  Port  of  London  Authority) ;  and  1384 
Miscellaneous  Authorities.     Total — 25,614. 

The  management  of  the  local  debt  of  the 
country  is  thus  divided  between  a  vast  number 
of  persons,  and,  as  is  usually  the  case  where 
individual  responsibility  is  lost  sight  of, 
administration  is  lax.  For  the  system  of 
administration,  see  Local  Government. 

Loans  outstanding  {Scotland),  1911-12. 
Local  Authorities. 
Revenue-producing  Undertakings  :— 
Gas  and  Electricity  Supply 
Tramways  and  Light  Railways   . 
Water  Supply  .... 
Markets    ..... 
Slaughterhouses 

Public  Baths  and  Washhouses    . 
Working  -  class     Dwellings     and 

Lodging-Houses^    .         ... 
Burial  Grounds 
Harbours  and  Ports  . 


£10,265,149 

4,389,877 

12,787,161 

418,184 

319,973 

299,996 

2,169,675 

211,355 

12,877,591 


£43,738,961 

Common  Good  (not  falling  under 

other  heads)  .... 

644,652 

Non-Revenue-producing  Services : — 

Poor  Relief        .... 

939,172 

District  Lunatic  Asylums  . 

1,538,168 

Education          .... 

6,648,030 

Cleansing           .... 

420,529 

Sewers,  Drains,  etc.  . 

3,968,525 

Hospitals           .... 

1,236,582 

General  Sanitary  Operations 

59,446 

Roads,  Streets,  and  Bridges 

2,051,195 

Watching,    Police   Stations,    and 

Prisons           .... 

383,240 

Public  Libraries         .         .         , 

87,681 

Sheriff  Court  Buildings 

6,602 

Public  Lighting 

67,693 

Fire  Brigade      .... 

131,446 

Public  Parks,  etc.      . 

1,109,354 

Buildings  (not  allocated  to  other 

Heads) 

2,186,133 

Distress   Committee    under   Un- 

employed Workmen  Act,  1905 

11,611 

District  Fisheries 

405 

Heritors,  for  Ecclesiastical  Pur- 

poses      

13,345 

Other  Purposes 

1,009,552 

Total     . 

£66,252,322 

1  Erected  under  the  Housing  of  the  Working  Classes 
Acts  and  under  Local  Acts. 


DE  CARDENAS  DI  MAQUEDA— DECENTRALISATION 


o]3 


Heritors,  for  Ecclesiastical  purposes  £13,345 
Other  purposes         .         .  .     1,009,552 


£66,252,322 

The   rateable    value    of   Scotland    for    1912 

was  £32,983,165. 

Loans  outstanding  (Ireland)  1911-12  : — 

Local  Authorities. 

Councils  of  Counties  . 

£431,743 

Lunatic  Asylums 

1,230,379 

Town  Councils  .... 

7,462,925 

Commissioners  of  Towns 

1,171,795 

Commissioners  under  Towns  Im- 

provement Act 

1,121,546 

Belfast  City  and   District  Water 

Commissioners 

1,898,723 

Joint  Boards  for  Sewerage,  Burial, 

Port  Sanitary,  and  other  purposes      243,552 

Rural  District  Councils 

6,769,765 

Boards  of  Guardians  . 

362,920 

Harbour  Authorities  . 

3,431,977 

£24,125,331 

The  local  debt  of  the  United  Kingdom  was 
thus,  at  the  dates  mentioned,  as  follows  : 
England  and  Wales,  1910-11       £540,211,480 
Scotland,  1911-12       .  .  .     66,252,322 

Ireland,  1911-12         .         .         .     24,125,331 

£630,589,133 


This  amount  should  be  added  to  the  National 
Debt  in  estimating  the  indebtedness  of  the 
country.  The  Local  Debt  bears  now  a  propor- 
tion of  about  88  per  cent  to  the  National  Debt 
and  is  continually  increasing.  Other  countries- 
show  the  same  tendency.  According  to  the 
Statesman  s  Year  Boole,  1913,  the  debt  of  the 
French  Communes  was  more  than  £170,000,000 
in  1910 — including  Paris.  The  debts  of  that 
city  alone  were  over  £100,000,000.  The 
departmental  debt  stood  at  over  £36,000,000 
in  1908.  The  local  debts  of  the  United 
States  (of  States,  Counties,  etc.)  aggregated 
$1,865,000,000  (£373,000, 000)in  1902.  The 
growthof  debts  of  this  description  is  rapid,  and  no 
very  accurate  general  statements  are  attainable. 

[Sir  S.  H.  Northcote  (Lord  Iddesleigh),  Twenty 
Years  of  Financial  Policy,  App.  B,  p.  398,  Lon- 
don, 1862. — K.  H.  Inglis  Palgrave,  The  Local 
Taxation  of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland,  London, 
1871. — G.  J.  Goschen,  Reports  and  Speeches  on 
Local  Taxation,  London,  1872. — Essays  edited  by 
J.  W.  Probyn  on  Local  Government  and  Taxation 
in  the  United  Kingdom,  London,  1882. — Wright 
and  Hobhouse,  Local  Government  and  Local 
Taxation,  London,  1884. — C.  F.  Bastable,  Public 
Finance,  1903,  Bk.  v.  oh.  viii. — Keports  of  the 
Local  Government  Board. — Local  Taxation  Returns 
(Scotland). — Local  Taxation  (Ireland)  Returns.] 

DE  CARDENAS  DI  MAQUEDA,  Diego 
Raffaele,  lived  in  the  second  half  of  the  18th 
century.     He  belongs  to  that  set  of  people  who, 

VOL.  T. 


if  two  are  discussing  what  four  and  four  is,  and 
one  says  "eight"  and  the  other  "ten,"  will 
drop  in  an  intermediate  opinion,  and  think  it 
might  be  "nine."  Liberty  of  commerce,  par- 
ticularly of  corn,  is  wrong,  so  is  state  interfer- 
ence ;  the  truth  is,  of  course,  between  the  two 
— a  little  liberty  and  a  little  regulation  by  the 
state.  For  De  Cardenas,  the  causes  of  dearth 
in  the  kingdom  of  Naples  are  three :  scarcity 
of  production  as  a  rule  ;  large  harvests  excep- 
tionally ;  then  government  interference.  The 
one  only  remedy  in  his  opinion  is  the  creation 
of  public  store-houses,  and  the  giving  power  to 
the  government  to  decide  annually  what  portion 
of  the  harvest  might  be  exported.  The  corn 
in  the  public  store-houses  ought  to  be  saleable 
by  a  system  of  warrants. 

The  title  of  his  work  is  Governo  economico 
intorno  ai  grani.  Napoli,  presso  Gaetano 
Tardano,  1784.  m.  p. 

DECENTRALISATION.  Few  terms  are 
used  more  at  random  or  are  harder  to  define 
tlian  decentralisation.  It  is  the  reverse  of 
Centralisation  {q.v.)  If  centralisation  be 
defined  as  the  centring  of  all  the  powers  of 
government  in  the  hands  of  a  single  person,  or 
body  of  persons,  and  presumably  in  a  single 
place,  namely  the  capital  of  the  state,  decen- 
tralisation may  be  defined  as  the  distributing 
the  powers  of  government  among  various  persons 
or  groups  of  persons,  and  presumably  in  various 
places  of  which  the  capital  is  only  the  most 
important.  Complete  centralisation  and  com- 
plete decentralisation  are  alike  impossible. 
Complete  centralisation  is  impossible,  because 
the  central  authority  must  under  all  cii-cum- 
stances  leave  much  to  agents  and  subordinates, 
and  cannot  wholly  deprive  them  of  a  discretion 
in  executing  their  functions.  Complete  decen- 
tralisation is  impossible,  for  this  Avould  imply 
the  perfectly  independent  action  of  many 
authorities,  in  other  words  the  dissolution  of 
the  body  politic.  The  decentralisation  Avhich 
is  possible  without  destroying  the  state  may 
take  different  forms.  The  functions  of  govern- 
ment are  distinguished  as  legislative,  judicial, 
and  executive  or  administrative.  All  those 
functions,  or  only  one  or  two  of  them,  may  be 
decentralised.  AH  are  decentralised  to  a  con- 
siderable degree  in  such  a  commonwealth  as 
the  United  States  of  America.  Legislation  is 
centralised  in  most  states  which  are  not  federal, 
e.g.  in  the  kingdom  of  Italy  or  in  the  French 
republic.  Administration  is  decentralised  in 
England  to  a  far  greater  degree  than  in  France, 
since  English  local  authorities  enjoy  a  far  larger 
independence  than  do  French  local  authorities. 
On  tiie  other  hand  the  administration  of  justice 
is  far  more  centralised  in  England  than  in 
France.  By  means  of  the  system  of  circuits  a 
very  small  number  of  superior  courts  has  been 
made  to  serve  the  wants  of  the  whole  kingdom. 
In  France,   under  the  monarchy,   there  were 

2  L 


614 


DECENTRALISATION—DECIMAL  SYSTEM 


thirteen  parliaments  or  high  courts  of  justice, 
and  although  these  have  disappeared,  the 
number  of  courts  and  of  judges  has  been  much 
increased  in  the  present  century.  Thus  we  see 
that  itis  possiblefor  different  functions  of  govern- 
ment to  be  decentralised  in  different  states. 

Again  the  political  significance  of  decentral- 
isation differs  according  to  the  nature  of  the 
function  decentralised.  Of  all  the  functions  of 
government,  legislation  is  the  most  momentous. 
Its  centralisation  is  therefore  intimately  con- 
nected with  the  unity  of  the  state.  The  legisla- 
tive decentralisation  in  federal  states,  arises 
from  the  fact  that  these  are  aggregates  of 
smaller  states,  which,  although  willing  to  com- 
bine for  certain  purposes,  are  unwilling  to  fore- 
go individual  existence  and  at  least  nominal 
sovereignty.  Judicial  decentralisation  usually 
owes  its  origin  to  the  desire  for  cheap  and 
speedy  justice,  which  can  be  had  only  by  bring- 
ing a  court  of  justice  within  convenient  reach 
of  every  one  who  wishes  to  go  to  law.  Adminis- 
trative decentralisation  usually  arises  from  a 
totally  different  impulse,  from  an  instinct  of 
self-government,  a  desire  to  execute  the  laws 
for  oneself  rather  than  to  have  them  executed 
by  officials. 

The  good  or  bad  consequences  of  decentralisa- 
tion diff'er  with  the  different  modes  of  decentral- 
isation, as  well  as  with  the  circumstances  of 
each  community.  Legislative  decentralisation 
is  seldom  strongly  desired  or  long  maintained, 
unless  in  states  spread  over  a  vast  area  like  the 
British  empire  or  the  United  States,  or  divided 
by  differences  of  race  or  religion  like  the  Austro- 
Hungarian  monarchy  or  the  Swiss  republic. 
Legislative  decentralisation  has  the  advantage 
of  allowing  a  freer  play  to  national  or  quasi- 
national  characteristics.  It  has,  however,  the 
disadvantage  of  leaving  the  less  civilised  parts 
of  a  state  to  persist  in  their  barbarism.  It  has 
also,  in  states  under  popular  government,  the 
disadvantage  of  opening  a  field  to  politicians 
of  low  moral  and  intellectual  type.  Judicial 
decentralisation  is  good  in  so  far  as  it  renders 
justice  cheap  and  rapid,  but  bad  in  so  far  as  it 
tends  to  produce  judges  undistinguished  either 
for  learning,  for  ability,  or  for  character.  Few 
states  have  attained  the  right  medium  in 
judicial  decentralisation.  In  England  it  has 
not  been  carried  far  enough  ;  in  France  and  in 
America  it  has  been  carried  much  too  far. 
Administrative  decentralisation  is  good  in  so 
far  as  it  places  the  administration  in  the  hands 
of  those  whom  it  immediately  aff"ects,  calls  forth 
their  public  spirit,  and  exercises  their  political 
capacity.  It  is  bad  in  so  far  as  it  entrusts 
administration  to  men  who  have  not  competent 
intelligence  or  are  not  conspicuous  enough  to 
fear  public  opinion.  In  short,  decentralisation 
is  good,  not  as  an  ultimate  end,  but  as  a  means 
of  good  government  and  of  national  training. 
Its  eff"ects  are  strictly  relative  to  all  the  con- 


ditions of  the  state  decentralised.  In  what 
directions  and  to  what  extent  decentralisation 
should  be  carried  in  any  given  commonwealth, 
can  be  determined  only  upon  mature  examina- 
tion of  all  the  circumstances  and  cautious  trial 
of  what  is  possible.  There  are  few  general  pro- 
positions on  the  subject  which  cannot  be  shown 
to  be  unsound  or  at  least  incorrect  by  familiar 
historical  instances. 

[Upon  the  theory  of  this  subject  the  reader  may 
consult  De  Tocqueville's  works,  especially  De,  la 
Dhnocratie  en  Amh^que,  and  Mill's  Representative 
Government;  for  illustrations  of  the  working  of 
decentralisation,  'Bvyc&'&  American  Comtnonwealth, 
— especially  the  chapters  relating  to  the  state  and 
municipal  authorities  ;  for  a  statement  of  the 
degree  of  administrative  decentralisation  now  ex- 
isting in  England,  the  volumes  on  Local  Govern- 
ment and  Poor  Relief  in  the  English  Citizen  Series.] 

F,  c. M. 

DECIMAL  SYSTEM  (Coinage,  Weights 
AND  Measures).  Viewed  from  an  economical 
standpoint,  the  non-adoption  in  a  compulsory 
manner  of  any  decimal  or  metric  system  of 
current  money,  weights,  and  measures,  through- 
out the  British  Empire  is  one  of  the  most 
glaring  examples  of  national  waste,  financially 
and  educationally,  that  the  spirit  of  unwilling- 
ness to  face  the  trouble  of  a  change  from  old 
ways  has  ever  inflicted.  Over  and  over  again 
this  has  been  pointed  out  to  parliamentary 
committees,  to  successive  prime  ministers, 
chancellors  of  the  exchequer,  presidents  of  the 
board  of  trade,  and  other  high  executive  func- 
tionaries, but  in  vain  so  far  as  any  practical 
action  is  concerned.  Not  only  scientific  men 
and  professors,  mathematical  and  politico- 
economical,  but  commercial  men  and  chambers 
of  commerce,  and  educational  experts  at  home, 
and  British  consuls  abroad,  have  urged  in  the 
most  convincing  manner  that  our  weights  and 
measures  and  money  are,  as  a  whole,  utterly 
unintelligible  to  the  large  majority  of  foreign 
persons  with  whom  it  is  our  desire  and  interest 
to  further  extend  our  trade,  and  that  this 
renders  English  price  lists  and  circulars  a  mere 
dead  letter  to  many  who  might  otherwise  become 
customers,  and  greatly  handicaps  British  in- 
dustries in  export  trade.  It  has  also  been  fully 
demonstrated  that  the  loss  of  valuable  time, 
and  the  imperfect  intelligence  developed,  by 
teaching  the  young  an  antiquated  non-decimal 
system,  is  a  fearful  extravagance  even  in  a 
country  like  ours  where  the  State  can  afford 
twenty  millions  a  year  in  the  cause  of  education, 
some  considerable  part  of  which  would  be  saved 
if  a  proper  decimal  system  were  substituted  for 
the  present  effete  and  unscientific  want  of 
system.  If  such  a  change  be  adopted  by  the 
legislature,  within  a  very  limited  time  there 
would  gradually  be  no  necessity  to  teach,  in 
public  or  other  schools,  the  present  puzzling, 
because  incoherent  with  each  other,  denomina- 
tions of  money,  weights,  and  measures  that  are 


DECIMAL  SYSTEM 


515 


behind  the  age  and  internationally  discredited. 
Our  space  does  not  admit  of  more  than  a  few 
remarks  under  each  head  of  importance  in  any 
comprehensive  view  of  this  question. 

I.  Origin  of  the  deciTnal  system.  Our  fellow- 
subjects  in  Hindostan  were  the  precursors  of  the 
Arabians,  and  it  is  believed  also  of  the  Chinese, 
in  the  discovery  and  use  of  the  decimal  system 
of  notation.  Writers  of  authority  on  the  early 
history  of  mathematical  science  concur  in  re- 
marking that  the  Arabians,  who  were  the  real 
introducers  of  the  system  into  Europe,  borrowed 
it  from  the  Hindoos.  In  Arabian  arithmetical 
works  which  date  back  more  than  a  thousand 
years  the  decimal  system  is  called  the  Indian 
method  of  computation,  the  Hindasi,  or  Indian 
arithmetic. 

II.  Use  of  the  system  in  ancient  times.  So 
far  as  Europe  is  concerned  it  was  not  until  the 
close  of  the  18th  century  that  any  effective 
decimalisation  of  coin,  weight,  or  measure  took 
place.  In  fact  the  theory  itself  of  decimal 
fractions  was  unknown  until  nearly  the  end  of 
the  16  th  century.  Calculations  of  the  value 
of  annual  rents  or  of  capital  sums,  receivable 
for  a  certain  term  of  years  or  at  the  expiry  of 
a  given  time,  at  any  particular  rate  of  interest, 
or,  in  other  words,  the  ascertainment  of  their 
discounted  present  worth,  had  continued  to  be 
attended  with  so  much  complexity  that  the 
search  for  some  remedy  for  this  led  to  more 
easy  and  effectual  means  of  computing  such 
values  being  sought  by  Simon  Stevin  of  Bruges. 
This  illustrious  man  of  science  invented  the 
theory  of  decimal  fractions,  in  the  construction 
of  tables  showing  the  values  of  such  annuities 
and  periodical  payments  ;  and  with  far-seeing 
foresight  predicted  the  enormous  boon  his  new- 
found science  would  prove  to  mankind,  in 
practice  as  well  as  theory,  for  all  future  time. 
The  discovery  was  first  printed  in  Flemish  and 
in  French  some  three  years  after  the  tables. 
In  French  it  is  included  in  the  second,  but 
separately-paged,  part  of  his  duodecimo  volume 
on  arithmetic,  printed  at  the  press  of  Christophe 
Plantin,  at  Lej^den,  in  1585.  The  fame  and 
practical  utility  of  "Xa  Disme"  or  "  De 
thiende,"  as  Stevin  entitled  it,  echoed  through- 
out Europe.  In  no  country  was  it  better  wel- 
comed than  in  England,  or  received  earlier 
attention  by  way  of  translation  and  of  extension. 
In  this  treatise  it  was  suggested  that  not  only 
all  weights  and  measures  should  be  decimalised, 
but  money  also,  by  the  latter  being  struck  in 
future  in  various  countries  into  "commence- 
ments," Stevin's  term  for  units,  and  ther 
subdivided  into  "primes"  (tenths) ;  "secondes" 
(hundredths);  "tierces"  (thousandths);  and 
80  on.  This  was  tantamount,  so  far  as  England 
was  concerned,  to  taking  the  pound  sterling  as 
the  unit  or  commencement,  the  florin  or  two- 
shilling  piece  as  the  prim£  or  tenth  of  the  unit, 
the   10  mil  piece  or  cent  as   the  seconde  or 


hundredth  of  the  unit,  and  the  1  mil  piece  as 
the  tierce  or  thousandth  of  the  unit.  All  this 
is  practically  identical  with  the  pound  and  mil 
scheme,  so  well  known  to  the  British  parliament 
and  public  at  the  present  date. 

At  the  beginning  of  the  16th  century,  it  is 
well  evidenced  by  the  book  on  arithmetic  by 
Cuthbert  Tonstall,  bishop -elect  of  London, 
printed  in  1522  at  London  and  Paris,  that  not 
only  in  England  and  France  commercial  accounts 
were  kept  according  to  a  vigesimal  and  duo- 
decimal subdivision  of  pounds  and  livres  into 
twenty  shillings  or  sols,  and  of  shillings  and 
sols  into  twelve  pence  or  deniers,  but  that  such 
was  the  general  practice  amongst  the  merchants 
of  other  commercial  states  of  Europe.  And  so  it 
continued  in  France  until  the  era  of  the  great 
revolution.  But  that  from  that  time  until  now 
France  and  every  other  country,  except  England, 
should  have  one  by  one  altered  to  a  decimal 
system  is  the  most  undeniable  proof  that  the 
advantages  of  a  decimal  system  over  all  others 
must  have  made  themselves  felt  and  understood 
and  acted  upon  by  all  except  our  own  country. 

III.  The  decimal  system  in  France.  Although 
the  United  States  of  America  had  decimal  sub- 
divisions of  the  dollar  into  cents  and  half  cents, 
by  its  legislation  in  1786,  whilst  the  great 
metric  reform  in  the  coinage  of  France  was  not 
made  before  1791,  the  change  by  France  from 
her  old  vigesimal  and  duodecimal  division  of 
the  livre  tournois  or  old  franc  into  the  new 
decimal  and  metrical  franc  and  centimes,  has 
been  the  real  turning-point  whereby  all  other 
European  countries  except  our  own  have  been 
led  to  decimalise  their  coinage  either  wholly  or 
in  part.  Those  which,  like  the  several  nations 
comprised  in  the  Latin  monetary  union,  have 
adopted  the  French  coinage  system  in  its 
entirety,  have  of  course  the  full  advantage  of  a 
wholly  homogeneous  system  wherein  weights  of 
coin  and  all  other  weights  and  measures  have  a 
definite  mutual  scientific  relation  to  each  other. 
But  even  those  wdiich,  like  the  German  empire 
or  Russia,  have  merely  decimalised  a  not  strictly 
metric  unit,  as  for  instance  the  mark  or  rouble, 
have  derived  much  substantial  advantage  from 
the  substitution  of  decimal  for  other  systems. 

IV.  History  of  the  deci^nal  movement  in 
England.^  This  country  was  specially,  indeed 
exclusively,  invited  by  the  French  government 
at  the  very  inception  of  the  idea  in  1790  to 
send  commissioners  to  Paris  to  join  with  theirs 
in  the  metric  and  decimal  reform.  The  anta- 
gonism to  almost  anything  French  which  pre- 
vailed here  at  the  time  prevented  us  from 
joining  this  movement,  much  to  our  national 
loss,  as  it  has  retarded  for  more  than  a  century 
our  participation  in  its  advantages.  Let  us 
hope  that  the  twentieth  century,  upon  which 
we  have  now  entered,  will  not  find  our  execu- 
tive of  the  same  slow  and  halting  minds  as 
we  shall  presently  show  they  have  been  in  the 


516 


DECIMAL  SYSTEM 


last  century.  It  would  be  well,  with  the 
present  progress  of  education,  that  they  should 
approach  this  question  with  a  greater  disposi- 
tion towards  securing  uniformity  Avith  the 
more  scientific  theory  and  practice  of  other 
great  nations  which  have  long  experienced  the 
benefits  that  accrue  from  it.  The  matter  has 
in  the  meanwhile  been  before  the  English  com- 
mercial and  scientific  world,  and  the  House  of 
Commons,  over  and  over  again.  So  early  as  in 
1824,  when  the  anti-Gallican  spirit  had  begun 
to  tone  down,  Sir  J.  Wrottesley  (afterwards 
Lord  Wrottesley)  moved  in  the  House  of 
Commons  for  inquiry  into  the  possibility  of 
coining  the  subdivisions  of  the  pound  sterling 
decimally,  that  is,  into  double  shillings  or 
florins,  and  into  1000  farthings  or  mils,  instead 
of  960  farthings  as  heretofore.  The  govern- 
ment rejected  the  plan  as  inconvenient,  although 
they  admitted  its  advantages.  In  1841  royal 
commissioners  were  appointed  to  restore  the 
standards  of  weight  and  measure  destroyed  at 
the  fire  which  burned  down  the  houses  of  Parlia- 
ment. They  reported  unreservedly  in  favour 
of  a  decimal  subdivision  of  the  pound  sterling, 
and  upon  the  facility  of  interposing  between 
the  pound  and  the  shilling  a  new  coin  equivalent 
to  two  shillings,  and  of  considering  the  farthing, 
now  passing  as  the  -g-^th  part  of  a  pound,  as 
the  TTjVirth  part  of  that  unit,  of  establishing  a 
coin  of  value  equal  to  rh^^^  P^^t  of  the  pound, 
and  of  circulating,  besides  these  principal 
members  of  a  decimal  coinage,  other  coins 
bearing  a  simple  relation  to  them,  including 
coins  of  the  same  value  as  the  present  shilling 
and  sixpence.  In  1843  a  second  royal  com- 
mission, consisting  of  the  same  members  as  the 
former  one,  with  the  addition  of  a  few  more 
scientific  men,  was  appointed.  They  proposed 
that  the  recommendations  of  the  first  commis- 
sion should  be  carried  out.  The  government 
however  shelved  the  matter,  and  took  no  action 
whatever.  In  1847  Sir  John  Bowring  moved 
in  the  Commons  for  an  address  to  the  Crown 
in  favour  of  the  coinage  of  silver  pieces  of  ^ijj-th 
and  rhr^^  of  the  pound.  The  government  fell 
in  with  this  view,  but  in  a  tentative  manner 
only.  They  came  to  a  resolution,  and  acted 
upon  it,  that  the  first  step  in  the  decimal  system 
should  be  to  establish  a  coin  equal  to  tV^^  ^^  ^ 
pound.  This  was  the  origin  of  the  modern 
English  florin,  stamped  one  tenth  of  a  pound, 
the  mintage  of  which  was  immediately  com- 
menced and  has  continued  until  now.  In  1853 
the  commissioners  appointed  ten  years  before 
wrote  to  Mr.  Gladstone,  then  Chancellor  of  the 
Exchequer,  strongly  m-ging  the  government  to 
issue  coins  related  to  the  millesimal  subdivi- 
sion of  the  pound  sterling,  and  of  the  value  of 
TTJWth,  TArtli  and  TTyV-irth  of  a  pound  (diff-er- 
ing  little  from  the  farthing,  the  halfpenny,  and 
the  penny),  and  that  these  might  be  extensively 
used  by  the  public  without  present  inconveni- 


ence, while  the  inscription  of  their  values,  aa 
estimated  in  the  decimal  scale,  would  afibrd  the 
means  of  shortly  introducing  that  scale  through- 
out the  entire  system.  These  were  sensible 
suggestions  and  about  the  best  that  can  now 
be  offered.  They  admit,  however,  of  one  im- 
portant improvement  which  we  have  personally 
repeatedly  urged,  namely,  that  the  coinage  of 
the  new  farthing  (one  mil),  the  new  halfpenny 
(two  mils),  and  the  new  penny  (four  mils)  ; 
should  be  struck  in  nickel.  A  small-sized, 
unmistakably  distinct  series  of  new  coins  of 
that  metal  would  obviate  all  confusion  or  trouble 
with  the  concurrent  old  bronze  coins,  for  such 
time  at  least  as  the  latter  might  have  to  cir- 
culate with  the  new  nickel  coins  until  the 
bronze  coins  were  called  in.  A  transition  period 
would  have  to  be  faced,  and  it  would  practically 
decide  in  which  direction  the  reform  is  to  work, 
by  the  voice  of  the  public,  based  on  the  adjust- 
ment of  its  common  wants  in  which  every  one 
is  interested  on  both  sides  of  the  question,  as 
debtor  and  creditor,  consumer  and  producer,  of 
commodities  and  conveniences  measured  by^the 
penny  and  its  subdivisions.  The  great  question 
would  be  whether  penny  fares  and  postages  and 
the  price  of  any  article,  or  service,  now  measured 
by  the  penny  or  -^^-^^^  of  a  pound,  should  be 
measured  in  future  by  the  4  mil  piece  or  -rr^-o-th 
of  a  pound,  or  by  the  5  mil  piece  or  -ij-^th  of  a 
pound.  The  halving  and  quartering  of  the  5 
rail  piece  present  awkward  fractions,  but  the  4 
mil  piece  with  its  perfect  halving  and  quartering 
is  dynamically  equally  convenient  with  the 
present  penny,  and  it  has  the  positive  advantage 
of  tending  to  economy  by  expenditure  of  -^-^--j-th, 
instead  of  -s^i-g-^h  part  of  a  pound,  often  answering 
the  same  purpose,  and  preventing  waste  by  its 
more  minute  subdivisions.  Mr.  Gladstone,  in 
1863,  declined  to  act  upon  the  recommendations 
of  the  commissioners,  but  consented  to  a  select 
committee  on  decimal  coinage.  The  twenty- 
five  witnesses  examined  were  unanimous  in 
recommending  it,  and,  with  one  exception, 
supported  the  pound  and  mil  scheme.  The 
committee  itself  reported  that  having  well 
weighed  the  comparative  merits  of  the  existing 
system  of  coinage  and  the  decimal  system,  and 
the  obstacles  which  must  necessarily  be  met 
with  in  passing  from  one  to  the  other,  they 
desired  to  repeat  their  decided  opinion  of  the 
superior  advantages  of  the  decimal  system,  and 
to  record  their  conviction  that  the  obstacles 
referred  to  are  not  of  a  nature  to  create  any 
doubt  of  the  expediency  of  introducing  that 
system  as  soon  as  the  requisite  preparations 
shall  have  been  made  for  the  purpose  by  means 
of  cautious  but  decisive  action  on  the  part  of 
the  government.  Our  readers  should  note  this 
well-advised  verdict,  that  after  weighing  the 
advantages  and  disadvantages  as  between  the 
present  vigesimo-duodecimal  coinage  and  the 
proposed  decimal  coinage,  they  pronounce,  as 


DECIMAL  SYSTEM 


517 


we  take  it  any  man  of  practical  and  theoretical 
knowledge  would  do,  in  favour  of  the  decimal 
system,  so  that,  as  we  have  now  got  about  forty 
years  more  education  into  the  understandings 
of  our  people  than  when  the  commissioners  met 
in  1853,  it  may  be  taken  for  gi*anted  that  they 
were  right  in  their  view.  But  it  neither  pleased 
Mr.  Gladstone  nor  his  government,  and  the 
taking  of  any  action  by  them  was  the  last  thing 
thought  of  in  appointing  the  commission.  The 
public  had,  however,  even  in  1853,  its  attention 
so  roused  by  the  favourable  report  of  the  select 
committee  that  all  kinds  of  rival  plans  were 
submitted  for  discussion  at  meetings  of  societies 
and  in  printed  pamphlets.  There  was  so  mucli 
doctrinaire  attachment  still  existing  even  to  the 
last  thread  of  the  strange  web  of  our  singular 
coinage  system,  that  champions  set  forth  the 
existing  farthing,  halfpenny,  penny,  ten  pence, 
twenty  pence,  lour  shillings,  eight  shillings, 
crown,  ten  shillings,  even  the  long-abandoned 
guinea,  as  better  bases  than  the  pound  sterling 
in  a  decimal  system.  Even  the  American  dollar 
and  the  French  franc  had  their  advocates. 
The  farthing,  halfpenny,  penny,  and  the  ten- 
penny  schemes  were  perhaps  the  strongest- 
supported  of  these  opposition  methods,  but  all 
four  of  them  fail  by  disturbing  the  pound 
sterling  to  an  impracticable  extent,  as  they 
make  this  time-honoured  unit  change  into  one 
of  £1  :  0  :  10,  instead  of,  like  the  pound  and  unit 
scheme,  leaving  it  quite  undisturbed.  In 
1854  the  late  Sir  William  Brown  of  Liverpool, 
a  practical  commercial  man,  after  having  well 
considered  the  question  in  concert  with  the 
"Decimal  Association,"  of  which  he  was  chair- 
man, and  amongst  whose  members  were  the 
most  accomplished  men  of  the  day  in  trade  as 
well  as  in  science,  moved  three  resolutions  in 
the  House  of  Commons :  (1)  That  in  the 
opinion  of  the  House,  the  initiation  of  the 
decimal  system  by  the  issue  of  the  florin  has 
been  eminently  successful  and  satisfactory. 
This  was  carried  by  135  to  36.  (2)  That  a 
further  extension  of  the  system  will  be  of 
public  advantage.  Carried  unanimously.  (3) 
That  an  humble  address  be  presented  to  her 
Majesty  to  complete  the  decimal  scale  with 
the  pound  and  florin,  as  suggested  by  two 
commissions  and  a  committee  of  the  Commons, 
by  authorising  the  issue  of  silver  coins  to  re- 
present the  value  of  the  one-hundredth  part  of  a 
pound,  and  copper  coins  to  represent  the  one- 
thousandth  part  of  a  pound,  to  be  called  cents 
and  mils  respectively,  or  to  bear  such  other  names 
as  to  her  Majesty  may  seem  advisable.  This 
was  withdrawn,  as,  with  its  usual  tactics  on 
this  question,  and  on  the  then  alleged  interests 
of  the  poorer  classes,  and  other  such  plausible 
pretexts,  but  really  with  the  view  of  again 
strangling  the  reform,  the  government  agreed  to 
appoint  a  royal  commission,  which  consisted, 
in  the  result,   of  three  men  being  appointed 


commissioners  who  were  bitter  enemies  to  any 
change,  two  of  them.  Lord  Overstone  and  Mr. 
Hubbard  (afterwards  Lord  Addiugton)  being,  to 
our  certain  knowledge,  given  to  saying  that  they 
had  made  their  money,  as  bankers  and  merchants, 
under  the  old  system,  and  that  as  that  was  good 
in  the  past,  it  would  be  good  enough  in  the 
future.  The  inevitable  result  of  the  commis- 
sion, notwithstanding  they  had  the  testimony 
of  men  of  advanced  scientilic  intellect,  and  of 
high  commercial  reputation,  before  them  in 
favour  of  the  decimal  system  of  coinage,  and 
especially  of  the  pound  and  mil  scheme,  was 
imfavourable.  The  royal  commission  arrived 
at  twelve,  on  the  whole,  antagonistic  resolu- 
tions. It  was,  however,  admitted  that  the 
pound  and  mil  scheme  is  the  only  form  in 
which,  under  the  then  state  of  public  feeling 
in  this  country  on  the  question,  the  introduc- 
tion of  the  decimal  principle  into  our  coinage 
covdd  be  contemplated  with  any  reasonable 
probability  of  sufl&cient  support.  It  was  also 
alleged  that  there  appeared  to  be  no  approach 
to  unanimity  of  opinion,  on  the  question  of  the 
introduction  of  decimal  coinage,  in  the  com- 
mercial or  other  classes  of  the  community.  This 
is,  however,  only  the  usual  stereotyped  sort  of 
phrase  in  which  governmental  non  jJossiimus 
is  wont  to  be  wrapped  up.  But  if  we  are  to 
wait  until  the  plebs  move  as  one  body  in  such 
a  cause  we  may  indeed  sit  still  and  await  the 
Greek  kalends.  Light  must  be  diffused  upon 
it,  but  the  reform  is  practicable  over,  and  not 
by,  the  heads  of  the  million.  The  "Decimal 
Association,"  founded  to  fan  the  sacred  flame 
of  the  movement  in  its  favour,  faded  out  of 
view  by  the  removal  through  death  of  such 
active  friends  of  it  as  Sir  William  Brown, 
Professor  De  Morgan,  Sir  John  Bowiing,  etc. 
Then  on  its  dissolution  another  body,  with 
like  objects,  the  "Metric  Association,"  was 
founded,  and  although  neither  money  nor  pains 
were  spared  by  its  members,  of  whom  the 
writer  is  one  of  the  few  survivors,  in  educating 
the  public  to  the  advantages  of  the  decimal  and 
metric  systems,  by  meetings,  deputations, 
pamphlets,  and  conferences  of  all  kinds  with 
educational  and  scientific  notabilities,  still, 
that  association  also  came  to  an  end,  as  human 
nature  tires  at  last  in  the  thankless  task  of 
pushing' forward  reasoning  on  subjects  of  argu- 
ment that  are  necessarily,  in  the  order  of  things, 
abstract  and  theoretical  in  form,  although  they 
are,  in  this  particular  instance,  also  both  real 
and  practical  and  within  the  possible  range  of 
not  very  distant  adoption.  On  the  ruins  as  it 
were  of  the  first  two  associations,  a  third 
"Decimal  Association"  has  been  founded,  and 
has  succeeded  in  gaining  a  more  influential  co- 
operation from  the  chambers  of  commerce  than 
was  formerly  possible.  It  remains  to  be  seen 
if  it  can  attain  its  objects  better  than  its  pre- 
decessors, the  associations  of  the  ^mst  generation. 


518 


DECIME— DECKER 


It  has  this  advantage  over  them,  that  public 
education  of  the  masses  has  now  made  vast 
progress,  and  places  the  latter  in  a  far  better 
position  to  accept  and  welcome  a  decimal 
reform  than  when  some  of  us  laboured  in  .the 
same  cause  in  years  long  gone  by.  It  would 
seem,  notwithstanding,  that  although  individuals 
may  improve  in  their  grasp  of  the  question, 
ministers  do  not.  A  Palmerston,  a  Gladstone, 
or  a  Goschen  are  all  much  the  same  in  their 
desire  to  put  a  spoke  in  its  wheel,  which  may 
pass  on  the  burden  and  responsibility  of  the 
change  to  some  distant  future.  Having  attended 
all  the  deputations  in  a  long  series  of  years 
which  have  ventured  to  trouble  the  Treasury 
and  Board  of  Trade  with  the  expression  of 
wishes  for  present  action  upon  it,  we  can  say 
we  have  never  discerned  even  the  faintest 
glimmer  of  sympathy,  in  any  minister,  for  the 
movement.  If  it  were  felt  in  their  inner  non- 
official  conscience,  it  was  stifled  by  the  know- 
ledge that  not  only  would  the  cry  of  reform  to 
a  decimal  system,  either  of  coinage  or  of  weights 
and  measures,  or  of  all  of  them,  gain  them  no 
political  votes,  but  perchance  might  lose  them 
a  few,  from  the  feeling  that  it  would  cost  the 
masses  trouble  and  thought,  and  the  collecting 
and  spending  branches  of  the  executive  the 
same,  and  some  ingenuity  of  arrangement 
besides,  if  any  change  in  the  present  antiquated 
system  be  brought  about.  There  is  unfortun- 
ately an  excess  of  timorousness  here.  If  actual 
experience  be  a  guide,  the  example  of  a 
great  country  like  the  German  Empire  having 
decimalised  its  coins,  weights,  and  measures, 
within  quite  recent  years,  proves  that  a  nation, 
certainly  not  better  if  so  well  educated  as 
England  in  these  days,  can  carry  out  such  a 
reform  in  a  limited  space  of  time  without  any 
real  difficulty,  and  much  to  its  advantage  both 
in  the  multifarious  daily  dealings  of  home  life 
and  in  its  trade  intercourse  with  the  rest  of 
the  world.  f.  h. 

DECIME.  French  bronze  token  coin  of  the 
nominal  value  of  10  centimes,  or  one-tenth  of  a 
franc.  Weight  10  grammes  or  154*3  grains. 
English  value  -96  penny.  f.  e.  a. 

DECIMES.  In  France,  as  in  other  countries 
of  Europe,  the  clergy  long  contended  for  the 
privilege  of  exemption  from  taxes.  It  was  a 
favourite  and  frequent  assertion  that  they  owed 
nothing  to  the  state  but  their  prayers.  The 
kings  were  natiu-ally  unwilling  to  dispense  with 
the  contributions  of  the  wealthiest  corporation 
in  the  realm.  From  the  time  of  the  crusades 
the  clergy  were  frequently  induced  or  compelled 
to  make  occasional  grants  to  the  crown,  usually 
for  some  definite  object,  and  often  sanctioned 
by  the  pope.  It  was  not  till  the  middle  of 
the  16th  century  that  these  grants,  under  the 
pressure  of  Huguenot  schemes  of  confiscation, 
became  permanent  and  regular  taxes.  In  1561, 
by  the  contract  of  Poissy,  the  clergy  undertook 


to  pay  1,600,000  livres  a  year  for  six  years. 
This  contract  was  renewed  in  1567,  and  ulti- 
mately the  d^cimes,  as  they  were  called,  became 
a  regular  payment,  granted  every  ten  years  by 
a  grande  assemble  of  the  clergy,  attended  by 
four  deputies  from  each  province.  To  settle 
all  disputes  about  the  assessment  and  collection 
of  this  payment  a  bureau  ginircd  des  dicimes 
was  erected  in  1580  in  each  of  the  eight  metro- 
politan sees  of  France. 

Though  the  consent  of  the  clergy  to  the 
grant  of  taxes  became  more  formal  than  real, 
they  retained  the  assessment  and  collection  in 
their  own  hands.  Necker  goes  out  of  his  way 
to  praise  the  system  they  had  adopted  in  the 
18  th  century.  The  decimes  formed  a  direct  tax 
upon  all  clergy  except  the  charitable  orders. 
For  the  purposes  of  assessment  the  clergy  were 
divided  into  eight  classes,  in  which  attention 
was  paid  to  other  considerations  than  mere 
difierence  of  income.  Thus  the  first  class  was 
composed  of  the  non-resident  officials  such  as 
the  abbes  and  secular  priors  ;  whereas  the  arch- 
bishops and  bishops  only  came  in  the  second 
class.  The  other  classes  were  mainly  arranged 
according  to  income,  the  lowest  consisting  of 
cures  with  500  livres  a  year.  The  first  class 
paid  a  fourth  of  income,  the  second  a  sixth, 
and  so  on  down  to  the  last,  which  paid  only  a 
twenty-fourth.  But  the  arrangement  was  not 
strictly  carried  out,  and  the  collegiate  clergy 
succeeded  in  throwing  an  ever-increasing  burden 
upon  the  cures. 

The  dicimes  were  not  paid  by  the  clerge 
dtranger,  i.e.  the  clergy  in  the  provinces  added 
to  France  in  the  17  th  and  18  th  centuries.  In 
four  of  these  provinces  the  clergy  paid  the 
ordinary  secular  taxes,  and  in  the  rest  a  com- 
position for  them. 

[Necker,  De  V administration  des  finances  de  la 
France,  tome  ii. — Gasquet,  Precis  cUs  institutions 
jpolitiques  et  sociales  de  Vancienne  France.  ]    r.  l. 

DECKER,  Sir  Matthew  (1679-1749), 
merchant,  and  economic  and  trade  writer,  was 
born  in  Amsterdam  and  came  to  London  in 
1702.  His  business  life  was  eminently  suc- 
cessful, leading  the  way  to  great  wealth  and 
many  honours.  He  was  a  director  of  the  East 
India  Company,  member  of  parliament  for 
Bishops  Castle,  high  sheriff  for  Surrey  in  1729, 
and  was  created  a  baronet  20th  July  1716. 
His  estates  were  large,  and  he  is  reputed,  by 
mistake,  to  have  been  the  first  to  produce  pine- 
apples in  England,  one  of  which  was  served  up  at 
a  great  banquet  at  Richmond  when  he  enter- 
tained George  I. 

His  importance  as  a  writer  rests  on  two 
treatises : — 

1.  Serious  Considerations  on  the  several  high 
duties  which  the  Nation  in  general,  as  well  as 
Trade  in  particular,  labours  under,  etc.,  with  a 
proposal  for  preventing  the  removing  of  goods, 
discharging  the  trader  from  any  search,   and 


DECKER 


51d 


raising  all  the  Publick  Supplies  by  one  single 
tax.     1743  (name  affixed  to  7th  edition  1756). 

2.  An  Essay  on  the  Causes  of  the  Decline  of  the 
Foreign  Trade,  consequently  of  the  valv^  of  the 
lands  in  Britain,  and  on  the  means  to  restore 
both.     1744  (said  to  have  been  begun  1739). 

Decker's  authorship  of  the  last-named  treatise 
has  been  impugned  by  M'CuUoch  on  grounds 
both  external  and  internal.  On  the  authority 
of  Fauquier,  IFays  and  Means,  p.  56  (1756), 
he  assigns  it  to  Richardson.  He  further 
considers  the  dissimilarity  of  the  systems  respec- 
tively expounded  as  evincing  an  obvious  ditier- 
ence  in  authorship.  With  regard  to  external 
evidence  it  may  be  noticed  that  the  evidence 
rests  on  the  assertion  made  by  Fauquier  which 
is  followed  by  Chalmers  in  1782.  Against  this 
may  be  placed  Postlethwayte's  authority  {Great 
Britain's  True  System,  pp.  163-175);  a  letter 
from  Lord  Townshend  to  Tucker  speaking  of 
the  treatise  as  Decker's  in  1752  (Hist.  MSS. 
Com.  Report,  xi.  App.  4)  ;  and  lastly,  the  2nd 
edition  printed  in  Dublin  in  1749,  which  has 
Decker's  name  on  the  title  page  as  author. 

Turning  to  the  question  of  internal  evidence, 
it  is  necessary  to  point  out  that  there  is  very 
little  ground  for  M'Culloch's  observations  with 
regard  to  incongi'uity.  So  far,  indeed,  is  this 
from  being  a  remarkable  feature  that  the 
opposite  may  rather  be  said  to  be  the  case, 
the  scheme  expounded  in  the  second  treatise, 
of  general  licenses  for  consumption,  being  an 
expansion  of  the  scheme  of  particular  licenses 
for  the  consumption  of  tea,  treated  of  incident- 
ally in  the  tirst  {Serious  Considerations).  The 
tone  of  the  two  is  similar,  and  the  grievance 
complained  of  the  same. 

To  sum  up  the  matter  it  may  be  said  that 
the  internal  evidence  is  strongly  in  favour  of 
the  two  treatises  being  written  by  the  same 
man,  and  as  there  is  no  ground  for  supposing 
that  Decker  did  not  write  the  Serious  Considera- 
tions, etc.,  a  work  always  attributed  to  him, 
he  must  be  credited  with  the  authorship  of  the 
second  treatise  also,  unless  the  external  evidence 
be  directly  opposed.  So  far,  however,  is  this 
from  being  the  case  that  its  balance  is  largely 
in  his  favour. 

Kext,  we  may  turn  to  the  contents  of  these 
two  works.  The  first,  the  Serious  Considerations 
on  the  High  Duties,  etc.,  opens  with  long  com- 
ments on  the  inducements  offered  by  heavy 
custom  duties  to  smuggling  ("  running  "),  which 
will  take  place  in  defiance  of  all  attempts  at 
suppression.  Such  a  condition  of  things  bring 
about  two  chief  evils,  civil  disorder  and 
perverted  morality.  Decker  then  notices  the 
great  advantage  which  would  be  brought  about 
by  a  repeal  of  the  import  duty  on  tea,  and  the 
substitution  of  a  license  duty  on  households 
wishing  to  consume  tea.  But  the  great  scheme 
developed  in  this  treatise  consists  in  the 
replacement  of  all  custom  duties  by  an  excise 


on  houses.  This  he  would  impose  in  proportion 
to  the  rating,  with  total  exemption  for  the 
poor.  Its  chief  advantages  are,  he  urges,  (1) 
just  and  certain  incidence,  (2)  convenience  in 
time  of  collection,  (3)  economy.  He  thus 
forestalls  the  four  canons  of  taxation  enunciated 
by  Adam  Smith. 

The  second  work,  Decline  of  the  Foreign  Trade, 
is  in  every  way  more  important  than  the  fore- 
going. While  proceeding  on  the  same  lines 
and  aimed  at  the  same  evil,  it  has  a  wider  and 
more  liberal  scope.  It  seeks  to  attain  its  end 
by  measures  which  would  affect  the  conduct  of 
trade  throughout  the  whole  kingdom.  Although 
the  title  is  pessimistic  in  the  extreme,  it  must 
be  observed  that  the  drift  of  the  whole  treatise 
is  rather  to  show  the  possibility  of  improvement 
than  to  assert  any  absolute  decline.  In  other 
words  England  might  be  made  much  greater 
than  she  is.  At  the  outset  he  has  to  confront 
a  particular  aspect  of  the  question  dealt  with 
in  the  foregoing  work.  The  proposal  to  abolish 
customs  and  to  make  England  a  free  port  was 
met  by  the  objection  that  such  an  alteration 
would  destroy  the  value  of  the  land.  This  he 
desires  to  controvert,  and  in  order  to  do  so 
really  divides  his  work  into  three  parts.  The 
first  part  is  devoted  to  a  detailed  criticism  of 
the  fiscal  difficulties  under  which  England  is 
labouring ;  the  second  part  to  showing  the 
intricate  connection  between  the  trade  of  a 
country  and  the  value  of  the  land  ;  while  in 
the  third  part  Decker  displays  the  great  sources 
of  wealth  and  prosperity  possessed  by  England, 
and  shows  how  the  references  he  suggests  would 
permit  her  to  avail  herself  of  these,  her  natural 
strength.  Some  attention  must  be  paid  to 
each  of  the  foregoing. 

The  first  part  treats  of  the  causes  of  difficulty. 
These  are  (1)  present  taxes,  (2)  monopolies, 
(3)  ill-judged  laws,  (4)  heavy  burden  of  the 
national  debt.  It  may  be  noticed  that  he 
criticises  the  East  India  Company  with  great 
severity,  and  urges  very  strongly  the  repeal  of 
the  navigation  laws  which  have,  he  says,  evil 
effects  on  trade  ana  shipping  alike.  The  criti- 
cisms and  complaints  comprised  under  the  fore- 
going headings  group  themselves  round  two 
great  matters  of  giievance  : — 

(a)  The  undue  and  artificial  exaltation  of 
certaiuf  branches  of  trade. 

(b)  The  enhancement  of  the  price  of  labour. 
In  the  second  part.  Decker  claims  that  the 

value  of  the  land  is  diminished  by  what  foreign- 
ers take  from  others  instead  of  us,  by  what  the 
poor  have  given  them  instead  of  buying,  by  the 
scarcity  of  people  and  the  scarcity  of  money. 

The  third  part  opens  with  a  description  of 
the  natural  advantages  which  England  ])0ssesse3 
over  her  two  chief  rivals,  France  and  Holland. 
Decker  shows  how  the  uniqueness  of  her  position, 
the  wealth  of  minerals  she  possesses,  the  fertility 
of  her  soil,  the  moderation  of  her  government, 


520 


DECLARATION  OF  PARIS 


and  the  daring  of  her  sailors  combine  to  give 
her  a  position  which  no  other  nation  can  claim. 
He  then  proceeds  to  unfold  his  proposals. 
These  are  eleven  in  number  and  are  fiscal, 
economic,  and  political.  Of  course  on^  of 
them  is  the  general  repeal  of  import  duties  and 
another  the  abolition  of  bounties.  To  replace 
the  revenue  derived  fi'om  the  former  of  these 
he  advocates  a  tax  on  the  consumption  of  things 
which  are  not  strict  necessaries.  The  tax,  as 
he  develops  it,  partakes  of  the  nature  of  an 
income  tax  with  considerable  exemptions,  since 
indulgence  in  different  luxuries  is  supposed  to 
indicate  the  possession  of  a  certain  income. 
Thus  the  unambitious  drinker  of  tea  is  to  be 
taxed  on  an  income  of  £25,  the  owner  of  two 
coaches  and  six  on  one  of  £8000. 

Such  are  the  contents  of  these  two  works, 
which,  taken  together,  supply  a  body  of  practical 
economic  doctrine,  set  off  by  illustration  of 
fact,  of  such  weight  and  importance  that  their 
author  must  rank  as  one  of  the  most  important 
of  the  precursors  of  Adam  Smith. 

[Nat.  Diet  Biog.  and  auth.  cited,  especially 
ref.  in  Oent.  Mag.  The  works  have  been  very 
insufficiently  treated  of,  though  A.  Smith  refers  to 
"  the  well-known  proposal  of "  Decker  in  bk.  v. 
c.  2,  W.  of  ]Sr.'\  B.  c.  K.  G. 

DECLARATION  OF  PARIS.  The  name 
given  to  an  important  international  agi-eement 
which  was  signed  at  Paris  in  1856.  During 
the  maritime  wars  of  the  17th  and  18th 
centuries  England  had  acted  upon  the  rule 
that  it  was  lawful  to  capture  the  goods  of  an 
enemy  in  the  vessel  of  a  neutral,  while  the 
goods  of  a  neutral  in  the  vessel  of  an  enemy 
were  not  under  ordinary  circumstances  good 
prize  of  war.  During  the  same  period  it  had 
been  the  traditional  policy  of  France  to  con- 
fiscate neutral  goods  found  in  enemies'  ships. 
Thus,  when  in  1854  England  and  France 
entered  into  an  alliance  against  Russia,  there 
seemed  to  be  no  escape  for  neutral  commerce. 
The  prospect  caused  much  perturbation  among 
merchants,  and  a  considerable  amount  of  press- 
ure was  brought  to  bear  by  neutral  govern- 
ments upon  the  allied  powers.  Accordingly  in 
March  1854  Great  Britain  declared  that  "Her 
Majesty  will  waive  for  the  present  the  right  of 
seizing  enemy's  property  laden  on  board  a 
neutral  vessel,  unless  it  be  contraband  of  war." 
France  notified  at  the  same  time  that  she 
would  not  capture  neutral  goods  found  in  an 
enemy's  ship.  And  further,  both  states  an- 
nounced that  they  would  not  make  use  of 
privateers  (see  International  Law,  section 
on  Laws  of  War).  At  the  close  of  the  war  the 
powers  assembled  in  conference  at  Paris,  agreed 
upon  a  "Declaration  concerning  Maritime  Law," 
which  embodied  and  made  permanent  the  con- 
cessions granted  during  the  struggle.  The 
Declaration  was  adopted  on  16th  April  1856, 
by   Great   Britain,    France,    Austria,    Prussia, 


Russia,  Sardinia,  and  Turkey  ;  and  all  maritime 
states  except  the  United  States,  Spain,  Mexico, 
and  Venezuela  have  since  acceded  to  it.  Its 
enacting  clauses  run  as  follows  : 

1.  Privateering  is  and  remains  abolished. 

2.  The  neutral  flag  covers  enemy's  goods 
with  the  exception  of  contraband  of  war. 

3.  Neutral  goods,  with  the  exception  of 
contraband  of  war,  are  not  liable  to  capture 
under  an  enemy's  flag. 

4.  Blockades  in  order  to  be  binding  must  be 
efiective,  that  is  to  say,  maintained  by  a  force 
sufficient  really  to  prevent  access  to  the  coast 
of  the  enemy. 

It  was  further  agreed  that  no  signatory 
power  should  be  at  liberty  in  its  dealings  with 
non-signatory  powers  to  enter  into  arrangements 
contrary  to  the  foregoing  articles. 

The  Declaration  of  Paris  is  one  of  the  greatest 
triumphs  won  by  commercial  interests  over  the 
strict  rules  of  maritime  warfare.  Its  importance 
resides  in  its  first  three  articles.  The  fourth 
did  no  more  than  formulate  a  principle  that 
had  been  acknowledged  for  more  than  a  century. 
Taken  literally  it  requires  an  impossibility  ;  for 
no  blockade  (see  International  Law,  section 
on  Laws  of  Neutrality),  however  strict,  can 
always  "prevent  access  to  the  coast  of  the 
enemy."  But  the  explanations  given  by  states- 
men at  the  time  and  afterwards  made  it  clear 
that  the  words  were  meant  to  be  understood  in 
a  reasonable  sense  as  merely  prohibitory  of 
ineffective  or  "paper"  blockades  (Dana's  note 
233  to  Wheaton's  International  Law).  The 
first  article  struck  at  a  most  obj  ectionable  practice. 
The  current  of  opinion  had  long  been  runniag 
strongly  against  the  use  of  privateers.  Nelson 
had  declared  that  they  were  only  one  degree 
removed  from  pirates.  It  may  be  hoped  that 
their  prohibition  by  the  Declaration  has  per- 
manently banished  them  from  civilised  warfare. 
But  the  new  device  of  a  volunteer  navy  bears 
some  resemblance  to  ancient  privateering.  Dur- 
ing the  Franco-German  War  of  1870-71,  the 
Prussian  government  invited  private  shipowners 
to  fit  out  their  vessels  for  attacks  upon  French 
men-of-war,  and  offered  temporary  commissions 
to  the  officers  of  such  ships.  The  project  was 
never  carried  into  effect.  France  denounced 
it  as  a  violation  of  the  Declaration  of  Paris  ; 
and  publicists  and  lawyers  have  differed  widely 
as  to  its  admissibility.  Its  legality  must 
depend  upon  the  nature  and  degree  of  the  con- 
trol exercised  over  the  volunteer  cruisers  by 
the  naval  authorities  of  the  state  to  which  they 
belong  (Hall,  International  Law,  part  iii. 
ch.  vii.)  But  there  can  be  no  valid  reason 
for  questioning  the  position  of  vessels  bought 
by  private  persons  and  handed  over  to  the 
government  as  an  addition  to  the  fleet,  or  of 
merchant  ships  built  under  an  agreement  that 
they  may  be  taken  by  the  government  and  fitted 
out  as  commissioned  cruisers  in  the  event  of  war. 


DECLARATION  OF  PARIS— DECLARED  AND  REAL  VALUES         521 


The  second  article  of  the  Declaration  has 
provoked  an  enormous  amount  of  controversy. 
Taken  along  with  the  third  it  amounts  to  a 
new  departure  in  the  law  of  maritime  capture. 
Up  to  1856  the  great  naval  powers  had  been 
divided  between  the  old  principle  that  the 
liability  of  goods  to  capture  should  be  deter- 
mined by  the  character  of  their  owner,  and  the 
more  modern  principle,  introduced  by  the 
Dutch  in  the  days  Avhen  they  were  the  great 
carriers  of  the  world's  merchandise,  that  the 
character  of  the  ship  in  which  the  goods  were 
laden  should  settle  their  fate.  The  plenipoten- 
tiaries assembled  at  Paris  in  1856  combined  the 
two  principles  and  adopted  that  application  of 
each  which  was  most  lenient  to  commerce.  A 
great  outcry  was  raised  in  this  country  because 
the  government  accepted  the  rule  "Free  ships, 
free  goods"  (see  Hansard,  vol.  cxlii.)  Many 
of  our  leading  statesmen,  among  them  the  late 
Earl  Derby,  the  late  Earl  Russell,  and  the  late 
Earl  of  Beaconsfield,  expressed  opinions  hostile 
to  this  part  of  the  Declaration  ;  and  a  popular 
agitation  against  it  was  maintained  with  great 
vigour  by  the  late  ]\Ir.  David  Urquhart.  On 
the  other  hand  it  was  supported  by  such  high 
authorities  as  the  late  Lord  Palmerston,  the 
late  Earl  of  Clarendon,  and  Mr.  Gladstone. 
The  truth  seems  to  i)e  that,  while  Great  Britain 
remains  neutral,  her  commerce,  and  especially 
her 'carrying  trade,  is  favourably  affected  by 
the  Declaration,  but,  should  she  be  engaged  in  a 
great  maritime  war,  the  enormous  volume  of  her 
exports  and  imports  would  offer  a  most  vulner- 
able mark  for  the  attack  of  the  swift  cruisers  of 
the  enemy,  whose  trade  would  seek  safety  under 
neutral  flags.  This  being  the  case,  it  seems 
worthy  of  consideration  whether  we  should  not 
go  a  step  farther,  and  agree  to  the  exemption 
of  all  private  property  from  maritime  capture, 
unless  it  is  contraband  of  war  or  destined  for  a 
blockaded  port  (Lawi-ence,  Essays  on  some  Dis- 
puted Questions  in  Modern  International  Law, 
vii.) 

The  Declaration  of  Paris  is  practically  irre- 
vocable. Commercial  interests  are  much  more 
powerful  now  than  they  were  in  1856  ;  and  the 
pressure  they  can  bring  to  bear  upon  govern- 
ments is  amply  sufficient  to  prevent  a  with- 
drawal of  the  privileges  then  gained.  Strictly 
speaking  the  Declaration  is  not  binding  on  the 
powers  which  have  declined  to  sign  it.  But 
those  of  them  who  have  been  engaged  in  war 
since  1856  have. invariably  observed  its  rules, 
Spain  and  Mexico  have  signified  their  approval 
of  the  second,  third,  and  fourth  articles.  The 
United  States  would  have  signed  the  Declara- 
tion, when  invited  to  do  so  by  France  immedi- 
ately after  the  Conference  of  Paris,  had  the 
first  article  been  extended  so  as  to  forbid  the 
capture  of  private  property  at  sea  unless  it  were 
contraband.  The  opposition  of  the  British 
government  prevented  the  acceptance  of  this 


amendment ;  and  consequently  the  great  Ameri- 
can republic  held  aloof.  But  in  its  civil  war 
of  1861-65  every  article  was  acted  upon,  in- 
cluding the  first.  Thus  there  is  an  uninter- 
rupted prescription  of  thirty-six  years  in  favoui 
of  the  Declaration.  Every  year  that  passes 
without  a  breach  of  the  rules  gives  them  an 
authority  derived  from  usage  and  precedent. 
Should  they  remain  unbroken  much  longer,  they 
will  become  part  and  parcel  of  the  corpus  of 
International  Law. 

[The  following  books  may  be  consulted :  Annual 
Register  for  1856. — Phillimore,  International  Law, 
vol.  iii.  3rd  ed.  (1879). — Wheaton,  International 
Law,  Dana's  edition,  notes  173  and  223. — Hal- 
leck,  International  Law,  Baker's  edition,  ch.  xviii. 
— Hall,  International  Law,  pt.  iv.  ch.  vii.  3rd 
ed.  (1890). — Wheaton,  Digest  of  the  International 
Law  of  the  United  States,  vol.  iii.  §§  342  and 
383-385. — Calvo,  Le  Droit  International,  vol.  iii. 
3d  ed.  (1880).]  t.  j.  l. 

DECLARATION  OF  WAR.  Formerly  it 
was  the  practice  to  make  a  formal  declaration 
of  war  either  by  letter  of  defiance  or  by  heralds. 
The  modern  custom  is  to  issue  a  manifesto, 
but  any  act  of  hostility  will  mark  the  begin- 
ning of  a  state  of  war.  The  property  of  enemy 
subjects  residing  in  the  belligerent  country  is 
not  liable  to  seizure,  and  is  protected  in  many 
cases  by  treaties.  Existing  contracts  between 
subjects  of  the  two  states  are  either  suspended 
or  extinguished  according  to  their  nature,  whilst 
all  fresh  trading  or  other  intercourse,  and  every 
species  of  private  contract  is  forbidden. 

[W.  E.  Hall,  International  Law,  Oxford,  1890.] 

J.  B.  c.  M. 

DECLARED  AND  REAL  VALUES.  For 
the  purpose  of  compiling  the  trade  statistics 
periodically  presented  to  parliament  it  is  re- 
quired of  every  importer  or  exporter  of  goods 
that  an  entry  should  be  made  at  the  custom- 
house of  the  port  of  arrival  or  departure,  con- 
taining amongst  other  particulars  those  of 
quantity  and  value.  These  values  are  now 
termed  "declared"  in  distinction  from  former 
values  denoted  as  "computed  real"  and 
"oflBicial."  The  earlier  form  was  the  latter  of 
these  three,  and  so  styled  because  there  were 
"fixed  official  rates"  founded  on  the  ascertained 
prices  which  all  known  articles  bore  in  the  year 
1694,  with  the  addition  of  such  new  articles  as 
sprang  up  afterwards  at  the  prices  they  each 
bore  in  the  first  year  of  their  introduction. 
This  method  was  discarded  from  the  "trade" 
accounts  in  1854,  but  continued  to  be  used  in 
the  "  finance  "  accounts  until  1870,  when  it  was 
dropped  altogether. 

In  1854  the  import  values  assumed  a  new 
aspect,  and  became  known  as  "computed  real." 
The  average  prices  which  had  prevailed  during 
each  month  were  obtained  from  experts,  and 
applied  to  the  quantities  returned  by  the  cus- 
toms officers  as  having  been  brought  to  account 


522      DECLARED  AND  REAL  VALUES— DECREE  OF  REGISTRATION 


during  the  past  month.  This  system  gave 
place  in  1871  to  one  by  which  the  importer 
was  required  on  the  first  entry  of  his  goods — 
which  took  place  before  they  left  the  ship — to 
state  the  quantity,  so  far  as  that  could  be  esti- 
mated by  weight  or  measurement,  and  the 
value  also  of  each  parcel  as  it  arrived.  This  is 
termed  the  "declared  value,"  and  is  that  shown 
in  the  monthly  and  annual  statements  issued 
from  the  board  of  trade  and  custom-house. 

For  the  exports  the  "official"  values  were 
prepared  in  like  manner  up  to  1870,  but  for 
other  reasons  merchants  were  at  a  much  earlier 
period  required  to  declare  the  value  of  their 
respective  shipments,  and  thus  the  "declared 
value,"  obtained  as  in  the  year  1798,  has  con- 
tinued up  to  the  present  time. 

Since  1870  the  published  values  rest  solely 
upon  the  authority  of  the  persons  by  whom 
the  several  entries  are  passed  ;  subject  to  such 
control  as  can  be  exercised  by  the  customs 
authorities  from  a  close  inspection  of  such 
imports  as,  being  liable  to  duty,  are  weighed 
or  measured,  and  a  cursory  examination  of 
such  as  are  free  from  any  charge  in  the  shape 
of  duty.  There  is  also  the  power  which  the 
clerks  engaged  in  the  compilation  of  statistics 
possess  of  calling  upon  the  importers  to  prove 
the  accuracy  of  their  statements  by  the  pro- 
duction of  the  invoices  or  other  documents  in 
their  possession.  For  the  exports  of  British 
goods  the  values  are  also  obtained  from  the 
declarations  of  the  shippers,  rendered  some  few 
days  after  the  vessels  in  which  they  are  ex- 
ported have  sailed. 

For  the  purpose  of  comparison  between  recent 
and  earlier  years  it  is  necessary  to  bear  in  mind 
the  reversal  of  previous  rules  as  to  the  period 
when  the  appraisement  took  place.  It  used, 
for  the  imports,  to  be  after  the  goods  had  been 
landed  and  been  subjected  generally  to  the  test 
of  the  markets  in  which  they  were  bought  and 
sold.  It  is  now,  before  they  have  been  even 
seen  by  the  owners  or  consignees.  For  the 
exports  the  valuation  used  to  be  prior  to  their 
being  sent  for  shipment,  and  when  the  quan- 
tity that  could  be  received  on  board  was  uncer- 
tain. Now  the  declaration  is  made  after  they 
are  beyond  the  reach  of  inspection,  but  when 
the  shipper  is  presumed  to  have  full  knowledge 
of  their  cost.  Thus  the  values  given  for  imports 
are  now  estimates  made  by  those  through  whose 
hands  they  pass,  of  what  they  ought  to  be 
worth.  Those  for  the  exports  should  be  the 
actual  amounts  for  which  they  have  been  ob- 
tained. Formerly,  that  is  since  the  abrogation 
of  "official  values,"  that  for  the  imports  was 
ascertained  after  many  or  most  of  them  had 
been  dealt  with  ;  for  the  exports  at  a  time  when 
the  shipper  to  a  great  extent  knew  only  the 
orders  he  had  given,  but  not  the  extent  to  which 
they  had  been  executed. 

Another  point  which  needs  to  be  borne  in 


mind  in  the  institution  of  a  comparison  between 
imports  and  exports  is,  that  the  moment  oi 
valuation  is  that  of  arrival  in  the  one  case,  and 
departure  in  the  other.  Thus  the  valuations  for 
imports  includes  all  the  charges  which  they  have 
incurred  for  transit  from  the  place  of  production, 
that  for  the  exports  excludes  everything  accru- 
ing after  they  leave  the  place  of  shipment. 

It  is  obvious  that  in  both  cases  the  accurac}' 
of  the  valuation  depends  upon  the  extent  to 
which  the  facts  are  known  to  the  person  by 
whom  the  customs  entry  is  made,  and  the  care 
he  bestows  upon  the  estimate  or  record  which 
he  makes  ;  and  in  neither  is  there  any  reason 
why  these  should  not  be  as  close  an  approxima- 
tion to  the  truth  as  was  secured  at  any  formei 
time,  or  in  the  records  of  other  countries.  In 
the  absence  of  any  motive  for  wilful  error  it  is 
not  probable  that  they  are  intentionally  mis- 
stated. The  chief  danger  lies  in  the  fact  that 
the  entry  may  be  made  upon  insufficient  infor- 
mation, and  there  is  a  tendency  to  adopt  aver- 
age prices  without  due  regard  to  the  fluctuations 
which  are  continually  taking  place.  To  procure 
absolute  accuracy  would  entail  such  a  minute 
inspection  and  calculation  as  would  tend  much 
to  impede  trade  transactions  and  be  the  occasion 
of  great  expense.  The  chief  security  consists 
in  the  multitude  of  small  entries  which  go  to 
make  up  the  large  totals,  and  in  the  many 
agents,  acting  independently  of  each  other,  by 
whom  the  particulars  are  gathered.  Thus  in- 
dividual errors  may  be  supposed  to  correct 
each  other.  Confidence  may  be  reposed  in  the 
results  obtained,  at  least  for  comparison  of 
one  period  with  another,  if  not  for  the  perfect 
accuracy  of  each  especial  year  or  month.  Al- 
though compiled  from  difi'erent  sources  and 
varying  methods,  there  should  be  no  breach  of 
continuity  in  the  records  of  the  "computed 
real"  and  the  "declared"  values,  but  no  fair 
comparison  can  be  made  in  either  case  between 
the  present  records  and  those  formerly  known 
as  "official." 

[For  fuller  information  on  this  subject  reference 
may  be  made  to  "  Eeport  of  Inspector- General  of 
Imports  and  Exports  in  1854," — "  Keports  of 
Commissioners  of  Customs." — Bourne,  S.,  "Offi- 
cial Trade  and  Navigation  Statistics,"  in  the 
Stat  Society's  Journal  for  1872,  p.  196,  and 
"  Trade,  Population,  and  Food, "  1880. —Gifi"en,  R., 
Essays  in  Finance  (2nd  series). — M'Culloch,  J.  K, 
Commercial  Dictionary,  articles  ' '  Imports  and 
Exports,"  "Balance  of  Trade." — Newmarch,  W., 
"  Progress  of  Foreign  Trade  of  United  Kingdom, 
1856-77,"  in  Stat.  Society's  Journal  for  1878, 
p.  187. — Parliamentary  Paper,  No.  405,  1881, 
"Trade  with  France  from  1861  to  1879."— "R. 
Giffen's  Reports  upon  changes  in  the  prices  of 
Imports  and  Exports,"  1879,  et  seq.'\         8.  Bo. 

DECREASING  RETURNS.  See  Diminish- 
ing Returns. 

DECREE  OF  REGISTRATION  (Scot.)  A 
Scotch  contract   usually  contains  a  clause  of 


DEDUCTIVE  METHOD 


523 


consent  to  registration  for  preservation  and 
execution  ;  this  may  be  followed  by  registra- 
tion in  the  court  books,  and  an  extract  of  the 
deed  from  the  court  books  is  equivalent  to 
an  extracted  judgment  of  the  court,  not  in 
foro,  but  enabling  summary  execution  to  be 
obtained,  unless  an  action  of  suspension  be 
raised  to  challenge  the  validity  of  the  deed 
r6£ristGrG(i  A  d 

DEDUCTIVE  METHOD.  By  the  deductive 
method  is  meant  a  method  of  reasoning  which 
begins  by  investigating  the  principal  forces 
determining  a  given  class  of  phenomena,  and 
the  general  laws  in  accordance  with  which 
these  forces  operate,  and  then  goes  on  to  trace 
the  consequences  which  ensue  from  their  action 
and  interaction  under  specified  conditions.  It 
proceeds,  theiefore,  from  the  more  general  to 
the  less  general.  The  conclusions  reached  may 
indeed  possess  a  high  degree  of  generality 
considered  in  their  relation  to  actual  concrete 
facts  ;  but  they  are  particular,  relatively  to  the 
very  wide  generalisations  which  constitute  the 
premisses. 

Recourse  is  had  to  the  deductive  method  in 
cases  where  the  method  of  direct  induction  is 
rendered  specially  fallible  by  reason  of  the 
great  complexity  of  the  phenomena  under  in- 
vestigation. There  are,  therefore,  prima  facie 
grounds  for  availing  ourselves  of  its  aid,  if 
possible,  in  the  social  sciences  ;  since,  as  Mill 
observes,  "of  all  effects,  none  depend  on  so 
great  a  complication  of  causes  as  social  phe- 
nomena" {Logic,  bk.  vi.  ch.  7,  §  1).  If  we 
can  effect  a  mental  isolation  of  the  principal 
forces  in  operation,  then  the  problems  to  be 
solved  will  be  simplified,  and  it  may  be  possible 
to  deal  separately  with  their  different  aspects. 
The  deductive  method  must  not,  however,  be 
identified  with  pure  deduction.  In  its  complete 
form  it  is  found  to  consist  of  three  steps. 
There  is,  first,  the  selection  of  premisses  ; 
secondly,  the  deduction  of  consequences  ;  and 
thirdly,  the  verification  of  consequences  by 
comparison  with  what  is  observed  actually  to 
occur.  The  final  step  has  for  its  object  not 
merely  to  test  the  accuracy  of  the  deductive 
reasoning  in  itself,  but  also  to  determine  the 
relevancy  of  the  premisses  to  the  actual  pheno- 
mena upon  which  the  reasoning  is  intended 
to  throw  light. 

It  is  at  once  clear  that  if  the  deductive 
method  is  to  be  of  practical  utility  in  any  science, 
it  must  start  from  a  basis  of  observation. 
Thus  in  political  economy  its  premisses  must 
not  be  chosen  arbitrarily,  but  must  correspond 
broadly  with  the  general  characteristics  actually 
displayed  by  men  in  their  economic  dealings 
with  one  another,  and  with  the  circumstances 
in  which  they  are  placed.  The  premisses 
are,  therefore,  partly  psychological,  and  partly 
obtained  by  an  investigation  of  the  physical 
and  social  environment  in  which  men's  economic 


activities  are  exercised.  It  is  not  necessary, 
however,  that  the  propositions  assumed  in 
regard  to  men's  motives  or  their  material  and 
social  surroundings  should  be  true  universally 
or  without  qualification.  To  attempt  any 
exact  correspondence  with  what  has  been  called 
the  "full  empirical  actuality"  would  be  to 
sacrifice  generality,  and  to  involve  ourselves 
afresh  in  those  complexities  of  actual  economic 
life  from  which  it  is  the  special  object  of  the 
deductive  method  temporarily  to  escape.  The 
requirements  are,  first,  that  the  motives  taken 
into  account  shall  be  exceptionally  powerful  in 
the  economic  sphere,  and  so  far  uniform  in  their 
operation  that  the  kind  of  conduct  deduced  from 
them  may  correspond  with  what  actually  happens 
in  the  great  majority  of  cases  ;  and,  secondly, 
that  the  circumstances  under  which  the  motives 
are  supposed  to  operate  shall  be  of  a  repre- 
sentative character,  either  as  regards  economic 
life  in  general,  or,  at  any  rate,  as  regards  a 
special  aspect  of  it  over  a  given  range. 

It  follows  tliat  the  deductive  method  involves 
a  process  of  abstraction.  A  condition  of  affairs 
is  assumed  in  which  the  operation  of  "disturb- 
ing causes  " — such  as  never  fail  to  be  present  in 
actual  experience — is  eliminated.  The  extent 
of  the  abstraction  admits  of  all  degrees,  and 
what  are  to  be  regarded  as  ' '  disturbing  causes  " 
will  vary  in  different  instances.  In  the  most 
abstract  reasonings  of  economics,  attention  is 
limited  to  general  principles  which  are  entirely, 
or  almost  entirely,  independent  of  social  in- 
stitutions and  economic  habits,  as,  for  exam|)le, 
the  law  of  diminishing  utility — namely,  that 
the  additional  satisfaction  which  a  person  derives 
from  an  additional  increment  of  any  commodity 
diminishes  as  the  stock  of  the  commodity  already 
in  his  possession  increases.  In  other  cases  ac- 
count may  be  taken  of  quite  special  conditions, 
such  as  a  monopoly  conferred  by  government, 
or  temporarily  established  by  effective  combina- 
tion. The  abstraction  frequently  takes  the 
form  of  assuming  a  stationary  condition  of 
affairs,  in  which  the  natural  progress  of  econ- 
omic life,  with  its  multiplicity  of  changes  and 
infinitely  complex  interactions,  is  supposed  to 
be  in  certain  respects  arrested,  so  that  some 
particular  agency  may  have  free  play  to  work 
out  its  own  proper  effects  unimpeded  and  under 
known  conditions.  In  order  to  express  this 
assumption,  deductive  political  economy  is  some- 
times said  to  study  society  statically,  whereas 
actual  society  is  dynamic.  The  analogy  implied 
in  the  use  of  these  terms  is  suggestive  ;  but  it 
must  not  be  pushed  too  far. 

Attempts  have  sometimes  been  made  defini- 
tively to  enumerate  the  premisses  of  deductive 
political  economy  ;  and  there  are  no  doubt  a 
few  premisses — such  as  the  law  of  diminishing 
utility,  already  referred  to,  and  the  hypothesis 
of  free  and  effective  competition — which  occupy 
a  central  position  in  economic  theory.     Any 


624 


DEDUCTIVE  METHOD 


exhaustive  enumeration  is,  however,  impossible  ; 
since,  in  order  to  suit  fresh  cases,  old  premisses 
may  at  any  time  be  modified  and  new  ones 
introduced.  And  it  is  important  not  to  lose 
sight  of  the  fact  that  in  having  recourse  to  the 
deductive  method  the  economist  is  not  rigidly 
tied  down  and  limited  in  his  choice  of  assump- 
tions. Even  Cairnes,  who  formulates  somewhat 
narrowly  what  he  regards  as  the  ultimate  and 
fundamental  principles  of  economic  reasoning, 
also  recognises  subordinate  causes  influencing 
human  conduct  in  the  pursuit  of  wealth,  which 
may  at  a  later  stage  be  incorporated  amongst 
the  premisses  of  the  science. 

"When  recourse  is  had  to  the  deductive  method, 
the  application  of  conclusions  to  actual  economic 
phenomena  is  of  course  dependent  upon  the 
realisation  of  the  conditions  assumed  in  the 
premisses.  The  conclusions,  moreover,  are  al- 
most always  subject  to  the  proviso  that  the 
causes  specially  under  consideration  shall  be 
allowed  to  work  out  their  effects  undisturbed  ; 
and  they  must  accordingly  be  regarded,  not  as 
positive  predictions  of  what  will  be  found  to 
occur  in  every  individual  instance,  but  as  state- 
ments of  tendencies  which  are  not  unlikely  to 
require  a  wide  range  of  experience  and  the  lapse 
of  a  considerable  interval  of  time  in  order  that 
their  operation  may  be  clearly  manifested.  For 
these  reasons  deductive  political  economy  is  said 
to  be  a  hypothetical  science  ;  but  this  must  not 
be  considered  to  imply  unreality  or  want  of 
correspondence  with  the  actual  order  of  economic 
phenomena.  For  so  long  as  the  premisses  are 
not  chosen  arbitrarily,  but  take  account  of  the 
most  uniform  and  powerful  of  the  forces  in 
operation,  the  conclusions  reached  will  be  of 
fundamental  importance  from  the  practical,  no 
less  than  from  the  scientific,  point  of  view. 
The  description  "hypothetical"  should,  there- 
fore, not  be  applied  to  political  economy  with 
any  disparaging  implication.  In  the  same  sense 
in  which  it  is  applicable  to  political  economy, 
it  is  also  applicable  to  such  sciences  as  mechanics 
and  astronomy. 

In  order  to  avoid  misunderstanding  and  error 
in  the  use  of  the  deductive  method,  it  is  neces- 
sary that  the  assumptions  which  constitute  the 
basis  of  the  argument  should  be  clearly  enunci- 
ated ;  and,  further,  that  the  conclusions  reached 
should  not  be  applied  to  any  given  state  of 
society  without  a  special  investigation  of  the 
relevancy  of  the  assumptions  to  the  actual  con- 
dition of  affairs.  It  has  been  already  pointed 
out  that  deductive  political  economy  obtains  its 
ultimate  premisses  from  observation.  But  it 
follows  from  what  has  just  been  said  that  this 
is  not  the  only  function  fulfilled  by  observation 
in  the  employment  of  the  deductive  method. 
Observation  also  determines  the  limits  within 
which  given  assumptions  are  approximately 
realised,  and  indicates  the  kind  of  allowance 
that  should  be  made  for  the  effects  of  "disturb- 


ing causes."  It,  moreover,  shows  in  what 
directions  premisses  must  be  modified  in  order 
that  they  may  be  adapted  to  special  economic 
conditions  ;  and,  finally,  it  serves  to  illustrate, 
test,  and  confirm  the  inferences  that  have  been 
deductively  obtained.  In  the  process  of  verifi- 
cation, however,  it  is  always  necessary  to  bear 
in  mind  the  special  character  of  these  inferences. 
In  so  far  as  they  relate  only  to  what  will  happen 
in  the  long  run,  time  must  be  allowed  for  effects 
fairly  to  manifest  themselves  ;  and  in  any  case 
it  must  be  remembered  that  a  general  tendency 
cannot  be  either  established  or  refuted  by  an 
individual  instance. 

In  the  application  of  the  deductive  method 
to  economic  problems  many  recent  economists 
have  availed  themselves  of  the  aid  afforded  by 
diagrams  and  mathematical  symbols  ;  and  it 
may  be  observed  in  passing  that  when  this  ia 
the  case  the  precautions  essential  to  the  right 
use  of  the  method  are  less  likely  to  be  over- 
looked. For  the  employment  of  mathematical 
methods  necessitates  a  full  analysis  and  clear 
statement  of  the  premisses  upon  which  the 
reasoning  is  based  ;  and  no  one  is  likely  to 
imagine  that  the  results  reached  can  be  applied 
offhand  to  the  solution  of  practical  problems. 
(See  Diagrams  ;  Graphical  Method  ;  Mathe- 
matical Method.) 

The  deductive  method  has  been  the  tradi- 
tional method  of  English  economics,  and  the 
part  which  it  plays  in  building  up  economic 
doctrines  has  been  specially  emphasised  by  Mill 
in  his  Unsettled  Questions  of  Political  Economy 
and  in  his  Logic,  and  by  Cairnes  in  his  Logical 
Method  of  Political  Economy.  Upon  this  point 
Jevons  also  expresses  his  agreement  with  them. 
"  I  think,"  he  says,  "that  John  Stuart  MiU  ia 
substantially  correct  in  considering  our  science 
to  be  a  case  of  what  he  calls  the  physical  or 
concrete  deductive  method  ;  he  considers  that 
we  may  start  from  some  obvious  psychological 
law  as,  for  instance,  that  a  greater  gain  is  pre- 
ferred to  a  smaller  one,  and  we  may  then  reason 
downwards,  and  predict  the  phenomena  which 
wiU  be  produced  in  society  by  such  a  law.  The 
causes  in  action  in  any  community  are,  indeed, 
so  complicated  that  we  shall  seldom  be  able  to 
discover  the  undisturbed  effects  of  any  one  law, 
but,  so  far  as  we  can  analyse  the  statistical 
phenomena  observed,  we  obtain  a  verification 
of  our  reasoning.  This  view  of  the  matter  is 
almost  identical  with  that  adopted  by  the  late 
Professor  Cairnes"  (^Theory  of  Political  Economy, 
1879,  p.  18). 

In  opposition  to  this  view,  writers  belonging 
to  the  more  advanced  wing  of  the  "historical 
school," — for  example,  Knies  and  Schmoller  in 
Germany,  and  Cliffe  Leslie  and  Ingram  in 
England, — either  reject  altogether  the  use  of  the 
deductive  method  in  economics,  or  hold  that 
the  part  which  it  has  to  play  is  unimportant 
and  soon  exhausted.     Thus  .amongst  the  pre- 


DEDUCTIVE  METHOD 


525 


railing  errors  of  economists,  Professor  Ingram 
includes  "that  of  exaggerating  immensely  the 
ofl&ce  of  deduction  in  their  investigations." 
"We  can,"  he  allows,  "sometimes  follow  the 
method  which  Mill  calls  the  d  priori  deductive, 
that  is,  we  can,  from  what  we  know  of  the 
nature  of  man  and  the  laws  of  the  external 
world,  see  beforehand  what  social  phenomena 
will  result  from  their  joint  action  ;  but  thougli 
the  economists  of  the  so-called  orthodox  school 
recognise  no  other  method,  we  cannot  really 
proceed  far  in  this  way,  which  is  available  only 
in  simple  cases."  Hence  it  is  argued  that 
"the  d  priori  deductive  method  should  be 
changed  for  the  historical "  {Statistical  Journal, 
1878,  pp.  617-626).  SimQarly,  Clitfe  Leslie 
lays  it  down  that  "the  abstract  and  a  priori 
method  yields  no  explanation  of  the  laws  de- 
termining either  the  nature,  the  amount,  or  the 
distribution  of  wealth."  "  On  the  other  hand," 
he  says,  "  the  philosophical  method  must  be 
historical,  and  must  trace  the  connection  be- 
tween the  economical  and  the  other  phases  of 
national  history"  {Essays,  1888,  p.  189). 

It  would  occupy  too  much  space  to  attempt 
here  a  discussion  of  the  various  arguments  by 
which  the  assailants  of  the  deductive  method 
attempt  to  make  good  their  position.  It  may, 
however,  be  observed  that  the  problems  which 
they  have  mainly  in  view  are  apt  to  be  diflerent 
from  those  which  the  deductive  economists  have 
mainly  in  view.  They  are,  for  example,  not 
unfrequently  thinking  of  historical  or  semi- 
historical  problems,  which  no  one  would  seri- 
ously maintain  to  be  capable  of  a  deductive 
solution, — as,  for  example,  the  changes  in  kind 
which  wealth  undergoes  in  different  states  of 
society.  For  further  illustrations  of  this  point 
reference  may  be  made  to  Cliffe  Leslie's  essay  On 
the  Philosophical  Method  of  Political  Economy. 

Critics  of  the  deductive  method  are,  more- 
over, apt  to  misinterpret  the  nature  of  the  con- 
clusions to  which  alone  it  professes  to  lead. 
"The  deductive  economist's  theory  of  profits 
and  prices,"  says  Cliffe  Leslie,  "will  be  found 
to  claim  to  be  true,  under  all  circumstances,  in 
the  case  of  every  individual  in  trade  and  of 
every  particular  article,  and  to  foretell  the 
exact  rates  at  which  goods  will  be  sold.  His 
theory  of  taxation  is  an  application  of  his  theory 
of  profits  and  prices  ;  and  it  proceeds  on  the 
assumption  that  prices  will  actually  conform  to 
the  cost  of  production,  so  nicely  in  every  parti- 
cular case,  that  every  special  tax  on  any  com- 
modity will  be  recovered  by  the  producer  from 
the  consumer,  with  a  profit  on  the  advance " 
{Essays,  p.  229).  It  is  certain  that  no  authori- 
tative writer  of  the  deductive  school  has  ever 
intended  to  lay  down  such  doctrines  as  these. 
The  doctrine,  for  example,  that  taxes  on  com- 
modities are,  under  ordinary  conditions,  paid 
by  consumers,  relates  solely  to  what  will  happen 
in   the  long  run.   and  writers  like   Mill   and 


Cairnes  have  never  for  a  moment  imagined  that 
every  individual  instance  will  afford  a  verifica- 
tion of  it.  Cairnes  is  very  emphatic  upon  this 
point.  Referring  to  the  doctrine  of  cost  of  pro- 
duction, he  says — "Is  it  meant  that  freely- 
produced  commodities  invariably  and  without 
exception  exchange  for  one  anotlier  in  propor- 
tion to  their  respective  costs  of  production ' 
If  this  is  what  the  doctrine  means,  the  assertion 
is  clearly  untrue.  In  what  sense,  then,  is  the 
statement  true,  that  cost  of  production  regulates 
the  value  of  freely-produced  commodities  ?  The 
answer  is,  it  is  true  hypothetically — in  the 
absence  of  disturbing  causes  ;  or,  to  express  the 
same  thing  in  a  different  form,  the  doctrine 
expresses  not  a  matter  of  fact,  but  a  tendency  " 
{Logical  Method,  pp.  93-4). 

Both  friends  and  foes  of  the  use  of  deduction 
in  economic  inquiries  have  too  often  implied 
that  the  use  of  one  method  excludes  the  use  of 
other  methods.  But  this  is  far  from  being  the 
case.  In  political  economy  the  inductive  and 
deductive  methods  are  of  varying  relative  im- 
portance in  different  departments  of  inquiry. 
But  in  every  department  the  value  of  either  is 
increased  in  so  far  as  it  can  be  sujiplemented 
by  the  valid  employment  of  the  other.  In- 
creased accuracy  and  abundance  of  observations 
and  improved  opportunities  for  making  valid 
inductions  will  never  render  deduction  superflu- 
ous, but  Avill,  on  the  other  hand,  provide  it 
with  a  broader  and  better  established  basis, 
extending  the  range  of  its  applicability,  leading 
to  its  further  developments,  and  increasing  the 
practical  utility  of  its  conclusions.  The  object 
of  the  present  article  is  to  explain  the  nature 
of  the  deductive  method,  and  for  a  detailed 
consideration  of  other  methods  reference  must 
be  made  to  Historical  Method,  Inductive 
Method,  etc.  But  whatever  method  may  be 
immediately  under  consideration,  it  is  most 
important  to  point  out  that  the  recognition  of 
its  utility  does  not  imply  the  denial  of  the 
utility  of  other  methods  in  their  proper  place 
and  under  proper  conditions. 

It  will  constantly  be  found  that  economists 
are  less  narrow  in  their  actual  method  of  setting 
about  the  solution  of  economic  problems  than 
they  are  in  what  they  write  about  method. 
Mill,  for  example,  while  sometimes  speaking  of 
the  inductive  method  as  if  it  were  altogether 
inefficacious  in  economics,  himself  gives  a  typical 
example  of  its  use  in  the  discussion  of  the 
economic  aspects  of  peasant  proprietorship, 
which  occupies  so  prominent  a  place  in  his 
political  economy.  Cliffe  Leslie,  on  the  other 
hand,  continually  has  recourse  in  his  own 
economic  reasonings  to  that  deductive  method 
which  he  elsewhere  so  vehemently  attacks. 
Some  striking  instances  of  this  will  be  found 
cited  in  an  article  on  "  Economic  ^Method  "  by 
Professor  Sidgwick  in  the  Fortnightly  Pevieu 
for  February  1879. 


526 


DEDUCTIVE  METHOD— DEED 


There  are  indications  that  in  the  future  the 
controversy  as  to  the  place  of  the  deductive 
method  in  political  economy  will  be  less 
prominent  than  it  has  been  in  the  past.  A 
compromise  is  being  effected,  and  economists 
are  coming  to  substantial  agreement,  llius, 
writers  who  carry  on  the  tradition  of  the  so- 
called  classical  school  fully  recognise  that 
induction  as  well  as  deduction  has  an  important 
part  to  play  in  the  building  up  of  economic 
doctrines.  Professor  Marshall,  for  example, 
writes — "  Induction  and  deduction  go  hand  in 
hand.  The  progress  of  economic  reasoning 
depends  on  the  study  of  economic  facts,  and, 
on  the  other  hand,  that  study  itself  requires 
to  be  guided  and  directed  by  the  scientific 
knowledge  which  is  the  outcome  and  abstract 
of  a  previous  study  of  facts.  Every  new  study 
of  facts  adds  to  our  knowledge  of  the  action 
of  economic  causes,  it  enables  us  to  form  a 
better  judgment  as  to  the  effects  which  any 
cause  is  likely  to  produce,  whether  acting 
singly  or  in  combination  with  others  ;  and  it 
puts  us  in  a  better  position  to  detect  the 
hidden  causes  of  results  which  come  under  our 
notice.  But  the  study,  to  be  serviceable,  must 
be  careful  and  thorough,  and  must  be  so 
arranged  as  to  isolate  the  action  first  of  one 
cause  and  then  of  another,  and  make  a  careful 
examination  of  each  "  (^Principles  of  Economics, 
1891,  p.  88).  On  the  other  hand,  economists 
whose  natural  sympathies  tend  in  the  direction 
of  the  historical  school  are  emphatic  in  their 
statements  that  the  deductive  method  is  very 
far  indeed  from  being  superseded.  ''These, 
then,"  says  Professor  Wagner,  *'are  the  two 
methods :  on  the  one  hand,  deduction  from 
psychological  motives  —  first  and  foremost, 
deduction  from  the  motive  of  individual  ad- 
vantage, then  from  other  motives ;  on  the 
other  hand,  induction  from  history,  from 
statistics,  and  from  the  less  exact  and  less 
certain,  yet  indispensable,  process  of  common 
observation  and  experience.  With  both  methods 
we  are  to  approach  the  various  problems  of 
political  economy,  and  to  solve  them  so  far 
as  we  can.  Which  method  is  most  to  be  used 
depends  on  the  nature  of  the  particular 
problems  ;  but  it  depends  also  on  the  turn  of 
mind,  very  likely  on  the  accident  of  training 
and  education,  of  the  individual  investigator" 
{Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  October 
1886,  p.  124).  Professor  Cohn,  again,  expresses 
very  clearly  the  view  that  deduction  and  in- 
duction are  to  be  regarded  as  supplementary, 
not  as  antagonistic,  methods.  "Our  general 
consideration  of  the  nature  of  induction,"  he 
remarks,  "has  taught  us  that  this  method  by 
itself  alone,  without  deduction,  is  blind.  Any 
historical  or  statistical  collection  of  facts  can 
have  a  meaning,  only  when  it  is  made  from  a 
point  of  view  suitable  to  the  subject  which  is  to 
be  considered.     This  material,  collected  from  a 


definite  point  of  view,  can  again  only  be  made 
of  use  for  the  discovery  of  a  causal  connection 
by  being  brought  under  the  light  of  a  previously- 
prepared  hypothesis.  The  hypothesis  is  tested 
by  this  new  material  with  regard  to  its  re- 
liability, while  in  its  turn  it  throws  new  light 
upon  the  material.  Thus  a  tentative  advance 
from  the  most  uncertain  suppositions  to  ever 
more  firmly  established  assumptions,  is  brought 
about  by  progressive  observations  "  {System  der 
Nationalokonximie,  vol.  i.  p.  33). 

[On  the  subject  of  the  present  article,  see  also 
Analytical  Method,  A  Priori  Reasoning,  etc. 
Some  discussion  of  the  deductive  method  and  of 
economic  method  in  general  will  be  found  in  most 
systematic  works  on  poUtical  economy.  Special 
reference  may,  however,  be  made  to  the  following : 
Bagehot,  Economic  Studies,  essays  i.  and  ii. — Block, 
Les  Progres  de  la  Science  Economique,  Introduc- 
tion.— Bohm-Bawerk,  "  Historical  versus  Deductive 
Political  Economy "  {Annals  of  the  American 
Academy  of  Political  and  Social  Science,  October 
1890). — Cairnes,  Character  and  Logical  Method  of 
Political  Economy. — Cherbuliez,  Pr6cis  de  la 
Science  Economique,  Introduction. — Cohn,  System 
der  JVatio7ialokonomie,IntToduction. — Cossa,  Guide 
to  the  Study  of  Political  Economy. — Cunningham, 
The  Use  and  Ahu^e  of  Money ,  ch.  i. — Dunbar,  "The 
Reaction  in  Political  Economy  "  {Quarterly  Journal 
of  Economics,  October  1886). — Ingram,  History 
of  Political  Economy,  and  Address  as  President 
of  Section  F  of  the  British  Association,  1878. — 
Jevons,  Theory  of  Political  Economy,  ch.  i. — 
Keynes,  Scope  and  Method  of  Political  Economy. — 
Clitfe  Leslie,  Essays  in  Political  Economy,  especi- 
ally essays  xiv.  to  xvii. — Lunt,  Present  Condition 
of  Economic  A^czeTice.— Marshall,  Present  Position 
of  Economics,  and  Principles  of  Economics,  bk.  i. 
ch.  vi.  —  Menger,  Die  Methode  der  Politischen 
Oekonomie. — Mill,  Unsettled  Questions  of  Political 
Economy,  essay  v.,  and  Logic,  bk.  vi.  ch.  ix. — 
Roscher,  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  Intro- 
duction.— Sax,  Das  Wesen  und  die  Aufgahen  der 
Nationalokonomie. — Von  Scheel,  "Die  Politische 
Oekonomie  als  Wissenschaft "  (in  Schonberg's 
Handhuch  der  Politischen  Oekonomie). — SchmoUer 
Zur  Litteraturgeschichte  der  Staats-  und  Sozial- 
wissenschaften.  —  Science  Economic  Discussion 
(essays  by  H.  C.  Adams,  R.  T.  Ely,  etc.)— 
Sidgwick,  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  Intro- 
duction, ch.  iii. ,  and  Scope  and  Method  of  Eco- 
nomic Science. —  Senior,  Political  Economy. — 
Wagner,  "Present  State  of  Political  Economy" 
{Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  October  1886).] 

J.  N.  K. 

DEED  (Scot.)  Any  formal  written  instru- 
ment, properly  authenticated,  stating  the 
terms  of  any  agreement,  contract,  or  obliga- 
tion, which  must  be  definite,  possible,  and 
lawful.  It  may  be  unilateral  or  bilateral,  etc.  ; 
it  may  be  gratuitous,  for  no  consideration  is 
necessary  ;  and  "sealing"  is  entirely  in  desue- 
tude, though  anciently  necessary  in  matters 
above  £100  Scots  (£8:6:  8),  and  only  dis- 
pensed with  by  statute  1584  in  the  case  of 
deeds  which  were  also  to  be  registered.    A.  d. 


DEED  OF  ARRANGEMENT 


527 


DEED  OF  ARRANGEMENT.  A  deed  of 
arrangement  (under  the  60  &  51  Vict.  c.  57) 
is  an  instrument  in  writing  "made  by,  for,  or 
in  respect  of,  the  affairs  of  a  debtor  for  the 
benefit  of  his  creditors  generally  (otherwise 
than  in  pursuance  of  the  law  ior  the  time 
being  in  force  relating  to  bankru})tcy)." 

The  definition  of  a  deed  of  arrangement  given 
by  the  act  is  very  wide.  It  includes  (1)  an 
assignment  of  property  (to  one  or  more  trustees 
for  realisation  and  distribution  among  creditors)  ; 
(2)  a  deed  or  agreement  for  a  composition  ;  (3) 
and  (where  creditors  obtain  any  control  over 
a  debtor's  property  or  business,  a  deed  of 
inspectorship  or  other  instrument  entered  into 
for  the  purpose  of  carrying  on  or  winding  up  a 
business  ;  (4)  a  letter  of  license  given  by  credi- 
tors authorising  a  debtor,  or  by  a  debtor 
authorising  some  one  else,  to  manage  or  dispose 
of  his  business  with  a  view  to  the  payment  of 
his  debts.  The  essential  feature  of  the  deed  in 
each  case  is  that  it  must  be  for  the  benefit  of 
the  debtor's  creditors  generally,  and  of  the  act 
that  such  deeds  must  be  registered  and  open 
to  public  inspection.  The  object  of  the  act, 
therefore,  is  not  to  sanction  deeds  of  arrange- 
ment which  would  otherwise  be  illegal,  or  to 
interfere  with  or  control  the  administration 
under  such  deeds,  but  simply  to  secure  due 
publicity.  Prior  to  1887  such  deeds  were 
simple  agreements  governed  by  common  law 
and  not  by  special  statute.  By  the  above- 
mentioned  act,  whicli  came  into  operation  on 
the  1st  of  January  1888,  deeds  of  arrangement 
became  subject  to  certain  statutory  conditions, 
the  absence  of  which  renders  them  absolutely 
void.  The  act  does  not  otherwise  aff"ect  their 
status,  or  give  any  validity  to  them  which  they 
would  not  otherwise  possess.  They  are  not 
required  to  be  in  any  particular  form,  and 
remain  voluntary  agreements  binding  only  on 
such  persons  as  accede  to  them,  and  enforceable 
only  in  accordance  with  the  provisions  which 
they  contain.  In  this  respect  they  are  essen- 
tially different  from  the  deeds  of  arrangement 
and  schemes  of  arrangement  which  have  been 
legalised  under  former  bankruptcy  acts,  and 
more  particularly  under  the  acts  of  1849,  1861, 
and  1869.  The  latter  enjoyed  certain  special 
privileges,  and  were  binding  upon  all  the  credi- 
tors of  a  debtor  when  adopted  by  a  certain 
majority  in  the  manner  prescribed  by  law. 
They  also  differ  in  the  same  manner  from  the 
"schemes  of  arrangement"  under  the  Bank- 
ruptcy Acts  of  1883  and  1890,  which  when 
assented  to  by  a  certain  majority  become  bind- 
ing on  dissenting  creditors,  subject  to  approval 
by  the  court  after  an  investigation  into  the 
debtor's  conduct  (see  Bankruptcy). 

The  chief  condition  imposed  upon  the  validity 
of  deeds  of  arrangement  by  the  act  of  1887  is 
that  they  shall  be  stamped  and  registered  in 
the  bills  of  sale  department  of  the  central  office 


of  the  supreme  court  if  in  England,  or  in  the 
bills  of  sale  office  of  the  high  court  of  justice  if 
in  Ireland,  within  seven  clear  days  after  their 
first  execution  either  by  the  debtor  or  by  any 
creditor.  Registration  is  effected  by  filing 
with  the  registrar  copies  of  the  deed  accom- 
panied by  affidavits  verifying  the  same  and 
containing  an  estimate  of  the  amount  of  pro- 
perty and  liabilities  included  thereunder,  the 
total  amount  of  composition  (if  any),  and  the 
names  and  addresses  of  the  debtor  and  his 
creditors.  The  leading  particulars  of  the  deed 
are  then  entered  in  a  register,  and  this  register 
together  with  the  deed  itself  is  open  to  inspec- 
tion by  any  person,  whether  he  be  a  creditor  or 
not,  on  payment  of  the  prescribed  fee  of  2s.  6d. 
While  all  deeds  are  thus  registered  in  the  central 
office  in  London,  separate  registers  are  kept  in 
the  county  court  of  the  district  in  which  the 
debtor's  place  of  business  or  residence  is  situ- 
ated, when  such  place  of  business  or  residence 
is  outside  the  London  bankruptcy  district.  In 
these  cases  the  registrar  at  the  central  office 
transmits  a  copy  of  the  deed  to  the  registrar  of 
the  county  court,  who  is  required  to  file  and  to 
permit  inspection  of  the  same  in  the  like  manner 
and  on  the  like  terms  as  in  the  case  of  the 
central  register. 

The  publicity  secured  by  the  act  has  un- 
doubtedly been  of  great  benefit  to  the  trading 
community.  Prior  to  its  passing,  an  insolvent 
trader,  if  he  could  induce  all  his  creditors  to 
assent,  was  often  in  a  position  to  effect  a  secret 
arrangement  of  his  affairs,  which  left  him  for 
some  months  and  even  years  full  liberty  to  trade 
and  incur  fresh  obligations  while  he  was  still 
under  the  burden  of  old  ones  which  remained 
undischarged,  and  which  were  ultimately  paid 
or  compounded  for  out  of  the  proceeds  of  assets 
subsequently  acquired  on  credit.  Such  arrange- 
ments were  often  disastrous  to  the  new  creditors 
who,  when  their  debtor  finally  passed  into  the 
bankruptcy  court,  had  the  mortification  of  find- 
ing that  the  goods  which  they  had  thus  parted 
with  to  an  apparently  solvent  trader  had  simply 
been  used  for  the  purpose  of  paying  off  old 
liabilities  under  a  secret  arrangement  with  the 
old  creditors.  This  practice  is  now  rendered 
more  difficult  owing  to  the  necessity  which  the 
Deeds  of  Arrangement  Act  imposes  of  register- 
ing sueh  deeds,  and  the  facilities  which  it 
provides  for  inspection.  The  publicity  thus 
given  is  readily  utilised  through  the  medium 
of  trade  societies  for  the  benefit  of  the  trading 
community. 

An  indirect  benefit  arises  from  the  informa- 
tion afiForded  with  respect  to  the  condition  of 
trade  throughout  the  country,  and  the  total 
amount  of  national  losses  by  insolvency.  Prior 
to  1888  no  means  existed  for  estimating 
the  amount  of  these  losses  except  in  regard 
to  cases  administered  under  the  Bankruptcy 
Act,  although  it  was  known  by  traders  that 


528 


DEED  OF  ARRANGEMENT 


a  considerable  number  of  such  arrangements 
annually  took  place,  especially  in  certain  trades 
such  as  the  grocery,  drapery,  etc.  The  follow- 
ing statistics  relating  to  the  number  and  scope 
of  the  deeds  of  arrangement  registered  u]ider 
the  act  of  1887  during  three  recent  years  are 
taken  from  the  annual  report  of  the  inspector- 
general  in  bankruptcy  for  the  year  ending  1912. 


Year. 

Number 
of  Cases. 

Liabilities. 

Assets. 

Estimated 

Loss  to 
Creditors. 

1900 
1907 
1912 

3354 
3488 
2770 

£ 
4,263,610 
5,214,504 
3,139,900 

£ 
2,480,913 
3,100,784 
1,654,553 

£ 

2,771,462 
3,354,034 
2,147,258 

Though  these  figures  are  not  so  large  as  the 
corresponding  figures  under  the  Bankruptcy 
Act,  they  show  the  considerable  extent  and 
important  character  of  the  insolvency  annually 
dealt  with  under  this  head. 

A  deed  of  arrangement  is  only  binding 
upon  the  creditors  who  assent  to  it,  and  if  it 
comprises  an  assignment  of  a  debtor's  property 
to  a  trustee  for  the  benefit  of  his  creditors 
generally,  it  is  an  act  of  bankruptcy.  Any 
creditor  who  does  not  accede  to  it  can  there- 
fore proceed  against  the  debtor  by  ordinary 
process,  and  may,  if  he  establishes  a  debt  of 
upwards  of  £50,  present  a  bankruptcy  petition 
against  him  ;  and  if  an  order  of  adjudication 
is  made  in  pursuance  of  a  petition  presented 
within  three  months  after  the  date  of  the  deed, 
the  latter  may  be  set  aside  and  become  void  at 
the  instance  of  the  trustee  in  the  bankruptcy. 
Any  person  who  has  dealt  with  the  estate 
included  in  the  deed,  whether  as  trustee  or 
otherwise,  thereupon  becomes  personally  liable 
as  a  trespasser  for  any  loss  sustained  by  his 
intervention.  After  this  period  of  three  months 
the  deed  cannot  be  challenged  under  the  Bank- 
ruptcy Act,  although  it  is  still  liable  to  be  set 
aside,  under  the  statute  of  Elizabeth  (13  Eliz. 
c.  5),.  if  it  can  be  established  that  it  was  entered 
into  for  the  purpose  of  defrauding  creditors. 
Although  therefore  no  creditor  is  bound  by  the 
deed  unless  he  assents  to  it,  he  practically 
loses  his  remedy  as  against  the  debtor's  property, 
unless  he  can  prove  fraud,  or  unless  he  takes 
steps  to  preserve  his  rights  by  a  bankruptcy 
petition  within  three  months  from  the  date  of 
the  deed  ;  and  although  he  can  after  that 
period  make  the  debtor  bankrupt,  he  is  not 
likely  to  derive  much  satisfaction  from  that 
course,  as  the  debtor  will  probably  obtain  his 
discharge  subject  to  a  period  of  suspension, 
while  the  creditor  may  lose  any  dividend 
which  he  might  have  received  under  the  deed 
of  arrangement. 

There  are  several  important  differences  be- 
twixt a  liquidation  under  a  deed  of  arrange- 
ment, and  one  under  the  Bankruptcy  Act. 
The  following  are  the  most  important. 


1.  Under  the  Bankruptcy  Act  every  debtoi 
must  undergo  a  public  examination  in  court. 
Under  a  deed  of  arrangement  no  examination 
takes  place,  either  in  court  or  otherwise,  except 
such  as  individual  creditors  choose  privately  to 
institute,  and  the  debtor  chooses  to  submit  to, 
prior  to  the  execution  of  the  deed. 

2.  The  release  of  the  debtor  from  his  obliga- 
tions is  subject  under  the  Bankruptcy  Act  to 
certain  statutory  limitations,  and  to  the  ap- 
proval of  the  court.  Under  a  deed  of  arrange- 
ment the  release  is  generally  the  main  con- 
sideration received  by  the  debtor  for  executing 
the  deed,  and  is  effected  either  by  the  instrument 
itself  or  in  such  method  as  the  latter  may  pre- 
scribe. A  release,  however,  is  not  necessarily  an 
essential  feature  of  the  deed ;  in  fact  the  deed  is 
sometimes  entered  into  merely  for  the  purpose  of  : 
giving  the  debtor  time  to  pay  his  debts  in  full. 

3.  The  trustee  in  bankruptcy  can  set  aside 
various  preferences  given  by  the  debtor  within 
certain  periods  prior  to  the  date  of  the  bank- 
ruptcy petition  which  would  not  be  capable  of 
being  impeached  as  fraudulent  at  common  law. 
Under  a  deed  of  arrangement  the  trustee  has 
no  such  power. 

4.  In  bankruptcy,  a  trustee's  accounts  are 
subject  to  regular  audit  by  the  board  of  trade  ; 
under  a  deed  of  arrangement  there  is  no  audit 
except  such  as  may  be  provided  by  the  terms  of 
the  deed. 

5.  A  trustee  in  bankruptcy  is  not  only  bound 
to  file  detailed  copies  of  his  accounts  in  court 
and  with  the  board  of  trade,  but  to  send  a 
summary  of  his  receipts  and  payments  to  every 
creditor.  Under  a  deed  of  arrangement  the 
trustee  is  under  no  obligation  to  send  any  •. 
account  to  creditors  (unless  specially  provided 
for  by  the  deed).  By  §  25  of  the  Bankruptcy 
Act  of  1890,  however,  trustees  under  deeds  are 
now  required  to  send  copies  of  their  accounts 
annually  to  the  board  of  trade,  where  they 
can  be  inspected  by  any  creditor  on  payment 
of  a  fee  of  one  shilling. 

While  it  is  obvious  that  deeds  of  arrangement 
thus  lack  many  of  the  safeguards  provided  in 
the  interests  of  the  creditors  and  of  the  public 
in  the  case  of  bankruptcy  proceedings,  it  is 
sometimes  easier  under  them  to  carry  on  the 
business  of  a  debtor  who  has  become  involved 
in  temporary  difficulties  with  a  view  to  payment 
of  a  composition,  than  would  be  practicable 
under  the  latter.  The  result  may  thus  bo  more 
beneficial  both  for  the  debtor  and  for  his 
creditors. 

(In  the  year  1890  the  inspector  -  general  in 
bankruptcy  wrote  in  his  report  for  that  year : — 
"  To  give  any  majority  of  creditors  the  power  to 
condone  the  offences  which  the  Bankruptcy  Act 
condemns  and  punishes  would  be  to  degrade 
commercial  morality  into  a  question  of  barter  and 
to  undo  much  of  the  benefit  which  the  act  has 
conferred  upon  honest  and  prudent  trade.     What 


DEED  POLL — DEFENCE 


529 


appears  to  be  required,  therefore,  is  to  give  any 
dissenting  creditor  the  power  to  bring  a  deed  of 
arrangement  which  aifects  his  interest  before  the 
court,  and  to  give  the  court  the  power  when 
satisfied  that  it  has  been  assented  to  by  a  certain 
majority  of  the  creditors,  that  no  otfeuces  under 
the  bankruptcy  law  have  been  committed,  and 
that  no  judicial  investigation  is  necessary,  to 
make  the  deed  binding  upon  all  the  creditors. 
With  a  measure  passed  on  these  lines  safeguard- 
ing on  the  one  hand  the  interests  which  the 
bankruptcy  law  was  designed  to  protect,  and 
providing  on  the  other  against  obstructive  tactics 
on  the  part  of  an  unreasonable  minority,  it  might 
be  fairly  hoped  that  the  controversy  between  the 
advocates  of  private  arrangements  on  the  one  hand 
and  bankruptcy  on  the  other  would  be  closed, 
and  that  the  two  systems  might  be  regarded  as 
forming  together  a  complete  code  of  bankruptcy 
procedure.")  J.  s. 

The  Bankruptcy  Act  1913,  which  came  into 
force  April  1,  1914,  has  improved  the  law  with 
regard  to  Deeds  of  Arrangement  in  so  far  as  it 
more  certainly  ensures  that  the  trustee  is  an 
honest  man,  and  that  the  deed  has  the  assent 
of  the  majority  of  creditors.  It  prohibits 
general  assignments  of  book  debts  unless  they 
are  registered  in  the  same  way  as  Bills  of  Sale, 
and  further  makes  failure  to  keep  proper  books 
after  any  deed  of  arrangement  has  been  etl'ected, 
in  the  event  of  subsequent  bankruptcy,  a 
punishable  offence.  Under  a  provision  of  this 
act  the  trustee  has  to  give  security  for  the 
due  performance  of  his  duties  unless  exonerated 
by  a  special  resolution  of  the  creditors  passed 
for  the  purpose. 

DEED  POLL.  A  deed  executed  by  one 
party  only.  It  is  so  called  because  the  top  of 
the  parchment  was  "polled"  or  shaved  quite 
even  instead  of  being  "indented." 

[Stephen's  Covimen  taries  on  the  Laws  of  England, 
bk.  ii.  pt.  i.  ch.  xvi.]  J.  e.  c.  m. 

DEFALCATION.  The  term  defalcation  is 
commonly  used  to  describe  the  action  of  a  clerk 
or  servant  who  wrongl'ully  appropriates  to  his 
own  use  money  which  he  has  received  on  account 
of  his  employer.  A  defalcation  in  this  sense, 
although  morally  equivalent  to  theft,  differs 
from  theft  in  the  circumstance  that  the  money 
has  never  come  into  the  possession  of  the  person 
entitled  to  it,  and  so  has  not  been  taken  out 
of  his  possession  by  the  offender.  Defalcation  is, 
however,  a  popular  rather  than  a  legal  term,  and 
is  often  used  with  no  very  definite  signification. 
The  legal  equivalent  of  defalcation,  as  above 
described,  is  Embezzlement  {q.v.)    f.  c.  m. 

DEFENCE.  Name  of  a  pleading  in  an 
action  by  which  the  defendant  replies  to  the 
plaintiff's  claim  as  set  out  on  the  indorsement 
on  the  writ  or  in  the  statement  of  claim.  It 
must,  like  every  other  pleading,  * '  contain  only 
a  statement  in  a  summary  form  of  the  material 
tacts  "  on  which  the  defendant  relies.  If  it 
has  been  settled  by  counsel  it  must  be  signed 

VOL.  1. 


by  him,  and  if  it  contains  more  than  720  words 
it  must  be  printed.  The  defence  may  consist 
(1)  in  a  denial  of  the  facts  alleged  by  the 
plaintiff ;  (2)  in  a  denial  of  the  legal  conclusions 
drawn  by  the  plaintiff  from  the  facts  stated  by 
him  ;  (3)  in  an  admission  of  the  facts  stated  by 
the  plaintitT  coupled  with  an  allegation  of  other 
facts  Avhich  take  away  the  plaintiirs  right  {e.g. 
a  contract  is  admitted,  but  it  is  alleged  that  it 
was  obtained  by  fraud,  or  that  it  has  been 
performed  before  action  brought,  or  that  the 
plaintiff  has  released  his  right).  Allegations 
of  fact  in  the  statement  of  claim,  if  not  denied 
specifically,  or  stated  to  be  not  admitted,  are 
taken  tp  be  admitted  by  the  defendant  (except 
in  the  case  of  an  infant  or  lunatic  defendant). 

E.  S. 

DEFENCE,  Cost  of.  The  feudal  system 
distributed  property  and  influence  in  proportion 
to  the  obligation  to  take  i^art  in  defence.  Its 
armies  were  essentially  militias.  The  gi-owth 
of  monarchy,  with  the  tendency  to  identify  the 
state  with  the  personal  ruler,  threw  the  cost  of 
defence  mainly  on  the  revenues  of  the  sovereign, 
obtained  by  taxes  in  lieu  of  the  ieudal  dues. 
War  came  to  be  regarded  as  the  personal  alfair 
of  the  king,  and  the  etibrts  made  in  war  were 
limited  by  the  size  of  the  standing  army  which 
he  was  able  to  maintain.  In  this  period  the 
art  of  war  became  a  distinct  profession  or  trade, 
and  the  superiority  of  a  standing  army  over  a 
militia  was  soon  recognised,  nowhere  more 
clearly  than  in  the  Wealth  of  Nations,  where 
the  two  were  well  distinguished.  ' '  The  prac- 
tice of  military  exercises,"  wrote  Adam  Smith, 
' '  is  the  sole  or  principal  occu]  )ation  of  the 
soldiers  of  a  standing  army,  and  tlie  mainten- 
ance or  pay  which  the  state  affords  them  is  the 
principal  and  ordinary  fund  of  their  subsistence. 
The  practice  of  military  exercises  is  only  the 
occasional  occupation  of  the  soldiers  of  a 
militia,  and  they  derive  the  principal  and  or- 
dinary fund  of  their  subsistence  from  some  other 
occupation."  Adam  Smith,  however,  clearly 
perceived  that  ' '  a  militia  whicli  has  served  foi 
several  successive  campaigns  in  the  field  becomes 
in  every  respect  a  standing  army. "  The  French 
revolution  identifying  the  nation  with  the 
sovereign,  brought  the  whole  nation  into  arms. 
The  force  thus  developed,  though  at  first  a  mere 
militia,  fulfilled  Adam  Smith's  prediction  and 
easily  crushed  the  comparatively  small  armies 
maintained  by  the  neiglibouring  monarchies, 
and  compelled  them,  too,  to  recognise  that 
defence  is  the  business  not  merely  of  the 
sovereign  but  of  the  nation.  This  view  has 
been  revived  by  more  recent  events,  and  at  the 
present  day  defence  is  conducted  as  far  as 
possible  by  the  emplo3nnent  of  the  whole  of  the 
national  resources. 

The  loss  of  productive  energy  and  of  capital 
caused  by  war  far  exceeds  the  pecuniary  expen- 
diture of  the   belligerents.      It  includes   also 

2  M 


630 


DEFENCE,  COST  OF 


material  destruction  on  a  great  scale,  the  inter- 
ruption of  trade,  tlie  cessation  of  industry,  the 
loss  by  death,  or  disablement  from  wounds  or 
disease,  of  a  great  number  of  workers.  The 
economic  losses  are  usually  great  in  proportion 
to  the  duration  of  the  war  ;  they  are  also  as  a 
rule  greater  on  the  defeated  side.  Accordingly, 
in  order  to  avoid  defeat,  to  shorten  the  duration 
of  a  possible  war,  and  to  render  attack  improb- 
able except  for  grave  motives,  preparations 
are  made  during  peace,  which  are  amongst  the 
principal  objects  of  government  expenditure. 

The  modern  continental  system  combines  the 
advantage  of  a  militia — the  soldier's  sustenance 
not  being  a  lifelong  burden  to  the  state — with 
that  of  a  standing  army,  which  consists  in 
superior  professional  skill.  The  leaders  and 
instructors  (officers)  and  their  assistants  (non- 
commissioned officers)  are  professional  soldiers, 
at  all  times  paid  and  maintained  by  the  state. 
The  rank  and  file  are  ordinary  citizens,  com- 
pelled to  devote  to  the  exclusive  practice  of 
military  exercises  the  minimum  time  within 
which  skill  in  arms  and  perfect  discipline  can 
be  acquired.  This  period  varies  in  the  con- 
tinental practice  between  two  and  three  years, 
with  an  exception  in  some  cases  in  favour  of 
well-educated  recruits,  who  serve  one  year  only. 
The  object  is  to  make  a  capable  soldier  of  every 
healthy  adult  male.  But  no  state  has  yet  been 
willing  to  incur  the  expense  of  training  the 
whole  of  the  men  born  in  any  one  year — the 
''annual  contingent" — for  the  fuU  period. 
Complete  or  partial  exemption  is  therefore 
granted,  usually  to  those  whose  productive 
services  have  a  special  value.  The  performance 
of  military  service  is  held  to  rest  on  a  primary 
obligation  and  not  on  contract,  so  that  the 
trifling  money  allowance  made  to  the  private 
soldier  is  not  properly  described  as  pay.  This 
organisation  produces  for  defence  an  army  com- 
prising the  majority  of  able-bodied  men  between 
the  ages  of  twenty  and  forty,  but  it  maintains 
in  time  of  peace  only  a  fraction  of  this  great 
number  at  the  public  cost. 

In  Great  Britain  the  obligation  to  military 
service  is  in  abeyance,  and  a  standing  army  of 
a  modified  18th-century  type  is  maintained  side 
by  side  with  an  old  militia — the  Special  Keserve 
— and  a  new  militia — the  Territorial  Force,  The 
standing  army  is  recruited  by  voluntary  enlist- 
ment on  the  basis  of  contract  for  pay.  The 
contract  is  for  twelve  years,  of  which,  since 
recent  changes  in  the  system,  nine  are  usually 
spent  with  the  colours  ;  during  the  remainder 
pay  is  received  in  return  for  the  liability  to  be 
recalled  upon  mobilisation.  The  Special  Reserve 
and  Territorial  Force  are  also  voluntarily  re- 
cruited ;  officers  and  men  receive  pay  for  each 
day  served.  In  both  alike  the  instructors 
(adjutants)  and  their  assistants  (non-commis- 
sioned officers),  assigned  to  them  from  the 
regular    army,    receive   continuously   the   full 


pay  of  their  respective  ranks,  with  extra 
allowances. 

The  relatively  great  cost  of  the  English  peace 
force  arises  partly  from  the  endeavour  to  attract 
recruits  by  the  off'er  of  pay — a  shilling  a  day — 
from  a  more  expensive  scale  of  clothing,  feeding, 
and  living,  and  from  the  fact  that  in  England 
wages  and  salaries  are  on  an  average  higher 
than  in  Germany.  Moreover,  the  British  army 
keeps  garrisons  in  the  West  Indies,  in  the 
Mediterranean,  South  Africa,  Ceylon,  the  Straits 
Settlements,  and  China,  These  garrisons  absorb 
about  45,000  men,  costing  nearly  four  millions, 
while  the  receipts  from  the  colonies  and  Egypt 
amount  to  only  £552,500.  Then  a  whole 
army  corps  is  kept  in  Ireland.  The  frequent 
movement  of  troops  thus  necessitated  causes 
some  expense.  In  Germany  the  doctrine  of 
duty  applied  to  defence  enables  the  scale  of 
living  and  clothing  to  be  kept  down  to  what  is 
necessary.  The  private  soldier  practically  re- 
ceives no  pay,  his  4id,  a  day  being  hardly 
enough  to  provide  food  necessary  in  addition  to 
what  is  supplied  by  the  government.  The 
pension  list  is  relieved  by  the  practice  of  em- 
ploying discharged  non-commissioned  officers  in 
the  civil  services,  notably  in  the  state  railways 
and  the  post  and  telegraph  offices. 

A  peace  army  withdrawing  from  productive 
labour  five  or  six  hundred  thousand  men,  in- 
volves, of  course,  a  larger  loss  of  productive 
energy  than  one  which  keeps  unproductive 
only  a  hundred  and  seventy  thousand  men. 
But  it  may  be  doubted  whether  the  continental 
system  involves  any  other  economic]  loss  differ- 
ent in  kind  from  that  which  accompanies  the 
British  standing  army.  The  soldier  with  the 
colours  is,  while  his  service  lasts,  withdrawn 
from  production.  The  economical  loss  under 
this  head  depends  on  the  number  so  withdrawn. 
If  the  number  is  small  a  selection  can  be  made 
of  those  who  would  be  inefficent  producers. 
If  it  becomes  considerable  more  efficient  pro- 
ducers must  in  any  case  be  taken,  whether  the 
enlistment  is  voluntary  or  the  service  a  duty. 
The  soldier  is  not  merely  a  non-producer,  but 
a  consumer.  It  is  evident  from  the  figures 
that  he  consumes  in  proportion  to  numbers 
much  more  largely  in  England  than  in  France 
or  Germany.  In  Germany,  at  least,  he  is  to 
some  extent  utilised  as  a  producer,  clothes  and 
shoes  being  in  many  cases  made  by  the  soldiers, 
and  thus  the  demand  on  the  taxpayer  reduced. 
That  the  soldiers  so  employed  as  workmen  are 
not  paid  for  their  work  is  perhaps  an  injustice, 
but  hardly  a  loss  to  the  nation.  On  the  other 
hand  it  is  necessary  to  give  due  weight  to  the 
fact  that  the  continental  system,  taking  recruits 
at  the  age  of  twenty  and  dismissing  them  at 
twenty-two  or  twenty-three,  withdraws  them 
from  industry  before  their  services  have  become 
very  valuable,  and  returns  them  to  it  with  their 
industrial  capacity  unimpaired.     It  is  widely 


DEFENCE,  COST  OF 


531 


believed  that  the  British  soldier,  on  passing 
into  the  reserve  after  seven  years  of  military 
life,  has  lost  mneh  of  his  industrial  value.  But 
the  evidence  given  to  Lord  Wantage's  Com- 
mittee showed  that  in  1891  the  majority  of 
the  reservists  were  in  regular  employment. 

The  German  one-year  "volunteers"  serve  at 
their  own  expense,  thereby  escaping  the  rest  of 
the  two  years'  term  normal  for  other  recruits. 
They  are  required  to  give  proof  of  superior 
education.  They  correspond  in  attainments  and 
amount  of  personal  expenditure  with  British 
volunteer  officers. 

The  aggregate  annual  expenditure  of  the 
European  States  upon  armies  and  navies  in 
time  of  peace  exceeds  at  the  present  time 
£300,000,000,  of  which  a  larger  proportion 
than  at  any  previous  period  is  devoted  to  naval 
forces.  The  expenditure  of  the  principal  Euro- 
pean Powers  is  approximately  as  follows  : — 

(Foreign  coins  converted  as  £1  =  20  Marks,  25  Francs 
and  Lire,  24  Crowns,  10  Roubles.) 
Great  Britain  (1912-13)  exclusive  of  India — 
Navy         ....  £44,365,000 
Ai'my        ....     28,071,000 

£72,436,000 

India  (1910-11)  military  services  including 

marine 19,706,500 

Austria  Hungary  (1909) — 
Army,    including    extra- 
ordinary expenditure  .  £16,995,506 
Navy         ....        2,643,244 


France  (1910)— 

Army 
Navy 


£32,913,905 

13,659,826 


German  Empire  (estimates  1910-11)— 

Army        ....   £35,492,350 
Navy         ....        7,902,600 

Italy  (estimates  1909-10)— 
Army  ordinary  and  extra- 


19,638,750 


46,573,731 


43,394,950 


ordinary 

£12,349,046 

Navy  ordinary  and  extra- 

ordinary 

6,785,441 

19,134,48 

sia  (estimates  1910)— 

Army        .        .        .        . 

£48,071,639 

Navy        .        .        .        . 

8,924,743 

56.996.38 

Switzerland  (estimates  1910)- 
Military  expenditure 


1,619,953 


The  following  tables  give  an  account  of  the 
forces  maintained  for  the  above  expenditure  : — 
Navies  (from  Dilke  return,  1910)  ;  ships  huilt  and  building. 


i 
1 

1 

>, 

I 

05 

1 

Battleships      .        .        . 
Armoured  coast  defence 

65 

23 

15 

41 

12 

34 

17 

vessels  . 

8 

2 

r 

10 

Armoured  cruisers  . 

41 

22 

6 

12 

10 

15 

13 

Protected  cruisers  let  CI. 

IS 

5 

7 

3 

2 

1         „               .,        2nd  „ 

44 

9 

2 

28 

3 

16 

14 

M        3rd  „ 

16 

8 

2 

12 

11 

2 

6 

Unprotected  cruisers 

2 

10 

.. 

6 

6 

Scouts      .... 

8 

8 

Torpedo  vessels 

23 

10 

c 

1 

5 

2 

2 

Torpedo  boat  destroyers 

187 

77 

97 

98 

23 

40 

59 

Torpedo  boats . 

116 

246 

63 

82 

96 

30 

69 

Submarines      . 

74 

79 

33 

i+1 

7 

iff 

12 

[Germany  liad  in  1910  eight  submarines  built ;  the 
number  building  was  not  known.  ] 


Armies  (approximate  figures). 


Peace 
Strength. 

Mobilised 
Army. 

Further 
Reserves. 

Great  Britain  (Jan.  1, 

1910)     . 
France  (1909)   . 
Russia 

Germany  (1909) 
Austria      Hungary 

(1909)     . 
Italy  (1909) 

165,686 

523,000 

1,200,000 

621,162 

382,808 
288,349 

II  llli 

350,758 
1,200,000 

9 

1,500,000 

? 
? 

The  expenditure  of  the  United  Kingdom  for 
defence  according  to  the  estimates  for  1910-11 


Navy— 
Personnel  (numbers  borne,  131,000)      .  £10,763,600 
Materiel  and  administration  .        .        .     27,077,700 

Non-efTective 2,762,400 

Amounts    borne    in    other    than  navy 
estimates 373,358 


Total  naval  expenditure  . 


(of  which  contributed  by  India  and 
Colonies,  £494,900). 
Army— 
T.  Personnel.     Regular  troops — 
(a)  173,060  regular  army     £16,496,658 
(h)  133,990  reserve       .        .    1,366,350 
(c)  Labour  and  educational 

establishments    .        .       936,737 

Total  regular  army      .        £18,799,745 

Special  Reserves  and  Territorial  Force— 

(a)  75,013  special  reserve, 

formerly  militia  .  £1,938,332 

(b)  274,712  territorial  force, 

formerly    volunteers 

and  yeomanry      .        .    3,257,803 

(c)  3010  Channel  Islands 

militia  .        .        .         28,332 

(d)2862  Malta  and  Ber- 
muda militia  and 
volunteers 


.  £40,977,258 


Total  Personnel  (662,647) 
II.  Stores  and  supplies   . 
III.  Staff  and  administration 

Total  army  estimates 


32,738 
£5,247,205 


£24,046,950 
3,953,089 
1,106,061 

£20,106,100 


(towards  which  India,  certain  colonies, •* 

and      Egypt      contribute      together 
£1,184,100). 

The  cost  of  maintaining  armies  and  navies 
during  peace  should  be  compared  with  the  cost 
of  war.  The  following  table  (after  JMr.  Edgar 
Crammond  in  Quarterly  Review,  Oct.  19 10)  shows 
approximately  the  outlay  incurred  in  the  princi- 
pal wars  of  recent  times  : — 


Date. 

War. 

Cost. 

1853-1854 

Crimean      .... 

£ 
340,000,000 

1859 

Italian         .... 

60,000,000 

1864 

Schleswig-Holstein    . 

7,000,000 

1861-1865 

American  Civil  War- 

Northern  States      . 

940,000,000 

Southern  States 

460,000,000 

1866 

Prussia,  Italy,  and  Austria 

66,000,000 

1870-1871 

Franco-German  War — 

French  expenditure 

540,000,000 

German          „ 

77,500,000 

1899-1902 

South  African  War- 

British  expenditure 

211,000,000 

1904-1905 

Russo-Japanese  War- 

Russian    expenditure     . 

300,000,000 

Japanese          „ 

203,000,000 

532 


DEFERRED  PAYMENTS— DEFERRED  STOCK 


The  place  of  "tlie  expense  of  defence"  in 
national  economy  was  well  considered  by  Adam 
Smith,  who  accounted  for  its  progressive  in- 
crease. In  recent  times  this  outlay  has  often 
been  regarded  as  analogous  to  the  premiums 
paid  for  insurance.  But  while  an  insurance 
company  undertakes,  in  the  contingency  con- 
templated by  the  policy,  to  pay  a  sum  by  way 
of  compensation,  there  is  no  similar  means  of 
repairing  the  damage  done  to  a  nation  in  war. 
The  money  spent  during  peace  on  armies 
and  navies  might  better  be  compared  to  the 
outlay  of  a  municipal  corporation  for  the 
maintenance  of  a  fire  brigade,  the  purpose 
being  not  to  compensate  for  loss  but  to  prevent 
it.  The  protection,  however,  in  the  case  of 
expenditure  on  armaments  is  not  against  war, 
but  against  defeat  and  its  consequences. 

The  most  important  question  concerning 
the  cost  of  defence  is,  Wherein  consists  true 
economy  ?  in  other  words.  Which  portion  of  the 
outlay  brings  in  the  largest  relative  return, 
what  are  the  essential  matters  on  which  money 
must  be  spent  during  peace,  and  what  prepara- 
tions admit  of  postponement  until  the  moment 
has  arrived  for  the  employment  of  force  ? 

The  table  of  the  cost  of  recent  wars  shows 
that  the  expenditure  in  actual  war  is  less  in 
the  case  of  a  well-prepared  than  in  that  of 
an  unprepared  State.  In  the  American  civil 
war  both  sides  were  unprepared.  ■  For  the 
South  African  war  Great  Britain  was  not 
prepared.  For  the  Franco-German  war,  Ger- 
many was  and  France  was  not  suitably  prepared. 
The  elements  of  preparation  for  war  are, 
first,  the  planning  and  directing  organism,  which 
consists  of  the  organs  of  command  and  of 
administration ;  secondly,  the  training  organism 
or  cadres  of  the  army ;  thirdly,  the  personnel  of 
the  rank  and  file ;  and,  lastly,  the  materiel  or  the 
implements  of  war.  Of  these  the  first,  the  organ 
of  forethought,  costs  proportionally  little,  but 
is  the  determining  factor  of  the  efficacy  of  the 
whole  outlay.  Thus  the  beginning  of  economy 
is  to  have  first-rate  ministries  for  Army  and 
Navy,  and  within  them  the  best  obtainable 
personnel  and  organisation  in  the  offices  that 
deal  with  strategical  and  tactical  problems. 
Next  in  importance  for  ultimate  success  is  the 
quality,  produced  by  training  and  selection,  of 
the  cadres,  the  officers  and  non-commissioned 
officers  who  educate  the  private  soldiers,  sailors 
and  marines.  The  discipline  and  technical  skill 
of  the  men  are  proportionate  to  the  quality  of 
the  cadres.  They  increase  with  the  time  which 
the  men  spend  in  active  training  until  the 
maximum  of  condition  has  been  reached,  after 
which  successive  increments  of  time  fail  to 
produce  corresponding  increments  of  discipline 
or  skill.  The  materiel  is  of  much  the  same 
quality  in  all  modern  armies  and  navies,  and  its 
cost  proportionate  to  the  size  of  the  army  or 
navy,  the  only  economy  being  that  produced 


by  good  judgment  in  the  purchase  or  manufac- 
ture, i.e.  by  the  quality  of  the  ministry  which 
buys  or  produces.  From  the  consideration  of 
these  factors  it  appears  that  for  an  army  or 
navy  of  a  given  size  the  cost  will  be  lowest 
when  the  ministry  and  the  cadres  are  the  best 
in  quality,  and  when  the  time  during  which  the 
common  soldier  or  sailor  remains  in  training  is 
not  prolonged  beyond  the  moment  when  further 
practice  produces  no  corresponding  addition  to 
quality.  In  the  case  of  an  army  this  period 
is  perhaps  two  to  three  years.  In  the  case  of 
navies  it  is  probably  longer,  but  the  acces- 
sible evidence  does  not  enable  the  time  to  be 
fixed. 

From  the  point  of  view  of  Great  Britain 
there  is  a  further  question  as  to  the  most 
economic  method.  It  concerns  the  relative 
amount  of  effort  to  be  given  to  naval  and  to 
military  preparation  respectively.  For  Great 
Britain  beyond  doubt  the  vital  matter  is  to 
obtain  victory  at  sea,  which  is  the  function  of 
naval  force  alone.  But  experience  shows  that 
naval  victory  may  be  facilitated  and  that  its 
effects  are  enhanced  by  the  co-operation  of 
military  with  naval  force.  Given  a  navy  of 
such  quality  and  size  as  to  have  the  probability 
of  decisive  victory  over  the  hostile  navy,  then 
the  chance  of  dictating  peace  on  satisfactory 
terms  will  be  increased  more  by  an  efficient 
mobile  army  able  to  operate  in  the  enemy's 
territory  than  by  further  naval  force. 

[See  Giffen,  ' '  Cost  of  Franco  -  German  War, " 
Essays  on  Finance, — Bastable,  Public  Finance, 
bk.  i.  ch.  ii.  on  "The  Cost  of  Defence."]    s.w. 

DEFERRED  PAYMENTS.  The  phrase 
"standard  for  deferred  payments"  is  applied 
by  Prof.  Walker  to  the  function  of  money 
which  Jevons  describes  in  the  following  passage 
and  its  context:  "Every  person  making  a 
contract  by  which  he  will  receive  something  at 
a  future  day,  will  prefer  to  secure  the  receipt 
of  a  commodity  likely  to  be  as  valuable  then 
as  now.  This  commodity  will  usually  be  the 
current  money,  and  it  will  thus  come  to  perform 
the  function  of  a  Standard  of  Value  "  (Walker, 
Money,  p.  10  ;  Jevons,  Money,  p.  14). 

The  term  "deferred  payments,"  when  used 
in  connection  with  "tabular  standard"  (or 
similar  phrases),  as  by  Prof.  Walker  in  his 
Money,  p.  159,  refers  specially  to  those  "long- 
enduring  debts  and  transactions,"  those  "con- 
tracts extending  over  long  series  of  years," 
which  Jevons  and  others  have  proposed  to 
regulate  by  a  standard  more  permanent  than 
money. 

[Jevons's  Money,  p.  325  ;  Currency  and  Finance, 
pp.  122,  297  (see  Index  Number,  Tabular 
Standard).]  f.  t.  e. 

DEFERRED  STOCK.  On  the  stock  ex- 
change the  securities  which  have  been  issued  by 
a  government  or  corporation  take  different 
ranks.     Thus  an  English  railway  company  is 


DEFICIENCY  ADVANCES— DEFICIT 


638 


liable  first  for  tlie  interest  on  its  debenture 
stock ;  next,  for  that  on  preferred  stock,-  if 
earned ;  next,  for  dividend  on  the  ordinary 
stock,  and  finally  for  dividend  on  deferred 
Stock  should  any  exist.  In  America  the  shares 
of  railways  usually  represent  the  "deferred" 
interest  of  the  original  constructors  in  the  profits 
of  the  railway  ;  mortgage  bonds,  and  perhaps 
preference  interest,  having  first  to  be  satisfied 
out  of  net  profits.  Most  of  the  American  rail- 
road shares  known  to  the  London  stock  exchange 
represent  nothing  more  solid  than  hope  deferred 
for  a  very  long  time,  but  these  are  not  known 
as  what  they  really  are,  viz.  deferred  shares. 
Of  late  years  it  has  been  largely  the  practice  of 
trust  companies  to  issue  preferred  and  deferred 
stocks,  the  former  being  entitled  to  a  given  rate 
of  interest  preferentially,  while  the  deferred 
section  of  the  capital  takes  the  residuary''  profit 
in  the  shape  of  a  dividend.  Deferred  stock  is 
usually  created  to  meet  the  demand  of  specu- 
lators who  favour  a  security  which  is  exposed 
to  violent  fluctuations.  If  an  English  railway, 
which  has  issued  deferred  stock,  be  responsible 
for  a  serious  accident,  the  holders  of  deferred 
stock,  who  previously  had  a  chance  of  a  divi- 
dend, may  see  the  prospect  of  dividend  entirely 
blotted  out  for  a  time.  The  deferred  stock  of 
an  English  railway  company  is  peculiar.  It  is 
the  result  of  an  option-  given  to  the  holders 
of  ordinary  stock.  For  example,  holders  of 
London,  Brighton,  and  South-Coast  Railway 
ordinary  stock  have  been  allowed  to  divide  each 
£200  of  ordinary  capital  into  £100  of  B  or 
preferred  stock  bearing  6  per  cent,  if  sucli  a 
dividend  be  earned,  and  £100  of  A  or  deferred 
stock,  which  receives  the  surplus.  Thus,  when 
a  dividend  of  7  per  cent  is  announced  on 
Brighton  Railway  ordinary  stock,  a  holder  of 
£200  stock  gets  £14  ;  but,  if  he  has  divided 
his  stock,  he  gets  £6  on  £100  preferred  capital 
and  the  surplus  £8  on  £100  deferred  capital. 
There  are  investors  who  buy  only  the  deferred 
stock,  regarding  themselves  as  residuary  legatees 
of  a  fine  estate  ;  others  avoid  such  a  stock  as 
being  too  speculative.  The  division  was  made 
to  meet  different  tastes  and  suit  different  tem- 
peraments and  deferred  railway  stock  is  simply 
the  result  of  that  division.  A.  e. 

DEFICIENCY  ADVANCES.  Under  sect.  1 2 
of  the  Exchequer  and  Audit  Departments'  Act, 
1866,  the  treasury  are  required  at  the  close  of 
each  quarter  to  prepare  an  account  of  the  in- 
come and  charge  of  the  consolidated  fund, 
including  under  the  latter  head  the  charges  for 
the  public  debt  due  on  the  fifth  day  of  the 
succeeding  quarter.  This  account  is  examined 
by  the  comiDtroller  and  auditor-general,  who 
nmat,  if  the  income  of  the  consolidated  fund  in 
Great  Britain  or  in  Ireland  for  the  quarter  is 
insufficient  to  defray  the  charge  upon  it,  cer- 
tify the  amount  of  the  deficiency  to  the  Bank 
of  England  or  to  the  Bank  of  Ireland  as  the  case 


may  be,  and  those  Banks  are  authorised  to  make 
advances  during  the  succeeding  quarter,  on  the 
application  of  the  treasury,  to  an  amount  not 
exceeding  in  the  aggregate  the  amount  of  the 
deficiency  so  certified.  These  advances  are 
secured  on  an  I.O.U.  of  the  government,  and 
are  paid  off  out  of  accruing  revenue  as  the  state 
of  the  exchequer  balance  admits.  They  bear 
interest  at  a  rate  agreed  upon,  for  each  occasion, 
between  the  cliancellor  of  the  exchequer  and 
the  Bank,  principal  and  interest  being  payable 
within  the  quarter  in  which  the  advance  is  made. 
The  formal  correspondence  between  the  chan- 
cellor and  the  Bank  respecting  these  advances 
is  annually  presented  to  parliament.  [See  e.g. 
Pari.  Paper,  No.  48  of  1910.] 

Under  sect.  5  of  the  Natioiuil  Debt  (Sinking 
Fund)  Act  of  1875,  the  surplus  of  income  above 
expenditure  in  any  year  (called  the  old  Sinking 
Fund)  may  be  applied  by  the  National  Debt 
Commissioners  in  paying  off"  deficiency  advances. 
(See  also  Deficiency  Bills.)  g.  h.  h. 

DEFICIENCY  BILLS.  A  term  used  to 
denote  the  exchequer  bills  formerly  issued  for 
the  special  purpose  of  being  given  to  the  Banks 
of  England  and  Ireland  as  security  for  the 
advances  required  to  make  good  the  deficiency 
on  the  consolidated  fund.  The  issue  of  these 
bills  was  regulated  by  the  Act  57  Geo.  III. 
c.  48,  sect§.  6-14,  which  ])rovided  that  if  upon 
making  up  the  accounts  of  the  income  and 
charge  of  the  consolidated  fund  for  each  quarter, 
it  appeared  to  the  treasury  that  the  produce  of 
that  fund  was  not  sufficient  to  defray  the 
charges  thereon,  it  should  be  lawful  for  the 
treasury  to  direct  that  exchequer  bills  should 
be  made  out  for  such  sum  or  sums  as  should 
be  sufficient  to  make  up  the  deficiency.  The 
interest  to  be  borne  by  the  bills  was  not  to 
exceed  the  rate  of  "three  pence  halfpenny  per 
centum  per  diem"  ;  the  Banks  of  England  and 
Ireland  were  empowered  to  advance  moneys  on 
the  credit  of  them  ;  and  they  were  to  be  placed 
as  so  much  cash  in  the  offices  of  the  tellers  of 
the  exchequer.  The  Act  above  referred  to  was 
repealed  by  the  Exchequer  and  Audit  Depart- 
ments Act,  18; 3,  which  substituted  for  them 
a  similar  but  simpler  institution  known  as 
Deficiency  At>\"ances  {q.v.)  t.  h.  e. 

DEFICIT.  In  public  finance,  an  excess  of 
expenditure  over  income,  either  {a)  actual  or 
(6)  estimated.  Unless,  of  course,  the  occurrence 
of  a  deficit  is  deliberately  contemplated — and 
the  practice  of  making  provision  annually  for  the 
requirements  of  the  coming  year  is  opposed  to 
such  a  course — an  actual  deficit  is  ordinarily 
due  either  to  the  failure  of  taxation  to  realise 
as  much  as  was  anticipated,  or  to  the  necessity 
for  meeting  extraordinary  and  unexpected  ex- 
penditure, as  in  the  case  of  war  and  warlike 
preparations.  Where  a  deficit  is  only  estimated, 
it  can  be,  and  frequently  is,  made  good  by  an 
increase  of  taxation,  unless  an  addition  to  the 


534 


DEFICIT— DEFINITIONS 


public  debt  is  deliberately  sanctioned,  or  some 
fund  or  available  asset  is  appropriated  to  meet 
the  deficiency.  Both  descriptions  of  deficit  are 
usually  referred  to  in  the  budget  speech  of  the 
chancellor  of  the  exchequer,  and  it  is  essetitial 
to  discriminate  between  the  two  in  considering 
the  finance  of  an  administration. 

The  following  table  shows  the  estimated  and 
actual  deficits  shown  in  regard  to  the  finance  of 
the  United  Kingdom  since  1842-43. 


Year. 

Chancellor 
of  the 

Deficits. 

Exchequer. 

Unrevised 
Estimate. 

Bevised 
Estimate. 

Actual. 

£ 

£ 

£ 

1842-43 

Goulburn 

2,469,000 

2,421,776 

1847-48 

Wood 

3,092,285 

1848-49 

„ 

.. 

2,03i,256 

209,378 

1852-53 

Disraeli 

2,125,000 

1854-55 

Gladstone 

2,840,000 

3,543,000 

6,19f;,808 

1855-56 

Lewis 

16,560,519 

18,895,000 

22,723,854 

1866-57 

» 

13,961,000 

9,373,000 

3,254,605 

1857-58 

.. 

247,346 

] 858-59 

Disraeli 

3,990,000 

1859-60 

Gladstone 

4,867,000 

1860-61 

» 

9,400,000 

1,286,000 

2,558,385 

1861-62 

2,412,006 

1867-68 

Disraeli 

955,000 

1,636,024 

1868-69 

Hunt 

2,078,000 

278,000 

2,380,824 

1870-71 

Lowe 

1,852,000 

1871-72 

>) 

2,713,000 

.. 

7,000 

1876-77 

Northcote 

774,000 

,. 

1877-73 

,, 

,. 

2,640,197 

1878-79 

i> 

4,559,676 

1,155,676 

2,291,817 

1879-80 

2,945,000 

.. 

2,840,698 

1882-83 

Gladstone 

200,000 

1884-85 

Childers 

1,043,000 

1,049,772 

1885-86 

,, 

14,932,000 

2,832,000 

2,642,543 

1S86-87 

Harcourt 

543,599 

,, 

^^ 

1889-90 

Goschen 

1,917,000 

*„' 

*.' 

1893-94 

Harcourt 

1,574,00b 

.. 

169,000 

1894-95 

J, 

4,502,000 

^, 

1895-96 

>> 

319,000 

1899-1900 

Hicks 

Beach 

2,640,000 

13,883,0001 

1900-190] 

II 

38,814,000 

22,541,000 

53,207,0001 

1901-2 

55,347,000 

48,87(5,000 

52,524,000 1 

1902-3 

^.  >j  . 

26,824,000 

24,174,000 

32,932,0001 

1903-4 

Ritchie 

5,415,000 

1904-5 

A.  Cham- 

berlain 

3,320,000 

.. 

.. 

1908-9 

Lloyd- 
George 

714,000 

1909-10 

>> 

15,762,000 

•• 

26,248,000  2 

1  South  African  war  period. 

2  Budget  of  the  year  not  passed  until  following  year. 
[For  earlier  years  see  Northcote,    Twenty   Years  oj 

Finaiicial  Policy,  1862  ;  Buxton,  Finance  and  Politics, 
1888.     See  also  Budget.]  t.  h.  e. 

DEFINITIONS.  Whately,  in  his  ninth 
"Introductory  Lecture  on  Polxtical  Economy" 
(published  1832),  observes  that  in  a  science  in 
which  terms  already  in  common  use  are  em- 
ployed there  is  greater  danger  of  neglecting 
questions  of  definition  than  in  a  case  where  the 
technical  terms  are  quite  new  to  the  student, 
and,  therefore,  obviously  demand  explanation. 
The  need  of  any  general  maxims  regarding  the 
definition  of  economic  terms  does  not  seem  to 
have  been  felt  till  after  the  appearance  of 
Ricardo's  chief  work.  Adam  Smith,  who  gave 
few  cut-and-dried  definitions,  had  generally 
used  words  in  the  sense  which  they  bore  in 
ordinary  language  and  had  endeavoured  to 
explain  and  illustrate  this  sense.     But  Ricardo, 


sometimes  disregarded  common  usage  alto- 
gether, and  attributed  entirely  new  significa- 
tions to  economic  terms.  For  instance,  he 
defined  the  rise  and  faU  of  wages,  rent,  and 
profit  in  such  a  way  that  wages  and  rent 
might  "fall"  when  they  had  "increased  one- 
half"  and  "  three -fourths  "  (Pri7iciples,  ch.  i. 
§  7,  in  Works,  p.  31).  Such  latitude  was 
sure  to  offend.  Malthus's  conservative  mind 
revolted  against  it,  and  in  his  Principles  (1820) 
he  protested  that  economists  were  not  at  liberty 
to  define  their  terms  just  as  they  pleased  (j). 
26).  In  1827  he  laid  down  in  his  Definitions 
in  Political  Economy  some  "rules  which  ought 
to  guide  political  economists  in  the  definition 
and  use  of  their  terms."  The  object  to  be  kept 
in  view,  he  says,  is  such  a  definition  and  appli- 
cation of  economic  terms  "as  will  enable  us 
most  clearly  and  conveniently  to  explain  the 
nature  and  causes  of  the  wealth  of  nations " 
(p.  4).  This  object  will  be  best  attained,  he 
thinks,  by  using  terms,  whenever  it  is  possible, 
in  the  sense  in  which  they  are  used  in  the 
common  conversation  of  educated  persons. 
When  it  is  necessary  to  make  distinctions 
which  are  not  made  in  common  conversation, 
the  previous  practice  of  economists,  and  especi- 
ally of  Adam  Smith,  should  be  followed,  and 
further  changes  only  admitted  when  it  can  be 
clearly  proved  that  they  would  decidedly  con- 
tribute to  the  advancement  of  the  science  (p. 
5).  Cairnes,  in  his  lecture  "Of  the  place  and 
purpose  of  Definition  in  Political  Economy" 
(Lect.  VI.  in  Logical  Method  of  Pol.  Econ., 
1857),  repeats  these  rules  in  substance,  but, 
less  conservative  than  Malthus,  insists  strongly 
on  the  necessity  of  gradually  improving  the 
definitions  of  economic  terms  as  knowledge  of 
the  science  increases.  In  a  frequently-quoted 
part  of  his  lecture  he  develops  a  proposition 
laid  down  by  Malthus  (in  Principles,  p.  25)  to 
the  effect  that  economic  distinctions  may  pro- 
perly resemble  the  distinction  between  animal 
and  vegetable  in  being  founded  on  differences 
of  degree.  Sidgwick  {Pol.  Econ.,  I.  ii.  §  1) 
observes  that  the  two  questions  what  is  com- 
monly meant  by  a  term  and  what  meaning  can 
most  conveniently  be  given  to  it  must  not  be 
confused  He  also  urges  powerfully  that  the 
process  of  searching  for  a  definition  is  extremely 
useful  altogether  apart  from  the  discovery  of  a 
satisfactory  one. 

It  must  not  be  forgotten  that  the  practical 
usefulness  of  political  economy  depends  chiefly 
on  its  wide  diff"usion,  so  that  the  formatiop 
of  an  economic  language  understood  only  by 
specialists  is  highly  undesirable.  For  the 
promotion  of  the  material  welfare  of  a  people 
few  things  can  be  more  useful  than  patient 
inquiry  into  the  actual  meaning  of  terms  like 
wealth,  income,  capital,  rent,  wages,  profits, 
when  used  in  common  language  by  ordinary 
people.     As  soon  as  ambiguities  and  inconsist 


DEFOE 


535 


eiicies  are  commonly  perceived,  language  may 
be  trusted  to  find  some  way  of  ridding  itself  of 
them  without  the  assistance  of  formal  defini- 
tions. 

Great  confusion  has  often  resulted  from  the 
practice  of  defining  mere  words  and  neglecting 
the  phrases  or  terms  of  which  the  words  con- 
stantly form  a  part.  For  instance,  many  defini- 
tions of  "wealth"  are  far  from  deciding  what 
is  meant  by  "  the  wealth  of  a  nation  "  or  "  the 
wealth  of  an  individual. "  E.  0. 

DEFOE,  Daniel  (1660  or  1661-1731), 
was  the  son  of  James  Foe,  a  retired  London 
tradesman  and  a  nonconformist.  At  the  age 
of  fourteen,  Daniel  was  sent  to  a  school  at 
Newington  Green,  kept  by  Mr.  Morton,  an 
ejected  nonconforming  minister.  Having  com- 
pleted his  education,  he  went  into  business. 
Keenly  interested  in  politics,  he  took  up  arms 
during  Monmouth's  rebellion  in  1685,  and 
joined  the  Prince  of  Orange's  army  in  1688. 

In  consequence,  perhaps,  of  not  giving  all 
his  mind  to  business,  he  failed  in  1692  for 
£17,000.  He  compounded  with  his  creditors, 
but  subsequently  paid  them  in  full.  He  had 
already  made  one  or  two  essays  in  litera- 
ture, and  about  this  time  composed  his  essay 
upon  Projects,  which  displays  his  practical  and 
inventive  turn,  recommending  the  establish- 
ment of  a  national  bank,  savings  banks,  friendly 
societies,  an  amendment  of  the  law  of  bank- 
ruptcy, and  improvements  in  education.  His 
first  hit  as  a  political  writer  was  with  a  doggerel 
poem,  the  True-horn  Englishman,  published  in 
1701,  which  ridiculed  the  exclusive  national 
pride  of  Englishmen,  and  their  grudge  against 
the  Dutch.  It  gained  for  Defoe  the  favourable 
notice  of  William  III.  Thenceforward  he 
found  constant  employment  as  a  journalist.  In 
1702  his  ironical  pamphlet,  The  Shortest  Way 
with  the  Dissenters,  led  to  his  conviction  for 
libel.  Released  from  prison  in  1704,  he  wrote 
first  for  Harley,  then  for  Godolphin,  and  for 
Harley  again  on  his  return  to  power.  But 
Defoe  was  again  committed  to  prison  in  1713, 
on  account  of  certain  writings  directed  against 
the  Jacobites.  Soon  afterwards  he  received  a 
pardon,  and  although  convicted  in  1715  for  a 
libel  on  Lord  Annesley,  he  was  not  sentenced, 
but  was  again  taken  into  the  service  of  the 
government.  Somewhat  later  he  produced  a 
series  of  works  of  special  economic  interest.  The 
Tour  through  Grreat  Britain,  published  1724-26  ; 
The  Complete  English  Tradesman,  published 
1725-27  ;  and  the  Plan  of  English  Commerce, 
published  1728.  He  had  combined  literature 
with  business,  and  was  fairly  prosperous  in  his 
later  years.  But  he  seems  to  have  met  with 
misfortune,  now  not  clearly  ascertainable,  before 
his  death  in  1731.  He  married  at  least  once, 
and  left  two  sons  and  four  daughters. 

Defoe  was  one  of  the  most  versatile  and 
voluminous  of  Encflish  writers.     Exclusive  of 


his  contributions  to  journals,  254  distinct  worka 
are  ascribed  to  him  by  his  biographer  Mr.  Lee, 
who  rejects  as  spurious  many  others  which  have 
been  ascribed  to  Defoe.  Some  of  those  enumer- 
ated, however,  appear  to  be  reprints.  Journal- 
ist, pamphleteer,  verse-maker,  novelist,  and 
moralist,  he  ranged  freely  over  the  varied 
interests  of  practical  life.  By  virtue  of  his 
lively  interest  in  concrete  things,  his  varied 
information,  and  his  vigorous  style,  he  is  an 
important  authority  for  economic  history, 
especially  for  the  condition  of  the  industrial 
.and  commercial  classes  in  the  first  part  of  the 
18th  century.  In  no  sense  a  scientific  writer, 
he  has  made  no  contribution  to  economic 
theory.  But  his  inventive  genius  occasionally 
suggested  improvements  in  the  economic  me- 
chanism of  the  nation,  and  his  lively  imagina- 
tion sometimes  placed  economic  truths  in  a 
singularly  vivid  light.  As  an  instance,  we 
may  take  from  Robinson  Crusoe — incomparably 
the  ablest  of  his  novels — Robinson  Crusoe's 
reflections  on  the  inutility  of  the  gold  and 
silver  which  he  found  on  the  wreck  of  the 
Spanish  ship  and  in  the  wreck  of  his  own 
ship,  and  which  to  him  was  not  wealth  at 
all.  "  I  smiled  to  myself  at  the  sight  of 
this  money  :  '  0  drug  ! '  said  I  aloud,  '  what 
art  thou  good  for  ?  Thou  art  not  worth  to  me, 
no,  not  the  taking  off  the  ground  :  one  of  those 
knives  is  worth  all  this  heap  :  I  have  no  manner 
of  use  for  thee.'  " 

[The  life  of  Defoe  has  been  written  by  Wilson 
(publ.  1830),  by  Chadwick  (publ.  1859),  by 
Lee  (publ.  1869). — See  also  Professor  Minto's 
Life  in  English  Men  of  Letters,  and  Mr.  Leslie 
Stephen's  Life  in  the  Dictionary  of  National 
Biography.'] 

For  a  complete  list  of  Defoe's  writings  so  far  as 
ascertained,  see  Lee's  Life.  Those  which  possess 
an  economic  interest  are  as  follows  :  An  Essay 
upon  Projects,  1697  (not  in  fact  published  until 
March  1698),  2nd  edition  1702.— The  Villainy  of 
Stock-jobbers  Detected  and  the  Causes  of  the  late 
Run  upon  the  Bank  and  Bankers  Discovered  and 
Considered,  1701. — Giving  Alms  no  Charity,  and 
Employing  the  Poor  a  Grievance  to  the  Nation 
(a  criticism  of  Sir  Humphrey  Mackworth's  Bill 
for  establishing  in  every  parish  a  manufactory 
for  the  employment  of  the  poor),  1704. — Remarks 
on  the  Bill  to  prevent  Frauds  committed  by 
Bankrupts,  1706. — An  Essay  upon  Public  Credit, 
and  An  Essay  upon  Loans,  1710.  —  An  Essay 
on  the  South  Sea  Trade,  1711. — An  Essay  on 
the  Treaty  of  Commerce  with  France,  1713. — 
Mercator,  or  Commerce  Revived  (a  paper  published 
thrice  a  week,  advocating  the  commercial  policy  of 
Harley  and  St.  John),  of  which  the  first  number 
appeared  26th  May  1713  and  the  last  20th 
July  1714. — Considerations  upon  the  Eighth  and 
Ninth  Articles  of  the  Treaty  of  Commerce  and 
Navigation  ; — Some  Thoughts  upon  the  Subject  of 
Comvierce  with  France  ;  and  A  General  History  of 
Trade,  all  published  in  1713. — Anatomy  of  Ex- 
change Alley,  1719. — The  Chimcera^  or  the  French 


536 


DEGREE  OF  UTILITY 


Way  of  Paying  National  Debts  Laid  Open,  1720. 
— A  Tour  thro'  the  whole  Island  of  Great  Britain, 
vol.  i.  1724,  vol.  ii.  1725,  vol.  iii.  1726,  repub- 
lished 1727  (subsequent  editions  being  all  more  or 
less  altered). — The  Complete  English  Tradesman, 
vol.  i.  1725,  vol.  ii,  1727. — Parochial  Tyrcfinny, 
1727. — A  Plan  of  the  English  Commerce,  1728, 
second  edition  1730. — An  Humble  Proposal  to 
the  People  of  England  for  the  Encrease  of  their 
Trade  and  Encouragement  of  their  Manufactures, 
1729.  r.  c,  M. 

DEGREE  OF  UTILITY.  This  phrase  was 
first  made  current  by  Jevons  in  his  Theory  of 
Political  Economy,  1871.  Its  precise  signifi- 
cance will  be  best  elucidated  by  an  analogy. 
'*  Degree  of  utility  "  stands  in  the  same  relation 
to  "total  utility"  as  "velocity"  to  "space 
traversed."  Suppose  we  have  a  body  pro- 
jected vertically  upwards  from  rest,  at  a  given 
speed.  We  may  inquire  first  at  what  height 
the  body  will  be  found  at  any  moment  after 
its  projection,  and  second  at  what  rate  it  will 
be  moving  at  any  point  of  its  course,  and 
clearly  the  rate  of  its  movement  is  the  rate  at 
Avhich  its  height  is  increasing  (whether  posi- 
tively as  it  rises,  or  negatively  as  it  falls).  This 
rate  may  be  measured  in  feet  per  second,  or  in 
miles  per  hour,  or  in  any  other  suitable  unit, 
but  in  any  case  it  varies  from  po^nt  to  point 
and  does  not  continue  the  same  during  any 
period,  however  short. 

We  must  now  extend  the  idea  of  measure- 
ment to  such  economic  conceptions  as  "satis- 
faction" and  "utility."  Measurement  consists 
essentially  in  determining  the  ratio  of  the  mag- 
nitude investigated  to  some  other  magnitude 
adopted  as  a  standard;  and  a  "satisfaction" 
would  accordingly  be  measured  if  we  could 
determine  its  ratio  to  some  standard  satisfac- 
tion, or,  which  amounts  to  the  same  thing, 
some  standard  dissatisfaction.  Thus  if  I  wish 
to  measure  the  satisfaction  derived  by  a  hungry 
man  from  the  consumption  of  a  certain  quantity 
of  bread,  I  may  inquire  how  much  labour  he 
Avould  perform,  under  stated  conditions,  rather 
than  go  without  it ;  or  what  he  would  pay  for 
it  sooner  than  go  without  if  an  unscrupulous 
monopolist  exacted  from  him  the  extreme 
famine  price.  Thus  if  we  take  any  standard 
we  choose  we  can,  ideally  at  least,  conceive  of 
any  concrete  "  utility  "  or  "  satisfaction  "  being 
measured  in  it.  But  we  must  remember  that 
such  measurements  are  based  on  the  relative 
magnitudes  of  different  satisfactions,  etc.,  to  one 
and  the  same  person,  and  do  not  profess  to  give 
us  means  of  comparing  a  satisfaction  experi- 
enced by  one  mind  with  a  satisfaction  experi- 
enced by  another  ;  for  no  one  can  say  that  the 
standard  unit  of  satisfaction  selected  means  the 
same  thing  to  two  different  men.  Nor  shall 
we  find  that  any  such  absolute  measui'ement  is 
needed  for  the  purpose  in  hand. 

Having  premised  so  much,  we  may  now 
work  out  the  economic  analogue  of  the  pro- 


jected body.  Suppose  we  take  such  a  com* 
modity  as  bread  supplied  to  a  hungry  man. 
Firstly,  we  may  inquire  what  amount  of  satis- 
faction the  man  has  derived  from  the  consump- 
tion of  any  given  quantity  of  bread  ;  in  which 
case  we  shall  be  investigating  the  "total 
utility"  or  "value  in  use"  of  that  quantity  of 
bread,  to  that  man,  under  those  conditions. 
Secondly,  we  may  inquire  at  Avhat  rate  (per 
ounce,  per  pound,  etc. )  the  consumption  of  the 
bread  is  conferring  satisfaction  upon  the  man 
at  any  point  in  the  course  of  his  meal ;  and  in 
that  case  we  shall  be  investigating  the  "degree 
of  utility"  of  the  bread.  This  "degi-ee  of 
utility  "  will  of  course  vary  from  point  to  point. 
When  the  man  was  at  his  hungriest  he  would 
be  deriving  relatively  great  satisfaction  per 
ounce  of  bread  consumed,  and  towards  the  end 
of  his  meal,  when  nearly  satisfied,  his  satisfac- 
tion per  ounce  would  be  relatively  small ;  and, 
theoretically,  it  will  not  remain  constant  during 
any  period,  however  short.  Now  this  * '  degree 
of  utility  "  is  obviously  the  rate  at  which  the 
"total  utility"  is  increasing;  just  as  the 
velocity  of  a  rising  or  falling  body  is  .the  rate 
at  which  "space  traversed"  or  "height"  is 
increasing. 

The  precise  relation  of  velocity  to  space 
traversed,  and  of  degree  of  utility  to  total 
utility,  is  expressed  mathematically  by  saying 
that  the  former  are  the  "differential  coeffi- 
cients," "first-derived  functions,"  or  "fluxions" 
of  the  latter  ;  and,  graphically,  if  the  latter  are 
expressed  by  areas  the  former  will  be  exj^ressed 
by  lines.     In  the  figure,  if  we  imagine  the  line 


c  d  moving  from  0  in  the  direction  of  the  arrow 
head,  at  a  uniform  rate,  to  represent  the  lapse 
of  time,  and  if  we  imagine  the  area  aO  cd  to 
represent  the  space  traversed  by  the  projected 
body  in  the  time  0  c,  then  the  intercept  c  d  will 
be  the  differential  coefficient  of  «  0  cd,  and  will 
represent  the  velocity  of  the  body,  or  the  rate 
at  which  it  is  rising,  at  the  point  of  time  repre- 
sented by  c.  Perhaps  this  will  be  sufficiently 
obvious  to  the  non -mathematical  reader  if  he 
reflects  that  velocity  represents  the  rate  at 
which  height  is  increasing,  as  time  lapses,  and 
observes  that  the  length  of  the  intercept  c  d 
likewise  determines  the  rate  at  which  the  area 


DE  LA  COURT— DELFICO 


637 


aOcd  increases  as  the  vertical  line  moves  in 
the  direction  of  the  arrow-head. 

Now  let  the  movement  of  the  vertical  from 
0  represent  the  consumption  of  the  bread,  so 
that  0  c  represents  the  amount  consumed  up 
to  any  given  point  of  the  meal  ;  and  let  a  0  c  ^ 
represent  the  total  satisfaction  derived  from 
the  consumption  up  to  the  point  reached,  then 
cd  will  still  be  the  differential  coefficient  of 
aO  cd,  and  will  represent  the  rate  per  unit 
(ounce,  etc.)  at  which  the  consumption  of  the 
bread  is  now  increasing  the  total  satisfaction 
reaped  by  the  consumer.  That  is  to  say  c  d 
represents  the  degree  of  utility  of  bread  at  the 
point  c,  the  amount  represented  by  0  c  having 
already  been  consumed. 

It  should  be  observed,  however,  that  when 
we  are  dealing  with  economic  quantities,  the 
line  a  d  will  probably  never  be  a  straight  line, 
but  always  a  curve  of  more  or  less  complexity  ; 
and  it  will  seldom  or  never  be  possible  to 
determine  its  actual  form  with  any  precision. 

The  main  interest  naturally  attaches  to  the 
degree  of  utility  of  that  increment  of  a  com- 
modity which  the  consumer  expects  to  obtain 
next,  or  which  he  may  have  to  relinquish,  that 
is  to  say  the  last  increment  he  has  secured  or 
the  next  he  hopes  to  secure.  This  is  called  by 
Jevons  the  "final  degree  of  utility"  (q.v.) 
Under  this  heading,  Final  Degree  of  Utility, 
references  to  the  most  important  books  on  the 
subject  will  be  found.  All  that  need  be  said 
here  is  that  the  analogy  of  the  moving  body 
insisted  on  above  was  developed  by  Professor 
Leon  AValras  of  Lausanne,  and  was  first  sug- 
gested by  his  father,  A.  A.  AValras  (see  Final 
Degree  of  Utility).  p.  h.  w. 

DE  LA  COURT..  See  Court,  Pieter  de  la. 

DE  LAJONCHERE  (beginning  of  the  18th 
century),  a  French  engineer,  was  one  of  the 
numerous  schemers  who  flourished  in  the  times 
of  Law  and  the  South  Sea  Company.  After 
having  written  on  the  fortification  of  large 
towns,  and  on  a  Projet  d'v/n,  Canal  de  Bourgognc 
pour  la  Communication  des  deux  Mers  (1718)  he 
published  his  SysUme  d'un  nouveau  Gouvey-ne- 
ment  en  Fran/ie  (Amsterdam  1720).  Although 
De  Lajonchere  expressly  denies  having  followed 
Vauban's  Dime  Royale,  he  starts  from  the  same 
initial  principle,  only,  as  was  aptly  remarked 
by  Dupin  {Oeconomiques,  iii.  210),  he  urges  it 
in  an  extravagant  manner.  He  advocates  one 
sole  tax,  to  be  paid  without  privilege  or  exemp- 
tion, by  all  Frenchmen  without  distinction,  to 
consist  of  a  percentage  collected  in  money  or 
in  kind,  on  the  general  produce  of  the  ground, 
mines,  quarries,  etc.,  by  a  "Compagnie  du 
Commerce,"  to  be  formed  for  the  purpose. 
This  company  was  to  have  the  monopoly  of 
foreign  trade,  its  shares  being  given  as  re- 
imbursement of  the  price  of  all  the  offices  sold 
by  the  king's  predecessors  and  of  the  capital  of 
the  rents  due  to  towns  or  individuals.     The 


com  collected  by  the  company  was  to  be  sold 
at  a  permanently  fixed  price.  The  comjjany 
was  also  to  be  entrusted  with  the  recoinage 
and  "diminutions"  of  the  metallic  currency, 
which  were  to  bring  it  down  to  what  De 
Lajonchere  calls  "its  intrinsic  value." 

[See  art.  {Journal  des  ^conomistes,  9th  Feb. 
18(53)  "Unj^mule  de  Law,"  by  de  Lavergiie.] 

E.  Ca. 

DE  LA  MARE,  Nicolas  (1639-1723),  ori- 
ginally a  ^nocureur-general,  later  on  a  conseiller 
commissaire  of  the  Chatelet  in  Paris,  was  not  an 
original  thinker,  but  a  most  industrious,  clear, 
and  conscientious  compiler,  and  his  Traill  de  la 
Police  (Paris,  1722-1735,  4  vols,  in  folio,  2nd 
ed.)  is  a  copious  mine  of  information.  The 
second  volume  (book  v.)  deals  with  the 
regulation  of  food  in  general,  and  of  corn  in 
particular.  In  it  will  be  found,  "according 
to  their  order,  all  the  laws,  ordinances,  and 
decrees,  which  have  provided  for  this  subject 
with  as  much  force  as  wisdom."  This  sentence, 
taken  from  the  preface,  is  completely  character- 
istic of  the  scope  of  De  la  Mare's  work,  and 
of  his  commentaries.  They  were  begun  in 
1677  at  the  request  of  the  president  of  the 
Parliament  of  Paris,  M.  de  Lamoignon,  and  an 
abridgement  was  made  in  1758  and  1769  by 
La  Poix  de  Freminville  in  his  Traill  de  la  Police. 
This,  however,  does  not  enable  the  reader  to 
dispense  with  consulting  the  original,    e.  Ca. 

DEL  CREDERE.  A  factor,  broker,  or 
mercantile  agent  who  undertakes  to  become 
surety  for  the  solvency  of  the  customer  with 
whom  he  transacts  a  sale,  receives  for  this  an 
extra  commission  called  a  del  credere  commis- 
sion. A.  D. 

DELEGATION.  Description  used  by  con- 
tinental bankers  of  a  document  drawn  in  the 
form  of  a  letter  of  credit  but  intended  to  pass 
from  hand  to  hand  like  a  bill  of  exchange. 
These  documents  are  used  on  the  continent  for 
the  purpose  of  evading  the  stamp  laws ; 
English  bankers  are,  however,  in  the  habit  of 
treating  them  as  ordinary  bills  of  exchange. 
They  are  generally  sent  out  for  acceptance  pro- 
vided with  the  bill  stamp  and  presented  after 
the  expiration  of  the  days  of  grace.  It  is  by 
no  means  certain  what  effect  would  be  given  to 
the  acceptance  of  such  a  document  in  a  court 
of  law,  'but  as  they  are  generally  addressed  to 
banks  and  commercial  houses  of  good  standing, 
and  are  drawn  at  very  short  dates,  the  question 
is  not  likely  to  arise.  e.  s. 

DELFICO,  Melchiorre  (born  in  the  latter 
half  of  the  past  century  at  Leognano,  died 
about  1835  at  Teramo),  is  generally  remembered 
only  for  his  Memoria  sulla  liberfA  del  Com- 
mercio,  which  has  been  included  by  Custodi  in 
his  Scrittori  Glassici  ;  but  this  does  not  quite 
do  justice  to  Delfico,  although  undoubtedly  his 
pamphlet  on  free  trade  is  his  principal  contribu- 
tion to  economic  science.     Delfico  was  not  only 


638 


DELICTUM— DELI  VERY 


an  absolute  free  trader,  but  also  what  would  now 
be  called  an  "absolute  individualist,"  believing 
in  the  beneficial  effects  of  unlimited  liberty  of 
the  individual  in  any  sort  of  economical  activity. 
Landed  proprietors,  merchants,  and  evire- 
prcTieurs  in  the  interest  of  the  community 
ought  to  be  left  to  themselves  and  allowed 
to  do  with  their  property  whatever  they 
pleased. 

Delfico,  in  his  Rifiessioni  sulla  vendita  dei 
feudi  and  in  his  Lettera  al  Duca  di  Cantalupo, 
defends  the  abolition  of  feudal  rights  over  landed 
properties  and  their  sale ;  he  sees  in  them  an 
impediment  to  the  proper  cultivation  of  the 
land,  which  gives  greater  returns  when  the 
proprietor  is  able  to  do  with  it  what  he  likes. 
For  the  same  reason  he  insists  on  the  abolition 
of  obnoxious  rights  like  those  consisting  in  the 
right  of  the  community  to  graze  its  cattle  on 
the  lands  of  the  proprietors,  which  renders  all 
sorts  of  plantations  impossible  {Memoria  per 
V  aholizione  delta  servitii  delpascolo  and  Discorso 
sul  Tavoliere  di  Fuglia).  All  Delfico's  other  writ- 
ings are  occupied  principally  with  different  as- 
pects of  the  free-trade  question.  He  argues  that 
a  dearth  of  food  would  never  happen  if  there 
were  free  trade,  and  that  the  means  to  which 
governments  usually  have  recourse  to  avoid  it, 
or  to  abate  it,  aggravate  famine  by  making 
production  unsafe  and  deterring  merchants  from 
risking  their  capital. 

Although  these  doctrines  were  not  new, 
coming  ten  and  twenty  years  after  Smith's 
criticism  of  the  protective  system,  Delfico  merits 
remembrance  as  a  thoroughgoing  follower  of 
liberal  doctrines  in  a  time  when  as  yet  they 
were  very  rare. 

The  writings  in  which  Delfico  defends  the 
principle  of  liberty  and  absolute  property  are  in 
order  of  date  the  following : — Memoria  sul  Tri- 
bunate della  Qrascia  e  suite  leggi  economiche  nelle 
provincie  confinanti  del  Regno,  Napoli,  1785. — 
Mernoria  sulla  necessitd  di  rendere  uniformi  i  pesi 
e  le  misure  del  Regno,  Napoli,  1787. — Memoria 
per  V  aholizione  a  moderazione  della  sermtH  del 
pascolo  invernale,  detto  dei  Regi  stucchi,  nelle 
provincie  marittime  di  Abruzzo,  Napoli,  1787. — 
Discorso  sul  Tavoliere  di  Fuglia  e  su  la  necessitd 
di  abolire  il  sistema  doganale  presente  e  non  darsi 
luogo  ad  alcuna  temporanea  riforma,  Napoli, 
1788. — Rifiessioni  su  la  vendita  dei  Feudi,  Napoli, 
1790. — Lettera  a  Sua  Fee.  il  sig.  Buca  di  Can- 
talupo, Napoli,  1795. — Memoria  sulla  libertd  del 
commercio,  Accademia  di  Padova,  1797. — Ragio- 
namento  suite  carestie,  Accademia  di  Napoli, 
1818. — Espressioni  delta  particolare  riconoscenza 
della  provincia  e  cittd  di  Teramo,  dovuta  alia 
memoria  dell'  immortale  Ferdinando  I.,  1833. — 
Annali  civili  del  regno  delle  Due  Sicilie,  vol.  i. 

M.  p. 

DELICTUM.  Expression  of  Roman  law 
denoting  a  wrongful  act — not  being  a  breach 
of  contract — which  gave  the  aggrieved  party 
the  right  to  claim  damages.     The  term  corre- 


sponds in  a  certain  measure  to  the  expressioc 
Tort  {q.v.)  used  in  English  legal  language. 

E.  S. 

DELIVERY  (of  Bills  of  Exchange).  Ac 
cording  to  the  law  of  the  United  Kingdom,  a 
contract  on  a  bill  of  exchange  is  incomplete  and 
revocable  until  delivery  of  the  instrument.  The 
drawer  of  a  bill  of  exchange  may,  after  having 
accepted  it,  cancel  the  acceptance  as  long  aa 
the  bill  has  not  been  returned  to  the  holder,  i 
unless  he  has  actually  informed  the  holder  that  1 
the  biU  has  been  accepted  (Bill  of  Exchange  » 
Act,  §  21).  This  is  not  so  according  to 
German  law  ;  a  German  acceptor  having  once 
affixed  his  signature  to  the  bill  is  irrevocably 
bound  (German  code,  §  21).  The  delivery 
required  by  English  law  need  not  consist  of  an 
actual  transfer  of  possession,  but  may  be  a  con- 
structive delivery  (see  Delivery  of  chattels). 
As  according  to  the  regulations  of  the  English 
post-office  a  letter,  after  being  posted,  cannot 
be  recalled  by  the  sender,  the  posting  of  the 
letter  constitutes  a  delivery.  In  some  other 
countries,  the  sender  may  stop  the  delivery  of 
a  letter  ;  where  this  is  permissible  the  delivery 
would  only  be  final  when  the  letter  has  reached 
the  address  to  which  it  has  been  directed. 

B.  s. 

DELIVERY  (of  Deeds).     See  Deed. 

DELIVERY  (of  Chattels).  In  all  systems 
of  ancient  law  legal  results  are  attained  by 
solemn  and  overt  acts  only.  To  admit  of  the 
possibility  of  altering  rights  of  ownership  or  of 
creating  obligations  enforceable  by  judicial  pro- 
cess without  the  use  of  recognised  formalities 
is  a  refinement  which  undoubtedly  is  familiar 
in  the  later  stages  of  Roman  jurisprudence,  but 
which  was  slow  to  penetrate  into  Germanic 
countries.  The  principle  of  allowing  the  law 
to  protect  facts  and  relations  created  by  the 
mutual  consent  of  the  parties  concerned — some- 
times authenticated  by  written  documents,  but 
in  many  cases  without  writing  or  formality  of 
any  kind — is  now  thoroughly  established  in 
all  civilised  countries ;  but  traces  of  the  older 
modes  of  thought  are  still  conspicuously  im- 
pressed on  modern  law,  and  more  particularly 
on  the  systems  of  law  administered  in  English- 
speaking  countries.  The  old  common  law  rule 
was  that  no  change  of  ownership  could  be 
effected  without  a  formal  delivery  to  the  new 
owner,  called  "livery  of  seisin,"  an  expression 
afterwards  used  in  the  case  of  land  only.  Land 
is  now  transferred  by  deed,  and  "livery  of 
seisin  "  is  a  thing  of  the  past,  but  delivery  is 
subject  to  the  exceptions  to  be  presently 
mentioned,  necessary  in  all  cases  where  pro- 
perty in  chattels  is  to  pass  from  one  person  to 
another.  Delivery,  according  to  modern  views 
does  not,  however,  necessarily  involve  a  visible 
change  of  possession.  There  may  be  a  con- 
structive delivery,  as  where  a  person  holding 
goods   in  one  capacity  (e.g.   as  agent   for  A) 


DELIVERY— DEMAND 


639 


begins  to  hold  them  in  another  capacity  (e.g. 
as  agent  for  B — this  is  a  delivery  from  A  to  B)  ; 
or  there  may  be  a  symbolical  delivery  (e.g.  the 
delivery  of  the  keys  of  a  warehouse  where 
certain  goods  are  may  operate  as  a  delivery  of 
the  goods).  The  delivery  of  documents  of  title 
relating  to  goods  {e.g.  a  bill  of  lading)  has 
generally  the  same  effect  as  the  delivery  of  the 
goods.  The  exceptions  to  which  reference  has 
been  made  above  are  the  following :  the  pro- 
perty in  chattels  can  now  be  transferred  without 
delivery — (a)  by  Deed  (q.v.)  ;  (b)  by  a  sale, 
where  the  parties  expressly  or  by  necessary 
implication  agree  that  the  change  of  property 
is  to  take  place  immediately  on  conclusion  of 
the  bargain  (a  sale  of  this  kind  is  known  by 
the  technical  name  of  bargain  and  sale).  The 
exceptions  comprise  a  large  class  of  transactions, 
but  modern  legislation,  in  view  of  the  dangers 
resulting  from  secret  changes  of  ownership — 
which  enable  insolvent  traders  to  make  a  show 
of  property  not  available  for  their  general 
creditors — has,  by  means  of  the  Bill  of  Sale  Acts 
(see  Bill  of  Sale)  introduced  new  safeguards 
(see  the  elaborate  judgment  of  the  court  of 
appeal  in  Cochrane  v.  Moore,  Law  Reports,  25 
Queen's  Bench  Division,  p.  57  ;  also  Benjamin 
on  Sales.  E.  s. 

DELIVERY,  Good.  On  the  stock  ex- 
change stock  is  said  to  be  delivered  when  it  is 
actually  supplied  to  the  buyer,  and  the  delivery 
is  good  or  not  according  to  the  rules  of  the 
stock  exchange,  and  the  nature  of  the  contract 
between  the  buyer  and  the  seller.  Contracts 
are  largely  made  in  a  manner  too  rough  and 
ready  to  permit  attention  to  every  stipulation. 
That  is  understood,  and  when  a  dispute  arises 
the  Committee  of  the  London  Stock  Exchange 
is  appealed  to,  and  the  decision  often  turns 
upon  the  question  whether  the  stock  or  share 
tendered  by  the  seller  constitutes  a  ' '  good  de- 
livery." If,  for  example,  the  numbers  on  the 
shares  delivered  are  not  the  numbers  which 
have  obtained  an  official  quotation  on  tlie  stock 
exchange,  the  delivery  is  bad  and  not  good. 
If,  for  another  example,  the  shares  in  an 
American  railway  do  not  bear  the  proper  stamp 
imposed  in  this  country,  the  delivery  again  is 
not  good,  but  is  not  irremediably  bad.  The 
term  "good  delivery"  covers  compliance  with 
the  official  rules  and  reasonable  conditions  on 
which  business  is  transacted  in  the  stock  ex- 
change, but,  in  practice,  the  question  only 
arises  in  two  cases — first,  when  the  numbers  of 
the  securities  do  not  agree  with  those  for  which 
an  official  quotation  has  been  granted,  and 
second,  when  the  bond  has  been  tampered  with 
by  the  holder.  This  often  happens  through 
coupons  being  carelessly  cut  off,  or  having  the 
name  of  the  holder  written  on  them  in  ink,  or 
through  being  torn  or  damaged.  a.  e. 

DE  LUCA,  Giovanni  Battista  (1614-83), 
was  born  at  Venosa,  became  a  lawyer  in  Naples, 


and  was  made  cardinal  by  the  pope  Innocent 
XL  De  Luca  is  best  known  as  a  lawyer,  but 
he  wrote  also  on  economical  and  fiscal  questions 
in  his  two  treatises  :  Theatrum  veritatis  et 
justitice,  Romae,  1669  ;  and  H  Principe  cristiano 
pratico,  Roma,  1679. 

As  an  economist  he  is  a  "  mercantilist "  of  the 
very  narrowest  species.  International  commerce, 
in  his  opinion,  is  only  a  means  of  getting 
money  from  foreigners  ;  raw  materials  are  to 
be  allowed  to  be  imported,  but  their  export  is  to 
be  prohibited,  because  only  when  they  are  trans- 
formed by  national  industry  will  they  procure  a 
favourable  balance  of  commerce.  ]\loney  is  not 
to  be  falsified  by  the  prince,  but  its  export,  and 
also  the  export  of  bullion,  is  to  be  prohibited, 
except  for  the  acquisition  of  those  wares  which 
cannot  be  produced  by  the  country.  Fanunes 
are  to  be  guarded  against  by  a  subtle  system  of 
regulation. 

In  normal  times  agriculture  is  to  be  aided 
and  importation  of  foreign  produce  to  be  pro- 
hibited. In  case  of  famine  all  are  to  sell  their 
produce  to  a  public  office  (UJicio  annonario,  a 
sort  of  store  for  corn  under  government  adminis- 
tration), which  is  not  to  pay  for  it  immediately, 
because  in  similar  calamities  "men  tend  to  be- 
come communists."  Supporting  economical 
doctrines  such  as  these,  De  Luca  shows  himself 
to  have  been  inferior  to  a  great  many  of  his  con- 
temporaries, who  had  already  seen  through  the 
grossest  eiTors  of  the  mercantile  system.  In 
financial  questions  he  takes  a  better  position. 
First  of  all  he  has  a  clear  idea  of  the  historical 
relativity  of  institutions,  so  that  when  he  dis- 
cusses the  question,  whether  direct  taxes  are  to 
be  imposed  with  the  consent  of  parliaments,  he 
insists  upon  this  being  decided  differently  in 
dififerent  nations,  and  with  due  regard  to  the 
different  customs  and  political  maturity  of  the 
various  nations. 

Taxes  in  general,  he  considers,  ought  to  be 
levied  in  such  a  manner  that  people  pay  them 
insensibly,  that  tax  collectors  cannot  exact 
more  than  the  government  receives,  that  all 
citizens,  without  privilege  and  exemption,  come 
to  bear  a  proportionately  equal  burden,  and 
that  no  tax  be  imposed  when  not  absolutely 
necessary  for  the  existence  of  the  state.  De 
Luca  distinguishes  correctly  the  revenue  from 
the  private  property  of  the  sovereign,  and 
makes  a  most  minute  examination  of  all  tlie 
different  descriptions  of  crown  rights.  He 
defends  the  state  monopoly  of  salt  and  tobacco. 

M.  p. 

DEMAND.  By  "demand"  in  jwlitical 
economy  is  meant  what  may  be  more  distinc- 
tively called  effective  demand,  that  is,  not  the 
mere  desire  for  anything,  but  desire  accompanied 
bv  the  offer  of  something  valuable  m  exchange. 
When,  therefore,  there  is  a  demand  Tor  any 
commodity  or  service,  there  must  be  a  supply 
of  some  other  commodity  or  service,  which  is 


540 


DEMAND 


proffered  in  exchange  for  it ;  and  when  two 
persons  are  engaged  in  exchange,  what  the  one 
demands  the  other  supplies,  and  vice  versd. 
It  follows  that  demand  and  supply  considered 
as  aggregates  are  strictly  interdependent,  and 
that  neither  can  increase  or  diminish  without 
necessitating  a  corresponding  increatse  or  diminu- 
tion of  the  other.  This  simple  consideration 
disposes  of  the  fallacy  that  there  may  be  an 
over-supply  of  commodities  in  general.  At  the 
same  time,  the  two  different  aspects  of  the 
phenomenon  of  exchange  are  clearly  to  be 
distinguished  from  one  another.  Demand 
depends  upon  men's  desires  to  satisfy  their 
wants  by  acquiring  a  command  over  new  goods 
or  services,  supply  upon  their  willingness  to 
undergo  efforts  or  part  with  goods  already  in 
their  possession.  Some  of  the  older  economists, 
e.g.  Ricardo,  tended  to  concentrate  attention 
upon  the  conditions  determining  the  supply  of 
commodities,  to  the  comparative  neglect  of  the 
analysis  of  demand.  This  aspect  of  the  problem 
has,  however,  been  brought  into  special  pro- 
minence in  recent  years  by  the  full  discussions 
of  "utility"  and  ''subjective  value,"  which 
are  characteristic  of  Jevons  and  the  Austrian 
school.  The  importance  of  a  full  consideration 
of  the  side  of  demand  as  well  as  of  supply  also 
receives  ample  recognition  in  Professor  Marshall's 
Frinciples  of  Economics. 

Assuming  the  use  of  a  medium  of  exchange 
which  represents  general  purchasing  power, 
the  question  has  been  raised  whether  the  de- 
mand for  any  commodity  should  be  measured 
by  the  quantity  of  the  commodity  demanded  or 
by  the  quantity  of  purchasing  power  offered 
in  exchange  for  it.  Cairnes,  criticising  Mill, 
considers  that  on  scientific  grounds  we  are 
bound  to  select  the  latter  of  these  alternatives. 
There  is  not,  however,  any  fundamental  diflfer- 
ence  between  the  two  when  properly  interpreted. 
The  quantity  of  any  commodity  which  people 
are  willing  to  buy,  and  the  amount  of  money 
which  they  are  willing  to  spend  upon  it,  are, 
generally  speaking,  equally  indeterminate  so 
long  as  nothing  is  said  as  to  the  price  at  which 
it  is  to  be  had.  If,  then,  we  measure  demand 
by  quantity  demanded,  it  can  only  be  Avith 
reference  to  some  particular  price  or  schedule  of 
prices  ;  and  hence  some  specific  quantity  of 
purchasing  power  offered  is  necessarily  implied. 
But  the  same  is  true,  mutatis  mutandis,  if  we 
start  from  the  quantity  of  purchasing  power 
offered.  For  example,  to  say  that  at  half-a- 
crown  a  pound  you  will  buy  six  pounds  of  tea 
is  precisely  equivalent  to  saying  that  at  that 
price  you  will  spend  fifteen  shillings  on  tea. 
It  may  sometimes  be  more  convenient  to  adopt 
the  mode  of  expression  preferred  by  Cairnes  ; 
but  usually  the  other  alternative  is  simpler  and 
less  liable  to  lead  to  error,  since  supply  and 
demand  can  in  this  case  be  more  directly  com- 
pared  and   equated.       The   demand    for    any 


commodity  at  a  given  price  may  then  be 
measured  by  the  amount  that  would  be  pur- 
chased if  obtainable  at  that  price  ;  and  the 
supply  at  a  given  price  may  be  con-espondingly 
measured  by  the  amount  that  would  be  offered 
for  sale  at  that  price.  If  the  amount  instead 
of  the  price  is  regarded  as  the  independent 
variable,  then  the  demand -price  for  a  given 
amount  of  any  commodity  may  be  defined  as 
the  price  just  required  to  attract  purchasers  for 
that  particular  amount ;  and  correspondingly  the 
supply-price  as  the  price  just  required  to  cause 
that  particular  amount  to  be  offered  for'  sale. 

It  is  clear,  however,  that  the  circumstances 
of  demand  will  be  very  incompletely  expressed, 
if  given  with  reference  to  some  one  particular 
price  only  or  some  one  particular  amount  only. 
We  need  what  Professor  Marshall  calls  a 
demand -schedule,  in  which  the  demand  at 
varying  prices  is  recorded.  For  example,  it 
may  be  that  in  the  early  spring  a  person  will 
buy  one  basket  of  strawberries  at  ten  shillings 
a  basket,  two  at  seven  shillings  and  sixpence, 
three  at  six  shillings,  four  at  five  shillings,  and 
so  on.  A  statement  of  this  kind  is  said  to 
constitute  his  demand-schedule  for  strawberries 
at  the  time  in  question.  If  the  requisite 
knowledge  were  forthcoming  it  would  be  possible 
to  draw  up  a  schedule  of  the  same  kind  repre- 
senting the  total  demand  for  any  commodity 
within  a  given  range  and  over  a  given  period. 
The  variation  of  demand  with  price  may  also  be 
expressed  diagrammatically,  and  the  exposition 
of  the  general  theory  of  supply  and  demand 
may  be  much  facilitated  thereby  (see  Demand 
Curves). 

With  improved  statistics  of  consumption, 
towards  which  valuable  contributions  might  be 
afforded  by  shopkeepers'  books  and  the  great 
co-operative  stores,  it  might  be  possible  to 
draw  up  empirical  demand-schedules  represent- 
ing approximately  the  actual  variation  of 
demand  with  price  for  certain  commodities  in 
general  use.  As  Cournot  remarks:  "If  we 
suppose  the  conditions  of  demand  to  remain  the 
same,  but  the  conditions  of  production  to 
change,  because  the  expenses  of  production  are 
raised  or  lowered,  or  monopolies  put  on  or 
suppressed,  or  taxes  increased  or  diminished, 
or  import  duties  imposed  or  removed,  then 
price  will  vary,  and  the  corresponding  varia- 
tions in  demand  will  give  us  our  empirical 
tables  "  (Principes  de  la  Theorie  des  Bichesses, 
§  56).  But,  as  is  also  recognised  by  Cournot, 
the  conditions  of  demand  rarely  do  remain  the 
same  for  any  considerable  length  of  time. 
There  are  constantly  in  progress  independent 
changes,  such  as  changes  in  fashions  and  habits, 
in  the  purchasing  power  of  money,  in  the 
wealth  and  circumstances  of  consumers,  and 
the  like,  which  cause  the  demand  at  a  given 
price  itself  to  vary.  Since,  therefore,  the 
statistical  calculation  would  have  to  cover  a 


I  ^\  I 


DEMAND 


541 


more  or  less  prolonged  period  of  time,  it  would 
always  be  liable  to  be  vitiated  by  the  eilects  of 
such  changes  as  the  above,  except  in  so  far  as 
these  effects  could  themselves  be  estimated  and 
allowed  for. 

For  theoretical  purposes,  however,  the  inquiry 
into  the  variation  of  demand  with  price  is  of 
thegreatest  value  and  importance,  independently 
of  any  exact  empirical  constructions.  Without 
elaborate  statistics  it  is  possible  to  determine  a 
law  of  demand  to  which  all  demand-schedules 
will  conform,  namely,  that — other  things  being 
equal — a  rise  in  price  will  be  accompanied  by  a 
diminished  demand  and  a  fall  in  price  by  an 
increased  demand.  Looked  at  from  tlie  other 
side,  the  law  may  also  be  expressed  by  saying 
that  the  greater  the  amount  of  any  commodity 
offered  for  sale  in  a  market  the  lower  will  be 
the  price  at  which  it  will  find  purchasers. 

The  above  law  of  demand  is  a  corollary  from 
the  law  of  diminishing  utility,  namely,  that 
the  additional  satisfaction  which  a  person 
derives  from  an  additional  increment  of  any 
commodity  diminishes  as  the  stocjc  of  the 
commodity  already  in  his  possession  increases. 
For  it  clearly  follows  from  this  law  of  diminish- 
ing utility  that  if  the  general  purchasing  power 
of  money  remains  unchanged,  then,  as  tlie 
amount  of  a  thing  which  a  person  already  has 
increases,  the  price  that  he  is  just  willing  to 
give  for  an  additional  increment  will  diminish. 

It  is  an  im])ortant  question  how  far  continuity 
may  be  assumed  in  the  variation  of  demand 
with  price,  so  that  any  alteration  in  the  latter, 
however  slight,  cannot  fail  to  be  accompanied 
by  some  alteration  in  the  former.  Such  an 
assumption  clearly  cannot,  in  general,  be  justified 
so  far  as  the  demand  of  individual  consumers  is 
concemed.  Individual  changes  in  demand  will 
almost  always  be  discontinuous  ;  in  other 
words,  there  will  almost  always  be  more  or  less 
wide  limits  of  price  within  which  demand  will 
be  constant.  The  price  of  coal,  for  example, 
might  go  on  rising  for  some  time  without  lead- 
ing any  given  householder  to  reduce  his  con- 
sumption of  coal,  although  he  would  probably 
take  steps  to  economise  to  a  material  extent 
when  the  rise  in  price  reached  a  certain  point. 
It  is  different,  however,  when  we  consider  the 
aggregate  demand  for  a  commodity  in  general 
use.  Individuals  of  all  degrees  of  wealth  and 
all  varieties  of  taste  will  now  contribute  towards 
the  result,  and  it  becomes  a  fair  assumption  that 
every  change  in  price  will  affect  the  demand  of 
certain  of  them,  even  if  it  leaves  the  demand  of 
others  unaffected.  It  may  further  be  assumed 
that,  as  Couniot  puts  it,  "demand  does  not 
pass  suddenly  from  one  amount  to  another  with- 
out passing  through  the  intermediate  amounts." 
The  assumption  of  continuity  becomes,  fof 
obvious  reasons,  specially  important  in  tlie 
mathematical  or  diagi'ammatic  treatment  of  the 
law  of  demand. 


In  speaking  of  demand  as  varying  with  price, 
it  is  not  of  course  intended  to  imply  that  there 
is  any  exact  proportion  in  which  the  one  rises 
or  falls  as  the  other  falls  or  rises.  No  two 
commodities  are  likely  exactly  to  resemble  one 
another  in  this  respect,  and  even  in  the  case  of 
the  same  commodity  there  will  he  dilierences  at 
different  points.  Thus,  supposing  price  to  fall 
fifty  per  cent,  demand  might  in  some  cases  be 
increased  two  or  three  hundred  per  cent  ;  it  is 
possible,  for  instance,  that  quite  a  new  class  of 
consumers  might  now  be  induced  to  buy  the 
commodity,  or  it  might  be  worth  while  to  put 
it  to  quite  a  new  use.  In  other  cases,  the 
increase  in  demand  might  not  exceed  ten  or 
fifteen  per  cent,  the  wants  of  old  purchasers 
being  quickly  satiated,  and  not  many  new 
purchasers  being  attracted.  In  the  former  case, 
demand  is  said  to  be  very  elastic  ;  and  in  the 
latter  case  very  inelastic.  Professor  Marshall 
gives  the  following  definition  :  "The  elasticity 
of  demand  in  a  market  is  great  or  small  accord- 
ing as  the  amount  demanded  increases  much 
or  little  for  a  given  fall  in  price,  and  diminishes 
much  or  little  for  a  given  rise  in  price " 
(Principles  of  Economics,  vol.  i.  1891,  p.  160)  ; 
and  he  afterwards  lays  down,  as  a  general  law  of 
variation  of  the  elasticity  of  demand,  the  prin- 
ciple that  as  a  rule  the  elasticity  of  demand  ot 
any  given  class  of  consumers  for  a  given  com- 
modity is  great  for  medium  prices,  and  small 
for  those  which,  relatively  to  the  means  of  the 
consumers  in  question,  are  very  high  or  very 
low.  For  so  long  as  price  remains  very  high 
considerable  elasticity  is  out  of  the  question, 
while  it  may,  on  the  otlier  hand,  fall  so  low  as 
to  reach  what  may  be  called  satiety  point, 
consumers  already  buying  as  much  as  they 
practically  care  to  consume.  It  is  important 
to  recognise  that  at  any  given  point  the  demand 
of  one  class  of  consumers  may  be  elastic,  while 
that  of  other  classes  is  inelastic.  In  tlie  case 
of  game,  for  example,  the  demand  of  the  upper 
middle  class  at  the  present  time  in  England  is 
probably  very  elastic,  while  it  is  much  less  so 
on  the  part  of  the  rich,  whose  consumption 
would  not  appreciably  be  affected  except  in 
the  case  of  very  great  scarcity,  and  on  the  part 
of  the  lower  middle  and  working  classes,  for 
whom  any  moderate  fall  would  still  leave  the 
price  too  high. 

Unless  we  confine  ourselves  to  very  short 
periods  of  time,  demand-schedules  are  them- 
selves liable  to  modification.  For  the  condi- 
tions of  demand  are  constantly  changing  ;  and 
this,  as  we  have  already  seen,  is  one  of  the 
chief  difficulties  in  the  way  of  obtaining  accurate 
empirical  data  in  regard  to  the  variation  of 
demand  with  price.  A  change  of  fashion,  for 
example,  might  cause  the  demand  for  lace  to 
be  gieater  at  every  point  throughout  the  list 
of  prices.  A  spread  of  teetotalism  would. 
ccetei-'is  paribus,  have  a  similar  effect  upon  the 


542 


DEMAND— DEMAND  CURVES 


o> 


^ 


p 


demand-schedules  for  certain  kinds  of  drink  ; 
and  an  increase  of  population  upon  the  demand- 
schedules  for  most  kinds  of  food.  In  all  these 
cases  there  may  be  said  to  be  a  rise  in  the 
demand-schedule. 

In  connection  with  this  point,  attention  may 
be  called  to  an  ambiguity  generally  attaching 
to  expressions  that  relate  to  variations  in 
demand.  The  law  of  demand  above  laid  down 
is  the  statement  of  a  variation  of  demand  with 
price  which  is  manifested  in  every  demand- 
schedule  ;  and  it  may  perhaps  be  said  to  relate 
to  a  static  condition  of  things,  in  which  there 
is  supposed  to  be  no  change  in  the  number  of 
purchasers  or  in  their  circumstances  or  tastes. 
But  Ave  may  pass  to  the  hypothesis  of  a  dynamic 
condition,  in  which  such  changes  as  these  do 
take  place.  We  then  have  to  recognise,  as  just 
pointed  out,  that  the  amount  of  any  commodity 
demanded  at  a  given  price  is  itself  subject  to 
variation,  or  that,  in  other  words,  demand- 
schedules  may  themselves  rise  or  fall.  By  an 
"  increase  of  demand,"  therefore,  may  be  meant 
either,  first,  the  extension  of  demand  which 
results  under  static  conditions  from  a  fall  in 
price,  or,  secondl};-,  an  increase  in  the  quantity 
demanded  at  a  given  price  which  may  occur 
under  dynamic  conditions.  Professor  Sidgwick, 
who  explains  this  ambiguity  very  clearly,  re- 
marks that  it  will  be  convenient  to  have  two 
unambiguous  terms  to  distinguish  the  two 
different  kinds  of  change  in  demand  ;  and  he 
accordingly  proposes  to  speak  of  the  former 
kind  of  increase  as  an  extension  of  demand,  and 
of  the  latter  as  a  rise  or  intensification  of 
demand.  For  the  opposites  of  "extension" 
and  "rise"  respectively,  he  uses  the  terms 
"  reduction  "  and  "fall"  {Principles  of  Political 
Economy,  1887,  p.  179). 

[The  articles  on  Final  Degree  of  Utility, 
Supply,  and  Supply  and  Demand,  Equilibrium 
BETWEEN,  should  be  read  in  connection  with  the 
present  article.  The  subject  of  demand  is  discussed 
in  all  systematic  works  on  political  economy  ;  but 
the  reader  may  be  specially  referred  to  Marshall's 
Principles  of  Economics,  bk.  iii.]  j.  n.  K. 

DEMAND  CURVES  represent  the  relation 
between  the  effective  demand  for  a  commodity 
and  the  terms  on  which  it  can  be  obtained. 
The  simplest  form  is  where  one  axis,  as  OY  in 
the  annexed  figure,  represents  price,  and  the 
other  axis,  OX,  the  quantity  of  a  commodity 
demanded  by  a  certain  individual  at  that  price. 
Thus  at  the  price  Oq  the  quantity  Op  is  demanded. 
The  curve  thus  representing  the  dispositions  of 
a  single  person  may  be  termed  an  "individual " 
demand  curve,  as  contrasted  with  the  "collec- 
tive "  demand  curve  appertaining  to  a  group  of 
persons  such  as  a  market  or  a  nation.  The 
collective  curve  for  a  group  may  be  derived 
from  the  individual  curves  of  the  persons  form- 
ing the  group  by  adding,  for  each  price,  the 
amounts  demanded  by  all  the  individuals  at 


that  price,  and  taking  this  sum^s  the  abscissa 
of  the  collective  curve  ;  the  ordinate  as  before 
representing  price.  The  collective  curve  may 
be  represented  by  Fig.  1,  if  the  scale  is  altered 


Fig.  1. 


so  that  a  unit  of  the  abscissa  should  represent 
a  larger  amount  of  commodity  than  when  the 
figure  stood  for  an  individual  demand  curve. 
This  method  of  representing  demand  by  a  curve 
was  introduced  by  Cournot  in  his  Principes 
MatMmatiques  de  la  ThAorie  des  Richesses,  1838. 
It  is  remarkable  that  he  began  and  ended  with 
the  collective  demand  curve,  instead  of  deriving 
it  from  the  individual  curve  like  many  recent 
writers.  Another  kind  of  demand  curve  is 
formed  by  taking  one  axis  as  before  to  repre- 
sent the  quantity  of  the  commodity  demanded, 
while  the  other  axis  represents,  not  as  before, 
the  price  of  each  unit  of  commodity,  but  the 
total  amount  of  money  (or  other  article  of 
exchange)  coiTesponding  to  each  amount  de- 
manded.   Thus  in  Fig.  2  the  curve  denotes  that 


O       d^uXof  Avvo^  f  X 

for  the  amount  of  money  (or  any  other  speci- 
fied article,  say  x)  Op,  there  is  demanded  the 
amount  Oq  of  the  article  y.  This  construction 
was  first  introduced  by  Prof.  Marshall  in  a  paper 
read  before  the  Cambridge  Philosophical  Society, 
1873  (to  which  reference  is  made  in  the  preface 
to  the  first  edition  of  the  author's  Principles  of 
Economics.)  The  construction  is  specially  suit- 
able to  the  case  where  there  is  a  certain  symmetry 


DEMAND  CURVES 


543 


between  the  conditions  of  supply  and  demand, 
as  in  international  trade.  It  vsdll  be  observed 
that  the  curve  in  Fig.  2,  which  has  been 
described  as  the  demand  curve  with  respect  to 
the  article  y,  may  also  be  regarded  as  the  supply 
curve  with  respect  to  the  article  x ;  since  it 
represents  the  amount  of  the  article  x  which 
the  party  or  parties  under  consideration  are 
willing  to  supply  for  each  amount  of  y.  This 
kind  of  demand  curve,  like  that  which  was  first 
described,  may  be  divided  into  two  species, 
individual  and  collective.  Another  kind  of 
demand  curve  is  used  by  Prof.  Walras  in  his 
Elements  d'Uconomie  Politique  Pure. 

The  demand  curve  is  a  potent  aid  to  abstract 
theory.  It  expresses  better  than  ordinary 
language  the  relation  between  price  and  quan- 
tity demanded  ;  of  which  in  general  we  know 
only  that  the  quantity  varies  inversely  with 
the  price,  but  are  ignorant  what  is  the  law  of 
variation.  This  ignorance  is  sometimes  not  com- 
plete ;  we  may  know  that  for  the  same  fall  in 
price  the  demand  increases  much  more  rapidly 
in  the  case  of  one  commodity  than  another  ; 
or  for  the  same  commodity  at  different  prices. 
This  difference  of  Elasticity  is  elegantly 
expressed  by  the  shape  of  the  curve.  In  the 
case  represented  by  Fig.  1  the  demand  is  very 
elastic  in  the  neighbourhood  of  B,  very  inelastic 
in  the  neighbourhood  of  A  and  C.  The  case 
thus  represented  is  a  very  general  one.  In 
Prof.  Marshall's  words  "the  elasticity  is  small 
when  the  price  of  a  thing  is  very  high  relatively 
to  their  means  [those  of  the  class  of  purchasers 
under  consideration],  and  again  when  it  is  very 
low  ;  while  the  elasticity  is  much  greater  for 
prices  intermediate  between  what  we  may  call 
the  high  level  and  the  low  level."  The  use 
of  some  such  device  as  the  demand  curve  is 
required  for  the  perfect  apprehension  of  the 
theory  of  value.  The  relation  of  "  individual " 
to  "collective"  demand  curves  best  expresses 
the  dependence  of  the  objective  fact  of  price  on 
the  subjective  dispositions  of  individual  persons. 
The  position  of  equilibrium  towards  which  the 
"  higgling  of  the  market"  tends  is  best  repre- 
sented by  the  intersection  of  a  demand  with  a 
Supply  Curve  (g-. v.)  Ordinary  language  does 
not  well  discriminate  the  change  in  price  due  to 
a  change  in  the  quantity  of  commodity  supplied, 
the  dispositions  of  the  parties  remaining  the 
same,  from  that  change  which  is  due  to  altera- 
tions in  taste.  The  latter  sort  of  change  is 
expressed  by  the  shifting  of  the  demand  curve 
from  right  to  left  (or  conversely),  so  that  to 
every  quantity  of  commodity  there  corresponds 
a  higher  (or  lower)  price.  The  demand  curve 
is  employed  by  Prof.  Marshall  in  the  proof 
of  several  recondite,  not  to  say  paradoxical 
theorems.  "  If  a  given  aggregate  taxation  has 
to  be  levied  ruthlessly  from  any  class,  it  will 
cause  less  loss  of  Consumers'  Rent  {q.v.)  if 
levied  on  necessaries  than  if  levied  on  comforts." 


Principles  of  Economics,  bk.  v.  ch.  xii.  §  4,  note, 
2nd  ed.,  cp.  ibid.  §  6).  The  doctrine  that 
"the  maximum  satisfaction  is  generally  to  be 
attained  by  encouraging  each  individual  to  spend 
his  own  resources  in  that  way  which  suits  him 
best "  is  seen  by  the  aid  of  the  demand  curve 
to  be  inaccurate. 

The  theory  of  the  demand  curve  must  be 
received  with  the  following  cautions  and  reserva- 
tions. First  (1)  it  should  be  observed  that  there 
are  "many  classes  of  things  the  need  for  which 
on  the  part  of  any  individual  is  inconstant, 
fitful,  and  irregular,"  for  instance  "wedding 
cakes,  or  the  services  of  an  expert  surgeon " 
(Marshall,  Principles  of  Economics,  bk,  iii.  ch. 
iii.,  §  5,  2nd  ed.)  The  individual  demand  curve 
in  such  a  case  is  discontinuous.  But  the  corre- 
sponding collective  curve  will  be  less  irregular. 
"The  fickleness  of  the  individual  is  merged 
in  the  comparatively  regular  aggi'egate  of  the 
action  of  a  large  number  of  people"  (Ibid.) 
Again  (2)  in  comparing  the  elasticity  of  demand 
curves  for  different  commodities  care  must  be 
taken  about  the  units  both  of  money  and  com- 
modity. The  same  dispositions  on  the  part  of 
purchasers  will  appear  more  or  less  "elastic," 
according  as  they  are  expressed  in  hundred- 
weights or  tons,  in  pounds  or  shillings.  An 
ingenious  method  of  avoiding  this  fallacy  is 
given  by  Prof.  Marshall  (Principles  of  Economics, 
bk.  iii.  ch.  iv.  §  1).  Again  (3)  demand  curves 
as  usually  understood  involve  a  postulate 
which  is  frequently  not  fulfilled  ;  namely,  that 
while  the  price  of  the  article  under  considera- 
tion is  varied,  the  prices  of  all  other  articles 
remain  constant.  This  postulate  fails  in  the 
case  of  rival  commodities  such  as  beef  and 
mutton.  The  price  of  one  of  these  cannot  be 
supposed  to  rise  or  fall  considerably  without 
the  price  of  the  other  being  affected.  The 
same  is  true  of  commodities  for  which  there  is 
a  "joint  demand"  as  for  malt  and  hops. 
And  in  the  case  of  a  necessary  of  life  the  price 
cannot  be  supposed  to  increase  indefinitely 
without  the  prices  of  other  articles  falling, 
owing  to  the  retrenchment  of  expenditure  on 
articles  other  than  necessaries.  The  price  of 
clothes  has  been  known  to  fall  during  a  famine 
(F.  NcAvman,  Lectures  on  Political  Economy). 
It  is  true  indeed  that  the  postulate  which  has 
been  stated  might  be  dispensed  with.  But  this 
can  only  be  done  at  the  sacrifice  of  two  of  the 
characteristic  advantages  which  demand  curves 
offer  to  the  theorist.  First,  unless  this  postu- 
late is  granted,  it  is  hardly  conceivable  that, 
when  the  prices  of  several  articles  are  disturbed 
concurrently,  the  collective  demand  curve  may 
be  predicted  by  ascertaining  the  disposition 
of  the  individual — a  conception  which,  as  em- 
ployed by  Prof.  Walras  (Elements  d' Economic 
Politique,  Art.  50),  aids  us  to  apprehend  the 
workings  of  a  market.  Secondly,  when  the 
prices   of   all   commodities    but   one   are   not 


544 


DEMESNE— DEMOGRAPHY 


supposed  fixed,  there  no  longer  exists  that 
exact  cori'elation  between  the  demand  curve 
and  the  interest  of  consumers  in  low  prices 
which  Prof.  Marshall  has  formulated  as  "con- 
sumer's rent."  In  considering  this  rel§,tion 
care  must  be  taken  to  distinguish  between 
demand  and  desire.  The  effective  demand  of 
the  rich  and  poor  man  for  oatmeal  may  be  the 
same.  But  tlie  intensity  of  desire  is  not  the 
same,  if  the  one  uses  the  article  to  feed  his  horses, 
the  other  for  his  own  frugal  meal.  Again 
(4)  there  is  an  artificial  rigidity  in  demand 
curves  which  imperfectly  corresponds  to  the  flux 
character  of  human  desires.  One  cause  of  change 
is  the  formation  of  new  habits  ;  the  disturbance 
of  the  demand  curve  thus  caused  is  well  repre- 
sented by  Messrs.  Auspitz  and  Jjieben  {Theorie 
des  Fi'eises).  The  increased  use  of  petroleum  is 
not  to  be  ascribed  simply  to  the  fall  in  price, 
the  demand  curve  being  supposed  constant, 
but  rather  to  the  fact  that  "petroleum  and 
petroleum  lamps  have  become  familiar  to  all 
classes  of  society  "  (Marshall).  One  important 
cause  of  alteration  in  demand  curves  is  the 
increase  of  the  consumer's  purchasing  power. 
The  case  in  which  that  increase  is  only  appar- 
ent, being  due  to  a  rise  in  prices  (and  the  converse, 
case),  may  be  specially  distinguished.  Owing 
to  the  variability,  it  may  be  doubted  whether 
Jevons's  hope  of  constructing  demand  curves 
by  statistics  is  capable  of  realisation.  In  the 
financial  year  1890-91,  after  the  reduction  of  the 
tax  on  tea  effected  by  Mr.  Goschen,  the  quan- 
tity of  tea  consumed  per  head  was  greater  than 
in  the  previous  year.  Is  it  possible  to  deter- 
mine whether  this  change  is  due  to  the  cheap- 
ening of  the  article — the  demand  curve  being 
supposed  the  same — or  to  an  alteration  of  the 
demand  curve  caused  partly  by  a  change  of 
taste  and  partly  by  an  increase  in  prosperity  ? 
Some  suggestions  for  evading  these  and  other 
difficulties  will  be  found  in  the  third  book  of 
Prof.  Marshall's  Frinciples  of  Economies. 

For  further  considerations  and  fuller  refer- 
ences, see  Mathematical  Method,   f.  y.  e. 

DEMAND  SCHEDULES.     See  Demand. 

DEMESNE.  Before  the  statute  "Quia 
Emptores"  (1290),  a  person  wishing  to  alien- 
ate land  did  not  entirely  sever  his  connection 
with  the  land  ;  he  remained  the  feudal  tenant 
of  the  king  or  superior  lord,  and  continued  to 
perform  the  duties  which  the  tenure  imposed 
upon  him,  but  was  at  the  same  time  the  feudal 
lord  (mesne  lord),  of  the  new  tenant.  That 
portion  of  the  manor  which  the  lord  did  not 
grant  to  freehold  tenants  in  the  way  just  de- 
scribed was  called  his  demesne  ;  it  was  either 
under  the  immediate  management  of  the  lord 
or  it  was  let  out  to  persons  in  a  subordinate 
position  called  "  villani  "  who  held  at  the  lord's 
will,  but  gradually  acquired  a  customary  right 
to  fixity  of  tenure.  The  successors  of  the 
"villani"  are  the  copyholders  of  the  present 


day  (see  Copyhold).  That  part  of  the  crown 
lands  which  was  not  granted  to  any  feudal 
tenants  but  remained  under  the  management 
of  royal  stewards  is,  in  a  similar  way,  called 
the  "royal  demesne,"  and  part  of  the  heredit- 
ary revenue  of  the  crown  was  formerly  derived 
from  it.  Since  the  accession  of  George  III. 
this  revenue  has  been  appropriated  by  parlia- 
ment, the  sovereign  receiving  a  fixed  annual 
sum  (see  Civil  List)  in  exchange.  e.  s. 

DE  METZ-NOBLAT,  Alexandre  (1820- 
1871),  bom  at  Colmar,  died  at  Nancy,  His  first 
occupation  was  the  law,  and  he  was  called  to 
the  bar.  But  he  preferred  the  profession  of 
literature,  and  soon  displayed  a  predilection  for 
economic  study.  His  principal  work,  published 
first  in  1863  (2  vols,  in  8vo),  was  entitled 
Analyse  des pMnom^nes  iconomiques.  This,  after 
receiving  some  not  very  important  alterations, 
was  republished  as  Les  lois  6conomiques,  the  first 
edition  in  1867  (1  vol.  in  8vo),  the  second  in 
1880  (1  vol.  in  12mo).  This  work  is,  practically, 
a  complete  treatise  on  political  economy ;  the 
author  was  professor  of  this  science  from  De- 
cember 1864  at  Nancy,  a  chair  which  still  ex- 
ists. Here  De  Metz-Noblat  made  the  mistake 
of  failing  to  keep  religion  sufficiently  apart  from 
economic  science — but  he  was  a  man  truly 
liberal  in  spirit.  He  was  a  disciple  of  Mai  thus, 
and  his  works  deserve  to  be  read  even  at  the 
present  day.  a.  c.  f. 

DEMISE.  Used  as  a  substantive  noun  and 
as  a  verb  in  the  same  way  as  the  word  "  lease," 
and  denoting  the  letting  of  land  or  premises 
for  a  number  of  years.  e.  s. 

DEMOGRAPHY.  This  word,  already 
unanimously  adopted  of  late  years  by  con- 
tinental nations,  has  only  recently  sought 
naturalisation  in  England.  It  still  remains 
to  be  seen  whether  the  attempt  will  only  be 
partially,  instead  of  entirely,  successful.  The 
word  ^^ D6mographie"  was  invented  by  Dr. 
Achille  GuiUard,  and  occurs  in  the  title  of  his 
book  M67nents  de  Statistique  Hwniaine  ou  Demo- 
graphie  Gomparie,  Paris,  1855,  intended  to  be 
"  an  exposition  of  this  new  science  as  illustrated 
by  the  most  authentic  documents  relating  to 
the  condition,  the  general  movement,  and  the 
progress  of  population  in  civilised  countries." 
It  should  be  observed  that  statistics  are  very 
properly  made  the  very  soul  of  this  so-caUed 
new  science  by  GuiUard,  although  he  might 
have  found  a  more  apposite  epigraph  to  his 
book  than  the  somewhat  crude  one  from 
Proclus,  "How  sublime  human  understanding 
has  been  in  the  creation  of  number." 

GuiUard  ventures  further  to  define  demo 
graphy  as  the  natural  and  social  history  of  the 
human  species,  or  as  the  mathematical  know- 
ledge of  populations,  their  general  movements, 
their  physical,  social,  intellectual,  and  moral 
condition.  All  this  is,  however,  merely  a  new 
name   for   something   very   old.       Writera   in 


DEMOGRAPHY— DEMOIVRE 


545 


almost  every  country  have,  in  the  past  three 
centuries,  foreshadowed  the  existence  of  normal, 
or  mathematical,  laws  of  population.  What 
they  failed  in,  as  compared  with  writers  of  our 
own  times,  was  the  want,  for  which  they  had 
no  help,  of  adequate  or  authentic  illustrative 
statistics.  Thus  our  own  Petty  and  Graunt, 
in  the  17th  century,  had  to  rely  upon  very 
scanty  parochial  and  other  registration  of 
births  and  deaths,  restricted  also  to  the  metro- 
politan area,  in  their  very  ingenious  general 
inductions  respecting  the  laws  of  population. 
In  certain  instances  such  statistical  observa- 
tions, partial  and  few  as  they  may  have  been, 
sufficed  to  suggest  to  great  minds  the  method 
of  deducing  a  mathematical  law.  Thus  with 
De  Witt  in  constructing  a  table  of  annuities  in 
Holland  in  1672,  and  with  Halley  later  on  in 
doing  the  same  in  a  more  complete  way  from 
the  Breslau  observations.  In  the  18th  century 
population  statistics  came  to  be  more  abund- 
antly available,  and  stimulated  the  composition 
of  such  works  as  those  of  Price,  Malthus,  etc. 
in  England,  Siissmilch  in  Germany,  Moreau  in 
France.  In  the  present  century  we  have  had 
abundance  of  laboiu-ers  in  the  same  (shall  we 
call  it  demographic  ?)  field — Milne,  and  Farr, 
and  numerous  others,  in  England.  The  same 
in  France  and  Germany,  etc. — for  instance, 
Quetelet,  Legoyt,  Block,  Levasseur,  Engel,  and 
Berg.  All  these  have  contributed  so  much  to  a 
knowledge  of  the  principles  which  regulate  the 
laws  of  the  movements  and  increase  of  popula- 
tion in  its  various  aspects,  that  but  little  is  left 
to  constitute  demography  a  new  science. 

The  word  demography  has,  to  a  certain 
extent,  been  familiarised  to  English  ears  by 
the  occurrence  in  1891  of  a  Congress  of 
Hygiene  and  Demography  in  London.  This  is 
a  peripatetic  body,  and  its  previous  sessions  had 
been  held  in  continental  capitals.  Notwith- 
standing some  admissible  advantages  accruing 
from  such  occasional  meetings  as  these,  it  can 
scarcely  be  pretended  that  much  fresh  know- 
ledge as  to  statistical  and  mathematical  deduc- 
tions respecting  population  was  added  by  them 
to  the  general  stock  ;  there  was  more  room  in 
them  for  the  general  outside  public  than  for 
scientific  experts.  Hence  arose  a  frequent 
degeneracy  into  occupying  time  with  hypotheses 
regardless  of  statistical  evidence,  a  repetition  of 
such  eccentricities  as  contributed  not  a  little  to 
the  final  collapse  some  years  since  of  the  Social 
Science  Association.  A  better  organisation  in 
some  respects,  although  still  by  no  means  a 
perfect  one,  for  discussing  the  population  and 
census  statistics  of  gi*eat  countries,  or,  in  other 
words,  demography  in  its  most  important 
aspects,  exists,  however,  in  the  International 
Statistical  Institute,  composed  almost  wholly  of 
representative  experts,  limited  as  to  number, 
from  almost  all  European  countries  and  from 
the  ITnited  States,  who  meet  biennially  in  difler- 

VOL.  I. 


ent  countries  ;  for  example,  in  1891  the  session 
was  held  in  Vienna,  in  1893  in  Chicago,  in  1905 
in  London,  and  in  1909  in  Paris.  F.  H. 

DEMOIVRE  (or  De  Moivre),  Abraham 
(1667-1754),  an  eminent  French  mathe- 
matician, born  at  Vitry,  after  the  revocation 
of  the  Edict  of  Nantes  retired  to  London, 
where  he  supported  himself  by  giving  private 
lessons  in  mathematics.  A  life  of  privation,  in 
which  mathematical  discoveries  were  the  princi- 
pal events,  terminated  in  London  1754.  The 
scientific  eminence  of  Demoivre  is  evidenced  by 
Newton's  habitual  saying  "Go  to  Mr.  Demoivre, 
he  knows  more  than  I  about  these  matters." 
Pope  bears  witness  to  his  fame  in  a  well-known 
verse, 

"Sure  as  De-moivre,  without  rule  or  line." 

[Of  the  spider.  Essay  on  Man,  ep.  iii.  1.  104.] 

Demoivre  not  only  improved  the  theory  of 
the  calculus  of  probabilities  by  his  Doctrine  of 
Chances,  but  also  extended  its  ap])lication  by 
his  Annuities  upon  Lives.  Many  of  the  methods 
now  employed  by  actuaries  may  be  traced  back 
to  this  great  mathematician  (see  Farren, 
Historical  Essay  on  .  .  .  Life  Contingencies,  p. 
46).  Demoivi-e  is,  however,  most  remembered  by 
statisticians  for  his  hypothesis  that  the  proba- 
bilities of  living  any  number  of  years  after  the 
age  of  twelve  (see  Annuities,  1st  ed.  Problem 
XL)  decrease  in  arithmetic  progression  up  to 
the  age  of  eighty-six  (taken  as  the  extreme 
limit  of  human  life).  The  formula  may  be 
thus  simply  written  :  Ix  (the  number  alive  at 
any  age  x  see  Life  Tables)  is  proportioned  to 
86-23  (cp.  Assurance  Magazine,  vol.  iii.) 
This  law,  roughly  corresponding  to  the 
observations,  long  served  as  a  good  working 
hypothesis,  and  even  still  affords  useful 
exercises  (see  Sutton,  Life  Contingencies).  De- 
moivre also  entertained  the  hypothesis  that 
the  probabilities  of  life  decrease  in  a  geometrical 
progression  {Annuities,  1st  ed..  Problem  III.), 
an  assumption  which  lends  itself  better  to  the 
calculation  of  joint  contingencies,  but,  being 
less  agreeable  to  the  facts,  has  not  found 
currency. 

The  first  edition  of  the  Doctrine  of  Chances 
(preceded  by  an  earlier  contribution  to  the 
calculus  of  probabilities,  De  Mensurd  Sortis) 
appeared  in  1718  ;  the  third,  purporting  to  be 
"  fuller,  clearer,  and  more  correct  than  the 
former,"  in  1756.  The  first  edition  of  the 
Annuities  uj^on  Lives  appeared  in  1724-25,  the 
fourth  in  1752.  The  treatise  appears  with  some 
modifications,  being  the  "most  improved  edition" 
according  to  Baily,  at  the  end  of  the  third 
edition  of  the  Doctrine  of  Chances,  with  the 
secondary  title,  the  Doctrine  of  Chances  applied 
to  the  Valuation  of  Annuities. 

[References  to  Demoivre  will  be  found  in  most 
of  the  leading  works  on  Assurance  and  cognate 
subjects.  The  following  may  be  specially 
mentioned :     R.   Price,   Reversionary  Payments, 

2  N 


546 


DEMONETISATION— DENAKIUS 


arranged  and  enlarged  by  W.  Morgan  (1812),  ch. 
iv.  ;  F.  Baily,  Doctrine  of  lAfe  Annuities  and 
Assv/rances,  preface  ;  W.  Sutton,  Life  Con- 
tingencies, ch.  vi.  et  passim.  See  also  the 
Assurance  Magazine,  vols,  iii.,  xii.,  xiii.,  xv. 
This  magazine,  in  the  vol.  for  1869,  contains *an  in- 
teresting generalisation  of  Demoivre's  hypothesis. 
Some  traits  of  Demoivre's  personality  are  recorded 
in  the  M4moire  sur  la  vie  et  sur  les  Merits  de  M. 
Abraham  de  Moivre,  par  M.  Maty.]       r.  T.  E. 

DEMOLOGY.     See  Demography. 

DEMONETISATION.  The  discontinuance 
by  a  government  of  the  use  of  a  coin,  and  its 
official  withdrawal  from  circulation,  are  known 
as  its  demonetisation.  A  recent  instance  of 
such  an  operation  was  furnished  in  this  country 
by  the  complete  withdrawal  from  circulation 
of  all  pre- Victorian  gold  coins ;  carried  out 
under  the  Coinage  Act,  1889,  and  the  royal 
proclamation  of  the  22nd  November  1890. 

The  coins  received  and  exchanged  at  the 
mint  between  13th  December  1889  and  28th 
February  1891,  were  of  the  value  of  £2,334,573 
in  sovereigns,  and  £128,575  in  half-sovereigns, 
of  which  £12,776  in  sovereigns  and  £712  in 
half-sovereigns  were  received  through  the  Sidney 
Mint,  and  £30,168  in  sovereigns  and  £2015  in 
half-sovereigns  through  the  Melbourne  Mint. 


1889-1891. 

Sover- 
eigns. 

Half- 
Bover- 
eignB. 

Total. 

Deficiency  in  weight 
Deficiency  in  standard 

Total  deficiency 

£42,352 
2,403 

£6,353 
129 

£48,705 
2,532 

£44,755 

£6,482 

£51,237 

The  average  deficiency  of  weight  of  the  sover- 
eigns was  2-236  grains,  and  that  of  the  half- 
sovereigns  3*046  grains  ;  while  that  due  to  the 
incorrectness  in  standard  fineness  amounted  to 
an  average  of  0"246  penny  per  £  sterling. 

Prior  to  the  issue  of  the  above-mentioned  pro- 
clamation, guineas  and  half-guineas  were  still 
"legal  tender"  for  payments,  although  none  had 
been  coined  since  1816,  and  they  had  long  since 
disappeared  from  circulation.  These  coins  are 
now,  therefore,  legally,  as  well  as  actually,  re- 
moved from  the  currency  of  the  country.  The 
Order  in  Council  of  16th  March  1892  authorised 
the  withdrawal  and  exchange  of  light  gold  coins. 
Since  that  date  to  the  present  time  (1912),  the 
light  gold  withdrawn  (United  Kingdom)  has 
been  of  the  value  of  £39,845.000  in  sovereigns, 
and  £2^,855,000  in  half-sovereigns. 


1892-1912. 

Sover- 
eigns. 

Half. 
Bover- 
elgas. 

TotaL 

Deficiency  in  weight 
Deficiency  in  standard 

£390,311 
11,652 

£521,281 
8,210 

£529,491 

£911,592 
19,862 

Total  deficiency 

£401,963 

£931,454 

',.  The  average  deficiency  of  weight  of  the 
sovereigns  was  1*19  grains,  and  that  of  the 
half-sovereigns  was  1-03  grains. 


Coin  to  the  value  of  about  £1,537,000  has 
been  withdrawn  from  the  Australian  Mints 
during  the  same  period.  The  particulars  of 
the  Australian  light  gold  withdrawn  in  1912 
are  as  follows  : — 


Nominal 
Value. 

Deficiency 

in 
Weight. 

Deficiency 
in  Weight 
per  Piece. 

Sovereigns 
Half-sovereigns 

£18,084 

8,294 

£      S.    d. 
137     8     9 
167    0     1 

d. 

2-521 
2-416 

21,378 

304    8  10 

The  demonetisation  of  a  coin  must  generally 
involve  loss.  If  the  countries  of  the  Latin 
Union  were  to  adopt  a  gold  standard,  instead 
of  the  present  4talon  boiteux,  the  demonetisation 
of  the  standard  silver  five- franc  piece  would,  at 
the  present  price  of  silver  (19 14),  entail  consider- 
able loss.  That  coin  contains  22-5  grammes  of 
fine  silver  which,  with  (English)  standard  silver 
at  the  (gold)  price  of  26jd.  per  ounce,  would 
be  worth  19-16d.  only,  whereas  it  is  now  rated 
at  47-62d.  (5  francs  at  25-22  fc.=£l).  The 
loss  therefore  would  amount  to  more  than  28.  4d. 
per  piece.  A  similar  result  would  accompany 
the  demonetisation  of  the  standard  silver  dollar 
of  the  United  States  ;  a  coin  which  when  first 
issued  yields  a  considerable  Seignorage  (q.v.) 
to  the  state.  In  connection  with  this  subject 
the  fact  should  not  be  lost  sight  of  that  whereas 
metal  in  the  form  of  coin  is  of  a  known  standard, 
and  is  received  without  question  as  to  its  fine- 
ness, ingots  must  be  assayed  in  order  to  ascer- 
tain their  purity,  and  this  operation,  involving 
expense  and  delay,  tends  to  make  the  exchange 
value  of  coin  stand  at  a  somewhat  higher  figure 
than  that  of  unstamped  bullion.         F.  E.  A. 

[See  also  Alternative  Standard.] 
DEMONSTRATIVE  LEGACY.  A  legacy 
of  a  portion  of  a  particular  fund,  as,  for  example, 
where  a  testator  bequeaths  £1000  out  of  his 
reduced  three  per  cents.  If  the  fund  out  of 
which  it  is  payable  fail,  the  legatee  is  neverthe- 
less entitled  to  have  the  legacy  paid  out  of  the 
general  assets,  and  even  if  the  general  assets  are 
insufficient  to  pay  all  the  legacies,  the  legatee 
is  entitled  to  his  legacy  in  fuU. 

[Williams  on  Executors  (pp.  11-65),  London, 
1879.]  J.  E.  c.  M. 

DEMURRAGE.  Compensation  payable  to  a 
shipowner  for  detention  of  a  ship  in  a  port  be- 
yond time  stipulated  in  the  Charter  Party 
(q.v.).  E.  s. 

DENARIUS.  Roman  silver  coin  first  struck 
269  B.C.,  seventy-two  being  coined  to  the  pound. 
Design — obverse,  the  head  of  Roma  and  the 
letter  X  indicating  ten  asses ;  reverse,  the  ■ 
Dioscuri  on  horseback,  charging.  From  217 
B.C.  eighty  denarii  were  struck  to  the  pound. 
In  100  B.C.  a  new  type  was  introduced,  and 
from  93  B.C.  many  different  kinds  were  in  use. 


DENARIUS— DENIERS  DE  CALAIS 


647 


[Wm.  Till,  An  Essay  on  the  Roman  Denarius, 
London,  1837. — J.  Y.  Akerman,  A  descriptive 
Catalogue  of  rare  and  unedited  Roman  Coins, 
London,  1834. — Also  see  Encydopcedia  Britan- 
nica,  9th  ed.,  vol.  xvii.,  art.  Numismatics,  §  ii. — 
Roman  Coins,  p.  652.]  F.  b.  a. 

DENARIUS  DEI  {God's  penny).  Earnest 
money  which  passed  at  the  making  of  a  bar- 
gain. This  was  regarded  as  a  binding  transac- 
tion by  the  custom  of  the  merchants  {Carta 
Mercator,  31  Ed.  I.  c.  4).  It  had  several  local 
uses  and  names.  Originally,  perhaps,  a  penny 
given  to  the  church  or  to  the  poor  at  the  con- 
clusion of  a  bargain.  Also  mentioned  as  a 
port-due,  an  exaction  forbidden,  however,  by 
statute.  In  this  sense  the  term  is  usually 
corrupted  as  Adieu — the  customer's  "  farewell  " 
or  "God-speed." 

[Maitland  in  Selden  Soc,  ii.  130  ;  Hall,  Cus- 
toms, ii.  166.]  H.  Ha. 

DENIER  (Coin).  The  word  denier,  originally 
merely  the  French  rendering  of  the  Latin 
denarius,  was  adopted  by  the  early  kings  of 
France  as  a  name  for  a  coin  of  pure  silver,  the 
weight  of  which  was  originally  about  one  penny- 
weight (or  denier).  In  the  reign  of  Charlemagne 
(768-814)  it  weighed  about  twenty-seven  or 
twenty-eight  grains,  in  the  reign  of  Charles  le 
Chauve  (843-877)  thirty- two  grains,  and  in 
that  of  Hugh  Capet  (987-996)  about  twenty- 
four  grains.  A  small  amount  of  copper  was 
first  added  to  the  metal  of  which  these  coins 
were  made  in  the  year  1103,  and  from  that 
time  onwards  the  amount  was  continually 
increased.  In  the  year  1577  deniers  were 
struck  which  were  composed  of  pure  copper. 

In  the  reign  of  Louis  IX.  (1226-1270)  a  coin 
of  fine  gold,  called  a  ^^ Denier  d  VAgn^l"  was 
struck,  as  well  as  two  kinds  of  silver  deniers 
called  respectively  "  i)e?w6r  Tournois"  and 
"Denier  Parisis."  From  this  time  the  word 
denier  was  used  as  the  name  for  several  coins, 
the  identity  of  which  was  determined  by 
qualifying  words,  such  as,  "  de  Vor  d  VEscu," 
"  de  I' or  au  Fleur  de  Lis,"  "  Parisis,"  etc. 

The  following  is  a  list  of  some  of  the  more 
important  issues  of  coins  bearing  the  name 
Denier : 

Gold  Coins. 


Reign. 

Coin. 

Weight. 

Fineness. 

Louis  IX.  (1226- 

1270) 
Philippe  le   Bel 

Denier  i  I'Agnel 

64  grains 

Fine 

Denier  k  I'Escu 

71  grains 

Fine 

(1285-1314) 

Philippe  de  Va- 

11 

71  grains 

Fine 

lois  (1327-1350) 

„ 

71  grains 

23  carats 

John  (1350-1364) 

»» 

71  grains 

22|  carats 

» 

71  grains 

21  carats 

„ 

,, 

71  grains 

18  carats 

II 

Denier  au  Fleur 

77  grains 

Fine 

deLis 

Silver  Coins. 


Reign. 

Coin. 

Weight 

Philippe  le  Ben 
Louis  Hutin      I  j«  ^ 
Philippe  le         fll 

Long              j  -^ 
Charles  le  Bel  (1321- 

1327) 
Philippe    de    Valois 

(1327-1350) 

f  Denier  Tournois 
( Denier  Parisis 

Denier  Parisis 

17i  grains 
17   grains 

17   grains 
13i  grains 
27i  grains 

The  coinage  of  "  Deniers  ;V  1  'Escu 
in  the  year  1854. 


discontinued 


F.  E.  A. 
Denier  (Tax).  The  Denier  d  Dieu  (see 
Denarius  Dei)  was  originally  a  small  extra 
sum  paid  on  the  conclusion  of  a  sale  or  bargain 
and  applied  to  a  charitable  purpose.  It  has 
since  come  to  mean  a  ready-money  payment 
handed  over  to  bind  a  bargain,  especially  in 
the  engagement  of  labourers,  servants,  or  lodg- 
ings. R.  L. 

Denier  (as  denoting  Price).  The  word 
Denier  is  now  obsolete  in  French  as  the  name 
of  a  coin,  but  it  has  survived  in  many  phrases 
of  common  use.  The  peasant,  in  France,  who 
borrows  money  stiU  describes  the  rate  of  interest 
as  denier-vingt  or  denier-dix  as  the  case  may  be 
(one  in  twenty  or  one  in  ten),  instead  of  saying 
5  per  cent  or  10  per  cent.  M.  Leroy-Beaulieu 
among  other  economists  sometimes  employs  the 
same  expression  conversely,  as  when  suggesting 
that  the  valuation  of  land  should  be  raised 
from  denier-vingt  to  denier-vingt-cinq  or  from 
twenty  to  twenty- five  times  the  rental.  In  his 
Trait6  de  la  Science  des  Finances,  referring  to 
Pitt's  plan  for  the  redemption  of  the  land  tax, 
in  1798,  he  says:  ''The  price  of  3  per  cent 
consols  was  50,  that  is  to  say  sixteen  to 
seventeen  times  the  annual  interest ;  in  other 
words,  they  were  negotiated  at  denier  seize  or 
denier  dix-sept,'hvit  landed  property  sold  at  denier 
trente  or  thirty  times  the  revenue,"  etc. 

Shares  in  mining  companies  founded  before 
the  French  Revolution  are  still  called  deniers, 
the  total  capital  being  represented  by  240  to 
300  deniers  according  to  the  variations  in  the 
value  of  the  livre  from  twenty  to  twenty-five 
sols,  the  sol  being  twelve  deniers.  If  calculated 
at  twenty  sols  the  part  proprietor  of  a  company 
was  said  to  possess  one,  two,  or  ten  deniers, 
meaning  -g^-j-,  ^-J-g-,  or  -^  of  the  total  stock. 
The  capital  of  the  great  Anzin  collieries,  which 
date  from  1757,  is  formed  of  288  deniers  or  full 
shares,  the  value  of  one  of  which  was  a  few 
years  back  as  high  as  £50,000.  They  are, 
however,  now  divided  for  negotiation  into  hun- 
dredth parts  called  centi^mes  de  deniers,  which 
are  quoted  under  that  name  on  the  mining 
exchange.  The  widow's  mite  is  still  Le  denier 
de  la  Veuve  ;  Peter's  Pence,  Le  denier  de  St, 
Pierre  ;  public  money,  les  deniers  publics,  etc. 
(see  also  Denarius.)  t.  l. 

DENIERS  DE  CALAIS  (or  Devoirs  de 
Calais) — Calais  dues  or  Calais  toll ;  a  fine  of 
19d.  per  sack  of  wool  paid  to  the  crown  by 


548 


DENIZEN— DENOMINATIONS  OF  BANK  NOTES 


merchants  for  license   to   export  staple  com- 
modities elsewhere  than  to  Calais. 

[Hall,  Customs,  i.  87,  231-278  ;  ii.  220-224.] 

H.  Ha. 

DENIZEN.  An  alien  who  has  been^made 
a  British  subject  by  letters  patent  and  not  by 
the  usual  certificate  of  a  secretary  of  state.  A 
denizen  has  not  the  full  rights  of  a  subject. 
He  could  always  hold  lands  by  purchase  or 
devise,  but  until  the  Naturalisation  Act,  1870, 
he  could  not  inherit.  Even  now  he  cannot  be 
a  privy  councillor  or  a  member  of  either  House 
of  Parliament,  nor  can  he  hold  any  office  of 
trust,  civil,  naval,  or  military. 

[Report  of  the  Royal  Commission  on  the  Laws 
of  Naturalisation  and  Allegiance,  1869. — Nation- 
ality,  by  Sir  A.  J.  E.  Cockburn,  London,  1869.] 

J.  E.  c.  M. 

DENNY,  William  (1847-1887),  member  of 
a  well-known  firm  of  shipbuilders  at  Dumbar- 
ton, on  the  Clyde,  was  not  only  eminent  in  the 
skilled  work  of  his  profession,  and  as  a  model 
"captain  of  industry,"  but  full  of  promise  as  a 
writer  on  social  and  economical  questions.  His 
Life  by  Professor  A.  B.  Brace  (Hodder  and 
Stoughton,  1888)  presents,  mter  alia,  a  multi- 
tude of  valuable  notes  from  his  various  letters 
and  speeches,  on  such  matters  as  the  organisa- 
tion of  a  workshop,  the  encouragement  of  inven- 
tion, the  uses  of  apprenticeship,  the  functions 
of  the  board  of  trade,  the  character  of  working 
men,  and  the  prospects  of  the  labouring  classes. 
He  had  a  strong  dislike  of  "absentee  em- 
ployers," and,  having  served  as  apprentice  him- 
self, had  knowledge  of  the  whole  situation  such 
as  few  other  employers  could  possess.  From  a 
comparatively  optimistic  view  of  the  relations 
of  employer  and  employed  and  the  influence  of 
competition  in  industry,  he  passed  gradually  to 
a  more  critical  attitude  and  less  sanguine  con- 
victions on  these  subjects.  In  his  address  on 
"The  Worth  of  Wages"  (publ.  Bennett,  Dum- 
barton, 1876),  he  stated  the  arguments  for 
piece-work  so  cogently  and  exhaustively  that 
his  own  conversion,  ten  years  or  so  later,  to 
a  different  view  was  all  the  more  remarkable. 
He  had  believed  that  the  wages  of  piece-work 
are  self-regulating,  but  he  became  convinced, 
after  a  larger  experience,  that  they  are  not  so 
— except  in  "  cases  where  rates  can  be  fixed  and 
made  a  matter  of  agreement  between  the  whole 
body  of  the  men  in  any  works  and  their  em- 
ployers"— but,  on  the  contrary,  they  "are 
liable,  under  the  pressure  of  heavy  competition, 
to  be  depressed  below  a  proper  level  "  (Letter  to 
Mr.  John  Rae  in  Life,  p.  1 1 3).  In  reading  his  ad- 
dress on  the  "  Industries  of  Scotland  "  delivered 
at  Dumbarton,  December  1878,  with  special  re- 
ference to  the  competition  of  the  Tyne  with  the 
Clyde  in  the  matter  of  shipbuilding,  we  need  to 
remember  this  change  of  opinion,  though,  like 
a  good  reasoner,  he  always  so  states  his  argu- 
ments that  we  can  judge  for  ourselves,    j.  b. 


DENOMINATIONAL  CURRENCY.  Se€ 
Currency  in  British  Colonies. 

DENOMINATIONS  OF  BANK  NOTES. 
The  denominations  in  which  bank  notes  are 
issued  appear  to  depend  mainly,  if  not  entirely, 
on  custom  and  convenience.  The  chief  question 
of  policy  is  as  to  the  issue  of  notes  correspond- 
ing in  denomination  to  coins  in  circulation, 
especially  to  the  coin,  whatever  it  may  be, 
which  forms  the  unit  of  the  currency.  It  is 
obvious  that  to  the  extent  to  which  such  notes 
circulate  they  must  displace  coin.  It  is  pos 
sible  that  some  part  of  the  coin  thus  withdrawn 
may  be  hoarded,  but  it  is  more  probable  that 
it  will  be  made  use  of  in  some  way  out  of  the 
country.  The  notes  not  being  exportable,  it  is 
probable  that  the  coin  will  be  used  for  the  pm-- 
chase  of  commodities  from  abroad,  and  thus 
the  issue  of  such  notes  may  lead  directly  to  the 
depletion  of  the  stock  of  coin.  On  the  question 
of  convenience  the  points  of  most  importance 
in  regard  to  the  issue  of  notes  of  small  values, 
are,  on  the  one  hand  the  convenience  of  porta- 
bility, on  the  other  the  discomfort  of  a  currency 
frequently  mutilated  and  dirty,  with  the  pos- 
sibility of  infection,  and  of  loss  or  destruction. 
The  prevalence  of  forgery  depends  largely  on 
the  denominations  of  the  notes  issued.  Greater 
caution  is  shown  in  dealing  with  a  £5  note  than 
in  taking  one  for  a  fifth  or  tenth  of  that  sum. 
Besides,  the  chance  of  detecting  a  forgery  is 
greatly  diminished  when  the  note  is  dirty  or 
worn  by  use.  The  maintenance  of  a  currency 
of  small  notes,  having  extensive  use,  in  a  clean 
and  sightly  condition,  would  involve  an  expense 
exceeding  any  profit  possible  to  be  derived  from 
its  issue,  except  where  current  rates  of  interest 
are  very  high  and  where  no  important  stock  of 
bullion  is  held  to  meet  the  notes.  The  expense 
would  also  probably  outweigh  any  economy 
arising  from  diminished  abrasion  of  the  coin. 
The  actual  loss  from  abrasion  of  the  English 
sovereign  is  about  one-tenth  of  a  penny  per 
annum,  while  the  cost  of  printing  a  note  has 
never  been  estimated  below  one  penny,  and  has 
been  found  in  practice  to  be  frequently  double 
that  sum  (see  Abrasion).  The  following  table 
gives  the  lowest  denominations  of  notes  issued 
in  some  of  the  principal  countries  of  the  world, 
though  not  now  in  all  cases  in  active  use. 


£  s.   d. 

Italy 

.  50  centesimi  =  about  0    0    5 

Austro-Hungary 

.     1  florin        = 

,      0    18 

France 

.    5  franca       = 

,      0    4    0 

United  States   . 

.     1  dollar       =     , 

,      0    4    2 

Germany  . 

.    5  marks       = 

,      0    5    0 

Norway     , 

.    5  kronor      =     , 

,      0    5    7 

Sweden      . 

.     5  rixdalers  =     , 

,      0    6    7 

British  India     . 

.     5  rupees      =     , 

,      0    6    8 

Belgium    . 

.  20  francs       =     , 

,       0  16    0 

Holland     . 

.  10  florins       =     , 

,      0  16    8 

Scotland  and  IieUuiO 

I       .     1  pound       =     , 

,       1    0    0 

England  and  Wales 

.     5  pounds     =     , 

,      5    0    0 

It  does  not  appear  from  these  figures  that  the 
denominations  of  bank  notes  are  dependent  on 
or  indicative  of  the  poverty  or  wealth  of  a 


DENOMINATOR— DEPARCIEUX 


549 


country.  But  some  closer  connection  in  this 
respect  may  be  found  in  the  extent  to  which 
the  smaller  denominations  preponderate,  though 
other  local  circumstances  may  have  a  share  in 
determining  this  matter.  We  may  contrast  the 
note  circulation  of  France  and  Belgium  in  1913. 


France. 

Belgium. 

Francs.          Amount 

Number 

Francs           Amount 

Number 

•          per  cent. 

per  cent. 

Jfianca.          percent. 

perceut. 

o^  ^^^K  1 

20    (16/-)     23 

64 

20  (16s.)  y      -4 

•4 

50   (£2)        11 

12-5 

25  (£1)    j 

100      (4)       40 

22 

50     (2)         16 

36-5 

500    (20)          5 

•5 

100     (4)         52 

59 

]()00    (40)       21 

1 

500  (20)           5 

1-1 



1000  (40)         26-G 

3 

100 

100 

100  lOO  I  R.  W.  B. 

DENOMINATOR,  Common.  The  term 
"  common  denominator  "  is  applied  by  Jevons  to 
the  function  of  money  which  he  thus  describes  : 
"  In  a  state  of  barter  the  price-current  list  would 
be  a  most  complicated  document,  for  each 
commodity  would  have  to  be  quoted  in  terms 
of  every  other  commodity.  .  .  .  Between  100 
articles  there  must  exist  no  less  than  4950 
possible  ratios  of  exchange.  .  .  .  All  such 
trouble  is  avoided  if  any  one  commodity  be 
chosen,  and  its  ratio  of  exchange  with  each 
other  commodity  be  quoted.  The  chosen 
commodity  becomes  a  common  denominator  or 
common  measure  of  value "  {Money,  p.  5). 
Jevons  here  uses  "denominator"  as  equivalent 
to  measure  of  value — the  term  which  he  more 
frequently  employs. 

According  to  Prof.  Walker  a  distinction 
should  be  drawn  between  denominator  and 
measure  of  value.  ' '  Curiously  -  coloured  bits 
of  paper  with  a  government  stamp  upon  them, 
which  it  is  felony  to  imitate,"  and  without 
"intrinsic  value,"  may  serve  the  purpose  of  a 
common  denominator,  but  not  that  of  a  common 
measure  of  value  (Walker,  Mo^iey,  pp.  9,  280- 
288).    (See  Standakd  of  Value.)     f.  y.  e. 

DEODAND.  Any  personal  chattel  which 
was  found  to  have  been  the  immediate  cause 
of  the  death  of  any  reasonable  creature,  was 
anciently  forfeited  to  the  crown,  to  be  given  to 
God,  as  by  distribution  in  alms  to  the  poor. 
It  seems  to  have  been  originally  intended  as  an 
expiation  for  the  souls  of  such  as  were  snatched 
away  by  sudden  death,  just  as  the  apparel  of  a 
stranger  found  dead  went  to  purchase  masses 
for  his  soul  (Thorpe,  Anglo-Saxon  Laws  and 
Institutes).  This  may  account  for  the  rule  of 
law  that  no  deodand  was  due  when  an  infant 
under  the  age  of  discretion  was  killed  by  a  fall 
from  a  cart  or  horse,  or  the  like,  not  in  motion ; 
whereas  if  an  adult  person  were  so  killed  the 
thing  was  forfeited.  If,  however,  the  horse, 
cart  or  other  thing  in  motion  killed  an  infant 
it  was  deodand,  as  the  misfortune  was  then  partly 
owing  to  the  negligence  of  the  owner,  who  was^ 
thus  rightly  punished.  If  a  thing  not  in  motion 
were  the  occasion  of  a  man's  death  only  that 
part  which  was  the  immediate  instrument  was 


forfeited  ;  but  11  it  were  in  motion  all  that  went 
to  make  the  wound  more  dangerous  was  forfeited. 
Thus  if  a  man,  climbing  up  the  wheel  of  a  cart, 
lell  and  was  killed,  only  the  wheel  was  deodand  ; 
but  if  the  wheel  ran  over  his  body,  not  only 
the  wheel  but  the  whole  cart  and  load  was 
deodand.  It  mattered  not  whether  the  owner 
of  the  thing  was  concerned  in  the  killing  or  not, 
for  if  a  man  were  killed  with  a  sword  the  sword 
was  deodand  although  not  belonging  to  the 
man  who  used  it.  For  this  reason  we  find  in 
old  indictments  for  homicide  the  instrument  of 
death  and  its  value  presented  by  the  grand  jury 
to  enable  the  king  to  claim  the  deodand. 
Deodands  were  not  due  for  accidents  happening 
on  the  high  seas  out  of  the  jurisdiction  of  the 
common  law,  neither  did  any  deodand  accrue 
in  the  case  of  felonious  killing,  but  cases  occur 
in  which  ships  were  valued  for  deodand  by 
reason  of  accidents  at  sea.  A  Latin  phrase 
attributed  to  Braeton  has,  by  mistranslation, 
given  rise  to  erroneous  statements  as  to  what 
constituted  a  deodand.  "Omnia  quae  ad 
mortem  movent, "  evidently  meaning  all  things 
which  tend  to  produce  death,  has  been  rendered 
"move  to  death";  thus  giving  rise  to  t^e 
theory  that  things  in  motion  only  were  to  be 
forfeited.  Deodands  were  finally  abolished  alto- 
gether by  statute  9  &  10  Vict,  c.  62.     h.  Ha. 

DEPARCIEUX  (or  De  Parcieux),  Antoine 
(1703-1768),  born  near  Nismes,  raised  himself 
from  the  rank  of  a  peasant  by  his  mathematical 
ability,  Avhich  was  at  first  exerted  in  the  con- 
struction of  sun-dials.  A  tranquil  life  devoted 
to  science  —  applied  mathematics  chiefly  — 
terminated  at  Paris,  1768. 

Deparcieux's  contributions  to  vital  statistics 
give  him  a  place  in  this  dictionary.  He  con- 
structed life-tables  based  upon  two  sets  of  ob- 
servations, relating  respectively  to  persons  who 
had  taken  part  in  the  French  Tontines  {q.v.\ 
and  to  the  inhabitants  of  religious  houses — monks 
and  nuns.  It  appeared  that  the  religious  celi- 
bates had  the  advantage  in  respect  of  longevity 
at  the  earlier,  but  not  at  the  later  periods  of 
life.  It  also  appeared  that  the  expectation  of 
life  at  every  age  was  greater  for  nuns  than  for 
monks.  Deparcieux  seems  to  have  been  the 
first  to  define  expectation  of  life  (which  he 
termed  vie  moyenne),  and  to  construct  separate 
life-tables  for  males  and  females.  Dei)arcieux's 
treatment  of  statistics  commands  the  suffrage 
both  of  the  mathematician  and  the  general 
reader.  "I  do  not  see  how  he  could  have 
made  a  better  use  of  his  data,"  says  the  speci- 
alist Milne  ;  while  the  lively  Voltaire  is  be- 
lieved to  have  taken  Deparcieux  as  the  model 
of  "the  geometer"  who  discourses  so  instruct- 
ively in  L'homme  aux  quarante  4cus. 

Deparcieux  is  sometimes  called  the  elder,  to 
distinguish  him  from  his  nephew,  Deparcieux 
the  younger,  who  wrote  on  the  same  class  of 
subjects  as  his  uncle,  but  with  less  effect. 


550 


DEPARTMENT 


Essai  sur  les  prohaUlitis  de  la  duHe  de  la  vie 
humaine  (1746). — Reponse  aux  objections  .  .  . 
{17 ^Q).— Addition  d  Vessai  .  .  .  (1760).— These 
works  are  in  the  library  of  the  British  Museum, 
entered  in  the  catalogue  under  the  head,  Parcieux. 
The  Reponse  is  bound  up  with  the  Addition. 
De  Moivre,  Doctrine  of  Chances^  3rd  ed.  (1756), 
penultimate  page. 

[Histoire  de  I'Academie  Royale,  Annee  1763, 
p.  155. — tloge  de  M.  De  Parcieux. — Richard 
Price,  Observations  on  Reversionary  Payments, 
4th  ed.  (1783),  vol.  ii.  p.  189.— Maseres,  PHn- 
dples  of  Life  Annuities  (1783),  Preface. — Tetens, 
Einleitung  zur  Berechnung  der  Leibrenten  (1785), 
p.  79. — F.  Baily,  Doctrine  of  Life  Annuities,  p. 
13. — Milne,  Valuation  of  Annuities  (1815),  vol. 
ii.  p.  555,,  and  p.  574. — Assurance  Magazine, 
vol.  ii.  p.  205,  and  vol.  xv.  p.  175. — Farr,  Vital 
Statistics,  p.  439. — Deparcieux's  celebrated  tables 
are  given  in  some  of  the  passages  above  referred 
to.  Other  references,  and  a  version  of  the  tables, 
will  be  found  in  the  article  on  Deparcieux  in 
Walford's  Insurance  Cyclopcedia.  ]  f.  y.  e. 

DE  PARIETJ.     See  Parieu,  Esquirol  de. 

DEPARTMENT.  A  separate  branch  or 
division  of  the  public  administration. 

The  varying  character  and  the  great  extent 
of  the  administrative  functions  of  the  state 
necessarily  require  for  their  efficient  discharge 
a  similar  division  of  labour  and  concentration 
of  specialised  knowledge  and  skill  to  that  which 
is  arranged  in  any  well  -  organised  industrial 
undertaking.  It  is  not  too  much  to  say  that 
without  the  most  elaborate  division  and  sub- 
division of  official  duties,  and  their  concentration 
within  appropriate  areas,  executive  government 
would  be  impossible.  In  addition  to  the  ad- 
vantages which  ordinarily  follow  the  specialisa- 
tion of  function,  an  esprit  de  corps,  or  desire 
to  look  with  a  single  eye  to  the  efficiency  of  a 
particular  department,  is  fostered  amongst  the 
more  responsible  members  of  its  staff.  Such  a 
result  is  of  the  greatest  possible  value  to  the 
public  at  large,  although  it  is  probable  that  in 
our  own  country  it  has  been  gained  at  the 
expense  of  the  necessary  "integration,"  and 
that  too  little  regard  has  been  paid  to  the 
necessity  for  that  "intimacy  and  firmness  of 
the  connections  between  the  separate  parts " 
upon  \v^hich  the  well-being  of  organisms,  physi- 
cal, industrial,  or  social,  must  depend.  In  the 
desire  to  avoid  increase  of  expenditure,  or  the 
undertaking  of  duties  not  quite  in  line  with  its 
own  special  functions,  a  department  will  at  times 
be  unwilling  to  perform  services  which  would  be 
of  advantage  to  the  community,  and  apart  from 
the  cabinet  or  the  treasury — the  one  too  much 
pressed  with  business  of  the  first  importance,  the 
other  looking  at  all  questions  mainly  from  the 
financial  side — no  means  of  rectifying  the  separ- 
atist tendency  exists. 

As  may  be  supposed  from  the  varying  re- 
quirements of  the  public  service,  the  actual 
division  of  the  administration  into  departments 


varies  from  time  to  time.  Some  of  them,  as  in 
the  case  of  the  treasury,  the  privy  council 
office,  the  home  office,  and  the  foreign  office, 
are  of  old  standing,  whilst  others,  as  the  office 
of  the  secretary  for  Scotland  and  the  board  of 
agriculture  and  fisheries,  have  been  more  recently 
constituted.  A  reference  to  the  particulars 
given  in  the  annual  estimates  for  civil  services 
will  afford  interesting  evidence  of  the  extension 
of  the  functions  of  government  in  this  country 
in  a  comparatively  recent  period. 

The  statement  as  to  the  "accounting  depart- 
ments and  services"  prefixed  to  the  estimates 
shows  that,  leaving  out  of  account  the  war 
office,  the  admiralty,  and  the  three  revenue 
departments — customs,  inland  revenue,  and 
post  office — the  main  divisions  of  the  public 
service  were  sixty-five  in  number,  of  which 
nine  were  exclusively  Scotch  and  seventeen 
Irish.  Some  of  these  may  be  said  to  exist  for 
the  control  and  service  of  the  remainder,  e.g. 
the  treasury,  office  of  works,  civil  service  com- 
mission, exchequer  and  audit  department,  and 
the  stationery  office.  The  amount  voted  to  be 
accounted  for  by  these  departments  for  the  year 
1909-10.  and  by  some  of  the  other  principal  de- 
partments, is  shown  in  the  following  table  : 


Accounting  Department. 


Treasury  (16  votes,  including  Old  Age 
Pensions) 

Office  of  Works  (12  votes) 

Board  of  Public  Works,  Ireland  (3  votes) 

Civil  Service  Commission 

Exchequer  and  Audit  Department  . 

Stationery  Office        .... 

Treasury  Solicitor      .... 

Treasury  Remembrancer  in  Ireland  (for 
County  Court  Officers,  Ireland)     . 

Home  Office  (3  votes) 

Foreign  Office  (2  votes) 

Colonial  OflBce  (3  votes)     . 

Board  of  Trade  (4  votes)    . 

Secretary  for  Scotland 

Chief  Secretary,  Ireland  (S  votes)     . 

Paymaster- General  (for  Supei-annuations, 
etc.) 

Paymaster  of  the  Supreme  Court  (2  votes) 

King's    and    Lord    Treasurer's    Remem- 
brancer (3  votes)     .... 

Accountant-General  of  the  Supreme  Court, 
Ireland 

Board  of  Agriculture  and  Fisheries 

Department  of  Agriculture,  etc.,  Ireland 

Ordnance  Survey        .... 

Local  Government  Board  . 

Registrar-General's  Office 

Local  Government  Board,  Ireland    . 

Prisons  Department  (England   and   the 
Colonies) 

Prisons  Department  (Scotland) 
,,  ,,  (Ireland)  . 

Land  Commission,  Ireland 

Dublin  Metropolitan  Police 

Constabulary,  Ireland 

Education    Department    (England    and 
Wales)     .        .  ... 

British  Museum         .... 

Public  Education  (Scotland)     . 
„  ,,         (Ireland) 

Sundry  other  Departments 

Total . 


Amount 
voted  for 
1909-10. 


£10,301,050 
2,089,676 
363,504 
38,403 
64,400 
762,960 
99,897 

110,875 
538,250 
667,877 
1,342,421 
527,220 
36,016 
459,574 

691,139 
366,825 

129,668 

104,919 
173,169 

267,501 
£00,076 
254,294 
44,315 
77,731 

753,737 

97,390 

112,695 

303,677 

96,963 

1,380,918 

13,648,792 

179,228 

2,147,541 

1,621,921 

695,521 


£40,750,143 


DEPARTMENT— DEPOPULATION 


651 


[The  estimates  for  Civil  Services,  1892-93  (P.P. 
No.  48  of  1892)  may  be  referred  to.  See  also 
Bureaucracy.]  t.  h.  e. 

DEPARTMENT  (France).  A  term  applied 
to  the  principal  territorial  and  administrative 
area  existing  in  France.  The  division  of  that 
country  into  departments  w^as  first  effected  by  the 
decree  of  the  22nd  December  1789,  the  arrange- 
ment being  embodied  in  Art.  I.  of  the  Consti- 
tution of  1791.  There  are  at  the  present  time 
eighty-six  departments,  or  eighty-seven  if  'the 
"territory  of  Belfort,"  the  remnant  of  one  of 
the  departments  ceded  to  Germany  in  1871,  be 
regarded  as  a  separate  department.  Since  1889, 
the  three  departments  of  Algeria  have  also  been 
treated,  for  most  purposes,  as  part  of  France 
proper.  The  area  of  a  department  ranges  from 
184  square  miles  in  the  case  of  the  Seine  to 
3597  square  miles  in  the  case  of  the  Landes,  the 
average  being  about  2300  square  miles,  or  more 
than  one-third  the  area  of  Wales.  A  department 
is  administered  by  a  prefect  appointed  by  and 
representative  of  the  central  authority.  He  is 
assisted  by  a  conseil  geniral,  elected  by  universal 
suffrage,  and  a  council  of  prefecture,  nominated 
by  the  central  authority,  for  the  purpose  of  de- 
ciding legal  questions  and  advising  the  prefect 
when  asked  to  do  so.  Each  department  is  divided 
into  "arrondissements,"  these  again  into  "can- 
tons," and  the  "cantons"  into  "communes." 

[See  Block's  Dictionnaire  de  V administration 
frangaise,  and  Dictionnaire  General  de  la  Poli- 
tique.— "Local  Government  in  France,"  by  M. 
Waddington,   Nineteenth    Century,   July    1888.] 

T.  H.  E. 

DEPOPULATION  (Term).  The  laying  waste, 
destroying,  and  unpeopling  of  a  place  (Co.  12 
Rep.  p.  30),  stated  to  be  "now  the  apparent 
effect  of  enclosing  lordships  and  manors,  where- 
by several  good  old  villages  have  been  reduced 
from  a  great  number  of  sufficient  farms  to  a 
few  cottages,"  by  Cowel  {Interpreter,  ed.  1637), 
in  whose  time  an  extensive  inquiry  into  the  de- 
population of  the  rural  districts  was  carried  out. 
The  same  writer  states  that  Depopulatores  agro- 
rum  "were  so  called  because,  by  prostrating 
and  ruining  houses,  they  seemed  to  depopulate 
towns  "  ;  and  depopulatio  agrorum  was  a  great 
offence  at  common  law  for  which  benefit  of  clergy 
was  denied.  The  pulling  down  of  farm-houses 
and  conversion  of  arable  into  pasture  was  checked 
by  4  Henry  VII.,  and  other  well-known  acts 
throughout  the  Tudor  period  (Cunningham,  I. 
468).  Depopulation  might  also  ensue  from 
excessive  taxation  or  purveyance  {Dialogus,  i. 
8).  The  unit  of  prosperity  in  the  earlier  and 
^  later  inquisitions  alike  was  the  plough  itself — 
the  extent  of  depopulation  being  ascertained 
by  the  reduced  number  of  ploughs  in  each 
village.  H.  Ha. 

DEPOPULATION,  in  Relation  to  Econo- 
mic History,  has  hitherto  been  chiefly  con- 
sidered as  a  remarkable  but  disconnected  pheno- 


menon. Thus,  while  it  is  usual  to  dilate  upon 
the  alarming  proportions  of  this  social  move- 
ment at  several  distinct  periods  of  our  history, 
it  has  not  always  occurred  to  the  general  his- 
torian to  regard  it  as  a  visitation,  possible 
under  the  political  environments  of  every  age. 

The  truth  is  that  the  same  causes — the  visi- 
tation of  God  and  the  inhumanity  of  man — 
have  not  infrequently  operated  to  produce  the 
same  results  throughout  successive  centuries. 
At  uncertain,  though  constantly  recurring  inter- 
vals, this  social  scourge  has  hindered  the  fairest 
prospects  of  industrial  progress.  Though  in 
recent  years  less  known  as  a  factor  in  economic 
life,  in  earlier  days  depopulation  saddened  the 
reigns  of  powerful  monarchs — causing  alike  the 
exultation  of  foreign  enemies  or  trade  rivals  and 
the  lament  of  successive  generations  of  social 
reformers. 

The  depopulation  of  Saxon  and  Norman 
England  was  rather  general  than  local,  and  of 
historical  rather  than  economic  interest,  except 
for  the  insight  that  is  afforded  by  it  into  the 
industrial  resources  of  the  country.  The  re- 
curring pestilences  and  famines,  and  the  partial 
invasions  of  the  next  three  centuries  left  an 
equally  indelible  mark  upon  the  page  of  history ; 
but  it  is  with  individual  enterprise  and  the 
public  policy  which  governed  its  ceaseless 
workings  from  the  14th  to  the  17th  century 
that  we  are  especially  concerned. 

The  "peace  of  the  plough"  is  perhaps  a 
fanciful  term  applied  to  a  very  real  force  in  the 
national  polity.  It  denotes  a  predominant 
interest  in  the  pursuit  of  agriculture,  as  form- 
ing the  very  basis  of  the  industrial  life  of  the 
nation.  Herein  its  chief  wealth  was  invested, 
hereby  its  entire  finances  were  adjusted,  and  the 
ploughshare  and  the  reaping-hook  continued  to 
be  idealised  as  the  symbols  of  native  industry 
for  centuries  after  they  had  been  practically 
replaced  by  the  shepherd's  crook  and  the 
weaver's  shuttle.  Therefore,  from  Saxon  times 
onwards  we  find  the  peace  of  the  plough  pre- 
served by  a  succession  of  remedial  measures  in- 
tended to  foster  a  frequently  declining  industry. 

It  is  to  be  remembered  that  down  to  the 
close  of  the  13th  century  not  only  the  main 
resources  of  the  country  but  the  chief  part  of 
the  royal  revenue  were  derived  from  this  source. 
This  is  tjie  period  of  the  great  prcedial  surveys, 
and  of  agi-icultural  treatises ;  the  period  of 
Carucage  and  Scutage  (q.v.),  and  of  royal 
commissions  of  inquiry  into  the  grievances  of 
the  rural  community.  The  Dialogus  de  Scac- 
cario  alludes  to  one  of  these  inquisitions  in  the 
well-known  story  of  the  king  on  his  progress 
being  waylaid  by  husbandmen  bearing  their 
idle  ploughshares  aloft  "as  a  symbol  of  agricul- 
tural depression."  A  few  original  fragments 
of  another  inquisition  of  the  12th  century  have 
sm'vived,  which  almost  anticipate  the  com- 
plaints of  the  English  peasant  insurgents  of  the 


552 


DEPOPULATION 


16tli  century.  The  Saxon  Chronicle  gives 
ample  instances  of  agricultural  distress  and  de- 
population over  a  wide  period,  but  it  is  not  till 
we  reach  the  middle  of  the  14th  century  that 
the  evil  assumes  the  characteristic  type  which 
so  long  prevailed.  Before  the  reign  of  Edward 
III.  the  interest  of  the  crown  in  the  distribu- 
tion of  wealth  had  undergone  a  change.  The 
sheriffs  farms  no  longer  enabled  the  king  "to 
live  of  his  own";  great  escheats  brought  with 
them  greater  waste  ;  the  last  desperate  attempt 
to  exact  the  full  feudal  liabilities  of  the  military 
tenants  by  new-fangled  inquisitions,  Nevill's 
taxation — as  odious  and  as  fruitless  as  Noy's 
ship-money — had  failed.  The  crown,  therefore, 
was  compelled  to  drift  with  the  flowing  tide. 
It  spread  its  nets  there  and  drew  in  an  ample 
revenue  from  customs  and  subsidies  and  farms 
of  the  Lombard  and  Flemish  publicans  in  place 
of  feudal  levies  and  the  plunder  of  the  Jewish 
mortgagees.  The  staple  articles  of  the  export 
trade  of  England  became  wool  and  fells,  and 
leather  and  fats.  Corn  was  henceforth  exported 
only  under  the  sliding  scale.  Then  followed 
the  plague,  and  in  its  wake  inclosures  and  con- 
vertible husbandry.  Then  the  prsedial  insurrec- 
tion, and  the  industrial  revolution  had  begun. 

From  the  close  of  the  14th  to  the  beginning  of 
the  17  th  century  we  can  trace  the  depopulation 
of  the  English  rural  districts  in  the  complaints 
and  remonstrances  of  the  oppressed,  backed  by 
a  long  string  of  useless  remedial  measures,  not 
wholly  inspired  as  might  be  supposed  by  the  good- 
will of  visionary  churchmen,  benevolent  despots, 
and  alarmist  legislators,  but  by  the  far-seeing 
policy  of  the  great  ministers  of  the  crown,  the 
obvious  meaning  of  which  is  apparent  in  most 
of  the  economic  tracts  of  the  16th  century  as  a 
preparation  for  the  deadly  struggle  between  the 
landed  and  the  moneyed  interests. 

In  one  aspect  the  Statute  of  Labourers  itself 
was  devised  for  the  encouragement  of  tillage. 
It  was  so  expressed  in  its  later  editions,  and 
alniost  simultaneously  the  act  of  depopulating 
is  mentioned  as  a  felony.  All  through  the 
15th  century  the  evil  grew  while  the  feudal 
system  dwindled.  The  feudal  surveys  of  Henry 
VI.  are  an  instructive  conmientary  upon  the 
Testa  de  Nevill  on  the  one  hand  and  the 
Statute  of  Fines  on  the  other.  It  was  in  the 
reign  of  Henry  VII.  that  the  suffering  conse- 
quent on  inclosures  was  first  brought  promin- 
ently forward  in  a  well-known  statute.  This, 
however,  and  the  similar  measures  of  the  next 
four  reigns  seem  to  have  given  no  real  relief  to 
the  congested  districts.  Even  the  partial  migra- 
tion of  labour  to  the  towns  was  insufficient  to 
cope  with  this  distress.  The  real  solution  was 
the  increased  employment  of  labour  made  pos- 
sible by  the  success  of  convertible  husbandry. 

There  are  many  valuable  materials  extant  to 
enable  us  to  estimate  both  the  causes  and  the 
extent  of  this  depopulation  in  the  16th  century. 


but  few  perhaps  as  complete  as  the  curious 
returns  made  in  the  year  1517  {Lansd.  MSS.,  i. 
60)  and  the  still  more  extensive  returns  made 
in  pursuance  of  letters-patent  dated  20th  August 
1608,  which  have  hitherto  been  little  known 
{Charuiery  Records,  Petty  Bag,  Depopulations). 

This  latter  instrument  recites  that  the  crown 
being  given  to  understand  that  there  are  in  many 
parts  of  England,  and  notably  in  the  county  oi 
Bedford,  *'  many  houses  pulled  downe,  lett  tc 
decay,  standinge  voide  and  uninhabited,  or  the 
ground  that  of  former  tymes  belonged  to 
dweUinge-houses  dismembered  and  taken  from 
them  and  greate  quantities  of  ground  hereto- 
fore used  for  arrable  converted  to  pasture,  by 
which  and  by  many  other  sinyster  and  corrupt 
practises  and  devises  our  Realme  is  in  many 
partes  wasted  and  depopulated  to  the  grievance 
of  our  people  the  damage  of  our  estate  and 
against  the  ancient  common  lawes  and  statutes 
of  our  Realme,  and  which  we  are  determined  to 
remeadie  and  redresse,"  the  lord-lieutenants  and 
certain  knights  and  esquires  of  several  of  the 
home  counties,  to  which  this  inquisition  seems 
to  have  been  confined,  are  hereby  empowered 
to  inquire  by  a  sworn  jury  and  examination  of 
witnesses  as  to  the  facts  alleged  in  the  schedule. 

The  articles  of  the  inquiry  are  to  the 
following  effect: — (1)  How  many  towns, 
villages,  churches,  hamlets,  boroughs,  parishes, 
dwelling-houses,  farms  or  farmhouses,  families, 
ploughs,  or  tenancies  in  the  county  of  Bedford 
have  since  the  twenty-fourth  year  of  Elizabeth 
been  depopulated,  and  by  whose  fault  and  by 
what  means  ;  and  the  population  maintained 
before  and  after  such  depopulation  ;  (2)  what 
grounds  have  been  converted  from  tillage  into 
pasture ;  (3)  what  lands  have  been  severed  from 
the  farm -buildings  ;  (4)  what  farm  buildings 
have  been  pulled  down  ;  (5)  who  hold  more 
than  one  farm ;  (6)  who  have  evicted  their 
tenants  ;  (7)  what  inclosures  have  been  made. 

The  returns  to  this  inquiry,  which  were 
ordered  to  be  made  into  the  Chancery  before  the 
October  following,  give  us  a  complete  picture 
of  the  agrarian  revolution  during  a  given 
period  within  a  given  district  They  are  as 
complete  in  their  way  as  the  Hundred  Rolls  of 
the  13th  century,  and  they  may  be  regarded 
as  the  summary  of  the  agrarian  question  before 
it  disappeared  from  public  view  for  another  two 
centuries.  It  was  upon  the  evidence  of  this 
commission  that  the  lawyers  of  the  17th  cen- 
tury based  their  definitions  of  depopulation, 
and  it  is  in  this  connection  that  it  has  descended 
to  us  as  an  economic  term. 

[Cunningham,  vol.  ii.  Appendix.— ^The  Inquisi- 
tion of  1517,  edited  by  I.  S.  Leadam. — Transac- 
tions of  R.  Hist.  Soc.  (N.S.)  vol.  vi.  pp.  167-314.] 

H.  Ha. 

DEPOPULATION  (Causes).  The  term  de- 
population is  now  used  in  a  sense  very  different 
from  that  originally  assigned  to  it.    Such  a  trufl 


DEPOPULATION 


55a 


depopulation,  or  stripping  a  country  of  its  in- 
habitants, as  has  occurred  in  the  past  in 
Mesopotamia,  Syria,  and  parts  of  central  Asia, 
is  scarcely  known  in  these  days,  but  the  term 
depopulation  is  now  applied  to  the  case  of  any 
country,  or  part  of  a  country,  in  which  the 
population  as  measured  from  time  to  time  is 
found  to  be  diminishing. 

The  causes  of  depopulation  are  numerous  ;  for 
convenience  they  may  be  grouped  under  three 
headings,  physical,  political,  and  economic,  but 
usually  several  causes  contribute  to  the  result. 

A.  Physical  Causes. — (1)  Volcanic  erup- 
tions, within  the  usually  restricted  limits  of 
their  action,  produce  more  considerable  effects 
than  might  be  supposed,  both  in  direct  destruc- 
tion of  life  and  in  rendering  large  tracts  of 
country  incapable  of  cultivation.  Among  the 
more  notable  outbursts  of  volcanic  force  which 
have  thus  caused  depopulation  may  be  men- 
tioned the  eruptions  of  Vesuvius  in  79  a.d.  and 
again  in  1822  ;  of  Etna  in  1669,  which  destroyed 
fourteen  villages  ;  of  Papandayang  in  Java  in 
1772,  which  is  said  to  have  buried  40  villages 
with  3000  persons ;  of  Galungung,  also  in 
Java,  in  1822,  which  killed  4000  people  ;  of 
the  Volcan  de  Agua  in  Guatemala  in  1541  ;  of 
Skaptar  Jokull  in  1783,  which  destroyed  one- 
sixth  of  the  inhabitants  and  one-half  of  the 
live  stock  of  Iceland,  and  rendered  great  part 
of  the  island  permanently  sterile  ;  of  the  "king 
of  volcanoes,"  Mauna  Loa,  in  Hawaii,  in  the 
years  1855,  1868,  and  1881  ;  of  the  oil  wells 
at  Baku  in  1887  ;  and  of  Tomboro,  in  the 
island  of  Sumbawa  in  1815,  said  to  have  de- 
stroyed 12,000  people.  Again  in  1883  one  of 
the  most  remarkable  outbursts  of  which  we 
have  records  occurred  in  Krakatoa,  causing  a 
loss  of  life  estimated  at  the  time  to  amount  to 
75,000  ;  while  lastly,  Tarawera  in  1886  covered 
a  large  tract  of  the  north  island  (New  Zealand) 
with  mud  and  ashes.  (See,  for  volcanic  pheno- 
mena generally,  Humboldt's  Cosmos). 

(2)  Floods. — The  Ho-ang  Ho  affords  the  most 
striking  instances, — in  1851-53  it  changed  its 
course  and  buried  whole  villages  in  mud ;  in 
1888,  breaking  down  its  banks  once  more,  it 
gave  rise  to  an  appalling  catastrophe,  over- 
whelming it  is  said  at  least  one  million  of  people 
and  causing  subsequently  widespread  famine. 

(3)  Changes  of  climate,  more  especially 
drought,  due  to  the  neglect  of  irrigation  works, 
or  the  destruction  of  forests,  may  cause  the  land 
to  be  incapable  of  sustaining  as  large  a  popula- 
tion as  formerly.  The  condition  of  Mesopo- 
tamia since  its  conquest  by  the  Turks  in  1515 
is  a  conspicuous  example  of  the  former.  North 
China  of  the  latter,  case.  Mr.  J.  A.  Baines, 
census  commissioner  of  India,  says  {Times  of 
India,  18th  April  1891)  that  the  census  proved 
that  a  local  malarial  fever  had  caused  consider- 
able emigration  from  Rajshahye  and  Nuddea 
in  Bengal. 


(4)  Pestilence  was  formerly  in  Europe,  as  it 
is  still  in  Asia,  both  a  potent  and  a  frequent 
cause  of  depopulation  (see  Black  Death).  In 
modern  times  the  epidemics  of  cholera  in  1849, 
1853,  1854,  1857,  and  1866,  of  smallpox  in 
1871,  and  of  influenza  in  1890,  1891,  and 
1892  decidedly  checked  the  natural  increase  of 
the  population  in  several  countries  of  Europe 
(see  Statistical  Chronology  of  Plagues  and  Pesti- 
lence as  affecting  Human  Life,  etc.,  by  C.  Wal- 
ford,  1884). 

(5)  Famines  resulting  from  failure  of  crops 
due  to  exceptional  seasons  or  plagues  of  locuste, 
or  to  great  disasters  such  as  the  bursting  of 
their  banks  by  rivers,  have  often  been  greatly 
aggravated  by  pestilence  or  war  ;  in  fact,  these 
three  causes  are  frequently  inseparably  bound 
together.  The  most  notable  instance  in  recent 
times  of  famine  causing  considerable  depopula- 
tion in  Europe  occurred  in  Ireland  in  1847, 
but  in  India  famines  still  from  time  to  time 
greatly  check  the  growth  of  population.  Great 
famines  occurred  in  1770,  1781-83,  1790-92, 
and  even  so  recently  as  1860-61  half  a  million 
of  people  perished  from  famine  in  North - 
West  India,  while  in  1865-66  it  is  believed 
that  one  and  a  half  million  perished  in  Orissa. 
However,  in  1874  and  1876  the  efforts  of  the 
Government  were  so  far  effectual  as  to  prevent 
any  great  loss  of  life  except  in  a  few  districts. 
Mr.  Baines  {Times  of  India,  18th  April  1891) 
says  that  the  famine  tracts  of  Madras,  which 
showed  considerable  depletion  in  1881,  filled 
up  rapidly  by  1891  owing  to  the  return  of 
emigrants  or  to  actual  immigration  from  other 
districts.  There  was  an  awful  famine  in  North 
China  in  1877-78  in  which  millions  are  reported 
to  have  perished  (see  Famines  of  the  World, 
etc.,  by  C.  Walford,  Journal  of  the  Statistical 
Society,  vol.  xli.  433,  vol.  xlii.  79). 

B.  Political  Causes. — (6)  War,  involving 
as  it  once  did  the  massacre  of  women  and 
children,  and  the  carrying  off  of  w^hole  nations 
into  slavery,  has  been  a  most  powerful  cause  of 
depopulation,  especially  in  Asia  and  Africa. 
The  extinction  of  aboriginal  races  in  recent 
times  has  often  been  a  result  of  increasing 
population,  the  stronger  race  displacing  the 
weaker,  but  the  conquests  of  such  nations  of 
warriors  as  the  Matabele  have  caused  gi'eat 
diminution  of  more  civilised  races  like  the 
Mashonas.  Modern  wars  are  comparatively 
short  in  duration,  while  owing  to  sanitary 
precautions  pestilences  do  not  so  often  follow 
in  their  train.  Thus  it  has  been  said  that  the 
war  between  Prussia  and  Austria  in  1866  was 
the  first  in  which  more  men  were  killed  in 
action  than  died  of  sickness.  In  France  in 
1854  and  1855  the  deaths  exceeded  the  births 
by  69,318  and  35,606  respectively,  and  in 
Austria  inl866by57,831;in  both  this  result 
was  the  combined  effect  of  cholera  and  war. 
In  France  again  in  1870  and  1871  there  was  an 


554 


DEPOPULATION 


excess  of  deaths  over  births  of  103,394  and 
444,889  respectively,  a  disastrous  result  of  the 
war,  the  commune,  and  an  epidemic  of  small- 
pox. 

(7)  Actual  deportation  of  the  people,  as  in  the 
familiar  instances  of  the  Jews  in  the  Babyldhian 
captivity,  the  Jews  expelled  from  Spain  (1492), 
and  the  Moors  also  from  that  country  (1609). 
This  heading  connects  itself  with  the  next  one 
to  be  considered. 

(8)  Religious  persecution  drove  the  Huguenots 
from  France,  the  Pilgrim  Fathers  from  England, 
and  is  now  driving  the  Jews  from  Russia,  to  the 
great  economic  disadvantage  of  the  persecuting 
country  in  each  case. 

(9)  Bad  government  is  not  perhaps  directly  a 
great  cause  of  depopulation,  but  indirectly  it 
assists.  Restrictions  on  trade,  oppressive  taxa- 
tion, bad  land  laws,  capricious  interference  with 
the  liberty  of  the  subject,  as  well  as  social  and 
political  agitation,  all  discourage  the  growth  of 
population ;  but  of  aU  acts  of  government 
probably  compulsory  military  service  has  most 
effect  in  stimulating  emigration. 

C.  Economic  Causes. — Though  the  action 
of  these  is  often  not  so  obvious  as  in  the  case  of 
natural  and  political  causes,  and  is  often  diffi- 
cult to  unravel  satisfactorily,  yet  they  are  really 
far  more  powerful  than  all  the  other  causes  put 
together. 

(10)  The  repeal  of  the  Poor  Law. — The  old 
law  of  settlement  in  England  was  intended  to 
prevent  men  from  leaving  their  native  parishes  ; 
it  was  a  protective  measure  which  tended  to 
keep  up  artificially  the  number  of  the  rural 
population ;  its  repeal  naturally  facilitated 
migration  and  to  that  extent  contributed  to 
local  depopulation.  The  same  is  true  of  the 
abolition  of  out-door  relief  to  able-bodied  men. 
The  poor  law  has,  however,  in  some  cases  pro- 
duced the  same  result  in  an  opposite  way :  i.e. 
some  landlords,  to  prevent  the  poor  from  becom- 
ing chargeable  upon  the  land,  cleared  their 
estates  of  cottages  and  so  caused  a  veritable  de- 
population within  a  limited  area. 

(11)  The  formation  of  deer  forests. — Some 
Scotch  landowners,  finding  they  could  obtain 
better  rents  by  devoting  their  land  to  sporting 
purposes,  have  followed  the  classical  example 
of  William  the  Conqueror,  and  removed  all 
agricultural  tenants  with  a  view  to  making 
deer  forests.  Naturally  this  has  taken  place 
only  in  those  parts  of  the  Highlands  where  the 
land  was  poor  and  ill  adapted  to  agriculture. 
To  some  extent  the  inhabitants  have  found 
compensating  employment  in  meeting  the  per- 
sonal wants  of  the  sportsmen.  The  real  objec- 
tion to  such  afforesting  seems  rather  to  be  to 
its  selfish  character  than  to  the  withdrawal  of 
a  small  quantity  of  land  from  cultivation. 

A  return  to  the  House  of  Commons  dated 
4th  August  1891  gives  certain  "particulars  of 
all  deer  forests  and  lands  exclusively  devoted 


to  sport  in  Scotland. "  From  this  we  learn  that 
the  total  amount  of  such  lands  was  in  1883  no 
less  than  2,292,153  acres,  and  that  274,980 
acres  have  been  afforested  since,  the  recent 
additions  being  in  the  counties  of  Argyll,  In- 
verness, Ross  and  Cromarty,  and  Sutherland. 
The  number  of  persons  displaced  is  not  given, 
but  there  are  various  indications  that  at  any 
rate  the  greater  part  of  the  land  devoted  to 
sport  can  be  of  but  slight  agricultural  value, 
thus  : — (1)  Two-thirds  of  the  estates  comprised 
land  having  an  altitude  exceeding  2500  feet 
above  the  sea,  while  in  only  four  estates  was 
the  highest  land  under  1000  feet.  (2)  In 
about  half  the  estates  the  rent  before  and  after 
afiForestation  is  given ;  in  the  very  great  majority 
of  cases  the  sporting  rent  is  greater  than  the 
old  rents,  often  several  times  as  great,  in  only 
three  cases  is  the  new  rent  25  per  cent  below 
the  old.  (3)  The  rent  before  afforestation 
averaged  in  more  than  one-fourth  of  the  acreage 
for  which  the  facts  are  available  from  nil  to 
under  2^d.  an  acre  ;  in  nearly  half  the  acreage 
between  3d.  and  8d.,  and  in  less  than  one-fourth 
between  9d.  and  Is.  8d.,  the  last  being  the 
highest  rent  recorded.  Land  commanding  such 
average  rents  could  sustain  but  a  trifling  pas- 
toral or  agricultural  population. 

(12)  The  repeal  of  the  com  laws,  by  bringing 
down  the  artificial  price  of  wheat,  caused  the 
tiQage  of  land  ill  adapted  for  the  growth  of 
cereals  to  be  no  longer  profitable  ;  hence  some 
lands  either  went  out  of  cultivation  altogether 
or  were  devoted  to  pastm-age,  in  either  case 
there  was  less  employment  for  labour  on  the 
farms  affected. 

(13)  The  application  of  machinery  to  agri- 
culture enables  the  same  amount  of  land  to  be 
cultivated  by  the  labour  of  a  smaller  number  of 
men.  The  cause  has  operated  widely  in  different 
parts  of  the  world. 

(14)  The  centralisation  of  manufactures,  duo 
to  the  adoption  of  the  factory  system,  has 
caused  the  decay  of  village  industries  such  as 
hand -loom  weaving,  and  has  lessened  the 
importance  of  the  village  craftsmen. 

(15)  T?ie  direct  attraction  of  large  towns,  not 
merely  as  offering  higher  wages  to  labour,  but 
as  affording  more  interests,  more  amusements, 
in  short,  more  "  life,"  is  a  potent  factor  in 
promoting  depopulation  in  rural  districts. 

(16)  Improved  education  and  a  cheap  press 
make  men  more  ambitious  and  more  restless, 
while  by  familiarising  them  with  new  ideas 
they  make  them  less  fearful  of  change.  More- 
over in  rural  districts  compulsory  education 
tends  to  prevent  children  from  being  early 
apprenticed  to  the  soil,  and  learning  the 
manifold  duties  connected  with  agricultural 
labour. 

(17)  The  rise  in  the  standard  of  living  is  a 
very  potent  and  widespread  cause  of  migi-ation, 
and  hence  of  rural  depopulation.     Men  are  no 


DEPOPULATION 


555 


longer  content  to  live  under  the  old  conditions 
which  satisfied  the  few  wants  of  their  grand- 
parents ;  they  want  better  food,  better  clothes, 
better  houses,  and  shorter  hours  of  labour  ;  to 
obtain  these  things  they  must  earn  better  wages; 
hence  they  are  stimulated  to  leave  their  homes 
in  search  of  more  remunerative  employment  than 
their  native  villages  afford.  This  cause  has  no 
doubt  been  largely  operative  in  keeping  up  the 
great  stream  of  emigration  from  Ireland,  a 
stream  which  commenced  to  flow  long  before 
the  potato  famine  brought  it  into  notoriety. 

(18)  Improved  communications,  railways  and 
steamships,  co-operate  powerfully  with  many 
of  the  above  causes  to  accelerate  the  depopula- 
tion of  the  rural  districts ;  they  bring  com  from 
distant  countries  where  it  can  be  grown  more 
cheaply,  and  so  bring  down  prices  ;  conversely 
they  make  more  fertile  soils  readily  accessible 
to  settlers  ;  they  bring  manufactured  articles  to 
remote  country  places  and  so  injure  village 
industries  ;  they  facilitate  the  removal  of 
labourers  to  factories  and  mines  ;  they  even,  as 
in  the  case  of  Cornwall,  transport  miners  to 
richer  and  more  easily  worked  lodes  in  distant 
lands  ;  in  a  few  cases  they  lead  to  local  de- 
population by  diverting  old  lines  of  traffic. 

(19)  Improvements  in  large  towns  lead  to  the 
depopulation  of  their  central  areas,  dwelling 
houses  are  turned  into  places  of  business  or 
removed  to  make  room  for  public  buildings, 
while  large  clearances  are  made  for  railways 
and  new  streets.  This  has  long  been  an 
obvious  fact  in  London,  but  a  like  movement 
is  also  in  progress  not  only  in  such  towns  as 
Manchester,  Liverpool,  and  Birmingham,  but 
even,  as  shown  by  the  last  census,  in  Sydney 
and  in  Adelaide  ;  no  doubt  the  same  is  true  of 
most  large  towns  throughout  the  world. 

(20)  An  abnormal  age  and  sex  constitution  of 
the  population,  the  result  of  war  or  emigration, 
lowers  the  marriage  rate  and  consequently  the 
rate  of  natural  increase.  In  England  there  is 
a  marked  excess  of  women,  in  many  of  her 
colonies  an  even  more  marked  deficiency  ;  in 
Ireland  and  in  many  rural  districts  of  England 
there  is  a  great  excess  of  old  people. 

(21)  Deferred  marriage  and  the  artificial 
limitation  of  children  both  contribute  to  de- 
population by  lowering  the  rate  of  natural 
increase.  The  first  is  a  powerful  cause  in  the 
upper  and  middle  classes  in  England,  the 
second  is  a  still  more  powerful  cause  in  France, 
and  is  said  to  be  in  some  portions  of  the  United 
States.  To  what  extent  families  are  thus 
restricted  in  England  is  uncertain,  but  the 
practice  has  many  able  advocates  and  the 
subject  is  now  widely  and  openly  discussed  in  a 
manner  that  would  not  have  been  believed  to 
be  possible  a  few  years  ago.  In  France  the 
peculiar  land  system  which  compels  the  division 
of  real  estate  equally  among  the  children  tends 
to  make  small  families  specially  desired. 


The  economic  question  arises  whether  pro- 
tection, in  whatever  form  applied,  can  succeed 
in  achieving  the  result  aimed  at.  In  the  case  of 
France,  which  restricts  its  birth-rate  to  such  a  de- 
gree that  it  increases  more  slowly  than  any  other 
nation,  does  France  produce  as  many  labourers 
as  she  requires  ?  If  so,  why  are  there  more 
foreigners  in  France  than  in  any  other  country  ? 
Does  she  have  to  import  Belgians,  Swiss,  and 
Italians  because  she  has  not  enough  French- 
men for  her  needs  ?  The  foreign  born  in  France 
increased  from  380,831,  or  I'l  per  cent  of  the 
population,  in  1851,  to  1,126,531,  or  2-9  per 
cent  of  the  population,  in  1886,  numbers  and 
proportions  not  approached  in  any  other  country 
of  Europe.  Between  the  censuses  of  1872  and 
1886  the  increase  in  the  population  of  Franco 
was  2,116,082,  of  which  385,863  persons,  or 
18  per  cent,  were  foreign  born.  The  census  of 
1891  showed  a  diminution  of  the  number  of 
foreigners  by  13,416,  probably  the  effect  of  the 
alien  law  of  1888.  In  1911  the  foreigners 
were  over  2  -7  per  cent  of  the  population. 

Rural  Depopulation  in  England  and  Wales. — - 
The  division  of  a  population  into  urban  and 
rural  is  a  matter  of  considerable  difficulty,  and 
strict  comparisons  at  successive  periods  are 
scarcely  practicable.  In  the  Census  of  England 
and  Wales  1881  it  is  shown  that  whereas  "  the 
town  population,  i.e.  inhabitants  of  the  districts 
and  sub-districts  which  include  the  chief  towns," 
increased  in  the  census  intervals  since  1851  by 
19-41,  18-09,  and  19-63  per  cent  respectively, 
"  the  country  population,  i.e.  the  inhabitants 
of  the  smaller  towns  and  the  country  parishes," 
increased  by  4-12,  7-32,  and  7-42  percent.  The 
Preliminary  Report  of  the  Census  of  England  and 
Wales  1891  shows  that  in  the  ten  years  1881- 
91  the  "urban  sanitary  districts "  increased  by 
15-3  per  cent,  the  "rural  sanitary  districts  "  by 
only  3-4  per  cent.  A  similar  increase  for  both 
urban  and  rural  districts  is  recorded  for  the 
decade  1891-1901.  Our  rural  population  in- 
creased, but  so  slowly  as  to  be  almost  stationary. 
But  the  census  of  1911  shows  an  improvement, 
an  important  factor  being  the  diminished  loss 
of  the  rural  districts  by  migration. 

Dr.  A.  L.  Bowley  in  a  paper  read  before  the 
Statistical  Society,  Rural  Populations  in  Ejigland 
and  Wales  (see  Journal,  1914),  discusses  rural 
population  '*  from  consideration  of  its  density  " 
as  being  more  satisfactory  than  definitions  based 
on  occupations  or  "on  the  administrative  dis- 
tinction between  urban  and  rural  districts, " 
which  latter  he  regards  as  misleading,  since,  as 
he  points  out,  the  population  of  many  rural 
districts  may  be  raised  by  the  inclusion  of  an 
industrial,  mining,  or  suburban  population.  The 
method  of  selection  has  been  to  include  all 
districts  in  which  the  density  (1911)  was  not 
over  30  per  100  acres,  and  such  districts  in 
which  it  was  30  to  50  per  100  acres  where  it 
could  be  ascertained  that  there  were  no  mines, 


556 


DEPOPULATION 


factories,  industries,  no  residential  district  for 
persons  working  in  large  towns,  no  disturbing 
causes  such  as  military  camps,  large  schools, 
asylums,  temporary  works  on  railways,  etc.  An 
examination  of  Dr.  Bowley's  tables  shows  that 
out  of  53  administrative  counties  the  strictly 
rural  population  had  decreased  in  33  since  1891 ; 
of  these,  9,  Cornwall,  Hereford,  Westmoreland, 
Denbigh,  Anglesey,  Merioneth,  Cards,  Mont- 
gomery, Pembroke,  lost  continuously ;  4,  North- 
ants,  Cumberland,  Radnor,  Carmarthen, dropped 
in  1901  and  have  not  altered  since ;  16,  Devon, 
Somerset,  Dorset,  Wilts,  Berks,  Bucks,  Norfolk, 
Suffolk,  Cambridge,  Lines,  Beds,  Oxford,  Glou- 
cester, Shropshire,  E.  and  N.  Ridings  of  Yorks, 
dropped  in  1901  and  rose  slightly  in  1911  ;  4 
remained  stationary,  Hunts  and  Northumber- 
land throughout  the  period,  Rutland  and  Breck- 
nock dropped  and  rose  again.  Of  the  20  counties 
in  which  the  rural  districts  have  improved,  6  im- 
proved continuously,  Hants  (with  L  of  Wight), 
Surrey,  Staffs,  W.  Riding  of  Yorks,  Lanes,  Flint ; 
9,  Kent,  Herts,  Essex,  Monmouth,  Worcester, 
Warwick,  Derby,  Notts,  Cheshire,  though  higher 
in  1911  than  in  1891,  had  dropped  in  1901  ; 
3,  Sussex,  Leicester,  Glamorgan,  were  stationary 
in  1901  and  rose  in  1911.  Durham  rose  in  1901 
and  has  not  altered  since.  Carnarvon  rose  in 
1901  and  dropped  slightly  in  1911. 


PopulatioB. 

iii 

Mining,  Indus- 

trial.  Suburban 

•s£:? 

Percentage  Growth. 

Areas  deducted. 

Counties. 

000  omitted. 

^i^ 

1891. 

1901. 

1911. 

1911. 

1891- 
1901.3 

1901- 
1911. 

1891- 
1911.3 

Cornwall 

154 

149 

145 

19 

-   3-2 

-     2.6 

-  5-8 

S.Westerni 

688 

642 

648 

17 

-   6-7 

+    I 

-  5-8 

Hants  1 

155 

159 

176 

21 

-1-  2-6 

-fll.l 

+11-4 

Surrey 

53 

59 

67 

S2 

+  11-3 

+  14 

+  26-4 

Home 

623 

609 

639 

2h 

-   2-2 

+  6 

+  2-6 

Counties  2 

Eastern 

1002 

959 

988 

19 

-  4 

+  3 

-  1 

S.  Midland 

522 

492 

503 

n 

-  5-7 

+    2 

-  3-6 

Western 

240 

234 

237 

ih 

-  2-5 

+    1.3 

-  1-2 

W.  Midland 

281 

280 

290 

-     -3 

+  >7 

+  3-3 

N.  Midland 

604 

509 

628 

19 

+  1 

+  4 

+  4-8 

and  N.W. 

Northern 

478 

463 

465 

10 

-  31 

+     -5 

-  2-7 

N.  Wales 

176 

177 

177 

18 

+     -5 

0 

+     -6 

Mid-Wales 

157 

147 

145 

8 

-  6-4 

~   i'5 

-  7-4 

S.  Wales 

109 

105 

103 

12 

-  3-7 

-   2 

-  5-5 

Glamorgan 

18 

18 

23 

19 

0 

+28 

+28 

1  Excluding  Cornwall.     2  Excluding  Hants  and  Surrey. 
3  Not  from  Dr.  Bowley's  table. 

The  rural  population  of  England  dropped 
-  7  per  cent  in  the  last  50  years  (see  below), 
and  only  5  out  of  the  14  districts  considered 
showed  an  increase.  Of  the  individual  counties 
only  10  showed  an  increase  in  the  50  years, 
Hants,  Surrey,  Kent,  Sussex,  Worcester,  Staffs, 
Cheshire,  W.  Riding  of  Yorks,  Flint,  Car- 
narvon, while  Derby  remained  unaltered.  Dr. 
Bowley  further  shows  that  the  rural  popula- 
tion increased  50  per  cent  in  the  period  1801- 
51,  was  stationary  between  1851-71,  fell  10  per 
cent  by  1901,  and  recovered  3  per  cent  by  1911. 


Increase  or  Decrease  per  cent  in  Eegistration 
Counties,  Industrial,  etc.  Regions  deducted, 
for  the  last  60  years. 


1861- 

1871- 

1881- 

1891- 

1901- 

1891- 

71. 

81. 

91. 

1901. 

11. 

1911.3 

Cornwall   . 

-3 

-IS 

-8 

-  4-7 

-   1-6 

-27 

S.  Western  1      . 

-2 

-   7 

-4 

-   7 

+  1 

-17 

Hants 

+2 

-   1-h 

+2 

+     -7 

+  9 

-M2-8 

Surrey       .    •     . 

+7 

+  1* 

+9 

+11 

-I-10-9 

+48 

Home  Counties  2 

+4 

= 

= 

-  S 

+  5 

+58 

Eastern     . 

-1 

-   5 

-4 

-  5 

+  3 

-11 

S.  Midland 

-1 

-   5 

-4-5 

-  6 

+  2 

-14 

Western    . 

+  1 

-  5 

-4 

-  3 

+  1 

-     -9 

W.  Midland       . 

+4 

= 

-2 

= 

+  3-5 

+  5-7 

North    Midland 

-1 

+  1 

-2 

r= 

+  4 

+  1-5 

and  N.W. 

Northern  . 

-4 

-   2 

-U 

-  u 

+  1 

-  9-9i 

N.  Wales  .        . 

+2 

+  3 

-7 

+ 1 

-  1-3 

Mid-Wales 

-   4 

-8 

-  6 

-   2 

-19 

S.  Wales    .        . 

-5 

-   2 

-2 

-  8 

+  4 

-13 

Rural  England  . 

= 

-   3-5 

-2.9 

-   3-7 

+  2.9 

-  7 

1  Excluding  Cornwall.    2  Excluding  Hants  and  Surrey. 
8  Not  from  Dr.  Bowley's  table. 

He  next  investigates  land  occupations,  and 
points  out  that  the  variations  in  rural  popula- 
tion are  not  parallel  with  those  of  persons  en- 
gaged in  agriculture.  These  showed  a  decrease 
from  1861  to  1901,  but  a  slight  increase  in  1911. 
Rural  Depopulation  in  Scotland. — Although 
the  population  of  Scotland  has  increased  in 
every  decade  since  1801,  the  phenomenon  of  so- 
called  depopulation  has  been  exhibited  in  certain 
areas.  Three  counties,  Perth,  Kinross,  and  Argyll, 
reached  their  maximum  in  1831  (Perth  and 
Kinross  are  now  slightly  rising) ;  one,  Inverness, 
in  1841  ;  five,  Sutherland,  Ross  and  Cromarty. 
Dumfries,  Kirkcudbright",  and  Wigtown,  in  1851 
(Ross  and  Cromarty  and  Dumfries  are  rising 
slightly) ;  five,  Shetland,  Orkney,  Caithness, 
Berwick,  Roxburgh,  in  1861  ;  two,  Elgin  and 
Nairn,  in  1881  (Nairn  improved  slightly  in 
1911);  two,  Banff  and  Selkirk,  in  1891  (Sel- 
kirk improved  slightly  in  1911).  In  Shetland, 
Orkney,  Caithness,  Sutherland,  Berwick,  and 
Wigtown  the  loss  has  been  continuous.  Forfar, 
Clackmannan,  and  Bute,  which  had  steadily  pro- 
gressed since  1801,  dropped  in  1911.  On  the 
other  hand  an  increase  has  been  steadily  main- 
tained at  each  census  in  Aberdeen,  Fife,  Stirling, 
Dumbarton,  Renfrew  (a  slight  exceptioninl901), 
Ayr,  Lanark,  Linlithgow,  and  Edinburgh ;  these 
counties  contain  some  of  the  largest  towns  in 
Scotland.  Eighteen  declining  counties  had  a 
collective  population  numbering  nearly  130,000 
less  than  the  sum  of  their  several  maxima. 
Argyll  has  lost  over  30,000,  Inverness  10,500. 
The  percentage  decline  was  nearly  30  in  Argyll, 
nearly  26  in  Wigtown,  nearly  22  in  Sutherland, 
17  in  Caithness.  Although  the  depopulation  is 
most  evident  in  the  Highlands,  and  more  especi- 
ally in  the  extreme  north  and  west,  yet  five  of 
the  lowland  counties  have  altogether  diminished 
by  over  30,000  persons  during  the  last  fifty 
3^ears.  The  most  active  cause  of  this  is  prob- 
ably the  attracting  force  of  the  labour  markets 
of  Glasgow  and  the  north  of  England.     The 


DEPOPULATION 


66? 


diminution  in  the  north  and  west  may  probably 
be  attributed  to  a  rise  in  the  standard  of  living 
and  consequent  emigration,  since  the  poor  soil 
did  not  afford  employment  for  more  labourers  ; 
but  no  doubt  the  concurrent  extension  of  sheep 
farming,  and  in  a  few  cases  the  formation  of 
deer  forests,  have  contributed  to  the  result. 
Where  the  barrier  of  the  sea  has  tended  to  check 
the  beneficial  operation  of  migration,  as  in  Lewis, 
the  population  has  continued  to  increase,  with 
the  disastrous  results  that  are  too  familiar. 

Depopulation  in  Ireland. — The  case  of  Ireland 
is  at  once  so  important  and  so  instructive  as  to 
merit  especial  attention.  A  century  ago  Ireland 
was  a  by-word  for  poverty  ;  the  people  had  few 
other  resources  than  tilling  the  soil,  and  this 
they  did  in  a  careless  manner,  demoralised  as 
they  were  by  long  dependence  almost  solely  upon 
the  potato,  a  crop  which  in  fair  seasons  gives 
food  for  forty  persons  by  the  labour  of  one.  The 
Irish  lived  under  almost  the  lowest  standard 
conceivable,  miserably  clothed  and  fed  and  even 
more  miserably  housed,  and  were  almost  chron- 
ically on  the  verge  of  starvation.  Famines 
occurred  in  1814,  1816,  1822,  and  1831.  Under 
these  distressing  circumstances  the  population 
continued  to  increase  till  at  the  census  of  1841 
it  numbered  8,196,597.  Even  at  that  time  the 
pressure  of  population  upon  the  means  of  sub- 
sistence had  begun  to  seek  relief  by  emigration, 
and  the  census  of  1841  showed  the  population 
to  be  considerably  less  than  liad  been  anticipated 
(see  Census  of  Ireland  ISJ^l,  vol.  i.  p.  ix.) ;  in  fact 
no  less  than  428,471  emigrants  are  recorded  as 
having  left  Ireland  for  the  colonies,  and  104,814 
for  Great  Britain,  during  the  decade  1831-41. 
Nevertheless  the  population  continued  to  in- 
crease, and  is  believed  to  have  reached  about 
8,295,061  by  the  middle  of  the  year  1845,  which 
would  give  a  density  of  525  to  the  square  mile. 
It  is  true  that  the  density  of  the  population  of 
England  and  Wales  in  1911  was  618  to  the 
square  mile,  in  Belgium  (1911)  652,  in  large 
districts  of  Bengal  from  292  to  about  438  ;  but 
the  first-named  countries  have  great  wealth  in 
minerals  and  manufactures  with  which  to  buy 
food  from  other  countries,  the  latter  has  a  very 
fertile  soil  and  a  tropical  climate.  The  potato 
rot  appeai'ed  in  1845  and  again  in  1846,  the 
main  food -supply  of  the  people  failed,  and 
famine  was  inevitable.  It  reached  its  height 
in  1847  and  was,  as  a  direct  result,  accompanied 
by  severe  epidemics  of  typhus  and  relapsing 
fevers.  It  is  believed  that  starvation  and  fever 
between  them  claimed  from  200,000  to  300,000 
victims,  and  when  the  people  were  again  num- 
bered in  1851  the  population  had  shrunk  to 
6,574,278,  or  1,622,319  less  than  in  1841,  but 
1,720,783  less  than  the  supposed  maximum  of 
1845.  The  population  thus  diminished  by  20 
per  cent  in  six  years.  The  greater  part  of  this 
startling  depopulation  was  due  to  the  great 
exodus  in  1847  and  the  following  years,  when 


the  Irish  poured  into  Liverpool  and  Glasgow 
and  spread  themselves  over  England  and  Scot- 
land, and  every  ship  sailing  for  North  America 
was  filled  with  Irish  emigrants. 

The  decrease  affected  every  county  in  Ireland 
except  Dublin  (it  was  least  in  Leinster,  greatest 
in  Connaught),  but  while  this  unexampled  de- 
pletion of  the  rural  districts  was  taking  place, 
there  was  an  increase  in  nine  town  districts 
amounting  in  the  aggregate  to  77,519.  Belfast 
and  Dublin  each  added  some  25,000  to  their 
numbers,  and  the  increase  amounted  to  6  per 
cent  in  Cork,  10^  per  cent  in  Limerick,  11  per 
cent  in  Dublin,  and  33  per  cent  in  Belfast.  The 
census  of  1851  showed  that  the  extent  of  land 
under  tillage  increased  by  2091  square  miles, 
and  the  value  of  agricultural  stock  and  crops 
was  greater  than  any  previously  recorded.  No 
fewer  than  355,689  "  fourth  -  class  houses," 
mostly  mud  cabins,  disappeared,  houses  of  the 
first  class  increased  by  10,084,  those  of  the 
second  class  by  54,574.  In  short  the  depopu- 
lation was  accompanied  by  a  very  notable  rise 
in  the  standard  of  living. 

Subsequent  enumerations  show  the  same 
thing, — a  steady,  though  less  rapid,  diminu- 
tion of  population  accompanied  by  a  rise  in  the 
standard  of  living.  The  census  of  1861  showed 
a  loss  of  population  of  775,311  or  11*8  per  cent; 
that  of  1871  a  loss  of  6-7  ;  that  of  1881,  4-4  : 
that  of  1891,  9-1  ;  that  of  1901,  5-2  per  cent. 
The  census  of  1911  shows  a  decline  of  1*7  per 
cent,  the  smallest  on  record  ;  a  decrease  in  the 
number  of  emigrants,  an  increase  in  the  number 
of  houses,  general  improvement  in  house  ac- 
commodation (the  mud  cabins  have  nearly  dis- 
appeared), a  decrease  in  poverty,  a  decrease  in 
the  death-rate.  (See  Sir  W.  J.  Thompson,  ' '  The 
Census  of  Ireland  1^11,"  Journ.  Stat,  and  Social 
Inquiry  Socy.  of  Ireland,  Dec.  1913.)  The 
total  diminution  of  the  population  of  Ireland 
since  1841  amounts  to  3,814,646,  or  46*5  per 
cent,  distributed  as  follows  :  Leinster,  41*5  per 
cent;  Munster,  57  per  cent;  Ulster,  33*9  per 
cent  ;  Connaught,  57*1  per  cent.  Except 
Dublin  and  Antrim,  every  county  is  smaller  in 
1911  in  numbers  than  in  1841. 

In  the  seventy  years  during  which  this  great 
and  real  depopulation  has  been  going  on,  the 
inhabitants  of  Galway  and  Lei  trim  had  dimin- 
ished by  over  68  per  cent ;  those  of  Kilkenny 
by  over  65  per  cent ;  but,  on  the  other  hand, 
some  of  the  towns  have  largely  increased, 
Londonderry  has  considerably  more  than 
doubled  and  Belfast  more  than  quadrupled  its 
population,  rivalling  in  their  rapid  progress 
the  most  prosperous  English  towns.  Dublin 
city  increased  between  1841  and  1901  by  over 
7  per  cent,  but  ''greater  Dublin,"  including  the 
suburbs,  by  over  24  per  cent.  The  alteration 
of  the  city  boundaries  renders  further  com- 
parison difficult. 

Rural  Depopulation  in  France. — It  is  we.ll 


658 


DEPOPULATION 


known  that  the  excej)tionally  low  birth-rate  of 
France  involves  a  correspondingly  small  rate  of 
natural  increase ;  it  is  perhaps  not  as  well  known 
that  depopulation  of  country  districts  is  a  no 
less  striking  phenomenon  in  France  than  in 
England  ;  while  it  need  scarcely  be  mentioned 
that  the  conditions  of  land  tenure  are  as  dif- 
ferent as  can  well  be  imagined.  The  population 
of  thewhole  country  continues  to  increase  slowly, 
a  large  proportion  (about  a  fourth)  of  this  in- 
crease being  due  to  the  immigration  of  foreigners; 
at  the  same  time  in  sixty  out  of  the  eighty- 
seven  departments  the  population  of  1911  is 
less  than  that  of  1886.  The  absolute  decrease 
amounts  to  60,000  for  the  fifty  years  (1861- 
1911)  in  Lot  et  Garonne,  Haute-Saone,  and 
Sarthe  ;  it  is  between  70,000  and  90,000  in 
Gers,  Lot,  Eure,  and  Mayenne  ;  it  is  no  less 
than  83,524  in  Calvados,  115,017  in  Orne,  and 
113,086  in  Manche.  As  a  rule  the  densely 
populated  departments  have  increased  in  dens- 
ity, while  the  sparsely  populated  have  lost 
population.  After  Paris  and  its  suburbs,  in 
which  the  largest  increase  was  to  be  found,  the 
Mediterranean  departments  show  the  highest 
and  most  equally  distributed  growth.  Next 
conies  the  industrial  district  in  the  north,  and 
then  the  group  surrounding  the  western  sea- 
port towns.  These  districts  showed  an  increase 
of  nearly  3,000,000  for  the  twenty-five  years 
1886-1911,  thus  leaving  a  decrease  of  over 
1,600,000  spread  over  the  remainder  of  the 
country.  Ten  departments  in  which  the  de- 
crease was  over  45,000  accounted  for  about 
520,000,  or  nearly  one-third  of  the  deficit. 

A  comparison  of  the  census  of  1911  with 
that  of  1906  continues  the  same  story.  In  no 
less  than  63  out  of  the  87  departments  there 
was  a  decrease  of  population,  amounting  to 
over  378,000.  The  decrease  was  most  marked 
in  Ardeche,  where  it  exceeded  15,000  ;  in  Allier, 
Haute-Loire,  Manche,  Somme,  and  Yonne, 
where  it  was  over  11,000.  The  net  increase 
of  the  whole  country  was  349,000,  against 
290,000  in  1906,  445,000  in  1901,  175,000  in 
1896,  and  124,045  in  1891  (the  smallest  re- 
corded). The  decrease  in  the  rural  population 
was  487,000  in  1901,  290,000  in  1906,  while 
the  urban  population  increased  by  901,000  in 
1901  and  610,000  in  1906,  a  probable  migra- 
tion from  country  to  town  of  about  450,000 
persons  in  1901  and  320,000  in  1906. 

Other  European  Countries. — The  tendency  of 
people  to  flock  into  cities,  which  has  been  shown 
to  be  closely  related  to  rural  depopulation,  is 
found  in  most  European  States  (see  Ravenstein, 
Journ.  Stat.  Socy.  lii.  1889,  p.  241) ;  for  Ger- 
many (Rovrie  de  Beaucaire,  Bull,  du  Ministh-e 
de  V Agriculture  de  France,  1886).  The  per- 
centage of  population  living  in  towns  rose  in 
Prussia  from  7-3  in  1816  to  30  in  1890,  in 
Belgium  from  13-5  in  1800  to  34-8  in  1890,  in 
Austria  from  4*4  to  15*8,  in  Norway  from  3-3 


to  16-7.  See  A.  F.  Weber,  Growth  of  Cities 
(New  York),  1899. 

The  United  States. — Perhaps  the  last  place 
where  we  should  expect  to  meet  with  this  phe- 
nomenon is  the  United  States,  yet  it  is  to  be 
found  there.  The  census  of  1900  showed  that 
the  state  of  Nevada  had  lost  in  twenty  years 
21,525  persons,  or  more  than  one-third  of  its 
population  ;  this  is  attributed  to  the  failure  of 
the  Comstock  and  other  mines.  The  state 
more  than  recovered  by  the  census  of  1910.  A 
comparison  of  the  censuses  of  1890  and  1910 
shows  that  while  every  state  except  Iowa  had 
increased  in  numbers  in  the  twenty  years, 
yet  this  was  concurrent  with  a  considerable 
rural  depopulation  in  every  state  but  Nevada, 
Nebraska,  and  Wyoming.  It  has  been  par- 
ticularly acute  in  Vermont,  New  York,  Ohio, 
Indiana,  Illinois,  Arizona,  California,  New 
Jersey,  Pennsylvania,  Michigan,  Missouri,  Okla- 
homa, Idaho,  Utah,  Washington,  and  Oregon. 
In  the  first  seven  of  these,  as  well  as  in  Maine, 
Maryland,  Virginia,  North  and  South  Carolina, 
Iowa,  Kentucky,  Tennessee,  Mississippi,  and 
Colorado,  it  had  set  in  some  years  before  1890, 
in  some  cases  since  1860.  Regarding  the 
United  States  as  a  whole,  the  rural  population, 
which  was  64  per  cent  of  the  total  in  1890, 
dropped  to  54  per  cent  in  1910,  while  the  actual 
numbers  rose  from  40,227,000  to  49,349, OOC. 
The  urban  population  rose  from  36  to  46  per 
cent  of  the  total,  the  actual  numbers  being 
22,720,000  and  42,623,000.  In  addition  to 
many  of  the  causes  that  have  operated  in  Europe, 
the  state  returns  show  that  large  numbers  of 
New  England  farms  have  been  abandoned 
either  because  the  soil  was  poor,  or  exhausted 
by  an  improvident  system  of  farming,  or  be- 
cause the  farms  were  inconveniently  situated. 
Thus  much  of  the  soil  of  New  England  has 
passed  out  of  cultivation,  the  cultivators  having 
gone  into  the  great  cities  or  migrated  to  the 
fertile  soils  of  the  western  prairies.  One  thing 
is  certain,  the  movement  cannot  be  attributed 
to  an  aristocratic  or  exclusive  land  system. 

Economic  Results. — With  regard  to  these  we 
shall  consider  the  British  Isles  only. 

There  is  no  doubt  that  the  present  tendency 
is  for  the  rural  population  to  be  reduced  to  the 
lowest  point  consistent  with  the  due  cultivation 
of  the  land,  and  for  all  subsidiary  industries  to 
move  into  larger  centres,  with  the  well-known 
result  that  the  proportion  of  modern  civilised 
populations  living  under  town  conditions  is  a 
gradually  increasing  one.  In  spite  of  sani- 
tary progress  a  population  reared  in  a  town  can 
scarcely  hope  to  be  as  hardy  and  vigorous  as 
one  born  and  bred  in  the  country,  so  that  some 
amocintof  racial  degeneration  appears  inevitable. 

Remedies. — All  deplore  the  decline  in  our 
rural  population,  and  many  seek  by  legislative 
or  other  means  to  check  it.  Bad  government 
may  of  course  be  improved,  bad  laws  may  be 


DEPOPULATION— DEPOSIT 


559 


repealed,  oppressive  taxation  may  be  removed 
or  its  burthens  equalised,  but  it  is  obvious  that 
the  causes  of  the  depopulation  of  rural  districts 
are  too  deep-seated  to  admit  of  eradication. 
The  great  fundamental  economic  law  of  supply 
and  demand  will  not  admit  of  denial.  The 
provision  of  allotments  for  labourers,  if  judici- 
ously carried  out,  might  be  very  beneficial  ;  an 
amendment  of  the  land  laws,  especially  by 
making  public  all  mortgages  and  charges  on 
land  by  a  system  of  registration,  and  so  facili- 
tating and  stimulating  the  transfer  of  land, 
would  make  our  land  system  healthier.  An 
extension  of  market  gardening  would  of  course 
pro  tanto  employ  more  hands  ;  something  may 
possibly  be  devised  to  foster  the  growth  of 
village  industries ;  more  businesses  may  be 
transferred  from  London  to  small  country 
towns,  as  has  already  been  done  in  the  printing 
trade  ;  country  life  may  be  made  less  dull, — still 
the  countryman  will  wend  his  way  to  London, 
Glasgow,  or  Belfast,  to  New  York  or  Montreal, 
to  Sydney  or  Melbourne.  The  remarkable 
uniformity  of  the  growth  of  large  towns,  not 
only  in  every  country  of  Europe,  but  in 
America  and  Australia,  proves  conclusively  that 
it  is  no  question  of  land  laws  that  regulates 
the  matter.  Do  not  let  us  deceive  ourselves 
by  expecting  that  results  will  in  this  country 
follow  land-law  reforms  which  have  not  appeared 
in  other  countries  where  a  diametrically  opposite 
system  has  been  established.  The  modern  man 
prefers  to  live  in  an  urban  or  suburban  district ; 
improved  means  of  communication  enable  him 
to  accomplish  the  object  of  his  desires,  and  no 
effort  will  prevent  him  from  doing  so,  or  will 
succeed  in  attaching  to  the  soil  a  greater  num- 
ber of  labourers  than  is  absolutely  required  to 
produce  sufficient  supplies  of  food  under  the 
easiest  conditions  attainable. 

The  following  extracts  from  the  History  of  New 
South  Wales  from  the  Records,  G.  B.  Barton  (1889), 
voL  i.  1783-1789  show  the  apprehensions  once 
felt  that  the  establishment  of  the  new  colonies 
would  deplete  the  parent  country. 

Page  8. — Sir  George  Young  sketched  the  pro- 
spective advantages  of  the  settlement  in  the  fol- 
lowing form.  ...  4.  The  settlement  of  the 
country  would  not  tend  to  "depopulate"  the 
parent  state,  as  the  settlers  would  be  principally 
collected  from  the  Friendly  Islands  and  China ; 
the  only  men  required  from  England  being  a  few 
skilled  workmen,  who  might  be  drawn  from  the 
ships  sent  out  on  the  service. 

Page  430. — Sir  G.  Young's  proposal — 

At  a  time  when  men  are  alarmed  at  every  idea 
of  emigration,  I  wish  not  to  add  to  their  fears  by 
any  attempt  to  depopulate  the  parent  state  ;  the 
settlers  of  New  South  Wales  are  principally  to  be 
collected  from  the  Friendly  Islands  and  China  ; 
all  the  people  required  from  England  are  only  a 
few  that  are  possessed  of  the  useful  arts,  and  those 
comprised  among  the  crews  of  the  ships  sent  out 
on  that  service.  G.  B.  L. 


DEPOSIT  (Sales  of  Land).  It  is  usual, 
on  the  sale  of  land  or  houses,  for  the  purchaser 
to  deposit  a  sum  (generally  £10  per  cent  of  the 
purchase- money)  as  soon  as  the  bargain  is 
concluded,  which  on  completion  is  considered 
as  a  payment  on  account  of  the  purchase-money, 
and  in  case  of  non- completion  through  the 
purchaser's  default  is  forfeited  to  the  vendor. 
When  the  sale  takes  place  by  auction  the 
de])osit  is  generally  paid  to  the  auctioneer,  who 
holds  it  as  stakeholder  for  both  parties,  but  in 
the  case  of  a  private  contract  the  deposit  is 
usually  paid  to  the  vendor.  In  cases  where 
the  vendor  is  not  entitled  to  receive  the 
purchase-money,  or  is  only  entitled  to  a  part 
of  it  (as  in  the  case  of  a  sale  by  a  tenant  foi 
life  under  the  Settled  Land  Act,  or  by  a 
mortgagor),  it  is  safer  for  the  purchaser  to  pay 
the  deposit  to  the  vendor's  solicitor  as  stake- 
holder, or  to  pay  it  into  a  bank  to  the  joini; 
account  of  his  and  the  vendor's  respective 
solicitors  [cp.  Earnest  Money].  e.  s. 

DEPOSIT  (Deposits).  The  term  "deposits" 
is  used  in  banking  in  a  technical  sense.  In 
considering  this  it  must  be  remembered  that 
banks  may  be  divided  into  three  classes — banks 
of  issue,  of  discount,  and  of  deposit.  In  the 
first  the  banker  trades  with  the  capital  of  the 
public,  in  the  second  with  his  own  capital,  and 
in  the  third,  by  far  the  most  important  at  the 
present  day,  with  that  of  his  customers.  Al- 
though in  its  present  development  deposit 
banking  is  entirely  modern,  as  an  institution 
it  is  of  ancient  origin.  The  Trapczitce  of  Athens 
received  deposits  at  least  as  early  as  the  sixth 
century  B.C.  They  held  money  at  interest,  and 
also  took  deposits  specially  for  the  purpose  of 
payment  to  a  third  party,  but  it  is  not  certain 
that  they  kept  running  accounts.  In  Rome, 
both  the  Argentarii  {q.v.)  or  private  money 
lenders,  and  the  Mensarii  (q.v.),  who  were 
appointed  by  the  state,  received  money  on 
deposit,  in  addition  to  money -changing  and 
money-lending.  They  kept  two  classes  of 
accounts.  On  the  one  interest  was  paid,  the 
account  was  then  called  creditum.  On  the  other, 
called  depositum,  no  interest  was  paid,  the 
lodgment  being  for  safety  or  for  convenience  of 
payment  to  a  third  party,  upon  verbal  request, 
or  written  authority  of  the  depositor,  but  it  is 
not  certain  whether  this  assignment  or  cheque 
(attributio,  perscriptio)  was  transferable.  In  the 
middle  ages  the  banks  of  Venice  and  Genoa,  al- 
though primarily  incorporations  of  public  credi- 
tors, also  took  deposits,  although  it  does  not  ap- 
pear whether  they  paid  interest  upon  them,  or 
lent  out  the  moneys  held.  The  chief  function  of 
these  banks  as  well  as  those  of  Amsterdam  and 
Hamburg  (see  Banks,  Early  European)  was 
to  remedy  the  deficiencies  of  the  circulating 
medium,  which  consisted  of  coins  of  different 
countries  and  kinds,  all  more  or  less  clipped  or 
defaced.    Owing  to  the  difficulty  of  dealing  with 


660 


DEPOSITION— DEPOtS  ET  CONSIGNATIONS 


such  a  currency  it  became  the  practice  to  deposit 
it  in  the  bank,  and  to  make  transactions  in  bank 
money.  These  deposits  could  not  generally  be 
withdrawn,  but  might  be  transferred  to  the 
credit  of  other  persons.  Banks  of  this  class 
did  not  lend  out  any  part  of  their  deports, 
and  therefore  did  not  increase  the  circulating 
capital  of  the  country.  Out  of  them  arose  the 
banks  of  issue,  dating  from  the  1 7th  century, 
which  have  now,  among  English-speaking  races 
at  least,  very  largely  given  place  to  the  modern 
banks  of  deposit.  In  these  the  cheque  has 
taken  the  place  of  the  bank  note,  and  by  the 
convenience  of  this  instrument  banking  has 
reached  a  degree  of  development  of  which  it 
had  not  previously  been  supposed  capable  (see 
Banks  and  Cheques,  Law  of). 

The  term  "deposit"  is  noviusedhoth.  generally 
and  specially.  Generally,  it  denotes  the  whole 
amounts  lodged  in  a  bank  under  whatever 
conditions  held.  Specially,  it  denotes  money 
lodged  at  interest,  usually  in  round  sums,  and 
not  subject  to  cheque  at  sight,  a  deposit  receipt 
being  given  against  every  sum  paid  in,  which 
receipt  must  be  given  up  on  repayment.  In 
its  special  application  the  use  of  the  term  is  the 
reverse  of  that  which  obtained  among  Roman 
bankers  as  quoted  above.  Connected  with  the 
special  use  of  the  term  is  the  subject  of  deposits 
in  Savings  Banks  (see  Banks).  Circulating 
capital  deposited  in  these  banks  is  not  available 
for  the  daily  needs  of  business,  as  their  funds 
are  invariably  employed  in  fixed  investments, 
but  they  are  more  useful  than  if  hoarded. 
Banking  deposits  are  frequently  taken  as  an 
index  of  prosperity.  In  comparing  returns  of 
deposits  held  in  different  countries,  or  at 
different  times,  regard  should  be  had  to  the 
following  considerations  among  others.  (1)  The 
proportion  of  the  whole  banking  institutions 
comprised  in  the  returns  under  discussion.  In 
comparisons  as  to  time,  important  alterations 
may  have  taken  place,  so  that  returns  at  one 
date  may  show  deposits  previously  existing  but 
then  concealed.  This  may  be  due  to  (a)  greater 
perfection  in  returns,  or  (h)  change  in  character 
of  banking  institutions,  e.g.  gradual  adoption 
by  private  banks  of  practice  of  publishing 
accounts,  or  their  absorption  by  banks  already 
publishing.  (2)  Character  of  banking  institu- 
tions. A  number  of  single  banks  will  show 
large  amounts  of  deposits  with  each  other, 
which  would  not  appear  at  all  in  the  case  of  a 
few  large  banks  with  many  branches,  e.g.  some 
300,000,000  of  dollars  (say  £60,000,000 
sterling)  of  such  cross  deposits  are  held  by  the 
national  banks  of  the  United  States.  (3) 
Peculiarities  in  making  up  balance  sheets  or 
returns,  e.g.  in  the  United  States  clearing 
exchanges  are  always  made  in  the  morning, 
therefore  the  whole  clearing  appears  among  the 
assets  of  the  previous  day,  and  the  deposits  are 
larger  by  a  corresponding  amount.     Thus   in 


returns  of  national  banks  at  different  selected 
dates  we  find —  ,o«c 


Deposits 

Clearing  Exchanges 


1869.  1880.  1890. 

mlns.  $  mlns.  $  mlns.  $ 

678  1280  1925 

154  244  84 


Net  Deposits  524  1036         1841 

In  sterling,  converting  the  %  as  6  =  £1. 
1869.  1880.  1890. 

Deposits  £135,600,000    £256,000,000     £385,000,000 

Clearing  Ex.        30,800,000         48,800,000         16,800,000 


Net  Deposits  £104,800,000  £207,200,000  £368,200,000 
Between  the  first  and  last  dates  the  increase  in 
gross  deposits  is  184  per  cent,  in  net  deposits 
251  per  cent.  (4)  Characteristics  of  business 
in  different  countries,  e.g.  as  between  France 
and  the  United  States,  where  totally  different 
financial  methods  prevail.  (5)  Characteristics 
of  banking  in  different  countries,  e.g.  Austral- 
asian banking,  where  probably  one-fourth  of  the 
deposits  shown  at  the  present  date  are  drawn  from 
the  United  Kingdom,  and  therefore  should  be 
deducted  in  estimating  the  wealth  of  those 
colonies.  R.  w.  b. 

DEPOSITION.  In  the  wider  sense  deposi- 
tion means  the  act  of  giving  evidence  in  a 
judicial  proceeding.  In  its  narrower  sense  it 
means  evidence  so  given  which  has  been 
recorded  in  writing.  It  is  a  fundamental 
principle  of  the  English  law  of  evidence  that 
wherever  it  is  possible  a  witness  must  be  pro- 
duced in  court  to  be  personally  examined  and 
cross-examined  ;  and,  if  this  can  be  done,  no 
record  of  evidence  formerly  given  by  him  will 
be  accepted  as  a  substitute  for  appearance.  If 
the  witness  cannot  be  produced  either  because 
he  is  dead  or  too  ill  to  travel,  or  insane,  or  kept 
out  of  the  way  by  the  person  against  whom  his 
evidence  is  used,  then  his  deposition  is  admis- 
sible. But  in  this  case  the  person  against 
whom  the  evidence  is  used  in  a  criminal  case 
must  have  had  the  opportunity  by  himself  or 
his  legal  adviser  of  cross-examining  thedeponent. 
When  any  person  has  been  arrested  upon  the 
charge  of  committing  an  indictable  offence,  the 
magistrate  before  whom  he  is  brought  should 
cause  all  the  evidence  given  to  be  taken  down 
in  writing.  Magistrates  are  also  empowered  to 
take  the  depositions  of  persons  who  are  so  Ul 
that  they  are  not  likely  to  be  alive  at  the  time 
of  the  trial. 

[See  Stephen,  Digest  of  the  Law  of  Evidence, 
art.  32  and  140-142].  f.  c.  m. 

DEPOSITUM.  Expression  of  Roman  law 
for  the  contract  which  arises  when  goods  are 
left  in  some  person's  custody,  no  reward  being 
given  to  that  person  for  keeping  them.    E.  s. 

DEPOTS  ET  CONSIGNATIONS  (Caisse 
DEs).  A  public  establishment  in  France  charged 
to  receive  and  manage  under  the  respon- 
sibility of  the  state  all  obligatory  deposits  of 
money  or  securities,  comprising  the  funds  of 
benefit  societies  and  savings  banks,  guarantee 
money,  judicial   consignations   pending  judg- 


DEPRECIATION 


561 


ment,  unclaimed  successions,  endowments  of 
public  institutions,  pension  funds,  etc.  The 
Caisse  was  charged  with  the  sinking  fund  of 
the  public  debt  until  its  suppression.  It  also 
receives  voluntary  deposits  ;  but  the  amount  is 
unimportant  since  the  interest  has  been  reduced 
to  1  per  cent.  The  total  liabilities  of  the 
Caisse,  on  the  31st  December  1909,  amounted 
to  £207,760,000,  nearly  three- fourths  of  which 
were  to  the  savings  banks.  The  funds  are 
employed  in  rentes,  treasury  bills,  and  advances 
to  public  bodies  ;  the  revenue  being  credited  to 
the  different  classes  of  deposit  accounts  at 
variable  rates  of  interest.  T.  l. 

DEPRECIATION.  Depreciation  is  a  term 
used  by  accountants  to  describe  the  reduction 
in  value  that  takes  place  in  the  machinery  and 
plant  of  a  factory  or  other  undertaking  in 
which  industrial  operations  are  carried  on,  which 
reduction  in  value  must  be  provided  for  in  the 
account  of  profit  and  loss,  before  arriving  at  a 
present  value.  Manufacturers,  shipowners,  or 
others  who  treat  the  annual  earnings  of  their  pro- 
perty as  income,  deducting  only  the  actual  out- 
goings for  repairs  will  soon  find  themselves  with 
a  diminished  capital.  But,  while  repairs  alone 
^vill  not  maintain  a  full  value  or  balance  the 
inevitable  effects  of  time  and  use,  the  necessity 
for  depreciation  may  be  reduced  or  avoided  by 
an  expenditure  out  of  current  earnings  for 
renewals  and  extensions.  Depreciation  arises 
from  various  causes,  but  among  manufacturers 
it  is  generally  confined  to  the  loss  by  "wear 
and  tear. "  Thus  in  the  statutes  under  which 
the  inland  revenue  is  collected  the  commis- 
sioners who  make  the  assessments  for  income  tax 
are  authorised  "  to  allow  such  deductions  as  they 
may  think  just  and  reasonable  as  representing 
the  diminished  value  by  reason  of  wear  and 
tear  during  the  year  of  any  machinery  or  plant 
used  for  the  pm-poses  of  the  concern."  But 
a  reduction  in  value  may  arise  from  other 
causes.  For  in  arriving  at  the  present  capital 
value  of  machinery  or  plant  it  must  also  be 
considered  whether  any  of  it  has  become  obsolete 
or  has,  owing  to  changes  in  trade,  a  less  earning 
power  than  formerly.  Alterations  in  value 
may  be  dealt  with  in  various  ways.  The  most 
usual  is,  to  write  off  in  each  annual  account  a 
percentage  from  the  capital  value  of  the  pre- 
ceding year,  this  percentage  either  differing  for 
the  various  classes  of  plant  such  as  buildings, 
boilers,  machinery,  and  horses,  or  being  an 
average  rate  over  the  whole.  This  system  of 
dealing  with  a  constantly  reducing  value 
spreads  the  depreciation  over  a  long  period. 
Far  5  per  cent  so  applied  would,  in  20  years, 
still  leave  36  per  cent  of  the  original  value. 
The  rate  of  depreciation  may  have  to  be  varied. 
Thus  if  owing  to  active  trade  a  manufactory 
has  been  working  longer  hours  than  usual,  or 
the  machinery  has  been  forced  to  meet  an 
exceptional  demand,  it  is  proper  and  prudent 
VOL.  I. 


to  write  off  more  than  usual  for  wear  and  tear. 
On  the  other  hand  dull  times  and  short  hours 
may  justify  a  lower  rate  than  usual,  though  it 
must  be  remembered  that  buildings  and  plant 
deteriorate  even  when  idle.  Notwithstanding 
this  annual  depreciation  the  tendency  of  most 
concerns  is  to  grow  in  value  owing  to  the 
expenditure  for  extensions,  which  may  under 
such  a  system  be  properly  added  to  the  capital 
value.  But  whatever  the  methods  adopted  for 
estimating  and  stating  the  depreciation,  it  may 
be  said  in  regard  to  any  of  them  that  the  object 
in  view  is  so  to  treat  the  nominal  capital  in  the 
books  of  account  that  it  shall  always  repre- 
sent as  nearly  as  possible  the  real  value. 

Occasional  valuations  may  serve  as  a  useful 
check  in  the  correctness  of  a  depreciation  system, 
and  it  is  frequently  from  the  inconvenience 
and  cost  of  making  them  that  they  are  not 
made  every  year.  An  error  may  be  in  either 
direction.  Where  there  is  only  one  proprietor 
or  few  partners,  an  excess  of  caution  may  do 
no  harm,  the  real  value  remaining  even  if  too 
much  is  written  off  for  depreciation  in  the  books 
of  account.  But  such  an  excess  is  unfair  in  the 
case  of  shareholders  who  may  have  only  a  fleet- 
ing interest  in  the  undertaking,  and  who,  not 
being  made  acquainted  with  the  details  of  the 
annual  "  profit  and  loss  "  accounts,  may  suffer 
a  diminution  of  income  and  a  reduced  value  in 
their  shares  for  the  sake  of  those  who  will  be 
shareholders  hereafter.  Where  the  nature  of 
the  property  may  render  it  difficult  to  estimate 
correctly  the  rate  of  depreciation,  the  case  is 
sometimes  met  by  establishing  a  Reserve 
(g.  v.)  which,  standing  separately  in  the  accounts, 
shows  to  all  concerned  a  fund  available  for 
division  in  the  future.  Sometimes  depreciation 
in  value  is  met  by  the  establishment  of  a 
Sinking  Fund  {q.v.)  Thus  the  tenure  of 
land  or  buildings  may  be  shortening ;  the 
exclusive  patent  rights  of  valuable  machines  or 
processes  may  have  only  a  short  time  to  run  ; 
or  the  minerals  in  a  mine  may  be  consuming. 
In  each  of  these  cases  a  fund  is  necessary  to 
give  back  the  capital  that  has  been  originally 
embarked  in  the  undertaking.  In  some  cases 
the  gross  earnings  are  divided  each  year  as  income 
among  the  shareholders,  each  of  whom  is  left 
to  provide  his  own  sinking  fund.  So  long  as 
the  facts  are  clearly  known  to  all  concerned  one 
system  may  be  as  good  as  the  other.  In  large 
permanent  undertakings  like  railways  there  is 
generally  no  separate  system  of  depreciation,  it 
being  deemed  that  the  value  of  the  property 
is  shown  to  be  maintained  by  the  continual 
working  and  by  taking  care  that  expenditure 
for  renewals  is  all  defrayed  out  of  current 
earnings. 

But  while,  in  a  large  undertaking  like  a 
railway,  the  annual  expenditure  for  repairs  and 
renewals  may  fairly  balance  the  deterioration 
that  is  continually  going  on,  smaller  concerns 

2  o 


562 


DEPRECIATION  OF  MONETARY  STANDARD 


not  having  so  extensive  a  plant  may  be 
subjected  to  irregular  outgoings  that  will  disturb 
the  annual  average  rate  of  profit.  In  some 
such  cases  instead  of  providing  beforehand  for 
exceptional  renewals  by  a  depreciation  rate  or 
reserve  fund,  the  necessary  money  is  borrowed 
and  charged  to  a  Suspense  Account  (q.v.) 
which  is  paid  off  by  instalments  in  future  years. 
This  is  obviously  unsound  where  the  expenditure 
has  merely  maintained  or  restored  the  earning 
power  of  the  concern,  and  has  not  increased  it. 

E.  M. 

DEPRECIATION  OF  MONETARY  STAND- 
ARD may  be  defined  as  the  lowering  of  the 
value  of  money  in  relation  to  goods.  The  con- 
ception of  a  change  in  the  value  of  the  thing 
in  relation  to  things  in  general  is  not  quite 
clear ;  and  has  been  pronounced  invalid  by 
high  authorities.  Thus  J.  S.  Mill  speaks  of 
the  "necessary  indefiniteness  of  the  idea  of 
general  exchange  value — value  in  relation  not 
to  some  one  commodity,  but  to  commodities  at 
large  "  {Political  JSconomy,  bk.  iii.  ch.  xv.  §  1). 
"  We  cannot  even  suppose  any  state  of  circum- 
stances "  in  which  the  idea  would  be  definite. 
Yet,  as  Dr.  Sidgwick  has  observed  (Political 
Economy,  bk.  i.  ch.  ii.),  the  same  MOl,  in  the 
chapter  next  but  one  preceding,  says  that 
"  during  the  last  five  years  of  our  long  struggle 
with  Napoleon  .  .  .  the  value  of  the  stand- 
ard itself  was  considerably  raised  "  ;  meaning 
"an  enhancement  in  the  value  of  gold"  in 
relation  to  commodities.  With  a  like  appear- 
ance of  inconsistency  Ricardo  has  some  passages 
like  the  following : 

"  It  has  indeed  been  said  that  we  might 
judge  of  its  value  [the  value  of  a  currency]  by 
its  relation  not  to  one  but  to  the  mass  of  com- 
modities. .  .  .  Such  a  test  would  be  of  no 
nse  whatever.  ...  To  determine  the  value  of 
a  currency  by  the  test  proposed  ...  is  evi- 
dently impossible  "  (Proposals  for  an  Economical 
and  Secure  Currency,  §  2). 

"When  we  speak  of  the  high  or  low  value 
of  gold,  silver,  or  any  other  commodity  in 
different  countries,  we  should  always  mention 
some  medium  in  which  we  are  estimating  them. 
Thus,  when  gold  is  said  to  be  dearer  in  Eng- 
land  than  in  Spain,  if  no  commodity  is  men- 
tioned, what  notion  does  the  assertion  convey  ? 
.  .  .  Gold  appears  dearer  or  cheaper  in  Spain 
as  the  fancy  of  the  observer  may  fix  on  the 
medium  by  which  he  estimates  its  value" 
(Political  Economy,  ch.  xxviii.)  But  elsewhere 
Ricardo  implies  the  conception  which  is  in 
question :  "In  saying  that  gold  is  at  a  high 
price  we  are  mistaken  ;  it  is  not  gold,  it  is 
paper  which  has  changed  its  value.  Compare 
an  ounce  of  gold,  or  £3  :  17  :  10^,  to  commod- 
ities, it  bears  the  same  proportion  to  them 
which  it  has  before  done"  (High  Price  of 
Bullion;  Works  ...  by  M'CuUoch,  p.  279,  ed. 
1888).     The  difficulties  urged  by  Ricardo  and 


J.  S.  Mill  show  that  variations  in  general 
prices  cannot  be  precisely  determined.  That 
it  is  not  wholly  indeterminate  their  admissions 
show — backed  by  the  reasoning  of  other 
theorists,  especially  Malthus  and  Jevons 
(q.v.),  and  the  evidence  of  ordinary  language. 
That  there  was  a  depreciation  of  money  in 
relation  to  things  in  general,  after  the  influx  of 
gold  from  California  in  this  century,  few  deny  ; 
that  there  was  such  a  depreciation  after  the  in- 
flux of  silver  from  America  in  the  16th  century, 
all  admit. 

Depreciation  as  here  defined  is  theoretically 
ascertainable  by  observing  the  variation  of  the 
price  of  each  of  a  number  of  articles,  and 
taking  the  average  of  those  variations.  For 
discussion  of  the  different  methods  of  taking 
such  an  average  see  Index  Numbers. 

A  summary  method  of  ascertaining  deprecia- 
tion is  afforded  by  the  use  of  some  one  typical 
article  as  a  measure  of  value — "a  measure  of 
the  power  of  purchasing  generally,  or  of  com- 
manding such  important  commodities  as  the 
necessaries  and  conveniences  of  life  "  (Malthus, 
Measure  of  Valu£,  p.  2).  As  the  article  best 
fitted  for  this  purpose  Malthus  selects  Labour 
(Pol.  Econ.,  2nd  ed.  ch.  2. — J.  Bonar,  Mal- 
thus and  his  Work,  bk.  iii.  ch.  2).  According  to 
this  view  the  depreciation  of  money  is  measured 
by  the  diminution  in  the  quantity  of  labour 
which  can  be  purchased  for  the  same  amount 
of  money.  Corn  also  has  been  proposed  as  a 
measure  of  value  when  the  comparison  is 
between  distant  periods  (Adam  Smith,  Wealth 
of  Nations,  bk.  i.  ch.  v.)  An  average  between 
com  and  labour  is  proposed  by  Malthus  in  the 
first  edition  of  his  Political  Economy.  In  this 
connection  should  be  mentioned  MiU's  state- 
ment :  "To  obtain  an  approximate  measure  by 
which  to  estimate  value  in  use,  perhaps  nothing 
better  could  be  chosen  than  one  day's  subsist- 
ence of  an  average  man,  reckoned  in  the 
ordinary  food  consumed  by  the  class  of  un- 
skilled labourers"  (Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  iii.  ch.  xv. 
§2). 

A  measure  proper  for  thus  determining  the 
depreciation  of  a  debased  coinage  or  an  incon- 
vertible  paper  money  is  bullion.  A  means  of 
applying  this  measure  is  afforded  by  the 
Exchanges  (g.  v.)  As  Ricardo  says  :  "While 
the  circulating  medium  consists  ...  of  coin 
undebased,  or  of  paper -money  immediately 
exchangeable  for  undebased  coin,  the  exchange 
can  never  be  more  above  or  more  below  par 
than  the  expenses  attending  the  transportation 
of  the  precious  metals.  But  when  it  consists 
of  a  depreciated  paper-money  [or  of  a  clipped 
coinage]  it  necessarily  will  fall  according  to  the 
degi-ee  of  depreciation.  The  exchange  will 
therefore  be  a  tolerably  accurate  criterion  by 
which  we  may  judge  of  the  debasement  of  the 
currency "  (High  Price  of  Bullion ;  Works,  p. 
274).      It  was  thus  that  the  depreciation  of  the 


DEPRECIATION— DEPRESSION,  AGRICULTURAL 


563 


paper-money  in  England  during  the  latter  part 
of  the  Napoleonic  war  was  shown  to  be  from  15 
to  20  per  cent.  The  accuracy  of  such  deter- 
minations countenances  Ricardo's  dictum  that 
"it  can  only  be  by  a  comparison  to  this  stand- 
ard that  .  .  .  depreciation  may  be  estimated. " 
Depi-eciation  proper  perhaps  the  lowering  of  value 
thus  measured  might  be  called  ;  it  is  not  neces- 
sarily coincident  with  depreciation  in  the  general 
sense  above  defined.  Thus  Mill  in  a  passage 
above  cited  {Pol.  Econ.,  iii.  13,  6)  states  that 
in  the  Napoleonic  war  "paper,  though  depreci- 
ated relatively  to  the  then  value  of  gold,  did 
not  sink  below  the  ordinary  value  at  other 
times  either  of  gold  or  of  a  convertible  paper." 
Professor  Walker  adduces  evidence  that  the 
premium  on  gold,  the  depreciation  of  the 
paper  currency  in  Ricardo's  sense,  "does  not 
measure  the  advance  of  general  prices,"  the 
depreciation  in  the  other  sense  of  the  term. 

The  propriety  of  the  definition  here  adopted 
is  that  from  it  flow  the  chief  consequences  for 
good  or  evil  which  are  attributed  to  deprecia- 
tion. (1)  A  first  approximation  to  an  estimate 
of  those  consequences  is  that  they  are  insigni- 
ficant. Money  being  regarded  as  consisting  of 
counters,  it  is  indifferent  whether  there  are  more 
or  fewer  such.  "  Let  us  suppose  that  to  every 
pound  or  shilling  or  penny  in  the  possession  of 
any  one  another  pound,  shilling,  or  penny  were 
suddenly  added  .  .  .  this  increased  value 
would  do  no  good  to  any  one  ;  would  make  no 
difference,  except  that  of  having  to  reckon  in 
higher  numbers"  (Mill,  Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  iii.  ch. 
viii.  §  2,  and  cp.  ch.  xiii.  §  4).  (2)  A  less 
abstract  view  takes  into  account  the  disturb- 
ance of  contracts  for  deferred  payments  ;  the 
gain  to  debtors  and  loss  to  creditors,  and 
persons  with  fixed  incomes.  As  producers 
often  belong  to  the  former  class,  it  has  been 
held  that,  when  prices  are  rising,  "everything 
takes  a  new  face  ;  labour  and  industry  gain 
life  "  (Hume,  Essay  on  Money).  On  the  other 
hand  Adam  Smith  says  of  a  debased  coinage  in 
a  passage  which,  according  to  Ricardo,  is 
"equally  applicable  to  a  depreciated  paper 
currency"  {High  Price  of  Bullion;  Works,  p. 
289),  "  it  occasions  a  general  and  most  perni- 
cious subversion  of  the  fortunes  of  private 
people  ;  enriching  in  most  cases  the  idle  and 
profuse  debtor  at  the  expense  of  the  industrious 
and  frugal  creditor"  {Wealth  of  Nations,  bk. 
V.  ch.  iii.  p.  423,  ed.  M'C.)  Diff"erent  effects 
doubtless  attend  different  species  of  deprecia- 
tion. That  which  is  due  to  government  tamper- 
ing with  the  currency  is  probably  the  most 
deleterious.  (3)  A  nearer  approximation  to  an 
estimate  of  the  disturbance  caused  by  the  de- 
preciation of  a  currency  is  obtained  by  taking 
into  account  the  different  degrees  in  which  the 
prices  of  different  articles  are  raised.  Incon- 
vertible paper-money  issued  by  the  government 
of  a  country  at  war  is  apt  to  swell  first  the  prices 


of  war-materials.  Again  a  change  in  the  agio 
of  gold  in  relation  to  inconvertible  paper  may 
make  itself  felt  in  articles  of  export  and  import 
sooner  than  in  the  inland  ti'ade  (see  Adolph 
Wagner,  Russische  Papierwdhrung,  and  Kramer, 
Papiergeld  in  Oesterreich,  1885).  The  following 
seems  to  be  the  order  in  which  diff'erent  classes 
of  articles  are  in  general  reached  by  a  course 
of  depreciation  :  first,  wholesale  commodities  ; 
second,  retail  commodities  ;  third,  labour.  (4) 
A  peculiar  evil  of  a  depreciated  paper-currency 
is  that  its  value  is  usually  fluctuating.  The 
evils  of  such  fluctuation  are  well  stated  by 
Professor  Walker  (  Wages  Question).  There  is 
reason  to  think  that  a  fluctuating  currency 
favours  the  large  capitalist,  who  is  best  able 
to  weather  such  disturbances.  In  the  case 
of  clipped  coinage  ill  eff"ects  are  produced 
by  the  diff'erence  in  the  value  of  the  coins 
according  as  they  are  more  or  less  worn 
(Walker). 

[For  the  general  principles  of  the  subject  see  the 
leading  authorities  which  have  been  cited.  Ad- 
ditional particulars  relating  to  the  consequences 
of  depreciation  may  be  found  among  tlie  follow- 
ing : — W.  Bela  Foldes,  Ursachen  und  Wirkungen 
des  Agios,  Konrad's  Jahrbuch,  1882.  —  H.  S. 
Foxwell,  Irregularity  of  Employment  and  Fluctu- 
ation of  Prices,  1886. — W.  S.  Jevons,  Investiga- 
tions on  Currency  and  Finance,  p.  77  et  seq.— 
K.  Knies,  "Geldentheurund,"  Zeitschrift  fiir  die 
Gesammte  Staatswissenschaft,  1858. —  Kramer, 
Papiergeld  in  Oesterreich,  1885. — Marshall,  Third 
Report  on  Industrial  Remuneration,  Appendix 
C,  vol.  ii.  p.  422.  — Scharling,  "  Detailpreise," 
Konrad's  Jahrbuch,  1886. — Vita  di  Marco, 
Moneta  e  Mezzi,  1885.  ]  f.  t.  e. 

DEPRESSION,  AGRICULTURAL.  Indus- 
trial enterprises  are  so  inextricably  interlaced 
that  agricultural  depression  cannot  be  dissevered 
from  commercial  depression.  A  glance  over  the 
last  fifty  years  reveals  one  prime  factor  in 
existing  financial  and  social  disturbances  and 
many  concun-ent  causes.  The  prime  factor  is 
the  substitution  of  machines  for  men  and  the 
consequent  increase  in  the  facilities  for  the  pro- 
duction and  rapid  distribution  of  produce.  One 
tendency  of  this  development  of  labour-saving 
agencies,  sea  and  land  carriage,  and  telegraphic 
communication,  has  been  to  extend  uniformity 
of  prices,  to  increase  the  stress  of  foreign  com- 
petition, to  render  depression  not  local  but 
almost  universal.  Subject  to  differences  pro 
duced  by  commercial  policy,  the  civilised  world 
has  now  but  one  market,  and  suffers  or  prospers 
together.  Another  tendency,  which  has  little 
direct  bearing  on  agricultural  depression,  has 
been  to  supply  the  world  so  completely  with  . 
manufactured  articles  that  a  danger  of  a  glut 
arises.  A  third  has  been  to  disturb  the  parts 
played  by  capital  and  labour  respectively. 
First,  handicrafts  and  domestic  manufactures 
were  swallowed  up  by  the  machinery  of  indi- 
vidual capitalists  ;  then,  the  last  was  in  turn 


564 


DEPRESSION,  AGRICULTURAL 


displaced  by  associated  capital,  combined  in 
increasing  masses  till  little  is  left  but  the  largest 
establishments.  Small  shops,  small  factories, 
small  banks,  small  sailing  ships  for  ocean  trans- 
port, are  replaced  by  stores,  gigantic  syndicates, 
joint-stock  companies,  huge  ocean  steamers. 
A  fourth  result  has  been  the  destruction  of 
great  quantities  of  what  once  was  accounted 
wealth.  To  take  one  illustration  only.  The 
opening  of  the  Suez  Canal  extinguished  the 
sailing  tonnage  constructed  to  make  the  voyage 
round  the  Cape,  and  the  new  ships  that  were 
built  to  take  the  place  of  the  old  sailing  vessels 
were  displaced  five  years  later  by  steamships. 
A  fifth  result  has  been  temporary  or  permanent 
diminution  of  employment.  For  instance,  the 
application  of  steam  and  machinery  on  farms, 
wharves  and  docks,  on  shipboard,  and  in  fac- 
tories, has  thrown  enormous  numbers  out  of 
work.  The  saving  efi'ected  in  different  depart- 
ments of  industrial  effort  by  this  displacement 
of  muscular  labour,  this  substitution  of  machines 
for  men,  varies  from  80  per  cent  in  the  shoe 
trade  to  40  per  cent  in  the  manufacture  of 
machinery  {United  States  Bureau  of  Labour 
Report,  1886).  Agricultural  labourers  are  least 
affected  by  this  effect  of  the  development  of 
labour-saving  agencies,  because  in  many  farming 
operations,  and  especially  in  the  care  of  stock, 
men  are  needed.  On  the  other  hand,  agricul- 
turists have  felt  more  severely  than  manufac- 
turers the  pressure  of  foreign  competition  which 
has  resulted  from  the  increased  facilities  of  sea 
and  land  carriage.  The  values  of  agricultural 
imports  rose  between  1866  and  1883  from 
£77-,069,431  (average  of  five  years  1866-70)  to 
£157,520,797. 

So  vast  a  change  necessarily  produced  distress. 
Other  causes  intensified  the  crisis.  Prices  were 
disturbed  by  appreciation  of  gold  in  relation  to 
commodities  and  depreciation  of  silver  rela- 
tively to  gold.  An  exceptional  demand  for 
gold  and  a  falling  off  in  the  supply  {Report  of 
the  Silver  Commission,  1876  ;  evidence  of  Sir 
Hector  Hay)  increased  the  purchasing  power  of 
the  metal  and  lowered  prices.  At  the  same 
time  the  depreciation  of  silver,  absolutely 
in  relation  to  commodities  in  general,  owing  to 
the  increased  yield  of  silver  mines,  and  rela- 
tively to  gold,  owing  to  the  enhanced  value  of 
that  metal,  disturbed  the  trade  with  countries 
which  employ  silver  or  silver  and  gold  as  their 
standards  of  value.  A  series  of  commercial 
disasters  further  aggravated  the  depression. 
The  prosperity  of  the  country  reached  its  height 
in  1866.  Since  that  date,  in  spite  of  temporary 
inflations,  it  has  never  reached  its  former  level. 
The  opening  of  the  Suez  Canal  (1869)  not  only 
brought  Indian  producers  into  competition  with 
English,  but  broke  down  the  system  of  ware- 
housing and  distribution  of  produce  by  which 
England  had  hitherto  benefited.  With  the 
year  1870  began  an  inflation  of  prices.      The 


sudden  withdrawal  of  France  and  Germany  from 
industrial  competition  enabled  England  to  in- 
crease her  exports  by  10  millions  ;  the  require- 
ments of  the  Suez  Canal  gave  extraordinary 
stimulus  to  the  shipbuilding  trade  ;  the  railway 
development  in  Germany  and  America  created 
exceptional  demand  for  coal  and  iron.  In  1874 
the  reaction  began  from  inflated  prices.  The 
decline  of  the  coal  and  iron  trade,  the  stoppage, 
partial  or  absolute,  of  cotton  mills,  disputes  be- 
tween masters  and  men,  bad  harvests,  compli- 
cations arising  out  of  the  Eastern  question,  the 
default  on  the  Turkish  debt,  depressed  every 
industry.  But  the  extent  of  the  weakness 
existing  in  some  parts  of  our  commercial  system 
was  not  revealed  till  the  failures  of  the  city  of 
Glasgow,  Caledonian,  and  West  of  England 
Banks  in  1878.  Various  causes  combined  to 
prolong  the  reaction  against  the  inflated  prices 
of  1871-73  and  the  abnormal  demand  then 
made  for  labour  and  shipping.  Of  these  causes 
some  were  foreign,  some  domestic,  some  tem- 
porary, and  some  permanent.  Fluctuations  in 
the  standards  of  value,  hostile  tariffs,  stagnant 
trade,  keenness  of  competition,  unsettled  politics, 
are  the  principal  causes  that  come  from  abroad. 
At  home  the  prolongation  of  the  depression  is 
attributed  to  the  slow  adjustment  of  supply  and 
demand,  owing  to  the  accumulation,  between 
1870  and  1873,  of  savings  not  invested,  to 
over-trading,  trade  imions,  deterioration  in 
quality  of  production,  commercial  failures, 
mutual  distrust,  wet  or  sunless  seasons.  Of 
these  causes  only  one,  foreign  competition,  with 
low  prices  as  its  consequence,  must  necessarily 
be  permanent. 

In  the  first  part  of  the  period  under  review 
the  collapse  of  agriculture  was  primarily  due  to 
bad  seasons  ;  in  the  second  to  low  prices.  An 
inclement  autumn  in  1872,  and  an  unfavourable 
spring,  neutralised  the  fine  harvest  weather  of 
1873.  1874  was  the  last  of  a  cycle  of  prosper- 
ous seasons.  Yet  rents  continued  to  rise  for  at 
least  two  years  longer.  From  1875  to  1877 
there  was  a  succession  of  bleak  springs  and 
rainy  summers,  producing  short  cereal  crops  of 
inferior  quality,  mildew  in  wheat,  mould  in 
hops,  blight  in  other  crops,  rot  in  sheep,  disease 
in  cattle,  deteriorating  the  finer  grasses  of  pas- 
tures, throwing  heavy  lands  into  foul  condition. 
Upon  British  farmers,  thus  enfeebled  by  three 
bad  seasons  in  succession,  fell  the  gi'owing  force 
of  foreign  competition,  which  was  suddenly 
quadrupled  by  the  extension  of  wheat  areas  in 
America  and  India,  and  the  new  facilities  of  sea 
and  land  transport,  and  the  low  freightage  rates 
of  commercial  depression.  The  sunless  ungenial 
1879  produced  the  worst  harvest  of  the  century. 
Since  1882  seasons  have  proved  less  uniformly 
inclement,  and  trade  has  shown  signs  of  revival. 
But  farmers  have  lost  their  capital,  and  are 
confronted  by  the  problem  of  low  prices  and  the 
difiiculty  of  holding  their  own  against  the  pro 


DEPRESSION,  AGRICULTURAL— DEPRESSION  OF  TRADE 


565 


duce  of  rich  unexhausted  soils.  It  is  probable 
tliat  for  many  years  to  come  this  competition 
in  com  and  provisions  will  rather  increase  than 
decrease. 

The  results  of  this  collapse  of  agriculture 
have  been  disastrous  to  the  landed  interests. 
The  increase  in  the  value  of  land  for  the  last 
half  century  has  been  lost.  The  annual  income 
of  landlords,  tenants,  and  labourers  was  less  in 
1886  (see  Sir  James  Caird's  evidence  before  the 
commission  on  the  depression  of  trade)  than  in 
1876  by  £42,800,000  ;  of  this  sum  it  has  been 
calculated  that  landlords  and  tenants  lost 
£20,000,000  each,  and  labourers  £2,800,000. 
Landlords  have  reduced  their  rentals  to  the 
point  at  which  they  stood  in  1836  ;  farmers 
have  lost  30  to  50  per  cent  of  their  capital  (Sir 
James  Caird's  Victorian  Agriculture);  the  money 
wages  of  labourers  have  fallen  and  many  have 
been  dismissed  from  employment.  The  land 
has  been  injured  by  bad  seasons  and  weak 
farming  ;  the  live  stock  of  the  country  has  been 
diminished ;  quantities  of  crops  have  been  ruined 
or  deteriorated  by  the  weather. 

The  loss  to  the  agricultural  classes  is  enor- 
mous. It  is  more  difficult  to  estimate  the  ab- 
solute loss  to  the  nation,  or  the  general  effect 
of  agricultural  depression  upon  commercial  pros- 
perity. The  nation  suffers  by  the  diminution 
in  the  purchasing  power  of  a  class,  by  the  de- 
struction of  capital  through  bad  harvests,  by 
the  restriction  in  the  demand  for  labour,  and 
by  the  removal  of  capital  from  one  industry  to 
another,  especially  if  it  be  a  removal  from  within 
to  without  its  boundaries.  It  does  not  at  once 
suffer  as  a  nation  from  the  low  prices  of  agri- 
cultural produce.  Thus  in  1851  the  supply  of 
meat  per  head  was  91  lbs.,  and  317  lbs.  of  wheat 
were  supplied  to  a  population  of  27  millions  at 
a  cost  of  £53,500,000.  In  1885  115  lbs.  of 
meat  were  supplied  per  head  at  a  greatly  reduced 
cost,  and  400  lbs.  of  wheat  to  36  millions  of 
people  at  a  cost  of  £43,700,000.  Hare  then, 
so  long  as  the  money  in  payment  for  this  food 
is  earned  in  other  industries,  the  nation  profits 
by  the  low  prices  which  ruin  agriculturists. 
l>ut  there  is  a  point  at  which  the  wider  interests 
of  the  nation  suli'er  from  cheapness  of  food,  if 
the  price  becomes  so  unremunerative  as  to  drive 
land  out  of  cultivation.  As  to  the  general  effect 
upon  commercial  prosperity,  the  depression  of 
agriculture  destroys  a  considerable  portion  of  the 
capital  engaged  in  land,  and  locks  up  another 
in  unrealisable  investments  ;  tends  to  congest 
the  labour  market  by  disturbance  of  the  relations 
of  supply  and  demand  for  agricultural  labour  ; 
drives  capital  from  land  into  other  investments, 
and,  by  restricting  the  field,  adds  to  the  over- 
production of  manufactured  articles. 

[The  following  books  and  pamphlets  treat  of  the 
practical  side  of  the  subject :  Sir  J.  Caird,  The 
Landed  Interest  and  the  Supply  of  Food;  and 
"  Victorian  Agriculture  "  (in  the  Reign  of  Queen 


Victoria,  voL  ii.). — R.  E.  Prothero,  The  Pioneers 
and  Progress  of  English  Agriculture.  Agricul- 
tural Depression  (Shrewsbury,  1879). — F.  Blood, 
ETiquiry  into  the  Causes  of  the  Depression  of  Trade 
and  Agriculture. — H.  Chaytor,  Agricultv/ral  De- 
pression.— J.  L.  Cowland,  Agricultural  Depression 
in  Devon  and  Cornwall. — E.  G.  Man,  Comnerce 
and  Prospects  of  England. — A.  J.  Burrows,  Agri- 
cultural Depression  and  how  to  meet  it.  — S.  Mason, 
Agricultural  Depression. — A.  A.  Walton,  Agricul- 
tural Depression. — Sir  J.  B.  Lawes,  Fertility. — 
R.  G.  Webster,  England's  Colonial  Granaries. — 
C.  Whitehead,  Fruit- Oroudng  in  Kent. — Sir  R.  H.L 
Palgrave,  "  Estimates  of  Agricultural  Losses  in  the 
United  Kingdom  during  the  last  thirty  years" 
{Journ.  of  Royal  Statistical  Soc,  vol.  Ixviii.  1905). 
See  also  Agriculture  m  England.  On  the 
politico-economical  side  of  the  subject,  A  Mon- 
gredieu,  History  of  the  Free  Trade  Movement. — 
F.  J.  B.  Hooper,  Free  Trade  and  English  Commerce 
hy  Mr.  Mongredien  ans^oered. — F.  Bastiat,  Popular 
Fallacies  regarding  Trade  and  Foreign  Duties. — 
R.  Gill,  History  of  Free  Trade.— V^.  F.  Ecroyd,  M.P., 
A  Speech  in  Reply  to  the  Attack  upon  Fair  Trade  by 
Mr.  Gladsto7ie.— Sir  E.  R.  Sullivan,  Bart.,  Free 
Trade  Bubbles. — Sir  T.  H.  Farrer,  Bart,,  Free 
Trade  and  Fair  Trade  (3rd  ed.  1886).]     r.  e.  p. 

DEPRESSION  OF  TRADE.  The  royal 
commission  appointed  in  Great  Britain  in  the 
year  1885,  to  inquire  into  this  subject,  thus 
defined  depression  of  trade,  in  the  report 
adopted  by  the  majority  of  its  members : — '*A 
diminution,  and  in  some  cases  an  absence,  of 
profit,  with  a  corresponding  diminution  of 
employment  for  the  labouring  classes."  The 
particular  instance  of  this  depression  into  which 
the  commission  made  inquiry  was  that  dating 
from  the  year  1875,  which  was  so  conspicuously 
marked  in  agriculture ;  but  the  statement 
quoted  from  the  report  may  be  taken  as  a 
description  of  what  is  commonly  meant  and 
understood  by  depression  of  trade.  The 
phrase,  however,  is  used  very  freely  and  very 
loosely  ;  and  it  is  therefore  best  to  anticipate 
more  particular  discussion  of  the  subject  by  a 
few  considerations  which  ought  to  be  kept  in 
mind,  and  which  the  above  definition  helps  to 
explain.  (1)  All  classes  are  not  affected  by 
depression  of  trade.  It  is  to  be  observed  that, 
in  the  first  instance  at  least,  profit,  and 
profit  alone,  is  by  hypothesis  curtailed.  If 
wages  suffer,  they  suffer  through  the  lack  of 
employment  which  results  from  the  withdrawal 
of  capital  found  to  be  invested  unprofitably. 
But  it  is  possible  that  profit  might  fall  simply 
through  the  exertions  of  the  labourers  to  obtain 
a  larger  share  of  the  product  as  wages  ;  and 
where  the  labourers  are  united  enough  to 
accomplish  this,  it  follows  of  necessity  that  if 
by  Trade  Unions  they  have  to  maintain  the 
"out  of  works,"  they  must  be  able  to  check 
competition  among  themselves.  It  might  be, 
therefore,  that  although  fewer  labourers  were 
employed  in  a  case  of  depression,  those  in  em- 
ployment might  not  sufler  but  gain.     Again, 


566 


DEPEESSION  OF  TRADE 


all  persons  who  are  in  receipt  of  fixed  salaries 
or  incomes  do  not  suffer  from  depression  of 
trade  ;  but,  inasmuch  as  one  significant  phase 
of  depression  is  a  general  reduction  in  prices, 
they  are  gainers  and  not  losers.  (2)  Although 
the  interdependence  of  industries  is  such  that 
a  diminution  of  profit  in  all  may  be  expected 
to  be  simultaneous,  or  nearly  so,  yet  it  must  be 
remembered  that  one  industry,  or  class  of  in- 
dustries, may  be  for  a  time  subject  to  severe 
depression  while  others  are  flourishing.  The 
retail  and  carrying  trades  are  in  a  different 
position  with  regard  to  the  earning  of  profits 
from  the  producing  trades  ;  for  their  percent- 
age of  profit  depends,  not  on  the  ratio  between 
cost  of  production  and  price,  but  on  the 
quantity  of  custom  and  the  number  of  trans- 
actions they  engage  in.  (3)  Depression  may 
affect  certain  traders  in  one  industry,  and 
may  not  affect  others.  During  the  series  of 
bad  years,  which,  like  Pharaoh's  lean  kine, 
followed  and  devoured  the  years  of  prosperity 
in  which  our  trade  went  up  by  leaps  and 
bounds,  there  were  plenty  of  people,  even  in 
England,  who  were  amassing  fortunes  in  busi- 
ness all  the  time.  Those  who  are  unsuccessful 
are  apt  to  lament  the  falling- off"  of  business  as 
the  cause  of  their  misfortunes  ;  while  the  more 
lucky  make  no  noise  about  their  prosperity. 
It  would  be  easy,  in  any  trade  or  profession, 
to  collect  a  multitude  of  evidence  from  people 
who  could  truly  say  their  business  was  de- 
pressed, in  the  sense  applied  to  the  word  by  the 
commission.  (4)  We  must  be  careful  to  dis- 
criminate between  a  genuine  depression  and 
that  gi-adual  process  of  thinning  down  profit 
which  arises  from  the  natural  tendencies  of  our 
civilisation,  and  which  is  not  temporary,  but 
permanent.  The  slow  but  certain  fall  in  the 
rate  of  interest,  the  larger  share  demanded  and 
gained  by  labour,  the  increased  competition, 
through  the  spread  of  education,  for  the  earn- 
ings of  business  management,  and  the  conse- 
quent reduction  of  these  earnings,  all  combine 
to  efl'ect  a  chronic  decline  in  profit. 

The  existence  of  a  genuine  depression  at 
times,  apart  from  all  the  above  considerations, 
is  imdoubted.  In  Great  Britain  there  have 
been  numerous  instances  of  such  depression 
during  this  century,  the  last  of  which  began 
about  the  year  1875,  and  was  the  subject  of 
the  investigations  of  the  royal  commission  of 
1885  mentioned  above.  But  the  earlier  phases 
of  depression  of  trade  off"er  in  one  respect  a 
distinct  contrast  to  the  most  recent — a  contrast 
which  seems  to  be  symbolic  of  the  modern 
conditions  of  commerce.  While  in  former 
times  trade  was  depressed  after  a  period  of 
great  inflation  followed  by  a  crisis,  the  depres- 
sion of  late  years  was  preceded  by  no  crisis  ; 
and  while  former  stages  of  depression  passed 
away  with  some  rapidity  and  gave  place  in  turn 
to  a  period  of  inflation,  the  revival  of  trade 


which  ultimately  occurred  after  1885  took  a 
long  time  to  become  apparent,  and  was  very 
gradual.  This  fact  would  seem  to  bear  out  the 
contention  that  trade  is  on  a  sounder  footing 
than  it  used  to  be,  however  hardly  depression 
may  bear  on  traders  ;  and  also  that  the  ten- 
yearly  cycle  through  which  British  commerce 
has  been  wont  to  pass  has  given  way  to  a  more 
equable  form  of  progress.  (For  an  account  of 
the  earlier  cycles  in  the  present  century,  see 
art.  Ceises.  Also  Leoni  Levi,  History  of 
British  Commerce. — Tooke's  History  of  Prices.) 

The  evidence  taken  by  the  royal  commission 
was  voluminous,  and  was  derived  from  repre- 
sentatives of  all  classes  of  the  community  ;  and 
from  it  we  can  gather  the  leading  features  of 
the  depression,  as  it  aff'ected  the  more  import- 
ant industries,  (For  the  effects  on  agriculture, 
see  Depression,  Agricultural.)  As  to  trade 
in  general,  there  was  a  concurrence  of  opinion 
that  profits  had  been  lowered,  while  wages  as  a 
rule  had  remained  firm  ;  but  this  latter  pro- 
position must  be  qualified  by  the  fact  that  to 
a  certain  extent  the  employment  of  labour, 
particularly  in  some  industries,  had  been  less 
regular,  and  the  real  wages  of  labour  therefore 
below  the  nominal  rate.  The  rate  of  interest 
had  also  fallen.  It  was  found  that  competi- 
tion fi'om  abroad,  both  in  our  own  and  in 
foreign  markets,  had  of  recent  years  become 
keener.  It  was  also  shown  in  the  evidence 
that  the  volume  of  foreign  trade  had  increased 
largely  even  during  the  depression,  but  that  in 
the  matter  of  values  the  increase  was  small  in 
comparison  with  that  of  earlier  periods.  It 
was  shown  that  the  income-tax  assessments 
under  schedule  D  (trades  and  professions)  had 
increased  very  considerably  since  the  beginning 
of  the  depression  ;  but  that  the  actual  number 
of  persons  with  large  incomes  had  decreased  by 
about  5  per  cent,  and  of  those  with  moderately 
large  incomes  in  much  the  same  proportion, 
while  incomes  between  £200  and  £1000  a  year 
had  increased  33  per  cent.  It  was  given  in 
evidence  by  a  number  of  witnesses  that  there 
was  a  great  and  apparently  a  permanent  tend- 
ency in  the  supply  of  commodities  to  outrun 
the  demand,  and  that  this  had  given  rise  to  a 
very  general  feeling  that  over-production,  as  it 
is  called,  was  the  chief  cause  of  the  depression. 
And  with  regard  to  labour,  it  was  discovered 
that  while  the  agricultural  labouring  popula- 
tion had  largely  diminished  in  numbers,  by 
reason  of  their  employers'  losses  and  the  throw- 
ing of  land  out  of  cultivation,  neither  the 
shipping  nor  the  textile  industries  showed  any 
sign  that  the  surplus  labour-population  had 
found  a  place  in  these  large  fields  of  employ- 
ment. 

From  these  data,  supplemented  by  many 
minor  and  incidental  points  disclosed  in  the 
course  of  the  evidence,  it  is  possible  to  arrive 
at  the  most  diverse  conclusions  as  to  the  causes 


DEPRESSION  OF  TRADE 


567 


of  the  depression,  and,  it  follows,  as  to  the 
remedies  which  ought  to  be  applied,  if  any. 
"What  may  be  called  the  most  pessimistic  side 
of  the  discussion,  which  was  supported  by 
numerous  witnesses,  was  embodied  in  a  separate 
report  signed  by  a  minority  of  the  commissioners. 
It  is  curious  that  in  one  important  matter  the 
view  taken  by  this  minority  coincides  with  the 
most  extreme  optimistic  opinion  ;  for  according 
to  both,  the  so-called  depression  is  not  a  passing 
phase  of  commerce,  but  a  permanent  change  in 
the  economy  of  the  state.  Those  who  hold 
the  pessimistic  view  were  able  to  point  to  the 
fact  that  an  immense  quantity  of  evidence  had 
been  given  before  the  commission  which  pointed 
to  a  diminished  employment  of  productive 
machinery,  especially  in  the  textile  industries  ; 
also  to  the  increase  in  the  value  of  imports  of 
textile  manufactures  and  the  decrease  in  the 
value  of  exports  of  the  same  article.  The  loss 
— partial  or  total — of  certain  foreign  markets 
for  British  goods  is  another  point  which  was 
urged  with  much  force  ;  the  inference  being 
that  foreign  governments,  having  found  that 
high  tariffs  were  successful  in  shutting  English 
goods  out  of  these  markets,  would  increase 
rather  than  diminish  them  : — a  view  which  the 
so-called  McKinley  Act,  passed  in  the  United 
States  since  the  commission  finally  reported, 
would  undoubtedly  have  been  used  to  strengthen, 
had  it  existed  at  the  time.  It  was  pointed  out 
by  those  who  held  the  opinion  referred  to  that 
increase  even  in  the  value  of  trade  in  certain 
commodities  is  no  proof  of  the  flourishing  con- 
dition of  such  industries.  It  was  shown,  for 
example,  that  in  the  ten  years  preceding  1883 
the  value  of  the  yearly  export  of  coal  and  iron 
had  increased  by  more  than  £17, 000, 000  ;  while 
it  was  notorious  that  the  coal  and  iron  trades 
had  been  suff'ering  greatly  during  that  period. 
The  remedies  proposed  are  generally  in  the 
direction  of  import  duties  of  one  kind  or 
another.  Tariff  duties  on  manufactures  coming 
from  abroad  are  the  most  extreme  form  of  this 
proposal ;  but  countervailing  duties  in  order  to 
balance  the  effect  of  bounties  when  they  are 
given,  and  a  fiscal  union  with  India  and  the 
colonies,  on  the  basis  of  a  protective  tariff  levied 
against  goods  coming  from  other  countries,  are 
more  frequently  recommended.  The  extreme 
view  on  the  other  side  was  not  represented  on 
the  commission  ;  but  this  may  possibly  have 
resulted  from  the  fact  that  a  number  of  the 
originally-appointed  commissioners  did  not  see 
their  way  to  accept  nomination.  That  view  is 
well  expressed  in  a  work  entitled  La  Crise,  by 
M.  Pirmez.  According  to  this  opinion  the 
depression  of  trade  is  merely  a  temporary 
accentuation  of  an  economic  movement  which 
has  been  slowly  going  on  for  years,  and  which 
is  destined  to  go  on  until  the  relations  between 
capital  and  labour  are  completely  changed. 
The  fall  in  profits  is  admitted,  and  also  the  fall 


in  interest ;  but  it  is  pointed  out  that  these 
events  happen  not  in  one  country  alone,  but  in 
all  countries  ;  and  that  therefore  the  fear  of 
the  desertion  of  any  country  by  capital  and 
consequent  diminution  of  wealth  and  employ- 
ment is  merely  illusory.  The  wages  of  labour, 
it  is  maintained,  do  not  fall,  but  rise  ;  and  it 
is  asserted  that  the  whole  tendency  of  the 
process  of  which  the  depression  is  a  phase  is  to 
reduce  the  interest  on  capital  merely  lent  or 
invested,  to  reduce  the  profits  of  capital  employed 
in  business,  and  to  reduce  the  wages  or  earn- 
ings of  business  management.  This  means  the 
wider  and  more  equal  distribution  of  wealth, 
and  is  therefore  regarded  as  a  matter  not  of 
apprehension,  but  of  congratulation.  It  may 
be  observed  that  one  of  the  proofs  largely  relied 
on  by  those  of  this  opinion, — founded  on  an 
analysis  of  the  income-tax  returns, — is  by  no 
means  conclusive.  These  returns  show  a 
gradual  decline  in  the  number  of  people  with 
large  revenues,  and  an  increase  in  the  number 
whose  incomes  are  moderate.  This  does  not 
in  any  way  prove  that  wealth  is  more  widely 
distributed,  unless  that  conclusion  is  borne  out 
by  independent  evidence.  If  at  one  time 
twenty  men  in  one  trade  make  £5000  a  year, 
and  four  hundred  under  £5000,  and  if  in  ten 
years'  time  the  figures  are  one  above  £5000  and 
419  below  it,  it  is  impossible  to  say,  without 
more  proof,  whether  that  result  is  due  to  a 
more  even  distribution  of  profit,  or  an  accumula- 
tion of  business  and  capital  in  a  single  hand,  to 
the  detriment  of  other  traders. 

Intermediate  between  these  two  extremes  a 
great  variety  of  views  prevail.  The  most 
general  is  that  the  depression  of  1874-85  was  a 
genuine  misfortune,  shared  no  doubt  by  Eng- 
land with  many  other  countries,  but  bearing 
with  particular  harshness  on  England,  because 
of  the  great  strides  made  by  foreign  competi- 
tion in  many  branches  of  industry  which  were 
contemporaneous  with  it.  Those  who  held 
this  opinion  did  not  regard  the  depression  as 
permanent ;  and  the  events  of  the  years  which 
have  followed  the  publication  of  the  commis- 
sion's report  go  far  to  bear  out  their  views. 
The  great  demand  for  goods  consequent  on  the 
Franco-German  war  is  not  unnaturally  held  to 
be  the  original  cause  of  what  is  called  over- 
production, but  is  truly  production  of  the 
wrong  things.  So  greatly  do  modern  modes  of 
manufacture  stereotype  industry,  and  so  curi- 
ously do  the  laws  relating  to  joint -stock 
companies  tempt  to  enterprise  which  offers  a 
great  temporary  advantage  but  no  permanent 
benefit,  that  we  constantly  see  capital  invested 
so  that  it  cannot  be  withdrawn  without  ruin  in 
some  industry  where  it  is  equally  unable  to 
produce  a  fair  return.  The  demonetisation  of 
silver  by  Germany  at  the  time  of  the  suspension 
of  the  Latin  league  also  contributed,  by  disturb- 
ance in  prices  to  the  difficulties  of  traders.   Those 


668 


DEPUTY— DE  QUINCEY 


who  hold  the  moderate  view  do  not  believe 
that  what  is  injurious  to  capital  is  necessarily 
of  advantage  to  the  labourers,  and  they  believe 
that  some  kinds  of  labour  suffered  severely 
during  the  recent  depression.  They  do  not 
believe  that  violent  remedies,  such  as  large 
import  duties,  would  be  serviceable,  but  rather 
look  for  such  measures  as  amendment  of  the 
Limited  Liability  Companies'  Acts  for  safety 
in  the  future,  coupled  with  improved  technical 
education  and  the  spread  of  knowledge  of  the 
world's  markets.  In  regard  to  the  matter  of 
countervailing  duties  a  considerable  difference 
of  opinion  prevails,  many  who  are  adverse  to 
any  form  of  protection  being  favourable  to  such 
an  impost  where  an  important  industry  is 
threatened  with  grievous  loss  or  extinction. 

[The  report  of  the  above-named  commission  con- 
tains an  immense  amount  of  information,  both  from 
English  and  foreign  sources,  bearing  on  this  subject, 
and  is  by  far  the  best  compendium  from  which  the 
question  may  be  studied.  Sir  R.  Giffen's  Growth 
of  Capital,  published  since  the  report,  forms  an 
excellent  statistical  commentary,  ]  M.  G.  D. 

DEPUTY.  In  law,  one  who  exercises  an 
office  or  other  function  in  another's  right,  whose 
forfeiture  or  misdemeanour  shall  cause  him 
whose  deputy  he  is  to  lose  his  office.  A  man 
cannot  appoint  his  deputy  in  all  cases,  but  only 
when  his  own  grant  of  the  office  justifies  him 
in  so  doing  (Cowel  ed.  1727).  In  another 
sense  the  term  is  used  of  offices  of  state,  and 
most  anciently  of  the  exchequer  and  mint. 
Thus  in  the  absence  of  the  king's  treasurer 
on  foreign  service  a  deputy  was  appointed  by 
commission,  and  in  later  times  this  practice 
was  extended  to  many  other  fiscal  offices.  In 
certain  cases,  such  as  the  hereditary  offices 
of  the  king's  court  and  exchequer,  the  holder 
in  fee  could  appoint  a  deputy  (Dialogtjs  de 
SoACCARio,  i.  3  ;  Madox,  Hist,  of  the  Exchequer, 
ch.  xxiiij.)  H.  Ha. 

DE  QUINCEY,  Thomas,  the  son  of  a 
prosperous  merchant,  was  born  1785,  and,  after 
a  brilliant  literary  career,  died  1859.  That  a 
genius  of  so  high  an  order  of  imagination  found 
the  abstract  reasoning  of  political  economy  "Not 
harsh  and  crabbed  as  dull  fools  suppose"  is 
instructive.  The  fascination  which  the  severer 
aspect  of  the  science  had  for  De  Quincey  is 
expressed  in  that  passage  of  the  Confessions  of 
an  Opium  Eater  where  the  writer  describes  how 
he  was  aroused  from  lethargy  by  the  study  of 
Ricardo's  Political  Economy  (1818).  The  fruit 
of  that  study  appeared  in  the  DialogiLes  of 
three  Templars  (1824),  a  brilliant  exposition 
and  defence  of  the  Ricardian  theory  of  value. 
The  paradox,  for  so  De  Quincey  admits  it  to  be 
in  a  good  sense,  that  real  value  is  measured  by 
quantity  of  labour,  that  "a  million  men  may 
produce  double  or  treble  the  amount  of  riches, 
of  'necessaries,  conveniences,  and  amusements, ' 
in  one   state  of  society   that   they  could   in 


another,  but  will  not  on  that  account  add  any. 
thing  to  value"  (Ricardo,  Political  Economy; 
chapter  on  "Value  and  Riches"),  is  expounded 
b}-  the  disciple  even  more  fearlessly  than  by 
the  master.      "  My  thesis,"  says  X,  the  Socrates 
of  the  dialogues,  who  represents  the  author's 
views,    "  is  that  no  such  connection  subsists 
between  the  two  [the  quantity  obtained  and 
the  value  obtaining]  as  warrants  any  inference 
that  the  real  value  is  great  because  the  quantity 
it  buys  is  great,  or  small  because  the  quantity 
it  buys  is  small."     **  I  have  a  barouche,"  says 
the    objector,    "which    is   worth    about    600 
guineas  at  this  moment.      Now,  if  I  should 
keep  this  barouche  unused  in  my  coach-house 
for  five  years,  and  at  the  end  of  this  term  it 
should  happen  from  any  cause  that  carriages 
had  doubled  in  value,  my  understanding  would 
lead  me  to  expect  double  the  quantity  of  any 
commodity  for  which  I  might  then  exchange  it, 
whether  that  were  money,  sugar,  besoms,  or 
anything  whatsoever.     But  you  tell  me  no." 
.  .  .   "You  are  in  the  right,"  replies  X,  "I  do 
tell  you  so  ....   If  A  double  its  value,  it 
will  not  therefore  command  double  the  former 
quantity  of  B  "  [B  representing  any  assignable 
thing]    (Fourth    Dialogue).      The    intelligent 
Bailey  (q.v.)  might  well  be  stirred  by  these 
startling  deductions  to  attempt  a  reply  (preface 
to  Critical  Dissertation).     In  the  later  dialogues 
Ricardo's  theory  of  value  is  defended  against 
Malthus.      This   controversy   had    been   com- 
menced in  the  "Measure  of  Value,"  published 
in  the  London  Magazine  for  December  1823. 
An  article  on  "  Malthus"  in  an  earlier  number  of 
the  same  journal  contains  a  mild  attack  on  the 
theory  of  population.     Some  of  the  points  are 
elucidated  in  a  letter  to  Hazlitt  which  appeared 
in  the  London  Magazine,  December  1823.     To 
the  same   period   belongs   a   sort   of  eloge  of 
Ricardo,  which  De  Quincey,  shortly  after  the 
death  of  his  revered  master,  contributed  to  the 
London  Magazine,  March  1824. 

De  Quincey's  latest  and  greatest  economical 
work  is  the  Logic  of  Political  Economy  (1844). 
The  more  original  portion  of  this  book  may  be 
described  as  a  vindication  of  the  part  played 
by  utility  in  the  determination  of  value.  The 
cause  is  just  and  the  reasoning  ingenious  ;  yet 
the  censure  with  which  J.  S.  Mill  tempers  his 
copious  citation  from  this  discourse  seems  de- 
served (PoZ.  Econ.,  hk.  in.  ch.  ii.  §  1,  and  §  3  end). 
Certainly  De  Quincey's  illustrations  are  perfect. 
The  rhinoceros  which  in  the  reign  of  Charles  II. 
was  sold  for  a  figure  far  above  the  cost  of 
importation,  the  Valdarfer  copy  of  Boccaccio 
which  Lord  Blandford  bought  for  £2240  and 
afterwards,  when  in  pecuniary  embarrassments, 
was  sold  by  auction  and  purchased  for  £750 
by  Lord  Spencer,  whom  he  outbid  at  the  first 
sale  ;  Popish  reliques  which  had  a  high 
value,  but  no  cost  of  production  (p.  60  et 
seq.,  ed.    1844); — these  and   other    "shining 


DE  QunsrcEY 


569 


instauces  "  throw  light  upon  an  obscure  subject. 
The  "dry  light"  of  logic  is  intensified  by  a 
coruscation  of  wit.  Sometimes,  however,  the 
doubt  occurs  whether  the  writer  was  as  com- 
petent to  point  a  moral  as  to  adorn  a  tale. 
Thus,  in  the  case  of  the  pearl-market,  and  the 
vividly-pictured  slave-market  (tftio?.  p.  77  etseq.) 
is  it  correctly  stated  that  for  * '  the  plebs  amongst 
the  slaves,"  and  the  "ordinary  pearls,"  value 
is  determined  by  cost  of  production,  while  "  the 
natural  aristocracy  amongst  the  slaves,  like  the 
rarer  pearls,  will  be  valued  on  other  principles  "  ? 
(see  Difficulty  of  Attainment).  Even  the 
famous  parable  of  the  musical  snuff-box  (cited 
by  Mill,  Fol.  Bern.,  bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.  §  1)  is  not 
rightly  interpreted  hj  its  author.  It  is  not  in 
general  true  of  a  bargain  between  two  isolated 
individuals  (see  Competition)  that  the  price 
will  be  "racked  up  to  U"  (ibid.  pp.  25-27)— 
the  measure  of  the  "intrinsic  worth  of  the 
article  in  your  individual  estimate  for  your 
individual  purposes  "  ;  in  other  words  its  Total 
Utility  (q.v.)  to  the  purchaser  (cp.  Mill,  loc. 
dt.  §  1  end).  The  following  passage  seems 
more  correct.  "  The  purpose  which  any  article 
answers  and  the  cost  which  it  imposes  must 
eternally  form  the  two  limits  within  which 
the  tennis-ball  of  price  flies  backwards  and 
forwards.  Five  guineas  being,  upon  the  particu- 
lar article  X,  the  maximwn  of  teleologic  price, 
the  utmost  sacrifice  to  which  you  would  ever 
submit,  under  the  fullest  appreciation  of  the 
natural  purposes  which  X  can  fulfil,  and  then 
only  under  the  known  alternative  of  losing  it 
if  you  refuse  the  five  guineas,  this  constitutes 
the  one  pole,  the  aphelion,  or  remotest  point  to 
which  the  price  for  you  could  ever  ascend." 
The  other  limit  is  fixed  by  the  cost  of  reproduc- 
tion. These  are  "the  two  limits  between 
which  the  price  must  always  he  held  potenti- 
ally to  oscillate"  {ih.  pp.  105,  106).  But 
even  here  it  is  not  clearly  stated  that,  in  the 
absence  of  competition,  the  terms  are  inde- 
terminate ;  the  "tennis-ball"  may  fall  anywhere 
between  the  extreme  limits.  It  is  nowhere 
stated  that  in  the  presence  of  competition 
the  upper  limit  is  formed,  not  by  total,  but 
Final  Degree  of  Utility.  De  Quincey  is  far 
removed  from  the  recent  theorists  to  whom  he 
bears  a  superficial  resemblance  by  his  not  having 
attended  to  final  utility  and  cognate  concep- 
tions. The  connection  between  demand  and 
value  is  denied  by  him  on  the  strength  of 
exceptional  though  striking  instances  {ibid.  p. 
231,  quoted  by  Mill,  bk.  iii.  ch.  iii.  §  2).  "A 
crazy  maxim,"  he  says,  "has  got  possession  of 
the  whole  world  :  viz.  that  price  is,  or  can  be, 
determined  by  the  relation  between  supply 
and  demand."  This  imperfect  conception  of 
supply  and  demand  is  the  special  object  of 
Mill's  severe  remarks  on  De  Quincey.  Mill's 
censure  is  endorsed  by  Mr.  Leslie  Stephen  in  his 
article  on  De  Quincey  in  the  Fortnightly  Review 


(1871).  Mr.  Shadworth  Hodgson  in  one  of  his 
Outcast  Essays  has  traversed  this  unfavourable 
verdict. 

Whatever  be  the  fate  of  De  Quincey 's  cardinal 
tenets,  it  is  certain  that  his  occasional  sugges- 
tions, the  minor  pearls  of  his  discourse,  enhanced 
as  they  are  by  a  setting  of  consummate  literary 
perfection,  will  preserve  a  lasting  worth.  Some 
important  corrections  of  Ricardo's  expressions 
deserve  particular  notice.  De  Quincey  perceived, 
just  as  clearly  as  more  recent  critics,  that  "  the 
current  rate  of  profits,  as  a  tiling  settled  and 
defined,  must  be  a  chimera."  He  exposes  "  the 
puerility  of  that  little  receipt  current  among 
economists,  viz.  unlimited  competition  for  keep- 
ing down  profits  to  one  uniform  level.  .  .  . 
Everybody  must  see  that  it  is  a  very  elaborate 
problem  to  ascertain  even  for  one  year,  still 
more  for  a  fair  average  of  years,  what  has  been 
the  rate  of  profits  upon  the  capital  employed 
in  any  one  trade"  {ibid.  p.  237  et  seq.)  What 
more  could  Cliff"e  Leslie  say  ?  De  Quincey 
complains  much  that  Ricardo,  while  insisting 
on  the  tendency  towards  the  degradation  of  soils 
(the  Law  of  Diminishing  Returns,  q.v.),  has 
not  sufficiently  emphasised  the  counter-tendency 
towards  improvement  in  the  arts  of  cultivation. 
"The  land  is  travelling  downwards,  but  always 
the  productive  management  of  land  is  travelling 
upwards"  (ibid.  p.  239).  De  Quincey  discerns 
what  a  handle  is  afforded  by  Ricardo's  partial 
statement  to  "  the  systematic  enemies  of 
property"  .  .  .  "the  policy  of  gloomy  dis- 
organising Jacobinism."  Rent  is  referred  by  De 
Quincey  not  to  the  "indestructible,"  but  the 
differential  powers  of  the  soil.  Rent  is  defined 
as  ''that  portion  of  the  -pi'oduce  froni  the  soil  (or 
from  any  agency  of  production)  which  is  paid 
to  the  landlord  for  the  iise  of  its  differential 
powers  as  nuasured  by  comparison  with  those  of 
similar  agencies  operating  on  the  same  market." 
The  parenthesis  exemplifies  the  pregnancy  of 
De  Quincey's  occasional  suggestions.  In  pre- 
senting the  theory  of  rent,  De  Quincey  employs 
an  admirable  geometrical  construction.  As  in 
the  construction  which  Prof.  A.  Marshall  has 
mside  famHisiT  (Economics  of  Indtcstry,  bk.  ii.  ch. 
iii.),  the  ordinate  in  De  Quincey's  diagram 
represents  produce.  But  the  abscissa  represents 
not  doses  of  capital  but  qualities  of  soil.  The 
two  constructions  have  been  combined  by  the 
present  writer  in  an  illustration  of  the  abstract 
theory  of  reni,  contributed  to  the  British 
Association  (Report,  1886).  Referring  to  the 
Tise  of  diagrams,  De  Quincey  well  says : — 
"A  construction  (i.e.  a  geometrical  exhibition) 
of  any  elaborate  truth  is  not  often  practicable  ; 
but,  wherever  it  is  so,  prudence  will  not  allow 
it  to  be  neglected.  What  is  called  evidentia, 
that  sort  of  demonstration  which  shows  out  .  .  . 
is  by  a  natural  necessity  more  convincing  to  the 
learner.  And,  had  Ricardo  relied  on  this  con- 
stmctive  mode  of  illustrating  his  chapters  upon 


i70 


DERELICT— DESCENT  OF  PROPJERTY 


rent  and  upon  wages,  they  would  not  hare  tried 
the  patience  of  his  students  in  the  way  they 
have  done."  Had  De  Quincey  pursued  his 
mathematical  studies  further,  and  applied  the 
conceptions  of  the  infinitesimal  calcuius  to  .the 
theory  of  value,  he  would  have  escaped  his 
capital  error  of  having  confused  integral  (or 
Total,  q.v.),  with  differential  (or  final)  utility. 
If  he  had  worked  with  c?U,  instead  of  U,  he 
might  have  anticipated  Jevons. 

All  the  works  which  have  been  referred  to  will 
presumably  be  included  in  The  Collected  Writings 
of  De  Quincey,  by  Professor  Masson,  1890.  In 
the  American  edition  of  1877,  called  the  Riverside 
edition,  all  are  to  be  found  except  the  letter  in 
reply  to  Hazlitt  [London  Magazine,  December 
1823),  and  the  iloge  of  Ricardo  (ibid.  March  1824). 
These  are  reprinted  in  De  Quincey's  Uncollected 
Writings  by  J.  Hogg,  1890.  The  Edinburgh  edi- 
tion of  De  Quincey's  works  in  sixteen  vols.,  com- 
pleted 1871,  omits  also  the  Logic  of  Political 
Economy.  Earlier  collections  are  still  more  in- 
complete. V.  Y.  B. 

DERELICT.  The  legal  quality  of  derelict 
was  recognised  by  the  Roman  Law  (Dig.  i.  xlvij. 
Tit.  ij.  De  Furtis).  Anything  wilfully  cast 
away  either  on  sea  or  land.  Goods  thrown  out 
of  a  ship,  to  lighten  the  same  in  case  of  distress, 
are  not  derelict  for  want  of  intention  (Just. 
Inst.  II.  1.  48).  Ifa  ship  made  jettison  without 
hope  of  recovering  the  goods  they  were  derelict 
to  the  finder  (Rolle  of  Olayron,  32,  34).  Derelict 
lands  suddenly  left  by  the  sea  belong  to  the 
crown,  except  in  case  of  an  arm  of  the  sea 
belonging  to  a  subject,  but  if  the  sea  recede 
slowly,  by  imperceptible  degrees,  the  land  thus 
gained  goes  to  the  owner  of  the  adjacent  soil. 
This  was  ascertained  by  commission,  and  is  a 
subject  for  a  jury.  Boats  or  other  vessels 
forsaken  or  found  on  the  seas  without  any  person 
in  them  are  called  derelict.  Of  these  the 
admiralty  has  the  custody  and  the  owner  can 
recover  within  a  year  and  a  day. 

[Moore  on  Foreshore. — Black  Book  of  Admiralty 
{Rolls).— Fleta,  III.  2. — Hale,  Dejure  Maris.] 

H.  Ha. 

DERELICTIO.  Expression  of  Roman  law 
for  the  abandonment  of  any  object  of  property 
with  the  intention  of  renouncing  all  rights  of 
ownership  over  it.  e.  s. 

DE  SANCTIS,  Marco  Antonio,  lived  in  the 
16th  century  and  the  beginning  of  the  17th. 
Toppi  (Biblioteca  napoletanu,  Napoli,  1678, 
p.  204)  says  he  was  born  at  Nocera  dei  Pagani, 
but  gives  no  other  biographical  indications. 
Two  dissertations  of  De  Sanctis  are  extant ; 
their  scientific  value  is  less  than  their  historical 
importance,  because  Antonio  Serra  would 
probably  never  have  written  his  famous  Breve 
trattato  delle  cause  che  possono  fare  abbondare  i 
regni  d'oro  e  d'argento  (1613),  if  it  had  not  been 
for  the  writings  of  De  Sanctis,  which  he  under- 
took to  refute.  The  two  pamphlets  of  De 
Sanctis  bear  the  titles :  Discorso  di  Marc' Antonio 


De  Sanctis  intorno  alii  effetti  che  fa  il  cambio  in 
Regno,  in  Napoli,  appresso  Costantino  Vitale. 
1605  ;  and  Secondo  discorso  di  Marc' Antonio 
De  Sanctis,  intorno  alii  effetti  che  fa  il  cambio 
in  Regno  sopra  una  risposta  che  ^  staia  fatta 
adverso  del  primo ;  in  Napoli,  nella  stamperia 
di  Felice  Stigliola,  a  Porta  Reale,  1605.  De 
Sanctis  endeavours  to  prove,  in  the  first  Discorso, 
that  the  only  remedy  against  the  scarcity  of 
money  which  was  felt  in  his  days  in  the  realm 
of  Naples,  would  be  an  act  of  the  government 
called  Prammatica,  by  which  the  value  of 
foreign  coin  should  be  fixed  in  the  money  of 
the  country,  and  heavy  penalties  prescribed  to 
enforce  the  established  ratio  in  the  payment  of 
all  bills  of  exchange  and  to  prevent  any  other 
attempt  to  give  money  a  value  different  from  that 
which  the  prammatica  prescribed.  His  advice 
was  followed,  but  given  up  two  years  later, 
when  the  effects  of  the  prammatica  had  made 
people  wiser.  The  first  pamphlet  of  De  Sanctis 
was  answered  by  an  anonymous  Genoese  author 
to  whom  he  replies  in  the  second  one. 

[Sir  T.  Twiss,  View  of  the  Progress  of  Pol. 
Econ.  in  Europe,  1847,  Lect.  I.]  m.  p. 

DESCENT  OF  PROPERTY.  Sir  Henry 
Maine  {Early  Law  and  Custom,  London,  1883) 
points  out  the  connection  between  ancestor 
worship  and  the  descent  of  property  in  the 
Eastern  and  the  Roman  Empires.  '*  Almost  all 
the  English  law  on  the  subject  of  the  descent  of 
personalty,  a  great  deal  of  continental  law  on  the 
same  subject,  and  some  part  of  our  law  of  realty 
has  for  its  foundation  the  118th  Novella  Consti- 
tutio  of  Justinian.  This  novella  is  the  last  re- 
vision of  the  older  Roman  law  of  succession  after 
death,  which  was  formed  by  the  fusion  of  the 
rules  of  inheritance  contained  in  the  venerable 
Twelve  Tables  with  the  equity  of  the  Praetor's 
Edict :  two  streams  of  law  profoundly  influenced 
at  their  source  as  no  reader  of  M.  Fustel  de 
Coulanges  can  doubt  by  the  worship  of  ances- 
tors "  (Maine).  In  the  Principles  of  the  Law  of 
Succession  to  Deceased  Persons,  by  T.  R.  Potts, 
London,  1888,  will  be  found  a  brief  sketch  of 
the  history  of  the  law  of  descent  in  England. 
Kenny  and  Laurence,  in  their  Essays  on  the 
Law  of  Prim/)geniture,  Cambridge,  1878,  trace 
the  history  of  primogeniture  in  England.  The 
Succession  Laws  of  Christian  Countries,  by  Eyre 
Lloyd,  London,  1877,  contains  a  summary  of 
the  law  of  descent  in  the  principal  European 
countries.  In  France,  Belgium,  Prussia, 
Austria,  and  other  continental  states,  on  an 
intestacy  all  children  take  equally,  no  distinc- 
tion being  drawn  between  males  and  females 
or  between  real  and  personal  property.  In 
England,  and  in  countries  that  have  adopted 
English  common  law  as  the  basis  of  their 
legislation,  the  eldest  son  as  a  rule  succeeds 
to  real  property  to  the  exclusion  of  all  other 
children,  whilst  the  personalty  is  divided 
between  the  widow  and   the   children.     Two 


DESIGNS— DESMARETS 


57] 


important  changes  were  introduced  in  the  19th 
century  in  England  and  Ireland.  By  the  53 
&  54  Vict.  c.  29,  if  there  is  no  issue,  and  the 
net  value  of  the  realty  and  the  personalty  does 
not  exceed  £500,  then  the  Avhole  estate  goes 
to  the  widow  :  if  the  net  value  exceeds  £500 
then  the  widow  is  to  have  £500,  whilst  by  the 
54  &  55  Vict.  c.  66,  §  84,  any  real  estate 
registered  under  the  act  is  on  the  death  of 
the  owner  intestate  to  devolve  on  the  personal 
representatives  as  if  it  were  personal  property. 

[For  economic  eifects  of  English  as  compared 
with  continental  law,  see  G.  C.  Brodrick,  English 
Land  and  English  Landlords,  1881.— Systems  of 
Land  Tenure  in  Various  Countries,  Cobden  Club 
Essays,  1870  (see  Bequest,  Power  of  ;  Land, 
Law  relating  to).]  j.  e,  c.  m. 

DESIGN'S,  Copyright  in.  By  laws  passed 
in  1737  and  1744  France  recognised  a  right  of 
property  in  designs  applied  to  silks.  In  1787 
England  by  the  29  Geo.  III.  c.  38  gave  protection 
to  the  first  inventor  of  a  design  for  linen  or  cotton 
cloth.  Subsequent  acts  extended  protection  to 
mixtures  of  flax  and  cotton,  and  to  animal  sub- 
stances. By  the  Patents,  Designs  and  Trade 
Marks  Act,  1883,  a  new  or  original  design  may 
be  registered  by  its  proprietor  for  a  particular 
class  or  classes  of  goods,  and  by  such  regis- 
tration the  proprietor  obtains  copyright  in 
the  design,  i.e.  the  exclusive  right  to  apply 
the  design  to  any  article  of  manu'acture  or 
substance  for  five  years.  This  act  has  been 
amended  at  different  dates  up  to  the  Patents 
and  Designs  Acts  of  1905  and  1907. 

[W.  N.  Lawson,  Patents,  Designs,  and  Trade 
Marks,  1889. — Edmunds  and  l^ertwick.  Law  of 
Copyright  in  Designs  (1909). — W.  M.  Freeman, 
The  Patents  and  Designs  Act,  1907  (1908).— R. 
Frost,  Patents  and  Designs  Act,  1907  (1908).— 
D.  Fulton,  Law  and  Practice  relating  to  Patents, 
Trademarks,  and  Designs  (1905). — J.  W.  Gordon, 
Statute  Law  relating  to  Patents  of  Inventions  and 
Registration  of  Designs  (1908). — G.  C.  Marks, 
Inventions,  Patents,  and  Designs,  with  text  of  Act 
(1907). — S.  G.  Pirani,  Index  of  Patent,  Design, and 
Trade  Mark  Cases,  1884-1909  ( 1 910).— Roberts  and 
Moulton,  Patents  and  Designs  Act,  1907  (1907). 
(See  Copyright.  )]  j.  e.  c.  m. 

DESMARETS,  Nicolas  (1648-1721),  con- 
troller-general of  finance  under  Louis  XIV. 
(1708-1715),  was  a  nephew  of  Colbert,  who  gave 
him  a  post  in  his  bureau.  He  rose  to  be  maitre 
des  requites,  and  on  the  death  of  his  uncle  in 
1 6  8  3  was  made  intendant  des  finances.  In  1 7  0  3 
the  king  nominated  him  a  director  of  finance 
(Saint  Simon,  Mimoires,  iv.  183),  and  in  1708 
gave  him  the  controllership  of  the  finances. 
"  II  ^tait  tout  h,  fait  I'homme  de  la  situation," 
says  Viihrer,  who  describes  him  as  possessing 
"une  remarquable  sagacity,  une  intelligence 
vive  et  profonde  h,  la  fois,  beaucoup  de  justice 
et  de  rectitude  dans  les  id^es  .  .  .  une  f<5con- 
dite,  une  abondance  d'imagination  in^puisable  " 
{La  Dette  Fublique,  i.  128).     The  condition  of 


affairs  was  most  alarming,  with  an  increased 
expenditure  and  a  diminished  revenue.  The 
income  from  taxation  had  fallen  from  112  to 
75  millions  of  livres,  the  yearly  expenses  had 
risen  from  119  to  220  millions.  The  debt  was 
2  milliards.  Arrears  of  36  millions  were  due 
to  the  army,  and  the  revenue  of  five  years  had 
been  spent  in  anticipation.  Desmarets  com- 
menced by  repealing  a  decree  which  permitted 
payments  in  specie  or  paper.  He  allowed  the 
capitation  tax  to  be  commuted  by  a  payment 
of  six  years  in  advance.  He  doubled  toll- 
duties  and  contracted  with  Samuel  Bernard 
and  others  loans  extending  to  230  millions. 
These  expedients  enabled  him  to  get  through 
1708,  but  the  troubles  of  the  next  year  began 
with  a  winter  of  unusual  severity.  To  meet 
the  famine  which  followed  he  brought  wheat 
from  all  parts  of  Europe,  enforced  a  sj)ecial 
tax  on  the  rich,  sold  the  undergrowth  of  the 
state  forests,  and  effected  a  recoinage.  He 
received  the  dignity  of  minister  from  Louis. 

The  king  did  not  accept  the  onerous  condi- 
tions offered  by  the  allies  in  1709.  To  meet  the 
enormous  charges  of  the  campaign  Desmarets 
proposed  a  war  tax  of  a  dixieme  on  all  property 
and  incomes.  Even  the  clergy  and  nobility 
were  not  exempted.  The  new  tax  produced 
25  millions.  He  also  borrowed  15  millions 
from  some  merchants.  In  1711  he  commenced 
a  more  regular  system  and  converted  into  5  per 
cent  rentes  all  the  various  state  loans.  The 
energy  and  ability  of  Desmarets  in  putting  tn 
order  the  financial  embarrassments  of  the  king- 
dom were  of  great  help  to  Louis  XIV.  "Si 
nos  gens  de  guerre  avaient  le  courage  et  le  genie 
de  Desmarets  nous  gagnerions  toutes  les 
batailles, "  said  Madame  de  Maintenon.  In  the 
seven  years  of  his  administration  the  net  pro- 
duce of  the  ordinary  revenues  did  not  exceed 
269  millions,  and  during  this  time  he  was 
obliged  to  find  1300  millions  of  extraordinary 
resources,  and  even  then  he  left  over  300 
millions  impaid  (A.  Vuitry,  Le  disordre  des 
Finances,  p.  25).  He  hoped  in  1715  to  pro- 
duce a  properly-balanced  budget  if  the  king 
lived  to  bestow  his  favour  for  two  years.  Louis 
died,  however,  1st  September  1715,  and  Des- 
marets was  dismissed  by  the  regent.  He  retired 
to  MaUlebois,  where  he  died  4th  May  1721. 
Saint  Simon,  who  was  Ul- disposed  towards 
Desmarets,  draws  his  character  as  that  of  a 
man  "qui  avoit  plus  de  sens  que  d'esprit,  et 
qui  montroit  plus  de  sens  qu'il  n'en  avoit  en 
effet ;  quelque  chose  de  lourd  et  de  lent, 
parlant  bien  et  avec  agrement,  dur,  emporte" 
Mimoires,  xviii.  157).  His  son,  the  Marquis 
Desmarets  de  Maillebois,  marshal  of  France,  is 
famous  for  his  Italian  campaigns. 

Desmarets  presented  to  the  Regent  Mimoire  su7 
V administration  des  finances  depuis  le  20  Fevrier 
1708  jusquau  ler  Septemhre  1715  [Paris,  1716] 
Svo,  (also  reprinted  about  1789,  and  in  the  An- 


572 


DESTUTT  DE  TRACY— DEVELOPMENT 


notes  Politiques  (1757)  of  the  Abbe  Castel  de  St. 
Pierre)  "  Tres-curieux,"  says  Lenglet  du  Fresnoy, 
•'  il  vient  de  main  de  maitre,  mais  il  n'a  pas  tout 
dit "  {Methode  pour  Hudier  VHistoire,  xii.  337). 
In  the  opinion  of  Voltaire  "ce  memoire  prouve 
qu'il  avait  des  talens,  une  grande  modestie  et'des 
intentions  droites  "  {Siecle  de  Louis  XIV.,  1819, 1. 
38  ;  see  also  ii.  31). 

[Saint  Simon,  Mimoires,  1856,  etc.,  tomes  ii., 
iv,,  vi.,  vii.,  ix.,  xi.,  xiii.,  xviii. — Nouveau  Dic- 
tionnaire  d'J^conomie  Politique,  1890,  i.  669-701. 
— F.  V.  de  Forhonn&is,  Recherches  et  considerations 
sur  les  Finances  de  France,  Basle,  1758,  2  vols. 
4to. — A.  Vuitry,  Le  desordre  des  Finances  d  la 
fin  du  regne  de  Louis  XIV.,  Paris,  1885,  8vo. — 
R.  Stourm,  Les  Finances  de  VAnden  Regime, 
Paris,  1885,  2  vols.  8vo. — A.  Vuhrer,  Histoire  de 
la  Dette  Puhlique  en  France,  Paris,  1886,  2  vols. 
8vo. — Month  yon,  Particularity  sur  les  Minis  tres 
des  Finances,  Paris,  1812,  8vo.]  H.  E.T. 

DESTUTT  DE  TRACY,  Antoine  Louis 
Claude,  Comte  (1754-1836),  born  in  the 
Bourbonnais,  died  at  Paris.  He  was  a  member 
of  the  constituent  assembly,  and  was  arrested 
and  imprisoned  during  the  Reign  of  Terror. 
He  was  set  at  liberty  after  the  9th  Thermidor, 
27th  July  1794.  Although  he  became  a  senator 
under  the  empire,  and  subsequently  a  peer  of 
France  under  the  Bourbon  restoration,  he  re- 
tained throughout  his  early  sympathies  with 
liberty.  From  the  year  1808  he  had  been  a 
member  of  the  French  Academy.  When,  in 
1832,  the  Academy  of  Moral  and  Political 
Science  was  re-established,  he  was  invited  to 
join  the  section  of  moral  science.  As  a  philo- 
sopher he  was  one  of  the  last  survivors  of  the 
icole  sensualiste,  a  school  whose  method  of 
thought  may  best  be  defined  in  the  words  of 
one  of  their  members,  "  Penser  c'est  sentir,  rien 
que  cela,"  and  he  was  also  an  economist  of  great 
distmction.  As  early  as  1798  he  wrote,  at 
the  request  of  the  well-known  Jefferson,  his 
Oommentaires  sur  I' Esprit  des  Lois  de  Montes- 
quieu (1  vol.  8vo,  1819).  In  this  work  he 
corrected  some  of  the  economic  errors  into 
which  that  able  thinker  had  fallen.  In  1804 
he  published  his  Traite  de  la  volonte,  part  of 
his  EUments  d'Ideologie,  the  larger  part  of 
which  formed  a  treatise  on  political  economy. 
This  work  was  reprinted,  without  any  modifi- 
cation, under  the  title  of  a  Traite  d'dconomie 
politique,  in  1823  (1  vol.  in  18mo).  In  these 
two  works,  the  commentary  and  the  treatise, 
Destutt  de  Tracy  shows  that  he  had  attained  a 
higher  level  than  the  majority  of  his  contem- 
poraries. He  has  obtained  a  popularity  equal 
to  his  deserts,  notwithstanding  the  somewhat 
metaphysical  form  with  which  he  had  invested 
his  subjects.  Bonaparte  had  him  in  view  when 
he  inveighed  against  the  "  Ideologues." 

A.  c.  f. 

Destutt  de  Tracy  and  Ricardo.  A  refer- 
ence to  M.  de  Tracy  will  be  found  in  Ricardo's 
Principles  of  Political  Economy  and  Taxation 


ed.  1852,  note  p.  171.  He  says  with  respect 
to  the  Elements  d'Idiologie,  **  In  this  work  M. 
de  Tracy  has  given  a  useful  and  an  able  treatise 
on  the  general  principles  of  political  economy, 
and  I  am  sorry  to  be  obliged  to  add,  that  he 
supports,  by  his  authority  the  definitions  which 
M.  Say  has  given  of  the  words  'value,' 
'riches,'  and  'utility.'"  In  the  text  Ricardo 
observes,  "  I  cannot  agree  with  M.  Say  in 
estimating  the  value  of  a  commodity  by  the 
abundance  of  other  commodities  for  which  it 
will  exchange  ;  I  am  of  the  opinion  of  a  very 
distinguished  writer,  M.  Destutt  de  Tracy,  who 
says,  that  '  To  measure  any  other  thing  is  to 
compare  it  with  a  determinate  quantity  of  that 
same  thing  which  we  take  for  a  standard  of 
comparison  for  unity.  To  measure,  then,  to 
ascertain  a  length,  a  weight,  a  value,  is  to  find 
how  many  times  they  contain  metres,  grammes, 
francs,  in  a  word,  unities  of  the  same  descrip- 
tion. * "  An  interesting  account  of  Ricardo's 
meeting  with  De  Tracy  is  given  in  the  Letters 
of  Ricardo  to  Malthus,  No.  Ixxxii.,  edited  by 
J.  Bonar,  p.  211,  ed.  1887. 

DETRACTION,  Droit  de.  In  France, 
before  the  Revolution,  the  right  of  aliens  to 
inherit  property  was  limited  by  the  droit  de 
detraction,  which  enabled  the  state  to  confiscate 
part  of  any  bequest  or  inheritance  falling  to  an 
alien.  For  the  history  of  its  abolition  see 
AuBAiNE,  Droit  d'.  It  need  only  be  remarked 
here  that  at  the  present  time,  should  the  laws 
of  another  country  impose  any  tax  of  this  kind 
on  a  share  of  an  inheritance  left  to  a  French- 
man, the  French  law  will,  where  possible, 
compensate  the  person  so  damnified  out  of  any 
share  of  the  inheritance  falling  to  an  alien 
resident  in  France.  In  England  and  other 
countries,  especially  Russia,  the  right  of  aliens 
to  inherit  land  is  either  entirely  denied  or 
severely  restricted  ;  but  these  rules,  though 
analogous  to  the  droit  de  detraction,  have  a 
political  not  a  financial  aim. 

[Les  Codes  annotees  de  Sirey,  Edition  entiere- 
ment  refondue,  par  P.  Gilbert,  1847. — Littre's 
French  Dictionary,  s.v. — Dictionnavre  general  de 
la  Politique,  par  Maiirice  Block,  1873,  s.v, 
"Stranger."]  c.  g.  o. 

DEVELOPMENT,  or  evolution,  as  distin- 
guished from  mere  change,  means  a  growth,  or 
the  unfolding  of  qualities  present,  but  at  first 
latent,  in  the  subject  concerned.  Darwinism 
{q.v.)  is  therefore  not  a  doctrine  of  develop- 
ment or  evolution  unless  we  regard  animated 
nature  collectively  as  one  subject  which  remains 
the  same  throughout  its  changes.  The  idea  of 
development  applies  to  man  and  human  societies, 
and  especially  to  their  science  and  culture,  for 
there  is  present  an  identity  of  the  subject 
(humanity)  with  continuity  through  the  changes 
— e.g.  from  Greece,  through  Rome  and  the 
middle  ages  to  modem  civilisation — and  pre- 
servation of  the  results  of  the  past 


DE  VIO— DEW 


573 


Economic  evolution  has  been  used  in  two 
senses  (a)  the  growth  of  new  forms  of  industrial 
organisation,  keeping  pace  with  new  wants, 
new  powers  of  science  over  nature,  and  new 
political  relations,  and  (&)  the  growth  of 
economic  theories,  which  may  or  may  not  be  in 
correspondence  with  (a).  The  name  is  best 
kept  for  the  first  of  the  two  phenomena ; 
and  the  latter  may  be  called  the  evolution  of 
economics.  In  both  cases  the  use  of  the  name 
evolution  instead  of  change  seems  to  imply  that 
both  the  outward  changes,  say  in  European 
industry  during  the  last  hundred  years,  and 
the  changes  in  theory,  say  from  Adam  Smith 
to  J.  S.  Mill,  have  followed  a  course  for  which 
it  is  possible  to  discover  some  logical  necessity. 

The  term  evolution  was  not  unknown  in  the 
last  century,  and  the  idea  became  the  ruling 
thought  of  Fichte  and  especially  of  Hegel  and 
his  followers.  In  England,  the  idea  has  gained 
currency  through  the  \vritings  of  Spencer  and 
Darwin  ;  and  evolution  in  the  sense  conceived 
by  biology  appears  to  be  the  essence  of  the 
popular  philosophy  of  our  day.  Marx  has 
applied  the  notion  to  economics,  and  the  rela- 
tion of  the  two  is  already  a  topic  of  controversy. 
The  extreme  left  of  the  school  of  historical 
economists  hold  that  there  are  as  many  forms 
of  economics,  all  relatively  true,  as  there  are 
separate  peoples  and  separate  epochs  ;  and  they 
would  not  distinguish  the  development  of 
economics  from  the  general  progress  of  historical 
change.  The  conception  of  economics  as  a 
body  of  doctrines  of  universal  validity  or 
absolute  truth  is  no  doubt  discredited  ;  but  the 
conception  of  "economic  categories"  as  a  per- 
manent basis  of  further  development  has  gained 
ground  ;  and  seems  indeed  to  be  required  by 
the  very  notion  of  development. 

[For  distinction  of  historical  and  economic 
categories,  see  A.  Wagner,  Lehrhuch  der  joolitischen 
Oekonoinie,  Grundlage,  pp.  352  seq.  and  the  refer- 
ences there  given  to  Rodbertus  and  Schaflle. — For 
distinction  of  development  from  Darwinism  see  E. 
Caird,  Philosophy  of  Kant,  (2nd  ed.  1889)  vol.  ii. 
pp.  539  seq.  and  S.  Alexander,  Moral  Order  and 
Progress  (1889),  pp.  139,  309,  382,  etc.]    J.  b. 

DE  VIO,  F.  ToMMASO  (1470-1534),  born  at 
Gaeta,  and  sometimes  called  Thomas  de  Vio 
Cajetan,  was  famous  for  his  learning  ;  at 
Ferrara,  where  he  held  disputations  with  Pico 
della  Mirandola,  he  was  made  a  Doctor  honoris 
causa ;  he  taught  philosophy  in  the  Ginnasio 
Romano,  and  Avas  made  Cardinal  of  S.  Sisto  by 
Leo  X.  He  was  consulted  in  all  the  weighty 
theological  questions  of  his  time.  Amongst 
these  was  the  question  of  Henry  VIII. 's  first 
marriage,  which  he  declared  valid.  He  was  sent 
to  Germany  to  controvert  the  opinions  of  Luther. 
He  wi'ote  a  great  many  works  of  which  a  list 
can  be  found  in  A.  Ciaconii :  Vitoi  et  res 
gestcB  Pontificum  romanorum  et  Cardinalium. 
Romse.  1677,  voL  iii.  p.  390-394.     Here  only 


the  more  important  concerning  economical 
topics  are  mentioned : 

De  Usura,  written  in  Milan,  1500  ;  De 
Cambiis,  written  also  in  MOan,  1499  ;  and  De 
Monte  Pietatis,  written  at  Pavia,  1498,  all 
published  1596  in  Venice  ;  F.  Thomse  de  Vio 
Caietani,  ordinisPraedicatorum,  Opuscula  omnia. 
Venetiis,  1596,  p.  168  et  seq.  In  his  pamphlet 
De  Usura,  De  Vio  does  not  discuss  the  argument 
ab  ovo  and  exhaustively,  intending  rather  to 
solve  some  special  cases  in  which  he  thinks  the 
current  opinions  of  canonists  wrong  or  exagger- 
ated. In  his  pamphlet  De  Cambiis,  he  declares 
himself  opposed  to  the  profession  of  what  then 
was  called  a  cambist,  recognising  only  the 
legitimacy  and  utility  of  the  change  of  money 
against  money.  In  his  pamphlet  De  Monte 
Pietatis,  he  proves  that  these  establishments  for 
pawnbroking  served  simply  to  cover  a  species 
of  usury.  De  Vio's  pamphlets  must,  therefore, 
be  considered  as  one  single  tract  in  which  he 
discusses  the  same  subject,  viz.  usury,  under 
three  different  aspects,  and  in  which  he  follows 
the  opinions  current  in  his  time,  although 
sometimes  showing  views  somewhat  broader 
than  those  of  the  canonists.  M.  P. 

DEVISE.  A  gift  of  land  or  other  real 
property  by  will.  The  person  to  whom  the 
gift  is  made  is  called  the  devisee.  e.  s. 

DEW,  Thomas  Roderick  (1802-1846),  was 
born  in  Virginia  and  was  educated  at  the  College 
of  William  and  Mary  ;  in  1827  he  was  appointed 
professor  of  history,  metaphysics,  and  political 
economy  in  the  same  institution,  and  in  1836 
president ;  he  died  at  Paris  while  travelling. 
Dew  was  a  most  thorough  and  earnest  teacher 
of  history,  and  exercised  great  influence 
throughout  the  south  in  upholding  public 
opinion  in  the  support  of  free  trade  and  negro 
slavery.  On  strictly  economic  subjects  he 
wrote  :  Lectures  on  the  Restrictive  System,  Rich- 
mond, 1829  (pp.  195).  In  this  Dew  questioned 
the  general  advantage  to  be  gained  from  manu- 
factures, since  they  are  liable  to  great  fluctua- 
tions ;  and  a  factory  population  is  not  only 
unfavourable  to  liberty,  but  turbulent  and  of 
necessity  dependent.  He  wrote  an  Essay  on 
the  Interest  of  Money  and  the  Policy  of  Law 
against  Usury,  Shellbank,  Va,,  1834  (pp.  24); 
in  which  iTsury  laws  are  regarded  as  influencing 
unfavojirably  the  distribution  and  circulation 
of  capital,  and  checking  the  natural  division 
of  employments  and  treating  the  question  with 
special  reference  to  the  farming  interest.  He 
also  wrote  a  Letter  on  the  Financial  Policy  of 
the  Administration  and  the  Laws  of  Credit  and 
Trade,  Washington,  1840  (pp.  16),  attributing 
the  crisis  of  1837  not  to  banks  but  to  the  com-se 
of  trade  ;  banks  are  the  effect  and  not  the 
cause  of  speculation.  Dew  opposed  the  sub- 
treasury  system  inasmuch  as  it  tended  to 
unsound  banking  operations.  For  an  interest- 
ing statement  of  his  educational  work  and  for 


574 


DIAGRAMS 


bibliographical  references,  see  Circ.  of  Informa- 
tion of  U.S.  Bureau  of  Educ,  No.  1,  1887. 
College  of  William  and  Mary,  by  Professor  H. 
B.  Adams,  pp.  54-56.  d.  r.  d. 

DIAGRAMS.  For  the  purpose  of  conveying 
readily  to  the  mind  the  general  facts  contaifted 
in  a  table  of  figures,  nothing  seems  better  suited 
than  some  form  of  diagrammatic  representation. 

When  the  relative  magnitudes  of  a  number 
of  disconnected  quantities  are  simply  concerned, 
a  series  of  geometrical  figures,  circles,  squares, 
or  oblongs  whose  areas  are  proportional  to  those 
magnitudes,  is  commonly  employed. 

The  delineation  of  the  varying  circumstances 
of  the  different  parts  of  a  country  in  respect  to 
such  matters  as  density  of  population,  degree 
of  poverty,  etc.,  by  colouring  a  map  in  different 
tints,  which  has  been  frequently  employed 
(recently  by  Mr.  Chas.  Booth  in  Labour  and 
Life  of  the  People),  is  a  method  which  is  very 
readily  understood. 

The  curves  which  record  the  readings  of  a 
barometer  or  thermometer  are  illustrations  of 
another  class  of  diagrams  which  are  very  largely 
used  for  economic  purposes. 

It  requires  a  very  special  training  to  be  pre- 
pared to  grasp  readily  the  salient  points  of 
complicated  schedules  of  figures,  which  can, 
however,  be  exhibited  very  readily  even  to  the 
untrained  by  means  of  such  diagrams.  This 
renders  them  of  gi'eat  service  to  the  teacher  of 
economics.  But  curves  of  similar  construction 
are  invaluable  adjuncts  in  the  study  of  economic 
theory,  possessing  all  the  general  advantages  of 
arithmetical  illustrations,  while  they  are  less 
liable  than  these  to  admit  the  unwary  assump- 
tion, in  the  data  of  illustrations,  of  the  result 
which  it  is  desired  to  establish  by  their  help. 

If  we  wish  to  draw  a  curve  showing  the 
variations  in  the  price  of  some  commodity  (say 
iron)  in  the  course  of  a  number  of  years  we 
proceed  as  follows.     Along  a  line  Ox  (Fig.  1) 


Fig.  1. . 


a  number  of  equal  distances  On^,  n^n^,  etc.,  are 
measured.     We  may  take  each  of  these  distances 


to  represent  some  convenient  interval  of  time, 
an  hour,  day,  year,  or  any  other  suitable  interval. 
From  the  points  0,  Wj,  n^,,  etc.  lines  OP,  n^.^,  n^V^ 
etc. ,  are  drawn  perpendicular  to  Ox  and  of  such 
lengths  as  to  be  proportional  to  the  price  of 
iron  at  the  epoch  represented  by  the  point 
from  which  the  line  is  drawn.  We  might 
for  example  draw  them  on  the  scale  of  one- 
twentieth  of  an  inch  for  each  shilling  of  the 
price  of  a  ton  of  iron,  or  on  any  other  convenient 
scale.  The  points  'P2J^^...\)QivLg  connected  by 
a  broken  or  curved  line,  such  a  line  will  exhibit 
the  variations  of  the  price  of  iron  with  the  pro- 
gress of  time,  in  a  manner  which  is  quite  as 
accurate  as  the  table  of  figures  from  which  the 
curve  is  derived,  and  which  is  far  more  striking 
to  the  eye  of  even  the  most  skilled  statisticiaa 

The  manner  in  which  the  connection  between 
time  and  price  is  thus  shown  may  be  employed 
to  show  the  concm*rent  variations  of  any  two 
connected  quantities  in  economics. 

If  the  abscissae  (the  distances  along  Ox)  re- 
present the  amounts  produced  in  a  given  time, 
such  as  a  month  or  year,  the  ordinates  {n^^ 
etc.)  denoting  the  corresponding  prices  at  which 
the  goods  could  be  profitably  produced,  the 
curve  becomes  the  ordinary  supply  curve. 

If  the  abscissae  denote  the  quantities  which 
could  find  purchasers  at  the  prices  denoted  by 
the  ordinates,  we  obtained  the  demand  curve 
(cp.  Demand  Curves). 

These  curves  cannot  be  drawn  completely 
from  records  of  experience,  because  actual  ex- 
perience covers  in  general  but  a  small  range 
of  prices  for  any  one  commodity.  No  un- 
certainty is,  however,  owing  to  this  cause,  intro- 
duced into  the  arguments  based  on  them,  since 
the  really  important  parts  of  them  are  those  of 
which  we  have  experience,  and,  in  addition  to 
this,  the  arguments  commonly  depend  not  so 
much  on  actual  lengths  of  lines  as  on  the  general 
direction  of  the  curve,  whether  upwards  or 
downwardSj  and  whether  the  slope  of  the  curve 
be  gradual  or  rapid. 

It  is  the  result  of  experience  that — except  in 
such  a  case  as  that  of  a  collector  of  rare  speci- 
mens of  some  kind,  when  his  collection  may 
be  doubled  in  value  by  the  addition  of  a  single 
specimen  which  renders  it  complete — people  are 
not  willing  to  pay  so  much  for  a  given  small 
addition  to  their  store  of  any  commodity  when 
they  already  have  a  large  amount  of  it,  as  when 
they  have  but  little  ;  this  enables  us  to  say  at 
once  that  the  demand  curve  must  slope  down- 
wards throughout,  whatever  be  its  shape  in 
other  respects. 

With  regard  to  the  supply  curve,  it  is  quite 
possible  that  its  slope  should  be  sometimes  up- 
wards, sometimes  downwards,  or  that  it  may 
be  horizontal  throughout  or  for  a  portion  of  its 
length.  If,  however,  we  are  considering  only 
small  changes  in  production,  not  involving  a 
reorganisation  of  the  industry  concerned,   an 


DIAGRAMS 


575 


increase  of  product  means,  in  general,  an  increase 
in  the  total  cost  out  of  proportion  to  the  addi- 
tion to  the  amount  of  produce,  i.e.  in  the 
neighbourhood  of  the  actual  price  the  curve 
slopes  upward  as  we  proceed  outwards  along  it, 
though  there  are,  doubtless,  cases  in  which  the 
contrary  is  true,  and  it  is  drawn  sloping  down- 
wards in  Fig.  5. 

For  the  problem  of  the  equilibrium  of  supply 
and  demand,  the  use  of  diagi-ams  enables  us  to 
grasp  more  clearly  than  any  other  method  the 
relations  between  the  quantities  involved. 

liTid  and  sS  (Fig.  2)  be  portions  of  the  curves 
of  demand  and  supply  intersecting  at  P  and 


Fig.  2. 


O  N  ^ 

PN  be  perpendicular  to  Ox,  then  PN  denotes 
a  price  which  will  equate  demand  and  supply. 
At  a  price  less  than  PN"  it  would  not  be  profit- 
able to  produce  so  much,  at  a  greater  price 
there  would  be  more  than  the  ordinary  profit, 
which  would  lead  producers  to  endeavour  to 
increase  their  businesses.  At  a  price  gi-eater 
than  PN  consumers  would  not  be  found  for  the 
whole  amount  ON,  at  a  less  price  consumers 
would  be  tempted  to  increase  their  consum[)- 
tion,  and  Avould  be  desirous  of  using  more  than 
the  amount  ON. 

Small  variations  from  the  conditions  indicated 
will  upset  the  balance  struck  at  the  price  PN. 
We  see  that  the  price,  which  may  be  taken  to 
measure  the  exchange- value  of  the  commodity, 
is  equal  on  the  one  hand  to  the  expenses  of 
production  at  the  margin,  and  also  to  the 
marginal  demand  price,  i.e.  to  the  estimate  in 
money- equivalent  made  by  purchasers,  of  the 
utility  to  them  of  those  portions  which  they 
consider  only  just  worth  their  outlay. 

If  the  curves  be  supposed  traced  back  to 
meet  Oy  (see  Fig.  3)  we  have  a  representation  of 
the  total  utility  to  consumers  of  the  quantity 
of  commodity  ON  in  the  area  between  the 
curve  Dd  and  the  lines  OD,  ON  and  NP. 

The  actual  outlay  being  measured  by  OMPN 
(if  PM  be  p9,rallel  to  Ox),  the  area  DMP  is  what 
is  called  by  Prof.  Marshall  the  Consumer's  Rent, 
being  the  excess  of  the  money  measure  of  the 
total  utility  over  the  money  cost. 


Under  certain  conditions  the  area  MsP  de- 
notes the  Producer's  Rent  measured  in  money. 

y 

Fig.  3. 


The  relations  expressed  by  these  curves  are 
represented  in  a  diff"erent  manner  by  Auspitz 
and  Lieben  in  their  v/ork  on  the  Theoric  des 
Preises.  The  curves  they  draAV  have  for 
ordinates  the  prices,  not  of  a  unit,  or  given 
quantity,  but  of  the  total  quantities  rejDresented 
by  the  corresponding  abscissse. 

The  price,  in  the  ordinary  sense  of  the  term, 
is  represented  by  the  trigonometrical  tangent  of 
the  angle  between  the  line  touching  the  curve 
at  any  point  and  the  line  Ox,  for  it  is  the  rate 
at  which  the  total  price  increases  as  the  amount 
increases. 

Lines  being  drawn  from  0  parallel  to  the 
tangents  at  every  point  to  the  total  cost  curve 
OS  to  intersect  the  corresponding  ordinates,  a 
second  curve  is  deduced  (the  dotted  curves  in 
Fig.  4).     A  similar  construction  applied  to  the 


total  demand  curve  gives  a  second  derived 
(dotted)  curve,  whose  intersection  with  the 
former  at  p  gives  the  position  of  equilibrium 
of  supply  and  demand  and  the  normal  exchange 
value.  ON  is  the  amount  produced  and  con- 
sumed, and  the  price  at  which  a  unit  of  it  is 
saleable  is  represented  by  the  ratio  of  PN  to  ON. 
Among  the  many  diagrams  expressing  the 


576 


DIALOGUS  DE  SCACCARIO— DICKINSON 


relations  between  different  economic  quantities, 
one  of  the  most  instinictive  is  that  which  deals 
with  the  case  of  Monopolies. 

Assuming  the  ordinary  supply  and  demand 
curves  for  a  commodity  the  sources  of  supply 
of  which  are  monopolised,  we  deduce  from  these 
a  third  by  measuring  along  each  ordinate 
NPQ  to  the  supply  and  demand  curves  a  portion 
NR  equal  to  the  part  PQ  between  the  two 
curves.  Where  the  demand  curve  lies  above 
the  supply  curve  the  distance  NR  is  measured 


Fig.  6. 


upwards  and  vice  versa.  This  curve  (Fig.  5) 
represents  the  possible  profit  obtainable  with 
different  amounts  of  the  given  commodity 
produced.  The  aim  of  the  monopolist  being 
supposed  to  be  to  make  the  total  gain  as  great 
as  possible,  the  scale  of  production  suitable  is 
that  denoted  by  OM  when,  MT  being  drawn 
parallel  to  Oy  to  meet  the  curve  at  T,  the  part 
of  the  tangent  at  T  to  the  third  curve,  which  is 
cut  off  by  Ox  and  0^,  is  just  divided  equally 
at  T.  In  this  case  the  product  of  OM  and  MT, 
which  expresses  the  total  profit,  is  greater  than 
for  any  other  position  of  T  upon  the  curve  RT, 
and  thus  the  condition  laid  down  is  satisfied. 
For  any  other  scale  of  production,  either  the 
lessened  rate  of  profit  out-balances  the  increased 
sales,  or  the  decrease  of  sales  out-balances  the 
increased  rate  of  profit.  Many  developments  of 
the  diagi-ams  here  referred  to  may  be  found  in 
the  footnotes  in  bks.  iii.  iv.  and  v.  of  Marshall's 
Principles  of  Economics,  and  the  examples  given 
will,  it  is  hoped,  be  sufficient  to  illustrate 
the  general  ideas  which  underlie  most  of  the 
diagrams  in  general  use.  A.  w.  f. 

DIALOGUS  DE  SCACCARIO.  This  notable 
treatise  was  written  about  1176  by  Richard 
Fitz- Nigel,  Bishop  of  London,  at  one  time 
treasurer  of  the  exchequer.  It  is  in  the  foinn 
of  a  dialogue  between  a  master  and  a  disciple, 
and  consists  of  two  books.  The  first  book 
describes  the  exchequer,  and  its  two  parts : 
the  lower,  or  receipt,  to  which  money  is  actu- 
ally paid  hj  the  sheriffs  and  other  officials,  and 
the  upper,  in  which  the  accounts  are  formally 
audited.     It  also  describes  the  functions  of  the 


justiciar,  chancellor,  treasurer,  and  other  officers 
of  the  exchequer.  The  second  book  describes 
the  summonses  to  the  exchequer,  and  the  various 
sources  from  which  the  revenue  is  derived. 
Besides  the  direct  information  about  the  finan- 
cial administration  of  the  Angevin  period,  the 
treatise  also  throws  a  flood  of  light  on  the 
history  of  constitutional  and  social  organisation 
from  the  Norman  conquest  to  Henry  II. 

The  Dialogus  was  "  translated  into  English  by 
a  gentleman  of  the  Inner  Temple,"  1758,  also  in 
Historical  Documents  of  the  Middle  Ages  (Bohn). 
It  is  printed  in  Madox,  History  of  tlie  Exchequer. 
Stubbs,  Select  Charters  gives  the  complete  Latin 
text.  See  also  Hubert  Hall,  Court  Life  under  the 
Plantagenets,  chs.  viii.  and  ix.,  and  F.  Liebei-mann, 
Einleitung  in  den  Dialogus.  e,  l. 

DICA.  A  kind  of  tally  used  for  checking 
the  receipt  or  issue,  not  of  money,  but  of 
household  provisions,  farm  produce,  and  even 
merchandise.  In  the  statutes  of  the  order  of 
Sempringham  it  is  provided  that  all  seed  issued 
out  of  the  grange  shall  be  checked  by  a  dica,  to 
be  divided  into  two  halves,  of  which  one  shall 
be  kept  by  the  warden  and  the  other  by  the 
granger.  In  the  Constitution  of  the  King's 
House,  a  treatise  probably  as  old  as  the  reign 
of  Henry  I.,  the  master  marshal  of  the  king's 
house  was  to  have  diem  against  all  the  king's 
officers.  From  this  it  appears  that  the  use  of 
tallies  for  public  accounts  originated  with  this 
regulation  for  the  king's  Chamber,  and  we 
know  that  the  early  name  of  the  Exchequer  or 
treasury  sessions  was  "  the  Tallies,"  the  revenue 
being  at  that  time  rendered  in  farm  produce 
{Dial.  i.  8).  The  same  meaning  is  probably 
contained  in  the  term  "diker"  of  leather, 
namely  ten  hides  in  every  bale,  these  being 
tallied  by  the  packer  and  owner  by  a  notch,  cut 
at  the  counting  of  every  tenth  hide.  In  the 
present  day  coals  are  still  "tallied"  in  a  pre- 
cisely similar  way  on  board  ship. 

{Stat.  Ord.  de  Sempringham,  p.  478.  — Pipe 
Roll  Society,  vol.  iii. — Red  and  Black  Books  of 
Exchequer.']  H.  Ha. 

DICKINSON  John  (1732-1808),  a  native 
of  Maryland,  came  to  London  to  study  law, 
and  was  called  to  the  bar  at  the  Middle 
Temple.  After  his  return  to  America  he  dis- 
tinguished himself  by  a  pamphlet  (1765) 
entitled  The  Late  Megulations  respecting  the 
British  Colonies  on  the  Continent  of  America 
considered,  in  which  he  showed  the  economic 
unwisdom  of  the  Sugar  Act  and  the  proposed 
Stamp  Act.  His  Letters  from  a  Farw.er  in 
Pennsylvania  to  the  Inhabitants  of  the  Bi'itish 
Colonies,  1768,  deny  the  assumed  authority  of 
the  British  parliament  to  tax  the  colonies. 
They  examine  the  claim  upon  historical,  con- 
stitutional, and  legal  grounds  ;  and  the  argu- 
ment, though  studiously  moderate  in  tone  and 
closely  reasoned,  is  stated  in  such  a  lucid  and 
captivating  manner  that  the  Letters  obtained  a 


DICKSON— DIDEROT 


577 


very  wide  circulation.  Dickinson  was  an  intel- 
lectual factor  of  the  first  importance  in  founding 
the  Independence  of  the  United  States,  and 
drafted  some  of  the  principal  state  papers  of 
the  time.  He  was  elected  president  of  Dela- 
ware in  1781,  and  of  Pennsylvania  in  1782. 

"The  Historical  Society  of  Pennsylvania  pro- 
poses to  print  a  more  complete  edition  of  his 
political  writings  than  that  which  was  published 
under  his  own  supervision  at  Wilmington  in 
1801."  The  Life  and  Times  of  John  Dickinson, 
by  Charles  J.  Stille,  LL.D.,  Philadelphia,  1891. 

II.  H. 

DICKSON,  Rev.  Adam  (1721-1776),  was 
born  at  Aberlady,  East  Lothian.  He  graduated 
at  Edinburgh  University  and  was  appointed 
minister  at  Dunse,  Berwickshire,  in  1750.  He 
was  transferred  to  Whittinghame  in  East  Lothian 
in  1769,  and  died  in  consequence  of  a  fall  while 
riding. 

Dickson  gave  much  attention  to  agriculture, 
and  published  in  1762  a  Treatise  on  Agriculture 
(new  ed.  1770,  2  vols.  8vo),  with  special  refer- 
ence to  the  soil  and  climate  of  Scotland.  One 
section,  On  Manures,  directed  against  Tull,  was 
reprinted  in  A.  Hunter's  Georgical  Essays 
(vol.  iii.,  1770).  He  also  wrote  Small  Farms 
destructive  to  the  Country  in  its  Present  Situation, 
1764,  and  An  Essay  on  the  Causes  of  the  Prese^it 
High  Price  of  Provisions,  etc.,  1773,  4to.  In 
this  pamphlet  he  contended  that  high  prices 
were  not  due  to  had  crops  but  that  they  were 
connected  with  luxury,  currency,  taxes,  and  the 
national  debt.  Among  other  remedies  he 
proposed  road-making,  ox-labour,  a  tax  on  stock- 
holders, and  an  export  duty  on  corn.  Dickson 
is  best  known  for  his  Husbandry  of  the  Ancients 
(1788,  2  vols.  8vo,  French  translation  by 
P^ris,  1802),  derived  from  the  "  Scriptores  rei 
rusticse  "  and  other  writers,  and  compared  with 
the  modem  system.  His  practical  knowledge 
enabled  him  to  clear  up  many  difficulties,  but 
his  scholarship  was  imperfect  (Smith,  Diet,  of 
Antiquities,  1890,  i.  83). 

[Biography  prefixed  to  Husbandry  of  Ancients, 
1788,  vol.  i. — Dictionary  of  Nat.  Biography,  xv. 
38.]  H.  R.  T. 

DIDEROT,  Denis  (1713-1784),  m  ins 
RELATION  TO  ECONOMICS.  There  is  hardly  a 
single  branch  of  science  which  does  not  owe 
some  kind  of  gratitude  to  the  universal  genius 
of  this  very  able  and  characteristic  French 
writer.  His  suggestive  mind,  his  common 
sense,  and  his  power  of  concentrating  the 
best  thoughts  of  his  contemporaries  into  one 
focus,  naturally  extended  themselves  to  the 
narrow  ground,  as  it  was  in  his  day,  of  political 
and  economic  science.  It  is  almost  impossible 
to  state  how  far  in  this  respect  Diderot  could 
lay  claim  to  originality.  He  is  known  to  have 
written  many  passages  in  the  most  celebrated 
works  of  his  time.  Rousseau  confessedly  studied 
his   style,    and    some   striking    pages   in    his 


Diseours  sur  VIn4galit6  and  in  Holbach's 
Systdm^  de  la  Nature  are  written  by  Diderot ; 
his  keen  wit  in  conjunction  with  that  of  Galiani 
produced  the  Dialogues  sur  le  commerce  des 
hleds.  It  was,  however,  his  connection  with 
the  great  Encyclop6die  (1751-1771)  which 
brought  him  into  closer  contact  with  students 
of  economic  phenomena,  and  which  also  led 
him  to  promote  and  animate  their  work.  The 
principles  of  mercantilism,  like  Forbonnais' 
l^Uvunts  du  Commerce,  as  well  as  the  first 
drafts  of  the  economic  system  of  the  physio- 
crats, Quesnay,  Morellet,  St.  Lambert,  Leroy, 
and  in  part  those  of  Turgot,  are  embodied  in  this 
vast  enterprise.  Diderot,  who  perhaps  became 
acquainted  with  Quesnay's  studies  through  a 
mutual  friend,  Leroy,  and  had  publicly,  in 
1748,  paid  homage  to  Quesnay  as  a  first-rate 
surgeon  {GEumes,  t.  ix.  p.  214),  did  not  blindly 
follow  the  track  of  his  school.  Perhaps  on 
account  of  the  withdrawal  of  Quesnay's  co- 
operation in  1757,  when  the  Encyclop6die  was 
suppressed,  their  relations  grew  colder.  Diderot 
preserved  an  independent  attitude,  declaring 
for  instance  in  1769  that  he  "did  not  approve 
the  opinions  of  the  Quesnelistes,  but  on  account 
of  their  sincerity  held  them  to  be  good  fellows 
who  did  their  best"  {(Euvres,  t.  iv.  pp.  80-85). 
Similar  opinions  may  be  found  in  the  Refutation 
suivie  de  Vouvrage  d'Helv6tius  intituU  L'HomTne, 
{(Euvres,  t.  ii.  p.  352),  and  in  Diderot's  recom- 
mendation of  economic  instruction  in  the 
Russian  universities,  made  to  Catherine  II.  in 
1775-1776  {(Euvres,  t.  iii.  p.  491).  We  even 
owe  to  him  the  knowledge  of  a  humble  outsider 
of  the  physiocratic  school — ^Boesnier  de  I'Orme, 
whose  anonymous  book  Du  Ritablissement  de 
rimpdt  dans  son  Ordre  Naturel  (Yverdun,  1769) 
has  been  ably  criticised  by  Diderot  {(Euvres, 
t.  iv.  p.  39)  ;  see  on  this  book  also  EpMmeridcs 
du  Citoyen,  1769,  t.  vi.  jip.  255-256,  t.  viii.  pp. 
136-163. 

Diderot's  own  contributions  towards  the  Ency- 
clopedic bear  the  features  of  the  different  influences 
of  his  time,  and  sometimes  of  a  slight  trace  of 
mercantilist  views  ;  he  often,  with  a  keen  instinct, 
adopts  the  attitude  of  his  physiocratic  friends, 
without  participating  in  their  extravagances  ;  not 
seldom  one  might  be  inclined  to  ascribe  him  an 
anticipation  of  modern  social  thought.  His  articles, 
moreover,'  are  interesting  as  exhibiting  the  vast 
diflFerence  between  economic  ideas  and  even  terras 
used  nowadays  and  at  the  time  of  their  formation. 
This  may  be  illustrated  by  the  following  extracts  : 

Agriculture  {(Euvres,  t.  xiii.  pp.  243-265)  con- 
tains a  history  of  ancient  and  mediosval  agricul- 
ture, instructions  for  husbandmen  for  each  month  in 
the  year,  and  describes  the  new  English  agri  .altural 
system  of  Jethro  Tull,  as  interpreted  by  Duhamel 
DU  MoNCEAU  (q.v.)  Artisan  (p.  373),  a  man  who  is 
engaged  in  the  mechanical  work  that  needs  the  least 
intelligence.  Balanciers  (p.  408),  gives  a  descrip- 
tion of  the  rules  of  the  corporation  of  makers  of 
weights  and  scales,  and  their  supervision  by  the 

2  P 


578 


DIDEROT 


Cow  des  monnaies.  Tlie  dififerent  meanings  of 
the  terms,  Benefice,  Gain,  Profit,  Lucre,  Emolu- 
ment (p.  425),  of  Besoin,  Necessiti,  Indigence, 
Paumete,  Disette  (p.  478)  are  explained.  Besoin 
(p.  427)  is  described  as  comprising  the  appetites 
of  the  body  and  the  desires  of  the  mind'^  its 
tendency  is  to  lead  primitive  man  on  the  one 
hand  to  a  system  of  associated  life,  on  the  other 
by  the  development  of  artificial  wants  to  bring 
about  the  dissolution  of  society.  The  articles 
Boucher  (p.  489)  and  Boulanger  {p.  498)  contain 
an  account  of  the  regulations,  apprenticeships,  etc. 
of  the  butchers'  and  bakers'  corporations.  In  Brut 
(p.  513)  raw-produce  is  distinguished  from  the 
finished  article.  Change  (t.  xiv.  p.  85)  is  said  to 
relate  to  the  barter  of  movables,  ichange  to  an 
estate,  etc.,  permutation  to  ecclesiastical  dignities. 
"There  are  few  exchanges,  in  which  absolutely 
good  faith  is  preserved  ;  generally  the  two  parties 
seek  to  deceive  each  other."  Chemins  (p.  116)  is 
a  history  of  highway  administration  in  Europe. 
Co-op^raieur  (p.  225) :  "  this  term  is  much  more 
frequently  used  in  theological  matters  than  in  any 
other."  Almost  the  same  moral  significance  is 
attached  to  the  word  Credit  (p.  240),  in  which 
reference  is  only  made  to  the  work  of  Duclos, 
Considerations  sur  les  Mceurs.  A  vindication  of 
the  natural  rights  of  mankind  is  contained  in 
Droit  Natwrd  (p.  296).  The  study  of  the  rules 
of  husbandry  is  recommended  in  an  article  on 
ilconomie  Rustique  ( p.  3  7  8 ) .  (Fondation,  although 
inserted  in  CEuvres,  t.  xv.  p.  12,  is  by  Turgot,  see 
the  Encyclopedie,  1757,  t.  vii.  p.  14).  Hoinme 
{Politique,  t.  xv.  p.  139)  the  pith  of  this  article  is 
derived  from  an  article  by  Quesnay,  which  the 
latter  had  suppressed.  The  existence  of  this  was 
recently  discovered  by  Dr.  S.  Bauer.  "The  wealth 
of  a  nation  is  the  produce  of  the  sum  total  of  its 
labours,  after  the  cost  of  labour  has  been  deducted. 
The  greater  the  net  produce  and  the  more  equal 
its  distribution,  the  better  the  administration. 
As  long  as  there  is  land  lying  waste,  a  man  is 
employed  to  disadvantage  in  manufacture.  The 
number  of  domestic  servants,  and  of  producers  of 
luxuries,  should  be  diminished.  The  maxim  that 
an  increase  of  comfort  among  the  agricultural 
classes  would  remove  a  spur  to  industry  is  the 
saying  of  an  ignorant  and  malignant  man.  The 
hope  of  living  the  life  that  a  man  longs  for,  urges 
him  to  his  particular  occupation,"  etc.  Honoraire 
(p.  140)  a  term  used  for  the  remuneration  of 
liberal  professions,  appointements  for  all  posts, 
gage  for  servants,  gage  for  soldiers,  salaire  for 
working  men.  Htpital  {ibid.),  deals  with  the  ad- 
ministration of  almshouses  and  hospitals.  In  this 
article,  to  quote  Mr.  Morley,  "  Diderot  struck  a 
keynote  of  diff'erence  between  the  old  Catholic 
spirit  and  the  new  social  spirit."  "It  would  be 
far  more  important  to  work  at  the  prevention  of 
misery  than  to  multiply  places  of  refuge  for  the 
miserable."  The  spirit  of  Rousseau  seems  to 
have  inspired  the  following  article :  Indigent  (p. 
204),  "a  man  who,  wanting  the  necessaries  of 
life,  exists  in  the  midst  of  his  fellow-citizens,  who 
exult  over  him  with  insolent  luxury,  rioting  in  the 
enjoyment  of  all  possible  superfluities.  Indigence 
is  not  a  vice,  it  is  worse  than  that.  There  are 
none  indigent  among  savages."     A  modem  line  of 


thought  pervades  the  notice  oi  Joumalier  {p.  314), 
* '  This  class  of  man  forms  the  greater  part  of  a 
nation  ;  a  good  government  ought  to  keep  his  lot 
principally  in  view.  Whenever  the  day  labourer 
is  miserable,  the  nation  is  miserable."  The  eulogy 
of  competition  is  contained  in  Lahorieux  (p.  406), 
"  Name  a  price,  and  competition  will  ensue ;  taxes 
and  despotic  government  annihilate  industry  by 
rendering  their  fruits  uncertain."  Lahowreur 
{Economie  Rustique,  p.  407)  again  brings  back 
reminiscences  of  Quesnay  :  "  Unhappy  the  nation 
in  which  the  farmers  are  poor,  for  agriculture 
greatly  needs  improvement.  Wherever  the 
corn  trade  is  restricted,  the  reduction  of  price 
falls  heavily  upon  the  cultivators  of  the  soil ; 
arbitrary  taxes,  moreover,  reduce  their  earnings 
and  obstruct  the  flow  of  national  revenue."  Like 
Rousseau,  in  the  article  Legislateur  (p.  427)  he 
admonishes  princes  to  visit  the  houses  of  the 
labouring  poor,  and  pleads  in  Legislation  (p.  436), 
for  the  simplest  legislation  and  the  system  the 
most  consonant  to  nature,  by  which  the  passions 
of  men  should  not  only  be  curbed,  but  directed  to 
advancing  both  private  and  public  interest.  The 
legislator  must  take  care  that  the  expenses  of 
associated  life  shall  fall  upon  the  rich,  who  enjoy 
the  corresponding  advantages  (see  Mr.  Morley's 
Diderot,  vol.  i.  p.  243-246).  In  the  article,  L/uxe 
{Morale  et  Philosophic,  vol.  rvi.  p.  5),  Diderot 
displays  his  utmost  ingenuity.  After  having 
refuted  by  historical  examples  all  sweeping  pro- 
positions for  and  against  luxury,  he  explains  it  to 
be  a  natural  outcome  of  civilisation  and  not  a 
necessary  cause  of  the  decline  of  empires.  Luxury 
must  be  in  proportion  to  the  general  production. 
"  There  was  more  luxury  in  the  years  of  magni- 
ficence of  Louis  XIV.'s  reign  than  in  1720,  and  in 
1720  this  luxury  was  more  excessive."  Luxury 
turns  away  attention  from  agriculture,  and  the 
privileges  granted  to  the  producers  of  luxuries 
create  an  artificial  irregularity  of  distribution  ; 
luxury  easily  escapes  taxation,  and  the  "  nouveaux 
riches,"  indulging  in  it,  demoralise  society.  The 
remedies  against  luxury  consist  in  its  gradual 
diffusion,  and  in  the  abolition  of  its  privileges. 
The  article  closes  with  the  admirable  sentence : 
"Jeprie  les  lecteurs  de  se  depouiller  egalement 
des  prejuges  de  Sparte  et  de  Sybaris  ;  et  dans 
I'application  qu'ils  pourraient  faire,  a  leur  si^cle 
ou  k  leur  nation,  de  quelques  traits  repandus  dans 
cet  ouvrage,  je  les  prie  de  vouloir  bien,  ainsi  que 
moi,  voir  leur  nation  et  leur  siecle  sans  des  pre- 
ventions trop  ou  trop  peu  favorables,  et  sans 
enthousiasme,  comme  sans  humeur"  (p.  30). 
Modem  ideas  and  Rousseauism  are  intermingled 
in  Misere  (p.  119),  "The  poor  common  people  are 
incredibly  stupid.  I  know  not  what  false  pre- 
possession closes  1;Jieir  eyes  to  their  present 
wretchedness,  and  to  the  still  deeper  wretchedness 
that  awaits  their  years  of  old  age.  Misery  is  the 
mother  of  crime.  It  is  rulers  who  make  men 
miserable,  and  it  is  they  who  shall  answer  in  this 
world  and  the  next  for  the  crimes  that  misery  has 
caused."  He  remarks  in  the  same  spirit  on  Opu- 
lence (p.  171),  "  It  is  but  seldom  that  this  does  not 
augment  the  natural  malignity  of  mankind,  and 
that  it  increases  happiness."  Propriety  {p.  439) 
is  shown  to  be  a  condition  of  security — security 


DIETERICI— DIFFICULTY  OF  ATTAINMENT 


579 


was  the  aim  of  men  in  forming  societies  ;  taxes 
the  means  to  uphold  them.  Where  a  king  pre- 
tends to  be  the  sole  proprietor  of  the  goods  of  his 
subjects,  anybody  may  become  king  by  force, 
ProstituSe  (p.  440)  is  explained  almost  only  in  the 
figurative  sense  as  applied  to  mercenary  writers. 
In  Representants  the  usefulness  of  representatives 
of  the  "nation"  in  the  vfa.y  of  advising  the  king 
are  explained.  All  "  citoyens  "  ought  to  choose 
men  as  representatives,  who  are  qualified  to  be  so 
by  reason  of  their  property  or  their  knowledge  of 
the  interests  of  the  people.  Members  from  the 
ranks  of  the  clergy,  the  nobility,  the  magistracy, 
merchants  and  cultivators  of  the  soil,  should  be 
chosen  for  these  assemblies.  Diderot's  opinions, 
one  sees,  are  on  this  point  more  akin  to  the 
doctrines  of  the  physiocrats,  and  to  those  of 
continental  liberalism,  than  to  those  of  modern 
democracy.  The  article  on  Souverains  (p.  166) 
does  not  go  beyond  the  current  theory  of  social 
contract  and  renunciation  of  natural  rights.  In 
Societe  (p.  130)  Diderot  proclaims  the  principle  of 
seeking  the  common  good  of  all,  not  only  as  the 
supreme,  but  as  the  universal  rule  of  conduct. 

After  the  completion  of  the  Encydopedie, 
Diderot  wrote  some  pamphlets  which  evince  his 
unceasing  interest  in  free  enterprise.  In  the 
Lettre  historique  et  politique  adressee  d  un 
Magistral  sur  le  Commerce  de  la  Librairie,  1767 
{(Euwes,  t.  xviii.  p.  7)  he  admits  that  "he  would 
consider  the  entire  and  absolute  abolition  of 
corporations  as  a  step  towards  a  wiser  govern- 
ment." Three  are  many  strikingly  characteristic 
remarks  on  commercial  and  economic  life  in  his 
Voyage  de  Ifollande,  1774  [CEuvres,  t.  xvii.  pp. 
406-468).  There  are  besides  in  his  Fragments 
politiques  scattered  ideas  about  the  dangers  of  a 
sudden  influx  of  the  precious  metals  {ibid.  t.  iv. 
pp.  41-50).  His  work  Man  per e  et  moi  concludes 
with  an  idea  of  statistics  of  the  distribution  of  in- 
come, and  the  postulate  of  exempting  the  physical 
necessary  from  taxation  (pp.  481-482).  A  highly 
curious  anticipation  of  the  modern  labour  question, 
as  exemplified  by  the  condition  of  the  miners  of 
Saxony,  is  contained  in  the  Refutation  suivie  de 
Vouvrage  d'HdvHius  intituU  V  Homme,  1774-1775 
{(Euvres,  t.  ii.  pp.  430-431). 

[The  passages  above  referred  to  are  quoted  from 
the  (Euvres  completes  de  Diderot,  edited  by  J. 
Assezat  et  M.  Tourneux,  1875-77,  20  vols.  ;  also 
Rosenkranz,  Diderot  (1866) — Morley,  Diderot 
and  the  Encyclopaedists,  2  vols.,  1878,  1891, 
especially  vol.  i.  pp.  177-247. — Du  Bois-Reymond, 
Zu  Diderot's  Qedachtniss,  1884.]  s.  b. 

DIETERICI,  Karl  Friedrich  Wilhelm 
(1790-1859),  a  gi-eat  name  in  statistics,  was 
bom  in  Berlin,  served  under  Bliicher  in  the 
Napoleonic  war,  held  several  public  appoint- 
ments— the  post  of  professor  of  political 
economy  (fiir  Staatswissenschaft)  from  1834, 
that  of  director  of  the  statistical  bureau  in  Berlin 
from  1844 — and  died  in  his  native  city.  His 
virtues  and  amiable  character  are  attested  by 
his  successor  Engel  {Report  of  the  International 
Statistical  Congress  at  London,  1860,  p.  43)  and 
others  who  speak  from  personal  knowledge. 

Both  in  the  spheres  of  political  economy  and 


statistics,  especially  the  latter,  Dieterici  was 
eminent.  In  his  inaugural  professorial  letter 
De  vid  et  ratione  osconomiam  politicam  docendi 
he  distinguishes  the  different  methods  of  culti- 
vating the  science  —  the  philosophical,  the 
juristical,  the  historical  ("Est  historica  via 
oeconomiam  politicam  docendi,"  written  in 
1835)  ;  the  political  or  statistical  method,  of 
which  Humboldt  is  given  as  an  instance  qui 
quantum  auri  et  argcnti  ex  America  in  Europam 
allatum  sit,  quantum  them  consumatur,  aliaque 
similia  accurate  .  .  .  explicavit ;  the  techno- 
logical method,  which  J.  G.  Biiscli  and  Ricardo 
have  followed,  both  praised  for  their  attention 
to  facts  and  experience.  The  true  method  is 
compound  :  et  mere  pMlosophando  et  mere 
experiendo  erratur.  Dieterici  promises  to  unite 
theory  and  experience.  The  facts  are  perhaps 
more  interesting  than  the  theory  in  his  most 
ambitious  contribution  to  economics,  On  Over- 
population (  Uber  den  Begriff  der  Uhervdlkerung, 
Akademie  dei-  Wissenschaften  in  Berlin  ;  Marz, 
1849).  True  to  facts,  experientid  maxime 
fretus  as  he  promised,  Dieterici  enriched  many 
departments  of  statistics.  His  memoir  on 
the  Mean  Duration  of  Life  (Uber  den  Begi'iff 
der  mittleren  Lebensdauer  iind  deren  Bcrcchnung  . 
fiir  den  preussischen  Staat,  Akademie  der 
Wissenschaften  in  Berlin,  December  1858) 
may  be  noticed  among  many  other  valuable 
contributions  to  vital  statistics,  which  will  be 
found  among  the  following  references. 

Die  Waldenser  und  ihre  Verhilltnisse  zum 
Brandenburgisch  -  preussischen  Staate  (1831). — 
Geschichtliche  und  statistische  Uebersicht  der  Uni- 
versitaten  im  preicssischen  Staate  (1836). — Statis- 
tische Uebersicht  der  Wichiigsten  Gegenstiinde  des 
Verkehrs  und  Verbrauchs  im  preussischen  Staate 
und  im  deutschen  Zollverbande  .  .  .  (1838-1857). 
— Statistischen  Tabellen  des  preussischen  Staats 
nach  der  amtlichen  Aufnahme  des  Jahres  1843. 
—  Uebersicht  der  Bodenfache  der  Bevolkerung 
und  des  Viehstandes  der  einzelnen  Kreise  des 
preussischen  Staats  (1845). — Die  Bevolkerung  des 
preussischen  Staats  nach  der  amtlichen  Aufnahme 
des  Jahres  1846  (1848). — Der  Volkswohlstand  im 
preussischen  Staate  .  .  .  (1846).  —  Ueber  Auswan- 
derungen  und  Einwanderungen  (1847).  —  Ueber 
preussische  Zustdnde  uber  Arbeit  und  Kapital 
(1848). — Oeddchtnissrede  (in  honour  of  Fred. 
William  III.),  1852. — Ilandbuchder  Statistik  des 
preussischen  Staats  (1858-61). — Much  of  Dieterici's 
work  is  contained  in  the  periodical  which  he  edited 
from  1848  till  his  death — Mittheilungen  des 
Statistischen  Bureau's  in  Berlin.  The  fourth 
volume  for  1851  contains  the  valuable  essay 
Ueber  den  Begriff  der  Statistik.  [Allgemeine 
Deutsche  Biographic. — Reports  of  the  first  four 
international  statistical  congresses,  passim.] 

F.  T.  B. 

DIFFERENTIAL  DUTIES.  See  Dis- 
criminating Duties. 

DIFFICULTY  OF  ATTAINMENT  is  a 
phrase  used  by  De  Quincey,  Mill,  and  others, 
to  denote  a  condition  which  must  be  superadded 


580 


DIFFICULTY  OF  ATTAINMENT 


to  utility  in  order  that  there  should  exist  value 
in  exchange.  **  Any  article  whatever,  to  obtain 
that  artificial  sort  of  value  which  is  meant  by 
exchange  value,  must  begin  by  offering  itself 
as  a  means  to  some  desirable  purpose  ;  and 
secondly,  even  though  possessing  incontestably 
this  preliminary  advantage,  it  will  never  ascend 
to  an  exchange  value  in  cases  where  it  can  be 
obtained  gratuitously  and  without  effort "  (De 
Quincey,  Logic  of  Political  Economy ,  p.  13; 
quoted  by  Mill,  Pol.  JEcon.,  bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.  §  1). 
The  difficulty  of  attainment  here  indicated  is 
primarily  that  which  is  experienced  by  the 
purchaser.  But  it  is  usual  to  extend  the  term 
to  the  diffi:culty  experienced  by  the  producer. 
Thus  De  Quincey  continues :  "Walk  into  almost 
any  possible  shop,  buy  the  first  article  you  see  ; 
what  will  determine  its  price  ?  In  the  ninety- 
nine  cases  out  of  a  hundred  simply  .  .  .  diffi- 
culty of  attainment.  ...  If  the  difficulty  of 
producing  it  be  only  worth  one  guinea,  one 
guinea  is  the  price  which  it  will  bear."  So 
Mill,  of  what  he  considers  the  general  case, 
"the  obstacle  to  attainment  consists  only  in 
the  labour  and  expense  necessary  to  produce 
the  commodity  "  (loe.  cit,  §  2).  And  by  others 
difficulty  of  attainment  is  used  as  equivalent  to 
cost  of  production.  Thus  Walker  (First  Lesson 
in  Political  Economy,  Art.  67),  "Cost  of  pro- 
duction is  only  another  name  for  difficulty  of 
attainment."  This  transition  from  the  sense  in 
which  the  difficulty,  like  the  other  factor 
utility,  is  experienced  by  the  individual  pur- 
chaser is  legitimate,  where  there  exists  such 
perfect  "industrial"  Competition  that  it  is 
free  to  any  one  to  enter  any  occupation.  In 
that  case  the  sacrifice  made  to  attain  a  com- 
modity by  purchase  tends  to  be  equivalent 
to  the  efforts  and  sacrifices  made  in  attain- 
ing it  by  production.  If  the  value  in  ex- 
change were  higher,  the  commodity  would 
not  be  purchased  ;  if  lower,  it  would  not  be 
produced. 

The  wider  conception  is  particularly  appro- 
priate to  the  case  which  Mill,  dividing  the 
different  kinds  of  difficulty,  places  second ; 
where,  "without  a  certain  labour  and  expense 
it  [the  commodity]  cannot  be  had  ;  but,  when 
any  one  is  willing  to  incur  this,  there  needs  be 
no  limit  to  the  multiplication  of  the  product " 
...  up  to  a  point  which  there  is  no  need,  for 
practical  purposes,  to  contemplate  {Pol.  Econ., 
bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.  §  1).  In  this  case  difficulty  of 
production  has  a  certain  pre-eminence  over  the 
co-factor  utility,  both  as  (a)  a  cause,  and  (&)  a 
measure  of  value,  (a)  The  cause  of  a  phe- 
nomenon being  usually  -a.  somewhat  arbitrarily 
selected  portion  of  its  total  antecedent  (Mill, 
Logic,  bk.  iii.  ch.  v.  §  3;  Venn,  Empirical  Logic, 
p.  57  et  seq.),  it  is  not  paradoxical  that  some- 
times utility,  sometimes  cost,  should  be  regarded 
as  the  cause  of  value.  Utility  indeed  is 
invariably   an   antecedent.      But  the  scale  of 


utility  (see  Demand  Curves),  may,  in  the  case 
supposed,  be  varied  without  any  variation  of 
value.  "If  the  demand  for  hats  should  be 
doubled,  the  price  would  immediately  rise ; 
but  that  rise  would  be  only  temporary,  unless 
the  cost  of  production  of  hats  .  .  .  were  raised" 
(Ricardo,  Pol.  Econ.,  ch.  xxx.)  Whereas,  if 
the  cost  of  production  of  an  article  is  varied,  j 

its  value   varies   concomitantly.       "Diminish  I 

the  cost  of  production  of  hats,  and  their  price  i 

will  ultimately  fall  to  their  new  natural  price,  | 

although  the  demand  should  be  doubled, 
trebled,  or  quadrupled"  (Ricardo,  ibid.)  Pre- 
diction, the  prerogative  of  causation,  is 
attached  to  cost  rather  than  utility.  (b) 
Accordingly,  in  the  case  supposed,  the  compara- 
tive difficulty  of  producing  two  commodities 
affords  a  simple  measure  of  their  relative  value. 
It  is  true  also  that  value  is  proportioned  to 
final  utility.  But  this  measure  cannot  be  read 
until  the  measurement  is  ah-eady  given.  We 
cannot  tell  what  the  final  utilities  will  be  till 
we  know  the  values.  In  some  cases  indeed 
(see  below  (4)  and  (5))  it  is  conceivable  that, 
given  the  dispositions,  the  Demand -Curves 
of  all  the  dealers  in  a  market,  we  could  deduce 
the  rate  of  exchange  which  will  be  set  up.  The 
calculation  is  indicated  by  Professor  Walras 
in  his  Aliments  d'l^conomie  Politique  Pure,  Art. 
50.  Still  difficulty  of  production,  in  the  case 
most  favourable  to  its  operation,  measures 
value  directly,  as  a  clock  measures  time ; 
whereas  utility  at  best  is  a  measure  like  the 
shadow  cast  by  the  sun,  which  can  only  be 
interpreted  by  a  difficult  calculation. 

This  theory  is  subject  to  several  reservations 
and  exceptions.  (1)  The  pre-eminence  of  diffi- 
culty of  production  as  a  regulator  of  value 
depends  largely  on  the  assumption  that  labour  is 
perfectly  homogeneous.  If  all  labour  consisted 
of  raising  weights  in  precisely  similar  circum- 
stances, the  theory  might  be  literally  true. 
"  If  ...  it  usually  cost  twice  the  labour  to  kiU 
a  beaver  which  it  does  to  kill  a  deer,  one  beaver 
should  naturally  exchange  for  or  be  worth  two 
deer  "  (Adam  Smith,  quoted  by  Ricardo),  there 
being  only  one  mode  of  labour,  work  being  as 
homogeneous  as,  say,  gold.  But  suppose, 
besides  effort  of  exertion,  the  sacrifice  of  waiting 
is  required.  Then,  as  between  commodities  in- 
volving these  elements  in  different  proportions 
(cp.  Ricardo,  ch.  i.  §  4),  it  would  no  longer  be 
possible  to  assign  the  rate  of  exchange  between 
the  commodities  without  being  given  the  com- 
parative remuneration  for  the  two  kinds  of 
sacrifice.  But  this  datum  could  not  in  general 
be  obtained  a  priori,  but  only  as  a  result  of 
the  higgling  of  the  market.  ^    Now,  in  fact,  there 

1  This  reservation  holds  even  upon  the  imaginary 
supposition  that  there  existed  a  competition  so  perfect 
that  it  is  free  to  any  one  to  choose  whether  he  will 
labour  or  abstain,  a  fortiori,  when,  as  in  reality  the 
abstainers  form  a  "non-competing  group";  and  so  fall 
under  head  (8). 


DlFb'ICULTY  OF  ATTAINMENT 


581 


are  not  only  two,  but  many,  kinds  of  sacrifice. 
The  general  principle  is  that  the  "net  advan- 
tages "  (Marshall,  Principles  of  Ecmiortiics,  vol.  i. 
2nd  ed.  p.  136)  in  occupations  between  which 
there  is  "industrial  competition"  (Caimes),  tend 
to  be  equal.  Accordingly  the  statement  that  the 
"quantity  of  labour  realised  in  commodities" 
(Ricardo)  regulates  their  exchangeable  value, 
can  be  true  only  on  an  average  with  wide  devia- 
tions. Take  the  case  put  by  De  Quincey  of  a 
pearl-diver  who  sometimes  obtains,  along  with 
'  *  ordinary, "  superior  pearls.  The  true  principle 
is  that  the  net  advantages  of  pearl-diving  are 
the  same  as  those  of  any  other  occupations  be- 
tween which  there  is  industrial  competition. 
How  much  truth  is  there  in  the  proposition 
that  the  value  of  any  pearl  is  proportioned  to 
the  "quantity  of  labour  realised"  in  it?  The 
instance  taken  is  a  mild  case  of  plural  occupa- 
tions, or  joint  production  (see  By-Pkoduct), 
The  application  of  the  general  principle  of  net 
advantages  here  affords  little  light  as  to  the 
value  of  particular  articles  (cp.  Sidgwick,  Pol. 
Econ.,  bk.  ii.  ch.  ii.  §  10). 

(2)  The  pre-eminence  of  difficulty  over 
utility,  as  a  regulator  of  value,  disappears  alto- 
gether when  we  pass  from  Mill's  second  case  to 
a  category  comprising  both  Mill's  third  case 
(Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.  §  2),  in  which  the 
cost  of  production  increases  with  the  quantity 
produced,  according  to  the  law  of  Diminishing 
Returns  {q.v.),  and  the  converse  case,  in  which 
the  cost  of  production  diminishes  with  the 
quantity  produced  according  to  the  law  of 
Increasing  Returns  {q.v.)  In  this  case  the 
two  factors,  utility  and  value,  become  co- 
ordinate. As  Professor  Marsliall  says  {Eco- 
nomics of  Lidustry,  Isted.  p.  148),  "the  amount 
produced  and  its  normal  value  are  to  be  re- 
garded as  determined  simultaneously  under  the 
action  of  economic  laws.  It  is  then  incorrect 
to  say,  as  Ricardo  did,  that  cost  of  production 
alone  determines  values  ;  but  it  is  no  less  in- 
correct to  make  utility  alone,  as  others  have 
done,  the  basis  of  value."  With  reference  to 
what  Jevons  calls  the  "mechanics  of  industry" 
it  seems  trifling  to  inquire  whether  the  force 
or  the  resistance  conti'ibutes  more  to  the  deter- 
mination of  equilibrium.  The  simuUaneoiisiiess 
of  the  two  conditions  is  indicated  by  Jevons  in 
his  discussion  of  cost  of  production  {Theory, 
ch.  V.)  Jevons  there  entertains  the  unreal 
conception  that  it  is  free  to  the  producer  to 
apply  his  efforts  in  "doses"  to  different  kinds  of 
production.  This  at  most  is  true  of  the  mere 
inventor  as  distinguished  from  the  entrepreneur 
and  operative.  Still  the  conception  may  be 
usefully  employed  as  symbolical  of  the  actual 
working  of  competition  in  a  regime  of  division 
of  labour  (Pantaleoni,  Principii.  Theorema  di 
liicardo  ed  Marshall).  The  simultaneousness 
of  the  two  conditions  may  best  be  shown  by 
imagining  the  disutility,  as  well  as  the  utility, 


to  be  of  the  sort  called  * '  final "  (see  Mathb- 
MATiCAL  Method). 

(3)  The  co-ordinateness  of  difficulty  of  pro- 
duction with  utility  disappears  when  industrial 
competition  is  no  longer  supposed.  In  this 
case  the  assumed  equation  between  the  pur- 
chaser's and  the  producer's  difficulty  of  attain- 
ment fails.  The  typical  instance  is  inter- 
national trade.  There  is  no  correspondence 
between  the  efforts  of  the  Chinese  producer  of 
tea  and  the  sacrifices  which  the  English  pur- 
chaser incurs  to  obtain  it.  It  is  pointed  out 
by  Cairues  that  the  principle  of  international 
trade  governs  domestic  industry  where  "non- 
competing  groups"  exist.  With  reference  to 
this  case,  as  well  as  the  preceding,  Dr.  Sidg- 
wick justly  says:  "It  is  not  merely  incon- 
sistent with  facts  but  with  other  parts  of  Mill's 
teaching,  to  say  broadly  that  *  the  value  of 
things  which  can  be  increased  at  pleasm-e  does 
not  depend  .  .  .  upon  demand'"  {Pol.  Econ., 
bk.  ii.  ch.  ii.  §  9).  In  this  case  the  value  of  an 
article  is  proportioned  to  its  final  utility  for  the 
purchaser  in  the  same  sense  as  in  the  preceding 
cases.  But  it  is  not  proportioned  to  the  diffi- 
culty of  attainment  in  the  same  sense. 

(4)  The  co-ordinateness  of  difficulty  of  pro- 
duction with  utility  is  not  even  supposable, 
when  we  pass  to  another  category.  Mill's  first : 
"things  of  which  it  is  i)hysically  impossible  to 
increase  the  quantity  beyond  certain  narrow 
limits;"  such  as  "ancient  sculptures"  .  .  . 
"rare  books  or  coins"  .  .  .  "houses  and 
building- ground  in  a  town  of  definite  extent," 
and  "potentially  all  land  whatever"  {Pol. 
Econ.,  bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.  §  2). 

(5)  With  MlLI's  first  class  go  those  com- 
modities which  are  temporarily  ' '  unsusceptible 
of  increase  of  supply  "  {ibid.  §  5)  ;  in  short  all 
cases  of  ]\Iarket  as  distinguished  from  Normal 
Value  (see  Value). 

(6)  Lastly,  all  cases  of  monopoly  must  be 
excepted  from  the  sphere  Avithin  which  the 
difticulty  of  attainment  experienced  by  the 
purchaser  is  equateable  with  the  difficulty  of 
production.  Outside  this  sphere  the  difficulty 
experienced  by  the  purchaser  is  due  to  the 
niggardliness  of  his  fellow-man,  ratlier  than  the 
stubbornness  of  nature  ;  and  is  measured  only 
by  his  own  reluctance  to  part  with  some  useful 
commodity,  and  not  also  by  his  (potential) 
effort  in  producing  the  article  pm'chased. 

It  is  easier  to  refine  upon  these  logical  dis- 
tinctions than  to  prove  what  is  the  relative 
extent  and  importance  of  the  categories  defined ; 
which  conception,  if  any,  may  be  taken  as 
typical  of  the  facts.  This  is  a  matter  of  judg- 
ment rather  than  demonstration  ;  about  which 
there  is  much  disagreement  between  economists 
of  the  last  and  the  present  generation.  The 
case  which  one  treats  as  the  general  rule, 
another  treats  as  exceptional  or  non-existent. 
Mill  speaks  of  his  second  category  as  "embrao- 


582 


DIFFUSION  THEORY  OF  TAXATION— DIME 


ing  the  majority  of  all  things  that  are  bought 
and  sold"  {P.  K,  bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.  §  2).  To  the 
same  effect  Ricardo  on  the  very  first  page  of  his 
Principles.  The  reservations  which  are  here  in- 
dicated under  heading  (1)  are  waived  by  Ricdrdo. 
Of  the  effect  of  the  rate  of  profits  on  value  he 
says,  *'  the  reader  "  however  should  remark  that 
this  cause  of  the  variation  of  commodities  is  com- 
paratively slight  in  its  effects  "  (ibid.  ch.  i.  §  iv.) 
The  difficulties  caused  by  the  difierence  in  the 
qualities  of  labour  he  dismisses  in  a  few  sen- 
tences (ch.  i.)  The  extreme  recoil  from  Ricardo's 
position  is  marked  by  the  Austrian  School 
(q.v.),  who  emphasise  utility  as  the  determining 
principle  of  value,  and  assign  quite  a  secondary 
place  to  Cost.  See  especially  Professor  Wieser, 
Ueber  den  Ursprung  .  .  .  des  wirthschaftlichen 
Werths;  and  Dr.  Bohm-Bawerk,  Kapital  und 
Kapitalzins,  interpreted  by  Mr.  James  Bonar  in 
the  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics,  October 
1888,  January  1889.  In  this  attitude  they  had 
been  anticipated  by  Jevons.  But  Jevons,  as  has 
been  shown,  admitted  cost  of  production  as  a 
simultaneous  factor.  The  simultaneousness  of 
the  two  conditions  in  a  regime  of  industrial 
competition  has  been  defended  by  the  present 
writer  in  the  Eevue  d'^conomie  Politique  for 
October  1890.  In  fine  there  are  those  who  re- 
gard all  abstract  theory  as  futile  (see  the  His- 
torical School).  Cliffe  Leslie  and  Held 
(q.v.),  Brentano  and  others,  harp  on  the  un- 
reality of  the  Ricardian  assumptions.  Neumann's 
article  on  prices  in  Schonberg's  Handbuch 
teems  with  cases  which  it  is  difficult  to  recon- 
cile with  any  theory  of  the  relation  between 
value  and  difficulty  of  attainment.       f.  y.  e. 

DIFFUSION  THEORY  OF  TAXATION. 
This  is  the  name  given  {e.g.  by  Mr.  F.  A. 
Walker,  Pol.  Econ.,  §  485)  to  the  theory  that 
the  individuals  from  whom  a  tax  on  a  particular 
kind  of  commodity,  exchange,  or  occupation, 
is  actually  levied  do  not  ultimately  bear  the 
burden,  but  shift  it  on  to  other  classes,  so  that 
the  tax  is  "diffused"  or  spread  over  a  large 
area  (see  Taxation).  e.  c. 

DIGGES,  Sir  Dudley  (1583-1639),  director 
of  the  East  India  Company,  was  one  of  the 
ablest  defenders  of  that  society.  The  loss, 
near  Bantam,  in  1613,  of  the  Trades  Increase, 
gave  rise  to  an  anonymous  pamphlet  (the 
Trades  Increase,  by  J.  R,  Lond.,  1615)  in 
which  the  author,  while  strongly  objecting  to 
all  the  then  existing  trading  companies  (see 
Foreign  Trade,  Regulation  of),  made  an 
especially  violent  attack  on  the  East  India 
Company,  to  whom  that  vessel  belonged.  He 
accused  them  of  restricting  the  supply  of  East 
India  commodities  and  of  other  objectionable 
practices,  and  maintained  that  their  trade  led 
to  the  diminution  of  the  naval  strength  of  the 
kingdom.  The  Company  wished  to  prosecute 
the  author  in  the  Star  Chamber,  as  some  parts 
of  the  book  were  held  to  be   "very  near  to 


treason  and  all  the  rest  very  dangerous." 
(Court  Minutes,  22nd  Feb.  1616).  Sir  Dudley 
Digges,  however,  was  of  opinion  that  a  book 
should  be  put  forth  refuting  the  charges  brought 
against  the  Company.  He  accordingly  pub- 
lished The  Defence  of  Trade :  in  a  letter  to  Sir 
Thomas  Smith,  Knight,  Governor  of  the  Hast 
India  Company,  From  one  of  that  Society, 
Lond.,  1615.  In  this  pamphlet  he  replied  to 
the  objections  to  the  Company  which  were  based 
upon  the  risks  of  the  trade,  the  frequent  loss 
of  ships  and  men,  and  the  consequent  decrease 
of  the  naval  strength  of  the  country.  He  also 
maintained  that  the  East  India  trade  "in- 
creased the  stock  of  the  kingdom  "  (p.  43),  and 
pointed  out  the  fall  in  the  prices  of  East  India 
goods  since  the  formation  of  the  Company. 

[State  Papers  Colonial  (East  Indies)  1610-15 
passim.  For  full  details  of  the  life  of  Sir  Dudley 
Digges,  vide  Diet.  Nat.  Biog.]  w.  a.  s.  H. 

DILIGENCE  (Scot.)  (1)  Care  in  regard 
to  the  subject-matter  of  a  contract ;  (2)  the 
procedure  of  the  court  whereby  witnesses  are 
made  to  attend  or  documents  caused  to  be  pro- 
duced ;  (3)  attachment  of  person  or  property 
at  the  instance  of  creditors  to  enforce  satisfac- 
tion of  a  debt  or  obligation.  A.  D. 

In  English  business  phraseology  due  dilig- 
ence is  an  expression  denoting  the  care  which 
persons  who  have  undertaken  certain  duties 
with  reference  to  the  performance  of  work 
or  the  custody  of  goods  must  bestow  on  such 
work  or  sucli  custody.  The  amount  of  care 
to  be  given  depends  on  the  nature  of  the  con- 
tract. When  a  reward  is  given  or  promised, 
such  "care  and  diligence  are  expected  as  are 
exercised  in  the  ordinary  and  proper  course  of 
similar  business,  and  such  skill "  as  the  person 
who  undertook  the  work  or  the  custody  "  ought 
to  have,  namely,  the  skill  usual  and  requisite 
in  the  business  for  which  he  receives  payment." 
When  no  reward  is  given  or  promised,  the  care 
usually  given  to  one's  own  afiairs  is  sufficient. 

e.  s. 

DILIGENTIA.  Expression  of  Roman  law 
for  the  care  which  was  required  in  certain 
relations  created  by  contract  or  otherwise.  The 
degree  of  diligence  required  varied  according  to 
the  circumstances  of  the  case.  Sometimes  it 
was  sufficient  to  give  the  care  which  the  person 
concerned  gives  to  his  own  affairs  ("  dU.  quam 
suis  rebus  adhibere  solet ") ;  sometimes  the 
diligence  of  a  careful  householder  ("dil.  boni 
patrisfamilias  ")  was  necessary.  e.  s. 

DIME.  United  States  silver  token  coin : 
nominal  value  ten  cents.  First  struck  in  1796, 
weight  41-6  grains,  fineness  892*4.  Altered 
in  1837  to  weight  41*25  grains,  fineness  900. 
Weight  again  reduced  in  1853  to  38*4  grains, 
and  fixed  in  1873  at  38*58  grains.  English 
standard  value  (silver  925  fine  at  5s.  6d.  an 
ounce)  5*16d.  Value  in  silver  francs,  900  fine, 
*5  franc.  F.  E.  A. 


DIME  KOYALE— DIMENSIONS  OF  ECONOMIC  QUANTITIES         583 


DiME  ROYALE.  In  1707,  at  the  most 
disastrous  period  of  the  war  of  the  Spanish 
Succession,  the  famous  Marshal  Vauban  pub- 
lished his  Projet  d'une  dime  royale,  which 
remains  the  most  memorable  contemporary 
impeachment  of  the  French  financial  system 
under  the  monarchy.  In  his  engineering  tours 
about  France,  Vauban  had  carefully  studied  the 
condition  of  the  agricultural  classes,  and  had 
arrived  at  the  most  gloomy  conclusions.  "  One- 
tenth  of  the  people  has  fallen  in  recent  years 
into  beggary  ;  five  other  tenths  cannot  afford 
an  alms  to  the  paupers,  because  they  are  on 
the  verge  of  beggary  themselves ;  of  the 
remaining  four -tenths,  three  are  in  a  bad 
condition,  overwhelmed  with  debts  and  litiga- 
tion ;  while  of  the  remaining  tenth  barely 
10,000  families  can  be  called  really  rich." 
For  this  deplorable  state  of  things  the  financial 
system  is  mainly  responsible,  and  of  this 
system  the  most  glaring  defects  are  the 
innumerable  exemptions  from  payment  and  the 
practice  of  farming  out  the  taxes,  by  which 
the  great  capitalists  make  a  fortune  at  the 
expense  of  the  people.  Vauban  reckoned  no 
less  than  eighteen  classes  of  persons  who  were 
exempt  from  the  taille  and  other  taxes.  The 
exemptions  were  due  in  great  measure  to  the 
practice  of  selling  offices,  which  had  grown  up 
in  the  15th  century.  To  make  them  valuable, 
the  monarchy  had  parted  with  the  right  of 
removal,  thus  losing  control  over  its  own 
servants.  When  they  could  no  longer  be 
trusted,  their  functions  were  given  to  a  new 
set  of  officials  :  these  in  their  turn  bought  their 
places,  became  useless,  and  were  superseded  by 
new  agents.  The  result  was  the  existence  in 
France  of  an  enormous  number  of  useless 
officials,  while  the  real  work  was  done  by  the 
intendants  and  their  agents.  An  office  without 
functions  was  worth  buying,  because  it  freed  its 
holder  from  direct  taxation.  Thus  the  sale  of 
offices  created  a  vast  disguised  public  debt,  the 
amount  of  which  was  as  difficult  to  estimate  as 
were  the  ruinous  terms  on  which  it  was  con- 
tracted. It  resulted  that  the  contributors  to 
direct  taxation  were  those  who  could  not  afi'ord 
to  purchase  exemption.  The  indirect  taxes, 
the  aides  (see  Aides,  Cour  des),  and  the  gabelle, 
were  as  ruinous  to  industry,  if  not  so  glaringly 
unfair  in  their  incidence,  as  the  taille. 

Vauban's  remedy  for  the  evils  which  he 
depicts  was  to  abolish  the  existing  taxes,  and 
to  substitute  one  single  impost,  levied  directly 
upon  real  and  personal  property,  from  which 
no  class  was  to  be  exempt.  This  dime  royale, 
etc.,  was  to  be  graduated,  varying  from  a 
twentieth  to  a  tenth  of  income,  and  was  to  be 
collected  directly  by  agents  of  the  government. 
The  suggestion  of  a  reform  which  attached  so 
many  vested  interests,  and  the  masterly 
exposure  of  profitable  abuses,  were  enough  to 
obliterate  in  the  minds  of  Louis  XIV.  and  his 


ministers  the  services  of  the  veteran  marshal, 
now  in  his  seventy- fourth  year.  The  council 
issued  a  decree  ordering  the  book  to  be  con- 
fiscated, and  prohibiting  its  sale  under  a  fine  of 
1000  francs.  On  24th  March  1707,  Vauban 
received  the  news  of  the  confiscation  of  his 
book  ;  on  the  30th  he  died,  broken-hearted  at 
the  ingratitude  of  a  sovereign  whom  he  had 
served  only  too  weU. 

The  Projet  d'une  dime  royale  which  has  fre- 
quently been  published  separately,  may  also  be 
found  in  Daire,  J^conomistes  financiers  du 
XVllP^"  Steele,  vol.  i.  p.  33.  r.  l. 

DIMENSIONS  OF  ECONOMIC  QUANTI- 
TIES. A  unit  is  a  concrete  magnitude  selected 
as  a  standard  by  reference  to  which  other 
magnitudes  of  the  same  kind  may  be  compared. 
A  derived  unit  is  a  unit  determined  with  refer- 
ence to  some  other  unit.  Thus  the  unit  of  area 
may  be  derived  from  the  unit  of  length  by  being 
defined  as  the  area  of  the  square,  erected  on 
the  unit  of  length.  The  unit  of  speed  may  be 
derived  from  the  unit  of  length  and  the  unit 
of  time,  by  being  defined  as  that  speed  at  which 
the  unit  of  length  is  traversed  in  the  unit  of 
time.  In  relation  to  the  derived  units  of  area 
and  speed,  the  units  of  length  and  time  would 
then  be  fundamental, — "fundamental"  being  a 
term  correlative  to  "derived." 

The  theory  of  dimensions  is  concerned  with 
"the  laws  according  to  which  derived  units 
vary  when  fundamental  units  are  changed" 
(Everett).  A  fundamental  unit,  together  with 
the  magnitudes  of  like  kind  referred  to  it,  is 
regarded  as  having  one  dimension.  Thus  a 
length  has  the  dimension  L.  The  unit  of  length 
enters  twice  into  the  unit  of  area,  first  deter- 
mining the  base  and  then  the  altitude  of  the 
unit  rectangle,  and  therefore  the  dimensions  of 
an  area  are  LL,  usually  written  \?.  If  we  alter 
the  unit  of  length,  say  from  a  foot  to  an  inch 
(1:12)  the  unit  of  area  wiU  be  reduced  in  the 
same  ratio  twice  successively  (1  :  144  in  all). 
The  variations  of  the  unit  of  area,  therefore, 
are  directly  as  the  squares  of  the  variations  in 
the  unit  of  length.  The  units  of  length  and 
of  time  enter  once  each  into  the  unit  of  speed, 
but  they  do  not  enter  on  the  same  footing.  If 
the  unit  of  time  be  the  minute,  and  the  unit  of 
length  the  foot,  the  unit  of  speed  wiU  be  a  foot 
per  mihute.  This  unit  will  become  smaller  if 
we  make  the  unit  of  length  smaller,  since  an 
inch  per  minute  is  a  smaller  speed  than  a  foot  per 
minute  ;  but  it  will  become  larger  if  we  make 
the  unit  of  time  smaller,  a  foot  a  second  being 
a  greater  speed  than  a  foot  a  minute.  This  is 
expressed  by  saying  that  the  dimension  of  time 
T  enters  negatively  into  speed.  The  dimensions 
of  speed,  then,  are  expressed  as  LT~\  A  unit 
into  which  a  dimension  enters  negatively  is 
always  a  unit  of  rate,  and  measures  amount  of 
x'per  unit  of  y, — y  being  the  quantity  the  dimen- 
sion of  which  enters  negatively. 


584 


DIMENSIONS  OF  ECONOMIC  QUANTITIES 


We  have  now  examined  simple  cases  of  the 
variations  of  derived  units,  but  it  is  obvious 
that  the  numerical  values  of  concrete  magnitudes 
vary  inversely  as  the  units  by  reference  to  which 
they  are  estimated.  The  smaller  the  unit,  the 
greater  the  numerical  value  of  any  given  magni- 
tude. The  numerical  value  of  a  magnitude, 
therefore,  will  vary  inversely  as  the  unit  whose 
dimension  enters  into  it  positively,  and  directly 
as  the  unit  whose  dimension  enters  into  it 
negatively.  Thus,  let  the  unit  of  speed 
(dimensions  LT~^)  be  a  foot  per  minute,  and 
let  the  numerical  value  of  a  certain  concrete 
speed  be  10,  i.e.  let  the  speed  be  ten  feet  per 
minute.  Then  change  the  unit  of  length  to 
an  inch  (1  :  12)  and  the  unit  of  time  to  a  second 
(1  :  60)  ;  the  derived  unit  will  now  be  an  inch 
per  second,  and  its  relation  to  the  former  derived 
unit  is  obtained  by  altering  directly  in  the  ratio 
of  1:12  (dividing  by  12)  and  inversely  in  the 
ratio  of  1  :  60  (multiplying  by  60),  so  that  the 
new  unit  is  five  times  as  gi^eat  as  the  old  one, 
an  inch  per  second  being  five  times  as  great  a 
speed  as  a  foot  per  minute  ;  but  the  numerical 
value  of  the  concrete  speed  we  had  to  express 
must  be  altered  inversely  as  1:12  and  directly 
as  1  :  60,  and  is  now  only  2 — i.e.  the  speed  is 
two  inches  per  second — or  one-fifth  of  what  it 
was  before. 

If  we  are  measuring  such  a  magnitude  as  feet 
of  vertical  motion  per  foot  of  horizontal  motion 
in  the  path  of  a  projectile,  the  dimensions  will 
be  LL~^  and  will  cancel  each  other.  No  change 
in  the  unit  of  length,  then,  will  in  any  way 
affect  the  numerical  value  of  this  magnitude,  and 
as  no  other  dimension  enters  into  it  at  all,  it  may 
be  said  to  have  no  dimensions.  Angular  magni- 
tudes, defined  as  ratios  between  arcs  and  radii, 
trigonometrical  functions,  and  ratios  generally 
are  of  this  nature.  They  have  no  selected 
units,  and  their  numerical  values  are  absolute. 

When  the  elements  of  the  theory  of  dimen- 
sions have  been  thoroughly  grasped  it  will  be 
easy  to  apply  it  to  economic  questions  ;  and  it 
will  be  found  an  invaluable  check  in  the  more 
intricate  problems  of  co-ordination  and  analysis. 
Thus,  if  the  unit  of  value-in-use  or  utility  be 
taken  as  fundamental,  and  regarded  as  having 
the  dimension  U,  and  if  the  commodity  we  are 
considering  be  taken  as  having  the  dimension 
Q,  then  Degree  of  Utility  (q.v.)  of  the  com- 
modity, being  the  rate  at  which  satisfaction  is 
secured  per  unit  of  commodity  consumed,  will 
have  dimensions  UQ~^,  and,  will  be  readily  dis- 
tinguished from  rate  of  enjoyment,  accruing  to 
the  consumer,  per  unit  of  tiTne,  with  dimensions 
UT~^.  Frice,  determined  by  marginal,  or  final. 
Degree  of  Utility  {q.v. ),  will  have  dimensions 
UQ-^  or  P  ;  and  hire,  being  price  per  unit  of 
time,  will  obviously  have  dimensions  PT~^  or 
UQ-^  T~^.  When  the  thing  hired  is  money  and 
is  used  commercially,  the  utility  derived  from 
it  is  a  commodity  of  like  nature  with  itself. 


The  dimension  U  then  becomes  Q,  and  the  dimen- 
sions of  interest  (as  a  rate)  are  QQ~^  T~^  or  T~^ 
which  will  be  found  on  reflection  and  experi- 
ment to  be  correct. 

The  theory  of  dimensions  should  be  applied 
to  economics  in  close  connection  with  the 
diagrammatic  method.  But  of  course  the 
connection  between  dimensions,  as  now  ex- 
plained, and  the  geometrical  dimensions  of  the 
diagrams  is  purely  arbitrary.  The  physicist 
may,  according  to  his  convenience,  represent 
the  height  of  a  projectile — a  magnitude  of  one 
dimension — by  a  line,  or  by  an  area,  and  speed 
by  a  line  or  an  inclination.  So  the  economist 
may  represent  a  magnitude  measured  by  a 
complicated  derived  unit  by  a  line,  or  a  magni- 
tude measured  by  a  fundamental  unit  by  an 
area  or  a  solid  ;  and  if  he  keeps  the  theory  of 
dimensions  well  before  him  he  may  vary  his 
methods  indefinitely  without  any  danger  of 
confusion.  In  all  cases,  however,  the  dimensions 
of  those  quantities  represented  by  areas  or  solids 
will  be  compounded  of  the  dimensions  of  those 
represented  by  the  lines  which  determine  them. 
Again,  those  who  have  any  acquaintance  with 
the  elements  of  the  calculus  will  see  that  if  the 
equation  of  a  curve  be  differentiated  to  x  then 
the  area  of  the  derived  curve  will  have  the  same 
dimensions  as  the  ordinate  of  the  fundamental 
curve  ;  the  ordinate  of  the  derived  curve  will 
have  the  dimensions  of  the  ordinates  of  the 
fundamental  curve  positively,  and  those  of  its 
abscissae  negatively  ;  and  the  abscissae  of  the  two 
curves  will  have  the  same  dimensions.  In  other 
words,  differentiation  introduces  the  dimensions 
of  the  variable  to  which  we  differentiate  nega- 
tively, and  integration  introduces  the  dimen- 
sions of  the  variable  to  which  we  integrate 
positively. 

By  way  of  illustration  take  a  figure,  on  the 
ordinate  of  which  intensity  of  desire,  or  degree 
of  utility,  is  represented,  while  supply  of  com- 
modity per  unit  of  time  is  measured  on  the 
abscissae.  Now  imagine  a  third  axis  (of  Z) 
perpendicular  to  the  page,  along  which  time  is 
measured.  Such  a  figure  will  enable  us  to 
represent  all  the  quantities  we  have  to  deal 
with  in  an  ordinary  problem  of  consumption. 
Rate  of  supply  is  represented  on  axis  of  X, 

Y 


dimensions  QT~^ ;  degree  of  utility  on  axis  of 
Y,  dimensions  UQ~^  ;  time  on  axis  of  Z,  dimen- 
sion T ;  rate  of  enjoyment  on  areas  parallel  to 
plane  of  axes  of  X  and  Y,  dimensions  UQ~^  QT"^ 


DIMINISHING  KETUENS 


685 


or  UT"-^ ;  total  enjoyment  on  solid  figure,  dimen- 
sions UQ~-^QT~^T,  or  U  ;  total  supply  on  areas 
parallel  to  plane  of  axes  of  X  and  Z,  dimensions 
QT~^T,  or  Q,  and  in  like  manner  price,  hire, 
total  sum  paid,  etc.,  may  be  read,  and  their 
dimensional  relations  seen  at  a  glance. 

[The  theory  of  dimension  was  (according  to 
Jevons,  Principles  of  Science,  1887,  pp.  325)iirst 
clearly  stated  by  Joseph  Fourier.  He  expounded 
it  with  great  lucidity  in  his  Th^orie  Analytique 
de  la  Chaleur,  1822,  §§159-162.  An  excellent 
popular  statement  of  the  theory,  as  it  has  since 
been  elaborated,  will  be  found  in  the  beginning 
of  Prof.  J.  D.  Everett's  C.G.8.  System  of  Units, 
1891.  Jevons  was  the  first  to  suggest  the 
application  of  the  theory  to  economics  {Theory 
of  Political  Economy,  1888,  pp.  232-252),  but  he 
unfortunately  fell  into  some  apparent  errors  and 
confusions  which  made  the  suggestion  barren 
in  his  hands.  A  criticism  of  his  treatment  of 
the  subject  and  an  independent  working-out  of 
his  suggestion,  by  the  writer  of  the  present 
article  will  be  found  in  the  American  Quarterly 
Journal  of  Economics  for  April  1889,  pp.  297- 
314.]  p.  H.  w. 

DIMINISHING  RETURNS.  The  law  of 
diminishing  returns  is  the  name  given  to  the 
proposition  that  increase  of  the  population  of  a 
country,  or,  more  strictly  speaking,  increase  of 
the  labour  expended  on  a  given  area,  tends  to 
be  acconi})auied  by  a  diminution  of  the  returns 
to  a  given  amount  of  agricultiu-al  industry. 
The  law,  it  is  added,  is  only  true  after  popula- 
tion has  reached  a  certain  degree  of  density, 
and  even  then  improvements  in  the  methods  of 
production  have  a  counteracting  tendency.  Its 
origin  is  to  be  found  in  the  corn-law  discussions 
of  ]814  and  1815.  During  the  great  war  cul- 
tivation had  been  extended  over  lands  of  a 
worse  quality  than  those  previously  occupied, 
and  the  conclusion  of  peace  threatened,  unless 
more  stringent  restrictions  on  importation  were 
enacted,  to  throw  these  lands  out  of  cultivation. 
It  was  generally  assumed  that  this  would  be  an 
evil  to  the  whole  nation,  and  not  only  to  the 
owners  and  cultivators  of  the  lands  in  question, 
as  it  was  supposed  that  every  increase  of  cul- 
tivation must  ultimately  lower  the  price  of  corn 
by  making  it  more  abundant.  But  Mai  thus, 
in  his  Observations  on  the  Com  Laws  (1814), 
attributed  "no  inconsiderable  part"  of  the 
difference  between  the  English  and  the  foreign 
price  of  corn  to  the  "necessity"  of  cultivating 
the  poorer  lauds,  from  which  a  given  amount 
of  produce  is  obtained  by  the  expenditure  of  a 
larger  quantity  of  labour  than  is  required  in 
raising  an  equal  amount  of  produce  on  the 
better  lands  (p.  40).  In  the  Nature  and  Progress 
of  P^nt  (January  1815)  he  worked  out  this  idea, 
and  mentioned  the  opposing  force  of  agricul- 
tural improvements,  which  he  considered  to  be 
rarely  sufficient  to  balance  the  necessity  of 
applying  to  poorer  land,  so  that  "the  quantity 


of  labour  and  capital  necessary  to  procure  the 
last  addition  that  has  been  made  to  the  raw 
produce  of  a  rich  and  advancing  country  is 
almost  constantly  increasing"  (p.  45).  Sir 
Edward  "West,  in  his  Essay  on  the  Application 
of  Capital  to  Land  (January  or  February  1815), 
put  forward  the  same  idea  of  an  actual  diminu- 
tion of  the  returns  to  agricultural  industry  in 
order  to  show  that  the  price  of  corn  would  not 
be  lower  than  the  price  at  which  importation 
was  allowed  (see  Corn  Laws).  Ricardo,  in  his 
Essay  on  the  Influence  of  a  Low  Price  of  Corn 
on  the  Profits  of  Stock  (February  1815),  used 
the  theory. that  with  the  increase  of  [lopulation 
the  returns  to  agriculture  diminish  "independ- 
ently of  all  improvements," — i.e.  supposing 
improvements  not  to  take  place, — as  an  argu- 
ment against  any  restriction  on  the  importation 
of  com.  For  this  purpose  it  was  not  necessary 
to  follow  West  and  Malthus  in  holding  that 
returns  have  generally  diminished  in  spite  of 
all  improvements,  but  there  can  be  no  doubt 
that  Ricardo  did  believe  that  improvements 
have  only  a  temporary  effect  in  retarding  the 
diminution  of  returns  {Low  Price,  Works,  p. 
377  n.  ;  Pi-inciples,  Works,  p.  QQ).  James 
Mill,  in  Elements  of  Political  Economy  (1821), 
insisted  on  an  actual  diminution  of  returns,  and 
paid  no  attention  to  the  effect  of  improvements 
in  production.  M'CuUoch,  in  Principles  of 
Political  Economy  (1825),  expressed  unhesi- 
tating belief  in  the  actual  diminution  of 
retm-ns  with  only  temporary  interruptions  due 
to  improvements  (pp.  205,  277,  278,  383). 
This  became  for  the  time  the  received  doctrine 
(see  Longfield,  Lectures,  1834-35,  p.  181). 
But  Dr.  T.  Chalmers  in  1832  denied  it,  and 
showed,  what  was  not  then  generally  under- 
stood, that  the  bringing  of  new  land  into  cul- 
tivation does  not  prove  that  an  actual  diminu- 
tion of  returns  has  taken  place,  as,  owing  to 
"improvements"  or  changes  in  human  know- 
ledge, the  labour  on  the  new  land  may  be  now 
as  productive  as  the  labour  on  the  old  land  was 
before  the  change  {Political  Economy,  in  Works,  * 
vol.  xix.  pp.  17-24).  H.  C.  Carey,  in  his  Poli- 
tical Economy  (1837-40),  brought  forward  facts 
to  show  that  the  returns  to  agricultural  in- 
dustry, so  far  from  diminishing,  have  actually 
increased  enormously  (vol.  i.  p.  58,  iii.  pp.  69, 
70).  J.'  S.  MiU's  teaching  on  the  subject  is 
not  altogether  consistent ;  sometimes  he  speaks 
as  if  there  were  no  doubt  that  returns  had 
increased  {e.g.  in  the  "  Introduction "  to  Pol. 
Econ.)  at  other  times  as  if  they  had  with  occa- 
sional interruptions  steadily  decreased  {PoL 
Econ.,  bk.  i.  ch.  xii.  §§  2  and  3,  esp.  in  1st  ed., 
ch.  xiii.  §  2,  bk.  iv.  ch.  ii.  §  3,  ch.  iii.  §  5). 
To  meet  Carey's  objection,  advanced  in  Past, 
Present,  and  Future  (1848),  and  in  Principles 
of  Social  Science  (1858),  that,  as  a  matter  of 
fact,  the  least  fertile  lands  are  cultivated  first, 
Mill  confined  the  operation  of  the  "law"  to 


680 


DIMINISHING  UTILITY— DIRECT  TAXATION 


old  countries.  Caimes  is  probably  the  last 
writer  of  importance  wbo  expressed  a  strong 
belief  in  an  actual  diminution  of  returns  {Lead- 
ing Principles,  2nd  ed.  p.  119). 

By  the  law  as  it  is  now  taught  (Sidgwick, 
Principles,  bk.  i.  ch.  vi.  ;  Marshall,  Principles 
of  Economics,  bk.  iv.  ch.  iii.)  no  suggestion  of 
any  actual  diminution  of  the  returns  to  agri- 
cultural industry  is  intended.  It  is  merely 
equivalent  to  the  proposition  that  in  each 
stage  of  progress  there  is  a  limit  beyond  which 
the  labour  expended  upon  a  given  area  cannot 
be  increased  without  causing  a  diminution  of 
returns.  The  position  of  the  limit  is  constantly 
being  changed  by  the  progress  of  knowledge, 
and  to  say  whether  it  has  been  passed  in  any 
particular  case  is  a  very  difficult  practical  ques- 
tion. And  even  in  a  case  where  the  produc- 
tiveness of  agricultural  industry  had  actually 
diminished,  it  would  not  necessarily  follow  that 
the  productiveness  of  all  industry  taken  together 
had  diminished.  Diminishing  returns  in  agri- 
culture niight  be  counterbalanced  by  increasing 
returns  in  other  industries.  On  this  point  see 
Increasing  Returns. 

In  the  older  statements  of  the  law  the 
"diminishing  return"  was  the  return  to  "a 
given  amount  of  labour  and  capital."  But  a 
given  amount  of  labour  is  not  always  aided  by 
the  same  amount  of  capital,  and  when  a  given 
amount  of  labour  is  assisted  by  a  greater  amount 
of  capital  the  returns  to  capital  may  diminish 
without  any  diminution  of  the  produce  of  a 
given  amount  of  labour.  (See  J.  B.  Clark, 
"Law  of  Wages  and  Interest"  in  Annuls  of 
the  American  Academy  of  Political  and  Social 
Science,  July  1890.)  e.  c. 

[For  a  fuller  account  of  the  discussions  of  1813 
to  1815,  see  E.  Cannan,«"The  Origin  of  the  Law 
of  Diminishing  Returns  "  in  the  Economic  Journal, 
March  1892.] 

DIMINISHING  UTILITY.     See  Utility. 

DINAR  {ancient).  An  Arabian  gold  coin 
weighing  about  sixty-six  grains.  It  formed* 
the  cii'culating  medium  of  a  great  part  of  both 
Asia  and  Africa  for  about  twelve  hundred  years. 

Dinar  (modem).  The  equivalent  of  the 
franc  in  Servia  (see  Franc).  f.  e.  a. 

DIODATI,  Domenico,  a  Neapolitan,  lived 
in  the  second  half  of  the  18  th  century.  He  was 
the  author  of  Illustrazione  delle  monete  che  si 
nominano  n^lle  Costituzioni  delle  Due  Sicilie, 
Napoli,  presso  Donate  Campo,  1788  a  book  which 
describes  the  coins  of  Frederick  II.,  Emperor  of 
Germany  and  King  of  the  Two  Sicilies,  and 
expresses  their  value  in  terms  of  money  current 
at  the  author's  date.  It  does  not  deal  with 
theory,  except  by  discussing  the  "three  dif- 
ferent values  of  money,  extrinsic  value,  intrinsic 
value,  and  commercial  value."  According  to 
Diodati  the  extrinsic  value  of  a  coin  is  the  one 
declared  by  the  state  ;  the  intrinsic  value,  the 
value  of  the  metal  in  it  ;  the  commercial  value. 


the  purchasing  power  of  a  coin  in  terms  of  com- 
mercial commodities.  m.  p. 

DIODATI,  LuiGi,  the  younger  brother  ol 
Domenico  Diodati,  also  wrote  on  coins,  from  a 
wish  to  continue  his  brother's  work.  His 
competence  in  questions  concerning  coins  was 
recognised  by  the  government,  which  made 
him  director  of  the  Neapolitan  mint.  He 
was  a  great  admirer  of  Broggia,  and  sent 
Broggia's  works  to  the  Russian  court  to  be  trans- 
lated into  Russian. 

In  his  book  Dello  staio  presente  della  fnoneta 
net  Pegno  di  Napoli  e  della  necessity  di  un 
alzamento,  con  Prefazion^ ;  Napoli,  stamperia 
Migliaccio,  1790,  and  in  a  sequel  to  it :  Risposta 
ad  alcune  critiche  fatte  all' opera  intitolata  .  .  . 
ut  supra  ;  Napoli,  1794,  Diodati  discusses  an 
abstruse  point  in  the  history  of  money,  which 
he  says  neither  De  Sanctis,  Serra,  Turbolo, 
Locke,  Melon,  Spinelli,  Galiani,  nor  Beccaria 
had  explained  completely,  viz.  the  true  cause 
why  gold  had  disappeared  in  1587  from  the 
kingdom  of  Naples.  The  usual  explanation 
of  this  fact  v/as  an  excess  of  imports  over 
exports,  whilst  it  was  due,  according  to  Diodati, 
to  the  monetary  reform  undertaken  by  the  other 
states  of  Italy,  each  of  which  had  raised  the 
nominal  value  of  their  coins.  In  conformity 
with  this  central  idea  of  his,  Diodati  advises 
his  government  to  raise  the  nominal  value  of 
money  in  the  kingdom  of  Naples,  so  as  to 
make  it  equal  to  that  of  other  Italian  states, 
and  explains  at  great  length  how  this  alteration 
should  be  carried  out — changing  the  money 
into  a  species  of  token  money.  The  reason 
which  Diodati  gives  for  the  elevation  of  the  nom- 
inal value  of  coins  in  other  states,  and  therefore 
for  doing  the  same  in  the  kingdom  of  Naples, 
consists  in  the  rise  of  prices  and  the  fall  in  the 
value  of  money,  consequent  on  the  discoveries 
of  silver  in  America,  and  the  impulse  these 
supplies  of  metal  gave  to  enterprise  and  business, 
whilst  reducing  all  fixed  incomes.  M.  P. 

DIRECT  TAXATION.  As  defined  by  Mill 
(Principles,  bk.  v.  ch.  ii.  §  1),  taxation  "which 
is  demanded  from  the  very  persons  who  it  is 
intended  or  desired  should  pay  it." 

Mill's  definition  has  been  generally  adopted 
(see  Prof.  J.  S.  Nicholson's  Art.  "Taxation," 
Encyclopcedia  Britannica,  9th  ed.),  e.g.  by 
Wagner  (Handbuch,  vol.  ii.  p.  152),  and  by 
Fawcett  (Manual,  5th  ed.,  bk.  iv.  ch.  iii.) 
The  latter  \vriter  abbreviates  the  definition  by 
the  statement  that  '  *  a  direct  tax  is  really  paid 
by  the  person  from  whom  it  is  levied." 

Practical  financiers,  as  Prof.  Bastable  states 
(Public  Finance,  bk.  iii.  ch.  i.),  "regard  those 
taxes  as  direct  which  are  levied  on  permanent 
and  recurrent  occasions." 

M'CuUoch  defined  a  direct  tax  as  one  which 
is  taken  directly  from  income  or  capital,  and 
Dr.  Ely  (Taxation  in  American  States  and 
Cities,  New  York,  1888,  p.  69)  observes  thar 


DIEECTORS,  LEGAL  DUTY  OF— DISABILITIES  OF  INFANTS        587 


"direct  taxes  are  taxes  on  trades,  including 
any  branch  of  business,  on  permits,  on  property 
consisting  of  other  economic  goods  than  articles 
of  consumption,  and  on  income."  Both  these 
definitions  would  include  taxes  on  articles  of 
luxury  such  as  dogs,  horses,  carriages,  and  also 
on  successions  and  gifts. 

In  this  connection  Prof.  Sidgwick's  remark 
maybe  noted,  "The  common  classification  of 
taxes  as  direct  and  indirect  appears  .  .  .  liable 
to  mislead  the  student,  by  ignoring  the  com- 
plexity and  diflBculty  of  the  problem  of  deter- 
mining the  incidence  of  taxation."  See  also 
Taxation.  t.  h.  e. 

DmECTORS,  Legal  Duty  of.  The  duties 
and  responsibilities  of  directors  of  joint-stock 
companies  and  other  associations  have  frequently 
been  discussed  in  the  com-ts,  and  their  position 
is  now  well  defined.  In  the  first  place,  a 
director  must  act  strictly  within  the  powers  of 
the  company  as  defined  by  the  memorandum  of 
association,  and  also  within  the  powers  en- 
trusted to  the  directors  by  the  articles,  and  if 
he  expends  any  money  or  incurs  any  loss  in 
consequence  of  transgressing  such  powers,  he 
is  liable  to  refund  the  amount.  As  regards 
transactions  within  such  powers  it  has  some- 
times been  said  that  directors  are  in  the  position 
of  trustees,  and  attempts  have  been  made  to 
make  their  duties  as  stringent  as  those  of  the 
trustees  of  wills  and  settlements,  but  the  courts 
have  consistently  opposed  that  view,  and  it  is 
now  well  established  that  "  if  the  directors  apply 
the  money  of  the  company  or  exercise  any  of 
its  powers  in  a  manner  which  is  not  ultra  vires, 
then  a  strong  and  clear  case  of  misfeasance 
must  be  made  out  to  render  them  liable  "  (see 
the  present  Lord -Justice  Kay's  judgment  In 
re  Faure  Electric  Accumulator  Company,  40 
Ch.  D.  141,  152)  ;  in  other  words,  unless  it 
can  be  proved  that  the  directors  have  been 
guilty  of  fraud  or  reckless  negligence,  they  can- 
not be  made  responsible  for  losses  arising  through 
any  of  their  acts  or  omissions  as  long  as  they 
have  not  transgressed  the  boundary  lines  laid 
do^vn  by  the  memorandum  and  articles. 

A  special  liability  is  imposed  upon  directors 
with  regard  to  prospectuses.  In  the  first  place, 
it  is  provided  by  Companies  Act  1867,  §  38,  that 
every  prospectus  issued  by  a  company  must 
contain  certain  particulars  respecting  contracts 
entered  into  by  the  company  or  its  promoters, 
and  that  the  absence  of  such  particulars  renders 
the  directors  liable  in  the  same  way  as  if  the 
prospectus  in  question  had  contained  a  fraudulent 
statement.  In  the  second  place,  directors  are 
liable  in  respect  of  fraudulent  statements  in 
prospectuses,  and  to  a  certain  extent  also  for 
untrue  statements  made  negligently,  but  in 
good  faith.  Before  the  Directors'  Liability  Act 
of  1890  proof  of  fraud  was  always  necessary, 
but  fraud  was  held  to  be  proved  if  a  false 
representation  had  been  made — (1)  knowingly, 


2)  without  belief  in  its  truth,  (3)  recklessly 
see  Lord  HerscheU's  judgment  in  Derry  v. 
Peek,  14  Appeal  Cases,  337,  359).  The  new 
act  imposes  a  more  stringent  liability,  inasmuch 
as  it  entitles  persons  who  take  shares  or  de- 
bentures on  the  strength  of  an  untrue  statement 
made  in  a  prospectus  to  claim  compensation, 
notwithstanding  the  absence  of  fraud,  unless 
it  can  be  shown  that  the  person  from  whom 
compensation  is  claimed  had  reasonable  cause 
to  believe,  and  did  in  fact  believe,  that  the 
statement  was  true.  Before  the  act  of  1890 
a  director  who  had  not  authorised  or  connived  at 
the  issue  of  a  prospectus  containing  a  false  state- 
ment was  not  liable ;  but  now  a  director  is  not 
absolved  from  his  liability  by  showing  that  the 
prospectus  was  issued  without  his  knowledge  or 
consent ;  he  must  further  show  that  "on  becom- 
ing aware  of  its  issue  he  forthwith  gave  reason- 
able public  notice  that  it  was  so  issued  without 
his  knowledge  or  consent "  (see  art.  under  this 
heading  in  Appendix).  e.  s. 

DIPtOM,  Major  Alexandee,  of  Muiresk 
(end  of  18th  century),  wrote  Inquiry  into  the 
Corn  Trade  and  Corn  Laws  of  Great  Britain, 
and  their  Influence  on  the  Frosperity  of  the 
Kingdom,  1796,  with  appendix  by  W.  Mackie 
of  Ormiston.  The  increase  of  foreign  imports 
of  corn  is  due  to  alteration  of  the  old  corn  laws. 
In  consequence  of  these  alterations,  Dirom  says, 
' '  Our  agriculture,  which  had  reached  its  highest 
prosperity  between  1730  and  1750,  has  ever 
since  been  rapidly  declining,  as  is  shown  by  the 
fact  that  137,000  more  people  were  employed  in 
the  cultivation  of  land  between  1741  and  1750 
than  between  1773  and  1784."  This  pamphlet 
was  answered  in  1798  by  Rev.  J.  Howlett 
(q.v.),  Dispersion  of  the  Gloomy  Apprcl tensions 
of  late  repeatedly  suggested  from  the  Decline  of 
our  Corn  Trade.  Mr.  Howlett  thinks  that  the 
increased  consumption  of  a  greater  population, 
the  demand  for  finer  grain  than  formerly,  and 
the  greater  numbers  of  live  stock,  especially 
horses — sufficiently  account  for  the  increased 
foreign  importation  (Dugald  Stewart,  Political 
Economy,  vol.  i.  247  seq.)  J.  b. 

DISABILITIES  OF  ALIENS.  The  only 
disability  to  which  aliens  now  remain  subject 
is  that  they  cannot  hold  any  shares  in  British 
ships  (see  Aliens  ;  and  Appendix).       e.  s. 

DISABILITIES  OF  INFANTS.  An  infant 
{i.e.  a  person  not  having  attained  the  age  of 
21  years)  cannot,  as  a  general  rule,  enter  into 
any  binding  contracts  or  make  any  valid  dis- 
positions of  property.  To  this  rule  there  are 
several  exceptions.  An  infant  may  (1)  if  a 
male,  marry  after  having  attained  the  age  of  14  ; 
if  a  female,  after  having  attained  the  age  of  12  ; 
(2)  with  the  consent  of  the  court  (a)  mak<» 
a  valid  marriage  settlement  (18  &  19  Vict.  o. 
43)  (h)  make  leases  and  grant  renewals  of 
leases  (11  Geo.  IV.  and  1  Will.  IV.  c.  66, 
§§16  and  17)  ;  (3)  enter  into  binding  contracts 


B88      DISABILITIES  OF  LUNATICS  AND  DRUNKARDS— DISCHARGE 


relating  to  the  supply  of  necessaries — the  term 
necessaries  not  being  confined  to  the  bare 
means  of  sustaining  life,  but  including  all  such 
things  as  are  considered  appropriate  to  the 
station  of  life  of  the  person  concerned  ;  (4^  an 
infant  after  attaining  the  age  of  21  cannot 
retain  property  subject  to  liabilities  acquired 
during  his  infancy  without  satisfying  the  liabili- 
ties incurred  during  that  time,  e.g.  arrears  of 
rent,  calls  on  shares.  On  the  same  principle 
an  infant  partner  who  on  attaining  21  retains 
his  share  of  the  profits,  must  allow  himself  to 
be  debited  with  his  share  of  the  losses  incurred 
during  his  minority.  (5)  Infant  holders  of 
gavelkind  land  may  alienate  such  land  subject 
to  the  performance  of  certain  formalities,  and 
there  are  other  local  customs  giving  infants  an 
exceptional  capacity  to  contract.  (6)  Infants 
holding  themselves  out  to  be  of  full  age  are 
liable  to  restore  any  advantage  they  have 
obtained  by  their  misrepresentation  to  a  person 
who  acted  on  the  faith  of  it.  e.  s. 

DISABILITIES  OF  LUNATICS  AND 
DRUNKARDS.  In  this  case  it  is  not  quite 
correct  to  speak  of  a  disability.  Infants  and 
married  women  are  under  permanent  restric- 
tions imposed  on  them  as  a  general  consequence 
of  their  status.  Mental  derangement,  on  the 
other  hand,  does  not  in  itself  create  a  new 
status.  No  transaction  could  be  invalidated  by 
the  simple  fact  that  a  party  to  the  transaction 
is  a  lunatic  or  a  drunkard  ;  on  the  other  hand, 
a  person  generally  sane  or  sober  may  under 
certain  circumstances  avail  himself  of  the  plea 
of  mental  incapacity.  The  rule  is,  that  a 
contract  or  a  disposition  of  property — which 
term  includes  testamentary  dispositions — is 
generally  not  binding  on  a  person  who  at  the 
time  of  making  the  contract  or  disposition  is 
not  of  sufficient  mental  capacity  to  imderstand 
the  nature  of  the  transaction.  Whether  the  in- 
capacity is  due  to  insanity  in  the  proper  sense 
of  the  word,  to  mere  temporary  derangement 
or  illness,  or  to  drunkenness,  is  quite  immaterial. 
As  a  general  rule  the  party,  or  representative 
of  the  party,  who  wishes  to  escape  an  obliga- 
tion on  the  ground  of  mental  incapacity  must 
bring  evidence  to  show  that  at  the  essential 
moment  such  incapacity  existed,  but  where  a 
person  has,  after  a  judicial  investigation  (inqui- 
sition), been  formally  declared  a  lunatic,  the 
presumption  is  reversed,  and  the  party  wishing 
to  uphold  a  transaction  to  which  the  lunatic 
was  a  party  must  prove  that  the  contract  or 
disposition  was  made  during  a  lucid  interval. 
There  is  one  exception  to  the  above-mentioned 
rule.  When  a  party  to  a  contract,  otherwise 
voidable  on  the  ground  of  the  mental  incapacity 
of  the  other  party,  did  not,  as  a  matter  of  fact, 
know  of  such  incapacity  and  had  no  reasonable 
ground  for  knowing  it,  and  where  it  is  impos- 
sible to  restore  the  parties  to  their  former 
position,  the  incapable  party  or  his  representa- 


tive must  abide  by  the  consequences  of  the 
contract.  Thus  the  personal  representative  of 
a  deceased  lunatic  who,  while  in  a  state  of 
mental  incapacity  not  known  to  the  other  side, 
had  purchased  an  annuity  from  an  insurance 
office,  cannot  recover  the  purchase  money. 
(See  Drunkards.)  e.  s. 

DISABILITIES  OF  MARRIED  WOMEN. 
It  is  generally  believed  that  the  Married 
Women's  Property  Act  of  1882  has  removed 
all  the  disabilities  of  married  women,  but  this 
is  not  the  case.  A  married  woman  having 
separate  property,  not  subject  to  a  restraint  on 
anticipation,  may  now  make  contracts  binding 
not  only  the  property  of  which  she  is  possessed 
at  the  time,  but  also  property  acquired  subse- 
quently, during  the  continuation  of  the  marriage, 
and  she  may  by  will  dispose  of  her  separate 
property  ;  but  great  anomalies  remain,  of  which 
the  following  may  be  quoted  as  instances.  A 
married  woman,  not  being  possessed  of  separate 
property,  who  purchases  goods  on  credit  and 
disposes  of  the  goods,  cannot  be  compelled  to 
pay  for  the  same  although  she  subsequently 
acquires  separate  property  of  great  value.  A 
married  woman  not  having  any  separate 
property,  but  knowing  that  her  husband  has 
made  a  will  under  which  she  wiU  be  entitled 
to  a  considerable  legacy,  makes  a  wiU,  with  the 
intention  of  securing  the  benefit  of  the  legacy 
to  some  friend  or  relative,  and  dies  after  her 
husband.  The  legacy,  will  go  to  her  next-of- 
kin,  as  her  will  can  only  dispose  of  "  separate 
property,"  and  property  acquired  after  her 
husband's  death  is  not  separate  property.  A 
married  woman  entitled  to  a  life  interest  in 
property  subject  to  the  usual  restraint  on 
anticipation,  but  not  possessed  of  other  separate 
property,  incurs  large  debts.  Her  creditors  are 
absolutely  without  any  remedy.  This  state  of 
things  is  most  unsatisfactory.  The  old  common 
law  rule  was  based  on  the  assumption  that 
husband  and  wife  were  one  person  ;  the  wife's 
proprietary  existence  ceased  on  the  day  of  her 
marriage,  and  became  absorbed  into  that  of  her 
husband,  who  took  all  her  personal  property, 
and  possessed  extensive  rights  of  control  and 
enjoyment  with  respect  to  her  real  property. 
This  view,  which  at  any  rate  had  the  advantage 
of  clearness  and  consistency,  has  now  been 
definitely  abandoned ;  a  wife  now  retains  all 
her  property  and  has  extensive  rights  of  dis- 
position ;  the  remaining  restrictions  have  no 
social  or  economical  reason,  and  their  practical 
inconvenience  is  obvious.  (See  Marriage 
Settlement.)  e.  s. 

DISCHARGE  (Scotland).  Extinction  of  a 
debt  or  obligation,  which  may  be  by — (1)  pay- 
ment or  performance ;  (2)  abandonment  of  claim 
by  creditor  ;  (3)  compensation  or  set-off ;  (4) 
novation  or  replacement  of  the  original  obliga- 
tion by  another  obligation  ;  (5)  delegation,  or 
replacement  of  the  original  debtor  by  anotb  er 


DISCHARGE  IN  BANKRUPTCY— DISCOUNT 


589 


debtor  ;  (6)  confusion,  the  debt  and  the  credit, 
in  a  condition  immediately  and  finally  to 
extinguish  one  another,  coming  to  coincide  in 
the  same  person.  Also  (Scotland)  the  docu- 
ment whereby  the  creditor  discharges  the 
debtor.  A.  D. 

DISCHARGE  IN  BANKRUPTCY.  The 
effect  of  a  discharge  in  bankruptcy  under  the 
Bankruptcy  Act  1883,  is  to  free  the  debtor 
from  all  debts  and  liabilities  provable  in  the 
bankruptcy,  except  crown  debts,  and  debts 
incurred  by  fraud  or  through  a  fraudulent  breach 
of  trust.  Crown  debts  can  be  released  by  a 
certificate  from  the  treasury.  By  the  amending 
act  of  1890,  it  is  further  provided  that,  unless 
the  court  otherwise  orders,  the  discharge  shall 
not  release  the  debtor  from  any  liability  under 
a  judgment  in  an  action  for  seduction,  or  under 
an  affiliation  order,  or  under  a  judgment  against 
him  as  a  co-respondent. 

Under  the  act  of  1869,  the  discharge  of  a 
bankrupt  was  a  matter  practically  in  the  hands 
of  his  creditors  unless  he  had  paid  a  dividend 
of  10s.  in  the  pound.  Under  the  acts 
of  1883  and  1890,  it  is  in  all  cases  a  matter 
for  the  judicial  discretion  of  the  court. 

At  any  time  after  being  adjudged  bankrupt, 
the  bankrupt  may  apply  to  the  court  for  an 
order  of  discharge,  but  the  application  cannot 
be  heard  until  after  his  public  examination  is 
concluded.  Notice  of  the  day  fixed  for  the 
hearing  must  be  gazetted,  and  sent  to  the 
creditors.  On  the  hearing,  any  creditors  who 
desire  it,  must  be  heard,  and  the  court  must 
take  into  consideration  a  report  of  the  official 
receiver  as  to  the  bankrupt's  conduct  and  afi'airs. 
If  it  is  shoAvn  that  the  debtor  has  been  con- 
victed of  a  misdemeanour  under  the  Debtors' 
Act  1869,  the  court  is  directed  to  refuse  the 
discharge.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  debtor  is 
shown  to  have  been  guilty  of  certain  minor  acts 
of  misconduct  specified  by  the  act,  such  as  the 
assets,  without  reasonable  excuse,  not  amount- 
ing to  1  Os.  in  the  pound,  or  not  keeping  proper 
trade  books,  or  trading  with  knowledge  of 
insolvency,  or  having  been  guilty  of  fraudulent 
conduct,  the  court  must  either  refuse  or  qualify 
the  discharge.  A  discharge  may  be  qualified 
either  by  suspending  it  for  a  specified  time, 
usually  not  less  than  two  years,  or  by  imposing 
conditions  as  to  after-acquired  property,  as,  for 
instance,  by  directing  judgment  to  be  entered 
up  against  the  debtor  for  a  certain  sum.  If  the 
debtor's  conduct  has  been  blameless  he  is  entitled 
to  an  unconditional  discharge,  and  may  also 
obtain  a  certificate  from  the  court  removing  any 
civil  disabilities  consequent  on  bankruptcy  (§  8 
of  the  Act  of  1890).  An  undischarged  bankrupt 
who  obtains  credit  from  any  person  to  the  extent 
of  £20  or  upwards  without  informing  such  person 
of  his  status  is  guilty  of  a  misdemeanour.  A  new 
Bankruptcy  Act  was  passed  in  1 9 1 3.     M.  d.  c. 

DISCLAIMER.  A  person  appointed  as  trustee 


of  a  will  or  settlement  who  does  not  wish  to 
accept  the  trust  will  find  it  safer  as  a  general 
rule  to  execute  a  deed  by  which  his  non-accept- 
ance is  stated.  A  deed  of  this  nature  is  called 
a  deed  of  disclaimer.  The  word  disclaimer  is 
also  generally  used  for  any  act  of  renunciation. 

E.  S. 

DISCOMMODITY.  The  terms  disutility 
and  discommodity  have  been  introduced  into 
the  nomenclature  of  political  economy  by 
Jevons  {Theory  of  Political  Economy,  1879,  pp. 
62,  63)  as  the  opposites  or  contraries  of  the 
terms  utility  and  commodity.  Thus,  by  disu- 
tility he  means,  not  the  mere  absence  of  utility, 
but  the  quality  of  causing  positive  inconvenience 
or  discomfort.  Similarly,  by  discommodity  he 
means  any  action  or  material  thing  which 
possesses  disutility.  The  term  discommodity 
is  used  in  much  the  same  sense  by  Professor 
Marshall.  "  While  demand  is  based  on  the 
desire  to  obtain  commodities,  supply  depends 
on  the  overcoming  of  the  unwillingness  to  under- 
go 'discommodities.'  These  fall  generally  under 
one  of  two  classes,  labour  and  the  abstinence 
involved  in  putting  off  consumption "  {Prin- 
ciples of  Economics,  vol.  i.  ed.  2,  1891,  p.  193). 

J.  N.  K. 

DISCOUNT.  The  term  ' '  discount "  signifies 
an  abatement,  or  deduction,  and  is  in  practice 
applied  in  several  ways  :  (1)  stocks  or  shares 
are  said  to  be  at  a  discount  when  their  market 
value  shows  an  abatement  from  par  value  ;  (2) 
the  stock  of  a  trader  is  sometimes,  from  bank- 
ruptcy or  other  cause,  sold  at  a  discount  from 
cost  price  ;  (3)  a  quoted  or  publislied  price 
may  be  by  custom  subject  to  an  abatement  or 
discount,  to  purchasers  for  the  trade,  or  for 
export ;  (4)  an  account  for  goods  delivered 
may  be  paid  at  a  date  earlier  than  is  usual  upon 
receiving  a  discount  therefrom ;  or  (5)  a  bill  of  ex- 
change, due  at  a  future  date,  may  be  discounted, 
i.e.  sold  for  cash  at  an  agreed  abatement. 

Excepting  in  the  first  case,  the  discount  is 

usually  expressed  at  a  rate  per  cent,  and  in 

cases  2,   3,   4,   the  formula  for  calculation  is 

P  X  K 
simply  D  =  --        .     In  the  discount  of  a  bill 

of  exchange,  the  time  it  has  to  run  is  taken  into 

P  X  R  X  T 
account,  and  the  formula  is  D  =  — — - —  ;  T 

representing,  in  theory,  fractions  or  multiples 
of  a  year,  but,  in  the  practice  of  a  banker,  a 
fraction  only. 

In  law,  and  in  fact,  the  operation  of  dis- 
counting a  bill  is  a  purchase,  and  the  property 
therein  passes  to  the  purchaser,  who  acquires 
all  the  usual  rights  of  a  holder  (see  Bill  of 
Exchange,  Endorser,  etc.)  In  practice,  a 
banker  always  places  the  amount  of  the  bill  to 
the  credit  of  his  customer,  debiting  him  at  the 
same  time  with  the  discount.  In  most  dis- 
count operations  the  effective  rate  of  interest 


590 


DISCOUNT 


upon  the  capital  employed  is  greater  than  the 
nominal  rate  of  discount.  In  the  first  three 
cases  referred  to  above,  time  is  an  uncertain 
factor,  and  the  effective  rate  will  be  increased 
according  to  the  shortness  of  the  time  that 
elapses  before  the  investment  is  realised  ;*  or 
will  be  diminished  if  that  time  should  exceed 
one  year.  In  obtaining  discount  upon  the 
])repayment  of  an  account  the  effective  rate  is 
dependent  upon  the  time  when  payment  would 
otherwise  become  obligatory.  In  discounting 
a  bill  of  exchange,  the  time  it  has  to  run  is 
taken  into  account  in  deciding  the  amowni  of 
discount,  and  the  only  advantage  in  the  effect- 
ive rate  over  the  nominal  rate  is  that — com- 
mon also  to  all  the  other  cases — arising  from 
the  fact  that  the  discount  is  received  at  once. 

Having  regard  to  this  fact,  it  is  taught  in 
the  schools  that  true,  discount  is  the  difference 
between  the  whole  sum  and  its  **  present  value," 
this  latter  being  defined  as  the  sum  which,  if 
put  out  at  interest  at  the  rate  named,  would 
amount,  at  the  end  of  the  given  term,  to  the 
sum  due.  It  is  also  further  laid  down  that  the 
current  method  of  charging  discount  produces 
less  to  the  holder  than  he  should  equitably 
receive,  and  examples  are  usually  given  only 
in  what  is  termed  the  "more  correct  rule"  of 
*  *  true  discount. "  But  this  teaching  is  altogether 
wrong,  and  appears  to  be  based  upon  the 
erroneous  notion  that  the  operation  of  dis- 
counting is  an  advance,  whereas  it  is  a  purchase. 
Moreover,  as  the  word  signifies  an  abatement, 
or  "reckoning  from,"  it  is  clear  that  such 
abatement  must  be  calculated  upon  the  gross 
sum,  and  not  upon  the  net  result  of  its  own 
deduction.  The  theory  of  "  tru^  discount,"  also 
connotes  the  idea,  which  is  equally  unsound, 
that  there  is  an  "equity"  in  rates  other  than 
that  obtained  by  free  sale  in  a  free  market. 
As  a  matter  of  fact  it  is  always  found  that  the 
discount  rate  on  bills  is  lower  than  the  rate  of 
interest  on  advances,  which  though  chiefly  due 
to  the  more  liquid  character  of  an  investment 
in  bills,  is  also,  no  doubt,  in  part  due  to  the 
advantage  under  discussion. 

The  extent  of  this  advantage  varies  directly 
with  the  nominal  rate,  but  in  greater  degree. 
Thus: 

With  discount  at  1%  the  effective  rate  is  I'Oi      %  p.  ann. 
„        »  3%  „         „  „     3-0927-1-%  „ 

„  5%  „         „  „     5-2631  +%  „ 

»  » 10%  „  „  „  iri  %  „ 
From  these  instances  it  appears  that  the  extra 
profit  increases  almost  as  the  square  of  the  rate. 
But  this  advantage  is  derived  in  the  way  of 
compound  interest,  and  is  therefore  dependent 
upon  the  frequency  with  which  the  profit  is 
received.  The  operation  of  the  rule  is,  how- 
ever reversed,  and  the  shorter  the  term  the 
less  is  the  profit.  The  rates  quoted  above  are 
based  upon  a  supposed  discount  of  twelve 
months'  bills,  and  as  bankers  very  rarely  dis- 


count bills  with  more  than  six  months  to  run, 
and  in  by  far  the  greater  number  of  cases  take 
bills  of  three  months,  or  less,  the  advantage 
they  obtain  is  very  much  less  than  is  generally 
supposed.  The  effective  rate  derived  from  a 
year's  full  employment  of  capital  in  discount- 
ing at  5  per  cent  is  as  follows : 

In  6  months'  bills  5-19375% 
„  3  „  „  5-16  % 
„  2       „  „      5-14875% 

As  this  presupposes  an  immediate  re-employ- 
ment of  the  full  amount  obtained  by  the  pay- 
ment of  each  bill  as  it  falls  due,  and  a  constant 
rate  of  6  per  cent,  it  is  considerably  above  the 
probable  experience.  R.  w.  B. 

DISCOUNT,  French  Stock  Exchange 
(Fr.  Escompte).  The  privilege  accorded  to 
buyers  for  the  account  on  French  bourses, 
to  demand  immediate  delivery.  The  right 
is  based  on  the  fiction  that  sellers  always 
possess  the  stock  or  shares  they  have  sold,  and 
is  reaffirmed  in  Art.  63  of  the  decree  of  the  7th 
October  1890,  relative  to  the  office  of  agent  de 
change: — "The  purchaser  may  at  all  times 
call  for  the  delivery,  by  anticipation,  of  the 
securities  negotiated,  whether  firm  or  at  option." 
Sellers  may,  however,  stipulate  that  the  opera 
tion  is  not  discountable.  The  privilege  is  not 
frequently  exercised,  and,  unless  the  market 
has  been  prepared  by  a  corner,  the  manoeuvre 
may  turn  against  those  who  employ  it,  for  if 
the  seller  has  no  difficulty  in  procuring  the 
stock,  the  effect  produced  may  be  the  reverse  of 
that  intended.  Notice  of  " discount"  must  be 
given  before  business  hours  by  the  buying  ag&nt 
de  change  to  the  selling  one  with  particulars 
which  are  posted  in  the  private  room  of  the  cor- 
poration in  the  bourse  building,  and  the  purchase 
money  must  be  deposited.  The  seller  is  allowed 
five  days  to  pass  the  stock  or  shares,  and  two  ad- 
ditional if  the  ti'ansfer  requires  the  acceptation  of 
the  buyer,  after  which  the  usual  measures  against 
defaulters  may  be  applied.  T.  l. 

DISCOUNT,  London  Stock  Exchange 
The  word  is  used  in  two  senses,  the  one  legiti- 
mate, the  other  being  a  piece  of  slang.  First  the 
scrip  of  a  new  issue  is  usually  quoted  at  a 
discount,  or  at  a  premium,  as  the  market  price 
falls  below  or  exceeds  the  amount  of  the  instal- 
ment so  far  paid  up.  Thus,  were  a  new  govern- 
ment bond  to  be  on  the  market,  on  which  only 
£25  per  cent  had  been  paid  up,  the  price — 
supposing  it  to  be  £26,  would  be  quoted  £1 
premium.  If,  for  another  example,  the  shares 
in  the  Manchester  Canal,  on  which  £10  had 
been  paid,  were  purchaseable  at  £8,  the  market 
price  would  be  £2  discount.  When  new  scrip 
has  been  fuUy  paid  up,  the  necessity  of  quoting 
at  a  premium  or  discount  ceases,  and  the  plair 
price  is  then  customarily  quoted.  The  second 
sense  in  which  the  word  discount  is  used  on  the 
stock  exchange  is  to  imply  a  preliminary  effect 
on  the  market  of  news,  or  some  other  influence 


DISCOVERIES— DISCRIMINATING  OR  DIFFERENTIAL  DUTIES      59i 


which  tends  to  raise  or  depress  prices.  There 
have,  again  and  again,  been  rumours  of  coming 
war  between  Russia  and  England,  and  a  fall  in 
prices  of  government  stocks  was  produced  merely 
by  the  "  discount "  of  the  effect  which  an  actual 
outbreak  of  hostilities  would  have  upon  the 
market.  Similarly,  the  shares  of  this  or  that 
joint -stock  company  sometimes  fall  in  the 
market,  or  rise,  as  the  case  may  be,  dealers  and 
speculators  being  anxious  to  discount  the  effect 
of  a  good  or  bad  dividend.  Occasionally  the 
effect  of  this  discounting  process  is  excessive, 
and  the  actual  occurrence  of  what  is  anticipated 
or  discounted,  and  the  confirmation  of  rumours, 
is  often  followed  by  reaction. 

On  the  stock  exchange  the  word  is  used 
rather  as  a  piece  of  slang  to  convey  the  impres- 
sion that  an  expected  event — say  the  death  of 
the  late  Emperor  Frederick  of  Germany — has 
been  acted  upon  in  advance  by  dealers  and 
others,  who  by  putting  down  or  raising  the 
quotations  of  the  stocks  in  which  they  deal, 
"discount"  the  probable  effect  of  that  event 
on  the  market.  Thus  we  hear  of  news  being 
discounted,  i.e.  anticipated  in  a  similar  way  as 
the  value  of  a  bill  is  anticipated  under  Discount. 

A.  E. 

DISCOUNT  HOUSES.    See  Bill  Broking. 

DISCOVERIES,  Geographical  (Influence 
ON  Trade  of).  The  effect  of  discovery  is  to 
modify  or  recast  the  conditions  under  which 
trade  and  industry  are  carried  on.  But  such 
effect  almost  invariable  though  it  be,  may  and 
does  manifest  itself  in  certain  different  directions, 
and  thus,  though  it  would  be  hard  to  describe 
within  reasonable  limits  the  results  produced 
in  the  economic  world  by  the  discoveries  which 
have  been  made,  it  is  possible  to  suggest  the 
directions  in  which  these  may  be  sought. 
Geogi-aphical  discoveries  may  affect  trade  in 
the  following  ways — 

a.  By  providing  new  sources  for  the  supply 
of  raw  material. 

h.  By  opening  up  new  markets. 

c.  By  the  ultimate  evolution  of  new  trade 
rivals  or  competitors. 

It  is  hardly  necessary  to  point  out  that 
newly-discovered  countries  may  pass  through  all 
the  phases  described  above  with  regard  to  other 
and  older-established  countries.  North  America, 
for  example,  is  the  great  source  of  cotton  supply, 
it  is  a  trade  rival,  and  for  some  time  it  offered 
a  large  opening  for  the  import  of  goods  of 
European  manufacture.  As  a  rule,  however, 
discovery  tends  to  promote  the  greater  differ- 
entiation of  trade  and  industry.  Each  country 
attains  to  a  distinct  and  separate  position  in 
regard  to  either  supply  or  manufacture. 

There  is,  however,  another  mode  in  which 
trade  is  affected  by  discovery. 

d.  By  opening  up  new  sources  for  the  supply 
of  the  precious  metals.  These  may  be 
discovered  in  an  old  country  ;  or  a  new  country 


possessing  gold  or  silver  mines  may  be 
suddenly  discovered.  The  discovery  of  the 
Americas  in  the  1 5th  century  was  of  this  latter 
character  (see  Geography,  Commercial  ; 
Precious  Metals,  Discoveries  of),  e.  c.  k.  g. 

DISCOVERIES  OF  PRECIOUS  METALS. 
See  Precious  Metals,  Discoveries  of. 

DISCOVERY  IN  ACTIONS.  Discovery  in 
its  widest  sense  means  the  procedure  by  which 
a  party  in  an  action  may  obtain  sworn  informa- 
tion from  his  opponent  with  reference  to  matters 
affecting  the  questions  in  dispute.  Such  in- 
formation may  be  obtained  (1)  by  administering 
interrogatories  (written  questions  relating  to 
relevant  matters  which  must  be  answered  by 
affidavit) ;  (2)  by  requiring  an  affidavit  of 
documents  (a  list  of  documents,  verified  by 
affidavit,  relating  to  the  matters  in  question  in 
the  action,  being  in  the  possession  or  power  of 
the  party  from  whom  discovery  is  sought)  ;  (3) 
by  giving  notice  to  produce  for  inspection  any 
documents  referred  to  in  the  pleadings  or  in  the 
affidavit  of  documents.  A  party  may  refuse  to 
answer  interrogatories  or  to  produce  documents 
for  inspection  on  certain  grounds,  as  for  instance 
because  the  answer  or  the  production  of  the 
document  would  subject  him  to  criminal  pro- 
ceedings, or  that  the  required  disclosure  would 
violate  professional  confidence  or  be  detrimental 
to  the  public  interest.  Non-obedience  to  an 
order  of  the  court  directing  discovery  may 
subject  the  disobedient  party  to  imprisonment. 

E.  s. 

DISCRIMINATING  OR  DIFFERENTIAL 
DUTIES.  Duties  imposed  upon  commodities, 
and  differing  in  amount  according  to  the  par- 
ticular source  from  or  mode  in  which  those 
commodities  are  obtained. 

When  discriminating  or  differential  duties 
have  been  imposed,  the  circumstances  most  fre- 
quently taken  into  account  have  been  {a)  the 
process  of  producujou  employed,  as  in  the  case 
of  a  manufactured  article  produced  either  by 
hand  or  by  steam  power  ;  (h)  the  material  used, 
as  in  the  case  of  sugar  made  from  cane  or  from 
beetroot ;  and  (c)  the  country  or  place  of  origin, 
as  in  the  case  of  what  are  termed  Corn  Laws 
{q.v.)     * 

In  cases  in  which  regard  has  been  had  to  the 
country  or  place  of  origin,  the  object  has  been 
either  to  protect  the  home  product,  or  to  favour 
importation  from  one  particular  place  or  in  one 
particular  manner,  as,  for  example,  where  lower 
duties  have  been  charged  on  the  produce  of  a 
colony  or  of  a  country  with  which  special  treaty 
obligations  are  in  force,  or  where  higher  duties 
are  imposed  on  goods  imported  in  shipping 
carrying  a  particular  flag. 

In  an  interesting  note  to  his  edition  of  the 
Wealth  of  Nations  (new  edition,  1863,  p.  599) 
M'CuUoch  discusses  the  effects  of  the  differential 
duties  imposed  on  foreign  timber  to  favour  our 
North  American  colonies,  and  Sir  Thomas  Farrer, 


592    DISCUSSION— DISTANCE  IN  TIME  AS  AN  ELEMENT  OF  VALUE 


in  Ids  Free  Trade  versus  Fair  Trade,  refers  some- 
what fully  to  the  proposals  of  the  fair  traders 
for  differential  duties  in  favour  of  the  colonies. 
The  latter  writer  remarks  that  such  duties  are 
"open  to  the  fatal  objection  which  makes  aU 
protection  odious  to  free  traders — viz.  that  they 
liinder  people  from  buying  and  selling  where 
they  find  it  to  their  interest  to  buy  and  sell ; 
that  they  limit  production  by  preventing  people 
from  using  their  natural  capacity  to  the  utmost 
in  making  and  selling  the  things  which  they 
can  make  better  than  others." 

J.  S.  Mill  arrives  at  somewhat  similar  con- 
clusions. "Whatever  else  maybe  alleged  in 
favour  of  such  distinctions,  whenever  they  are 
not  nugatory  they  are  economically  wasteful. 
They  induce  a  resort  to  a  more  costly  method 
of  obtaining  a  commodity,  in  lieu  of  one  less 
costly,  and  thus  cause  a  portion  of  the  labour 
which  the  country  employs  in  providing  itself 
with  foreign  commodities,  to  be  sacrificed  with- 
out return  "  {Principles,  bk.  v.  chap.  iv.  §  5). 

The  considerations  affecting  discriminating 
or  differential  duties  are  very  closely  connected 
with  those  relating  to  the  general  subject  of 
free  trade  and  protection  (see  also  Most 
Favoured  Nation  Clause).  t.  h.  b. 

DISCUSSION  (Scotland).  (1)  A  cautioner  or 
surety,  if  not  bound  jointly  and  severally  with 
the  principal  debtor,  was  formerly  entitled  to 
demand  that  the  principal  debtor  should  be 
"discussed" — i.e.  that  the  creditor  should 
employ  his  means  of  recourse  against  him, 
before  he  himself  was  interfered  with.  This 
privilege  is,  since  19  &  20  Vict.,  c.  60,  §  8, 
now  only  possessed  by  cautioners  who  have 
expressly  stipulated  for  it.  (2)  Heirs  who  re- 
present the  ancestor  are  liable  for  all  his  debts  ; 
but  only  in  a  certain  order,  which  depends  on 
the  character  in  which  they  succeed ;  and 
those  who  come  later  in  this  order  are  entitled 
to  insist  that  before  they  themselves  are  called 
upon,  those  who  come  earlier  should  be  "dis- 
cussed," i.e.  made  to  choose  between  paying  the 
debts  and  renouncing  the  succession.  In  Eng- 
lish law  choice  is  described  as  being  "put  to 
Election  "  (see  Election). 

[Lord  M'Laren  on  Wills,  §  2269.]  A.  D. 

DISHONOUR  OF  A  BILL.  Refusal  to 
accept ;  or  non-payment  when  due  (see  Bill 
OF  Exchange  ;  Diligence  ;  Noting  of 
Bills  ;  Protest  of  Bills).  a.  d. 

DISPOSITION  (Scotland).  Generally  a  uni- 
lateral deed  of  conveyance.  The  "disponer" 
"sells  and  dispones"  or  "gives,  grants,  and 
dispones"  to  the  "disponee,"  the  thing  con- 
veyed. A  "disposition  and  settlement,"  or 
"  trust  disposition  and  settlement,"  a  disposi- 
tion, reserving  liferent  and  dispensing  with  the 
necessity  of  actual  delivery  of  the  deed,  to 
trustees  with  powers  and  under  directions  speci- 
fied, is  a  common  form  of  making  one's  will. 


"Dispositions    in    security,"   or    "bonvl    and 
disposition  in  security,"  are  forms  of  mortgage. 

A.  D. 

DISTANCE  IN  TIME  AS  AN  ELEMENT 
OF  VALUE.  Distance  does  not  "lend  enchant- 
ment to  the  view"  of  a  future  pleasure  com- 
pared with  the  same  pleasure  regarded  as 
present.  "There  is  no  man  perhaps  to  whom 
a  good  to  be  enjoyed  to-day  would  not  seem  of 
very  different  importance  from  one  exactly 
similar  to  be  enjoyed  twelve  years  hence,  even 
though  the  arrival  of  both  were  equally  certain  " 
(John  Rae,  Statement  of  soTne  new  Principles  of  J 
Political  Fconomy,  Boston,  1834,  a  work  referred  t! 

to  by  Mill  in  terms  of  high  encomium,  Pol. 
Econ.,  bk.  i.  ch,  xi.)  This  incident  of  our  moral 
nature  has  often  engaged  the  attention  of 
philosophers.  Thus  Locke  {Essay  concerning 
Hwman  Understanding,  bk.  ii.  ch.  xxi.  §  63) : 
"When  we  compare  present  pleasure  or  pain 
with  future,  we  often  make  wrong  judgments 
of  them,  taking  our  measures  of  them  in 
different  positions  of  distance.  Objects  near 
our  view  are  apt  to  be  thought  greater  than 
those  of  a  larger  size  that  are  more  remote  ; 
and  so  it  is  with  pleasures  and  pains,  the 
present  is  apt  to  carry  it,  and  those  at  a  distance 
have  a  disadvantage  in  the  comparison." 
Hume  gives  a  more  refined  explanation  of  the 
influence  of  distance  on  the  will  {Treatise 
on  Human  Nature,  bk.  ii.  pt.  iii.  §  7  ; 
compare  the  remarks,  bk.  i.  pt.  iii.  §  9,  with 
respect  to  a  future  state).  Jevons  expresses 
the  depreciation  of  future  pleasures  by  a 
fractional  factor  (a  function  of  the  distance  in 
time).  Multiplying  the  future  pleasure  by  this 
factor  we  have  its  value  relatively  to  present 
pleasure  ^  {Theory  of  Political  Economy,  3rd  ed. 
p.  72,  cp.  p.  34).  The  factor  expressing  the 
effect  of  remoteness  should  be  unity,  if 
human  nature  were  perfect.  As  Professor 
Sidgwick  says  {Methods  of  Ethics,  bk.  ii.  ch.  ii. 
p.  1,  note),  the  "equal  and  impartial  concern 
for  aU  parts  of  one  conscious  life  is  perhaps  the 
most  prominent  element  in  the  common  notion 
of  the  rational — as  opposed  to  the  merely 
impulsive — pursuit  of  pleasure."  But  in  fact 
human  nature  always  falls  short  of  this  ideal ; 
and  according  to  the  degree  of  such  imperfection 
nations  and  classes  differ  in  the  desire  of 
accumulating  the  means  of  future  pleasure 
(see  examples  quoted  from  Rae  by  Mill,  Pol. 
Econ.,  bk.  i.  ch.  xi.)  The  "extent  of  the  in- 
tellectual powers  "  is  assigned  by  Rae  as  one  of 

1  Jevons's  equations  between  pleasures  Qoe.  cit.)  at 
different  distances  of  time  relate  primarily  to  firud 
utilities.  But  it  deserves  attention  that  the  equations 
hold  for  utilities  not  qualified  as  final,  upon  certain 
not  violent  assumptions,  which  are  stated  by  Professor 
Marshall  in  his  Principles  of  EcoTiomics,  p.  179.  It  is 
impossible  to  resist  the  conclusion,  however  paradoxical 
at  first  sight,  that  the  depreciation  of  future  pleasures, 
the  rate  at  which  they  are  "discounted,"  is  measured 
by  the  rate  of  discount  in  the  loan  market  (Pri'tciples, 
loc  cit.,  and  Mathematical  Appendix,  note  6). 


DISTANCE  IN  TIME  AS  AN  ELEMENT  OF  VALUE 


593 


the  circumstances  which  determine  the  ''effective 
desire  of  accumulation. " 

A  wiser  ground  for  preferring  present  goods 
is  their  comparative  certainty.^  The  "bird  in 
the  bush"  may  never  come  to  hand.  The 
uncertainty  of  the  future  is  gi'eater,  the  lower 
the  state  of  civilisation.  "Stability,  .  .  . 
the  reign  of  law  and  order,"  is  assigned  by 
Rae  as  another  condition  of  the  effective  desire 
of  accumulation. 

Again  some  pleasures  are  more  "urgent" 
than  others.  Tastes  may  change,  the  sense 
of  pleasure  will  be  dulled  in  some  cases  and 
intensified  in  others  by  advancing  age.  The 
young  man  who  looks  forward  to  indulging 
himself  in  Alpine  tours  when  he  has  made  his 
fortune  "would  much  rather  have  them  now, 
partly  because  they  would  give  him  much 
greater  pleasure  now  "  (Marshall,  Principles  of 
Economics,  bk.  iii.  ch.  v.)  On  the  other  hand 
it  may  be  foreseen  that  certain  wants  will  be 
more  pressing  at  a  future  time  than  at  present. 
Ice  will  be  wanted  more  next  summer  than 
now  in  winter  (Bohm  -  Bawerk).  Age  will 
require  more  comforts  than  youth.  Prudence 
dictates  spreading  out  the  consumption  of  a 
given  store  of  wealth  according  to  the  law 
indicated  by  Jevons  (loc.  cit. ) 

The  distance  in  time  over  which  con- 
sumption is  thus  distributed  is  extended  beyond 
the  lifetime  of  the  individual  by  his  interest 
in  posterity.  As  Mill  says  {loc.  cit):  "If 
mankind  were  generally  in  the  state  of  mind 
to  which  some  approach  was  seen  in  the 
declining  [Roman]  empire — caring  nothing  for 
their  heirs  as  well  as  nothing  for  friends,  the 
public,  or  any  object  which  survived  them — 
they  would  seldom  deny  themselves  any  in- 
dulgence for  the  sake  of  saving  beyond  what 
was  necessary  for  their  own  future  years."  Rae 
places  the  prevalence  of  the  "social  and 
benevolent  affections"  first  among  the  con- 
ditions of  the  effective  desire  of  accumulation. 

The  play  of  the  various  motives  which  have 
been  indicated  determines  the  value  of  future 
with  respect  to  present  wealth  on  the  loan 
market,  in  other  words  the  rate  of  interest.  The 
spendthrift  borrower  prefers  present  to  future 
satisfactions.  The  borrower  of  capital  to  be 
employed  in  business  is  moved  by  the  prospect 
of  future  profits.  The  lender  is  deterred  by 
providence  from  grasping  all  the  immediate 
pleasure  which  is  in  liis  power.  Also  invest- 
ment in  the  "personal  capital"  of  skill  and 
knowledge  is  governed  by  motives  acting  at  a 
great  distance  in  time.  The  remuneration  of 
the  skilled  artisan  and  entrepreneur  may  be  ex- 
pected to  compensate  the  sacrifices  made  by 
parents    for   the   education  of  their   children 

1  It  is  not  easy  to  distinguish  the  influence  in  the 
will  of  mere  remoteness  from  that  of  the  uncertainty 
which  attends  future  events.  Is  it  possible  to  evaluate 
separately  the  Jevonian  factors  p  and  q'i  (See  Theory, 
loc.  cit. :  and  cp.  Pantaleoni,  Principij). 

VOL.  I. 


(Cp.  Adam  Smith,  Wealth  of  Natums,  bk.  1. 
ch.  X.,  and  Marshall,  Principles  of  Economics, 
bk  vi.  ch.  v.,  2nd  edition). 

Thus  distance  in  time  is  an  element  in  the 
value  of  two  important  agents  of  production^ 
borrowed  capital  and  trained  labour.  It  is 
accordingly  also  an  element  in  the  value  of 
products  (so  far  at  least  as  the  agents  of  pro- 
duction enter  in  different  proportions  into  the 
products — Ricardo,  Pol.  Econ.,  ch.  i.  §§  4  and  5, 
cp.  Mill,  Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  iii.  ch.  iv.  §§  3-5). 

Also  the  demand  for  commodities,  as  well  as 
the  supply  of  them,  is  affected  by  the  distance 
in  time  over  which  motives  range.  Where 
providence  prevails,  there  will  be  a  demand 
for  durable  clothing  and  articles  of  furniture 
rather  than  drinks  and  other  objects  of  im- 
mediate gratification  (Rae,  op.  cit.  ch.  vii.) 
Now  in  the  case  of  articles  of  which  the  cost 
of  production  varies  with  the  quantity  produced 
— that  is  in  the  case  of  most  articles — the 
extent  of  demand  is  apt  to  affect  value  (Sidgwick, 
Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  ii.  ch.  ii.  and  Marshall, 
passim).  In  this  way  then,  also  distance  in 
time  is  an  element  of  value. 

[Leading  authorities  on  this  subject  are  John 
Rae,  M.D.,  Statement  of  some  new  Principles  of 
Political  Economy,  especially  ch.  vi.  and  vii. 
Bdhm-Bawerk,  Positive  Theory  of  Capital  (trans- 
lated by  Wm.  Smart) ;  especially  bk.  v.  and  parts 
of  bk.  i. — Marshall,  Principles  of  Econoviics,  2nd 
edition,  bk.  iii.  ch.  v.,  and  other  passages  relating 
to  discounted  pleasures.  Other  authorities  are 
cited  in  Pantaleoni's  Princij)ij.  The  subject  is 
referred  to  in  most  recent  treatises  on  political 
economy  under  the  head  of  Capital.  Among  the 
earliest  of  such  references  are  Senior's  Observations 
on  Abstinence  in  his  Political  Economy,  pp.  58- 
59  ;  and  the  following  remarkable  passage  which 
occurs  in  S.  Bailey's  Critical  Dissertation  on 
Value,  p.  218. 

"  The  time  necessary  to  produce  a  commodity 
may,  equally  with  the  requisite  quantity  of  labour 
be  a  consideration  which  influences  the  mind  in 
the  interchange  of  useful  or  agreeable  articles. 
We  generally  prefer  a  present  pleasure  or  enjoy- 
ment to  a  distant  one,  not  superior  to  it  in  other 
respects.  We  are  willing,  even  at  some  sacrifice  of 
property,  to  possess  om'selves  of  what  would  other- 
wise require  time  to  procure  it,  without  waiting 
during  the  operation,  of  what  would  require  labour 
without  personally  bestowing  the  labour.  If  any 
article  wete  offered  to  us,  not  otherwise  attainable 
except  after  the  expiration  of  a  year,  we  should  be 
willing  to  give  something  to  enter  upon  present 
enjoyment.  On  the  part  of  the  capitalist  who 
produces  and  prepares  these  articles,  the  time 
required  for  the  purpose  is  evidently  a  considera- 
tion which  acts  upon  his  mind.  If  the  article  is 
wine,  he  knows  that  the  quality  is  improved  by 
keeping ;  he  is  aware  that  the  same  excellence 
cannot  be  imparted  to  any  wine  without  the 
employment  of  capital  for  an  equal  period  ;  and 
that  people  will  be  found  to  give  him  the  usual 
compensation  rather  than  employ  their  owb 
capital  in  producing  a  similar  article. "]    f.  y.  b. 

2q 


594 


DISTRESS 


DISTRESS.  The  different  kinds  of  distress 
may  be  distinguished  according  to  (a)  duration 
or  (&)  cause,  (a)  may  be  temporary  or  chronic. 
The  cotton  famine,  as  it  is  called,  during  the 
years  of  the  American  civil  war,  produced 
temporary  distress  in  Lancashire,  which  came 
to  an  end  with  the  resumption  of  business  at 
the  close  of  the  war ;  change  of  fashion  often 
does  the  same  in  towns  which  depend  upon  a 
single  industry,  as  Nottingham.  On  the  other 
hand  we  speak  of  the  distress  in  certain  parts 
of  London  as  chronic,  meaning  that  the  standard 
of  living  is  habitually  low.  So  too  (6)  the  cause 
may  vary.  Distress  may  be  due  to  disturb- 
ances of  the  market,  a  collapse  of  credit,  a  fall- 
ing off  in  demand,  or  a  change  in  its  direction. 
Again,  it  may  be  due  to  the  failure  of  a  crop, 
as  of  the  potato  in  the  west  of  Ireland,  or  the 
famines  in  various  parts  of  India.  The  treatment 
of  distress  will  vary  with  the  kind  of  distress, 
and  will  aim  either  at  the  alleviation  of  it,  when 
actually  existing,  or  the  removal  of  its  causes, 
and  so  the  prevention  of  its  recurrence.  In  the 
case  of  widespread  temporary  distress,  temporary 
measures  of  relief  are  often  tried.  The  poor- 
law  is  often  stretched  to  allow  of  relief  to  able- 
bodied  labourers  after  a  labour-test,  instead  of 
limiting  it  to  the  workhouse,  and  in  the  same 
spirit  charity  is  often  in  such  cases  admini- 
stered with  the  help  of  a  labour-test,  works  of 
public  improvement  being  set  on  foot,  and 
wages  paid  out  of  charitable  funds.  If  care- 
fully managed,  with  strict  inquiry  and  personal 
supervision,  these  remedies  are  sometimes  effect- 
ive, but  they  are  attended  with  great  dangers. 
They  are  often  demoralising  to  the  employed, 
for  the  work  done  is  quite  disproportionate  to 
the  wages  paid  ;  they  are  largely  resorted  to 
by  persons  whose  distress  is  chronic  and  due  to 
causes  within  their  own  control ;  they  attract 
applicants  from  other  districts,  and  so  swell 
the  evil ;  they  divert  employment  rather  than 
increase  it ;  they  come  to  be  regarded  as  a 
permanent  source  of  relief.  All  these  evils  are 
intensified  when  temporary  distress  is  met  by 
indiscriminate  almsgiving.  The  object  of 
remedies  should  be  to  remove  the  causes  from 
which  distress  comes,  but  this  is  no  easy  task. 
When  it  arises  from  speculation,  or  change  of 
fashion,  the  cure  can  be  found  only  in  a  higher 
sense  of  responsibility  on  the  part  of  both  pro- 
ducers and  consumers.  "When  it  is  due  to 
overcrowding  of  a  locality  or  an  industry,  the 
cure  must  be  sought  in  organised  effort  directed 
towards  an  increased  mobility  of  labour  from 
place  to  place  and  employment  to  emplojrment, 
an  increased  efficiency,  a  higher  standard  of 
living,  a  truer  knowledge  of  self-interest.  The 
state  can  do  much,  by  insisting  upon  the 
minimum  at  least  of  sanitary  progress,  the 
provision  of  an  elementary  and  perhaps  a 
technical  education  ;  but  the  individual,  by 
example  and  by  influence,  can  do  far  more. 


The  mistakes  so  commonly  made,  with  the 
best  intentions,  in  attempts  to  relieve  distress, 
arise  from  the  scale  on  which  such  attempts 
are  made  more  than  from  any  other  single 
cause.  Before  relief  can  be  undertaken  the 
mass  must  be  broken  up  into  its  constituent 
units,  for  every  individual  differs  in  history, 
in  circumstances,  and  in  prospects  from  every 
other,  and  to  attempt  to  apply  the  same  remedy 
to  aU  cases  is  as  dangerous  as  it  would  be  in 
medicine.  But  the  power  of  discriminating 
between  different  kinds  of  need  is  itself  the 
result  of  long  experience,  and  even  when  a 
judgment  has  been  formed  on  this  point,  the 
remedy  is  often  far  to  seek.  It  would  be 
impossible  to  lay  down  any  rule  which  would 
cover  all  cases  of  distress,  but  perhaps  the 
following  principles  apply  to  a  large  majority 
of  them.  1.  The  help  given  should  be  deter- 
mined far  more  by  the  future  than  the  past  or 
even  the  present,  the  two  latter  being  valuable 
chiefly  as  a  guide  to  the  former.  Many  a 
remedy  which  is  effective  for  the  moment  is 
disastrous  in  its  after  effects,  and  it  will  be  so 
in  proportion  as  it  fails  to  make  the  recipient 
independent  of  further  help.  2.  All  relief 
should  be  adequate  to  effect  its  purpose.  3. 
Help  in  money  and  kind,  though  often  inevit- 
able, should  be  sparingly  given,  for  it  tempts 
the  recipient  to  have  recourse  to  it  on  every 
emergency.  4.  The  results  of  the  help  given 
should  be  felt  after  the  need  for  it  is  past,  a 
man,  e.g.  who  has  been  assisted  by  a  loan  should 
be  taught,  when  the  loan  is  repaid,  to  continue 
the  economies  required  to  pay  the  instalments, 
and  put  an  equivalent  amount  weekly  in  the 
savings-bank.  5.  The  responsibility  of  the 
members  of  a  family,  one  to  another,  should  be 
enforced  and  developed.  6.  Lastly,  the  know- 
ledge and  the  judgment  necessary  to  put  these 
principles  in  practice  can  rarely  be  attained 
unless  men  act  in  some  sort  of  combination. 

[The  relief  of  distress  is  the  subject  of  the  publi- 
cations of  the  Charity  Organisation  Society,  15 
Buckingham  Street,  W.C.,  especially  the  Charity 
Organisation  Review,  and  the  preface  to  the 
Charities  Register.  —  Moggridge,  Method  in 
Almsgiving. — Booth,  Life  and  Labour. — Prety- 
man,  Dispauperisation. — Mackay,  The  English 
Po(yr.'\  L.  R.  P. 

DISTRESS  (Legal  Term).  The  legal  remedy 
known  as  distress  consists  in  the  taking  of  a 
chattel  of  the  wrongdoer  by  the  injured  party  as 
a  means  either  of  compelling  the  wrongdoer  to 
give  redress  or  of  obtaining  satisfaction  out  of 
the  thing  seized.  Generally  speaking,  the  party 
who  has  suffered  by  a  breach  of  contract,  or  by 
a  tort,  must  bring  his  action  for  damages,  and, 
if  the  wrongdoer  fails  to  pay  the  damages 
awarded,  must  have  the  goods  of  the  wrongdoer 
taken  in  execution  by  legal  process.  He  cannot 
of  his  own  motion  seize  chattels  of  the  wrong-  jJ 
doer.    The  remedy  by  distress  is  available  prin-     ^ 


DISTRESS— DISTRIBUTION 


596 


cipally  in  the  following  cases :  (a)  where  a 
tenant  has  made  default  in  paying  his  rent ;  (b) 
where  a  person  liable  to  tithe  rent  charge  has 
made  default  in  paying ;  (c)  where  a  person 
liable  to  pay  certain  rates  and  taxes,  e.g.  poor 
rate  or  highway  rate,  has  made  default  in  pay- 
ing. Also  when  cattle  stray  and  do  damage 
they  may  be  distrained  upon  by  the  party 
injured. 

Of  the  above  cases  the  first  is  the  most  im- 
portant. Subject  to  certain  exceptions,  the 
landlord  may  distrain  upon  the  tenant  as  soon 
as  the  tenant  has  made  default.  A  distress 
may  not  be  made  by  night.  In  making  a 
distress  it  is  not  lawful  to  break  open  the  outer 
door  of  a  house,  but  when  the  liouse  has  once 
been  entered,  any  inner  door  may  be  forced  in 
search  of  goods.  All  goods  found  on  the  pre- 
mises, wliether  belonging  to  the  tenant  or  to  a 
third  party,  may  be  taken  subject  to  certain 
exceptions,  of  which  the  chief  are  as  follows  : 

(a)  in  favour  of  the  goods  of  a  guest  at  an  inn  ; 

(b)  in  favour  of  goods  received  by  the  debtor  to 
be  worked  up  in  the  way  of  his  trade  ;  (c)  in 
favour  of  the  bedding,  the  apparel,  and  the 
tools  of  the  debtor  and  his  family.  The  goods 
distrained  must  be  kept  five  days, — or  fifteen 
days  if  the  owner  so  request  in  writing  and  give 
security  for  any  additional  cost  incurred, — after 
which  they  may  be  sold.  The  surplus  left, 
after  satisfying  the  debt  and  costs,  must  be  paid 
to  the  debtor.  If  the  proceeds  of  sale  do  not 
satisfy  the  debt  and  costs,  a  second  distress  can 
be  levied.  The  person  distrained  upon  has  legal 
remedies  for  irregular,  excessive,  or  wrongful 
distress. 

Historically  the  remedy  of  distress  appears  to 
be  a  relic  of  the  period  when  legislators  sought 
rather  to  regulate  than  to  suppress  the  use  of 
self-help  by  injured  parties.  It  occupies  a  far 
more  important  place  in  the  early  Celtic  and 
German  codes  than  in  modern  law.  It  has  been 
retained  only  in  cases  where  the  claim  of  the 
creditor  was  regarded  as  particularly  strong. 
It  has  been  criticised  as  exceptional,  as  harsh, 
and  as  unnecessary  ;  but  whether  it  should  be 
altogether  abolished  is  an  open  question. 

[For  the  outline  of  the  law  of  distress,  consult 
Stephen's  Commentaries,  vol.  iii.  pp.  261-274. — 
For  its  details  see  Oldham  and  Parker,  Law  of 
Distress. — For  an  historical  investigation  of  the 
remedy  see  Maine  On  the  Early  History  of  Institu- 
tions, lectures  9  and  10.]  f.  c.  m. 

DISTRIBUTION  (or  in  full  The  Distribu- 
tion OF  Wealth),  serves  in  most  economic 
text  books  as  the  heading  of  that  part  of  politi- 
cal economy  which  deals  with  difierent  classes 
of  income  such  as  rent,  profit,  interest,  wages, 
and  their  subdivisions.  The  use  of  the  phrase 
in  this  way  is  of  modern  origin. 

The  system  of  the  Physiocrats  {q.v.)  in- 
volved the  conception  of  the  annual  produce  of 
a  country  being  divided  between  the  productive 


class,  the  sterile  class,  and  the  landlord  clasa 
The  process  of  payments  and  exchanges,  inter 
mediate  between  production  and  consumption,  by 
which  the  division  (^''partage"  (Euvres  de  Ques- 
nay,  ed.  Oncken,  1888,  p.  315)  was  effected, 
was  called  *'the  distribution  of  the  expenses  of 
a  nation"  ("la  distribution  des  depenses  d'une 
nation,"  ibid.  p.  320).  The  Tableau  li'conomique 
(see  Physiocrats)  was  an  arithmetical  represen- 
tation of ' ' the  regular  order "  ("  Vordre  rdgidier, " 
ibid.  p.  319)ofthisdistributiou.  If  AdamSmith's 
accoimt  of  the  economical  table  {W.  of  N.,  bk. 
iv.  ch.  ix.)  be  compared  with  Quesnay's  Analyse 
du  Tableau  {CEuvres,  ed.  Oncken,  pp.  305-328), 
no  doubt  can  be  felt  that  the  latter  part  of  the 
title  of  book  i.  of  the  Wealth  of  Nations,  "of 
the  order  according  to  which  its  [labour's]  pro- 
duce is  naturally  distributed  among  the  differ- 
ent ranks  of  the  people,"  was  like  the  title  of 
Turgot's  Reflexions  sur  la  formation  et  la 
distribution  des  richesses,  suggested  by  the 
physiocratic  system.  But  in  adopting  the 
physiocratic  phrase,  Adam  Smith  slightly 
altered  its  meaning.  Though  he  followed  the 
physiocrats  in  attaching  great  importance  to  the 
division  of  the  produce  between  the  productive 
and  the  unproductive  class  ( JF.  of  N.,  bk.  i. 
ch.  vi.  ad  fin.,  and  bk.  ii.  passim),  what  he 
understood  by  the  distribution  of  the  produce 
seems  to  have  been,  chiefly  at  any  rate,  its 
division  into  wages,  profits,  and  rent ;  ' '  The 
price  ...  of  all  the  commodities  which  com- 
pose the  whole  annual  produce  of  the  labour  of 
every  country,  taken  complexly,  must  ...  be 
parcelled  out  among  difierent  inhabitants  of  the 
country,  either  as  the  wages  of  their  labour,  the 
profits  of  their  stock,  or  the  rent  of  their  land  ; 
the  whole  of  what  is  annually  either  collected 
or  produced  by  the  labour  of  every  society,  or, 
what  comes  to  the  same  thing,  the  whole  price 
of  it,  is  in  this  manner  originally  distributed 
among  some  of  its  different  members"  (ibid. 
bk.  i.  ch.  vi.) 

Having  thus  stated  that  the  produce  is 
divided  or  distributed  into  the  three  great  por- 
tions of  wages,  profit,  and  rent,  Adam  Smith 
might  have  been  expected  to  proceed  to  discuss 
the  circumstances  which  determine  the  propor- 
tions in  which  it  is  divided  between  the  three, 
to  explain  what  determines  the  relative  magni- 
tude of  the  whole  of  wages,  the  whole  of  profit, 
and  the  whole  of  rent.  He  does  not  do  so, 
however,  but  "endeavours  to  explain  what  are 
the  circumstances  which  determine"  (see  ch. 
vii.  ad  fin.),  the  absolute  magnitude  of  per  capita 
wages,  the  rate  of  profit  or  ratio  between  profit 
and  capital,  and  the  absolute  magnitude  of  rent 
per  acre.  There  is  therefore  considerable  justice 
in  J.  B.  Say's  remark  that  the  Wealth  of 
Nations  contains  "no  complete  and  well-con- 
nected account  of  the  manner  in  which  riches 
are  distributed  among  the  community  "  (Traits, 
8vo,  ed.   1876,  p.   37).     Say  did  not  supply 


696 


DISTRIBUTION 


much  of  the  deficiency  himself,  but  his  plan  of 
making  "production"  and  "distribution"  the 
lieadings  of  separate  parts  of  political  economy 
lias  been  generally  followed  by  later  economists. 
It  was  introduced  into  England  by  James  Mill 
in  his  Elements  (1821).  Ricardo  was  fed  by 
the  course  of  his  argument  against  the  corn 
laws  (see  his  Essay  on  the  Infiuence  of  a  Low  Price 
of  Com,  1815)  to  attach  great  importance  to 
the  proportions  in  which  the  whole  produce  of 
the  earth  is  divided  between  rent,  profit,  and 
wages.  "To  determine  the  laws  which  regulate 
this  distribution  is,"  he  declares,  "the  prin- 
cipal problem  in  political  economy  "  (Principles 
of  Pol.  Econ.,  pref.)  But  this  problem  did  not 
supersede  the  older  question  as  to  the  cir- 
cumstances which  determine  the  ratio  between 
interest  and  capital,  and  the  absolute  magnitude 
of  rent  and  per  capita  wages. 

As  regards  the  distribution  of  profits  and 
rent  among  individual  capitalists  and  landlords, 
economists  have  usually  been  silent,  taking  it 
for  granted  that  every  one  knows  why  some 
individuals  possess  much  property  and  others 
little  or  none.  As  regards  the  distribution  of 
wages  among  individual  labourers,  it  has  in  a 
similar  manner  been  assumed  that  the  reasons 
why  some  individuals  earn  more  than  others 
working  in  the  same  occupation  are  too  obvious 
to  require  explanation,  but  it  has  been  usual  to 
follow  Adam  Smith  (IF.  of  N.,  bk.  i.  ch.  x.), 
in  an  endeavour  to  explain  why  the  earnings  of 
the  average  workman  in  some  trades  are  greater 
than  those  of  the  average  workman  in  other 
trades. 

The  distribution  of  wealth  or  income  into 
rent,  profit,  and  wages,  and  the  distribution  of 
these  three  shares  among  individuals,  under 
present  conditions,  is  the  result  of  Exchange 
\q.y.)  Without  exchange  there  could  not, 
private  property  being  understood  to  be  estab- 
lished, be  any  conception  of  a  joint  income  to 
be  distributed.  The  value  of  the  joint  income 
reckoned  in  pounds  sterling  is  merely  the  sum 
of  the  values  of  all  the  separate  incomes,  and 
without  exchange  these  separate  incomes  could 
have  no  values  to  add  together  (see  Value). 
The  proportion  of  the  whole  income  which  falls 
to  any  man's  share  is  determined  by  the  value 
of  his  contribution  to  the  production  of  that 
income,  whether  his  contribution  be  work 
licrformed  or  the  use  of  land  and  capital. 
ITiis  fact  was  so  little  recognised  until  recently,' 
that  James  Mill  and  his  son  both  thought  it 
desirable  to  ])ut  distribution  before  exchau^e 
in  their  treatises  (see  Sidgwick,  Pol.  Econ.  bk 
ii.  ch.  i.  §  1). 

For  an  account  of  the  various  theories  which 
have  been  held  respecting  Profit,  Rent,  and 
Wages,  see  these  headings.  For  an  explanation 
of  the  "wealth"  the  distribution  of  which  is 
discussed  in  political  economy,  see  Wealth. 

The  word  distribution  is  sometimes  used  by 


economists  not  in  the  technical  sense  dealt  with 
above,  but  as  equivalent  to  the  process  of  con- 
veying commodities  from  the  producers  to  the 
consumers,  and  of  dividing  large  quantities  of 
a  commodity  into  small  quantities.  See  for 
example  the  long  discussion  on  distribution  in 
Malthus  (Pol.  Econ.,  1820,  ch.  vii.  §§  6,  7,  8, 
9).  This  use  of  the  word  and  kindred  expres- 
sions is  older  than  the  technical  usage.  Lewis 
Roberts,  in  his  Treasure  of  Traffike,  1641,  speaks 
of  "Commerce  or  Traflftke  which  distributeth  " 
the  produce  of  a  country  "into  forraigne  parts." 
Adam  Smith  says  that  money  "circulates  and 
distributes"  produce  "to  its  proper  consumers  " 
(W.  of  H.,  bk.  ii.  ch.  ii.),  and  we  still 
sometimes  speak  of  merchants  and  retailers  as 
"distributors,"  and  of  co-operative  shopkeeping 
as  "distributive  co-operation."  The  kind  of 
distribution  contemplated  in  these  modes  of  ex- 
pression is  a  part  of  the  process  of  Peoduction 

DISTRIBUTION,  Ethics  of.  The  prim- 
ary fact  of  economics  is  the  production  of 
wealth.  The  division  of  the  product  among 
those  who  create  it  is  secondary  in  logical  order  ] 
and,  in  a  sense,  in  importance.  Yet  the  most 
important  subject  of  thought  connected  with 
social  economy  is  distribution.  If  the  term  be 
used  broadly  enough  it  designates  all  of  the 
economic  process  that  presents  moral  problems 
for  solution.  On  the  settlement  of  the  ethical 
questions  concerning  the  division  of  the  social 
income  depends  not  only  the  peace  of  society 
but  the  fruitfulness  of  industry.  It  is  a  strik- 
ing fact  that  Ricardo,  whose  studies  carried 
economic  science  forward  in  the  direction  of  the  j 
truth  concerning  distribution,  but  stopped  short 
of  that  goal,  and  so  strengthened  the  hands  of 
social  agitators,  realised  the  paramount  im- 
portance of  the  subject  on  which  his  thought 
was  chiefly  concentrated :  "To  determine  the 
laws  which  regulate  this  distribution,"  he  says 
in  his  preface,  "is  the  principal  problem  in^ 
political  economy." 

Scientific  errors  concerning  the  law  of  dis- 
tribution react  more  harmfully  on  production 
than  do  errors  of  doctrine  concerning  production 
itself.  Among  self-asserting  people,  industry 
loses  fruitfulness  whenever  the  belief  is  widely ' 
diffused  that  products  are  shared  according  to 
an  unjust  principle.  If  it  were  a  general  con- 
viction that  social  evolution  is  in  the  direction 
of  iniquity, — that  distribution  abeady  robs  the : 
workers  and  will  rob  them  more  hereafter, — no  < 
force  could  prevent  a  violent  overturning  of 
the  social  order. 

Industry  has  its  fruits  and  its  sacrifices ;  it'i 
creates  useful  things  at  the  cost  of  working; 
and  waiting.  Where  production  is  carried  on;' 
in  a  collective  way,  both  the  products  andj 
the  burdens  of  the  process  have  to  be  shared  j 
by  different  classes  of  men  according  to  some] 
principle.     The  apportionment  that  has  to  bf  j 


DISTRIBUTION,  ETHICS  OF 


697 


made  is  not  only  of  products,  which  represent 
positive  values,  but  of  sacrifices,  which  may  be 
treated  as  negative  values  of  a  "subjective" 
kind.  While  the  term  distribution,  as  cur- 
rently used,  designates  only  the  apportionment 
of  the  positive  values,  or  products,  it  is 
capable  of  being  used  in  a  more  complete  sense, 
and  made  to  include  the  apportionment  of  the 
negative  ones  also.  It  would  then  include  all  of 
economic  science  that  involves  moral  problems. 

Both  parts  of  this  twofold  distributive 
process  must  in  any  case  be  studied  if  the 
ethical  questions  connected  with  industry  are 
to  be  solved.  There  is  no  independent  standard 
of  justice  in  the  distribution  of  products  only. 
What  a  man  ought  to  get  out  of  the  collective 
income  of  mankind  depends  on  how  much  he 
or  some  one  who  represents  him  has  sacrificed 
in  helping  to  create  it.  The  apj)ortionment  of 
the  positive  values  referred  to  is  inseparably 
connected  with  that  of  the  negative  values. 
Political  economy  must  tell  us  how  both 
products  and  biu'dens  are  actually  shared,  and 
ethics  must  tell  us  how  both  of  them  ought  to 
be  shared,  if  the  existing  plan  of  social  industry 
is  to  be  morally  tested. 

Political  ecoiioiny  has  not  as  yet  furnished 
a  theory  of  the  actual  distribution  of  positive 
values,  or  products  of  industry,  that  has  met 
with  general  acceptance.  It  has  scarcely 
attempted  to  furnish  a  theory  of  the  distribution 
of  the  negative  values.  Ethical  science  has 
not  furnished  a  clear  standard  of  justice  in  the 
double  apportionment. 

Every  producer  experiences  in  his  own  person 
the  double  elfect  of  industry  ;  he  is  first 
burdened  and  then  rewarded.  The  net  elfect 
of  the  two  influences  on  the  man's  well-being 
may  be  termed  the  subjective  resultant  of 
production.  A  complete  science  of  distribution 
must  study  the  economic  resultants  in  the  case 
of  difl'erent  classes  of  men.  How  is  a  labourer 
on  the  whole  afiected  by  industry  ?  What  is 
the  measure  of  the  net  benefit  that  comes  to 
him  from  this  source  ?  How  is  a  capitalist 
affected  ?  How  do  the  net  efiects  compare  with 
each  other  ?  What  tendencies  are  at  work  to 
change  the  two,  both  absolutely  and  relatively  ? 
These  are  economic  questions  ;  while  the  ethical 
question  is  what  the  resultants  in  the  two 
cases  ought  to  be. 

The  jjersonal  resultant  of  industry  is  always 
a  positive  quantity.  Work  yields  a  net  gain  ; 
the  fruits  of  it  are  worth  more  than  they  cost. 
For  the  most  hardly-used  classes  an  industrial 
life  is,  by  economic  tests,  more  than  worth 
living.  The  hours  of  labour  in  a  day  are 
increasingly  burdensome  as  the  period  of  work 
is  prolonged.  A  man  might  labour  three  hours 
a  day  with  little  weariness  and  no  injury. 
The  eighth  hour  is  wearying,  and  the  tenth  is 
more  so.  There  comes  a  time  at  which  work 
uatmally  stops,   if  the  man  is  free,   because 


working  longer  would  cost  more  in  the  way  of 
pain  than  it  would  secure  in  the  way  of  pleasure. 
Final  or  marginal  labour  is  that  which  just 
pays  for  the  weariness  that  it  costs.  The  gain 
that  comes  through  labour  oflsets  the  burden 
that  it  entails  at  the  point  in  the  working  day 
at  which  the  burden  is  greatest.  The  less 
onerous  labour  of  the  earlier  hours  affords  a  net 
personal  gain.  If  the  man  is  paid  by  the  hour 
he  earns  a  part  of  his  wages  very  easily.  Intra- 
marginal  labour,  as  we  may  term  it,  a  fiords  a 
net  subjective  gain,  what  some  would  call 
PiiODUCERs'  Rent  (q.i\) 

Though  the  wages  of  all  hours  may  be  equal 
by  money  standards,  they  are  of  unequal  utility 
to  the  man  who  gets  them.  His  first  earnings 
are  spent  on  necessities,  later  ones  on  comforts, 
and  final  or  marginal  ones  on  things  that  figure 
in  his  estimate  as  luxuries.  The  last  hour  of 
his  labour  may  ensure  to  him  only  the  least 
important  thing  that  he  gets  at  all.  It  is  the 
minimum  benefit  secured  by  an  hour's  labour 
that  offsets  the  maximum  sacrifice  caused  by  it. 
There  is  therefore  a  second  net  gain  coming  to 
the  worker  in  the  spending  of  his  money. 
As  the  sixpence  or  dime  that  is  spent  for  a 
luxury  benefits  the  man  enough  to  oli'set  the 
weariness  of  final  or  most  fatiguing  labour,  those 
that  are  spent  for  food,  clothing,  etc.,  aff'ord 
an  additional  benefit.  The  man  enriches  him- 
self whenever  he  buys  a  loaf  of  bread.  In 
general  the  sacrifices  and  the  benefits  of  pro- 
duction just  oflTset  each  other  at  the  point  at 
which  the  sacrifices  are  the  greatest  and  the 
gains  are  tlie  least.  Everywliere  except  at  the 
margin  the  gains  are  greater  and  the  sacrifices 
are  less. 

Again  the  positive  resultant  of  industry  is 
increased  by  social  organisation.  Anarcliy,  even 
if  it  were  peaceful,  would  increase  sacrifices  and 
diminish  rewards.  Whatever  might  be  true  of 
a  sparsely  settled  world,  a  crowded  world  is 
dependent  on  the  multiplying  of  productive 
power  that  combination  brings.  All  classes 
are  debtors  to  society.  No  serious  case  can  be 
made  against  the  existing  social  order  on  the 
ground  that  it  lessens  the  gain  that  labour 
naturally  brings. 

The  indictments  brought  against  the  social 
order  are  based  on  the  comparative  treatment 
that  society,  accords  to  men  of  different  classes. 
Are  the  benefits  conferred  on  different  ones 
what  they  ought  to  be  relatively  ?  Does  society 
proceed  capriciously  in  the  allotment  of  rewards 
and  sacrifices  ?  Do  some  classes  fail  to  get  the 
proportionate  benefit  that  is  properly  theirs  ? 
Are  social  tendencies  in  the  direction  of  equity 
or  away  from  it  ?  These  are  the  ethical  questions 
to  be  solved  by  a  comparison  of  the  ideally  just 
disti'ibution  with  the  actual  one. 

Of  the  ideals  of  distribution  that  have  been 
advanced  none  has  been  crude  enough  to  pro- 
vide for  the  apportionment  of  the  products  oJ 


598 


DISTRIBUTION,  ETHICS  OF 


industry  and  take  no  account  of  the  burdens. 
A  rule  of  equal  rewards  for  unequal  sacrifices 
would  have  no  moral  support.  Ethical  studies 
in  this  held  really  have  as  their  object  the  at- 
tainment  of  a  rule  for  adjusting  what  we  have 
termed  the  personal  resultants  of  industiy,  or  a 
rule  that,  if  followed  in  practice,  would  make 
the  net  effect  of  industry  on  the  welfare  of 
different  classes  equitable.  Communistic  theories 
make  equality  nearly  synonymous  with  equity  ; 
but  the  thing  that  is  to  be  equalised  is  seldom 
mere  property  or  income.  If  the  principle  of 
equality  be  carried  into  refinements,  so  as  to 
bring  to  one  level  the  net  benefits  that  society 
confers  on  all  its  members,  the  rule  approaches, 
though  it  is  still  far  from  reaching,  the  ultimate 
moral  ideal  of  distribution. 

The  better  socialistic  ideals  are  refinements  of 
the  rule  of  equality.  In  applying  the  rule  to 
individuals,  inheritance  is  the  first  disturbing 
influence  encountered.  The  law  of  inheritance 
is  based  on  a  certain  solidarity  of  families. 
Where  it  is  iu  force  the  sacrifices  of  a  parent 
may  accrue  to  the  benefit  of  a  child.  What  we 
have  termed  the  resultant  of  industry  in  the  case 
of  the  heir  to  an  estate  is  not  to  be  measured 
by  adding  together  positive  values,  represented 
by  the  enjoyments  that  the  property  brings, 
with  negative  values,  represented  by  the  in- 
heritor's own  sacrifices.  If  he  be  considered 
apart  from  his  family  the  values  in  the  case 
are  nearly  all  positive.  A  crude  levelling  of 
individuals'  net  gains  accruing  from  industry 
demands  the  abolition  not  only  of  inheritance, 
but  of  gifts  from  parents  to  children.  Where 
it  is  advocated  it  is  in  the  interest  of  purely  in- 
dividualistic equality. 

The  handing  over  of  aU  capital  to  the  state 
sweeps  away  even  more  completely  inequalities 
of  wealth  in  permanent  possession.  In  theory 
it  might  avoid  the  evil  connected  with  the 
abolition  of  inheritance,  that,  namely  of  reduc- 
ing the  capital  that  is  necessary  if  wages  are  to 
be  sustained  at  a  high  rate  ;  since  it  is  conceiv- 
able that  the  state  itself  might  accumulate 
capital  with  needed  rapidity.  This  measure 
also  would,  in  effect,  disregard  the  solidarity  of 
families  and  tend  to  put  men  on  a  footing  of 
individualistic  equality. 

Economic  difficulties  do  not  need  to  be  con- 
sidered in  the  shaping  of  a  moral  ideal.  The 
vesting  of  all  capital  in  the  state  would  save  the 
student  of  applied  ethics  one  serious  difficulty, 
that,  namely,  of  determining  whether  the  sacri- 
fice of  abstinence  is  unduly  rewarded  as  com- 
pared with  that  of  labour,  or,  in  other  words, 
whether  interest  is  too  high  as  compared  with 
wages.  A  socialistic  state  has  its  moral  duty 
simplified,  since  it  has  only  to  reward  different 
kmds  of  labour  equitably. 

A  scheme  that  is  too  crude  to  have  much 
support  makes  the  wages  and  the  working  hours 
equal  for  aU.     Estimate  the  wages  iu  money  or 


its  equivalent,  gauge  labour  by  time  only,  and 
bring  both  to  an  equality  in  the  case  of  the 
whole  adult  population.  Even  the  rewards  are 
not  thus  in  reality  equalised,  and  the  sacrifices 
are  very  unequal.  In  real  rewards  unmarried 
men  would  be  favoured  and  large  families  would 
suffer.  The  real  sacrifices  incurred  would  vary 
according  to  the  nature  of  the  work  performed. 

An  improvement  on  this  scheme  provides  a 
stipend  for  each  dependent  member  of  a  family, 
and  tries  to  equalise  sacrifices  by  so  reducing 
the  number  of  hours  of  labour  per  day  in  occu- 
pations that  are  disagreeable  or  hurtful,  as  to 
bring  all  employments  to  a  certain  uniformity 
of  burdensomeness.  In  the  case  of  very  dis- 
agreeable work  the  hours  would  be  reduced  to  a 
minimum,  while  in  occupations  that  are  less 
and  less  repellent  they  would  be  shortened 
proportionately  less.  Production  would  of 
course  suffer  by  this  arrangement,  and  the  ideal 
that  the  plan  of  division  presents  is  that  of 
small  but  equal  pay,  with  easy  work,  for  all. 

Another  scheme  does  not  content  itself  with 
equalising  what  we  have  termed  the  personal 
resultants  of  industry,  but  aims  to  level  in- 
equalities of  condition  that  lie  at  the  back  of 
industry  itself.  Society  should  do  more  for  the 
lame  and  the  blind  than  for  those  who  have  all 
faculties  in  possession,  in  order  that  the  ulti- 
mate condition  of  all  may  be  made  as  nearly 
equal  as  is  possible.  Here  is  the  levelling  policy 
in  perhaps  its  most  ambitious  mood.  It  is  not 
the  treatment  of  men  by  society  that  is  to  be 
equalised,  but  the  treatment  of  them  both  by 
nature  and  society.  The  industrial  organism 
is  to  deal  with  its  members  unequally  in  order 
that  it  may  somewhat  neutralise  the  partiality 
of  nature. 

A  rule  of  division  that  is  often  regarded  as 
ethically  lower  than  either  of  those  above 
specified  is  that  of  compensation  according  to 
actual  production.  Give  to  a  man  the  wealth 
that  he  creates,  neither  more  nor  less.  Every 
one  owns  what  he  brings  into  existence ;  let  not 
society  wrest  or  filch  from  him  any  part  of  it. 
Let  it  keep  itself  clear  from  robbery  and  fraud. 

If  workers  lived  side  by  side  in  peaceful 
anarchy,  with  no  division  of  labour  and  no  ex- 
changes, each  man  would  get  what  he  created. 
He  would  get  little,  but  he  would  get  aU  that 
would  be  his  own.  Introduce  now  a  social 
union  that  multiplies  products  ten-fold  but  in- 
creases some  men's  returns  only  five-fold,  and  you 
seem  to  benefit  these  men  and  to  rob  them  at 
the  same  time.  If  in  organised  industry  some 
of  the  product  that  is  distinctly  attributable 
to  labour  itself  finds  its  way  into  the  hands  of 
men  who  do  not  create  it,  the  labourer  suffers  a 
^v^ong,  even  though  the  share  that  he  still  keeps 
may  be  larger  by  reason  of  the  fact  of  his  con- 
nection with  the  men  who  rob  him.  Such  is 
the  conception  of  industrial  society  that  exists 
in   many   minds.     The   socialistic   indictment 


DISTRIBUTION,  LAW  OF 


59e 


against  society  is  that  it  filches  from  workers  a 
part  of  their  share  of  the  extra  product  of 
industry  due  to  organisation.  Does  society, 
under  natural  law,  take  from  labour  a  product 
that  is  distinctly  attributable  to  it  ?  This  is  one 
of  the  most  important  questions  in  economics. 
A  successful  analysis  of  social  production 
answers  it.  "What  needs  to  be  known  is  what 
part  of  the  composite  result  of  industry  is  dis- 
tinctly due  to  labour  itself.  In  a  land  peopled 
by  isolated  producers  and  managing  to  live  in 
peice,  each  man  would  get  his  own  ;  does  ex- 
change vitiate  this  result  ?  If  so,  organisation 
proceeds  here  on  an  unusual  principle  ;  since 
the  complications  of  society  as  a  rule  disguise 
essential  facts  of  primitive  industry,  but  do  not 
annul  them.  The  presumption  is  that  the  man 
who  got  his  own  when  he  worked  alone  gets  it 
when  he  trades  with  his  neighbour  on  terms  of 
genuine  freedom,  and  that  a  true  analysis  of 
social  relations  will  show  the  fact.  If  so, 
society  tends  actually  to  conform  to  the  rule 
"to  every  man  the  product  that  is  distinctly 
attributable  to  the  sacrifices  that  he  or  others 
in  his  interest  have  made. "  There  is  common 
honesty  in  the  distribution  that  takes  place 
under  natural  law. 

[The  literature  of  the  subject  of  economic  ethics 
is  not  as  scanty  as  it  is  one-sided.  The  basis  of 
the  socialistic  movement  is  ethical,  and  much  of 
its  literature  is  designed  to  prove  that  society  is 
organised  on  a  plan  that  systematically  wrongs 
workers  in  the  apportionment  of  the  social  income, 
A  defence  would  naturally  aim  to  show  that  the 
law  of  distribution  is  not  itself  iniquitous,  however 
many  particular  cases  of  injustice  might  arise 
under  it.  A  weak  point  in  the  defence  is  the  lack 
of  a  clear  demonstration  of  the  complete  nature  of 
the  actual  law  of  distribution,  a  lack  that,  as  is 
hoped,  may  soon  be  supplied.  In  the  meanwhile 
statistics  are  appealed  to  on  both  sides  to  prove, 
on  the  one  hand,  that  the  actual  apportionment  of 
wealth  is  departing  more  and  more  from  the  ideal 
standard,  and,  on  the  other,  that  it  is  tending 
towards  it.  For  important  socialistic  arguments 
see  Rodbertus's  Zur  Erkenntniss  unserer  Staats- 
wirthscho/tlichen  Zustande  ;  Marx's  Kapital ;  and 
Louis  Blanc's  Organisation  du  Travail.  For  an 
argument  aiming  to  prove  that  the  private  owner- 
ship of  land  involves  progressive  injustice  in  dis- 
tribution see  Henry  George's  Progress  and  Poverty. 
Of  the  numerous  replies  to  this  work,  that  contained 
in  F.  A.  Walker's  Land  and  its  Rent  may  be 
specially  mentioned.  An  historical  treatment  of 
this  subject  is  found  in  Thorold  Rogers's  Six 
Centuries  of  Work  and  Wages.  A  theory  of  a 
law  of  utilitarian  morality  in  economic  evolution 
is  presented  in  G.  de  Molinari's  La  Morale  Econo- 
miciue.  See  also  M.  Minghetti,  Des  Rapports  de 
VEconomie  Publique  avec  la  Morale  et  le  Droit 
(Guillaumin  et  Cie).  Many  of  the  best  studies  of 
the  favourable  features  of  the  existing  mode  of 
apportioning  the  social  income  are  to  be  sought 
in  the  standard  treatises  on  political  economy  men- 
tioned in  connection  with  article  Distribution, 
ItAVf  OF  {q.v.)]  J.B.  C. 


DISTRIBUTION,  Law  of.  The  most  im- 
portant share  of  the  income  of  society  is  the 
one  falling  to  labour.  The  so-called  "wage 
fund "  theory  accounted  for  the  rate  at  which 
labourers  are  paid  on  the  ground  that  wages 
come  from  a  fund  of  capital  devoted  to 
this  purpose,  and  that  the  rate  per  man  de- 
pends on  the  size  of  the  fund  and  the  number 
of  the  claimants.  The  discovery  of  the  fact 
that  wages  come  from  the  product  of  industry, 
and  not  from  capital,  has  made  a  new  theory 
necessary,  and  has  opened  the  way  to  the 
discovery  of  a  general  law  of  distribution. 

The  parties  in  the  division  of  the  general 
product  of  industry  are  —  (1)  those  who  con- 
tribute to  production  the  element  labour  ;  (2) 
those  who  contribute  instruments,  or  wealth 
in  productive  forms  ;  and  (3)  those  who  bring 
labour  and  productive  wealth  into  co-ordination 
by  hiring  both  of  these  agents,  and  receiving 
and  selling  their  products.  The  labour  furnished 
includes  the  work  of  management,  as  well  as 
other  kinds  of  industrial  effort ;  and  the  pro- 
ductive wealth,  as  the  term  is  here  used, 
includes  land  as  well  as  other  instruments. 
The  co-ordinating  function  is,  in  this  enumera- 
tion, kept  distinct  from  the  other  two  ;  the 
man  who  performs  it  is  not  to  be  treated  in 
this  connection  as  a  labourer  or  as  a  capitalist, 
but  as  the  employer  of  both  labour  and  capital. 

The  shares  to  be  accounted  for  are  thus 
wages,  interest,  and  pure  profit,  and  these  shares 
will  include  the  rent  of  land  and  the  wages  of 
superintendence.  The  generic  varieties  of  gain 
come  from  putting  forth  productive  effort  of 
some  kind,  from  furnishing  productive  wealth 
in  some  form,  and  from  bringing  the  effort  and 
the  wealth  into  co-ordination. 

The  scientific  law  of  distribution  determines 
what  reward  shall  attach  to  the  performing  of 
one  of  these  functions.  It  does  not  gauge  the 
income  of  a  particular  man,  since  a  man  nearly 
always  performs  more  than  one  function.  A 
capitalist  usually  works,  a  labourer  usually 
has  capital,  and  an  entrepreneur,  or  co-ordinator 
of  labour  and  capital,  almost  invariably  owns 
some  productive  wealth,  and  does  some  directive 
work.  A  scientific  study  aims  to  discover 
what  determines  the  gain  that  attaches  to  the 
working,  to  the  saving,  and  to  the  co-ordinat- 
ing. As  a  man  is  a  composite  functionary,  it 
tells  us  how  much  he  naturally  gets  in  each 
of  his  various  capacities. 

The  Nature  of  the  Distributive  Process. — Social 
production  is  a  synthesis  of  distinguishable 
elements.  Distribution  is  an  analysis  ;  and  it 
reverses  the  synthetic  operation  step  by  step. 
In  organised  production  one  worker  does  not 


complete  a  product  from  the  liegini 


if  he 


-applies  his  energy  to  crude  nature  and  begins 
"the  making  of  something  that  the  wants  of 
society  require,  he  ]  asses  the  product  in  an 
incomplete  state  to  a  successor.      This   man 


600 


DISTRIBUTION,  LAW  OF 


in  turn  advances  the  article  nearer  to  completion 
and  hands  it  over  to  a  third  man.  The  product, 
when  ready  for  final  use,  has  passed  through 
the  hands  of  a  series  of  workers  each  of  whom 
has  put  his  touch  on  it  and  passed  it  to  his 


The  process  may  be  represented  by  the 
following  diagi-am : — 

SyrUheds  resulting  in  the  completed  product, 
clothing. 


Ist  Sub-Product. 

Elementary  Utility. 

Wool. 


2ncl  Sub-P. 
Place  U. 
Transport- 
ing. 


Resulting  from  the 
joint  action  of  Ca- 
pital and  Labour. 


Joint  re- 
sult of  C. 
and  L'. 


3rd  Sub-P. 
Form  U. 

Manufac- 
turing. 


Joint  re- 
sult of  C", 
audL". 


4th  Sub-P. 
Form  U. 
Tailoring. 


Joint  re- 
sult of  C". 
and  L'". 


The  garment,  when  completed,  is  an  aggre- 
gate of  distinct  utilities,  and  we  use  the  term 
sub-product  to  denote  the  quality  imparted  to 
it  by  each  specific  group  of  producers.  The 
sharing  of  the  value  that  a  coat  represents 
among  the  groups  that  have  performed  the 
specific  operations  of  production  is  an  analytical 
operation,  that  follows,  in  a  reverse  direction, 
the  steps  of  the  productive  synthesis. 

The  first  sub-product  in  the  series  is  wool. 
It  embodies  an  "elementary  utility,"  or  one 
that  results  from  calling  a  raw  material  into 
existence.  The  merchant's  sub-product  is  only 
the  special  utility  imparted  to  the  wool  by 
conveying  it  to  his  warehouse,  assorting  it, 
and  dividing  it  into  quantities  convenient  for 
purchasers.  It  is  mainly  a  "place  utility," 
which  is  the  service -rendering  quality  that  a 
thing  acquires  by  being  taken  to  the  place 
where  it  can  be  used  ;  though  in  a  complete 
statement  it  would  be  necessary  to  recognise 
a  "form-utility"  due  to  assorting  and  dividing. 
The  manufacturer's  sub -product  is  not  the 
cloth,  but  the  "form-utility"  imparted  to  the 
wool  by  transmuting  it  into  cloth.  The  tailor's 
sub-product  is  the  further  "form-utility"  im- 
parted to  the  cloth  by  making  a  coat  of  it.  Each 
specific  utility  is  created  by  the  joint  action 
of  labour  and  capital ;  and  each  of  these  agents 
must  have  its  share  of  the  value  embodied  in 
its  sub-product. 

In  order  that  the  action  of  labour  and  capital 
within  the  sub-groups  may  be  a  joint -action 
at  all,  it  is  necessary  that  a  certain  co-ordinat- 
ing act  be  done.  Some  one  must  hire  labour 
of  the  right  kind,  borrow  capital  and  invest 
it  in  the  proper  forms,  and  cause  the  two  to 
co-operate.  This  is  the  work  of  the  entre- 
preneur, in  an  unusually  limited  sense  of  the 
term.  This  functionary,  in  his  capacity  as 
entrepreneur,  is  not  a  capitalist  and  not  a 
labourer,  however  frequently  it  may  happen 
that  the  man  who  performs  the  co-ordinating 
function  may  perform  others  as  well.  The 
uo-ordiuator,  as  such,  is  not  a  business  manager 


or  superintendent.  The  performing  of  this 
function  does  not  require  salaried  labour ; 
indeed,  after  the  process  is  begun,  it  scarcely 
requires  efibrt  at  all. 

Bargaining  operations  first  divide  the  total 
product  of  industry  among  the  general  groups 
of  which  society  as  a  whole  is  composed.  How 
much  wealth  shall  come  to  the  entke  group 
of  workers,  capitalists,  and  entrepreneurs  who 
are  engaged  in  the  creating  of  the  finished 
products,  woollen  garments  ?  That  depends  on 
the  price  for  which  the  garments  seU.  A 
myriad  of  finished  products  from  other  groups 
in  the  world  at  large  must  come,  by  way  of 
exchange,  to  minister  to  the  wants  of  the  men  in 
this  one  group  ;  and  the  quantity  and  quality 
of  those  products  is  fixed  by  the  sale  of  the 
clothing.  This  sale,  and  others  like  it,  perform 
the  first  and  most  generic  dividing  act  that 
takes  place  in  the  process  of  distribution.  It 
determines  the  total  income  of  those  who  con- 
tribute to  the  production  of  clothing. 

What  fixes  the  part  of  the  income  of  this 
general  group  that  goes  to  each  of  the  sub-groups 
that  compose  it  ?  Bargains  again.  Each  group 
must  buy  the  utilities  made  by  those  that  come 
earlier  in  the  series,  and  seU  them,  with  the 
addition  of  its  own  utility,  to  the  group  that 
succeeds  it.  The  manufacturing  group  buys 
wool  and  sells  cloth  ;  and  what  it  receives,  less 
what  it  pays,  constitutes  the  reward  of  the 
manufacturing  operation.  As  the  first  division 
of  the  income  of  society  resolves  it  into  rewards 
of  general  producing  groups,  the  first  sub- 
division resolves  the  portion  falling  to  one 
general  group  into  shares  for  the  sub-groups 
that  constitute  it. 

A  further  division  is  to  be  effected  :  it  is 
that  of  the  shares  falling  to  labourers,  to 
capitalists,  and  to  entrepreneurs  in  each  sub- 
group. Here  is  the  test  operation  of  dis- 
tribution ;  in  this  smallest  of  fields  is  created 
and  divided  the  wealth  that  rewards  each  class 
in  industrial  society. 

The  productive  operation  from  the  fruit  of 
which  labour  and  capital  get  their  pay  is 
intra-groupal ;  it  goes  on  within  the  specific 
industry  in  which  a  particular  force  of  men  and 
their  quota  of  capital  are  engaged.  The  value 
that  rewards  woollen  weavers  and  spinners  and 
the  men  who  furnish  them  capital  is  created 
wholly  within  the  mill,  and  the  sum  that  is 
divided  between  these  classes  is  a  sum  on  which 
no  others  have  any  claim.  Yet  the  fact  that 
labour  and  capital  both  migrate  freely  from 
group  to  group,  so  that  workers  from  any 
group  are  able  to  share  in  the  special  gains 
that  may  come  to  the  earners  in  any  other, 
creates  a  certain  solidarity  of  labour  on  the  one 
hand,  and  capital  on  the  other.  Give  to  the 
wool  spinners  an  advance  of  w?iges,  and  move- 
ments of  labour  will  in  the  end  distribute  the 
gain  among  the  whole  working  class.      On  the 


DISTEIBUTION,  LAW  OF 


601 


other  hand,  change  the  cardinal  relations  of 
labour  and  capital  as  a  whole,  and  you  change 
them  in  the  end  within  every  sub-group. 
Labour  is  in  reality  t7'ans-groupal,  and  capital 
is  the  same.  Each  is  a  productive  agent,  the 
field  of  which  extends  directly  across  the  sub- 
groups of  the  diagram.  It  is  the  relation  of 
all  capital  to  all  labour  that  determines  wages 
and  interest.  The  law  of  wages  is  nothing  if 
not  general,  and  the  same  is  true  of  the  cor- 
relative law  of  interest. 

It  is  a  familiar  fact  that  interest  and  wages 
tend  toward  uniformity  in  different  occupations. 
Men  of  different  productive  powers  may  earn 
different  rewards,  even  within  a  single  trade  ; 
and  the  labour  of  management  regularly 
receives  more  than  work  of  the  ordinary  kinds. 
Men  difier  in  the  amount  of  working  force 
that  they  possess,  but  men  of  like  power  tend 
to  receive  uniform  wages  throughout  the  series 
of  industrial  groups.  If  wages  are  high  in  the 
woollen  mill  the  young  men  and  women  who 
are  about  entering  the  field  seek  out  this  part 
of  it,  and  by  their  competition  reduce  the 
wages  there  prevalent  to  the  rate  that  prevails 
elsewhere.  Interest  tends  to  a  similar  uni- 
formity ;  under  free  competition  it  tends  to 
keep  the  same  rate  in  all  industries. 

With  interest  has  often  been  vaguely  grouped 
what  we  have  termed  pure  profit  itself;  the 
gross  gains  loosely  attributed  to  capital  tend 
toward  equality.  It  is,  however,  in  a  special 
way  that  the  element  that  we  have  distinguished 
as  pure  profit  tends  toward  equality  in  different 
industries.  Wherever  it  comes  into  existence 
it  sets  at  work  forces  that  tend  to  sweep  it 
again  out  of  existence.  In  a  way  this  gain  is 
self- annihilating.  The  uniform  rate  toward 
which  pure  profit  tends, — though  it  never 
reaches  it  in  all  groups  at  once, — is  a  zero  rate. 
Here,  indeed,  we  reach  controverted  ground, 
and  can  claim  only  to  present  one  theory,  not 
a  view  that  has  universal  support ;  but  the 
evidence  in  favour  of  the  correctness  of  the 
view  is  simple  and  conclusive.  Competition 
tends  to  annihilate  pure  profit.  The  existence 
in  one  sub-gi'oup  of  a  gain  that  is  in  excess 
both  of  interest  on  all  the  productive  wealth 
that  is  there  used,  and  of  pay  for  all  labour,  is 
an  inducement  to  the  entrepreneurs  of  the 
group  to  hire  in  the  market  both  capital  and 
labour,  and  secure  the  pure  profit  that  their 
joint  industry  creates.  Let  w^oollen  mills  pay 
wages,  including  salaries,  and  a  double  interest 
on  the  capital  that  they  use,  and  the  mills  will 
speedily  enlarge  their  capacity.  The  increase 
in  the  product  will  then  reduce  the  price  of  it, 
and  ultimately  bring  the  enlargement  to  an 
end.  Under  natural  law  the  sub-groups  are  in 
stable  equilibrium  when,  aside  from  insurance 
and  taxes,  each  earns  wages  on  all  labour^ 
including  the  labour  of  management,  interest 
on  all   capital  employed,    and  nothing  more. 


On  this  point  the  testimony  of  experience 
confirms  the  conclusions  of  theory. 

The  equilibrium  is  never  in  practice  perfect. 
Causes  that  cannot  here  be  analysed  in  any 
fulness  cause  the  element  pure  profit  to  con- 
tinually reappear.  Inventions,  as  applied  in 
particular  industries,  give  to  one  and  another 
of  the  sub-groups  a  gain  that  is  in  excess  of 
that  which  perfectly  stable  conditions  would 
afford.  The  occupation  of  new  land  creates, 
in  a  local  way,  a  pure  profit  for  the  earlier 
comers.  Continually  appearing  in  particular 
parts  -of  the  field,  and  slowly  disappearing  by 
reason  of  competition, — such  is  this  element  of 
the  social  income.  If  we  watch  a  single  sub- 
group we  find  the  profit  at  intervals  appearing 
and  disappearing;  if  we  watch  the  industrial 
field  as  a  whole  we  find  it  everywhere  present, 
though  not  long  at  the  same  points. 

Pure  profit  depends  on  a  relation  between 
industrial  groups.  What  the  manufacturer 
pays  to  the  earlier  groups  in  the  series  above 
represented,  and  what  he  receives  from  the 
tailoring  gi'oup,  determine  this  part  of  his  gain. 
The  actual  position  of  the  entrepreneur  himself, 
in  the  diagram  that  describes  the  sub-groups, 
is  on  the  line  that  separates  his  own  industry 
from  the  following  one.  He  is  a  purchaser  of 
everything  that  is  produced  on  the  left  of  that 
line.  In  the  buying  of  materials  he  purchases- 
the  products  of  the  earlier  sub-groups,  and  in 
the  paying  of  wages  and  interest  he  virtually 
buys  the  sub-product  created  in  the  group  to 
which  he  himself  belongs.  The  entrepreneur 
of  the  woollen  mill  buys  wool,  and  so  pays  for 
the  sub-products  created  by  wool  growers  and 
merchants  ;  and  he  buys  the  form-utility  created 
in  the  woollen  mill  itself  by  making  bargains 
with  workmen  and  capitalists,  giving  them 
fixed  sums,  and  inducing  them  to  relinquish 
their  claims  on  the  cloth.  As  the  place  of  a 
particular  workman  and  of  a  particular  amount 
of  capital  is,  in  the  diagi-am,  intra-groupal,  so 
that  of  a  particular  entrepreneur  is  inter -groupal. 
Workers  and  capitalists  get  their  pay  from 
results  secured  wholly  within  their  own  in- 
dustries, while  entrepreneurs  get  theirs  from 
the  fruits  of  mercantile  transactions  between 
earlier  groups  and  later  ones.  Pure  profit  does 
not  depend  on  the  relation  between  capital  and 
labour.  Moreover,  where  this  profit  exists  it 
is  localj  it  depends  on  the  relations  between 
adjacent  groups. 

We  have  shown  that  there  is  no  law  of  wages 
that  is  merely  local.  There  is  no  force  that 
gauges  the  pay  of  wool-spinning  independently 
of  the  wages  paid  in  other  employments. 
There  is  a  level  toAvard  Avhich  all  wages  tend. 
There  is  likewise  a  level  toward  which  interest 
in  every  group  tends.  What  is  the  law  that 
fixes  these  levels  ?  What  is  the  general  law  of 
wages  and  interest  ?  Here  again  we  are  on 
ground    that   is    actively   contested,    and    we 


602 


DISTEIBUTION 


therefore  only  indicate  the  nature  of  a  certain 
theory  without  claiming  for  it  a  position  of 
general  acceptance,  and  without  arguing  any 
points  in  controversy. 

In  presenting  it  we  may  utilise  a  Ricardian 
formula  for  determining  the  rent. of  land.  If 
we  apply  to  a  fixed  area  of  land  an  increasing 
amount  of  labour,  we  get  returns  that  diminish 
-per  capita.  The  first  man  set  working  on 
100  acres  creates  a  certain  amount  of  wealth 
as  the  result  of  the  tillage.  Adding  a  second 
man  does  not  double  the  crop.  Adding  a 
third  does  not  increase  by  a  half  the  product 
due  to  the  former  two.  Each  man,  as  he 
comes  into  the  field,  adds  less  to  the  total 
output  of  the  industry  than  did  any  of  his 
predecessors. 

This  hypothesis  makes  the  men  enter  the 
field  in  a  certain  order  of  time,  and  the  one 
who  is  the  final  man  is  so  in  a  literal  sense — he 
is  the  last  to  arrive.  Actually  putting  the 
men  into  the  field  one  at  a  time  is  not  necessary 
in  order  to  reveal  the  principle  that  governs  the 
final  productivity  of  labour.  Let  the  full 
complement  of  men  occupy  the  field  at  once, 
and  there  wUl  still  be  what  may  be  treated  as 
the  final  increment  of  labour.  Take  any  man 
away  from  the  force  that  tills  the  field,  and  the 
remaining  men  will  gain  in  per  capita  pro- 
ductivity by  reason  of  his  absence.  The 
departure  of  one  man  out  of  a  force  numbering 
twenty  does  not  reduce  the  crop  by  a  twentieth, 
since  the  nineteen  men  remaining  work  at 
better  advantage  by  reason  of  the  withdrawal 
of  one.  The  final  productivity  of  labour  is 
gauged  by  what  would  be  lost  if  one  man  out 
of  the  force  were  to  stop  working.  We  may, 
by  way  of  illustration,  actually  set  the  men 
working  one  at  a  time,  and  find  what  the  last 
comer  creates  ;  or  we  may  set  them  all  working 
at  once  and  see  wliat  would  be  lost  by  the 
departure  of  one.  The  conclusion  is  the  same 
in  either  case :  the  final  unit  of  labour  is  the 
least  productive. 

If,  now,  land  were  the  only  form  of  pro- 
ductive wealth  that  figured  in  the  case,  wages 
would  equal  the  amount  created  by  this  final  or 
twentieth  man.  That  would  gauge  the  amount 
that  the  employer  would  lose  through  the 
departure  of  any  one  man  in  the  force.  It 
would  determine  what  he  could  afford  to  pay 
to  any  one.  Each  man  tends  to  get  what  he  is 
separately  worth. 

•What  would  be  true  in  the  case  of  labour 
applied  to  land,  and  using  no  other  capital 
worth  considering,  is  actually  true  of  labour 
applied  to  a  fixed  amount  of  general  capital, 
or  to  a  fixed  quantum  of  wealth  in  all  pro- 
ductive forms,  including  both  land  and  other 
instruments.  For  the  field  of  limited  extent 
in  the  Ricardian  illusti-ation  substitute  a  fixed 
value,  expressible  in  i)0unds  or  dollars,  and 
invested   in  such  appliances  of  every  kind  as 


the  needs  of  the  working  community  require. 
If  there  are  a  hundred  men  in  the  force,  the 
departure  of  one  of  them  will  not  reduce  the 
product  by  1  per  cent.  His  departure  will  add 
somewhat  to  the  productivity  of  the  remaining 
workers.  After  he  is  gone  the  capital  will 
adapt  itself  in  form  to  the  needs  of  the  ninety- 
nine,  and  it  will  be  in  a  slight  degree  more 
ample  in  quantity  per  man.  Wages  are  gauged, 
as  in  the  former  case,  by  the  final  productivity 
of  labour.  What  on  the  whole  is  lost  by  the 
departure  of  one  man  fixes  the  importance  to 
employers  of  every  man.  If  each  man  gets 
what  employers  would  lose  by  his  absence,  he 
gets  what  he  is  eli'ectively  worth. 

This  principle  in  a  reversed  application  fixes 
the  rate  of  interest.  It  is  the  productivity  of 
the  final  increment  of  capital,  as  employed  by 
a  fixed  labour  force,  that  gauges  the  pay  of 
each  increment.  Let  there  be  100  men  using 
100  units  of  capital.  Take,  now,  one  unit  of 
capital  away,  and  you  will  not  reduce  the 
product  by  1  per  cent.  The  99  units  of 
capital  will  have  gained  in  productivity  per 
unit  in  consequence  of  the  departure  of  the 
hundredth.  The  loss  inflicted  on  the  entre- 
preneur by  the  withdrawal  of  the  one  unit  of 
capital  gauges  the  importance  of  any  single 
unit.  Each  unit  of  capital  gets  as  its  com- 
pensation what  would  be  lost  if  one  unit  of 
capital  were  withdrawn.  This  diminution  of 
the  total  product  due  to  the  departure  of  the 
final  unit  of  capital  gauges  the  importance  to 
the  entrepreneur  of  each  separate  iinit.  It 
determines  what  he  will  pay  for  the  use  of  each 
one.  Interest  is  therefore  gauged  by  the  final 
productivity  of  capital.  Each  pound  or  doUar 
tends,  under  natural  law,  to  secure  for  its 
owner  what,  in  production,  it  is  separately 
worth. 

[For  statements  in  harmony  with  this  theory  see 
J.  B.  Clark's  Philosophy  of  Wealth  and  Capital 
and  its  Earnings,  and  Clark  and  Gidding's  Modei-n 
Distribviive  Process.  See  also  Quarterly  Journal 
of  Economics  for  April  1891. 

For  other  views  on  the  subject  see  F.  A. 
Walker's  Political  Economy,  and  E.  v.  Bdhm- 
Bawerk's  Capital  and  Interest. — J.  E.  Cairnes's 
Leading  Principles  of  Political  Economy. — F.  D. 
Longe,  Refutation  of  the  Wage  Fund  Theory  oj 
Modem  Political  Economy. — W.  T.  Thornton's 
treatise  on  Labour. — F.  A.  Walker's  treatise  on 
Wages. — Henry  George's  Progress  and  Poverty. — 
F.  V.  Wieser's  Nat'Arlicfte  Werth,  and  the  treatises 
of  Adam  Smith,  Ricardo,  J.  S.  Mill,  Jevons, 
Carey,  Sidgwick,  Marshall,  A.  C.  Pigou,  Roscher, 
Wagner,  Knies,  Cohn,  Schouberg,  J.  B.  Say, 
Garnibb,  Gide,  and  others.]  j.  b.  c. 

DISTRIBUTION,  Uses  of  the  Term.  In 
the  early  half  of  this  century  English  econo- 
mists fell  into  the  habit  of  grouping  their 
subjects  under  three  heads,  of  which  Distribu- 
tion and  Production  were  almost  always  two, 
while  the   third   varied  (Consumption,    James 


DISTRIBUTION— DISTRIBUTION  OF  THE  PRECIOUS  METALS      603 


Mill ;  the  Nature  of  Wealth,  Senior  and  John 
]\[ill).  Adam  Smith  had  not  followed  the 
physiocrats  and  Turgot  (''Formation  et  Dis- 
tribution de  la  Richesse  ")  in  giving  prominence 
to  the  term,  and  he  has  often  been  accused  of 
neglecting  distribution  in  favour  of  production 
(see  Sidgwick,  Pol.  Econ.,  pp.  24-25).  Ricardo, 
on  the  contrary,  wrote  to  Malthus  in  1820  : 
"Political  Economy  you  think  is  an  inquiry 
into  the  nature  and  causes  of  wealth  ;  I  think 
it  should  rather  be  called  an  inquiry  into 
the  laws  which  determine  the  division  of  the 
produce  of  industry  amongst  the  classes  who 
conciu-  in  its  formation.  Every  day  I  am  more 
satisted  that  the  former  inquiry  is  vain  and 
delusive,  and  the  latter  only  tite  true  object  of  the 
science"  {Letters,  p.  175).  John  Mill  {Pol.  Econ., 
1848)  lays  stress  on  the  difference  which,  he 
says,  exists  between  the  laws  of  production  and 
the  laws  of  distribution.  The  former  are 
physical  facts  ;  the  latter  are  of  human  institu- 
tion solely.  It  has  seemed  to  later  economists 
hardly  possible  to  assert  the  purely  physical 
character  of  the  first  (see  Mill  himself.  Unsettled 
Questions,  p.  133)  or  the  purely  arbitrary  char- 
acter of  the  second,  or  generally  speaking  to  con- 
sider distribution  quite  apart  from  production, 
consumption,  and  the  nature  of  wealth.  But 
it  has  seemed  desirable  to  define  the  several  dis- 
tinct notions  clearly,  for  the  purpose  of  methodic 
investigation,  and  the  question  arises  whether 
(a)  distribution  is  to  be  detached  from  exchange 
and  transportation,  etc.,  or  {b)  is  to  be 
the  genus  of  which  they  are  species.  The 
latter  is  the  view  implied  in  the  common 
language  of  men.  The  dividend  is  sometimes 
conceived  as  the  total  wealth,  sometimes  as  the 
total  income  of  the  country,  the  participants 
being  the  inhabitants.  Distribution  of  wealth 
is  perhaps  less  strictly  a  question  for  the  mere 
economist  than  distribution  of  income.  The 
narrower  view  (advocated  amongst  others  by 
Prof.  Walker,  Pol.  Econ.  (London,  1888),  pp.  31, 
187-193,  and  by  Ricardo  in  the  words  above 
quoted)  is  that  distribution  must  be  confined 
to  the  sharing  of  the  product  among  the 
producers.  It  is  urged  again  that  it  must  not 
include  mere  transportation  of  goods,  e.g.  from 
the  place  where  they  are  not  wanted  and  not 
saleable  to  the  place  where  they  are  both, — this 
being  not  a  distribution  but  a  completing  act  of 
production  (Sidgwick,  Pol.  Econ.,  p.  171,  etc.) 
According  to  this  view  it  would  exclude  many 
cases  of  exchange,  for  exchange  might  mean  a 
transfer  from  producers  to  non-producers.  On 
the  other  hand,  John  Mill  expressly  regards 
distribution  as  including  exchange  (which  is 
simply  distribution  under  competition,  see  Pol. 
Econ.,  III.  i,  §  1),  and  certainly  to  Ricardo  ex- 
change and  distribution  were  nearly  convertible 
terms.  Professor  Marshall  even  devotes  «, 
special  section  to  "value  or  distribution  and 
exchange"  {Principles,  bk.  vii.)    Professor  New- 


comb  {Pol.  Econ.,  II.  ii.  61)  avoids  the  term  and 
describes  the  three  operations  needed  to  present 
the  consumer  with  the  finished  article  as 
production,  transportation,  and  exchange.  If 
we  confine  distribution  to  a  sharing  among 
producers,  we  find  that  we  must  (1)  include 
those  who  are  not  producers  in  the  ordinary 
sense  of  the  word,  e.g.  landlords,  and  (2)  we 
must  exclude  middlemen  and  retailers  into 
whose  hands  the  goods  pass  by  exchange  on 
their  way  to  the  consumer,  and  (3)  we  must 
nevertheless  include  labourers  and  capitalists 
who  have  bargained  for  parts  of  the  product, 
as  wages  and  interest.  Exchange  would  thus 
be  partly  excluded,  partly  included  ;  and  we  are 
made  to  realise  the  difficulty  of  separating  in 
theory  what  is  conjoined  in  practice.       J.  l. 

DISTRIBUTION,  COST  OF.  See  Produc- 
tion AND  DiSTKIBUTION. 

DISTRIBUTION,  STATUTES  OF.  These 
Statutes  (22  &  23  Car.  II.  c.  10  and  1  Jas. 
II.  c.  17)  regulate  the  distribution  of  the 
residuary  personal  estate  of  a  person  dying 
intestate — not  being  a  married  woman.  In 
case  of  the  intestacy  of  a  married  woman  tlie 
husband  takes  the  whole  residuary  personalty 
for  his  own  benefit.  In  all  other  cases  it  is 
divided  as  follows  : — 

1.  The  widow  takes  one -third  if  any  de- 
scendants survived  the  intestate,  and  one-half 
if  none  survived. 

2.  The  children  and  descendants  of  deceased 
children  take  two-thirds  if  a  widow  survived 
the  intestate,  and  the  whole  if  the  intestate 
left  no  widow  ;  the  descendants  of  deceased 
children  in  each  generation  together  take  the 
share  which  their  deceased  parent  would  have 
had  if  he  or  she  had  survived  the  intestate. 

3.  The  half  remaining  in  the  case  of  a  widow 
but  no  descendants  surviving  the  intestate,  or 
the  whole  in  the  case  of  neither  widow  nor  de- 
scendants surviving  him,  goes  to  his  father, 
and  if  the  latter  does  not  survive  him,  to  his 
mother,  his  brothers  and  sisters,  and  the  children 
(but  not  the  remoter  descendants)  of  brothers 
and  sisters,  the  mother  and  each  brother  or 
sister  taking  equal  shares,  and  the  children  of  a 
deceased  brother  or  sister  together  taking  the 
share  which  their  deceased  parent  would  have 
had,  had  he  survived  the  intestate.  If  none  of 
the  relatives  named  survive  the  intestate  the 
next  of-  kin  nearest  in  degree  are  entitled  in 
equal  shares.  (See  Bequest,  Power  of  ; 
Descent  of  Property.)  e.  s. 

DISTRIBUTION  OF  THE  PRECIOUS 
METALS.  On  this  branch  of  the  theory  of 
international  trade  the  conclusions  of  the 
"older  school"  of  economists  are  still,  in  the 
main,  unshaken.  Adam  Smith's  contribution 
to  the  general  theory,  although  invaluable  (see 
Mercantile  System),  was  largely  negative. 
It  is  to  his  successor  Ricardo  that  we  owe  the 
first  clear  statement  of  the  principles  which 


604 


DISTRIBUTION  OF  THE  PRECIOUS  METALS 


regulate  the  territorial  distribution  of  the 
precious  metals  {Principles,  ch.  vii.  p.  77). 
"Gold  and  silver,  having  been  chosen  for  the 
general  medium  of  circulation,  are,  by  the 
competition  of  commerce,  distributed  in  such 
proportions  amongst  the  different  countries  of 
the  world  as  to  accommodate  themselves  to 
the  natural  traflBc  which  would  take  place  if 
no  such  metals  existed,  and  the  trade  between 
countries  was  purely  a  trade  of  barter."  Not- 
withstanding modem  developments  of  trade 
and  credit,  this  dictum,  slightly  supplemented, 
still  holds  good.  To  realise  its  full  meaning 
it  is  necessary  to  go  back  a  stage,  and  to  recall 
the  principle  which  regulates  international 
trade  when  carried  on  by  barter  (see  Barter). 
This  has  been  stated  by  Mill  (Principles,  bk. 
iii.  ch.  xviii.)  "The  produce  of  a  country  ex- 
changes for  the  produce  of  other  countries  at 
such  values  as  are  required  in  order  that  the 
whole  of  her  exports  may  exactly  pay  for  the 
whole  of  her  imports."  This  law  of  interna- 
tional values  applies  also,  without  essential 
alteration,  after  the  introduction  of  the  precious 
metals,  and  one  of  the  leading  functions  of 
money  in  international  trade  consists  in  adjust- 
ing temporary  disturbances  of  the  equation, 
since  (Tooke,  State  of  the  Currency)  "an  in- 
creased export  of  ordinary  commodities  cannot 
always  be  made  with  the  promptness  which 
a  sudden  exigency  may  demand."  There  is 
general  agreement  among  economists  in  regard- 
ing prices  as  being  now  the  chief  agent  in 
effecting  the  movements  of  gold  and  silver, 
both  between  mining  and  non-mining  countries, 
and  between  non-mining  countries  themselves. 
It  is  by  successive  waves  of  price  that  the  gold 
of  Australia  and  California  is  exchanged  for 
the  products  of  commercially  related  countries, 
and,  through  those  countries,  is  further  divided 
among  the  nations  of  the  world  ;  so  that  any 
alteration  in  the  stock  of  one  is  ultimately 
felt  by  all  (for  the  differences  in  the  case  of 
India  in  relation  to  this  process,  see  Bastable's 
Theory  of  Intervutional  Trade,  p.  67).  In 
view  of  the  number  and  variety  of  influences 
affecting  prices,  the  frequency  of  the  transmis- 
sion of  gold  and  silver  is  thus  largely  accounted 
for.  One  of  these  influences — improvement  in 
production — ^may  be  selected  for  reference,  both 
on  account  of  its  increasing  importance,  and 
because  it  is  a  favourite  illustration  with 
writers  on  the  subject.  Thus  Ricardo  {Prin- 
ciples, p.  80,  and  frequently  elsewhere) — "The 
improvement  of  a  manufacture  in  any  country 
tends  to  alter  the  distribution  of  the  precious 
metals  ^mongst  the  nations  of  the  world." 
That  this  is  so  may  be  easily  seen.  Leaving 
out  of  consideration,  as  being  suflGiciently 
obvious,  the  effect,  in  attracting  a  flow  of 
money,  of  the  cheapening  of  commodities  not 
previously  exported  (see  Mill,  Principles,  bk. 
iiL  ch.  xxi.),  we  find  that  an  improvement  in 


a  country's  methods  of  production  may  have 
different  results,  according  to  the  effect  of  the 
consequent  cheapness  upon  the  foreign  demand. 
Unless  that  demand  happen  to  be  increased 
in  proportion  to  the  cheapness,  there  wiU  be 
a  movement  of  the  precious  metals  in  one 
direction  or  the  other  pending  the  re-adjust- 
ment of  the  disturbed  international  equation, 
and  experience  shows  that,  cceteris  paribus,  the 
influx  is  generally  in  the  direction  of  the 
country  which  excels  in  manufactures.  A 
national  advantage  in  the  production  of  com- 
modities valued  for  export  may  have  the  same 
effect. 

For  the  effect  of  improved  banking  facilities 
on  distribution,  see  Lord  Overstone,  Tracts,  etc., 
on  Metallic  and  Paper  Currency,  p.  473  ff. 

Recent  improvements  in  foreign  methods  of 
production  have  been  suggested  as  a  possible 
partial  explanation  of  the  fact,  of  which  there 
seems  little  room  for  doubt,  that  the  quantity 
of  gold  in  this  country  is  now  less  than  it 
was  forty  years  ago  (see  Bibliography  at  end. 
Far  more  powerful  causes  than  this,  however, 
may  be  found  in  the  great  developments  which 
recent  years  have  witnessed  in  our  banking 
and  credit  system,  and  in  other  economising 
devices  which  have  enabled  a  greater  volume 
of  transactions  to  be  carried  on  upon  a  compara- 
tively smaller  metallic  basis.  The  great  dis- 
parity, for  instance,  between  the  amount  of 
money  per  head  of  the  population  in  the 
United  Kingdom,  in  France,  Germany,  and 
the  United  States,  is  largely  due  to  the  differ- 
ence in  the  habits  of  these  nations  in  regard  to 
banking  and  credit.  The  amount  in  circula- 
tion in  1912  was  estimated  as  follows : — 

Estimated  stock  of  gold  and  silver,  and  actual 
amount  of  "  uncovered "  paper  money  on 
31st  Dec.  1912  in  the  United  Kingdom, 
France,  Germany,  and  the  United  States. 

(The  %  converted  as  5=:£1.)  Annual  Report  of 
the  Director  of  the  Mint  (U.S.A.),  1913,  pp.  64,  65. 

In  Millions  op  Pounds  Sterling 


Country. 

Population. 

Gold. 

United  Kingdom 
France        .... 
Germany    .... 
United  States    . 

Millions. 
45 
39 
65 
96 

Millions. 
146-2 
240-0 
172-7 
375-9 

Country. 

Silver. 

Uncovered 
Notes. 

Total  Metal- 
lic Stock  and 
Uncovered 
Notes. 

United  Kingdom 
France 
Germany    . 
United  States    . 

Millions. 
23-3 
82-2 
52-3 
108-4 

Millions. 

23-0 

65-2 

52-3 

152-3 

Millions. 
192-5 
387-4 
277-3         ' 
636-6        1 

DISTEIBUTION  OF  THE  PRECIOUS  METALS 


605 


Amount 

PER  Capita 

IN  Sterling. 

Country. 

Gold. 

Silver. 

Total 
Coin. 

Paper. 

Total 

Coin 

and 

Paper. 

United  Kingdom 
France 
Germany    , 
United  States     . 

£  s.d. 

3  6  2 
6    4   6 
2  14  8 

4  0  0 

£s.d. 
0  10  7 
2    2  8 

0  16  7 

1  3  0 

£  s.  d. 
3  16  9 
8  7  2 
3  11  3 
5    3  0 

£  s.d. 

0  10  5 

1  13  9 

0  16  7 

1  12  5 

£    s.  d. 
4    7    2 
10    0  11 
4    7  10 
6  15    5 

The  fact  of  the  use  of  two  metals,  in  different 
countries,  as  standards  of  value,  though  of  the 
utmost  importance  in  other  connections,  does 
not  necessitate  any  re-statement  of  the  question, 
since  it  will  be  found  that  the  movements  of 
both  metals  are  regulated  by  the  same  general 
laws  (see  Del  Mar's  History  of  the  Precious 
Metals,  p.  190).  The  influence  of  legislation 
upon  the  distribution  of  the  precious  metals  is 
worthy  of  notice.  The  marked  increase  which 
recent  years  have  witnessed  in  the  proportion 
borne  by  silver  to  the  total  metallic  stock  of  the 
United  States  is  chiefly  owing  to  this  cause 
(see  Bland  Act),  while  the  reform  of  the 
Austrian  currency  must  alter,  to  some  extent, 
the  general  proportions  in  which  both  gold  and 
silver  are  at  present  distributed. 

Circulation  of  gold,  silver,  and  uncovered  notes 
per  head  of  the  population  in  the  various 
countries  of  the  world  for  1912.  The  state- 
ment, with  those  above,  must  be  understood 
only  as  estimates  (from  United  States  Mint 
Report). 

Dollars  converted  at  $5=£1. 


Un- 

Couutry. 

Gold. 

Silver. 

covered 

JS'otes. 

Total. 

£      8.   d. 

£    8.    d. 

£   s.    d. 

£    8.    d. 

United  Kingdom    . 

3    6    2 

0  10    7 

0  10    5 

4    7    2 

Australia 

7    9    1 

0    8  11 

7  18    0 

Canada    . 

4    4    4 

2  is   7 

6  17  n 

India       .        .        . 

0    6    3 

0  14    5 

0    0    8 

1    1    4 

South  Africa  . 

1  19    5 

0  13    8 

2  13    1 

Straits  Settlements 

0  10    1 

0  14    2 

0  io   3 

1  14    6 

Austria-Hungary    . 

14    6 

0  12    7 

13    3 

3    0    4 

Belgium  . 

1  13    8 

13    6 

0    7  10 

3    5    0 

Bulgaria . 

0    9    2 

0    4    6 

0    9    3 

1    2  11 

Cuba        .        .       . 

2  16    0 

0    0  11 

2  16  11 

Denmark 

1  12    7 

0  12    0 

18    3 

3  12  10 

Egypt      .        .        . 

3    9    1 

0    ,5    9 

0    2    6 

3  17    4 

France     . 

6    4    6 

2    2    8 

1  13    9 

10    0  11 

Germany 

2  14    8 

0  16    7 

0  16    7 

4    7  10 

Greece      . 

0    7  11 

0    4    9 

1  12  10 

2    5    6 

Haiti        .        .        . 

0    6  11 

0    5    2 

0  16  10 

1    8  11 

Italy        .        .        . 

19    3 

0    2  10 

1    1     6 

2  13    7 

Japan 

0  11    0 

0    4    6 

0    7  10 

13    4 

Korea 

0    13 

Oil 

0    2    2 

0    4    6 

Mexico     . 

0    8    6 

0  15    3 

0  13  11 

1  17    8 

Netlierlands    . 

2  10    0 

0  19  10 

2    0    6 

5  10    4 

Norway   . 

1     8    1 

0    6    4 

0  16  11 

2  11    4 

Portugal . 

2  10    6 

12    8 

2    7  10 

6    10 

Koumania 

0  18    1 

0    7    1 

19    3 

2  14    5 

Kussia  and  Finland 

1  18    7 

0    2    7 

0  19    9 

3    0  11 

Servia      . 

0  13    9 

0    1  10 

0    6  11 

1    2    6 

Siam 

0    0    Oi 

0  18  11 

0    1     6 

10    6 

South  America 

1.5  16    1 

2  19    8 

11    6  10 

30    2    8 

Spain 

15    9 

1  16    6 

0  19    9 

4    2    0 

Sweden    . 

1    2    7 

0    6    4 

0  18    8 

2    7    7 

Switzerland     . 

2    9  11 

0  17    2 

1  12  10 

4  19  11 

Turkey    . 

14    6 

0    4    7 

1     9    1 

Central  America    . 

0    1    8 

0  10    2 

5    i    4 

5  13    2 

United  States 

4    0    0 

1    3    0 

1  12    5 

6  15    5 

[See  Kicardo,  The  High  Price  of  Bullion.— 
F.  A.  Walker,  Money,  ch.  iii. — ''Movements  of 
the  Precious  Metals,"  by  J.  Shillcock,  Journal 
Institute  of  Bankers,  vol.  ii.  p.  497.     For  statis- 


tics and  estimates  of  production,  distribution, 
total  stock,  coinage,  and  use  in  the  arts  of  the 
precious  metals,  see  Jevons,  Investigations,  p. 
262,  etc. ;  Palgrave,  Appendix  B,  Third  Report 
of  Royal  Commission  on  Trade  Depression,  1886  ; 
Soetbeer,  "Materials,"  etc.,  transl.  in  Appendix 
to  Final  Report  of  the  Gold  and  Silver  Commis- 
sion, 1878  ;  Reports  of  Deputy  Master  of  the 
Mint,  and  Reports  of  Director  of  the  United 
States  Mint.]  f.  e.  s. 

[N.  W.  Senior,  Three  Lectures  on  the  TransmiS' 
sion  of  the  Precious  Metals  from  Country  to 
Country,  1827. — J.  E.  Cairnes,  "The  Australian 
Gold  Episode  "  (in  Essays  in  Pol,  Econ. ,  Theor. 
and  ApjMed,  1873).] 

The  course  of  the  distribution  of  the  precious 
metals  depends  largely  on  the  position  of  the 
producing  countries.  Thus  in  classical  antiquity 
they  moved  from  Asia  Minor  and  Spain  to 
Greece  and  Italy.  The  opening  of  the  American 
mines  in  the  16th  century  gave  a  ncAv  direction 
to  the  monetary  current  which  passed  first  to 
Spain  and  Portugal,  to  be  thence  distributed  to 
the  principal  centres  of  European  trade,  outlying 
countries  remaining  longunaffected  (Clifl"e  Leslie, 
Essays,  2nd  ed.,  pp.  269-300).  At  present 
Australia,  Canada,  South  Africa,  the  United 
States,  Mexico,  and  South  America  are  the 
sources  of  monetary  currents  that  flow  to  the 
countries  most  closely  connected  by  trade  (see 
Gold  ;  Silver).  Of  equal  importance  is  the 
tendency — noticed  by  Pliny  (70  A.D.),  and  still 
in  action — of  the  precious  metals  to  move  east- 
wards, in  consequence  of  the  habits  of  hoarding 
produced  by  industrial  insecurity.  India  has 
always  been  the  chief  recipient,  her  imports  for 
1853-1912  being:— silver,  £519,846,000;  gold, 
£305,858,000.  She  is  believed  to  have  taken 
about  28  per  cent  of  the  world's  production  of 
gold  during  1912  and  1913  ;  but  the  people  are 
beginning  now  to  use  banks  and  investments, 
and  the  old  hoarding  habit  shows  signs  of  de- 
clining. China  and  the  Dutch  East  Indies  also 
absorb  silver. 

Besides  these  permanent  movements,  various 
agencies  lead  to  temporary  changes  in  distribu- 
tion. Thus  the  Autumnal  Drain  (q.v.)  on  the 
Bank  of  England  is  now  well  known,  and  the 
same  phenomenon  is  noticeable  in  the  United 
States,  where  "moving  the  crops"  leads  to  a 
demand  for  increased  currency  in  the  West,  and 
a  corresponding  drain  on  New  York.  Such 
internal  fluctuations  are  paralleled  by  inter- 
national movements.  A  bad  harvest  in  England 
is  one  of  the  causes  of  a  foreign  drain,  sometimes 
ending — as  in  1847 — in  a  crisis.  More  gener- 
ally, any  trade  disturbance  will  show  its  effect 
in  redistribution  of  the  stock  of  bullion,  an  ad- 
I'ustment  facilitated  and  carried  out  through  the 
mechanism  of  the  Foreign  Exchanges  {q.v.) 
Travellers  may  directly  transport  some  portion 
of  the  money  of  the  world,  and  governmental 
requirements  may,  apart  from  the  exchanges, 


606 


DISTRIBUTIVE  JUSTICE— DIVIDEND 


lead  to  transfers  of  bullion  as  of  other  com- 
modities (Clare,  M(mcy  Market  Frwier,  p.  109). 
State  administrations  often  accumulate  money 
in  the  process  of  collecting  revenue,  and  further 
create  hoards  for  military  or  other  purposes,  e.g. 
the  German  Treasure  of  £6,000,000  at  Span- 
dau.  In  some  countries  coin  is  locked  up 
by  the  Treasury  at  times  to  a  very  large 
amount.  The  creation  of  central  banks,  on 
the  other  hand,  has  drawn  a  large  propor- 
tion of  the  metallic  cu'culation  to  a  few 
points,  and  thereby  —  artificial  restrictions 
apart — has  made  redistribution  easier.  The 
telegraph  is  an  additional  aid  in  securing  speedy 
readjustment  of  the  existing  stock  when  re- 
quired, and  in  connection  with  the  refined 
system  of  the  exchanges,  and  modern  credit 
arrangements,  reduces  the  need  for  money 
bullion  to  the  minimum. 

[G.  Clare,  Money  Market  Primer,  London, 
1891. — W.  Jacob,  Production  and  Consumption 
of  the  Precious  Metals,  2  vols.,  London,  1831 
(chs.  iii.  viii.  and  xiii.  deal  with  movements  of  the 
metals). — A.  Sotbeer,  Materials,  etc.,  trans.  F. 
W.  Taussig,  in  U.S.  Consul's  Eeports,  No.  87, 
Dec.  1887,  pp.  615-528].  c.  f.  b. 

DISTRIBUTIVE  JUSTICE  in  political 
economy  means  justice  in  the  distribution  of 
wealth  (see  Distributiox,  Ethics  of).  As  to 
what  constitutes  a  just  distribution,  opinions 
agree  only  in  being  chiefly  of  a  negative  rather 
than  a  positive  character.  The  communist 
does  not  contend  that  perfect  justice  would  be 
attained  by  his  system  of  equality  modified 
by  differences  of  need,  so  much  as  that  the  in- 
justice of  the  present  great  inequalities  of 
wealth  is  obvious.  The  socialist  says  little 
about  the  distribution  of  wealth  which  would 
prevail  if  his  arrangements  for  making  the 
state  the  only  proprietor  of  land  and  capital 
were  carried  out,  but  insists  at  length  on  the 
injustice  of  allowing  private  owners  of  property 
to  enjoy  a  part  of  the  produce  of  labour  without 
having  worked  for  it.  The  defender  of  private 
property  seldom  follows  Bastiat  {q.v.)  in  main- 
taining that  the  present  system  is  just,  but 
contents  himself  with  urging  that  the  schemes 
of  social  reformers  would  be  even  less  just.  The 
ordinary  person  who  has  not  thought  much 
about  the  subject  does  not  question  the  justice 
of  the  distribution  which  is  the  result  of  private 
property  and  exchange  as  a  whole,  but  he  is 
constantly  denying  the  justice  of  essential  parts 
of  it.  Compassion  for  poverty  and  sympathy 
with  the  worker  as  against  the  idler  frequently 
lead  him  to  deny  the  justice  or  fairness  of  per- 
fectly honest  and  open  bargains.  Still  more  often 
it  happens  that  self  interest  leads  him  to  deny 
the  justice  of  the  existing  distribution  so  far  as 
he  himself  is  concerned  ;  the  widely-accepted 
maxim  of  distributive  justice,  "a  fair  day's  wages 
for  a  fair  day's  work,"  is  often  understood  by 
the  employed  as  meaning  a  little  more  wages  or 


a  little  less  work,  and  by  the  employer  as  mean- 
ing  a  little  more  work  or  a  little  less  wages, 
than  the  amount  fixed  by  free  competition. 

Economists  have  usually  declined  to  discuss 
distributive  justice  at  any  length,  holding  that 
it  is  a  question  of  ethics  rather  than  of  econo- 
mics (see  Communism  ;  Individualism  ;  Pro- 
perty ;  Socialism). 

[Cairnes,  Leading  Principles,  pt.  11.,  eh.  v. — 
Sidgwick,  Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  iv,  ch.  vi. — H.  Rash- 
(lall,  "  What  is  Justice  ? "  in  the  Economic  Review, 
October  1891  and  April  1892.]  E.  c. 

DISTRINGAS.  A  writ  of  distringas  was 
formerly  used  for  the  purpose  of  protecting 
persons  beneficially  interested  in  stock  standing 
in  another  person's  name.  This  procedure  does 
not  exist  any  more,  but  a  notice  may  now  be 
sent  to  the  bank  or  company  in  the  books  of 
which  the  stock  in  question  is  registered,  accom- 
panied by  an  afiidavit  stating  that  the  person 
issuing  the  notice  is  beneficially  interested  in 
the  stock.  The  bank  or  company  to  whom  the 
notice  is  given,  must,  as  soon  as  the  person  in 
whose  name  the  stock  is  standing  attempts  to 
transfer  the  same,  inform  the  person  who  issued 
the  notice,  who  may  thus  take  immediate  pro- 
ceedings to  obtain  an  order  of  the  court  restrain- 
ing the  transfer.  If  no  such  restraining  order 
be  obtained  within  a  week  the  transfer  of  the 
stock  must  take  place.  E.  s. 

DISUTILITY.     See  Discommodity. 

D'lVERNOIS,  Sir  F.  See  Ivernois,  Sir 
F.  D'. 

DIVIDEND  on  Stock  and  Shares.— The 
amount  of  interest  or  profit  divisible  among 
holders  of  stock  or  shares  ;  also  the  amount 
payable  to  each  stockholder  or  shareholder. 

Questions  as  to  payment  of  dividends  to 
shareholders  in  incorporated  companies  are 
frequently  before  the  courts  ;  it  is  now  a  well- 
established  principle  that  such  dividends  must 
be  paid  out  of  profits  and  not  out  of  capital, 
and  that  any  clause  in  articles  of  association 
authorising  payment  of  dividends  from  capital 
or  guaranteeing  a  certain  rate  of  interest  to  the 
shareholders  in  all  events  is  invalid  and  cannot 
be  acted  upon  {Trevor  v.  Whitworth,  Law 
Reports  12  Appeal  Cases  409  ;  Ghdnness  v. 
Land  Corporation  of  Ireland,  Law  Reports  22 
Chancery  Division  349.  As  regards  railway 
companies  and  similar  companies,  see  the  Com- 
panies Clauses  Act,  1845,  §  121,  and  as  regards 
companies  governed  by  Table  A  to  the  Com- 
panies Act  1862,  see  Table  A,  Art.  73). 

The  rule  that  dividends  must  not  be  paid  out 
of  capital  would,  among  prudent  business  men, 
be  thought  to  involve  the  further  rule  that 
only  so  much  of  the  profits  is  available  for 
dividend  as  remains  after  making  provision  for 
depreciation  in  any  of  the  assets  in  which  a 
company's  funds  are  invested.  A  rule  of  this 
nature  is  frequently  contained  in  articles  of 
association,  or  acted  on  by  directors  when  the 


DIVIDEND— DIVIDEND  WARRANT 


607 


articles  are  silent  on  the  subject.  In  the 
absence  of  such  a  rule,  the  directors  cannot, 
however,  be  compelled  by  dissentient  share- 
holders to  make  such  provision.  The  excess  of 
money  obtained  by  working  the  property  of  a 
company  over  the  cost  of  working  it  may,  in 
such  a  case,  be  divided  among  the  shareholders, 
though  the  property  itself  is  of  a  wasting 
nature — like  a  mine,  a  quarry,  or  a  patent.  It 
is  also  left  to  the  discretion  of  the  directors  to 
decide  what  expenses  are  properly  chargeable  to 
revenue  and  what  to  capital  (Zee  v.  Neuchatd 
Asphalte  Company,  Law  Reports  41  Chancery 
Division  1 ;  as  to  the  desirability  of  legislation 
making  it  incumbent  on  directors  to  provide  for 
depreciation  of  capital  before  paying  dividends, 
see  Capital,  supra,  p.  221).  In  well-managed 
companies  the  directors  provide  that  the  valua- 
tion of  the  assets  in  the  balance  sheet  is  correct ; 
which  is  not  possible  unless  sufficient  is  taken 
from  profits  to  provide  for  any  depreciation. 

Dividends  in  companies  are  not  always  paid 
pari  passu  to  all  shareholders.  Companies 
frequently  issue  preference  shares  which  receive 
a  fixed  percentage  on  their  nominal  amount, 
whilst  the  other  shares,  called  ordinary  shares, 
are  entitled  to  whatever  remains  after  payment 
of  the  preferential  dividend.  Dividends  pay- 
able to  preference  shareholders  must,  like 
dividends  on  ordinary  shares,  come  out  of  profits, 
and  cannot  therefore  be  paid  when  the  profit  is 
insufficient.  It  is  generally  stated  in  the 
articles  whether  preference  shares  are  to  be 
cumulative, — that  is  to  say,  whether  a  deficiency 
in  dividend  arising  from  insufficiency  of  profits 
in  one  year  is  to  be  made  good  out  of  profits 
of  subsequent  years,  or  whether  preferential 
dividends  are  to  be  paid  out  of  the  profits  of 
each  year  only  —  non-cumulative  dividend. 
Should  no  special  stipulation  exist,  dividends  on 
preference  shares  in  companies  registered  under 
the  Companies  Acts  are  cumulative  ( Webb  v. 
Earle,  Law  Reports  20  Equity  556),  but  as 
regards  railway  companies  and  other  similar 
companies  governed  by  the  Companies  Clauses 
Acts,  it  is  provided  by  Companies  Clauses  Act, 
§  121,  that  "if  in  any  year  ending  on  the  day 
prescribed  in  the  special  act,  and  if  no  day  is 
described,  then  on  the  31st  day  of  December, 
there  are  no  profits  available  for  the  payment 
of  the  full  amount  of  preferential  dividend  or 
interest  for  that  year,  no  part  of  the  deficiency 
shall  be  made  good  out  of  the  profits  of  any 
subsequent  year  or  out  of  any  other  funds  of 
the  company." 

Railway  companies  have  of  late  years  fre- 
quently used  a  privilege  conferred  on  them  by 
the  Railway  Regulation  Act,  1868,  §  13, 
enabling  them  subject  to  certain  conditions  to 
divide  the  whole  or  a  part  of  their  ordinary 
stock  into  preferred  and  deferred  ordinary  stock.  - 
The  dividend  available  for  that  part  of  the 
ordinary  stock  which  has  been  so  divided  is 


apportioned  as  follows :  the  preferred  stock 
receives  a  certain  maximum  dividend  (generally 
six  per  cent),  and  any  balance  remaining  over 
goes  to  the  defen-ed  stock.  The  latter  is,  of 
course,  a  habitual  object  of  stock -exchange 
gambling,  speculators  always  favouring  securities 
liable  to  sudden  rises  and  ialls,  and  it  can  hardly 
be  said  that  it  was  wise  for  parliament  to  create 
special  facilities  for  speculative  operations  in 
]-ailway  shares,  as  such  operations  cannot  fail  to 
liave  an  indirect  influence  on  the  management 
of  the  companies  to  which  they  relate. 

"Where  dividends  have  been  paid  improperly 
to  shareholders,  the  directors  are  liable  to 
refund  the  amount  out  of  their  own  moneys, 
and  when  the  action  has  been  brought  before 
the  1st  January  1890,  they  cannot  plead  any 
statute  of  limitations,  being,  in  that  respect, 
exactly  in  the  same  position  as  the  trustees  of 
a  settlement  or  will  who  have  committed  a 
breach  of  trust  {In  re  Sharpe,  Law  Reports  (92) 
1  Chancery  154). 

As  regards  so-called  "bonus  dividends,"  see 
Bonus. 


[Lindley,  Company  Law. — Buckley,  Companies 
Acts. — Palmer,  Company  Precedents. — Hodges, 
Railways. — Browne  and  Theobald,  Law  of  Railway 
Companies.  ]  e.  s. 

DIVIDEND,  Medieval.  One  part  or  the 
other  of  an  indenture  or  chirogi-aph,  a  term  con- 
fined to  the  practice  of  the  exchequer,      h.  Ha. 

DIVIDEND  (in  Bankruptcy).  The  rate- 
able share  in  money  which  a  creditor  who  has 
proved  his  debts  receives  out  of  the  proceeds  of 
his  debtor's  estate  is  called  a  dividend.  When 
the  estate  is  a  large  one  dividends  are  declared 
and  paid  from  time  to  time  as  the  estate  is 
realised.  When  the  assets  do  not  exceed  £300, 
the  bankruptcy  rules  of  1886  direct  that  the 
estate  shall,  when  practicable,  be  distributed  in 
a  single  dividend.  In  other  cases,  under  the 
Bankruptcy  Act  1883,  the  first  dividend  is 
directed  to  be  distributed  within  four  months 
from  the  conclusion  of  the  first  meeting  of 
creditors,  and  subsequent  dividends  at  intervals 
of  not  more  than  six  months  (§  58).  Before 
the  declaration  of  the  final  dividend,  notice 
must  be  given  to  persons  claiming  to  be  creditors, 
but  who  have  hitherto  failed  to  establish  their 
claims. 

Unclaimed  dividends  are  paid  into  a  govern- 
ment account  of  the  Bank  of  England  called 
the  "Bankruptcy  Estates  Account"  (§  162). 

M.  D.  c. 

DIVIDEND  WARRANT.  A  dividend 
warrant  may  be  described  as  a  cheque  for  the 
payment  of  a  dividend.  It  may  be  crossed  in 
the  like  manner  as  a  cheque,  and  is  in  the  main 
governed  by  the  same  rules.  In  one  respect, 
however,  it  appears  to  be  peculiar.  When  a 
cheque  is  payable  to  the  order  of  two  or  more 
payees,  it  requires  the  indorsement  of  them  all, 
but  if  a  dividend  warrant  be  payable  to  the 


608 


DIVISIBILITY  OF  MONEY— DIVISION  OF  LABOUR 


order  of  two  or  more  payees  it  is  the  practice 
of  bankers  to  pay  on  the  indorsement  of  any 
one  of  them.  This  practice  appears  to  have 
received  legislative  sanction,  for  §  97  of  the 
Bills  of  Exchange  Act,  1882,  in  terms  provides 
that  nothing  in  that  act  is  to  affect  ."the 
validity  of  any  usage  relating  to^  dividend 
warrants  or  the  indorsement  thereof." 

M.  D.  0. 
DIVISIBILITY  OF  MONEY.  DIVISIONS 
OF  MONEY.  The  divisibility  of  the  material 
of  money  is  an  important  factor  in  its  usefulness. 
It  is  essential  that  the  mass  should  be  readily 
divisible  into  parts,  great  or  small,  with  exact- 
ness and  without  deterioration ;  and,  again, 
that  the  sum  of  those  parts,  if  re-united,  should 
be  equal  in  value  to  the  original  mass.  The 
precious  metals  fully  meet  these  requirements  ; 
and  this  quality,  in  addition  to  their  other 
merits  in  respect  of  durability  and  portability, 
has  secured  for  them  their  position  as  the  money 
of  civilisation.  The  divisions  and  subdivisions 
of  money  are  both  the  cause  and  effect  of  the 
scale  of  prices.  They  have  not  in  many  cases 
been  selected  for  theoretical  appropriateness, 
but  have  been  determined  by  practical  con- 
venience, to  suit  the  habits  of  the  people  among 
whom  they  circulate.  In  these  instances  they 
bear  some  reference  to  the  scale  of  ordinary 
transactions,  but  it  will  be  found  not  unfre- 
quently  that  the  denominations  and  divisions 
of  money  have  prescribed  prices.  Especially  is 
this  the  case  with  fees  for  personal  services, 
where  neither  the  value  of  the  thing  done  nor 
the  cost  of  doing  it  can  be  stated  with  accuracy. 
Such  are  the  fees  current  in  the  medical  and 
other  professions,  which  are  quoted  in  guineas 
or  half  guineas  ;  such  also  are  the  legal  fees  of 
68.  8d.  and  13s.  4d.,  corresponding  respectively 
to  the  **  noble  "  and  the  "mark."  In  all  these 
cases  the  rate  of  payment  was  prescribed  by  a 
denomination  of  money  formerly  in  use,  and 
the  price  has  survived  while  the  coin  has  dis- 
appeared. Another  instance  is  to  be  found  in 
the  parliamentary  railway  fare  of  one  penny 
per  mile.  At  the  time  that  this  rate  was  fixed 
there  was  no  experience  as  to  the  cost  of  carry- 
ing passengers,  nor  was  any  pretence  made  of 
apportioning  the  rate  to  the  cost  or  value  of 
the  service  performed.  The  selection  was 
purely  arbitrary,  and  was  suggested  by  the 
existence  of  the  coin.     It  would  undoubtedly 

have  been  20  or  30  per  cent  more — or  less had 

the  subdivisions  of  the  shilling  been  less  or  more 
numerous.  So  also  with  the  penny  post. 
This  point  is  further  illustrated  by  the  diflferent 
rates  charged  in  diflferent  countries  for  interna- 
tional postage,  where  charges  would  be  uniform 
but  for  the  diflference  in  the  divisions  of  money. 
In  five  countries  of  the  Postal  Union,  as  shown 
below,  the  rates  differ  by  as  much  as  12  per  cent 
among  themselves,  ranging  from  6  per  cent  above 
the  English  rate  of  2^d.  to  6  per  cent  below  it. 


Equivalent. 

Rate 

2id.= 

of2^d. 

Charged. 

1000. 

Germany 

pfgs.  21-281 

pfgs.  20 

=   939 

France 

cents  26-272 

cents  25 

=   952 

Holland 

cents  12-595 

cents  12i 

=   993 

Sweden 

ore     18*916 

ore     20 

=  1057 

Portugal 

reis    46-918 

reLs     50 

=  1066 

Again,  increase  or  reduction  in  small  charges 
will  necessarily  follow  the  subdivisions  of  money. 
Thus  fares  by  omnibus  or  tramcars  have  been 
not  unfrequently  reduced  or  raised  e.g.  from  2d. 
to  Id.  OTvice  versa,  when  there  could  be  no  ground 
for  supposing  that  the  cost  of  carrying  a  pas- 
senger had  been  reduced  or  increased  by  any- 
thing like  50  or  100  per  cent.  r.  w.  b. 

DIVISION  OF  LABOUR.  By  the  "division 
of  labour,"  or,  as  it  is  sometimes  called,  the 
"  division  of  employment,"  is  understood  the 
separation  of  the  total  labour  required  for  the 
manufacture  of  a  single  product  into  various 
distinct  processes,  and  the  allocation  of  each 
of  these  processes  to  a  particular  labourer  or 
body  of  labourers.  It  is  to  be  distinguished 
from  the  simple  combination  of  labour,  which 
consists  in  the  massing  together  of  homogeneous 
labour  to  produce  a  great  effect.  Thus  in  road- 
making,  although  a  hundred  men  are  employed 
to  lay  the  metal  on  a  road,  there  is  no  division 
of  labour,  whUe  in  the  publication  of  a  news- 
paper, where  one  man  arranges  the  types, 
another  classifies  the  material,  another  corrects 
the  proofs,  etc.,  there  is  division  of  labour. 
The  phrase  division  of  labour  has  become 
current  through  its  use  by  Adam  Smith  in  the 
famous  chapters  in  which  he  opens  the  Wealth 
of  Nations  (h^.  i.  chs.  i.-iii.) 

Historically  speaking,  the  division  of  labour 
commences  with  the  specialisation  of  indus- 
tries, and  the  specialisation  of  processes  in  the 
same  industry,  to  which  alone  we  strictly  apply 
the  term,  is  only  an  extension  of  the  same 
tendency.  In  an  early  state  of  society  each 
man  is  his  own  smith,  clothier,  armourer ; 
he  is  farmer,  hunter,  fisherman,  carpenter,  all 
in  one.  The  earliest  division  of  labour  is  made 
when  one  individual  devotes  his  whole  time  to 
some  special  work,  such  as  boat -building,  or 
the  making  of  bows  and  arrows  ;  and  we  may 
therefore  say  that  it  is  coincident  with  the  first 
creation  of  capital.  (See  Bagehot's  JSconomic 
Studies,  pp.  57,  58).  To  the  specialisation  of 
industry  follows  its  organisation,  viz.  the 
formation  of  groups  of  labourers  whose  efforts 
are  all  directed  towards  the  manufacture  of 
one  particular  product.  The  organisation  of 
industry  leads  necessarily  to  the  division  of 
labour,  which  indeed  becomes  in  time  the 
principal  feature  of  that  organisation.  In  a 
state  of  society  where  industry  is  very  highly 
organised  a  single  product  is  frequently  the 
result  not  only  of  a  variety  of  diflferent  processes 


DIVISION  OF  LABOUB 


609 


in  one  industry,  but  the  work  of  a  number  of 
different  industries  also.  Some  of  these  are 
termed  "  subsidiary  industries,"  (see  Marshall's 
JEconomics  of  Industry,  p.  52).  In  the  manu- 
facture of  machinery  a  whole  series  of  trades 
are  employed,  from  the  digging  of  the  mineral 
to  the  finishing  of  the  machine.  This  combina- 
tion of  industries  is  in  reality  division  of  labour 
in  an  extended  form. 

Of  the  consequences  of  the  division  of  labour 
the  most  important  is  the  increase  in  the 
quantity  of  work  which  it  enables  the  same 
number  of  people  to  perform  in  the  same  amount 
of  time.  For  this  improved  effectiveness  of 
labour  Adam  Smith  assigns  three  causes.  (1) 
The  workman  acquires  greater  dexterity  in  his 
work,  because  it  consists  of  some  one  simple 
operation,  and  he  can  therefore  do  it  better  and 
more  quickly  than  if  he  had  to  vary  his  labour. 
In  other  words,  he  has  constant  practice,  and 
therefore  approaches  nearer  to  perfection.  It 
needs  no  illustration  to  point  out  the  extra- 
ordinary degree  of  skill  which  continuous 
practice  in  any  branch  of  human  employment 
is  known  to  confer.  (2)  The  workman  also 
saves  time  when  he  is  entirely  devoted  to  a 
single  process,  because  he  does  not  require  to 
pass  constantly  from  one  place  to  another,  or 
exchange  one  tool  for  another.  Adam  Smith 
also  suggests  that  where  the  work  is  continuous 
the  application  of  the  labourer  is  greater  than 
it  is  where  he  has  to  begin  new  work  every  now 
and  then.  (3)  By  the  direction  of  his  whole 
attention  to  a  single  operation,  or  a  single 
process,  the  workman  becomes  so  thoroughly 
familiar  with  it  that  any  advantageous  change 
in  the  machinery  he  deals  with  will  naturally 
occur  to  him  more  readily  than  it  does  to  those 
who  have  their  attention  divided  between 
several  items  of  labour.  To  these  causes  (4) 
increased  aptitude  and  skill  has  been  added. 
The  recognition  of  this  is  generally  ascribed  to 
Mr.  Babbage,  though  that  author  stated  that 
he  found  it  in  a  foreign  work  (see  C.  Babbage) 
on  economics  (Gioja,  Nuovo  P^-ospetto  delle 
Sdcnze  Economiche,  Milan,  1815).  Increased 
aptitude  and  skill  is  created  by  the  specialisation 
of  labour  ;  it  consists  in  the  economy  of  work 
that  is  gained  when  each  man  is  employed  on 
the  kind  of  labour  he  is  best  fitted  for.  Where 
a  workman  has  two  or  more  things  to  do,  he 
will  be  less  fitted  for  some  than  for  others  ;  but 
the  concentration  of  his  energies  on  one  single 
kind  of  work  enables  him  constantly  to  labour 
at  the  things  he  finds  most  suitable. 

That  the  division  of  labour,  from  the  above 
causes,  increases  the  productivity  of  labour,  and 
that  very  greatly,  is  not  denied.  It  is  urged, 
however,  that  there  are  counterbalancing  results 
of  the  division,  less  direct  perhaps  than  those 
above  noted,  but  still  traceable  to  it,  which 
have  an  opposite  efiect  on  the  productivity  of 
labour  ;  and  this  apart  altogether  from  other 
vol..  I. 


advantages  or  disadvantages  due  to  it.  (1) 
Where  labour  is  very  highly  specialised,  the 
effect  of  perpetual  concentration  of  the  mind  on 
a  single  operation  is  deadening  to  the  mental 
faculties.  We  are  all  aware  that  variety  of 
occupation  produces  a  healthy  state  of  mind, 
and  that  while  perpetual  practice  of  one  thing 
brings  about  a  kind  of  mechanical  perfection,  it 
has  a  deteriorating  effect  on  the  faculties  in 
general.  The  principal  way  in  which  this  con- 
sequence of  the  division  of  labour  acts  on  its 
productivity,  perhaps,  is  that  it  counterbalances 
to  a  large  extent  the  probability  of  useful  in- 
ventions which  we  counted  among  the  results 
on  the  other  side  of  the  question.  On  the 
other  hand,  it  is  urged  that  work  performed 
mechanically  frees  the  mind  and  gives  more 
time  for  thought.  (2)  A  more  important  con- 
sideration, but  one  which  affects  not  the  labour 
of  the  individual  so  much  as  labour  in  the 
gross,  is  this — that  the  specialisation  of  labour 
of  necessity  involves  the  unsuitability  of  the 
average  workman  for  any  kind  of  work  other 
than  that  he  has  been  trained  to.  For  example, 
suppose  that  a  workman  is  employed  on  some 
small  but  delicate  mechanical  operation,  which 
he  has  trained  himself  by  long  practice  to  per- 
form  with  extraordinary  celerity  and  accuracy. 
Some  change  in  the  market,  or  new  invention, 
or  development  of  mechanical  science, — and 
where  industry  is  highly  organised  all  these 
causes  are  to  be  looked  for — renders  unnecessary 
the  continuance  of  the  particular  piece  of  work 
he  has  hitherto  done.  Had  he  been  in  the 
habit  of  doing  work  in  which  there  was  variety 
or  versatility,  it  would  be  much  easier  for  him 
to  turn  his  hand  to  something  new  ;  but  in  the 
highly -specialised  condition  of  industry  it  is 
now  unlikely  that  he  will  find  any  work  corre- 
sponding to  that  he  has  been  obliged  to  aban- 
don. This  disadvantage  we  may  call  want  of 
elasticity  of  labour ;  and  we  may  note  that  it 
tends  to  lessen  the  productive  power  of  the 
total  labour-force  in  existence.  (3)  Inasmuch 
as  health  and  physical  capacity  are  invaluable 
in  their  effect  on  the  power  of  all  labourers, 
anything  which  impairs  or  weakens  the  strength 
of  the  workman  diminishes  the  efficiency  of  his 
work.  The  manifold  division  of  labour  has  led 
in  our  time  to  the  employment  in  the  same 
business  of  far  larger  quantities  of  operatives 
than  used  to  be  massed  together  in  Adam 
Smith's  days.  Therefore,  though  he  states 
that  "we  can  seldom  see  more,  at  one  time, 
than  those  employed  in  a  single  branch,"  at 
the  present  time  it  is  common  to  have  all  the 
branches  of  a  great  industry  working  together 
in  the  same  place.  For  convenience'  sake,  this 
has  led  to  the  massing  together  of  great  popu- 
lations in  large  centres  of  industry  ;  and  thus 
the  conditions  of  life,  as  to  health,  have  been 
rendered  less  advantageous  to  the  labourers. 
From  these  considerations  it  may  be  deduced 

2r 


610 


DIVISION  OF  LABOUR 


that  while  the  division  of  labour  increases  to  a 
great  degree  the  productivity  of  labour,  it  has 
counterbalancing  effects  which  modify  the 
advantage.  When  we  look  at  some  of  the 
other  less  obvious  results  of  the  division  of 
labour,  we  see  that  it  is  in  most  cases  opgn  to 
argument  whether  they  have  a  tendency  to 
augment  the  net  result  of  labour,  or  the  reverse. 
We  have  already  seen  that  the  monotony  of 
work  which  a  great  specialisation  leads  to  must 
be  regarded  as  an  etfect  which  modifies  the 
advantages  derived  from  long  and  continuous 
practice  ;  and  in  its  general  influence  on  the 
workman  we  are  bound  to  suppose  it  must  have 
a  tendency  to  impair  his  mental  faculties.  On 
the  other  hand,  it  is  pointed  out  that  concur- 
rently with  the  progress  of  that  specialisation, 
the  labouring  classes  have  attained  to  a  con- 
tinually higher  standard  of  education,  and  to 
a  greater  development  of  mental  power.  This 
may  be  partly  explained  by  the  fact  that  an- 
other result  of  the  specialisation  of  labour  is 
that  a  greater  and  greater  proportion  of  the  total 
work  done  comes  to  possess  in  some  degree  the 
character  of  skilled  labour  ;  in  other  words,  it 
makes  demands  on  the  mind  of  the  labourer  as 
well  as  on  his  body.  Brute  force  counts  always 
for  less  as  the  organisation  of  industry  pro- 
gresses, and  the  most  striking  example  of  this 
tendency  which  we  see  in  our  own  day  is  the 
ever-increasing  field  for  the  work  of  women. 
The  interdependence  of  industries  is  another 
consequence  of  which  much  may  be  said 
favom'ably  as  well  as  the  reverse.  When  all 
farm  labour  is  done  by  hand,  movements  in 
other  branches  of  work  can  only  very  indirectly 
affect  those  engaged  in  agriculture.  But  when 
machinery  is  introduced  for  ploughing,  reap- 
ing, etc.,  the  business  of  farming  comes  to  be 
intimately  connected  with  ironwork,  the  making 
of  machinery,  and  probably  with  the  hewing  of 
coal  also.  Therefore  the  cost  of  production  to 
the  farmer  will  be  affected  by  inventions  in 
machinery,  by  alterations  in  the  wages  of  the 
classes  of  workmen  who  make  machinery,  and 
by  variations  in  the  price  of  coal  and  iron. 
The  interdependence  of  industries,  of  which  the 
above  is  a  very  obvious  example,  is  a  most 
important  factor  in  modem  life.  On  account 
of  the  hanging  together  in  a  greater  or  less 
degree  of  all  trades,  good  or  bad  fortune  has 
a  tendency  to  visit  all  simultaneously.  This 
interdependence  also  breeds  a  feeling  of  common 
interest  among  employers  of  all  classes,  and 
also  between  labourers  on  every  field  ;  -with  the 
result  that  we  now  see  an  increasing  tendency, 
especially  on  the  part  of  labour,  to  band  its 
forces  together  for  some  general  object,  or  for 
some  special  advantage.  A  universal  strike  in 
any  large  industry  would  paralyse  the  entire 
trade  of  the  country. 

The  division  of  labour  can  be  carried  out 
much  farther  in  some  industries  than  in  others : 


and,  as  Adam  Smith  points  out  {Wealth  of 
Nations,  bk.  i.  ch.  iii.),  it  is  only  limited  by  the 
extent  of  the  market.  This  latter  considera- 
tion, however,  is  of  very  much  less  importance 
now  than  it  was  in  the  days  when  he  wrote. 
The  improvements  in  the  means  of  transit 
made  within  the  last  hundred  years  have  been 
so  great  as  in  large  measure  to  abrogate  the 
old  limitations  of  market.  The  expenses  and 
difficulties  of  land-carriage,  which  Smith  notices, 
have  been  so  greatly  reduced  that  goods  are 
constantly  sent  to  market  by  long  journeys 
across  country.  Still,  in  the  smaller  industries, 
it  must  always  be  the  case  that  in  a  market 
where  the  customers  can  only  be  drawn  from  a 
limited  area,  the  division  of  labour  cannot  be 
carried  to  any  great  extent.  As  among  differ- 
ent industries,  the  division  is  generally  carried 
out  furthest  where  two  conditions  are  satisfied  : 
a  large  employment  of  workers,  and  the  con- 
tinued repetition  of  identical  operations.  In  a 
small  business  it  is  clearly  impossible  to  sub- 
divide the  work  done  very  minutely.  Where 
the  same  work  can  be  done  continuously,  again, 
a  greater  division  of  labour  is  possible  than 
where  it  has  to  be  varied  at  different  periods. 
Thus  agriculture  is  an  industry  in  which  the 
division  of  labour  can  never  be  very  greatly 
extended,  because  the  same  people,  from  the 
very  nature  of  their  business,  must  be  employed 
in  different  operations  at  different  seasons  of 
the  year.  On  the  other  hand,  in  a  cotton 
factory,  the  division  of  labour  is  probably 
extended  to  its  farthest  possible  present  limits. 
These  differences  form  one  of  the  many  causes 
which  bring  about  the  continuous  flow  of  popu- 
lation in  this  country  from  rural  to  urban 
districts  ;  a  tendency  which  it  is  hopeless  to 
check  so  long  as  we  purchase  food  in  great 
quantities  from  foreign  countries  with  our 
manufactured  goods. 

It  is  noticeable  that  in  retail  trades,  in 
which  a  vast  quantity  of  capital  is  invested 
and  a  multitude  of  labourers  employed,  there 
does  not  appear  to  be  as  much  scope  for  divi- 
sion of  labour  as  in  manufacture.  Here  the 
tendency  is  not  for  a  particular  retailer  of 
goods  to  confine  himself  more  and  more  to  the 
sale  of  a  special  kind  of  article,  but  for  large 
retailers  to  spread  their  business  over  as  many 
commodities,  and  over  as  great  a  variety  of 
commodities  as  possible  ;  and  by  this  means  it 
would  appear  that  retail  trade  is  more  remunera- 
tive when  it  is  general  than  when  it  is  special- 
ised. The  profits  of  the  retailer  depend  less 
on  the  amount  of  work  done  by  his  workmen 
or  the  percentage  of  profits  on  the  sale  of  goods 
than  on  the  total  number  of  sales  he  can  make  : 
what  is  commonly  called  his  turn-over.  Causes 
which  in  manufacturing  industries  increase  the 
power  and  value  of  labour,  therefore,  have  no 
such  effect  on  the  labour  employed  in  the  retail 
trade.     With  the  retail  trades  must  be  classed 


DIZAIN— DOCK 


6n 


those  great  organisations  called  the  carrying 
trades,  which  aim  at  the  same  object,  viz.  the 
bringing  to  market  of  goods  already  made. 

[The  question  of  the  division  of  labour  is  dis- 
cussed in  all  the  standard  English  works  on  politi- 
cal economy.  See  also  TJie  Economy  of  Machinery 
and  Manufactures  by  Babbage,  chs.  xix.  to  xxiii., 
where  many  interesting  facts  in  illustration  of  the 
division  of  labour  are  recorded.  The  socialist  point 
of  view  may  be  studied  in  Capital,  by  Karl  Marx, 
translated  into  English  by  Samuel  Moore  and 
Edward  Aveling,  and  edited  by  F.  Eugels,  and  in 
Hyndman's  Historical  Basis  of  Socialis7n.  The 
most  complete  monograph  on  the  History  of  Divi- 
sion of  Labour  is  that  by  Schmoller  in  Jakrhuch 
fvx  Oeseizrjebung,  1889.]  M.  G.  D. 

DIZAIN,  a  coin  struck  in  France  in  the 
reign  of  Charles  VIIL,  worth  ten  deniers,  and 
was  also  known  as  a  Carolus.  R.  l. 

DOBBS,  Arthur  (1689-1765),  was  the  eldest 
son  of  Richard  Dobbs  of  Castletown.  He  be- 
came high  sheriff  of  Antrim  in  1720,  was 
member  for  Carrickfergns  in  the  Irish  parlia- 
ment 1727-1760,  and  was  appointed  engineer- 
in-chief  and  surveyor  general  in  Ireland  by 
Walpole.  His  Essay  on  the  Trade  and  Improve- 
ment of  Ireland  (Dublin,  1729-1731,  2  parts, 
8vo,  reprinted  in  Tliom's  Collection  of  Tracts, 
1861,  ii.  321,  etc.)  is  full  of  valuable  informa- 
tion on  Irish  trade  and  population  drawn  from 
official  sources.  He  advocated  a  better  system 
of  land  tenure.  In  1732  he  introduced  an  en- 
closure act  in  the  Irish  parliament  (see  Viscount 
Mountmorres,  Impartial  Refections  on  the 
Present  Crisis,  1796,  8vo). 

[M'Culloch,  Literature  of  Political  Economy, 
1845,  p.  46. — Dictionary  of  National  Biography, 
voh  XV.  p.  132, — Appleton,  Gyclopcedia  of 
American  Biography,  vol.  ii.  p.  189.]     h.  r.  t. 

DOCK. 

Development  of  the  Modem  Dock  System,  p.  611;  London 
Docks,  p.  611 ;  Provincial  Dock  Development,  p.  613  ; 
Warrants,  p.  615 ;  Effect  of  Economic  Changes  upon 
Docks,  p.  615 ;  Competition  in  relation  to  Docks,  p. 
621 ;  Incidence  of  Dock  Charges,  p.  621 ;  Dock  Finance, 
p.  621 ;  Dock  Ownership,  p.  621 ;  Public  Ownership, 
p.  621 ;  (1)  Management,  p.  621 ;  (2)  Public  Conveni- 
ence, p.  621 ;  (3)  Finance,  p.  621 ;  List  of  Mercantile 
Docks  in  the  United  Kingdom,  pp.  616-620. 

Development  of  the  Modern  Dock  System. — 
The  first  commercial  dock  in  this  country  was 
the  Howland  Great  Wet  Dock  at  Rotherhithe, 
constructed  in  1660  by  private  enterprise.  This 
dock,  known  later  as  the  Greenland  Dock,  now 
forms  part  of  the  system  of  the  Surrey  Com- 
mercial Docks.  The  earliest  example  in  this 
country  of  a  dock  owned  by  a  municipality  is 
the  harbour  at  Port-Glasgow  on  the  Clyde,  con- 
structed by  the  municipality  of  Glasgow  in 
1662,  on  account  of  the  distance  of  the  usual 
port,  Irvine,  and  the  necessity  of  conveying 
merchandise  for  twenty  miles  by  pack-horses 
(Deas,  "The  River  Clyde,"  Inst,  of  Naval 
Arch.,  vol.  XXX.  p.  20).  The  next  important 
incident  in  dock  history  is  the  construction  of 


the  Mersey  Docks  in  1708.  In  1665  the  gross 
burthen  of  the  15  vessels  that  represented  the 
shipping  trade  of  Liverpool  was  268  tons.  At 
this  time  Liverpool  possessed  a  natural  harbour 
of  about  a  mile  in  length,  in  a  "small  creek" 
off  the  north  bank  of  the  Mersey.  The  mouth 
of  this  pool  became,  in  1708,  the  first  Mersey 
Dock — the  Old  Dock,  now  no  longer  in  exist- 
ence (Lyster,  on  "Recent  Dock  Extensions  at 
Liverpool,"  Inst.  Civ.  Eng.,  vol.  c,  pt,  ii.). 
This  dock  was  constructed  by  the  Co]"poration 
of  Liverpool  (Rees,  Encyclopaedia,  vol.  xii.,  art. 
"Docks").  The  condition  of  the  great  docks 
of  the  country  was  as  follows  (1911)  : — 

London  Docks. — The  eight  docks  described  in 
Table  A  are  under  the  management  of  the  Port 
of  London  Authority,  established  by  the  Port  of 
London  Act  1908.  The  docks  generally,  and  the 
channels  of  approach  to  them,  are  entirely  in- 
adequate to  their  work,  and  considerable  addi- 
tions have  been  undertaken  (1911). 

The  Act  of  1908  provides  that,  to  enable  the 
Authority  to  represent  tlie  varied  interests  con- 
cerned, it  should  consist  of  28  members,  of 
whom  1  is  appointed  by  the  Admiralty,  2  by 
the  Board  of  Trade,  4  by  the  London  County 
Council  (2  being  members  and  2  not  members 
of  the  Council),  2  by  the  Corporation  of  London 
(1  being  a  member,  1  not  a  member),  1  by  the 
Trinity  House,  18  being  elected  by  the  Payers 
of  Dues,  Wharfingers,  and  owners  of  River 
Craft,  1  member,  however,  being  elected  by 
Wharfingers  only. 

Besides  the  docks  and  warehouses,  the  Port 
of  London  Authority  controls  the  Avaterway  of 
the  Thames  from  Teddington,  practically  to  the 
Nore,  a  distance  of  70  miles.  The  dock  pro- 
perties include  a  total  area  of  2583  acres,  with 
a  river  frontage  about  3  miles,  28  miles  of 
quays  available  for  shipping,  and  about  120 
miles  of  railways.  There  are  many  cranes  with 
all  appliances  for  the  work.  The  Port  Authority 
also  exercises  much  of  the  jurisdiction  of  the 
Waterman's  Company. 

The  purchase  of  the  dock  undertakings  was 
effected  by  the  issue  of  Port  Stock  in  substitu- 
tion for  the  various  dock  stocks  raised  by  the 
separate  undertakings  and  companies  which 
constructed  the  original  dock  system,  and  whose 
dates  extended  from  the  year  1660  practically 
to  1908  ;  the  amounts  were  (1912)  : — 

3  %  *' A''  stock  (issued  1909)  .  £9,379,752 
4%"B"stock(  ,,  1909)  .  13,210,706 
3|  %  Inscribed  stock  (issued  1911)   2,000,000 

£24,590,458 

Since  1886  the  growth  in  the  size  of  the  vessels 
using  the  Port  has  been  continuous,  and  the  ton- 
nage of  the  shipping  enteringand  leaving  the  Port 
of  London  from  foreign  countries,  British  posses- 
sions and  coast-wise,  in  1912,  was  29,495,521 
tons.    A  scheme  for  the  development  of  the  Port 


TATSTF   A -LONDON   DOCKS   (  Work  under  construction  in  Italics) 

^^     — ^ i^^  ■  o : — Tw-3 — 5^§T= ^     s:j~g~^ 


°    ||2 


612 


DOCK 


613 


has  been  arranged  to  cost  about  £14,500,000, 
the  first  part  now  under  construction  (1911-14) 
costing  about  £6,000,000.  Besides  the  addi- 
tions described  in  Table  A,  an  extensive  dredging 
programme  has  been  undertaken,  widening  and 
deepening  all  channels  ;  a  large  cold  store,  fitted 
with  electric  lifts,  in  Smithfield,  for  a  further 
80,000  carcasses,  is  added  (total  accommodation 
for  frozen  meat  in  London  Docks  approaches 
1,350,000  carcasses)  ;  also  two  additional  pneu- 
matic grain  elevators,  100  tons  an  hour  capacity, 
with  suction-pipes,  etc.,  and  large  new  Offices. 
Frovincial  Dock  Development.  —  While  the 
dock  system  of  the  Thames  was  developing, 
that  of  the  Mersey  was  growing  rapidly.  The 
growth  of  the  cotton  trade,  and  the  increasing 
importation  of  American  produce,  especially 
wheat,  stimulated  the  provision  of  docks  and 
warehouses  at  the  chief  ports  on  the  western 
sea-board.  The  Mersey  and  the  Clyde  became 
great  industrial  centres  and  great  harbours. 

Liverpool — The  Mersey  Docks  and  Harbour 
Board,  formed  by  Act  of  1857 — consisting  of 
28  members,  24  elected  by  the  Dock  Rate-payers, 
4  a2)pointed  by  the  Mersey  Conservancy  Com- 


are  a  striking  feature  of  the  docks.  Special 
warehouse  accommodation  for  the  storage  ol 
grain  has  been  provided  both  at  Liverpool  and 
at  Birkenhead.  The  wool  warehouse  will  take 
118,000  bales  of  wool,  while  the  tobacco  ware- 
house is  probably  tlie  largest  warehouse  in  the 
world.  There  are  large  cold  storage  depots. 
Tank  accommodation  is  provided  for  the  storage 
of  petroleum.  The  railway  facilities  connect 
the  great  railway  companies  with  the  quays  ; 
the  Board  also  owns  an  extensive  system  of 
lines  traversing  and  intersecting  the  dock  estate 
in  all  directions.  The  port  is  used  by  all  the 
great  steamship  companies — the  White  Star,  the 
Cunard,  Elder  Dempster,  Dominion  Line,  etc. 
In  1909  the  number  of  vessels  had  risen  to 
24,799,  with  tonnage  of  16,747,479,  the  total 
rates  paid  on  vessels  £730,469  :  17  :  7,  and  the 
rates  and  dues  paid  on  goods  £633,121  :  3  :  5. 
As  regards  export  trade  Liverjiool  stands  with- 
out a  rival  in  the  Kingdom,  as  the  following  com- 
parative figures  of  the  values  of  exports  for  the 
year  1909  will  show  :  Liverpool,  £157,464,098  ; 
London,£120,545,867;Hull,£27,194,425;Glas- 
gow,  £27,023,646;;  Southampton,  £26,710,818. 


Table  B. — Meesey  Docks. 


Dock  Estate. 

Water  Area. 

Lineal  Quayage. 

Depth  of  Sill. 

Liverpool  Docks— 
60  Docks  and  Basins 

Birkenhead  Docks— 
21  Docks  and  Basins 

Acres. 
506 

427  acres  2967  sq.  yds. 
171     „      3259    „     „ 

26  miles  1466  yards 
9     „      1422      „ 

Varies  from  2'  6"  above  to 

20'  below  O.D.S. 
Varies  from  O.D.S.  to  18'  3" 

below  O.D.S. 

Varies  from  3'  I"  above  to 
16'  2"  below  O.D.S. 

Varies  from  4'  1"  to  7'  8" 
below  O.D.S. 

Total      . 

167Yi 

599     „      1386    „     „ 

36     „      1128      „ 

Liverpool  Graving  Docks 
Birkenhead  Graving  Docks 

Length  of  Floor    .        .     10,147'  2" 
„             „            .         .       2,430' 0" 

Total 

12,577'  2" 

New  Docks  are  under  construction.  To  provide  accommodation  for  vessels  of  exceptional  size  (up  to  1000  ft. 
in  length)  the  construction  of  a  large  Dock  has  been  commenced,  capable  of  being  used  as  a  graving  Dock  when 
necessary.  The  dimensions  of  the  Dock  are  :  length,  1020  ft.  ;  width,  120  ft.  ;  water -area,  over  3  acres  ;  depth  of 
sill,  25  ft.  below  Old  Dock  Sill.  The  New  Gladstone  Docks  are  to  consist  of  Half-tide  Dock,  870  ft.  long  by 
130  ft.  wide,  with  a  Sill  30  ft.  below  datum,  a  Lock,  and  two  Branch  Docks. 

missioners  (the  First  Lord  of  the  Admiralty, 
the  Chancellor  of  the  Duchy  of  Lancaster,  and 
the  President  of  the  Board  of  Trade) — controls 
the  Port  of  Liverpool  and  Birkenhea'd. 

The  docks  are  equipped  with  very  powerful 
modern  appliances.  Hydraulic  power  stations 
are  placed  at  suitable  centres,  the  power  being 
used  for  opening  and  closing  the  dock  gates,  and 
for  dealing  with  cargoes.  Steam  and  electric 
power  is  also  provided.  The  natural  disadvan- 
tages of  the  river — i.e.  the  bar,  and  the  im- 
mense rise  of  the  tide,  the  total  range  between 
high  and  low  water  being  as  much  as  33  feet 
on  extreme  spring  tides  and  11  feet  on  neap 
tides — have  been  met  by  very  complete  dredging 
appliances,  by  an  immense  floating  landing- 
stage,  nearly  half  a  mile  long,  carried  on  iron 
pontoons,  and  held  in  position  by  bridges  con- 
nected with  the  shore  and  stage  by  swivel  joints 
and  mooring-chains.    The  warehouses  and  sheds 


Li  the  import  trade  Liverpool  is  second  to  Lon- 
don alone,  and  much  exceeds  all  other  ports. 
The  principal  articles  of  trade  are  corn,  cotton, 
tobacco,  sugar,  cattle,  petroleum,  and  provisions. 
The  borrowing  powers  of  the  Board  are  as 
follows:  amoimt  authorised  (1859  to  1906), 
£31,789,554  ;  amount  borrowed,  £25,720,874. 

Manchester. — The  Harbour  and  Port  of  Man- 
chester was'  constituted  by  the  Manchester  Ship 
Canal  Act  1885,  and  the  Manchester  Ship 
Canal  Co.  is  the  Harbour  Authority  of  the  Port. 
The  Ship  Canal  was  opened  for  traffic  in  1894. 

There  are  many  lines  of  steamers  sailing  to 
the  principal  countries  of  the .  world.  Man- 
chester is  now  the  second  port  for  cotton  in  the 
Kingdom,  the  third  fruit  port,  and  the  fourth 
-in  value  of  exports  and  imports.  The  traffic 
lias  increased  from  less  than  1,000,000  tons  in 
1894  to  nearly  5,000,000  in  1911,  and  the 
revenue  from  less  than  £100,000  in  1894  to 


614 


DOCK 


over  £550,000  in  1910.  The  work  has  been 
carried  out  under  unexampled  engineering 
difficulties  and  corresponding  expense,  greatly 
owing  to  the  district  which  it  serves  being  the 
most  densely  populated  in  England. 

There  are  21  Directors  of  the  Company,  10 
elected  by  the  Shareholders,  and  11  by  the 
Manchester  Corporation.  The  capital  powers 
amount  to  £18,573,230,  and  the  expenditure  on 
capital  account  to  June  30,  1910,  £16,796,925. 

The  imports  into  Manchester  are  raw  cotton 
(American  and  Egyptian),  timber,  grain,  oil, 
fruit,  frozen  meat,  wood  pulp ;  the  exports  are- 
manufactured  cotton,  coal,  agricultural  machines, 
acids,  and  an  enormous  quantity  of  general 
merchandise. 

The  equipment  of  the  principal  docks  at 
Manchester  includes  hydraulic,  steam,  and 
electric  cranes  of  great  power.  Bonded  ware- 
houses are  also  provided. 

Table  C. — Manchester. 


(a)  Principal  docks  at  fj^^^^  ^^^^^     ^gg^  ^^.^.g      ^^ter 
Manchester— 9     J      ^^^^    ^^^  apxps !    nnavs.  2S6A 

dge-  ( 
(in-J 
lall  i 


A     1     /in*.i  J     1  -»     area,  120  acres;   quays, 
docks  (10th  dock  y    ^^^^^^  g^  j^ji^g  i^^"i_ 


Total  area,  .70  acres  ;  water  area, 
15  acres';  storage  ground  (in 
addition),  77  acres. 


proposed), 
(&)  Runcorn   (Bridge 
water)  Docks  " 
eluding     Small 
Graving  Dock), 
(c)  Manchester  Dry  Docks  Co.  Ltd, 
1.  3'2i  miles  from  Manchester. 

Shipbuilding  and  Repairing  Yards. 
•D^„4-^-...  i?i^nf  r^SO  ft.  long,  70  ft.  wide,  en- 
"^Innl     N     trance  16  ft.  deep;  capable 
mg  uocK.       1^    ^^  lifting  vessels  of  2500  tons. 
2.  2  miles  from  Manchester. 


Graving 
Dock 

Dry  Dock 

Floating 
Pontoon' 


■  535  ft.  long,  65  ft.  wide,  22  ft.  water 

on  the  blocks. 
425  ft.  long,  65  ft.  wide,  18  ft.  water 

on  the  blocks. 
'200  ft.  long,  63  lit.  wide,  16  ft.  water 

on  the  blocks ;  capable  of  lifting 
of  2000  tons. 


The  Canal  has  its  entrance  at  Eastham,  19 
miles  from  the  bar  at  the  mouth  of  the  river 
Mersey.  It  is  35^  miles  long,  and  its  depth, 
as  well  as  that  of  the  four  large  docks  at  Man- 
chester, is  from  26  to  28  feet.  There  are  three 
locks  at  Eastham,  forming  three  separate  en- 
trances by  which  access  is  obtained  whenever 
the  tide  is  less  than  16  ft.  2  in.  above  the  Old 
Dock  sill.  The  principal  docks  (see  Table  C) 
at  Manchester  are  50  miles  from  the  sea.  The 
Company  also  owns  the  Runcorn  Docks,  ship- 
building and  repairing  yards,  about  fifty 
wharves  and  lay -byes  situated  at  various  points 
between  Eastham  and  Manchester ;  besides 
these  there  are  the  EUesmere  Port  Docks,  the 
property  of  the  Shropshire  Union  Railway  (see 
Table  E).  There  are  oil  tanks  owned  by  various 
companies,  with  a  total  capacity  of  26,912,282 
gallons  (99, 119  tons),  and  large  cold-air  storage. 

A  gi-ain  elevator  is  situated  on  the  canal, 
with  storage  capacity  of  40,000  tons. 

The  Manchester  Dock  railways  are  80  miles 
in  extent  and  completely  intersect  the  dock 
estate.  The  Ship  Canal  Company's  railways, 
running  alongside  the  canal,  are  connected  with 


the  other  great  railway  companies  of  the  King- 
dom. There  is  also  direct  communication  with 
fourteen  other  canal  companies. 

Clyde  Navigation. — At  Glasgow  the  trustees 
of  the  Clyde  Navigation,  by  deepening  the  river- 
channel  and  erecting  quays  upon  the  banks,  had 
practically  converted  the  Clyde  into  a  dock  ;  but 
the  extension  of  trade  rendered  necessary  the 
construction  of  the  Kingston  Dock,  1867  , 
Queen's  Dock,  completed  1880  ;  and  Prince's 
Dock,  completed  1897.  The  combined  area  of 
these  docks  is  74  acres.  The  expansion  of 
the  mineral  trade,  in  the  importation  of  iron  ore 
and  the  exportation  of  coal,  also  led  to  the 
construction  of  the  Rothesay  Dock,  Clydebank, 
6  miles  below  Glasgow,  opened  1907  and 
having  an  area  of  20^  acres.  Special  accom- 
modation is  provided  for  landing  and  housing 
cattle  and  storing  timber,  and  a  large  granary 
is  (1911)  in  course  of  construction.  The  North 
British,  Caledonian,  and  Glasgow  &  South- 
Western  Railway  Companies  have  access 
through  branch  lines  to  the  docks,  and  the 
trustees  own  about  36  miles  of  harbour  railway 
on  the  street  level.     (See  Table  D.)  ! 

Table  D. 

Particulars  as  to  Glasgow  Harhour  arid  DocJcs^ 

1911. 

First  Act  for  improving  the  River  Clyde  1759. 
First  Act  for  improving  the  Harbour 

of  Glasgow 1809. 

First  Act  for  making  a  Dock  at  Glasgow  1 840. 

Length  of  Quays 19,234  lin.  yds. 

Area  of  Quays,  Roads,  and  Shed  space  187  acres. 

Area  of  Shed  space       ....  66|  acres. 
Area  of  Timber  Yards  .        .        .        .34  acres. 

Area  of  Water  Space     ....  325  acres. 
Amount  of  Parliamentary  Borrowing 

Powers £8,500,000 

Amount  of  Debt £6,979,868 

Total    Capital    Expenditure    to    30th 

June  1910  .        .        .        .        .        .  £9,298,587 

Total  Income  of  Trustees  from  1752    .  £17,258,267 

Income  for  year  to  30th  June  1910      .  £555,403 
Depth  of  Water,  at  average  Low  Water 

Springs— In  River     .        .        .        .  22  to  24  feet. 

In  Glasgow  Harbour         .  16  to  23  feet. 

In  Docks    ....  22  to  28  feet. 
Rise  of  average  Spring  Tides— 

In  River 10  to  12  feet. 

In  Glasgow  Harbour  and  Docks       .  12  feet. 

For  a  general  description  of  the  other  docks  [ 
of  the  country  see  Table  E.  This  table  gives  a , 
summary  of  the  principal  features  of  each  of  the ; 
docks  described.  We  only  regret  that  the  limits 
of  space  compel  the  exclusion  of  many  interest- 
ing details.  Since  the  table  was  first  compiled 
in  1892  much  improvement  has  taken  place  in 
dock  accommodation.  Among  these  may  be 
mentioned  those  carried  out  at  Bristol,  where 
the  capital  invested  has  increased  nearly 
£4,000,000  within  the  last  twenty  years,  and 
at  Southampton,  where  the  capital  invested 
has  increased  over£3,000,000.  On  the  Huniber, 
new  docks  have  been  opened  at  Immingham 
(1912)  and  Hull  (1914)  in  direct  communica- 
tion  with  the  collieries  of  Derbyshire,  Notts,  and 
South  Yorks,  and  are  equipped  for  dealing  with 


DOCK 


615 


the  rapid  shipment  of  coal,  the  equipment  being 
largely  electrical.  At  Cardiff  the  area  of  docks  and 
basins  has  increased  by  nearly  100  acres  and  the 
capital  invested  by  over  £2, 000, 000.  Very  great 
improvements  have  been  made  on  the  river  Tyne 
under  the  care  of  the  Tyne  Improvement  Com- 
missioners, who  have  spent  nearly  £7,000,000 
on  their  work.  They  state,  in  their  report,  that 
"the  river  Tyne  is  the  only  port  of  refuge  on 
the  East  Coast  between  the  Humber  and  the 
Forth."  The  great  improvement  in  the  river 
has  been  accompanied  by  a  vast  increase  in  the 
industries  carried  on — shipbuilding  and  repair- 
ing, chemical  works,  iron  and  steel  manufac- 
tories, hemp  and  wire  rope  works,  potteries,  etc. 
They  add  :  "  While  Tynesiders  now  living  can 
well  remember  the  time  when  there  Avere  less 
than  7  feet  of  water  on  the  bar  at  low  water, 
there  is  now  a  depth  approaching  25  feet  at  low 
water,  shortly  to  be  increased  to  30  feet,  and 
vessels  of  the  largest  class  are  enabled  to  enter 
and  leave  the  port  at  almost  any  state  of  the 
tide."  The  docks  belonging  to  the  North 
Eastern  Railway  Company  also  provide  accom- 
modation for  the  timber  traffic,  the  storage  of 
grain,  and  other  cargoes.  On  the  Clyde  the 
area  of  docks  and  basins  has  more  than  doubled 
since  our  statement  in  1892,  and  the  income 
has  increased  in  fully  the  same  proportion.  In 
this  connection  we  may  mention  that  at  Swansea 
the  capital  invested  has  increased  from  about 
£1,400,000  to  over  £4,000,000,  while  the  area 
of  docks  and  basins  has  groAvn  from  60  acres 
to  126  acres.  At  Newport  (Monmouthshire) 
the  area  of  docks  and  basins  has  increased 
from  about  56  to  more  than  150  acres  ;  the 
South  Dock,  of  110  acres,  being  the  largest 
single  dock  enclosed  by  artificial  walls  in  Great 
Britain.  Since  1892  the  area  of  the  docks  and 
basins  at  Dover  has  increased  from  17-^  to  91 
acres,  and  the  docks  at  Fleetwood  from  10  to 
25  acres. 

Dock  Warrants. — Under  this  system  goods 
may  be  ''mobilised  like  money."  Such  goods 
are  necessarily  stored  at  great  financial  centres 
under  the  control  of  public  bodies.  See  Clear- 
ing System  ;  Conditioning  ;  Cotton  Clear- 
ing ;  Dock  Warrant  ;  Sampling  and 
Grading. 

Effect  of  Economic  Changes  upon  Docks. — 
Besides  the  general  causes  which  affect  the 
business  of  docks,  certain  special  causes  have 
had  important  influences  upon  them.  Their 
influence  varies  with  the  nature  of  the  trade  of 
the  port,  and  with  the  incidence  of  the  dock 
charges.  At  Liverpool  the  incidence  of  the 
charges  upon  ships  and  goods  was  as  follows  in 
1910  :— Of  a  total  of  £1,290,000,  dock  tonnage 
rate  was  45  per  cent,  dock  rates  27  per  cent, 
dues  on  goods  23  per  cent,  warehousing  5  per- 
cent. At  London,  under  the  old  system  with" 
which  the  arrangements  of  the  Port  of  London 
Authority  mainly  coincide,  warehousing  yields 


70  per  cent  and  all  other  charges  30  per  cent. 
Thus  any  changes  affecting  warehousing  must 
have  more  important  effects  on  Liverpool  than 
on  London.  The  warehouses  in  the  Thames 
are  not  exclusively  for  goods  in  bond,  but  the 
system  of  warehousing  grew  up  under  a  policy 
of  protection,  when  articles  now  free  of  duty 
were  taxed  and  stored,  under  the  supervision  of 
the  customs,  in  the  warehouses  till  the  duty 
was  paid.  The  facilitation  of  commercial  inter- 
course makes  warehousing  less  necessary  and 
less  profitable.  Markets  become  more  closely 
di'awn  together  and  more  sensitive,  and  the 
risks  and  expense  of  prolonged  holding  of  goods 
becomes  out  of  proportion  to  the  possible  profits. 
Among  the  many  economic  effects  of  the  open- 
ing of  the  Suez  Canal  were  two  in  which  docks 
were  directly  affected.  The  first  of  these  was 
the  impetus  given  to  the  building  of  steamers 
of  large  size,  the  great  development  of  which 
has  taken  place  since  ;  the  second,  its  influence 
on  the  entrepot  trade  of  Great  Britain.  The 
opening  of  the  Canal  reopened  the  direct  trade 
routes  between  Europe  and  the  East.  This, 
with  the  development  of  international  commerce 
resulting  from  various  causes,  enabled  France 
and  Germany  to  employ  lines  of  steamers  on 
direct  routes  between  Continental  and  Eastern 
ports,  and  hence  the  entrep6t  trade  of  London 
gradually  diminished.  Other  causes  also,  for 
example  the  lowering  of  prices,  have  had  the 
effect  of  stimulating  direct  communication  (cp. 
Dep.  Trade  Com.,  Report,  III.  Q.  10,848).  Of 
these  the  most  potent  was  the  expansion  of 
trade,  enabling  the  Continental  ports  to  culti- 
vate direct  relations  with  the  East.  Navigation 
laAVS  (of  France  and  Spain,  e.g.)  have  stimu- 
lated direct  intercourse  by  granting  bounties  on 
ships  and  cargoes.  Although  from  a  national 
point  of  view  the  importance  of  the  entrepot 
trade  may  be  exaggerated,  and  although  at  its 
highest  point  it  was  not  more  than  one- sixth 
of  the  total  import  of  foreign  produce,  yet  the 
fluctuations  in  it  affect  London  more  seriously 
than  any  other  port  in  the  United  Kingdom. 

Notwithstanding  this  the  imports  of  London, 
£205,639,879  in  1909,  are  the  highest  in  the 
Kingdom,  and  the  exports,  £116,974,484,  are 
second  only  to  Liverpool. 

Individual  docks  have  been  subject  to  the 
influence  of  changes  in  the  technique  of  pro- 
duction. '  The  alteration  in  the  sugar  trade 
through  the  extensive  substitution  of  beetroot 
for  cane-sugar  seriously  affected  the  revenue 
of  the  West  India  Docks,  while  the  substitution 
of  artificial  alizarine,  and  of  the  aniline  dyes 
for  madder,  cochineal,  and  other  products,  has 
led  to  the  almost  entire  disappearance  of  these 
from  the  London  import  lists,  and  to  the  im- 
portation from  Germany  and  France  of  theii 
substitutes.  These  substitutes  are  mainly 
imported  at  the  provincial  ports,  e.g.  Hull, 
Newcastle,  Harwich,  and  Leith. 


616 


DOCK 


g     O 


r^    &• 


^1 

cSOD     . 


S     °  ^  ^ 

^  Si's 


-1 

(h  s>  d 


I    2 


::::.    s 


^"1 


»^'  4  S    *-'"2 


i  ^  ^ 

O        ?5        B 

•|   5  S 

^  ^"  4 

.a    §   I 
I   '"-  .*" 

oc&ag-g 

H      5 


0)  n  « ■ 


^    g  <»5o 


•2.2  £  fe  3  S 

H  fin 


^^^1 


I- 

EH   N 

r-03 


•S  to  i^ 
O 


s 


.11 


)  o)       S 


3'S 

°°a   -3 


a 
'        I 

^    I 


.^3 


"  Q  9 
N)  f<    ..'2 


^3  O  OO  A  _i| 


.-5 


III 


"(S  O  ti5  -1^ 


agi 


|3S 


53  ^.5^  S 
03   r  _ 

CO    tc  4^    O 

-5  43  ra  bo 


>.ss-s 


o<« 


^^ 


5'   ??  - 


O   03   0!1 

"-as;^ 


8 


o  o 


fif^ 


H       tHoODhtcIs 


^^ 


CM  g  a 

4S43   w 

fe  to 


OOQ  OiadSoQ 

10  ^  00  _3  >o 

C<)         (M  ^  CO 


do 
WW 

SP(M 


EhH 

OQOJ 
H^W 


as 

o  d 

Em  ^ 

O 


9    03^ 

a-S  ^ 

III  'i 

p,Wg.    ^ 

8^6   6 


•S      S      '>oS 

^-l  CO    r-  CO-Cl^oo 

2  "^ -e --"rt  o '-' 

s  I  is 


11 

^1 


^W 

S3  u 

9  S 


§83 

•gm«P3 


I. 

9« 


2g« 


§1^ 
.S*^  a 

►^    £_.    03 


i     5 

W2    I 
9-2    ^ 


B^ 


f^4i 


i 

o 


J 


^    I 


3       3 


«     PQ 


I  I 


^1 

o  5* 
.2  m 


o      w 


Iw 


^   S  «S 

^BW 


DOCK 


617 


^^5  o 


o  o  * 


o3   c3^- 


£;  c  o 

O    =40 

g-2o 


--lis  P 


<1     cu 


!l 

i 

1 

III 

0 

P4 

i 

oS 

EH 

5l|  . 

S 

s 

J 

Hi 

t 

o 

1. 

111 

- 

^^-^ 

gogo 

c« 

o  s^ 


SO.^- 


au   H^ 


5    C    '^-'^ 


o  3  a    u 


Sp^H  gcc  go 
H      O      H 


CD    <ri 


2|o 

S  Cm  P^ 

m     O 


S     O 

O       d 
~      o 


Hi 

oo  cJ 

«0        «w 


y  00  ^  -XJ    O 


c3^ 

o.§ 


32 


ibo 


:3:=:d 

11 


nil 


do 


«S         -^ 


£S 


ox  cri 


.2  I! 


OQ  S 


S     ^ 


-=!■ 


i>> 


E=5 


-§5    lit 


11 


£:  .2  ^''is  3  S  2  o  d 

>s-  t^  o  a  a 


I  s|  I  ^ ".  :§ 

^  -  I  g  II 

!2i    .  o  >       S      ^ 


3        .     •      -U  +D 

S    O  J-3  "d    =^ 


O      0-1 


ab-2 


(l^  4o  "^  P,Ph  4i  d 


3  g  -^ 

A  •   K  "» 

■-;  3  tH  .  o 

™  fci   O  O   r^ 

hj  hS  ^ 


cq.fi 

11 

armarthensh 

Dock. 

Copper   -  "Wor 

Dock. 

urry  Port  Dock 

2 

>^l 

O     s      W 

;.:i 

^     ^q 

CO    t< 


618 


DOCK 


1 

a 

t 
o 
c 

•c 

Copperas,     Bricks,     and 
dries. 

md  Coke,  Chemicals,  Fire- 
ks  and  Clay  Goods,  Manure, 
iir  and  Meal,  Pig  Iron,  Steel 

Iron,  Lead,  Lead  Colours, 
et  and  Pipe  Lead,  Purple 
1  Ore,  Grindstones, 
nd  Coke,  Bricks,  Chemicals, 
Iron,  and  Machinery. 

Do. 

1° 
"J 

Is 

•So 

m 

1 

el 
H 

fl" 

2 

l-H 

0 

.S 

i 

6 

1 

: 

1 

1 

0 

i 

1 

S" 

1 

"3  fl 

an 

0 

1 

r 

i 

mi 

Ill 

1 

' 

"si 

OS§3 

§ 

II 

g. 

T3  © 

15 '2 

1 

It 

i 

a 

: 

1! 

fl-s 

1 

g;mg 

=-1 

1 

w 

1 

1 

11 

PIIIJ 

1 

HO 

55 

& 

a" 

U. 

mn 

03  JS  Q  -S  O 

M 
s 
•43 

l-^i 

§i 
ll 

.2  to         «  ^^  g 

11    P^^ 

lll|il 

itliiliii 

!§ 

«« 

p  »^ 

Areao 

Docks 

and 

Basins 

CO             . 

s     s 

8 

gss- 

- 

r*l 

S55 

^^^ 

H'h      f^*H 

H 

.H    -H 

tl 

^ 

s 

?2§ 

!  i 

66    66 

OS-*        lOO 

I-H  CI           W  CO 

1 

: 

PS(^S 

3 

31 

s 

§- 

« 

S- 

^' 

00 

* 

* 

«i=fl 

«s 

^ 

e« 

^ 

<^ 

<"  s  s 

. ■ > 

r-t         O 

t~                       Tj< 

OS 

(M 

lO  05 

0 

fc 

o      >o 

%           S 

Jg 

00 

WOO 

; 

00 

a 

aU 

rH         rH 

^ 

r-(rH 

fe« 

i 

o 

3  1 

HI 

11^ 

&    i 

6 

1 

!5 

< 

ft     .j:^ 

III 
III 

1 

!J1 

o2 

1  S 

1  ll 

1-3         ^ 

6 

o 

.id     . 

■^1 

3 
s 

.i4 

0 
0 

X 

^ 

11 

o 

i    & 

1 

t 

^ 

1^ 

Qf2 

fl 
'0 

1 

1 

1 

M 

1    1 

ii  1 

55    "^ 

1 

t 

1 

s 

§ 

fl 
0 

3 

1 

1 

It  § 

^ 

^ 

II 

J3 

l| 

1 

1 

a 

.fl 

DOCK 


619 


, 

J3 

1 

— « 

1 

^1 

oT 

1 

2 

o 

1 

3 

2 

C-i 

o 

% 

.5 

«r 

rC 

Sg- 

t) 

o 

s 

2 

w  . 

? 

1 

s 

1 

5 

1 

fcc 

1 

o 

6 

1 
1 

"Si 

1 

i 

3 

1. 
11 

2 
o 

6 

O 

^1 

3 
1 

3 
o 

E 

'5 

'^ 
b 

3 

f 

O 

1 

o 

^ 

gl 

11 

o 

1 

"i 

3 

-i 

a  a 

o 

1 

" 

S 

o 

o 

^ 

o 

i_ 

S 

o 

o 

o 

fe 

zj 

o 

o 

O 

O 

1 

2 
o 

s 

d 

1 

i 

5 

10 

o 

1 

o 

1 

s 

i 
1 

I 

1 

2 

B 

o 

a 
1 

1 

I 

a 

e 

d 

g 

O 

O 
1 

aT 

a 

s 

en 

c 

1 

6 

4) 

a 

o 

o 

ft 

e 

H 

1 

Is 

ii 

a 
O 

fa 

P 

HO 

II 

^1 

1 

II 

8 

q:3 

— ^ 

i| 

1" 

- 

1 

a 

1 

a 

1 

p 

a 

^2 
So 

1 

a 

1^ 

1^ 
o  >- 

: 

.S3 

1° 

u-To 

i 

o 

o 
to 

O  g 

ll 

^3 

1^ 

P 

Is 

8 

1 

o 

IS 

3 

o 
o 

1 

73     • 

II 

O  ^ 

3 
O 

1 

ill 

S  -o 

<o 

s-1§ 

t- 

rtlCI 

CO 

00 

CO 

c^' 

-iti 

00 

. 

H 

&^ 

OC^  00 

1-4 

0) 

o 

^ 

?3 

od 

00 

eh" 

d 

od 

d 

c5 

f, 

CO 

66 

1,00 

c^ 

o 

^ 

^ 

<_, 

<_, 

o 

"S  o 

c  ^ 

(N 

S 

I- 

O  o 

•^ 

00 

no 

o 
o 

'^- 

o-^ 

o" 

cT 

oT 

^^?l 

<^ 

-^ 

ajq, 

^ 

■^ 

•v^ 

UH 

<^ 

«♦« 

i6 

=rt 

^ 

<^ 

■^ 

^^S 


■jj  J^  CO  CO  J 


l-H    ^  00 

>>*^  CO 

T'    3  r-( 

|8 


^^O 
^    >. 


CO 


Ph 


3 
.30 


ll 


W2 


pq 
.S« 

^  "3 


rQ'-' 

.3   O 


<1 


5 


.a    s^ 


^  ^ 


620 


DOCK 


1 

1 

Si 

i 

1 . 

o           ^ 

00 

>< 

f 

2           1 
i           f 

1    1  r 

1- 

a 

a 
2 

boO 

III 

rf 

1 

a   ^ 

II 

^      6 
i.  i 

ll            i: 

r   1  ll 

to 

l« 

1    2 

is 

1 

a 

s 

S 

II 

if 

III 

O         M 

B    Is 

1 

1 

Hi  1  |l 

go 

1 

a 

l^il 

1" 

1 

mi 

•3-1^1     1 

§  mw  a    g 

r- 1 

H               ^       -^ 

H 

O          H 

H      H 

Q          HO 

OS 

5^ 

:ii  11  iiil 

"  I'll 

1   all 
4  5^^ 

i  -sllil 

M 

@ 

^ 

S-S^is    W22Sl 

^^ 

»n           Tf 

<i 

00               g         OJ 

52; 

D 

HH 

H 

II 

OJCO 

d 

1— 1 

^§ 

o 

CO 

>-!§ 

?^,     §?S'" 

ll 

1        s    ^ 

s? 

88    8 

s  s 

o           o      '^       o 

Q 

o               o"      g" 

(S" 

oo      un 

00           l-H 

CO          to      Q  ®  Q  "^ 

Q 

S 

oa 

"^                5*1       p^ 

^ 

or=^    «^ 

«t« 

«*J 

^4j 

<VJ          crt      C      H 

!ll 

s 

o 

8       S 

CO         00 

g          fe      g? 

^ 

H 

f^    CO 

"Is 

^ 

^ 

la    m% 

II 

!l 

s5  ■ 

g 

2^     ^ 

a      ^    a 

1 

1 

o 

1 

liil 

gtdoSo 

Jill 

a    o  a 

|i  1  h 

^  a       e3  M-i  rs  a 

!25            pq     Q 

O 

o       ^ 

s   (2 

M          Q     O 

^1 

1      1^ 

o 

3 
s 

1 

o 

is 

S2 
O 

a 

1 

1^ 

■g'< 

tJ              S-S 

• 

1                8 

, 

— j 

1 

1               xs^ 

1  111 

II 

1 

§ 

\ 

44* 

a 

1 

5  i 

3     a 

i  1 

111 

DOCK 


621 


Competition  in  relation  to  Docks. — In  almost 
all  the  provincial  ports  the  dock  corporations, 
whether  mnnicipal,  trustee,  or  joint- stock, 
exercise  a  local  monopoly.  Occasionally  ports 
are  so  near  each  other  as  virtually  to  enter  into 
competition  for  the  same  trade  ;  but  each  dock 
and  harbour  authority  in  the  provinces,  with 
rare  exceptions,  enjoys  a  monopoly  of  the  trade 
of  the  port.  At  Liverpool  and  Glasgow,  c.cj. 
there  is  no  competition  in  docks,  and  rates  are 
fixed  exclusively  with  regard  to  the  needs  of 
the  trust  for  maintenance  and  interest,  although 
there  is  a  necessary  limit  fixed  by  the  com- 
petition of  other  large  ports. 

Incidence  of  Dock  Charges. — The  policy  of 
dock  owners  as  regards  the  incidence  of  charges 
varies  very  widely.  The  charges  in  each  port 
have  arisen  largely  through  local  custom.  The 
charges  may  be  broadly  divided  into  charges  on 
the  ship  and  charges  on  the  goods.  Charges 
on  the  ship  may  be  divided  into  dues  and  rent. 
Dues  are  usually  charged  on  net  register  tonnage, 
though  they  have  been  from  time  to  time 
charged  on  the  gross  tonnage,  as  in  1856  at 
Sunderland.  (For  discussion  on  the  policy  of 
charging  on  the  net  or  on  the  gross  tonnage, 
see  Royal  Com.  on  Tonnage,  Report,  1881  ; 
also  e.g.  Slapping  World,  vol.  i.  pp.  274,  323, 
365,  and  402).  Under  the  Harbour  Docks  Act 
of  1847  preferential  rates  are  prohibited. 

Dock  rent  is  charged,  as  in  London,  on  gross 
tonnage.  In  some  cases  rent  begins  on  entrance, 
in  other  cases  it  begins  after  a  certain  period 
has  elapsed.  Charges  on  goods  may  be  divided 
into  rates  including  landing,  weighing,  and 
delivery  in  the  case  of  imported  goods  ;  collec- 
tion, wharfage,  and  porterage  in  the  case  of 
exported  goods  ;  and  warehouse  rent.  There 
are  besides  special  charges  on  particular  classes 
of  goods.  The  rates  on  goods  are  fixed  partly 
with  regard  to  the  difficulty,  risk,  and  cost  of 
handling  them,  and  partly  with  regard  to  the 
value  of  the  goods.  At  Bristol  no  rates  are 
charged  on  exports.  It  is  clear  that  dock  rates 
80  levied  must  act  in  a  measure  as  a  bounty  on 
exports,  and  as  a  corresponding  tax  on  imports. 
(On  differential  rates  for  freemen  and  foreigners, 
see  Maitland,  History  of  London.')  There  seems 
much  need  for  simplification  in  dock  charges. 
Tlie  classification  adopted  finally  by  the  railway 
companies  might  form  the  basis  of  a  classifica- 
tion for  docks  with  advantage  both  to  shippers 
and  dock  corporations. 

Dock  Finance. — The  capital  invested  in  docks 
in  the  United  Kingdom  may  be  estimated  as 
not  less  than  £200,000,000.  This  represents 
their  probable  cost. 

It  is  doubtful  whether  the  total  return  on 
the  capital  invested  can  average  from  3  to  3^ 
per  cent.  In  London  in  1909  the  interest  on 
the  £9,150,000  "A"  Port  Stock  is  at  3  per 
cent;  the  £13,210,000  "B"  Port  Stock  is  at 
4  per  cent.     At  Liverpool  £4,677,000  of  the 


loans  are  between  4  per  cent  and  4^  per  cent, 
£11,710,000  between  3  per  cent  and  3^  per 
cent,  and  £64,000  between  2^  per  cent  and  2\ 
per  cent. 

Dock  Ownership.  —  Tlie  ownership  of  the 
docks  in  the  United  Kingdom  is  distributed  as 
follows  : 


State  Ownership .... 

Municipal  Do 

Local  Public  Trust  Ownership  . 

Public  Ownership 

Joint-Stock  Ownership 
Private         Do. 

Private  Ownership 


37 


Public  Ownership. — The  question  of  public 
ownership  of  docks  has  been  frequently  dis- 
cussed. There  are  three  main  points  involved 
— 1st,  management ;  2nd,  public  convenience  ; 
3rd,  finance. 

(1)  Management. — It  is  argued  that  a  number 
of  men  selected  by  their  townsmen  for  known 
fitness  for  administration  may  administrate  as 
efficiently  as  similar  men  selected  for  the  same 
reason  by  a  body  of  shareholders.  No  consider- 
able support  can  be  found  for  objecting  to  ad- 
ministration of  docks  by  public  trusts  in  the 
records  of  such  bodies.  The  examples  of  Liver- 
pool and  Glasgow  are  very  note^vorthy  as  highly 
successful  and  efficient  trusts.  The  same  class 
of  men  is  employed  in  the  practical  details  of 
administration,  both  in  companies  and  in  cor- 
porations. (2)  Public  Convenience. — There  is 
some  reason  for  doubt  whether  any  general  case 
could  be  made  out  on  this  ground  for  or  against 
public  control.  The  slowness  witli  which  public 
bodies  sometimes  meet  public  demand  has  fre- 
quently been  exemplified  in  the  case  of  docks 
under  both  joint-stock  and  public  management. 
(3)  Finance. — While  dock  property  may  one 
day  be  extremely  remunerative,  it  is  still  in  a 
period  of  transition.  The  joint -stock  dock 
shareholder  has  had,  during  these  past  few 
years,  in  some  cases,  to  go  without  his  dividend, 
while  the  public  trust  bondholder  has,  as  a 
rule,  got  his  interest.  In  this  reference  it 
should  be  remembered  that  municipalities  have 
other  resources  at  their  command  than  dock 
charges.  The  broad  ground  of  the  advantage 
in  the  public  interest  of  public  ownership  and 
control  of  all  services  which  are  essentially 
local  monopolies,  is  the  argument  usually  em- 
ployed in  favour  of  placing  docks  under  public 
control.     (See  Monopolies.) 

[Harb.  Docks  and  Piers  Clauses  Act  1847. — Sdect 
Com.  Ho.  of  Com.  Harh.Accovi.,  1883.— Z)e^.  Trade 
Com.  Report  iii.,  Entrepot  Trade,  queries  10,072, 
10,074,  10,098,  10,169,  10,283,  10,291,  10,673, 
10,692,  10,848,  and  11,334.  —  Macpherson's 
Annals. — Porter's  Progress  of  the  Nation,  sec.  iii., 
1837. — Colquhoun,  Commerce  and  Police  of  the 
Thames. — Locke,    Hist,   of  Navigation,   1744.—- 


622 


DOCK— DOCK  LABOUR 


Vaughan  Tracts  on  Docks  and  Commerce,  1839. — 
Cruden,  'llist.  of  the  Port  of  London,  1843.— 
Eden,  Flan  for  the  Imprwement  of  the  Port  of 
London,  11^^.— Reasons  for  Extending  Wharves 
in  London,  1797.— Telford  and  Douglas,  An  Ac- 
count of  the  Improvements  of  the  Port  of  London, 
etc.,  1801. — Forrow,  The  Thames  and  itsJ)ocks, 
1877.— Capper,  The  Port  and  Trade  of  London, 
1 862! —Howell,  A  Days  Business  in  the  Port  of 
London,  1850.— "Various  histories  of  London  and 
of  the  Thames  and  district,  e.g.  Boydell,  Maitland, 
Pennant,  Brayley,  Knight,  Walford,  Loftie.— 
Burrows,  The  Cinque  Ports,  1888.— Lyster,  "Re- 
cent Dock  Extensions  at  Liverpool,"  Proc.  Inst. 
Civ.  Engrs.,  vol.  c.  pt.  ii.— Mason,  A  brief  Hist, 
of  the  Dock  Co.  at  Kingston-upon-HuLl,  1885. — 
The  Industrial  Rivers  of  the  United  Kingdom, 
1888.— Deas,  "The  River  Clyde,"  Proc.  Inst,  of 
Naval  Arch.,  vol.  xxx.  p.  20.— B. A.  Meeting  New- 
castle, Official  Handbook  of  Industries,  1889. — 
Inst,  of  Mech.  Engrs.,  Liverpool  Meeting,  1891, 
Official  B.m.dAio6)s..— Shipping  World  Annual.— 
Lindsay,  Hist  of  Merchant  Shipping  and  Ancient 
Commerce,  1874.  —  "Dock  Companies  Shares," 
Jour.  Stat.  Sac,  xxxix.p.  495.— Turnbull,  Dock  and 
Port  Charges. — Thubron,  Dock  and  Port  Charges. 
— "  Floating  Docks  in  London,"  Industries,  vol.  1. 
p.  337. — Harcourt,  Docks  and  Harbours. — First 
AnnvM  Report  of  the  Port  of  London  Authority, 
31st  March  1910.  — Port  of  London  Authority, 
Visit  of  the  Instiiicte  of  Joiirnalists,  17th  Sept. 
1910. — Tables  of  Rates  and  Charges. — Accounts 
of  the  Mersey  Docks  and  Harbour  Board. — The 
Port  of  Liverpool :  Its  Rise  and  Progress. — Port 
of  Manchester  Official  Sailing  List  and  Shipping 
Guide,  and  the  other  official  handbooks  and  guides 
of  the  different  docks  issued  by  the  authorities 
concerned. — Encyclopcedia  Britannica,  11th  ed., 
vol.  viii.,  "Docks." — Charles  Booth,  Life  and 
Labour  of  the  People  in  London,  1903.] 

DOCK  LABOUR.  The  iuformation  given 
by  Mr.  Charles  Booth  in  Life  and  Labour  of 
the  People  in  London,  vol.  3,  Second  Series 
(Industry),  remains  the  best  source  for  informa- 
tion on  the  conditions  of  men  employed  daily 
on  the  docks  and  wharves  and  in  warehouses, 
now  under  the  control  of  the  Port  of  London 
Authority,  and  their  earnings. 

Those  employed  are  mentioned  in  the  First 
Report  of  that  Authority  for  the  year  ended 
3l8t  March  1910  as  follows  :— 

"All  the  undertakings  transferred  to  the 
Authority  were  found  to  be  working  under  dif- 
ferent systems  in  regard  to  the  employment, 
payment,  and  classification  of  staff;  and  the 
work  of  reconciling  these  differences  in  practice 
and  of  a  general  re -classification  is  making 
good  progress.  The  annual  charge  in  re- 
spect of  superannuation  and  benevolent  allow- 
ances at  present  amounts  to  £70,405.  The 
question  of  establishing  one  pension  scheme 
for  the  whole  of  the  staff  is  under  consider- 
ation. 

"The  staff  of  the  Authority  at  the  31st 
March  1910  numbered  11,297,  as  follows  : — 


Salaried  stafT 1,156 

Wages  staflf— 
Permanent  men  on  the  establishment      5,074 
Not  established,  but  regularly  em- 
ployed by  the  week ....      2,123 
Extra  men — 
Daily  average 2,944 


11,297' 


And  the  Report  continues:  "In  accordance 
with  the  requirements  of  section  28  of  the  Act, 
the  Authority  has  taken  into  consideration  the 
question  of  the  regulation  of  the  engagement 
of  casual  labour." 

•  In  time  it  may  be  expected  that  the  organisa- 
tion of  the  labour  required  will  be  arranged  on 
a  better  footing  than  previously. 

Meanwhile  Mr.  Booth's  remarks  on  the  sub- 
ject will  be  read  with  interest.  "  The  earnings 
of  the  professional  docker  are  shared  by  a  con- 
siderable number  of  incomers  from  other  trades 
who  seek  work  at  the  docks,  not  because  the 
docks  are  busy,  but  because  their  own  trades 
are  slack,  and  herein  lies  the  peculiar  difficulty 
of  dock  industry.  If,  instead  of  coming  at 
all  times,  these  men  from  other  trades  were  in- 
troduced only  when  the  docks  were  busiest, 
their  numbers  could  even  be  increased  with 
advantage,  and,  combined  with  a  reduction  in 
his  own  ranks,  would  probably  lead  to  improve- 
ment in  the  position  of  the  professional  docker." 
"The  varying  demand  for  labour  at  the  docks 
can  be  provided  for  in  four  different  ways  :  (1) 
by  maintaining  at  all  times  a  sufficient  force  to 
cope  with  the  largest  amount  of  work  offering  ; 
(2)  by  working  overtime  when  needed  ;  (3)  by 
drawing  upon  outside  labour  for  additional 
hands  in  busy  times  ;  (4)  by  postponing  some 
of  the  work.  Of  these  four  it  is  upon  the  first 
alone  that  the  employers  now  rely,  and  the 
only  mitigation  of  its  hardship  is  the  extent  to 
which  the  men  may  themselves  find  other  work 
in  slack  times." 

The  wages  received  are  difficult  to  estimate. 
The  work  includes  great  variety  of  labour, 
stowing  cargo  requiring  skill  and  care  ;  dis- 
charging cargo,  though  not  needing  exactly  the 
exercise  of  the  same  qualities,  must  be  efficiently 
performed.  The  classes  employed  extend  from 
the  "Amalgamated  Stevedores  Society  "down 
to  general  and  casual  labourers.  The  average 
value  of  the  work  of  the  two  last-mentioned 
classes  may  be  put  at  from  4s.  6d.  to  4s.  3d. 
for  those  regularly  employed.  It  is  impossible  to 
estimate  the  earnings  of  the  casual  labourer.  A 
careful  regulation  of  the  work  is  essential  to  avoid 
the  evils  so  long  connected  with  dock  labour 
Into  the  methods  proposed  to  secure  this  we 
cannot  go  here.  Mr.  Booth  truly  says,  "of  all 
the  causes  of  poverty  and  misery,  irregular 
work,  coupled,  as  it  always  must  be,  with 
irregular  lives,  is  by  far  the  greatest.  A  change 
in  this  would  effect  more  than  almost  anything 
else  could  do  for  the  welfare  of  the  people." 
To  the  owners  of  dock  property  also  a  propei 


DOCK  WAEEANT— DOCTRINAIRE 


arrangement  for  the  supply  of  efficient  and 
dependable  labour  is  most  important.  It  is 
regularity  of  employment  which  it  is  most 
desirable  to  secure.  The  more  regularly 
employed  men  obtain  also  the  higher  rates 
of  pay. 

The  statement  given  above  refers  to  the 
labour  employed  in  the  London  docks.  The 
circumstances  of  the  other  docks  in  the  country 
differ  considerably  from  these,  but  what  has  been 
stated  will  show  the  importance  of  this  industry 
to  the  commerce  of  the  United  Kingdom. 

[Booth,  Life  and  Labour  of  the  People  in  Lon- 
don, vol.  ill.  second  series.] 

DOCK  WARRANT.  A  document  by  which 
a  dock  company  or  other  dock  owner  certifies 
that  the  holder  is  entitled  to  receive  certain 
goods  specified  therein,  deposited  with  such 
dock  company  or  other  dock  owner  (see  Dock 
warrants  in  art.  Dock,  p.  615).  A  dock 
warrant  is  generally  transferable  by  indorse- 
ment ;  a  holder,  though  in  good  faith,  and 
though  he  had  given  value  for  it,  was  formerly 
in  a  less  favom-able  position  than  the  holder  of 
a  bill  of  lading ;  but  since  the  Factors  Act  of 
1877  a  transfer  of  a  warrant  by  the  buyer  or 
owner  of  the  goods  to  which  it  refers,  to  a  person 
who  takes  the  document  in  good  faith,  has  "the 
same  effect  for  defeating  any  vendor's  lien  or 
right  of  stoppage  in  transitu,  as  the  transfer  of 
a  bill  of  lading  has  for  defeating  the  right  of 
stoppage  m  transitu"  (Factors  Act,  1889,  §10). 
(See  Commercial  Instrument.)  e.  s. 

DOCQUET.  (1)  Declaration  by  a  notary 
authenticating  an  instrument  of  sasine  (Scot- 
land, before  1845) ;  (2)  Declaration  by  a  notary, 
by  a  justice  of  the  peace,  or  by  the  parish 
minister  in  his  own  parish,  authenticating  the 
signature  of  a  person  unable  to  write  (Scotland)  ; 
(3)  Authentication  of  a  mercantile  account  by 
signature,  initials,  or  jotting. 

[Scotland  :  Dickson  on  Evidence,  §§  797-800.] 

A.  D. 

DOCTRINAIRE  is  a  term  of  reproach  desig- 
nating one  who  applies  theory  without  due 
regard  to  facts.  The  doctrinaire  forgets  that 
in  social  science  a  consilience  between  deduc- 
tion and  verification  is  generally  requisite  (see 
Mill,  Logic,  bk.  vi.  ch.  viii.  ix.)  He  is  like 
the  Aristotelian  doctors  in  the  age  of  Galileo, 
who  continued  to  believe  that  bodies  fall  faster 
the  heavier  they  are  in  spite  of  experiments 
proving  the  contrary.  However,  such  open 
defiance  of  facts  is  rare  even  in  political  economy. 
An  instance  is  the  resolution  of  the  British 
parliament  that  bank  notes  had  not  depreciated 
with  respect  to  gold  in  1811,  when  the  guinea 
was  commonly  exchanged  for  24s.  shillings  in 
paper  money  and  silver.  The  more  usual  type 
of  doctrinaire  is  one  who  has,  so  to  speak,  a 
tolerably  correct  theory  of  gravitation,  but 
makes  no  allowanoe  for  the  resistance  of  the 
air.     The  omission  of  this  concrete  fact  may  or 


may  not  be  serious  according  to  circumstances. 
The  abstraction  may  be  legitimate  in  the  case 
of  a  stone  dropped  from  a  height,  but  fatal  in 
the  case  of  a  feather.  An  economic  principle 
like  laissez-faire  may  be  valid  in  general,  but 
in  some  important  case  be  counteracted  by 
peculiar  circumstances.  Such  peculiarities  dis- 
tinguish the  labour  market  from  markets  in 
general  (see  Marshall,  Principles  of  Economics, 
bk.  vii.  chaps,  iv.  v.  vi.)  Those  who  opposed 
the  Factory  Acts  on  the  principle  of  laissez-faire 
were  doctrinaires — so  time  has  proved.  But 
prior  to  the  additional  experience  of  the  last  half 
century  it  was  not  easy  to  see  who  was  the 
doctrinaire  and  who  the  empiric.  A  hesitation 
between  the  rule  and  the  exception  may  often 
be  reasonable.  In  general  no  short  and  handy 
rule  can  be  given  for  steering  between  the 
Scylla  of  empiricism  and  the  Charybdis  which 
swallows  up  the  doctrinaire.  Some  cautions 
against  the  more  dangerous  extreme,  some  educa- 
tion of  the  instinct  or  tact  which  is  required  in 
order  to  hold  the  right  mean,  may  be  obtained 
from  the  example  of  those  who  have  made  ship- 
wreck, and  from  the  precepts  of  the  wise. 

A  signal  example  is  afforded  by  the  so-called 
currency  principle  in  banking  (see  Bank  Note  ; 
Currency  Doctrine),  which  was  held  by 
Lord  Overstone,  and  largely  influenced  the 
Bank  Act  of  1844.  Those  who  relied  on  this 
principle  fixed  too  exclusive  attention  on  the 
"quantity-theory"  of  money,  neglecting  inci- 
dents peculiar  to  a  convertible  currency,  and 
the  fact  that  bank  notes  form  but  a  small 
part  of  the  English  circulation.  The  theory 
is  contrary  to  the  fact  that  after  crises,  while 
prices  have  greatly  fallen,  the  notes  in  the 
hands  of  the  public  have  greatly  increased  (see 
Palgrave,  Journal  of  the  Bankers'  Institute, 
January  1890).  Other  examples  are  afforded  by 
some  of  Ricardo's  followers.  Ricardo,  as  Pro- 
fessor Marshall  says,  is  "more  responsible  than 
any  one  else  for  the  habit  of  endeavouring 
to  express  great  economic  doctrines  in  short 
sentences  ; "  for  instance,  ' '  The  natural  price 
of  labour  is  that  price  which  is  necessary  to 
enable  the  labourers  one  with  another  to  subsist 
and  to  perpetuate  their  race"  (Pol.  Econ.,  ch.  v.) 
"A  tax  on  wages  is  in  fact  a  tax  on  profits" 
{ibid.  ch.  xvi.)  "Nothing  is  more  common 
than  to  see  hats  or  malt  rise  when  taxed  .  .  . 
so  with  labour,  when  wages  are  taxed,  its  price 
rises"  (ibid.)  "The  natural  tendency  of  profits 
is  to  fall "  (ch.  vi.)  Those  who  have  interpreted 
these  dicta  litei-ally,  without  regard  to  qualify 
ing  passages,  both  "the  hangers-on  of  the 
science  who  have  used  it  simply  as  an  engine 
for  keeping  the  working  classes  in  their  places, " 
and  also  some  socialists — may  be  considered 
doctrinaires  (see  Marshall,  Principles  of  Eco- 
nomics, pp.  63,  532,  672).  The  appellation 
was  probably  deserved  by  M'Culloch  when  he 
applied   to   the   concrete  ease  of  Ireland    his 


624 


DOCTRINAIRE— DOGMA 


abstract  theory  that  a  landlord  does  not  injure, 
but  rather  benefits  his  countrymen  by  becoming 
an  Absentee  (q.v.)  However,  in  this  and 
other  instances,  it  may  be  proper  to  attribute 
the  mistake  rather  to  the  reasoning  process 
than  to  a  neglect  of  experience.  The  holder  of 
a  false  doctrine  is  not  necessarily  a  doctrfnaire. 
Still  it  is  true  that  the  bad  consequences  of 
wrong  theories  have  been  aggravated  by  neglect 
of  oiSinary  experience  and  want  of  common 
sense.  Examples  of  wrong  theories  and  their 
consequences  will  be  found  in  the  articles  on 
Balance  of  Trade  ;  Mercantile  System  ; 
Physiocrats  ;  Wages  Fund,  and  many  other 
headings — beginning  with  L.  P.  Abeille  (q.v.) 
the  doctrinaire  who  taught  that  a  rise  in  the 
price  of  corn  was  beneficial  to  the  community, 
and  that  high  com  prices  make  high  wages. 

Such  instances  fully  justify  Burke's  condem- 
nation of  the  mathematical  method  in  human 
affairs  (Eefledions  on  the  French  Revolviion, 
Letter  to  a  Noble  Lord,  et  passim).  Burke's 
indignation  is  directed  chiefly  against  the 
political  doctrinaires  of  his  own  time.  But  it 
is  equally  applicable  to  the  "economists  and 
sophisters  "  of  a  later  age.  It  should  be  noticed 
that  the  same  Burke  does  not  on  occasion  shrink 
from  applying  economic  theory  Avith  some 
severity  (see  Thoughts  on  Scarcity,  remarks  on 
the  * '  Labouring  Poor  ").  An  instructive  protest 
against  the  abuse  of  abstract  reasoning  is  con- 
tained in  Richard  Jones's  Hent  and  other 
writings.  Whewell,  in  his  preface  to  the  works 
of  R.  Jones,  aptly  compares  the  doctrinaire  to 
one  who  should  assume  that  the  surface  of  the 
earth  was  entirely  detemiined  by  gravitation  ; 
making  abstraction  of  the  forces  of  cohesion  by 
which  the  mountains  are  "  in  fluctuation  fixed." 
To  complete  the  metaphor,  it  should  be  observed 
that  the  abstract  hypothesis  works  very  well  for 
the  greater  part  of  the  surface  of  the  terraqueous 
globe.  The  difficulty  is  to  discern  in  each  case 
what  is  the  character  of  the  subject  matter,  how 
far  the  hypothesis  of  perfect  fluidity  is  admissible. 
The  importance  of  facts  cannot  be  stated  more 
emphatically  than  by  Mill  in  his  Unsettled  Ques- 
tions. The  economist  must  not  rest  satisfied 
until  he  has  examined  all  the  facts  which  appear 
contrary  to  his  theory,  and  either  made  allow- 
ance for  exceptions,  or  ascertained  that  the 
appearance  was  illusory.  The  theorist  who 
v/ill  not  take  this  trouble  must  be  content  to 
hold  his  opinions  with  great  modesty.  Mill 
repeats  this  lesson  in  his  account  of  Auguste 
Comte  ;  whose  warnings  against  the  danger  of 
isolating  political  economy  from  social  science 
deserve  much  attention.  Another  source  of 
instruction  is  afforded  in  the  German  historical 
school.  Those  especially  who  have  shown  that 
they  appreciate  the  value  of  abstract  reasoning 
(see  Wagner,  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics, 
1886)  teach  with  authority  that  theory  without 
experience   is   barren.      The  method  of  Prof. 


Cohn  is  very  instructive.  In  his  classical  work 
on  English  railways  he  overthrows  by  argu- 
ments drawn  from  experience  the  doctrinaires 
who  preach  an  equal  mileage  rate  and  fares 
proportionate  to  cost.  Over  the  ruins  of  this 
demolished  doctrine  he  builds,  upon  a  broader 
basis  of  fact,  a  new  theory  which  differs  from 
the  old,  not  in  being  less  simple — for  it  is 
capable  of  being  expressed  in  mathematical  form 
(seeHadley,  Railway  Transportation,  Appendix ; 
and  art.  on  Duptjit) — but  in  better  represent- 
ing the  real  circumstances.  Among  English 
economists  who  have  stigmatised  the  intellectual 
vice  which  is  the  subject  of  this  article  should 
be  noticed  Cliffe-Leslie  {Essays)  ;  Prof.  Ingram 
(Presidential  Address,  Section  F,  British  Asso- 
ciation, 1878)  ;  Dr.  Cunningham  {Growth  of 
English  Commerce,  passim).  Even  unscientific 
writers  like  Carlyle  {q.v.)  may  impart  com- 
mon sense.  Literary  humour  is  a  potent 
antidote  against  the  crotchets  of  doctrinaires. 
Take  as  examples:  Voltaire's  "L'homme  aux 
quarante  ^cus  ;"  Scott's  Malachi  Malagrowther ; 
some  of  Thomas  L.  Peacock's  stories,  especially 
Crotchet  Castle  ;  part  of  Ruskin's  Unto  this  Last 
(Abstract  Political  Economy  ;  Facts). 

DOCTRINE  OF  POPULATION  (Malthus). 
See  Malthus,  Rev.  T.  R. ;  Population. 

DOGMA.  This  term,  which  properly  should 
signify  nothing  more  than  opinion,  has  come  to 
signify  an  opinion  adopted  without  proof  and 
maintained  with  passion.  In  political  economy 
the  term  dogmatic,  like  the  terms  abstract, 
unhistorical,  etc.,  is  often  applied  to  the  old,  or, 
as  they  are  more  indulgently  described,  the 
classical  economists.  These  economists  are 
sometimes  supposed  to  have  based  their  system 
upon  certain  arbitrary  assumptions  or  dogmas 
such  as  the  universal  selfishness  of  human 
nature,  the  universal  prevalence  of  competition, 
and  the  universal  tendency  of  population  to 
outrun  the  means  of  subsistence.  They  are 
sometimes  contrasted  with  the  later  economists, 
who  are  said  to  have  employed  induction  rather 
than  deduction,  and  to  have  consulted  history 
rather  than  to  have  employed  arguments  derived 
from  the  working  of  their  own  minds.  The 
difference  in  so  far  as  it  exists  is  only  one  of 
degree.  No  economist — indeed  no  scientific 
inquirer — can  avoid  holding  opinions  which 
those  who  differ  from  him  might  stigmatise 
as  dogmas.  The  processes  of  induction  and 
historical  inquiry  would  be  both  endless  and 
fruitless  to  one  who  undertook  them  with  a 
perfectly  blank  mind.  Induction  is  possible 
only  if  we  assume  the  uniformity  of  nature. 
History  has  no  lessons  for  us  if  we  do  not 
assume  a  certain  continuity  in  human  character. 
In  framing  an  induction  or  in  writing  a  history 
there  is  always  implied  a  process  of  selection 
among  numberless  facts.  Such  a  selection  can 
proceed  only  upon  some  principle  adopted  by 


DOITKIN— DOLES 


625 


the  inquirer  ;  a  principle  which  he  does  not 
find,  but  bring.  "  Let  any  one  watch  the 
manner  in  which  he  himself  unravels  a  compli- 
cated mass  of  evidence  ;  let  him  observe  how, 
for  instance,  he  elicits  the  true  history  of  any 
occurrence  from,  the  involved  statements  of  one 
or  of  many  witnesses  ;  he  will  find  that  he  does 
not  take  all  the  items  of  evidence  into  his 
mind  at  once  and  attempt  to  weave  them 
together  ;  he  extemporises,  from  a  few  of  the 
particulars,  a  first  rude  theory  of  the  mode  in 
which  the  facts  took  place,  and  then  looks  at 
the  other  statements  one  by  one  to  try  whether 
they  can  be  reconciled  with  that  provisional 
theory  or  what  alterations  or  additions  it 
requires  to  make  it  square  with  them  "  (Mill, 
Logic,  bk.  iii.  ch.  xiv.)  Hardly  any  progress 
therefore  can  be  made  in  political  economy 
without  assuming  certain  general  propositions. 
On  the  other  hand,  such  propositions  must  be 
regarded  as  merely  provisional,  and  must  always 
be  liable  to  revision  as  research  goes  on.  The 
same  remark  applies  to  the  conclusions  reached 
from  such  premisses  which  in  turn  afford  a 
point  of  departure  for  new  theorising. 

[See  articles  Classical  Economists  ;  Doctrin- 
aire, and  the  authorities  therein  cited,] 

F.  C.  M. 

DOITKIF.  A  small  base  coin  —  probably 
of  Flemish  origin — prohibited  by  Statute  3 
Henry  V.  ch.  i.  Hence  the  expression  "not 
worth  a  doit."  h.  Ha. 

DOLE-FISH.  The  proportion  of  fish  received 
as  their  allowance  or  share,  according  to  custom, 
by  the  fishermen  employed  in  the  North  Sea 
fisheries. 

[Statute  35  Henry  VIII.  ch.  vii.]  h.  Ha. 

DOLES.  A  dole  is  defined  by  Dr.  Johnson 
as  "provisions  or  money  distributed  in  charity," 
but  the  ordinary  use  of  the  term  in  modern 
times  implies  somewhat  more  than  this.  A 
dole  is  now  generally  understood  to  be  opposed 
to  regular  or  permanent  help,  and  to  be  com- 
paratively small  in  amount.  Doles  figure  largely 
in  the  charitable  bequests  of  old  time.  Thus 
at  Oxford,  on  St.  Thomas's  Day,  there  were 
given  away  more  than  seventy  such,  ranging 
in  value  from  13s.  6d.  up  to  £5,  and  hardly 
any  town  or  parish  in  England  is  without  them. 
Every  kind  of  condition  may  be  attached.  They 
are  confined  to  freemen,  to  residents  in  certain 
parishes,  to  regular  attendants  at  church,  to 
widows,  to  spinsters,  to  servants,  to  young 
men,  to  old  men,  to  cripples,  to  the  blind. 
The  modern  spirit,  embodied  in  schemes  issued 
by  the  charity  commissioners,  has  abolished 
large  numbers  of  them,  but  they  still  survive 
in  places  which  resist  reform.  The  objections 
to  the  dole-system  are  numerous  and  weighty. 
"The  practice  of  distributing  doles,"  said  Sir 
George  Jessel  in  the  famous  Campden  case, 
"should  be  more  honoured  in  the  breach  than 
in  the  observance.  There  is  no  doubt  that  it 
VOL.  I. 


tends  to  demoralise  the  poor  and  benefit  no 
one  .  .  .  the  extension  of  doles  is  simply  the 
extension  of  mischief."  What  are  the  grounds 
for  so  sweeping  a  condemnation  ?  The  first 
principle  in  administering  charity  is  that  it 
should  be  adequate  to  its  purpose  of  relieving 
distress  or  re-  establ  ishing  independence.  Neither 
of  these  objects  is  secured  by  doles.  They  are 
not  suflBcient  in  amount  to  meet  a  crisis,  nor 
continuous  enough  to  provide  for  old  age  ;  in 
many  cases  it  is  expressly  forbidden  that  the 
same  person  shall  be  a  recipient  on  two  consecu- 
tive occasions.  Again,  they  are  often  so  numer- 
ous, and  so  unimportant  in  amount,  as  to  be 
given  without  any  of  that  preliminary  inquiry 
which  is  essential  to  wise  almsgiving,  and  hence 
they  fall  largely  into  the  hands  of  persons  who 
make  anything  but  a  good  use  of  them.  The 
conditions  attached  to  the  receipt  of  doles  are 
often  of  an  absurd  kind.  They  hardly  ever 
further  their  object,  they  lead  to  gross  hypocrisy. 
It  is  idle  to  suppose  that  any  religious  body 
receives  moral  support  from  the  membership  of 
those  who  are  attracted  by  them  ;  in  the  great 
majority  of  cases  it  is  brought  into  disrepute 
by  the  inconsistency  of  the  profession  and 
practice.  Hence,  far  from  being  strengthened 
by  such  gifts,  religion  itself  comes  under  the 
suspicion  of  aiding  and  abetting  unreal  con- 
formity, and  its  moral  infiuence  is  weakened 
and  its  progress  stayed.  Add  to  these  objec- 
tions the  canvassing  for  such  gifts,  the  loss  of 
self-respect  involved,  the  temptations  to  dis- 
honesty in  appearance  and  in  phrase,  the 
melancholy  effect  on  children  of  witnessing  such 
conduct  on  the  part  of  their  parents,  the  in- 
ducement offered  to  give  up  the  attempt  to  gain 
an  honest  livelihood  and  seek  it  by  begging 
and  fawning,  the  attractions  which  such 
periodical  distributions  have  for  the  idle  and 
self-indulgent  from  every  quarter  to  settle  in 
the  favoured  parish  or  town,  and  it  is  not  diflS- 
cult  to  see  that  charitable  bequests  in  the  form 
of  doles  tend  almost  inevitably  to  increase  the 
very  evils  which  their  founders  hoped  to  abate. 
A  single  example  will  illustrate  this.  The 
charities  of  the  city  of  Bristol  were,  in  1892, 
estimated  thus: — endowed  £50,000,  subscrip- 
tion and  Colston  £41,000,  private  £50,000,  in 
addition  to  a  poor-law  expenditure  of  £55,500 — 
in  all  £196,600  annually  spent  on  a  population 
of  221,665'  (census  of  1891).  And  what  are 
the  results  of  the  system  pursued  in  many 
cases  ?  It  is  said  to  demoralise  and  pauperise. 
"The  poor,  qualified  by  residence  in  parishes 
in  which  endowments  exist  to  receive  their 
benefits,  look  upon  them  as  a  right,  apply  for 
them  regularly,  irrespective  of  need,  and  accept 
them  with  thanklessness.  Jealousies  and  dis- 
contents grow  round  their  distribution.  The 
thought  that  they  will  fall  in  induces  unthrifti- 
ness  ;  debts  are  run  up  to  be  paid  off  by  them  ; 
and  if  not  this,  being  something  beyond  and 

:2s 


DOLLAR 


outside  the  ordinary  sources  of  income,  they  are 
deemed  fittingly  applicable  for  some  unwonted 
and  needless  expenditure.  Many  waste  their 
hearts  in  expectancy,  and  their  time — years 
may  be, — better  spent  in  efforts  to  earn  their 
living,  in  the  continual  pursuit  of  gifts.  •  The 
adroit  professional  charity-hunters  get  the  lion's 
share  of  them.  The  industrious  old  people  find 
themselves  too  late.  Much  of  the  money,  and 
even  gifts  in  kind,  quickly  sold  or  pawned,  are 
spent  in  drink"  {The  Condition  of  the  BHstol 
Foot).  So  far  doles  have  been  treated  as  a 
form  of  bequest  only.  The  same  characteristics 
and  the  same  results  are  seen  in  part  in  the 
case  of  indiscriminate  charity  by  individuals, 
and  of  out-door  relief  given  by  boards  of 
guardians. 

[Charity  Commission  Act,  ed.  E.  E.  Mitcheson, 
1887. — Charity  Commission  Reports. — Charities 
Register  and  Digest,  Introd.  pp.  cxlv.  et  seq. — 
Foor  Law  Commission,  Report  and  Evidence 
(1837). — Rep(yrt  of  the  Committee  to  Inquire  into 
the  Condition  of  the  Bristol  Foor  (1885).— Con- 
fessions of  an  old  Almsgiver  (1871).]      l.  B.  p. 

DOLLAR 

History  of,  p.  626  ;  of  Account,  p.  627  ;  Hard  (Stock  Ex- 
change use  of  word),  p.  627 ;  Hard  Spanish,  p.  627  ; 
United  States— gold  and  silver  dollar,  p.  627 ;  Trade 
(United  States),  p.  627 ;  Maria  Theresa  or  Levantiner 
Thaler,  p.  628 ;  Mexican  or  Peso,  p.  628 ;  South  and 
Central  American  Republics  and  British  Honduras,  p. 
628. 

DoLLAE,  History  of.  The  name  dates 
from  the  year  1517,  when  the  Counts  of 
Schlick  directed  a  large  coinage  of  the  already 
familiar  silver  "  gulden  groschen  "  in  Joachims - 
thai  {i.e.  St.  James's  Dale)  in  Bohemia,  whence 
the  coins  came  to  be  known  as  Joachimsthaler, 
or  simply  thaler,  the  coin  of  the  Dale.  In 
1566,  at  the  Convention  of  Augsburg,  the 
thaler  was  adopted  as  an  imperial  coin,  under 
the  name  of  "reichs-thaler,"  or  "rix-dollar." 
At  this  date  the  millesimal  fineness  of  the  coin 
was  reduced  from  937*5  to  888,  though  the 
weight  remained  the  eighth  of  a  Cologne  mark, 
or  about  451  grains  troy.  The  standard  was 
again  settled  at  Leipzig  in  1690,  and  subse- 
quently in  1763  ;  but  these  changes,  and  the 
history  of  the  rix-doUar,  are  unimportant  for 
the  purposes  of  this  article,  seeing  that 
with  the  close  of  the  17th  century  the  name 
(modified  to  "dollar")  was  usurped — at  least 
among  English-speaking  peoples — by  a  Spanish 
coin,  the  history  of  which  it  is  now  necessary 
to  trace. 

The  unit  of  the  (silver)  monetary  system  of 
Spain  had  been  the  "real"  or  "royal"  since 
at  least  the  days  of  Pedro  the  Cruel  (before 
1369)  and  was  retained  by  Ferdinand  and 
Isabella  in  their  Mint  Edict  of  13th  June 
1497.  It  was  the  multiple  of  this  unit,  the 
"piece  of  eight"  reals,  weighing  by  law 
423-9  grains,  of  931  millesimal  fineness,  and 
therefore  containing  some  394^  grains  of  fine 


silver,  which  was  poured  forth  from  the 
Spanish-American  mints  after  the  conquest  of 
Mexico  and  Peru,  early  in  the  16  th  century,  in 
such  profusion  as  to  become  a  universal  coin, 
reaching  even  China — by  way  of  Goa  and  the 
Philippines — before  the  close  of  the  16th  cen- 
tury. Thus,  as  the  rix-doUar  and  the  "piect  of 
eight "  were  practically  of  identical  fine  weight 
and  value — 4s.  6d.  sterling  being  the  accepted 
standard, — it  came  about  that,  the  geographical 
meaning  of  "dollar"  (or  thaler)  having  been 
forgotten,  the  "piece  of  eight"  obtained  the 
name  of  the  "Spanish  dollar."  And,  as  the 
rix-doUar  began  to  lose,  even  in  Germany,  its 
earlier  importance — except  as  money  of  account 
— the  name  "dollar,"  from  the  beginning  of 
the  18th  century  onwards,  was  entirely  usurped 
by  the  Spanish  coin,  which  after  1686  ceased 
in  the  Peninsula  to  be  a  "piece  of  eight,"  and 
became  a  piece  of  ten  reals  of  "new  plate." 
In  1728  the  Bourbon  kings  of  Spain,  in  issuing 
the  new  device  of  the  "globe  dollar,"  took  the 
opportunity  to  reduce  the  gross  weight  to  417  "6 
grains,  and  the  millesimal  fineness  to  916-6, 
and  in  1772  the  fineness  was  further  reduced  to 
902-7  for  the  later  device  of  the  "  Carolus,"  or 
"pillar"  dollar.  The  latter  standard  was 
preserved  in  Spain  up  to  1848,  and  survives  to 
the  present  day  in  the  Mexican  dollar,  the  lineal 
descendant  since  1821  of  the  Spanish  dollar. 

It  should  be  added  that  under  Spanish  rule 
the  dollar  was  uniformly  below  standard. 
Prior  to  1728  its  fine  content  was  found  by  the 
English  mint  to  be  only  385  grains,  as  against 
394-6  by  law  ;  between  1728  and  1772  only 
377  grains,  as  against  382-8  by  law ;  and  be- 
tween 1772  and  1810  only  371  grains,  as 
against  377  by  law.  The  Mexican  dollar, 
dating  from  1821,  has  steadily  improved,  until 
in  the  present  day,  as  shown  by  investigations 
at  the  London  Mint  in  1891,  the  dollar  is 
practically  up  to  its  legal  standard. 

Though  Spanish  America  was  lost  to  Spain 
by  the  revolutionary  wars  of  1810-21,  and 
though  with  1810  the  Spanish  dollar  practically 
ceased  to  be  coined,  yet  it  still  continues  to 
circulate  as  the  standard  coin,  to  the  exclusion 
of  the  Mexican  dollar,  the  dominant  coin  of  the 
far  East,  in  certain  Malay  and  Siamese- Malay 
States — Rhaman,  Lege,  Patani,  and,  to  a  less 
degree,  Kelantan.  But,  of  far  greater  import- 
ance than  the  modern  circulation  of  the  Spanish 
dollar  itself  is  the  line  of  its  descendants. 
Apart  from  (i.)  the  dollar  of  the  Philippines  ; 
(ii.)  the  Mexican  dollar  and  (iii.)  the  debased 
piastre  of  Turkey  ;  the  Spanish  dollar  has  origi- 
nated the  silver  dollar  of  the  United  States, 
which,  in  1785,  was  avowedly  modelled  on  the 
average  of  the  Spanish  coins  in  circulation,  and 
so  indirectly  of  the  gold  U.S.  dollar  worth 
49  -316d.  sterling.  Another  gold  descendant  is 
the  two-dollar  piece  of  Newfoundland.  The 
Hong-kong    Mint     dollar    of     1866-68,    the 


DOLLAR 


627 


Japanese  "yen,"  of  1871  onwards,  and  the 
recent  Canton  dollar,  are  immediately  derived 
from  the  Mexican,  not  the  Spanish  dollar. 
Most  of  the  South  American  dollars  are  now 
"dollars"  only  in  name,  being  in  reality  five- 
franc  pieces  weighing  only  25  (instead  of 
slightly  over  27)  grammes.  In  Spain,  which 
has  adopted  the  monetary  system  of  the  Latin 
Union,  the  new  five-peseta,  or  five-franc,  piece 
is  similarly  known  as  a  dollar. 

[Synonyms.  Pieza  de  a  ocho.  Peso  duro.  Piece 
(or  Royal)  of  Eight,  Piastre,  Colonato,  Cob  (from 
coba,  slang  Spanish  for  Real)  Gourde,  Escudo  de 
Plata,  etc.] 

[Becher,  Bas  Oesterreichische  Munzwesen  (Wien, 
1838). — Heiss,  Monedas  •  Hispano  Christianas 
(Madrid,  1865). — Linderraan,  Money  and  Legal 
Tender  in  the  United  States  (1877). — Zedler, 
Universal- Lexicon  (1745),  s.v.  "Thaler." — Mint 
Report  for  1891.]  K.  C. 

Dollar  of  Account.  On  the  stock  ex- 
change of  London  it  has  been  for  many  years 
usual  to  reckon  the  United  States  dollar  as 
worth  always  4s. ;  although  the  actual  exchange 
value  of  the  American  dollar  is  usually  near 
4s.  2d.  It  is  obviously  useful  to  have,  for  pur- 
poses of  quotation,  a  dollar  which  is  worth 
exactly  one-fifth  of  a  pound  sterling.  American 
railroad  shares  are  always  quoted  in  these 
dollars,  and  the  par  value  of  100  dollars  stock 
in  New  York  would  be,  as  a  rule,  nearly  103 
dollars  in  London  ;  and  the  dollars  in  which 
dividends  on  those  shares  are  paid  give  the 
shareholder  a  rather  better  percentage  than 
appears  when  the  rate  of  dividend  is  reckoned 
at  so  much  per  100  of  the  nominal  4s.  dollars 
in  which  London  quotations  are  given.   A.  e. 

Dollar,  Hard  (Stock  Exchange  use  of  word). 
This  was  the  name  given  on  the  London 
stock  exchange  to  certain  bonds  issued  by  the 
state  of  Buenos  Ayres.  A  hard  dollar  was  ori- 
ginally intended  to  mark  the  difference  between 
two  currencies  of  the  Argentine  Republic,  the 
soft  dollar  having  fallen  to  an  indefinite  depre- 
ciation in  consequence  of  the  over-issue  of  paper 
money  by  that  state.  The  hard  dollar,  then, 
had  a  special  value  ;  but  in  the  year  1889  it 
was  found  expedient  to  convert  the  hard  dollar 
bonds  into  sterling  bonds  bearing  S^  per  cent, 
so  discreditable  was  it  found  by  the  Argentine 
government  that  its  "hard"  dollars  should  be 
depreciating  almost  as  much  as  the  baser  cur- 
rency from  which  it  was  formerly  distinguished. 

a.  E. 

Dollar,  Hard  (Spanish).  The  old  Span- 
ish dollar  was  known  as  the  peso  duro,  or  hard 
dollar.  It  was  struck  and  issued  from  1707 
to  1868,  when  the  peseta  (franc)  system  of  cur- 
rency was  adopted  in  Spain. 

The  following  is  a  list  of  the  various  weights 
and  finenesses  at  which  this  coin  was  issued  at 
different  times  ;  from  which  it  will  be  seen 
that,  for  a  coin  circulating  for  so  long  a  period 
as  161  years,  the  variations  were  not  great : 


Wei-ht. 

w  o    . 

Value  in 

Value  in 

OT 

s 

g8i2 

silver  925 

standard 

Year. 

Grains. 

£-:§ 

fine  at 

silver 

rf 

p^"" 

5s.  6d.  per 

francs 

o 

ounce. 

(900  fine), 
francs. 

pence. 

1707-28 

423-89 

27-468 

930-500 

58-638 

5-680 

1728-72 

417-74 

27-064 

909-722 

56-491 

5-471      ' 

1772 

417-74 

27-064 

902-778 

56-064 

5-429      1 

1848 

405-75 

26-291 

900-000 

54--281 

5-258 

1850 

402-87 

26-105 

900-000 

53-897 

5-221 

1854-68 

400-64 

25-960 

900-000 

53-598 

5-192 

The  subdivisions  of  the  peso  duro  were  all, 
until  the  year  1864,  of  proportionate  weight 
and  fineness  to  the  peso.  In  that  year  the 
escudo,  or  half-peso,  only  was  struck  in  metal 
of  the  same  fineness  as  the  peso,  the  remaining 
divisional  pieces  becoming  merely  tokens,  with 
a  millesimal  fineness  of  810.  These  coins,  how- 
ever, were  still  coined  proportionate  in  weight 
to  the  hard  dollar. 

The  hard  dollar,  which  was  first  struck  in 
1772,  is  of  exactly  the  same  weight  and  fineness 
as  the  Mexican  dollar,  and  was,  in  fact,  the 
coin  of  which  originally  the  Mexican  dollar  was 
the  copy.  f.  e.  a. 

Dollar  (United  States).  The  standard  of 
value  in  the  United  States,  and  both  a  gold 
and  a  silver  coin. 

Gold  Dollar.  —  Standard  gold  coin  first 
authorised  by  Act  of  Congress  in  1849,  and 
first  issued  in  that  year.  Weight  25-8  grains, 
fineness  900.  Value:  English  standard  (916-6 
fine  at  £3:17:  10^-  per  oz.)  49-32d.  ;  French 
standard  (900  fine)  5-18  francs. 

Silver  Dollar.  —  Standard  silver  coin  first 
struck  in  1793.  Weight  416  grains,  fineness 
892-4  ;  altered  in  1837  to  weight  412-5  grains, 
fineness  900.  Value :  English  standard  (925 
fine  at  5s.  6d.  per  oz.)  55'184d.  ;  French 
standard  (900  fine)  5-346  francs.  The  coinage 
of  silver  dollars  was  discontinued  in  1873,  when 
the  gold  dollar  was  established  the  sole  stand- 
ard of  value.  In  1878,  however,  an  act  was 
passed  reinstating  the  silver  dollar  as  a  stand- 
ard coin,  and  their  coinage  was  recommenced. 

F.  E.  A. 

Dollar,  Trade  (United  States).  A  silver 
coin  struck  for  use  in  the  trade  between  the 
United  States  and  China  during  the  five  years 
1874  to  1878  inclusive.  Weight  420  grains, 
fineness  900.  Value :  English  standard  (925 
fine  at  5s.  6d.  per  oz.)  56-19d.  ;  French 
standard  (900  fine)  5-443  francs.  These  coins 
were  originally  legal  tender  in  the  United 
States  to  the  amount  of  $5,  but  were  demone- 
tised in  1876,  and  were  then  only  struck  for 
depositors  of  bullion  on  the  condition  that  they 
were  exported.  In  1878,  however,  their  coin- 
age was  discontinued,  as  considerable  quanti- 
ties had  found  their  way  back  to  the  United 
States,  where  they  were  put  into  circulation 
at   a   profit.      The   total   amount   coined  was 


628 


DOLLAR— DOMBASLES 


$35,959,360,  equal  to  nearly  £8,000,000  ster- 
ling Those  circulating  in  the  United  States 
(about  $7,000,000,  or  roughly  £1,400,000) 
were  redeemed  by  the  government  at  their 
nominal  value.  f*  ^'  -'^• 

Dollar,  Maria  Theresa,  or  Leva^iner 
Thaler.  Austrian  silver  (trade)  coin,  first 
struck  in  1765.  Since  1780,  however,  these 
coins  have  always  been  issued  bearing  the  date 
of  that  year  and  the  effigy  of  the  Empress  Maria 
Theresa.  They  are  issued  for  use  in  the  Levant 
and  Asiatic  trade.  Weight  433  -15  grains,  fine- 
ness 833-3.  Value:  English  standard  (925 
fine  at  5s.  6d.  per  oz.)  53 -Gd. ;  French  standard 
(900  fine)  5*2  francs.  This  coin  has  no  sub- 
sidiary divisional  pieces.  It  will  continue  to 
be  coined  under  the  new  Austrian  currency 
arrangements.  r-  E.  A. 

Dollar,  Mexican,  or  Peso.  Silver  coin  ; 
weight  417-74  grains,  fineness  902-7.  Value  : 
English  standard  (925  fine  at  5s.  6d.  per  oz.) 
56-064d.  ;  French  standard  (900  fine)  5-429 
francs.  The  coins  subsidiary  to  the  Mexican 
dollar  are  ^  Peso  (50  cents),  ^  Peso  (25  cents), 
^  Peso  (10  cents),  -^  Peso  (5  cents),  all  of 
which  are  902  7  fine,  and  proportionate  in 
weight  to  the  dollar.  This  coin  circulates  in 
China,  Hong-Kong,  the  Straits  Settlements, 
and  the  .East  generally,  being  received  by 
weight.  It  is  also  bought  and  sold  as  bullion 
in  all  parts  of  the  world.  "  Chopped  dollars," 
which  are  Mexican  dollars  that  have  been 
chopped  or  stamped  with  a  mark  by  the 
Chinese,  are  a  circulating  medium  in  Hong- 
Kong,  Foochow,  Canton,  and  Amoy,  where 
they  are  usually  received  at  the  rate  of  717 
Canton  taels  per  1000  dollars.  f.  e.  a. 

Dollar  (South  and  Central  American  Ke- 
publics).  In  the  Argentine  Republic,  Chili, 
Colombia,  Ecuador,  Guatemala,  Honduras, 
Peru,  Uruguay,  and  Venezuela,  the  standard 
of  value  is  the  silver  dollar,  a  coin  of  385-8 
grains,  25  grammes,  of  silver  900  fine.  Value: 
English  standard  (925  fine  at  5s.  6d.  per 
oz.)  51-613d.  ;  French  standard  (900  fine)  5 
francs. 

The  Guatemalan  dollar  is  the  standard  of 
value  in  the  colony  of  British  Honduras. 

F.  E.  A. 

DOLLAR,  Spanish.     See  Dollar,  Hard. 

DOLUS.  Expression  of  Roman  law  de- 
noting wrongful  intention  in  the  widest  sense. 
Fraud  presupposes  "dolus,"  but  there  may  be 
"dolus"  without  fraud;  for  instance  an  in- 
cendiary, or  a  person  committing  an  assault  is 
actuated  by  "  dolus."  E.  s. 

DOMAINE.  In  mediaeval  France,  as  in 
mediaeval  England,  the  king  was  expected  to 
"live  of  his  own,"  and  to  apply  to  his  subjects 
for  aid  to  meet  any  extraordinary  expenses. 
Hence  domaine  comes  to  mean,  not  only  the 
lands  which  the  king  possesses  like  any  other 
landowner,    but  the   whole   of    the    ordinary 


revenue  of  the  crown,  as  distinguished  from 
the  extraordinary  revenue  or  taxes.  The 
domaine  matiriel,  or  crown  lands,  was  declared 
inalienable  by  an  edict  of  1318,  which  was 
frequently  renewed,  and  grants  from  it  were 
frequently  resumed  by  the  crown.  In  spite  of 
these  measures,  however,  it  continued  steadily 
to  diminish  until  the  l7th  century.  The 
domaine  immaMriel  consisted  mainly  of  the 
almost  innumerable  rights  which  belonged  to 
the  crown.  The  most  important  of  these  were 
the  droit  d' amortissenient,  the  payment  by  a 
corporation  for  leave  to  acquire  real  property, 
the  droit  d'aubaine  (see  Aubaine,  Droit  d'), 
by  which  the  crown  inherited  the  property  of 
foreigners  dying  in  France,  the  droit  de  hdtardise, 
by  which  the  property  of  bastards  feU  to  the 
king,  the  droit  de  franc-fief,  and  the  droit  de 
rigale.  The  domain  revenue  also  included  the 
proceeds  of  the  sale  of  offices,  and  the  Paulette 
{q.v.)  paid  by  members  of  the  parliament  and 
other  courts.  In  the  18th  century  the  domaine 
was  calculated  to  bring  in  about  forty- onp 
million  francs  (£1,640,000).  R.  l. 

DOMBASLES,  Alexandre  Mathieu  de 
(1777-1843).  With  the  support  of  M.  de 
Villeneuve-Bargemont  {q.v.)  the  author  of 
the  Economie  Folitique  Chretienne,  at  that  time 
prefect  of  the  department  of  the  Moselle,  he 
founded  in  1822  the  model  farm  of  Roville,  the 
first  agricultural  school  established  in  France. 
His  teaching  was  mainly  experimental,  and  to 
the  end  he  maintained  that  "in  reality  the 
agricultural  improvements,  which  result  from 
chemistry  or  vegetable  physiology,  amount 
hitherto  to  very  little  indeed.  .  .  .  The  theory 
of  agriculture  consists  of  rules,  which  are  to  be 
deduced  from  the  comparative  observation  of 
facts  in  a  great  number  of  various  cases.  .  .  . 
An  agricultural  school  ought  to  be  an  agri- 
cultural clinique"  {CEuvres  Diver ses,  Paris,  1843, 
pp.  214-225).  As  an  experimental  teacher, 
Mathieu  de  Dombasles  rendered  immense  ser- 
vices to  French  agriculture  by  the  publication 
of  his  results  in  the  Annates  de  Roville  (9 
volumes,  1825,  and  following  years)  ;  he  was 
one  of  the  promoters  of  the  beetroot-sugar 
industry,  popularised  the  methods  of  breeding 
of  Bakewell,  and  of  farming  of  Sir  John  Sinclair, 
and  in  a  pamphlet,  De  Vlmpdt  sur  les  Eaux  de 
Vie  (1824),  tried  to  induce  the  French  govern- 
ment to  protect  the  distillation  of  spirits  from 
potatoes.  He  also  thoroughly  explained  the 
advantages  and  disadvantages  both  of  small 
and  of  large  farms  in  his  essay  on  L'Etendue 
des  Propriet6s  Rurales  dans  ses  rapports  avec  la 
prosperity  de  V Agriculture  (1825). 

In  connection  with  agi-iculture,  Mathieu  de 
Dombasles  often  approaches  economic  ques- 
tions (see  the  first  part  othis  (Euvres  Diver  ses 
entitled  Economie  Politique).  He  was  a  staunch 
protectionist  and  an  opponent  of  French  colonial 
enterprise  in  Algeria.     He  also  objected  to  the 


DOMESDAY  BOOK 


628 


teaohing    of    agriculture    in    country    primary 
schools.  E.  ca. 

DOMESDAY  BOOK  is  the  name  which,  at 
least  since  the  12th  century,  has  been  borne 
by  the  record  of  the  great  survey  of  England 
made  by  order  of  William  the  Conqueror. 
Apparently  the  decree  for  the  survey  was  issued 
at  a  moot  held  at  Gloucester  at  the  midwinter 
of  1085-86,  and  the  work  was  completed  in  the 
course  of  the  following  year.  Royal  commis- 
sioners (legati)  were  sent  into  each  shire  with 
a  list  of  interrogatories,  to  which  they  were  to 
obtain  sworn  answers  from  local  juries.  Their 
procedure  seems  to  have  been  this — they  held 
a  great  shire  moot,  at  which  every  hundred  or 
wapentake  of  the  shire  was  represented  by  a 
jury,  while  every  vill  was  represented  by  a 
deputation  of  villagers.  From  each  hundred- 
jury  they  obtained  a  verdict  about  all  the  land 
in  the  hundred,  the  villagers  being  at  hand  to 
correct  or  supplement  verdicts,  while  "the 
whole  shire  "  was  also  present,  and  from  time 
to  time  appeal  could  be  made  to  its  testimony. 
The  statement  thus  supplied  was  "reduced 
into  writing  and  duly  transmitted  to  the  king. 
It  was  afterwards  methodised  and  abstracted, 
and  fairly  transcribed  in  the  great  volume  of 
Domesday  and  deposited  in  the  royal  treasury 
at  Winchester,  amongst  the  other  muniments 
of  the  realm.  It  still  exists,  fresh  and  perfect 
as  when  the  scribe  put  pen  to  parchment,  the 
oldest  cadastre,  or  survey  of  a  kingdom,  now 
existing  in  the  world "  (Palgi'ave,  History  of 
Normandy  and  England,  vol.  iii.  p.  575).  Our 
best  information  about  the  form  of  the  original 
verdicts  is  contained,  not  in  Domesday  Book 
itself,  but  in  a  document  known  as  the  "  In- 
quisitio  Comitatus  Cantabrigiensis. "  This 
seems  to  be  a  copy  made  in  the  12th  century 
of  the  verdicts  delivered  by  the  juries  which 
represented  some  of  the  hundreds  of  Cambridge- 
shire. The  verdicts  having  been  obtained, 
they  were  sent  to  the  king's  treasury,  and  a 
digest  was  made  of  them  by  the  royal  officers. 
This  digest  is  Domesday  Book.  If  we  may 
draw  a  general  inference  from  Cambridgeshire, 
the  materials  supplied  by  the  commissioners 
were  subjected  to  a  process  of  rearrangement. 
A  scheme  that  was  wholly  geographical  gave 
way  to  one  which  was  partly  geographical, 
partly  proprietary.  Domesday  Book  deals  with 
each  shire  separately,  but  within  the  shire  it 
collects,  under  the  name  of  each  "tenant  in 
chief,"  all  the  estates  that  he  holds,  no  matter 
in  what  hundred  they  may  be.  For  example, 
the  Cambridgeshire  verdicts  showed  that  Count 
Alan  had  lands  in  many  hundreds.  In  the 
original  verdicts  the  entries  relating  to  his 
estates  were  therefore  scattered  about ;  in 
Domesday  Book  they  are  all  collected  together. 
Domesday  Book  consists  of  two  volumes,  some- 
times called  "Great  Domesday"  and  "Little 
The   latter   deals   with    Essex, 


Norfolk,  and  SufTolk  ;  the  former  with  so  much 
of  the  rest  of  England  as  was  surveyed.  A 
document  in  the  keeping  of  the  cathedral 
chapter  of  Exeter,  and  known  as  ' '  the  Exon 
Domesday,"  contains  an  account  of  a  large  part 
of  the  south-western  shires,  which  is  very  closely 
connected  with  that  gi\'cn  by  what,  for  dis- 
tinction's sake,  is  sometimes  called  "the  Ex- 
chequer Domesday."  Seemingly  this  Exon 
Domesday  is  independent  of  the  Exchequer 
Record,  and  goes  back  by  a  different  route  to  the 
original  verdicts.  The  same  may  perhaps  be 
said  of  the  "  Inquisitio  Eliensis,"  an  account  of 
the  estates  held  by  the  church  of  Ely.  This 
Ely  inquest  must  not  be  confused  with  the 
Cambridgeshire  incpiest. 

Domesday  Book  was  printed  and  published 
in  1783  in  two  folio  volumes.  A  third  volume 
containing  indexes  was  published  in  1811,  and 
this  was  followed  in  1816  by  a  fourth  volume 
containing  the  Exon  Domesday,  the  Ely  In- 
quest, and  some  other  matters.  Of  late  years 
useful  facsimiles  have  been  published  by  the 
Ordnance  Survey  Office  of  various  parts  of  the 
great  Exchequer  Record,  and  can  be  obtained 
at  moderate  prices.  The  important  Cambridge- 
shire Inquisition  was  first  published  by  N.  E. 
Hamilton  in  1876. 

A  large  literature  has  gradually  been  collect- 
ing round  Domesday  Book.  Among  the  older 
books  Robert  Kelham's  Domesday  Book  Illus- 
trated (1788)  and  the  essays  of  Philip  Carteret 
Webb  deserve  to  be  mentioned.  Sir  Henry  Ellis, 
in  his  General  Int7'oduction  to  Domesday  Book 
(1833),  supplied  valuable  indexes,  and  summed 
up  the  older  learning.      In  the  fifth  volume  of 

E.  A.  Freeman's  Norman  Conquest  good  use 
has  been  made  of  all  that  bears  on  political 
history,  on  the  history  of  great  men,  great 
churches,  great  events.  James  F.  Morgan's 
England  under  the  Norman  Occvjyation  (1858) 
is  a  good  introduction  to  the  study  of  Domes- 
day, and  the  like  may  be  said  of  W.  de  Gray 
Birch's  Domesday  Book  (1887).  A  new  epoch 
in  the  scientific  exploration  of  the  record  is 
marked  by  the  various  works  of  R.  W.  Eyton 
dealing  with  Dorset,  Somerset,  Lincoln,  and 
Stafford,  especially  by  the  key  to  Domesday 
Book.  Two  volumes  of  essays  by  various  writers, 
called  Domesday  Studies  (1888-91),  contain  two 
valuable  papers  by  J.  H.  Round,  besides  other 
matters.  In  some  county  histories  Domesday 
has  been  well  used,  but  here  it  is  possible  to 
name  only  the  books  of  general  importance. 

F.  Seebohm's  English  Village  Community  has 
done  much  to  awaken  a  new  and  an  economic 
interest  in  our  oldest  statistics. 

Much  remains  to  be  done.  The  student  who 
approaches  Domesday  from  the  economic  side 
will  at  once  see  that  he  has  before  him  a  vast 
mass  of  detailed  statistics  which  ought  to  tell 
him  much  about  agiiculture,  prices,  rents,  and 
the  like.     At  the  same  time  he  will  feel  that 


U30 


DOMESTIC  SYSTEM  OF  INDUSTRY 


he  is  debarred  from  making  use  of  these  pre- 
cious materials  by  the  difficulty  of  discovering 
the  meaning  of  the  crabbed  formulas  which  are 
repeated  on  page  after  page.  The  difficulty  is 
a  very  real  one.  Domesday  Book  stands  alone. 
It  is  so  far  removed  in  time  from  the  documents 
which  most  nearly  resemble  it,  the  extents  of 
manors  which  are  found  in  monastic  cartularies, 
that  we  have  to  explain  it  out  of  itself  or  not 
at  all,  for  we  shall  look  in  vain  for  help  else- 
where. Then  again  the  terms  that  it  employs 
as  technical  terms  are,  we  may  say,  derived 
from  two  different  languages  which  have  only 
of  late  come  into  contact  with  each  other. 
About  half  of  them  have  been  introduced  by 
the  Norman  conquerors,  while  the  other  half 
are  words  which  were  in  use  in  England  under 
Edward  the  Confessor.  Hence  many  puzzles  ; 
for  example,  what  word  did  English  juries  say 
when  French  clerks  wrote  down  villanus? 
Then  again,  the  more  our  record  is  studied, 
the  more  plainly  do  we  see  that  one  main  pur- 
pose governs  both  its  form  and  its  matter. 
King  William  is  not  collecting  miscellaneous 
information  in  the  spirit  of  a  scientific  inquirer. 
He  is  in  quest  of  geld.  Domesday  Book  is  a 
geld  book,  a  tax  book.  Geldability,  actual  or 
potential,  this  is  its  main  theme.  If  then  we 
are  to  understand  its  statistics,  the  first  thing 
necessary  is  a  theory  of  geld,  of  the  manner  in 
which  the  great  tax  has  been  and  is  assessed 
and  collected.  Towards  the  construction  of 
such  a  theory  not  a  little  has  been  done  by 
modern  writers,  especially  by  Eyton  and  Round, 
but  until  the  work  has  been  completed,  specu- 
lations about  rents  and  values  seem  doomed  to 
failure.  Everywhere,  for  example,  the  question 
meets  us  whether  we  are  reading  of  real  areal 
units  of  land  or  of  units  which  are  the  results 
of  a  rude  system  of  taxation,  and  a  great  deal 
of  labour  must  yet  be  spent  on  the  book  before 
this  question  will  have  been  adequately 
answered.  F.  w.  m. 

DOMESTIC  SYSTEM  OF  INDUSTRY. 
This  system  is  opposed  to  that  of  carrying  on 
manufacturing  industry  in  factories  {see  Fac- 
tory System).  It  was  very  general  in  England 
before  the  changes  which  were  effected  at  the 
close  of  the  last,  and  the  opening  of  the  present 
century  {see  Industrial  Revolution).  Until 
the  introduction  of  any  but  the  simplest 
machinery,  manufacturing  industry  had  been 
closely  associated  with  agriculture,  and  had 
been  canied  on,  with  few  exceptions,  in  country 
towns  and  villages,  in  the  houses  of  craftsmen 
or  handicraftsmen,  who  worked  Avith  their  own 
hands,  aided  by  simple  tools  and  appliances, 
and  were  hence  called  manufacturers  (Latin, 
manus,  a  hand,  and  facere,  to  make).  They 
were  assisted  by  apprentices  {see  Apprentice- 
ship) whose  number  and  time  of  service  were 
fixed  by  law,  and  by  a  few  Journeymen  {q.v.), 
or  liired  labourers,  whose  wages  were,  in  theory 


at  least,  settled  by  the  magistrates.  These 
apprentices  and  journeymen  lived  in  the  same 
house  with  the  master-craftsman,  and  ate  at 
his  table.  Thus  in  the  woollen  trade,  which 
was  the  staple  industry  of  the  country,  the 
spinning,  weaving,  and  dyeing  were  carried  on 
in  the  houses  of  craftsmen,  few  of  whom  pos- 
sessed more  than  three  or  four  looms,  or  had 
working  under  their  direction  more  than  eight 
or  ten  people — men,  women,  and  children. 
There  were  apparently  even  now,  and  there  had 
been  for  some  time  previously,  cases  of  produc- 
tion conducted  under  the  modern  system,  by 
which  one  individual  supplies  and  controls  the 
capital  which  is  needed,  but  the  actual  processes 
of  industry  were  pursued,  with  apparently  few 
exceptions,  in  the  houses  of  the  craftsmen. 
This  domestic  system  had  its  unfavourable  side, 
but  it  seems  to  have  often  led  to  a  feeling  of 
warm  personal  attachment  between  the  master 
and  his  men.  With  the  introduction  of  machin- 
ery, however,  and  in  a  more  marked  and  general 
degree  with  the  employment  of  steam  as  the 
motive  power  of  that  machinery,  the  domestic 
system  of  industry  gave  place  to  the  factory 
system  ;  and,  although  it  is  still  found  in  some 
employments,  it  is  now  the  exception  rather 
than,  as  it  once  was,  the  rule.  The  fact  that 
steam  can  only  be  generated  in  a  fixed  spot, 
and  that  the  motive  power  thereby  furnished 
can  only  be  distributed  over  a  small  area  has, 
no  doubt,  tended  to  favour  the  concentration  of 
industry  in  large  factories  ;  and  it  has  been  said 
that  the  discovery  and  substitution  of  some  fresh 
motive  power,  such  as  electricity,  or  of  some 
fresh  source  of  motive  power,  such  as  petroleum, 
which  can  be  distributed  along  wires  or  pipes 
from  a  common  centre  over  a  wide  area,  might 
lead  to  the  revival  of  the  domestic  system  of 
industry.  But  there  are  various  economies  of 
management,  and  of  purchase  and  sale,  which 
lend  an  advantage  to  production  on  a  large 
scale  {see  Industries,  Large  and  Small)  ;  and 
these  would  continue  to  operate,  even  if  a  fresh 
motive  power,  or  source  of  motive  power,  were 
generally  introduced.  And  they  would  prob- 
ably outweigh,  except  in  certain  occupations 
where  the  domestic  system  is  still  found,  the 
benefits  of  the  close  personal  interest  which  is 
felt,  and  of  the  continual  watchfulness  which 
is  exercised,  by  the  small  master.  It  should 
be  noted  that  some  of  the  instances,  which  now 
exist,  of  the  domestic  system  meet  with  censure 
rather  than  approval  on  the  part  of  the  public. 
What  is  known  by  the  ambiguous  term  of 
the  Sweating  system  seems  to  be  in  reality 
one  variety  of  the  domestic  system  of  industry. 
In  many  cases  it  appears  to  be  a  system  under 
which  work  is  carried  on  in  the  houses  of  small 
masters  ;  and  the  conditions  of  labour  of  the 
chain -makers  and  others  in  some  parts  of 
England  are  so  far  similar  to  those  of  the 
workers  under  the  sweating  system  in  London 


DOMICIL  OR  DOMICILE 


631 


that  they  are  instances  of  a  domestic  system  of 
industry  which  has  earned  the  severe  censure 
of  popular  opinion.  The  characteristic  evil  of 
East  London  seems  to  be  the  multiplication  in 
certain  trades  of  small  masters — the  ease  with 
which  a  man  can  start  on  his  own  account,  and 
the  reckless  competition  which  of  necessity 
ensues.  It  is  the  prosecution  of  industry  iu 
domestic  establishments  outside  the  sphere  of 
the  factory  inspector  ;  for  the  domestic  system 
baffles  that  publicity,  and  tends  to  deaden  that 
sense  of  responsibility  to  popular  opinion,  to 
which  the  employer  in  a  large  factory  is  sub- 
ject. The  domestic  system,  in  short,  may  be 
said  to  be  suited  to  a  small  population,  a 
limited  market,  and  an  unbroken  routine  ;  it 
is  unsuited  to  a  large  population  where  pub- 
licity is  less  easily  attained,  and  to  a  world- 
wide market  which  is  subject  to  rapid  and 
continual  change,  and  requires  the  sustaining 
resources  of  considerable  capital  and  the  exer- 
cise of  bold  and  vigilant  enterprise. 

[For  an  account  of  the  domestic  system,  as  it 
formerly  prevailed,  the  student  should  consult 
Toynbee,  Industrial  Revolution,  ch.  iv.  and  lecture 
ii.,  and  W.  C.  Taylor,  Hist,  of  the  Factory  System  ; 
and  for  a  cousideration  of  some  of  its  modern  illus- 
trations, Booth,  Life  and  Lahour  of  the  People  in 
London,  Series  1,  vols,  ii.,  iii.,  andiv.,  and  Series  2, 
vol.  i.,  and  Reports  of  the  Committee  of  the  House 
of  Lords  on  the-  Sweating  System.']  '         L.  L.  p. 

DOMICIL  OR  DOMICILE.  The  validity 
of  a  person's  marriage,  the  legitimacy  of  his 
children,  and  the  devolution  of  his  personal 
property  after  his  death,  to  a  great  extent, 
depend  on  the  law  of  his  domicil.  A  definition 
of  this  term  is  contained  in  the  following  pass- 
age of  Justinian's  Code  (X.  40.  7):  "ubi  quis 
larem  rerumque  ac  fortunarum  suarum  summam 
constituit,  unde  rursus  non  sit  discessurus  si 
nihil  avocet,  unde  cum  profectus  est  peregrinari 
videtur,  quo  si  rediit  peregiinari  jam  destitit " 
(where  a  person  has  established  his  household 
gods,  and  the  centre  of  his  affairs  and  his  for- 
tunes ;  the  place  he  will  not  leave,  if  no  special 
cause  calls  him  forth,  away  from  which  he 
seems  a  wanderer,  returning  to  which  he  is  a 
wanderer  no  longer).  Hence  Prof.  Dicey,  Law 
of  Domicil,  defines  domicil  as  the  legal  equiva- 
lent for  "home." 

This  definition  would  leave  persons  without 
a  fixed  abode,  and  persons  who  cannot  choose  a 
home  for  themselves,  without  a  domicil ;  and 
iu  order  to  avoid  the  complications  which  would 
result  from  that  fact,  some  artificial  rules  have 
been  introduced  into  modern  law,  according  to 
which  a  domicile  is  ascribed  to  everybody  who 
has  no  "domicil  of  choice."  These  rules  are 
the  following : — 

(1)  Every  person  on  his  birth  acquires  the 
domicil  of  his  father.  This  is  called  the 
"domicil  of  origin."  A  "domicil  of  origin" 
is   retained   until  a   "domicil   of  choice"  is 


acquired;  on  the  other  hand,  a  "domicil  of 
choice  "  may  be  abandoned  without  the  acquisi- 
tion of  a  new  domicil,  and  in  such  a  case  the 
domicil  of  origin  revives  ;  e.g.  Su  person,  whose 
father  was  domiciled  in  Germany  at  the  time 
of  his  birth,  establishes  a  permanent  home  in 
England  with  the  intention  of  remaining  there 
for  the  rest  of  his  life.  He  has  then  an 
English  "domicil  of  choice."  At  some  subse- 
quent time  he  decides  to  leave  England,  but  is 
undecided  as  to  the  country  in  which  he  wishes 
to  settle  ;  from  the  moment  at  which  he  leaves 
England  his  German  domicil  of  origin  revives. 

(2)  A  wife  on  marrying  acquires  her  husband's 
domicil,  and  whenever  a  father  or  a  husband 
assumes  a  new  domicil,  his  infant  children  and 
his  wife  assume  the  same  domicil.  If  the 
father  or  husband  abandons  a  domicil  of  choice 
without  assuming  a  new  one,  the  infant 
children  and  the  wife  assume  the  father's  or 
husband's  domicil  of  origin,  in  the  same  way 
as  he  does  himself. 

The  importance  of  being  able  to  ascertain  a 
person's  domicil  at  a  given  time  may  be  illus- 
trated by  the  following  examples.  If  the 
father  of  an  illegitimate  child,  at  the  time  of 
the  child's  birth,  was  domiciled  in  England,  the 
child  can  never  become  legitimate  ;  if,  on  the 
other  hand,  the  father  at  the  time  of  the  child's 
birth  was  domiciled  in  Scotland,  he  may  legiti- 
mate the  child  by  marrying  the  mother. 

If  a  man  marries  his  deceased  wife's  sister 
both  being  at  the  time  of  the  marriage  domi- 
ciled in  a  country  where  marriage  with  a 
deceased  wife's  sister  is  permissible,  the  mamage 
is  valid.  If,  on  the  other  liand,  he  or  she  was 
at  the  time  of  the  performance  of  the  ceremony 
domiciled  in  England,  the  marriage  is  invalid  ; 
altliough  the  law  of  the  country  in  which  the 
ceremony  was  performed  allows  such  marriages. 

If  a  person  who  dies  domiciled  in  Scotland, 
and  leaving  a  wife  and  children,  has  bequeathed 
all  his  residuary  personal  estate  to  a  stranger, 
the  stranger  will  receive  one-third  only,  and 
the  other  two-thirds  will  go  to  the  wife  and  to 
the  children  ;  if,  on  the  other  hand,  the  testator 
at  the  time  of  his  death  was  domiciled  in  Eng- 
land, no  part  of  the  residuary  personalty 
will  go  to  the  wife  or  children.  If  a  person 
dying  intestate  and  unmarried,  leaving  sur- 
viving him  his  father  and  his  mother  and  a 
brother,  was  at  the  time  of  his  death  domiciled 
in  France,  the  father,  the  mother,  and  the 
brother  will  each  be  entitled  to  a  third  of  the 
intestate's  property  ;  if,  on  the  other  hand,  the 
intestate  was  at  the  time  of  his  death  domi- 
ciled in  England,  the  father  will  be  entitled  to 
the  whole. 

There  are  many  circumstances  imaginable 
under  which  it  may  be  extremely  difficult  to 
ascertain  what  a  person's  domicil  is.  Many 
persons  who  have  emigrated  to  a  foreign 
country  do  not  know  themselves  whether  they 


632 


DOMICILE,  SCOTCH— DON  GRATUIT 


look  upon  it  as  a  peiroanent  home,  or  whether 
they  will  some  day  return  to  their  native  place ; 
and  even  if  they  have  a  well-established  inten- 
tion, there  may  be  no  evidence  from  which  it 
can  be  proved.  With  the  increased  facilities 
of  international  communications  and  the  ex- 
pansion of  international  trade,  cases  in  wliich 
such  doubts  arise  will  become  more  and  more 
frequent,  and  the  question  arises  whether  it 
would  not  be  better  to  substitute  the  principle 
of  nationality  for  the  principle  of  domicil ;  in 
other  words,  whether  it  would  not  be  better  to 
establish  the  rule  that  an  individual's  personal 
rights  should  be  determined  by  the  law  of  the 
country  whose  subject  or  citizen  he  is.  There 
are,  however,  many  objections  to  this  proposal, 
and  as  no  rule  can  be  suggested  which  will 
clear  away  all  difficulties  connected  with  the  sub- 
ject, the  balance  of  convenience  is  in  favour  of 
the  rule  to  which  we  are  accustomed. 

[Dicey,  The  Law  of  Domidl.—'Westlake,  Private 
Inteniational  Law. — Foote,  Private  International 
Law. — ^Phillimore,  International  Law,  vol.  iv. — 
Nelson,  Cases,  etc.,  of  Private  International  Law.] 

£.  s. 

DOMICILE,  Scotland.  Examples:  (1) 
A  person's  father — or,  if  he  be  illegitimate,  his 
mother — ^was  a  domiciled  Scotsman  (or  Scots- 
woman) at  the  time  of  his  birth — domicile  of 
origin;  (2)  A  person,  his  own  master,  has  be- 
come a  domiciled  Scotsman  by  actual  residence 
with  the  intention  of  remaining  in  Scotland, 
and  the  result  of  quitting  his  native  country,  a 
circumstance  which  must  be  proved — domicile 
of  choice  ;  (3)  An  Englishwoman,  say,  marries 
a  domiciled  Scotsman  ;  she  becomes  a  domiciled 
Scotswoman  —  d&micile  by  operation  of  law. 
There  is  a  general  presumption  in  favour  of  the 
domicile  of  origin  as  against  the  domicile  of 
choice,  and  thus  the  domicile  of  origin  is 
readily  held  to  have  been  recovered  on  a  Scots- 
man's return  to  Scotland  from  life  abroad. 
These  are  forms  of  that  domicile  which  govern 
the  legitimation  of  children,  the  succession  to 
movable  (personal)  property,  and,  in  general, 
the  family  relations :  this  is  the  domicile  of 
succession.  There  are  still  some  delicate  ques- 
tions not  finally  decided  as  to  the  domicUe 
necessary  to  give  jurisdiction  to  the  Scotch 
courts  in  cases  of  divorce.  Domicile  of  citation 
is  by  custom  the  place  at  which  a  person  may 
lawfully  be  cited  to  appear  before  the  court, 
this  being  the  place  where  he  has  resided  for 
forty  days  until  he  has  ceased  for  forty  days  to 
reside  there  ;  but  this  is  a  domicile  for  the 
purposes  of  procedure  (see  Jukisdiotion, 
Scotland).  a.  d. 

DOMICILED  BILL.  A  bill  "drawn  pay- 
able elsewhere  than  at  the  residence  or  place 
of  business  of  the  drawee  "  is  said  to  be  ' '  domi- 
ciled. "  Such  bills  must  be  presented  for  accept- 
ance before  they  are  presented  for  payment, 
and  if  the  holder,  in  consequence  of  this  obliga- 


tion to  procure  acceptance,  cannot,  with  the 
exercise  of  reasonable  diligence,  present  a  domi- 
ciled biU  in  proper  time  for  payment,  he  will 
be  excused  and  the  drawers  and  indorsers  will 
not  be  discharged  in  consequence  of  the  delay. 
Domiciled  bills,  whether  accepted  or  not,  must 
at  maturity  be  presented  at  the  place  of  pay- 
ment, e.g.  a  bill  in  Liverpool  payable  in 
London  remains  unaccepted  ;  the  holder  must, 
at  maturity,  present  the  bill  in  London, 
although  no  special  address  for  payment  be 
given  ;  this  can  be  done  by  handing  the  bill  to 
a  notary,  who  in  his  protest  will  declare  that  no 
address  was  given.  e.  s. 

DOMINIUM.  Expression  of  Roman  law 
denoting  property  in  its  fullest  and  most 
extended  sense.  e.  s. 

DOMUS  CONVERSORUM.  See  Jews  in 
England. 

DONATIO  MORTIS  CAUSA.  A  gift  given 
by  a  person  believing  himself  or  herself  near 
death,  subject  to  the  implied  condition  that  it 
is  to  be  returned  should  the  anticipation  of 
death  by  the  existing  disorder  prove  unfounded. 
A  gift  of  this  sort  is  invalid  if  the  delivery  of 
the  object  of  the  gift  remains  incomplete,  e.g. 
an  unindorsed  bill  of  exchange  handed  over  to 
the  donee  by  way  of  donatio  mortis  causa  cannot 
be  retained  after  the  donor's  death.         E.  s. 

DONATION  (Scotland).  Gift,  free  or  for 
some  cause  not  enforceable  by  law.  Must  in 
general  be  explicit,  and  adequately  proved ; 
and  is  then  enforceable  if  the  subject  be  not 
yet  delivered  to  the  donee.  Fathers  and  grand- 
fathers may  revoke  gifts  to  children  or  grand- 
children so  far  as  to  secure  themselves  a  com- 
petence in  the  event  of  indigence.  Free  gifts 
between  husband  and  wife  are  revocable  at  any 
time  during  the  life  of  the  donor,  even  after 
the  death  of  the  donee  ;  but  not  if  there  have 
been  a  legal  or  a  natural  obligation  to  make  the 
provision  made.  In  doubtful  circumstances  it 
is  generally  presumed  there  is  no  donation  ;  a 
debtor  is  not  presumed  to  make  a  gift  to  his 
creditor  ;  but  these  are  really  jury  questions. 

A.  D. 

DONATO,  Nicolo,  a  Venetian  who  lived 
in  the  last  century,  known  by  his  book  on 
politics,  which  contains  a  treatise  on  public 
finance :  i'  uomo  di  governo,  trattati  due, 
Verona,  1753.  This  was  translated  into  French: 
L' Homme  d'etat,  par  Nicolo  Donate,  Liege,  1767. 
In  his  book  there  is  a  classification  of  public 
finance  under  seven  headings,  and  a  statement 
giving  details  of  public  expenditure  relating 
more  particularly  to  the  Venetian  state,  m.  p. 

DON  GRATUIT.  The  D^cimes  (q.v.),  the 
ordinary  contributions  of  the  clergy,  were  not 
sufficient  to  satisfy  the  French  monarchy  in  the 
17th  and  18th  centuries.  The  clerical  assem- 
blies were  frequently  called  upon  to  make 
additional  payments,  and  these  grants,  in 
theory  voluntary,  grew  under  Louis  XIV.  into 


DOEIA— DOUANE 


633 


a  practically  compulsory  payment  of  about 
15,000,000  livres  (£600,000),  renewed  every 
five  years.  This  don  gratuit,  as  it  continued 
to  be  called,  was  nearly  always  raised,  not  by 
taxation,  but  by  loan.  The  credit  of  the  clergy 
was  so  good  that  it  was  easier  for  them  to 
borrow  than  it  was  for  the  government.  Ac- 
cording to  Necker  the  clerical  debt,  raised  for 
payment  of  the  don  gratuit,  amounted  in  1784 
to  134,000,000  francs.  The  Marquis  du 
Bouille,  in  his  memoirs,  asserts  that  the  interest . 
upon  this  debt  was  paid  out  of  the  Decimes 
{q.v.),  and  thus  reduced  the  nominal  con- 
tribution to  the  state  to  such  an  extent  that 
the  chm-ch  was  a  source  of  expense  rather  than 
of  revenue. 

[Necker,  De  V Adiimiistration  des  finances  de  la 
France,  tome  ii. — Gasquet,  Memoires  du  Marquis 
du  BouilU,  p.  44. — Precis  des  Institutions  poli- 
tiqices  et  sociales  de  Vancienne  France.'\        R.  L. 

DORIA,  Paolo  Matt.,  born  in  Genoa 
1675,  died  at  Naples  1743.  He  wrote  princi- 
pally on  mathematical  and  philosophical  sub- 
jects. He  lived  nearly  all  his  life  at  Naples, 
and  is  known  to  have  been  a  friend  of  Vico. 
In  his  political  tract  La  vita  civile  con  un  trattato 
(Mia  educazione  del  Principe,  published  for 
the  first  time  in  1710  and  republished  in  1852 
(Turin),  he  seeks  to  ])rove  that  the  adminstration 
of  a  state  by  a  prince,  in  its  object  and  in  its 
means,  is  qualitatively  identical  to  that  of 
private  interests  by  private  people,  and  is  only 
more  complex.  The  one  fundamental  rule  for 
a  sound  administration  of  the  state  is  a 
financial  rule  which  consists  in  burdening  the 
tax-payer  least,  whilst  the  prince  takes  most 
from  him,  and  in  taxing  in  such  a  manner 
"  that  although  paying  much,  everybody  should 
think  he  is  paying  little."  Doria  is  a  strict 
follower  of  St.  Thomas  Aquinas  in  his  theories 
concerning  the  relative  importance  of  agri- 
culture and  manufactures,  in  the  functions 
attributed  to  money,  and  in  his  opinions  about 
commerce.  He  has  to  be  classed  amongst 
the  most  inveterate  of  the  mercantilists. 

M.  p. 

DORMANT  (or  SLEEPING)  PARTNER. 
A  partner  who  takes  no  active  part  in  the 
business  of  the  firm,  and  who  is  not  known 
to  be  a  partner.  Such  a  partner  is  liable  for 
the  acts  of  his  co-partners  in  the  transaction 
of  business  in  the  ordinary  way,  but  he  has  no 
authority  to  bind  the  firm. 

[Sir  F.  Pollock,  The  Law  of  Partnership, 
London,  1890.]  j.  e.  c.  m. 

DORMER,  Diego  Josi,  was  born  in  Saragossa 
during  the  first  half  of  the  17th  century.  He 
graduated  as  doctor  of  law  at  the  university 
of  Huesca,  and  became  later  on  general  chronicler 
of  the  kingdom  of  Aragon  and  archdeacon  in 
the  metropolitan  church  of  Saragossa.  He  was 
all  his  life  a  most  devoted  and  abundant 
historical  writer. 


In  1684  he  published  in  Saragossa  his 
Discursos  histoi-icos-politicos,  a  very  scarce  book, 
in  which,  according  to  Don  Manuel  Colmeiro 
(Biblioteca  de  los  Economistas  Esparwles)  he 
"explains  with  exquisite  clearness  the  true 
character  of  commerce,  the  nature  of  exchange, 
the  use  and  utility  of  money,  and  the  inefficiency 
of  the  prohibitive  system.  ...  It  is  one  of  the 
most  original  works  of  its  class,  bold  and 
precise  in  its  economic  doctrine.  The  author 
is  greatly  in  advance  of  his  time,  and  deliberately 
])uts  aside  the  prevailing  prejudices,  not  only  in 
Spain,  but  throughout  Europe." 

[For  a  com.plete  list  of  his  works,  see  Latasa, 
Biblioteca  Nueva  de  Aragon,  iv.  p.  197.] 

E.  ca. 

DOS.  Expression  of  Roman  law  for  the 
property  brought  by  the  wife  into  marriage. 
During  the  continuation  of  the  marriage  the 
wife  retained  the  ownership,  but  the  husband 
had  the  right  of  management  and  enjoyment. 
After  the  dissolution  of  the  marriage  the  rights 
of  the  parties  varied  according  to  the  special 
circumstances  of  the  case.  e.  s. 

DOSES  (of  Capital).  A  term  introduced  by 
James  Mill  {Elements  of  Political  Economy)  to 
denote  the  portions  of  capital  which,  according 
to  the  theory  of  Rent  (q.v.),  will  be  successively 
applied  to  land  up  to  the  point  at  which  the 
portion  last  applied  affords  only  ordinary 
profits.  As  Jevons  observes  (Theory  of  Political 
Economy,  2nd  ed.  p.  232),  "  He  evidently  means 
by  a  dose  of  capital  a  little  more  capital,  and 
though  the  name  is  peculiar,  the  meaning  is 
s\\\\\)\yi:hdXoia,\\  increment  of  capital.  .  .  .  It  is 
mere  pedantry  to  insist  upon  calling  that  a 
dose  in  economics  •  which  in  all  the  other 
sciences  is  called  by  the  perfectly  established 
and  expressive  term  increment.'"  As  the 
equivalent  of  "increment,"  dose  may  be  em- 
ployed wherever  the  reasotiing  requires  that  we 
should  consider  a  variable  quantity  as  increased 
by  degrees  up  to  the  Margin  {q.v.)  at  which 
further  increase  ceases  to  be  advantageous. 
Thus,  Prof.  Marshall  speaks  of  a  dose  of  labour 
as  well  as  of  capital  {Principles  of  Economics, 
bookiv.  ch.  iii.  §2).  Some  difficulties  attending 
the  use  of  the  term  "dose  of  capital"  are 
cleared  up  by  Prof.  Marshall  at  the  end  of  the 
cljapter  referred  to.  f.  y.  e. 

DOUANE  {Fr.  Customs).  The  earliest 
customs  duties  in  France,  as  in  Englar^d,  were 
levied  upon  exports,  and  arose  from  the  practice 
of  buying  permission  to  transport  goods  from 
the  kingdom  in  spite  of  royal  edicts  prohibiting 
exportation.  Import  duties  seem  to  have  arisen 
from  the  fact  that  foreign  merchants  had  to 
purchase  leave  to  carry  on  trade  in  France, 
and  hence  came  the  practice  of  apportioning 
-their  payments  to  the  goods  which  they 
'introduced.  These  customs  duties  were  origin- 
ally called  droits  de  haul  passage.  The  name 
douane  was  introduced  later,  and  was  borrowed 


634 


DOUBLE  ENTRY— DOUBLOON 


from  the  Venetian  term  dogana.  The  great 
diflFerence  between  France  and  England,  which 
illustrates  the  much  later  development  of 
unity  in  the  former  country,  lies  in  the  fact 
that  the  douane  is  originally  a  provincial,  not 
a  national  charge.  Every  province  had  its 
own  customs  duties,  often  of  great  intricacy 
and  variety  ;  and  these  charges,  dating  from 
the  days  of  provincial  independence,  were 
maintained  as  a  source  of  revenue,  after  the 
provinces  had  been  absorbed  by  the  central 
monarchy.  It  did  not  require  much  economic 
insight  to  understand  the  enormous  hindrance 
which  such  a  system  opposed  to  the  development 
of  internal  trade  and  production.  Colbert,  the 
most  practical  if  not  the  most  enlightened  of 
French  financiers,  made  a  vigorous  attempt  to 
abolish  the  provincial  douanes,  and  to  have  no 
custom-house,  except  on  the  frontier,  but  he 
was  successfully  resisted  by  the  "local  pro- 
tectionists." He  succeeded,  however,  in 
'establishing,  in  1664,  a  sort  of  zollverein  in 
twelve  of  the  most  important  provinces,  called 
the  cinq  grosses  fermes,  within  which  the 
circulation  of  goods  was  to  be  free.  Beyond 
these  were  the  provinces  riputdes  itranghres, 
which  refused  to  accept  Colbert's  scheme  and 
retained  their  local  customs,  and  the  provinces 
Urangbres,  those  which  were  added  to  the  crown 
after  1664,  and  received  special  privileges  at 
the  time  of  their  union.  Colbert  also  succeeded 
in  simplifying  and  making  more  uniform  the 
charges  which  he  failed  to  abolish.  The  system, 
as  he  left  it,  lasted  with  slight  modifications 
till  the  Revolution,  when  the  provinces  dis- 
appeared, and  with  them  the  last  trace  of  the 
provincial  douaiie.  •  r.  l. 

DOUBLE  ENTRY.     See  Book-keeping. 

DOUBLEDAY,  Thomas  (1790-1870),  son  of 
a  soap  manufacturer  in  Newcastle,  was  a  radical 
of  Cobbett's  stamp,  of  great  influence  during 
the  agitation  for  the  Reform  Act  of  1832.  He 
deserves  notice  here  chiefly  for  his  book  on 
The  True  Law  of  Population  shewn  to  he  connected 
with  the  food  of  the  people,  London,  1841,  2nd 
ed.  1843,  which  contained  in  an  expanded  form 
a  theory  he  had  brought  forward  in  a  letter 
to  Lord  Brougham  in  Blackwood's  Magazine, 
March  1837.  This  theory,  which  he  describes 
as  a  "great  general  law,"  is  that  "whenever  a 
species  or  genus  is  endangered,  a  corresponding 
efibrt  ^)s  invariably  made  by  nature  for  its 
preservation  and  continuance  by  an  increase  of 
fecundity  or  fertilitj'-, "  the  state  of  low  nourish- 
ment or  "depletion,"  being  thus  favourable 
while  high  feeding  or  "repletion,"  is  unfavour- 
able to  fertility,  both  in  vegetables  and  animals. 
Fertility  is  in  inverse  ratio  to  nutriment,  even 
in  the  case  of  human  beings.  In  poor  and  ill- 
fed  communities  population  increases  in  the 
ratio  of  the  poverty  and  poor  living;  in 
a  highly-fed  and  luxurious  nation  population 
decreases  and  decays.     He  shows  a  goodly  list 


of  examples,  from  the  English  peerage  to  Pit- 
cairn  Island,  to  countenance  his  conclusion. 
In  his  9th  chapter  he  uses  his  knowledge  of  the 
tallow  and  soap  trade  to  support  the  position 
that  there  had  been  a  decrease  in  the  consump- 
tion of  meat  in  England.  But  his  law  is  an 
empirical  uniformity  of  which  he  has  not  traced 
the  deeper  causes.  Physiologists  and  biologists 
have  emphatically  pronounced  against  him. 
(See  Dr.  Charles  Loudon,  Prohlhne  de  la  Popu- 
lation et  de  la  Subsistance  (quoted  by  Double- 
day  himself)  ;  and  Herbert  Spencer,  Biology, 
vol.  ii.  pt.  vi.,  Law  of  Multiplication,  ch.  xii. 
pp.  455,  480,  483  note  ;  Darwin,  Descent  of 
Man,  vol.  i.  ch.  iv.  132,  ed.  1871.) 

The  book  is  indirectly  an  attack  upon 
Malthus  ;  but  the  Essay  on  Population  is  more 
directly  criticised  in  Doubleday's  Financial, 
Monetary,  and  Statistical  History  of  England 
from  1688  to  the  present  time  in  17  letters 
addressed  to  the  Young  Men  of  Great  Britain, 
1847,  Letter  x.,  pp.  206  seq.  The  writer 
falls  into  the  vituperative  style  of  his  master 
Cobbett. 

Other  writings  of  Doubleday  are : — 

Letters  in  the  Newcastle  Chronide  on  the 
Petition  of  the  Chamber  of  Commerce,  Newcastle- 
on-Tyne,  for  the  Continued  Circulation  of  Local 
One  Pound  Notes  (which  he  opposes),  by  a 
Member  of  the  Chamber,  1828. — Two  Letters  to 
Lord  Althorp  in  Cobbett's  Register,  13th  April 
and  25th  May  1833  (on  excise  duties  on  soap), 
Political  Life  of  Sir  Robert  Peel,  2  vols.,  1856. — 
Touchstone,  a  series  of  political  letters  addressed 
to  the  newspapers,  republished,  with  a  preface  by 
John  Paul  Cobbett. — On  Mundane  Moral  Govern- 
ment and  its  Analogy  with  Material  Government, 
1852. — Matter  for  Materialists,  a  letter  in  vindi- 
cation of  Bishop  Berkeley,  1870.  He  wrote  also  a 
romance,  The  Eve  of  St.  Mark,  and  several  stage 
plays,  Diocletian,  Caius  Marius,  etc. 

[See  "Life"  by  G-.  J.  Holyoake  in  the 
Dictionary  of  National  Biography  J\  J.  B. 

DOUBLE-FLORIN,  English  token  silver 
coin  of  the  nominal  value  of  4s.,  first  struck 
in  1887,  the  year  of  Queen  Victoria's  Jubilee, 
in  pursuance  of  a  royal  proclamation.  It  was 
of  precisely  the  same  design  as  the  florin. 
"Weight  349*09  grains,  fineness  925.  Value  in 
silver  francs  (900  fine),  4*64  francs.  This  coin 
has  ceased  to  be  issued.  f.  e.  a. 

DOUBLE  STANDARD.  See  Bimetal- 
lism ;  Standard  of  Value. 

DOUBLOON,  History  of.  A  gold  coin  of 
Spain,  prior  to  the  adoption  of  the  monetary 
system  of  the  Latin  Union.  The  name  "  doub- 
loon "  has  been  diverted  by  general  consent  from 
the  Spanish  pistole  or  double  escudo  (whence 
"doblon"  in  Spanish)  to  the  quadruple  pistole, 
or  *  *  doblon  de  a  ocho. "  Like  the  Dollar  {q.  v. ), 
the  doubloon  was  a  multiple,  and  not  a  unit. 
Corresponding  to  the  silver  unit,  or  real,  was 
the  gold  unit,  or  escudo  ( =  $2),  concerning  the 
standard  of  which  the  emperor  Charles  V.  and 


DOUBLOON— DOVE 


635 


his  mother  Donna  Juana  enacted,  in  1537,  that 
"the  escudos  which  we  have  commanded  to  be 
struck  shall  be  22  carats  fine,  and  shall  weigh 
68  to  the  mark  of  gold  of  om-  kingdoms  of 
Castile,  which  is  the  fineness  and  weight  of 
the  larger  escudos  of  Italy."  As  this  makes 
the  gross  weight  of  the  escudo  52*2  grains 
troy,  the  escudo  was  thus  practically  a  ducat 
(see  Ducat).  From  1537  to  1772  the  8-escudo 
piece  or  "doubloon,"  was  916*6  fine  per  mille, 
reduced  in  1772  to  901,  and  in  1786  to  875, 
the  legal  weight  remaining  417*6  grains  troy 
from  1537  up  to  1848.  Both  in  1772  and  in 
1786  the  reduction  in  fineness  was  effected  not 
by  a  public  law,  but  by  a  Real  drden  reservada 
addressed  to  the  mints.  The  doubloon  (Peso 
Duro  de  Oro)  never  had  the  universal  currency 
of  its  silver  analogue  the  dollar  :  and  even 
in  the  New  World  it  was  hard  pressed  by  its 
Portuguese  competitors,  the  **  moidore  "  and  the 
"Johannes."  The  reason,  in  the  words  of  Newton, 
was  that  "gold  in  Spain  is  of  16  times  more 
value  than  silver  of  equal  weight  and  allay. 
But  this  high  price  keeps  their  gold  at  home  in 
good  plenty,  and  carries  away  the  Spanish  silver 
into  all  Europe."  The  Spanish  doubloon  was 
succeeded  after  1821  by  various  South  American 
doubloons,  which  enjoy  a  limited  currency  in 
the  New  World,  and  are  specially  quoted  in  the 
London  bullion -market.  In  1848  the  "doblon 
d'Isabel"  was  introduced  in  Spain,  to  be 
supplanted  by  the  20 -peseta  piece  on  the  entry 
of  Spain  into  the  Latin  Union. 

As  the  fine  content  by  law  was  (1)  382*8 
grains  from  1537  to  1772,  (2)  376*2  grains  from 
1772  to  1786,  and  (3)  365*4  grains  from  1786 
to  1848,  in  theory  the  sterling  value  of  the 
doubloon  (at  £3:17:10^  per  oz.  of  standard 
gold)  was  (1)  £3  :  7  :  9,  (2)  £3  :  6  :  8,  and  (3) 
£3  :  4  :  8  for  the  same  three  periods  respectively; 
but  the  results  of  assays  reduce  these  values 
roughly  by  the  odd  pence.  Thus,  after  1786, 
the  sterling  value  of  a  doubloon  as  issued  was 
£3  :  4s.  (see  Dollar).  r.  c. 

DOUBLOON.  Spanish  gold  coin,  not  struck 
since  1868,  when  the  peseta  (franc)  system  of 
currency  was  adopted.  Weight  129*43  gi-ains, 
fineness  900.  Value  :  English  standard  (916*6 
fine,  at  £3  :  17  :  10^  an  oz.)  £1  :  0  :  7^- ;  French 
standard  (900  fine)  26  francs.  Similar  coins 
of  slightly  varying  values  circulate  in  the  South 
American  republics  and  in  Mexico. 

The  old  doubloon  or  onza  weighed  418  grains, 
fineness  8  7  5, — value,  English  standard  £3  :  4  :  9, 
French  standard  81  *6  francs.  This  coin  is  still 
current  in  Spain,  Mexico,  and  the  South  and 
Central  American  republics. 

A  doubloon  (or  4-dollar  piece)  is  current  in 
the  Philippine  Islands.  Weight  104*4  grains, 
fineness  875.  Value :  English  standard  16s.  2d. ; 
French  standard  20*4  francs.  r.  E.  A. 

DOUGLASS,  William  (about  1691-1752) 
was  born  in  Giflford,  Scotland  ;  he  settled  as  a 


physician  in  Boston  in  1718  ;  and  wrote  much 
on  medical  subjects.  He  wrote  a  valuable 
Summary,  historical  and  political,  of  the  first 
plaiiiing,  progressive  improvement,  and  present 
state  of  the  British  Settlements  in  North  America, 
Boston  and  London,  1755,  in  which  frequent 
reference  is  made  to  the  paper  currencies  of  the 
several  colonies.  He  was  especially  interested 
in  the  monetary  policy  of  Massachusetts,  and 
contributed  to  discussions  on  the  subject  of  a 
land  bank  and  paper  bills :  An  Essay  concerning 
Silver  and  Paper  Currencies  more  especially  with 
regard  to  the  British  Colonies  in  New  England, 
Boston,  1738,  pp.  23  (a  direct  reply  to  a  con- 
temporary pamphlet.  Some  ohscrvatiovs  on  the 
scheme  projected  for  emitting  60,000  I.  Bills  of  a 
new  tenour,  to  be  redemed  with  Silver  a.nd  Gold, 
showing  the  various  operations  of  these  Bills  and 
their  tendency  to  hurt  the  Publiclc  Interest,  Boston, 
1738,  pp.  25,  which  has  itself  been  erroneously 
attributed  to  Douglass)  ;  A  discourse  concerning 
the  currencies  of  the  British  plantations  in 
America,  etc.,  Boston,  1740,  pp.  47  (also  with 
Postscript,  pp.  47-62).  This  was  reprinted  in 
London  in  1751,  and  is  included  in  a  collection 
of  tracts  on  Paper  Currency,  edited  by  Mr.  J.  R. 
M'Cullocli,  printed  by  Lord  Overstone  in  1857. 
It  is  referred  to  in  Smith's  Wealth  of  Nations, 
bk.  ii.  ch.  ii.  Douglass  clearly  sums  up  and 
accounts  for  the  infatuation  for  issues  of  paper 
money  which  prevailed  at  that  time.  The  fol- 
lowing reasons  are  assigned  :  that  usurers  might 
be  prevented  from  imposing  high  interest  upon 
borrowers  ;  the  scarcity  of  silver  money,  which 
was  shipped  away  to  settle  foreign  balances  ; 
that  it  might  be  available  to  meet  the  demands 
of  a  growing  trade  ;  and  to  relieve  debtors, 
"since  by  large  emissions  lands  rise  in  denomina- 
tion value,  and  debts  become  really  less." 

[^  Brief  memoir  of  William  Douglass,  M.D.  By 
Timothy  L.  Jenni.son,  M.D.,  hiMed.  Com.  of  Mass. 
Med.  Soc,  Boston,  1836,  vol.  v.  pp.  195-240.] 

D.  R.  D. 

DOVE,  Patrick  Edward  (1815-1873). 
Dove  is  one  of  the  first  notable  writers  of 
this  century  who  advocated  the  complete 
nationalising  of  the  land.  In  his  Theory  of 
Human,  Progression  and  Natural  Probability  oj 
a  Beign  of  Justice  (dedicated  to  Victor  Cousin) 
(Edinburgh)  1850,  Dove  lays  down  the  philo- 
sophical foundation  of  his  theories  of  reform. 
Three  things  are,  in  his  view,  indispensable  to 
the  well-being  of  the  human  race — (1)  the 
Bible,  (2)  ' '  a  right  view  of  material  phenomena, " 
(3)  "  a  right  view  of  mental  phenomena."  The 
science  of  politics  gives  us  a  right  view  of  equity 
or  justice,  and  leads  us  to  the  conclusion  that 
humanity  progresses  from  diversity  of  privileges 
to  ail  absolute  equality  of  rights  ;  it  points  the 
way  to  a  reconslruction  of  the  natural  and  God- 
given  order  of  society,  from  which  the  political 
institutions  of  actual  history  have  so  widely 
departed.     We  shall  reach  the  millennium, — 


636 


DOVE— DOWER 


first  in  mathematics,  when  all  mathematical 
truth  is  discovered  and  applied,  then  in  the 
physical  and  mechanical  sciences  and  arts,  and 
then  in  political  science.  The  perfection  of 
the  last  would  bring  the  political  millennium, 
and  one  of  its  conditions  would  be  the -aboli- 
tion of  the  private  ownership  of  land.  This  is 
Dove's  central  proposition.  Though^  he  is  not 
otherwise  communist  or  even  socialist,  he 
demands  that  the  land  should  be  held  in 
common.  His  arguments  are  given  at  length  in 
his  later  book  Elements  of  Political  Science 
(Edinburgh),  1854  ;  but  they  are  sketched  in 
the  earlier  with  substantial  completeness. 
Legislation  is  needed  not  to  grant  rights  but 
to  secure  rights  already  granted  by  nature,  the 
chief  being  liberty  and  property.  There  is  a 
progress  towards  absolute  equality  in  regard  to 
"natural  property";  "the  earth  and  all  it 
contains  belongs  'for  the  time  being'  to  the 
existing  generation,"  and  its  distribution  must 
not  be  determined  by  the  dispositions  of  past 
generations,  when  these  have  been  contrary  to 
equity.  The  assignment  to  private  owners, 
for  example,  of  the  abbey  lands,  under  Henry 
VIII.,  is  "now  exactly  equivalent  to  the  im- 
position of  a  taxation  on  articles  of  consumption, 
equal  to  the  present  rental  of  those  lands,  so 
that  those  who  are  labourers  have  actually  the 
rental  of  the  land  taken  away  from  them  in  the 
shape  of  taxes  ;  were  there  no  taxes  the  aliena- 
tion of  the  lands  would  be  of  comparatively 
minor  importance."  Taxation  must  fall  either 
on  land  or  on  industry  ;  and  it  is  no  burden  to 
the  community  unless,  as  now,  it  is  taken  from 
land  and  left  to  lie  upon  labour.  Political 
economy  is  a  non-moral  science,  and  unlike 
political  science  it  is  inductive  and  statistical ; 
it  simply  traces  the  effects  of  certain  human 
actions  on  social  welfare.  But  the  two  studies 
mutually  depend  on  one  another.  "  In  the 
arts  man  creates  form  ;  in  political  economy  he 
creates  value  ;  in  politics  he  creates  property." 
Evolution  must  proceed  from  the  arts  to  political 
economy  before  finally  attaining,  in  politics  to 
the  "rational  system  of  property,"  an  open 
career  for  all  human  talents  and  all  burden  of 
taxation  borne  by  the  rent  of  land. '  Dove 
thinks  this  system  wiU  be  only  introduced  by 
a  very  gradual  change  of  public  opinion.  He 
is  no  revolutionist,  but  he  does  not  discuss  the 
practical  steps  by  which  the  change  would  be 
introduced  with  least  friction.  He  is  content 
for  the  most  part  to  enlarge  on  the  defects  of 
the  present  system.  That  a  shilling  a  day 
should  be  given  to  one  who  labours,  and  £1000 
a  day  to  one  who  does  not  labour,  seems  to  him 
to  set  Solomon  at  defiance.  His  discussion  of 
rent  is  suggestive  ;  but  his  strength  lies  else- 
where than  in  purely  economical  argument,  and 
his  criticisms  of  older  economists  are  often 
founded  on  misunderstanding.  He  was  from 
the  first  a  free  trader.     His  sketch  of  Andrew 


Yarranton,  "the  genuine  founder  of  political 
economy  in  England,"  is  a  useful  contribution 
to  economic  history  (see  appendix  to  Elennents 
of  Political  Science).  A  certain  dilfuseness  of 
style  may  perhaps  in  some  degree  explain  his 
failure  to  obtain  the  popular  favour  accorded 
to  more  recent  writers  of  the  same  way  of 
thinking,  who  have  added  nothing  to  his 
doctrines  and  have  lacked  his  philosophical 
breadth. 

[For  a  full  list  of  the  writings  of  P.  E.  Dove, 
and  an  account  of  his  life,  see  Dictionary  oj 
National  Biography.}  J.  b. 

DOWER.  The  term  dower  is  used  in  two 
totally  different  senses.  In  the  first  or  popular 
sense  it  corresponds  to  the  French  dot  and  the 
Roman  dos,  a  portion  which  the  bride  brings 
to  assist  in  defraying  the  expenses  of  married 
life,  whether  originally  her  own  or  given  by 
her  father  or  other  near  relative.  Over  this 
portion  the  husband  acquires  certain  restricted 
rights  during  the  continuance  of  the  marriage. 
In  some  countries,  notably  in  France,  it  is  a 
matter  of  course  that  every  bride  should  have  a 
dower,  and  one  of  the  main  objects  of  French 
thrift  is  to  provide  every  daughter  with  a  suit- 
able dower.  In  England  there  is  no  general 
custom  of  this  kind,  although  it  is  common  for 
fathers  in  the  middle  and  upper  classes  to  settle 
some  property  on  a  daughter  when  about  to  be 
married. 

In  the  second,  or  legal  sense,  dower  signifies 
the  provision  to  which  a  widow  is  entitled  out 
of  the  land  of  her  deceased  husband.  At 
common  law  a  widow  was  entitled  for  her  life 
to  one-third  of  the  freehold  lands  of  which  her 
husband  died  possessed.  When  the  title  to 
dower  had  once  attached,  it  could  not  be 
defeated  by  any  act  of  the  husband,  and  thus 
the  right  of  dower  became  a  serious  obstacle  to 
the  alienation  of  land.  Accordingly  the  statute 
of  uses  (27  Henry  VIIL,  c.  10)  enacted  that 
when  provision  for  the  wife  had  been  made  by 
way  of  jointure,  she  should  lose  her  right  to 
dower.  Subsequently  the  right  of  dower  was 
often  defeated  by  means  of  a  technical  contriv- 
ance known  as  a  conveyance  to  uses  to  bar 
dower.  But  by  the  Act  3  &  4  Will.  IV.  c  105, 
known  as  the  Dower  Act,  the  wife's  right  of 
dower  in  her  husband's  land  was  rendered 
liable  to  be  defeated  by  any  act  of  alienation 
performed  by  him,  or  by  a  declaration  executed 
by  him  under  seal  or  inserted  in  his  will.  In 
short  the  right  of  dower  is  subjected  entirely 
to  the  husband's  discretion.  Under  these 
circumstances  the  right  of  dower  has  ceased  to 
have  any  importance.  The  making  of  a  suit- 
able provision  for  a  widow  is  one  of  the 
principal  objects  of  marriage  settlements,  and 
such  a  settlement  is  almost  always  made  on  the 
marriage  of  persons  in  the  landowning  class. 
The  origin  of  the  common  law  right  of  dower 
is    found   by   Maine   in  the   influence  of  the 


DRACHMA— DRAIN  OF  BULLION 


637 


medieval  church  which  was  exercised  in  favour 
of  the  wife. 

[Williams  and  Goodeve  on  Real  Property  — 
Keuelm  Digby,  History  of  the  Law  of  Real 
Property. — Maine,  Ancient  Law,  ch.  vii.] 

F.  c.  M. 

DRACHMA.  Greek  modern  unit  of  value 
equal  to  1  franc,  and  divided  into  100  lepta 
(centimes).  Weight,  4  "98  grains  gold  900 
fine,  or  77*16  grains  silver  900  fine.  English 
standard  value  :  gold  (9 16 -6  fine  at  £3  :  17  :  10^ 
per  oz.)  9-52d.,  silver  (925  fine  at  5s.  6d.  per 
oz.)  10"32d.  The  silver  drachma  piece  is  a 
token  coin,  835  fine,  weight  77*16  grains,  value 
•93  drachma.  The  smallest  staiidard  coin, 
both  in  gold  and  silver,  is  the  five-drachma 
piece.  Greece  is  a  member  of  the  Latin 
Union  {q.v.). 

Drachma  was  the  name  of  the  ancient  Greek 
unit  of  value.  The  Attic  drachma  was  a  silver 
coin  weighing  about  66  grains.  F.  E.  a. 

DRAFTS  ON  DEMAND.  See  Cheques, 
Law  of. 

DRAGONETTI,  Giacinto  (end  of  18th 
century),  a  Neapolitan,  wrote  in  1767  a  treatise 
on  virtues  and  remuneration  of  virtue,  Trattuto 
delle  virtu  e  deipremi;  a  spese  di  Giov.  Gravier, 
1767,  in  which  he  also  discusses  economic  topics, 
and  shows  considerable  knowledge  of  the  most 
recent  economic  literature  of  his  time.  Agri- 
culture especially  is  discussed  by  him  and 
regarded  as  the  pivot  of  the  economic  welfare 
of  the  state.  He  compares  navigation  to  "a 
bridge  crossing  the  seas  which  unites  the  whole 
inhabited  globe  "  ;  he  considers  it  so  import- 
ant that  the  state  is  boimd  to  protect  it.  But 
social  progress,  though  it  takes  its  origin  in 
agriculture  and  maritime  commerce,  must  be 
maintained  by  a  system  which  rewards  virtue 
and  punishes  crime.  Such  a  system  would 
harmonise  private  with  public  interest,  and — 
through  private  interest — encourage  the  pro- 
motion of  public  interests.  m.  p. 

DRAGONETTI,  Ltjigi  (early  part  of  19th 
century),  wrote  Proposta  di  un  novella  piano 
di  Jinanze  per  il  Regno  di  Napoli,  1820,  Napoli, 
a  book  suggesting  reform  in  the  management 
of  the  finances  of  the  kingdom  of  Naples,  inter- 
esting as  showing  the  defects  existing  at  that 
date.  Amongst  other  matters  we  find  him 
urging  on  the  government  punctuality  in  pay- 
ment of  the  interest  on  the  public  debt,  in 
order  to  maintain  the  standing  of  the  national 
credit,  and  to  induce  foreigners  to  invest  capital. 
He  recommends  that  the  tax  on  land  should  be 
based  on  a  cadastral  survey  (doomsday-book) 
and  that  personal  property  and  capital  employed 
in  business  should  bear  its  fair  share  of  the 
burden.  Dragonetti  advises  that  the  tariff  for 
the  taxation  of  imports  and  exports  should  not 
be  unduly  high,  and  that  it  should  frequently 
be  revised,  so  as  to  bear  a  uniform  proportion  to 
the  changes  of  values  in  commodities,     m.  p. 


DRAIN  OF  BULLION.  The  stock  of 
bullion  held  by  the  Bank  of  England  is  subject 
both  to  all  the  influences  which  produce  move- 
ments of  bullion  between  different  countries, 
and  to  all  those  which  arise  out  of  the  condition 
of  internal  trade.  Some  of  these  latter  are 
periodical  in  occurrence  and  almost  regular  in 
extent  (see  Autumnal  Drain),  whilst  others 
are  occasional  and  uncertain  in  both  respects, 
but  all,  whether  internal  or  foreign,  if  occurring 
alone,  carry  with  them  the  elements  of  reaction, 
and  thus  the  average  level  is  fairly  maintained. 
When,  however,  two  or  more  of  these  influences, 
acting  in  the  same  direction,  have  come  into 
play  at  the  same  time,  a  drain  of  bullion  from 
the  Bank  has  resulted,  producing  danger  and 
alarm,  and  requiring  special  efforts  on  the  part 
of  the  directors  to  counteract  it.  Continued 
drains  of  bullion,  of  more  or  less  importance, 
have  been  recorded  as  occurring  in  the  years 
1780-83,  1791-93,  1795-97,  1817-19,  1824-25, 
1830-82,  1834-35,  1836,  1839,  1846-47,  1857, 
and  1866.  The  points  most  worthy  of  notice 
in  these  movements  are  :  (a)  their  cause  ;  (h) 
their  duration  and  extent  ;  and  (c)  the  measures 
by  which  they  have  been  relieved. 

The  causes  have  been  both  general  and  special. 
So  far  as  the  general  causes  can  be  classified, 
they  may  be  grouped  as  below,  the  occasions 
upon  which  each  one  was  most  strongly  in  force 
being  annexed. 

Group  I.  Domestic. 


1824-25,  1834-36,  1847, 

1866. 
1793,  1824-25,  1836, 
1847,  1857,  1866. 

824-25, 
1834-36, 


Joint-stock  speculation 
Banking  panic  .  .    \ 

Commercial  distress  . 


Deficient  harvests 


ri783,    1793,    i; 
\      1830-32,     1£ 
{     1857. 
/1783,  1795-96,  1830-32, 
1      1839,  1847. 


Group  IL  Foreign. 

,    .,.  ri793,  1795-96,  1824-25, 

Loans  or  subsidies      .    i       1834-36 

Joint -stock  speculation     1825. 

.  ,  ^.  ,  ri832,    1830-37,    1839, 

Commercial  distress 


/1832,    II 
t      1857. 


It  will  be  seen  that  no  distinct  line  can  be 
drawn  between  the  groups,  or  the  causes  com- 
posing them.  Commercial  distress  may  give 
rise  to  banking  panic,  or  vice  versa ;  or  either 
of  these  may  be  largely  due  to  joint-stock  specu- 
lation. So,  also,  a  domestic  cause  may  give 
rise  to  a  foreign  drain,  as  when  a  bad  harvest 
leads  to  large  importations  of  corn  ;  or,  a  drain 
for  foreign  purposes  may  have  a  domestic  origin, 
^s  in  the  granting  of  loans  or  subsidies,  or  float- 
ing foreign  speculations  on  the  home  market. 
Or,  a  drain  commencing  in  one  cause  m^.y  be 


638 


DRAIN  OF  BULLION 


continued  thi-ough  other  influences.  There  are 
also  special  causes  to  be  found  in  almost  every 
crisis. 

In  duration  they  have  varied  greatly.  The 
earliest  appear  to  have  lasted  during  two  or 
three  years  ;  thus,  from  August  1780  to  October 
1783  ;  from  August  1791  to  February  1793  ; 
from  February  1795  to  February  1797;  from 
August  1817  to  August  1819.  In  these  cases 
the  records  show  continuous  decline  throughout 
each  period,  but  as  the  figures  are  given  only 
for  February  and  August  in  each  year,  there 
may  have  been  intermediate  increases.  In 
1824-25,  1830-32,  1834-35  the  decline  lasted 
from  one  to  two  years,  and  in  later  times  the 
movement  extended  over  but  a  few  months. 


These  figures  should  be  studied  in  connection 
with  some  others  that  cannot  be  shown  here,  as 
the  proportion  held  by  the  outflow  to  the  initial 
stock  :  or  with  the  average  of  the  preceding  year 
or  period,  and  the  rate  of  the  decrease.  For 
the  years  since  1844  a  most  important  considera- 
tion is  the  state  of  the  banking  reserve.  This 
it  was  that  gave  to  the  drain  of  1866  an  im- 
portance beyond  that  which  would  appear  to 
attach  to  the  figures  as  given  above. 

Since  1866  the  outflow  has  rarely  taken  the 
form  of  a  persistent  drain,  whilst  the  average 
stock  having  been  much  higher,  decreases  of 
considerable  amount  have  not  caused  so  much 
alarm.  Movements  of  this  character  took  place 
in  1876  when  the  bullion  decreased  from 
£29,394,000  on  18th  August  to  £21,704,000 
on  29th  December ;  and  in  1879  when  from 
£35,694,000on  30th  July,  it  fell to£27,602,000 
on  31st  December.  In  each  case  the  initial 
stock  was  very  much  beyond  the  average  of 
preceding  years,  and  the  reserve  was  also  ab- 
normally large. 

The  manner  in  which  a  drain  of  bullion 
should  be  encountered  has  been  the  subject  of 
much  controversy,  and  very  different  methods 
have  been  followed  at  different  times.  In  1783 
the  directors  laid  down  the  maxim  that  a  drain 
snould  be  met  by  contracting  their  issues  until 
the  exchanges  became  favourable,  and  they 
were  successful  in  acting  upon  these  lines.  In 
1798  relief  was  obtained  by  extended  powers 
being  granted  for  the  issue  of  exchequer  bills. 


In  1797  the  drain  was  only  arrested  by  the 
passing  of  the  Restriction  Act,  and  the  subse- 
quent suspension  of  cash  payments.  In  1819 
the  directors  communicated  to  the  House  of 
Commons  a  resolution  denying  that  the  ex- 
changes were  to  be  regarded  in  regulating  their 
issues.  In  1825  the  Bank  endeavoured,  in  May, 
greatly  to  contract  their  issues,  but  finding 
that  the  outflow  continued  at  an  accelerated 
pace,  they  adopted  in  December  exactly  the 
opposite  policy,  and  lent  money  freely.  In 
1830-32,  and  1834-35,  the  outward  movement 
appears  to  have  been  suffered  to  run  its  course 
without  any  special  measures  being  taken.  In 
1836  the  pressure  was  met  by  a  generous  policy, 
and  large  advances  were  made  by  the  bank. 

Up  to  this  date  the  policy  of  the  Bank  fluctu- 
ated between  leaving  matters  to  right  them- 
selves, or  taking  action  by  contracting  their 
issues,  or  by  freely  extending  them.  The  plan 
of  raising  the  rate  of  discount  was  not  in  any 
case  adopted.  It  was  indeed  not  so  fuUy 
available  as  now,  nor  was  it  equally  likely  to 
be  effective.  The  transit  of  bullion  was  more 
expensive  and  less  expeditious,  and  a  larger  rise 
was  necessary  to  produce  an  influx.  There  was 
also  less  floating  capital  ready  for  employment 
in  any  market  off'ering,  and  therefore  less 
probability  of  attraction  by  increased  rates. 
Upon  at  least  one  occasion  in  earlier  years  a 
serious  drain  of  bullion  had  occurred  in  the  face 
of  favourable  exchanges.  During  all  these 
years  the  Usury  Law^s  {q.v.)  were  at  least 
nominally  in  force.  No  doubt  in  practice  they 
were  largely  evaded,  but  they  could  not  be 
publicly  disregarded  by  the  Bank  of  England. 
It  was  not  till  1833  that  these  laws  were  relaxed 
at  all,  and  they  continued  partly  in  force  for 
twenty  years  longer.  But  in  fact  the  directors 
did  not  make  fuU  use  of  such  powers  as  they 
even  then  possessed.  From  June  1822  tiU  July 
1836  the  bank  rate  remained  at  4  per  cent, 
with  the  exception  of  the  period  from  December 
1825  to  July  1827,  during  which  it  was  main- 
tained at  5  per  cent. 

During  the  drain  of  1839,  which  was  more 
serious  than  any  then  on  record,  the  rate  was 
raised,  on  20th  June,  to  5|  per  cent,  and  on  1st 
August  to  6  per  cent,  these  being  the  first  occa- 
sions since  1695  on  which  the  oflScialrate  had 
been  placed  above  5  per  cent.  Since  then,  in 
seasons  of  pressure,  recourse  has  always  been  had 
to  increased  rates  of  discount.  In  1847  it  was 
raised  to  8  per  cent ;  and  in  1857  and  1866  to 
10  per  cent.  This  last  occasion  is  noteworthy 
as  one  where  a  high  rate  failed  to  attract  gold, 
as  the  bullion  decreased  by  2|  millions  from 
21st  March  to  30th  May,  notwithstanding  that 
the  rate  was  raised  by  successive  stages  from  6 
per  cent  to  10  per  cent.  Yet  during  the  same 
period  the  Bank  of  France,  with  a  rate  not  ex- 
ceeding 4  per  cent,  was  constantly  gaining  gold. 
This  was  due  to  the  great  doubts  felt  on  the 


DRAKE— DRAPIER'S  LETTERS 


639 


Continent  as  to  the  state  of  commercial  credit 
in  England.  In  later  years,  when  an  efflux  of 
gold  has  been  anticipated,  it  has  been  prevented 
by  a  timely  rise  in  the  bank  rate. 

One  other  point  in  connection  with  drains  of 
bullion  requires  notice.  It  is  an  almost  invari- 
able experience  that  such  movements  have  an 
immediate  effect  upon  the  notes  in  reserve, 
instead  of  acting  upon  the  circulation,  as  was 
expected  by  the  framers  of  the  Act  of  1844, 
The  following  instances  illustrate  this  clearly  : 


Bank  of 

England. 

1846-7. 

Bullion. 

Note  Reserve. 

Circulation. 

29th  Aug. 

1847. 
SOth  Jan. 
17th  Apr. 
SOth  Oct. 

£16,366,000 

12,902,000 
9,330,000 
8,439,000 

£9,450,000 

5,704,000 
2,558,000 
1,177,000 

£20,/^6,000 

20,1^69,000 
20,2h3,000 
20,833,000 

1857. 

18th  July 
12th  Oct. 
11th  Nov. 

Bullion. 

Note  Reserve. 

Circulation. 

£11,841,000 
10,110,000 
7,171,000 

£5,687,000 

4,024,000 

958,000 

£19,978,000 
19,990,000 
20,183,000 

In  both  these  instances  the  bullion  was  de- 
creased by  50  per  cent,  whilst  the  circulation 
remained  almost  unaltered.  Upon  the  next 
occasion  the  decrease  of  bullion  was  attended 
by  a  much  greater  decrease  in  the  reserve  of 
notes,  whilst  the  circulation  increased  by  more 
than  25  per  cent. 


1866. 

Bullion. 

Note  Reserve. 

Circulation. 

21st  Mar. 
9th  May 
SOth  May 

£14,456,000 
13,156,000 
11,878,000 

£7,918,000 

4,951,000 

415,000 

£20,636,000 
22,ShU,000 
26,019,000 

An  important  movement  in  the  opposite 
direction,  of  more  recent  occurrence,  illustrates 
the  direct  action  upon  the  reserve,  instead  of 
upon  the  circulation,  of  an  influx  of  bullion. 


1907. 

Bullion. 

Note  Reserve. 

Circulation. 

2nd  Oct. 

6th  Nov. 

18th  Dec. 

£37,106,838 
28,725,225 
33,076,729 

£25,636,348 
17,694,795 
22,399,234 

£29,920,m 
29,l480,U30 
29,127,1^95 

[For  history:  H.  D.  M'Leod,  Theory  and  Practice 
of  Banking,  also  Reports  of  Parliamentary  Com- 
mittees on  the  Bank  of  England,  Banks  of  Issue,  etc. 
For  fluctuations  in  circulation  and  effect  on  Bank 
of  England  Rate,  see  Sir  R.  H.  Inglis  Palgrave,  J5ariZ:; 
Rate  and  the  Money  Market,  1903;  also  Documents 
492  and  578,  U.  S.  A.  National  Monetary  Commis- 
sion, 1910,  by  the  same  author.]  R.  w.  b. 

DRAKE,  James  (1667-1706-7),  bom  at  Cam- 
bridge, became  M.D.  in  London  in  1694,  and 
Fellow  of  the  CoUege  of  Physicians  in  1706. 
His  high  Tory  pamphlets,  among  which  two 
especially  deserve  attention,  were  the  cause  of 
much  persecution  to  him.  Besides  being  the 
author  of  medical  treatises  he  wrote  anony- 
mously A  Short  History  of  the  Last  Parliament, 
1699,  in  which  he  refutes  the  opinion  that 
exchequer  bills   had  the  nature  of  **  money" 


created  by  government,  and  shows  them  to  be 
mere  money-saving  instruments  of  credit.  In 
his  pamphlet  An  Essay  concerning  the  Necessity 
of  Equal  Taxes  and  the  Dangerous  Consequences 
of  the  Encouragement  given  to  Usury  among  us 
of  late  years.  With  some  Proposals  to  promote 
the  Former  and  give  a  check  to  the  Latter.  By 
the  author  of  the  History  of  the  Last  Parlia- 
ment, London,  1702,  Drake  argues  that  money 
should  be  taxed  by  reducing  interest,  and  that 
public  credit  "  be  rais'd  to  a  Par  with  the  best 
private  security,  and  that  no  higher  Interest  or 
Praemium  be  allow'd  upon  it."  This  end  will 
be  answered  "by  a  just  and  equal  Tax  obliging 
all  Ranks  and  Degrees  of  men  to  pay  to  the 
support  of  the  Government  in  proportion  to 
their  share  in  the  Publick  and  the  benefits  they 
reap  from  it"  (p.  5).  He  contends  that  "for 
the  eleven  first  years  of  the  late  war,  10s.  in 
the  £  per  annum,  principal  and  interest,  was 
paid  by  land,  under  which  latter  name  husbandry, 
manufacture,  and  trade  are  comprehended  as 
having  their  existence  from  and  being  no  more 
than  the  product  and  improvement  of  land, 
which  is  the  principal  stock,  and  gives  birth 
and  maintenance  to  them  all"  (p.  2).  This 
passage,  as  well  as  his  struggle  against  stock- 
jobbing and  trading  companies,  counects  Drake 
with  authors  like  Asgill,  Barbon,  Briscoe,  and 
other  Tory  writers  on  finance. 

{Dictionary  of  National  Biog.raphy,  vol.  xv. 
pp.  446-447,  where  the  last-named  tract  is 
omitted  ;  for  the  first  tract  see  Philippovich,  Die 
Bank  von  England,  1885,  p.  68.]  s.b, 

DRAPIER'S  LETTERS.  In  1722  Ireland 
complained  of  the  want  of  copper  coin.  Copper 
had  apparently  been  undervalued  as  compared 
with  silver,  and  in  consequence  had  been 
driven  from  the  country.  In  its  place  a 
number  of  tokens  and  worthless  coins  had  been 
used  as  small  change.  The  English  government 
decided  to  remedy  what  was  an  undoubted 
grievance.  Unfortunately  Ireland,  unlike 
England  and  Scotland,  had  no  public  mint,  so 
that  coinage  was  a  subject  of  private  contract, 
and  such  contracts,  in  the  eighteenth  century, 
were  invariably  occasions  for  jobbery  and 
corruption.  On  21st  Sept.  1723  a  patent 
was  issued  to  "William  Wood  to  coin  copper  to 
the  value  of  £108,000.  The  economic  and 
other  objections  to  the  patent  were  unanswer- 
able. Wood  himself  had  purchased  it  for 
£10,000  from  the  Duchess  of  Kendal,  George 
I.  's  mistress.  That  his  own  profits  would  have 
been  excessive  is  proved  by  the  fact  that  he 
was  compensated  for  the  withdrawal  of  the 
patent  by  a  pension  of  £3000  a  year  for  eight 
years.  The  total  issue  was  ridiculously  out  of 
proportion  to  the  needs  of  the  country,  as  it 
was  estimated  at  more  than  a  fourth  of  the 
whole  currency.  Finally  the  issue  was  debased. 
A  pound  of  copper  was  worth  at  the  outside 
13d.  ;    in  England   it  was  coined  into  23d.  ; 


640 


DRAWBACKS— DRAWING 


but  by  "Wood's  patent  it  might  be  coined  into 
30d.  To  these  objections  it  must  be  added 
that  no  Irish  official,  not  even  the  lord- 
lieutenant,  or  the  council,  had  been  consulted 
about  the  terms  of  the  patent. 

The  patent  was  itself  a  scandalous  j»b,  and 
it  was  also  a  needlessly  irritating  assertion  of 
English  sovereignty.  Irish  opinion  was  roused, 
and  both  houses  of  parliament,  usually  sub- 
missive, petitioned  against  the  scheme.  A 
haughty  and  threatening  answer  on  the  part 
of  Wood  only  added  fuel  to  the  flame.  In 
1724  Swift  came  forward  as  the  mouthpiece  of 
the  prevalent  discontent  in  a  series  of  letters 
which  were  signed  M.  B.  Drapier,  and  professed 
to  be  the  work  of  a  Dublin  tradesman.  The 
importance  of  the  letters  is  political  rather  than 
economic.  Swift  had  no  practical  or  theoretical 
grasp  of  currency  questions.  He  made  no 
attempt  to  state  the  real  objections  to  the  new 
coinage.  On  the  contrary  he  adopted  all  the 
prevalent  prejudices,  and  exaggerated  and 
illustrated  them  with  that  suppressed  yet 
masterful  irony  in  the  use  of  which  he  has 
never  been  surpassed.  In  the  famous  fourth 
letter  he  quitted  the  immediate  question  at  issue, 
denounced  the  abuses  of  English  misgovern- 
ment,  and  asserted  the  rights  of  the  Irish  nation 
to  independence.  The  printer  of  the  letter  was 
prosecuted,  but  the  jury  rejected  the  bill  in 
spite  of  judicial  browbeating.  The  author, 
though  his  identity  was  notorious,  was  left 
unattacked,  and  the  government  found  it 
necessary  to  yield  to  the  storm  which  it  had 
provoked.  The  whole  importance  of  the  episode 
lies  in  the  impulse  which  it  gave  to  the  opposi- 
tion to  English  rule  in  Ireland. 

[The  letters  are  to  be  found  in  Swift's  col- 
lected works.  For  comments  on  them,  see  Craik's 
Ln^t  of  Swift ; — Lecky's  Histoi'y  of  England  in 
the  Eighteenth  Century  and  Leaders  of  Public 
Opinion  in  Ireland  ; — Stanhope's  History  of  Eng- 
land.] R.  L. 

DRAWBACKS.  In  theory  a  drawback  is 
a  portion  of  the  "mercantile  system,"  and  is 
intended  to  promote  and  encourage  the  exporta- 
tion of  commodities.  It  consists  in  the  repay- 
ment of  a  duty  which  has  been  already  paid  in 
connection  with  the  manufacture  of  the  com- 
modity in  question,  such  repayment  to  be  made 
on  its  export.  Theoretically,  therefore,  draw- 
backs correspond  to,  and  are  similar  to,  Bounties 
(q.v.),  with  this  distinction — that  a  bounty  is 
a  direct  gift  to  the  exporter  of  goods,  while  a 
drawback  should  be  merely  the  remittance  of  a 
tax  in  his  behalf.  It  is  this  difference  which 
caused  Adam  Smith  to  hold  drawbacks  to  be 
the  most  reasonable  form  of  encouragement  to 
exportation  ;  because,  although  they  must  from 
their  nature  favour  certain  classes  of  exporters, 
they  cannot  operate  so  as  to  draw  more  trade 
into  any  particular  channel  than  would  have 
been  drawn  had  neither  the  tax  nor  the  remit- 


tance of  it  existed  :  in  other  words,  they  simply 
cancel  the  tax  and  leave  trade  free  to  follow  its 
most  natural  course.  It  must  always  be  remem- 
bered that  Smith  held  very  strong  views  in 
favour  of  absolute  non-interference  with  industry, 
and  was  consequently  averse  to  indirect  taxation. 
Drawbacks  may  be  manipulated  so  as  to  have 
the  same  effect  as  bounties  and  other  devices 
for  encouraging  exportation.  Where  this  is 
the  case  there  is  not  only  a  loss  of  revenue  to 
the  country  which  repays  the  tax,  but  a  sub- 
sidy is  given  on  exports  which  amounts  to  pay- 
ing the  foreign  consumer  to  buy  certain  goods. 
Drawbacks,  it  will  be  seen,  are  much  more 
restricted  in  their  nature  than  bounties.  As 
worked  in  this  country  they  are  comparatively 
unimportant.  They  are  of  no  use  in  encourag- 
ing a  rising  industry  in  a  new  country,  and 
are  generally  granted  simply  for  the  purpose  of 
increasing  the  amount  of  export  trade.  Adam 
Smith's  discussion  of  them  (bk.  iv.  chap.  4) 
may  be  read  with  great  interest.  J.  S.  Mill, 
in  bk.  iv.,  where  he  deals  with  the  various 
forms  of  protection,  adverts  to  drawbacks  ;  and 
generally  all  modern  economists,  who  have 
written  on  the  subject  of  political  economy  at 
large,  treat  of  drawbacks  along  with  bounties. 

M.  G.  D. 

DRAWER  OF  A  BILL  OF  EXCHANGE. 
The  person  giving  the  order  to  pay  contained 
in  a  bill  of  exchange  is  called  the  "drawer." 
If  the  bill  is  not  paid  at  maturity,  he  is  bound 
to  reimburse  the  holder,  provided  that  all  the 
necessary  formalities  have  been  observed  (pre- 
sentation in  proper  time,  notice  of  dishonour, 
protest  in  the  case  of  foreign  bills,  etc.)  (See 
Bill  of  Exchange.)  e.  s. 

DRAWING.  This  word  is  used  to  announce 
the  redemption  of  certain  bonds,  as  the  borrower 
applies  a  periodical  sinking  fund  to  that  pur- 
pose. The  practice  was  originally  connected 
with  the  simple  process  of  drawing  lots.  A 
borrowing  government,  for  example,  may  en- 
gage to  pay  off  1  per  cent  of  its  loan  every 
year,  and  then  the  question  arises  as  to  which 
bond  out  of  every  hundred  in  circulation  shall 
be  redeemed  in  order  to  make  the  redemption 
fair.  A  drawing  is  announced,  the  function 
being  attended  by  public  officials  and  other 
persons  of  unimpeachable  integrity,  and  the 
bonds  which  happen  to  be  drawn  by  lot  are 
then  advertised  for  repayment  at  par,  or  at 
whatever  the  stipulated  price  of  repayment  may 
be.  Cases  have  been  known  in  which  holders 
of  drawn  bonds  have  gone  on  receiving  dividends 
in  ignorance  of  the  drawing,  and  other  cases 
are  on  record  in  which  the  drawn  bonds  having 
been  sold  on  the  stock  exchange,  it  has  been 
discovered  several  months  or  years  afterwards 
that  the  said  bonds  were  not  a  good  delivery 
(see  Delivery,  Good).  A  question  also  has 
arisen  where,  if  a  borrowing  government  form- 
ally promises  the  drawing  of  1  per  cent  of  its 


DRENGAGE— DRUMMOND 


641 


debt  each  year,  it  is  really  empowered  also  to 
redeem  2  or  3  per  cent,  or  even  the  whole  of 
the  outstanding  debt,  and  in  the  years  of  active 
redemptions — 1888-90 — borrowers  found  it  so 
easy  to  raise  fresh  loans  at  diminished  rates  of 
interest  that  they  were  continually  exceeding 
the  rate  of  redemption  by  drawing  beyond  the 
proportion  originally  stipulated.  The  system 
of  drawing  is  not  altogether  commendable,  and 
was  originally  employed  to  give  a  kind  of  specu- 
lative attraction  to  bonds  which  would  other- 
wise have  been  neglected  by  steady  investors. 
That  is,  the  objectionable  element  of  hazard 
enters  into  the  question,  which  ought  to  be  purely 
one  of  the  solidity  of  the  borrower.         a.  e. 

DRENGAGE.  A  form  of  land  tenure, 
common  in,  if  not  confined  to,  the  district 
comprised  in  the  ancient  kingdom  of  North- 
umbria.  Drenghs  are  mentioned  in  Domesday 
and  in  the  survey  called  the  Boldon  Book. 
Sir  Henry  Ellis  says  :  "  The  drenchs  or  drenghs 
were  of  the  description  of  allodial  tenants  .  .  . 
and  from  the  few  entries  in  which  they  occur  it 
certainly  appears  that  the  allotments  of  territory 
they  possessed  were  held  as  manors  "  (General 
Introduction  to  Domesday,  tom.  i.  fol.  269). 
But,  as  menial  services  were  required  of  them 
or  their  servants,  at  least  in  Durham,  they 
must  have  been  inferior  to  military  tenants. 
The  instance  in  the  Pipe  Rolls  of  Westmoreland, 
25  Henry  II.  of  the  enfranchisement  of  drenghs, 
and  the  particulars  given  in  the  records  of  the 
palatinate  as  to  the  services  attached,  show 
that  drengagc  was  by  no  means  a  free  tenure. 
The  services  of  a  dretigh  were  to  plough,  sow, 
and  harrow  portions  of  his  lord's  land,  to  keep 
a  dog  and  horse  for  his  use,  attend  the  chase 
with  him,  etc.  "A  drengage  seems  to  have 
consisted  of  sixteen  acres  to  be  ploughed,  sown, 
and  harrowed  "  (Blount's  Fragmenta  Antiqui- 
tatis).  The  word  is  derived  by  Greenwell,  in 
his  glossary  to  the  Boldon  Book,  from  the 
Anglo-Saxon  "dreogan,"  to  work.  Another 
derivation  is  from  the  Danish  ''dreng"  a 
servant  or  boy.  Spelman,  however,  defines 
drenghs  as  those  who  at  the  coming  of  William 
the  Conqueror  were  put  out  of  their  lands  and 
afterwards  restored  by  him  on  proof  of  owner- 
ship (Tomlins),  and  Cowel  says  "drenched"  is 
an  obsolete  word  meaning  "overcome,"  and 
compares  the  German  "tringen"  (see  also 
Cornage). 

[Prof.  Maitland,  JSngl.  Hist.  Rev.,  October 
1890.— iVb^es  and  Queries,  I.  vii.  137,  298.— See- 
bohm,  Village  Communities,  71.]  H.  Ha. 

DRINKS,  Taxes  on.     See  Taxes. 

DROFLAND,  or  Drtfland.  Apparently 
an  ancient  service  in  the  nature  of  driving  the 
lord's  cattle  to  the  fair,  commuted  for  a  quit-rent; 
but  according  to  Cowel  {Interpreter,  s.v.)  a.  due 
payable  to  the  lord  for  the  right  of  passage 
I  with  cattle  through  the  manor  (see  Thistle- 
Rent).  H.  Ha. 
VOL.  I 


DROIT,  ANNUEL.     See  Patjlette. 

DROITS  OF  ADMIRALTY.  In  England 
the  Lord  High  Admiral  (an  office  that  has  still 
a  legal  existence)  has  the  benefit  of  all  captures 
made  at  sea  by  non-commissioned  vessels,  and 
also  of  all  captures  of  shi^js  or  goods  made  in 
the  ports  of  England  and  Ireland  through 
vessels  coming  in  by  stress  of  weather  or  other 
accident,  or  by  mistake  of  port  or  by  ignorance, 
not  knowing  of  the  war,  and  also  of  all 
derelicts. 

By  the  1  &  2  Vict.  c.  2  it  was  enacted  that  the 
profits  derived  from  droits  of  admiralty  should  be 
paid  into  the  exchequer  for  the  benefit  of  the 
state.  Phillimore's  International  Law,  vol.  ill. 
London,  1873.  j.  e.  c.  m. 

DROITS  D'AUBAINE.     See  Aubaine. 

DROZ,  Joseph,  born  at  Besan9on  in  1773, 
died  at  Paris  1850.  The  incidents  of  his  life 
were  varied,  and  so  were  his  opinions.  Belong- 
ing to  a  family  of  high  legal  standing,  he  com- 
menced life  as  a  volunteer  when  the  Revolution 
broke  out ;  but  afterwards  laying  down  his 
arms,  became  professor  of  rhetoric  at  the  central 
school  of  Besangon.  He  subsequently  returned 
to  Paris,  where  he  was  closely  associated 
with  the  habitues  of  the  Society  d'Aiiteuil. 
The  members  of  this  club,  who  were  Epicur- 
ean in  spirit  and  taste,  in  most  things  kept 
themselves  detached  from  the  life  of  the  19th 
century.  He  derived  from  this  association  a 
fund  of  sanguine  optimism  which  never  failed. 
Towards  the  close  of  his  life,  he  came  under 
the  influence  of  religion.  He  joined  the  Aca- 
dimie  fran(^aise  in  1824,  and  the  Academic 
des  Sciences  morales  et  politiqucs  in  1833.  In 
1829  he  published  his  Economic  politique  ou 
principes  dc  la  science  des  richcsscs,  1  vol.  in 
8vo,  a  valuable  work,  but  one  in  which  he  fails 
to  distinguish,  with  sufiicient  exactness,  moral 
IVom  economic  precepts.  He  also  published  in 
1839-42  the  Histoire  du  r^gne  de  Louis  XVI. 
pendant  les  annees  oii  Von  pouvait  pr6venir  et 
diriger  la  Revolution  franqaise,  3  vols,  in  8vo. 
The  dual  title  of  this  work  is  a  sufficient  in- 
dication of  the  line  of  thought  pursued  in  it  and 
the  object  proposed.  A.  c.  f. 

DRUMMOND,  Henry  (1786-1860),  banker, 
economist,  and  theologian,  was  the  eldest  son 
of  Henry  Drummond  {d.  1794).  He  was 
brought  up  by  his  maternal  grandfather,  Vis- 
count Melville,  and  was  educated  at  Harrow 
and  Cambridge,  but  took  no  degree.  He  be- 
came a  partner  in  the  well-known  house  at 
Charing  Cross,  and  for  many  years  had  a  lead- 
ing share  in  its  administration.  Between  1810 
and  1813  he  was  M.P.  for  Plympton  Earls, 
and  carried  through  parliament  a  bill  against 
embezzlement  by  bankers  of  securities  under 
their  charge,  which  became  law  (52  Geo.  III.  c. 
63).  With  his  wife  he  started  in  June  1817 
on  a  pilgrimage  to  Palestine,  but  on  passing 
through  Geneva  he  stopped  to  contend  with 

2  T 


642 


DRUMMOND— DRUNKAKDS 


the  consistory  on  ecclesiastical  discipline.  In 
1825  he  founded  the  professorship  i  of  economy 
at  Oxford.  He  was  an  apostle,  evangelist,  and 
prophet  of  the  Irvingite  Church,  and  built  a 
church  for  that  community  at  Albury,  where 
he  lived.  From  1847  to  his  death  Jie  was 
M.P.  for  West  Surrey.  He  was  a  frequent 
speaker  in  the  House  of  Commons.  Sir  Henry 
Holland  speaks  of  "the  genial  temperament 
and  masculine,  though  eccentric  intellect  of 
Henry  Drummond  .  .  .  who  could  not  tread 
along  the  highway  of  common  opinion  either  in 
religion  or  politics,  but  his  aberrant  path  was 
always  pursued  with  honesty  as  well  as  vigour  " 
{Eecollectims,  1872,  p.  156).  Some  of  Drum- 
mond's  numerous  speeches  and  pamphlets  were 
collected  by  Lord  Lovaine,  1860,  2  vols.  8vo. 
His  economical  publications  are  : 

Elementary  Propositions  on  the  Currency,  Lon- 
don, 1819,  8vo  (reprinted  with  additions  in  1826, 
again  in  1848,  and  with  Speeches,  etc.,  1860,  vol. 
ii.). — Cheap  Com  best  for  Farmers,  London,  1826, 
8vo  (anonymous :  the  landlords  are  the  only 
gainers  by  the  tax,  all  others,  including  the 
farmers,  suffer). — Justice  to  Corn  Growers  and  to 
Corn  Eaters,  London,  1839,  8vo  (in  favour  of 
repeal  with  restrictions). — Cannes  lohich  lead  to  a 
Bank  Restriction  Bill,  London,  1839,  8vo  ("the 
Bank  of  England  is  the  only  body  which  ought  to 
have  the  power  of  issuing  paper  money,"  p.  20). — 
On  the  Com  Laws,  London,  1841,  8vo. — On  the 
Condition  of  the  Agricultural  Classes  of  Great 
Britain  and  Ireland,  with  extracts  from  the  Parlia- 
mentary Reports  and  Evidence  from  1833  to  18Jfi, 
and  remarks  by  the  French  editor  published  at 
Vienna,  London,  1842,  2  vols.  8vo  (with  preface 
by  Drummond ;  translation  of  two  volumes  pub- 
lished by  the  Austrian  government  to  show  "  the 
folly  of  supposing  that  it  is  commerce  and  manu- 
factures rather  than  agriculture  which  constitute 
the  true  wealth  of  this  country,"  pref.  xi.-xii. ).  — 
Letter  to  the  Bishop  of  Winchester  on  Free  Trade, 
London,  1846. — Speech  on  Motion  on  Public  Ex- 
penditure, London,  1849. — Letter  to  the  Working 
Classes  in  Trades  and  Manufactures,  London,  1859 
(on  the  bad  treatment  received  by  them  "from 
manufacturers,  millowners,  and  poor-law  guardians, 
and  of  the  exertions  made  by  noblemen  and  gentle- 
men to  protect "  them — p.  29). 

[Lord  Lovaine,  Memoir,  1860. — Oliphant,  Life  of 
Edw.  Irving,  1862. — Diet,  of  National  Biography, 
xvi.  pp.  28,  29. — Historical  Register  of  the  Uni- 
versity of  Oxford,  1888,  pp.  67,  68.]      h.  r.  t. 

DRUNKARDS,  Legislation  respecting. 
The  care  and  the  cure  of  habitual  drunkards  has 

1  Drummond  charged  his  estate  wth  a  yearly  rent  of 
£100  for  the  endowment.  The  corainissioners  of  1877  in- 
creased the  emoluments  to  £300  from  the  revenues  of 
All  Souls,  besides  £200  attached  to  a  fellowship  of  the 
college  The  professorship  is  for  five  years,  but  holders 
of  the  otflce  may  now  be  re-elected.  The  following  have 
been  the  professors:  1825,  Nassau  W.  Senior;  1830, 
Richard  Whateley ;  1832,  W.  F.  Lloyd ;  1837,  Herman 
Merivale;  1842,  Travers  Twiss;  1847,  N.  W.  Senior 
(second  time) ;  1852,  G.  K.  Ilickards ;  1857.  C.  Neate  ■ 
1862,  J,  B.  Thorold  Rogers  ;  1868,  Bonamy  Price  (again 
in  1873,  1878,  and  1883) ;  1888,  J.  B.  T.  Rogers  (second 
time);  1891,  P.  Y.  Bdgeworth. 


of  recent  years,  received  more  attention  on  the 
part  of  social  reformers  than  formerly.  A  series 
of  Acts  dealing  with  habitual  drunkards,  both 
non-criminal  and  criminal,  have  been  passed 
between  1879-1900.  Habitual  drunkards  are 
defined  as  persons  who  through  continued  ex- 
cessive drinking  of  intoxicating  liquor  are 
dangerous  either  to  themselves  or  others,  or  in- 
capable of  managing  their  affairs,  and  the  care 
of  such  cases  comes  as  much  within  the  province 
of  legislation  as  the  reception  and  detention  of 
lunatics.  A  person  with  whom  the  craving  for 
intoxicants  has  become  an  irresistible  impulse, 
is  not,  strictly  speaking,  a  person  of  sound  mind, 
and  it  would  be  no  undue  interference  with  the 
liberty  of  the  subject  if  such  a  person  could  be 
kept  in  confinement  against  his  will.  The  law 
now  provides  for  voluntary  admission  to  a 
licensed  retreat,  and  for  the  committal  of 
criminal  cases,  or  cases  constantly  appearing  in 
the  police  courts,  to  reformatories.  Retreats  are, 
in  England,  licensed  by  the  county  or  borough 
council  of  the  district  in  which  they  are  situate, 
and  are  under  the  control  of  the  Home  Secretary 
and  an  Inspector  of  Retreats.  Application  for 
admission  to  a  retreat,  stating  the  length  of 
time  the  applicant  undertakes  to  remain  there, 
must  be  accompanied  by  the  declaration  of  two 
persons  that  he  is  an  habitual  drunkard.  The 
declaration  must  be  made  before  a  justice  of  the 
peace,  who  must  satisfy  himself  that  it  is  in 
accordance  with  facts  and  the  intention  of  the 
applicant.  The  maximum  time  of  detention 
is  two  years,  but  a  case  may  be  readmitted. 
British  legislation  has  recognised  the  principle 
that,  if  a  dipsomaniac  has  once  allowed  himself 
to  be  confined  in  a  licensed  retreat,  he  cannot 
leave  it  before  the  expiration  of  the  time  during 
which  he  has  undertaken  to  remain,  unless  he 
is  previously  discharged  or  allowed  to  go  out  on 
leave  under  provisions  similar  to  those  laid 
down  in  the  Lunacy  Act. 

Besides  licensed  retreats  the  law  provides 
for  certified  and  for  state  (of  a  more  penal 
character)  inebriate  reformatories  in  which 
persons  convicted  of  crime  committed  while 
under  the  influence  of  drink  may  be  detained. 
Cases  convicted  of  being  drunk  in  any  public 
place  three  times  within  a  year  may  also  be 
detained  in  these  reformatories.  In  1908  there 
were  20  licensed  retreats  with  493  voluntary 
patients,  11  certified  inebriate  reformatories, 
the  number  of  committals  in  that  year  being 
262,  and  in  the  ten  years  1897-1908,  3002. 
There  were  two  state  inebriate  reformatories,  the 
average  number  of  inmates  being  116. 

Some  interesting  statistics  were  published  in 
1890  relating  to  the  Dairy mple  House  at  Rick- 
mansworth.  The  following  facts  as  to  the  family 
history  of  224  persons  discharged  from  that 
retreat  are  stated  : — Insanity  in  family,  19 
cases  ; — inebriety  in  family,  i.e.  of  one  or  more 
of  the  parents,  34  ; — of  the  grandparents,  10  ; 


DRY  EXCHANGE— DUCAT 


643 


of  the  brothers,  14  ;  of  the  uncles,  35  ;  in  all, 

93  cases  ; — no  history  obtainable,  112  cases. 
Out  of  these  discharged  patients  there  were — 

94  doing  well ;  10  improved  ;  74  not  improved ; 
10  insane  ;  1  dead  ;  35  not  heard  from.  Less 
encouraging  statistics  are  given  by  the  Inebri- 
ates After-care  Association.  Of  407  selected 
cases  discharged  between  1903-8,  82  were  pro- 
gressing satisfactorily ;  114  were  unsatisfactory ; 
and  221  had  been  lost  sight  of. 

The  property  of  inebriates  is  now  protected 
in  the  same  way  as  that  of  lunatics.  The 
Lunacy  Act,  1890  (§  116),  authorises  the  judge 
in  lunacy  to  give  certain  directions  as  to  the 
management  and  administration  of  the  property 
of  any  individual  ' '  with  regard  to  whom  it  is 
proved  to  the  satisfaction  of  the  judge  in  lunacy 
that  such  person  is,  through  mental  infirmity 
arising  from  disease  or  age,  incapable  of  manag- 
ing his  affairs,"  and  in  such  a  case  to  appoint 
some  person  to  act  in  a  similar  capacity  as  the 
committee  of  a  lunatic's  estate  (see  Committee)  ; 
and  the  Lunacy  Act,  1891,  §  27  (4),  provides 
that  the  last-mentioned  power  may  be  exer- 
cised with  reference  to  individuals  who  are  not 
lunatics. 

The  Licensing  Act  of  1902  })roliibits  the  sale 
of  liquor  to  persons  known  to  be  drunkards. 

The  law  relating  to  drunkenness  in  Germany, 
Austria,  France,  some  of  our  colonies  and  else- 
where, provides  that  a  dipsomaniac  who  exposes 
himself  or  his  family  to  the  risk  of  impoverish- 
ment, or  who  imperils  the  security  of  any  other 
person,  may  be  placed  under  guardianship. 
A  provision  of  this  nature,  if  applied  with  care 
and  discrimination,  must  be  beneficial  to  the 
persons  concerned  no  less  than  to  society  at 
large.  e.  s. 

[Wyatt  Paine,  Inebriate  Reformatories  and  Re- 
treats, 1899  ;  G.  Blackwell,  Habitual  Inebriates 
Act,  1879-98,  1899 ;  A.  Shadwell,  Drink,  Temper- 
ance, and  Legislation,  1902  ;  S.  Freeman,  Guide  to 
Stat.  Law  against  Drunkenness  in  England,  1906  ; 
H.  N.  Barnett,  Legal  Responsibility  of  the  Drunk- 
ard, 1908  ;  Annual  Reports  of  Inspector  under 
Inebriates  Act.  For  other  countries,  see  Pari. 
Paper  (1902),  cd.  1474.] 

DRY  EXCHANGE  {Cambium  sicmm).  A 
euphemism  applied  to  the  "coverture"  or 
"colouring"  of  the  stringent  statutes  passed 
during  the  Tudor  period  against  usury.  "A 
cleanly  term  invented  for  the  disguising  of  foul 
usury,  in  which  something  is  pretended  to  pass 
on  both  sides  whereas  in  truth  nothing  passes 
but  only  on  the  one  side "  (Cowel).  Usury, 
which  was  condemned  by  religion  and  law  alike 
during  the  middle  ages,  was  from  the  middle 
of  the  1 6th  century  no  longer  to  be  confounded 
with  the  legitimate  employment  of  capital ; 
but  the  sentiment  which  inspired  the  above 
enactments  was  that  of  governing  classes  asso- 
ciated with  the  landed  interest. 

[Cunningham,  Growth  of  English  Industry  and 


Commerce,   1890,  495  et  seq. — Hall,  Elizabethan 
Society,  ch.  Iv.]  H.Ha. 

DRY  RENT  (Rene  sec).  An  annual  rent- 
charge  reserved  upon  lands  conveyed  by  deed, 
without  the  insertion  of  a  clause  of  distraint. 

H.  Ha. 

DUBOS,  Ap.b^  J.  B.  (1670-1742),  a  mem- 
ber of  the  French  Academy,  and  author  of 
historical  works  and  of  a  treatise  on  poetry 
and  painting. 

The  one  book  of  his  which  requires  notice 
here  is  entitled  Les  Interests  de  VAngleterre  mal 
entendus  dans  la  guerre  prisente  (Amsterdam, 
1703),  and  professes  to  be  a  translation  from  an 
English  book.  Speaking  thus  as  an  English- 
man, the  Abbe  remonstrates  against  the  war 
policy  of  the  English  administration.  He  is 
well  acquainted  with  contemporary  English 
pamphlets  on  the  Tory  side,  especially  with 
Davenant,  whom  he  often  quotes.  He  success- 
ively examines  the  effect  of  war  on  each  branch 
of  English  trade  and  manufactures,  and  dis- 
tinctly states  (p.  80)  that  "the  attempts  we 
(the  English)  shall  be  obliged  to  make  in  order 
to  enforce  in  the  (American)  colonies  the  just 
obedience  they  owe  to  the  state  which  has 
founded  them,  will  perhaps  lead  them  to 
rebellion,  when  they  will  have  learned  that 
they  can  do  without  us." 

Voltaire  addresses  him  in  a  letter  dated  30  th 
October  1738,  as  "the  most  useful  and 
judicious  writer  he  knows,"  but,  when  writing 
to  other  people,  he  indulges  in  sarcasm  about 
the  Abbe's  "mistaken"  notions  as  to  the  in- 
terest of  England.  e.  ca. 

DUCAT,  History  of.  A  gold  coin  (worth 
about  9s.  4^d.)  in  extensive  use  on  the  continent 
till  this  century,  and  adopted  by  successive 
emperors  as  the  standard  coin  of  the  empire  in 
the  middle  ages.  The  coin  first  makes  its 
appearance  in  1140  A.D.,  when  Roger  II.,  King 
of  Sicily  and  Duke  of  Apulia  and  Calabria, 
issued  silver  coins  to  which  he  gave  the  name 
"ducati,"  probably  because  they  were  first 
struck  in  the  duchy  of  Apulia,  especially  called 
"  il  ducato,"  and  bore,  in  an  abbreviated  form, 
the  inscription — "Sit  tibi,  Christe,  datus, 
quem  tu  regis,  iste  Ducatus  "  (Let  this  Duchy, 
0  Christ,  which  thou  rulest,  be  dedicated  to 
thee).  The  coin  then  spread  through  Italy 
until,  in  1252,  it  was  formally  adopted  at 
Florence,  and  gold  pieces  were  issued  under  the 
name  of  "ducati  gigliati."  These  ducati 
gigliati,  or  florens  d'or,  as  they  were  called 
elsewhere,  were  24  carats  fine,  and  64  to  the 
fine  mark.  Thirty-two  years  later,  by  a  law 
passed  in  1283  a.d.,  ducats  were  struck  at 
Venice  by  the  Doge  John  Dandolo,  the  second 
of  the  four  celebrated  Doges  Dandolo,  67  to  the 
fine  mark,  and  each  bearing  the  inscription  of 
the  original  ducat  of  Apulia.  In  the  16th 
century,  these  ducats  received  the  name  of 
"zecohini"  (sequins)  from  Zecca,  the  Venetian 


644 


DUCAT— DUCHATEL 


mint,  whence  their  Anglo -Indian  name  of 
"chicks"  (Rs.  4). 

By  the  beginning  of  the  14th  century  these 
florens  d'or  and  Venetian  ducats  had  spread 
throughout  the  states  of  Italy,  and  especially 
the  Church  states,  where  Florentine  ducats 
were  universally  adopted  and  issued  as  '^novelli 
ducati  papales,"  with  only  slight  variations 
from  the  original  standard  of  1252.  The 
Florentine  coin  thence  spread  into  Hungary, 
whither  it  was  followed  by  the  Venetian  ducat, 
until  in  1365,  Venetian  ducats  were  struck  by 
the  king  Ludwig,  at  Kremnitz,  of  23f  carats 
fine,  and  67,^  to  ^^^  Cologne  mark.  Later 
on  **  imperial "  ducats  were  issued  at  23^  carats 
fine,  and  6  8  /^  to  the  tine  mark.  From  Hungary 
and  Bohemia  the  Venetian  ducat,  preceded 
however  by  the  floren  d'or,  was  introduced 
into  Germany,  and  continued  to  circulate  as  a 
foreign  coin  throughout  its  various  states,  right 
up  to  the  Augsburg  Convention  of  1559.  In 
this  year  the  imperial  diet  of  Germany  adopted 
the  ducat  into  the  currency  of  the  empire 
(Ferdinand  I.)  at  a  prescribed  "  dukaten-fuss  " 
of  23f  carats  fineness,  and  67  to  the  Cologne 
mark  (and  therefore  67f|-  to  the  fine  mark) — 
a  "footing"  subsequently  maintained  both  by 
the  Leipzig  Convention  of  1690,  by  the  Austro- 
Bavarian  Convention  of  1753,  and  the  Frank- 
furt Coinage  Union  of  1765. 

This  adoption  of  the  ducat  into  the  currency 
of  the  empire  had  the  effect  of  causing  the 
surrounding  states  to  follow  the  lead  of  striking 
ducats  for  themselves.  Yet  in  every  case, 
though  both  the  floren  d'or  and  the  Venetian 
ducat  (by  this  time  known  as  the  sequin)  had 
previously  obtained  in  circulation,  it  was  the 
latter  coin  that  was  adopted  and  struck  as  the 
standard  of  cuiTency  by  the  several  states  ; 
by  the  cantons  of  Switzerland  in  the  ]  6th  and 
early  I7th  centuries,  at  fineness  and  weights 
varying  from  23^  carats  and  68^  ducats  to 
the  fine  mark,  at  Berne,  to  23f  carats  and  67^% 
respectively,  at  Basel  and  St.  Gallen  ;  by 
Denmark  in  1647  at  23^  carats  fine,  and  68/^ 
ducats  to  the  fine  mark  ;  by  Holland,  a  little 
later,  at  2Z^^  carats  fine,  and  68^  to  the  fine 
mark  ;  by  Russia,  Poland,  and  Sweden,  about 
the  same  time,  or  a  little  earlier,  at  rates 
varying  from  23^  carats  fine  to  23f,  and  78  to 
68^  ducats  to  the  fine  mark,  and  continued 
to  be  coined  tiU  well  into  the  present  century. 
Ducats  were  even  struck  by  the  Porte,  and 
some  issued  by  Sultan  Mahomet  IV.  are 
known  (1649-1693  a.d.).  A  Barbary  ducat 
was  current  in  the  West  Indies  early  in  the 
last  century. 

The  history  of  the  ducat  in  France,  Spain, 
and  Portugal  is  slightly  diflferent.  As  regards 
the  latter  country,  Pope  Calistus  III.  having 
in  1455  demanded  supplies  for  an  expedition 
against  the  Turks,  Alphonso  V.,  then  king, 
had  quarter-ducats,  or  "  Crusados  "  struck  in 


1455,  first  at  23  carats  fineness  ;  later  at  22 
carats  fine  and  28 9  J  of  these  crusados  to  the 
fine  mark.  These  Crusados  or  Portuguese 
quarter- ducats  are  the  ' '  Kreuz-dukaten  "  of  the 
German  middle  ages.  Still  later  (1722-1750), 
new  crusados  were  issued  at  the  same  fineness 
as  before,  but  at  an  increased  weight,  viz.  237 
to  the  fine  mark.  In  France,  where  the  ducat 
was  early  introduced,  the  Florentine  coin  (64 
to  the  fine  mark)  was  adopted  over  its  elsewhere 
successful  rival,  thanks  to  the  fact  that  at  this 
time  (14th  century)  the  Pope  resided  at 
Avignon ;  while  in  Spain  in  1537,  under 
Emperor  Charles  V.,  the  Italian  and  French 
ducat,  under  the  name  of  the  "escudo"  (22 
carats  fine,  and  68  to  the  Castilian  mark  =69^ 
nearly  to  the  fine  Cologne  mark)  began  and 
long  continued  to  form  the  basis  of  the 
Spanish  gold  monetary  system  (see  Doub- 
loon). 

By  far  the  most  common  "ducats"  were  those 
current  in  Hungary,  Germany,  Holland,  and 
Russia,  and  averaged  in  value,  each  containing 
roughly  53*9  grains,  about  9s.  4^d.  apiece. 
The  Swedish  ducat,  however,  was  only  worth 
about  9s.  3^d.,  while  the  modern  Italian  gold 
ducat  was  much  less.  Silver  ducats  were  also 
struck  in  several  places,  and  varied  in  value 
much  more  than  the  gold  ;  e.g.  the  silver 
ducats  of  Italy  were  worth  3s.  4d.  ;  those  of 
Holland  (the  daalders)  4s.  2d.  ;  while  the 
silver  ducat  of  Sicily  had  the  value  of  3s.  4|d. 
Ducats  were  also  issued  made  of  platinum 
(Russia),  and  earlier  of  copper  and  lead  (Venice, 
Germany,  France,  and  Holland),  while  they  were 
not  infrequently  struck  as  medallions. 

[Vergara,  Monete  del  Regno  di  Napoli,  Roma, 
1715. — Philippi  Argelati,  De  Monetis  Italice^  5 
vols.,  Mediolani,  1750. — Johann  Tobias  Kohler, 
Vollstdndiges  Ducaien- Cabinet,  2  vols.,  Hanover, 
1760. — Bonneville,  Traite  des  Monnaies,  Paris, 
1806].  w.  L. 

DUCAT  {Modern).  Austrian  standard  gold 
coin,  weight  53*86  grains,  fineness  986.  Value ; 
English  standard  (916-6  fine  at  £3  :  17  :  10| 
per  oz.)  9s.  4|d.  ;  French  standard  (900  fine) 
11 '85  francs. 

Ducats  were  the  principal  medium  of  exchange 
in  Italy  for  several  centuries.  (See  Ducat, 
History  of.)  f.  e.  a. 

DUCHATEL,  Comte  Tanneguy,  born  at 
Paris  in  1803,  died  in  1867.  He  was  on  several 
occasions  a  minister  of  state  and  organised  the 
commission  of  inquiry  which  resulted  in  the 
law  of  24th  May  1834.  This  replaced  a  large 
number  of  prohibitions  on  imports  by  customs 
duties  (the  report  of  this  inquiry  has  been 
published  in  3  vols.  8vo).  In  1829  he  published 
a  work  entitled  De  la  chariM  dans  ses  rapports 
avec  I'dtat  moral  et  le  hien-etre  des  classes  infiri- 
eures  de  la  socUti,  1  vol.  in  4to.  This  was 
reprinted  in  1836  without  any  change  except 
that  of  the  title,  which  became  Considerations 


DUCPETIAUX— DUE 


645 


d'economie  politique  sur  la  lienfaisance  ou  de  la 
charite,  etc.,  1  vol.  in  8vo.  Blanqui  reproaches 
him  with  too  unqualified  an  acceptance  of  the 
doctrines  of  Malthus ;  but  this  should  rather 
be  reckoned  as  a  point  in  his  favour.  He  was 
received  in  1846  into  the  Acadimie  des  Sciences 
morales  et  politiques.  His  claims  to  be  a  de- 
scendant of  the  Tanncguy  du  Chatcl  of  the  15th 
century  appear  to  be  unfounded.  a.  c.  f. 

DUCPETIAUX,  Edouard,  born  in  Brussels 
in  1804,  died  1868.  In  1828  he  published 
several  pamphlets  on  Repressive  and  Provident 
Justice,  and  on  the  penalty  of  death.  Shortly 
after  the  revolution  of  1830  he  was  appointed 
general  inspector  of  the  Penitentiary  and  Bene- 
ficent Institutions  of  the  new-born  kingdom. 
Ducpetiaux  was  a  prolific  and  indefatigable 
writer  on  the  subjects  which  had  from  the 
beginning  of  his  life  attracted  his  attention. 
His  principal  works  on  the  punishment  of 
criminals  are  :  Progres  et  ]Etat  de  la  Mforme 
P6nitentiaire  (1838),  and  Des  Conditions  de 
V Emprisonnement  se]}ar6  ou  cellulaire  (1857), 
in  which  he  shows  himself  a  consistent  advocate 
of  the  cellular  system  as  being  the  punishment 
best  adapted  to  awaken  a  sense  of  morality  in 
the  prisoner,  by  the  predominance  of  the  prin- 
ciple of  amendment  over  the  principle  of  pure 
repression.  He  was  no  less  devoted  to  the 
solution  of  the  problems  connected  with  the 
condition  of  the  working  classes.  In  connec- 
tion with  this  we  may  mention  his  Condition 
Physique  et  Morale  des  Jeunes  Ouvriers  (1843), 
his  Paup4risme  en  Belgique  (1844),  \ns,  M6moire 
sur  le  PaupSrisme  dans  les  Flandres  (1850), 
which  obtained  a  prize  from  the  Royal  Academy 
of  Belgium,  and  his  important  Budgets  J^cono- 
miques  des  Classes  Ouvrieres  en  Belgique  (1865). 
All  his  works  were  published  in  Brussels. 

His  book  on  the  condition  of  young  opera- 
tives is  a  very  full  inquiry  into  their  state  and 
the  legislation  on  this  matter  in  the  principal 
countries  of  Europe  and  in  the  United  States ;  but 
his  two  essays  on  pauperism  in  Belgium  are  the 
most  likely  to  interest  the  English  reader.     The 
former  is  rather  too  rhetorical,  but  the  second 
gives  a  very  graphic  account,  based  on  statistics 
and  exhaustive  personal  investigations,  of  the 
•   miserable  state  of  the  population  of  Flanders 
after  the  decay  of  the  weaving  by  hand  of  flax 
and  linen.     In  1848  in  the  two  provinces  of 
East  and  West  Flanders  the  average  wages  of 
the  adult  male  weaver  had  fallen  to  6d.  a  day, 
the  number  of  deaths  exceeded  the  number  of 
births  by  4541.(20,715  against    16,174)  and 
about  one-third  (453,658)  of  the  population  of 
;    Flanders  had  to  be  assisted  by  state  charity. 
:    Ducpetiaux  ascribed  this  miserable  situation  to 
{    an  excess  of  population,  and  to  an  excessive 
V  prevalence  of  laissez-faire.     He  called  upon  the 
1    state  to  interfere  by  fostering  the  spirit  of  asso- 
'    elation,    popular    education,    emigration,    and 
curing    labour    to    adult    and    able-bodied 


paupers.  Notwithstanding  his  appeal  to  the 
state,  he  is  no  friend  to  the  English  poor  system, 
which  he  calls  a  devouring  cancer  (p.  272). 
He  is  not  an  antagonist  of  the  factory  system, 
and  vigorously  asserts  that  mechanical  work  ia 
only  degrading  because  it  is  too  protracted 
{Condition  des  Jeuiies  Ouvriers,  ii.  p.  6). 

Ducpetiaux  also  promoted  charitable  con- 
gresses in  Belgium.  Towards  the  end  of  his 
life  he  changed  political  sides,  passing  from  the 
liberal  into  the  clerical  party,  but  he  remained 
to  the  last  a  steadfast  adherent  of  Malthus' s 
views  on  moral  restraint,  which  were  considered 
by  his  new  political  allies  as  having  a  tendency 
to  immorality.  e.  ca. 

DUE  (gerihta,  rectitudo,  rectum).  That 
which  is  owing  to  the  crown  or  to  any  corporate 
body  or  to  any  individual  subject  by  prescrip- 
tion or  charter.  There  is  this  distinction  to  be 
made  between  a  "due"  and  a  "custom"  that 
the  former  is  warranted  by  the  common  law, 
being  usually  levied  by  virtue  of  written  laws 
and  contracts  which  are  as  ancient  as  the 
common  law  itself,  while  the  latter,  in  its  first 
origin  at  least,  was  a  more  or  less  uncertain 
and  unauthorised  impost,  so  that  we  find  the 
term  "recta"  and  "mala"  applied  to  the 
respective  forms  of  the  custom  which  were 
authorised  by  statute  or  contract,  or  else  levied 
at  the  will  of  the  king  or  other  lord  alone. 

Agaia,  a  "due"  for  the  most  part  seems  to 
arise  from  the  ownership  or  cultivation  of  the 
soil  itself,  and  therefore  it  is  perhaps  the  most 
primitive  form  of  tax;  whereas  a  "custom" 
for  the  most  part  seems  to  arise  from  the 
exchange  or  conversion  of  the  products  of  the 
soil  by  way  of  merchandise.  The  most  typical 
due  of  any.  Church-seed  (q.v.),  is  certainly 
more  than  a  century  older  than  any  other 
customary  contribution.  Several  kinds  of  dues 
may  be  enumerated,  as  ecclesiastical,  seignorial, 
municipal,  and  fiscal  or  regal.  Of  these  ecclesi- 
astical dues  are  of  very  great  antiquity,  for 
those  that  are  still  familiar  to  us  in  the  present 
day  as  tithes  (see  Tithes)  and  church-rates  can 
be  traced  back  to  the  English  laws  of  the  8th 
century,  although  many  others  which  were  paid 
to  the  early  church  have  long  since  disappeared. 
A  still  greater  antiquity  could  even  be  claimed 
for  them  in  this  country  by  reference  to  the 
doctrinal  writings  of  the  7th  century,  and  the 
analogy  of  Prankish  customs. 

The  well-known  compact  between  the  Anglo- 
Saxon  sovereignty  and  the  church  in  virtue  of 
which  the  king's  dignity  and  the  archbishop's 
were  respectively  maintained,  and  the  peace  of 
the  crown  and  church  went  hand  in  hand,  is 
further  exemplified  by  the  arrangements  enforced 
by  the  state  for  the  temporal  welfare  of  the 
he^ly  order.  Anglo-Saxon  finance  is  no  intri- 
cate problem,  simply  because  whilst  the  king 
lived  of  his  own,  the  working  expenses  of 
government  were  amply  met  by  the  threefold 


I 


646 


DUE 


allodial  obligation.  But  in  contrast  to  their  reti- 
cence on  the  subject  of  lay  taxation,  the  Saxon 
laws  are  replete  with  the  most  elaborate  direc- 
tions for  the  payment  of  ecclesiastical  dues. 
"We  enjoin  to  every  Christian  man  bj  virtue 
of  his  Christendom,"  is  the  refrain  of  these 
laws,  "that  he  pay  tithe  and  church-scot  and 
Rome-scot,  and  plough-alms,  and  light-scot 
and  soul-scot."  These  injunctions  are  found 
equally  in  secular  and  ecclesiastical  dooms,  and 
they  take  the  place  of  honour  in  the  proceed- 
ings of  great  councils  like  that  of  Greatanlea. 
Under  the  later  Saxon  kings  the  injunction  of 
the  pious  sovereign  becomes  far  more  stringent 
until  it  is  stereotyped  in  the  precise  legal  defini- 
tions given  in  the  Latinised  version  of  the  12th 
century  jurists,  so  that  at  length  in  the  "  laws 
of  Henry  I."  we  find  tithe  and  church-scot  and 
other  dues  embraced  under  the  general  heading 
De  placitis  Ecclesix  pertinentibus  ad  Begem. 

It  is  true  that  in  Anglo-Saxon  times  the  dues 
of  the  church  were  put  in  charge  for  the  crown 
by  means  of  a  heavy  fine  for  non-compliance  or 
even  by  absolute  distraint  in  which  the  king's 
reeve  was  required  to  assist  the  bishop's  officer 
and  the  local  incumbent ;  and  we  also  find  the 
doctrine  prevailing  that  if  the  occupier  were  too 
poor  to  pay,  the  lord  should  pay  for  him. 

It  is  possible  that  the  rigour  of  this  system 
of  assessment  and  collection  of  church  dues 
was  somewhat  mitigated  by  the  reflection  that 
these  were  eventually  offerings  made  to  God,  a 
theory  carefully  fostered  both  by  the  crown 
and  the  church,  so  that  the  term  God's  dues 
{godcunde  gerihta  or  Del  rectitudines)  is  actuaUy 
synonymous  with  church-dues  during  the  latter 
part  of  the  Anglo-Saxon  period  at  least,  and 
thus  perhaps  the  sentence  of  excommunication 
decreed  by  King  Edmund's  laws  on  all  defaulters 
was  justified.  On  the  other  hand,  the  refusal 
to  pay  Peter's  pence  was  a  contempt  which  led 
to  the  appearance  of  the  offender  before  the 
court  of  Rome  itself  to  make  atonement.  In 
addition  to  the  above  persistent  injunctions, 
these  early  laws  provided  further  for  the  pay- 
ment of  church  dues  to  be  made  at  fixed  and 
appropriate  seasons.  Thus  tithes  became  due 
always  as  the  plough  entered  the  tenth  field, 
or  more  probably  in  actual  practice,  plough- 
alms  were  rendered  at  Easter,  tithes  of  cattle 
at  Pentecost,  the  fruits  of  the  earth  at  AU- 
hallowtide,  and  church-seed  at  Martinmas  ;  the 
tenth  cheese  as  it  was  made,  or  the  milk  drawn 
on  the  tenth  day.  In  the  same  way  Rome-scot 
was  payable  on  St.  Peter's  feast-day ;  and  light- 
scot  at  Candlemas,  Easter  Eve,  and  All-hallows 
Eye.  Finally,  in  order  to  mark  the  precision 
with  which  these  dispositions  were  made,  we 
find  provision  for  the  payment  of  soul-scot  at 
the  open  grave,  wherever  the  death  might 
take  place. 

The  statistics  available  for  the  purpose  of 
estimating  the  nature  and  extent  of  these  con- 


tributions are  unfortunately  not  nearly  so 
abundant  as  these  details  of  the  means  for  in- 
suring their  payment,  or  at  least  they  are  not 
so  authentic  for  the  earlier  period.  It  may 
easily  be  gathered,  however,  that  the  imit  of 
assessment  was  the  plough  and  the  normal  sum 
assessed  on  every  plough  the  penny.  In  fact 
the  Anglo-Saxon  Scaet  like  the  Anglo-Norman 
Denarius,  was  the  synonym  of  money,  while 
the  medium  of  exchange  in  both  periods  might 
be  equally  treasure  in  kind  or  in  currency. 
Add  to  this  primitive  basis  of  calculation  the 
further  connection  between  the  plough  and  the 
hearth  as  representing  the  stake  of  one  family 
in  the  soil,  and  it  will  be  possible  to  account 
for  nearly  every  ecclesiastical  assessment  that 
fell  upon  the  husbandman  free  or  unfree. 
Moreover,  denarius  might  be,  and  does  indeed 
appear  to  have  been,  used  in  its  original  mean- 
ing of  a  tenth  part  (see  Deniee).  Thus  the 
thane  is  required  to  render  a  tenth  of  aU  that 
he  has ;  a  tithe  which,  reduced  to  terms  of 
money  according  to  the  normal  assessment  of 
the  hide,  would  be  found  equivalent  to  a  tenth 
penny.  The  church -scot  was  originally  a 
measure  of  corn  that  was  probably  equivalent 
to  a  tenth  part  of  the  produce  of  the  normal 
virgate  holding,  and  equally  it  was  assessed 
upon  every  hearthstead  at  which  the  tiller  was 
found  seated  in  the  midwinter  before  it  fell 
due.  So  the  plough-scot  and  Rome-scot  were 
expressed  in  convertible  terms  of  the  hearth, 
the  plough,  or  the  penny.  The  light-scot  was 
always  a  money  payment  of  a  halfpenny  on 
every  hide  of  land  because  candles  were  im- 
ported from  the  continent,  but  if  wax  were  not 
available,  other  produce  of  the  soil  such  as 
cattle  was  certainly  rendered  in  kind,  pecunia 
and  denarius  being  once  more  convertible 
terms. 

Although  no  secular  institution  was  endowed 
with  an  oblatory  revenue  as  ancient  or  as  ex- 
tensive as  that  arising  from  the  dues  of  the 
church,  it  is  perhaps  possible  to  trace  a  certain 
analogy  between  the  ecclesiastical  and  municipal 
corporations  herein.  Pious  sovereigns  who  had 
invested  the  church  by  virtue  of  binding  ordi- 
nances with  the  power  of  levying  dues  upon 
all  products  of  the  soil  within  the  parochial 
*'ministery,"  were  succeeded  in  direct  line  of 
descent  and  policy  by  others  who  invested  the 
towns  one  by  one  with  a  like  implied  privilege 
by  the  terms  of  royal  charters.  The  one  body 
held  by  free  alms,  the  other  by  the  firma 
burgi.  The  latter  stood  in  need  of  contribu- 
tions for  the  repair  of  streets  or  quays  and 
general  administrative  purposes,  the  former 
distrained  upon  its  flock  on  the  plea  that 
churches  must  be  repaired,  the  poor  relieved, 
and  the  clergy  themselves  housed  and  fed. 
Whatever  the  value  of  this  analogy  may  be, 
it  is  certain  that  the  dues  legally  raised  foi 
purposes  of  municipal  self-government,  pontage, 


DUE 


647 


nmrage,  pavage,  quayage,  moreage,  towage, 
terrage,  strandage,  cranage,  mesonage,  anchor- 
age, keelage,  bushelage,  lestage,  ballastage, 
measurage,  average,  primage,  and  the  like  afford 
by  far  the  best-known,  the  most  enduring,  and 
the  most  regular  examples  of  dues.  Indeed  it 
might  be  thought  that  the  still  more  historic 
contributions  known  as  gable  tax,  tallage,  and 
the  like,  would  fall  under  the  head  of  dues  in 
a  system  of  common  assessment  for  self-taxa- 
tion, but  here  as  elsewhere  we  must  sharply 
distinguish  between  rent  and  taxation  on  the 
one  hand,  and  between  imperial  or  parlia- 
mentary taxation  and  customary  dues  on  the 
other. 

This  necessary  distinction  brings  our  inquiry 
within  still  narrower  limits  in  the  case  of  seigno- 
rial  or  manorial  dues,  as  well  as  those  that 
were  levied  by  the  king  as  lord  paramount  of 
the  whole  realm.  Extents,  court  rolls,  and 
ministers'  accounts,  together  with  surveys, 
such  as  Domesday  Book,  the  Boldon  Book, 
and  the  Hundred  Rolls,  present  us  with  an 
infinite  variety  of  payments  in  the  nature  of 
commuted  rents  and  pecuniary  mulcts,  the 
legal  definitions  of  which  are  set  forth  in  the 
various  Bxpositiones  Vocahulorum  appended  to 
most  of  the  fiscal  registers  of  the  13th  and 
14th  centuries,  but  none  of  these  can  properly 
be  regarded  as  dues.  Some  such  there  are, 
however,  but  their  existence  was  from  the  first 
anomalous,  and  they  are  chiefly  remembered 
in  the  present  day  amongst  the  curiosities  of 
manorial  tenures.  In  certain  cases,  however, 
an  inland  town  or  seaport  might  continue  for 
centuries  under  the  jurisdiction  of  a  lord  who 
enjoyed  the  tolls  and  other  dues,  just  as  a  lay- 
man might  appropriate  the  dues  intended  for 
the  support  of  the  church,  and  in  such  cases 
the  seignorial  interest  takes  the  place  of  the 
ecclesiastical  or  municipal  or  fiscal. 

The  dues  or  '*  rights  "  of  the  crown  qud  lord 
paramount  of  the  whole  land  must  be  carefully 
distinguished  from  the  normal  sources  of  im- 
perial revenue  on  the  one  hand  and  from  the 
customary  revenue  by  prerogative  or  grant  of 
parliament  on  the  other  hand.  What  remained 
were  the  seignorial  dues  received  by  the 
sovereign  from  the  manors  and  farms  composing 
his  demesne,  and  from  escheats  and  vacant 
churches,  together  with  certain  other  rights 
appertaining  to  his  kingly  state  alone.  Even  in 
the  most  primitive  state  of  kingship  the  tribal 
ruler  appears  to  have  received  a  contribution 
from  the  products  of  the  soil,  the  tradition  of 
which  still  lingered  in  the  mises  and  prises  of 
the  13  th  century.  That  is  to  say,  the  king 
took  toll  of  certain  staple  products  to  maintain 
the  rude  splendour  which  was  as  essential  to  a 
civil  state  of  society  as  the  ceremonies  and 
"ministery  "  of  the  church.  As  far  as  we  are 
at  present  enabled  to  distinguish  between  a 
recognised  rent  or  custom  and  a  specific  due, 


it  seems  probable  that  the  several  forms  of 
purveyance  were  of  the  latter  nature,  together 
with  those  tolls  or  perquisites  which  are 
peculiar  to  the  fiscal  period  that  precedes  the 
development  of  parliamentary  supply.  Such 
an  assessment  as  the  avalage  is  probably  of 
this  nature  (Madox,  i.  775).  On  the  other 
hand,  many  more,  which  are  popularly  regarded 
as  dues,  are  really  in  the  nature  of  rent,  such 
as  the  firma  unius  nodis  of  Domesday  Book 
and  the  gafol  or  gahlum  (Round,  Domes. 
Studies,  vol.  i.) 

A  considerable  revenue  was  certainly  obtained 
from  the  end  of  the  12th  to  the  close  of  the 
13th  century  by  way  of  dues  upon  merchandise 
at  the  outports  and  inland  barriers,  which  can 
scarcely  be  included  under  the  head  of  customs. 
Thus  in  addition  to  the  general  exactions 
alluded  to  in  several  public  charters,  we  have 
notices  of  a  disme  and  quindisme  levied  as 
early  as  the  reign  of  Richard  I.,  chiefly,  no 
doubt,  upon  foreign  imports  (Pipe  Roll,  10 
Ric.  1  m.  12b).  These  and  other  dues  appear 
to  have  been  more  or  less  consolidated  under 
the  administration  of  the  royal  chamberlains 
at  London  and  Southampton.  The  exactions 
of  the  king's  officers  at  the  Tower  of  London, 
forbidden  in  several  of  the  city  charters,  were 
clearly  of  the  same  nature.  It  is  interesting 
to  note,  moreover,  the  inclusion  of  the  profits 
or  droits  arising  from  the  sale  of  prizes  of  war 
and  contraband  goods  amongst  the  chamber- 
lains' accounts  ;  these,  like  deodands,  forming 
a  link  between  the  casual  and  the  customary 
revenue  of  the  crown. 

With  the  statutory  recognition  and  limitation 
of  the  ancient  dues  of  the  crown  in  respect  of 
the  products  of  the  soil  exported  under  the 
distinctive  term  of  Recta  custuma  and  the 
corresponding  definition  of  the  dues  formerly 
payable  at  discretion  upon  imports,  such  as 
wines  by  the  name  of  Recta  prisa,  their  history 
may  be  said  to  belong  thenceforth  to  that  of 
the  customs  revenue.  Prises  and  mises  are  for 
the  future  associated  with  the  unconstitutional 
abuses  of  purveyance,  together  with  caption  and 
emption,  and  other  relics  of  the  old  tribal  state. 
Certain  other  dues  continued  to  be  levied  in 
the  king's  name,  such  as  the  penny  (denier 
or  devoir  once  more),  by  the  ganger  of  wines 
and  the  aulnager  of  cloths,  and  even  the  Calais 
dues  themselves  (see  Deniers  de  Calais)  ;  but 
these,  like  the  god's-penny,  and  the  cocket,  and 
tronage  dues,  are  properly  to  be  regarded  as 
official  fees  or  perquisites,  outside  the  custom- 
ary revenue  it  is  true,  and  yet  not  included  in 
the  revenue  returns  for  fiscal  purposes.  It 
was  by  such  dues  as  these,  sanctioned  by  the 
authority  of  the  crown,  and  even  put  in  charge 
for  the  crown,  that  the  royal  ministers,  from 
the  smelter  of  the  exchequer  to  the  treasurer  of 
England,  eked  out  their  scanty  fees  in  gremit 
scaccarii  itself.  h.  iia. 


648 


DUE  DATE— DUNCAN 


DUE  DATE  (BiU  of  Exchange).  This  is 
the  date  at  which  the  holder  of  a  bill  of 
exchange  may  claim  payment  from  the  drawee. 
The  following  rules,  as  to  the  way  of  ascertain- 
ing that  date,  are  applicable  in  the  case  of  bills 
payable  within  the  United  Kingdom.  *  A  bUl 
is  payable  on  demand  :  (a)  if  it  is  expressed  to 
be  payable  on  demand,  or  at  sight,  or  on  pre- 
sentation ;  (b)  if  no  time  for  payment  is 
expressed  (Bill  of  Exchange  Act,  §  10).  The 
due  date  of  a  bill,  not  payable  on  demand,  is 
found  by  adding  three  days  (which  are  called 
the  days  of  grace)  to  the  time  of  payment  named 
in  the  bill,  but  this  rule  is  subject  to  the 
following  exceptions  :  (a)  when  the  last  day  of 
grace  is  a  bank  holiday,  or  a  Sunday  immediately 
following  a  bank  holiday,  the  bill  is  payable  on 
the  siuxeeding  business  day  {e.g.  if  a  bill  is  drawn 
payable  on  the  23rd  December  in  a  year  when 
the  26th  of  December  falls  on  a  Saturday,  the 
due  date  would  be  the  28th  December) ;  (b)  when 
the  last  day  of  grace  is  Good  Friday,  Christmas 
Day,  or  a  Sunday  (not  immediately  following  a 
bank  holiday),  the  due  date  falls  on  the  pre- 
ceding business  day  (thus,  in  a  year  in  which 
Christmas  Day  falls  on  a  Friday,  a  bill,  drawn 
payable  on  the  22nd  December  is  due  on  the  24tli, 
whereas  in  the  same  year,  a  bill  drawn  payable 
on  the  23rd,  as  shown  above,  is  due  on  the  28th 
only).  Where  a  bill  is  payable  at  a  fixed  period 
after  sight  the  time  begins  to  run  from  the 
date  of  acceptance,  or  in  the  case  of  an  unac- 
cepted bill  from  the  date  of  noting  or  pro- 
testing (Bill  of  Exchange  Act,  §  14  [3]).  On 
the  continent  a  bill  is  sometimes  stated  to  be 
payable  after  usance  (or  after  two  or  more 
usances),  the  usance  being  either  a  fixed  time, 
or  a  time  varying  according  to  the  distance  of 
the  place  of  issue  from  the  place  of  payment. 
In  France  the  duration  of  a  usance  is  thirty 
days,  the  time  being  computed  from  the  day 
foUoming  the  date  of  the  bill  (Code  de  Com- 
merce, §  132)  ;  the  German  and  Italian  codes 
do  not  recognise  this  mode  of  fixing  the  due 
date.  In  all  continental  countries  a  recognised 
practice  exists  of  making  bills  payable  at  some 
named  fair  or  market  ("Messwechsel "  or 
**  Marktwechsel " — German  Code,  §§  4,  18, 
35;  "payable  en  foire " — French  Code  de 
Commerce,  §§  129  and  133;  "  pagabile  in 
fiera" — Italian  Codice  di  Commercio,  §§  252 
and  286).  If  the  fair  or  market  extends  over 
a  day,  such  bills  are  payable  on  the  day  pre- 
ceding the  last  day  of  the  fair  or  market.  The 
importance  of  those  assemblages  having  much 
decreased  of  late  years,  bills  bearing  such 
indications  are  becoming  scarce.  e.  s. 

DUFAU,  F.  P.,  born  in  1795,  was  the 
director  of  the  Institute  for  the  Blind  in 
Paris,  and  wrote  several  works  on  the  subject 
of  their  proper  treatment.  In  1840  he 
published  a  volume  entitled  TraitS  de  Statis- 
tique   ou   tMorie   de    Vitude   des    lots    d'aprks 


lesquelles  se  d6velopperd  les  fails  soeiaux-,  »uivi 
d'wn  Essai  sur  la  statistique  physique  et  morale 
de  la  population  frav/^aise.  In  the  theoretical 
part  he  does  not  approve  of  the  adoption  of 
coloured  statistical  maps,  as  being  "only  able 
to  convey  vague  and  indistinct  notions  to  the 
mind."  In  the  second  part,  he  intended  to 
apply  the  rules  set  down  by  himself  to  the 
study  of  the  population,  territory,  and  state  in 
France  ;  but  declares  that,  owing  to  the  want 
of  sufficient  materials,  he  has  been  obliged  to 
give  up  the  two  last  divisions  of  his  investiga- 
tions. This  work  received,  in  1841,  a  prize  from 
the  Academy  of  Sciences  in  Paris.  In  1847, 
under  the  title  of  Lettres  d  une  Dame  de  Chariti, 
he  gave  a  complete  description  of  the  institu- 
tions and  associations  for  the  alleviation  of  the 
sufierings  of  the  poor.  E.  Ca. 

DUHAMEL  DU  MONCEAU,  Henri  Louis 
(1700-1781)  was  inspector  general  of  the  navy, 
member  of  several  learned  societies,  and  author 
of  numerous  treatises  on  manufactures,  forestry, 
and  agriculture  ;  the  principal  of  which  are  his 
TraiU  de  la  conservation  des  Grains  (1753)  ; 
^cole  d' Agriculture  (1759)  ;  EUmenis  d' Agri- 
culture (which  went  through  several  editions 
from  1754  to  1779);  and  the  Traite  de  la 
Culture  des  Terres  (1753-1761),  written — at 
least  the  last — to  advocate  in  France  the  methods 
of  cultivation  originated  in  England  by  Jethro 
Tull.  He  is  mentioned  as  a  distinguished  agri- 
culturist by  Voltaire  in  his  Pr4cis  du  Si^cle  de 
Louis  X  V.  (ch.  xliii. )  and  in  his  Lettre  d  l' Homme 
aux  QiMrante  J^cus,  although  in  the  latter  with 
some  mockery  on  the  pecuniary  results  of  his 
experiments.  A.  Young  calls  him  a  "useful 
genius"  (Travels  in  France,  1792,  i.  65). 

In  1764  Duhamel  printed  a  small  pamphlet 
of  only  fifteen  pages  {Mflexions  sur  la  Police 
des  Grains),  in  which  he  asserts  that,  in  order 
to  keep  agriculture  in  a  healthy  condition, 
the  price  of  com  must  not  fall  below  a  price 
sufficient  to  meet  the  necessary  expenses  of  the 
farmer,  nor  be  carried  too  high,  so  as  to  cause 
famines,  which  grind  the  poor  and  the  artisans. 
The  natural  regulations  of  a  good  policy  would 
be  (1)  to  allow  an  entirely  free  inland  trade  of 
corn  ;  (2)  to  suppress  all  tolls  on  the  inland 
carriage  of  corn,  either  by  land  or  by  water ; 
(3)  to  allow  every  citizen  to  store  corn  until  a 
time  of  dearth ;  (4)  to  grant  free  export,  without 
any  privilege  of  person,  when  the  storehouses 
are  fuU  and  the  crops  continue  to  be  abundant. 

Duhamel  ends  by  distinctly  denying  that 
France  ought  to  follow  the  example  of  England, 
there  being  a  great  difference  in  many  respects 
between  the  conditions  of  the  two  countries. 

E.  ca. 

DUMOULIN.     See  Molinaeus. 

DUNCAN,  Henry,  D.D.  (1774-1846),  a 
minister  distinguished  for  his  philanthroi>ic 
labours  and  practical  sagacity,  is  best  renicm- 
bered  as  the  founder  of  savings  banks.     It  is 


DUNCAN 


649 


true  that  he  was  neither  the  fii'st  to  suggest  the 
formation  of  such  banks  nor  the  first  to  estab- 
lish them.  Such  banks  existed  on  the  Con- 
tinent, in  England,  and  even  in  Scotland,  before 
Dr.  Duncan  founded  the  "  parent  institution  " 
at  Ruthwell  in  1810.  But  the  name  of  Dr. 
Duncan  is  as  justly  connected  with  savings 
banks  as  those  of  Cobden  and  Bright  with  Free 
Trade  ;  he  did  for  the  one  movement  what 
they  did  for  the  other. 

The  attention  of  Dr.  Duncan  had  been  early 
drawn  to  the  condition  of  the  poor,  and  he 
thought  and  read  much  on  the  subject.  One 
day  there  came  into  his  hands  a  pamphlet 
bearing  the  title  Tranquillity,  the  author  of 
which,  Mr.  John  Bone,  propounded  a  scheme 
for  the  gradual  abolition  of  poor-rates  in  Eng- 
land. A  subordinate  feature  of  this  scheme 
was  the  ' '  erection  of  an  economical  bank  for 
the  savings  of  the  industrious."  The  sugges- 
tion germinated  rapidly  in  the  mind  of  Dr. 
Duncan.  He  saw  in  it  the  means  of  elevating 
the  condition  of  the  labouring  classes  and  of 
preventing  the  introduction  of  a  compulsory 
poor-rate,  a  measure  which  he  regarded  as 
certain  to  injm-e  the  community.  The  result 
of  his  study  and  elforts  was  the  establishment 
in  his  own  parish  of  a  bank  for  savings,  and  the 
publication  of  its  rules  (Rules  and  Kegulations 
of  the  Parish  Bank  Friendly  Society  of  Ruth- 
well,  instituted  26th  May  1810).  The  rules 
set  forth  clearly  and  plainly  the  nature  and 
advantages  of  the  scheme,  the  system  of 
management,  the  provision  for  deposits  and 
withdi-awals.  The  latter  were  in  certain  de- 
fined cases  subject  to  the  judgment  of  the 
managing  body.  The  experiment  at  Ruthwell, 
though  made  in  a  parish  of  only  1100  people, 
purely  agricultural,  without  resident  heritors, 
and  where  the  majority  of  those  grown  up  were 
already  members  of  friendly  societies,  was  most 
encouraging.  From  the  first  Dr.  Duncan  in- 
tended that  his  scheme  should  be  adopted 
everywhere,  and  by  tongue  and  pen  he  spread 
the  knowledge  of  what  was  being  done  in  his 
parish.  In  1814-15  the  movement  attracted 
a  large  measure  of  public  notice  and  advanced 
rapidly.  The  table  of  Dr.  Duncan  was  heaped 
with  letters  of  inquuy  ;  and  to  save  his  time, 
and  to  promote  the  cause  he  had  at  heart,  he 
published  in  1815  an  Essay  on  the  Nature  and 
Advantages  of  Parish  Banks,  a  greatly  enlarged 
edition  of  which  appeared  in  the  following  year. 
The  essay  is  in  four  sections.  The  first  dis- 
cusses, with  candour  and  breadth  of  mind,  the 
objects  and  principles  of  savings  banks  ;  the 
second  relates  their  history  so  far  as  known  to 
the  author,  who  speaks  of  his  own  labours  with 
singular  modesty  ;  the  third  advocates  co- 
operation between  savings  banks  and  friendly 
societies ;  the  fourth,  consisting  of  miscellaneous 
remarks,  deals  vigorously  with  the  morality  of 
saving   and  the  question  of  a  poor-law.      In 


1817  Dr.  Duncan  was  forced  to  take  the  field 
against  Mr.  J.  H.  Forbes,  the  future  judge 
Lord  Medwyn,  who  had  denied  that  the  Ruth- 
well  bank  was  the  "  parent  institution,"  claim- 
ing that  distinction  for  Edinburgh,  and  who 
had  exalted  the  management  of  the  Edinburgh 
bank  at  the  expense  of  that  of  Ruthwell.  He 
showed  without  passion,  and  with  dignity  and 
courtesy,  that  both  these  assertions  were  er- 
roneous {Letter  to  J.  H.  Forbes,  Esq.).  This 
same  year  a  measure  was  framed  by  Mr.  Rose 
in  the  interests  of  savings  banks,  but  its  pro- 
visions, while  highly  beneficial  to  depositors  in 
England  and  Ireland,  were  disadvantageous  to 
those  in  Scotland.  Dr.  Duncan  convinced  Mr. 
Rose  that  this  was  the  case,  and  Scotland  was 
not  included  within  the  scope  of  the  act.  Two 
years  later,  a  bill  adapted  to  the  peculiar  circum- 
stances of  Scotland,  drafted  by  Dr.  Duncan, 
and  expounded  and  defended  by  him  in  Scot- 
land and  London,  passed  both  Houses.  The 
vindication  of  the  measure  is  contained  in  his 
Letter  to  W.  R.  K.  Douglas,  Esq.,  M.P.,  on 
the  expediency  of  the  Bill  brought  by  Mm  into 
Parliament  for  the  protection  and  encourage- 
ment of  Savings  Banks  in  Scotland.  A  Letter 
to  Managers  of  Banks  far  Saving  in  Scotland, 
1819,  informed  them  of  the  steps  they  needed 
to  take  in  order  to  take  advantage  of  the  act. 
In  1824  the  Scotch  banks  were  forced  to  reduce 
the  interest  of  5  per  cent  which  they  had 
hitherto  allowed  on  deposits  from  savii)gs  banks, 
and  Dr.  Duncan  sought  to  procure  for  the 
savings  banks  of  Scotland  the  right  to  purchase, 
if  they  saw  fit,  those  government  debentures 
the  acquisition  of  which  was  made  compulsory, 
by  the  act  of  1817,  on  savings  banks  in  England 
and  Ireland.  But  the  treasury  refused  to 
treat  Scotland  exceptionally.  In  1835  a 
measure  was  passed,  with  Dr.  Duncan's  hearty 
approval,  making,  the  regulations  for  savings 
banks  uniform  in  the  three  kingdoms,  but 
at  the  same  time  conceding  to  Scotch  banks 
established  before  the  date  of  the  act  the 
privilege  which  Dr.  Duncan  had  advocated  in 
1824. 

It  should  be  added  that  Dr.  Duncan  was  a 
free  trader,  and  that  he  published  in  1820  a 
letter  to  Mr.  Douglas,  M.P.,  in  which  he  con- 
tended for  the  abolition  of  all  commercial 
restrictions.-  In  1830  he  published  Presbyters 
Letters  on  the  West  Indian  question,  in  which, 
with  his  usual  sobriety  of  statement  and  calm- 
ness of  judgment,  he  argued  against  immediate 
and  unconditional  emancipation,  and  in  favour 
of  emancipation  at  a  fixed  but  not  distant  date — 
substantially  the  policy  which  three  years  later 
was  adopted  by  parliament. 
,  [Besides  the  pamphlets  cited,  see  Memoirs  of  the 
Rev.  Henry  Duncan,  D.D.,  by  the  Kev.  G.  J.  C. 
Duncan  (Edinburgh,  Wm.  Oliphant  and  Son, 
1848),  and  the  article  by  Prof.  Blaikie  in  the  Diet 
of  Nat.  Biog.]  .  w.  p. 


650 


DUNCAN— DUNOYER 


DUNCAN,  John,  according  to  M'CuUoch 
(Literature  of  Political  Economy,  1845,  p.  286) 
was  the  author  of  the  following  work,  directed 
partly  against  indiscriminate  almsgiving : — 

Collections  relative  to  systematic  relief  of  the  Poor 
cU,  different  Periods  and  in  different  Countriis :  with 
observations  on  Charity,  its  proper  objects  and  its 
influence  on  the  welfare  of  Nations,  Bath,  1815, 
8vo.  H-  R-  T. 

DUNCAN,  Jonathan  (1799-1865)  son  of 
Jonathan  Duncan,  governor  of  Bombay,  was 
born  there,  and  died  in  London.  He  took  his 
B.A.  degree  at  Cambridge  in  1821  and  lived 
for  some  time  in  the  Channel  Islands.  He 
edited  the  Guernsey  and  Jersey  Magazine 
(1836-37)  and  published  several  historical 
works,  original  and  translated.  After  1841  he 
lived  chiefly  in  London  and  devoted  himself  to 
currency  reform,  on  which  subject  he  wrote  : 

How  to  reconcile  the  rights  of  Property,  Capital, 
and  Labour — Tract  I.  of  the  Currency  Reform 
Association,  London,  1846,  8vo  (all  published; 
"money  need  not,  and  indeed  ought  not,  to 
possess  any  intrinsic  value "  (p.  6),  "  value  .  .  . 
is  labour  condensed"  (p.  10)). — The  National 
Anti-Gold  Law  League;  the  principles  of  the 
League  explained  versits  Sir  R.  Peel's  currency 
measures,  and  the  partial  remedy  advocated  by  the 
Scottish  Banks,  London,  1847,  8vo. — Letters  on 
Monetary  Science;  by  Aladdin,  London,  1848, 
8vo  (contributions  signed  by  this  pseudonym  to 
Jerrold's  Weekly  News,  written  "to  emancipate 
the  human  mind  from  the  gross  errors  of  bullionism 
and  the  servile  idolatry  of  a  comparatively  useless 
metal "). — The  Principles  of  Money  demonstrated, 
and  bullionist  fallacies  refuted,  London,  1849, 
sra.  8vo,  —  The  Journal  of  Industry,  30th 
November  1850  to  15th  March  1851,  small  folio 
(only  sixteen  numbers  published  ;  chiefly  devoted 
to  currency). — TJie  Bank  Charter  Ad  ;  ought  the 
Bank  of  England  or  the  People  of  England  to 
receive  the  profts  of  the  national  circulation,  2nd 
ed.,  London,  1858,  8vo. 

[Did.  of  Nat.  Biography,  xvi.  170,  171.] 

H.  B.  T. 

DUNDAS,  Henry  (1742-1811),  first  Vis- 
count Melville,  successively  solicitor-general  and 
lord  advocate  of  Scotland,  and  thereafter  a 
prominent  member  in  difierent  offices  in  several 
administrations,  honoured  with  the  friendship 
of  Pitt,  and  for  many  years  the  dictator  of  Scot- 
land, was  regarded  during  his  lifetime  as  a 
high  authority  on  questions  of  trade  and  com- 
merce, more  especially  in  connection  with  the 
East  Indies.  From  the  formation  of  the  board 
of  control,  he  was  in  fact,  though  not  in  name, 
the  minister  for  India.  In  1793  he  moved 
the  renewal  of  the  monopoly  granted  to  the 
company.  The  speech  he  delivered  on  this 
occasion  was  afterwards  published,  having  as  a 
preface  the  eulogy  pronounced  on  it  by  Pitt  in 
the  course  of  the  subsequent  debate  {Substance 
of  the  Speech  of  the  Bight  Hon.  Henry  Dundas, 
on  the  British  Government  and  Trade  in  the 
East  Indies,  23rd  April  1793,  London,  181$). 


From  an  economical  point  of  view  the  most 
important  statement  in  the  speech  is  the  declara- 
tion that  the  existing  arrangement  in  India 
was  "in  opposition  to  established  theories  in 
goveminent  and  commerce."  The  experience 
of  nine  years  had  however  justified  the  system. 
The  same  views  are  expressed  in  his  Letters  upon 
an  Open  Trade  to  India  (London  1813).  He 
contends  that  the  question  cannot  be  treated 
as  a  purely  commercial  one  and  strenuously 
asserts  that  the  trade  to  India  should  not  be 
open. 

[Stanhope's  Life  of  Pitt. — Omand's  Lord  Advo- 
cates of  Scotland,  ii. — articles  in  Diet,  of  Nat. 
Biog.  and  Ency.  Brit]  w.  p. 

DUNNING,  Richard  (fl.  1685-1698),  pub- 
lished A  Plain  and  Easy  Method,  showing 
how  the  office  of  overseer  of  tJie  poor  may  be 
managed,  whereby  it  may  be  £9000  per  annum 
advantage  to  the  couniy  of  Devon,  withovi  abat- 
ing the  weekly  relief  of  any  Poor  (1685)  ;  and 
Bread  for  the  Poor,  by  R.  D.  (1698).  He 
defended  the  old  poor  law  (43  Eliz.  c.  2), 
which  he  maintained  was  sufficient  to  reduce 
poverty,  and  suggested  various  methods  for  its 
better  administration.  The  chief  value  of 
Dunning's  pamphlets  consists  in  the  informa- 
tion they  contain  relative  to  the  condition  of 
the  labouring  classes  in  Devonshire  at  the  end 
of  the  17  th  century. 

[Eden's  State  of  the  Pocrr  (1797),  i.  225,  248- 
252.]  w.  A.  s.  H. 

DUNOYER,  Charles  (1786-1862),  bom  at 
Carennac  (Lot),  died  at  Paris.  He  studied 
law  at  Paris  ;  then  assisted  in  preparing  the 
Becueil  de  jurisprudence  of  Sirey.  He  wel- 
comed the  fall  of  the  empire,  though  he  only 
accepted  the  legitimist  monarchy  so  far  as  it 
respected  the  liberty  of  the  people.  In  con- 
junction with  Charles  Comte  he  established, 
12th  June  1814,  the  journal  entitled  Le  Censeur, 
but  the  Terreur  blanche  compelled  them  to 
discontinue  the  publication  of  this  paper  in 
1816.  They  resumed  it  eighteen  months  later, 
but  modified  its  title  to  Le  Censeur  Europeen. 
The  increasing  severity  of  the  press  laws,  how- 
ever, seriously  hampered  them,  and,  finally, 
the  assassination  of  the  Duke  of  Berry,  13th 
February  1820,  and  consequent  troubles  led  to 
the  entire  suspension  of  the  paper.  After  this 
Comte  and  Dunoyer,  notwithstanding  the 
similarity  of  their  political  and  economic 
opinions,  were  compelled  to  separate — the 
former  went  to  Switzerland,  while  Dunoyer 
devoted  himself  exclusively  to  economics.  He 
gave  at  Paris  in  the  Athenaeum  Institution  a 
course  of  lectures  on  political  economy  and  moral 
science,  which  were  afterwards  published  in  a 
volume  bearing  the  title  of  L'industrie  et  la 
'morale  considirdes  dans  leurs  rapports  avec  la 
liberty,  in  8vo,  1825. 

When  the  Ordonnances  of  the  26th  July  1830 


DUODECIMAL  SYSTEM— DUPIN 


651 


appeared,  Dunoyer  protested  in  writing  against 
this  breach  of  the  charter  of  1814.  After  this, 
despairing  of  the  elder  branch  of  the  Bourbon 
family,  he  turned  to  Louis  Philippe,  whose 
accession  to  power  he  welcomed  with  enthusi- 
asm. Appointed,  shortly  after  the  **  three 
days,"  prefect  of  the  department  of  the  AUier, 
he  was  transferred  in  1832  to  the  prefecture 
of  the  Somme  ;  this  he  quitted  in  1838  to 
enter  the  council  of  state.  This  last  post  was 
better  suited  to  his  disposition,  wliich,  though 
calm,  was  full  of  energy,  and  ill- adapted  to 
the  compromises  and  the  half-measures  which 
necessity  requires  of  practical  politicians. 

In  1830  he  reprinted  his  volume  of  1825 
with  many  additions,  under  the  title  of 
Nouveau  traiU  cC6conoime  sociale,  etc.,  2  vols., 
1830,  in  Svo ;  but  just  before  the  second 
volume  was  put  into  circulation  a  fire,  in 
1835,  consumed  nearly  all  the  copies.  Ex- 
tending the  scope  of  his  work,  Dunoyer 
republished  it  in  1845  under  the  title  De  la 
liberty  du  travail  ou  simple  exposd  cles  conditions 
dans  lesquelles  les  forces  humaines  s'exercent 
avec  leplus  de  puissance,  3  vols,  in  8vo.  Besides 
being  the  author  of  this  masterly  work,  Dunoyer 
was  a  contributor  successively  to  the  Revue 
Encyclopidique,  the  Revuefraru^aise,  the  Journal 
des  debats,  and  the  Journal  dcs  economistes.  The 
revolution  of  1848  was  a  heavy  blow  to  him, 
royalist  and  liberal  as  he  was  in  his  political  con- 
victions ;  he  remained,  however,  on  the  council 
of  state,  and  only  relinquished  his  seat  there 
after  the  coup  d'etat  of  1851.  Bitterly  hostile 
to  the  second  empire,  as  lie  had  been  to  the 
first,  he  wrote  a  work  directed  against  the  new 
order  of  affairs.  This  book,  which  was  pub- 
lished after  his  death,  and  then  only  at 
Brussels,  is  entitled  Le  second  empire  et  une 
nouvelle  restauration,  2  vols.,  1865,  in  8vo. 
He  was  elected,  in  1832,  a  member  of  the 
Institute  (Academie  des  Sciences  morales  et  poli- 
tiques),  and  in  1845  president  of  the  society  of 
political  economy.  His  miscellaneous  works 
{Notices  d'economie  sociale),  and  the  second 
edition  of  his  book  La  Liberie  du  travail,  were 
published,  both  at  the  same  time,  in  1886  (3 
vols,  in  8vo),  through  the  filial  care  of  his  son 
Anatole  Dunoyer. 

Dunoyer  was  one  of  the  great  economists  of 
the  19th  century.  He  wrote  with  much  force 
in  support  of  the  theory  of  "immaterial 
wealth,"  even  going  so  far  as  to  say  that,  from 
the  economic  point  of  view,  no  "  wealth  "  could 
be  other  than  "immaterial."  He  was  a  warm 
supporter  of  the  theories  of  Malthus  on  popula- 
tion ;  but  he  was  no  believer  in  the  theory  of 
rent,  considering  that  there  was  only  one  factor 
in  production,  i.e.  labour.  Firm  and  elevated 
in  character,  rigid  in  life  and  thought,  even 
more  severe  towards  himself  than  towards 
others,  Dunoyer  was  one  of  those  men  whose 
career  affords  one  of  the  highest  examples.     He 


died  in  the  enjoyment  of  that  esteem  which  hia 
frank  and  loyal  conduct  won  for  him  in  every 
public  position  that  he  had  occupied. 

A.  c.  f. 

DUODECIMAL  SYSTEM.  The  following 
remarks  under  this  rubric  are  given  simply 
because,  as  we  have  devoted  considerable  room 
to  the  subject  of  the  decimal  system,  it  might 
be  supposed  that  we  had  not  fairly  considered 
the  relative  merits  of  an  alternative,  or,  as 
some  may  imagine,  a  superior  system.  But 
the  fact  is  that  there  never  has  been,  and 
undoubtedly  never  will  be,  any  true  duodecimal 
system  in  use  by  mankind  in  notation,  calcula- 
tion, weights,  measures,  or  coin.  The  funda- 
mental reason  for  this  is  that  whilst  the  number 
of  digits  in  the  universally-accepted  decimal 
system  corresponds  with  the  natural  number  of 
fingers  on  the  hand,  or  with  what  may  be 
called  the  digital  system,  whereby  all  savage 
races,  and  even  cultivated  man,  assist  their 
arithmetic,  this  cannot  be  in  a  notation  by 
twelves.  The  latter  would  require  fresh  addi- 
tional integers  beyond  the  nine  in  use.  Enor- 
mous, almost  insuperable,  diflficulties  would  be 
involved  in  this.  It  is  true  that  a  dozen,  like 
a  score,  has  always  been  a  favourite  group  of 
numbers.  But  this  has  had  no  real  effect  on 
the  more  effective  arrangement  for  large  as  well 
as  small  numbers  into  decimal  groups  of  10, 
100,  1000,  and  so  on,  in  preference  to  12,  144, 
1728,  and  so  on.  Even  as  regards  money, 
although  it  is  correct  to  say,  as  pointed  out  in 
the  article  Decimal  System,  that  all  European 
nations  once  had  a  system  of  account,  but  not 
all  of  them  of  coinage,  divided  into  twentieths 
of  the  pound  or  livre,  and  into  twelfths  of  the 
shilling  or  sol,  they  have  all,  except  England, 
deliberately  discarded  the  duodecimal  as  well 
as  the  vigesimal  part  of  this  arrangement,  so  as 
to  gain  the  superior  advantages  of  the  decimal 
subdivision.  The  division  of  the  year  into  12 
months,  the  foot  into  12  inches,  and  the  now 
almost  obsolete  English  apothecaries'  pound 
into  12  ounces,  are  practically  the  sole  remain- 
ing relics  of  the  system.  F.  H. 

DUPIN",  Baron  Charles  (1784-1873),  born 
at  Varzy  (Nievre),  died  at  Paris.  He  came 
out  in  1803  with  distinction  from  the  Poly- 
technic school,  after  having  been  at  the  head 
of  the  list  iji  the  entrance  examination.  Louis 
XYIII.  created  him  a  baron  (1824),  Louis 
Philippe,  a  peer  of  France  (1837) ;  he  was 
appointed  a  representative  of  the  people  after 
the  revolution  of  1848,  and  Napoleon  III. 
made  him  a  senator.  "The  changes,"  he  said 
satirically,  "are  not  in  myself,  but  in  the 
powers  that  be  ! "  Dupin,  who  was  endowed 
with  much  ability,  devoted  his  life  to  the 
extension  of  technical  teaching  in  France.  It 
was  he  who  suggested  that  map  of  France  in 
two  colours  (black  and  white)  which  shows  by 
gi-aduated  shades  the  degree  to  which  primary 


652 


DUPIN— DUPONT 


instraction  has  been  carried  in  every  depart- 
ment. This  most  useful  statistical  method, 
though  now  familiar,  was,  in  1827,  quite  a 
novelty.  Of  his  writings  as  an  economist  wo 
may  mention  Le  petit  producteur  fran^ais,  Paris, 
1827,  7  vols,  in  8vo. 

In  a  familiar  yet  witty  style  this  little  book 
describes,  in  the  form  of  a  dialogue,  the  strictly 
regulated  system  existing  in  France  before 
1789,  and  the  commercial  and  industrial 
liberty  which  the  majority  of  modem  econ- 
omists desire  to  see  realised.  The  names  of 
the  two  personages,  the  old  "Prohibant"  and 
the  young  "Lefranc,"  show  clearly  enough  the 
side  to  which  Dupin  inclined  then.  Afterwards 
he  became  one  of  the  pillars  of  the  protectionist 
system.  This  time  it  was  not  the  "powers 
that  be  "  who  had  changed. 

[See  French  Diet,  de  I'J^c.  politique.  — His  work 
The  Commercial  Poioer  of  Great  Britain,  exhibiting 
a  complete  View  of  the  Public  Works  of  this  Country, 
with  atlas  and  plans,  was  translated  from  the 
French,  2  vols.  (Knight),  1825.]  a.  o.f. 

DUPIlsr,  Claude,  bom  towards  the  end 
of  the  17th  century,  died  in  1769  ;  he  was  the 
grandfather  of  Madame  Georges  Sand,  TiAe 
Am-ore  Dupin.  First  an  officer  in  the  French 
army,  he  became  aftei-wards  a  fermier  gindral. 
In  1745  he  printed  anonymously  his  Oecono- 
miques  (Carlsruhe,  3  vols.),  but  the  name  of 
the  place  (Carlsruhe)  appears  to  have  been  used 
to  deceive  the  police.  Notwithstanding  these 
l>recautions,  Dupin  found  it  advisable  to  with- 
draw from  circulation  all  the  copies  he  could 
coUect,  and  very  few  are  known  to  exist  in 
our  days.  The  chapter  entitled  Mimoire  sur 
les  Bleds  was  published  separately  in  1748, 
and  reprinted  in  the  Journal  J^conomique 
(February  and  March  1760).  Dupin  appears 
to  be  entitled  to  the  honour  of  having  been  the 
first  in  France  to  advocate  a  more  liberal  policy 
conceming  the  corn  trade,  as  Herbert's  essay 
was  only  published  in  1755.  "When  corn  is 
dear,"  he  says,  "money  is  lavished  to  import 
it  from  foreign  countries.  Is  it  not  a  mistake 
not  to  be  forgiven,  to  prevent  its  export  when 
its  price  is  gone  down  to  nothing  (vol.  i.  p.  205). 
...  If  the  trade  in  com  were  constantly  free, 
com  would  never  be  wanting  (vol.  i.  p.  208)." 
However,  he  does  not  push  his  deductions  from 
this  principle  to  their  legitimate  conclusion, 
for  in  his  proposed  legislation  on  this  subject, 
although  he  recommends  a  free  inland  trade, 
he  shackles  it  with  numerous  formalities,  and 
as  for  foreign  trade,  he  only  allows  com  to  be 
exported  when  the  price  is  lower  than  12  livrcs 
per  sack  ;  from  12  to  18  livres,  com  may  be 
imported  against  payment  of  a  duty  of  3  Hvres 
per  Paris  setter;  from  18  to  24  livres,  the 
duty  is  to  be  only  of  5  sous  per  sack.  At  24 
livres  a  bounty  of  2  livres  is  to  be  granted  on 
imports. 

Some  terse  and  pregnant  remarks  may  also 


be  gathered  mostly  from  the  rest  of  the  first 
volume,  for  instance  this  one  (p.  115),  "  Money 
ought  to  be  considered  like  any  other  com- 
modity and  never  restrained  in  its  natural 
course"  ;  but  such  enlightened  opinions  are 
not  followed  to  their  ultimate  conclusion. 
"Never  has  money  been  drawn  from  a  state 
without  its  being  provided  with  the  same 
value  of  goods  or  produce,  and  we  must  suppose 
that  these  goods  were  useful  to  the  buyer,  for 
the  simple  reason  that  he  has  bought  them" 
(Oec.  vol.  i.  p.  114).  "Money,  which  flows  out 
of  a  state,  calls  other  money  in  ;  the  money 
that  comes  in  calls  other  money  out.  This 
is  the  mechanism  of  trade  ;  to  oppose  it  is  to 
ignore  and  to  destroy  the  principles  of  trade. 
...  It  is  the  interest  of  a  state  to  have  rich 
neighbours  ;  if  they  are  poor,  they  will,  not 
come  to  buy  our  superfluous  goods.  A  shop- 
keeper sells  nothing  in  a  place  peopled  with 
beggars.  .  .  .  It  is  an  absolute  mistake  to 
think  that  we  can  dispense  with  our  neighbours, 
and  that  they  cannot  go  on  without  us  ;  the 
richer  our  climate,  the  more  we  need  them  to 
consume  our  excess  of  riches.  If  heaven  has  not 
granted  us  certain  goods,  or  if  the  disorder  of 
the  seasons  deprives  us  of  our  usual  produce, 
these  same  neighbours  will  come  to  our  help  " 
(p.  115). 

Besides  this  work  Dupin  wrote,  also  anony- 
mously, and  with  the  assistance  of  two  Jesuit 
fathers,  some  very  bitter  R6flexion^  sur  quelques 
parties  d'un  livre  intituU  VEsprit  des  Lois 
(1749),  but  Madame  de  Pompadour  interfered, 
and  almost  the  whole  edition  was  suppressed 
by  the  author.  In  1759,  Dupin  criticised 
Montesquieu's  views  on  trade,  finance,  and 
the  influence  of  climate  under  the  title  of 
Observations  sur  wn,  livre  irditule  VEsprit 
des  Lois,  but  in  a  more  temperate  style,  and 
without  any  indication  of  author,  date,  or 
place. 

For  a  very  Retailed  account  of  the  printing  and 
suppression  of  Dupin's  books,  see  Du  Plessis' 
notice  on  01.  Dupin  in  the  Bulletin  du  Biblio- 
phile, Paris,  1859,  p.  309.  e.  Ca. 

DUPONT  (or,  as  he  himself  wrote,  Du 
Pont),  Pieere  Samuel  (1739-1817),  received 
the  addition  of  de  Nemours  to  his  surname 
from  the  place  which  he  represented  at  the 
constituent  assembly,  in  order  to  distinguish  him 
from  another  Dupont  in  the  same  assembly,  and 
was  one  of  the  greatest  of  the  "men  of  great 
learning  and  ingenuity  in  France  "  (Adam  Smith) 
who  were  called  "economists."  Born  at  Paris, 
Du  Pont  early  ranged  himself  on  the  side  of 
the  Physiocrats  (q.v.)  His  first  work  (1763) 
attracted  the  friendship  of  Quesnay  and  other 
leaders.  The  most  valuable  of  their  doctrines, 
free  trade,  was  ably  advocated  by  him  in  his 
Exportation  et  importation  de  grains,  1764. 
If  Quesnay  was  the  father  of  physiocracy, 
Dupont  was  its  godfather,  for  he  gave  it  its 


DUPONT— DUPONT-WHITE 


653 


name  by  the  publication  of  bis  Fhysiocratie, 
1767  ;  a  collection  of  Quesnay's  articles,  which 
the  editor  introduced  by  a  Discours  (see  Daire's 
Physiocrates,  part  L  tome  ii.  p.  19).  To  the  same 
period  belongs  his  Origine  et  Progres  d'une 
SdeTice  TwuvelU  (see  Daire,  Ihid.  tome  ii.  p. 
335),  based  upon  that  "little  book  written 
by  Mr.  Mercier  de  la  Riviere,"  which  Adam 
Smith  calls  "the  most  distinct  and  best  con- 
nected account  of  this  doctrine"  {IV.  of  iV., 
bk.  iv.  ch.  ix.).  Many  other  expositions  of 
physiocratic  doctrine  were  contributed  by 
Dupont  to  the  Journal  de  V Agriculture  .  .  . 
and  the  E'phtmeHdes  (q.v.),  which  he  success- 
ively edited  (1765-1772).  He  was  aided  in 
his  editorial  work  by  the  pen  and  advice  of 
Turgot.  Almost  the  only  cloud  in  the  friend- 
ship between  the  two  publicists  arose  when 
Dupont,  with  the  usual  indiscretion  of  editors, 
ventured  to  "touch  up"  the  now  celebrated 
"Reflexions  sur  .  .  .  la  richesse,"  contributed 
by  Turgot  to  the  Ephem6rides.  When  Turgot 
became  minister  he  did  not  forget  his  friend. 
Dupont  was  appointed  to  an  important  and 
confidential  post ;  which  he  forfeited  on  the 
fall  of  Turgot,  but  was  afterwards  employed 
under  Vergennes,  in  an  office  not  altogether 
congenial  to  a  great  opponent  of  the  commer- 
cial system,  the  "bureau  de  la  balance  du 
commerce."  The  practical  ability  of  Dupont 
w^as  displayed  in  the  negotiation  of  the  treaty 
which  secured  the  independence  of  America 
(1783),  and  the  treaty  of  commerce  with 
England  (1786).  In  the  constituent  assembly 
Dupont  de  Nemours  played  a  considerable 
[»art.  He  was  president  for  some  time.  His 
eloquent  voice  was  often  heard  on  the  side  of 
sound  theory  and  good  sense.  His  protests 
against  the  creation  and  increase  of  the  issue 
of  assignats  were  founded  upon  the  justest 
reasoning.  Siding  with  the  king  at  the  emeute 
of  10th  August  1792,  Dupont  fell  under  the 
ban  of  the  extreme  party.  While  hiding  from 
their  pursuit,  he  wrote,  during  this  period  of 
enforced  leisure,  his  optimistic  PhilosopMe  de 
Vunivers.  Discovered  at  length  and  dragged 
to  prison,  Dupont  would  infallibly  have  been 
guillotined,  but  for  the  timely  fall  of  Robes- 
pierre. Under  the  directory  Dupont  obtained 
the  influence  due  to  his  financial  ability  ;  but  on 
the  revolution  of  the  18th  Fructidor  he  aban- 
doned politics  and  retired  to  America.  He 
resided  in  France  during  the  empire,  devoted 
to  literary  pursuits.  It  was  during  this  period 
that  he  edited  the  works  of  Turgot  (1809), 
which  he  enriched  with  interesting  notes. 
Dupont  took  office  under  Louis  XVIII.  in 
1814,  but  on  the  return  of  Napoleon  once 
more  retired  to  America,  where  he  died  in 
1817. 

It  is  impossible  in  a  curt  abstract  to  convey 

kan  adequate  impression  of  the  exuberant  genius 
which,  during  more  than  half  a  century,  con- 


tinned  to  pour  forth  eloquent  discussions  on 
varieties  of  subjects  ranging  from  the  "philo- 
sophy of  the  universe  "  to  the  habits  of  insects. 
If  in  political  economy  Dupont  made  no  great 
advance  ;  if,  contrary  to  the  advice  of  Turgot, 
he  turned  in  one  circle,  confined  to  a  narrow 
sect  ;  he  at  least  purified  and  embellished  the 
doctrines  of  that  sect.  He  empliasised  what 
was  best  in  its  teaching,  the  principle  of  laissez- 
faire.  With  potent  voice  he  bade  trade, 
Lazarus-like,  be  loosed  ;  "Otez-lui  ses  liens  et 
laissez-le  aller."  The  magic  of  his  eloquence 
was  enhanced  by  the  influence  of  a  character 
noble  and  disinterested.  He  lived  up  to  his 
motto  :  aimer  et  connaitre.  The  breadth  of 
his  public  spirit  corrected  the  narrowness  of 
his  theory  (see  EphemiiIRIDEs). 

[A  full  account  of  Dupont's  economical  career  is 
given  in  Schelle's  Du  Pont  de  Nemours  et  Vecole 
Physiocratique,  18S8.  Among  earlier  authorities 
may  be  mentioned  Daire  ;  who,  in  the  first  part 
of  his  Physiocrates,  tome  ii.  p.  307,  gives  an  outline 
of  Dupont's  life  and  a  selection  from  his  writings. 
Other  authorities  are  referred  to  by  Schelle,  wh(r 
also  gives  a  list  of  Dupont's  writings,  occupying 
forty  8vo  pages.  The  principal  of  these  works 
have  been  mentioned  above.  Some  more  detailed 
references  to  the  EpMmerides  may  here  be  added. 
The  "impot  direct  et  unique"  of  physiocratic 
theory  is  discussed  by  Dupont  in  Ephemerides, 

1770,  torn.  V.  {Principes  des  Finances)  ;  the 
"liberty  of  commerce"  Ibid.  (1770,  vol.  vi.  ;  ei 
passim),  the  wastefulness  of  slave -labour  {Ibid. 

1771,  vol.  vi.)  The  Fragments  in  EpMvi.,  1771, 
vol.  vii.,  contain  some  striking  reflections  on  the 
theory  of  population,  a  subject  which  was  resumed 
by  Dupont  in  his  last  work,  and  according  to 
Schelle  one  of  his  best,  Examen  du  livre  de  M. 
Malthus,  1817.  See  also  Briejlicher  Verkehr  Carl 
Friedriclis  von  Baden  mit  Miraheau  und  Du  Pont, 
2  vols.,  Heidelberg,  1892.]  F.  Y.  E. 

DUPONT-WHITE,  Charles  (1807-1878), 
born  at  Rouen.  After  having  practised  as 
a  barrister  at  the  court  of  cassation  from 
1831  to  1843,  he  became,  in  1848,  general 
secretary  at  the  ministry  of  justice.  Distin- 
guished by  the  elegance  of  his  style,  he  was  a 
sound  economist  and  a  resolute  thinker,  but 
too  ardent  a  champion  of  centralisation  and 
the  extension  of  governmental  authority.  His 
earliest  work,  entitled  Essai  sur  les  relations  du 
travail  avec  le  capital,  1  vol.  in  8vo,  1846, 
shows  that  the  bent  of  his  mind  was  adverse  to 
liberty.  In  that  volume  he  vigorously  opposes 
the  maxim  of  Gournay,  laissezfaire,  laissez- 
passer.  Of  his  other  publications,  the  best 
known  are  :  De  la  suppression  de  I'impdt  du  sel 
et  de  r octroi,  br.  in  8vo,  1847  (he  would  gladly 
have  substituted  for  these,  taxes  on  landed 
property  and  capital),  L'individu  et  Vdat,  1 
vol.  in  8vo,  1856,  and  La  Centralisation  (a 
sequel  to  the  last  mentioned),  1  vol.  in  8vo, 
1860.  His  other  works  are  principally  poli- 
tical.     He  also  tianslated  the  works  of  Jolin 


654 


DUPRE  DE  SAINT-MAUR— DUPUIT 


Stuart    Mill    on    Liberty    and    Eepresentative 
Government.  A.  c.  f. 

DUPRE  DE  SAINT-MAUR,  Nicolas  Fran- 
cois, born  at  Paris  about  1695,  died  1774. 
He  is  better  known  in  the  present  time  by  his 
works  on  money  than  by  his  translation  of 
Milton's  Paradise  Lost  (Paris,  1729,  3  vols,  in 
8vo),  which  nevertheless  secured  his  admis- 
sion into  the  French  academy  in  1733.  His 
economic  writings  mentioned  below  are  now 
necessarily  out  of  date,  and  their  places  taken 
by  more  recent  works  on  the  same  subject. 
They  may  still,  however,  be  consulted  with 
advantage. 

Essai  sur  les  monnaies  ou  reflexions  sur  le  rap- 
port entre  V argent  et  les  denrees,  1  vol.  in  4to,  1746, 
and  Recherches  sur  la  valeur  des  monnaies  et  sur  le 
prix  des  grains  avant  et  apres  le  concile  de  Franc- 
furt  (1  vol.  12mo,  1762).  A.  c.  f. 

DUPUIT,  A.  J.  Etienne-Juvexal  (1804- 
1866),  was  born  in  Piedmont  and  died  in  Paris. 
An  engineer  and  mathematician,  holding  the 
office  of  Lnspecteur-gendral  des  ponts  et  chaussies, 
Dupuit  was  led  both  by  his  occupations  and 
studies  to  reflect  upon  the  advantage  which 
the  public  derive  from  means  of  communication, 
and  on  the  method  of  measuring  with  precision 
that  species  of  advantage,  and  utility  in  general. 
His  profound  reflections  are  embodied  in  two 
articles  in  the  Annales  desponds  et  chauss6es,  viz., 
"  De  la  mesure  de  I'utilite  des  travaux  publics," 
1844,  and  *'De  I'influence  des  peages  sur  I'utilite 
des  voies  de  communication,"  1849.  The  author 
of  these  papers  ''must  probably  be  credited  with 
the  earliest  perfect  comprehension  of  the  theory 
of  utility,"  as  Jevons  says  (Theory,  preface, 
p.  30).  By  the  example  of  water  supplied  at 
different  prices  to  a  town,  Dupuit  shows  in  the 
first  paper  that  "tons  les  produits  ont  une 
utilite,  non  seulement  pour  chaqiie  consomma- 
teur,  mais  pour  chacun  des  besoins  h  la  satisfac- 
tion desquels  il  les  emploie."  To  measure  the 
total  utility  obtained  by  a  purchaser,  Dupuit 
employs  a  construction  similar  to  that  which 
Professor  Marshall  has  made  familiar  [Prin- 
ciples of  Economies,  bk.  iii.  ch.  vi.).  The  curve 
in  the  annexed  diagram  represents  the  varia- 
tion of  demand  with  price  ;  the  abscissa 
measured  along  OP  corresponding  to  price,  and 
the  ordinate  measured  along  ON  to  the  quantity 
of  the  commodity  purchased.  The  constraction 
is  the  same  as  that  of  Cournot  {q.v.),  published 
in  1838  ;  which  Dupuit  does  not  appear  to  have 
seen.  Upon  the  principle  that  "il  n'y  a 
d'utilite  reelle  que  celle  qu'on  consent  h,  payer, " 
the  total  utility  corresponding  to  the  consump- 
tion of  the  quantity  or  is  measured  by  the 
area  ornp.  For  the  utility  of  each  portion  such 
as  //'  is  represented  by  the  amount  of  money, 
/nW,  which  the  purchaser  is  just  willing  to 
give  for  that  increment  of  commodity.  (The 
reservations  with  which  this  representation 
must  be  accepted  are  well  stated  by  Professor 


Marshall,  loe.  cit.).  Such  is  the  absolute  utility, 
not  taking  into  account  what  the  purchaser  has 
to  pay  for  the  quantity  or.  This  value  being 
subtracted,  the  ''relative  utility"  (Professor 
Marshall's  "consumer's  rent"),  is  np?.  By 
parity  of  reasoning  the  (relative)  utility  incident 
to  the  drop  from  the  price  op'  to  op  is  iiqn'. 
Dupuit  assumes  the  area  of  the  triangle  oiqn'  (a 
straight  line  beingdrawn  through  nn')  to  be  greater 


than  this  relative  utility,  on  the  assumption  that 
the  curve  is  convex  ;  which  would  seem  not  to 
be  universally  admissible.  The  paper  concludes 
with  some  very  weighty  reflections  on  the 
mathematical  method  in  political  economy. 
Referring  to  the  objection  that  statistical  data 
for  the  measurement  of  utility  are  not  obtain- 
able, Dupuit  replies  "quequand  on  ne  pent 
savoir  une  chose  c'est  deja  beaucoup  que  de 
savoir  qu'on  ne  salt  rien."  If  the  earlier 
theorists,  instead  of  formulating  the  balance  of 
trade,  had  confined  themselves  to  declaring 
that  the  question  was  above  their  powers, 
they  would  perhaps  have  done  a  greater  ser- 
vice than  those  who  afterwards  exposed  their 
errors. 

In  the  second  paper  (1849),  Dupuit  applies 
these  principles  to  the  measurement  of  the 
advantage  derived  by  the  public  from  roads  and 
other  means  of  communication.  First  he  shows 
that  the  method  proposed  by  J.  B.  Say  for 
evaluating  this  utility  is  inadmissible.  He 
proves  that  a  government  seeking  a  minimum 
return  to  meet  fixed  charges  and  the  maximum 
advantage  of  the  public,  will  in  general  impose 
a  different  scale  of  charges  for  canals  and  rail- 
ways, from  a  monopolistic  company  seeking  a 
maximum  return  (cp.  Marshall,  bk.  v.  ch.  xiii.) 
The  incidents  peculiar  to  a  regime  of  monopoly, 
that  price  is  not  in  general  proportional  to  cost, 
that  articles  will  be  charged  according  to  what 
they  will  bear,  that  a  mileage  rate  is  not  to  be 
expected,  etc.,  seem  to  be  stated  here  as  per- 
fectly as  by  the  most  recent  writers  on  railway 
problems. 

These  important  principles  are  restated  by 
Dupuit  in  several  of  his  articles  in  the  Diction- 
naire  d^^conomie  Politique,  of  which  the  follow. 


DUQUESNOY— DUTCH  AUCTION 


655 


ing  is  a  complete  list — "Eaux," 
"Routes,"  "  Voies  de  Communication."  It  will 
be  seen  from  the  last  that  Dupuit  is  not  blind  to 
the  advantages  of  competition ;  though,  in  cases 
where  it  is  impossible,  he  accepts  governmental 
management.  With  these  articles  should  be 
read  one  which  appears  to  have  been  originally- 
designed  for  the  Dictionnaire,  and  accordingly  is 
referred  to  in  the  article  on  "  Peages  " — the  ad- 
mirable paper  on  "  Utilite"  in  the  Journal  des 
Aconomistes,  for  July  1853 ;  perhaps,  as  the 
editor  of  the  Journal  says,  more  "clear  and 
methodical "  than  the  memoirs  upon  which  it 
is  based,  and  which  have  been  here  described. 

A  full  statement  of  the  oflBces  which  Dupuit 
held,  of  the  engineering  works  which  he  con- 
structed, and  of  the  books  and  papers  which  he 
wrote,  both  in  his  capacity  of  engineer  and  of 
economist,  will  be  found  in  Titres  Scientifiques, 
1857  (British  Museum,  sub  voce  Dupuit). 

F.  Y.  E. 

DUQUESISrOY,  Adrien  Cyppjen  (1763- 
1808).  A  member  of  the  States  General  of 
France,  where  he  generally  voted  with  Mirabeau, 
he  was  maire  of  Nancy,  and  later  on  of  an 
arrondissement  of  Paris,  and  one  of  the  chief 
writers  in  the  Ami  des  Patriotes  (1792).  He 
did  most  useful  work  by  his  Recueil  de  Memoires 
sur  les  ^tablissements  d'humaniU,  including 
translations  of  Rumford,  Eden,  Bentham, 
Ruggles,  Howard,  etc.  He  also  published, 
separately,  translations  of  Hoeck's  Statistical 
View  of  the  States  of  Germany,  and  of  Bentham's 
Tracts  on  the  Poor  {Esquisse  d'un  Ouvrage  en 
faveur  des  Pauvres),  Paris,  1802.  e.  ca. 

DURATION  OF  LIFE  (as  an  Element  of 
Well-being).  Length  of  days  is  referred  to  in 
the  earliest  literature  as  a  blessing  to  the 
individual ;  but  it  has  been  reserved  for  modern 
statistics  to  estimate  more  exactly  the  advantage 
which  a  community  derives  from  an  increase 
in  the  longevity  of  its  members.  A  rough 
measure  of  the  prolongation  of  life  is  afforded  by 
the  Expectation  of  Life  {q.v.).  Thus,  for 
the  period  1871-80,  as  compared  with  the 
period  1838-54,  the  mean  life-line  of  males 
(41-35  years),  is  longer  by  1-439139  years. 
In  other  words  a  million  of  males  bom  in  the 
later  period  would  live  1,439,139  years  more 
than  in  the  case  of  the  former  period.  So  a 
million  of  females  would  live  2,777,584 
additional  years,  if  born  in  the  later  period. 
Or,  taking  the  mean  annual  number  of  births 
as  858,878  —  437,492  males  and  421,386 
females — the  additional  years  lived  by  this 
annual  number  of  children  would  be  1,800,047. 
But  this  addition  of  nearly  two  million  years 
of  life  does  not  represent  the  whole  advantage 
which  the  community  derives  from  the  change 
in  the  death-rate.  For  of  these  additional 
years  the  greater  part — 66  per  cent  in  the  case 
of  males  and  65  per  cent  in  the  case  of  females 
— are  lived  at  the  most  useful  period  of  life, 


the  period  at  which  the  individual  is  least 
dependent  on  others  and  most  productive, 
namely,  between  the  ages  twenty-five  and  sixty- 
five.  This  calculation  is  taken  from  the  supple- 
ment to  the  forty-fifth  annual  report  of  the 
Registrar- General  (1885).  A  similar  conclusion 
had  already  been  reached  by  Dr.  Noel 
Humphreys  upon  somewhat  different  and  less 
perfect  data  {op.  cit.  x.  note  ;  and  Journal  of 
the  Statistical  Society,  1883). 

As  to  the  causes  which  have  contributed  to  this 
gain  of  life,  see  the  Registrar -General's  supple- 
mentary report  above  referred  to,  and  Dr.  G.  B. 
Longstaff's  paper  on  *'  The  Recent  Decline  in  the 
English  Death-rate,"  Journal  of  the  Statistical 
Society,  1884 ;  and  his  Studies  in  Statistics. 
Some  other  writers  on  the  subject — not  all  wise — 
are  mentioned  by  Dr.  Humphreys  at  the  beginning 
of  the  paper  above  referred  to  {Journ.  Stat.  Soc. , 

1883).  F.  T.  E. 

DUSSARD,  Hipp.  (1798-1876),  bom  at 
Morez,  died  at  Nyer  near  Olette  (Eastern 
Pyrenees).  He  commenced  life  as  a  publicist, 
writing  in  the  Revue  Phwyclopidiquc,  1819-33  ; 
the  Bulletin  de  Ferussac  (a  periodical  devoted 
to  science  and  industry),  1823-30  ;  and  in  the 
Temps,  the  journal  founded  15th  October 
1829  by  Jacques  Coste,  which  ceased  to  appear 
17th  June  1842,  up  to  whicli  date  he  remained 
a  contributor.  He  signed  the  protest  of  the 
journalists  against  the  ordonnance  of  July  1830, 
but  he  did  not,  like  many  others,  derive  any 
advantage  from  the  new  regime,  as  he  preferred 
to  remain  in  opposition.  He  supplied,  in  1844, 
working  with  Eug.  Daire,  the  notes  to  the 
edition  of  the  works  of  Turgot  (2  vols,  large  in 
8vo.)  published  by  Guillaumin.  He  assisted 
from  its  commencement  (in  1841)  in  editing 
the  Journal  des  ^conomistes,  in  which  he  wrote 
many  articles,  having  been  editor-in-chief  of  that 
journal  from  February  1843  to  May  1845.  He 
was  the  traffic  manager  of  the  Paris  and  Rouen 
railway,  and  distinguished  himself  after  the 
revolution  of  1848  by  placing  himself  at  the 
head  of  the  courageous  volunteers  who  under- 
took the  defence  of  the  railways  in  the  neigh- 
bourhood of  Paris,  which  had  been  overrun  by 
bands  of  incendiaries.  His  brave  conduct 
gained  for  him  the  office  of  prefect  of  the  Seine 
inferieure,  in  which  position  he  successfully 
closed  the  national  workshops  (see  Ateliers 
Nationaux)  ;  this  judicious  intervention 
brought  to  an  end  the  labour  disturbances, 
and  restored  the  confidence  of  employers.  He 
left  this  post  for  the  council  of  state,  in  which 
he  did  not  remain  long ;  his  name  having 
been  drawn  as  one  of  the  members  who  had  to 
retire.  Returning  to  private  life,  he  busied  him- 
self with  various  occupations,  such  as  works  of 
irrigation,  forestry,  and  railways,  in  the  manage- 
ment of  all  which  he  displayed  great  ability. 

A.  C.  f. 

DUTCH  AUCTION.     See  Auction. 


606 


DUTCH  SCHOOL  OF  ECONOMISTS 


DUTCH  SCHOOL  OF  ECONOMISTS.  In 
Holland,  during  the  l7th  century,  tlie  most 
glorious  period  of  Dutch  history,  economics 
were  not  regarded  as  an  independent  science, 
deserving  separate  treatment.  Economic  theory 
at  that  date  must  be  sought  for  in  the  works  of 
eminent  writers  on  theology,  jurisprudence,  and 
politics.  Perhaps  the  best  information  can 
be  found  by  studying  the  means  adopted  to 
promote  the  general  welfare  of  the  country. 
Practice  preceded  theory.  The  discussions  on 
practical  questions  of  the  day  gave  rise  to  in- 
numerable pamphlets,  and  by  searching  these 
we  may  still  trace  the  general  ideas  underlying 
action.  Laspeyres  and  Van  Rees  among  others 
have  done  good  service  in  utilising  these  sources 
of  information.  The  titles  of  their  works  are 
mentioned  below. 

In  this  place  attention  can  only  be  called  to 
some  of  the  most  illustrious  writers  whose 
opinions  on  economic  questions  were  ahead  of 
their  times,  although  m  many  cases  the  living 
generation  refused  to  be  guided  by  their  advice. 

Hugo  Gkotitjs  (1583-1645)  advocated  free- 
dom of  commerce  as  one  of  the  natural 
rights  of  man.  It  leads  to  a  useful  division  of 
labour  between  nations.  Both  parties  gain  by 
the  exchange,  the  abundance  of  the  one  supply- 
ing the  penury  of  the  other.  Grotius  allows 
the  right  of  free  immigration  to  foreigners.  In 
his  opinions  concerning  value  we  find  a  forecast 
of  the  most  recent  theories,  as  he  distinctly 
asserts  the  subjective  element  in  the  determina- 
tion of  price.  "Mensura  ejus  quod  res 
quaeque  valeat  maxime  est  naturalis  indigentia. 
.  .  .  Non  tamen  haec  unica  est  mensura. 
Nam  hominum  voluntas,  quae  rerum  domina 
est,  multas  res  magis  desiderat  quam  sunt 
necessariae.  .  .  .  Et  contra  evenit  ut  res 
maxime  necessariae  minoris  sint  propter 
copiam"  {De  Jure  Belli  ac  Fads,  ii.  ch.  xii.  §  14, 
n.  1).  Grotius  describes  money  as  the  common 
measure  of  value,  and  regards  fixity  of  purchasing 
power  as  the  first  quality  money  ought  to 
possess.  Though  gold  and  silver  do  possess  that 
quality  in  a  satisfactory  degree,  he  recognises 
that  abundance  and  scarcity  in  the  precious 
metals,  as  in  other  goods,  will  bring  with  them 
variations  in  their  purchasing  power.  Grotius 
was  among  the  first  to  defend  the  taking  of 
interest  on  scientific  grounds,  and  distinguished 
the  different  elements  in  the  interest,  viz. — the 
price  for  the  use  of  capital, — the  wages  of  the ' 
creditor  and  the  insurance -premium  for  his 
risk.  Nevertheless  he  was  opposed  to  taking 
compound  interest,  and  advocated  the  fixing  of 
a  maximum  interest  by  legislation. 

Graswinckel  (1600-1668)  is  conspicuous 
for  his  defence  of  free  trade  in  com,  and  for  his 
clear  insight  into  the  causes  of  the  general  rise 
of  prices  during  the  latter  part  of  the  16th  and 
the  beginning  of  the  17th  century.  He  de- 
scribes the  pernicious  eflfects  of  forbidding  the 


re-export  of  foreign  corn,  as  the  doing  thia 
would  deter  foreign  producers  from  sending 
their  com  to  our  markets.  Even  in  a  state  of 
famine,  when  it  would  be  legitimate  on  general 
grounds,  practical  considerations  make  Gras- 
winckel advise  against  such  a  prohibition, 
because  the  best  remedy  is  the  high  price 
itself.  As  water  flows  to  the  lowest  level,  so 
com  flows  to  the  highest  market.  Their  own 
private  interest  will  prevent  merchants  from 
exporting  corn  in  times  like  these.  A  policy 
that  proscribes  itself  ought  not  to  be  proscribed 
by  odious  restrictions.  Graswinckel  clearly 
sees  the  use  of  forestalling  com  in  times  of 
approaching  dearness.  It  is  folly  to  consider 
speculators  as  the  cause  of  the  dearness.  He 
that  keeps  in  his  granaries  the  corn  he  has  got, 
in  the  hope  of  a  rising  price,  does  not  cause 
the  high  price,  but  the  expected  rise  causes  him 
to  keep  what  he  has  got.  The  best  thing 
government  can  do  for  preventing  excessive 
dearness  is  to  collect  statistics  respecting  the 
quantity  of  corn  still  in  the  country.  The 
knowledge  where  this  quantity  is,  which  wiU 
probably  be  more  than  enough  to  feed  the 
people  for  two  years,  will  dispel  unreasonable 
fears  and  prevent  hoarding  by  private  indi- 
viduals. Apprehension  of  dearness  is  the  prin- 
cipal cause  of  dearness. 

Concerning  the  rise  of  general  prices  in  his 
time,  Graswinckel  wrote:  "The  change  has 
been  one,  not  in  the  commodities,  but  in  the 
money.  As  there  is  four  times  more  money 
in  the  world  than  there  was  before,  there  must 
necessarily  follow  a  decline  in  money  and  a  rise 
in  commodities,  if  such  can  be  called  a  rise. 
For  leaving  money  out  of  account,  and  nieasur 
ing  commodities  against  each  other,  wages 
among  the  rest,  all  things  have  remained  at 
their  former  level."  Considering  these  varia- 
tions in  the  value  of  money,  he  expressed  the 
opinion  that  the  best  way  to  fix  the  rent  of 
land  would  be  to  stipulate  for  payment  in  corn. 

Salmasius  (1588-1658)  was  the  most  influ- 
ential among  the  many  writers  who  defended 
the  taking  of  interest.  But  while  most  of  them 
hoped  to  protect  the  lower  classes  against  ex- 
cessive rates  by  legislation  or  by  the  monopoly 
of  a  public  body,  Salmasius  recommended  con- 
fidence in  free  competition,  as  that  would  com- 
pel money-lenders  to  lower  interest  to  a  fan- 
rate  in  order  to  augment  their  business. 

The  works  of  Pieter  de  la  Court  (1618-1685) 
on  economic  subjects  are  among  the  best,  not 
only  of  this,  but  of  all  other  countries.  One  of 
his  works,  the  Aanwysing,  pub.  1669  (see  below), 
has  been  ascribed  by  deliberate  fraud  to  the 
statesman  Johan  de  Witt,  in  a  French  transla- 
tion under  the  title  Mimoires  de  Jean  de  WiU, 
1709  (also  in  English,  1743,  Political  Maxims  of 
the  State  of  Holland,  by  John  de  "Witt,  pensionary 
of  Holland,  London,  J.  Nourse).  De  la  Court 
deserves  a  high  place  in  the  history  of  economic 


DUTCH  SCHOOL  OF  ECONOMISTS 


657 


thought  for  his  ardent  defence  of  the  freedom 
of  industry  against  corporations  and  monopolies. 
In  his  native  city,  Leyden,  he  found  ample 
evidence  for  illustrating  his  conviction  that 
industry  suffers  under  government  tutelage, 
and  that  the  interests  both  of  producers  and 
consumers  are  best  served  by  free  competition, 
even  in  freedom  to  make  cheap  goods,  perhaps 
of  low  quality,  but  within  the  means  of  their 
customers.  Producers  ought  to  have  absolute 
liberty  in  order  to  be  able  to  follow  tlie  changing 
tastes  and  fashions  of  consumers.  Regulations, 
even  if  they  could  be  efficient  in  the  beginning, 
would  remain  unaltered  long  after  they  had 
become  obsolete,  as,  even  under  the  best  of 
governments,  a  law  once  made  is  only  amended 
when  much  harm  has  been  done.  De  la  Court 
not  only  attacked  the  regulation  of  industry  and 
the  testing  of  manufactured  goods  by  public 
authority,  but  also  all  close  corporations  of 
producers.  Under  the  pretence  of  protecting 
citizens  against  aliens,  and  of  procuring  work 
for  native  industries,  these  corporations  de- 
prive all  their  fellow-citizens  of  the  liberty  of 
buying  where  they  find  the  commodity  can  be 
had  the  cheapest  and  the  best ;  they  retard  the 
increase  of  the  community  by  increasing  the 
difficulty  of  finding  a  living  in  it ;  they  give 
rise  to  all  kinds  of  vexatious  disputes  concern- 
ing the  limits  of  their  rights,  and  in  the  end 
they  do  not  even  benefit  those  persons  for  whose 
profit  they  were  intended,  as  b}^  secure  earnings 
and  luxury  men  everywhere  are  made  idle,  lavish, 
and  stupid.  Still  De  la  Court  did  not  defend 
freedom  of  trade  in  the  modern  sense  of  the  term. 
He  recommended  freedom  of  labour  and  of 
competition  as  the  best  policy  for  strengthening 
his  native  country,  but  he  was  not  opposed  to 
import  and  export  duties  on  foreign  manufac- 
tures as  high  as  the  interests  of  commerce  would 
permit. 

Of  the  statesman,  Johan  de  Witt,  we  may 
mention  here  a  memoir  on  the  value  of  annuities, 
the  one  of  his  writings  which,  excepting  his 
correspondence,  has  most  attracted  public 
attention. 

We  can  only  recall  the  names  of  other  dis- 
tinguished writers   as   Usselinox,   Boxhorn, 
I    Huber,  Bynkershoeic,  Noodt,  etc. 
!        In  the  18th  century  we  find  among  others 
'    the  works  of  Ricard,  De  VEspine,  and  Le  Long 
on  commerce,  of  Pinto  on  credit,  of  Luzae  on 
the  wealth  of  Holland,  and  many  treatises  on 
the  decline   of  prosperity  and   the  means  of 
reviving  trade. 

Among  political  arithmeticians  Kbrsseboom 
deserves  to  be  remembered  as  an  original  writer, 
who  improved  the  method  of  Halley  in  con- 
structing life-tables  by  following  out  the  history 
i  of  a  generation  of  persons  of  a  certain  age, 
I  individually,  till  all  of  them  had  died.     Struyck 
\  and  Nieuwetytk  worked  in  the  same  direction. 
In  the  19th  century  political  economy  has 
VOL.  T. 


found  a  place  in  the  curriculum  of  the  Dutch 
universities.  Along  with  statesmen  like  Van 
HoGENDORP,  Van  Hall,  and  Thorbecke,  the 
Professors  Aokersdyk,  Van  Rees,  and  Visser- 
ING  are  to  be  named  among  its  most  distinguished 
representatives.  The  central  figure  among  Dutch 
economists  of  the  last  generation  was  W.C.Mees, 
for  many  years  (1863-1884)  the  president  of  the 
Netherlands  Bank.  His  works  on  economics 
are  not  very  numerous,  but  all  of  them  are 
characterised  by  great  power  and  originality  of 
thought.  He  never  joined  in  the  optimism  of 
the  French  school  of  Basti  at  and  other  partisans 
of  laissez-faire.  Neither  could  he  assent  to 
the  principles  of  the  German  economists  who 
regarded  economics  as  a  purely  historical  study. 
Against  the  French  he  maintained  the  funda- 
mental truth  of  Maltiius'  doctrine  on  population, 
against  the  Germans  the  necessity  of  abstract 
economic  reasoning.  In  questions  of  economic 
method  he  followed  Ricardo,  but  with  a  fuller 
understanding  of  the  limitations  of  the  abstract 
treatment,  and  a  much  more  careful  handling 
of  his  hypothesis.  His  book,  Chapters  in  Poli- 
tical Economy,  a  model  of  sound  reasoning  and 
clear  insight  into  the  problems  of  distribution 
and  foreign  trade,  has  not  met,  even  in  his 
native  country,  with  the  degree  of  attention  it 
deserved,  as  it  was  more  difiicult  reading  than 
most  of  those  who  concerned  themselves  with 
economics  were-  accustomed  to.  It  may  be 
considered  as  the  best  exposition  of  the  general 
theory  of  economics  before  the  works  of  Jevons 
and  the  Austrian  school  of  economists.  In 
1869  Mees  deduced  from  a  correct  theory  of 
value  the  principles  of  international  bimetallism 
which,  since  that  date,  have  steadily  gained 
ground  among  students  of  monetary  science  in 
all  countries.  In  other  papers,  read  before  the 
Dutch  Royal  Academy  of  Science  at  Amsterdam, 
he  treated  of  the  incidence  of  taxation  and  of 
the  elementary  conceptions  of  political  economy. 
In  his  youth  he  published  an  exhaustive  history 
of  banking  in  the  Netherlands. 

Among  recent  Dutch  economists  iV.  G.  Pier  son, 
successor  of  Mees  as  president  of  the  Netherlands 
Bank  and  atone  time  chancellor  of  the  exchequer, 
held  high  rank.  His  Principles  of  Economics 
was  translated  into  English  (Macmillan,  1902- 
1912).  In  his  Manual  of  Political  Economy 
he  succeeded  in  interesting  cultivated  people  in 
the  study  of  scientific  economics.  Through 
this  work  the  latest  improvements  in  economic 
theory,  initiated  by  Jevons,  Mengeu,  and 
others,  and  their  application  to  problems  of 
distribution,  have  reached  wide  circles  of 
readers.  Pierson  combines  an  extensive  know- 
ledge of  the  literature  of  political  economy  and 
a  full  appreciation  of  the  historical  inquiries  of 
our  eastern  neighbours,  Avith  the  gift  of  prudently 
using  the  deductive  method.  Though  his  mode 
of  treatment  is  less  systematic  than  that  of 
Mees,  it  is  much  more  attractive  ;  he  always 

2u 


658 


DUTCH  SCHOOL  OF  ECONOMISTS 


tries  to  interest  his  readers  in  the  general 
knowledge  he  wishes  to  impart  to  them,  by 
reference  to  the  practical  problems  on  which 
the  theories  throw  light. 

The  study  of  Mees  and  Pierson  by  the 
younger  generation  of  economists  explains  the 
slight  influence  in  Holland  of  the  German 
school  of  Schmoller  and  others,  who  recommend 
an  exclusively  inductive  treatment  of  economics, 
and  the  favourable  reception  of  the  doctrines 
of  the  Austrian  school.  The  question  of 
economic  method  was  much  discussed  in  the 
Netherlands  a  few  years  before  the  work  of 
Menger  on  the  subject  appeared.  Borgesius  and 
Levy  had  recommended  the  inductive  treatment, 
and  were  refuted,  among  others,  by  D'Aulnis, 
Pierson,  and  Heymans.  Since  1880  the  con- 
troversy may  be  considered  as  closed. 

Following  the  lead  of  Mees  and  Pierson, 
many  young  authors  have  attempted  to  work 
out  special  problems  on  deductive  principles. 
In  this  spirit  Beaujon  wrote  on  the  theory  of 
international  trade,  Harte  on  interest,  Falken- 
hirg  on  the  rate  of  wages,  Verryn  Stuart  on 
socialistic  theories  of  value.  Much  highly 
original  work  has  been  done  by  applying  the 
principles  of  Jevons  and  Menger  to  the  theory 
of  taxation,  in  the  works  of  Cohen  Stuart  on 
the  progressive  income  tax,  and  by  Tasman  on 
the  incidence  of  taxation. 

Another  feature  of  the  Dutch  economic 
school  of  the  present  day  is  its  adherence  to 
the  fundamental  ideas  of  Malthus'  doctrine  of 
population.  Excepting  a  few  writers,  among 
others.  Professors  Fissering  and  Cort  van  der 
Linden,  aU  are  convinced  that  the  great  mass 
of  the  people  cannot  permanently  better  its 
standard  of  living,  if  it  does  not  diminish 
competition  by  limiting  its  numbers.  A  lively 
controversy  arose  about  Malthusianism  and  so- 
called  Neo-Malthusianism  about  the  years 
1875-76.  Ghreven  and  Fan  Houten  defended 
neo-Malthusianism  against  the  objections  of 
Professor  Evers  and  others.  Pierson  lately 
declared  in  his  treatise  that  all  the  objections 
to  that  doctrine  which  an  economist  was 
competent  to  judge  of,  appeared  to  him  to  be 
invalid,  and  that  the  question  ought  to  be  de- 
finitely settled  on  medical  grounds.  Professed 
neo-Malthusians  were  called  more  than  once  to 
professorships  at  the  public  universities,  and  a 
neo-Malthusian  league  has  set  up  an  active 
propaganda  since  1880. 

Next  in  importance  to  a  due  regulation  of 
aumbers,  Dutch  economists  regard  all  kinds  of 
measures  for  "social  reform."  They  do  not 
proclaim  Malthusianism  as  a  panacea  for  all 
evils,  but  they  are  convinced  that  all  other 
measures  for  elevating  the  masses,  however 
useful  in  themselves,  will  avail  little,  unless 
"peopling  up  to  them "  as  Mill  expressed  it, 
is  prevented.  The  theory  of  laissez-faire,  which 
never  had  been  accepted  without  qualification, 


even  by  the  older  generation  of  economists,  such 
as  De  Bruyn  Kops  and  Fissering,  is  visibly 
losing  ground  m  the  minds  of  the  general 
public,  and  is  regarded  as  insufficient  and  in- 
complete by  all  scientific  writers  on  economics. 
Here  the  impulse  came  from  Germany.  The  new 
German  school  of  the  **  Kathedorsocialisten" 
found  eloquent  and  ardent  expositors  in  Fan 
Houten,  Kerdyk,  Borgesius,  and  others.  Van 
Houten  initiated  the  factory -legislation  in 
1874,  and  since  that  date  public  opinion  has 
been  steadily  ripening  for  more  extended  state 
interference.  Since  1886  parliamentary  and 
royal  commissions  have  collected  materials  for 
further  legislation  concerning  the  interests  of 
the  working  classes,  outside  agriculture.  A 
weekly  paper  on  social  questions,  under  the 
able  editorship  of  Kerdyk,  has  worked  since 
1887  in  the  same  direction.  Compulsory 
insurance  has  been  recommended  by  various 
writers,  and  government  seems  not  unwilling  to 
propose  such  a  measure.  Trade-unionism  and 
the  co-operative  movement  not  having  attained 
among  the  working  classes  that  degree  of 
development  their  friends  had  wished  for,  the 
necessity  of  state  interference  begins  to  be 
recognised  by  many  who  would  have  preferred 
self-help. 

Socialism  in  its  most  uncompromising  shape 
is  actively  propagated  by  Domela  Nieuwenhuis 
and  others  by  means  of  papers  and  public 
meetings,  and  finds  an  increasing  number  of 
adherents  among  the  younger  generation  in  the 
great  cities  and  in  the  northern  provinces. 
Quack  has  been  occupied  for  many  years  in 
writing  an  extensive  history  of  socialism,  which 
has  now  been  carried  down  to  the  year  1850. 
D'Aulnis  has  given  an  able  criticism  of  modem 
socialistic  theories  from  Marx  downwards. 

In  commercial  matters  there  is  but  one  opin- 
ion among  economists  in  Holland.  Free  trade 
is  considered  the  best  policy  for  countries 
generally,  and  more  so  for  a  small  country, 
where  trade  flourishes  and  combinations  among 
producers  would  easily  dominate  the  market  if 
foreign  competition  were  excluded.  Beaujon 
defended  free  trade  with  great  acumen  in  the 
second  part  of  his  essay  on  international  trade. 
An  agitation  for  duties  on  corn,  set  up  a  few 
years  ago,  vigorously  defended  by  Diepen  and 
in  a  more  scientific  spirit  by  Harte,  has  met 
with  energetic  resistance  on  the  part  of  our 
best  writers,  e.g.  Pierson  and  the  younger 
Mees,  and  may  be  said  to  have  subsided  since 
that  date. 

In  the  "battle  of  the  standards,"  Dutch 
economists,  since  the  exposition  by  Mees  of  the 
principle  of  bimetallism,  are  agreed  that  theor- 
etically that  would  be  the  best  system,  because 
it  would  give  the  greatest  guarantee  of  fixity 
of  value  in  the  standard  coins.  We  possess 
many  valuable  articles  on  the  question  by  Bois- 
sevain,  who  recently  gave  a  very  able  defence 


DUTCH  SCHOOL  OF  ECONOMISTS 


659 


of  the  bimetallic  theory  against  its  English  and 
continental  opponents  in  his  work  The  Mone- 
tary Qtiestion. 

The  necessities  of  the  exchequer  and  the  need 
for  reform  in  the  fiscal  system  have  directed 
attention  in  an  unusual  degree  to  (questions  of 
finance.  Sickenga  has  published,  commencing 
mih.  1863,  an  historical  exposition  of  the  rise  of 
the  present  system,  in  establishing  which  men 
like  GoGEL,  Van  Hall,  and  Betz  took  a  promin- 
ent part ;  Sprenger  Van  Eyk  wrote  a  masterly 
risumS  of  the  present  situation  with  all  its  im- 
perfections ;  Pierson,  Van  Nierop,  Cort  van  der 
Linden  and  Treuh  are  among  the  most  dis- 
tinguished writers  on  the  principles  of  taxation. 

Holland  possesses  a  Monthly  Review,  of  long 
standing,  exclusively  devoted  to  economics, 
edited  from  the  first  by  De  Bruyn  Kops  and 
after  his  death  (1888),  by  a  committee,  in- 
cluding many  of  the  writers  mentioned  above. 

Statistics  are  much  indebted  to  De  Bosch 
Kemper,  who  founded  the  Dutch  statistical 
society  and  has  edited  since  1849  the  year  book 
of  that  society. 

Below  are  given  the  titles  of  the  works  men- 
tioned in  this  article. 

Laspeyres,  Geschichte  der  volksxoirthscJiaftUchen 
A  nschauungen  der  Nlederldnder  und  ihrer  Litter- 
atur  zur  Zeit  der  RepuUik,  1863. — Van  Rees, 
Geschiedenis  der  Staathuishoudkunde  in  Neder- 
land  tot  het  einde  der  achttiende  eeuw  (History  of 
political  economy  in  the  Netherlands  to  the  end 
of  the  18th  century),  2  vols.  1865-68. 

17th  century :  Grotius,  Mare  liberum,  1609  ; 
Irdeiding  tot  de  Hollandsche  Rechtsgeleerdheid 
(Introduction  to  Dutch  jurisprudence)  ;  De  jure 
belli  ac  pads,  1625. — Graswinckel,  Aenmerkingen 
ende  betrachtingen  by 't  Piacaetboek  op  't  Stuck  van 
de  Lyftocht  (Remarks  on  the  edicts  concerning  the 
trade  in  corn),  1651. — Salmasius,  De  usuris,  1638  ; 
De  modo  usurarum,  1639  ;  Dissertatio  de  foenore 
trapezitico,  1640. — Pieter  de  la  Court,  Het  welvaren 
der  stad  Leyden  (The  Welfare  of  the  city  of  Ley- 
den),  1659  ;  Interest  van  Holland  ofte  gronden  van 
Hollands-  Welvaren  (The  Causes  of  the  wealth  of 
Holland),  explained  by  V.  D.  H.  (Van  der  Hove, 
=  De  la  Court),  1662  ;  Aanwysing  der  heilsame 
politike  Gronden  en  Maximen  van  de  Republike 
Win  Holland  en  West  Friesland  (Demonstration  of 
the  salutary  political  maxims  of  the  Dutch  Re- 
public), 1669. — Johan  de  Witt,  Calculatie  van  de 
loaardye  der  Ly^renten  (Calculation  of  the  value 
of  Annuities,  etc.),  1671. 

18th  century  :  Le  Moine  de  I'Espine,  De  Koop- 
handel  van  Amsterdam  {Le  Commerce  d'A.),  1715 
(new  editions  by  Le  Long). — Ricard,  Traiti  du 
Commerce,  1715  ;  Le  nigoce  d' Amsterdam,  1722. 
— Kersseboom,  Proeve  van  politiqxbe  Rekenkunde, 
vervat  in  drie  verhandelingen  tot  eene  proeve  om  te 
weeten  de  probable  vienigte  des  voiles  in  deprovintie 
van  Holland  en  West-  Vriesland  (Essay  in  Political 
Arithmetic,  contained  in  three  dissertations  on  the 
probable  numbers  of  the  population  of  the  pro- 
vinces of  Holland  and  West  Friesland),  1748  (the 
original  editions  from  1738  to  1742). — Pinto, 
Traits  de  la.  cvrculation  et  du  credit,  1773. — Luzac, 


Hollands  rykdom  (The  Wealth  of  Holland),  4  vols. 
1780-83. 

19th  century :  Van  Hogendorp,  Bydragen  tot 
de  huishouding  van  staat  in  het  Koningryk  der 
Nederlanden  (Contributions  to  the  Political  Eco- 
nomy of  the  Kingdom  of  the  Netherlands),  10  vols., 
1818-25. 

De  Bruyn  Kops,  Beginselen  der  staathuisJwud- 
kunde  (Principles  of  Political  Economy),  1850. — 
Five  editions — Vissering,  Handboek  der  praktischt 
staathuishoudkunde  (Manual  of  Practical  Political 
Economy),  1860. — Four  editions— Mees,  W.  C, 
Overzicht  van  eenige  hoofdstukken  der  staathuishoud- 
kunde (Sketch  of  some  Chapters  in  Political 
Economy),  1866. — Pierson,  Grondbeginselen  der 
staathuishoudkunde  (First  Principles  of  Political 
Economy  (1875-76). — Three  editions — Leerboek 
der  staathuishoudkunde  (Manual  of  Political  Econ- 
omy), 2  vols.,  1884-90. 

Hey  mans,  Karakter  en  methode  der  staathuis- 
houdkunde (Scope  and  Method  of  Political  Econ- 
omy), 1880. — Harte,  De  rentestand  (On  the  Rate 
of  Interest),  1883. — Falkenburg,  Bydrage  tot  de  leer 
van  liet  arbeidsloon  (On  the  Theory  of  Wages), 
1890. — Verryn  Stuart,  Ricardo  en  Marx,  1890. — 
Cohen  Stuart,  Bydrage  tot  de  theorie  der  pro- 
gressieve  inkomstenbelasting  (On  the  Theory  of  the 
Progressive  Income-tax),  1889. — Tasman,  Afwente- 
ling  van  belastingen  (On  the  Incidence  of  Taxation), 
1889. 

Greven,  De  Ontwikkeling  der  Bevolkingsleer 
(The  Development  of  the  Theory  of  Population), 
1875. — Articles  in  the  periodical  Vragen  des  Tyds 
(Questions  of  the  Times)  since  1875,  by  Van 
Houten,  Kerdyk,  Borgesius,  etc. — Sociaal  Weekblad 
(Weekly  Paper  on  Social  Questions),  since  1887, 
ed.  Kerdyk. — Quack,  De  Socialisten,  Personen  en 
stelsels  (The  Socialists,  the  Men  and  the  Systems), 
1875  seq.,  3  vols. — D'Aulnis  de  Bourouill,  Het 
hedendaagsche  Socialisme  toegelicht  en  beoordeeld 
(A  Description  and  Criticism  of  Contemporary 
Socialism),  1886. 

Beaujon,  Handel  en  handelspolitieck  (On  Foreign 
Trade  and  its  Policy),  1886. — Harte,  Vryhandel 
en  Bescherming  (Free  Trade  and  Protection),  1890. 
— Mees  (M.),  Nadulen  van  het  protectionisme  voor 
de  werkende  klassen  (Why  the  Working  Classes 
lose  by  Protection),  1891. 

Mees,  W.  C,  Proeve  eener  geschiedenis  van  het 
bankwezen  in  Nederland  (Essay  on  the  History  of 
Banking  in  the  Netherlands),  1838  ;  De  viunt- 
standaard  in  verband  met  depogingen  tot  invoering 
van  eenheid  van  munt  (On  the  Monetary  Standard 
and  an  International  Unit  of  Money),  1869. — 
Boissevain,  The  Monetary  Question,  1891. 

'S>\ckeng2i,^  Bydrage  tot  de  geschiedenis  der  be- 
lastingen in  Nederland  (Contributions  to  the  His- 
tory of  Taxation  in  the  Netherlands),  1864 ; 
Geschiedenis  der  Nederlandsche  belastingen  sederi 
het  jaxir  1810  (History  of  Dutch  Taxes  from  the 
year  1810),  1883,  2  vols. —Sprenger  van  Eyk,  De 
ryks-en  gemeentebelastingen  in  Nederland  (General 
and  Local  Taxation  in  the  Netherlands),  1891. — 
Treub,  Ontwikkeling  en  verband  van  de  Ryks, 
Provinciate- en  Gemeentebelastingen  in  Nederland 
(On  the  Development  of  and  the  Relation  between 
Imperial,  Provincial,  and  Local  Taxes  in  the 
Netherlands),  1885. — Cort  van  der  Linden,  Leer- 


t 


660 


DUTENS— DWELLINGS,  INDUSTRIAL 


boek  der  Jinancim.  De  theorie  der  hdastingen 
(Manual  of  Finance.  The  Theory  of  Taxation), 
1887. 

Sloet  tot  Oldhuis,  Tydschriftvoor  staathuishoud- 
Iffiinde  en  Statistiek  (Magazine  of  Political  Economy 
and  Statistics),  1841-75,  28  vols.— De  Bniyn  Kops, 
De  Economist,  1852-91,  69  vols. —StaatMndig  en 
staathuishoudkundig  jaa/rhoekje  (Annual  of  the 
Dutch  Statistical  Society),  1849-84,  36  vols.— 
Jaar^fers.  Annuaire  statistique  des  Pays- Bos, 
since  1881 ;  Bydragen vanhet Statistisch Instituut, 
since  1885  (Publications  of  the  Statistical  Bureau 
of  that  Society). — Palkenberg,  Bydrage  tot  de  leer 
van  het  Arbeidsloon,  on  the  lines  of  the  Austrian 
economists. — Cossa,  Introdvzione  alio  Studio  delta 
Uc&n.  Pol,  1892.  H.B.G. 

DUTENS,  Joseph  Michel  (1765-1848), 
bom  at  Tours,  was  inspector-general  of  roads 
and  bridges  (jponts  et  chauss^es)  from  1830  to  the 
time  of  his  death.  In  his  writings  he  manifests 
a  spirit  retrograde  even  relatively  to  the  time 
when  he  lived,  and  favourable  to  government 
regulation.  With  aU  this  he  was  conscientious 
and  hardworking.  In  1840  he  was  admitted  to 
the  Academy  of  Moral  and  Political  Science. 

The  economic  works  published  by  him  are 
entitled  :  Analyse  raisonnie  des  principes  fonda- 
mentauxdel'Sconomie  politique,  1  vol.  in  8vo,  1804. 
— Philosophie  de  Viconomie  politique  ou  nouvelle 
exposition  des  principes  de  cette  science,  2  vols,  in 
8vo,  1835. — Essai  comparatif  sur  la  formation  et 
la  distribution  du  revenu  de  la  France  en  1815 
et  1835,  in  8vo,  1842.— Finally,  Des  pretendues 
erreurs  dans  lesqueUes,  au  jugement  des  modemes 
economistes,  seraient  tombSs  les  anciens  iconomistes, 
relativement  au  principe  de  la  richesse  nationale, 
in  8vo,  1846.  a.  c.  f. 

DUTOT.  No  biographical  details  respecting 
this  author  are  discoverable.  It  is  only  known 
that  he  was  cashier  of  the  India  Company  in 
which  the  well-known  John  Law  was  concerned. 
(The  name  of  this  company  was  changed  from 
that  of  Gompagnie  d' Occident  to  that  of  Gom- 
pagnie  des  Indes,  May  1719.)  The  book  of 
which  Dutot  was  the  author  is  entitled  Rifleadons 
politiques  sur  les  finances  et  le  commerce  (2  vols. 
1718-1738,  reprinted  in  1743,  1764,  and  also 
in  the  collection  of  GuiQaumin).  In  it  he  exa- 
mines the  questions  what  would  be  the  eflFect  on 
the  public  revenue,  on  the  price  of  merchandise, 
on  the  foreign  exchanges,  and  in  consequence 
on  trade,  of  the  increase  and  diminution  of  the 
monetary  value  {i.e.  of  the  purchasing  power) 
of  the  cii-culating  medium  (money).  This  work, 
although  too  partial  to  the  Syst^me  of  Law,  is 
very  instructive  reading,  especially  when  its 
date  is  remembered.  It  was  written  in  opposi- 
tion to  the  views  of  Melon  (g'.v.) 

["Les  Reflexions  de  Dutot  sect  incontestable- 
ment  ce  qu'il  y  a  de  plus  profond  sur  le  systfeme 
de  Law,  et  sur  la  cause  de  sa  chute,"  Thiers.    See 
reference  in  M'Culloch's  Literature  of  Pol.  Eccm 
P-344.]  A.c.f. '' 

DUTY,  CUSTOMS.     See  Customs. 

DUTY,  EXPORT.    See  Exports,  Duties  on 


DUTY,  IMPORT.    See  Import  Duties. 

DUTY,  Legacy,  Probate,  Succession. 
See  Death  Duties. 

DU  VERNEY.     See  Paris  Du  Verney. 

DUVILLARD  de  DURAND,  Etienne 
(1755-1832),  bom  in  Geneva  of  an  ancient 
French  Huguenot  family.  He  was  member  of 
the  French  Academic  des  Sciences,  and  head  of 
the  statistical  department  of  population  in  the 
office  of  the  French  ministry  of  the  Interior  ;  he 
is  best  known  by  his  Tables  of  Mortality,  which 
are  inserted  (p.  159)  in  his  Analyse  et  Tableaux 
de  I'lnJluenAX  de  la  petite  V&role  sur  la  Mortaliti 
(Analysis  and  Tables  of  the  Influence  of  Small- 
pox on  Mortality),  Paris,  1806.  They  have 
long  been  in  use  in  France.  According  to 
Querard  {France  Littdraire),  he  left  mathemati- 
cal dissertations  in  manuscript  under  the  titles 
of  "social  mathematics,"  "mathematical  statis- 
tics of  population,"  and  "A  mathematical 
theory  of  banking  and  finance,"  which  are  the 
object  of  a  report  to  the  Acadimie  des  Sciences, 
given  as  an  appendix  to  the  Analyse  et  Tableaux. 
In  1 7  8  7  he  published  his  Recherches  sv/r  les  Rentes, 
les  Emprunts  et  les  Remboursements.       e.  ca. 

DWELLINGS,  Industrial,  may  be  defined 
as  homes  for  the  poorer  wage-earning  classes 
specially  constmcted  with  a  view  to  meeting 
the  particular  needs  of  the  occupants,  and 
ameliorating  their  physical  and  moral  condition 
Since  about  the  year  1840  the  construction  of 
such  dwellings,  in  or  near  centres  of  labour,  has 
been,  in  this  country,  the  object  of  public  and 
private  enterprise,  as  well  as  of  extensive 
national  and  local  legislation  (see  Dw^ellings, 
Regulation  by  the  State  in  England,  and 
bibliography  of  same).  The  object  of  such 
enterprise  has  been  "to  provide,  instead  of 
miserable  house  accommodation  for  which  ex- 
tremely high  rents  are  charged,  which  is  ill 
arranged,  insanitaiy,  overcrowded,  and  lacking 
the  conditions  under  which  the  ordinary 
decencies  of  life  can  be  observed,  clean  homes 
at  moderate  rents,  with  proper  ventilation  and 
sanitary  arrangements,  and  not  too  far  from 
the  places  where  the  occupants  have  to  work  " 
{Report  of  Dwellings  Gommittee  of  Gharity  Ch'- 
ganisation  Society,  August  1881,  the  whole  of 
which  report  may  be  advantageously  studied  on 
the  subject).  The  various  evils  resulting  from 
the  unsatisfactory  dwellings  of  the  poor  wiQ  be 
found  detailed  in  the  evidence  given  before  the 
Royal  Commission  on  the  Housing  of  the  Work- 
ing Classes,  1885,  and  in  the  First  Report  of  the 
Commissioners  issued  in  1889  ;  but  it  may  be 
briefly  stated  that  in  the  design,  construction, 
and  location  of  industrial  dwellings  it  is  speci- 
ally intended  to  mitigate  or  remove  the  follow- 
ing defects : — (1)  Undue  crowding,  either  of 
houses  on  a  site  or  of  occupants  in  single 
apartments.  (2)  The  immorality  which  is  tlie 
frequent  result  of  so  large  a  number  occupying 
one  room  as  to  make  decency  impossible.     (3) 


DWELLINGS,  INDUSTRIAL 


661 


The  wasteful  disposal  of  tenants  on  a  given 
area,  owing  to  their  homes  being  inconveniently 
planned  or  designed  originally  for  a  different 
class  of  occupant.  (4)  Unduly  high  rents 
resulting  partly  from  the  last  defect.  (5)  Un- 
healthy conditions  arising  from  the  overcrowd- 
ing above  mentioned,  from  faulty  construction, 
or  from  lack  of  proper  sanitary  appliances.  (6) 
Inconvenient  distance  from  the  daily  work  of 
the  tenants. 

Whereas  it  has  been  stated  that,  in  a  specially 
constructed  building,  from  1200  to  1600 
tenants  can  be  accommodated  per  acre  without 
overcrowding,  while  the  same  area  would,  even 
in  a  "crowded  "  district  contain  only  some  300 
or  400  if  housed  in  the  old-fashioned  manner 
and  in  old-fashioned  dwellings,  it  is  reasonable 
to  expect  that  a  great  financial  profit  to  the 
owners  should  accompany  the  substitution  of 
"model"  dwellings  for  houses  of  the  old  un- 
satisfactory class.  According  to  reports,  events 
did  not,  in  the  earlier  days  of  the  movement, 
altogether  justify  these  expectations,  though 
some  of  the  companies  owning  industrial  dwell- 
ings realise  substantial  interest  on  their  capital. 
It  appears  that  legislation  while  facilitating  the 
acquisition  of  land  for  the  purpose  of  building 
model  blocks,  has  occasional!}^  given  such  delay 
and  publicity  to  the  transaction  as  to  prejudici- 
ally aff"ect  the  cost.  Hence  in  some  of  the 
provincial  towns  of  Great  Britain  the  more 
cautious  movements  of  the  purchasers,  even 
when  backed  by  legislation,  have  been  attended 
with  more  successful  results  tlian  similar  but 
more  open  negotiations  in  the  metropolis,  where 
the  knowledge  of  the  compulsory  powers  has 
led  to  exorbitant  demands  for  compensation. 
(At  the  same  time  see  the  evidence  on  p.  418 
of  the  Royal  Commission  Minutes,  and  the 
suggestions  there  made  as  to  the  terms  on 
which  the  Peabody  Trust  bought  from  the 
Board  of  Works.)  Further  it  has  been  stated 
by  experts  specially  called  in  to  advise  on  the 
financial  aspects  of  these  schemes,  that  ' '  to 
build  for  the  lowest  self-supporting  class  in 
central  positions  in  London  the  land  must 
practically  be  given."  This  statement  and  the 
fact  that  more  than  one  "Dwellings  Company  " 
now  secures  a  satisfactory  interest  on  its  outlay, 
are  to  be  reconciled  partly  by  the  circumstance 
that  it  is  not  always,  nor  perhaps  often,  the 
lowest  classes  who  occupy  the  "model"  dwell- 
ings, partly  by  the  fact  that  not  all  the  dwell- 
ings even  of  one  company  are  built  on  "central" 
sites,  and  partly  also  by  the  consideration  that 
the  associations  which  promote  these  buildings 
may  be  broadly  divided  into  two  classes  : — (1) 
Those  which  are  purely  philanthropic,  or  at 
least  do  not  make  a  dividend  their  first  aim. 
(2)  Those  whose  primary  object  is  to  realise  a 
large  proportion  of  rental  to  outlay.  It  is 
satisfactory,  however,  to  learn  from  the  pub- 
lished accounts  of  1890  that,  with  the  exception 


of  the  Peabody  Trustees,  even  the  most  philan- 
thropic of  these  institutions  realise  a  dividend 
of  from  4  to  5  per  cent,  the  percentage  of  gross 
rental  upon  cost  varying  from  7*6  to  9*1. 
During  that  year  the  Peabody  Trust  received  a 
gross  rental  of  5*1  per  cent  on  cost,  and  spent 
2*1  percent.  The  Improved  Industrial  Dwell- 
ings Co.,  whose  undertakings  have  been 
amongst  the  most  extensive,  pay  a  5  per  cent 
dividend,  while  4|  per  cent  is  reached  by  the 
Metropolitan  Association,  which  has  been  nearly 
fifty  years  in  existence.  The  Peabody  Trust, 
instituted  in  1862  during  the  lifetime  of  Mr. 
Peabody,  ranks  among  the  most  important  of 
the  metropolitan  agencies.  It  was  stated  in 
1881  that  whereas  the  rents  of  three-room  tene- 
ments in  their  buildings  varied  in  a  period  of 
five  years  from  3s.  lid.  to  4s.  4^d.  per  week, 
the  average  wages  of  the  tenants  of  these  rooms 
was  from  £1:3:1  to  £1  :  5  :  10.  Thus  less 
than  one-fifth  of  the  wages  was  expended  in  rent, 
a  satisfactory  condition  in  face  of  the  evidence 
given  before  the  Commission  that  in  dwellings 
of  the  unimproved  class  88  per  cent  of  the 
poor  population  paid  more  than  one -fifth  of 
their  income  in  rent,  46  per  cent  paying  from 
one-fourth  to  one-half,  while  3s.  10-|d.  might 
be  taken  as  the  average  rent  of  one  room  let  as 
a  tenement.  The  Trustees  at  the  time  of  the 
commission  were  stated  to  let  their  rooms  at 
about  20  per  cent  less  than  the  commercial 
companies,  their  charge  for  a  single  room  being 
2s.  and  upwards.  No  doubt  the  lowness  of 
their  rents  has  served  to  keep  down  the  rental 
in  the  "model"  dwellings  of  other  proprietors. 
There  is  great  competition  for  admission  to  the 
Peabody  buildings  in  the  more  popular  neigh- 
bourhoods, recommendations  of  good  character 
are  required  of  the  applicants,  and  thus  it  is  a 
sort  of  guarantee  of  respectability  to  have  lived 
in  a  Peabody  Building.  A  result  of  this  com- 
petition and  the  consequent  selection  of  appli- 
cants is  that  the  better  class  are  chosen,  and  con- 
sequently the  Trustees'  dwellings  are  practically 
not  available  fof  the  lowest  or  poorest  classes. 

An  epoch  in  the  early  history  of  the  "  dwell- 
ings "  movement  was  marked  by  the  erection, 
on  ground  adjoining  the  Great  Exhibition  of 
1851,  of  a  model  dwelling  from  designs  of  Mr. 
Roberts,  and  under  the  initiative  of  Prince 
Albert,  who  was  at  the  time  President  of  the 
Society  for  the  Improvement  of  the  Condition 
of  the  Labouring  Classes.  The  special  feature 
in  the  construction  of  this  block,  which  contained 
four  complete  dwellings  on  two  floors,  was  its 
fireproof  nature.  The  walls  were  of  special 
hollow  bricks,  and  the  floors  of  a  similar  material 
set  in  arches  and  covered  with  ' '  metallic  lava." 
Each  tenement  contained  a  living  room,  parents* 
'bedroom,  two  small  bedrooms,  a  scullery,  and  a 
"w.o.  (For  illustrations  and  descriptions  of 
this  building  see  The  Builder,  1851,  pp.  174, 
311,  343).     In  the  following  year  a  competition 


I 


DWELLINGS,  INDUSTRIAL 


was  instituted  at  Nottingham  for  designs  of 
similar  buildings  ;  and  a  block  of  dwellings, 
more  or  less  on  the  "Prince  Albert"  model, 
was  erected  at  Windsor.  About  the  same  date 
various  efforts  were  made  in  the  provinces  to 
improve  labourers'  dwellings,  chiefly  in  tHe  north 
of  England,  by  the  enterprise  of  large  owners  of 
land  or  employers  of  labour.  Such  were  the 
building  of  the  workmen's  colonies  at  Saltaire 
and  Copley,  by  Mr.  (afterwards  Sir  Titus)  Salt 
and  by  Mr.  Akroyd  respectively,  the  latter 
building  also  the  village  of  Akroydon.  Good 
examples  of  such  colonies  are  the  model  settle- 
ments at  Port  Sunlight  near  Liverpool,  Bourne- 
ville  near  Birmingham,  and  Earswick  near 
York.  In  1851  Mr.  Denison  built  a  set  of 
single  men's  lodgings  at  Leeds,  and  similar 
lodgings  were  built  in  Huddersfield  in  1854. 
Sir  Sydney  (then  Mr.)  Waterlow  was  among  the 
first  promoters  of  the  typical  modern  metro- 
politan artisans'  dwellings.  He  began  his 
operations  in  1860,  at  first  with  his  own  capital, 
and  built  no  fewer  than  ninety  tenements.  His 
next  step  was  the  formation  of  the  Improved 
Industrial  Dwellings  Company,  the  above-men- 
tioned "Society  for  the  Improvement  of  the 
Condition  of  the  Labouring  Classes,"  and  the 
"  Metropolitan  Association,"  being  already 
established.  The  principal  organisations  in 
existence  in  London  (1909)  are  the  Metropolitan 
Association  for  Improving  the  Dwellings  of  the 
Industrious  Classes,  dating  from  1847,  with 
fourteen  sets  of  dwellings  containing  1441  tene- 
ments (5105  rooms)  ;  the  Improved  Industrial 
Dwellings  Company  with  5421  tenements 
(19,945rooms) ;  the  Peabody  Fund  with  eighteen 
sets  of  dwellings  containing  5469  tenements 
(12,328  rooms)  ;  the  Artisans',  Labourers',  and 
General  Dwellings  Company,  ten  sets  of  buildings 
with  1467  tenements  (3495  rooms)  and  6195 
cottage  dwellings ;  the  East  End  Dwellings  Com- 
pany with  2096  tenements  (4276  rooms)  ;  the 
Guinness  Trust  with  eight  separate  buildings 
containing  2574  tenements  (5338  rooms)  ;  the 
six  Rowton  Houses,  hotels  for  working  men 
with  rooms  for  5162  persons.  These,  all  private 
enterprises,  working  on  a  commercial  basis, 
with  others  of  the  same  kind,  provide  accom- 
modation for  over  150,000  persons.  The  late 
Mr.  W.  R.  Sutton  in  1909  left  nearly  £2, 000, 000 
for  providing  good  working-class  dwellings,  and 
blocks  for  the  housing  of  300  families  have  been 
begun  in  the  City  Road.  As  early  as  1867 
thirty  towns  in  the  provinces  of  England  had 
formed  an  association  or  taken  some  definite 
action  towards  improving  the  dwellings  of 
artisans,  but  this  is  not  carried  out  on  a  large 
scale.  Newcastle,  Leeds,  Hull,  and  Dublin  are 
among  those  towns  in  which  private  enterprise 
assists  improved  housing.  Municipal  building 
has  extended  in  the  provinces.  Down  to  the 
end  of  1906,  142  local  authorities  (including 
the  London  County  Council  and  twelve  Metro- 


politan Boroughs)  had  put  into  practice  Part 
III.  of  the  Housing  Act  of  1890,  which  provides 
for  the  erection  of  working-class  dwellings. 
These  were  sixty -nine  County  Boroughs  and 
Town  Councils,  forty -nine  Urban  District 
Councils,  and  twelve  Rural  District  Councils. 
The  dwellings  consist  of  lodging-houses,  block 
dwellings,  tenement  houses,  cottage  flats,  and 
cottages,  providing  20,606  dwellings,  with 
56,949  rooms.  London,  Liverpool,  Manchester 
and  Salford,  Birmingham,  and  Newcastle,  Edin- 
burgh, Glasgow,  Aberdeen,  Dublin,  and  Belfast 
are  among  the  towns  which  have  done  most 
in  this  way.  The  figures,  however,  show  that 
municipal  building  has  done  less  in  the  whole 
United  Kingdom  than  private  enterprise  in 
London  alone. 

A  great  work  in  the  "housing  of  the  poor" 
was  carried  on  for  more  than  twenty  years  by 
Miss  Octavia  Hill  upon  a  system  of  her  own, 
which  is  known  by  her  name.  Miss  Hill,  who 
was  opposed  to  the  prevalent  methods  of  building 
and  conducting  *' model  dwellings,"  objects  to 
them,  among  other  reasons,  because  they  do 
not  help  the  most  necessitous  poor,  nor  can  they 
in  any  way  ameliorate  the  actually  criminal 
classes,  who  are  obviously  undesirable  tenants 
for  blocks.  They  are  a  nuisance  to  more  respect- 
able neighbours,  and  if  grouped  together  are 
destructive  to  property.  The  cardinal  point  of 
Miss  Hill's  "system"  is  a  carefully  organised 
method  of  rent  collection.  She  has  at  her 
service  a  body  of  unpaid  collectors  whose 
self-imposed  duty  is,  while  collecting  the  pay- 
ments due,  to  inspect  the  tenants  and  their 
manner  of  life,  and  by  every  means  of  personal 
influence  to  assist  the  more  degraded  to  im- 
provement. Though  Miss  Hill  has  built 
several  new  houses,  her  work  has  principally 
consisted  in  buying  up  old  buildings,  generally 
for  the  sake  of  tenants  already  occupying  them, 
over  whom  she  is  desirous  of  exercising  moral 
influence,  while  at  the  same  time  ameliorating 
the  condition  of  their  homes.  The  first  act  on 
acquiring  a  property  is,  if  needful,  "to  put  the 
drains,  water-supply,  and  roofs  to  rights." 
Other  improvements  follow  in  porportion  as 
the  tenant  shows  himself  appreciative  of  these 
attentions,  and  ready  to  protect  his  dwelling 
from  misuse  and  destruction. 

As  regards  the  general  principles  of  construc- 
tion which  are  found  to  be  most  successful  in 
block  dwellings,  it  may  be  noticed  that  the 
buildings  of  the  best  types,  though  varying, 
have  certain  essential  features  in  common. 
They  differ  from  ordinary  tenements  in  having 
a  staircase,  or  staircases,  which  are  not  only 
common  to  the  tenants,  but  open  to  the 
public  ;  the  door,  if  any,  at  the  entrance  being 
open  at  least  by  day.  Five  or  six  stories  is 
the  usual  height  ;  the  buildings  commonly 
stand  round  a  wide  square  or  quadrangle 
entered  by  an  archway  from  the  street,   the 


DWELLINGS,  INDUSTRIAL 


663 


entrance  to  the  staircases  being  from  within 
the  square.  Light  and  air  are  primary  con- 
siderations, and  tall  dwellings  should  not 
stand  in  a  narrow  street,  but  with  an  open 
space  round  them,  or  the  tenants  of  the  lower 
rooms  will  have  insufficient  light.  The  stair- 
cases are  sometimes  open  to  the  air,  but  if 
built  within  the  block,  should  be  lined  with 
glazed  bricks.  They  are  generally  so  tall  and 
narrow  that  top  light  is  insufficient,  and  in 
the  best  buildings  they  are  provided  with  good 
windows.  All  windows  of  rooms  should  open 
direct  into  the  space  in  front  or  back  of  the 
buildings,  not  into  narrow  areas,  as  it  is  import- 
ant to  get  direct  daylight.  Sanitary  accommo- 
dation is  one  of  the  debated  problems  among 
designers  of  these  buildings.  For  convenience, 
cheapness,  and  simplicity,  it  is  better  to  collect 
the  apparatus  into  a  distinct  portion  of  tlie 
building.  Where  the  tenements  are  arranged 
on  the  external  gallery  system,  with  only  one 
or  tv/o  staircases  in  a  block,  the  w.c.  accommo- 
dation is  sometimes  grouped  together  by  the 
staircases.  But  among  the  more  respectable 
class  of  residents  greater  privacy  is  preferred, 
and  a  separate  w.c.  is  provided  for  a  small 
group  of  tenants.  An  approved  arrangement 
is  that  on  each  floor  of  a  staircase  there  should 
be  four  sets  of  rooms,  one  wash-house  (with 
copper  washing  trays  and  a  bath)  serving  the 
whole  set  of  four,  and  two  sinks  and  closets. 
By  means  of  this  distribution  a  certain  privacy 
is  maintained,  and  in  the  matter  of  the  wash- 
house  an  objection  is  met  which  is  almost  fatal 
to  the  prospects  of  some  of  the  dwellings  in 
which  a  wash-house  common  to  the  block  is 
provided  in  the  upper  part  of  the  building. 
In  the  best  blocks,  however,  the  dwellings  are 
self-contained,  each  having  a  scullery  fitted  with 
copper  and  sink,  and  beyond  it,  shut  off  by  a 
door,  a  closet  and  coal-bunker. 

Tenements  in  model  dwellings  vary  in  size 
from  one  to  six  rooms,  but  by  far  the  greater 
number  consist  of  two.  Rents  (weekly)  vary 
from  4s.  6d.  for  2  rooms  to  15s.  6d.  for  6 
rooms  in  London  ;  3s.  for  2  rooms  to  7s.  9d.  for 
6  rooms  in  the  provinces.  In  Scotland  2s,  for 
one  room  to  6s.  5d.  for  3  rooms  ;  in  Ireland 
Is.  6d.  for  one  room  to  6s.  9d.  for  4  rooms. 

The  occupations  of  the  tenants  vary  so 
greatly  as  to  defy  analysis  ;  all  whose  work  is 
inoffensive  or  is  not  done  at  home  are  con- 
sidered suitable  tenants  if  respectable  ;  but  in 
well-managed  blocks  those  trades  are  considered 
inadmissible  which  can  be  in  any  way  obnoxious 
to  occupants  of  the  building.  It  is  important 
to  realise  the  proportion  of  wages  to  rent.  In 
a  set  of  one-roomed  tenements  rented  at  from 
3s.  to  4s.  the  wage-earners  were  found  to  make 
from  about  15s.  to  288.  a  week,  in  another 
building,  three-roomed  tenements  at  4s.  6d. 
were  occupied  by  families  in  which  the  father 
earned  from  25s.  to  30s. 


The  diflBculty  of  obtaining  sufficient  sites  in 
central  positions  has  induced  the  building  of 
blocks  of  artisans'  dwellings  in  suburban  dis- 
tricts. The  consequent  distance  of  the  occupants 
from  their  work  leads  to  two  difficulties  :  the 
impossibility  of  return  for  the  midday  meal,  and 
the  expense  of  travelling.  The  former  of  these 
has  been  obviated  by  the  action  of  many  em- 
ployers who  have  provided  mess-rooms  for  their 
work-people.  The  second  difficulty  is  partly 
met  by  the  institution  of  woikmen's  trains. 
These  trains  have  been  of  great  service  to  the 
working  classes  living  in  the  suburbs.  But  a 
family  in  which  there  are  two  or  three  wage- 
earners  has  so  much  to  pay  in  travelling  that 
the  cheapness  of  the  trains  is  not  a  sufficient 
compensation  for  the  added  expense  of  living 
far  from  work.  Again  there  are  some  classes 
of  work,  such  as  small  jobs  for  tailors,  in  which 
whole  families  are  often  engaged,  which  cannot 
be  carried  on  if  the  distance  between  the  shop 
and  the  home  is  great. 

To  meet  the  difficulties  which  attend  the 
acquisition  of  the  ownership  of  a  tenement  in 
a  block  dwelling,  the  Chambers  and  Offices 
Act  was  passed  in  1881.  Its  purpose  is  "to 
facilitate  the  management  of  blocks  of  buildings 
occupied  in  sections  as  separate  tenements,  and 
the  disposal  of  each  separate  tenement."  The 
number  of  small  houses  purchased  through 
Building  Societies  (q.v.)  by  members  of  the 
working  classes  shows  a  great  desire  on  their 
part  to  own  their  homes.  In  this  connection 
should  be  mentioned  the  work  of  the  "Tenant 
Co-operators,  Limited,"  a  society  formed  in  1888 
to  apply  to  the  owning  and  letting  of  workmen's 
dwellings  the  principle  of  co-operation.  This 
has  been  developed  on  slightly  different  lines 
carrying  out  tlie  method  known  as  Co-partner- 
ship Housing,  the  Ealing  Tenants,  Limited, 
1901,  being  the  first  society  entirely  doing  this. 
In  1905  a  central  organising  body  was  formed, 
called  the  Co-partnership  Housing  Council,  to 
encourage  and  assist  the  movement  which  is 
growing  with  great  rapidity.  Tenants  con- 
tribute a  share  towards  the  capital  with  which 
land  is  bought,  and  well  -  designed  and  well- 
placed  houses  are  built.  The  rents  allow  of  a 
return  of  5  per  cent  on  share  capital  and  4  per 
cent  on  loan  capital.  Surplus  profits  are  divided 
among  tenants  in  proportion  to  rental,  the 
amounts  being  credited  to  each  tenant  in  shares 
until  his  share  capital  equals  the  value  of  the 
house  he  rents,  which  then  becomes  his  own, 
his  subsequent  share  in  the  profits  being  paid 
to  him  in  cash.  There  are  now  (1909)  twelve 
societies.  The  movement  is  both  sound  and 
vigorous  and  promises  to  do  good  work  in  the 
future.  Its  sphere  is  at  i)resent  essentially 
suburban,  but  it  has  been  proposed  by  the 
Select  Committee  on  Rural  Housing  (see 
Reports)  that  a  Co-partnership  Housing  Society 
should  bo  formed  in  every  English  county. 


664 


DWELLINGS,  MODEL:   FRANCE 


The  rural  employers  of  labour  have,  in  a  large 
number  of  cases  all  over  the  country,  built  im- 
proved and  sanitary  cottages  for  their  employ6s. 
In  many  cases  this  work  has  been  one  of  pure 
philanthropy,  for  it  is  impossible  at  the  present 
rates  of  wages  to  demand  of  an  agriaultural 
labourer  a  rent  which  will  remunerate  the  builder 
of  a  model  cottage  in  a  genuinely  rm-al  district. 

A  substantial  diminution  in  overcrowding 
took  place  between  1891  and  1911,  the  percent- 
age of  overcrowded  population  having  dropped 
in  England  and  Wales  from  11-23  per  cent  in 
1891  to  8-20  per  cent  in  1911. 

[C.  Booth,  Life,  and  Labour  of  the  People  in 
London,  1st  Series,  vol.  3,  1904. — Journ.  of  Stat. 
Soc,  1875, 1891.— Royal  Inst.  Brit.  Arohts.  Trans- 
actions, 1866-1875. — Reports  of  Mansion  House 
Council  on  Dwellings  of  the  Poor. — Bd.  of  Trade 
Reports. — Cost  of  Living  of  Working  Classes,  Eng- 
land, 1908 — in  German  Towns,  1908 — in  French 
Towns,  1909 — Proceedings  of  International  Hotcs- 
ing  Congress,  Loudon,  1907. — New  Encyclopaedia 
of  Social  Reform. — Dewsnup,  Housing  Problem  in 
England. — Nettlefold,  Practical  Housing  Reform : 
— Practical  Town  Planning. — ShadweU,  Indus- 
trial Efficiency,  ch.  xi.  "Housing." — Co-partner- 
ship, and  works  recommended  therein  (monthly 
publication,  Bloomsbury  Sq.,  W.C.)]  P.  w. 

DWELLINGS,  Model,  of  Working  Classes 
IN  Francb.  Need  for  better  housing  of  the 
working  classes  in  France  was  brought  to  public 
notice  as  early  as  1851,  when  many  etlbrts  to- 
wards improvement  began.  In  1852  a  sub- 
vention of  10,000,000  francs  (£400,000)  was 
decreed  in  favour  of  improvements  in  workmen's 
dwellings,  i.e.  6,000,000  (£240,000)  to  raising 
asiles  at  Vincennes  and  Le  Vesinet ;  2,000,000 
(£80,000)  to  the  construction  of  seventeen 
houses  in  Paris  ;  and  2,000,000  (£80,000)  to 
builders,  includmg  £48,000  awarded  on  condi- 
tions in  Paris,  at  the  rate  of  one-third  of  expenses 
actually  incurred  in  building.  The  financial 
results  of  this  last  scheme  were  unsatisfactory. 
Napoleon  I II.  built  forty-one  houses  in  Paris,  and 
offered  them  to  a  workmen's  society  which  should 
subscribe  100,000  francs  (£4000).  The  Societe 
co-operative  immobili^re  accepted  the  offer. 

In  Paris  the  high  cost  of  land,  building 
materials,  and  labour  rendered  improvement 
difficult.  It  was  stated  in  1890,  that  6000 
francs  (say  £240)  was  the  lowest  sum  which  a 
detached  workman's  residence  could  cost  in 
Paris.  The  lowest  estimate  for  contiguous 
model  dwellings  was  5000  francs  (£200)  per 
house  ;  and,  in  each  case,  the  rent  was  fixed  at 
about  8  per  cent  per  annum  upon  the  capital. 
A  group  of  ten  houses,  sold  at  cost  price  (5500 
francs  [£220]  each)  to  the  SocUti  des  habitations 
ouvrikres  de  Pa^ssy-AtUeuil,  was  let  out  upon 
the  Mulhouse  system  (v.  infra).  Each  house 
contained  two  rooms,  a  kitchen,  cellar  and 
garden,  and  could  be  bought  by  a  twenty  years' 
tenancy  at  from  450  to  500  francs  (£18  to  £20) 
a  year.     The  main  difficulties  encountered  in 


Paris  were  the  low  wages  of  the  woikmen  con- 
cerned, their  deficient  sanitary  education,  and 
want  of  attachment  to  a  particular  residence. 

A  pioneer  effort  was  that  at  Mulhouse  (now 
German  territory)  where  was  founded  in  1853 
the  Soddi  mulhoiisienne  des  Citis  ouvrieres, 
under  the  presidency  of  M.  Jean  DoUfus.  Its 
shares  of  5000  francs  (£200)  apiece  originally 
numbered  sixty,  and  were  held  by  twelve 
persons,  but  were  increased  to  seventy -one 
divided  among  twenty  holders.  300,000  francs 
(£12,000)  of  the  subvention  above,  referred 
to  were  received  from  the  emperor.  Small 
houses,  with  separate  gardens,  were  built  and 
offered  to  tenants  at  a  yearly  rent  of  8  per 
cent  on  the  cost  price.  Share  capital  might 
not  receive  more  than  4  per  cent.  Any  surplus 
after  payment  of  expenses  was  devoted  to 
works  of  public  utility.  The  distinguishing 
feature  of  the  society,  however,  was  its  system 
of  sale.  By  advancing  about  one -tenth  of 
the  cost  of  the  house  the  tenant  became  its 
incipient  owner.  A  yearly  rent  of  about  10 
per  cent  on  the  cost  paid  for  a  period  of  from 
12  to  15  years  made  him  the  absolute  owner. 
Interest  upon  the  cost  of  the  house  was  cal- 
culated at  5  per  cent,  and  the  same  interest 
was  allowed  upon  all  sums  paid  by  the  tenant 
over  and  above  ordinary  rent.  The  amount 
standing  to  a  tenant's  credit  was  paid  over  in 
full  in  case  of  his  death,  removal,  etc.  The 
experiment  yielded  excellent  financial  and 
moral  results.  By  1889,  1124  houses,  costing 
3,485,275  francs  (£139,400);^ had  been  builtand 
sold  ;  4,584,020  francs  (£183,360)  had  been 
received  ;  sums  due  amounted  to  424,950  francs 
(£17,000).  Rents  were  always  regularly  paid. 
The  occupants  of  the  houses  exceeded  8000. 
The  rules  forbade  sub-letting.  One  family  only 
resided  under  each  roof.  And  a  house  once 
acquired  might  not,  without  the  directors' 
sanction,  be  resold  within  ten  years.  The  price 
of  a  house,  originally  about  2500  francs  (£100), 
was  in  1890  upwards  of  5000  francs  (£200). 
The  rise  was  partially  explained  by  the  ex- 
haustion of  the  subvention  in  the  construction 
of  roads,  drains,  and  so  forth  at  an  early  stage. 
Such  expenses  were  afterwards  thrown  upon 
houses  as  they  were  built.  Houses  were  fre- 
quently mortgaged  by  their  tenants.  At  Lille, 
in  1865,  a  society  very  similar  to  that  of 
Mulhouse  was  started  —  the  municipality 
guaranteeing  5  per  cent  interest  on  its  capital 
up  to  2,000,000  francs  (£80,000).  Napoleon 
III.  presented  100,000  francs  (£4000)  to  the 
society.  At  Havre  the  Mulhouse  system  was 
adopted  by  a  society  founded  in  1871,  capital 
200,000  francs  (£8000).  The  mimicipality 
voted  it  a  subvention  of  25,000  francs  (£1000) 
and,  following  the  example  of  Lille,  offered 
a  guarantee  of  interest  upon  capital  up  to 
500,000  francs  (£20,000).  By  1890  117 
houses  had  been  built,  and  half  of  them  sold. 


DWELLINGS,  MODEL:   FRANCE 


665 


At  Orleans  a  society,  founded  by  two  workmen 
in  1879,  had  by  1890  built  and  sold  220 
houses,  and  paid  5  per  cent  upon  its  capital, 
then  of  450,000  francs  (£9000).  At  Nancy  a 
society  of  200,000  francs  (£8000)  capital,  by 
the  same  date  built  and  sold  57  houses,  costing' 
from  4500  (£180)  to  7000  francs  (£280).  It 
is  said  that  this  society  paid  too  much  for  its 
land.  Having  paid  5  per  cent  up  to  1884,  it 
then  fell  to  2^  per  cent,  and  was  wound  u]). 
At  Rouen  a  society  with  200,000  francs  capital 
'£8000)  was  formed  in  1885,  and  a  block  of  six 
houses  was  built  to  accommodate  ninety-five 
families.  Interest  on  shares  was  limited  to  4 
per  cent.  By  1890  there  were  seventy  tenants 
in  residence,  of  whom  twenty  were  small  em- 
ployes. The  Avages  of  tenants  ranged  from 
600  francs  (£24)  to  1200  francs  (£48)  a  year. 
Rents  ranged  from  87  francs  (£3  ;  10  :  0)  (one 
room)  to  450  francs  (£18)  (four  rooms)  a  year. 
These  prices  compared  favourably  with  those 
of  other  lodgings  far  less  comfortable  and 
healthy  in  the  same  central  quarter.  Societies 
similar  to  those  described  were  established  at 
St.  Quentin,  Amiens,  Nantes,  Lyons,  Rheinis, 
and  elsewhere  (that  of  Rheims  being  on  a 
co-operative  basis),  undertaking  the  improve- 
ment of  old  dwellings  as  well  as  the  con- 
struction of  new.  At  Lyons,  Marseilles,  and 
other  towns,  savings  banks  were  encouraged 
to  invest  their  profits  in  aid  of  the  construction 
of  workmen's  houses. 

Ein[)loyers  engaging  regularly  a  laige  number 
of  hands,  in  many  cases  supplied  their  opera- 
tives with  suitable  houses  rent  free  within  easy 
distance  of  their  work.  Among  others  may  be 
named  the  settlements  of  Anzin,  Ijcaueourt, 
Blanzy,  Commentry,  Le  Creusot,  ]\laine,  and 
Noiseul.  The  experiment  of  M.  Jean  Godin  at 
Guise  is  described  under  FAMiLisTfeRE  {q.v.). 

There  is  substantial  agreement  among  French 
writers  as  to  the  superiority  of  suburban 
cottages  over  town  dwellings. 

[Jules  Simon,  VOuvrierr,  Paris,  1861. — Le 
Travail,  Paris,  1866.— E.  Miiller  et  E.  Cacheux, 
Les  Ilahitations  ouvrieres  en  tons  pays,  Paris,  1879. 
— Marjolin,  Les  Causes  et  les  effects  des  logements 
insalubres,  Paris,  1881. — Du  Mesnil,  L' Llabitation 
du  pauvre  d  Paris,  Paris,  1882.  —  E.  Laurent, 
Les  Logements  insaluhres,  Paris,  1882. — G.  Picot, 
Un  Devoir  social  et  les  logements  d'ouvriers,  Paris, 
1885. — E.  Cacheux,  Habitations  ouvrieres  et  pour 
employes,  Laval,  1885. — E.  Cheysson,  La  Que.stion 
des  habitations  ouvrieres  en  France  et  d  Vetranger, 
Paris,  1886. — A.  Delaire,  Les  Logements  d'ouvriers 
et  le  devoir  des  classes  dirigeantes,  Lyons,  1886. 
— A.  Raffalovich,  Le  I^ogement  de  Vouvrier  et  du 
pauvre,  Paris,  1887. — A.  Perrot,  Les  Citis  ouvrieres 
de  Mulhouse  (4th  ed.)  Mulhouse  and  Paris,  1889. 
— E.  Rostand,  Questions  d'iconomie  socicde  dans 
une  grande  ville  populaire  [i.e.  Marseilles),  Paris, 
1889. —  Compte  rendu  du  Gongris  international 
des  habitations  d  bon  marchi  {Official  lieport  of 
tJie  Paris  Exhibition,  1889).— 0."  Triidiuger,  Die 


Arbeiterwohnungs/rage,  Preisschrift  (1889). — 
Board  of  Trade  Report,  "  Cost  of  Living  in  French 
Towns,"  1909.]  h.  H. 

A  gi-eat  advance  !in  the  development  of  the 
housing  of  the  working  classes  in  France  took 
place  in  1894,  when  a  law  was  passed  to  promote 
the  building  of  improved  dwellings  bearing  the 
name  and  putting  into  practice  the  principles 
of  M.  Siegfried,  the  founder  in  1889  of  a 
society  called  the  Socidc  Fraw^aise  des  habita- 
tions d  bon  7narcM.  More  recent  laws  are  the 
Public  Health  Act  of  1902  and  the  Housing  of 
the  Working  Classes  Act  1906,  followed  by 
regulations  drawn  up  in  1907.  The  former  act 
empowers  municipalities  to  buy  land  com- 
pulsorily  in  connection  with  providing  healthy 
habitations.  The  act  of  1906  established 
Gomites  de  patronage  in  every  department.  It 
provides  grants  in  aid  of  working-class  dwellings 
and  remits  certain  taxes  on  tliose  that  fulfil 
certain  conditions.  Under  its  auspices  housing 
societies  are  formed  and  public  bodies,  such  as 
savings  banks,  charitable  institutions,  etc.,  are 
encouraged  to  invest  money  in  l»uildings  con- 
nected with  these  societies.  There  are  forty- 
six  societies  in  Paris  alone  and  many  in  the 
[U'ovinces.  The  standard  of  good  housing  is 
still  lower  in  France  than  in  England.  Single 
dwellings  are  far  less  frequent  in  France,  and 
there  is  also  a  much  larger  proportion  of  small 
tenements,  consisting  of  one  to  three  rooms  only, 
in  that  country  than  in  England,  Rents  are 
generally  lower  in  France  than  in  England. 
The  provision,  mentioned  above,  by  large  em- 
ployers. Mining  Companies,  Railway  Companies, 
and  manufacturers,  notably  MM.  Schneider  and 
Creusot,  of  dwellings  for  tlieir  work-people  has 
made  great  strides.  Their  houses  are  excellently 
built  and  arranged  and  have  large  gardens. 

Housing  reform,  which  meets  with  great 
difficulties  in  Germany  owing  to  the  recent 
great  increase  in  urban  population,  has  been 
vigorous  in  both  public  and  private  eflbrt, 
especially  during  the  last  tweiity  years.  S{)aco 
cannot  here  be  given  for  an  account  of  the  work 
in  this  or  other  foreign  countries.  See  Board 
of  Trade  Jteport,  "Cost  of  Living  in  German 
Towns,"  1908  ;  Encyclopcedia  Brilannica,  11th 
ed.),  voL  13,  "Housing." 

DWELLINGS  (Regulations  by  the  State 
IN  England).  The  regulation  of  dwellings  by 
the  state  m  England  is  of  very  modern  origin. 
Down  to  the  nineteenth  century  the  responsi- 
bilities of  the  government  in  matters  of  health 
were  ignored  or  confined  to  the  ideals  of  in- 
dividuals. The  first  impetus  to  any  recognition 
of  such  responsibility  was  given  by  the  poor-law 
commissioners  in  their  fourth  and  fifth  reports 
(1838-39),  and  probably  originated  with  their 
-secretary  Mr.  Chadwick  (afterwards  Sir  E. 
X/HADWIck).  The  conmiissioners  utilised  the 
opportunity  afibrded  by  a  j)urely  financial 
question  to  direct  inquiries  into  the  "  prevalence 


666 


DWELLINGS:   STATE  REGULATION  IN  ENGLAND 


of  certain  physical  causes  of  fever  in  the  metro- 
polis," and  also  into  "some  of  the  physical  causes 
of  sickness  and  mortality  to  which  the  poor  are 
particularly  exposed."  A  further  report  on  the 
sanitary  condition  of  the  labouring  population 
of  Great  Britain,  issued  by  them  in  1842,  directed 
attention  to  "the  condition  of  the  residences 
of  the  labouring  classes  where  disease  is  found 
to  be  most  prevalent,"  and  to  "circumstances 
connected  with  the  internal  economy  and  bad 
ventilation  of  places  of  work,  lodging-houses, 
dwellings,  etc."  Already  in  1840  the  subject 
had  attracted  the  attention  of  the  House  of 
Commons,  and  a  select  committee  had  reported 
in  favour  of  a  general  buildings  act,  a  general 
sewerage  act,  the  establishment  of  a  central 
board  of  health,  and  the  appointment  of 
sanitary  inspectors  in  large  towns.  Legislation 
on  the  subject  falls  under  two  heads,  viz.  (L) 
to  enforce  sanitation,  and  (XL)  to  facilitate  the 
repair  or  removal  of  insanitary  buildings. 

I.  Under  this  head  may  be  mentioned : — 
(a)  Two  acts  passed  by  the  influence  of  Lord 
Shaftesbury  in  1857  to  control  common  lodging- 
houses.  Subsequent  acts,  1866-67,  have  placed 
the  control  of  these  houses,  usually  distinguished 
by  having  a  common  sitting-room,  with  the 
police.  (&)  For  London,  the  Nuisances  Re- 
moval Act  of  1855,  extended  and  amended  by 
the  Acts  of  1866  and  of  1876.  By  the  first  of 
these  a  nuisance  is  defined  to  include  foul  and 
defective  drains  and  cesspools,  accumulations 
of  filth,  and  overcrowding  ;  information  as  to 
such  may  be  given  by  persons  immediately 
affected,  by  any  two  inhabitant  householders, 
or  by  any  official  person  to  the  local  authority, 
who  is  bound  to  ascertain  by  inspection  the 
truth  of  the  information,  and  if  satisfied,  to  call 
on  the  person  responsible — in  cases  of  structure, 
the  owner — to  remove  the  nuisance.  Failure 
to  do  so  may  be  met  by  an  order  issued  by  a 
magistrate,  and  ultimately  by  the  closing  of 
the  house.  Under  the  Act  of  1866  the  local 
authority  is  empowered  to  make  regulations  in 
the  case  of  houses  occupied  by  more  than  a 
single  family  (1)  for  fixing  the  number  of 
inmates,  (2)  for  registration,  (3)  for  inspection, 
(4)  fo7  general  supervision,  (5)  for  cleansing, — 
and  to  inflict  penalties  in  cases  of  neglect.  To 
these  powers  the  Act  of  1874  added  similar 
powers  with  respect  to  ventilation,  paving,  and 
drainage,  separation  of  the  sexes,  notification 
of  infectious  or  contagious  disease,  which  last 
was  made  compulsory  by  the  Act  of  1889. 
Further  regulations,  of  a  more  minute  kind, 
and  also  as  to  new  buildings,  are  contained  in 
the  Metropolis  Management  Acts  of  1855  and 
1862.  Whilst  the  above  refer  to  existing 
buildings,  the  erection  of  new  buildings  in 
London  is  regulated  by  the  Metropolitan  Build- 
ing Acts  of  1855  and  1878.  (c)  Outside 
London  the  action  of  the  local  authority  is 
governed  by  the  Public  Health  Act  of  1875. 


As  in  London,  the  local  authority  is  empowered 
to  make  by-laws  dealing  with  houses  occupied 
by  more  than  one  family,  and  also  for  the 
notification  of  disease.  It  is  compelled  to 
appoint  medical  officers  and  inspectors  of 
nuisances,  to  report  on  the  sanitary  condition 
of  the  district  generally.  Procedure  for  dealing 
with  sanitation  is  still  regulated  (1911)  by 
these  acts  and  by  a  Public  Health  Act  (London) 
1891,  amending  and  consolidating  j^revious 
legislation.  The  work  of  the  authorities  in- 
cludes, besides  the  details  mentioned  above, 
construction,  with  special  attention  to  the  pre- 
vention of  damp  and  decay,  the  cleaning  of 
streets,  the  removal  of  house-refuse,  the  pro- 
vision of  sanitary  conveniences,  and  the  water- 
supply. 

II.  The  early  acts  designed  to  provide  for 
the  demolition  of  insanitary  buildings  are  the 
Torrens'  Acts  (1868,  1879  and  1882),  so  called 
from  their  promoter,  W.  T.  Torrens,  and  the 
Cross  Acts  (1875,  1879  and  1882)  from  Viscount 
Cross.  The  former  apply  to  single  or  small 
groups  of  houses,  while  the  latter  deal  with 
large  areas,  i.e.  places  with  more  than  25,000 
inhabitants.  By  the  Housing  of  the  Working 
Classes  Act  of  1885  the  administration  of  the 
sanitary  acts,  hitherto  permissive,  was  made 
compulsory  upon  the  local  authority  ;  all  son- 
tracts  with  regard  to  buildings  presupposed  a 
sanitary  state  ;  the  Cross  Acts  were  extended 
to  every  urban  sanitary  district ;  the  local 
authority  was  empowered  to  build  lodging- 
houses  and  to  make  loans  to  building  societies. 
The  Housing  of  the  Working  Classes  Act  1890, 
amended  in  1894,  1900  and  1903,  and  the 
Housing,  Town  Planning,  etc..  Act  1909,  carry 
on  now  ( 1 9 1 1 )  the  sam  e  principles.  By  Part  i.  of 
the  Act  of  1890,  the  local  authority  may  order 
an  inspection  of  suspected  houses,  and  if 
necessary,  prepare  an  "improvement  scheme" 
to  be  laid  before  the  Local  Government  Board 
which,  in  its  turn,  issues  an  order,  confirmed 
by  special  Act  of  Parliament,  to  the  local 
authority  to  destroy  the  premises  after  paying 
compensation.  Under  Part  ii.  the  local 
authority  can  simply  serve  notices  on  owners 
to  repair  such  premises  at  their  own  expense, 
and  on  failure  to  comply  may  issue  an  order  to 
close  them,  followed  by  an  order  to  destroy 
them  if  action  is  delayed  for  three  months. 
This  involves  the  consideration  of  re-housing 
displaced  persons,  by  the  purchase  of  land 
and  raising  of  loans,  dealt  with  under  Part 
iii.  the  provisions  of  which  have  been  since 
strengthened  and  in  some  cases  made  com- 
pulsory, where  before  only  permissive,  by  the 
Act  of  1909.  This  Act  enforces  with  greater 
stringency  the  regulations  for  the  closing  and 
destruction  of  insanitary  houses.  It  extends 
the  powers  described  above  to  County  Councils, 
and  increases  those  of  the  local  authorities. 

iRepts.  of  Commission  (1885)  and  Committees 


DWELLINGS— EAENINGS  OF  MANAGEMENT 


667 


H.  G.,  1881-82.— H.  Duff,  Legal  Obligations  in 
respect  of  Dwellings  of  the  Poor,  1884. —  What  to 
do  and  how  to  do  it.  Manual  of  law  affecting  the 
Housing  and  Sanitary  Condition  of  Londoners.  — 
E.  Spencer,  Artizans'  and  Labourers'  Bioellings, 
1881.— D.  Schloss,  Homes  of  the  Poor,  1885.— 
Repts.  of  Mansion  House  Council  on  the  Dtoellings 
of  the  Poor,  1885,  seq. — C.  S.  Loch,  DiceUings  of 


the  Poor,  1882. — Rawlinson,  Old  Lessons  in  Sani- 
tary Science  revived,  1883. — Aschrott,  Verein  fur 
Socialpolitik,  1886. — Dwellings  of  the  Poor,  Kept. 
of  Investigation  by  Church  of  Scotland,  Glasgow, 
1891. — Booth,  Life  and  Labour  of  the  People  in 
London,  1st  Series,  vol.  3. — E.  R.  Dewsnup,  The 
Housing  Problem  in  England. — Co-partnership, 
esp.  Jan.  and  Aug.  1910.]  L.  R.  P. 


EAGLE.  United  States  standard  gold  coin 
of  the  value  of  ten  dollars,  weight  258  grains, 
fineness  900,  value — English  standard  (916*6 
fineat£3  :  17  :  10|anounce)£2  :  1  :  1^,  French 
standard  (900  fine)  51*83  francs.  Also  double, 
half,  and  quarter  eagles  of  the  same  fineness 
and  of  proportionate  weight.  f.  e.  a. 

EARNEST  MONEY.  Probably  derived 
from  the  same  root  as  the  word  Arles  (q.v.), 
which  is  used  in  some  English  dialects,  and 
can  be  traced  from  the  Latin  word  arrha,  a 
sum  of  money  paid  down  on  conclusion  of  a 
bargain  as  a  security  for  its  due  performance. 
It  generally  becomes  forfeited  in  case  the  bar- 
gain remains  unperformed,  but  this  depends  on 
the  an-angement  between  the  parties.  The 
payment  of  earnest  money  establishes  the 
validity  of  a  contract  for  the  sale  of  goods  of 
a  value  exceeding  £10,  which  might  otherwdse 
be  void  under  the  statute  of  frauds  {e.g.  the 
administration  of  the  estates  of  deceased  persons, 
the  taking  of  partnership  accounts,  foreclosure 
and  redemption  of  mortgages,  the  execution  of 
trusts,  partition  actions,  guardianship  matters, 
etc.)  E.  s. 

EARNINGS  AND  INTEREST  FUND. 
This  term  was  employed  by  Professor  and  Mrs. 
Marshall  {Economies  of  Industry,  bk.  ii,  ch.  vi. 
§  3,  old  edition)  to  denote  that  part  of  the 
"net-income  of  the  country"  which  remains 
"after  deducting  rent  and  taxes."  The  share 
of  this  income  which  "the  landlord  can  claim 
as  rent"  is,  they  remarked,  "fixed  by  definite 
economic  laws,"  and  the  share  taken  by  the 
state  as  taxes  is  arbitrary  in  character ;  and  the 
amount,  therefore,  "which  remains  after  de- 
ducting rent  and  taxes  from  the  net  annual 
income  "  may  be  regarded  as  a  "given  fund," 
and  called  the  "Wages  and  Profits  Fund,"  or 
the  "  Earnings  and  Interest  Fund."  The  latter 
expression  is  preferred  because  the  earnings  of 
management  are  "  similar  in  nature  "  to  those 
of  other  kinds  of  labour,  and  "  are  in  the  long- 
run  governed  by  the  same  laws."  It  seems 
therefore  better  to  classify  the  receipts  of  the 
employer  (see  Employers  and  Employed). 
so  far  as  they  represent  earnings  of  manage- 
ment, together  with  other  earnings,  and  to 
include  his  receipts,  so  far  as  they  represent 
interest  on  capital,  under  the  same  head  as 
interest  generally. 

[See  also  Professor  Marshall's  article  on  "Theories 


and  Facts  about  Wages, "  printed  in  the  Report  oj 
the  Industrial  Remuneration  Conference,  1887, 
pp.  186,  etc.  In  his  Principles  of  Economics,  2nd 
ed.,  bk.  vi.  ch.  ii.  §  1,  footnote  2,  Professor  Mar- 
shall adduces  reasons  for  withdrawing  the  expres- 
sion as  being  liable  to  misunderstanding.  He 
would  substitute  the  idea  of  a  stream  or  flow  for 
that  of  a  fund,  and  would  not  "put  rent  aside," 
in  the  way  the  phrase  might  suggest.  ]      L.  L.  P. 

EARNINGS  OF  MANAGEMENT.  A 
technical  term  for  one  of  the  elements  of  j^ro- 
fits,  according  to  classical  English  economics. 
Profits,  regarded  by  Mill  as  the  return  to  capital, 
are  divided  by  him  into  three  portions :  interest, 
insurance  for  risk,  and  wages  of  superintend- 
ence, or  earnings  of  management,  as  they  are 
now  more  commonly  called.  They  consist  of  all 
the  profit  that  is  left  over  after  the  other  two 
elements  have  been  abstracted  ;  and  unfortun- 
ately, according  to  the  threefold  division,  it  is 
impossible  in  any  other  way  to  allocate  the  share 
which  falls  to  management.  We  have  an  exact 
criterion  of  interest  on  borrowed  capital,  on 
first-class  security  in  consols  and  corporation 
stocks.  Risk  generally  fixes  its  own  price  by 
means  of  insurance  ;  but  there  is  no  scale  or 
measure  for  the  earnings  of  management,  and 
in  consequence  they  are  held  to  vary  with  each 
individual  case,  though  as  a  greater  profit  may 
be  considered  as  roughly  representing  a  greater 
quantity  of  business  capacity,  the  one  should 
roughly  measure  the  other. 

The  earnings  of  management,  being  in  reality 
a  payment  for  skilled  labour,  are  in  a  proper 
sense  wages  ;  and  they  appear  in  the  market  as 
such  in  the  countless  instances  where  business 
supervision  is  delegated  to  subordinates.  As 
understood  generally,  they  embrace  the  great 
bulk  of  profits,  however.  There  is  thus  a 
difficulty  in  bringing  under  the  same  term  the 
great  percentages  on  capital  frequently  earned 
as  profits,  a-nd  the  comparatively  small  salaries 
attached  to  the  delegated  management  of 
business  —  a  difficulty  which  the  admitted 
superiority  of  personal  supervision  is  not  suffi- 
cient to  solve.  A  limited  liability  company 
for  banking,  insurance,  or  other  purposes 
divides  among  its  shareholders  say  8  to  10  per 
cent.  Half  of  this,  at  the  very  least,  is  earn- 
ings of  management,  according  to  hypothesis. 
But  it  goes  to  people  who  do  not  manage  the 
concern  ;  while,  as  to  those  who  do,  their  salaries 
are  fixed  by  the  demand  for  and  supply  of 


668 


EARNINGS  OF  MANAGEMENT— EASTERLINGS 


business  power,  so  that  the  management  of  the 
business  is  paid  for  at  its  full  price.  It  would 
therefore  seem  that  there  is  still  an  element  in 
profits,  unaccounted  for,  which  cannot  properly 
be  held  as  covered  by  the  term  earnings  of 
management.  • 

With  this  proviso,  however,  the  form  of 
wages  may  be  in  general  considered  as  the  price 
accruing  to  the  capitalist  for  the  services  he 
renders  in  managing  his  business,  and  his 
capacity  as  being  measured  and  determined  by 
that  price.  The  exercise  of  this  capacity  can- 
not, by  any  careful  method  of  reasoning,  be 
counted  as  anything  but  labour,  unless  indeed 
that  term  be  unscientifically  restricted  to  manual 
labour  only, — a  labour  which  is  employed 
to  develop  a  visible  and  material  product.  It 
is,  in  the  highest  meaning  of  the  words,  skilled 
labour  ;  and  yet  it  differs  in  one  singular  respect 
from  almost  every  form  of  work  so  classified. 
The  skilled  workman  in  general,  whether  his 
energy  be  that  of  brain  or  muscle,  whether  he 
be  mechanic  or  scientific,  artisan,  journeyman, 
lawyer,  doctor,  or  Avriter,  works  in  a  particular 
industry,  within  the  compass  of  which  his 
sphere  is  limited.  In  a  word,  his  labour  is 
specialised.  The  work  of  business  management, 
on  the  other  hand,  is  as  little  specialised  as 
anything  outside  of  mere  muscular  labour-power 
can  be.  Professor  Marshall  gives  two  reasons 
for  .this  {Principles,  1st  ed.,  vol.  i.  p.  643)  : 
first,  that  every  one  has  to  manage  the  business 
of  his  own  life,  and  secondly,  because  technical 
knowledge  is  becoming  in  most  cases  subordi- 
nate to  the  non-specialised  faculties  of  judgment, 
resource,  and  the  like.  It  may  be  suggested 
that  perhaps  the  cause  of  the  wide  scope  of 
business  power  is  that  it  rests  upon  just  those 
faculties  which  underlie  all  technical  or  special 
skiU,  plus  versatility.  It  would  be  a  gi-eat 
mistake  to  suppose  that  this  faculty  is  not  a 
talent  in  itself,  and  quite  apart  from  other 
species  of  ability.  Many  men  possess  qualities 
which  place  them  in  a  distinguished  position  in 
some  sphere  of  activity,  who  yet  are  not  fitted 
to  manage  any  public  business,  and  sometimes 
show  themselves,  notwithstanding  the  universal 
training  above  mentioned,  singularly  unfortu- 
nate in  the  management  of  their  own.  No  more 
striking  instance  of  the  existence  of  a  special 
faculty  of  business  power  can  be  found  than 
that  of  the  number  of  men,  eminent  in  thought 
and  action,  who  have  turned  out  indifferent  or 
incapable  statesmen. 

Earnings  of  management,  being  in  reality  a 
species  of  wages  paid  for  a  particular  kind  of 
labour,  are  regulated  by  the  supply  of  business 
capacity  in  a  community,  and  the  demand  for 
managers.  It  must  be  noticed,  however,  that 
the  phrase  is  commonly  used  to  denote  all  that 
remains  of  profits  after  rent  and  interest  are 
deducted.  In  purely  productive  industries 
there  may  seem  to  be  little  distinction  between 


the  two  ;  but  in  retail  business  the  difference  ia 
important.  In  the  latter,  the  gross  profit  does 
not  principally  depend  on  the  amount  of 
capital  employed,  but  on  the  number  of  trans- 
actions performed ;  and  in  these  industries,  as 
to  a  lesser  extent  in  all,  the  profits  proper  which 
accompany  success  are  far  in  excess  of  the 
market  value  of  the  business  capacity  of  the 
capitalist.  Used  in  the  wider  sense,  the  phrase 
covers  all  the  advantage  that  fortuitous  circum- 
stances, monopoly,  or  other  causes  in  trade  may 
confer  on  an  owner  or  investor  of  capital  (see 
CoNJUNCTUR  ;  Dearness,  Artificial  ;  Mono- 
poly). M.  G.  D. 

EASEMENT.  The  owner  of  one  piece  of 
land  may  be  allowed  to  exercise  cei-tain 
rights  over  another  piece  of  land  belonging  to  a 
different  owner.  If  these  rights  consist  of  the 
privilege  of  taking  away  tangible  objects  (e.g. 
peat,  underwood,  fish,  etc.),  they  are  called 
profits  ;  in  all  other  cases  they  are  called  ease- 
ments. The  piece  of  land  to  which  the  benefit 
of  an  easement  attaches  is  called  the  "domi- 
nant tenement "  ;  the  one  which  is  subject  to 
its  burden  has  the  name  of  the  "  servient  tene- 
ment." If  the  owner  of  the  dominant  tene- 
ment is  entitled  to  use  the  servient  tenement 
for  certain  purposes  {e.g.  for  the  purpose  of 
walking  over  it  or  driving  cattle  over,  or  taking 
a  drain  through  it),  the  easement  is  called  an 
"afl^mative"  one  ;  if,  on  the  other  hand,  the 
owner  of  the  servient  tenement  is  restrained 
from  exercising  his  privileges  of  ownership  in 
certain  ways  {e.g.  from  erecting  buildings  which 
obstruct  the  lights  of  the  dominant  tenement, 
or  from  removing  buildings  so  as  to  take  away 
the  support  from  a  wall  on  the  dominant  tene- 
ment), the  easement  is  called  a  "negative"  one. 
Easements  are  acquired  (1)  by  express  grant 
from  the  owner  of  the  dominant  tenement ;  (2) 
by  implied  grant ;  this  arises  when  part  of  the 
property  is  sold  having  apparently  privileges 
in  the  nature  of  easements  relating  to  another 
part  of  the  property,  e.g.  when  a  house  is  sold 
enjoying  certain  lights,  in  consequence  of  an 
adjoining  piece  of  land  belonging  to  the  same 
owner  not  having  been  built  over,  the  o^vner 
will  not  after  the  sale  be  allowed  to  erect  build- 
ings obstructing  such  lights  ;  (3)  by  prescrip- 
tion, i.e.  by  enjoyment  for  a  certain  number  of 
years.  The  subject  of  easements  is  treated 
very  fully  in  the  notes  to  Sury  - .  Pigot,  in 
Tudor's  Leading  Cases  on  Real  Property ;  see 
also  Gale  on  Easements  ;  Goddard  on  Easements 
(see  Property,  Law  of).  e.  s. 

EASTERLINGS.  This  name  was  given  in 
the  middle  ages  to  the  German  merchants  who 
visited  England,  and  ultimately  came  to  be 
applied  generally  to  the  members  of  the  Hanse- 
atic  League.  Mediaeval  law  in  all  countries 
connected  the  licence  to  trade  with  nationality. 
The  foreigner  had  no  rights,  except  such  as 
could  be  acquired  by  individuals  or  communities 


EASTERLINGS—EAST  INDIA  COMPANY 


669 


who  could  afford  to  purchase  them  from  the 
ruler  of  the  country.  In  order  to  obtain  such 
trading  privileges  in  England,  the  German  mer- 
chants formed  themselves  into  a  hansa  or  guild. 
The  original  hansa  in  London,  which  has  its 
origin  in  the  reign  of  Edgar,  was  formed  by  the 
merchants  of  Cologne.  They  continued  to 
have  a  monopoly  of  trading  privileges  until  the 
13th  century,  though  the  natives  of  other 
towns  had  succeeded  in  gaining  admission,  and 
the  association  had  groAvn  to  include  traders 
from  the  Rhine  valley  and  Westphalia.  But 
the  rising  towns  of  northern  Germany  resented 
the  exclusive  pretensions  of  Cologne,  and  set 
themselves  to  break  down  the  monopoly.  In 
1266  and  1267,  Hamburg  and  Liibeok  were 
allowed  to  form  hansas  of  their  own,  on  the 
model  of  that  of  Cologne.  Under  Edward  I. 
these  three  associations  were  united  into  the 
great  German  hansa,  of  which  we  find  the  first 
documentary  mention  in  1282.  The  buildings 
of  this  corporation  on  the  banks  of  the  Thames, 
consisting  of  dwellings  and  warehouses,  were 
known  as  the  Steelyard  (StaJilhof).  The  cor- 
porate property  and  discipline  were  administered 
by  an  alderman  elected  annually,  with  the  help 
of  two  assistants  and  a  cou.ncil  of  nine.  For 
their  privileges  from  the  state,  the  Easterlings 
contracted  for  the  payment  of  customs  duties, 
while  they  discharged  their  obligations  to  the 
city  by  annual  payments  to  the  lord  mayor 
and  by  maintaining  a  watch  and  ward  at  the 
Bishop's  gate.  Originally  the  hansa  was  an 
indej.eudent  community,  but  in  the  course  of  a 
long  struggle  with  the  jealous  and  rival  native 
population,  it  came  to  rely  more  and  more 
upon  the  growing  league  of  towns  in  North 
Germany,  and  ultimately  became  a  "counter" 
or  depot  of  the  Hanseatic  League. 

Although  the  Easterlings  were  traders  and 
left  money-dealing  in  the  hands  of  the  Lom- 
bards, yet  their  name  came  to  be  applied  to 
money.  Probably  this  was  due  to  the  excellent 
quality  and  uniform  weight  of  their  own  coins. 
Matthew  Paris  tells  us  (sub  ann.  1247),  that 
•■'moneta  esterlingorum,  propter  sui  materiam 
desiderabilem,  detestabili  circumcisione  coepit 
deteriorari  et  corrumpi."  The  statutes  of 
Edward  I.  refer  to  a  definite  coin  called 
"sterling,"  which  is  thus  described  :  Denarius 
Anglise,  qui  vocatur  Sterlingus,  rotundus  sine 
tonsura,  ponderabit  32  grana  frumenti  in  medio 
spicfe,  et  20  denarii  faciunt  unciam,  et  12  uncise 
faciunt  libram.  From  England  these  coins 
passed  to  France,  and  we  find  frequent  references 
to  them  in  the  middle  ages.  That  the  quality 
of  the  coins  was  for  the  time  excellent  is  proved 
by  the  survival  of  the  term  sterling,  to  denote 
money  of  standard  weight  and  quality,  to  the 
present  day. 

[Pauli,  Pictures  of  Old  England. — Kunze, 
llansedkten  aus  Englo,nd,  1275  - 1412. — Du 
Gangs,    Olossarium,  s.v.    "  Esterlingus. " — Helen 


Zimmem,  Hansa  Tovms  (Story  of  the  Nations 
Series).]  r.  l. 

EAST  INDIA  COMPANY  (1600-1858). 
The  circumstances  attending  the  formation  and 
the  aims  present  to  the  minds  o'"  the  promoters 
of  the  East  India  Company  did  not  differ 
materially  from  those  which  influenced  the 
foundation  of  the  other  "venturer"  Companies 
of  the  same  epoch,  from  among  which  it  stands 
out  pre-eminent  by  reason  of  the  magnitude  of 
its  operations,  and  its  profound  imperial  import- 
ance. Like  them  its  early  attempts  were 
ventures  for  the  sake  of  quick  gains  ;  like  them 
it  owed  much  to  the  spirit  of  daring  enterprise 
characteristic  of  the  age.  The  dilference  which 
became  so  marked  afterwards  was  due  to  several 
causes  ;  partly  to  the  larger  sphere  of  its 
activity  ;  partly  to  a  difference  in  its  manage- 
ment ;  and  partly  to  certain  embarrassments  in 
which  it  found  itself  involved  through  its  rela- 
tions with  native  powers  and  the  rivalry  of  con- 
tinental companies  and  European  nations. 

From  very  early  times  the  East  had  been 
viewed  as  a  great  source  of  wealth,  and  con- 
sequently as  a  gi-eat  goal  of  trade.  This  feeling 
was  accentuated  rather  than  lessened  after  the 
Portuguese  had  discovered  and  at  first  monopo- 
lised the  passage  round  the  Cape  of  Good  Hope. 
Many  schemes  of  adventure  had  been  formed, 
and  some  of  them  tried.  The  Levant  Company 
had  striven,  but  without  much  success,  to  ex- 
tend its  operations  overland  in  the  direction 
of  India.  On  the  other  hand,  attempts  had 
been  made  to  open  a  north-west  passage  which 
should  be  to  the  English  what  the  Cape  route 
liad  been  to  Portugal.  One  of  these  found 
place  in  1591,  when  a  license  was  granted  by 
Queen  Elizabeth  to  send  out  three  ships.  They 
were  sent  under  Captain  Raymond,  but  without 
success.  But  the  hope  of  trade  with  India  was 
not  abandoned  ;  the  prospect  was  too  promising. 
In  1599,  no  doubt  after  some  preliminary  action, 
the  project  which  was  to  issue  in  the  formation 
of  the  East  India  Company  was  first  put  on  a 
substantial  basis.  On  22nd  September  of  that 
year  a  record  was  drawn  up  of  the  people  who 
had  agreed  to  subscribe  to  the  intended  voyage 
to  the  East  Indies.  On  24th  September  a 
meeting  of  the  subscribers  was  held,  and  in  due 
course  a  charter  was  applied  for.  For  a  time 
operations  were  checked  owing  to  negotiations 
of  the  government  with  the  Dutch,  but  in  the 
autumn  of  the  next  year  the  matter  was  pro- 
ceeded with  ;  and  on  31st  December  1600  a 
charter  was  issued  to  the  Governor  and  Company 
of  Merchants  of  London  trading  to  the  East 
Indies.  The  charter  was  drawn  on  the  lines  of 
those  previously  issued  to  other  companies, 
from  which  it  differed  in  no  important  point. 

The  history  of  the  company  can  only  be  re- 
. viewed  in  its  essential  features.  These  cluster 
chiefly  round  two  points  ;  (1)  the  mode  of  con- 
duct of  the  company  ;  (2)  its  negotiations  with 


670 


EAST  INDIA  COMPANY 


native  powers,  and  rivalry  with  other  European 
companies  and  powers. 

(1)  The  early  voyages  of  this  company  were 
like  those  of  certain  others,  of  the  nature  of 
separate  "ventures,"  that  is,  members  of  the 
company  subscribed  in  varying  proj)ortions 
towards  a  certain  expedition,  the  proceeds  of 
which  were  afterwards  distributed  among  them 
according  to  their  respective  shares.  This 
method  endured  till  1612,  when  what  was 
termed  the  first  joint  stock  was  subscribed. 
This,  however,  is  a  term  which  is  likely  to  lead 
to  misunderstanding.  It  did  not  imply  the 
formation  of  a  permanent  capital  divided  into 
shares  and  distributed  among  the  members  of 
the  company  in  varying  proportion.  It  was 
little  other  than  a  somewhat  prolonged  series 
of  ventures.  Subscriptions  were  taken  up  in 
the  most  various  amounts  from  members, 
none  of  whom  were  necessarily  bound  to  sub- 
scribe, and  paid  into  the  hands  of  the  governor 
and  directors,  who  then  applied  the  money  at 
their  discretion  for  the  equipment  of  a  number 
of  expeditions  for  the  benefit  of  the  subscribers. 
Thus  the  first  joint  stock  subscribed  in  1612 
was  distributed  among  four  voyages,  and  came 
to  an  end  in  1617  ;  the  second  joint  stock, 
contributed  1617-18,  furnished  three  voyages, 
and  so  on.  Such  a  method,  while  in  some 
respects  a  decided  improvement  on  that  pre- 
viously pursued,  had  serious  drawbacks.  With 
each  succeeding  voyage  the  amount  of  "dead 
plant "  belonging  to  the  company,  in  the  form 
of  factories  in  India,  etc.,  was  increased  ;  and 
so  the  relations  of  the  members  of  future  to 
those  of  preceding  joint  stocks  were  rendered 
somewhat  complicated. 

Meantime  the  company  was  experiencing  a 
foretaste  of  the  difficulties  and  dangers  which 
finally  caused  it  to  assume  political  responsi- 
bilities. On  the  one  hand  it  had  to  contend  with 
private  rivals  (Interlopers,  q.v.)  at  home  ;  on 
the  other,  the  rivalry  of  continental  powers  and 
companies  1  threatened  its  existence  in  India. 
So  early  as  1602  a  factory  had  been  founded  at 
Bantam,  despite  the  keen  opposition  of  the 
Portuguese.  As  operations  extended,  new 
factories  were  established,  notably  one  at  Surat 
in  1612,  and  new  enmities  incurred.  The 
relations  with  the  Mogul  were  rendered  more 
amicable  by  the  tact  and  capacity  of  Sir 
Thomas  Roe.  But  the  Dutch  were  about  to 
prove  the  most  formidable  opponents  of  the 
young  company.  The  friction  which  had  arisen 
owing  to  various  causes,  chiefly  perhaps  to  the 

1  The  following  is  a  list  of  the  chief  foreign  companies 
licensed  to  trade  to  East  Indies.  The  Dutch  Com- 
pany, founded  1602.  The  French  Companies  ;  the  first 
founded  1604 ;  the  second,  1611 ;  the  third,  1615 ;  the 
fourth  by  Richelieu,  1642  ;  and  the  fifth,  1644.  In  1719 
the  French  Company  of  the  Indies  was  established,  and 
lasted  till  1796.  The  first  Danish  company,  1612,  and 
the  second  1670.  In  1723  the  Osteiid  Company  was 
established;  in  1731  the  Swedish  Company;  and  in 
1733  the  Royal  Company  of  the  Philippine  Islands. 


efforts  of  the  company  to  establish  a  trade  vnth 
the  Spice  Islands,  assumed  such  serious  propor- 
tions, that  the  attempts  to  bring  about  a  peaceful 
settlement  by  the  Treaty  of  Defence  made  in 
1619  proved  unavailing,  and  the  opportunity 
of  much  future  quarrel  was  given  by  the 
massacre  of  Amboyna.  The  immediate  result 
was  the  withdrawal  of  the  English  from  the 
neighbourhood  of  the  Malay  archipelago.  In 
a  few  years  new  efforts  were  made  in  the  main- 
land and  a  factory  was  established  at  Armagaon, 
which  growing,  absorbed  that  at  Masulipatam. 
In  its  time  abandoned,  it  was  supplanted  by 
the  settlement  of  Fort  St.  George  (1639-40). 
The  acquisition  of  this  station  marked  a  new 
step  in  the  progress  of  territorial  aggrandise- 
ment. In  1646  grants  were  made  in  Bengal, 
and  in  1661  Bombay  was  ceded  to  the  British 
Crown  as  part  of  the  dowry  of  Catharine  of 
Braganza  on  her  marriage  with  Charles  II. 
The  quan-el  with  the  Dutch  had  been  rendered 
of  less  importance  than  it  threatened,  through 
the  energetic  action  of  Cromwell,  who  in  the 
treaty  of  1654  had  inserted  a  clause  dealing 
with  the  demands  made  on  both  sides  for  com- 
pensation for  injury.  To  adjust  these,  a  com- 
mission  of  award  was  appointed  and  began  its 
sittings  30th  August  1654.  But  owing  to 
events  such  as  these,  and  in  part,  no  doubt, 
to  the  increasing  importance  of  the  companies' 
factories,  a  more  definite  territorial  aim  would 
seem  to  have  presented  itself  to  the  minds  of 
some.  It  became  a  matter  for  consideration 
whether  the  company  was  to  be  considered  one  of 
commerce  alone,  or  one  which  had  other  beside 
trade  interests.  But  yet  another  point.  As- 
suming that  commerce  was  its  chief  aim,  could 
its  attainment  be  assured  without  the  acquisition 
of  territory  by  the  company  ?  Such  territory 
would  need  to  be  protected.  The  appointment 
of  Sir  Josiah  Child  as  governor  in  1686  was  with- 
out doubt  a  distinct  advance  in  the  direction  of 
this  new  policy.  Again,  in  1687,  when  the  ques- 
tion of  the  grant  of  charters  and  commissions 
was  mooted  with  the  king  (James  II.)  and  his 
council,  he  had  agreed  that  it  would  be  better  if 
such  charters  and  commissions  were  gi-anted  by 
the  court  of  the  company  instead  of  emanating 
from  himself.  The  company,  it  should  be  noticed, 
had  in  1624,  supplemented  its  ordinary  judicial 
authority  by  the  power  of  punishing  its  servants 
by  martial  law.  Matters  were  such,  that  further 
advance  was  natural,  and  in  1689-90,  instruc- 
tions were  sent  from  home  to  the  regency  of 
Bombay,  as  also  to  Madras,  which  contained  the 
following  noteworthy  sentences:  "The  increase 
of  our  revenue  is  the  subject  of  our  care  as  much 
as  our  trade  ;  'tis  that  must  maintain  our  force 
when  twenty  accidents  may  interrupt  our  trade  ; 
'tis  that  must  make  us  a  nation  in  India  ;  with- 
out that  we  are  but  as  a  great  number  of  inter- 
lopers, united  by  His  Majesty's  royal  charter,  fit 
only  to  trade  where  no  body  of  power  thinks  it 


EAST  INDIA  COMPANY 


671 


their  interest  to  prevent  us  ;  and  upon  this 
account  it  is,  that  the  wise  Dutch,  in  all  their 
general  advices  which  we  have  seen,  write  ten 
paragraphs  concerning  their  government,  thsir 
civil  and  military  policy,  warfare,  and  the 
increase  of  their  revenue,  for  one  paragraph  that 
they  write  concerning  trade." 

These  words  are  an  open  declaration  in  favour 
of  the  new  policy.  Commerce,  if  still  a  main 
aim,  was  henceforth  to  be  undertaken  on  a 
secure  basis  of  territorial  possession  and  political 
dominion. 

At  home,  however,  the  company  had  found, 
and  were  still  to  find,  their  exclusive  rights 
questioned  and  combated.  At  the  outset  their 
progress  had  been  hampered  by  the  grant  of  a 
royal  license  to  trade  to  Cathay,  Japan,  etc., 
given  to  Sir  Edward  Michelbourne,  who  had 
made  full  use  of  his  opportunities  to  wring 
booty  from  the  natives.  They  had  convinced 
the  king  (James  I. )  of  the  need  of  maintaining 
their  powers,  and  had  received  a  renewal  of  their 
charter.  But  a  more  serious  rival  menaced  them 
in  the  next  reign.  In  1635a  license  was  gi-anted 
to  an  association  formed  by  Sir  William  Courten. 
This  association,  afterwards  known  as  that  of 
the  Assada  merchants,  sent  out  ships  and 
entered  upon  commerce  to  tlie  detriment  of  the 
East  India  Company,  both  by  reason  of  competi- 
tion and,  as  was  also  alleged,  by  reason  of  the 
bad  treatment  the  natives  experienced  at  the 
hands  of  its  servants.  In  answer  to  the  petition 
of  the  company,  the  king  (Charles  I.),  in  1639, 
promised  the  withdrawal  of  the  license,  but  the 
promise  remained  unfulfilled.  In  1650  a  kind 
of  amalgamation  took  place,  and  the  Assada 
merchants  became  members  of  the  company. 
But  in  so  doing  they  did  not  wish  to  deprive 
themselves  of  the  right  to  trade  in  their  own 
bottoms,  in  other  words,  they  wished  to  bring 
about  a  return  to  the  earlier  principles  of 
separate  ventures,  in  part  accordance  with 
which  the  commerce  of  the  company  had  been 
carried  on  before  1612.  In  consequence,  they 
appealed  to  the  Protector  against  the  enforce- 
ment of  the  joint-stock  trading.  The  company 
replied,  and  in  1654  obtained  a  decision  from 
the  council  of  state  in  favour  of  joint-stock 
management  and  exclusive  trading. 

Such  had  been  the  history  of  the  company 
before  its  important  declaration  in  1689.  Al- 
most immediately  after  that  events  took  place 
in  England  which  nearly  brought  about  its  ex- 
tinction. The  arbitrary  and  severe  measures 
which  had  marked  several  of  their  acts  in  India 
had  excited  the  animosity  of  the  House  of 
Commons,  already  prejudiced  against  societies 
not  of  their  own  creation.  In  1690  a  com- 
mittee reported  in  favour  of  the  formation  of 
a  new  company  which  should  be  constituted  by 
act  of  parliament  and  not  derive  its  authority 
from  royal  charter.  In  accordance  with  this  re- 
commendation, next  year  the  king  (William  III.) 


was  petitioned  by  the  Commons  to  dissolve  the 
old  company.  His  apparent  neglect  of  this 
request  does  not  seem  to  have  aroused  much 
feeling.  Not  so,  however,'  his  renewal,  in 
1693,  of  the  charter.  A  declaration  was  drawn 
up  and  passed,  asserting  the  right  of  all  English- 
men to  trade  to  East  Indies  and  elsewhere  unless 
prohibited  by  act  of  Parliament,  and  the  king 
gave  way.  In  1698  a  new  association,  termed 
the  English  Company,  was  formed  (with  right 
of  exclusive  trading  after  1701),  and  the  exist- 
ence of  the  old  company  was  limited  to  the 
three  years  from  date  for  which  they  could  claim 
notice.  To  maintain  their  control  over  India, 
members  of  the  old  and  now  condemned  company 
bought  up  shares  in  the  new  company.  During 
these  three  years  the  two  companies  traded  in 
rivalry,  in  which  the  older  association,  fortified 
by  experience  and  provided  with  stations,  ships, 
and  stock,  had  a  distinct  advantage.  As  the 
last  year  (1701)  ran  on,  the  old  company  not 
unnaturally  showed  itself  more  willing  to  enter- 
tain the  idea  of  a  compromise,  to  which  the 
members  of  the  new  company  were  not  averse, 
and  in  January  1702  a  partial  union  was  effected 
under  the  title  of  "The  United  Company  of 
Merchants  trading  to  the  East  Indies."  Several 
causes  of  difiiculty  and  dispute  remained  over  ; 
but  the  need  of  harmonious  working  was  too 
great  to  allow  of  their  long  continuance  ;  and 
in  1708,  on  the  arbitration  of  Lord  Godolphin, 
a  complete  and  final  union  was  brought  about. 

The  early  opponents  of  the  company  had 
been  overcome  ;  its  right  as  against  home  com- 
petitors was  established  ;  a  settlement  in  India 
obtained.  It  was  an  acknowledged  political 
power  as  well  as  a  trading  company. 

(2)  In  this  direction  it  had  to  progress,  for 
the  animosities  aroused  by  its  dominion,  coupled 
with  the  ambition  of  France,  made  it  impos- 
sible for  it  to  exist  as  it  was,  one  power  among 
many  others.  It  had  soon  to  choose  between 
supremacy  or  political  extinction. 

The  death  of  Aurungzebe  (1707)  and  the 
consequent  disruption  of  the  Mogul  empire 
afforded  the  opportunity,  and  in  part  created 
a  necessity  for  further  political  action  on  the 
part  of  those  European  companies  whose  in- 
terests were  involved  in  India.  The  French 
under  La  Bourdonnais  initiated  a  policy  of 
advance,  which  under  the  more  skilful  and 
more  ambitious  guidance  of  Dupleix  became  a 
policy  of  aggression  and  conquest.  They 
sought  to  subordinate  or  expel  their  rivals,  the 
English,  and  to  establish  themselves  as  a 
ruling,  if  not  predominant,  power  in  the 
country.  Inaction  on  the  part  of  the  English 
company  was  impossible,  and  ill -prepared 
though  they  were,  a  strenuous  resistance  was 
offered  to  the  designs  of  the  French.  Under 
'the  leadership  of  Clive  the  English,  too,  pro- 
gressed towards  sovereignty,  and  the  battle  of 
Plassey  (1757)  made  them  virtual  masters  of 


672 


EAST  INDIA  COMPANY— EASTLAND  COMPANY 


the  NawaVs  dominions.  Their  creature,  Meer 
JaflBer,  whom  they  placed  upon  the  throne, 
made  them  a  grant  of  territory  in  Bengal.  A 
few  years  after  they  stepped  into  the  position 
of  what  we  may  term  definite  individual  sove- 
reignty, receiving  from  the  Mogul  emperor  an 
acknowledgment  of  their  right  to  the  Avenues 
of  the  three  provinces  —  Bengal,  Behar,  and 
Orissa,  which  they  combined  into  a  presidency 
of  Bengal.  Other  acquisitions  were  made  in 
the  neighbourhood  of  their  other  stations.  The 
French  war  was  a  turning  point  in  the  history 
of  the  East  India  Company.  When  it  emerged 
successful,  the  political  ambitions,  inchoate  till 
then,  had  realised  themselves  in  power,  destined 
ultimately  to  become  imperial.  The  task  of  its 
control  was  in  fact  too  important  to  be  com- 
mitted to  the  sole  will  of  a  trading  company, 
and  henceforth  governmental  interference  and 
supervision  begins. 

The  economic  interest  of  the  new  period 
centres  chiefly  in  two  subjects — the  economic 
settlement  of  India,  and  the  successive  acts 
whereby  the  state  drew  affairs  more  and  more 
witliin  its  own  control. 

By  the  act  of  1773  an  important  change  was 
made  in  the  government  of  India.  Till  that 
date  the  government  of  each  province  had  been 
separate,  the  direction  in  each  case  resting  with 
a  council  composed  of  the  senior  civil  members 
in  the  company's  service.  By  this  enactment 
alterations  were  made  in  certain  directions.  A 
governor-general  was  appointed  and  a  supreme 
council  specially  constituted  for  Bengal.  To 
this  governor  and  council  the  other  presidencies 
were  placed  in  subordination  so  far  as  the 
making  of  war  and  the  entering  into  treaties 
were  concerned.  In  addition  the  home  govern- 
ment, while  recognising  for  the  first  time  the 
possession  by  the  company  and  its  servants  of 
administrative  functions,  provided  that  every- 
thing in  the  company's  correspondence  which 
related  to  civil  or  military  afiairs,  which  con- 
cerned either  the  government  of  the  country  or 
the  administration  of  the  revenue,  should  be 
laid  before  the  ministry.  In  the  constitution 
as  thus  established,  there  were  three  grave 
defects: — The  governor  was  left  dependent 
on  the  will  of  the  council ;  no  definite  connec- 
tion was  established  between  the  various  pre- 
sidencies ;  the  relations  between  the  ministry 
and  the  Indian  government  were  but  ill -de- 
fined. It  was  to  remedy  the  two  latter  of  these 
that  the  act  of  1784,  which  established  the 
board  of  control,  was  passed.  This  body  con- 
sisted of  six  members  of  the  privy  council,  of 
whom  the  chancellor  of  the  exchequer  and  one 
of  the  chief  secretaries  of  state  were  to  form 
two.  But,  as  in  the  absence  of  these  two  ex- 
officio  members  the  senior  of  the  remaining  four 
was  to  preside  at  the  board,  the  chief  power 
was  vested  in  the  hands  of  one  man  who,  under 
the  title  of  the  president  of  the  board  of  control, 


performed  many  of  the  functions  which  now 
fall  to  the  lot  of  the  secretary  of  state  for  India. 
The  first  defect  noticed  above  was  largely 
remedied  by  the  act  (26  Geo.  iii.  c.  1&),  which 
Lord  Cornwallis  obtained  when  he  took  the 
post  of  governor -general.  By  it  he  and  his 
successors  were  empowered  to  override  the 
council  in  cases  of  emergency. 

To  Lord  Cornwallis  is  due  the  organisation 
of  the  young  empire.  Under  his  rule  British 
officials  became  something  more  than  mere 
collectors  of  the  revenue  ;  under  him  the  out- 
lines of  the  land  system  were  laid  down ;  and  it 
was  owing  to  him  that  the  administration  be- 
came so  efiective  and  so  honest.  In  1793  the 
charter  was  renewed  for  another  twenty  years. 
Lord  Cornwallis  had  regulated  the  condition 
of  the  country  and  Lord  Wellesley  established 
the  preponderance  of  the  British  power.  His 
policy,  though  it  was  not  formally  assented  to 
by  the  company,  was  necessary  for  the  sake 
of  peace  and  stability.  "When  he  left  India 
the  company  was  established  as  the  great 
sovereign  power.  In  1813  the  charter  was 
once  more  renewed.  When  in  1833  it  came 
up  again  for  renewal  changes  were  made.  The 
power  of  trade  was  taken  away  from  the  com- 
pany, despite  the  protest  of  those  who,  still 
faithful  to  earlier  conceptions,  continued  to  view 
trading  as  its  main  function.  A  further  access 
of  power  was  granted  to  the  governor-general 
and  the  supreme  council. 

Further  progress  was  made  in  the  direction, 
both  of  the  acquisition  of  wholly  new  territories 
and  of  the  subordination  to  active  government 
of  the  protected  or  dependent  native  states. 
But  the  rule  of  the  company  was  about  to  end 
after  a  period  of  some  two  and  a  half  centuries 
from  its  beginning.  The  fanatical  outburst 
which  swelled  into  the  mutiny  aroused  a  feeling, 
whether  right  or  wrong  cannot  be  here  dis- 
cussed, that  the  government  of  India  was  too 
important  to  be  left  to  the  directors,  however 
controlled,  of  a  company  originally  formed  for 
the  purpose  of  trade,  and  in  1858  it  was  for- 
mally and  finally  transferred  to  the  crown. 

[Bruce,  Annals  of  British  India. — Histories  by 
James  Mill  and  others. — Chesney,  Indian  Polity. 
— Parliamentary  Papers  and  Keports.] 

E.  C.  K.  G. 

EASTLAND  COMPANY  (established  1568). 
This  company  was  an  association  of  the  English 
merchants  trading  to  and  from  the  Baltic. 
From  the  wording  of  their  charter  it  seems  that 
they  were  formerly  called  the  Dantzig  merchants. 
In  1568  a  charter  was  issued  to  the  traders 
desirous  of  associating  themselves,  granting  to 
them  "to  enjoy  the  sole  trade  through  the 
Sound,"  into  Norway,  Sweden,  Poland,  Lithu- 
ania (except  Narva,  the  trade  with  which  was 
claimed  by  the  Russian  Company),  Prussia, 
and  also  Pomerania,  from  the  river  Oder  east- 
ward to  Dantzig,  Elbing,  Konigsberg,  Ebling, 


EATON— ECK 


673 


Braunsberg,  also  to  Copenhagen  and  Elsinore, 
and  to  Finland,  Gothland,  Bornholm,  and 
Oland.  The  company  thus  constituted  was  a 
"regulated  one,"  and  the  members  of  it  were 
entitled  to  trade  ' '  in  their  own  bottoms. "  The 
provisions  of  the  charter  were  much  the  same 
as  those  laid  dowTi  in  other  cases.  The  various 
privileges  were  confirmed  in  1629,  with  the 
single  proviso  that  the  trade  in  grain  between 
the  countries  and  districts  enumerated  and 
England  was  thenceforth  to  be  free.  During 
the  early  as  well  as  during  the  latter  portion  of 
its  existence,  the  difficulties  encountered  by  the 
company  were  considerable  ;  in  particular  they 
found  themselves  impeded  in  their  passage 
through  the  Sound.  Thus  in  1602  complaints 
were  made  with  regard  to  the  excessive  charges 
levied  on  their  vessels  when  passing  through  ; 
in  1653  they  petitioned  Cromwell  on  account 
of  the  detention  of  their  ships  in  Denmark.  At 
home  they  met  with  disfavour  from  the  strong 
and  growing  feeling  against  monopolies.  But 
on  the  whole  they  received  considerable  support, 
an  ordinance  being  passed  in  their  favour  in 
1647.  The  privileges  so  warmly  cherished  did 
not  long  survive  the  Restoration,  for  in  1672 
it  was  decreed,  firstly,  that  there  should  be  a 
free  trade  to  Norway,  Denmark,  and  Sweden  ; 
secondly,  that  any  one  should  be  entitled  to 
trade  to  the  other  Baltic  ports  within  the 
limits  of  the  Eastland  Company's  charter  on 
bis  joining  that  company,  which,  it  provided, 
any  trade  could  do  on  payment  of  40s. 

[Macpherson,  Annals ;  MS.  authorities.] 

]<:.  c.  K.  G. 

EATON,  Daniel  Isaac  (1752  ?- 1814),  a 
London  bookseller  who  upheld  the  cause  of 
freedom  of  the  press,  at  the  cost  of  eight 
prosecutions,  for  the  publication  of  works  by 
Thomas  Paine  and  Pigot,  of  his  own  periodical 
(see  below),  and  of  a  free  -  thinking  work  of 
doubtful  authorship  called  Ucce  Homo.  Very 
few  of  the  trials  ended  in  a  conviction.  His 
weekly  periodical.  Hog's  Wash,  or  Politics  for 
the  People,  1794,  dealt,  not  systematically,  with 
political  and  social  subjects  in  a  violently  re- 
volutionary spirit.  Rhetorical  hatred  of"  kings 
appears  as  a  set-off  to  real  consideration  for  the 
poorer  classes.  The  unequal  distribution  of 
wealth  was  treated  as  the  fundamental  mis- 
chief ;  parliamentary  reform,  peace,  the  lower- 
ing of  taxes,  especially  of  duties  on  necessaries, 
subscriptions  for  poor  labourers,  republican 
government  for  the  sake  of  economy,  the  re- 
cognition of  the  natural  equality  of  men  ;  these 
are  some  of  the  various  remedies  proposed. 

Eaton  translated  Helvetius's  Law  of  Nature  and 
True  Sense  and  meaning  of  tlie  System  of  Nature, 
1810,  and  Feret's  Preservative  against  Religious 
Prejudices,  1810. 

[Howell's  State  Trials,  xxii.  763-822  ;  xxiii. 
1013-1054  ;  xxxi.  927-958  —Notes  and  Queries, 
3rd  series,  vol.  x.  396.— Z)zc^.  Nat.  Biog.  xvi.  336. 

E.  O.  P. 

VOL.  T. 


EBAUDY  DE  FRESNE,  born  (c.  1760)  at 
Vesoul,  published  in  1788  his  Trait6  d' Agricul- 
ture considiree  tant  en  elle  mime  que  dans  ses 
rapports  avec  VEconomie  (''Treatise  of  Agricul- 
ture considered  in  itself  and  in  its  relations 
with  Economy  "),  3  vols.  8vo  ;  and  presented 
in  1790  his  Plan  de  Pcstauration  et  de  Libera- 
tion, based  on  the  former  work  to  the  National 
Assembly  of  France.  According  to  De  Fresne, 
French  agriculture  was  suffering  from  the  undue 
extent  of  corn-growing,  and  an  excessive  con- 
sumption of  fodder  in  large  towns,  resulting 
in  a  loss  of  manure.  He  advocates  the  extension 
of  pasture  lands,  and  a  more  developed  produc- 
tion of  cattle  and  consumption  of  meat  (instead 
of  bread),  but  most  of  the  methods  he  suggests 
to  reach  this  end  are  very  unpractical,    e.  ca. 

ECK,  JoHANN  (1486-1543),  was  professor  of 
theology  at  Ingolstadt,  and  is  best  known  as 
the  antagonist  of  Luther  ;  he  played  also  an 
interesting  part  in  the  movement  of  economic 
thought.  He  was  among  the  first,  if  not  in- 
deed the  very  first,  to  maintain  that  a  contract 
to  pay  a  certain  percentage  for  the  use  of  money 
was  not  necessarily  usurious.  His  justification 
he  apparently  found  in  the  theory  of  *'the 
triple  contract,"  contractus  trinus,  which  had 
grown  up  before  his  time,  but  which  he  would 
appear  to  have  been  the  first  to  popularise.  A 
contract  of  partnership  (societas),  where  both 
partners  shared  in  the  risk  and  gain  according  as 
their  undertaking  prospered,  had  long  been  recog- 
nised by  theologians  as  lawful.  It  was  argued 
that  as  another  sort  of  contract,  a  contract  of 
insurance,  was  also  in  itself  free  from  objection, 
it  was  permissible  for  one  partner  to  contract 
with  the  other  to  receive  a  less  return  than  he 
might  otherwise  fairly-  expect,  on  condition 
tliat  in  any  ease  his  capital  should  be  restored 
to  him.  It  would  then  be  equally  lawful  to 
add  a  fm-ther  contract  by  which  the  investor 
insured  himself  against  the  chances  of  fluctuating 
dividends  by  surrendering  a  further  portion  of 
the  return  he  might  otherwise  look  for,  in  ex- 
change for  the  promise  of  a  definite  annual 
percentage.  By  the  combination  of  these  three 
contracts  in  one — "the  triple  contract,"  the 
investor  obtained  a  security  both  for  the  return 
of  his  capital  and  for  a  certain  annual  percent- 
age ;  so  that  the  contract,  though  still  techni- 
cally one  of  partnership,  was  essentially  one  of 
loan. 

Eck,  who  before  his  controversy  with  Luther 
had  already  sought  fame  as  a  public  disputant, 
announced  himself  in  1514  at  Ingolstadt  as 
ready  to  maintain  the  thesis  that  merchants 
might  lawfully  bind  themselves  to  pay  5  per 
cent.  The  Bishop  of  Eichstatt,  as  ordinary 
and  chancellor,  forbade  the  disputation  ;  and 
the  university  of  Mainz,  being  consulted  by  its 
archbishop,  gave  the  opinion  that  it  was  inex- 
pedient. Thereupon  Eck,  assisted  with  money 
and  letters  of  recommendation  by  the  great 

2x 


674 


ECONOMIC  FREEDOM— ECONOMIC  HARMONY 


German  financiers  the  Fuggers,  set  off  for  the 
university  of  Bologna,  and  there  defended  the 
same  proposition  with  much  applause  from  the 
jurists.  This  Bologna  disputation  excited 
general  attention  ;  it  was  ironically  referred  to 
in  the  LUUroe,  Ohscuroi-um  Firorum  as  showing 
that  usury  was  allowed  by  "theology";  and 
the  humanist  Pirkheimer  wrote  to  Eck  that 
now  the  great  merchants  dared  to  say  that  any 
bargain  was  just.  About  the  same  time  Eck 
stated  a  case  for  the  Sorbonne  ;  and  although 
the  faculty  gave  no  decision,  the  opinion  of 
Eck  was  adopted  by  the  distinguished  Scotch 
divine  at  Paris,  John  Major.  The  subject  fell 
into  the  background  with  the  appearance  of  the 
Lutheran  controversy.  It  is  probable  that  the 
extremely  conservative  position  taken  up  at 
first  by  the  Protestant  divines  on  the  question 
of  usury  prevented  for  a  time  the  development 
of  opinion  among  Catholic  theologians  in  the 
direction  pointed  out  by  Eck.  A  bull  of  Sixtus 
V.  in  1586  condemned  all  contracts  for  insur- 
ing either  the  capital  or  a  certain  rate  of  profit. 
But  this  was  explained  away  ;  and  "  the  triple 
contract"  was  very  generally  recognised  as 
lawful  by  Catholic  divines  and  faculties  from 
the  beginning  of  the  17th  century. 

[Schmoller,  Zur  Oeschichte  der  nationalokono- 
mischen  Andchten  in  Deutschland,  1861,  pp.  127- 
128. — Janssen,  Oeschichte  des  deutschen  Volkes, 
15th  ed.,  1890,  i.  p.  444  (where  it  is  urged  that 
Eck  was  altogether  alone ;  and  that  he  did  not 
defend  usury  but  merely  the  triple  contract,  and 
that  only  in  the  case  of  rich  merchants  who  received 
money  for  trading  purposes). — Endemann,  Stvdien 
in  der  romanisch-canonisiischen  Wirthschafts-u. 
Rechtslehre,  vol.  i.  1874,  pp.  384-385.— Funk, 
Zins  u.  Wucher,  1868,  pp.  84-86  (where  the  argu- 
ment in  defence  of  the  triple  contract  is  spoken  of 
as  justified  by  circumstances),  and  Oeschichte  des 
kirchlichen  Zinsverbotes,  1876,  pp.  57-64  (where 
it  is  described  as  mere  sophistry). — Ashley,  Econ- 
omic Hist.,  vol.  i.  pt.  ii. — Th.  Wiedemann,  Dr. 
Johann  Eck,  1865.]  w,  j.  a. 

ECONOMIC  FREEDOM.  This  is  a  term 
properly  signifying  a  condition  in  which  com- 
petition acts  without  influence  from  other  causes. 
If  used  in  the  same  popular  sense  as  free  trade, 
it  ought  to  mean  merely  freedom  from  legisla- 
tive imposts  or  governmental  supervision.  In 
order  to  meet  the  requirements  of  a  scientific 
phrase,  however,  it  must  be  given  a  more 
extended  meaning  ;  and  include  the  absence  of 
such  determining  causes  of  value  as  combination, 
custom,  immobility  of  capital  and  of  labour, 
etc.  Professor  Marshall  uses  the  term  as 
generally  descriptive  of  modern  industry  as 
compared  with  the  economic  condition  of  the 
middle  ages ;  and  this  is  a  singularly  happy 
definition  from  a  literary  point  of  view.  Those 
influences  which  are  most  powerful  at  the 
present  day  in  affecting  exchange  values  are 
styled  economic  causes,  which  in  reality  ex- 
presses the  fact  that  competition  has  a  much 


wider  range  than  it  had  in  past  centuries. 
This  is  the  necessary  result  of  the  discoveries 
and  inventions  of  modern  times.  The  railway, 
the  steamboat,  the  telegraph,  aU  combined 
towards  the  amalgamation,  for  fixing  of  prices, 
of  all  the  markets  of  the  world  ;  the  breaking- 
up  of  much  that  was  ancient  and  customary, 
which  went  on  simultaneously  with  these  inno- 
vations, introduced  strict  contract  and  com- 
mercial principle  into  every  sphere  of  industry. 
Education,  spread  throughout  all  classes,  intro- 
duced an  equality  between  contracting  parties 
previously  unknown.  Economic  freedom,  how- 
ever, though  correctly  applied  to  describe  modern 
industry  in  a  wide  sense,  is  not  properly  a 
scientific  term  ;  and  if  it  is  so  used,  it  may 
lead  to  great  confusion.  In  the  first  place, 
there  are  points  in  which  the  industry  of  to-day 
is  not  so  free  as  it  was  in  earlier  times  ;  in  the 
matter  of  wages,  for  instance,  although  industry 
is  now,  in  Great  Britain  generally,  free  from 
legislative  interference,  it  is  more  liable  than 
ever  to  interference  from  combinations,  whether 
of  masters  or  of  men  ;  moreover,  the  very  con- 
ditions of  modem  trade  cause  an  interlacing 
between  different  branches  so  intimate  that  they 
affect  each  other  in  greater  measure  than  at  any 
earlier  period.  Again,  in  using  such  a  phrase, 
we  must  not  forget  that  the  era  it  applies  to 
has  been  as  yet  very  brief ;  and  that,  though 
it  is  an  important  era  to  ourselves,  it  may  turn 
out  to  be  of  merely  passing  value  in  the  pro- 
gress of  a  science  yet  so  young  as  that  of 
economics. 

Strictly  speaking,  economic  freedom  involves 
a  great  deal  more  than  we  admit  even  in 
industry  under  present  conditions.  The  repeal 
of  differential  duties,  which  established  free 
trade,  is  the  most  prominent  sign  of  the  econo- 
mic tendencies  of  the  age  in  England  ;  but 
absolute  freedom  involves  no  less  the  repeal  of 
duties  on  tea,  sugar,  wine,  etc.,  and  in  fact  the 
abolition  of  all  indirect  taxation.  The  absence 
of  all  restrictions  on  the  hire  and  sale  of  land, 
and  of  aU  regulation  of  the  hours  of  labour,  are 
essentials  to  economic  freedom  in  the  strict 
application  of  the  words.  Freedom  of  combina- 
tion is  to  most  minds  a  necessary  attribute  of 
economic  freedom  ;  yet  the  results  of  combina- 
tion are  such  as  to  destroy  that  absolutely  un- 
fettered competition  which  is  of  the  essence  of 
the  term.  M.  G.  D. 

ECONOMIC  GOODS,  see  Goods,  Economic. 
ECONOMIC  HARMONY.  A  phrase  ren- 
dered  classical  by  Bastiat,  the  title  of  the  last 
of  whose  works  it  forms  {Harmonies  ^cono- 
miques).  In  this  work  (chap,  x.)  may  be  found 
the  key  to  the  meaning  of  the  term,  "  the  con- 
stant approximation  of  all  men  towards  a  level 
which  is  always  rising — in  other  terms,  im- 
provement and  equalisation  —  in  one  word, 
harmony."  This  sentence,  if  understood  as  a 
precept   of  action,   combining  legislative  and 


ECONOMIC  HISTORY 


67a 


social  effort,  miglit  stand  as  an  expression  of 
the  aims  of  a  eoUectivist  or  socialist  of  the 
present  day.  But  with  Bastiat  it  expressed  a 
doctrine,  not  a  precept ;  and  therefore  bears  an 
interpretation  diametrically  opposed  to  the 
theory  of  the  communist.  For  indeed  Bastiat's 
fundamental  principles  of  harmony  he  termed 
property  and  liberty ;  and  his  doctrine  of 
economic  harmony  is  that,  under  absolutely  free 
exchange  of  labour  and  other  commodities, 
and  the  fullest  security  of  private  property, 
whether  in  land  or  other  things,  the  arrange- 
ments of  providence  are  such  as  to  continually 
improve  the  condition  of  the  human  race  ;  and 
that  any  disturbance  of  these  fundamental  laws 
retards  that  improvement.  Professor  Marshall 
{Principles,  1st  «d..  vol.  i.  p.  453)  states  the 
doctrine  thus :  "  The  maximum  satisfaction 
is  generally  to  be  attained  by  encouraging 
each  individual  to  spend  his  own  resources  in 
the  way  which  suits  him  best ; "  and  he  follows 
with  some  interesting  criticisms  of  the  theory, 
or  rather  limitations,  of  its  operation.  The 
latter  definition,  which  is  a  description  of  what 
has  been  termed  "enlightened  self-interest," 
scarcely  includes  all  that  is  involved  in  the 
individualist  theory  of  Bastiat ;  but  it  is  an 
accurate  statement  of  the  principle  which  under- 
lies it. 

The  phrase  economic  harmony  represents,  in 
another  form,  the  extreme  individual  theory, 
and  can  hardly  be  properly  called  an  economic 
doctrine  ;  it  is  rather  an  ethical  or  utilitarian 
deduction  from  economic  data.  But  it  is  used 
as  a  normal  rule  chiefly  to  exhibit  the  limita- 
tions to  which  it  is  subject.  It  rests  really 
upon  the  premiss  that  it  is  inditierent  to  any 
one  except  the  consumer  in  what  manner  wealth 
is  consumed  ;  a  position  not  seriously  main- 
tained by  any  economist,  and  explicitly  opposed 
to  the  last  of  Mill's  four  classical  propositions 
regarding  capital — "a  demand  for  commodities 
is  not  a  demand  for  labour."  The  importance 
of  consumption  as  a  factor  in  economics  has  of 
late  years  come  to  be  more  highly  appreciated  ; 
and  its  effect  on  an  idea  of  maximum  satisfac- 
tion will  be  found  to  modify  greatly,  if  not  to 
destroy  as  a  normal  principle,  the  doctrine  of 
economic  harmony. 

[See  Harmonies  of  Economics.]       m.  g.  d. 

ECONOMIC  HISTORY.  As  to  the  relation 
between  economic  history  and  economic  theory, 
five  views  are  possible,  which  may  for  con- 
venience be  given  the  following  brief  designa- 
tions : 

(1)  "The  710  -  connection  view."  This  was 
the  view  of  those  who  regarded  political  economy 
as  a  purely  deductive  science,  derived  infallibly 
from  a  few  simple  abstract  postulates  which 
every  reasonable  being  must  necessarily  grant. 
Political  economy,  in  this  view,  was  not  only 
not  "greedy  of  facts  "  ;  it  could  be  constructed 
in  absolute  disregard  of  any  alleged  facts  except 


the  assumed  postulates.  To  those  who  held 
this  view,  economic  history  had  no  direct 
interest,  any  more  than  heraldry  or  genealogy. 

(2)  "The  hand -maid  view."  This  view, 
which  is  but  a  slight  modification  of  (1),  is  still 
very  generally  current.  It  is  that  of  those  who 
while  believing  that  "economic  laws"  are  to 
be  obtained  by  deduction  from  given  assump- 
tions, are  interested  to  find  illustrations  or 
confirmations  of  their  conclusions  in  facts 
furnished  by  economic  history.  If  the  facts 
agree  with  the  theory,  so  much  the  better  for 
the  facts  ;  if  not,  then  they  are  left  alone,  and 
the  implication  is  that  the  historian  is  mistaken 
with  regard  to  them. 

(3)  "The  corrective  view"  is  again  a  modi- 
fication of  the  preceding.  It  grants  that 
economic  history  may  sometimes  furnish  reason 
for  questioning  abstract  conclusions,  and  pro- 
poses in  that  case  to  re-examine  the  original 
postulates,  and  either  to  modify  them,  or,  if 
they  are  still  tenable,  to  examine  into  the  dis- 
turbing influences  which  have  affected  the 
result.  This  is  a  position  which  has  been 
avowedly  held  by  many  recent  writers,  e.g.  by 
Cairnes  ;  but  there  are  few  examples  of  the 
practical  application  of  the  implied  rule. 

(4)  "The  concurrent  view"  is  one  appropri- 
ate to  a  period  of  compromise  following  upon 
one  of  controversy,  and  it  is  at  present  not 
infrequently  expressed.  It  is  that  economic 
history  and  economic  theory  have  each  an 
interest  and  importance  of  their  own  which 
will  attract  students  whose  bent  is  in  one  or 
other  direction  ;  and  it  leaves  to  the  future  the 
decision  of  the  question  what  bearing  historical 
work  may  have  on  economic  method. 

(5)  Finally  "The  supersession  view,"  which 
is  one  often  held  by  what  are  called  "econo- 
mists of  the  historical  school,"  teaches  that  the 
science  of  political  economy,  as  it  has  been 
created  by  the  classical  economists,  will  ulti- 
mately be  replaced  by,  or  incorporated  in,  a 
science  based  on  historical  investigation. 
Among  the  writers  of  this  school,  again,  there 
are  two  divergent  tendencies.  Some  think 
that  the  political  economy  of  the  future  will 
resemble  that  of  the  classical  school  in  contain- 
ing "  laws  "  or  brief  generalisations  concerning 
rent,  wages,  profits,  interest,  etc.,  but  derived 
wholly  or  chiefly  from  induction  from  observed 
facts  past  or  present.  This  view,  however,  is 
seldom  directly  formulated,  and  may  perhaps 
be  said  to  be  due  to  a  certain  vagueness  of 
thought  as  to  the  character  of  economic  "laws." 
Others  hold  that  political  economy  will  ulti- 
mately be  replaced  by  a  doctrine  of  economic 
development — a  philosophy  of  economic  his- 
tory ;  a  view  which  is  largely  due  to  the  influ- 
ence of  modern  conceptions  of  evolution,  and 
of  the  organic  nature  of  society  (see  Historical 
School  and  Historical  Method).  In  their 
view,  abstract  deductive  theory  will  continue  to 


876 


ECONOMIC  LAW— ECONOMIC  MAN 


be  of  use,  as  a  mincyr  method  of  investigation,  and 
as  a  useful  preparatory  training,  but  it  will  no 
longer  dominate  the  field  of  economic  thought. 

[G.  Schmoller,  on  Die  Schriften  von  Karl 
Menger  u.  W.  Dilthey  zur  Methodologie  der  Staats- 
und  Sozialwissenschaften  in  Zur  LitterOturge- 
schichte  der  Staats-  und  Sozialwissenschaften 
(1888).— K.  Menger,  Methode  der  Sozialwissen- 
scha/t.'—Die  Iirthiimer  des  Historismus  (1884).— 
J  N.  Keynes,  Scope  and  Method  of  Political 
Economy  (1891),  ch.  ix.,  note  B.— W.  J.  Ashley, 
Economic  History,  vol.  1.  pt.  1  (1888),  pre- 
face ;  and  On  the  Study  of  Economic  History  m 
the  (Harvard)  Quarterly  Journal  of  Economics 
for  January  1893.— J.  K.  Ingram,  History  of 
Political  Economy  (1888),  ch.  vi.  These  books, 
especially  those  of  Ingram  and  Keynes,  will  guide 
the  reader  to  the  very  considerable  literature  upon 
the  subject.]  W.J. a. 

ECONOMIC  LAW.  This  phrase  has  fre- 
quently given  rise  to  confusion.  Law,  in  its 
imperative  sense,  belongs  to  no  science ;  properly 
speaking,  it  is  a  term  in  the  art  of  legislation. 
Law,  in  its  indicative  sense,  as  a  statement  of 
cause  and  effect,  is  pm-ely  scientific  ;  and  when 
political  economy  is  treated  as  a  positive  science, 
it  is  in  this  sense  that  the  phrase  is  used  (see 
Marshall,  Principles,  introd.).  In  common 
parlance,  however,  an  economic  law  is  fre- 
quently understood  to  be  something  impera- 
tive, or  at  least  a  statement  that  a  certain 
course  of  action  is  wise  or  just ;  and  the  con- 
fusion between  the  art  of  legislation  based  on 
economic  formulae  and  the  science  of  economics 
itself  (from  which  the  works  even  of  the  classi- 
cal English  economists  are  not  free)  has  done 
much  to  spread  this  misunderstanding.  To 
break  the  laws  of  a  science  is  in  one  sense  im- 
possible, as  they  are  merely  generalised  state- 
ments of  fact ;  yet  it  is  not  uncommon  to  hear 
it  said  that  a  certain  course  of  action  will  break 
the  laws  of  political  economy  ;  when  what  is 
intended  to  be  conveyed  is  that  it  will  lead  to 
a  result  different  from  that  expected,  and  that 
the  laws  of  economics  prove  this.  Thus  it  is 
dften  said  that  to  regulate  the  hours  of  labour, 
or  to  introduce  differential  import  duties,  is  to 
break  economic  law  ;  and  M.  de  Laveleye,  in 
his  very  able  effort  to  include  the  science  of 
economics  in  an  art  of  sociology,  evidently 
considers  luxury  liable  to  be  condemned  in  a 
similar  manner.  (See  also  his  Elements  of 
Political  Economy,  for  an  account  of  economics 
treated  as  an  art  with  definite  moral  aims.) 

The  laws  of  a  science  are  always  in  them- 
selves useful  as  guides  to  action,  merely  because 
of  the  deductions  we  draw  from  them.  The 
objection  made  to  this  view  of  the  subject,  that 
rich  laws  are  entirely  barren  and  uninstructive, 
is  therefore  one  which  would  apply  equally  to 
every  science.  In  another  form,  however,  the 
objection  has  considerable  force.  A  scientific 
law  presupposes  unchanging  circumstances  ;  and 
any  alteration  in  these  introduces  a  new  law  to 


vary  the  relations  of  cause  and  effect.  In 
physical  science  we  find  uniformity  to  a  fai 
greater  extent  than  in  economics.  It  is  this 
uniformity  which  has  caused  the  phrase  "  exact 
science "  to  be  used ;  and  mathematics,  in 
which  the  circumstances  never  change,  is  the 
most  exact  of  all  sciences.  But  in  economics, 
where  the  conditions  are  dependent,  not  on  the 
inanimate  forces  of  natm-e,  but  on  the  varia- 
tions of  human  feeling,  passion,  sentiment,  and 
taste,  it  may  well  be  thought  that  no  generalisa- 
tion, comprehensive  enough  to  be  useful,  can 
be  made.  The  older  English  economists  were 
aware  of  this  ;  and  to  get  out  of  the  difficulty 
they  presupposed  a  state  of  matters  in  which 
mankind  is  governed  by  one  single  passion, 
viz.  the  desire  for  wealth.  Happily  they  never 
adhered  to  the  limitation  they  set  for  them- 
selves ;  indeed,  a  science  of  economics  on  these 
lines  is  as  inconceivable  as  a  science  of  dynamics 
where  every  force  is  neglected  excepting  that  of 
gravity.  The  great  complexity  and  variety  of 
circumstance  which  surround  every  economic 
problem  are  such  as  to  render  the  enunciation 
of  general  laws,  on  a  large  scale,  barely  possible, 
and  if  possible  barely  useful.  In  consequence 
of  this,  few  efforts  have  been  made  to  reduce 
any  economic  truths  to  theorems  ;  nor  is  it 
probable  that  any  such  theorems  will  be  found 
of  great  value.  Economic  laws  are  rather 
expressions  of  tendencies  than  actual  predic- 
tions of  cause  and  effect  (see  Laws  of 
Political  Economy). 

[See  Der  Gebrauch  des  Ausdruckes  "  Gesetz"  in 
der  National  Okonomie,  by  J.  Bonar,  Zeitschrift 
fiir  Volkswirthschaft,  1892.]  M.  g.  d. 

ECONOMIC  MAN.  This  term  has  been 
often  used  to  indicate  a  more  or  less  imaginary 
being  postulated  for  theoretical  purposes  by 
Abstract  Political  Economy  (g'.-v.)  Those 
writers  who  defend  the  use  of  the  conception, 
have  regarded  it  as  analogous  to  the  perfectly 
rigid  or  perfectly  smooth  body  assumed  in 
theoretical  mechanics.  Speaking  rouf'^ly,  the 
economic  man  is  one  who  in  his  economic  rela- 
tions is  moved  only  by  regard  to  his  own 
material  interests.  But  in  reality  there  is  con- 
siderable ambiguity  in  the  use  of  the  term. 
It  can  be  most  clearly  understood  when  applied 
to  the  sphere  of  contracts.  Thus  Dr.  Keynes, 
maintaining  in  a  qualified  form  the  legitimacy 
of  the  conception,  writes  {Scope  and  Method  of 
Political  Economy,  1891,  p.  121):  "Is  it  not 
a  patent  fact  that  in  buying  and  selling,  in 
agreeing  to  pay  or  to  accept  a  certain  rate  of 
wages,  in  letting  and  hiring,  in  lending  and 
borrowing,  the  average  man  aims  at  making  as 
good  a  bargain  for  himself  as  he  can  ? "  Hence 
in  relation  to  contract,  the  notion  of  the  econo-' 
mic  man  is  tolerably  clear.  He  may  perhaps 
be  best  defined  negatively,  either  as  one  who  is 
not  moved  by  regard  to  the  interests  of  the 
opposite  party  to  the  contract ;  or,  more  gener- 


ECONOMIC  MAN— ECONOMIC  SCIENCE 


677 


ally,  as  one  who  is  not  influenced  by  such 
motives  as  class-prejudice,  public  opinion,  resent- 
ment, compassion,  or  personal  partiality.  When 
we  pass  to  economic  actions  outside  the  sphere 
of  contract,  it  is  not  so  easy  to  define  the 
economic  man.  We  may  consider  first  the 
nature  of  the  objects  upon  which  a  man's 
material  resources  are  expended.  So  far  as 
economists  have  treated  the  problem  of  demand 
and  consumption  on  a  deductive  basis,  they 
have  certainly  not  assumed  that  the  economic 
man  normally  or  necessarily  expends  such 
wealth  as  he  may  have  acquired  only  upon 
objects  subserving  his  individual  interests. 
For  example,  the  family,  rather  than  the 
individual,  is  often  taken  as  the  unit  in  econo- 
mic science.  But  the  economic  man  may  be 
admitted  to  determine  his  expenditure  under 
an  indefinite  variety  of  influences,  such  as 
philanthropy,  love  of  ostentation,  etc.  In  fact, 
the  deductive  economist,  in  his  indifference  to 
the  purposes  for  which  wealth  in  general  is 
desired,  cannot  rightly  be  charged  with  recog- 
nising none  but  egoistic  motives  to  its  acquire- 
ment. Passing  from  consumption  to  produc- 
tion, we  have  to  recognise  the  universally 
antagonising  principles  to  the  desire  of  wealth, 
namely,  aversion  to  labour  and  to  the  postpone- 
ment of  enjoyments.  These  aversions  are  no 
doubt  of  a  purely  egoistic  kind.  But,  as  all 
economists  have  recognised  their  importance, 
they  clearly  have  not  represented  the  economic 
man  as  inspired  merely  by  a  desire  for  accumu- 
lation, irrespective  of  the  eflbrt  or  sacrifice 
involved.  Indeed,  they  have  gone  further  in 
difl'erentiating  the  various  motives  operating  in 
industry.  For,  from  Adam  Smith  downwards, 
they  have  allowed,  not  only  for  aversion  to 
toil  in  general,  but  also  for  various  degrees 
of  aversion  corresponding  to  various  kinds 
of  employment.  But  another  and  somewhat 
different  qualification  is  necessary  in  concrete 
applications  of  economic  doctrine.  In  the 
abstract  sciences  it  is  frequently  convenient 
to  take  no  account  of  forces  of  the  nature  of 
friction.  Thus  there  are  influences  which 
retard,  and  perhaps  permanently  modify,  the 
tendency  to  equilibrium  of  supply  and  demand. 
These  influences  are  mainly  those  of  custom, 
habit,  and  ignorance.  For  example,  a  labourer 
is  not,  or  has  not  been,  easily  moved  to  change 
his  abode  or  mode  of  employment,  in  circum- 
stances in  which  he  would  immediately  do  so 
if  he  were  deliberately  to  balance  its  advan- 
tages and  disadvantages,  including  risk  of 
adventure  and  breach  of  old  associations,  etc. 
Similarly,  important  limits  to  the  mobility 
of  capital  exist.  The  actions  neither  of  the 
labourer  nor  of  the  capitalist  are  wholly  the 
result  of  cool,  unimpassioned,  and  completely 
informed  reason.  Economists  of  all  schools 
have,  of  course,  recognised  these  facts.  But 
it  may  specially  be  noted  that  the  deductive 


economists  of  the  most  declai-ed  type  have 
attributed  to  the  working  classes  a  character 
which  is  the  reverse  of  economic.  An  import- 
ant part  of  the  doctrines  of  Ricardo  and  of  his 
followers  is  based  on  the  tendency  of  the  labour- 
ing class  to  multiply  until  their  resources  are  re- 
duced to  the  level  of  bare  subsistence.  In  this 
notable  case,  the  chiefs  of  the  deductive  school 
have  postulated  a  particularly  uneconomic  man. 
With  respect  to  the  range  of  application  of 
the  conception  of  the  economic  man,  there  are 
some  not  unimportant  differences  of  view  among 
the  supporters  of  the  abstract  method.  Bage- 
hot,  for  example,  regards  the  conception  as 
applicable  only  to  the  latest  phases  of  economic 
development.  Mill  and  Cairnes,  on  the  other 
hand,  hold  that  the  results  of  the  abstract 
method  indicate  universally  operative  tendencies, 
the  realisation  of  which  is,  more  or  less,  actually 
interfered  with  by  conflicting  forces.  A  slight 
modification  of  this  view  represents  the  motives 
of  the  purely  economic  man  as  manifesting 
themselves  in  the  long  run, — on  the  ground  that 
other  and  conflicting  motives  cancel  one  another 
when  a  sufficiently  large  area  is  contemplated. 

[Mill,  Unsettled  Questions  of  Political  Economy, 
Essay  v. — Cairnes,  Logical  Method  of  Political 
Economy,  Lecture  ii. — Bageliot,  Economic  Studies, 
Essays  i.,  ii.  — Keynes,  Scope  and  Method  oj 
Political  Economy,  chs.  i.,  iv.,  vii. — Sidgwiek, 
Principles  of  Political  Economy,  Introduction, 
ch.  iii. — Marshall,  Principles  of  Economics,  1891, 
vol.  i.  pp.  71-81. — ClifTe  Leslie,  Essays  in  Politi- 
cal Economy,  1888,  Essays  i.,  xv. — G.  J.  Goschen, 
Address  on  "  Ethics  and  Economics,"  to  the  British 
Economic  Association,  Economic  Journ.,  Sept. 
1893.] 

The  idea  of  a  semi-economic  man,  one  for  whom 
the  advantage  of  another  counts,  not  indeed  for  as 
much  as  his  own,  but  still  for  something,  is  sug- 
gested by  Prof.  Edgeworth  in  his  Mathematical 
Psychics,  pt.  i.  end  of  §  2.  A  similar  conception 
is  more  usefully  employed  by  Prof.  Marshall  in  his 
consideration  of  the  compromise  benefit  of  a  mono- 
polist (PWwa)j^es,  bk.  V.  ch.  xii. ).  The  whole  subject 
of  egoism  and  sympathy  in  their  economic  aspect  is 
well  treated  by  Prof.  Pantaleoni  in  the  beginning 
of  his  Principii  di  Economia  pnra.  See  also  Mr. 
Bonar's  discussion  of  utilitarianism  in  his  Philo- 
sophy and  Political  Economy,  1893.        w.  e.  J. 

ECONOMICS,  for  other  articles  under  this 
heading  see  Political  Economy. 

ECONOMIC  SCIENCE  and  ECONOMICS. 
The  terms  "economy"  and  "economic"  or 
"economical,"  are  now  used  chiefly  in  two 
meanings,  which  it  is  well  to  distinguish  clearly ; 
since,  though  divergent  in  their  history,  they 
are  liable  to  fusion,  and  therefore  in  some  degree 
to  confusion. 

"Economy"  originally  meant,  in  Greek,  the 
management  of  the  affairs  of  a  household, 
especially  the  provision  and  administration  of 
its  income.  But  since  both  in  the  acquisi- 
tion and  in  the  employment  of  wealth  it  is 


678 


ECONOMIC  SCIENCE 


fundamentally  important  to  avoid  waste  either 
of  labour  or  of  its  produce,  ''economy"  in 
modern  languages  lias  come  to  denote  generally 
the  principle  of  seeking  to  attain,  or  the  method 
of  attaining,  a  desired  end  with  the  least 
possible  expenditure  of  means  ;  and  the  words 
*  *  economy, "  "  economic, "  * '  economical, "  are 
often  used  in  this  sense,  even  without  any  direct 
relation  to  the  production,  distribution,  or 
consumption  of  wealth.  Thus  we  speak  of 
"economy  of  force"  in  a  mechanical  arrange- 
ment without  regard  to  its  utility,  and  of 
"  economy  of  time  "  in  any  employment  whether 
productive  of  wealth  or  not. 

On  the  other  hand,  as  there  is  an  obvious 
analogy  between  the  provision  for  the  needs  of 
a  state  and  the  provision  for  the  needs  of  a 
household,  "political  economy,"  in  Greek,  came 
to  be  recognised  as  an  appropriate  term  for  the 
financial  branch  of  the  art  or  business  of  govern- 
ment. It  is  found  in  this  sense  in  a  treatise 
translated  as  Aristotle's  in  the  13th  century  ; 
and  so,  when,  in  the  transition  from  mediaeval 
to  modern  history,  the  question  of  ways  and 
means  obtrusively  claimed  the  attention  of 
statesmen,  "political  economy"  was  the  name 
naturally  given  to  that  part  of  the  art  of  govern- 
ment which  had  for  its  aim  the  replenishment  of 
the  public  treasury,  and, — as  a  means  to  this, — 
the  enrichment  of  the  community  by  a  provident 
regulation  of  industry  and  trade.  And  the  term 
retained  this  meaning  till  the  latter  part  of  the 
1 8th  century  without  perceptible  change — except 
that,  towards  the  end  of  this  period,  the  enrich- 
ment of  the  people  came  to  be  less  exclusively 
regarded  from  the  point  of  view  of  public  finance, 
and  more  sought  as  a  condition  of  social  well- 
being. 

But  in  the  latter  part  of  the  18th  century, 
under  the  ^influence  primarily  of  the  leading 
French  " Economistes "  or  "Physiocrats"  — 
Quesnay,  De  la  Riviere,  and  others — the  con- 
ception of  political  economy  underwent  a  funda- 
mental change,  in  consequence  of  a  fundamental 
change  in  the  kind  of  answer  which  these  thinkers 
gave  to  the  question  "how  to  make  a  nation 
wealthy."  The  Physiocrats  proclaimed  to 
France,  and  through  France  to  the  world,  that 
a  statesman's  true  business  was  not  to  Tnake  laws 
for  industry  and  trade  in  the  hope  of  increasing 
wealth ;  but  merely  to  ascertain  and  protect 
from  encroachment  the  simple  and  immutable 
laws  of  nature,  under  which  the  production  of 
wealth  would  regulate  itself  in  the  best  possible 
way  if  governments  would  abstain  from  meddling. 
A  view  broadly  similar  to  this,  but  less  extreme, 
and,  partly  for  this  reason,  more  directly  influ- 
ential, was  expounded  in  Adam  Smith's  Wealth 
of  Nations.  Instead  of  showing  the  statesman 
how  to  "provide  a  plentiful  revenue  or  sub- 
sistence for  the  people  "—which  was  one  of  the 
two  main  objects  of  political  economy,  accord- 
ing to  the  traditional  view — Adam  Smith  aims 


at  showing  him  how  nature,  duly  left  alone, 
tends  in  the  main  to  attain  this  end  better 
than  the  statesman  can  attain  it  by  govern- 
mental interference.  Accordingly,  so  far  as  the 
widespread  influence  of  Adam  Smith's  teach- 
ing went,  that  branch  of  the  statesman's  art 
which  aimed  at  * '  providing  a  plentiful  revenue 
for  the  people"  tended  almost — though  not 
altogether — to  shrink  to  the  simple  maxim  of 
laisser  /aire :  leaving  in  its  place  a  scientific 
study  of  the  processes  by  which  wealth  is  pro- 
duced, distributed,  and  exchanged,  through  the 
spontaneous  and  partly  unconscious  division  of 
labour  among  the  members  of  human  society, 
independently  of  any  governmental  interference 
beyond  what  is  required  to  exclude  violence  or 
fraud.  A  part,  indeed,  of  the  old  art  of  political 
economy — that  which  aimed  at  "  supplying  the 
state  with  a  revenue  sufficient  for  the  public 
service  " — remained  indispensable  to  the  states- 
man ;  but  it  was  held  that  this  traditional  art 
required  to  be  renovated  by  being  rationally 
based  on  the  doctrines  of  the  new-bom  science 
just  described.  It  is,  then,  this  scientific  study 
of  a  department  of  social  activity  that  most 
writers  on  the  subject  now  primarily  mean  by 
the  term  "political  economy":  such  part  of 
the  old  governmental  art  so  called,  as  the  doc- 
trine of  the  new  science  is  held  to  admit,  being 
commonly  regarded  as  "applied  political 
economy."  In  consequence  of  this  change  the 
adjective  "economic,"  instead  of  the  too  cum- 
brous "politico-economic,"  has  come  to  denote 
the  matters  investigated  by  the  science  of  poli- 
tical economy,  and  the  propositions  and  argu- 
ments relating  to  them. 

By  thinkers  and  duly -instructed  students 
this  distinction  between  "science"  and  "art" 
— between  the  study  of  "  what  is  "  and  the  study 
of  "what  ought  to  be" — is  usually  regarded  as 
simple  and  clear  ;  and  accordingly  Avhen  such 
persons  speak  of  the  "  laws  of  political  economy  " 
they  mean  not  rules  by  which  the  process  of 
the  social  production  and  distribution  c.Xvealth 
ottght  to  be  governed,  but  general  relations  of 
CO -existence  and  sequence  among  phenomena 
of  this  class,  ascertained  by  a  scientific  study  of 
this  process  as  it  actually  takes  place.  This 
distinction,  however,  has  been  found  difficult  to 
establish  in  common  thought :  even  well-edu- 
cated persons  still  occasionally  speak  of  the 
"laws  of  political  economy"  as  being  "violated  " 
by  the  practice  of  statesmen,  trades-unions,  and 
other  individuals  and  bodies.  It  is  partly  in 
order  to  prevent  this  confusion  that  the  terms 
"economic  science"  and  "economics"  have 
recently  come  more  and  more  into  use,  as  a  pre- 
ferable alternative  for  political  economy,  so  far 
as  it  is  the  name  of  a  science.  As  to  the  scope 
of  this  science, — it  would  be  generally  agreed 
that  it  is  a  branch  of  a  larger  science,  dealing 
with  man  in  his  social  relations  ;  that  it  is  to 
an  important  extent,  but  not  altogether,  capable 


ECONOMISTES— EDEN 


679 


of  being  usefully  studied  in  separation  from 
other  branches  of  this  science  ;  and  that  it  is 
mainly  concerned  with  the  social  aspect — as 
distinct  from  the  special  technical  aspect — of 
such  human  activities  as  are  directed  towards  the 
production,  appropriation,  and  application  of 
the  material  means  of  satisfying  human  desires, 
so  far  as  such  means  are  capable  of  being  ex- 
changed. It  would  also  be  generally  agreed 
that  the  method  of  economic  science  is  partly 
deductive,  partly  inductive  and  historico- 
statistical.  But  to  attempt  a  more  precise 
determination  of  its  method  and  scope,  and 
especially  of  its  relation  to  the  art  or  system  of 
practical  rules  which  should  guide  the  action 
of  governments  or  private  individuals  in  eco- 
nomic matters,  would  require  us  to  enter  into 
questions  of  a  highly  controversial  kind  ;  which 
will  be  more  conveniently  discussed  when  we 
come  to  deal  with  the  older  and  wider  term 
Political  Economy  {q.v.)  h.  s. 

ECONOMISTES.  The  narrower  term  Physio- 
chats  {q.v.)  is  now  generally  applied  to  the 
writers  who  were  known  in  their  own  time,  and 
to  Adam  Smith,  Malthus,  etc.,  as  the  J^cono- 
mistes.  The  chief  members  of  the  "  sect "  were 
QuESNAY,  the  elder  Mirabeau,  Mercier  de  la 
RiviteRE,  Du  Pont  de  Nemours,  Abeille,  Bau- 
DEAu,  Rowland,  Saint  P^ravy,  Le  Trosne. 

As  to  the  origin  of  the  name  compare  Mira- 
beau (Letter  of  20th  December  1767  to  J.  J. 
Rousseau):  "Dema  part,  je  fondai  chez  moi 
un  diner  et  une  assemblee  tons  les  mardis.  J'y 
re9us  tons  les  etrangers  qui  viennent  voir  le 
baton  flottant  sur  I'onde,  les  magnats  qui  me 
viennent  voir,  et  surtout  la  jeunesse.  C'est  de 
ces  assemblees,  qui  ont  ete  fructueuses  k  I'exces, 
que  nous  est  venu  le  nom  d'ficonomistes." 
Levallois,  J.  J.  Rousseau,  ses  amis  et  ses  ennemis, 
Paris,  1865,  ii.  385. 

[For  further  remarks  on  the  Economistes,  see 
Physiocrats.]  h.  h. 

£lOU.  A  French  coin,  so  called  from  the 
shield  covered  with  fleurs-de-lis  which  was 
stamped  upon  it.  It  Avas  originally  a  gold 
coin,  and  was  first  struck  in  1336.  But  the 
historic  ecu  of  the  17th  and  18th  centuries 
was  a  silver  coin  (ecu  blanc),  corresponding  to 
the  English  "crown,"  and  worth  six  francs. 
There  was  also  petit  dcu  or  demi-ecu,  worth 
three  francs.  These  coins  were  in  circulation 
at  the  beginning  of  the  present  century.  In 
recent  times  the  term  4cu  has  been  applied  to 
a  piece  of  five  francs.  r.  l. 

The  gold  ecu  of  1336  was  made  of  pure  metal. 
(See  Traite  Historique,  des  Monnoyes  de  France, 
Le  Blanc,  Paris,  1692. )  The  silver  ecu,  first  struck 
in  1641,  was  of  silver,  913  fine.  (See  Traite  des 
Monnaies  d'or  et  d' argent,  Bonneville,  Paris,  1806.) 

F.  B.  a. 

EDEN,  Sir  Frederick  Morton,  Bart. 
(1766-1809),  graduated  at  Oxford,  and  was 
chairman  and  one  of  tho  founders  of  the  Globe 


Insurance  Company.  Eden's  independent  posi- 
tion was  favourable  to  his  completing,  in  the 
thirty-second  year  of  his  age,  his  principal  work, 
involving  much  study  and  expensive  research, 
The  Stale  of  the  Poor.  This  book,  called  by 
M'Culloch,  "the  grand  storehouse  of  informa- 
tion respecting  the  labouring  classes  of  Eng- 
land," entities  its  author  to  rank  with  Arthur 
Young  as  one  of  those  immediate  successors  of 
Adam  Smith  who  best  developed  the  inductive 
branch  of  political  economy.  The  importance 
of  facts  as  a  foundation  of  theory  is  insisted  on 
in  the  preface  and  opening  pages  of  this  work 
(p.  xxix  and  p.  4)  ;  "These  and  many  similar 
questions  [relating  to  the  poor  laws]  cannot, 
as  it  seems  to  me,  be  fully  and  satisfactorily 
answered,  unless  many  minute  circumstances 
are  previously  stated,  which  have  rarely  been 
sufficiently  attended  to  in  the  plausible  and 
ingenious  but  unsolid  speculations  of  several 
merely  theoretic  reasoners."  Such  writers 
"  voluntarily  impose  upon  themselves  the  task, 
so  much  and  so  justly  complained  of  by  the 
Israelites,  of  making  bricks  without  straw." 
"The  edifice  of  political  knowledge  cannot  be 
reared  without  its  'hewers  of  stone'  and 
'drawers  of  water.'  I  am  content  to  work 
among  them."  "  I  have  purposely  and  almost 
wholly  abstained  from  drawing  conclusions  from 
the  facts  here  presented  to  the  public."  For- 
tunately not  "wholly."  In  the  first  chapter 
of  his  second  book  Eden  discourses  freely  "of 
national  establishments  for  the  maintenance  of 
the  poor,  and  of  the  English  Poor  Laws,  and  of 
Mr.  Pitt's  proposed  bill  for  the  better  relief  of 
the  poor."  His  reflections  upon  the  events  and 
opinions  which  he  records  are  just  and  striking  : 
for  instance,  on  the  "fathers  of  the  poor," 
whom  Child  {q.v.)  proposed  to  create,  "not 
only  clothed  in  the  garbs,  but  vested  with  the 
powers  of  papal  inquisitors  "  (p.  188)  ;  or,  with 
reference  to  Henry  VIII. 's  confiscations,  on 
the  danger  of  reposing  confidence  in  "  the  most 
specious  promises  made  by  any  reformers  by 
violeTice,  whether  they  be  overbearing  despots 
like  Henry  the  Eighth,  canting  Puritans  like  the 
parliament  and  their  adherents  in  the  time  of 
our  First  Charles,  or  blustering  and  boastful 
constitution-mongers  like  many  of  the  modern 
revolutionists."  Although  Eden  declares,  "I 
have  never  wasted  that  time  in  polishing  a 
sentence -which  I  thought  I  could  better  employ 
in  ascertaining  a  fact,"  he  enhances  by  consider- 
able literary  attractions  the  curious  and  im- 
portant information  which  he  has  collected. 

The  subjects  which  Eden  principally  dealt  with 
are  suflBciently  indicated  by  a  title  which  is  almost 
a  catalogue  :  The  State  of  the  Poor,  an  history  of 
the  labouring  dasses  in  England  from  the  Con- 
quest to  the  present  period,  in  which  are  particu- 
larly considered  their  domestic  economy  with  respect 
to  diet,  dress,  fuel,  and  habitation,  and  the  various 
plans  which  from  time  to  time  have  been  proposed 


680 


EDEN— EDGEWORTH 


and  adopted  fcrr  the  relief  of  the  poor,  together 
imth  Parochial  Reports  relative  to  the  administra- 
tion of  Workhouses,  and  Houses  of  Industry  ;  the 
state  of  Friendly  Societies,  and  other  public  institu- 
tions, in  several  agricultural,  commercial,  and 
manufacturing  districts,  with  a  large  appendix, 
. . .  1797.  A  translation  of  the  less  detailed  parts  of 
this  work  is  published  in  Duquesnoy's  Recueil  de 
Mimoires  sur  les  Etablissements  d'Humanite,  No. 
21,  1799  ;  and  also  separately,  1800.  There  is  an 
analysis  of  Eden's  work  by  Cabanis,  in  the  Mercure 
Frangais,  Nos.  29,  30,  32,  an.  vi.  (1798).  Eden 
is  also  the  author  of  (1)  Porto- Bello,  or  a  Plan 
for  the  Impyr&veTnent  of  the  Port  and  City  of 
London,  1798.— (2)  An  Estimate  of  the  Nurriber 
of  Inhabitants  in  Great  Britain  and  Ireland, 
1800,  written  on  the  eve  of  the  first  census,  and 
estimating,  by  means  of  the  number  of  baptisms, 
the  population  of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland 
(inclusive  of  sailors  and  soldiers)  as  10,710,000. 
(The  real  number,  according  to  the  census,  was,  in 
round  figures,  14,991,000).— (3)  Eight  Letters  on 
the  Peace  and  on  the  Commerce  and  Manufactwres 
of  Great  Britain,  1802,  defending  the  peace  with 
France,  and  illustrating  the  economical  position  of 
England  by  statistics  and  interesting  reflections. — 
(4)  Address  on  the  Maritime  Rights  of  Great  Britain, 
1808  (first  edition  1807),  commending  the  orders 
in  council  of  1807,  and  "ofi'ering  some  suggestions 
on  the  measures  necessary  to  render  the  United 
Kingdom  independent  of  other  countries  for  the 
most  indispensable  articles  now  supplied  by  foreign 
commerce."  The  suggestions  comprehend  a  plan 
for  the  encouragement  of  Anglo -Merino  sheep, 
which  the  author  defends  against  "  Adam  Smith, 
the  great  enemy  of  bounties,"  having  regard  to 
"what,  on  the  whole,  in  pecuniary  or  political 
advantage,  will  be  the  gain  to  the  country  when 
the  measure  is  carried  into  full  effect."  Eden 
is  stated  (in  Walford's  Insurance  Cyclopcedia\ 
to  have  privately  printed  a  considerable  pamphlet 
On  the  Policy  and  Expediency  of  granting  In- 
surance Charters,  1806,  to  which  M'CuUoch  refers 
in  his  Literature.  There  is  among  the  Bentham 
MSS.  {BHt.  Mus.  Addit  MSS.,  31,235)  a  letter 
from  Eden  to  Vansittart,  containing  observations 
on  Bentham's  scheme  of  annuity  notes,    f.  t.  e. 

EDGEWORTH,  Maria  (1767-1849),  daugh- 
ter of  R.  L.  Edgeworth,  owing  to  the  great 
popularity  of  her  moral  tales  for  children, 
has  had  considerable  influence  on  the  attitude 
of  thought  in  England  regarding  economic 
questions.  An  intimate  friend  of  Malthus, 
Richard  Jones,  and  Ricardo,  and  well  ac- 
quainted with  their  works,  her  writings  evince 
considerable  power  of  applying  economic  prin- 
ciples successfully  in  everyday  life.  Her  novels 
and  tales  were  directly  written  to  inculcate  a 
utilitarian  morality,  and  the  virtues  which  she 
specially  exalts  are  those  assumed  to  exist  in 
the  economic  man  of  abstract  theory  —  in- 
telligence, honesty,  love  of  truth,  industry, 
prudence,  and  judgment ;  she  excelled  in  her 
truthful  portraits  of  the  stupid,  the  wilfully 
ignorant,  the  extravagant,  and  the  sentimental, 
against  whom   she  directed   a  keen  wit  and 


satire,  the  more  deadly  because  good-humoured. 
Her  books  for  children  dwelt  on  the  pains  ol 
idleness  and  the  pleasures  of  industry,  an  aspect 
of  the  labour  question  now  too  little  regarded. 
Her  pictures  of  life  among  the  Irish  peasantry 
and  the  English  working  classes  contain  fre- 
quent reference  to  the  lucrative  employment  of 
young  children  ;  but  although  she  believed  that 
work  was  pleasurable  even  when  remunerated, 
and  goes  so  far  as  to  make  four  orphans  under 
thirteen  years  of  age  support  themselves  (see 
Parent's  Assistant: — The  Orpham),  the  children 
in  her  stories  always  seek  and  receive  facilities 
for  educating  themselves.  Numerous  instances 
of  generous  and  yet  discriminating  relief  of  the 
distressed,  to  be  found  both  in  her  fiction  and  in 
her  life,  show  her  to  have  been  in  advance  of  her 
time  in  her  views  on  almsgiving ;  her  stories, 
Rosamond  and  Egerton  Abbey,  exemplify  this. 
(See  also  article  in  Charity  Organisation  Review, 
Nov.  1889).  To  the  economist  the  most  valu- 
able of  her  writings  are  the  novels  dealing  with 
the  relations  of  landlord  and  tenant  in  Ireland. 
The  land  agent,  middleman,  or  "journeyman 
gentleman"  is  presented  in  all  his  aspects, 
good,  bad,  and  indifferent.  Castle  Rackrent  is  a 
delightful  history  of  three  generations  of  Irish 
spendthrift  and  absentee  landlords,  written  from 
the  point  of  view  of  an  old  family  retainer. 
The  hero  of  The  Absentee,  whose  parents  have 
deserted  their  Irish  estates  for  London  society, 
travels  incognito  to  inspect  the  condition  and 
treatment  of  their  tenantry  ;  and  the  account 
of  his  adventures,  given  by  one  who  had  her- 
self acted  as  land  agent  on  her  father's  estate 
and  who  was  entirely  free  from  party  spirit,  is 
well  worth  studying  apart  from  its  artistic 
merits.  The  nearest  approach  to  definite  exposi- 
tion of  economic  theories  is  to  be  found  in 
Ennui,  in  the  criticism  of  the  well-meant  actions 
of  an  Irish  landlord  by  his  Scotch  agent.  Mr. 
M'Leod  *'  doubted  whether  the  best  way  of  en- 
couraging the  industrious  was  to  give  premiums 
to  the  idle."  "He  was  told  that  somi  -Indian 
Brahmins  were  so  very  compassionate  that  they 
hired  beggars  to  let  fleas  feed  upon  them.  He 
doubted  whether  it  might  not  be  better  to  let 
the  fleas  starve."  "He  doubted  whether  long 
leases  alone  would  make  impro^dng  tenants." 
"He  doubted  whether,  if  a  farm  could  support 
but  ten  people,  it  were  wise  to  encourage  the 
birth  of  twenty.  It  might  be  doubted  whether 
it  were  not  better  for  ten  to  live  and  be  well 
fed  than  for  twenty  to  be  bom  and  be  half 
starved."  "  He  doubted  whether  it  would  not 
encourage  the  manufacturers  to  make  bad  stuffs 
and  bad  linen,  since  they  were  sure  of  a  sale 
and  without  danger  of  competition,"  and  "he 
doubted  whether  it  would  not  be  better  for  a 
man  to  buy  shoes  if  he  could  buy  them  cheaper 
than  he  could  make  them."  The  admirable 
portrait  of  King  Corny  in  Ormond  elicited  warm 
praise  from  Macaula^. 


EDMONDS— EDWARDS 


681 


[Helen  Zimmem's  Maria  Edgeworthy  1883. 
The  books  for  children  still  widely  read  are : 
Frank,  Rosamond,  Harry  and  Lucy,  The  Parent's 
Assistant,  Moral  Tales,  and  Popular  Tales.  See 
also  article  in  International  Journal  of  Ethics 
for  April  1892,  where  the  writer  has  treated  this 
subject  at  greater  length.]  c.  e,  c. 

EDMONDS,  Thomas  Rowe  (1803-1889), 
bom  at  Penzance,  educated  at  Cambridge  (B.  A. , 
1826),  was  actuary  of  the  Legal  and  General 
Life  Assurance  Society  from  1832  to  1866. 
He  wrote  Life  Tables,  1832  ;  Inquiry  into  the 
Prmei'ples  of  Population,  1832  ;  Laws  regulat- 
ing Human  Mortality,  1866  ;  and  contributed 
many  papers  on  the  same  subject  to  the  Lancet. 
He  also  published  : — 

Practical,  Moral,  and  Political  Econoviy,  or  the 
Government,  Religion,  and  Institutions  most  con- 
ducive to  Individual  Happiness  and  to  National 
Power,  London,  1828,  8vo.  (**The  social  system 
is  the  limit  towards  which  all  governments  tend, 
and  at  which  they  cannot  fail  to  arrive  sooner 
or  later,"  p.  283.  The  author  considers  that 
labourers  should  work  six  hours  a  day,  and  pro- 
poses a  tax  on  marriage.) 

[Walford,  Insurance  Cyclopcedia,  ii.  470-74. — 
F.  Boase,  Modern  English  Biography,  i.  961. — 
Marx,  Misere  de  la  Philos.,  pp.  49-50.]  h.  r.  t. 

EDUCATION,  Economic  Aspects  of. 
Trade  and  industry  may  be  affected  by  educa- 
tion in  two  ways.  In  the  first  place,  their  pro- 
gress may  be  assisted  by  General  Education, 
which,  though  developed  without  any  im- 
mediate or  particular  reference  to  their  well- 
being,  must  necessarily  promote  it  by  quickening 
the  intelligence  and  calling  into  play  the 
latent  capacities  of  the  people  of  any  country. 
In  the  second  place,  a  particular  industry  will 
be  advanced  by  means  of  Technical  Education, 
which  renders  those  employed  or  likely  to  be 
employed  in  any  industry  more  fully  ac- 
quainted with  the  nature  of  its  processes  and 
with  such  branches  of  general  education  as  may 
be  deemed  to  have  a  direct  and  immediate 
bearing  on  these.  It  is  education  directed  to 
an  end,  and  a  particular  end.  General  Educa- 
tion, in  its  early  stages,  may  be  the  same  for  all 
classes,  notwithstanding  their  differences  of 
calling  ;  in  its  later  or  specialised  stages  it  will 
dii'ect  attention  to  certain  cognate  branches  of 
study  with  the  view  of  inducing  students  to 
concentrate  their  powers  on  the  problems 
presented  by  these  studies.  Should  these 
problems  coincide  with  or  resemble  those  in- 
volved in  the  profession  or  trade  they  may 
adopt,  they  wiU  be  additionally  benefited. 
Technical  Education,  on  the  other  hand,  will 
have  regard  to  the  special  requirements  of  the 
profession  or  trade  in  which  the  students  in 
question  are,  or  are  likely  to  be  employed.  It 
will  be  evident  that  the  term  Techniatl  Educa- 
tion, though  usually  employed  as  above,  may  be, 
expanded  so  as  to  include  or  imply  an  education 
more  fitly  described  as  specialised  education. 


General  Education. — In  order  that  the  ad- 
vantages of  such  education  may  be  fully  felt 
it  is  necessary  that  it  should  (1)  in  its  primary 
stages  be  national  ;  (2)  in  its  later  or  specialised 
stages  be  open  to  all  those  fitted  to  avail  them- 
selves of  it.  The  first  of  these  conditions  has 
been  recognised  by  civilised  nations.  As  a  rule 
it  has,  so  far  at  least  as  a  certain  minimum, 
been  made  compulsory.  There  is  overwhelming 
testimony  to  the  benefits  conferred  on  industry 
by  such  a  state  of  things.  The  second  condition 
is  less  fully  regarded,  little  provision  being 
made  in  many  countries,  among  which  we  must 
include  England,  where  the  higher  education  is 
costly.  The  advantages  of  a  high  standard  of 
General  Education  may  be  seen  from  many  ex- 
amples, as  for  instance  the  position  of  America 
and  in  some  degree  that  of  Germany.  England, 
where  in  industry  the  standard  of  workmanship 
is  high,  owes  her  position  to  causes  somewhat 
different.  She  owes  much  to  her  political 
condition,  and  much  also  to  the  free  and  fair 
intercourse  of  life  common  to  her. 

Technical  Education. — The  early  recognition 
of  the  desirability  of  such  training  may  be 
gathered  from  the  evidence  before  Royal  Com- 
missions, etc.  (see  especially  "  Royal  Commission 
to  inquire  into  condition  of  the  Handloom 
Weavers,"  Pari.  Paper,  1841,  vol.  x.),  in  which 
the  difference  in  artistic  merit  between  English 
and  French  work  is  instanced  and  the  demand 
made  for  the  establishment  of  schools  of  design, 
etc.  But  England  made  much  less  rapid  advance 
in  this  respect  than  most  of  the  chief  foreign 
countries,  where  highly  -  organised  systems  of 
technical  instruction  have  been  adopted  (see 
L' Enseignment  Commercial,  par  Eugene  Leautey). 
In  this  country,  on  the  contrary,  little  was 
achieved  till  1890. 

[The  "  economic  value "  of  the  intelligence  of 
the  population  is  borne  witness  to  by  all  our  lead- 
ing economic  authorities.  See  e.g.  Marshall, 
Principles  of  Economics,  1st  ed.  pp.  264-276.] 

E.  C.  K.  G. 

EDWARDS,  Bryan  (1743-1800)  was  born 
at  Westbury.  In  1759  he  went  out  to  Jamaica 
to  the  house  of  his  uncle,  a  merchant  in  that 
island.  On  his  uncle's  death  he  succeeded  to 
the  business  and  other  property.  His  chief 
interests  lay  in  the  West  Indies,  and  though 
shortly  before  his  death  he  returned  to  England 
and  sat  in  parliament  as  member  for  Gram- 
pound,  he  continued  to  act  chiefly  in  the 
interest  of  the  West  Indies.  His  principal 
work  is  ITie  History,  Civil  and  Commercial,  of 
the  British  Colonies  in  the  West  Indies,  published 
in  1793  ;  a  third  edition  of  this  work  appeared 
in  1&07  in  an  enlarged  form,  containing  a  brief 
autobiography  and  chapters  on  the  French  colo- 
nies in  the  West  Indies.  These  were  first  pub- 
lished in  1797  as  A  Historical  Survey  of  the 
French  Colony  in  the  Island  of  San  Domingo, 
The  economic  importance  of  the  book  which 


682 


EDWARDS— EFFICIENCY  OF  LABOUR 


reached  a  fifth  edition  in  5  vols.  8vo,  in  1819, 
lies  (a)  in  the  full  and  accurate  account  of  the 
West  Indies  contained  in  it ;  (b)  in  an  able  and 
temperate  discussion  of  the  slavery  question 
from  the  point  of  view  of  a  defender,  though  not 
an  advocate  of  it.  He  considers  it  impossible 
to  abolish  the  slave  trade,  but  insists  that  it 
should  be  placed  under  government  regulation, 
and  considers  that  the  importation  of  a  larger 
number  of  negresses  would  bring  the  trade  to 
a  natural  end.  His  arguments  in  defence  of 
slavery  are  of  the  usual  type,  but  he  admits 
that  the  institution  has  a  tendency  to  injure 
the  character  of  the  planters. 

He  also  wrote  Thoughts  on  the  Late  Proceed- 
ings of  Government  respecting  the  Trade  of  the 
West  India  Islands  with  the  United  Staies, 
1784  ;  Speech  at  a  Free  Conference  between  the 
Council  and  Assembly  of  Jamaica  on  Wilber- 
force's  Proposition  concerning  the  Slave  Trade, 
1790 ;  and  some  other  pamphlets  on  West 
Indian  Questions. 

[British  Museum  Catalogue.  —  Dictionary  of 
National  Biography. — M'Culloch,  Lit.  Pol.  Econ., 
p.  92.]  c.  G.  c. 

EDWARDS,  George,  M.D.  (1752-1823). 
George  Edwards  took  his  doctor's  degree  at 
Edinburgh  in  1772,  and  practised  at  Barnard 
Castle  in  Durham,  and  afterwards  in  London, 
where  he  died.  Besides  a  few  medical  works 
he  published  a  large  number  of  pamphlets  upon 
social  questions,  propounding  various  remedies 
for  the  social  ills  which  weighed  upon  England 
in  the  early  part  of  the  19th  century.  He 
seems,  however,  to  have  been  more  impressed 
with  the  evils  than  capable  of  studying  them 
scientifically  ;  and  to  have  been  little  more 
than  a  political  visionary.  His  chief  discovery 
in  his  own  eyes  was  the  invention  of  the  income 
tax.  The  British  Museum  contains  about  forty 
pamphlets  by  him,  which  are  principally  de- 
voted to  recommending  the  precepts  contained 
in  his  larger  books. 

Their  titles  are:  The  Aggrandisement  and 
National  Prosperity  of  Great  Britain,  1787. — 
The  Royal  and  Constitutional  Regeneration  of 
Great  Britain,  17 S7.— The  Practical  Means  of 
effectually  exonerating  the  Public  Burthens  of  pay- 
ing the  National  Debt,  and  of  raising  the  Supplies 
of  War  vnthout  new  Taxes,  1790. — Effectual 
Means  of  providing  against  Scarcity  and  High 
Prices  of  different  Articles  of  Food,  1800  ;  A 
Plan  of  an  Undertaking  .  .  .  for  the  improve- 
vient  of  Husbandry,  etc.,  Newcastle,  1783,  8vo. — 
Radical  Means  of  counteracting  the  present 
Scarcity  and  preventing  Famine  in  the  Future  ; 
including  the  Proposal  of  a  Maximum  founded 
on  a  New  Principle,  etc.,  London,  1801,  fol.— ^ 
Plain  Practical  Plan  by  which  Great  Britain  may 
extricate  herself  from  her  present  Difficulties,  etc., 
London,  1808,  4to  ;  with  many  more  of  the  same 
kind. 

[Gentlemen  s  Magazine,  1823  ;  Dictionary  of 
National  Biography;  Allibone's  Dictionary  Brit, 
and  Amxr.  Authors,  i.]  c.  g.  c. 


EFFECTS.  This  is  one  of  the  vague  and 
undefined  words  which  often  occur  in  legal 
documents,  and  are  a  frequent  cause  of  litigation. 
A  gift  of  the  testator's  efiects  in  a  will,  unless 
restrained  by  the  context,  means  a  gift  of  the 
whole  of  the  personal  property,  and  may,  if 
other  circumstances  favour  such  an  interpreta- 
tion, include  even  real  estate.  The  word  also 
occurs  in  partnership  deeds  in  the  combination 
**  estate  and  effects  of  the  partnership,"  which 
has  been  held  to  include  all  the  property  of  the 
partnership  "available  for  the  purpose  of  dis- 
charging the  debts  and  liabilities."  (Steuart 
V.  Gladstone,  10  Chancery  Division  626.) 

EFFECTUAL  DEMAND.  See  Demand; 
Demand  Curves. 

EFFICIENCY  OF  LABOUR  is  the  resultant 
of  combined  (1)  strength,  (2)  skiU,  (3)  diligence 
and  care  on  the  part  of  the  labourer.  The  pro- 
duct of  his  labour  is  manifestly  governed  very 
largely  also  by  the  efficiency  of  the  tools  he  is 
supplied  with,  and  the  efficiency  of  the  superin- 
tendents under  whom  he  serves  ;  but  these  are 
rather  external  aids  furnished  from  the  side  of 
capital  than  constituent  conditions  of  efficient 
labour  itself.  The  most  perfect  tools  are  value- 
less in  the  hands  of  the  inefficient,  whereas 
the  truly  efficient  workman,  according  to  an 
eminent  practical  authority,  Mr.  Nasmyth, 
the  inventor  of  the  steam  hammer,  is  a  man 
who  can  always  produce  his  result  with  the 
tools  that  lie  to  his  hand,  or,  as  the  same  idea 
is  expressed  in  the  curious  maxim  of  another 
eminent  engineer,  Maudsley,  the  criterion  of 
the  thorough  mechanic  is  to  be  able  to  cut  a 
plank  with  a  gimlet  and  bore  a  hole  with  a  saw. 
The  workman  who  can  do  as  well  with  bad  tools 
as  his  neighbour  does  with  good,  will  accomplish 
with  good  tools  much  more  remarkable  results ; 
but  the  secret  of  his  efficiency  in  both  cases 
lies  in  the  physical,  mental,  and  moral  energies 
of  the  man's  own  being. 

(1)  The  first  condition  of  the  fit  workman  is 
physical  vigour — not  merely  muscular,  but 
general  vigour,  for  as  Professor  M.  Foster  ob- 
serves *'  the  power  of  doing  work  hangs  not  on 
the  muscle  alone,  but  on  the  heart,  the  lungs, 
the  nervous  system,  and  indeed  the  whole  body" 
(Text-booJc  of  Physiology,  p.  845).  Nervous 
energy  is  of  especial  moment,  because  fatigue 
is  much  more  a  nervous  than  a  muscular  con- 
dition. Professor  Foster  considers  it  doubtful 
whether  men  ever,  even  in  their  severest 
efforts,  draw  on  more  than  a  portion  of  the 
store  of  energy  lodged  in  their  muscles  ;  it 
is  the  store  of  energy  in  the  nerves  that  gives 
out.  People  differ  much  in  their  power  of 
sustaining  hard  and  continuous  exertion,  and 
in  the  degree  of  ardour  and  "go"  they  throw 
into  it,  and  the  difference  depends  on  the 
general  conditions  of  sound  physical  health, 
especially  on  original  constitution,  more  or  less 


EFFICIENCY  OF  LABOUR 


683 


plentiful  diet  and  adequate  or  inadequate  repose. 
A  mountain  stock  has  more  grit  than  the 
average,  even  though  it  has  been  more  poorly- 
fed  ;  and  Mr.  Jones,  one  of  Mr.  Brassey's 
managers,  always  preferred  mountaineers  for 
railway -making  when  he  could  obtain  them. 
English  workmen  enjoy  better  fare  and  shorter 
hours  than  other  workmen,  and  they  are  noted 
for  their  physical  strength,  their  endurance, 
and  their  rapidity  at  work.  Mr.  Brassey  found 
English  navvies  able  to  do  heavier  work,  to  do 
more  work  in  the  day,  and  to  remain  afterwards 
fresher  for  an  extra  spurt  if  required,  than  any 
other  navvies  in  the  world.  In  constructing 
the  Paris  and  Rouen  railway,  in  which  he 
employed  4000  Englishmen  and  6000  French- 
men, he  took  great  pains  to  ascertain  the  rela- 
tive industrial  capacity  of  the  two  nations, 
and  he  came  to  the  general  conclusion  that 
three  Englishmen  did  the  work  of  four  French- 
men. In  ''shifting"  materials  the  English 
navvy  was  found  to  do  twice  as  much  work  in 
the  day  as  the  French,  though  he  worked  two 
hours  less,  and  he  received  twice  the  wages, 
and  a  half-franc  more,  because  he  could  be 
counted  on  for  additional  speed  under  pressure ; 
while  for  the  hard  work  of  mining  and  tunnel- 
Img,  Mr.  Brassey  employed  none  but  English- 
men ;  and  even  in  Italy,  where  he  found  the 
Piedmontese  excellent  workers — in  some  respects 
better  than  the  English — and  employed  them 
in  tunnelling  in  dry  rock,  he  still  reserved  the 
more  arduous  labour  of  tunnelling  in  clay  for 
English  limbs  (Brassey,  IForJc  and  Wages,  pp. 
118,  146).  For  mere  strength  Englishmen 
excel  even  their  better- fed  but  longer- worked 
American  kinsmen.  ''When  we  want  physical 
force  combined  with  skill,"  says  the  well-known 
American  ironmaster,  Mr.  A.  Hewitt,  "we  get 
Englishmen"  {Trade  Union  Commission  Re- 
port, qu.  6980).  In  girder  rolling  he  said  the 
Americans  were  more  active  and  better  rollers, 
but  when  it  came  to  puddling  the  heavy  bars 
there  were  no  workmen  like  the  English  ;  and 
the  reason  was,  what  he  thought  every  observer 
must  remark,  that  the  English  were  superior  to 
the  Americans  in  physical  development.  Sir 
I.  L.  Bell,  in  a  comparison  of  five  American 
furnaces  with  those  of  Cleveland,  calculates 
that  the  workers  in  an  English  furnace,  with 
a  shorter  working  day,  move  2400  tons  of 
fuel,  ore,  and  limestone  in  the  week,  while  the 
same  number  of  Americans  move  only  2100  tons 
{Iron  Trade  of  United  Kingdom,  p.  137). 
Luxemburg  ironstone,  again,  is  not  harder  to 
work  than  Cleveland  ironstone,  but  two  Cleve- 
land miners  turn  out  10|  tons  of  stone  in  an 
eight  hours'  day,  whereas  two  Luxemburg 
miners  turn  out  only  1 0  tons  in  a  twelve  hours' 
one  {ib.  86).  In  continental  textile  mills 
Mr.  Mundella  always  found  five  hands  doing 
work  that  was  done  in  England  by  three. 
During  the  eight  hours  strike  in  Melbourne  in 


1859,  it  was  ascertained  for  a  wager  that  an 
English  bricklayer  laid  half  as  many  bricks 
again  in  the  day  as  a  German.  Then  in  Eng- 
land itself,  the  well-fed  Midland  labourer  will 
do  twice  the  work  of  the  ill-fed  Dorset  hind  ; 
whilst  the  Australians,  the  best-fed  and  shortest- 
worked  race  of  work-people  in  the  world,  strike 
even  English  eyes  for  the  extraordinary  vigour 
and  "go"  they  put  into  their  work.  Lord 
Brassey  praises  the  "remarkable  physique"  of 
the  Australian  navvy,  and  Captain  Henderson, 
R.N.,  said  Australian  dockers  coaled  a  ship 
three  times  as  fast  as  English  ones  {Proceedings 
of  Royal  Colonial  Institute,  xix.  122).  More 
specific  proof  still  exists  of  the  connection  be- 
tween work  and  feeding.  Mr,  Brassey  often 
employed  agricultural  labourers  for  navvy  work, 
and  when  they  first  came  they  would  lie  down 
utterly  exhausted  about  three  in  the  afternoon, 
but  after  twelve  months  of  good  wages  and 
better  diet  than  they  enjoyed  before,  they  be- 
came quite  fit  to  do  their  work  without  any 
difficulty.  Irishmen  in  their  own  country  are 
the  poorest  of  workmen,  mainly  because  of 
their  poor  fare.  Arthur  Young  said,  in  his  time, 
that  an  Essex  labourer  at  half-a-crown  a  day 
was  cheaper  than  a  Tipperary  labourer  at  five- 
pence  ;  and  Mr.  J.  Fox  said  to  the  Trade  De- 
pression Commission  that,  though  he  paid  the 
hands  in  his  Manchester  mill  20  per  cent  higher 
wages  than  the  hands  in  his  Cork  mill,  the 
real  cost  of  the  work  was  the  same  in  both. 
But  when  the  Irish  come  over  to  England  and 
get  better  diet  their  working  power  soon  im- 
proves ;  Sir  I.  L.  Bell  says,  many  young  Irish- 
men come  to  Cleveland  ironworks,  and  though 
not  worth  much  at  first,  yet  "as  soon  as  their 
improved  style  of  living  permits  it,"  they  be- 
come equal  to  any  workman  in  Cleveland,  both 
for  ability  and  will  to  work.  M.  Chevalier 
mentions  that  when  Messrs.  Manby  and  Wilson 
started  their  French  foundry  at  Charenton  in 
1820,  they  brought  over  a  few  of  their  English 
hands  with  them,  and  found  these  did  far  more 
work  than  the  French  labourers.  Suspecting 
the  reason  to  be  better  nourishment,  they  took 
steps  to  get  the  French  work-people  to  eat  as 
much  meat  as  the  English  ;  and  the  result  was, 
that  in  a  short  time  they  did  nearly  as  much 
work  as  the  English  too.  The  eff"ect  of  shorten- 
ing hours  of  labour  in  improving  industrial 
energy  will  be  treated  separately,  but  even  the 
minor  changes  in  the  sanitary  conditions  of  work, 
effected  by  the  Factory  Acts,  have  caused  such 
a  perceptible  increase  in  productive  capacity 
that  Dr.  J.  Watts  says  Lancashire  cotton  opera- 
tives care  far  more  about  being  employed  in  a 
good  mill,  with  plenty  of  air  and  light,  than 
about  the  exact  price  per  lb.  they  get  for  spin- 
ning or  per  piece  for  weaving,  because  "they 
know  practically  what  is  the  effect  of  these 
conditions  upon  the  weekly  wages  "  {Fads  about 
the  Cotton  Famine,  p.  44).     The  same  sound 


684 


EFFICIENCY  OF  LABOUR 


physical  conditions  which  enlarge  productive 
capacity  at  the  time  also  extend  the  term  of 
efficient  working  life. 

(2)  Skill  is  a  compound  of  general  mental  in- 
telligence, special  technical  culture,  and  acquired 
manual  dexterity.  All  work  involves  head 
work.  The  good  workman  must  be  a  thinking 
and  planning  being,  and  according  to  his  general 
intelligence  will  be  his  share  of  the  supreme  in- 
dustrial qualities  of  resourcefulness,  versatility, 
and  precision.  The  intelligent  man  needs  a 
shorter  apprenticeship  and  less  superintendence, 
and  is  less  wasteful  of  materials,  all  simply  be- 
cause he  understands  better  than  the  ignorant 
man  the  nature  of  the  stuff  he  handles,  the 
working  of  the  tools  and  machinery  he  uses, 
and  the  end  and  object  of  the  commodity  he  is 
making.  Hence  the  immense  industrial  value 
of  general  education.  The  want  of  education 
has  hitherto  been  the  chief  industrial  defect  of 
the  English  workman.  Escher,  a  Swiss  manu- 
facturer, who  employed  about  2000  hands  of 
all  nationalities,  said,  in  1840,  that  while  the 
English  workmen  were  the  best  in  what  they 
had  actually  learnt,  they  were  of  less  value  out- 
side their  own  specific  work  than  the  Swiss  or 
the  Scotch,  because  of  their  inferior  education 
(MiU,  Political  Economy,  bk.  i.  ch.  vii.  §  5). 
But  on  the  other  hand,  a  later  Swiss  manu- 
factm'cr,  Herr  Wunderley,  who  also  employed 
men  of  all  European  nationalities  in  his  mills, 
stated  to  the  Technical  Instruction  Commission 
that  there  was  a  certain  practicality  and  method 
in  English  labour — a  mechanical  genius,  he 
termed  it — which  seemed  to  enable  it  to  do, 
without  much  knowledge,  what  continental 
labour  did  with  it  (Technical  Instruction  Com- 
mission Report,  p.  269).  Mr.  Mundella,  too, 
thinks  that  English  labourers  naturally  more 
inventive  than  foreigners,  more  apt  in  devising 
means  for  ends,  but  this  is  probably  due  in 
some  degree  to  their  greater  physical  energy, 
their  greater  determination  not  to  be  mastered 
by  a  difficulty;  for  Mr.  E.  Rose,  in  1832, 
stated  one  of  the  chief  diflferences  between 
French  and  English  work-people  to  be  that  the 
French  got  much  sooner  bewildered  with  a 
difficulty  and  gave  in,  while  the  English  still 
kept  on  trying  to  find  a  way  out  until  the  thing 
was  done  (Senior,  Political  Economy,  p.  150). 
But  all  are  agreed  that  this  and  other  in- 
dustrial capacities  would  be  greatly  developed 
by  better  education.  Mr.  E.  Peshine  Smith 
states  that  the  Massachusetts  Board  of  Education 
procured  from  the  owners  of  factories  in  that 
state,  some  fifty  years  ago,  a  report  of  the  dif- 
ferent rates  of  wages  paid  and  the  education 
of  the  recipients,  and  the  amount  of  wages 
varied  exactly  as  the  education,  the  lowest  being 
foreigners  who  signed  their  name  with  a  mark, 
and  the  highest  the  girls  who  went  to  school 
in  winter  and  worked  in  the  mills  in  summer. 
He  adds  that  it  was  estimated  that  popular 


education  gave  an  advantage  of  20  per  cent  to 
the  American  manufacturer  in  competition 
with  foreigners  (Manvnl  of  Political  Economy, 
151).  American  manufacturers  used  to  say 
that,  from  their  better  education,  two  American 
mill  hands  would  do  the  work  of  three  English 
ones,  and  Mr.  Harris  Gastrell,  in  his  report  to 
the  English  Foreign  Office  in  1873,  admits 
that  this  may  be  so  still  in  the  mills — now 
apparently  a  minority — where  American  has  not 
been  superseded  by  foreign  labour  (p.  682). 
Sir  W.  Fairbairn  said,  that  for  difficult 
engineering  work  they  always  looked  out  for 
the  best -educated  workmen  ;  and  when  Mr. 
Mundella  asked  a  Swiss  manufacturer  how  his 
countrymen  had  taken  the  ribbon  trade  from 
the  French,  he  was  answered,  *' We  beat  them 
by  means  of  an  educated  people." 

Special  dexterities  are,  generally  speaking, 
the  result  of  special  training  and  practice. 
No  doubt  cunning  of  hand  may  be  inherited 
like  other  faculties,  but  even  then  greater 
facility  still  comes  from  repetition.  This  is 
the  source  of  the  increment  of  production 
obtained  through  division  of  labour.  The 
jack-of-all-trades  never  has  the  chance  of  be- 
coming master  of  any ;  but  when  every  man 
confines  himself  to  a  separate  trade,  the  sum 
of  their  total  work  is  improved,  both  in  quality 
and  quantity,  through  the  greater  perfection 
each  man  acquires  in  the  performance  of  his 
special  branch  of  work  by  means  of  constant 
repetition.  On  the  other  hand,  an  extreme 
sub-division  of  labour  may  involve  a  certain 
monotony  which  is  not  favourable  to  efficiency 
even  in  the  special  branch  of  work  concerned, 
and  is  certainly  adverse  to  general  efficiency. 
Marx,  however,  exaggerates  the  ill  effects  of 
specialisation  when  he  caUs  the  modern  "detail 
workman"  a  mutilated  and  crippled  monstrosity, 
a  mere  bit  of  the  machine  he  sits  and  watches. 
Mr.  Nasmyth,  with  much  more  practical  experi- 
ence, says  he  has  often  been  struck  to  observe 
how  this  process  of  watching  the  beautiful  and 
precise  working  of  machinery  exercised  a  posi- 
tively intellectualising  effect  upon  the  labourer 
which  was  not  unfavourable  to  versatility. 
Another  essential  for  good  work,  hardly  behind 
manual  facility,  is  visual  accuracy,  and  Mr. 
Nasmyth  thinks  the  average  workman  comes  far 
short  in  this  quality  ;  he  found  that  his  own 
men  in  general  spent  most  of  their  time  in 
applying  the  rule  and  straightedge,  while  the 
dexterous  workman  seldom  used  these  tools 
at  all  ;  his  eye  was  enough. 

Intermediate  between  this  cunning  of  ^ye  and 
hand,  and  general  mental  intelligence,  stand 
certain  special  mental  capacities,  such  as  artistic 
taste  and  mastery  of  sciences  cognate  to  the 
workman's  trade,  which  are  of  great  importance 
for  good  work,  though  some  authorities  contend 
they  are  less  the  concern  of  the  manual  labourer 
who  executes  the  work  than  of  the  designers  and 


EFFICIENCY  OF  MONEY— EGOISM 


685 


managers  who  direct  it.  The  French  have  long 
excelled  all  other  nations  in  taste,  and  the 
Germans  have  pushed  to  the  front  in  some 
industries  through  their  better  technical  and 
scientific  instruction. 

(3)  Diligence  and  care  are  the  moral  virtues  of 
labour,  and  in  the  national  distribution  of 
industrial  qualities  they  are  the  portion  of  the 
Germans.  The  English,  as  Defoe  said,  are 
the  most  diligent-lazy  people  in  the  world, 
very  strenuous  in  their  work  while  they  are  at 
it,  but  prone  to  breaks  of  idleness  after  pay- 
days, or  at  other  times,  for  purposes  of  dissipa- 
tion. This  is,  of  course,  a  great  advance  in 
diligence  over  the  uniform  sluggishness  and 
aversion  to  labour  of  many  inferior  races,  but 
it  stands  much  below  the  diligence  of  the 
Germans,  who  are  not  only  steady  and  docile 
in  general,  but  have  a  conscientiousness  and 
power  of  taking  pains  which  alone  render  them, 
says  Sir  C.  W.  Siemens,  preferable  to  other  work- 
people for  many  special  kinds  of  work.  No 
race  is  incurably  indolent.  The  Scotch  in  the 
last  century  were  counted  the  laziest  people  in 
the  United  Kingdom,  and  in  this  century  are  the 
most  industrious.  The  Irish  are  still  thought 
idle  in  Ireland  and  found  active  out  of  it. 
The  diligence  is  always  due  to  circumstances, 
to  a  change  from  conditions  in  which  nothing 
was  to  be  made  by  working  to  conditions  in 
which  present  work  is  seen  establishing  future 
comfort,  and  is  made  pleasant  and  cheerful  by 
the  hope  so  inspired.  The  great  encourager  of 
willing  industry  is  good  wages.  It  is  an  old 
contention  —  which  was  already  successfully 
refuted  with  a  considerable  induction  of  facts 
by  Adam  Smith  (  Wealth  of  Naiions,  bk.  i.  ch. 
viii.) — that  good  wages  only  make  men  indolent, 
enabling  them  to  supply  their  wants  with  so 
much  less  labour  ;  and  Professor  Caimes  (Some 
Leading  Principles  of  Pol.  PJcon.,  p.  240)  has 
made  a  kindred  objection,  that  good  wages  are 
a  bad  thing,  because  they  always  encourage 
dissipation  ;  but  both  these  objections  err  by 
drawing  an  unwarrantable  conclusion  as  to  the 
general  operation  of  good  wages  from  the  ex- 
perience of  their  operation  in  particular  in- 
stances only.  The  countries  of  the  highest 
wages  are  also  the  countries  of  the  highest 
productivity ;  and  while  wages  have  been  gener- 
ally rising  for  half  a  century,  drunkenness  has 
been  lessening.  j.  R. 

EFFICIENCY  OF  MONEY.  This  term  is 
proposed  by  Mill  to  express  "the  average 
number  of  purchases  made  by  each  piece  in 
order  to  eflfect  a  given  pecuniary  amount  of 
transactions."  According  to  the  **  quantity 
theory,"  in  that  rudimentary  form  which  makes 
abstraction  of  Credit,  the  value  of  money  will 
be  inversely  proportional  to  the  quantity  multi- 
plied by  the  efficiency  thereof.  This  proposition 
is  not  true  of  the  rapidity  of  circulation,  when 
defined,   e.g.   by   Roscher,   as   the   number   of 


purchases  made  by  each  piece  per  year  (or  other 
unit  of  tiTne)  ;  unless  indeed  the  total  amount 
of  transactions  is  regarded  as  constant. 

A  wider  definition  of  "  efficiency  "  covers  the 
circulation  of  instruments  of  credit  as  well  as 
coins.  Thus  Mill:  "as  money  tells  upon 
prices  not  simply  in  proportion  to  its  amount, 
but  to  its  amount  multii^lied  by  the  number  of 
times  it  changes  hands,  so  also  does  credit." 
Mr.  Macleod  has  in  view  this  wider  sense  when 
he  introduces  the  happy  phrase  "duty"  of 
money  (Economic  Philosophy,  i.  p.  211). 

There  is  reason  to  believe  that  the  efficiency 
of  money  in  both  these  senses  varies  from  time 
to  time.  Mill  says  {Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  iii.  ch.  xii. 
§  3),  "  the  money  of  the  community  is  virtually 
increased  in  a  time  of  speculative  activity  .  .  . 
by  increased  rapidity  of  circulation."  So 
Walker  {Pol.  Econ.,  art.  174),  "the  rapidity  of 
circulation  varies  from  day  to  day  with  the 
state  of  trade  and  the  temper  of  the  public 
mind."  But  precise  observations  of  the  extent 
of  variation  are  wanting.  "On  that  subject 
there  are  no  statistics,"  says  Prof.  Marshall 
{Evidence  hefore  the  Royal  Commission  on  Pecent 
Changes  in  the  value  of  Silver  and  Gold). 

Much  the  same  may  be  said  of  efficiency  in  a 
third  sense  in  which  the  term  is  sometimes 
used,  namely,  to  denote  the  amount  of  pecuni- 
ary transactions  which  a  given  quantity  of  the 
metallic  standard  either  effects  directly  by  hard 
cash  payments,  or  supports  and  renders  possible 
by  acting  as  a  reserve.  We  may  say  that  the 
efficiency  of  money  in  this  sense  is  greater  in 
one  country  {e.g.  England)  than  another ;  but 
an  accurate  measure  is  not  to  be  expected  ;  for 
even  if  we  could  ascertain  (1)  the  total  amount 
of  metallic  money,  whether  in  active  circulation, 
or  in  reserve,  and  also  the  "  efficiency  "  (in  the 
first  sense  of  the  term)  of  that  part  which  is  in 
active  circulation  ;  and  (2)  the  total  volume  of 
things  on  sale ;  we  should  still  require  to  know 
the  average  number  of  times  each  of  these  things 
changes  hands  during  the  year,  the  rapidity  of 
the  circulation  of  goods,  and,  as  Prof.  Marshall 
says  {loc.  cit),  "with  regard  to  that  we  have  no 
statistics  whatever  ;  indeed  there  has  never  been 
any  attempt  to  obtain  statistics  on  the  subject." 

[Mill,  Political  Economy,  bk.  iii.  ch.  viii.  §  3, 
ch.  xii.  §§  3,  4. — Walker,  Political  Economy,  art. 
174. — Money,  p.  62. — Roscher,  System  of  Political 
Economy,  §  123,  and  authorities  there  cited. — H. 
D.  Macleod,  Economic  Philosophy,  i.  p.  211. 

On  the  statistical  aspect  of  the  subject  some 
hints  may  be  obtained  from  the  following  :  On 
Currency,  anonymous,  attributed  to  Sir  J.  W. 
Lubbock,  London  (Charles  Knight  and  Co.),  1840 
(included  by  Jevons  in  his  list  of  Mathematico- 
Economic  books). — Dr.  Franz  Krai,  Geldwert  und 
Preishewegung  (Staatswissenschaftliche  Studien, 
Dr.  L.  Elster).]  See  Rapidity  of  Circulation. 

F.  Y.  E. 

EGOISM.  This  term  may  be  said  to  have 
a  popular  and  also  a  philosophic  meaning.      In 


686 


EGOISM 


popular  usage  it  is  nearly  equivalent  to  selfish- 
ness, and  expresses  the  temper  of  mind  which 
sacrifices  to  one's  own  welfare  the  welfare  of 
others.  Economists  have  often  been  accused 
of  assuming  that  all  men  are  egoists  in  this 
sense,  and  of  giving  practical  precepts  in  con- 
formity with  this  assumption.  In  philosophic 
usage  egoism  has  a  more  subtle  meaning. 
Egoistic  psychology  finds  the  only  possible 
motive  of  action  in  the  desire  to  attain  pleasure 
and  to  avoid  pain,  although  it  allows  that  this 
desire  may  often  prompt  to  actions  which  in 
ordinary  parlance  would  be  called  unselfish. 
Egoistic  ethics,  taking  its  premisses  from  egoistic 
psychology,  defines  morality  as  the  intelligent 
pursuit  of  that  which  instinct  compels  us  to 
pursue,  as  the  rational  pursuit  of  pleasure  and 
avoidance  of  pain,  although  it  tries  to  show 
that  such  morality  is  compatible  with  what 
is  commonly  known  as  unselfishness.  The 
founders  of  modern  political  economy  have 
often  been  censured  for  assuming  the  truth  of 
egoistic  psychology  and  the  validity  of  egoistic 
ethics.  This  charge  is  quite  distinct  from  the 
other  charge,  although  the  two  are  commonly 
confused.  The  first  has  excited  most  odium. 
The  second  is  more  difficult  to  disprove.  No 
distinguished  economist  has  said  that  men  all 
are  and  ought  to  be  selfish.  But  many  dis- 
tinguished economists  have  held  that  self-love 
is  the  mainspring  of  human  action. 

Adam  Smith's  view  respecting  the  influence 
of  self-love  on  economic  action  is  most  plainly 
stated  in  his  account  of  the  principle  which 
gives  occasion  to  the  division  of  labour  (  Wealth 
of  Nations,  bk.  i.  ch.  ii.):  "Man  has  almost 
constant  occasion  for  the  help  of  his  brethren, 
and  it  is  in  vain  for  him  to  expect  it  from  their 
benevolence  only.  He  will  be  more  likely  to 
prevail  if  he  can  interest  their  self-love  in  his 
favour  and  show  them  that  it  is  for  their  own 
advantage  to  do  for  him  what  he  requires  of 
them.  ...  It  is  not  from  the  benevolence  of 
the  butcher,  the  brewer,  or  the  baker,  that  we 
expect  oui-  dinner,  but  from  their  regard  to 
their  own  interest.  We  address  ourselves  not 
to  their  humanity,  but  to  their  self-love  ;  and 
never  talk  to  them  of  our  own  necessities,  but 
of  their  advantages.  Nobody  but  a  beggar 
chooses  to  depend  chiefly  upon  the  benevolence 
of  his  fellow-citizens."  At  first  sight  this 
passage  seems  to  assert  that  selfishness  is  the 
only  economic  motive.  But  on  further  con- 
sideration it  will  appear  that  the  operation  of 
self-love  here  described  is  not  of  that  injurious 
kind  which  would  commonly  be  considered 
selfish.  Tradesmen  who  undertook  to  supply 
everything  gratis  would  be  far  less  useful  to 
society  than  tradesmen  who  expect  a  fair  price 
for  their  goods.  Such  an  expectation  is  not 
selfish  in  the  popular  sense  of  the  term.  It  is 
only  conformable  to  common  sense.  Similarly, 
when    Adam    Smith    recommended    complete 


economic  liberty  and  trusted  to  self-love  to 
generate  the  best  economic  system,  he  did  not 
mean  to  preach  selfishness  in  the  popular  sense. 
The  self-love  to  which  he  trusted  was  self-love 
restrained  by  the  criminal  and  civil  law,  by 
pubHc  opinion,  by  conscience,  and  by  social 
and  amiable  instincts.  With  his  sentiments 
we  may  compare  those  of  Malthus  expressed  in 
the  Appendix  to  his  Essay  on  Population :  "The 
great  Author  of  nature  ...  by  making  the 
passion  of  self-love  beyond  comparison  stronger 
than  the  passion  of  benevolence,  has  at  once 
impelled  us  to  that  line  of  conduct  which  is 
essential  to  the  preservation  of  the  human 
race.  ...  He  has  enjoined  every  man  to 
pursue  as  his  primary  object  his  own  safety  and 
happiness  and  the  safety  and  happiness  of 
those  immediately  connected  with  him.  .  .  . 
By  this  wise  provision  the  most  ignorant  are 
led  to  promote  the  general  happiness,  an  end 
which  they  would  have  totally  failed  to  attain 
if  the  moving  principle  of  their  conduct  had 
been  benevolence.  Benevolence  indeed  as  the 
great  and  constant  source  of  action  would 
require  the  most  perfect  knowledge  of  causes 
and  effects,  and  therefore  can  only  be  the  attri- 
bute of  the  Deity." 

Here  self-love  is  not  only  stated  as  the 
actual,  but  justified  as  the  best,  motive  of 
ordinary  human  action.  Yet  the  self-love  here 
justified  is  not  selfishness  commonly  so  called. 
Thus  it  includes  "those  immediately  connected 
with"  oneself,  i.e.  one's  family.  Again  the 
benevolence  here  disparaged  seems  confined  to 
the  desire  of  doing  good  directly  to  others. 
The  scope  of  such  benevolence  must  always  be 
narrow  for  most  men.  In  ninety-nine  cases 
out  of  a  hundred  the  greatest  service  which  a 
plain  man  can  render  to  society  is  to  do  his 
own  work  well.  His  work  will  doubtless  be 
ennobled  by  his  perceiving  that  it  has  a  value 
for  society  as  well  as  for  himself.  But  if  he 
were  to  forsake  it  and  devote  himself  entirely 
to  works  of  charity  he  would  be  less  useful  than 
in  his  old  calling.  Malthus  felt  that  he  had  laid 
himself  open  to  misinterpretation,  for  he  adds 
in  a  note  :  "It  seems  proper  to  make  a  decided 
distinction  between  self-love  and  selfishness, 
between  that  passion  which  under  proper  regu- 
lations is  the  source  of  all  honourable  industry 
and  of  all  the  necessaries  and  conveniences  of 
life,  and  the  same  passion  pushed  to  excess 
when  it  becomes  useless  and  disgusting  and 
consequently  vicious." 

These  quotations  do  not  justify  the  inference 
that  Adam  Smith  and  his  successors  alleged 
that  mankind  universally  were  or  ought  to  be 
selfish  in  the  plain  sense  of  that  term.  "  This 
opinion  may  be  dismissed  at  once  as  a  popular 
error  which  finds  no  support  in  the  teaching  or 
practice  of  the  best  economists "  (Marshall, 
Principles  of  Economics,  bk.  i.  ch.  vi. ,  '  'Economic 
Motives.")     But  the  above  quotations  do  show 


EGOISM— EIGHT  HOUKS  MOVEMENT 


687 


that  the  founders  of  modern  jjolitical  economy 
accepted  an  egoistic  psychology  and  an  egoistic 
ethics.  In  other  words,  they  took  for  granted 
the  current  philosophy  of  their  day.  That 
philosophy  regarded  man  simply  as  a  subject 
of  pleasure  and  pain,  and  defined  morality  as 
the  line  of  conduct  which  led  to  happiness. 
The  motive  of  duty  to  one's  fellows  was  found 
in  the  gratification  of  the  social  instinct. 
Human  shortcomings  were  made  good  by  the 
over-ruling  benevolence  of  God  or  of  nature 
which  led  every  man  to  promote  the  good  of 
others  even  when  thinking  solely  of  his  own. 
It  may  well  be  that  such  a  philosophy  is  in- 
adequate or  even  corrupting  ;  but  it  is  unfair 
to  blame  an  economist  for  accepting  the  philo- 
sophy current  in  his  own  day.  With  the 
ultimate  solution  of  psychological  or  ethical 
problems  an  economist  has  nothing  to  do.  As 
a  man  of  science  he  has  only  to  estimate  the 
motives  which  actuate  men  in  producing,  dis- 
tributing, and  consuming  wealth.  As  an 
adviser  of  individuals  or  of  states,  he  has  only 
to  take  for  granted  the  highest  morality  known 
to  his  age. 

Egoism  or  selfishness  in  the  popular  sense  is 
perhaps  more  conspicuous  in  the  economical 
sphere  than  in  any  other  sphere  of  human 
activity.  Yet  even  here  it  affords  no  universal 
key.  "  Ethical  forces,"  says  Prof.  Marshall 
in  the  preface  to  his  Principles  of  Economics, 
"are  among  those  of  which  the  economist  has 
to  take  account.  Attempts  have  indeed  been 
made  to  construct  an  abstract  science  with  re- 
gard to  the  actions  of  an  '  economic  man, ' 
who  is  under  no  ethical  influences,  and  who 
pursues  pecuniary  gain  warily  and  energetically, 
but  mechanically  and  selfishly.  But  they  have 
not  been  successful,  nor  even  thoroughly  carried 
out.  For  they  have  never  really  treated  the 
economic  man  as  perfectly  selfish  ;  no  one 
could  be  relied  on  better  to  endure  toil  and 
sacrifice  with  the  unselfish  desire  to  make  pro- 
vision for  his  family  ;  and  his  normal  motives 
have  always  been  tacitly  assumed  to  include 
the  family  aff"ections.  But  if  they  '  include 
these,  why  should  they  not  include  all  other 
altruistic  motives,  the  action  of  which  is  so  far 
uniform  in  any  class  at  any  time  or  place  that 
it  can  be  reduced  to  general  rule  ?  There  seems 
to  be  no  reason."  And  in  the  chapter  on 
economic  motives  above  referred  to.  Prof.  Mar- 
shall points  out  that  it  is  the  measurable,  not 
the  selfish  character  of  motives,  which  brings 
them  within  the  range  of  economic  inquiry. 
Of  course  the  motives  thus  measurable  are 
not  simple  but  highly  complex.  We  may  be 
able  to  measure,  e.g.  the  force  of  the  complex 
motive  which  leads  a  particular  class  in  a  par- 
ticular country  to  spend  money  on  the  educa- 
tion of  their  children.  But  we  cannot  measure, 
nor  for  economical  purposes  is  it  necessary  to 
measure,  the  relative   importance  of  the  ele- 


ments in  this  complex  motive,  such  as  desire 
for  the  worldly  advancement  of  one's  children, 
desire  for  their  spiritual  perfection,  etc.  Nor 
need  we  determine  how  far  each  particular 
motive  approaches  to  pure  selfishness  or  pure 
unselfishness. 

In  giving  practical  advice  the  economist 
must  equally  take  account  of  ethics.  It  will 
be  useless  or  mischievous  to  give  advice  which 
the  common  conscience  of  mankind  declares  to 
be  immoral ;  and  equally  useless  or  mischiev- 
ous to  give  advice  which  assumes  that  gi'eat 
masses  of  human  beings  are  exempt  from  human 
weakness.  In  estimating  the  force  of  egoism 
under  actual  conditions,  and  the  possibility  of 
controlling  it  to  higher  issues,  the  economist 
will  be  guided  aright  only  by  a  sagacity  which 
is  the  gift  of  nature,  although  it  may  be  im- 
proved by  study.  It  would  not  be  hard  to 
show  that  even  so  well-informed  a  writer  as 
Mill  thought  contemporary  men  more  selfish 
than  they  are,  and  expected  men  in  the  future 
to  be  less  selfish  than  they  are  likely  to  prove. 

[See  Goschen  in  jEcon.  Journ.,  Sept.  1893,  and 
Economic  Man.]  f.  c.  m. 

EGRON,  Adrien  Ci^sar,  born  in  Tours,  was 
a  printer  and  publisher  in  Paris  (fl.  first  half  of 
19th  cent.).  He  printed  in  1844  his  Livre  de 
VOuvrier;  ses  devoirs  envers  la  SociStS,  la  fa- 
mille,  et  lui-mime  and  in  1847  his  Livre  du 
Pauvre ;  devoirs  de  celui  qui  donne  et  de  celui 
qui  7'egoiL  Both  works  consist  mainly  of  a  series 
of  extracts  out  of  different  writers  from  the  Bible 
and  Aristophanes  to  modern  times,  illustrating 
the  duties  of  the  rich  and  of  the  poor  respect- 
ively. These  are  connected  by  rather  prolix 
considerations  of  his  own.  He  is  much  more  a 
Christian  moralist  than  an  economist.    E.  ca. 

EIGHT -PIECE  (or  piece -of- eight).  A 
Spanish  silver  coin  of  the  value  of  eight  reals, 
was  for  many  years  known  as  a  "piece-of-eight" 
throughout  the  British,  American,  and  West 
Indian  colonies,  where  it  was  the  principal  coin 
in  use  from  the  time  of  the  foundation  of  those 
colonies  until  the  early  part  of  the  19  th  century. 
It  circulated  in  the  United  States  until  as  late 
as  the  year  1857,  when  it  was  withdrawn  from 
circulation  in  that  country  and  demonetised. 
Pieces-of-eight  were  also  to  be  found  in  circula- 
tion in  New  South  Wales  during  the  early  years 
of  that  colony's  existence  ;  and  they  are  still 
used  in  some  of  the  islands  of  the  East  Indian 
archipelago.  The  title  "  piece-of-eight "  fell 
into  disuse  about  the  end  of  the  17th  century, 
when  the  coin  began  to  be  known  as  the 
''Spanish"  or  "hard"  dollar  (see  Dollar, 
Hard).  f.  e.  a. 

EIGHT  HOURS  MOVEMENT.  An  agita- 
tion for  a  universal  eight  hours  day  of  labour 
— for  eight  hours  work  without  diminution  of 
pay — was  begun  in  England  as  far  back  as 
1833,  by  two  large  employers,  John  Fielden, 
M.P.,  and   Robert   Owen,   and   a   special   or- 


688 


EIGHT  HOURS  MOVEMENT 


ganisation,  the  National  Regeneration  Society, 
as  it  was  termed,  was  formed  to  carry  on 
the  agitation,  but  it  led  to  no  results,  and  the 
question  was  not  practically  raised  ^  in  this 
country  again  tiU  the  present  energetic  move- 
ment sprang  up  here  and  on  the  continent 
simultaneously  about  the  year  1887.  Mean- 
while a  successful  beginning  had  been  made 
with  the  eight  hours  movement  by  the  working 
class  in  Victoria  in  1856,  in  New  South  Wales 
in  1863,  and  in  the  United  States  in  1866, 
and  under  the  same  general  influences  which 
brought  the  question  up  in  Europe,  this 
Australian  movement  took  a  fresh  start  in 
1884,  and  the  American  in  1886.  Of  the  fifty- 
two  trades  of  Melbourne  which,  by  1892,  enjoyed 
the  eight  hours  day,  thirty-two  obtained  it  since 
1884.  In  the  United  States,  where  the  agita- 
tion died  away  altogether  after  the  industrial 
depression  of  1873,  in  which  its  previous  gains 
were  all  lost,  the  struggle  was  renewed  every 
spring  with  a  great  campaign  of  strikes,  and 
the  eight  hours  day  spread  among  the  more 
poAverful  trades. 

A  special  plea  for  the  eight  hours'  day  is  set 
up  on  behalf  of  certain  exceptional  trades  on 
account  of  their  dangerous,  unhealthy,  or 
exhausting  character,  but  with  respect  to  the 
mass  of  ordinary  occupations  the  demand  is 
usually  based  on  one  or  other  of  two  different 
and  indeed  opposite  grounds.  The  advocates 
of  one  section  base  it  on  the  necessity  of  the 
eight  hours  day  for  realising  the  recognised 
claim  of  modern  workpeople  to  reasonable 
leisure  for  the  culture,  enjoyments,  and  duties 
of  life,  and  on  the  small  cost,  if  any,  at  which 
the  claim  can,  in  their  view,  be  realised, 
inasmuch  as  experience  seems  to  justify  the 
expectation  that  the  personal  efficiency  of 
labour  would  be  so  much  improved  under  an 
eight-hours  system  that  the  rate  of  individual 
production  would  remain  as  high  as  before. 
Another  section  plead  for  the  eight  hours  day 
because  they  believe  it  will  result  in  the 
contrary  alternative  of  a  general  diminution 
of  individual  production,  and  they  think  it 
will  prove,  on  that  account,  a  sure  means  of 
increasing  the  demand  for  labour,  thinning  the 
ranks  of  the  unemployed,  and  raising  the 
general  rate  of  wages.  The  latter  plea,  though 
apparently  the  most  prominent  and  influential 
in  the  present  movement,  is  unsolid,  going 
against  the  possibilities  of  the  case  in  its  view 
of  the  eff'ect  of  a  general  diminution  of  individual 
production,  and  against  its  probabilities  in  its 
view  of  the  effects  of  a  general  eight  hours  day. 
On  the  former  point  it  is  admitted,  by  those 
who  use  this  plea  with  discrimination  (cp.  Webb 
and  Cox,  Eight  Hours  Day,  p.  107),  that  if  a 
general  diminution  of  individual  production 
involved  a  corresponding  diminution  of  the 
aggregate  production  of  the  country,  it  would 
necessarily  cause  a  fall  instead  of  a  rise  in  the 


demand  for  labour,  because  the  amount  of  work 
which  society  requires  done  at  any  given  time 
depends  strictly  on  the  extent  of  the  produce 
of  society  at  that  time.  But  they  contend 
that  the  aggregate  production  of  the  country 
will  not  be  diminished,  inasmuch  as  any 
shortcomings  wiU  be  made  up  by  the  work  of 
those  who  are  at  present  unable  to  obtain 
employment  at  all.  They  seem  to  believe  it 
possible  to  make  work  for  the  unemployed  by 
means  of  capital  that  only  comes  into  existence 
as  the  product  of  the  work  it  is  supposed  to 
make,  but  if  they  can  do  that  under  an  eight 
hours  system,  why  cannot  they  do  it  now  ? 

As  a  matter  of  experience  the  eight  hours 
day  has  surprisingly  little  effect  on  the  numbers 
of  the  unemployed.  In  Victoria,  for  example, 
where  three-fourths  of  the  population  now  work 
only  eight  hours  a  day,  the  unemployed  are 
strangely  enough  a  greater  and  more  constant 
trouble  than  they  are  here,  and,  stranger  still, 
they  seem  to  have  become  even  a  greater 
trouble  since  the  eight  hours  day  became 
general  some  years  ago  than  they  were  before. 
Whatever  are  the  causes  of  this  redundancy, 
the  eight  hours  day  has  had  little  influence 
to  check  them ;  and  the  reason  of  this  is  twofold. 
First,  shortening  the  hours  of  labour  has  no 
possible  effect  on  the  ordinary  causes  of  fluctua- 
tions of  employment,  bad  harvests,  injudicious 
speculations,  wars,  bad  weather,  sudden  changes 
of  fashion,  etc.  ;  and  second,  shortening  the 
hours  of  labour  involves  no  corresponding 
shortening  of  the  product  of  labour,  because 
it  enables  the  labourer  very  largely,  in  many 
cases  completely,  to  recover  by  the  greater 
intensity  and  energy  of  his  work  what  he  loses 
by  its  shorter  duration. 

The  degree  of  this  recovery  naturally  diflers 
in  different  occupations,  but  we  have  now  had 
extensive  experience  of  the  eight  hours  day, 
and  the  results  of  that  experience  show  (1)  that 
there  are  extremely  few  occupations  in  which  no 
recuperation  at  all  takes  place,  but  the  diminu- 
tion of  work  has  been  exactly  proportional  to 
the  diminution  of  time  of  work  ;  and  (2)  that 
in  the  majority  of  trades  in  which  the  experi- 
ment has  been  tried,  the  recuperation  has  been, 
not  partial  merely,  but  complete.  Nay,  in  a 
number  of  cases  there  has  been  a  positive  in- 
crease of  product.  Mr.  W.  Allan,  Scotia  Engine 
Works,  Sunderland,  for  example,  found  the 
labour  cost  of  his  engines  to  have  become  slightly 
less.  Mr.  Beaufoy,  M.P.,  vinegar  and  jam 
manufacturer,  gets  more  work  done  in  the  year, 
and  without  any  overtime,  than  he  ever  got 
done  even  with  some  months'  overtime  before, 
and  he  did  not  employ  a  single  additional  hand 
except  three  or  four  gate-keepers.  The  South 
Yorkshire  miners  had  their  hours  reduced  in 
1858  from  twelve  to  eight,  and  turned  out 
much  more  in  the.  short  day  than  they  did  in 
the  long  one.     The  men  in  some  of  the  depart. 


EIGHT  HOURS  MOVEMENT 


689 


ments  of  the  Springfield  Armoury,  U.S.A., 
were  found  in  1868  to  have  done  considerably 
more  work  in  eight  hours  than  they  used  to  do 
in  ten  ;  and  in  the  other  departments  the  old 
rate  of  production,  though  not  similarly  exceeded, 
was  fully  maintained.  The  same  result  of  a 
full  maintenance  of  the  old  rate  of  production 
is  reported  of  many  other  eight  hour  experi- 
ments in  trades  so  various  as  iron  shipbuilding, 
chemical  manufacture,  engineering,  glass- 
making,  cabinet-making,  printing,  masonwork, 
cutlery,  soda  manufacture,  typefounding. 
There  is  more  than  one  instance  of  this 
occurring  even  in  cotton -spinning,  when  the 
mills  were  working  slack  time.  The  reason  is 
in  all  cases  the  same  ;  less  lost  time  and  more 
physical  energy.  While  the  period  of  nominal 
work  is  shortened,  the  period  of  effective  work 
is  really  lengthened.  The  large  number  of  the 
trades  in  which  the  eight  hours  day  has  been 
already  introduced  without  interfering  with  the 
amount  of  production  certainly  suggests  the 
probability  of  its  similarly  successful  introduc- 
tion into  most  other  productive  trades.  The 
London  gas-workers,  indeed,  did  not  maintain 
their  production,  but  then  the  reduction  in  their 
hours  was  very  great,  from  twelve  to  eight,  and  as 
it  was,  their  product  per  hour  was  so  much  im- 
proved that,  though  their  hours  were  shortened 
by  a  third,  they  did  in  one  of  the  gasworks  one- 
sixth,  in  another  one-seventh,  and  in  a  third 
only  one-twelfth  less  work.  There  are  other 
trades,  like  gate-keeping,  and  perhaps  certain 
branches  of  tram  and  railway  service,  in  which 
the  work  is  not  susceptible  of  compression  into 
shorter  time,  but  they  are  not  numerous.  And 
it  is  worthy  of  notice  that  the  Huddersfield 
Tramways,  on  substituting  two  eight  hours 
shifts  for  one  fourteen  hours  day,  did  not  require 
twice  as  many  conductors  and  drivers  as  before, 
but  only  half  as  many  again.  Under  all  these 
circumstances  the  very  current  expectation  that 
the  eight  hours  day  will  do  anything  consider- 
able in  thinning  the  number  of  the  unemployed 
is  illusory,  and  the  true  hope  of  the  movement 
lies  in  the  probability — the  very  great  proba- 
bility— that  the  eight  hours  day  may  be 
generally  introduced  without  in  any  way  im- 
pairing production,  and  therefore  without  in 
any  way  either  lowering  the  rate  of  wages 
or  lessening  the  competing  capacity  of  the 
nation. 

Those  who  believe  in  this  probability  will 
not  be  greatly  concerned  whether  the  eight 
hours  day  is  to  come  by  trade-union  agency  or 
by  legislative  enactment,  the  aspect  of  the  ques- 
tion on  which  opinion  in  this  country  is  chiefly 
divided.  There  cannot  be  said  to  be  two 
opinions  about  the  desirability  of  the  eight 
hours  day  in  itself ;  for  experience  of  previous 
shortening  of  hours  justifies  the  expectation 
that  the  leisure  will  be  a  much  more  abundant 
source   of  good   than   of  ill   to   the   working 

VOL.  I. 


classes  ;  but  even  among  these  classes  them- 
selves there  is  a  strong,  though  declining, 
opposition  to  obtaining  it  by  compulsory  legis- 
lation. Unconditional  compulsion,  indeed,  is 
not  contemplated  by  any  one,  except  in  the 
case  of  certain  special  trades,  such  as  mining  and 
baking,  which  are  alleged,  rightly  or  wrongly, 
to  be  more  dangerous  or  unhealthy  than  the 
rest ;  what  is  commonly  demanded  by  the  advo- 
cates of  legislation  is  an  eight  hours  law  con- 
ditioned by  trade  option  in  some  form  :  either 
(1)  in  the  form  of  making  the  law  enforceable 
only  on  such  trades  as  petition  for  it  by  a  clear 
majority  of  their  members  (or  of  their  organised 
members)  in  the  whole  country  ;  or  (2)  in  the 
form,  carried  by  decisive  votes  in  the  trade- 
union  congresses  of  1891  and  1892,  and  known 
as  the  trade  exemption  principle,  of  making 
the  law  enforceable  on  all  trades  which  do  not 
petition  by  a  majority  of  their  members  (or  of 
their  organised  members)  to  be  exempted  from 
its  operation  ;  or  (3)  in  the  form — commended 
by  Mr.  Gladstone  in  1892,  and  known  as  the 
local  trade  option  principle — of  giving  the  right 
of  option  or  exemption  to  the  majority  of  each 
trade  in  each  district.  These  limitations  proceed 
from  a  general  recognition  that  an  eight  hours 
day  cannot  be  equally  practicable  or  suitable  for 
all  the  twelve  thousand  different  occupations  of 
England,  and  that  any  law  fixing  the  hours  of 
ordinary  adult  labour  must  be  applied  with 
considerable  elasticity  in  accordance  with  the 
desires  and  circumstances  of  diverse  trades. 
But  legislative  interference  is  alleged  to  be 
necessary  in  order  to  enable  trades  to  get  what 
they  desire,  inasmuch  as  under  present  con- 
ditions, though  a  majority  of  adult  labourers  in 
a  trade  might  want  an  eight  hours  day,  they 
could  always  be  prevented  from  obtaining  it 
as  long  as  a  minority  were  willing  to  work 
longer,  and  the  interference  is  accordingly  repre- 
sented as  really  promoting  instead  of  infringing 
the  freedom  of  adult  labour. 

On  the  other  hand,  the  opponents  of  eight 
hours  legislation  contend  that  it  makes  a  pre- 
judicial inroad  on  the  freedom  and  independence 
of  the  labourer,  that  it  will  prove  disastrous  to 
production  and  trade,  and  that  in  any  case  it 
is  unnecessary  since  trade -union  agency  will 
answer  the  purpose  more  safely  and  more 
effectually.  Trade-union  agency  has  certainly 
proved'  sufficient  in  Victoria.  Of  the  fifty-two 
eight  hours  trades  of  Melbourne,  not  one  got 
the  eight  hours  by  law,  and  though  the  miners 
in  other  districts  have  had  an  eight  hours  act 
since  1883,  many  of  them  had  the  eight  hours 
day  long  before.  A  factory  act,  restricting 
women's  hours  to  eight,  has  existed  in  that 
colony  since  1874  ;  but  in  accordance  with  one 
of  its  clauses,  its  operation  has  been  very  gener- 
ally suspended  by  the  minister  at  the  request 
of  the  workers  ;  and  though  the  number  of  sus- 
pensions is  now  diminishing,  the  enforcement  of 

2t 


690 


EINERT-EJECT,  EJECTMENT,  EJECTION 


the  eight  hours  day  in  the  factories  depends 
more  really  on  opinion  than  on  the  law.  On 
the  other  hand,  many  eight  liours  laws  were 
passed  in  the  United  States  in  the  first  heat  of 
thTmovement,  forty  years  ago,  but  they  have 
long  been  inoperative,  and  all  recent  gams  frave 
been  won  by  trade-union  agency.  Long  labour 
conflicts  are,  however,  costly  and  hurtful  to 
trade,  while  their  results  are  short-lived,  and 
English  trade-unionists  incline  to  legislation 
tliimu'h  a  desire  to  avoid  the  expense  and  misery 
of  a  strike,  and  their  belief  that  law  will  better 
secure  permanence  in  the  arrangements. 

In  1909,  the  coal  mines  (eight  hours)  Act  was 
passed,  and  came  into  operation  in  Durham  and 
Northumberland,  January  1910. 

[Hadfield  and  Gibbins,  A  Shorter  Working  Bay, 
1892.— Webb  and  Cox,  Eight  Hours  Day,  1891-— 
John  Rae,  "The  Balance-Sheet  of  Short  Hours," 
in  Contemp.  Rev.,  Oct.  1891,  and  Eight  Mows 
for  Work,  1894.-- J.  M.  Robertson,  The  Eight 
Hours  Question,  1893.— W.  J.  Shaxby,  An  Eight 
Hours  Day,  1898.]  J.  »• 

EINERT,  Carl  (1777-1855),  a  German 
jurisconsult,  known  for  his  theory  of  foreign 
exchanges.  Alluding  to  the  influence  of  politi- 
cal economy  on  the  development  of  jurisprudence 
and  commercial  legislation,  Cossa  remarks  that 
"Einert's  book  {Das  WechselrecU),  propounding 
a  legal  theory  of  the  bill  of  exchange  founded 
on  its  modem  economic  functions,  contributed 
largely  to  prepare  the  way  for  the  German  law  of 
1848,  which  marked  a  new  epoch  in  the  history 
of  the  legislation  of  Mils  of  exchange  "  {Guide  to 
Study  of  Political  Economy,  ed.  1880,  pp.  30, 31). 
Das  Wechselrecht,  nach  dem  Bediirfniss  des 
Wechselgesch&fts  im  neunzehnten  Jahrhunderte, 
Leipzig,  1839,  8vo, — Ueber  das  Wesen  und  die 
Form  des  Literal- Contracts  wie  dieser  zur  Zeit  der 
Justinianeischen  Gesetzgebung  au^gebildert  gewesen 
und  Vergleichung  desselben  mit  dem  Wechsdf 
Leipzig,  1852,  8vo. 

[Dr.  C.  Einert  namentlich  in  seinen  Beziehungen 
zu  der  jungsten  Entwickdung  des  deutschen  Wech- 
selrechts  dargestelU,  Leipzig,  1855,  8vo. — All- 
gemeine  Deutsche  Biographie,  v.  759.]    H.  B.  T. 

EISDELL,  Joseph  Sal  way  (fl.  19th  cent.), 
author  of:  A  Treatise  on  the  Industry  of  Nations, 
or  the  Principles  of  National  Economy  and  Taxa- 
tion, London,  1839,  2  vols.  8vo  (vol.  i.  deals  with 
production,  and  vol,  ii,  with  distribution,  consump- 
tion, and  taxation  ;  translated,  with  introduction, 
by  Prof.  F.  Ferrara,  in  Biblioteca  ddV Economista, 
Serie  I. ,  vol.  viii.  Ferrara  calls  it  a  mere  compila- 
tion without  special  character,  but  interesting,  as 
showing  the  views  of  the  English  school  of  econo- 
mists, "  se  una  scuola  inglese  vi  ha  "). — An  Essay 
on  the  Causes  and  Remedies  of  Poverty,  London 
1852,  sm.  8vo  ("poverty  and  crime,  therefore,  among 
a  great  mass  of  the  population,  are  the  sign  and 
evidence  of  industrial  improvement,  not,  however, 
yet  universally  adopted,"  p.  58).  h.  r.  t.. 

EISELEN,  JoHANN  Friedrich  Gottfried 
(1785-1865),  bom  at  Rothenburg,  died  at 
Halle,  where  he  gave  much  attention  to  the 


conduct  of  the  aff'airs  of  the  city.  He  edited 
a  second  edition  of  L.  H.  von  Jakob's  Die 
Staats-Finanzwissenschaft,  1837,  and  wrote  : 

Grundzuge  der  Staatswirthschaft  oder  der  freien 
Volksudrthschaft  und  der  sich  darauf  beziehenden 
Regierungskunst,  Berlin,  1818,  8vo. — Handbuch 
des  Systems  der  Staatsurissenschaft,  Breslau,  1828, 
8vo. — Die  Lehre  von  der  Volksurirthschaft  in 
ihren  allgemeinen  Bedingungen  und  in  ihrer 
hesonderen  Entudckelung,  oder  wissenschaftliche 
Darstdlung,  der  burgerlichen  Gesellschaft  als 
Wirthschaftssystem,  Halle,  1843,  8vo. 

[Allgemeine  Deutsche  Biographie,  v.  764.] 

H.R.T. 

EJECT,  EJECTMENT,  EJECTION.  The 
object  of  proceedings  in  ejectment  is  to  recover 
possession  of  land.  The  action  of  ejectment, 
properly  so-called,  was  abolished  by  the  Com- 
mon Law  Procedure  Act  of  1852.  It  was  used 
as  a  means  of  ascertaining  the  title  to  land.  It 
involved  a  remarkable  series  of  fictions  designed 
to  escape  from  the  inconveniences  attaching  to 
what  were  known  as  real  actions  {i.e.  actions 
for  the  recovery  of  real  estate).  The  party 
claiming  delivered  to  the  party  in  possession  a 
declaration  containing  the  names  of  imaginary 
parties,  John  Doe  and  Richard  Roe.  The 
declaration  set  out  that  John  Doe  was  lessee 
of  the  land  in  question,  holding  of  the  real 
plaintiff,  and  had  been  ousted  by  Richard  Roe. 
A  notice  signed  by  Richard  Roe  was  served 
upon  the  real  defendant,  to  inform  him  that 
Richard  Roe  had  no  real  title  to  the  land,  and 
that  judgment  would  go  against  him  by  default, 
so  that  the  real  defendant  would  be  turned  out, 
unless  he  appeared  to  defend  his  title.  The 
action  was  then  tried  as  between  John  Doe  and 
the  real  defendant.  If  John  Doe  obtained 
judgment,  this  was  tantamount  to  a  judgment 
in  favour  of  the  real  plaintifi',  under  whom 
John  Doe  claimed.  The  place  of  the  old  action 
of  ejectment  is  now  taken  by  an  action  for  the 
recovery  of  land,  which  differs  little  from  other 
actions  in  the  High  Court.  Proceedings  brought 
by  an  undisputed  proprietor  wishing  to  get  rid 
of  a  tenant  whose  term  has  expired,  or  who  has 
made  default  in  payment  of  his  rent,  are  com- 
monly described  as  proceedings  in  ejectment. 
Such  proceedings  may  be  taken  either  at  com- 
mon law  or  under  the  Common  Law  Procedure 
Act  of  1852.  The  action  at  common  law 
cannot  be  brought  unless  the  landlord,  or  his 
agent  authorised  for  that  purpose,  has  made 
a  demand  of  the  precise  amount  of  rent  then 
due,  and  on  the  precise  day  on  which  the  rent 
becomes  due  under  the  terms  of  the  agreement. 
The  demand  must  be  made  before  sunset  of  that 
day,  and  the  tenant  may  pay  at  any  time  up 
to  midnight.  It  must  be  made  either  at  the 
place  where  the  rent  is  payable  or  on  the  land 
itself.  The  necessity  for  the  demand  is  the 
same,  even  though  there  be  no  person  on  the 
land  to  pay.     But  any  or  all  of  these  require- 


ELASTICITY— ELECTION 


691 


ments  may  be  dispensed  with  by  the  express 
terms  of  the  lease.  The  Common  Law  Pro- 
cedure Act,  1852,  dispenses  with  the  formal 
demand  if  half-a-year's  rent  be  owing,  and  no 
sufficient  property  to  meet  the  claim  can  be 
found  on  the  premises.  But  this  enactment 
applies  only  when  the  agreement  of  tenancy 
gives  the  landlord  a  right  of  re-entry  for  non- 
payment of  rent.  When  half-a-year's  rent  is 
in  arrear,  and  neither  the  value  of  the  premises 
nor  the  annual  rent  amounts  to  £50  a  year, 
the  county  court  can  order  that  the  landlord 
shall  be  put  in  possession  of  the  premises. 
By  whatever  procedure  effected,  ejectment  is 
the  ultimate  remedy  of  a  landlord  against  a 
defaulting  tenant.  By  means  of  ejectment  he 
recovers  possession  of  the  land  for  which  he  no 
longer  receives  rent.  Unless  he  could  in  the 
last  resort  employ  this  remedy,  the  premises 
which  he  has  let  would  often  be  practically 
valueless  to  him.  For  there  may  be  no  suffi- 
cient goods  on  the  premises  to  distrain  upon, 
and  the  defaulting  tenant  may  not  be  sub- 
stantial enough  to  make  it  worth  while  to  bring 
an  action  against  him  personally.  Besides 
default  might  be  made  again  and  again  by  a 
tenant  remaining  in  possession.  The  circum- 
stances which    make    ejectment  of  defaulting 

.  tenants  peculiarly  unpopular  seem  to  be  these  : 
— sympathy  with  the  instinctive  attachment 
which  almost  all  persons  feel  for  a  place  which 
they  have  long  inhabited  ;  a  vague  notion  of 
proprietary  right  in  a  tenant  who  has  occupied 
the  land  a  long  time,  and  a  more  definite 
feeling  of  injustice  when  the  tenant,  although 
a  defaulter,  has  in  years  past  executed  improve- 
ments which  have  added  to  the  permanent 
value  of  the  land.  In  this  last  case,  adequate 
compensation  should  be  made,  but  the  power 
of  vindicating  proprietary  right  is  essential  to 
the  well-being  of  society.  Ejectment  and 
eviction  are,  legally  speaking,  the  same  process, 
but  eviction  is  perhaps  the  term  oftenest  used 
in  common  parlance  (see  Eviction). 

[Wharton,  Law  Lexicon,  Art.  Ejectment. — 
Woodfall,  Landlord  and  Tenant  (14th  ed.),  ch. 
22. — Copinger  and  Munro,  The  Law  of  Rents, 
chs.  xxiv.  and  xxv.  ]  F.  c.  M. 

ELASTICITY  is  a  technical  term  employed 
by  Prof.  Marshall,  to  denote  the  sensitive- 
ness of  the  response  which  a  certain  thing 
returns    to    changes    in    another    thing    that 

-  stands  in  a  causal  relation  to  the  former ; 
i.e.  the  ratio  between  the  percentage  increase 
(or,  it  may  be,  diminution)  of  one  thing, 
say  X,  and  the  percentage  increase  (or  dimi- 
nution) of  another,  say  y.     (1)  in  symbols :  , 

•- — -,  or  —  •  -  (cp.  Marshall,  Frinciples  of 

X-        y         Ay   x^ 

Economies,  2nd  edition,  bk.  iii.  ch.  iv.  p.  160, 

et   seq.,    Journal    of    the    Statistical    Society, 

Jubilee  Vol.  1885,  p.  256). 

An   important   case    is   the    "elasticity   of 


demand."  "The  elasticity  of  demand  in  a 
market  is  gieat  or  small  according  as  the 
amount  demanded  increases  much  or  little  for 
a  given  fall  in  price,  and  diminishes  much  or 
little  for  a  given  rise  in  price "  (Marshall, 
Principles  of  Political  Economy,  bk.  iii.  ch. 
iii.  1st  ed.).  The  difference  in  this  respect 
between  different  commodities  has  been  felt, 
though  not  so  accurately  conceived  and  ex- 
pressed, by  some  other  writers.  Thus  Mill : 
' '  If  the  article  is  a  necessary  of  life,  which, 
rather  than  resign,  people  are  willing  to  pay 
for  at  any  price,  a  deficiency  of  one -third 
may  raise  the  price  to  double,  triple,  or  quad- 
ruple "  {Political  Economy,  bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.  §  4). 
And  again,  "  Some  things  are  usually  alfected 
in  a  greater  ratio  than  that  of  the  excess  or 
deficiency,  others  usually  in  a  less.  .  .  .  The 
amount  of  what  people  are  willing  to  expend 
on  it  .  .  .  may  be  aftected  in  very  unequal 
degrees  by  difficulty  or  facility  of  attainment " 
{ibid.  bk.  iii.  ch.  viii.  §  2).  [Compare  Auspitz 
and  Lieben,  Theorie  des  Preises,  p.  41,  et  seq. — 
Seligman,  Shifting  and  Incidence  of  Taxation, 
p.  148,  et  seq. —  Irving  Fisher,  Mathematical 
Investigations  in  the  Theory  of  Value  and  Prices, 
p.  46,  et  seq."]  Prof.  Marshall  holds  that  in 
general  the  elasticity  of  demand  "is  small, 
when  the  price  of  a  thing  is  very  high  rela- 
tively "  to  the  means  of  a  class  of  purchasers, 
"and  again  when  it  is  very  low;  while  the 
elasticity  is  much  greater  for  prices  intermediate 
between  what  we  may  call  the  high  level  and 
the  low  level "  (Marshall,  Principles  of  Econo- 
mies, bk.  iii.  ch.  iv.  §  2).  The  elasticity  of 
demand  is  a  prime  factor  in  determining  the 
interest  whicli  the  consumer  has  in  a  fall  of 
price  (see  Coxsumer's  Rent),  and  the  effects 
of  bounties  and  of  monopolies  {op.  cit.  bk.  v.). 

ELASTICITY  OF  DEMAND.  See  previous 
article  and  Demand. 

ELDER,  William  (1806-1885),  was  born  in 
Pennsylvania,  and  died  in  Washington.  He  prac- 
tised medicine  and  wrote  frequently  for  the  press. 
Besides  several  volumes  in  general  literature, 
he  published  The  Debt  and  Resources  of  the 
United  States,  Philadelphia,  1863,  pp.  32  ; 
Questions  of  the  Day,  Philadelphia,  1871,  pp. 
367 ;  and  Conversations  on  Political  Economy, 
Philadelphia,  1882,  pp.  316.  Elder  belonged  to 
the  Carey  School,  and  advocated  a  political 
economy  which  was  national  as  opposed  to 
cosmopolitan.  He  introduced  the  term  "  guar- 
antyism "  to  denote  the  various  charitable, 
savings,  and  philanthropic  agencies  to  promote 
thrift.  D.  R.  D. 

ELECTION.  The  doctrine  of  election  was 
introduced  by  the  courts  of  equity  (see  Equity), 
and  may  be  shortly  stated  as  follows  :  if  by  a 
will  or  deed  a  testator  or  donor  disposes  of 
property  belonging  to  another  person,  and  by 
the  same  instrument  confers  a  benefit  on  that 


692 


ELEGIT— ELIOT 


person,  sucl).  person  cannot  at  the  same  time 
accept  the  benefit  conferred  upon  him  and 
refuse  to  surrender  his  property  in  accordance 
with  the  disposition  of  the  testator  or  donor. 
He  must  choose  ("  is  put  to  his  election  ")  as  to 
whether  he  wiU  accept  the  benefit  and  surremder 
the  property  in  question,  or  whether  he  will 
keep  his  property  and  forego  the  benefit,  or  at 
least  part  of  it,  the  principle  being  that  where 
the  value  of  the  benefit  under  the  will  or  deed 
exceeds  the  value  of  the  property  with  respect 
to  which  the  election  arises,  the  party  dis- 
appointed by  the  election  is  not  entitled  to 
compensation  beyond  the  value  of  that  property. 
Thus  if  a  testator  by  his  will  gives  A  an  estate 
belonging  to  B,  of  the  value  of  £10,000,  and 
by  the  same  instrument  gives  B  a  legacy  of 
£20,000,  B  may  elect  to  conform  to  the  will 
by  conveying  the  estate  in  question  to  A  and 
receiving  the  legacy  of  £20,000  ;  but  if  he 
elects  against  the  will,  he  must  pay  £10,000  to 
A  by  way  of  compensation  and  may  retain  the 
remaining  £10,000.  In  many  cases  the  facts 
are  not  so  simple  and  the  doctrine  frequently 
gives  rise  to  considerable  difficulty.         E.  s. 

ELEGIT  (Writ  of).  A  writ  of  execution 
(see  Execution),  by  virtue  of  which  a  judg- 
ment creditor  is  enabled  to  take  possession  of 
the  debtor's  land.  The  writ  does  not  in  itself 
authorise  the  creditor  to  sell  the  land,  but  an 
order  for  that  purpose  may  be  obtained  by 
application  to  the  chancery  division  of  the 
high  court  (27  &  28  Vict.  c.  112,  §§  4-6). 
Execution  by  "writ  of  elegit"  was  introduced 
by  the  Statute  of  Westminster  (13  Ed.  I.  c.  18), 
and  originally  extended  to  the  debtor's  chattels 
(excluding  beasts  of  the  plough),  but  was 
restricted  to  one-half  only  of  the  land.  The 
last-named  restriction  was  removed  by  1  &  2 
Vict.  c.  108,  whilst  on  the  other  hand  the 
Bankruptcy  Act  1883,  §  146,  enacts  that  writs 
of  elegit  are  no  longer  to  extend  to  chattels. 
A  recital  is  contained  in  the  writ,  showing  that 
the  creditor  has  chosen  this  means  of  execution 
in  preference  to  others,  which  in  the  original 
Latin  form  (quod  "elegit")  included  the  word 
from  which  the  name  is  derived.  E.  s. 

ELEVATOR.  Part  of  the  machinery  in 
unloading  vessels  (see  Docks,  Mechanical  Appli- 
ances at  Docks).  In  America  a  public  ware- 
house for  produce  (see  Warehouses). 

ELIBANK,  Patrick  Murray,  fifth  lord 
(1703-1778),  lawyer,  soldier,  and  pamphleteer, 
was  admitted  a  member  of  the  Faculty  of 
Advocates  at  Edinburgh  in  1728,  and  served 
in  the  Carthagena  expedition  under  Lord  Oath- 
cart  in  1740.  He  thought  the  existence  of  the 
national  debt  a  very  great  calamity,  and  stock- 
holders and  stock-jobbers  a  most  pernicious 
class  of  men,  whose  ill-gotten  wealth  gave 
them  the  power  to  further  their  speculations  by 
embarking  the  nation  on  harmful  lines  of 
policy.     He  accuses  them  of  having  caused  the 


war  of  1739  ;  and  suggests  that  their  property 
might  with  advantage  be  confiscated,  like  the 
property  of  the  monasteries  in  1537,  and  the 
proceeds  devoted  to  encouraging  our  manufac- 
tures by  bounties. 

On  economic  subjects  Lord  Elibank  wrote  An 
Inquiry  into  the  Origin  and  Consequences  of  the 
Public  Debt,  Edinburgh,  1753-1754.— ^ssay  on 
Paper  Money  and  Banking  from  Essays  on  the 
Public  Debt,  Frugality,  etc.,  1755.  This  essay  is 
reprinted  in  M'Culloch's  Seled  Tracts  on  Paper 
Currency,  etc.,  London,  1857.  M'Culloch  says 
of  this,  "It  is  a  poor  performance." — Letters  on 
the  proposed  Plan  for  altering  Entails  in  Scotland, 
Edinburgh,  1765.— See  also  Douglas's  Peerage  of 
Scotland.  ^-  H. 

ELIOT,  Francis  Perceval  (c.  1756-1818), 
entered  the  civil  service,  and  for  some  years 
before  his  death  was  a  commissioner  of  audit 
at  Somerset  House.     His  economic  writings  are 
chiefly  on  subjects  connected  with  currency  and 
banking.       He   considered    that   notes   might 
safely  be  issued  on  good  securities,  and  need 
not  be  restricted  to  representing  actual  deposits  . 
of  bullion.     He  belongs  to  a  class  of  writers 
fostered  by  the  Bank  Restriction,  who,  in  Sir] 
Robert  Peel's  words,    "would  not  admit  the] 
doctrine  of  a  metallic  standard."     Eliot  advo-] 
cated  an    "ideal  money"  which   "admits  ol 
invariable  value,  because  it  is  not  formed  of 
substantial  and  therefore  variable  materials.* 
.  .  .  "The  money  of  account  remains  in  itself 
fixed   and   undepreciated,   while   the   precious 
metals  may  either  be  suffering  an  intrinsic  de- 
preciation," or  the  converse  (Observations,  p.  i 
33).     As  General  Walker  remarks,  it  is  scarcely] 
Avorth  while  to  separate  the  parts  of  truth  and] 
error  here.     Otherwise  a  rudimentary  concep-| 
tion  of  the  standard  which  is  formed  by  an| 
Index  Number  might  be  ascribed  to  Eliot.' 
Compare  the  context  of  the  passages  above  cited  j 
(and   OhservatioTis,  p.   41),   where  reference  isj 
made  to  Sir  George  Shuckburgh.     Consistently! 
with  this  view,  Eliot  maintains  that  during  thej 
war  it  was  the  gold  which  was  appreciated  notj 
the  paper  depreciated.     He  wrote  : 

Demonstration  or  Financial  Remarks  with  occa* 
sionaZ  observations  on  Political  Occurrences,  18071 
(the  first  part  discussing  sinking  funds,  the  latterl 
part  "noticing  in  a  summary  way  some  of  thej 
principal  events  since  the  decease  of  that  ever  toj 
be  regretted  statesman,"  Pitt.) — Observations  <m\ 
the  Fallacy  of  the  supposed  depreciation  of  the  Paper  j 
Currency  of  the  Kingdomunthreasons  for  dissenting^ 
from  the  Report  of  tJie  Bullion  Committee,  1811  ;j 
Second  edition,  with  a  supplement  replying  to  2 
criticisms,  1811. — Letters  on  the  Political  Situation  ] 
of  this  Country,  addressed  to  the  Earl  of  Liverpool 
by  Eliot  under  the  signature  of  Falkland. — Pam- 
phleteer, Nos.  vi.  and  vii.  (1814),  No.  x.  (1815), 
No.  xiii.  (1816). 

[Quarterly  Review,  February  1811 — "Tracts  on] 
the   Report  of  the   Bullion   Committee." — Peel,j 
speech  on  the  Bank  Charter  A.ct,   May  1844.-— j 
I  Walker,  Money,  p.  277.  j  f.  y.  e. 


ELIZABETHAN  LEGISLATION— ELLIS 


693 


ELIZABETHAN  LEGISLATION.  For 
notice  of  the  legislation  of  the  period  of  Queen 
Elizabeth,  in  its  reference  to  economic  changes, 
see  Legislation. 

ELKING,  Henry  {fl.  1720),  who  was  at  one 
time  extensively  engaged  in  the  Greenland  whale 
fishery,  published  (1)  The  Interest  of  England 
considered  with  respect  to  its  Manufactures,  etc., 
London,  1720,  8vo.  This  pamphlet  was  directed 
against  the  importation  of  calicoes  by  the 
East  India  Company,  to  which  Elking  attri- 
butes "the  decay  of  trade,  the  melting  of  coin, 
the  scarcity  of  silver,  and  the  increase  of  poor." 
The  importation  of  East  India  calicoes  was,  in 
accordance  with  these  principles,  prohibited  in 
the  following  year  (1721).  (2)  A  View  of  the 
Crreenland  Trade  and  Whale  Fishery,  with  the 
National  and  Private  Advantagesthereof,  London, 
1722,  8vo,  2nd  ed.  1825.  Reprinted  in  vol.  iv. 
of  the  Oversione  Collection  of  Select  Economical 
Tracts,  1859.  This  is  one  of  the  most  valuable 
of  the  early  pamphlets  on  the  whale  fishery. 
Elking  gives  an  account  of  its  origin,  and  pro- 
gress of  the  fishery  and  its  condition  at  the  time 
he  wrote,  and  suggests  means  for  getting  it  once 
more  into  English  hands.  (3)  The  Interest  of 
Great  Britain  considered,  etc.,  London,  1723. 

[M'Culloch'a  Literature  of  Pol.  Econ.,  p.  233. — 
Halkett  and  Laing's  Dictionary  of  Anonymous 
Literature,  1240. — Brit.  Mus.  Cat.]    w.  a.  s.  H. 

ELLIOTT,  Ebenezer(1781-1849).  Ebenezer 
Elliott,  the  "  corn-law  rhymer, "  was  born  at 
Masborough  near  Sheffield,  and  was  the  son  of 
a  manufacturer  who  had  obtained  a  share  in  a 
small  iron-work  in  that  place.  He  received 
very  little  education,  but  at  an  early  age  he 
began  both  to  read  largely  and  to  write  verses. 
His  early  attempts  in  verse  writing  are  not  of 
much  value.  On  his  marriage  he  invested  the 
money  his  wife  brought  him  in  his  father's 
business.  But  the  trade  was  declining  at  the 
time  ;  his  father  died  worn  out  by  business 
anxieties ;  and  after  a  few  years  spent  in  a  hope- 
less struggle,  Elliott  found  that  he  was  a  ruined 
man,  ruined,  he  always  maintained,  by  the 
corn  laws.  In  the  year  1821,  however,  he 
made  a  fresh  attempt,  and  for  some  years  he 
prospered.  But  after  the  year  1837  trade  again 
began  to  fall  off,  and  when  in  1842  he  gave  up 
business,  he  was  only  able  to  take  with  him 
the  sum  of  £6000.  The  losses  of  these  five 
years  were  another  result  of  the  bread-tax  he 
so  hated.  This  hatred  was  the  passion  that 
inspired  all  his  best  poems.  He  was  filled  with 
fierce  indignation  against  the  law  that  had  kept 
him  poor,  as  an  employer,  and  that  pressed 
so  hardly  on  the  workers  whom  he  wished  to 
benefit.  In  The  Splendid  Village,  The  Village 
Patriarch,  and  above  all,  in  The  Banter,  the 
reader  feels  the  depth  of  his  feeling  for  the  poor 
and  his  hatred  of  the  landlord  class.  In  the 
Corn-law  Ehynus  (1831)  the  whole  of  his  bitter 
anger  breaks  out.     No  one  can  read  them  with- 


out feeling  some  share  of  the  indignation  that 
inspired  them,  and  as  a  picture  of  the  state  of 
men's  minds  at  the  time  their  force  and  brevity 
make  them  invaluable.  c.  G.  C. 

[Watkin's  Life,  Poetry,  and  Letters  of  Ebenezer 
Elliott,  1850. — Athenceum,  12th  January  1850. — 
Poetical  Works,  1876.] 

ELLIS,  William  (died  1758),  a  self-taught 
farmer  of  unusually  wide  agiicultural  knowledge. 
His  early  writings  made  his  name.  He  was 
afterwards  employed  by  a  bookseller  to  write 
in  monthly  instalments,  but  made  tlie  mistake 
of  producing  the  required  quantity  by  padding 
with  quack  receipts,  old  wives'  tales,  etc.,  and 
thereby  injured  his  reimtation.  He  was  too 
much  occupied  in  travelling  about  the  country, 
acting  as  a  consulting  farmer  and  selling  seeds 
and  agricultural  implements,  to  work  his  own 
farm  at  Little  Gaddesden,  Herts,  according 
to  his  own  teaching  ;  on  his  journeys,  however, 
he  learned  the  methods  of  farming  prevalent  in 
diflerent  counties,  and  his  habits  of  observation 
enabled  him  to  enrich  his  writings  with  shrewd 
criticism  and  comparisons.  He  treats  most 
fully  of  the  management  and  breeds  of  sheep, 
the  use  of  manures,  the  growing  of  timber, 
especially  of  oaks,  the  need  of  different  soils, 
and  the  latest  improvements  in  ploughs.  His 
style  is  homely,  often  rough,  and  sometimes 
ungrammaticah 

The  following  is  a  list  of  bis  works  : — 

The  Practical  Farmer ;  or.  The  Hertfordshire 
Husbandman,  1732. — Chilternarvd  Vale  Farming 
explained,  1733.: — The  London  and  Country 
Brewer  (see  Country  Housetvife,  p.  12). — New 
Experiments  in  Husbandry  for  the  Month  of 
April,  17S6.—The  Timber  Tree  improved,  1738. — 
Tlie  Shepherd's  Sure  Guide,  1749. — A  Compleat 
System  of  expierienced  imjjinrements,  made  on 
Sheep,  grass  lamhs,  and  hi >  use  lambs,  1749. — 
The  Modern  Husbandman,  1750. — The  Country 
Housewife  s  Family  Companion,  1750.  —  Every 
Farmer  his  own  Farrier,  1759. — In  1772  was 
published  Ellis's  Husbandry  abridged  and  method- 
ized, the  original  padding  and  some  of  the  less 
intelligible  and  interesting  matter  being  omitted. 

[Biographical  notice  in  preface  to  last  named 
work.]  E.G.  p. 

ELLIS,  William  (1800-1881),  ably  dis- 
charged for  fifty  years  the  duties  of  chief  under- 
writer to  the  Indemnity  Insurance  Office.  Ellis 
is  mentioned  by  Mill  in  his  Autobiography  {a.-mong 
the  disciples  of  Bentham)  as  "an  original 
thinker  in  the  field  of  political  economy,  now 
honourably  known  by  his  apostolic  exertions 
for  the  improvement  of  education."  Of  these 
distinctions  the  latter  appears  the  more  perma- 
nent. Ellis  used  to  convey  to  the  young  a 
knowledge  of  political,  or  as  he  preferred  to  say 
"social,"  economy  and  of  "right  conduct,"  by 
the  method  of  "Socratic"  dialogue.  His 
method  deserves  this  epithet,  so  far  as  it  incul- 
cated the  homely  virtues  with  the  zeal  of  the 
Socrates   of  Xenophon.     A    Platonic    vein   of 


894 


ELLMAN— EMANCIPATION 


speculation  is  not  to  be  looked  for  in  Ellis's 
dialogues. 

A  good  account  of  Ellis's  "  conduct  teaching  is 
riven  in  the  Memmrs  written  by  his  granddaughter, 
Ethel  Ellis,  1888.  The  Life,  by  E.  K.  Blyth, 
1889,  describes  his  economical,  as  well  a*  his 
educational,  work  ;  and  contains  a  complete  list  of 
his  writings.  Of  these  may  be  mentioned :  various 
articles  in  the  Westminster  Review;  including  one 
on  M'Culloch's  Political  Economy/  by  Ellis  and 
J  S.  MiU  jointly  (July  1825) ;  Outlines  of  Social 
Economy,  1846  ;  Progressive  Lessons  xn  Social 
Science;  Philosocrates,  1861-64. 

J.  S.  Mill  refers  to  an  essay  by  Ellis,  published 
in  the  Westminster  Review  for  January  1826,  as 
"  the  most  scientific  treatment  of  the  subject  which 
I  have  met  with  "  (Pol.  Econ.,  ch.  iv.  §  2).  The 
subject  is  "the  effect  of  the  employment  of 
machinery  on  the  happiness  of  the  working  classes, 
an  effect  which  the  writer  pronounces  to  be  bene- 
ficial with  less  qualification  than  economists  would 
now  generally  employ.  f.  y.  e. 

ELLMAN,  John  (1753-1832).  A  success- 
ful farmer  of  Glynde  in  Sussex,  best  known  for 
his  improvements  in  the  breed  of  Southdown 
sheep,  for  the  origination  of  the  Sussex  Agri- 
cultural Association,  and  as  one  of  the  founders 
of  the  Smithfield  Cattle  Show.  As  an  agricul- 
turist he  was  so  much  esteemed  by  his  contem- 
poraries that  his  biographer,  Walesby,  writing 
shortly  after  his  death,  claims  that  EUman  had 
by  his  discoveries  so  increased  the  productive- 
ness of  agi-iculture  as  to  effectually  disprove  the 
doctrines  of  Malthus.  EUman  himself  abstained 
from  abstract  economics,  and  is  chiefly  inter- 
esting to  students  of  the  science  for  his  helping 
Arthur  Young  {q.v.)  with  materials  for  the 
latter's  Annals  of  Agriculture.  Ellman  ap- 
pears, from  his  correspondence  with  Young  in 
this  connection,  to  have  supposed  that  the  Poor 
Rate  {q.v.)  and  similar  imposts  fell  almost  ex- 
clusively on  the  farmers,  who  had  to  support  the 
used-up  labourers  when  past  work  in  factories. 
He  also  urged  very  strongly  that  the  wages  of 
labour  should  be  proportional  to  the  labourer's 
skill. 

[See  life  of  Ellman  in  preface  to  Baxter's  Library 
of  Agricvltwre,  4th  ed.,  1851. — Yaxm^s  Annals  of 
Agriculture,  London,  1784,  etc.;  and  Dictionary 
of  National  Biography,  London,  1888.]     a.  h. 

ELUS  were  financial  oflBcers  in  France  who 
superintended  the  collection  of  taxes  in  those  pro- 
vinces which  had  not  estates,  or  assemblies,  of 
their  own.  They  are  to  be  distinguished  from 
the  tresoriers,  who  collected  the  domain  revenue. 
The  dlus  originated  in  1356,  when  the  states- 
general  made  the  most  notable  attempt  to  impose 
constitutional  checks  upon  the  crown.  Not 
content  with  claiming  the  sole  right  of  imposing 
taxes,  they  insisted  upon  entrusting  their  collec- 
tion to  their  own  elected  officials  (Mm).  Charles 
V.  subsequently  maintained  both  the  taxes  and 
the  collectors  of  1356,  though  he  turned  the 
latter  into  royal  officials,  and  they  continued 


till  the  revolution.  The  district  of  an  4lu  wa* 
called  an  Section,  and  hence  the  provinces  which 
had  no  estates  come  to  be  called  the  pays 
d'electim,  as  distmgmshed  from  the  pays  d' Stats. 
The  provincial  estates  were  quite  distinct  from 
the  Etats  g^n^raux  (q.v.) 

[De  Tocqueville,  L'Ancien  Eigime.]        R.  L. 

EMANCIPATION.  The  general  subject  ia 
dealt  with  in  connection  with  Serfdom, 
Slavery,  Enfranchisement  of  Land,  and 
ViLLENAGE,  but  the  emancipation  of  the  negro 
slaves  in  America  offers  some  points  of  special 
economic  interest.  The  main  influences  which 
led  to  abolition  were  unquestionably  moral  and 
religious;  but  there  had  been  growing  up  a  strong 
suspicion  that  the  system  was  wasteful,  and  it 
was  too  palpably  an  outrage  upon  the  prevalent 
laissez-faire  principle  to  last  far  into  the  19th 
century,  wherever  English  ideas  were  in  vogue. 
A  close  scrutiny  brought  out  that  the  one  solid 
basis  of  efficiency  was  the  easiness  of  direction 
of  unskilled  labour  in  large  masses,  but  the  fol- 
lowing objections  left  a  large  adverse  balance. 

(1)  Slave  labour  wasted  the  soil  through  its 
lack  of  intelligence  ;  (2)  it  confined  agriculture 
to  certain  products,  especially  sugar,  cotton, 
tobacco  ;  (3)  it  prevented  the  rise  of  manufac- 
tures ;  (4)  it  degraded  labour,  and  thus  arrested' 
immigration  of  fresh  white  people,  and  prevented 
the  formation  of  an  industrious  middle  class ; 
(5)  it  prevented  the  industrial  development  of 
which  the  negro  population  was  capable  ;  (6) 
it  kept  down  the  gross  production  of  a  com- 
munity in  favour  of  net -production  ;  and 
further,  kept  back  net-production  in  general,  in 
favour  of  the  net-production  appropriated  to  a 
small  portion  of  the  community.  AUov/ing  for  , 
the  general  material  progress  of  the  world  as  a 
stimulant,  and  in  the  case  of  the  British  "West 
Indies  for  the  equalisation  of  the  sugar  duties 
in  1846  and  the  rise  of  beet  sugar  sines  1860, 
as  obstructions,  a  comparison  of  the  present 
condition  of  the  countries  affected  with  their 
condition  before  emancipation  substantiates  this 
arraignment  of  the  slave  system  in  every  point. 

(1)  With  greater  intelligence  and  better  J 
appliances  the  soils  are  no  longer  wastefully' 
exhausted.  Mr.  Briggs,  an  intelligent  Barbados  1 
planter,  who  resolutely  improved  his  methods,  i 
made  a  large  fortune  soon  after  emancipation,  I 
and  the  soil  of  that  island  now  appears  likely! 
to  continue  to  yield  its  50,000  tons  of  sugar  a| 
year  indefinitely.  (2)  Agriculture  has  been^j 
extended  and  varied.  In  the  West  Indies  the 
once  despised  "subsidiary"  products  have,  in 
gross,  taken  the  chief  place  from  sugar,  except  r 
in  Barbados  ;  lands  hitherto  thought  useless' 
have  been  brought  into  cultivation — 50,000] 
acres  were  added  to  cultivated  areas  in  Jamaica , 
alone  between  1880  and  1890  ;  in  South  Carolina 
the  forests  are  giving  employment  to  700  timber 
mills ;  in  Brazil  coffee-production  increasesl 
every  decade.     (3)  Manufactures  have  sprung; 


EMANCIPATION— EMBARGO 


695 


into  existence  in  the  Southern  States.  In 
South  Carolina  minerals  are  being  worked, 
notably  the  phosphate  rock  ;  and  manufactures 
have  passed  from  8^  million  dollars  before 
emancipation  to  16f  millions  in  1880  and  32 
millions  in  1884.  In  the  West  Indies  to  turn 
to  manufactures  would  be  pernicious  waste  of 
natural  advantages,  and  no  one  desires  to  see  it 
done..  (4)  The  lower  classes  of  the  white  race 
are  rapidly  improving  their  position.  Professor 
Bryce  says  of  the  South,  "  The  chasm  that  used 
to  divide  the  poor  whites  from  the  planters  has 
been  in  many  places  bridged  over  by  the  growth 
of  a  middle  class  of  small  proprietors  in  the 
country  and  of  manufacturing  industries  in  the 
coal  and  iron  regions  "  (^American  Commonwealth, 
iii.  p.  95).  In  the  West  Indies  there  is  no 
change  in  this  respect ;  the  employing  class  has 
diminished  (Jamaica  from  40,000  to  17,000), 
and  opinion  is,  on  the  whole,  against  the  suit- 
ability of  these  colonies  for  any  other  class  of 
white  people.  (5)  There  has  arisen  in  the 
West  Indies  a  peasant  class  of  negroes  of  whom 
it  is  no  exaggeration  to  say  that  they  have  the 
most  favoured  lot  that  has  ever  fallen  to  any 
considerable  portion  of  their  race.  In  Barbados, 
where  there  was  no  unoccupied  land  available 
for  squatting,  the  emancipated  negroes  at  once 
became  wage-earners,  and  they  so  continue  ; 
in  Jamaica  there  was  abundance  of  land  avail- 
able, and  the  planters  were  so  ill-tempered  in 
their  attitude  to  the  new  status  that  the  negroes 
in  large  numbers  became  independent  peasants, 
and  the  separation  of  labour  from  capital  has 
therefore  been  far  wider  than  it  needed  to  have 
been.  There  are  now  over  90,000  small  holdings 
among  the  100,000  families  in  the  colony.  In 
Trinidad  and  Demerara  also  the  negroes  aban- 
doned plantation  work,  and  resort  was  made  to 
East  Indian  coolies  for  this  purpose  ;  still  the 
negro  population  increases  and  prospers  on  other 
products — cocoa,  for  example,  and  fruits  not 
requiring  much  capital  and  adapted  for  small- 
scale  production.  In  the  Southern  States, 
whatever  is  to  be  allowed  as  to  their  low  politi- 
cal and  social  condition  from  a  European  point 
of  view,  it  cannot  be  gainsaid  that  there  are 
now  millions  of  negroes  industrially  wealthy 
in  comparison  with  the  condition  of  their 
fathers,  whose  labour  had  little  influence  upon 
their  own  material  well-being.  (6)  The  gross 
produce  of  all  the  countries  affected  has  more 
than  kept  pace  with  the  growth  of  population, 
and  the  wealth  is  more  widely  distributed. 
Whereas,  in  former  times  60,000  families 
worked  in  Jamaica  on  slave  rations,  while  some 
8000  received  an  abnormal  return  for  both 
capital  and  superintendence,  an  examination  of 
the  imports  now  shows  that  there  is  a  very 
considerable  net-produce  in  the  hands  of  the 
common  people  of  the  colony.  If  the  summit 
of  luxury  has  fallen,  the  level  of  subsistence 
has  risen   to  a  stage  of  comfort  and  civilised 


life.  The  statistics  of  all  the  countries  in 
question  indicate  a  similar  change.  Even  in 
Cuba,  where  the  emancipation  has  not  led  to 
any  extensive  industrial  change,  the  output  of 
sugar  has  not  been  affected  so  far. 

The  following  remarkable  figures  are  given  for 
Brazil : — Annual  produce  of  coffee,  1835-1840, 
slave-trade  in  existence,  88  million  lbs. ;  1855-1860, 
slave  trade  abolished,  264  millions  ;  1872-1877, 
emancipation  bypurcliase  in  progress,  389  millions  ; 
1890,  emancipation  completed,  880  millious. 

Of  course  fixed  capital  was  lost  during  the 
transition,  but  when  the  old  capitalist  class  still 
represents  Jamaica,  for  example,  as  a  standing 
reproach  to  Great  Britain,  serious  inquirers  will 
find  this  unsupported  by  the  official  statistics  of 
the  colony.  If  a  colony  with  an  increasing 
area  of  cultivation,  an  increasing  public  revenue, 
and  increased  expenditure  on  public  institutions 
of  all  kinds,  increased  support  of  voluntary 
religious  bodies  including  a  now  disestablished 
branch  of  the  Episcopal  church,  and  a  pauperism 
of  less  than  one  per  cent,  is  a  reproach,  where 
are  the  jewels  of  an  imperial  crown  to  be  sought  ? 

[The  economic  chapters  and  appendices  in 
Cairnes's  TheSlave  Power,  2nd  ed.,  1863,  excellently 
introduce  the  subject,  which  can  be  further  studied 
in  the  histories  of  the  various  colonies  (especially 
Gardner's  Jamaica,  1873),  of  the  United  States 
of  America,  of  Cuba,  and  of  Brazil.  For  the 
present  condition  of  the  countries  affected,  the 
many  statistical  works  published  in  America  show 
the  situation  in  the  southern  states  ;  whilst  our 
colonies  can  be  studied  in  the  Reports  in  their 
Blue  Books,  issued  from  time  to  time  by  the 
colonial  office  for  a  few  pence  each.  Amongst 
noteworthy  articles  of  recent  issue  are  N.  Lubbock, 
Our  West  Indian  Colonies  (from  sugar-merchant's 
point  of  view). — Royal  Colonial  Institute  Proceed- 
ings, vol.  xvii. — H.  Fowler,  "Capital  and  Labour  for 
the  West  Indies,"  ibid.,  vol.  xxi. — Lord  Brassey, 
"The  West  Indies  in  1892,"  ibid.,  vol.  xxiii.— D. 
Morris,  "  Fruit  as  a  Factor  in  Colonial  Commerce," 
ibid.,  vol.  xviii. — C.  S.  Salmon,  Capital  and  Labour 
in  West  Indies,  Pamphlet,  1883.]  a.  c. 

EMBARGO.  The  word  "  embargo  "  used  in 
a  general  sense  means  any  prohibition  affecting 
commerce  ;  in  a  more  special  sense,  it  is  a  term 
of  international  law  implying  the  seizure  of 
foreign  ships.  Formerly  ships  belonging  to  a 
foreign  power  were  placed  under  embargo  in 
contemplation  of  war,  but  in  modern  times 
this  practice  has  been  discontinued,  and  the 
only  occasion  on  which  an  embargo  of  ships  is 
now  resorted  to  is  when  it  is  sought  to  use 
reprisals  in  the  case  of  any  specific  wrong  com- 
mitted by  any  foreign  state.  If  in  such  a  case 
the  relations  between  the  two  powers  concerned 
re-assume  their  normal  condition,  the  ships 
which  have  been  placed  under  embargo  are  re- 
leased ;  if  on  the  other  hand  war  is  declared,  the 
ships  are  confiscated  (see  Angarie,  Droit  d'). 

[Hall's  International  Law,  3rded.  1890,  pp.  366 
373.]  E.  s. 


696 


EMBEZZLEMENT— EMIGKATION 


EMBEZZLEMENT.  This  offence  is  defined 
in  Mr.  Justice  Stephen's  Digest  of  the  Grimi'nal 
Law  (Art  309)  as  "the  conversion  by  a  clerk, 
or  servant,  or  person  employed  in  the  capacity 
of  a  clerk  or  servant,  of  any  chattel,  money,  or 
valuable  security  delivered  to  or  received  or 
taken  into  possession  by  him  for  or  in  the 
name  or  on  account  of  his  master  or  employer." 
Embezzlement  differs  from  theft  principally  in 
the  circumsUnce  that  the  thing  embezzled  has 
not  yet  come  into  the  possession  of  the  person 
entitled  to  it,  and  is  not  taken  out  of  his  pos- 
session by  the  offender,  whilst  in  the  case  of 
theft  the  thing  stolen  is  taken  by  the  offender 
out  of  the  possession  of  the  person  entitled  to 
it.  Thus,  if  a  shopman  receives  money  for 
goods  sold  by  him  for  his  employer  and  puts 
this  money  into  the  till  and  then  takes  it  out 
of  the  till  and  appropriates  it,  he  commits  a 
theft  of  the  money.  But  if  the  shopman,  after 
receiving  the  money,  puts  it  into  his  pocket 
and  afterwards  applies  it  to  his  own  purposes, 
this  is  embezzlement.  If  a  clerk  or  servant 
appropriates  a  thing  given  into  his  custody  by 
his  employer,  this  act  is  not  embezzlement  but 
theft.  For  the  thing  so  misappropriated  is 
regarded  by  law  as  still  in  the  possession  of  the 
employer.  A  further  distinction  between  theft 
and  embezzlement  lies  in  the  fact  that  theft 
may  be  committed  by  anybody  upon  anybody, 
but  that  embezzlement  can  be  committed  only 
by  a  clerk  or  servant  or  person  employed  in  the 
capacity  of  a  clerk  or  servant  and  with  refer- 
ence to  property  belonging  to  the  employer. 
Accordingly,  before  an  offence  against  pro- 
perty can  be  described  as  embezzlement,  it 
must  be  shown  that  the  property  was  in  the 
possession  of  the  oflfender,  and  that  he  stood  in 
the  relation  of  a  clerk  or  servant  to  the  injured 
party.  The  ascertainment  of  these  points  is 
often  a  matter  of  great  nicety.  Embezzlement 
is  a  felony,  and  renders  the  criminal  liable  to  a 
maximum  penalty  of  fourteen  years'  penal 
servitude. 

[For  the  present  state  of  the  law  regarding  em- 
bezzlement, consult  Stephen,  Digest  of  the  Grim- 
inal  Law,  Arts.  297,  309-312,  and  325.  For  the 
history  of  the  law  regarding  embezzlement,  see 
Stephen,  History  of  the  Criminal  Law,  vol.  iii. 
pp.  161-156.]  p.  c.  M. 

EMBLEMENTS  (from  the  med.  Latin  word 
enLbladare  =  to  sow  with  com),  technical  name 
for  growing  crops.  Where  the  owner  of  land 
dies  intestate,  the  emblements  do  not  go  with 
the  land,  but  devolve  on  the  personal  repre- 
sentative for  the  benefit  of  the  next  of  kin  {e.g. 
if  a  man  dies  leaving  two  sons  and  one  daughter, 
the  land  goes  to  the  eldest  son,  and  the  emble- 
ments are  divided  between  the  three  children 
in  equal  parts).  A  person  entitled  to  land  for 
his  own  life,  or  during  the  life  of  another 
person,  is  entitled  to  the  crops  sown  during  his 
tenancy  and  reaped  after  its  termination  ;  but 


it  is  now  provided  (by  14  &  15  Vict.  c.  25), 
that  in  the  case  of  land  held  at  rack  rent,  the 
tenant  or  his  representative  may  after  the 
termination  of  the  tenancy  hold  on  the  same 
terms  to  the  end  of  the  current  year  ;  and  the 
rule  as  to  emblements  does  not  therefore  come 
into  operation  in  such  cases.  E.  s. 

EMERSON,  GoTJVEENEUR,  M.D.  (1796- 
1874),  was  born  in  Delaware  and  settled  as  a 
physician  in  Philadelphia.  He  devoted  much 
of  his  time  to  scientific  and  agricultural  in- 
quiries ;  and  gave  special  attention  to  medical 
and  vital  statistics.  In  1872  he  translated  and 
prepared  a  preface  for  The  Organisation  of 
Labor  by  F.  Le  Play,  Philadelphia,  pp.  41 7,.  ( 
preface,  pp.  v.-xiii. 

[Biographical  Encyd.  of  Pennsylvania,  1874,j 
p.  27.]  D.  R.  D. 

EMIGRATION  —  its     Effects    on    ti 
Country  of  Origin.      In  aU  that  has  been 
written  on  the  subject  of  emigration,  a  minor 
place  has  been  assigned  to  the  discussion  of  it 
effects  upon  the  population  of  the  country  whichj 
the  emigrant  leaves.      The  assumption,  how- 
ever, that  these  effects  must  be  in  every  way| 
beneficial  underlies  most  of  the  pamphlet  anc 
other  literature  on  the  subject  of  emigratioi 
and   colonisation   which   exercised   the  public 
mind  in  this  country  during  the  period  from' 
1820  to  1850,  or  thereabout. 

It  would  be  idle  to  dwell  on  the  pre-historio 
migrations  of  the  Indo-European  races,  or  the 
hardly  less  remote  expatriation  of  the  Phoeni- 
cians.    Nor  will  our  knowledge  of  the  economic 
condition  of  the  ancient  Greeks  justify  us 
drawing  too  confident  conclusions  from  the  mosti 
regular  system  of  emigration  which  the  ancient] 
world  exhibited.     The  Romans  were  not  girenj 
to  emigrate  in  the  sense  in  which  we  now 
the  term,  although  they  made  great  political^ 
use  of  their  "colonies."     Nor  can  the  descents 
of  the  barbarous  hordes  of  the  north  on  the] 
declining  Roman  empire  in  the  early  centurie 
of  our  era,  or  the  victorious  career  of  Spa 
conquest  in  the  new  world  in  the  16th  century, 
be  considered  to  famish  any  economic  lesson. 
Such   movements   of   population   as   those   of j 
the    Flemings    and    Huguenots    to    England! 
in   the    14th  and    17th   centuries  were  preg- 
nant with    economic    results,    but   were    tooj 
partial  and  irregular  to  constitute  an  era  of| 
emigration. 

The  beginning  of  emigration,  as  we  have  to 
consider  it,  may  be  placed  in  the  I7th  century  ; 
and  the  nations  which  chiefly  furnish  instances 
of  it  are  the  English,  the  French,  the  Dutch, 
and  Portuguese.  The  motives  which  prompted 
these  earlier  streams  of  emigration  were  usually 
love  of  adventure  or  political  discontent.  The 
feature  which  marked  this  emigration  off  from 
previous  movements  was  its  steady  set  towards 
new  countries  ;  the  freshness  and  emptiness  of 


7 


EMIGRATION 


697 


the  new  lands  swelled  the  volume  of  the  stream 
which  they  attracted.  There  can  be  little 
doubt  that  the  new  impulse  reacted  with  a 
considerable  effect  on  the  conditions  of  life  in 
the  countries  which  the  emigrants  left  behind  ; 
the  Dutch  being  at  that  time  the  first  to  feel 
the  influence. 

With  the  19  th  century  emigration  entered 
on  a  new  phase,  and  then  England  was  in  the 
van.  She  was  suffering  from  acute  commercial 
distress  at  home,  and  anxious  about  her  vast 
possessions  abroad.  It  occurred  to  a  certain 
section  of  thinkers  that  the  latter  could  be 
utilised  as  a  remedy  for  the  former,  and  various 
schemes  of  state-aided  emigration  to  the 
colonies  were  much  debated  throughout  the 
second  quarter  of  the  century,  both  in  and  out 
of  parliament.  Such  were  those  to  facilitate 
emigration  from  the  south  of  Ireland  to  Canada 
(1823)  and  to  relieve  distress  in  the  Highlands 
of  Scotland  (1841).  At  this  time,  indeed,  the 
idea  of  emigration  became  merged  in  the  more 
complex  idea  of  colonisation.  "  Of  colonisa- 
tion," writes  Wakefield,  "the  principal  ele- 
ments are  emigration,  and  the  permanent 
settlement  of  the  emigi'ants  on  unoccupied 
land."  We  refer  again  later  to  the  distinction 
between  the  secondary  results  of  emigration 
to  a  foreign  state,  and  those  of  emigi-ation  to 
a  colony  or  similar  possession. 

What  was  thought  of  the  economic  bearing 
of  emigration  at  the  time  alluded  to  may  best 
be  gathered  from  the  following  passage  from 
Wakefield's  book : 

"My  fancy  pictures  a  sort  and  amount  of 
colonisation  that  would  amply  rej»ay  its  cost 
by  providing  happily  for  our  redundant  people  ; 
by  improving  the  state  of  those  who  remained 
at  home  ;  by  supplying  us  largely  with  food  and 
the  raw  materials  of  manufacture ;  and  by 
gratifying  our  best  feelings  of  national  pride, 
through  the  extension  over  the  unoccupied  parts 
of  the  earth  of  a  nationality  truly  British  in 
language,  religion,  laws,  institutions,  and  attach- 
ment to  the  empire." 

The  first  words  of  this  passage  strike  the 
keynote  of  the  modern  intention  in  emigration. 
The  movements  of  the  individual  and  the  larger 
schemes  projected  by  the  state  are  alike  con- 
nected with  the  sense  of  undue  pressure  and 
competition  at  home.  Love  of  adventure, 
political  complications,  religious  difficulties, 
which  have  been  active  forces  in  causing  emi- 
gration formerly,  play  a  less  conspicuous  part 
now.  Yet  they  are  still  not  absolutely  unim- 
portant :  the  existing  movement  of  the  Jews  from 
Russia  is  strongly  influenced  by  these  motives. 
The  circumstances  are  too  recent  to  enable  us 
to  judge  whether  the  eflect  on  the  prosperity  of 
Russia  may  not  be  similar  to  that  experienced 
by  Spain  after  the  expulsion  of  the  Jewish- 
Mahommedan  population  in  the  time  of  Ferdi- 
nand and  Isabella.     The   former  large  emigra- 


tion from  Germany,  which  was  usually  assigned 
to  the  existence  of  conscription,  may  with  greater 
probability  be  traced  to  the  pressure  of  financial 
burthens  resulting  from  military  expenditure. 
Professor  Mayo  Smith,  in  his  recent  work,  laid 
it  down  that  persons  rarely  emigrate  in  order 
to  better  themselves,  but  because  they  are 
actually  pinched  at  home. 

And  this  at  once  suggests  the  most  important 
o  f  the  questions  which  our  subj  cot  presents.  The 
effect  of  emigi'ation  on  any  particular  state  must 
largely  depend  upon  the  functions  which  have 
daily  been  discharged  by  the  emigrant.  We 
must  ascertain  then,  what  are  the  classes  of 
people  who  do  emigrate.  It  is  not  enough  to 
speak  about  "relieving  one  labour  market  and 
supplying  another  " ;  we  must  discover  if  we 
can  what  branch  of  labour  is  chiefly  aflected, 
and  to  what  extent  its  efficiency  is  impaired  by 
the  removal  of  its  active  members. 

Next  in  importance  is  the  question  of  volume 
of  emigration  and  drain  on  the  population. 

Thus  emigration  must  be  examined  both  as 
to  quantity  and  quality  ;  but  having  arrived 
at  some  decision  on  these  points  in  any  par- 
ticular case,  and  at  an  estimate  of  the  actual 
loss  to  the  country  which  they  involve,  we 
shall  have  to  set  off  against  it  the  advantages 
gained  by  the  persons  left  behind,  the  freedom 
from  over  -  competition,  the  raising  of  the 
standard  of  comfort,  and  so  forth — a  subtle  and 
difiicult  inquiry.  In  this  way  we  should  gauge 
what  may  be  considered  the  primary  results  of 
emigi-ation. 

The  secondary  results  are  partly  commercial, 
partly  political.  Mill  kept  the  first-named  very 
clearly  before  him  when  he  penned  the  follow- 
ing passage  : — 

"The  question  is  in  general  treated  too  ex- 
clusively as  one  of  distribution — of  relieving 
one  labour  market  and  supplying  another.  It 
is  this,  but  it  is  also  a  question  of  production, 
and  of  the  most  efl&cient  employment  of  the 
productive  resources  of  the  world.  Much  has 
been  said  of  the  good  economy  of  importing 
commodities  from  the  place  where  they  can  be 
bought  cheapest  ;  while  the  good  economy  of 
producing  them  where  they  can  be  produced 
cheapest  is  comparatively  little  thought  of. 
.  .  .  The  exportation  of  labom'crs  and  capital 
from  old  to  new  countries,  from  a  place  where 
their  productive  power  is  less  to  a  place  where 
it  is  greater,  increases  by  so  much  the  aggregate 
produce  of  the  labour  and  capital  of  the  world. 
It  adds  to  the  joint  wealth  of  the  old  and  the 
new  country  what  amounts  in  a  short  period 
to  many  times  the  mere  cost  of  effecting  the 
transport.  There  needs  be  no  hesitation  in 
affirming  that  colonisation,  in  the  present  state 
of  the  world,  is  the  best  affair  of  business  in 
which  the  capital  of  an  old  and  wealthy  country 
can  engage." 

Similarly  Wakefield,  in  a  work  which  followed 


V 


r 


698 


EMIGRATION 


Mill's:  "  The  practice  of  colonisation  ...  has 
reacted  with  momentous  consequences  on  old 
countries  by  creating  and  supplying  new  objects 
of  desire,  by  stimulating  industry  and  skill,  by 
promoting  manufactures  and  commerce,  by 
greatly  augmenting  the  wealth  and  population 
of  the  world"  ;  and  he  goes  on  to  add  in  words 
which  we  may  quote  without  tying  ourselves  to 
accept  them,  "it  has  occasioned  directly  a 
peculiar  form  of  government,  the  really  demo- 
cratic, and  has  been,  indirectly,  a  main  cause 
of  the  political  changes  and  tendencies  which 
now  agitate  Europe." 

The  above  sketch  of  the  lines  to  be  followed 
in  an  investigation  into  the  effects  of  emigi'ation 
may  be  considered  to  hold  good  generally  for 
all  times  and  for  all  peoples  ;  but  it  is  question- 
able whether  any  sufficiently  trustworthy  data 
exist  to  enable  us  to  draw  fair  inferences  con- 
cerning the  earlier  emigrations.  Even  in  regard 
to  recent  years  we  shall  do  well  if  we  can 
arrive  at  fairly  accurate  conclusions  in  respect 
of  one  or  two  countries,  such  as  England  or 
Germany,  in  which  statistics  are  becoming 
understood.  It  is  hardly  necessary  to  observe 
that  the  case  of  the  United  States,  whose  statis- 
tics are  suflBciently  careful  and  elaborate,  fur- 
nishes no  illustration  of  the  efiect  of  emigi-ation. 
Such  emigration  as  may  take  place  from  the 
States  is  so  individual  and  spasmodic  that, 
compared  with  the  large  volume  of  Immigra- 
tion (q.v.),  it  may  be  neglected. 

In  considering  the  results  of  emigration  from 
Europe  in  the  17th  and  18th  centuries,  it  is 
almost  impossible  to  separate  political  and 
economic  phenomena. 

Spain  suddenly  found  an  area  for  her  develop- 
ment which  has  been  unequalled  even  by  Great 
Britain  ;  she  subdued  many  native  peoples  and 
settled  a  vast  territory.  There  was  a  constant 
flow  of  Spaniards  to  Central  and  South  America. 
The  ease  of  conquest  and  the  lust  of  gain  had  a 
large  share  in  the  deterioration  of  the  national 
character  ;  loss  of  population  and  a  false  con- 
ception of  wealth  completed  the  downfall  of  an 
empire.  If  it  be  sought  to  fasten  a  portion  of 
the  blame  on  emigration  it  will  not  be  forgotten 
that,  while  the  drain  on  the  resources  of  the  old 
country  was  excessive,  the  Spanish  emigrants 
were  for  the  most  part  the  worst  type  of  mer- 
cenary soldiers. 

The  history  of  Portugal  presents  rather  differ- 
ent features.  The  Portuguese  in  those  days,  as 
now,  were  deeply  imbued  with  the  trading 
instinct ;  they  had  far  more  capacity  than  the 
Spaniard  for  settling  down  on  new  territory. 
The  effect  of  discovery  and  conquest  in  this 
case  is  parallel  to  that  upon  Holland  ;  a  people 
dwelling  in  a  circumscribed  area  suddenly  rose 
to  the  level  of  a  first-class  state  ;  the  more  rapid 
loss  of  power  by  Portugal  was  probably  due  to 
the  weakness  of  its  political  constitution  as 
compared  with  that  stern  combination  of  free 


men  who  had  gone  through  thie  fire  of  oppres- 
sion and  emerged  a  fresh  nation. 

The  Netherlands  form  the  best  instance, 
besides  our  own  country,  of  the  beneficial  effects 
of  regular  emigration.  To  them  it  was  a  safety- 
valve  :  the  closing  years  of  the  1 6th  century 
had  purged  away  the  dross  of  the  nation  ;  it 
was  composed  of  men,  on  the  whole,  remark- 
ably even  in  power,  will,  and  capacity  ;  to 
avoid  fretting  and  wear  and  tear  at  home  a 
proportion  of  such  men  must  find  an  outlet 
abroad  ;  the  emigration  from  Holland  accord- 
ingly included  many  of  the  best  of  its  citizens, 
and  they  did  not  hesitate  to  settle  permanently 
in  their  new  homes,  and  reproduce  the  political 
constitutions  and  commercial  aptitude  of  the 
mother  country.  On  the  other  hand  the  volume 
of  emigration  was  not  large,  and  we  have  De 
"Witt's  authority  for  the  fact  that  there  was  a 
constant  immigration  into  the  free  republic 
from  surrounding  nations  ;  the  centre  of  the 
system  was  never  exhausted.  The  new  settle- 
ments distinctly  increased  the  trade  and  power 
of  the  Netherlands  ;  the  monopoly  which  they 
established  of  the  East  India  trade  was  only 
partly  due  to  the  chartered  company  ;  it  could 
not  have  lasted  so  long  but  for  the  Dutch  mer- 
chants on  the  other  side  of  the  world. 

We  may  pass  over  France,  which  furnishes 
no  further  lesson,  and  take  the  early  history  of 
English  emigration.  There  we  find  emigration 
proceeding  along  two  distinct  lines — the  inten- 
tional transporfiN,tion  by  the  great  companies  of 
such  persons  as  would  form  a  useful  community, 
and  the  voluntary  expatriation  of  large  bodies 
of  persons  of  the  same  political  or  religious 
persuasion.  The  class  of  emigrants  who  left 
England  at  that  time  was  thus,  in  the  main,  a 
very  good  one.  It  was  only  natural  that  the 
intention  of  the  founders  of  the  settlements 
should  be  better  than  the  results  attained. 
The  proposal  in  the  case  of  Carolina — that  not 
more  than  100  or  150  settlers  should  be  sent 
over  the  first  year,  and  none  but  labourers, 
artisans,  and  skilful  seamen  should  be  sent 
during  the  next  two  or  three  years — is  a  fair 
sample  of  the  way  in  which  the  nucleus  of  a 
colony  was  intended  to  be  constituted.  But  in 
practice  it  was  impossible  to  avoid  an  influx  of 
worthless  characters  ;  and  in  spite  of  Bacon's 
warning,  adventurers  and  government  alike 
could  not  resist  the  temptation  of  sending  out 
condemned  prisoners,  vagrants,  gipsies,  and  bad 
characters, — people  ''divers  ways  gathered  up 
in  England." 

England,  however,  did  not  lose  by  the 
exodus.  "Virginia,"  says  Doyle,  "was  the 
offspring  of  economical  distress : "  in  fact,  Great 
Britain  could  at  the  time  afford  to  part  with  a 
large  slice  of  population.  The  ablest  workmen 
and  richest  merchants  did  not  go  ;  those  who 
did  emigrate,  whether  honest  men  or  rogues, 
left  a  feeling  of  relief  among  those  who  remained 


/ 


EMIGRATION 


699 


behind  them  ;  there  was  more  elbow-room,  but 
there  was  no  gap  ;  the  work  at  home  went  on 
better. 

The  number  that  emigrated  at  this  period 
was  considerable  ;  although  our  information  is 
not  sufficient  to  be  tabulated.  To  Virginia 
alone  1261  persons  went  in  1619,  1000  in  one 
year  previous  to  1635,  2000  the  next  year, 
1600  the  next,  and  so  on — many  thousands  in 
all ;  and  the  movement  was  steady  year  by 
year.  In  1639  an  order  in  council  was  issued 
with  the  object  of  restraining  the  efflux  of  popu- 
lation. There  was  an  alarm  that  this  was 
becoming  a  drain  on  the  country's  resources. 
But  the  very  next  year  there  were  appeals  for  the 
rescission  of  the  order  in  whole  or  in  part ;  and 
Sir  Josiah  Child,  writing  in  1692,  denies  that 
there  ever  had  been  a  drain  on  the  people. 

In  the  large  extent  of  this  emigi-ation  lay  the 
germs  of  its  future  benefit  to  England.  The 
plantations  called  out  enterprise  and  activity 
on  the  part  of  those  who  remained  behind. 
**  I  say,"  writes  Child,  "that  for  provisions, 
clothes,  and  household  goods,  seamen  and  all 
others  employed  about  materials  for  building, 
fitting,  and  victualling  of  ships,  every  English- 
man in  Barbadoes  or  Jamaica  creates  employ- 
ment for  four  men  at  home."  The  emigration 
of  a  considerable  number  of  men,  and  the  suc- 
cessful growth  of  their  settlements  in  new 
lands,  transformed  England  into  the  first  com- 
mercial and  carrying  nation  of  the  world. 

In  the  18th  century  the  stream  of  emigra- 
tion flowed  more  slowly  ;  the  severance  of  the 
United  States,  and  the  wars  in  which  Great 
Britain  was  engaged,  both  contributed  to  check 
it ;  and  when  next  it  assumed  larger  propor- 
tions a  new  era  had  begun — the  era  of  emigra- 
tion without  conquest  or  settlement,  directed 
as  much  to  foreign  countries  as  to  British 
possessions.  In  1815  the  number  of  emigrants 
from  the  United  Kingdom  was  2081,  in  1820 
it  was  25,729,  in  1830,  56,907  ;  in  that  year 
the  Colonisation  Society  was  formed  ;  in  the 
next  year  the  first  effort  was  made  to  regulate 
emigi-ation  ;  an  agent  general  for  emigration 
and  certain  '*  South  Australian  "  comniissioners 
were  the  chief  centres  of  authority  for  some 
years,  and  in  1840  the  Colonial  Land  and  Emi- 
gration Board  was  established  in  Downing 
Street.  It  had  become  clear  that  the  matter 
was  one  of  great  interest  both  to  the  mother 
country  and  the  colonies.  On  the  one  hand 
was  the  theory  described  as  "shovelling  out 
the  paupers,"  on  the  other  was  the  demand 
that  no  emigrant  should  be  sent  to  the  colonies 
except  under  proper  safeguards,  and  with  some 
guarantee  of  his  fitness.  And  on  the  lines 
which  wore  settled  fifty  years  ago,  the  attitude 
of  the  state  towards  emigration  has  remained 
ever  since.  Tlio  activity  of  societies  and  other 
quasi-public  influences  has,  however,  been  grow- 
ing, till  we  are  confronted  at  the  present  day 


with  the  efforts  of  philanthropists  and  charit- 
able institutions  such  as  the  Church  Army. 

We  can  now  examine  in  more  detail,  in  the 
case  of  our  own  country,  the  answers  to  the 
questions  propounded  above. 

1.  As  regards  the  stamp  of  the  emigrants 
from  England  it  is  specially  noted  in  1845  that 
one-half  were  unskilled  labourers,  and  four- 
fifths  of  the  remainder  agricultural  labourers 
and  farmers,  the  great  bulk  being  exceedingly 
poor  and  depending  on  immediate  employment 
for  subsistence.  And  a  study  of  the  Board  of 
Trade  returns  for  the  last  lew  years  confirms 
the  same  opinion.  "'There  seems  no  doubt," 
says  Sir  R.  Giffen  in  his  report,  "  of  the  broad 
facts  that  the  majority  of  the  adult  male 
emigrants  are  laboui'ers,  and  of  single  adult 
female  emigrants,  domestic  servants."  In  the 
last  nine  months  of  1912  out  of  223,608  adult 
emigrants  (British  subjects)  leaving  the  United 
Kingdom  124,156  were  males,  and  99,452 
females,  classified  as  follows  : 

Male— 

Agricultural 23,289 

Commercial  and  professional        ,        ,  19,770 

Skilled  trades 38,816 

Labourers 30,942 

Miscellaneous         .        .        ,        .        .  11,330 

Female — 

Domestic  and  other  servants        .        ,  31,983 

Dressmakers  and  other  trades      .        .  5,765 

Teachers,  clerks,  and  iirofessions         ,  3,379 

No  stated  occupation    ....  58,325 

It  may  reasonably  be  assumed  that  the  major- 
ity of  those  whose  occupations  are  notstated  were 
also  unskilled  labourers  ;  hence  it  is  probable 
that  some  156,000  out  of  224,000,  about  sixty- 
nine  per  cent,  were  of  this  description.  The 
reports  of  the  Emigi'ants'  Information  Office  may 
at  first  sight  appear  to  contradict  this,  as  the 
larger  percentage  of  their  recorded  inquiries  has 
been  from  mechanics  ;  this,  however,  is  natural 
from  the  position  of  the  office  in  London,  and 
the  general  readiness  of  the  mechanic  as  com- 
pared with  the  unskilled  labourer  in  availing 
himself  of  an  institution  of  this  kind. 

It  would  appear  to  be  the  fact  that  neither 
of  the  ordinary  tenets  as  to  the  class  of  persons 
who  leave  the  country  is  correct.  The  pauper 
cannot  go — despite  the  theory  that  emigration 
was  to  relieve  the  weakest  portion  of  the  com- 
munity ;  the  receiving  country  rejects  him,  and 
the  regulations  which  agents  of  government 
here  and  abroad  have  sought  to  enforce  con- 
stantly tend  to  encourage  the  better  class  of 
emigrant.  Macintyre,  writing  seventy  years 
ago,  insisted  on  this:  "Emigration,  as  it  is 
carried  on  from  this  country,  does  not  afford  any 
relief  to  the  masses  of  the  people  reduced  to  the 
verge  of  starvation."  "  The  conditions  required 
of  the  persons  selected  for  emigration  show  that 
they  are  picked  individuals."  Emigration  has 
done  little  or  nothing  towards  elevating  the 
lowest  classes  of  our  people.  But,  on  the 
other  hand,  it  appears  to  be  untrue  that  only 


V 


700 


V- 

EMIGRATION 


the  best  of  them  are  leaving  us.  "With  some 
reservation  as  to  what  stamp  of  man  is  really 
the  best  and  strongest  in  a  community,  we  need 
uot  accept  that  theory.  While  it  is  obvious  that 
a  man  must  have  some  capital  before  he  can  emi- 
grate to  Australasia  or  the  States,  especiaily  if 
he  take  his  family  with  him,  and  that  he  must 
have  some  energy  to  cause  him  to  make  the 
eflfort  to  move,  the  fact  seems  to  be  that  the 
best  and  most  skilled  workers,  those  who  feel 
they  can  make  their  way,  remain  at  home  ; 
the  less  competent  hands  emigrate.  The  figures 
given  above  support  this  opinion,  which  is  en- 
dorsed by  Sir  R.  Giffen  (comp.  Francis 
Galton's  Hei-editary  Genius,  p.  346).  Hence 
it  appears  that  the  loss  of  productive  power  to 
the  country  is  not  serious.  And  if  the  pro- 
ductive capacity,  the  skill  and  worth  of  the 
emigrants  is  improved  in  their  new  sphere,  there 
is  a  clear  economic  gain  to  the  world  at  large. 
A  more  real  disadvantage  to  a  country  is  found 
in  the  tendency  of  males  to  emigrate  in  greater 
numbers  than  females.  Emigration  in  this 
aspect  appears  as  contributing  indirectly  to  the 
gi-cater  immorality  and  pauperism  which  usu- 
ally result  from  the  excess  of  females.  Simi- 
larly there  may  be  a  loss  to  the  community  in 
having  to  educate  and  bring  up  a  new  set  of 
children  to  take  the  place  of  adult  emigrants. 

The  questions  of  the  effect  of  the  removal  of 
labour  on  wages,  and  the  prospect  of  thereby 
raising  the  standard  of  comfort  amongst  the 
labouring  classes,  are  matters  which  bring  us  to 
the  consideration  of  the  volume  of  emigration. 
To  raise  wages  in  any  particular  trade  it  is 
necessary  that  an  ample  number  of  that  par- 
ticular craft  should  be  removed  at  one  time  ; 
and  that  is  an  event  which  does  not  occur. 
Some  effect  might  be  produced  on  all  trades  by 
the  removal  of  a  very  large  mass  of  general 
labour ;  but  neither  is  that  at  present  attain- 
able ;  though  there  is  a  growing  tendency 
towards  encouraging  emigration  in  families  and 
small  communities,  e.g.  to  the  state  colonies 
of  the  Argentine  Republic. 

In  computing  the  volume  of  emigration,  we 
must  obviously  set  off  against  it  the  total  of 
immigration  in  each  year.  Thus  in  1912  the 
gross  number  of  emigrants  from  the  United 
Kingdom  to  non- European  countries  (including 
foreigners  and  children)  was  656,835;  the 
number  of  immigrants  was  340,696  ;  the  net 
emigration  being  thus  316,139.  Sir  R.  Giffen 
notes  that  both  vary  in  well-defined  cycles, 
guided  by  the  state  of  trade  ;  when  prosperity 
is  at  its  height  there  is  a  decline  of  gross  emigra- 
tion, accompanied  by  increase  of  immigration. 
It  has  unfortunately  happened  of  late  years  in 
England  that  the  immigrants  who  take  the 
place  of  our  British  emigrants  are  foreigners  of 
a  lower  stamp  than  our  own  people ;  so  that 
there  is  a  double  loss  apart  from  mere  figures  ; 
for  these  foreigners  not  only  replace  better  men. 


but  tend  again  to  lower  the  standard  of  comfort 
and  depress  the  status  of  the  workers. 

The  annual  average  number  of  persons  of 
British  and  Irish  origin  who  have  emigrated 
since  1851,  with  proportion  to  the  total 
population  of  the  United  Kingdom,  is  as 
follows : 


Period. 

1851-1860 
1861-1870 
1871-1880 
1881-1890 
1891-1900 
1901-1910 
1911-1912 


Annual 
Average. 

164,085 
157,182 
167,891 
255,853 
174,279 
284,146 


Proportion 

to  Total 
Population. 

•58  per  cent 
•50  „ 
•51  „ 
•70  „ 
•44  „ 
•65       „ 


461,096         1-01 


These  figures  include  tourists  and  travellers  as 
well  as  emigrants.  In  1912  a  new  method  of 
computation  was  adopted  demanding  a  state- 
ment of  the  countries  of  last  and  of  intended 
future  permanent  residence.  It  is  now  possible 
to  separate  emigrants  from  and  immigrants  to 
the  United  Kingdom  from  passengers  passing 
through.  Thus  in  1912-13  out  of  474,509 
British  subjects  who  left  for  non -European 
countries,  407,729  were  bond  fide  emigrants, 
and  of  341,660  persons  (British  and  alien)  who 
arrived,  74,798  intended  to  remain. 

Of  the  emigrants  from  the  United  Kingdom 
in  1912  about  25  per  cent  went  to  the  United 
States,  40  per  cent  to  British  North  America, 
18  per  cent  to  Australia,  13  per  cent  to  other 
British  Colonies,  and  4  per  cent  to  other 
foreign  countries. 

The  secondary  results  of  emigration  are  {a) 
commercial ;  (6)  political. 

(a)  They  differ  according  as  the  emigrants  go 
to  a  foreign  country  or  a  colony.  When  a  colony 
is  protected  like  a  foreign  country  against  British 
goods,  it  does  not  much  matter  commercially 
whether  he  goes  to  a  colony  or  not.  But  where 
preference  is  given  to  British  goods,  and  there 
is  a  growing  tendency  towards  this  among  our 
colonies,  it  makes  a  great  difference.  The 
general  effect  is  well  described  by  Wakefield. 

**The  emigrants  would  be  producers  of  food 
.  .  .  and  raw  materials  of  manufacture  for  this 
country  ;  we  should  buy  their  surplus  food  and 
raw  materials  with  manufactured  goods.  Every 
piece  of  ouy  colonisation,  therefore,  would  add  to 
the  power  of  the  whole  mass  of  new  countries 
to  supply  us  with  employment  for  capital  and 
labour  at  home.  Thus  employment  for  capital 
and  labour  would  be  increased  in  two  ways  and 
two  places  at  the  same  time  ;  abroad,  in  the 
colonies,  by  the  removal  of  capital  and  people 
to  fresh  fields  of  production  ;  at  home  by  the 
extension  of  markets  or  the  importation  of  food 
and  raw  materials," 

How  true  this  is  may  be  seen  by  the  growth 
of  trade  between  Great  Britain  and  her  colonies 
(see  Imports   and  Exports).     The   enhance- 


EMIGRATION 


701 


ment  of  Great  Britain's  commercial  prosperity, 
owing  to  emigration  to  her  colonies  and  the 
United  States,  is  an  admitted  fact.  But  when 
the  emigrant  goes  to  a  foreign  country  and  is 
lost  in  the  general  mass  of  its  population,  it  is 
impossible  to  earmark  his  particular  effect  on 
increase  of  trade  :  if  trade  were  free,  old  associa- 
tion might  do  much  ;  but  in  the  vast  majority 
of  cases  the  matter  is  determined  by  other 
causes.  Of  all  the  nations  who  have  most 
increased  the  national  commerce  with  foreigners 
through  emigration,  we  should  select  the  Ger- 
mans as  the  most  successful  at  the  present  day. 
But  a  large  emigration  may  sometimes  pro- 
duce a  transfer  of  trade  which  is  a  distinct  loss 
to  a  country.  England  seems  to  be  experiencing 
something  of  this  sort  in  consequence  of  the 
high  tariffs  of  other  countries,  e.g.  the  McKinley 
Act  of  the  United  States  ;  when  manufactures 
are  transferred  bodily  to  their  best  market 
there  Avill  be  a  loss  of  people  and  of  proiits 
to  England.  But  in  this  case  emigration  is 
a  result  rather  than  a  cause,  differing  herein 
from  the  emigration  of  the  Flemings  from  the 
Low  Countries  in  the  14th  century,  which  pro- 
duced a  transfer  of  the  woollen  manufacture  to 
England. 

(h)  With  purely  political  results  of  emigra- 
tion we  are  not  here  concerned.  On  the  one 
hand,  it  tends  to  the  union  of  nations  and  to 
the  establishment  of  peace  ;  on  the  other,  it  is 
always  increasing  the  responsibility  of  a  nation 
towards  foreign  powers.  England  with  her 
many  subjects  scattered  over  the  globe,  and  her 
vast  possessions  across  the  seas,  is  the  great 
example  of  the  double  responsibility.  We  are 
'  not  likely  now,  as  the  Romans  did,  to  make 
emigration  a  distinct  method  of  control  over 
subject  peoples. 

In  reviewing  the  foregoing  results  we  have 
purposely  selected  Great  Britain  as  their  chief 
exponent.  And  we  have  dealt  with  the  king- 
dom as  a  whole  :  in  Scotland  and  Ireland,  taken 
separately,  we  find  two  well-marked  opposite 
results.  Scotland  has  sent  out  a  steady 
stream  of  emigi-ants  whose  departure  has  only 
strengthened  those  who  were  left  behind,  Ire- 
land, partly  from  poverty,  partly  from  political 
causes,  has  been  rapidly  depleted  of  the  stronger 
part  of  her  population.  In  examining  the  emi- 
gration from  other  countries,  we  also  find  special 
phases  to  arrest  us.  Norway  and  Sweden  have 
both  been  centres  of  a  large  emigration,  which 
appears  to  be  gaining  strength.  In  Norway 
the  causes  and  effects  have  been  akin  to  the 
case  of  Scotland.  In  Sweden  the  parallel  is 
rather  with  Ireland.  In  Italy  the  large  annual 
emigration  is  becoming  a  serious  drain,  and 
the  face  of  the  country  is  already  showing 
this.  The  loss  of  the  more  enterprising 
peasantry  is  making  more  helpless  those  who 
are  left  behind.  Germany,  on  political  grounds, 
has  checked  the  tendency  to  emigrate  ;    she 


does  not  wish  to  lose  her  soldiers  at  the  best 
period  of  their  lives. 

The  comparative  strength  of  emigration  in 
certain  European  countries  may  be  gauged  by 
the  following  figures  for  1910-11  : 

Great  Britain  and  Ireland  .     10-05  per  1000 


Holland    . 

7-30 

Germany  . 
Italy         . 
Norway    . 
Sweden     . 

•39 
.     15-43 

.       5-0-2 
.       3-59 

These  figures  show  the  gross  emigration  ;  we 
must  go  further  for  the  net  result.  In  the 
last  three  countries  mentioned  there  is  little 
immigration  to  balance  the  drain.  One  of  the 
best  instances  where  population  has,  decade  after 
decade,  been  kept  stationary  by  emigration  is 
that  of  tlie  Leeward  Islands  in  the  West  Indies. 
Emigration  from  France  is  very  slight. 

Before  concluding,  a  reference  is  required  to 
the  considerable  annual  emigration  from  India 
to  the  British  tropical  colonies,  and  from  China 
to  the  Australian  colonies  and  the  United 
States.  The  Indian  government  do  not  en- 
courage emigration,  except  under  very  strict 
conditions  and  safeguards.  The  Chinese  law, 
till  recently  at  any  rate,  prohibited  it  ;  but 
pressure  of  population  set  the  law  at  defiance, 
and  the  government,  as  is  its  wont,  connived. 
In  1852  Sir  E.  Bowring  expressed  the  opinion 
that  it  left  greater  ease  to  those  who  remained 
and  cleared  the  country  of  vagrants.  Hardly 
any  women  leave  China,  and  this  gives  the 
movement  a  special  feature.  An  indirect  effect 
of  slow  growth  may  be  expected  in  the  case 
of  Indian  coolie  emigration,  especially  that 
to  the  West  Indies.  The  lowest  classes  of 
the  population  go  :  their  return  at  a  stated 
period  is  part  of  their  agi-eement ;  they  come 
back  much  improved  in  circumstances,  with 
standards  of  living  gi'eatly  raised.  But  the 
population  of  both  China  and  India  is  so 
crowded  that  hardly  a  mark  can  yet  be  said 
to  have  been  left  upon  it  by  emigration. 

[The  aspect  of  emigration  here  discussed  is 
but  slightly  referred  to  in  most  published  works. 
Special  attention  may  be  called  to  chapters  II.  and 
IX.  of  Immigration  and  Emigration  :  A  Study  in 
Social  Science,  Prof.  Mayo  Smith,  London,  1890  : 
this  book  has  a  full  bibliography. — The  reports 
of  the  Emigration  Commissioners  from  1832  to 
1870. — Jhe  annual  statistics  of  the  Board  of 
Trade,  especially  the  reports  for  1877  and  1891. 
First  and  second  reports  on  the  Emigrants'  In- 
formation Office,  1887-88. — An  Essay  on  Planta- 
tions, by  Sir  Francis  Bacon. — A  Treatise,  by  John 
de  Witt,  Pensioner  of  Holland. — A  Discourse 
concerning  Plantations,  by  Sir  Josiah  Child  (all 
three  re-published  amongst  select  tracts,  London, 
1827). — The  Effects  of  Distant  Colonisation  on  the 
Parent  State,  Thomas  Arnold,  lSl5.—Thovghts 
on  Population  and  Starvatic>n,  by  J.  J.  Mac- 
intyre,  London,  1841. — Letter  on  the  Condition 
\  of  England,  by  R.  Torreus,   1843.—^  View  of 


702 


EMINENT  DOMAIN 


th^  Art  of  Colonisation,  by  E.  Gibbon  Wake- 
field London,  1849.— An  essay  Ueber  italumsche 
Au^anderung  und  FeMarheU  in  ItaUenxsche 
Gvps-Figv/rffn,  you  W.  Kaden,  Leipzic,  1891.] 


C.  A. 


[For  the  effect  on  the  country  which  receives 
the  emigrants,  see  Immigration.] 

EMINENT  DOMAIN.  This  term,  in 
constant  use  among  American  lawyers  and 
publicists,  but  still  hardly  familiar  in  England, 
seems  to  be  derived  from  a  phrase  of  Grotius 
(De  Jure  Belli  ac  Pads,  1.  i.  ch.  iii.  vi.  §  2) 
where,  speaking  of  the  attributes  of  supreme 
public  authority  in  a  state,  he  says:  "in 
quibus  comprehenditur  et  dominium  eminens 
quod  civitas  habet  in  cives  et  res  civium  ad 
usum  publicum."  That  is  to  say,  there  is  in 
every  state  a  paramount  authority  over  the 
persons  and  property  of  its  subjects  for  matters 
of  public  advantage.  It  will  be  carefully 
observed  that  this  is  not  a  right  of  property, 
and  is  quite  independent  of  the  laws  or  doctrines 
as  to  the  tenure  of  any  kind  of  property  which 
prevail  in  this  or  that  state.  Where  the  state, 
or  a  public  department,  in  a  corporate  capacity, 
or  as  an  ideal  or  "moral"  person,  is  the 
owner  of  any  property,  its  rights  are  the 
ordinary  rights  of  an  owner.  The  right  or 
power  now  in  question  is  to  supersede  the 
ordinary  rights  of  the  subject,  whatever  they 
may  be.  In  other  passages  Grotius  calls  it 
"supereminent,"  as  if  to  make  this  clear. 
Being  a  power  above  ordinary  legal  rights,  it 
can  be  set  in  motion  only  by  an  exercise  of 
legal  sovereignty  ;  in  other  words  it  can  take 
effect  in  a  civilised  state,  except  perhaps  in 
singular  emergencies,  only  by  express  legislation 
or  under  some  authority  conferred  by  express 
legislation.  This  passage  alone  does  not  make 
it  clear  whether  Grotius  contemplated  the 
right  or  power  of  "eminent  domain"  as  some- 
thing capable  of  being  in  frequent  and  normal 
action,  and  having  a  settled  place  in  the  institu- 
tions of  public  law.  Perhaps  he  was  here 
thinking  rather  of  impressing  men  for  service 
against  an  invader,  entering  on  private  land  to 
make  fortifications  (a  power  attributed  to  the 
crown  from  ancient  times  by  the  common  law 
of  England),  taking  horses  and  provisions  for 
urgent  military  needs,  and  the  like.  But  in  a 
later  chapter  (1.  iii.  ch.  xx.  vii.  §  1)  he  dis- 
tinctly says  that  it  is  not  merely  an  emergency 
power,  but  exists  for  the  sake  of  the  public 
weal  in  general.  In  modern  usage  we  speak  of 
"  eminent  domain "  only  as  exercisable  with 
regard  to  property.  Experience  has  shown 
that  many  objects  of  public  utility  and  necessity 
cannot  be  eflFected  without  overriding  the 
ordinary  rights  of  owners,  and  especially  the 
right  of  parting  with  one's  property,  if  at  all, 
only  on  such  terms  as  one  thinks  fit  to  accept. 
On  the  other  hand  it  is  found  necessary  or 
expedient  to  make  interference  of  this  kind  as 


little  burdensome  to  the  individual  as  is  con- 
sistent with  accomplishing  the  public  objects  in 
view,  and  to  avoid,  both  in  fact  and  in  appear- 
ance, anything  like  arbitrary  disturbance  of 
private  rights.  Hence  the  exercise  of  sove- 
reignty in  this  kind  is  reduced  to  rule  and 
brought  under  legal  and  judicial  categories. 
Under  names  denoting  either  th^  power  itself, 
as  "eminent  domain"  in  America,  or  the 
principal  mode  and  eflect  of  its  exercise,  aa 
"  compulsory  purchase  "  in  England,  "expro- 
priation pour  cause  d'utilite  publique"  in 
France,  "  Zwangsenteignung  "  in  Germany 
(where,  however,  "  Expropriation "  is  in  more 
general  use),  we  find  the  matter  dealt  with, 
on  substantially  similar  lines,  in  the  legislation 
and  jurisprudence  of  most  civilised  countries. 

The  principles  recognised,  it  is  believed,  in 
all  jurisdictions,  though  secured  by  various  forms 
of  procedure,  are  that  private  property  is  not 
to  be  taken  by  compulsion  unless  for  some 
object  of  which  the  public  utility  has  been 
proved,  that  it  must  not  be  taken  without  just 
compensation,  and  that  the  compensation  must 
be  paid  or  at  least  put  in  the  way  of  impartial 
ascertainment  before  possession  can  be  required. 
The  enactment  of  the  French  Civil  Code  "  Nul 
ne  peut  6tre  contraint  de  ceder  sa  propriete,  si 
ce  n'est  pour  cause  d'utilite  publique,  et 
moyennant  une  juste  et  prealable  indemnite" 
(art.  646)  may  be  taken  as  a  concise  and  typical 
statement.  It  is  copied  or  translated  in  many 
other  codes  {e.g.  Civil  Code  of  Lower  Canada, 
art.  407).  The  exercise  of  eminent  domain  on 
terms  of  just  compensation  goes  back,  in  France, 
to  the  early  14th  century  (see  Philippe  le  Bel's 
ordinance  quoted.  Law  Quart.  Rev.,  iii.  316). 
A  law  of  1841  (to  be  found  in  the  collections 
of  Lois  usuelles)  now  regulates  the  procedure  in 
France  ;  it  has  probably  served  as  a  model  for 
similar  legislation  in  many  of  the  countries 
which  have  adopted  the  Napoleonic  codes  or 
come  under  their  influence.  In  England  the 
method  has  been  for  promoters  of  public  works, 
such  as  canals,  bridges  over  navigable  rivers, 
and  in  later  times  railways,  to  apply  to  parlia- 
ment for  incorporation,  and  at  the  same  time 
to  seek  the  grant  of  compulsory  powers.  Parlia- 
ment cannot  of  course  be  bound  by  any  positive 
law  in  the  exercise  of  its  supreme  power  of 
law-making,  but  the  settled  practice  of  Parlia- 
ment in  dealing  with  private  bills  embodies 
all  the  essential  safeguards.  What  is  called 
"proving  the  preamble"  of  a  private  bill  is 
really  a  quasi-judicial  process  of  establishing, 
by  full  and  often  keenly-contested  argument, 
the  utility  of  the  proposed  undertaking.  Com- 
pensation used  to  be  separately  provided  for  in 
every  Act  granting  compulsory  powers  to  take 
land:  at  length  "the  multiplicity  of  such 
statutes  and  the  general  similarity  of  their 
provisions  led  to  the  enactment  of  various 
general  laws,  notably  the  Lands  Clauses  Con- 


EMMERY— EMPIRICISM 


703 


solidation  Act  of  1845,  which,"  together  with 
later  amending  Acts  dealing  with  particular 
matters  of  procedure,  "is  really  a  code  regulating 
the  law  and  practice  of  the  eminent  domain." 
(Mr.  Carman  F.  Randolph  in  Law  Quarterly 
Eeview,  iii.  323).  ''Lands  Clauses  Acts"  and 
**  Compensation "  are  the  English  lawyer's 
practical  catch  -  words  on  the  subject.  The 
ultimate  feudal  superiority  of  the  crown  has 
nothing  to  do  with  eminent  domain,  although 
the  two  things  have  sometimes  been  confused 
even  by  able  writers.  It  is  sufficient  to  say 
that  the  principles  are  the  same,  and  the 
practice  alike  in  all  essential  matters,  in  France, 
where  feudal  tenures  have  long  been  abolished, 
and  in  the  United  States,  where  they  never  had 
any  effective  existence. 

Eminent  domain  has  been  described  by  the 
highest  American  authority,  the  Supreme  Court 
of  the  United  States,  as  "the  right  which 
belongs  to  the  society  or  to  the  sovereign  of 
disposing  in  cases  of  necessity,  and  for  the 
public  safety,  of  all  the  wealth  contained  in 
the  State" — Pollard' s  lessee  v.  Hagan  (1844), 
15  Curtis,  391,  395,  s.c.  3  How.  212.  It  is 
carefully  distinguished  by  American  publicists 
from  the  right,  which  they  call  the  police 
power,  of  restraining  the  use  of  private 
property  in  ways  which  may  be  dangerous, 
offensive,  or  otherwise  injurious  to  the  public 
weal.  The  specially  full  discussion  and  defini- 
tion of  these  topics  in  the  United  States 
proceeds  from  the  fact  that  the  legislative 
power,  both  of  the  federal  and  of  the  state 
governments,  is  not  unlimited,  but  must  be 
exercised  in  conformity  with  the  constitutions 
of  the  United  States  and  of  the  respective 
states  of  the  union. 

[American  treatises  on  Constitutional  Law  ; 
Kent's  Comm.,  ii.  339,  and  eh.  xv.  of  Cooley  on 
Constitutional  Limitations  will  suffice  for  most 
general  purposes  ;  also  recent  works  on  Eminent 
Domain  by  Lewis,  1888  ;  and  Mill,  2nd  ed.  same 
date. — In  England,  Cripps  on  the  Principles  of 
the  Law  of  Compensation,  3rd  ed.  1892.  Mr. 
Randolph's  article  above  cited,  L.Q.R.,  iii.  314, 
gives  a  convenient  general  view.]  F.  P. 

EMMERY  DE  Sept  Fontaines,  Henri 
Charles  (1789-1842),  was  chief  engineer  of 
the  Fonts  et  Cliaussies.  He  superintended  the 
construction  of  the  canal  of  Saint  Maur,  and  of 
the  bridge  over  the  Seine  at  Ivry,  and  about 
five  miles  of  sewers  and  six  miles  of  water- 
conduits  were  laid  by  him  in  Paris  between  1832 
and  1840.  He  principally  wrote  on  subjects 
connected  with  his  profession,  but  published  in 
1837  a  short  pamphlet  of  thirty-two  pages, 
Amelioration  da  sort  des  Ouvriers  dans  les 
Travaux  Publics,  in  which  he  condensed  the 
results  of  his  own  experience  of  the  state  of 
workmen  employed  in  extensive  public  works. 
He  strongly  advocated  the  arbitration  of  the 
State  Ingenietirs  in  all  contentions  arising  be- 


tween contractors  for  the  State  and  their  work- 
men, and  the  responsibility,  according  to  the 
case,  of  the  State  or  of  the  head  contractors  for 
accidents  or  ill-health  resulting  from  unhealthi- 
ness  of  work.  He  gives  some  interesting  statis- 
tical details  on  the  amount  of  indemnities  al- 
lowed under  these  heads  of  the  principal  works 
he  had  superintended.  On  an  average,  they 
amounted  to  35  francs  (say  £1 :  8s.)  per  case,  and 
to  the  proportion  of  3,  2*25,  and  0*50  francs  per 
1000  francs  (2s.  5d.,  Is.  10|d.  and  5d.  per  £40) 
of  the  gross  cost  of  works  performed.       e.  Ca. 

EMPANEL.  To  put  the  names  of  jurymen 
on  a  list  which  is  called  the  panel.  e.  s. 

EMPHYTEUSIS.  An  expression  of  Roman 
law,  for  the  permanent  letting  of  land  at  a 
chief  rent,  called  pcnsio.  The  tenant  was,  for 
all  practical  purposes,  the  owner  of  the  land 
(cp.  Feu).  e.  s. 

EMPIRICISM.  Empiricism  is  a  term  of 
somewhat  vague  import.  Perhaps  it  is  oftenest 
used  in  an  unfavourable  sense  to  describe  the 
frame  of  mind  of  one  who  cannot  or  will  not 
reason  from  general  principles,  but  guides  him- 
self in  every  emergency  by  reference  to  particu- 
lar experiences.  Consistent  empiricism  in  this 
sense  is,  strictly  speaking,  impossible.  The 
empiric  who  most  loudly  disclaims  recourse  to 
general  propositions  must  employ  them  as  soon 
as  he  begins  to  apply  his  empirical  wisdom. 
He  must  reflect  somewhat  after  this  fashion  : — 
The  present  case  resembles,  or  does  not  re- 
semble, certain  cases  which  I  have  known. 
Therefore  certain  results  which  followed  in 
those  cases  are  likely,  or  are  unlikely,  to  ensue 
in  this  case.  Therefore  I  ought,  or  I  ought 
not,  to  take  such  and  such  measures.  Here 
the  most  scrupulous  empiric  is  reduced  to  em- 
ploy  both  induction  and  deduction,  to  form  a 
theory  applicable  to  more  than  the  single  case 
before  him  ;  in  a  word,  to  have  recourse  to 
general  reasoning.  It  is  true  that  he  may  not 
utter  his  argument  aloud,  that  he  may  be  him- 
self unconscious  that  he  is  argiiing.  Men  of 
practical  genius,  whether  soldiers  or  statesmen, 
men  of  business,  or  medical  men,  often  carry  out 
extremely  complicated  and  subtle  processes  of 
reasoning  which  they  have  no  time  to  note, 
which  language  is  hardly  adequate  to  express, 
and  which  produce  upon  bystanders  the  effect 
of  a  happy  unaccountable  knack.  Such  men 
are  often  mistaken  for  mere  empirics,  but  that 
is  only  because  they  theorise  so  rapidly  and  so 
weU. 

Empiricism,  in  so  far  as  it  is  serious,  may  be 
described  as  an  illogical  protest  against  the 
abuse  of  logic.  Most  persons  of  systematic 
mind  are  in  such  a  hiu-ry  to  complete  a  system 
that  they  wiQ  not  take  time  either  to  ascertain 
all  the  facts  important  to  be  known  or  to  give 
to  each  known  fact  its  due  place  and  signifi- 
cance.  Accordingly  they  make  wild  work  when 
they  apply  their  systems  to  the  facts  of  life. 


704 


EMPLOYERS  AND  EMPLOYED 


The  mischief  thus  occasioned  has  often  led  men 
ot  real  sagacity  to  express  themselves  as  though 
all  reasoning  were  useless  in  practice,  whilst 
they  only  meant  to  say  that  any  reasoning 
which  is  to  be  of  use  in  practice  must  be 
difficult.  .      ,         ^   • 

The  empiric  and  the  theorist  have  by  turns 
exerted  a  dominating  influence  upon  the  study 
of  political  economy  among  all  nations.  Until 
the  18th  century  books  of  economic  theory  were 
comparatively  few,  and  their  practical  influence 
was  comparatively  small.  Statesmen  and  the 
public  sought  economic  guidance  chiefly  from 
persons  actually  engaged  in  industry  and  com- 
merce. Of  this  empirical  wisdom  Sir  Thomas 
Gresham  may  be  taken  as  a  favourable  instance. 
If  its  admonitions  were  now  and  then  disre- 
garded, this  was  less  in  deference  to  the  opinion 
of  economic  theorists  than  in  deference  to  a 
supposed  interest  of  government  or  doctrine  of 
religion  or  morals.  But  in  the  course  of  the 
18th  century  theoretical  writers  upon  political 
economy  began  to  acquire  an  unprecedented 
authority.  To  their  teaching  chiefly  was  due 
the  revolution  in  favour  of  individual  freedom 
and  unrestrained  competition  which  filled  the 
first  lialf  of  the  1 9th  century.  Since  the  middle 
of  the  century  empiricism  has  perhaps  regained 
some  of  its  former  power.  The  views  of  Adam 
Smith  and  his  immediate  successors  were  per- 
haps more  deeply  coloured  by  the  circumstances 
of  their  own  age  than  they  themselves  could  be 
conscious  of,  or  would  have  admitted  at  the 
time,  for  nothing  is  more  difficult  even  for  the 
deepest  thinker  than  to  clear  himself  of  the  influ- 
ence of  the  atmosphere  in  which  he  moves  and 
has  moved  all  his  life.  The  correction  of  eco- 
nomic doctrine  by  later  students  has  made  the 
main  theory  enunciated  at  once  more  accurate 
and  comprehensive,  and  less  easy  of  practical 
application.  Political  power  has  passed  to 
classes  who  do  not  read  political  economy,  and 
politicians  do  not  think  it  prudent  to  quote 
economists.  But  political  economy  may  regain 
its  former  influence  when  it  is  more  generally 
studied  and  its  lessons  are  enforced  by  the 
stem  teaching  of  actual  experience.      f.  g.  m. 

EMPLOYERS  AND  EMPLOYED.  During 
recent  years  economic  writers  have  been  bring- 
ing into  greater  prominence  the  functions  of 
the  employer  in  industrial  aflairs.  The  older 
English  economists  regarded  the  agents  con- 
cerned in  the  production  of  wealth  as  three  in 
number,  viz.  land,  labour,  and  capital ;  and 
in  a  similar  way  they  considered  that  the 
classes  concerned  in  the  distribution  of  wealth 
were  three  in  number  also,  viz.  landlords, 
labourers,  and  capitalists.  The  landlord  received 
rent,  the  labourer  wages,  and  the  capitalist 
profits.  They  analysed  indeed  the  share  of  the 
capitalist  or  Profits  into  the  constituent  ele- 
ments of  interest  on  capital,  insurance  against 
risk,  and  wages  of  superintendence  or  manage- 


ment ;  but  they  did  not  apparently  establish 
any  distinct  conception  in  their  own  minds — 
nor  did  they  endeavour  to  instil  any  such  con- 
ception into  the  minds  of  their  readers— of  the 
employer  as  separate  from  the  capitalist.  And  it 
was  natural  that  they  should  adopt  this  position; 
for  it  is  only  with  the  modern  development  of 
the  Banking  and  Bill-Broking  system,  which 
permits  of  the  systematic  lending  of  capital  by 
one  man,  or  body  of  men,  to  another,  and  only 
also  with  the  modern  growth  of  large  indus- 
tries (see  Large  and  Small  Trade)  that  the 
functicns  of  the  employer  have  acquired  a 
marked  and  separate  importance  of  their  own. 
Under  the  Domestic  System  of  Industry, 
which  previously  prevailed,  manufacture  was 
carried  on  mainly  in  the  houses  of  craftsmen, 
who  were  generally  employers  on  a  small  scale, 
working  for  the  most  part  for  a  market  near  at 
hand,  the  conditions  of  which  varied  but  little, 
and  supplying  in  the  main  from  their  own 
resources  the  capital  needed  for  conducting 
their  business.  But,  with  the  changes  conse- 
quent on  the  Industrial  Kevolution  at 
the  close  of  the  18th  and  the  opening  of  the 
19th  century,  manufacturing  industry  passed 
from  villages  to  towns,  and  from  the  house  of 
the  craftsman  to  the  factory  of  the  employer. 
The  functions  of  the  employer  as  such  became 
important ;  for  he  had  to  anticipate  the  fluctu- 
ating demands  of  a  world-wide  market,  and  to 
direct  the  operations  of  a  multitude  of  workmen 
who  were  engaged  under  an  organised  system 
of  minute  Division  of  Labour  on  small 
portions  of  work,  all  of  which  were  necessary 
to,  and  formed  part  of,  a  complete  manufacture. 
He  now  acquired  also  to  some  extent  a  separate 
character  from  that  of  the  capitalist ;  for, 
although  he  generally  possessed  some  capital  of 
his  own,  he  could,  through  the  agency  of 
bankers  and  others,  obtain  the  loan  of  further 
capital  from  those  who  did  not  wish  to  enter 
on  active  business  for  themselves,  but  were 
glad  to  receive  interest  for  the  use  of  their 
surplus  wealth.  And  hence  at  the  present 
time,  while  it  is  recognised  that  the  functions 
of  the  employer  and  of  the  capitalist  are  to 
some  extent  as  a  general  rule  combined  in  one 
person,  and  while  it  is  still  held  by  most  writers 
that  the  term  profits  should  be  understood  as 
including  interest  on  capital  as  well  as  wages 
or  earnings  of  superintendence  or  management, 
it  is  also  considered  that  an  adequate  classifica- 
tion of  those  among  whom  the  wealth  produced 
in  a  country  is  distributed  should  assign  a 
distinct  place  to  employers  as  such,  and  by 
some  writers  it  is  urged  that  the  term  **  profits  " 
should  be  confined  to  that  part  of  the  employer's 
receipts  which  belong  to  him  as  such,  that 
is,  to  his  earnings  or  wages  of  management  or 
superintendence,  and  should  not  be  extended  to 
the  interest  which  he  obtains  as  a  capitalist  for 
himself,  or  hands  over  to  some  one  else  from 


EMPLOYERS  AND  EMPLOYED 


705 


whom  he  has  procured  a  loan.  This  last  view 
is  held,  amongst  others,  by  the  American  econo- 
mist, General  F.  A.  Walker,  who,  together  with 
Bagehot  in  England,  has  been  specially  instru- 
mental in  bringing  the  importance  and  distinc- 
tive character  of  the  functions  of  the  employer 
into  due  prominence.  He  has  even  adopted 
{Political  Economy,  pt.  iv.  ch.  iv.)  a  theory 
which  regards  the  profits  of  the  employer,  using 
the  term  profits  in  this  narrow  sense,  as  being 
of  the  nature  of  Rent,  and  depending  for 
amount  on  the  natural  ability  possessed,  and 
the  opportunity  enjoyed,  by  different  employers, 
in  the  same  way  as  the  economic  rent  of  land 
depends  on  its  fertility  and  situation.  But 
among  English  writers,  at  any  rate,  the  term 
profits  is  generally  employed  in  the  wider  sense  ; 
although  there  is  a  growing  tendency  to  regard 
that  part  of  them  which  represents  earnings  or 
wages  of  management  or  superintendence,  as 
governed  by  similar  laws  to  those  which  deter- 
mine the  earnings  of  labour  generally. 

The  employer's  labour,  it  is  held,  is  labour  of 
a  high,  and  indeed  of  a  special  class,  but  it  is 
none  the  less  labour,  and  it  must  not  be  con- 
founded in  any  way  with  interest  on  capital 
(see  Earnings  and  Interest  Fund).  Bagehot 
has  compared  {Economic  Studies,  pp.  53,  etc.) 
the  modern  employer  to  the  editor  of  a  news- 
paper, or  the  general  of  an  army,  and  has 
remarked  in  a  striking  passage  that  just  as  the 
general  of  an  army  is  "  nowadays  a  man  at  the 
far  end  of  a  telegraph — a  Count  Moltke  with 
his  head  over  some  papers — who  sees  that  the 
proper  persons  are  slain,  and  who  secures  the 
victory,"  so  in  commerce  the  "whole"  is  now 
"an  affair  of  money  and  management — of  a 
thinking  man  in  a  dark  office  comj)uting  the 
prices  of  guns  or  worsteds."  The  employer 
"  settles  what  goods  shall  be  made,  and  what 
not ;  what  brought  to  market,  and  what  not. 
He  is  the  general  of  the  army  ;  he  fixes  on  the 
plan  of  operations,  organises  its  means,  and 
superintends  its  execution.  If  he  does  this 
well,  the  business  succeeds  and  continues  ;  if 
he  does  it  ill,  the  business  fails  and  ceases. 
Everything  depends  on  the  correctness  of  the 
unseen  decisions,  on  the  secret  sagacity  of  the 
determining  mind."  In  a  similar  way  General 
Walker  (  Wages  Question,  ch.  xiv. ),  after  remark- 
ing that  the  conditions  of  admission  to  the 
employing  class  are  a  "long  self-initiation,  a 
high  premium  of  immediate  loss,  and  a  great 
degree  of  uncertainty  as  to  ultimate  success," 
quotes  from  M.  Courcelle-Seneuil's  Operations 
de  Banque  (p.  392)  an  enumeration  of  the 
qualities  which  an  employer  should  possess. 
They  are  "du  jugement,  du  bon  sens,  de  la 
fermete,  de  la  decision,  une  appreciation  froide 
et  calme,  une  intelligence  ouverte  et  vigilante, 
pen  d'imagination,  beaucoup  de  memoire  et 
d'application  "  (judgment,  good  sense,  firmness, 
decision,  a  calm  and  cool  temper,  an  open  and 
VOL.  1. 


alert  mind,  little  power  of  imagination,  great 
power  of  memory  and  of  application).  Professor 
and  Mrs.  Marshall  {Economics  of  Industry,  bk.  iii. 
ch.  ix.  §  4,  old  edition)  regard  the  work  of  the 
employer  as  consisting  of  two  main  varieties. 
' '  The  first  is  that  of  organising  the  production  ; 
of  determining  what  shall  be  made,  and  how  it 
shall  be  made  ;  and  of  deciding  where  and 
when  to  buy  and  sell.  We  may,"  they  remark, 
"  adopt  an  American  term  and  call  this  engineer- 
ing the  business.  The  second  part  of  his  work, 
which  may  be  called  that  of  superintendence, 
consists  in  providing  for  the  proper  carrying 
out  of  his  instructions."  As  the  size  of  the 
business  increases,  the  employer  tends  more 
and  more  to  depute  the  duties  of  superintend- 
ence to  subordinate  managers  and  foremen,  and 
to  concentrate  his  own  thought  and  attention 
on  the  engineering  of  the  business.  To  some 
extent  he  becomes,  as  Bagehot  has  aptly  ex- 
pressed it  {Economic  Studies,  p.  59),  like  a 
cabinet  minister,  who  may  be  shifted  from 
one  department  of  state  to  another  in  successful 
reliance  on  the  specialised  knowledge  of  the 
subordinate  permanent  officials.  He  ceases 
indeed  to  be  personally  acquainted  with  his 
actual  workmen,  but  he  is  able  to  bring  his 
ability  and  experience  to  bear  more  exchisively 
on  the  work  of  management.  ' '  The  highest 
class  of  employers,"  writes  General  Walker 
{Political  Economy,  pt.  iv.  ch.  iv.)  consists  of 
those  "rarely-gifted  persons  who,  in  common 
phrase,  seem  to  turn  everything  they  touch 
into  gold  ;  whose  commercial  dealings  have  the 
air  of  magic  ;  who  have  such  power  of  insight 
as  almost  to  seem  to  have  the  power  of  fore- 
sight ;  who  are  so  resolute  and  firm  in  temper 
that  apprehensions  and  alarms,  and  repeated 
shocks  of  disaster,  never  cause  them  to  relax 
their  hold  or  change  their  course  ;  who  have 
such  command  over  men  that  all  with  whom 
they  have  to  do  acquire  vigour  from  the  contact, 
and  work  for  them  as  they  would  not,  jierhaps 
could  not,  work  for  others,  just  as  great 
captains  (see  Industry,  Captains  of)  inspire 
their  armies  with  a  confidence  which  alone 
goes  far  to  make  them  invincible."  Below 
these  men  come  a  "much  larger"  class  of  a 
"high  order  of  talent,  though  without  genius 
or  anything  savouring  of  magic" — "men  of 
natural  mastery,  sagacious,  prompt,  and  resolute 
in  their  "avocations."  Then  come  the  "men 
who,  on  the  whole,  do  well,  or  pretty  well,  in 
business  ; "  and  lower  down  come  a  "  multitude 
of  men  who  are  found  in  the  control  of  business 
enterprises  for  no  very  good  reason  that  can  be 
seen  by  those  who  know  them."  The  passages 
which  have  been  quoted  will  sufficiently  indi- 
cate the  nature  of  the  work  and  qualities 
required  of  a  modern  employer,  and  will  explain 
the  high  remuneration  which  he  often  com- 
mands. The  average  earnings,  indeed,  of 
employers  seem  now  to  be  falling,  with  the 

2  z 


706 


EMPLOYERS  AND  EMPLOYED— EMPLOYERS'  LIABILITY  ACT 


general  diffusion  of  education  and  the  rapid 
spread  of  inventive  discovery.  But  the  modem 
world  of  business  offers  greater  opportunities  for 
exceptional  talent  and  extraordinary  luck  than 
have  perhaps  ever  before  been  afforded  ;  and 
tbe  amount  of  capital  and  of  labour  plaoed  at 
the  disposal  of  a  single  employer  is  frequently 
very  considerable.  The  employer  is  in  a^  sense 
the  pivot  on  which  the  modem  world  of  indus- 
try revolves,  and  the  distinctive  prominence 
into  which  he  has  been  brought  in  more  recent 
economic  literature  has  conduced  to  greater 
definiteness  in  questions  of  distribution  gener- 
ally, and  in  particular  in  the  consideration  of 
three  matters  of  the  first  importance.  The 
conception  that  a  conflict  between  labour  and 
capital  is  involved  in  the  relations  of  employers 
to  employed  is  shown  to  be  somewhat  mislead- 
ing ;  for  the  employer  is  in  a  sense  a  labourer 
as  well  as  the  employed,  and  h6  often  does  not 
furnish  himself  the  whole  of  the  capital  which 
he  uses.  It  may  even  be  supplied  by  indi- 
viduals who  are  themselves  employed  in  his 
own  or  in  other  trades.  The  employer  is  in 
reality  a  middleman,  a  kind  of  "buffer"  inter- 
vening between  one  set  of  individuals  and 
another ;  and,  while  he  may  have  to  bear  the 
first  brunt  of  the  conflict,  he  may  also  shift 
part  of  the  burden  on  to  others.  The  conflict 
is  not  then  entirely,  though  it  may  be  partly, 
between  labom-  and  capital ;  but  it  is  in  some 
degree  between  one  class  of  labourers  and 
another,  who  are  both  interested  in  obtaining 
the  supply  of  capital  on  advantageous  terms, 
and  are  on  the  other  hand  respectively  anxious 
to  secure  for  themselves  the  larger  share  of  the 
produce  remaining  when  the  claims  of  capital 
have  been  met.  Another  question,  on  which 
considerable  light  is  thrown  by  the  modern 
analyses  of  distribution,  is  the  question  of 
co-operative  production  (see  Co-operation). 
This  has  sometimes  been  represented  as  a 
question  of  combining  the  functions  of  capital 
and  labour  in  the  persons  of  the  same  indi- 
viduals ;  but  in  reality,  as  General  Walker  has 
shown  (Wages  Question,  ch.  xv.),  it  involves 
the  elimination  of  the  employer.  The  work- 
men wish  to  take  the  responsibilities  of  manage- 
ment upon  themselves,  and  to  secure  for  their 
own  benefit  the  profits  of  the  employer.  They 
are  unable  to  dispense  with  capital,  even  if 
they  entertain  such  a  wish  ;  and  they  may 
acquire  capital,  and  become  capitalists,  without 
co-operative  production.  But  the  object,  at 
which  they  really  aim,  is  more  difficult,  for  the 
functions  of  the  employer  are  very  important, 
and  they  are  making  an  attempt  to  undertake 
them  themselves.  A  third  and  last  question, 
which  is  affected  by  the  distinctive  importance 
of  these  functions,  is  that  of  Socialism  (q.v.) 
Modern  socialist  writers  represent  the  products 
of  manufacture  as  due  entirely  to  the  labour  of 
the  actual  workmen,  and  therefore  as  belonging 


of  right  to  them.  They  regard  the  employer 
as  an  exploiter  and  robber  of  labour,  and  they 
consider  profits  as  the  outcome  of  the  surplus 
value  (cp.  Value)  of  what  the  labourer  produces 
over  what  is  required  for  his  subsistence.  This 
theory  of  surplus  value  is  fallacious  in  other 
respects  ;  but  part  of  its  error  may  be  traced  to 
a  failure  to  distinguish  the  functions  of  the 
employer  as  such  from  those  of  the  capitalist  as 
such,  and  to  separate  that  portion  of  profits 
which  forms  the  reward  or  earnings  of  the 
difficult  work  of  management  from  that  which 
is  simply  and  solely  interest  on  capital. 

[In  addition  to  the  books  mentioned  above  the 
student  should  consult  J.  S.  Mill,  Political  Econ- 
omy, bk.  ii.  ch.  XV.  for  the  older  definition  of 
profits,  and  the  Boston  Quarterly  Journal  of  Econo- 
mics for  1888  and  1893  for  the  controversy  raised 
by  General  Walker's  Tlieory  of  Business  Profits. 
Reference  should  be  made  to  Marshall's  Principles 
of  Economics,  bk.  iv.  ch.  xii.,  bk.  vi.  chs.  vii.  and 
viii.,  and  Sidgwick's  Political  Economy,  bk.  ii. 
chs.  i.  and  viii.,  for  the  disposition  to  regard  the 
labour  of  employers  as  subject  to  the  laws  affect- 
ing labour  generally.  For  the  tendency  to  a  fall 
in  average  profits  Leroy-Beaulieu's  "  Essai  sur  la 
repartition  des  richesses,  ch.  xi.  and  the  Report  of 
the  Industrial  Remuneration  Conference,  1887, 
pp.  4,  etc.  and  186,  etc.,  should  be  studied. 
Pierstorff,  UntemehmergeTmnn. — H.  v.  Mangoldt, 
Die  Lehre  vom  Unternehmergeunnn. — Loria,  La 
rendita  fondiaria  e  la  sua  elisione  naturale  (see 
also  Entrepreneur).  ]  l.  l.  p. 

EMPLOYERS'  LIABILITY  ACT,  1880, 
43  &  44  Vict.  c.  42,  extends  and  regulates  the 
liability  of  employers  to  make  compensation 
for  personal  injuries  suff"ered  by  workmen  in 
their  service.  At  common  law  the  liability 
of  an  employer  differed  with  respect  to 
persons  in  his  employment,  from  that  with 
respect  to  persons  not  in  his  employment  (see 
Common  Employment,  Doctrine  of).  He 
was  not  liable  to  his  servants  for  the  conse- 
quences of  acts  done  by  fellow-servants  in  the 
course  of  their  service.  He  was,  however, 
liable  to  them  for  injuries  resulting  from  the 
negligence  of  himself  or  his  partner.  Thus  he 
was  bound  to  take  reasonable  care  that  his 
plant  and  machinery  were  in  a  safe  condition, 
and  that  servants  selected  by  him  were  com- 
petent to  their  work.  But  his  liability  to 
persons  not  in  his  service  was  far  more  exten- 
sive. He  was  liable  for  injuries  caused  to 
them  by  his  servants,  even  when  he  had  not 
been  guilty  of  any  negligence,  even  when 
he  had  expressly  forbidden  the  act  producing 
injurious  consequences.  The  difference  of  the 
employer's  liability  towards  his  servants  and 
towards  the  public  might  conceivably  be  justi- 
fied by  the  fact  that  the  public  has  no  choice 
as  to  incurring  the  danger  which  may  result 
from  his  undertaking,  whilst  a  workman  can 
choose  whether  or  no  he  will  take  service  with 
any  particular  employer.     But  the  distinction 


EMPLOYING  CLASS— EMPLOYMENT 


707 


came  to  be  more  oppressively  felt  as  industry 
was  more  and  more  concentrated  in  huge  con- 
cerns, such  as  railways  and  factories,  where 
the  range  of  choice  between  employers  is  limited, 
and  service  involves  co-operation  with  a  multi- 
tude of  other  "hands"  about  whose  individual 
care  or  dexterity  nobody  can  learn  much.  The 
influence  of  the  working  class  was  exerted  to 
obtain  a  modification  of  the  common  law,  and 
the  Employers'  Liability  Act  embodies  a  com- 
promise on  the  subject.  It  provides  that  in 
five  specified  cases  the  workman  who  has  sus- 
tained injury  through  the  action  of  a  fellow- 
workman  may  bring  an  action  for  redress  as 
though  he  were  not  in  the  same  employment. 
Where  the  injury  arises  from  (1)  any  defect  in 
the  works,  plant,  or  machinery  ;  (2)  the  neglect 
of  any  person  superintending  ;  (3)  the  neglect 
of  any  person  whose  orders  the  workman  was 
bound  to  obey  when  the  injury  took  place  ;  (4) 
the  act  of  any  fellow-servant  done  in  obedience 
to  the  rules,  by-laws,  or  instructions  (if  improper 
or  defective)  of  the  employer  or  his  delegate  ; 
(5)  the  negligence  of  any  signalman,  pointsman, 
or  person  having  charge  of  a  locomotive  on  a 
railway,  the  workman  is  put  on  the  same  footing 
with  the  public.  The  act  excluded  seamen, 
domestic  servants,  and  any  servant  not  employed 
in  manual  labour.  Notice  of  an  injury  had  to 
be  given,  and  the  action  brought  within  a  limited 
time,  and  the  amount  of  the  compensation  did 
not  exceed  three  years'  earnings.  If  the  injury 
proved  fatal,  the  right  of  action  passed  to  the 
dead  man's  representative.  A  new  principle 
with  regard  to  Employers'  Liability  was  intro- 
duced by  the  Workmen's  Compensation  Act, 
1897,  by  which,  in  certain  employments,  work- 
men had  the  right  to  compensation  for  all  injuries 
received  while  in  the  performance  of  their  duties 
entirely  irrespective  of  negligence.  The  Work- 
men's Compensation  Act,  1906,  extended  this 
right  to  all  persons  in  service  including  seamen, 
but  excluding  the  naval,  military,  and  police 
services,  persons  earning  more  than  £250  a 
year,  casual  labourers,  etc.  The  conditions  of 
claim  are  (1)  personal  injury  by  accident, — 
wilful  injury  excluded  except  when  resulting  in 
death  or  permanent  disablement,  but  including 
death  or  disablement  from  industrial  diseases  ; 
(2)  the  accident  must  arise  from  and  during 
employment ;  (3)  the  period  of  complete  dis- 
ablement must  be  at  least  one  week  ;  (4)  notice 
of  the  accident  must  be  given  as  soon  as  practic- 
able ;  (5)  medical  examination  is  required.  The 
serious  and  wilful  misconduct  of  the  workman 
forfeits  all  claim. 

[See  Workmen's  Compensation  Act,  1906, 
6  Edw.  7,  ch.  58.  For  the  previous  state  of 
the  law  see  Macdonell,  The  Law  of  Master  and 
Servant.  For  a  discussion  of  the  principles 
involved,  see  Sir  Frederick  Pollock,  Essays  on 
Jurisprudence  and  Ethics  (essay  v.,  "  Employers' 
Liability '').] 


EMPLOYING  CLASS.  General  F.  A. 
Walker,  who  has  contributed  greatly  to  bring 
into  due  prominence  the  functions  discharged 
by  the  employer  (see  Employers  and  Em- 
ployed) in  the  modern  world  of  industry, 
draws  a  distinction  {Wages  Question,  ch.  xiv.) 
between  what  he  calls  a  "false  employing 
class"  and  the  "real  employing  class,"  to 
the  latter  of  which  alone  these  functions  in  his 
opinion  properly  belong.  The  "  false  employ- 
ing class "  includes,  in  the  first  place,  those 
who  hire  servants  who  help  their  employers 
rather  to  consume  the  wealth  they  have  previ- 
ously produced  than  to  produce  fresh  wealth. 
In  the  second  place  it  includes  artisans  who 
are  employers  on  so  small  a  scale  that  they 
have  only  single  apprentices  ;  and  in  the  third 
place  it  comprises  those  who  are  nominally 
employers,  but  practically  are  partners  of  the 
employed  ;  and,  fourthly  and  lastly,  it  contains 
those  who  "cling  to  the  skirts"  of  the  profes- 
sion. The  "real  employing  class,"  therefore, 
is  the  "comparatively  small  body  of  men" 
which  is  reached  by  eliminating  these  various 
kinds  of  "  false  "  employers.  l.  l.  p. 

EMPLOYMENT.  The  number  of  persons 
employed  in  the  performance  of  labour  in  a 
country  obviously  cannot  exceed  the  number  of 
persons  capable  of  labour  existing  in  the  country, 
and,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  it  is  never  for  any  length 
of  time  very  much  below  this  number  ;  in  all 
countries  the  able-bodied  unemployed,  includ- 
ing not  only  the  men  "out  of  work,"  but  all 
others  who  from  whatever  cause  are  not  engaged 
in  labour,  are  but  a  minute  fraction  of  the  whole 
able-bodied  population.  This  is  sufficient  to 
show  that,  broadly  speaking,  the  number  of 
persons  employed  is  regulated  in  the  main  by 
the  number  of  persons  seeking  employment,  or 
in  other  words,  desirous  of  earning  a  livelihood 
by  labour.  In  a  small  community,  say  of  ten 
or  twelve  persons,  living  in  entire  isolation  from 
their  fellows,  every  one  would  find  it  easy 
enough  to  obtain  employment,  though  he  might 
find  that  a  great  deal  of  employment  produced 
very  little  food.  In  a  great  community  where 
co-operation  in  the  production  of  wealth  is 
eff'ected  by  means  of  exchange,  the  fact  that 
there  is  always  a  certain  small  proportion  of 
persons  seeking  employment  who  are  unable  to 
find  it  is  chiefly  due  to  the  circumstance  that, 
owing  to  the  division  of  employments,  every 
kind  of  production  comes  to  be  carried  on  by 
people  who  have  by  training  and  experience 
acquired  particular  skill  in  that  kind  of  pro- 
duction, so  that  when  the  demand  for  any  one 
commodity  slackens  and  the  number  of  those 
who  produce  it  has  to  be  reduced,  or  at  any  rate 
not  increased  at  its  normal  rate,  the  persona 
deprived  of  this  employment  are  not 
mediately  absorbed  in  other  employments 

[Marshall,  Elements  of  Economics  of  IM^ry, 
pp.  368,  369.] 

■^LIBRARY 


^^S^' 


708 


EMPLOYMENT— EMULATION 


EMPLOYMENT  OF  WOMEN  AND 
CHILDREN  IN  AGRICULTURE.  See  Fe- 
male Labour. 

EMPLOYMENTS.     See  articles  on  Laboub. 

EMPTION.  The  right  of  the  crown,  exer- 
cised from  time  immemorial,  to  take  arid  buy 
"at  its  need"  or  "for  its  use"  an  indefinite 
amount  of  commodities,  at  such  price  or  on  such 
terms  of  payment  as  the  circumstances  of  the 
cage  might  warrant.  It  was  claimed  by  Edward 
I.  in  1297  that  the  king  was  "free  to  buy  and 
sell  like  another  "  ;  the  advantage  to  the  crown 
being  that  such  purchases  were  paid  for  by 
tallies,  and  the  amount  of  the  maltolte  de- 
ducted from  the  purchase-money  (see  Mala- 
tolta).  Hall,  History  of  Custom  Revenue, 
vol.  i.  pp.  62,  64  ;  (see  also  Preemption  and 
Purveyance).  h.  na. 

EMPTIO-VENDITIO.  The  Roman  contract 
of  sale,  or  of  buying  and  selling  as  it  is  called 
in  order  to  denote  its  bilateral  character,  is 
formed  by  one  contracting  party  promising  to 
pay  a  sum  of  money  or  price  (jpretium),  and  the 
other  party  promising  to  deliver  a  thing  (vurx) 
in  return.  The  contract  is  binding  by  mere 
agreement  between  the  parties,  neither  requir- 
ing any  formality  nor  delivery  on  one  side,  and 
30  belonging  to  the  class  of  contracts  called  con- 
sensual. Arrha  (see  Arles  ;  Earnest  Money), 
a  sum  of  money  or  other  object  of  value  fre- 
quently given  by  a  contracting  party  to  afford 
evidence  of  the  contract,  and  a  security  for  its 
fulfilment,  is  not  a  requisite  of  the  contract  itself. 
There  can  be  no  contract  of  emptio-venditio  un- 
less a  determinate  price,  or  a  price  which  can  be 
made  so  {id  certum  est  quod  certum  reddi  potest), 
is  made  part  of  the  agreement.  It  was  at  one 
time  a  subject  of  dispute  whether  the  price  must 
necessarily  be  in  money  ;  thus  the  Sabinian 
school  of  jurists  maintained  that  exchange  was 
a  species,  and  the  oldest  species,  of  sale,  citing 
in  support  of  their  view  the  lines  of  Homer — 
"  Here  touched  Achaean  barks  in  quest  of  wine. 

They  purchased  it  with  copper  and  with  steel, 

With  hides,  with  horned  cattle,  and  with  slaves." 
(Poste's  G?atw5,  III.  §  141.) 
But  the  view  prevailed  that  sale  was  a  contract 
distinguished  from  barter  or  exchange  by  the 
fact  that  it  had  for  its  object  the  payment  of 
a  sum  of  money  for  a  thing. 

When  the  contract  of  emptio-venditio  is  com- 
plete the  vendor  is  bound  to  deliver  the  thing 
to  the  purchaser  and  the  purchaser  to  pay  the 
price  of  the  thing,  but  one  party  cannot  be 
compelled  to  perform  his  part  if  the  other  will 
not  perform  on  his  side.  The  obligation  of 
the  vendor  is  not  to  make  the  purchaser  owner 
of  the  thing,  but  only  to  give  him  possession 
of  it.  If,  however,  the  purchaser  is  evicted  by 
a  third  party  who  has  a  superior  title,  the 
vendor  is  obliged  to  make  good  to  him  the  loss. 
Ownership  of  the  thing  does  not  pass  to  the 
purchaser  until  possession  of  it  has  been  de- 


livered to  him  and  he  has  paid  the  price,  if  it 
is  a  ready-money  transaction.  But  though  the 
property  has  not  passed  to  the  purchaser,  he  is 
subject  to  the  risk  (joericuluvi)  of  its  accidental 
loss,  i.e.  of  loss  which  cannot  be  attributed  to 
the  negligence  of  the  vendor  from  the  time  of 
entering  into  the  contract  [respuit  emptori). 
This  rule  is  only  applicable  where  there  is  a 
specific  object  appropriated  to  the  contract.  If 
the  thing  is  determined  only  by  its  genus  or 
kind,  the  risk  does  not  attach  to  the  purchaser 
until  the  thing  has  been  weighed,  measured,  or 
counted,  and  the  purchaser  has  had  notice  of 
this  having  been  done.  The  purchaser,  on  the 
other  hand,  could  claim  all  accessions  and 
profits  of  the  thing  bought  arising  between  the 
making  of  the  contract  and  the  date  of  delivery. 

The  vendor  is  liable  on  account  of  defects  in 
the  thing  sold,  not  only  when  he  represents 
that  they  are  absent,  or  fraudulently  conceals 
their  existence,  but,  according  to  the  law  estab- 
lished by  the  edict  of  the  curule  ^diles,  who 
had  jurisdiction  over  the  market,  even  on 
account  of  latent  defects  of  the  existence  of 
which  he  was  unaware.  Thus  in  the  Roman 
contract  of  sale  there  is  an  implied  warranty 
that  the  thing  sold  is  free  from  defects.  Such, 
in  brief  outline,  are  the  main  features  of  the 
contract  of  emptio-venditio,  with  which  those 
of  the  English  contract  of  sale  of  goods  may  be 
usefully  compared.  e.  a.  w. 

EMIJLATION,  Effects  of,  on  Society. 
The  feeling  of  emulation  may  be  defined  as  the 
desire  to  excel  one's  fellow  -  creatures  in  any 
respect  whatsoever.  It  thus  admits  of  infinite 
variations,  produces  the  most  dissimilar  conse- 
quences, and  gives  rise  to  the  most  contradictory 
judgments.  At  its  best  the  spirit  of  emulation 
is  hardly  distinguishable  from  the  desire  to 
achieve  greatness  or  perfection,  at  its  worst  the 
spirit  of  emulation  is  hardly  distinguishable 
from  envy  and  uncharitableness.  It  is,  however, 
an  indestructible  instinct,  which  maybe  schooled 
but  cannot  be  extirpated,  and  which  is  most 
powerful  in  the  most  vigorous  natures.  Further, 
it  prompts  to  unceasing  effort  because  it  is 
insatiable.  The  plain  animal  appetites  may 
be  sated  ;  but  emulation  incessantly  creates 
anew  its  object  of  desire,  and,  the  more  it  has 
accomplished,  finds  the  more  to  be  done.  Next 
to  the  instinct  of  self-preservation  and  the 
instinct  of  sex,  the  instinct  of  emulation  has 
probably  had  greater  effects  than  any  other 
upon  the  economic  history  of  mankind.  We 
may  consider  its  effects  shortly  under  three 
heads  :  (1)  Emulation  in  accumulating  wealth, 
(2)  Emulation  in  expending  wealth,  (3)  Emula- 
tion in  other  directions. 

(1)  Emulation  in  accumulating  wealth.  The 
desire  to  be  richer  than  one's  neighbour,  to 
excel  him  in  the  power  and  consideration  given 
by  wealth,  has  been  a  prime  factor  in  accumula- 
tion.    Its  force  has  varied  chiefly  with   two 


EMULATION— ENCLOSURES 


709 


I 


circumstances :  with  the  degree  of  desire  for 
wealth  characterising  any  given  society,  and 
with  the  proportion  of  persons  who  have  had  a 
chance  of  acquiring  riches.  As  to  the  former 
circumstance,  societies  have  differed  consider- 
ably in  the  value  which  they  assign  to  wealth 
in  comparison  with  the  other  goods  of  life. 
The  causes  of  this  difference  are  too  many  and 
too  subtle  to  be  enumerated  here  ;  but  among 
the  most  influential  are  different  moral  and 
religious  ideals,  different  stages  of  political 
development,  different  degrees  of  command 
over  the  resources  of  nature.  As  to  the  latter 
circumstance — the  proportion  of  persons  who 
can  indulge  a  spirit  of  emulation  in  the  pursuit 
of  riches  is  exceedingly  variable.  In  many 
societies  a  small  proportion  has  been  above,  and 
a  large  part  has  been  below,  any  active  emula- 
tion in  wealth.  Sometimes  a  class  of  nobles 
has  owed  its  pre-eminence  rather  to  birth  and  to 
military  prowess  than  to  riches,  and  has  there- 
fore been  less  emulous  of  riches.  Often  a  class 
of  slaves  who  were  legally  incompetent  to  hold 
property,  or  of  serfs  who  were  not  adequately 
protected  by  law  in  the  enjoyment  of  their 
property,  or  a  class  of  underpaid  free  labourers 
who  could  barely  earn  their  daily  bread  and 
nothing  more,  has  found  it  difficult  or  im- 
possible to  rise  into  a  more  comfortable  condi- 
tion, still  more  to  compete  in  a  rivalry  of  riches. 
In  such  a  case  the  spirit  of  emulation  dies  out, 
because  not  fed  with  hope.  These  remarks 
might  be  illustrated  from  the  history  of  mediaeval 
Europe,  in  which  the  emulation  of  riches  ap- 
pears as  a  great  force  only  in  certain  classes  and 
in  certain  places.  But  in  such  communities  as 
our  colonies  and  the  United  States  of  America, 
in  which  material  well-being  is  the  accepted 
ideal,  in  which  every  citizen  has  hopes  of  realis- 
ing this  ideal,  and  in  which  the  command  over 
natural  resources  is  almost  unbounded,  the 
emulation  of  wealth  becomes  a  passion  as  uni- 
versal as  it  is  intense,  and  impels  to  an  amazing 
economic  development. 

It  is  conceivable,  indeed,  that  emulation  in 
the  pursuit  of  wealth  might  become  so  intense 
as  to  lessen,  not  to  augment,  the  wealth  of 
society.  Thus  a  community  of  men  so  zealous 
in  the  pursuit  of  wealth  that  they  grudged 
time,  trouble,  and  money  for  national  defence,  or 
for  alleviating  social  evils,  might  end  in  sub- 
jection to  a  foreign  power  or  in  mere  anarchy  ; 
and  would  in  either  case  be  reduced  to  com- 
parative poverty.  The  same  result  might 
foUow  if  emulation  in  the  pursuit  of  riches  led 
to  a  universal  disregard  of  commercial  integrity 
or  to  a  neglect  of  all  liberal  culture.  For  there 
is  no  instinct  which,  if  left  to  itself,  will  not 
sometimes  defeat  itself. 

(2)  Emulation  in  expending  wealth  must  be 
taken  to  mean  emulation  in  expenditure  which 
is  not  directly  productive.  The  immediate 
result  of  such  emulation  is  to  lessen  wealth. 


Its  ultimate  result  will  depend  on  many  con- 
siderations. Thus  the  wealthy  citizens  ol 
Rome  rivalled  each  other  in  expenditure  on 
public  works  intended  for  the  health  and 
recreation  of  the  public  ;  the  burghers  of 
mediaeval  Europe  in  building  and  endowing 
churches  ;  the  nobles  of  France  in  display  at 
Versailles.  Clearly  each  of  these  modes  of 
emulation  in  expense  differed  from  the  rest  in 
its  ultimate  economic  effects,  although  each 
was  in  the  first  instance  non-productive.  Again, 
emulation  in  expense  has  different  economic 
results  accordingly  as  it  is  the  emulation  of  a 
productive  or  of  a  non-productive  class.  The 
courtier  of  Versailles,  when  he  had  squandered 
his  fortune,  remained  poor  or  had  to  squeeze 
his  dependents.  The  American,  when  he  has 
spent  lavishly  in  Europe,  goes  back  to  his 
country  and  works  yet  harder  to  make  another 
fortune. 

(3)  Emulation  in  other  directions.  Every 
form  of  emulation  soon  or  late  produces  economic 
consequences.  In  all  ages  wealth  has  followed 
power,  and  has  been  kept  by  strength.  Few 
nations  have  got  wealth  and  none  have  kept  it 
unless  there  was  an  emulation  of  public  spirit 
and  military  vu'tue  among  their  citizens.  In- 
tellectual emulation,  emulation  in  knowledge  and 
culture,  has  always  stimulated  economic  and  in- 
dustrial development,  and  often  most  effectually 
when  it  has  been  most  free  from  sordid  motives. 
Thus  the  wealth  of  modern  Germany  is  directly 
due  to  the  intelligence  of  the  age  of  Goethe  and 
the  public  virtue  of  the  age  of  Bismarck.  Again, 
the  economic  condition  of  the  later  Roman 
empire  and  of  the  middle  ages  must  have  been 
considerably  affected  by  the  emulation  of  ascetic 
piety  which  withdrew  so  many  of  the  strongest 
wills  and  keenest  intellects  from  the  world  to 
the  cloister.  The  immediate  result  was  an 
economic  loss,  although  this  may  have  been 
partially  countervailed  by  the  civilising  influ- 
ence of  many  monastic  bodies.  Even  emulation 
in  mere  sjJorts  and  pastimes  would  be  found  to 
influence  occasionally  the  economic  state  of 
society.  f.  c.  m. 

ENCABEZAMIENTO,  a  contract  between 
the  Spanish  treasury  and  the  local  authorities, 
by  which,  after  a  preliminary  estimate  of  the 
taxes  to  be  levied,  the  latter  engaged  to  collect 
and  remit  the  amount.  The  first  known 
encabezamiento  goes  back  to  1494.  e,  ca. 

ENCLOSURES.  Of  "enclosing,"  i.e.  the 
fencing  round  of  land  which  had  previously 
lain  open,  whether  as  common  field  or  as 
common  waste,  we  hear  but  little  before  the 
13th  century,  when  the  necessity  for  statutory 
regulation  points  to  the  existence  of  the  custom 
and  of  differences  between  the  lords  of  manors 
and  their  tenants.  About  the  origin  of  those 
conmion  rights  of  pasture  which  play  so  im- 
portant a  part  in  the  history  of  enclosures, 
there  has  been  much  controversy  ;  but  there  is 


710 


ENCLOSURES 


an  increasing  consensus  of  opinion  as  to  the 
main  legal  points.  Although  in  strict  feudal 
theory  the  laud  belonged  to  the  king  as  the 
supreme  landlord,  the  lords  of  manors  came  in 
course  of  time  to  be  treated  as  owners  of  the 
soQ  within  the  manor,  who  in  various  "ways 
granted  certain  rights  over  it  to  their  tenants. 
Land  might  be  cultivated  by  the  tenants  for 
their  lord  or  for  themselves  according  to  a  com- 
mon system  of  husbandry,  upon  certain  terms 
which  in  many  cases  included  certain  pasture 
rights.  These  might  be  (1)  rights  over  the 
arable  land  during  the  year,  when  under  the 
three-field  system  it  was  lying  fallow,  or  during 
the  period  between  harvest  and  the  sowing  of 
seed  ;  or  (2)  the  right  of  herding  a  certain 
number  of  animals  in  a  common  close  ;  or  (3) 
rights  over  the  wastes  and  woods  belonging  to 
the  manor.  "Whether  the  lord  could  from  the 
earliest  times  enclose  at  will  is  a  matter  of  some 
controversy,  but,  by  the  statute  of  Merton,  1236 
(20  Hen.  III.  c.  4),  a  parliamentary  sanction  was 
given  to  the  enclosure  of  wastes  by  the  lord  of 
a  manor,  provided  that  sufficient  pasture  was 
left  for  the  requirements  of  his  freehold  tenants ; 
while  by  the  Statute  of  Westminster,  II.,  1285 
(13  Edw.  I.  c.  46),  enclosure  was  permitted  as 
against  commoners  who,  without  being  tenants, 
possessed  pasture  rights  by  a  special  grant. 
Until  the  middle  of  the  14th  century  the  en- 
closure of  open  fields  in  the  interests  of  tillage 
continued,  and  many  agreements  were  made 
between  lords  and  commoners  destroying  the 
common  rights  over  the  arable  land  between 
harvest  and  seed-time,  and  sometimes  involving 
exchange  of  laud.  Since  such  enclosure  simply 
implied  the  rearrangement  of  estates,  and 
required  the  same  resident  population  as  before, 
while  the  conversion  from  wood  and  waste  into 
arable  land — another  feature  of  the  time — found 
employment  for  a  larger  population,  no  grievance 
could  arise,  and  the  agricultural  gain  was  great. 
But  owing  to  the  scarcity  of  labour  after  the 
ravages  of  the  Black  Death  (1349),  and  the  conse- 
quent introduction  of  the  lease  system,  atten- 
tion was  turned  to  the  advantages  of  pasture 
farming  over  tillage.  When  to  these  influ- 
ences there  was  added,  in  the  15th  century,  a 
desire  to  promote  commercial  interests  by 
increasing  the  supply  of  wool  for  exportation, 
pasture  farming  was  still  more  widely  intro- 
duced. Sheep  could  not  be  properly  reared 
upon  open  commons,  or  upon  the  small  scat- 
tered strips,  and  thus  arose  the  policy  of 
enclosing  commons  wherever  this  was  possible, 
either  by  force,  or  by  voluntary  agreement ; 
while  the  profits  of  sheep- farming  led  to  the 
conversion  of  much  arable  into  pasture  land. 
Tenants  were  encouraged  to  consolidate  their 
holdings,  to  exchange  their  strips  in  the  open 
fields  for  separate  farms,  and  to  divide  the 
common  pasture  with  the  lord,  or  in  some  way 
to  make  an  agreement  with  him.    The  economic 


advantage  of  enclosure  for  grazing  purposes 
was  doubtless  great,  but  the  social  and  political 
dangers  were  considerable,  as  was  pointed  out 
by  many  contemporaiy  writers  who  dwelt  upon 
the  depopulation  of  vast  tracts,  the  diminished 
sphere  for  employment,  the  iikcrease  of  pauperism, 
the  pressure  of  evictions,  and  the  loss  of  custom- 
ary rights.  These  evils  became  more  apparent 
after  the  dissolution  of  the  monasteries  ;  the 
earlier  agricultural  system  had  been  retained 
on  many  estates  which  were  confiscated,  and 
thus  passed  under  the  new  system,  while  the 
customary  rights  of  the  tenants  were  held  to 
be  overridden  by  the  royal  grant.  Various 
statutes  were  enacted  throughout  the  16th 
century  for  the  encouragement  of  tillage,  but  it 
was  not  until  its  close  that  the  danger  passed 
away.  Edward  VI.  issued  a  commission  in 
1548,  to  investigate  the  matter  throughout  the 
country,  but  it  was  unable  to  put  an  end  to  the 
social  discontent,  which  found  an  expression  in 
Rett's  Rebellion  in  1549.  The  subject  was 
summarised  in  the  charge  read  by  John  Hales 
at  the  opening  of  the  commission,  and  in  the 
Brief  Conceipt  of  English  Policy  (see  ed.  1893 
under  the  title  of  A  Discourse  of  the  Common- 
weal of  this  Realm  of  England,  and  article  by 
Miss  E.  Lamond,  English  Historical  Heview, 
1891).  By  the  close  of  Elizabeth's  reign  com- 
plaints about  enclosures  in  the  interest  of  pasture 
farming  seem  to  have  ceased  ;  this  was  partly 
due  to  the  encouragement  given  to  the  growth 
and  export  of  corn,  a  course  which  had  a  more 
beneficial  effect  in  reviving  tillage  than  the 
many  statutes  passed  with  that  object.  From 
this  time  onwards  enclosure  of  waste  and 
common  fields  alike  is  chiefly  advocated  in  the 
interest  of  tillage,  not  of  pastm*e.  In  the  1 7th 
century  many  writers  advocated  enclosures  of 
common  fields  for  the  improvement  of  tillage. 
Steps  were  taken  for  the  draining  and  enclosing 
of  the  fens  under  the  direction  of  Cornelius 
Vermiiyden,  a  Zealander,  while  the  Earl  of 
Bedford  headed  an  enterprise  for  enclosing  the 
level  which  bears  his  name.  In  each  case  the 
undertakers  were  rewarded  with  a  portion  of 
the  lands  thus  reclaimed,  and  this  led  under 
the  Commonwealth  to  serious  riots  on  the  part 
of  the  fen  men,  whose  customary  rights  were 
thus  set  aside.  The  only  other  noteworthy 
feature  in  the  history  of  17th-century  enclosing, 
was  occasioned  by  the  financial  necessities 
of  Charles  L,  which  led  him  to  institute  pro- 
ceedings against  those  who  had  encroached  upon 
the  royal  forests.  Heavy  fines  were  imposed 
upon  offenders  who  had  thus  enclosed,  but  it 
is  doubtful  whether  the  king  derived  as  much 
profit  from  this  source  of  revenue  as  he  had 
anticipated. 

Until  the  reign  of  Charles  II.  enclosures  were 
effected  by  agreement  between  the  owners  of 
land  and  those  who  possessed  rights  of  common, 
commissioners   beinii    appointed   to    allot   the 


ENCLOSURES 


711 


lands  ;  the  agreement  was  ratified  by  the  court 
of  chancery,  or  by  royal  licence  where  crown 
interests  were  concerned,  but  from  the  reign  of 
Charles  II.  a  parliamentary  sanction  was 
required.  This  was  only  given  after  the  con- 
sent of  the  landlord,  the  tithe  owner,  and  four- 
fifths  of  the  commoners  had  been  obtained  in 
favour  of  enclosure.  During  the  first  half  of 
the  18th  century  enclosing  continued  slowly  ; 
but  the  rise  of  a  moneyed  class  interested  in  agri- 
culture and  willing  to  spend  money  on  agricul- 
tural improvements,  the  increased  use  of  green 
crops,  which  raised  the  profits  of  tillage,  but 
which  could  not  be  profitably  worked  under  the 
open-field  system,  the  increase  of  population 
together  with  the  withdrawal  of  a  large  portion 
from  agricultural  labour,  the  difficulty  of  pro- 
viding a  sufficient  food-supply  and  the  danger 
of  dependence  upon  foreign  countries,  together 
with  the  famine  prices  produced  by  the  French 
wars — all  these  various  causes  combined  necessi- 
tated the  utmost  development  of  natural 
resources,  and  gave  an  enormous  impetus  to 
enclosure  both  of  open  fields  and  of  common 
wastes  from  about  1760  onwards.  The  rate  of 
progress  is  most  easily  shown  by  a  few  figures. 
In  the  reign  of  Anne  there  were  three  private 
bills  for  enclosure,  in  that  of  George  I.  16,  and 
imder  George  II.  226,  a  total  of  245  in  fifty- 
eight  years,  while  the  sixty  years  of  George  III.  's 
reign  show  the  astounding  number  of  3209 
private  bills  as  well  as  the  general  enclosing 
act  of  1801.  Unlike  the  enclosures  of  Tudor 
times,  those  of  the  18th  century  were  entirely 
in  the  interests  of  tillage.  It  is  hard  to  esti- 
mate by  how  much  the  actual  area  brought 
under  tillage  was  extended,  since  a  great  many 
enclosures  aff"ected  open  fields  already  under 
cultivation.  In  1797,  when  over  1720  private 
bills  had  been  passed,  the  select  committee  on 
enclosures  reported  that  of  the  46,000,000 
acres  which  England  was  supposed  to  contain, 
about  7,800,000  were  uncultivated  wastes, 
while  1,200,000  were  in  the  state  of  common 
fields,  and  it  has  been  estimated  that  about 
4000  parishes,  containing  open  fields,  chiefly 
in  the  eastern  and  some  of  the  midland  counties, 
out  of  a  rough  total  of  8500,  were  enclosed 
between  1760  and  1844.  Where  such  en- 
closures took  place  with  due  regard  to  common 
rights  the  gain  was  great,  as  the  customary 
course  of  agiiculture,  and  the  difficulty  of 
introducing  changes  such  as  machinery  or  a 
better  rotation  of  crops,  were  almost  insuper- 
able obstacles  to  improvement.  The  enclosure 
of  the  wastes  was  also  an  economic  gain,  for  in 
many  cases  they  were  previously  worthless,  the 
cattle  reared  on  them  were  of  an  inferior  kind, 
and,  as  Sir  John  Sinclair  pointed  out  in  an 
address  incorporated  in  the  report  of  the  select 
committee  of  1795,  it  was  found  more  profit- 
able to  hire  land  for  the  breeding  of  sheep  of  a 
more  valuable  sort  than  to  turn  them  on  to  a 


common  for  nothing.  Nor  must  it  be  forgotten 
that  though  much  suffering  was  probably 
inflicted,  still  it  was  a  social  gain  to  clear  some 
districts  of  an  idle  and  lawless  population — the 
haunts  of  thieves  who,  more  especially  near  the 
capital,  were  a  public  nuisance, — while  the  drain- 
ing of  vast  tracts  was  not  without  beneficial 
eff'ects  upon  the  public  health.  In  many  cases 
the  enclosures,  as  carried  out,  were  hurtful  to 
the  labourers,  whose  cottages  had  been  on  the 
commons,  and  who  had  been  able  to  keep  a 
cow,  which  was  no  longer  possible  when  enclos- 
ure of  the  open  fields  and  of  the  waste  deprived 
them  of  customary  pasture  rights — often  with- 
out compensation.  The  expense  of  enclosing 
and  the  loss  of  pasture  rights  is  one  of  the 
many  causes  which  contributed  to  the  dis- 
appearance of  the  yeomanry  during  this  period. 
The  force  of  the  argument  against  enclosures 
lies  in  the  fact  that  the  poor  did  not  in  many 
cases  receive  compensation  for  the  loss  of 
traditional  rights.  The  enclosure  bills  did  in- 
deed provide  that  all  legal  rights  should  be 
regarded,  and  on  the  whole  the  commissioners 
tried  to  act  fairly,  but  the  expense  of  enclosing 
was  very  great ;  much  of  the  money  compensa- 
tion paid  to  the  commoner  was  swallowed  up 
in  legal  expenses,  and  the  poor  man  was  doubt- 
less at  a  disadvantage  in  contesting  the  rival 
interests  of  a  wealthy  neighbour.  After  receiv- 
ing reports  from  various  select  committees 
which  had  communicated  with  the  board  of 
agriculture,  parliament  in  1801  passed  a  general 
enclosing  act  (41  Geo.  III.  c.  109)  with  the 
object  of  cheapening  and  facilitating  the  pro- 
cess of  enclosure,  and  of  thus  protecting  the 
interests  of  the  poor.  By  the  act  certain 
general  provisions  were  laid  down,  which 
rendered  the  private  acts  shorter,  though  the 
expense  of  an  application  to  parliament,  and 
of  referring  contested  cases  to  a  parliamentary 
committee,  still  remained. 

In  1836  an  act  (6  &  7  WiU.  IV.  c.  115) 
was  passed  by  which  enclosure  of  common  fields 
was  facilitated.  Possessors  of  common  rights 
to  the  number  and  value  of  two-thirds  might 
nominate  commissioners  to  carry  out  enclosure 
of  common  fields,  provided  that  these  were 
beyond  certain  distances  of  the  larger  towns. 

By  the  general  enclosure  act  of  1845  (8  &  9 
Vict.  c.  118)  this  method  was  extended  to  the 
common  wastes.  An  enclosure  commission 
was  appointed  to  deal  with  land  of  various 
kinds  in  England  and  Wales.  (1)  All  lands 
held  in  severalty,  or  subject  to  definite  common 
rights,  could  be  enclosed  by  the  authority  of 
the  commissioners  without  parliamentary  sanc- 
tion. By  15  &  16  Vict.  c.  79,  the  commissioners 
were,  however,  forced  to  submit  proposals  deal- 
ing with  land  as  above  described  to  parliament. 
(2)  All  lands  over  which  imdefined  rights  of 
common  existed — and  all  wastes  within  16  miles 
of  London,  or  within  certain  distances  of  other 


712 


ENCOMIENDA— ENCYCLICAL 


towns  In  such  cases  the  commissioners  held 
an  inquiry,  and  then  drew  a  scheme  ;  aU  the 
schemes  for  the  year  being  presented  to  parlia- 
ment in  one  general  act.  The  commissioners 
were  thus  substituted  for  the  parliamentary 
committee,  and  it  was  hoped  by  the  pronfoters 
of  the  measure  that  examination  on  the  spot 
would  prove  a  security  to  the  poor,  whose 
interests  were  directly  protected  by  clauses 
empowering  the  commissioners  to  make  allot- 
ments and  recreation  grounds.  (3)  Village  and 
town  greens,  as  well  as  the  New  Forest,  and  the 
Forest  of  Dean,  were  excluded  from  the  opera- 
tion of  the  act. 

In  1852  parliamentary  sanction  was  made 
compulsory  for  the  enclosure  of  land  held  in 
severalty  without  definite  common  rights.  In 
1893  the  statute  of  Merton,  though  not  re- 
pealed, was  greatly  modified ;  and  no  enclosure 
may  henceforth  be  made  imder  that  act  with- 
out the  consent  of  the  board  of  agriculture, 
which  in  dealing  with  such  proposals  is  in- 
structed to  carry  out  the  requirements  of  the 
Commons  Act  of  1876,  when  considering  appli- 
cations for  the  general  enclosure  of  a  common. 

[T.  E.  Scrutton,  Commons  and  Common  Fields 
(1887).— R.  E.  Prothero,  Pioneers  and  Progress  of 
English  Farming  {1^%%).— Reports  from  Com- 
mittees of  the  House  of  Commons,  IX.,  1774-1802. 
—Reports  of  the  Board  of  Agriculture— General 
Report  on  Enclosures  (1805).— Notice  of  enclos- 
ures in  Bacon's  History  of  Henry  VII.,  p.  93,  vol. 
vL ,  Bacon's  Works,  Ellis  and  Speddiiig's  edition. 
— LeadaiT),  Inquisition  of  1517  in  Transactions 
of  Royal  Historical  Society,  N.S.,  vi.  169].  w.  c. 

ENCOMIENDA,  the  name  of  the  estates, 
comprising  both  land  and  its  Indian  inhabitants, 
granted  by  the  Spanish  crown  to  the  con- 
quistadores  or  military  adventurers  in  America. 

E.  oa. 

ENCROACHMENT.     See  Trespass. 

ENCYCLICAL.  The  encyclical  of  Pope  Leo 
XIII.  on  the  condition  of  labour,  dated  15th 
May  1891,  which  is  the  subject  of  this  notice, 
receives  its  name  from  its  opening  words 
Berum  novarum.  Here,  as  in  previous  encycli- 
cals, notably  the  one  Quod  Apostolici  Muneris, 
issued  in  the  first  year  of  Leo  XIII.  (1878), 
the  question  of  capital  and  labour  is  considered 
mainly  in  its  connection  with  the  recent  ad- 
vances of  socialism.  It  offers  us,  as  M.  Charles 
Perin,  emeritus-professor  of  the  University  of 
Louvain,  puts  it,  a  "synthesis  of  the  economic 
order  according  to  the  divine  laws  which  regu- 
late human  conduct,"  and  it  is  important  as 
constituting  "la  verite  catholique  pour  I'ordre 
economique,"  or,  as  we  should  put  it,  an 
authoritative  statement  on  the  part  of  the 
Roman  Catholic  Church  on  the  economics  of 
labour.  Its  distinguishing  feature  is  the  intro- 
duction of  the  principles  of  justice  and  charity 
in  the  solution  of  economic  questions.  The  en- 
cyclical opens  with  an  allusion  to  the  "spirit  of 


revolutionary  change,"  and  the  influence  of  this 
in  the  "  field  of  practical  economy  "  ;  it  dwells 
on  the  danger  of  social  agitation  in  the  presence 
of  real  grievances  such  as  "the  misery  and 
wretchedness  which  press  so  heavily  at  this 
moment  on  the  larger  majority  of  the  very  poor," 
and  the  isolated  and  defenceless  condition  of 
working  men,  "the  callousness  of  employers, 
and  the  gi-eed  of  unrestrained  competition" 
{Encyclical  Letter,  ofl[icial  translation,  p.  4).  It 
then  proceeds  to  examine  the  remedies  proposed 
on  the  one  hand  by  socialists,  which  it  condemns, 
and  those  which  are  within  the  province  of  the 
church  and  state,  which  it  recommends,  dwell- 
ing in  conclusion  on  self-help  by  means  of  asso- 
ciation and  the  importance  of  a  wider  diffusion 
of  Christian  charity  in  all  human  relationships 
which  strikes  at  the  root  of  all  social  evils. 
(1)  The  socialistic  proposals  are  characterised 
as  unjust  and  tending  to  rob  lawful  possessors, 
and  putting  the  state  into  "a  sphere  that  is 
not  its  own"  (p.  5),  and  thus  depriving  the 
labourer  of  the  liberty  of  choosing  his  own  em- 
ployer and  using  the  proceeds  of  his  work. 
Private  property  is  defended,  as  against  the 
socialistic  recommendation  of  collective  owner- 
ship as  being  "according  to  nature's  law," 
whilst,  "the  authority  of  the  divine  law  adds 
its  sanction  "  (pp.  7,  8) ;  and,  considering  the 
rights  of  the  family  as  co-ordinate  with  those 
of  the  state  "our  first  and  fundamental  prin- 
ciple, therefore,  when  we  undertake  to  alleviate 
the  condition  of  the  masses,  must  be  the  in- 
violability of  private  property"  (p.  11).  The 
pope  here  falls  into  the  common  error  of  sup- 
posing that  all  private  property  is  excluded  in 
the  schemes  of  modern  socialism,  whereas  it  is 
only  instruments  of  production — private  owner- 
ship in  lands,  capital,  and  machinery — which 
are  to  be  abolished  and  become  state  property, 
the  state  directing  the  process  of  production, 
with  the  disappearance  of  the  wages  system  in 
the  socialistic  state.  (2)  The  encyclical  de- 
clares inequality  as  in  the  nature  of  things 
permanent,  and  points  out  the  methods  of 
the  church  under  these  circumstances  for 
remedying  the  evils  arising  therefrom.  It 
is  the  duty  of  the  church  to  teach  and  to 
train  men  in  the  principles  of  social  ethics 
(pp.  18,  19),  whereby  the  poor  may  learn  "to 
sutfer  and  endure "  and  to  abstain  from 
violent  measures  in  compassing  their  ends, 
whilst  the  rich  are  taught  to  ' '  religiously  re- 
frain from  cutting  down  the  workman's  earnings, 
either  by  force,  by  fraud,  or  by  usurious  deal- 
ing" (pp.  13,  14).  The  church,  too,  in  her 
institutions,  as  in  the  past,  guards  the  "patri- 
mony of  the  poor"  by  means  of  "deposits  of 
piety  "  flowing  from  Christian  self-sacrifice  and 
charity.  (3)  The  state  as  the  organ  of  dis- 
tributive justice  protects  each  class  with  a  view 
to  the  common  good  ;  all  well- constituted  states 
are  bound   "to  provide  those  bodily  and  ex 


ENDORSEMENT— ENDOWMENTS 


713 


ternal  commodities  the  use  of  which  is  necessary 
to  virtuous  action."  "  It  is  only  by  the  labour 
of  the  working  man  that  states  grow  rich. 
Justice,  therefore,  demands  that  the  interests 
of  the  poorer  population  be  carefully  watched 
over  by  the  administration"  (pp.  22,  23). 
Sunday  rest,  and  the  protection  of  health  and 
the  prevention  of  excessive  labour  of  children 
and  females  being  among  the  subjects  demand- 
ing state  interference,  as  also  the  restraint  of 
the  disturbers  of  social  peace,  "to  save  the 
workman  from  their  seditious  arts,  and  to  protect 
lawful  owners  from  spoliation"  (p.  25).  On 
the  wages  question  Leo  XIII.  proves  himself  to 
be  "le  paj)e  des  proletaires"  in  demanding  of 
the  state  protection  against  unscrupulous  em- 
ployers, who  under  a  semblance  of  free  contract 
deprive  the  labourer  of  his  due.  Distinguishing 
between  this  theory  and  facts,  between  normal 
wages  and  fair  wages,  he  points  out  that  the 
working  man,  having  nothing  but  his  wage  to 
fall  back  upon  for  a  livelihood,  is  bound  to 
come  to  terms  with  the  master  even  to  his  own 
disadvantage,  unless  he  is  protected  by  the 
state  or  boards  of  conciliation  authorised  by 
the  state  to  secure  the  rights  of  both  parties  of 
the  contract,  and  this  on  the  equitable  principle 
that  "each  one  has  a  right  to  procure  what  is 
required  in  order  to  live"  (p.  28).  (4)  In  the 
last  place  the  pope  recommends  association  and 
corporation  as  after  the  pattern  of  Christian 
confraternities  under  the  fostering  influence, 
though  without  undue  controlling  power,  of  the 
state  as  means  of  mutual  support  and  protection 
against  encroachments  ;  but  it  is  by  a  return  to 
Christian  faith  and  charity  alone  that  the  evils 
of  society  can  be  cured  in  the  end, — so  concludes 
the  encyclical  which  thus  becomes  what  Anatole 
Leroy-Beaulieu,  in  his  appreciative  study  of  La 
Papaut^,  le  Socialisme,  et  la  Democratie,  calls 
"un  code  de  morale  sociale"  (see  pp.  QQ,  67). 
But  also,  as  the  same  writer  points  out,  so  far 
from  coming  into  conflict  with  the  principles  of 
political  economy,  as  now  understood,  the  en- 
cyclical is  on  a  line  with  its  most  recent  de- 
velopments {ib.  p.  50),  adding  to  the  moral 
factor  the  religious  forces  without  which  selfish- 
ness and  greed  would  be  the  only  prompting 
motives  of  economic  action. 

[Charles  Perin,  L'£conomie  Politique  d'apres 
V Encyclique  sur  la  condition  des  ouvriers,  Paris, 
1891. — Note  sur  le  juste  Salaire  d'aprds  I'En- 
cycUque  rerum  novarum  by  the  same. — Henri  Joly, 
Le  Socialisme  Chretien  under  the  head,  Les  der- 
niires  ecoles. — Anatole  Leroy-Beaulieu,  Papacy, 
Socialism,  and  Democracy,  trans,  from  the  French 
by  B.  L.  O'Domiell,  Chapman  and  Hall,  1892, 
gives  the  text  of  the  encyclical  in  an  appendix. — 
Henry  George,  On  the  Condition  of  Labour,  1891. 
—Also  W.  T.  Stead,  The  Pope  and  the  New  Era, 
1890.]  M.  K. 

ENDORSEMENT.    See  Bill  of  Exchange. 
ENDOWMENTS.     Adam  Smith  in  a  well- 


known  passage^  has  vn'itten  strongly  on  the 
subject  of  endowments.  In  his  eyes  they  tend 
to  hinder  capital  and  labour  from  taking  their 
natural  course.  In  certain  professions,  notably 
that  of  holy  orders,  the  existence  of  endow- 
ments, to  encourage  and  support  those  who  are 
preparing  for  them,  has  attracted  large  numbers 
of  men  who  would  otherwise  have  carried  their 
energies  into  different  fields.  Hence  a  depres- 
sion of  incomes  in  those  professions,  for  the 
number  applying  for  employment  in  them  is 
greater  than  the  work  requires.  A  change  in 
circumstances  since  Adam  Smith  wrote  has 
robbed  his  particular  instance  of  much  of  its 
force,  for  the  endowments  in  question  have,  as 
a  rule,  been  diverted,  and  the  growth  of  popu- 
lation coupled  with  well-defined  religious  re- 
vivals has  greatly  increased  the  work  of  the 
clergy.  But  Adam  Smith  goes  farther,  and 
maintains  that,  tested  by  experience,  endow- 
ments have  failed  to  secure  any  good  object. 
The  universities,  he  says,  are  largely  endowed, 
and  have  failed  to  make  any  great  additions  to 
the  learning  of  the  country,  which  is  no  more 
than  might  have  been  expected  d  priori,  for  the 
motive  to  exertion  being  removed  by  the  cer- 
tainty of  income  independent  of  it,  exertion 
itself  would  tend  to  diminish.  Dr.  Johnson,^ 
though  not  accepting  Adam  Smith's  con- 
clusions, put  the  same  argument  in  a  popular 
form  when  he  says,  "Why,  sir,  we  would  all 
be  idle  if  we  could." 

As  the  growing  tendency  of  the  present  time 
is  to  employ  endowments  for  the  advancement 
of  learning  or  the  furtherance  of  education,  it 
may  be  worth  while  to  examine  the  reasoning 
at  greater  length.  The  objections  to  endow- 
ments may  be  put  in  the  form  of  a  dilemma — 
either  a  given  result  is  worth  having,  and  then 
the  public  are  ready  to  pay  for  it,  or  the  public 
is  not  ready  to  pay  for  it,  and  then  it  is  not 
worth  having ;  in  the  one  case  endowments 
are  superfluous  and  cripple  energy,  in  the  other 
they  are  wasted.  It  will  be  observed  that  this 
argument  is  based  on  the  assumption  that  the 
public  are  the  best  judges  in  such  matters.  To 
this  it  is  objected  that  although  the  common 
exchanges  of  life  may  safely  be  left  to  competi- 
tion, and  the  public  are  able  to  judge  of  quality 
in  the  matter  of  tea,  sugar,  etc. ,  the  case  is  very 
difierent  when  learning  and  the  higher  forms 
of  education  are  involved.  The  public,  or  at 
least  the  English  public,  are  not  qualified  to 
discern  good  and  bad  in  such  matters.  The 
demand  for  books  and  teaching  in  the  highest 
subjects  is  never  likely  to  be  sufficient  to  make 
it  worth  any  one's  while  to  wi'ite  upon  or  teach 
such  subjects  as  a  profession,  and  many  persons 
who  have  the  ability  and  the  taste  requisite  are 
powerless  to  pursue  the  subjects  for  want  of 

1  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  i.  chap.  x. ;  cp.  bk.  v.  cliap 
i.,  art.  ii. 

2  Boswell's  Life  of  Johnson,  a.d.  1776. 


714 


ENDOWMENTS— ENEMY  GOODS 


^^^^.  In  such  cases  endowments,  it  is  argued, 
may"profitably  be  used  to  provide  the  means  of 
subsistence  for  men  who  are  in  reaHty  great 
public  benefactors.  Certain  chairs,  for  instance, 
at  the  universities  need  endowments  to  support 
their  holders  in  the  absence  of  a  sufficient 
number  of  students  ready  to  pay  fees  to  main- 
tain their  teacher.  Certain  forms  of  study  and 
research  are  never  Hkely  to  be  sufficiently 
remunerative  to  provide  those  who  pursue  them 
with  the  means  of  livelihood,  and  must  conse- 
quently be  endowed.  Outside  these  special 
cases  it  is  readily  granted  that  endowments,  by 
making  men  independent  of  their  exertions, 
tend  to  weaken  their  industry ;  but  unless  these 
particular  subjects  are  endowed,  the  level  of 
learning  and  of  teaching  is  likely  to  be  lowered, 
for  the  subjects  studied  and  taught  will  be 
those,  and  those  only,  which  bear  directly  on 
practical  life.  The  question  is  not,  perhaps, 
one  which  admits  of  a  final  answer.  The 
enthusiasm  which  leads  a  man  to  adopt  an 
impopular  subject  may  in  many  cases  be  trusted 
to  keep  him  industrious,  independently  of 
reward.  A  certain  habit  of  mind  is  observable 
in  those  who  are  mainly  supported  by  endow- 
ments, a  tendency  to  delay  publication,  an 
excessive  self-criticism,  a  want  of  definiteness — 
all  these  go  far  to  postpone,  if  not  to  destroy 
the  realisation  of  the  results  of  their  work.  It 
has  been  remarked  that  in  this  country  a  large 
amount  of  the  best  work  has  been  done  by  men 
who  have  a  regular  employment,  and  with  whom 
the  advancement  of  learning  is  a  secondary 
occupation.  J.  S.  Mill,  e.g.,  wrote  his  princi- 
pal treatises  in  the  intervals  of  his  work  as  a 
clerk  in  the  India  House.  Grote's  History  of 
Greece  was  the  work  of  a  banker,  and  other 
instances  might  be  quoted.  In  the  great 
majority  of  cases  a  certain  amount  of  teaching 
is  a  help  and  not  a  hindrance  to  research. 
The  most  successful  use  of  endowments  has, 
perhaps,  been  in  cases  where  they  have  been 
employed  to  support  men  who  have  already 
made  themselves  a  name  in  a  subject,  and  who 
have  been  set  free  from  the  necessity  of  working 
for  their  daily  bread  at  some  occupation  which 
they  have  hitherto  practised.  But  the  method 
of  distributing  endowments  is  distinct  from  the 
question  of  their  inherent  advantages  or  draw- 
backs. In  German  universities  endowments 
are,  as  a  rule,  only  a  part  of  the  income  of  a 
professor,  the  proportion  that  he  earns  by  fees 
being  gi-eater  or  less  as  his  subject  is  popular 
or  the  reverse. 

Apart  from  the  encouragement  of  research, 
endowments  are  largely  used  to  forward  the 
higher  education  of  the  country.  The  univer- 
sities expend  large  sums  annually  in  scholar- 
ships to  attract  students  ;  and  fellowships,  being 
now  largely  used  as  prizes  at  the  end  of  a 
university  course,  are  additional  inducements 
to  students  to  undertake  it.    The  consideration 


of  poverty  enters  but  little  into  their  distribu 
tion.     Here  again  a  question  may  be  raised  as 
to  the  wisdom  of  such  a  policy.     Studies,  it 
will  be  urged,  which  are  not  self-supporting  in 
the  sense  of  attracting  students  by  their  own ; 
charms,    are    not    worth    supporting    at    all. 
Others  will  hold  that  studies  which  do  not  bear  j 
directly  on  practical  life  (in  German  phrase 
not  "  bread  studies  ")  have  a  value  of  their  own,! 
of  which  the  public  are  not  the  best  judges,  but] 
which  make  it  worth  while  to  support  them  bj 
endowments  ;   and  that  while   studies  whicl 
are  a  direct  preparation  for  business  may  safely] 
be  left  to  themselves,  it  is  the  interest  of 
country   to   preserve   others   from   extinction,] 
We  have  in  England  no  logical  principle  applied 
to  the  graduation  of  studies  or  their  mutus' 
relation ;  but  the  tendency  of  the  present  day  i| 
to  use   endowments   largely   to   facilitate 
passing  from  the  lower  to  the  higher  grade 
Instances  are  not  wanting  of  those  who  by  the 
means  have  risen  from  elementary  schools 
high  places  in  the  universities.     In  practice  il 
must   be   owned   that   endowments   often   (1] 
cheapen  education  for  a  class  who  can  perfectlj 
well  afford  to  pay  for  it,  by  providing  plant 
etc.,  for  the  great  public  schools  and  the  uni^ 
versities  ;  (2)  enable  poor  men  to  live  at  a  need^ 
lessly  expensive  rate,  which  is  determined  b] 
the  standard  of  comfort  set  by  more  wealth] 
companions. 

Two  subsidiary  points  may  be  mentioned. 

1.  The  system  of  confining  the  advantage 
of  endowments  to  certain   localities   is  bein| 
gradually  modified.     It  is  argued  that  migra- 
tory habits  and  facilities  of  communication  have 
greatly  lessened  the  reality  of  local  divisions  ; 
that,  on  the  whole,  every  locality  gains  by  the^ 
process  ;  that  waste  is  avoided,  and  the  supplj 
of  endowments  made  to  correspond  more  nearly 
to  the  number  of  persons  qualified  to  make 
good  use  of  them. 

2.  The  abolition  of  any  poverty  qualificatioi 
mentioned  above,  has  been  severely  criticised<] 
It  may  be  defended  on  the  ground  that  it 
almost  impossible  to  make  such  a  qualificatioi 
real.  Poverty  is  difficult  to  define,  and  it 
impossible  to  formulate  any  system  of  compenJ 
sation  as  between  ability  and  want  of  means 
Moreover,  on  the  whole,  the  present  tendency 
to  distribute  endowments  by  competition,  mak'^ 
ing  ability  and  not  poverty  the  test,  tends 
raise  the  whole  level  of  education,  and  so 
benefit  the  poor  ;  whilst  the  spur  of  poverty  il 
sufficient  to  ensure  industry,  and  the  temptatioi 
to  idleness  which  go  with  wealth  are,  in  the 
great  majority  of  cases,  strong  enough  to  pi 
vent  members  of  the  wealthy  class  from  com- 
peting successfully. 

[Mill,  Pol.  Econ.,  bk.  v.  chap.  xi.  §  15.— Turgot 
Fondation  et  Fondations,  (Euvres,  vol.  iii.,  ec' 
1808.]  L.  R.  P. 

ENEMY  GOODS.     In  early  times  the  pr 


ENFACED  PAPER— ENFANTIN 


715 


perty  of  the  enemy,  wherever  found,  was  liable 
to  capture.  By  custom  and  treaty  the  harsh- 
ness of  this  rule  has  been  modified,  and  the 
modem  practice  may  be  summed  up  as  fol- 
lows : — (1)  Movable  property  belonging  to  an 
enemy  state  may  be  appropriated  ;  immovable 
property  may  be  occupied  but  not  alienated. 
(2)  Movable  private  property  is  liable  to  con- 
tribute to  the  support  of  the  invading  army, 
contributions  and  requisitions  bemg  levied  for 
that  purpose  ;  immovable  private  property  is 
exempt  from  appropriation.  (3)  Private  pro- 
perty on  the  high  seas  is  liable  to  capture 
except  where  it  is  on  board  a  neutral  vessel. 
(4)  Private  property  within  the  jurisdiction  of 
the  belligerent  is  not  as  a  rule  liable  to  capture. 

[International  Law,  by  W.  E.  Hall,  Oxford, 
1890.  Many  writers  advocate  the  exemption  of 
private  property  at  sea  from  capture.  The 
United  States  has  more  than  once  made  this  pro- 
posal, and  in  some  modern  wars  this  principle 
has  been  followed.  See  De  Laveleye,  Du  Respect 
de  la  Propriete  Priv^e  en  Temps  de  Guerre. — 
Bluntschli,  "  Du  droit  de  Butin,"  Rev.  de  Droit 
International,  torn.  ix.  and  x.,  and  articles  in  the 
same  review  by  M.  Vidari,  torn.  iii.  (1871). — 
M.  Gessner,  torn.  vii.  (1875),  and  the  reports  pre- 
sented to  the  Institute  of  International  Law, 
torn,  viii.  (1875).]  j.  e.  c.  m. 

ENFACED  PAPER  or  RUPEE  PAPER. 
The  title  applied  by  stock  exchange  custom 
to  Indian  government  securities,  the  interest 
on  which  is  payable  in  silver  rupees.  The 
capital  also  is  expressed,  or  enfaced,  on  the 
certificate  as  being  so  many  silver  rupees,  the 
value  of  which  in  the  London  market  varies 
according  to  the  value  of  silver  in  relation  to 
gold.  The  word  "enfaced"  might  almost  as 
well  be  applied  to  any  other  kind  of  security, 
inasmuch  as  all  have  more  or  less  on  their 
face  a  description  of  the  security  represented. 
Custom,  however,  has  lent  the  word  simply  to 
those  Indian  rupee  stocks  which  bear  interest 
at  4  per  cent  and  upwards,  the  interest  of 
course  being  payable  in  silver,  and  subject  to 
an  increase  or  decrease  in  sterling  value  accord- 
ing to  the  value  of  silver  in  the  bullion  market. 
The  Indian  government  cannot  borrow  so  easily 
or  at  so  low  a  rate  of  interest  in  silver  as  it 
can  in  gold,  the  mass  of  investors  having  been 
repelled  by  the  possibility  of  fluctuations  in 
'  the  sterling  value  of  the  interest  receivable. 
At  the  same  time  it  has  been  thought  well 
by  Indian  statesmen  to  avoid  accumulating  a 
large  sterling  debt,  lest  the  Indian  government 
should  some  day  encounter  a  heavy  fall  in 
the  value  of  silver,  which  would  compel  it 
to  tax  the  natives  of  India  to  the  extent  that 
more  rupees  would  be  required  to  provide  each 
pound  sterling.  A.  E. 

ENFACEMENT  is  the  converse  to  endorse- 
ment (see  Bill  of  Exchange).  The  word 
does  not  appear  to  have  been  in  use  before  the 
year  1858,  when  the  Indian  Government  de- 


cided to  pay  the  interest  on  the  Indian  home 
debt  in  London  by  means  of  drafts  at  sight  on 
India,  and  issued  the  following  notification  : — 

' '  When  holders  of  notes  in  Calcutta  desire 
that  the  interest  thereon  should  be  made  pay- 
able by  bills  issued  in  London,  they  must 
present  their  notes  at  the  office  of  the  Account- 
ant-General  to  the  Government  of  India, 
where  an  enfacement  will  be  made  on  each  of 
the  notes  in  question  as  follows  :  Interest  pay- 
able in  London  hy  draft  on  Calcutta  (or  Madras, 
as  the  case  may  be)." 

[Geo.  Clare,  "  Stock  Exchange  Securities,"  Jour- 
nal  of  the  Institute  qf  Bankers,  vol.  xiv.  p.  226.] 

ENFANTIN,  Prosper,  called  "  Le  Pere" 
(1796-1864),  was  born  at  Paris  and  died  in  the 
same  city.  Having  first  been,  in  conjunction  with 
Bazard  {q.v.),  a  leader,  he  became,  after  Bazard 
retired,  the  sole  chief  of  the  St.  Simonians, 
and  did  his  utmost  to  promote  the  success  of 
that  economico-religious  sect,  up  to  the  date  of 
its  fall.  Commencing  as  a  devotee  of  mysti- 
cism, Enfantin  finally  adopted  the  doctrine  of 
"free  love";  this  brought  him  into  trouble 
with  most  of  his  fellow-religionists.  He  was 
condemned  on  28th  August  1832  by  the  assize 
court  of  the  department  of  the  Seine,  in  com- 
pany with  Charles  Duveyrier  and  Michel 
Chevalier,  to  a  year's  imprisonment  and  a 
fine  of  100  francs,  for  having  assisted,  without 
previously  obtaining  permission,  in  the  forma- 
tion of  an  association  consisting  of  more  than 
twenty  members,  and  in  the  promulgation  of 
articles  injurious  to  public  morality. 

The  penalty  was  before  long  commuted,  and 
Enfantin  made  his  way  to  Egypt,  where  he 
studied  the  question,  now  long  since  settled,  of 
piercing  the  Isthmus  of  Suez. 

Subsequently,  after  remaining  for  several 
years  at  Tain  (Dr6me),  he  returned  to  Paris, 
and  was  appointed,  in  1845,  a  director  of  the 
first  company  for  constructing  a  railway  from 
Paris  to  Lyons. 

After  the  revolution  of  1848  he  founded,  in 
conjunction  with  Charles  Duveyrier,  the  journal 
Le  Credit,  which  continued  to  appear  till  1850. 
Finally  Enfantin  became  the  administrator  of 
the  second  Paris,  Lyons,  and  Mediterranean 
Railway  Company — a  post  which  he  continued 
to  hold  till  his  death. 

Before  the  fall  of  the  St.  Simonian  School, 
Enfantin  published,  in  conjunction  with  others, 
Doctrine  de  St.  Siinon,  Exposition,  2  vols.  8vo, 
1830-32  ;  afterwards^  in  his  own  name,  ^co- 
nomie  politique  et  Politique,  1  vol.  8vo  ;  Morale, 
1  vol.  8vo,  etc.  After  the  dispersion  of  the  St. 
Simonian  School,  Enfantin  wrote  a  volume. 
Colonisation  de  I'Algerie,  1843,  8vo,  in  this, 
across  a  web  of  original  ideas  and  among  pas- 
sages which  show  deep  historical  study,  may  be 
traced  the  opinions  of  the  early  socialists. 

His  works  were  collected  by  zealous  disciples, 
and  printed  in  9  vols.  Svo,  1866-73.    A.  c.  f. 


716 


ENFRANCHISEMENT 


ENFRANCHISEMENT,  the  Uberation  of 
the  serf  from  his  forced  astriction  to  his  lord's 
estate,  and  his  forced  labour  for  his  lord's 
behoof.  Though  not  liable,  like  the  slave,  to  be 
sold  from  master  to  master,  or  to  give  his  whole 
time  to  his  master's  work,  the  serf  was  still 
practicallj  chained  to  the  estate  to  which  the 
right  to  his  labour  was  legally  appendant,  and 
he  could  still  be  compelled  to  his  work  by 
whips  or  imprisonment  at  his  master's  will. 
There  was  a  third  strand  in  his  bondage — his 
subjection  to  his  lord's  civil  and  criminal  juris- 
diction, which  left  him  defenceless  against 
arbitrary  exactions,  and  therefore  operated  often 
quite  as  injuriously  on  his  economic  position  as 
the  other  two,  but  it  was  not  felt  to  involve 
the  same  personal  indignity  as  they  did,  and 
the  serf  is  commonly  considered  enfranchised 
when  he  is  released  from  them,  although  he 
may  continue  subject  to  his  lord's  general 
authority.  Enfranchisement  has  proceeded 
perhaps  more  generally  from  moral  than  from 
economic  motives,  but  it  has  usually  justified 
itself  immediately,  and  always  eventually,  by 
bringing  with  it  a  decided  economic  advance. 
The  pinch  of  serfdom  was  the  forced  labour  ; 
when  that  was  commuted  to  a  money  payment 
the  astriction  to  the  estate  fell  away  of  itself, 
for  want  of  any  practical  reason  for  enforcing  it 
longer.  But  though  the  astriction  to  the  spot 
was  less  grievous  to  individuals — except  indeed 
among  the  Russian  peasantry,  whose  chief  com- 
plaint, Haxthausen  tells  us,  always  was  that  it 
restrained  their  idle  propensity  to  rove — it  was 
always  most  pernicious  to  the  progress  of  the 
community,  because  it  stopped  all  division  of 
labour,  limiting  occupations  to  the  little  round 
of  work  in  a  rural  village,  and  preventing  the 
rise  of  towns,  and  trade,  and  manufactures. 
Russia  consequently,  where  serfdom  was  only 
abolished  in  1861,  is  still,  in  spite  of  the  ac- 
knowledged industrial  gifts  of  its  people,  little 
more  than  a  vast  nation  of  crofters,  every  man 
half  indiflFerent  agriculturist  and  half  indifferent 
tradesman ;  and  even  in  agriculture,  though  it  is 
now  one  of  the  largest  exporters  of  grain  in  the 
world,  its  system  of  husbandry  continues  almost 
primitive,  and  there  has  never  arisen  a  modern 
farming  class  ^^'ith  the  requisite  skill  and  capital 
for  practising  improved  methods.  The  ill  effects 
of  the  forced  labour  were  always  more  directly 
obvious.  The  serf  who  got  a  small  holding  to 
cultivate  for  his  own  support,  but  was  obliged 
to  give  three  days  a  week  (the  usual  quota)  to 
his  lord's  work,  could  neither  do  justice  to  his 
own  fields  nor  to  his  lord's,— not  to  his  own 
because  he  was  called  away  from  them  precisely 
when  he  most  required  to  be  upon  them,  and 
not  to  his  lord's  because  he  gave  his  labour  re- 
luctantly, sometimes  with  bitter  ill-will,  and 
he  had  no  interest  except  to  give  as  little  of  it  as 
he  dared.  His  holding  is  sometimes  called  the 
wages  for  hia  labom-,  and  his  labour  the  rent  for 


his  holding  ;  but  that  was  a  bad  form  of  wages, 
because  it  repressed  instead  of  encouraging  the 
labour  it  was  supposed  to  reward,  and  this  was  a 
bad  form  of  rent,  because  it  interfered  with  the 
proper  cultivation  of  the  land  which  was  supposed 
to  yield  it.  Serf  labour,  like  aU  discouraged 
labour,  was  habitually  indolent.  Professor  R. 
Jones  was  informed  by  the  English  engineer 
who  superintended  the  making  of  the  road  from 
Hamburg  to  Berlin  in  1830,  that  the  Prussian 
free  labourers  he  employed  broke  thrice  as  much 
granite  in  the  day  as  the  Mecklenburg  serfs,  and 
that  when  he  tried  to  animate  the  latter  by 
mixing  them  in  the  same  gangs  with  the  former, 
the  experiment  failed  because  it  had  exactly 
the  contrary  effect  of  making  the  free  labourers 
slacken  their  exertions  to  the  bond  pace  {Dis- 
tribution of  Wealth,  p.  52).  The  peasants  on 
Russian  state  lands,  whose  labour  rents  were 
commuted  into  money  rents  long  before  the 
universal  emancipation,  are  much  more  energetic, 
enterprising,  and  prosperous  than  the  recently- 
emancipated  serfs  (Thun,  Landwirthschaft  u. 
Gewerbe  in  Mittelrussland,  p.  43).  Roscher 
quotes  two  authorities  who  made  personal  in- 
vestigations into  the  relative  industrial  capacity 
of  serf  and  free  labourer  in  the  same  com- 
munities, and  one — Jakob — counted  two  free 
labourers  equal  to  three  serfs,  while  the  other 
—  V.  Flotow — counted  three  free  labourers 
equal  to  four  serfs  {System  d.  Volkswirthschaft, 
i.  152).  The  difference  is  still  more  strikingly 
shown  by  Hanssen,  who  mentions  that  on  the 
estate  of  Rixdorf  in  E.  Holstein,  where  labour 
rents  were  commuted  in  1780,  it  required 
ninety-two  horses  and  seventy-five  men  to  work 
the  home  farm  before  the  commutation,  and 
only  thirty-six  horses  and  fourteen  men  after  it 
{AufhebuTig  der  Leibeigenschaft  in  Schleswig  u. 
Holstein,  p.  39).  Usually,  too,  though  the 
labourers  were  fewer  the  harvest  was  greater. 
The  eminent  Danish  statesman,  Count  J.  H.  E. 
von .  Bemstorflf,  finding  he  could  not  with  serf 
labour  make  his  property  yield  enough  to  pay 
the  taxes,  freed  the  serfs  in  1767,  paid  them 
wages  for  the  work  they  did,  and  obtained  a 
net  return  of  £150  a  year  (Sugenheim,  Gesch. 
d.  Aufhebung  d.  Leibeigenschaft,  p.  500). 
Storch  mentions  that  he  nearly  tripled  the  pro- 
duction of  his  estate  by  this  enfranchisement, 
raising  his  product  of  rye  in  the  ratio  of  from  3 
to  8^,  of  barley  from  4  to  9^,  and  of  oats  from 
2|-  to  8  {Cours  d' J^conomie  polit. ,  iv.  306). 

In  factory  work  it  has  been  generally  found 
impossible  to  employ  serf  labour  remuneratively 
at  all.  Haxthausen  found  some  old  serf  factories 
in  Russia  during  his  visit,  but  they  were  in  a 
very  languishing  condition,  and  most  of  the 
Russian  manufacturers,  though  they  had  gener- 
ally begun  with  their  unemployed  domestic 
serfs,  and  then  changed  them  for  some  of  their 
agricultural  serfs  who  were  stronger,  had  all  in 
the   end   to  learn  the  same  secret — that  the 


ENFRANCHISEMENT  OF  LAND 


717 


Russian  was  a  bad  workman  when  he  worked 
on  compulsion,  but  became  an  excellent  work- 
man when  he  worked  for  hire.  Force  extorts  but 
the  minimum  of  effect ;  it  is  hope  that  draws 
out  the  maximum.  They  consequently  set 
their  serfs  free,  imposed  a  small  annual  charge 
as  commutation  duty,  and  engaged  them  in  the 
ordinary  way  for  wages  {Russian  JSmjnre,  i.  110), 
precisely  as  Storch  says  had  been  done  in 
Moscow  factories  as  far  back  as  1805  (Cours, 
iv.  30). 

Enfranchisement  has  occasionally  resulted 
ill,  but  that  has  been  due  either  to  moral  defects 
in  the  particular  individuals  or  groups  enfran- 
chised, or  to  the  excessive  burden  of  the  com- 
pensation dues  or  other  conditions  of  the  en- 
franchisement. Freedom  necessarily  contains 
the  possibility  of  doing  worse  as  well  as  the 
possibility  of  doing  better.  J.  G.  Kohl  re- 
peatedly came  across  villages  in  Little  Russia 
with  free  peasants  living  on  one  side  and  serfs 
living  on  the  other,  and  he  always  found  that 
while  the  most  prosperous  inhabitants  of  the 
village  were  among  the  free  peasants,  so  also 
were  the  most  miserable  {Reisen  im  Innern  von 
Russland,  ii.  300).  On  the  Zamoiski  estates  in 
Poland,  enfranchisement  seems  to  have  had  a 
curious  double  action  ;  it  trijDled  the  production 
on  the  proprietor's  fields  (Cox,  Travels  in 
Poland,  i.  22),  but  it  had  a  bad  effect  on  the 
serfs'  own,  because  they  became  drunken  and 
neglected  their  work  (Burnett,  Present  view  of 
Poland,  106).  The  gi-eat  Russian  emancipation 
of  1861  is  the  most  notable  example  of  the 
natural  and  good  operation  of  enfranchisement 
being  vitiated  by  concomitant  economic  and 
social  conditions.  j.  r. 

ENFRANCHISEMENT  OF  LAND  FROM 
COPYHOLD  AND  SIMILAR  TENURES, 
History  of.  The  enfranchisement  of  copy- 
hold lands  in  England  has  passed  through  three 
stages.  It  is  necessary  for  the  purpose  of 
tracing  its  history  to  consider  (1)  enfranchise- 
ment at  common  law  ;  (2)  voluntary  enfran- 
chisement under  the  copyhold  acts  1841- 
1887;  (3)  compulsory  enfranchisement  under 
the  copyhold  acts  1852-1887. 

1,  Enfranchisement  at  common  law.  Copy- 
hold lands  and  lands  of  similar  tenure  must, 
according  to  the  law  of  England,  be  "parcel" 
of  a  manor,  or  in  other  words,  wherever  lands 
are  held  by  copy  of  court  roll,  the  freehold  in 
those  lands  is  in  other  hands  than  those  which 
hold  the  "copy."  The  process  of  enfranchise- 
ment unites,  in  the  hands  of  the  copyholder, 
the  freehold  and  the  copyhold  interest.  It  is 
evident  that  nothing  short  of  the  whole  freehold 
interest  will  suflBee  to  clear  the  land  of  all  its 
copyhold  incidents,  and  therefore  an  enfran- 
chisement at  common  law  may  be  effected  "by  j 
any  lord  entitled  to  the  manor  in  fee  simple, 
or  who  has  a  power  to  enfranchise  or  a  power  of 
sale  and  exchange,"  but  it  cannot  be  effected 


by  a  lord  with  a  more  limited  interest  or  less 
extensive  powers.  An  enfranchisement,  there- 
fore, before  the  year  1841,  was  carried  out 
through  a  conveyance  of  the  fee  simple  of  the 
copyhold  in  question,  from  the  lord  of  the 
manor  to  the  tenant  for  an  agreed  price.  The 
fact  that  the  tenant  himself  had  only  a  limited 
interest  in  his  copyhold  estate  did  not  affect 
the  validity  of  the  enfranchisement,  which 
would  enure  for  the  benefit  of  the  estates  of 
those  who  succeeded  him.  Unless  special  pro- 
visions were  inserted  in  the  conveyance,  three 
somewhat  unexpected  results  would  follow  from 
the  enfranchisement.  (1)  That  the  mines  and 
minerals  would  pass  from  the  lord  to  the  copy- 
holder ;  (2)  that  the  copyholder's  rights  of 
common  in  the  "waste"  of  the  manor  would 
be  extinguished  ;  (3)  that  all  mortgages,  or 
other  incumbrances  affecting  the  lord's  title, 
would  affect  the  enfranchised  lands  in  the 
hands  of  the  quondam  copyholder.  It  will  be 
readily  understood  that  the  difliculties  attend- 
ing enfranchisement,  under  such  conditions, 
rendered  the  conversion  of  copyholds  into  free- 
holds a  cumbrous  and  costly  process. 

In  1802  we  find,  in  the  Land  Tax  Redemp- 
tion Act,  provisions  which  enable  owners  of 
limited  estates  in  manors  to  make  enfranchise- 
ments for  the  purpose  of  obtaining  money  for 
redeeming  the  land  tax.  This  apj)ears  to  be 
the  first  indication  of  the  principle  subsequently 
worked  out  in  the  copyhold  acts. 

2.  In  the  year  1841  was  passed  the  first  of 
the  acts  which  "provide  the  means  for  an 
adequate  compensation  for  the  rents,  fines,  and 
heriots  payable  to  the  lords  of  manors,  in  re- 
spect of  lands  of  copyhold  and  customary 
tenure,  and  for  facilitating  the  voluntary 
enfranchisement  of  sucli  lands,  and  for  im- 
proving such  tenure."  This  act  created  a 
body  of  commissioners  called  the  copyhold 
commissioners,  now  the  land  commissioners, 
whose  consent  and  approval  must  be  obtained 
to  enfranchisements  made  under  the  act. 
Under  this  protection  the  legislature  felt  itself 
enabled  to  give  authority  to  the  lord  of  any 
manor,  "whatever  may  be  his  estate  or 
interests  therein,"  to  enfranchise  "all  or  any 
of  the  lands  holden  of  his  manor,"  and  to  any 
tenant,  "whatever  may  be  his  estate  and 
interest,"  to  accept  such  enfranchisement.  The 
consideration  was  payable  in  money,  but  by 
agreement  such  money  might  be  made  payable 
at  a  future  time.  Whenever  the  lord  who 
enfranchised  had  a  limited  interest  only,  the 
money,  so  soon  as  it  was  paid  over,  was  to  be 
invested,  and  to  be  subject  to  the  same  trusts 
as  those  affecting  the  manor  to  which  the 
enfranchised  copyhold  had  previously  belonged. 
It  was  now  enacted  that  any  rights  of  common 
belonging  to  the  land  enfranchised  should 
continue  to  be  attached  thereto  after  it  had 
become  freehold,  and  that  the  lord's  right  to 


718 


ENFEANCHISEMENT  OF  LAND 


mines  and  minerals,  under  the  enfranchised 
land,  should  not  pass  upon  the  enfranchisement 
unless  expressly  commuted.  Upon  payment  of 
the  sum  payable  for  enfranchisement,  the 
tenant  was  authorised  to  charge  it  upon  the 
lands  enfranchised,  with  aU  the  power^  and 
rights  of  a  first  mortgagee.  Finally,  the  title 
to"  the  enfranchised  copyholds  was  to  be  sepa- 
rated for  ever  from  the  title  to  the  manor. 

By  this  act,  therefore,  three  of  the  main 
impediments  to  general  enfranchisement  were 
done  away  with;  for  (1)  it  was  no  longer 
necessary  to  obtain  the  conveyance  from  an 
absolute  owner  ;  (2)  it  was  no  longer  necessary 
expressly  to  reserve  the  lord's  mines  and 
minerals  and  the  tenant's  rights  of  common  ; 
and  (3)  the  enfranchised  copyholder  had 
nothing  to  fear  from  any  encumbrances  clog- 
ging the  estate  of  his  former  lord.  But 
enfranchisement  still  remained  a  matter  of 
agreement,  and  could  not  be  forced  upon  an 
tm willing  lord.  Amending  acts  are  a  sure 
sign  that  a  statute  is  not  a  dead  letter,  and 
the  Copyhold  Act  of  1841  was  followed  by 
those  of  1843  and  1844.  The  act  of  1843 
provided  that  the  consideration  for  enfranchise- 
ment, which  under  the  act  of  1841  was  a 
lump  sum  of  money,  might  in  future  be  paid 
wholly  or  in  part  by  an  annual  rent  charge, 
or  might  take  the  shape  of  a  conveyance  of 
lands  forming  part  of  the  manor  to  which  the 
enfranchised  lands  had  previously  belonged. 
The  act  of  1844  extended  the  last-mentioned 
provision  to  any  lands  which,  in  the  opinion 
of  the  copyhold  commissioners,  could  be  con- 
veniently held  with  the  manor  to  which  the 
enfranchised  lands  had  previously  belonged, 
although  themselves  not  belonging  to  such 
manor. 

These  three  acts  of  1841,  1843,  and  1844, 
constituted  a  short  code  under  which  volun- 
tary enfranchisement  could  be  satisfactorily 
carried  through.  But  it  was  not  until  1852 
that  compulsory  enfranchisement  became  pos- 
sible for  either  lord  or  tenant. 

3.  The  system  of  compulsory  enfranchise- 
ment, which  was  inaugurated  by  the  Copyhold 
Act  of  1852,  was  applied  in  the  first  instance 
to  those  copyholds  only  to  which  a  new 
tenant  was  admitted  on  or  after  1st  July  1853, 
or  in  other  words,  so  long  as  an  existing  estate 
in  the  copyhold  continued  to  subsist,  neither 
lord  nor  tenant  could  force  an  enfranchisement 
upon  tenant  or  lord.  But  six  years'  experience 
of  the  act  of  1852  enabled  the  legislature  to 
extend  its  provisions  to  all  copyholds  whenever 
the  last  admission  had  been  made  to  them. 

The  key-note  to  the  system  of  compulsory 
enfranchisement  is  valuation  of  the  lord's 
interest  by  independent  valuers,  under  the 
supervision  of  the  copyhold  commissioners. 
The  difficulty  which  compulsory  enfranchise- 
ment had  to  deal  with  was  the  amount  of 


compensation  to  be  paid  to  the  lord  in  respect 
of  fines  and  other  sources  of  profit  to  which, 
if  the  copyhold  interest  continued,  he  wouldJ 
become  entitled  at  uncertain  intervals,  audi 
which,  upon  enfranchisement,  required  to  be 
turned  into  money  once  and  for  all.  Without 
going  into  the  meaning  as  to  "  the  lord's  fine,' 
it  may  be  sufficient  to  say  that  such  fines  are 
payable  when  a  new  tenant  is  admitted,  that 
is,  entered  upon  the  court  rolls  as  the  person 
holding  the  copyhold  tenement  "according  to 
the  custom  of  the  manor."  Originally  the 
price  given  to  induce  the  lord  to  accept  the 
new  tenant,  the  fine,  was  in  its  nature  arbitrary 
and  uncertain,  and  depended  in  each  manor 
upon  the  custom  of  that  particular  manor. 
But  the  courts  of  the  king  had,  at  an  early 
date,  established  that  the  courts  of  the  manorial 
lords  could  not  by  custom  give  efficacy  to 
unreasonable  fines,  and  in  course  of  time  de- 
veloped the  working  rule  that  "two  years' 
improved  value  of  the  land,  after  deducting 
quit-rents,"  was  the  maximum  amount  which 
the  lord  of  a  manor  should  be  entitled  to  receive 
upon  the  admission  of  a  new  tenant. 

How  then  does  the  act  of  1852  meet  this 
problem  ?  In  the  first  place  all  fines  and  ofher 
manorial  dues,  payable  upon  the  admission, 
which  under  that  act  supplies  the  opportunity 
for  enfranchisement,  are  to  be  discharged  before 
any  further  step  is  taken.  Then  the  valuers, 
or  their  umpire,  or  the  single  valuer  agreed  upon 
by  lord  and  tenant,  must  ascertain  the  value 
of  the  manorial  rights  now  exercised  for  the  last 
time.  The  valuation,  when  made,  must  take 
the  form  of  an  award,  must  be  confirmed  by  the 
copyhold  commissioners,  must  be  registered  at 
the  office  of  the  commissioners,  and  must  be 
entered  upon  the  court  rolls.  The  amount  of 
the  valuation,  failing  agreement,  is  to  be  paid 
by  the  tenant  in  a  lump  sum,  if  he  has  claimed 
the  enfranchisement ;  but  if  the  lord  has 
insisted  on  the  change  of  tenure,  the  compensa- 
tion will,  in  the  absence  of  express  agreement, 
take  the  form  of  an  annual  rent-charge.  In 
either  case  the  "enfranchisement  considera- 
tion" is  a  first  charge  upon  the  lands  en- 
franchised. 

Two  provisions  of  this  act  are  noteworthy, 
as  showing  the  caution  with  which  the  legis- 
lature introduced  compulsory  enfranchisement. 
Firstly,  power  is  given  to  the  lord  to  buy  out 
the  copyholder  compulsorily  if  he  can  show,  to 
the  satisfaction  of  the  commissioners,  that  his 
"mansion-house,  park,  garden,  or  pleasure 
grounds,"  may  suffer  from  the  tenant's  enlarged 
powers  of  dealing  with  the  lands  which  are 
ceasing  to  be  copyhold.  Such  a  power  might 
well  be  granted  to  the  lord  if  the  tenant 
threatened  to  open  a  marl  pit  or  cut  down 
standing  timber  upon  land  with  which  he  could 
not  so  deal  whilst  still  a  copyholder.  Secondly, 
if  it  be  found  at  any  time  that  the  person  who 


( 


ENGLISH  EARLY  ECONOMIC  HISTORY 


719 


purported  to  enfrancliise  was  not  the  lord  at^ 
all,  it  is  provided  that  the  true  lord  is  to  re- 
cover the  consideration  for  the  enfranchisement 
from  the  person  who  wrongfully  received  it, 
instead  of  forcing  the  tenant  to  pay  the  money 
again  and  look  to  the  wrong-doer  for  com- 
pensation. 

Valuers  acting  under  the  Copyhold  Act 
1852  must  take  into  consideration  "facilities 
for  improvement,"  as,  for  example,  the  possi- 
bility that  the  land  may  become  building  land, 
and  the  hindrances  to  such  improvement,  as, 
for  example,  the  probability  that  it  will  not 
become  buUding  land  for  some  years. 

The  Copyhold  Act  1858  is  to  the  Copyhold 
Act  1852  what  the  Copyhold  Acts  1843  and 
1844  are  to  the  Copyhold  Act  1841.  It  con- 
tains such  improvements  as  the  working  of  the 
principal  act  had  suggested.  Thus  for  the 
deed  of  enfranchisement  specified  by  the  act 
of  1852,  which  the  parties  would  execute,  was 
substituted  an  award  of  enfranchisement  to  be 
made  by  the  copyhold  commissioners  ;  owners 
of  at  least  two-thirds  of  the  value  of  copyholds 
held  in  undivided  shares,  obtained  the  power 
to  insist  on  an  enfranchisement  whatever  their 
co-tenants  might  desire ;  and  one  form  of  certifi- 
cate of  charge  was  provided  for  securing  the 
payment  of  consideration  money,  compensation 
money,  and  expenses  of  enfranchisement,  as 
the  case  might  be. 

Speaking  generally,  the  costs  of  a  voluntary 
enfranchisement  are  paid  in  manner  agreed  by 
the  parties,  or,  failing  agreement,  are  paid  as 
directed  by  the  commissioners  ;  while  the  costs 
of  a  compulsory  enfranchisement  are  to  be  paid 
by  the  party  who  has  insisted  upon  abolishing 
the  copyhold  tenure. 

In  1887,  after  an  interval  of  thirty  years, 
an  act  was  passed  "to  make  further  provisions 
for  enfranchisement"  of  copyhold  lands.  An 
important  provision  of  this  act  is  that  the 
steward  of  any  manor,  when  a  new  tenant 
comes  for  admission  to  a  copyhold,  must  hand 
to  such  tenant  a  notice  stating  that  he  is 
entitled,  if  he  desires,  to  enfranchise  the  copy- 
hold. A  further  provision  of  great  import- 
ance prevents  the  lords  of  manors  from  making 
grants  of  portions  of  the  "waste"  of  their 
manors.  Again,  the  tenant  may  pay  the  com- 
pensation for  an  enfranchisement  on  which  he 
has  insisted  by  means  of  a  rent-cliarge  of  4  per 
cent  of  the  amount  of  compensation.  Finally, 
the  compensation  to  the  steward  of  the  manor 
is  fixed  by  a  schedule  to  the  act,  and  the  land 
commissioners  are  directed  to  "  frame  a  scale  of 
compensation"  such  as  "will  facilitate  enfran- 
chisement." The  scale  published  in  conformity 
with  this  act  comprises  a  table  in  which  is  cal- 
culated the  number  of  years'  annual  value  pay- 
able to  the  lord,  according  to  the  age  of  the 
tenant,  as  compensation  for  the  loss  of  future 
fines.     An  act,  consolidating  all  earlier  legisla- 


tion, was  passed  in  1894,  under  which  both 
compulsory  and  voluntary  enfranchisements  are 
now  effected.  The  powers  formerly  in  the  hands 
of  the  land  commissioners  are  now  exercised  by 
the  Board  of  Agriculture,  whose  consent  must  be 
obtained  both  for  voluntary  and  compulsory 
enfranchisements.  The  latter  are  effected  by 
an  award  made  by  the  Board,  and  the  Board 
directs  the  valuation  for  compensation.  The 
party  demanding  the  enfranchisement  must 
bear  the  expense.  The  tenant  has  in  all  cases 
the  choice  of  paying  the  compensation  either  in 
a  gross  sum  or  as  an  annual  rent  charge,  but 
when  the  lord  is  the  compelling  party,  the 
compensation  is  paid  as  a  rent  charge  unless 
the  tenant  desires  otherwise. 

Enfranchisements  on  crown  lands,  church- 
lands,  and  university  and  college  lands,  are 
the  subject  of  special  statutes. 

[Brown,  Qopyhold  Enfranchisement  Acts,  1888. 
— Scriven,  On  Copyholds,  6th  edition,  1882. — 
Elton,  Law  of  Copyholds,  1898,] 

ENGLISH  EARLY  ECONOMIC  HISTORY. 

— In  the  present  state  of  historical  investigation, 
it  is  difficult  to  give  a  complete  account  of  the 
development  of  political  economy  in  England. 
Many  writers  have  devoted  attention  to  the 
subject,  and  reached  important  conclusions,  but 
comparatively  little  use  has  been  made  of  the 
v^ast  stores  of  material  relating  to  the  later 
middle  ages,  and  the  rise  and  fall  of  the  mer- 
cantile system.  Particular  movements  have 
indeed  been  carefully  investigated,  and  we  are 
not  without  indications  of  the  general  course 
of  development.  To  take  an  illustration  from 
mathematics,  certain  points  on  the  curve  of 
development  have  been  ascertained  ;  we  have 
some  idea  of  its  shape  ;  we  know  also  that  the 
English  curve  is  only  one  of  a  large  family  of 
curves,  other  members  of  which  may  be  found  on 
the  continent.  But  of  its  direction  between  the 
points  ascertained,  and  of  the  ditterences  be- 
tween it  and  others  of  the  same  class,  we  know 
little. 

The  subject  may  be  best  approached  by  con- 
sidering the  influence  of  the  mediseval  church. 
Before  the  conversion  of  the  Anglo-Saxons  to 
Christianity  there  was  little  commerce,  but 
Christian  merchants  resorted  to  England  while 
the  inhabitants  were  still  pagans,  and  so  brought 
them  into  contact  with  a  more  highly  developed 
economy  than  their  own.  Many  of  the  prin- 
ciples which  we  find  in  mediseval  economic 
teaching  may  probably  be  traced  back  to  this 
or  an  earlier  period  ;  for  example,  the  idea 
of  money  as  a  pledge,  which  exercised  an  im- 
portant influence  on  economic  doctrine  in 
England  far  into  the  17th  century.  Neither 
the  condemnation  of  avarice  nor  hostility  to 
usury  was  peculiar  to  Christianity.  The  social 
system  of  the  middle  ages,  greatly  modified  as 
it  was  by  Christian  teaching,  had  its  foundations 
in  a  pre-Christian  state  of  society.    But  making 


720 


ENGLISH  EARLY  ECONOMIC  HISTORY 


every  allowance  for  the  influence  of  ideas  and 
customs  derived  from  earlier  times,  the  fact 
that  the  new  religion  obtained  a  linn  hold  on 
the  jjopulation  while  industry  and  commerce 
were  still  in  their  infancy,  is  of  primary  im- 
portance in  tracing  the  development  of  p<jlitical 
economy.  Early  economic  institutions  and  laws 
are  stamped  with  the  teaching  of  the  church. 
Subsequent  modifications  of  doctrine  are  largely 
the  outcome  of  the  struggle,  on  the  part  of  the 
church,  to  guide  or  control  new  economic  forces 
as  they  gradually  came  into  operation.  To 
follow  rightly  the  course  of  development  it  is 
firat  of  all  necessary  to  understand  the  position  of 
the  church  with  regard  to  trade  and  industry. 

From  the  earliest  times  the  church  had  had 
forced  upon  it  the  duty  of  applying  the  prin- 
ciples of  Christianity  to  social  life.  Outside 
Palestine  the  earliest  converts  were  found  in 
the  busy  trading  centres  of  Asia  Minor  ;  and  the 
first  persecutions  were  probably  due  to  the  fact 
that  the  new  religion  threatened  various  trading 
interests,  and  tended  to  the  overthrow  of  the 
existing  social  system  (Ramsay's  Church  in  the 
Roman  Empire,  pp.  12,  199,  200,  etc.).  But 
the  church  was  hostile  to  the  ordinary  usages  of 
the  world  only  in  so  far  as  they  were  in  conflict 
with  the  ideal  of  Christianity,  which  supplied  a 
standard  by  which  all  actions  in  the  economic 
sphere  could  be  tested.  Everything  incon- 
sistent with  the  profession  of  Christianity  was 
condemned,  and  uncompromising  obedience  to  its 
precepts  was  enjoined.  The  process  of  applying 
Christianity,  in  changing  or  widely  differing 
social  conditions,  went  on  in  the  earlier  centuries 
of  the  Christian  era  and  throughout  the  middle 
ages.  The  work  of  the  church  was  not  so  much 
to  introduce  new  principles  of  action  as  to  test 
those  already  known,  assimilating  those  which 
were  not  hostile  to  Christianity,  and  giving  them 
new  significance  when  considered  in  the  light  of 
the  Christian  faith. 

The  pursuit  of  gain  as  an  end  in  itself  was 
obviously  inconsistent  with  Christianity,  and 
the  condemnation  of  avarice  in  every  form  is 
one  of  the  most  striking  characteristics  of  the 
teaching  of  the  church.  This  may  be  regarded 
as  the  fundamental  principle  of  mediaeval  econ- 
omics. Its  different  parts  are  so  closely  inter- 
woven with  each  other  that  we  can  without 
much  difficulty  reconstruct  the  whole  system 
from  any  one  of  its  elements.  Closely  bound 
up  with  the  condemnation  of  avarice  was  hos- 
tility to  many  methods  of  acquiring  wealth 
which  have  since  been  adopted  by  civilised  com- 
munities, and  chief  amongst  those  forbidden 
methodswas  Usury (5'. -y.),  the  objection  to  which 
extended  to  aU  forms  of  investment  for  the  sake 
of  gain.  But  the  general  teaching  of  the  church 
would  have  had  comparatively  little  influence 
but  for  its  wide  and  far-reaching  application  of 
the  principle  of  association.  The  interests  of 
the  individual  were  subordinated  to  those  of  the 


community.  The  duty  of  helping  those  in  need, 
and  the  brotherhood  of  all  Christians,  were  in- 
sisted on.  It  was  this  side  of  the  teaching  of 
the  church  (see  Christianity  and  Economics  ; 
Church,  the  Me  DiiEVAL)  which  accelerated,  if  it 
did  not  initiate,  the  formation  of  gilds  and  other 
associations,  and  ultimately  led  to  the  creation 
of  the  elaborate  system  of  the  middle  ages  for 
the  regulation  of  trade  and  the  restraint  of  com- 
petition. Insistence  also  on  a  just  or  reasonable 
price  for  commodities,  the  approximate  deter- 
mination of  which  was  easier  in  this  early  stage 
of  industrial  development  than  it  would  be  in 
modern  times,  led  to  numerous  laws  framed 
with  a  view  to  realising  that  object.  It  may  be 
noticed  as  evidence  of  the  hold  which  mediaeval 
doctrines  obtained,  that  the  expression  ''just 
price  "  (JusTUM  Pretium),  interpreted  to  mean 
that  price  which  most  closely  approximated  to 
cost  of  production,  was  used  as  a  synonym  for 
"cost  price  "as  late  as  the  end  of  the  16  th 
century. 

{Vide  R.  Recordb's  Orounde  of  Aries,  1543, 
frequently  reprinted  and  edited  by  Dr.  Dee,  Jolm 
Mel  lis,  Eobert  Norton,  and  others.) 

The  early  hostility  of  the  church  to  usury  was 
based  on  the  biblical  records  and  on  the  authori- 
tative declarations  of  the  Christian  fathers  and 
the  councUs.  Had  the  church  maintained  its 
original  attitude  there  can  be  no  doubt  that  its 
influence  would  have  seriously  hampered  econo- 
mic development.  It  became  impossible,  how- 
ever, to  regard  with  hostility  many  of  the  new 
methods  of  acquiring  wealth  which  appeared 
with  the  extension  of  trade  and  commerce,  and 
thus  began  one  of  the  most  interesting  move- 
ments of  thought  of  the  middle  ages,  viz.  the 
adaptation  of  the  principles  of  Christian  teach- 
ing on  the  subject  of  lending  and  borrowing  to 
the  needs  of  a  changing  environment.  This 
process  begins  about  the  twelfth  century.  The 
canonist  writers,  on  the  one  hand,  endeavoured 
to  separate  the  essential  from  the  non-essential 
elements  of  the  doctrine  of  usury,  and  to  apply 
it  to  mercantile  transactions,  strengthening 
their  position  by  appeals  to  Aristotle's  doctrine 
of  the  barrenness  of  money,  the  conception  of 
natv/ral  law,  and  other  arguments  ;  while,  on 
the  other  hand,  merchants  and  traders,  anxious 
to  escape  the  "censure  of  usury,"  appear  to 
have  been  not  unwilling  to  submit  to  decisions 
which,  on  the  whole,  did  not  seriously  hamper 
freedom  of  investment.  Bond  fide  credit  agencies, 
bills  of  exchange,  loans  for  trading  purposes,  the 
payment  of  interest  whenever  the  lender  could 
show  that  the  loan  would  result  in  "  certain  gain 
lost"  or  "actual  loss  incurred,"  rent  charges, 
partnership,  loans  on  bottomry,  and  other  ex- 
pedients for  securing  a  return  for  the  invest- 
ment of  capital,  were  gradually  approved  by  the 
canonist  writers,  and  the  outcome  of  the  move- 
ment was  that  the  doctrine  of  usury  was  stripped 


ENGLISH  EARLY  ECONOMIC  HISTORY 


721 


of  everything  likely  to  prove  an  obstacle  to  the 
practice  of  ordinary  business  methods. 

Such  was  the  course  of  movement  on  the 
continent.  But  for  the  present  we  are  only 
entitled  to  say  that  there  was  a  general  similar- 
ity between  English  and  continental  opinion 
during  this  period.  No  doubt  many  passages 
may  be  quoted  from  English  statutes  which 
appear  to  be  suggested  by  the  canon  law.  The 
influence  of  the  church  was  great,  and  the  trading 
classes  would  not  lightly  risk  excommunication 
for  the  sake  of  gain.  "Goods  lost,  nothing  lost ; 
credit  lost,  much  lost;  soul  lost,  all  lost,"  is  an 
old  proverb  ;  and  even  as  late  as  1486  Pope 
Sixtus  IV.  thought  it  worth  while  granting  to 
the  inhabitants  of  the  Channel  Islands  "the 
help  and  authority  of  the  church  by  interdict, 
anathema,  and  other  forms  of  censure,  for  the 
repression  of  piracy,  robbery,  and  violence " 
{Materials  for  history  of  the  reign  of  Henry  VII. 
(Rolls  series)  i.  280).  The  ordinary  teaching  of 
the  church,  whatever  may  have  been  its  practice, 
was  hostile  to  avarice  and  covetousness  (vide, 
for  example,  the  homily  in  Ashm.  MSS.  750), 
and  occasionally  the  influence  of  the  Gilds 
{q.v.)  may  have  been  favourable  to  the  rule  of 
the  Canon  Lavs^  {I-v.)  [Ordinances  of  the  Gild  of 
St.  Leonard,  Lynn,  Toulmin  Smith's  collection, 
p.  50].  The  usury  laws  also  were  enforced  and 
had  the  support  of  the  trading  classes  (Liber 
Alhus,  ed.  1861,  318,  319,  339).  But  such 
evidence  enables  us  to  say  only  that  there  was  a 
general  similarity,  which  indeed  we  should 
expect,  between  England  and  the  continent ;  and 
in  the  development  of  economic  doctrine  the 
points  of  difference  are  of  equal  if  not  of  greater 
importance.  The  backwardness  of  investigation 
prevents  us  from  dealing  with  the  latter  with 
any  completeness  of  detail.  The  following, 
however,  may  be  noted.  Neither  the  canon  law 
nor  the  civil  law  was  received  in  England  as 
authoritative  "except  educationally,  and  as 
furnishing  scientific  confirmation  for  empiric 
argument."  (Stubbs,  Lectures  on  Mediceval  and 
Modern  History,  307.)  The  canonists,  however, 
claimed  that  "a  suit  might  be  brought  in  the 
ecclesiastical  courts  for  every  matter  which  was 
not  cognisable  in  the  courts  of  secular  law,  and  for 
a  great  many  matters  which  were  so  cognisable  " 
{ib.  316),  and  there  was  a  long  conflict  on  the 
subject.  The  system  of  rent  charges  was  not  gene- 
rally prevalent  in  England,  and  montes  pietatis 
were  never  established  (see  Mont  de  Vitrt).  An 
attempt  to  introduce  the  latter  was  made  without 
success,  by  Gerard  Malynes,  early  in  the  17th 
century  {Lex  Mercatoria,  1622).  The  economic 
legislation  of  the  14th  and  15th  centuries  was 
largely  empirical.  In  the  regulation  of  foreign 
trade  especially,  and  in  the  organisation  of  the 
customs,  the  measures  adopted  were  mainly  de- 
termined by  the  fiscal  necessities  of  the  govern- 
ment, and  we  can  see  very  early  the  tendency  to 
subordinate  trade  to  the  exigencies  of  foreign 
VOL.  I. 


diplomacy  (e.  9'.  in  the  relations  between  England 
and  Flanders)  which  became  so  prominent  a 
feature  of  later  commercial  development. 
Councils  of  merchants  were  summoned  by 
Edward  I.  and  Edward  III.  to  advise  with  them 
on  questions  of  trade  (see  Rymer,  Foedera  (1821) 
vol.  ii.  pt.  V.  1057).  The  general  impression  we 
get  from  a  study  of  the  legislation  of  this  period 
and  from  such  arguments  as  are  recorded  in  the 
Rolls  of  Parliament,  is  that  many  of  the  meas- 
ures adopted  were  tentative  and  experimental. 
To  understand  therefore  the  economic  ideas  of 
the  time  we  must  examine  closely  the  statutes 
and  institutions  in  which  they  were  embodied. 
Such  were  the  statutes  regulating  wages  and 
prices,  the  organisation  of  the  crafts,  the  staple 
system,  restraints  on  the  exportation  of  bullion, 
statutes  of  employment,  and  usury  laws.  We 
may  notice  the  following  points:  (1)  The  move- 
ment of  thought  on  the  subject  of  usury  was 
slower  in  England  than  on  the  continent.  (2) 
Financial  methods  well  known  on  the  continent 
were  not  introduced  into  England  until  com- 
paratively recent  times.  The  discussion,  there- 
fore, of  various  credit  agencies  which  did  so  much 
to  modify  continental  opinion  was  scarcely  pos- 
sible in  England.  (3)  The  impression  prevailed 
— with  what  reason  it  is  unnecessary  here  to 
discuss — that  the  staple  system,  while  imposing 
certain  regulations  on  all  merchants  alike, 
was  not  imfavourable  to  freedom  of  enter- 
prise. (4)  Money,  so  far  from  being  subject 
to  the  same  laws  as  other  commodities,  was 
supposed  to  be  essentially  different  from  them. 
It  was,  in  fact,  not  a  commodity  at  all,  but  a 
pledge,  a  medium  of  exchange,  circulating  under 
the  authority  of  the  prince  or  commonwealth, 
its  value  determined  solely  by  that  authority. 
The  first  appearance  of  those  forces  which  were 
destined  to  break  up  the  mediseval  system 
should  be  noted.  In  the  reign  of  Richard  II.  we 
have  the  first  navigation  act ;  then  the  begin- 
ning of  various  trading  companies,  especially 
that  of  the  merchant  adventurers  (see  Adven- 
turers, Merchants  ;  Navigation  Laws). 

We  are  now  in  a  position  to  trace  the  subse- 
quent development  of  economic  doctrine  in 
England.  The  reign  of  Henry  VII.  was  of 
great  importance  in  the  economic  history  of  the 
country,  and  its  industrial  and  commercial  pro- 
gress very  soon  brought  about  far-reaching 
changes  in'  economic  ideas.  From  the  middle 
of  the  16th  century  onwards  there  were  few 
years  in  which  some  book  or  pamphlet  was  not 
published  on  subjects  of  economic  interest, 
and  such  works  may  be  reckoned  by  thousands. 
It  is  diflBcult  to  draw  a  sharp  line  of  division 
between  economic  and  non-economic  publica- 
tions. We  shall,  however,  keep  as  closely  as 
possible  to  the  main  line  of  development  of 
doctrine,  and  in  a  later  section  indicate  the 
relation  to  it  of  other  currents  of  thought. 

English  statesmen  and  writers  in  the  middle 

3  a 


722 


ENGLISH  EARLY  ECOI^OMIC  HISTORY 


of  the  16th  century  had  to  face  the  most  diffi- 
cult economic  problems  which  could  possibly  be 
submitted  to  them.     The  mediaeval  system  for 
the  municipal  control  of  trade  was  unsuitable 
for  the  regulation  of  the  new  economic  forces 
which  the  extension  of  the  domestic  system, 
especially  in  the  woollen  industry,  brought  into 
deration.     The  decay  of  tillage,  and  the  growth 
of  enclosures,  appeared  to  threaten  the  country 
with  the  evils  of  depopulation,  as  well  as  a 
great  increase  in  poverty.     The  social  changes 
induced  by  the  reformation  seemed  to  be  equally 
momentous.     In  relation  to  foreign  trade,  the 
loss  of  Calais  inflicted  a  death-blow  on  the  staple 
system,  and  the  withdrawal  of  the  privileges  of 
the  Hanse  merchants  injured  the  interests  of  a 
section  of  English  merchants,  although  it  left 
the  way  clear  for  the  development  of  a  national 
foreign   trade  by  the  merchant  adventurers. 
In  the  growth  of  industry  and  commerce  these 
difficulties  were  inevitable.     There  must  have 
been  great  disturbance  and  loss  to  some  classes, 
but  in  time  the  country  would  have  settled  down 
to  the  new  conditions.     The  evils,  however,  of 
the  period  of  transition  were  aggravated  by  a 
currency  problem  of  the  first  magnitude.     The 
debasement  of  the  coinage  under  Henry  VIII. 
and  Edward  VI. ,  coupled  later  on  with  the  influx 
of  the  new  silver  from  the  American  mines,  led 
to  a  rise  of  prices  without  parallel  in  the  history 
of  the  country.     The  evils  of  the  debasement 
were  felt  especially  by  the  landed  interest,  the 
government,  and  the  working  classes.     It  is  im- 
portant to  keep  these  facts  in  mind,  for  they 
formed  the  subject-matter  of  the  earliest  economic 
literature.     One   treatise — the   Brief e   Conceit 
of  English  Policy,  attributed  to  William  Staff"ord, 
and  published  in  1581,  but  really  written  by 
John  Hales  about  1549  {Eng.  Hist.  Review,  vi. 
284) — deals  with  these  questions  as  a  whole,  and 
sums  up  the  aims  of  the  government  at  this 
time.     The  writer  shows  a  clear  insight  into 
the  causes  of  the  high  prices  ;  his  work  is  in- 
valuable as  a  storehouse  of  information,  and  in 
it  we  have  a  broad  outline  of  the  theory  of  the 
balance  of  trade,  which  was  elaborated  in  the 
following  years.     The  Brief e  Conceit,  however, 
scarcely  enables  us  to  trace  distinctly  the  relation 
between  the  opinions  which  have  already  been 
described,  and  later  economic  doctrine.     To  do 
that  we  must  go  to  the  history  of  the  merchant 
adventurers. 

With  the  growth  of  their  trade,  the  merchant 
adventurers  naturally  adopted  means  of  avoid- 
ing the  transmission  of  bullion,  such  as  bills  of 
exchange,  which  had  long  been  in  use  for  certain 
transactions.  Until  the  middle  of  the  16th 
century  aU  went  weU,  but  then  the  fluctuations 
in  the  ratio  of  exchange  between  London  and 
Antwerp,  and  other  places,  brought  into  pro- 
minence the  usurious  aspects  of  bill  discounting, 
and  the  opponents  of  the  merchant  adventurers 
attributed  the  rise  in  prices  to  their  practices. 


It  was  commonly  believed  that  it  was  within 
the  power  and  the  exclusive  right  of  the  govern- 
ment to  fix  the  rate   of  exchange,  and   thus 
determine  the  prices  of  commodities.     We  can- 
not here  detail  the  circumstances  which  gave 
rise  to  this  theory.     It  must  suffice  to  say  that 
when   it  arose  it  was  not  altogether  absurd  ; 
there  was  much  in   the   ordinary   practice   of 
merchants  to  give  some  show  of  truth  to  the 
theory  ;  and  it  was  closely  bound  up  with  the 
doctrine   of  usury.     From  the  middle  of  the 
16th   century  until   late   in   the  17  th  it  was 
advocated  in  pamphlets,  and  pressed  upon  the 
attention  of  the  government,  which  was  really 
uncertain  how  to  act.      It  was  the  basis  of  the 
charge  of  usury,  which  was  one  of  the  most 
usual  arguments  against  the  merchant  adven- 
turers {vide  the  Treatise   on  Exchange,   1564, 
printed  in  Milles's  Customers  Replie,  1604),  and 
the  economic  world  was  divided  into  two  opposite 
camps  —  the   buUionists,    represented   by   the 
advocates  of  the  Staple  System  {q.v.),  and  the 
newer  mercantile   school   represented    by   the 
merchant  adventurers  and  their  supporters.    In 
his  economic  works,  nine  in  number,  though 
only    five     survive,    Thomas     Milles,    head 
customer  of  Sandwich,  undertook  the  defence 
of  the  staple  system,  and  denounced  the  mono- 
polising tendency  of  the  merchant  adventurers. 
In  his  Customers  Apology  (1601),  we  have  a 
curious  anticipation  of  Adam  Smith's  canons  of 
taxation,  and  one  of  the  earliest  instances  of 
the  claim  for  free  trade  based  upon  the  theory 
of  natural  rights  (cp.  Report  from  the  Committee 
on  the  Free  Trade  Bills,  1604,  JouvTials  of  the 
House  of  Commons,  ii.  218-221.    The  monopoly 
of  the  merchant  adventurers  was  "against  the 
natural  right   and   liberty  of  the  subjects  of 
England.")    The  attacks  on  the  company  called 
forth   John   Wheeler's    Treatise    of   Commerce 
(1601).     Wheeler  was  secretary  to  the  mer- 
chant adventurers,  and  his  statements  are  not 
free  from  bias  and  inaccuracy,  but  his  book  is  a 
good  defence  of  their  policy  and  aims.    Wheeler's 
reply  to  Milles  provoked  another  attack  from 
the  latter,  in  the  Customers  Replie  (1604),  in 
which  he  added  to  the  force  of  his  own  argu- 
ments by  reprinting  the  Treatise  on  Exchange  in 
Merchandise  and  Merchandising  Exchange  men- 
tioned above.     We  need  not,  however,  follow 
him  through  his  other  works.  His  mantle  fell  on 
Gerard  Malynes,  who  was  more  moderate  in  his 
views,  and  had  more  knowledge  and  experience 
than  Milles.     Meanwhile,  the  East  India  Com- 
pany had  obtained  their  charter,  and  in  it  a 
clause  allowing  them  to  export  bullion.    In  con- 
sequence of  this,  the  controversy  on  the  foreign 
exchanges,  the  brunt  of  which  had  been  borne 
by  the  merchant  adventurers,  was  turned  against 
the  East  India  Company.     Matters  were  also 
complicated  by  the  introduction  of  a  new  element 
into  the  discussion,  viz.  the  relative  advantages 
of  joint -stock   and   regulated    companies   for 


ENGLISH  EARLY  ECONOMIC  HISTORY 


723 


carrying  on  distant  trade,  the  East  India  Com- 
pany being  an  example  of  the  former,  and  the 
merchant  adventurers  of  the  latter.  It  must 
also  be  pointed  out  that  the  state  of  trade  in 
the  reign  of  James  I.  caused,  reasonably  or  un- 
reasonably, much  anxiety ;  and  the  currency,  the 
privileges  of  the  trading  companies,  the  price 
of  wool,  the  navigation  acts,  etc.,  formed  from 
time  to  time  the  subject  of  government  inquiry. 
We  shall  deal  with  these  issues  later  on  ;  they 
are  mentioned  now  to  show  how  impossible  it 
becomes  with  the  growing  complexity  of  economic 
questions  to  separate  the  writers  of  this  period 
into  well-defined  gi'oups.  Early  in  the  reign  of 
James  I.  there  was  some  possibility  of  the 
revival  of  the  old  machinery  for  the  regula- 
tion of  the  foreign  exchanges.  The  controversy 
burst  into  new  life  in  1622.  To  meet  the 
charges  brought  against  the  East  India  Com- 
pany, Thomas  MuN  published,  in  1621,  his 
Discourse  of  Trade  from  England  to  the  East 
Indies,  which  was  devoted  partly  to  showing 
the  advantages  of  the  exportation  of  bullion. 
It  is  interesting  to  notice,  however,  that  as  yet 
Mun  had  not  entirely  broken  away  from  the 
old  school,  for  in  this  work  he  approved  of  the 
statutes  of  employment.  Edward  Misselden, 
for  some  time  deputy  governor  of  the  mer- 
chant adventurers  at  Delft,  had  long  devoted 
attention  to  the  woollen  trade,  and  in  1622  he 
published  his  Free  Trade,  or  the  means  to  make 
Trade  flourish.  In  this  work  he  discusses  the 
reasons  for  the  backwardness  of  the  English 
cloth  trade,  and  defends  the  company  organisa- 
tion. But  for  some  cause  he  appears  to  have 
been  not  unwilling  to  disarm  the  opposition 
to  the  merchant  adventurers  and  to  turn  it 
against  the  East  India  Company  ;  and  amongst 
the  causes  of  the  decay  of  trade  he  enumerates 
the  exportation  of  bullion  by  the  latter. 

Now  Malynes  had  already,  in  his  earlier 
pamphlets,  found  a  sufficient  cause  not  only  for 
depression  of  trade,  but  for  all  social  evils,  in  the 
theory  of  the  foreign  exchanges  which  we  have 
already  noticed.  To  his  mind  the  only  remedy 
likely  to  prove  efficacious  was  the  revival  of 
the  staple  system.  Naturally,  therefore,  he 
thought  Misselden  completely  mistaken  in  the 
causes  to  which  he  attributed  the  supposed 
decay  of  trade,  and  he  approved  of  a  joint- 
stock  company  for  the  East  India  trade.  He 
therefore  replied  to  Misselden  in  his  Mainten- 
ance of  Free  Trade  (1622),  in  which  he  re- 
iterated his  theory  of  the  foreign  exchanges. 
This  pamphlet  was  almost  immediately  followed 
by  his  great  folio  Lex  Mercatoria,  in  which  he 
expressed  the  same  views. 

We  may  digress  for  a  moment  to  point  out 
that  we  probably  owe  to  Malynes  the  introduc- 
tion of  the  word  "capital"  into  England.  At 
the  beginning  of  the  17th  century  this  word  was 
unknown,  or  at  any  rate  not  in  use  in  England. 
In  his  Lex  Mercatoria,  Malynes  endeavours  to 


popularise  the  Italian  and  Dutch  method  of 
keeping  accounts,  and  he  describes  the  capital 
or  stock  of  a  merchant  as  consisting  of  the  goods 
in  his  warehouse,  his  ready  money,  debts  due 
to  him,  houses  and  lands  in  his  possession, 
and  his  "plate,  apparell,  and  household  stuff." 
"Capital,"  as  used  by  Malynes,  was  derived 
from  capitale,  very  numerous  instances  of  which 
may  be  given  from  continental  treatises  on 
mercantile  law. 

To  return  to  the  controversy  of  1622, 
Malynes's  work  was  not  allowed  to  pass  unques- 
tioned. In  1623,  Misselden  replied  in  his 
Circle  of  Commerce,  or  the  Ballance  of  Trade, 
in  which  he  completely  refuted  Malynes's  theory 
of  the  foreign  exchanges,  and,  taking  up  the 
defence  of  the  East  India  Company,  pointed 
out  the  advantages  of  the  exportation  of  bullion, 
and  sketched  the  theory  of  the  balance  of  trade. 
Malynes  again  replied,  but  his  theory  had  been 
completely  demolished.  Thus  the  mercantilists 
not  only  arrived  at  a  truer  doctrine  of  inter- 
national trade,  but  in  doing  so  destroyed  a 
theory  with  which  the  old  views  with  regard 
to  usury  were  closely  bound  up.  In  1628 
Thomas  Mun  further  developed  the  argument 
for  the  exportation  of  bullion  in  the  Petition  and 
Remonstrance  of  the  East  India  Covipany,  which 
was  republished  in  1641.  Meanwhile,  Sir 
Ralph  Maddison  had  been  devoting  attention 
to  the  subject.  He  had  sat,  with  Mun  and 
others,  on  the  royal  commission  of  1622, 
though  for  some  reason  his  name  was  omitted 
on  the  reappointment  of  the  commission  in 
1625.  Under  the  commonwealth  and  the  pro- 
tectorate he  was  regarded  as  a  great  authority 
on  currency  questions.  He  gave  a  clear  state- 
ment of  the  theory  of  the  balance  of  trade  in 
England's  looking  in  and  out,  1640,  a  work 
which  was  reprinted  in  1641,  and  again,  with 
a  few  verbal  changes  and  additions,  in  1655 
under  the  title  of  Great  Britain's  liemembrancer. 
Maddison,  however,  holds  a  middle  position 
between  Malynes  and  Mun,  for  his  views  on 
currency  and  the  foreign  exchanges  appear  to 
be  based  upon  the  works  of  the  former.  Mun 
incorporated  the  arguments  of  tlie  Petition  and 
Remonstrance  in  England's  Treasure  by  Foreign 
Trade,  published  in  1664,  some  years  after  his 
death,  and  this  work  became  the  chief  bulwark 
of  the  mercantile  system  in  England.  It  passed 
through  many  editions  and  exercised  an  in- 
fluence almost  incredible  at  the  present  time. 
Thus  the  great  system  of  which  we  find  the 
general  outline  in  the  Brief e  Conceit  of  English 
Policy  was  furnished  with  an  economic  basis. 
But  before  we  describe  the  principal  character- 
istics of  Mun's  work,  it  is  desirable  to  trace 
the  development  of  the  other  lines  of  thought 
which  his  book  brought  to  a  focus. 

The  economic  writers  of  the  16  th  and  the 
17th  centuries  agreed  in  maintaining  that  the 
unrestricted  operation  of  the  motive  of  self- 


724 


ENGLISH  EARLY  ECONOMIC  HISTORY 


interest  led  to  disorders  in  the  state,  and  that  an 
eflBcient  system  of  industrial  and  trade  organ- 
isation was  necessary  to  direct  the  economic 
activities  of  the  country  into  the  right  channels. 
They  set  before  themselves  a  definite  object, 
the  "public  good,"  by  which  they  mea»t  the 
creation  of  a  ''commonwealth,"  in  which  the 
various  trading  interests  should  be  so  balanced 
as  to  secure  the  greatest  economic  efficiency  of  the 
various  elements  consistent  with  the  self-suffi- 
ciency of  the  nation  as  a  whole ;  and  considerable 
prominence  is  given  to  this  idea  as  an  "economic 
motive  "  in  the  works  of  the  best  writers.  Thus 
Mun  distinguishes  between  three  sorts  of  gain,  (i) 
that  of  the  commonwealth,  which  was  sometimes 
the  merchant's  loss  ;  (ii)  that  of  the  merchant, 
"which  he  doth  sometimes  justly  and  worthily 
effect,  although  the  commonwealth  be  a  loser"  ; 
and  (iii)  that  of  the  king,  "whereof  he  is  ever 
certain"  (Bnglaiid's  Treasure,  etc.,  p.  64),  but 
he  had  previously  stated  the  rule  that,  in  com- 
merce, "private  gain  was  ever  to  accompany 
the  publique  good  "  {ih.  p.  3).  The  pursuit  of 
the  public  good,  interpreted  in  the  sense  given 
to  it  above,  was  a  real  force  in  the  economic 
world,  and  the  suppression  of  a  trade  "hurtful 
to  the  commonwealth  "  was  generally  approved. 
Taking  the  mercantile  system  at  its  best,  it 
shows  a  distinct  advance  on  mediseval  ideas  in 
the  substitution  of  the  wider  interests  of  the 
nation  for  those  of  the  craft  or  the  munici- 
pality. On  the  other  hand,  it  must  be  admitted 
that  the  majority  of  the  writers  show  little  or 
no  consciousness  of  a  high  national  aim.  The 
"  hurtful "  trade  generally  happened  to  be  that 
of  a  rival  company,  a  dependency,  or  a  neigh- 
bouring nation.  The  mercantilists  differed  too 
from  the  laisser  faire  school  in  the  views  they 
held  on  the  relation  of  economic  questions  to 
religion,  politics,  and  other  subjects.  Economic 
interests  could  not  be  isolated.  Prosperity  was 
the  result  of  various  economic,  political,  and  re- 
ligious forces  mutually  interdependent.  Thus 
Sir  William  Temple  remarks  of  Holland : 
"  The  trade  of  this  country  is  discovered  to  be 
no  effect  of  common  contrivances,  of  natural 
dispositions  or  situation,  or  of  trivial  accidents, 
but  of  a  great  concurrence  of  circumstances," 
amongst  which  he  enumerates  the  immigration 
of  aliens,  the  constitution  and  credit  of  the 
government,  liberty  of  conscience,  security  of 
life  and  property,  and  the  interest  of  the  people 
in  their  government,  as  well  as  causes  of  a 
more  strictly  economic  character  {Observations 
upon  the  United  Provinces,  Collected  Works, 
1723,  i.  65).  One  of  the  mercantilist  tests  of 
economic  prosperity  separates  them  so  sharply 
from  more  modern  schools,  that  it  deserves  to 
rank  as  a  fundamental  principle  of  their  teach- 
ing. This  was  the  quantity  of  the  precious 
metals  which  the  country  contained.  A  thorough 
examination  of  mercantile  doctrines  in  relation 
to  the  circumstances  of  the  time  does  not  exoner- 


ate the  writers  from  the  charge  of  confusion  of 
thought  on  this  subject.  There  is  no  evidence 
that  this  led  to  any  evils  in  the  ordinary  economic 
life  of  the  community.  But  on  foreign  trade 
as  a  whole,  and  on  the  popular  estimation  in 
which  different  branches  of  foreign  trade  were 
held,  it  had  enormous  influence  :  "  The  ordinary 
means  to  increase  our  wealth  and  treasure," 
says  Mun,  "is  by  Forraign  Trade,  wherein  we 
must  ever  observe  this  rule :  to  sell  more  to 
strangers  yearly  than  we  consume  of  theirs  in 
value."  The  economic  pamphlets  of  the  period 
abound  with  similar  statements.  They  cer- 
tainly mean  that  the  benefit  of  foreign  trade 
is  measured  by  the  excess  in  value  of  exports 
over  imports,  and  that  branches  of  commerce 
which  can  not  bear  this  test  should  be  dis- 
couraged, or  even  suppressed  altogether.  Al- 
though there  is  no  "historical  justification" 
for  this  doctrine,  we  can  see  how  it  arose.  We 
may  dismiss  the  idea  that  the  mercantilists 
thought  "wealth"  and  "money"  identical. 
No  man  could  believe  more  firmly  than  Gerard 
Malynes  in  the  necessity  of  securing  a  constant 
influx  of  bullion,  yet  we  owe  to  him  the  first 
clear  definition  of  capital  in  the  English  lan- 
guage. His  book,  bound  up  with  Daffome's 
Merchants'  Mirrour,  one  of  the  most  complete 
works  on  book-keeping  then  in  existence,  was 
very  generally  used  as  the  chief  authority  on 
mercantile  affairs.  The  strongest  advocates  of 
the  theory  of  the  balance  of  trade  were  success- 
ful business  men.  Mun  was  one  of  the  ablest 
East  India  merchants  of  his  time.  There  is 
no  trace  of  any  confusion  of  wealth  with  money 
in  their  business  transactions,  and  they  exported 
bullion  like  any  other  commodity.  We  must 
therefore  seek  some  other  explanation  of  the 
fallacy.  Although  the  old  bullionist  theory  of 
the  foreign  exchanges  had  been  refuted,  the 
writers  of  the  17th  century  could  not  free  them- 
selves from  the  conceptions  on  which  it  was 
based,  and  such  works  as  Roberts's  Mappe  of 
Commerce  (1638),  or  even  Alexander  Justice's 
General  Treatise  of  Monies  and  Exchanges 
(1707),  in  which  the  ratios  and  methods  of 
exchange  between  London  and  other  trading 
centres  are  given  in  great  detail,  show  that 
international  transactions  were  still  carried  on 
in  much  the  same  manner  as  under  the  staple 
system.  The  king's  Exchanger  {q.v.)  had 
disappeared,  but  the  cambists  and  goldsmiths 
performed  his  functions  with  great  profit  to 
themselves.  Communication  between  one 
country  and  another  was  slow  and  difficult ; 
credit  agencies  were  little  developed  ;  and  in 
such  circumstances  the  old  view  of  the  precious 
metals  was  not  easily  eradicated.  It  remained 
firmly  fixed  in  the  popular  mind.  It  was 
more  natural  to  regard  the  changes  which 
lapse  of  time,  expanding  commerce,  and  the 
rise  in  prices  had  brought  about,  as  modifica- 
tions of  an  old  tlieory,  than  to  invent  a  new 


ENGLISH  EARLY  ECONOMIC  HISTORY 


725 


and  more  accurate  one.  The  strict  analogy- 
drawn  by  the  writers  of  this  period  between 
the  business  transactions  of  an  individual  and 
the  foreign  commerce  of  the  nation  as  a  whole 
gave  to  the  old  theory  a  greater  persistence. 
The  fact  that  during  the  17th  century  imports 
and  exports  were  a  fairly  good  test  of  inter- 
national indebtedness  had  the  same  influence. 
It  may  also  be  pointed  out  that  English  imports 
consisted  of  a  greater  proportion  of  luxuries, 
such  as  spices,  wines,  silks,  and  fine  linen,  and 
a  smaller  proportion  of  necessaries  and  raw 
materials  than  at  the  present  day,  while  bullion 
was  indispensable  for  trade  with  the  east,  in 
the  then  backward  state  of  English  manufac- 
tures. So  the  mercantilists  tried  to  keep  down 
the  importation  of  commodities  which  in  their 
opinion  sapped  the  vitality  of  the  nation,  and 
to  secure  the  bullion  which  they  required  (see 
Mercantile  System). 

We  are  now  in  a  position  to  understand  the 
attitude  of  the  school  of  which  Mun  was  the 
typical  representative  to  the  economic  questions 
of  the  16th  and  the  17th  centuries.  It  is 
obvious  that  the  mercantilists  were  not  likely 
to  take  much  theoretical  interest  in  the  finely - 
drawn  distinctions  of  the  canonist  writers  on  the 
subject  of  usury.  Theological  influences  were  not 
strong  in  this  country  ;  and  true  to  the  English 
tradition,  the  mercantilists  preferred  expediency 
to  metaphysics.  It  is  probable  that  the  views 
of  the  later  canonists  were  never  thoroughly 
popularised  in  England.  During  the  refor- 
mation period  there  was  much  controversy,  and 
towards  the  end  of  the  16tli  century  many 
pamphlets  were  written,  amongst  which  we  may 
mention  Nicholas  Sanders's  Briefe  Treatise  of 
Usury  (1568),  Thomas  Wilson's  Discourse  of 
Usurie(l5Q9),  Rogers's  translations  of  the  works 
of  M.  P.  Cajsar  and  N.  Hemming  (1578),  H. 
Smith's  Examination  of  Usury  (1592),  and  Miles 
Mosse's  Arraignment  and  Conviction  of  Usury 
(1595).  But  the  development  of  trade  and  com- 
merce, which  at  an  earlier  period  might  have 
imparted  great  vitality  to  such  discussions,  took 
place  subsequent  to  the  reformation,  and  though 
the  influence  of  the  contending  schools  may  be 
traced  in  the  legislation  of  the  period,  English 
writers  appear  to  have  regarded  the  subject 
mainly  as  one  of  practical  expediency. 
Malynes  was  indebted  to  Wilson's  Discourse  for 
some  of  his  arguments  and  illustrations,  but 
even  those  who  were  willing  to  prejudice  the 
merchant  adventurers  by  attributing  their 
"usurious"  practices  to  the  influence  of  Rome, 
were  on  the  whole  hostile  to  the  prohibition  of 
usury.  The  doctrine  was  important  only  as  a 
support  to  an  erroneous  theory  of  the  foreign 
exchanges,  and,  with  the  refutation  of  the  latter, 
interest  in  the  former  disappeared.  The  Cul- 
PEPERS,  father  and  son,  Thomas  Manley,  and 
other  writers  from  time  to  time  engaged  in  the 
controversy.     The  average  English  position  is 


stated  in  Sir  J.  Child's  Brief  observations  con- 
cerning Trade  and  the  interest  of  Money  (1668). 
In  T?ie  Interest  of  Money  mistaken,  or  a  treatise 
proving  that  the  Abatement  of  Interest  is  the 
Effect  and  not  the  Cause  of  the  Riches  of  a  Nation, 
published  in  the  same  year,  an  attempt  is  made 
to  correct  a  current  popular  fallacy.  Mun's  view 
was  the  ordinary  view  of  the  time  ;  favourable 
to  usury,  he  held  that  **this  course  in  the  rich 
giveth  opportunity  presently  to  the  younger  and 
poorer  merchants  to  rise  in  the  world,  and  to 
enlarge  their  dealings ;  to  the  performance 
whereof,  if  they  want  means  of  their  own,  they 
may  and  do  take  it  up  at  interest :  so  that  our 
money  lies  not  dead  ;  it  is  still  traded  "... 
"usury  and  trade  rise  and  fall  together"  (^Eng- 
land's  Treasure,  etc.  144,  146).  With  the  views 
of  Locke  and  the  other  writers  of  the  end 
of  the  17th  century  we  shall  deal  in  a  later 
section. 

While  the  theoretical  discussion  of  interest 
and  usury  attracted  few  writers,  the  constitu- 
tion of  the  trading  companies  assumed  great 
importance  in  economic  controversy.  This 
was  inevitable,  for  at  the  beginning  of  the  reign 
of  James  I.  the  whole  of  the  foreign  trade  of 
the  country  except  that  carried  on  with  France 
was  monopolised  by  one  or  another  of  the  com- 
panies, and  they  were  one  of  the  most  import- 
ant factors  in  economic  development  from  the 
beginning  of  the  16th  to  the  middle  of  the 
18th  century.  During  the  period  which  we 
are  now  considering,  viz.  from  the  beginning  of 
the  16th  century  until  the  publication  of  Mun's 
work  (1664),  there  were,  roughly  speaking,  two 
stages  in  the  controversy  on  this  subject.  In 
the  first  stage  the  Merchant  Adventurers  Com- 
pany was  the  most  powerful  of  the  associations 
then  in  existence.  The  controversy  naturally 
took  the  form  of  a  struggle  between  the  mer 
chant  adventurers  and  those  who  looked  for 
a  solution  of  the  great  problem  of  the  organisa- 
tion of  foreign  commerce  to  a  revival  in  some 
form  of  the  staple  system.  The  first  stage  may 
be  said  to  terminate  with  the  free-trade  bills  of 
1604,  to  which  reference  has  already  been  made. 
After  the  failure  of  these  bills  the  position  of  the 
companies  was  assured,  although  hostility  to 
them  in  one  form  or  another  is  a  most  marked 
feature  of  17th  century  history,  and  Cromwell 
tried  the  experiment  of  a  free  and  open  trade 
with  the  East  Indies  in  1653.  The  case  for 
the  merchant  adventurers  is  stated  with  gi-eat 
moderation  in  an  anonymous  treatise,  Towch- 
inge  the  Multitude  of  Marchantes  for  ventinge  of 
Eng.  clothes  {Rawl.  MSS.,  D.  23).  After  point- 
ing out  that  the  government  should  provide 
for  only  so  many  merchants  "  as  have  acquaint- 
ance, and  as  have  polycy  and  understandinge  to 
trade  together  to  buy  up  all  clothes  vendyble 
for  raarchant  venturers,  and  to  carry  them 
together,  by  one  consorte  of  Marchants,  unto 
one  certen  marte,"  the  writer  goes  on  to  say* 


726 


ENGLISH  EARLY  ECONOMIC  HISTORY 


'« I  do  also  suppose  y*  it  is  not  profy table  for  the 
realme  to  have  a  multytude  of  Marchante  Ven- 
terers,  y'  have  but  small  stockes,  and  thereby 
they  have  but  small  credytt,  and  suche  march- 
antes  can  not  convenyently  tary  for  theyre  sales, 
nor  yet  keepe  necessarye  order. "  The  opponents 
of  the  companies,  as  we  have  seen,  claimed 
free  trade  as  their  natural  right  and  inheritance, 
but  "  this  generall  lybertye  .  .  .  would  cause 
a  greate  confusion,  and  a  greate  dysorderto  growe 
in  the  ventyng  of  Englyshe  clothes,  whereby 
would  follow  yt  or  Englyshe  clothes  would 
be  soulde  at  a  lower  pryce,  then  is  fytte  for  the 
benefytte  of  o^  realme,  and  strange  wares  for 
England  would  be  boughte  at  a  dearer  pryce  than 
is  convenyent  for  our  commonweale  of  Eng- 
lande."  On  the  other  side  the  arguments,  in 
addition  to  the  one  mentioned  above,  were  very 
strong.  It  was  urged  that  freedom  of  trade 
would  lead  to  the  increase  of  wealth  and  ship- 
ping, the  more  equal  distribution  of  wealth, 
and  the  increase  of  revenue.  It  was  further 
maintained  that  the  company  organisation  was 
no  longer  necessary,  and  that  if  trade  were 
free,  commerce  might  be  extended  beyond  its 
present  limits. 

The  growth  of  the  East  India  Company, 
which  was  incorporated  on  the  last  day  of  the 
16th  century,  led  to  the  second  stage  of  the 
controversy.  The  merchant  adventurers  were 
what  was  called  a  regulated  company  ;  the 
East  India  Company  was  organised  on  the 
joint-stock  principle  {vide  Companies).  Now 
many  people  who  objected  to  monopoly  in  every 
form  were  of  opinion  that  the  former  was  less 
injurious  to  trade  than  the  latter,  and  the  East 
India  Company  had  a  long  and  arduous  struggle 
before  it  won  the  victory.  The  conflict  had  to  be 
waged  Avith  the  Turkey  Company,  whose  trade 
in  raw  silk  was  ruined  by  the  enterprise  of  the 
East  India  merchants,  with  those  who  were 
alarmed  at  the  exportation  of  bullion,  with  the 
free  traders  and  interlopers,  and  with  those 
who  thought  the  East  India  trade  disastrous  to 
the  growth  of  the  navy.  The  last-mentioned 
cause  of  hostility  gave  rise  to  a  sharp  con- 
troversy between  Sir  Dudley  Digges  and 
an  anonymous  writer,  J.  R.,  in  1615.  "The 
East  India  men,"  says  the  latter,  "not  able 
to  furnish  those  places  they  resort  to,  keep  out 
others  from  coming  amongst  them.  .  .  .  Besides, 
how  tedious  and  costly  they,  and  all  other 
companies,  make  it  to  their  own  associates, 
whereas  out  of  orders,  and  cause  of  upholding 
their  trade,  men  can  neither  dispose  of  their 
own  as  they  would  nor  have  the  benefit  under 
a  long  time  ?  How  private  do  they  and  other 
companies  make  it  when  .  .  .  how  plentifully 
soever  the  commodities  are  brought  in  and  at 
what  advantage  soever  they  buy  them,  they 
will  be  sure  to  keep  up.  the  price,  either  by 
sending  most  part  of  the  commodities  abroad, 
or  else  by  buying  all  others  into  their  hands  ? " 


Digges's  reply,  The  Defence  of  Trade,  on  behalf 
of  the  company,  probably  derived  more  force 
from  the  position  of  the  author  than  from  the 
arguments  he  employed.  The  company  of 
course  could  point  to  the  fact  that  the  prices 
of  eastern  produce  had  fallen  since  their  incor- 
poration, and  they  made  as  much  as  possible 
of  this  argument,  which  was  further  elaborated 
by  Mun  in  his  Discourse  of  Trade  to  the  East 
Indies  (2nd  ed.  1623).  The  company  and  its  ad- 
vocates, however,  appear  to  have  evaded  rather 
than  answered  the  objections  of  their  opponents. 
No  one  during  the  17th  century  wanted  freedom 
of  trade  in  the  modern  sense  of  the  words.  It 
was  universally  recognised  that  some  form  of 
regulation  was  necessary,  and  most  people  would 
have  chosen  the  company  organisation.  The 
object  of  the  free-trade  bills  (1604)  was  not  to 
break  down  all  restraints  on  free  competition, 
but  to  throw  the  companies  open  to  all  who 
cared  to  join  them,  imposing  by  government 
authority  such  charges  as  were  necessary  to 
keep  up  their  official  establishments  in  foreign 
ports.  It  was  the  monopoly  of  the  companies 
which  roused  the  hostility  of  the  outsiders. 
The  companies  seem  to  have  imagined  that 
when  they  had  shown  the  advantages  of  the 
trades  they  monopolised,  and  proved  the  neces- 
sity for  regulation,  they  had  answered  their 
opponents.  Mun  wrote  England's  Treasure 
long  before  the  end  of  the  struggle.  But  his 
book  did  good  service  to  the  company.  Their 
exportation  of  bullion  could  no  longer  be  urged 
as  a  reasonable  ground  of  objection,  and  the 
East  India  trade  had  been  proved  to  be  favour- 
able to  the  growth  of  the  navy. 

It  has  become  a  commonplace  to  regard  the 
navigation  acts  as  the  natural  outcome  of 
mercantile  doctrine.  The  political  circimi- 
stances  of  the  time,  the  growth  of  foreign 
commerce,  and  along  with  it  the  necessity  of 
providing  adequate  means  for  its  defence,  and 
the  foundation  of  colonies,  showed  the  great 
importance  of  a  powerful  navy.  The  economic 
writers  of  the  period  were  naturally  influenced 
by  the  general  movement,  and  they  urged  the 
encouragement  of  trades,  especially  the  fisheries, 
which  were  favourable  to  the  growth  of  the 
navy.  The  vast  increase  in  the  wealth  of  the 
country,  and  the  greater  ease  with  which  large 
sums  can  be  raised  by  taxation,  have  made 
inapplicable  to  the  present  age  the  practical 
suggestions  of  the  mercantilist  writers.  But 
the  importance  of  a  mercantile  marine  as  a 
naval  reserve  is  felt  as  keenly  now,  especially  in 
times  of  danger,  as  in  the  period  under  discus- 
sion. The  economic  arguments,  however,  by 
which  the  navigation  acts  were  defended,  give 
to  those  measures  a  peculiar  character.  There 
were  navigation  acts  in  the  reign  of  Richard 
II.  Those,  however,  we  need  not  djLscuss.  It 
is  the  series  of  acts  commencing  in  the  reign  of 
Elizabeth,  and  culminating  in  the  great  act  of 


ENGLISH  EARLY  ECONOMIC  HISTORY 


727 


the  Long  Parliament  (1651),  re-enacted  at  the 
restoration,  to  which  we  shaU  devote  our  atten- 
tion {vide  Navigation  Acts).  The  Merchant 
Adventurers  Company,  which  as  we  have  seen 
played  such  an  important  part  in  the  develop- 
ment of  the  mercantile  system,  early  associated 
itself  with  this  naval  policy.  Thus  we  find 
them  advocating  it  in  1551.  One  of  their 
Articles  and  Allegations  .  .  .  against  the 
Hanse  Merchants  {Rawl.  MSS.  C.  394,  flF.  37, 
38)  was  to  the  effect  that  whereas  they  "  have 
and  by  all  waies  do  indevoure  themself  to 
supporte  and  maignteigne  to  their  power,  the 
whole  Navie  of  this  your  Ma*®'  realme,  by 
fraightinge  and  ladinge  of  the  same  and  to 
contynue  a  greate  nomber  of  your  Ma*^  sub- 
jects in  maroners  crafte  :  the  said  Esterlinges 
to  the  intollerable  decay  therof,  both  inwardes 
and  also  outwardes  do  contynuelly  lade,  fraight 
and  shippe  their  goodes,  wares  and  marchandises 
in  foreyne  and  strange  bottomes,  and  vessells." 
They  then  point  out  the  loss  to  the  country 
of  the  money  paid  for  freight  and  insurance. 
This  is  an  argument  which  recurs  over  and 
over  again,  and  it  is  evident  that  the  writers 
of  the  period  attached  great  importance  to  it. 
Mun  argues  that  we  must  "use  our  own  shipping 
and  so  get  the  merchant's  gains,  insurance  and 
freight,"  though  generally  speaking  "commerce 
should  be  free  to  strangers  to  bring  in  and 
carry  out  at  their  pleasure  "  {England's  Treasure, 
p.  22).  The  influence  of  the  navigation  acts 
was  made  the  subject  of  government  inquiry, 
and  much  attention  was  given  to  the  subject 
throughout  the  17th  century.  The  Advocate 
(1651),  which  was  published  to  allay  the  dis- 
content caused  amongst  some  classes  by  the 
act  of  1651,  and  which  we  find  reflected  later 
on  in  the  writings  of  Roger  Coke,  shows 
how  these  acts  were  regarded  as  part  of  a 
general  scheme  of  economic  policy.  This  work 
points  out  that  it  was  the  design  of  the  Dutch 
* '  to  engross  universal  trade  that  so  they  might 
poiz  the  affairs  of  any  other  state  about  them 
and  make  their  own  considerable."  The  ad- 
vantages which  Holland  has  over  England  are 
then  enumerated.  Their  ships  are  built,  pro- 
visioned, and  convoyed  at  less  cost  than  those 
of  England.  Their  "cheapness  of  freight," 
which  is  an  advantage  of  20,  15,  and  10  per 
cent  over  England,  has  forced  English  merchants 
to  hire  and  freight  Dutch  ships.  They  employ 
a  "great  stock";  give  "prudent  care  to  their 
manufactures " ;  make  the  negotiation  of  com- 
mercial treaties  their  "interest  of  state";  im- 
pose small  customs  ;  encourage  inventions  ; 
have  a  low  rate  of  interest ;  facilitate  their 
trade  by  a  bank;  and  pursue  an  enlightened 
land  policy.  Some  "  unalterable  laws  in  manu- 
factures" are  enunciated.  (1)  There  is  no 
manufacture  or  artificial  commodity  which 
cannot  be  transplanted  into  any  country. 
(2)  All  manufactures,  if  they  are  of  a  certain 


goodness,  are  of  a  certain  value  and  price  also. 
(3)  Two  persons  selling  or  making  commodities 
of  a  like  goodness,  he  shall  have  the  preference 
of  the  market  that  will  sell  them  the  cheapest. 
And  so  in  international  trade.  (4)  The  cheap- 
ness of  manufactures  and  artificial  commodities 
depends  upon  the  plenty  and  cheapness  of  the 
raw  material,  and  upon  the  price  of  labour. 
The  price  of  labour  depends  upon  the  price 
of  victuals,  house-rent,  and  other  things  neces- 
sary. The  Dutch  have  no  extraordinary  ad- 
vantages over  England.  Such  as  they  are,  they 
are  due  to  the  carelessness  of  England.  By 
trade  alone  can  wealth  and  shipjiing  be  increased, 
and  so  the  power  of  any  nation  sustained.  A 
commonwealth  can  only  be  enriched  by  reducing 
into  general  practice  the  courses  used  by  private 
men  for  that  purpose.  Hence  England  should 
encourage  native  manufactures  ;  and  weaken 
Dutch  shipping.  Commodities  must  be  imported 
from  the  immediate  places  of  their  production 
or  growth,  or  as  near  as  conveniently  may  be. 
Exports,  native  or  other  commodities,  must  be 
sent  to  the  farthest  market,  where  they  will 
yield  the  greatest  price  and  have  the  quickest 
sale.  After  these  reasons,  it  is  hoped  that 
little  or  no  dissatisfaction  with  the  navigation 
acts  will  remain. 

The  examples  we  have  given  show  the  man- 
ner in  which  the  mercantilists  approached  the 
questions  of  their  time,  and  it  is  unnecessary 
to  trace  in  detail  the  economic  policy  which 
found  expression  in  the  corn  laws  and  bounties, 
in  the  commercial  treaties,  and  the  foundation 
of  colonies.  We  have  said  "policy,"  for  the 
mercantile  system  was  a  collection  of  practical 
expedients,  based  indeed  on  the  fundamental 
principles  we  have  noticed,  but  never  elaborated 
into  a  scientific  economic  system.  Such  was 
the  state  of  economic  thought  when  Mun's  book 
was  published,  and  we  can  now  understand  the 
popularity  with  which  it  was  received.  As 
a  scientific  work  it  has  no  merit  whatever. 
But  it  appealed  to  a  very  strong  and  growing 
sentiment,  and  put  into  words  what  most 
people  believed  at  the  time  of  its  publication. 
Mun's  work,  with  its  sequel  the  British  Mer- 
chant, the  name  given  to  the  series  of  papers 
written  in  opposition  to  De  Foe's  Mercator, 
during  the  controversy  on  the  free- trade  clauses 
of  the  Treaty  of  Utrecht  (1713),  gives  the  best 
idea  of  mercantilism  as  an  economic  system. 
But  before  the  time  of  its  greatest  influence 
forces  had  been  set  in  operation  which  ulti- 
mately overthrew  it,  and  we  must  now  briefly 
sketch  this  movement. 

We  have  already  seen  the  character  of  the 
early  opposition  to  the  trading  companies,  and 
the  appeals  to  natural  right  as  the  basis  of  free 
trade.  The  companies  won  the  victory,  for  in 
the  relation  of  the  government  to  trade,  and 
the  unsettled  state  of  the  countries  to  which  the 
companies  traded,  their  organisation  was  neces- 


728 


ENGLISH  EARLY  ECONOMIC  HISTORY 


sary,  and  they  included  amongst  their  niimbers 
the  wealthiest  and  most  influential  of  the  mer- 
chants. The  outsiders  on  the  other  hand  were 
weak  and  disunited.  But  with  the  extension  of 
commerce  the  number  and  influence  of  the  latter 
grew  ;  and  it  became  clear  that  the  exclusive 
privileges  of  the  companies  were  an  anomaly. 
The  great  statute  of  monopolies  (1625)  was  a 
step  towards  freedom  of  trade  ;  for  although 
many  of  the  evils  complained  of  remained  un- 
checked, it  established  the  principle  that  none 
should  monopolise  for  private  gain  what  was 
the  equal  right  of  all  English  citizens  ;  and  it 
restricted  the  royal  prerogative  in  the  regula- 
tion of  trade.  The  agitation  against  the  trading 
companies  was  not  without  important  results, 
for  the  most  powerful  of  them,  the  East  India 
Company,  was  reorganised  ou  a  broad  national 
basis  (1692-1702).  In  the  18th  century  we 
find  little  discussion  of  a  subject  which  had 
been  of  such  importance  in  the  century  before, 
and  Tucker's  pamphlet  on  the  Turkey  Company 
{Reflections  on  the  expediency  of  opening  the 
trade  to  Turkey,  1753)  only  expressed  what  was 
true  of  all  the  companies  then  in  existence. 
It  is  doubtful  whether  at  this  time  they  were  a 
serious  restriction  on  trade,  but  they  had  per- 
formed the  useful  functions  they  once  had,  and 
it  was  absurd  to  continue  their  privileges.  In 
other  directions  also,  e.g.  in  Walpole's  colonial 
policy,  and  the  decay  of  the  Elizabethan  system 
for  the  regulation  of  wages  and  industry,  we 
can  see  a  movement  towards  free  trade. 

Meanwhile  the  theory  of  natural  right  was 
shattering  the  philosophical  basis  on  which  the 
mercantile  system  rested.  The  instances  we 
have  given  from  the  history  of  the  trading 
companies  may  probably  be  referred  to  popular 
sentiment,  or  to  conceptions  derived  from 
English  common  law.  At  any  rate,  the  latter 
was  appealed  to  in  the  Commons  debates  of 
1601  (Townshend's  Historical  Memorials; 
D'Ewes's  Journals.)  But  the  theory  grew  in 
influence  and  the  range  of  subjects  to  which  it 
was  applied  ;  and  the  levellers  claimed  universal 
suffrage  and  other  measui-es  as  the  natural  right 
of  all  men  {Clarke  Papers,  edited  by  C.  H.  Firth 
for  the  Camden  Society,  Introduction).  Economic 
and  popular  sentiment  coalesced  with  the  philo- 
sophical movement,  and  with  the  development 
of  the  theory  of  the  social  contract  the  way  was 
paved  for  an  individualist  system  of  political 
economy.  Philosophical  conceptions,  however, 
derived  from  this  source,  had  little  or  no  influence 
on  economic  theory  until  the  time  of  Hume. 
HoBBES  and  Locke  took  the  economic  ideas  of 
their  age  as  they  found  them  ready  made  by 
the  pamphleteers  of  the  17th  century,  and 
merely  stated  them  with  greater  clearness. 
During  the  period  with  which  we  have  to  deal, 
the  economic  is  of  greater  importance  than  the 
philosophical  movement.  The  attempt  to  deal 
witli  the  practical  difficulties  of  the  l7th  and 


the  18th  centuries  supplied  those  fundamental 
economic  conceptions  without  which  the  science 
could  have  made  no  progress. 

We  have  seen  that  one  of  the  chief  sources  of 
error  in  the  works  of  the  mercantilist  writers  wa? 
their  confusion  of  thought  on  the  nature  and 
functions  of  money.  The  foundation  of  the 
Bank  of  England  (1694)  and  the  recoinage 
(1696)  called  forth  an  immense  number  of 
pamphlets  dealing  directly  or  indirectly  with 
this  subject.  It  is  from  this  period  that  we 
can  date  the  theoretical  discussion  of  economic 
questions,  and  the  attempt  to  work  out  a 
scientific  system.  English  writers  had  dis- 
cussed continental  banks  many  years  before 
the  foundation  of  the  Bank  of  England.  We 
may  mention,  for  example,  the  Treatise  on 
Exchange  (1564),  to  which  reference  has  already 
been  made.  In  works  intended  for  the  guid- 
ance of  merchants,  such  as  Malynes's  Lex 
Mercatoria  (1622)  and  Lewis  Roberts'  Merchants 
Mappe  of  Commerce  (1638),  it  was  natural  that 
the  writers  should  explain  so  important  a 
feature  of  continental  practice.  The  superi- 
ority of  the  Dutch  was,  as  we  have  seen,  partly 
attributed  to  their  banking  system,  and  during 
the  17th  century  the  advisability  of  adopting 
it  in  England  was  frequently  urged  upon  the 
government  {e.g.  Hugh  Morrell  to  William 
Lenthall,  ii.  Jan.  1646-47,  Portland  MSS.,  vol. 
i.  p.  405).  Generally  the  establishment  of  a 
bank  was  advocated  in  pamphlets  in  which  its 
advantages  were  discussed.  Amongst  these  we 
may  mention  Thomas  Violet's  Advancement  of 
Merchandise,  1651;  Sir  Ralph  Maddison's  Great 
Britain's  Remembrancer,  1655  ;  Samuel  Lambe's 
Seasonable  Observations,  1657  ;  W.  Potter's 
Tradesman's  Jewel,  1659  ;  Francis  Cradocke's 
Wealth  Discovered,  1661  ;  Sir  Edward  Ford's 
Experimental  Proposals,  etc.  1666,  etc.,  which 
show  that  for  some  years  before  the  great 
experiment  people's  minds  were  much  occupied 
with  the  subject.  As  these  proposals  took  a 
more  definite  shape  the  number  of  books  pub- 
lished became  larger.  The  banking  question 
was  associated  with  the  coinage,  the  public  debt, 
and  general  questions  of  trade  and  commerce. 
Sir  Dudley  North,  Sir  William  Petty,  John 
Locke,  Nicholas  Barbox,  Michael  Godfrey, 
William  Lowndes,  William  Paterson,  Robert 
Murray,  John  Asgill,  Simon  Clement,  are 
some  among  the  many  names  which  may 
be  found  in  English  controversy  during  these 
years.  One  pamphlet  followed  another  with 
such  rapidity,  and  discussion  was  so  general, 
that  it  is  difficult  to  single  out  any  one  author 
as  the  representative  of  the  others.  North's 
Discourses  (1691),  however,  should  be  noticed, 
and  the  works  of  N.  Barbon  show  a  deeper 
insight  into  economics  than  those  of  his  con- 
temporaries. Locke's  Consideratiotis  of  the 
Lowering  of  Interest  and  Raising  tJie  Valu^  oj 
Money  (1691),   followed  by  his  Further  Cm- 


ENGLISH  EAELY  ECONOMIC  HISTORY 


729 


siderations  (1695),  not  only  refuted  tlie  argu- 
ments advanced  by  William  Lowndes  and 
others,  in  favour  of  his  scheme  for  restoring 
the  coinage,  and  so  saved  the  country  from  a 
great  disaster,  but  contributed  much  that  was 
of  permanent  value  in  economic  science.  In 
spite  of  these  merits,  however,  Locke  was 
strongly  under  the  influence  of  the  mercantile 
doctiine.  The  great  controversy  of  1691  to 
1696  finally  disposed  of  the  theory  of  money 
which  underlaid  the  mercantile  system,  and 
the  relaxation  of  its  influence  was  now  only  a 
question  of  time.  The  persistence  of  an  old 
theory,  long  after  its  refutation,  is  a  common 
phenomenon  in  the  history  of  human  thought. 
While  the  discussion  of  currency,  banking,  and 
credit  undermined  the  theoretical  framework 
of  the  mercantile  system,  and  the  growth  of 
statistics  threw  doubt  upon  the  balance  of 
trade  as  a  test  of  economic  prosperity,  the 
accumulation  of  capital  and  the  development 
of  commerce  were  removing  the  conditions  of 
which  the  mercantile  system  was  partly  the 
reflex.  During  the  first  fifty  years  of  the  18th 
centmy  economic  progress  was  slow.  Defoe 
indeed  in  his  Mercator  had  urged  a  principle 
which  would  have  led  to  important  results  if 
it  had  been  acted  upon.  He  recommended  no 
less  than  the  isolation  of  economic  questions. 
"Gain  is  the  desire  of  merchandise:  trade  is 
a  commutation  of  merchantable  commodities 
between  one  country  and  another,  and  for  the 
mutual  profit  of  the  traders.  The  language  of 
nations  one  to  another  is,  /  let  thee  gain  hy  mc, 
that  I  Tnay  gain  hy  thee  .  .  .  Trading  is  a  matter 
entirely  independent  in  its  nature,  and  neither 
consults  other  interests,  nor  depends  on  any 
interests,  but  what  relate  to  itself"  {Mercator, 
No.  21).  But  it  was  the  British  Merchant 
and  not  Mercator  that  was  sent  to  every  parlia- 
mentary borough  for  the  use  of  the  inliabitants. 
Why  is  it,  we  may  ask,  that  for  so  great 
a  length  of  time  little  progi-ess  in  economic 
science  has  to  be  recorded  ?  Certainly  it  was  not 
due  to  lack  of  interest  in  economic  subjects. 
There  seems  to  have  been  no  difficulty  in  obtain- 
ing a  hearing.  There  are  literally  hundreds  of 
economic  writers  in  England  between  1500  and 
1762,  and  every  trade  crisis  or  controversy  pro- 
duced its  score  or  so  of  pamphlets.  The  reasons 
for  the  slow  gi*owth  of  the  science  seem  to  have 
been  as  follows  : — (1)  With  few  exceptions  the 
economic  works  of  this  period  were  written 
merely  to  advocate  some  definite  object, — 
to  urge  the  adoption  of  some  scheme  for  the 
improvement  of  trade,  to  defend  those  whose 
interests  were  threatened  by  new  develop- 
ments, e.g,  the  numerous  pamphlets  on  the 
East  India  Company,  and  their  relations  with 
the  Levant  Company,  or  to  protest  against  some 
abuse  and  to  suggest  a  remedy,  e.g.  the  pam- 
phlets on  the  poor  laws,  the  coinage,  public  credit, 
etc.      This    close    relation    between   economic 


literature  and  the  practical  life  of  the  nation 
was  unfavourable  to  the  development  of  a 
system  of  economic  doctrine.  Mun  {England' i 
Treasure  hy  Foreign  IVade,  1664)  expressly 
states  that  his  work  was  not  intended  as  an 
exhaustive  and  systematic  treatise  on  the  econo- 
mics of  the  1 7th  century.  He  proposed  to  dis- 
cuss only  ''so  much  of  the  merchant's  practice 
as  concerned  the  bringing  of  treasure  into  the 
kingdom."  (2)  Such  being  the  objects  of  the 
Avriters,  there  is  a  strong  bias  in  most  of  them 
in  favour  of  the  organisation  or  project  with 
which  they  happened  to  be  identified.  The 
biogi-aphies  of  the  earlier  writers  are  therefore 
of  importance,  for  their  personal  relations  with 
hostile  organisations  or  individuals,  and  events 
in  their  lives,  aff"ected  their  views  to  a  great 
extent.  (3)  When  once  a  controversy  was  con- 
cluded, no  one  endeavom-ed  to  develop  and 
apply  the  general  principles  which  may  have 
been  stated  in  the  course  of  it.  Thus  the 
currency  contioversy  in  1694,  and  the  defence 
of  the  East  India  Company,  led  to  a  statement 
of  the  main  outlines  of  the  principle  of  the 
division  of  labour  (Simon  Clement  ;  Discourse 
of  General  Notions,  etc.,  1695  ;  Considerations  on 
the  East  India  Company,  etc.).  Other  writers 
such  as  Petty,  Berkeley,  Addison,  etc. ,  also  enun- 
ciate this  principle.  But  it  lay  unregarded  until 
Adam  Smith  made  it  one  of  the  fundamental 
principles  of  the  Wealth  of  Hat  ions.  (4)  The 
early  writers  had  to  depend,  for  the  most  part, 
on  their  own  knowledge  and  experience  to  sug- 
gest or  illustrate  their  arguments  ;  trustworthy 
information  on  economic  subjects  was  neither  so 
copious  nor  so  widely  diffused  as  it  is  at  the 
present  time.  Sir  William  Petty,  John  Gkaunt, 
Gregory  King,  and  Charles  Davenant,  who  laid 
the  foundations  of  statistical  science,  all  lived 
in  the  latter  half  of  the  17th  century.  So  late 
as  1699  Davenant  complains  {Essays  on  Trade), 
that  "the  aids  and  lights  which  might  be 
gathered  from  the  public  accompts  and  offices 
have  been  industriously  withheld  from  all  who 
are  not  servile  applauders  of  the  wild  and  de- 
structive conduct  ...  of  some  persons  of  no 
small  power  in  the  management  of  affairs." 
He  and  Gregory  King  are  "beginners  of  an  art 
not  yet  polished,  and  which  time  may  bring  to 
more  perfection."  (5)  The  early  writers  em^ 
ployed  in  their  works  the  language  of  ordinary 
business. '  They  had  no  scientific  terminology. 
Now  the  language  of  the  market-place  is  not 
characterised  by  scientific  precision,  and  their 
looseness  of  phrase  gave  rise  to  endless  misunder- 
standing. 

The  point  of  view  from  which  early  economic 
literature  should  be  regarded  becomes  therefore 
quite  clear.  It  must  be  studied  along  with  the 
history  of  the  times  at  which  it  was  written. 
This  must  be  carefully  borne  in  mind,  or  we 
shall  form  an  erroneous  estimate  of  the  value  of 
these  early  works  and  the  ability  of  the  writers. 


730 


ENGLISH  SCHOOL  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY— Before  A.  Smith 


We  must  not  expect  a  uniformity,  consistency, 
and  completeness  of  doctrine  and  practice  which 
are  not  to  be  found.  Nothing  could  be  more 
fatal  to  the  right  appreciation  of  this  period  than 
to  investigate  it  with  the  idea  that  we  shall 
find  in  it  only  illustrations  of  a  well-rotfnded 
set  of  general  propositions. 

[Much  has  been  written  on  the  history  of  econo- 
mics. Vide  especially  Ashley,  Economic  History, 
vol.  i.  pts.  L  and  ii. — Cunningham,  English  Industry 
and  Commerce. — Endemanu,  Die  NaiionaloJcono- 
mischen  Grundsatze  der  Canonistischen  Lehre. — 
Hewius,  English  Trade  and  Finance. — Heyking, 
Handetshilanztlieorie. — Knies,  Politische  (Ekono- 
mie. — Roscher,  Geschichte  der  Nationalokonomik  in 
Deutschland. — Political  Economy  (trans.  Lalor), 
Geschichte  der  engliscJten  Volkswirtschaftslehre. — 
Schanz,  Englische  Handelsjpolitik.]     w.  a.  s.  H. 

ENGLISH  SCHOOL  OF  POLITICAL 
ECONOMY. 

Before  Adam  Smith,  p.  730 ;  Modern  Economics,  p.  733. 

Before  Adam  Smith. — The  English  writers 
on  political  economy  before  Adam  Smith  do  not 
at  any  time  present  the  marks  of  a  "school," 
properly  so  called.  The  nearest  approach  to  a 
"school,"  so  far  as  community  of  doctrine  is 
concerned,  is  found  among  the  mercantilists  ; 
but  even  these  writers  owe  no  allegiance  to  any 
personal  authority.  Their  views  are  individual 
and  independent ;  and  it  is  only  with  Adam 
Smith  that  the  English  school  par  excellence 
begins.  The  rise  of  that  school  was  affected 
by  many  influences,  English  and  foreign.  Of 
these  the  genesis  of  economic  theory  in  England 
must  be  sought  chiefly  through  the  writings  of 
the  authors  whose  names  are  mentioned  in  the 
rapidly-connected  sketch  which  follows. 

There  is  much  that  is  of  interest  not  only  to 
the  economic  historian  but  also  to  the  student 
of  economic  theory  in  the  early  statutes  and  the 
records  of  the  social  history  of  England,  but  few 
English  writers  earlier  than  the  17th  century 
call  for  special  mention  in  this  article.  Lang- 
land,  in  his  Visions  of  Piers  the  Plowman  (14th 
century),  and  the  writer  of  the  Libell  of  Englishe 
Policy e  (15  th  century)  incidentally  supply  some 
interesting  illustrations  of  the  course  of  life  in 
England  during  those  periods.  The  writings 
of  Walter  of  Henley  (13th  century),  Fitz- 
HERBERT  (16th  ccntury),  and  Tusser's  Five 
hundreth  pointes  of  good  husbandrie  (Tottel's 
edition,  1573),  throw  light  on  the  state  of 
agriculture  and  the  condition  of  the  people. 
"  W.S."  (see  Hales,  John)  in  his  Discourse  of 
the  Common  Weal  of  this  Realm  of  England 
(written  1549,  printed  1581),  acutely  discusses 
the  contemporary  depression  of  agriculture  and 
industry.  His  attempts  to  show  that  the 
"alteration  of  the  coyne  is  the  cheifest  and 
principall  cause  of  this  universall  dearthe  "  are 
highly  interesting  examples  of  early  economic 
argument  and  analysis.  More's  Utopia,  1518, 
imbued  as  it  is  with  the  ideas  of  classical  anti- 


quity, has  more  affinity  with  the  Repuhlic  oi 
Plato  than  with  the  industrial  Utopias  of  later 
writers.  The  chief  impetus  to  the  publication 
of  Discourses  upon  Trade,  was  afforded  by  the 
problems  of  policy  in  colonial  trade  by  which 
the  commercial  activity  of  the  English  people, 
following  upon  the  enterprise  of  navigators  and 
adventurers,  found  itself  confronted.  This  is 
noticeable  as  early  as  the  essays  of  Bacon,  1597 
(  "  Of  Plantations  "),  and  the  writings  of  Raleigh. 
From  the  incorporation  of  the  East  India  Com- 
pany, 1600,  there  is  a  continuous  succession  of 
writers  on  the  theory  of  foreign  trade  which 
formed  the  kernel  of  the  old  Mercantile 
System.  The  mercantile  school  may  indeed  be 
said  to  continue  its  existence  in  quite  different 
forms  from  this  time  to  the  days  of  Steuart. 
The  traffic  in  the  precious  metals  naturally 
attracted  the  attention  of  statesmen  and  of 
merchants  alike  ;  and  from  the  reign  of  Edward 
III.  onward,  attempts  were  made  to  regulate 
its  exchange  for  imported  commodities.  The 
inevitable  export  of  bullion  for  the  East  India 
trade  found  an  ingenious  apologist  in  Mun, 
who,  in  his  Discourse  of  Trade  from  England 
into  the  East  Indies,  1621,  and  England's 
Treasure  by  Forraign  Trade,  published  1664, 
shifted  the  gi'ound  of  the  Balance  of  Trade 
from  the  position  which  it  holds  in  the  writings 
of  Armstrong  (1530)  and  Malynes  (1601), 
He  argued  that  this  export,  like  the  seed  cast 
away  by  the  husbandman,  was  in  the  long  run 
amply  repaid  in  kind,  and  that  the  raw  material 
which  the  precious  metals  purchased,  when 
worked  up  and  sold  to  foreign  countries,  caused 
the  national  stock  of  bullion  to  be  increased  and 
not  diminished.  "The  title  of  Mun's  book, 
England's  Treasure  in  Foreign  Trade,  became  a 
fundamental  maxim  in  the  political  economy, 
not  of  England  only,  but  of  all  other  commercial 
countries"  {Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  iv.  ch.  i.). 
Malynes,  The  Canker  of  Ihigland's  Common- 
wealth, 1601,  and  Lex  Mercatoria,  1622,  de- 
scribes the  Ancient  Law  Merchant  as  well  as 
the  contemporary  habits  and  institutions  of 
trade  ;  and  Lewes  Roberts,  Merchants  Mappe 
of  Commerce,  1638,  Treasure  of  Trafficke,  1641, 
explains  the  operations  of  commerce,  and  recom- 
mends practical  measures, — e.g.  free  export  of 
gold  and  silver,  and  low  customs, — for  its  pro- 
motion. His  Mappe  of  Commerce  is  a  mercan- 
tile geography,  showing  the  situation,  ex- 
changes, and  commodities  of  trade  of  different 
places.  Misselden  (Free  Trade,  1622,  Circle 
of  Commerce,  1623)  exhibits  the  Spaniards  as 
warnings,  the  Dutch  as  models  in  mercantile 
policy,  and  disputes  with  Malynes  the  causes 
and  consequences  of  an  unfavourable  balance 
of  trade.  The  examjale  of  the  low  rate  of 
interest  in  Holland  further  stimulated  the 
Culpepers,  father  and  son,  to  urge  the  reduc. 
tion  by  parliament  of  the  legal  rate  of  interest — 
a  demand   supported   with    much    weight    by 


ENGLISH  SCHOOL  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY— Before  A.  Smith       731 


Child  (1668),  whose  business  instincts,  superior 
to  his  scientific  theory,  were  probably  not  at 
fault  when  he  supposed  such  a  measure  would 
redound  to  the  encouragement  of  English 
commerce.  The  unsoundness  of  some  of  the 
arguments  which  he  employs  was  pointed  out  in 
The  Interest  of  Money  Mistaken,  1668. 

Passing  by  the  utopia  of  Harrington 
{Oceana,  1658),  and  such  agi-i cultural  writings  as 
those  of  Blith,  The  English  Improver  Improved, 
1652,  Hartlib,  Legacy  of  Husbandry,  1655, 
WoRLiDGE,  Sy sterna  Agricalturae,  1668,  and 
John  Smith,  England's  Iviprovement  Revived, 
1670,  we  come  to  the  speculations  of  Hobbes, 
1670,  and  Asa  ill,  1696,  on  the  nature  and  causes 
of  wealth.  Particular  recommendations  for  the 
improvement  of  trade  by  the  naturalisation  of 
aliens,  and  in  favour  of  the  policy  of  enclosures, 
are  found  in  Fortrey,  England's  Interest  and 
Improvement,  1663,  and  Coke,  1671.  Portrey's 
statement  that  the  country  "lost"  £1,600,000 
a  year  by  its  trade  with  France,  long  had  a  dis- 
couraging effect.  The  despondent  tone  of  most 
writers  of  this  time  is  echoed  in  the  title  of 
Britannia  Languens,  1680,  and  in  the  argu- 
ments of  its  pseudonymous  author  (Philanglus), 
that  the  importation  of  foreign  luxuries  was  a 
"  consumptive  trade  "  which  threatened  to  bring 
about  the  decay  of  the  nation  while  money  was 
exported  for  them.  The^  s^e  writer  urges  the 
"legal  regulation"  of  trade,  to  prevent  its 
destruction  by  "private  interest  "and  by  the 
"cloggs"  of  navigation  acts,  companies,  mono- 
polies, etc.  Similar  views  with  regard  to 
the  eastern  trade  are  found  in  Pollexfen's 
England  and  East  India  Inconsistent  in  their 
Manufactures,  1697 — a  reply  to  Davex ant's 
Essay  on  the  East  Indian  Trade,  1696-97.  A 
more  hopeful  note  is  struck  in  England's  Great 
Happiness:  wherein  it  is  demonstrated  that  a 
great  part  of  our  Complaints  are  Causeless,  1677, 
and  in  the  optimistic  preface  of  Petty's  Political 
Arithmetic,  1682,  which  opposed  to  vain  imagin- 
ings and  timid  surmises  the  positive  conclusions 
of  comparative  statistics,  and  drily  observed 
that  the  price  of  food  was  "so  reasonable,  as 
that  men  refuse  to  have  it  cheaper,  by  admitting 
of  Irish  cattle."  The  best  thought  of  the  time 
had  now  for  many  years  been  directed  into  the 
channels  of  trade,  and  produced,  as  was  natural, 
an  abundant  crop  of  pamphlet  literature  on  all 
questions  connected  with  "the  Science  of  the 
Great  Commerce."  Comparative  study  of  other 
nations,  especially  of  France,  Holland,  and  Spain, 
was  one  main  source  of  the  inspiration  of  these 
writings,  and  numerous  proposals  sprung  up  for 
establishing  banks  (see  Asgill,  Briscoe,  Gary, 
Chamberlain,  Cradocke,  Lewis,  Murray, 
Paterson)  and  for  emulating  Holland  in  other 
matters.  This  spirit  is  shown  in  Yarranton's 
England's  Improvement  by  Sea  and  Land:  To 
outdo  the  Dutch  urithout  fighting,  etc.  (pt.  i.-1677  ; 
pt.  ii.  1681),  in  Sir  Wm.  Temple's  Observations 


on  the  Netherlands^  1693,  and  in  the  popularity 
of  the  translations  of  "John  de  Witt's"  True 
Interest  and  Political  Maxims  of  Holland,  1702, 
etc.  (see  Dutch  School). 

An  important  epoch  is  marked  by  Graunt's 
Natural  and  Political  Observations  upon  the  Bills 
of  Mortality,  1662,  with  which  begins  the  science 
of  Demography,  as  statistics,  and  the  theory 
of  taxation  may  be  said  to  commence  with 
Graunt's  more  famous  friend  Sir  Wm.  Petty, 
whose  remarkable  treatises  on  Taxes  and  Con- 
tributions, 1662,  Political  Arithmetic,  1682, 
and  the  Political  Anatomy  of  Ireland,  1691, 
exhibit  an  ingenuity  of  method  and  grasp  of 
principle  rarely  if  ever  shown  by  his  prede- 
cessors. The  first  table  of  mortality  was  pub- 
lished by  Halley  in  1693.  Davenant  (1699) 
and  Gregory  King  (in  1696)  continued  the 
work  of  statistics  (see  Arithmetic,  Political)  ; 
while  the  current  views  on  the  balance  of  trade 
found  an  able  opponent  in  Barbon  (1690),  who 
was  soon  to  cross  swords  with  Locke  on  the 
subject  of  money. 

The  proposals  of  Lownd]':s,  tlien  secretary  to 
the  treasury  (1695),  to  coin  the  new  (silver) 
money  lighter,  provoked  the  opposition  of  Locke, 
whose  able  writings  on  money  at  this  critical 
period  of  the  great  recoinage  (see  Pecoinages) 
are  still  appealed  to  in  controversies  of  to-day 
upon  the  history  of  the  currency.  The  earlier 
work  of  Vaughan,  Discourse  of  Coin  and  Coinage, 
1675,  should  also  be  mentioned  here.  Mingled 
with  the  discussions  of  semi-political  questions  by 
earlier  authors  are  many  glimpses  of  a  broader 
consistent  theory,  general  principles  of  which  now 
begin  more  clearly  to  emerge.  The  close  of  the 
17th  century  is  indeed  a  time  conspicuous  for  the 
ability  of  English  economic  writers.  Barbon's 
Discourse  of  Trade,  1690,  contains  some  striking 
analyses  of  value,  price,  interest,  and  rent. 
North's  Discourse  of  Trade,  1691,  is  an  admir- 
able exposition  of  the  merits  of  free  exchange. 
Fleetwood's  Sermons  against  Clipping  and 
Sweating  of  the  Precious  Metals,  1694,  precede 
by  thirteen  years  his  Chronicon  Preciosiun  or 
history  of  prices,  familiar  to  students  of  Adam 
Smith.  The  problem  of  the  conditions  of  the 
poor  which  had  fitfully  occupied  statesmen  since 
the  date  of  Richard  XL,  in  whose  reign  the 
earliest  legislation  for  dealing  with  impotent 
beggars  took  place,  seriously  engaged  the  atten- 
tion of  Firmin  (1678),  Hale  (1683),  Child  (who 
proposed  the  appointment  of  poor-law  guardians 
or  "fathers  of  the  poor"),  Gary  (1695)  and 
Bellers,  Proposals  for  Raising  a  Colledge  of 
Industry  of  all  Useful  Trades,  etc.  1695-1696. 
From  Defoe's  lively  and  prolific  pen  came,  in 
1704,  the  vigorous  essay,  Giving  Alms  no  Charity 
and  Employing  the  Poor  a  Grievance  to  the 
Nation,  in  which  it  was  contended  that  work- 
house labour  should  not  be  employed  in  com- 
petition with  outside  industry.  The  same 
writer's  Compleat  English  Tradesman,  1725-27, 


732     ENGLISH  SCHOOL  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY— Before  A.  Smith 


and  Plan  of  the  English  Cmnmerce,  1728,  are  the 
chief  of  his  other  numerous  works  on  subjects 
relating  to  trade.  John  Houghton,  F.K.S., 
Collection  for  the  Improvement  of  Husbandry  and 
Trade,  1692-1703  (particulars  of  prices  of  corn, 
cattle,  coal,  hops,  wool,  etc.) ;  The  British 
MereJiant;  or  Commerce  Preserved,  1713  (papers 
collected  and  published  by  Charles  King,  1721) ; 
and  Defoe's  Mo'cator,  or  Commerce  Revived,  1713, 
1714  (an  opposition  paper  to  The  British 
Merchant),  aflbrd  useful  details  for  the  history 
of  commerce. 

Law's  Money  and  Trade  considered,  1705, 
exhibits  at  once  the  power  and  the  defects  of 
his  erratic  genius  ;  original,  daring,  and  acute, 
he  admits  no  limit  to  the  bounds  of  credit,  and 
has  little  thought  of  its  contraction.  His  book 
marks,  however,  a  real  advance  in  the  study  of 
money  and  credit.  Wood's  Survey  of  Trade, 
1718,  also  deals  with  money  and  bullion. 
Madox  is  an  invaluable  source  of  information  for 
the  economic  historian  in  his  Antiquities  of  tJie 
Exchequer,  1711,  and  Firma  Biirgi,  1726.  In 
Ireland  appeared  about  the  same  time  the  well- 
known  Drapier's  Letters,  1725,  in  which  Swift 
inflamed  the  anger  of  his  countrymen  against 
Wood's  copper  halfpence  ;  Dobbs'  essay  on 
"The  Trade  and  Improvement  of  Ireland," 
1729-31  ;  and  Berkeley's  Querist,  1735,  a 
collection  of  searching  and  suggestive  inquiries 
in  economics,  revealing  at  once  the  author's 
mind  and  the  degree  of  development  which  the 
science  had  then  attained.  Swift's  Modest  Pro- 
posal for  preventing  the  Children  of  Poor  People 
from  being  a  burden  to  th^ir  Parents  or  the 
Country,  1730,  is  an  elaborate  joke  framed  in 
a  tone  of  ironical  and  pseudo-economic  savagery. 
Gee's  Trade  and  Nam.gation  of  Great  Britain 
considered,  1729,  is  a  despondent  treatise  of 
mercantilism,  affecting  to  show  ' '  that  the  surest 
way  for  a  nation  to  increase  in  riches  is  to  pre- 
vent the  importation  of  such  foreign  commodi- 
ties as  may  be  raised  at  home."  Vanderlint's 
Money  Answers  all  Things,  1734,  on  the  other 
hand  ably  argues  for  free  trade,  while  Mande- 
ville's  Fable  of  the  Bees,  or  Private  Vices, 
PuMick  Benefits,  1706,  1714,  1723,  etc.,  urges 
the  social  advantages  of  individual  liberty. 
Both  books  mark  a  movement  in  the  direction 
of  Laissez-Faire.  Decker's  Proposals,  1743, 
for  raising  the  whole  revenue  by  a  single  tax  on 
houses,  and  the  Essay  on  the  Causes  of  the  Decline 
of  the  Foreign  Trade,  1744,  show  much  ingenuity 
in  the  study  of  taxation.  John  Smith's  Chroni- 
con  Busticum  Commerciale,  or  Memoirs  on  Wool, 
1747,  is  an  industrious  compilation  of  standard 
value  upon  this  great  branch  in  the  history  of 
EngHsh  trade.  Equally  laborious  but  less  praise- 
worthy are  the  Dictionaries  of  Trade  and  Com- 
merce of  Postlethwayt  (1751),  Rolt  (1761) 
and  Mortimer  (1766).  Postlethwayfs,  the 
best  of  the  three,  was  founded  mainly  upon  the 
French  dictionary  of  Savary.     In  1761   and 


1753  appeared  translations  from  the  Spanish  oi  •  '2 
UsTARiTZ  and  Ulloa  of  the  history  of  trade  in 
Spain,  and  in  1753  a  translation  from  the 
German  of  Magens'  Universal  Merchant  (post- 
script 1756).  The  last  two  writers  are  men- 
tioned by  Adam  Smith.  Franklin's  Observa- 
tions concerning  tlie  Increase  of  Mankind,  1751  ; 
Hume's  essay  of  "  The  Populousness  of  Ancient 
Nations"  in  his  Political  Essays,  1752;  and 
Wallace's  Dissertation  on  the  Numbers  of  Man- 
kind in  Ancient  and  Modern  Times,  1753,  show 
an  interest  in  the  progress  of  population,  its 
causes  and  limits,  nearly  half  a  century  before 
Malthus.  The  middle  of  the  18  th  century 
recalls  the  end  of  the  1 7th  by  the  fertile  ability 
of  its  economic  writers.  Hume's  Essays  contri- 
buted powerfully  to  the  development  of  sounder 
views  on  money  and  the  balance  of  trade. 
Wallace,  in  his  Characteristics,  1758,  discusses 
the  functions  of  paper  money  and  credit.  The 
essays  of  Patrick  Lord  Elibank,  on  Tlie  Public 
Debt  were  published  in  the  same  year  (1753) 
as  Fielding's  Proposal  for  making  an  Effectual 
Provision  for  the  Poor.  The  most  important 
writings  appearing  at  this  time  were,  however, 
those  of  Cantillon,  Massie,  and  Tucker, 

Cantillon's  posthumous  Essai  (published 
1755)  is  the  earliest  approach  to  a  complete 
presentation  of  economic  principles,  tracing  the 
distribution  of  wealth  JDy  the  guiding  thread  of 
a  central  theory  of  value.  Its  influence  was 
gi'eatly  felt  in  the  French  School,  but  is  also 
clearly  seen  in  the  Essay  on  Money  and  Coins 
of  Harris  (1755-58).  Massie  (see  infra), 
though  best  known  by  his  criticisms  of  Decker's 
and  Fauquier's  proposals  in  taxation  and  by 
his  Essay  on  the  Governing  Causes  of  the  Natural 
Rate  of  Interest  (1750),  has  been  shown  by  Dr. 
Cunningham  to  have  left  a  bibliography  of 
economic  literature  of  the  highest  value  {Eco- 
n/miic  Journal,  vol.  i.  No.  1).  Tucker  (see 
infra),  dean  of  Gloucester,  is  remarkable  for 
the  breadth  and  liberality  of  view  with  which 
he  regards  the  economic  aspect  of  colonial  and 
foreign  politics.  Tucker  accepted  with  pride 
the  sarcasm  of  Warburton,  that  he  made  a 
religion  of  trade  as  other  ecclesiastics  had  been 
known  to  make  a  trade  of  religion.  The  dignity 
of  economic  study  did  not  much  longer  need 
vindication.  His  Reflections  on  the  Expediency 
of  a  Law  for  the  Naturdlisation  of  Foreign  Pro- 
testants, 1751,  were  translated  into  French  by 
Turgot  (1755).  His  Brief  Essay  on  the  Advan- 
tages and  Disadvantages  which  respectively  attend 
France  and  Great  Britain  with  regard  to  Trade, 
1750,  is  said  by  Blanqui  to  show  the  influence 
upon  Tucker  of  the  French  economists  with 
whom  he  was  in  close  correspondence.  But 
there  can  be  little  doubt  that  in  their  relations 
with  Tucker  at  this  time  they  were  rather 
disciples  than  masters. 

The  high  esteem  in  which  the  early  English 
writings  was  held  abroad  was  no  doubt  ]arge])i 


ENGLISH  SCHOOL  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY— Modern  Economics    733 


due  to  the  superiority  of  English  commerce 
which  gave  them  birth.  It  was  felt  with  justice 
that  a  natioji  of  successful  merchants  were 
worth  listening  to  on  matters  of  trade.  The 
French  in  particular  richly  repaid  their  debt  to 
us  through  Adam  Smith,  upon  whose  mind  they 
impressed  their  systematic  and  logical  views  ; 
but  it  should  not  be  forgotten  that  those  views 
were  largely  founded  on  the  practical  judgments 
of  English  Avriters.  Nor  can  the  diligent  student 
of  the  Wealth  of  Nations  fail  to  be  struck  by  the 
extent  to  which  that  work  is  rooted  upon  the 
earlier  English  writings.  And  though  in  the 
crucible  of  Adam  Smith's  mind  the  materials  of 
his  predecessors  are  often  refined,  they  still  do 
not  defy  recognition,  but  testify  to  the  close 
continuity  of  the  English  school. 

It  has  not  been  possible  in  this  slight  account 
to  do  more  than  enumerate  some  of  the  writers 
who  preceded  Adam  Smith.  For  fuller  notices 
the  student  is  referred  to  the  separate  articles 
under  the  names  of  the  authors.  Contempor- 
aries of  Adam  Smith  are  dealt  with  in  a  later 
portion  of  this  article.  It  is  only  necessary  to 
mention  as  appearing  before  1776,  the  Three 
Tracts  on  the  Corn  Trade  and  Corn  Laws,  1758, 
by  Charles  Smith,  whom  Adam  Smith  has 
described  as  "ingenious  and  well-informed"  ; 
the  important  Inquiry  into  the  Principles  of 
Political  Economy  oi^'TY.VA.'KT,  1767  (see  infra)  ; 
Anderson's  History  of  Commerce,  1764  ;  Fer- 
guson's History  of  Civil  Society,  1767  ;  Price 
on  Reversionary  Paymenis,  1769,  and  on  the 
National  Debt,  1774  ;  and  Arthur  Young's 
Farmer's  Letters,  1771,  Rural  Economy,  1773, 
and  Political  Arithmetic,  1774,  with  some  of  his 
earlier  Tours  in  the  English  counties,     h.  h. 

Modern  Economics.  Period  I.  Adam 
Smith. — After  the  Union  of  1707,  Scotland 
began  to  play  a  part  in  English  economic 
study.  Francis  Hutcheson  (professor  of  moral 
philosophy  at  Glasgow,  died  1747)  turned  the 
attention  of  Scottish  philosophers  to  economic 
questions,  on  which  he  himself  touches,  though 
briefly,  in  his  published  works  (e.g.  in  his  In- 
quiry into  the  Original  of  our  Ideas  of  Beauty 
and  Virtue,  etc.,  1st  ed.  1725).  The  notion  of 
the  "greatest  happiness  of  the  gi-eatest  mmaber" 
appears  in  Hutcheson,  and  he  also  lays  stress 
on  the  connection  between  industry  and  self- 
interest,  industry  and  property,  thus  carrying 
on  the  discussion  raised  by  Mandeville  {Fable  of 
the  Bees,  etc.,  1706,  and  later  eds.),  on  the  nature 
of  the  motives  to  economic  action.  The  activity 
of  the  Scotch  press  (Foulis,  Urie,  etc.)  in  the 
publication  and  reprinting  of  economic  treatises 
becomes  noticeable  about  this  time  (say  1750  to 
1770).  Adam  Ferguson  in  the  4th  ed.  of  his 
History  of  Civil  Society  (1773),  announced  the 
forthcoming  work  of  Adam  Smith,  which  was  to 
be  "a  complete  theory  of  national  oeconomy  "4 
but  Ferguson's  own  economicalviews(e.^.  on  divi- 
sion of  labour)  are  given  incidentally  along  with 


his  political  philosophy,  and  not  in  a  separate 
treatise.  In  his  Institutes  of  Moral  Philosophy 
(1769),  where  he  treats  of  economical  questions, 
he  borrows  to  some  extent  from  Joseph  Harris 
{Essay  on  Mon^y  and  Coins,  1757).  To  much 
greater  effect  David  Hume,  who  had  learned 
from  Hutcheson,  had  prepared  the  way  for  his 
friend  Adam  Smith  by  his  keen  criticism  of  the 
cun-ent  views  of  the  balance  of  trade,  to  say 
nothing  of  his  pregnant  remarks  on  the  other 
subjects  embraced  by  the  "Mercantile  Theory" 
{Essays  on  Comynercc,  Money,  Interest,  etc., 
1752).  Economical  subjects  receive  separate 
consideration,  and  Hume's  reasonings  upon 
currency,  credit,  and  population  were  of  special 
influence.  In  the  controversy  as  to  the 
populousness  of  ancient  nations  he  took  the 
side  of  the  moderns.  In  the  matter  of  public 
credit,  or  national  debts,  he  took  the  view  that 
national  debt  would  eventually  prove  the  ruin 
of  modern  nations.  He  points  out  that  the 
quantity  of  metallic  money  in  a  country  does 
not  determine  the  rate  of  interest,  also  that  a 
time  of  increasing  currency  is  a  time  of  lively 
trade.  He  thinks  that  commercial  jealousy 
rests  on  a  false  idea  that  one  party  must 
always  be  the  loser,  in  a  bargain.  He  goes, 
if  not  as  far  as  Adam  Smith,  nearly  as  far  as 
Josiah  Tucker  {Advantages  and  Disadvantages 
which  respectively  attend  France  and  Great  Britain 
uith  regard  to  Trade,  1750).  But  it  was  left  to 
Sir  James  Steuart  and  Adam  Smith  to  recognise 
for  their  own  country  what  had  already  been 
made  good  by  the  pliysiocrats  in  France  (see 
Physiocrats  and  French  School),  that 
economical  subjects  must  be  a  study  by  them- 
selves. Sir  James  Steuart's  book  {An  Inquiry 
into  the  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  being  an 
Essay  on  the  Science  of  Domestic  Policy  in  Free 
Nations),  written  in  exile  in  Germany,  and  first 
published  (in  Edinburgh)  in  1767,  made  no 
impression  on  the  public  to  be  compared  with 
that  of  Adam  Smitli's  Inquiry  into  the  Nature 
and  Causes  of  the  Wealth  of  Nations  (1776)  ; 
and  was  rather  a  revised  edition  of  the  mer- 
cantile theory  than  a  new  departure.  The  im- 
mediate popularity  of  Adam  Smith's  work,  on 
the  other  hand,  was  largely  due  to  its  crush- 
ing criticisms  (especially  in  bk.  iv.)  of  the 
"commercial  system,"  which  was  tracked 
out  and  destroyed  in  all  its  logical  ramifica- 
tions, however  tenaciously  it  might  afterwards 
survive  in  political  practice.  The  idea  of 
"natural  liberty"  organising  industry,  and 
transforming  society  "of  its  own  accord,"  was 
stated  by  Adam  Smith  even  more  boldly  than 
by  the  French  economists,  and  he  avoided  their 
mistake  of  restricting  productiveness  to  agri- 
culture (bks.  iv.  ix.)  In  his  chapters  "  On  the 
Revenue  of  the  Sovereign  or  Commonwealth  " 
(bk.  V. ),  he  came  out  as  * '  the  greatest  of  theorists 
on  finance "  (Bastable) ;  and  no  economical 
treatise  ever  exerted  greater  political  influence. 


734 


ENGLISH  SCHOOL  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY— Modern  Economics 


On  economic  theory  its  influence  has  been  also 
very  gi-eat,  though  it  was  not  so  immediately 
visible,  and  is  now  partly  spent.  The  defini- 
tion of  wealth,  the  discussions  on  labour,  wages, 
rent,  interest,  and  the  short  remarks  on  value, 
served  as  starting-points  for  more  thorough 
and  satisfactory  consideration  of  these  maf,ters. 
Adam  Smith's  method  of  reasoning,  though  fre- 
quently deductive,  involves  so  full  an  illustra- 
tion from  facts  and  statistics,  where  such  were 
accessible,  that  he  has  often  been  claimed  as 
an  inductive  economist.  The  industrial  changes 
then  taking  place  in  England  gave  his  treatise 
a  peculiar  historical  importance,  if  they  were 
not  indeed  responsible  for  its  creation.  Simi- 
larly, if  we  pass  by  Bentham's  correction  of  one 
false  concession  in  "the  Wealth  of  Nations" 
(see  Bentham),  the  next  contribution  to  Eng- 
lish political  economy  was  largely  occasioned 
by  a  change  in  the  condition  of  the  people. 

Period  II.  Malthus  and  Ricardo. — The 
poor  law  of  W.  Pitt,  proposing  a  bounty  on  large 
families,  and  the  popularity  of  Godwin's  political 
theories,  led  Malthus  to  bring  forward  in  his 
Essay  on  Population,  1798,  a  clear-cut  theory  of 
' '  the  principle  of  population. "  He  inquired  into 
the  nature  and  causes  of  poverty,  as  Adam  Smith 
into  those  of  wealth.  The  tendency  of  popu- 
lation to  increase  up  to  the  limits  of  the  means 
of  subsistence  was  brought  out  more  strongly 
than  the  checks  on  this  tendency,  which  were 
not  adequately  stated  till  the  book  had  emerged 
from  the  floods  of  criticism  into  a  second  edition 
(1803).  The  views  of  Malthus  on  general 
economic  theory  were  not  elaborated  with  such 
perfect  lucidity  as  his  doctrine  of  population  ; 
he  tended  either  to  fall  back  on  physiocratic 
views,  or  to  theorise,  as  on  the  measure  of  value 
and  the  corn  laws,  with  a  subtlety  inconsistent 
with  clearness.  He  maintained  views  on  over- 
production which  brought  on  him  the  damaging 
criticisms  of  J.  B.  Say.  On  the  other  hand, 
he  shares  with  James  Anderson,  and  Sir  E. 
West,  the  credit  of  first  stating  what  is  usually 
called  the  Ricardian  theory  of  agricultural 
rent,  that  rent  is  the  eff'ect  not  the  cause  of 
price,  and  that  it  depends  on  the  graduated 
fertility  of  lands.  Ricardo,  who  first  ob- 
tained fame  by  his  Letters  on  the  High  Price 
of  Oold  Bullion  (1809),  and  made  an  enduring 
mark  on  the  theory  of  currency,  owes  his  prom- 
inence in  economic  literature  to  his  Principles  of 
Political  Economy  and  Taxation  (1817).  In 
this  book  he  pushed  the  theory  of  rent  farther 
than  its  discoverers,  and  made  it,  together 
with  a  new  theory  of  value,  the  centre  of  a 
theory  of  the  distribution  of  wealth  between 

the  three  parties  concerned  in  its  production 

the  labourers,  the  employers,  and  the  landlords. 
The  value  of  manufactured  articles  is  deter- 
mined mainly  by  the  quantity  of  labour  neces- 
sary to  the  production  of  them,  and  of  agri- 
cultural products  by   the  quantity  of  labour  | 


necessary  to  the  cultivation  of  the  worst  land 
actually  cultivated.  The  height  of  this 
"  margin,"  to  use  the  phrase  of  Dr.  Chalmers, 
determines  the  amount  of  profits  to  the 
employers,  and  the  amount  of  rent  to  the 
owners  of  all  land  above  the  worst.  Ricardo's 
qualifications  of  this  theory  were  neither 
numerous  enough  nor  clearly  enough  stated  ; 
and,  even  if  the  theory  had  not  been  reproduced, 
as  by  M'CuLLOCH,  without  the  qualifications,  a 
reaction  against  Ricardian  political  economy 
could  be  only  a  matter  of  time.  But  it  held 
the  field  for  nearly  a  generation  after  the 
publication  of  the  Principles.  It  found  popu- 
larisers  both  humble  and  eminent  (Mrs.  Marcei 
and  De  Quincey)  :  James  Mill  followed  it 
wholly,  and  Senior  with  reservations  that 
seemed  in  those  days  unimportant,  though  in 
after  times  the  acuteness  of  Senior  has  been  bettei 
recognised.  Torrens  did  not  succeed  in  estab- 
lishing his  claims  to  independent  authority,  nor 
did  Chalmers  restore  the  authority  of  Malthus. 
Whately,  Longfield,  Lawson  wrote  clearly 
but  without  making  any  decidedly  new  depar- 
ture. Professor  Richard  Jones,  in  appealing 
against  Ricardo  to  the  history  of  India,  was 
before  his  time.  The  minor  writers  (see  below) 
left  fruitful  hints,  but  made  few  converts  among 
students  of  the  subject.  Robert  Ow^en  and  his 
followers  gained  little  hearing  in  the  world  oi 
letters.  The  victory  of  Free  Trade  (1846),  the 
passing  of  the  early  Factory  Acts,  the  rise  of 
Chartism,  and  the  regulation  of  the  paper 
currency  (see  Banking),  affected  the  course  of 
economic  discussions  ;  and  the  French  Revolu- 
tion of  1848  played  a  part  in  England  as  well 
as  on  the  Continent  French  and  German 
writers  began  to  acquire  greater  influence  than 
ever  before. 

Period  III.  John  Stuart  Mill. — Their  in- 
fluence was  shown  in  John  Stuart  Mill's  Politi- 
cal Economy  (1848).  This  book  was  an  attempt 
to  combine  abstract  economical  theory  with  the 
modifications  necessary  for  its  application  in 
the  concrete,  and  to  view  the  whole  of  economics 
in  relation  to  other  parts  of  the  philosophy  of 
society.  As  Mill  went  beyond  Bentham  in  his 
ethics,  he  went  beyond  Ricardo  in  his  economics. 
Long  before  this  time  Mill  had,  like  Senior,  given 
attention  to  the  question  of  method,  which  was 
afterwards  to  become  an  object  of  lively  discussion. 

The  study  of  Comte  and  other  foreign 
writers  had  led  Mill  to  doubt  whether  abstract 
theory  was  allowable  at  all  in  social  inquiry. 
He  retained  it,  however,  for  political  economy  ; 
and  in  his  chief  economic  book  the  abstract 
theory  is  presented,  along  with  the  modifica- 
tions, being  little  more  than  a  careful  re-state- 
ment of  Ricardian  principles.  He  had  wished 
to  do  for  his  own  day  what  Adam  Smith  had 
done  for  his  (see  preface  to  Mill's  Political 
Economy)  ;  and  the  influence  of  his  book  was  so 
great  that  it  seemed  as  if  a  new  departure  had 


ENGLISH  SCHOOL  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY— Modern  Economics    735 


been  taken  and  a  new  era  begun.  But  Mill 
was  so  far  from  overthrowing  the  old  doctrines 
that  he  really  strengthened  their  hold  at  a  time 
when  it  had  been  loosened.  Yet,  by  his  em- 
phasis on  the  relativity  of  abstract  economics  to 
particular  societies,  and  on  the  possibility  of 
far-reaching  changes  in  the  social  system,  he 
showed  an  affinity  with  "historical  economists," 
and  ** scientific  socialists."  The  former  foimd 
their  earliest  representatives  in  Cliffe  Leslie  and 
Thorold  Rogers  ;  and  their  views  are  now 
energetically  advocated  by  Ingram,  Cunning- 
ham, and  Ashley.  The  Christian  Socialism 
(of  Maurice,  Kingsley,  Ludlow,  Nealb, 
Hughes)  grew  out  of  Owen  and  Chartism  ;  and 
its  upholders,  in  advocating  co-operative  pro- 
duction, appealed  rather  to  philanthropy  and 
human  brotherhood  than  to  cool  economic 
theory.  The  scientific  socialism  of  Marx, 
avowedly  based  on  the  Ricardian  theory  of 
value,  can  hardly  be  said  to  have  representatives 
in  this  country  among  professed  economists.  In 
his  views  of  Land  Reform,  Mill  (like  his  father), 
approached  very  near  to  socialism  ;  but  his  atti- 
tude to  socialism  as  a  general  policy  is  quite  as 
truly  critical  as  sympathetic. 

Period  IV.  W.  S.  Jevons. — This  cool  re- 
ception of  scientific  socialism  is  mainly  due 
to  the  rejection,  by  Jevons  and  his  closest 
followers,  or  the  serious  modification,  by  Mar- 
shall and  Sidgwick,  of  the  Ricardian  theory 
of  value.  The  ideas  of  Jevons  have  had  greater 
power  since  his  death  than  during  his  life. 
He  was  too  impatient  at  the  almost  universal 
submission  to  Mill's  authority  to  do  Mill  com- 
plete justice.  But  he  was  one  of  the  first 
critics  of  Mill  who  attracted  general  attention 
at  all ;  and,  since  his  time,  there  has  been  less 
submission  to  authority  of  any  kind.  There  has 
no  doubt  been  a  line  of  \mters  who  follow  the 
older  school  very  straitly  (Fawcett,  Cairnes, 
Mallet)  as  among  statesmen  there  has  been  a 
line  of  supporters  of  the  old  economic  policy 
identified  with  Bright  and  Cobden.  But 
changed  conditions  have  forced  most  leading 
statesmen  to  go  beyond  laissez-faire  ;  and  new 
aspects  of  old  problems  have  led  theoretical 
economists  into  deeper  study  of  particular 
questions  (e.g.  Consumption)  than  before.  The 
mathematical  treatment  of  economical  data  has 
practically  fallen  into  the  hands  of  a  wing  of 
the  school  of  final  utility,  which  is  often  spoken 
of  as  a  school  by  itself,  the  mathematical  school 
(Edgeworth,  Wicksteed).  Amongst  the  many 
writers  who  have  taken  part  in  discussions  on 
currency  and  banking,  Mr.  H.  D.  Macleod  has 
fallen  back  on  Whately's  view  that  economics 
is  simply  catallactics,  Bonamy  Price  has  pro- 
fessed to  represent  unaided  common  sense, 
Bagehot  has  insisted  on  the  need  of  formulating 
deductive  economics  for  "advanced  "  nations, 
and  on  the  impossibility  of  doing  so  for  unci  viUse'd 
peoples.     Bagehot's  lucid  writings  on  banking 


and  depreciation  helped  to  keep  these  questions 
before  the  minds  of  economists  ;  and  the  fall  of 
silver  since  1870  has  made  bimetallism  versus 
monometallism  an  object  of  lively  debate.  The 
dominant  view  among  professed  economists  after 
Jevons  seems  to  be  that  bimetallism  under 
certain  conditions  is  possible,  but  that  the  con- 
ditions are  difficult  of  fuUilment.  The  ques- 
tion has  been  discussed  in  close  connection  with 
the  subject  of  the  metallic  reserves  of  our 
English  banks,  and,  in  this  as  well  as  other  con- 
nections, the  wisdom  of  the  Bank  Charter  Act 
of  1844  is  not  now  upheld  by  the  majority  of 
economists.  A  large  part  of  the  recent  work 
of  economists  in  England  has  been  the  re- 
statement of  the  older  doctrines,  with  the 
fresh  light  aff'orded  by  the  theory  of  value  laid 
down  in  1871  by  Jevons  in  this  country, 
and  substantially  one  with  the  theory  of  the 
Austrian  School  of  Economists.  In  connec- 
tion with  this,  there  has  been  practically  a  new 
theory  of  wages  and  profits,  towards  which  not 
only  Jevons  but  Walker  has  contributed  very 
essentially.  The  idea  of  a  wages  fund,  as  held 
by  Ricardo's  immediate  successors,  and  till  1869 
by  J.  S.  Mill,  has  been  abandoned  as  Longe 
and  W.  T.  Thornton  had  foretold.  The  dis- 
tinction of  interest  from,  profits  — -capitalist 
from  employer,  has  been  better  kept  in  view 
— largely  owing  to  the  writings  of  Walker 
The  application  to  wages,  interest,  profits, 
and  even  taxation,  of  the  idea  of  final  utility 
has  been  pursued  vigorously.  Probably  at  no 
time  have  questions  of  economic  theory  ever 
been  more  ardently  discussed  in  England  than 
at  present ;  and  these  discussions  have  hope 
of  greater  fruitfulness  than  before,  because 
conducted  now  (a)  with  a  much  more  adequate 
knowledge  of  Avhat  is  written  and  said,  about 
the  subjects  concerned,  on  the  Continent  of 
Europe,  and  in  the  United  States  of  America, 
and  (b)  with  a  closer  regard  to  the  facts  of 
everyday  life,  as  the  touchstone  of  all  theories. 
Economists  are  more  conscious  than  at  any 
previous  time  of  the  importance  of  statistics  for 
the  understanding  of  the  phenomena  of  society. 
They  are  also  more  keenly  aware,  partly  from 
the  influence  of  Carlyle  and  Ruskin,  of  their 
need  of  contact  and  sympathy  with  men  and 
associations  of  men  in  the  surrounding  world, 
though  they  keep  in  mind  the  distinction  of  an 
econoniic  theory  from  a  mere  record  of  facts  or 
a  mere  utterance  of  philanthropic  aspiration. 

Even  in  this  short  sketch  it  would  be  wrong 
to  omit  mention  of  the  minor  writers  and 
amateur  economists.  Every  great  industrial  or 
financial  change,  besides  awaking  a  correspond- 
ing movement  of  speculation  among  professed 
economists,  has  been  reflected  in  the  fugitive 
literature  of  the  day ;  and  there  has  often  been 
a  subordinate  movement  of  social,  political,  and 
economic  theory,  apparently  quite  aside  from 
the   path  of  the   classical    economists.      The 


736    ENGLISH  SCHOOL  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY — Modern  Economics 


writings  of  the  agriculturist,  Arthur  Yotjng, 
and  the  financier  and  politician,  Richard  Price, 
had  a  certain  influence  on  economical  study. 
In  tlie  dark  days  of  the  French  War  the  writings 
of  William  Godwin  maybe  said  to  have  given  the 
first  impulse  to  the  socialistic  speculations  after- 
wards earned  out  by  Charles  Hall,  Robert  Owen, 
Edmonds,  Gray,  J.  F.  Bray,  and  William 
Thompson,  With  Thomas  Spence  begins  the 
movement  for  the  nationalising  of  the  land, 
countenanced  in  theory  at  least  by  James  Mill, 
and  advocated  in  later  times  by  Dove,  George, 
and  A,  R,  Wallace.  The  books  of  Paine  include 
not  only  deistic  and  political  utterances,  but 
useful  admonitions  in  regard  to  paper  currency 
in  the  early  days  of  the  suspension  of  cash 
payments.  Ld.  Liverpool's  Coins  of  the  Realm 
(1805),  with  the  mass  of  pamphlets  (see  e.g. 
H.  Thornton,  Lord  King,  Boyd,  Baring,  Bos- 
anqttet,  Huskisson,  Trotter)  called  forth  by 
suspension  and  by  the  Bullion  report,  form  a 
considerable  literature,  in  the  face  of  which  (and 
often  by  the  aid  of  it)  the  theories  of  economists 
like  Ricardo  shaped  themselves.  Such  books 
as  Thomas  Tooke's  History  of  Prices,  ably  con- 
tinued by  Newmarch,  and  in  a  less  degree 
Colqtthoun's  book  on  theHesources  oftheBritish 
Empire,  and  (later)  Porter's  on  the  Progress  of 
the  Nation,  helped  to  point  economists  to  the 
more  ample  use  of  statistics  ;  and  this  service  is 
now  rendered  by  ^vriters  like  Guy,  Rawson,  Pal- 
grave,  Booth,  Giifen,  and  others  in  the  journal  of 
the  "Royal  Statistical  Society"  (founded  1834). 
The  "  refutations  "  of  Mai  thus  on  population 
proceeded  from  all  sorts  and  conditions  of  men. 
Many  m6n  of  the  stamp  of  Cobbett  and  Per- 
ronet  Thompson  took  up  every  economic  con- 
troversy that  had  a  conspicuous  political  side. 
The  new  Com  Law  of  1815  gave  birth  to  a 
multitude  of  pamphlets  and  books  on  the  corn 
laws,  and  eventually,  after  Huskisson's  reforms, 
to  the  movement  that  took  shape  in  the  Anti- 
Corn  Law  League,  and  was  kept  up  vigorously 
by  the  Manchester  School  of  Free  Traders. 
Concurrently  with  this  movement  and  later  in 
its  political  victory  came  the  agitation  for  ex- 
tension of  the  Factory  Acts,  with  a  literature  of 
its  own.  The  discussions  in  regard  to  emigra- 
tion (see  Selkirk)  and  (later)  colonisation  (see 
ToRRENs,  Wakefield,  and  Hill-Burton)  aa 
well  as  in  regard  to  the  reform  of  the  poor  law, 
produced  not  only  small  tracts  but  large  volumes 
in  which  economists  still  find  useful  materials. 
The  value  of  English  blue  books  on  such  topics 
can  hardly  be  over-estimated,  and  since  the  estab- 
lishment of  a  labour  department  (1893)  their 
usefulness  in  this  particular  field  maybeexpected 
to  increase.  Where  economic  policy  has  touched 
closely  the  business  of  the  City,  as  in  the  Bank 
Charter  Act,  the  repeal  of  protective  duties,  and 
the  repeal  of  the  navigation  act,  commercial 
men  have  taken  the  lead  in  the  composition  of 
pamphlets  contending  for  or  against  particular 


measures  by  the  aid,  as  a  rule,  of  a  populai 
political  economy.  Yet  on  such  matters  as 
banking  and  the  foreign  exchanges  such  pam- 
phlets have  not  unfrequently  achieved  a  per- 
manent place  in  classical  economic  literature. 

The  great  development  in  the  last  seventy 
years  or  organisation  among  the  working  classes 
has  led  to  considerable  modifications  of  economic 
theory  (see  Wages  Fund).  This  organisation 
has  shown  itself  most  notably :  (1)  in  trade 
unions  and  other  benefit  societies  among 
skilled  labourers  ;  (2)  in  co-operative  societies 
for  sale  of  goods.  The  former  are  federated 
somewhat  loosely  in  the  trade  union  congress, 
the  latter  very  compactly  in  the  co-operative 
union.  Hitherto  co-operative  production  in 
the  sense  of  partnerships  of  workmen  has  not 
advanced  rapidly.  The  latest  phases  of  the 
organisation  of  the  working  classes  are  :  (1)  the 
growth  of  trades  societies  among  women,  and 
especially  (2)  the  "new  unionism,"  which  has 
two  chief  features  (a)  the  organisation  of  un- 
skilled labom'ers,  (h)  the  policy  of  united  action 
by  all  the  organised  groups  when  the  interest 
of  perhaps  only  one  is  at  stake.  These  move- 
ments have  undoubtedly  influenced  politics  in 
the  direction  of  greater  interference  by  the  state 
than  was  contemplated  by  our  forefathers. 

Indications  that  political  economy  has  not  lost 
its  attractiveness  for  the  English  mind  may  be  seen 
in  the  foundation  of  the  British  Economic  Associa- 
tion (1890),  its  organ  the  Econ.  Journal  (1891), 
and  indeed  in  the  present  Dictionary.  The  Econ. 
Review  (1891)  covers  partly  the  same  ground, 
though  not  so  strictly  economic  as  the  Econ. 
Journal.  The  Cobden  Club  is  still  on  the  watch 
againstprotection  and  over-interference  of  the  state. 
The  Statistical  Society  has  a  journal  coeval  with 
the  society,  embodying  its  transactions,  with  much 
other  valuable  matter.  The  Economist,  under  the 
editorship  of  such  men  as  Wilson,  Bagehot,  and 
Palgrave,  has  done  valuable  service  in  presenting 
clear,  vigorous,  and  solid  economic  argument  on 
questions  of  the  day.  With  the  Statist  it  repre- 
sents on  the  whole  the  views  of  the  economists  of 
the  City.  The  Bankers  Magazine  does  the  same 
for  the  world  of  bankers.  M  any  papers  of  a  strictly 
economical  character  (especially  those  of  Jevons 
and  Giffen)  have  been  published  in  journals  like  the 
Contemporary  Revieiv,  not  addressed  to  profes- 
sional economists  but  to  the  educated  public  gener- 
ally. It  is  to  be  regretted  that  fugitive  economic 
literature,  whether  in  pamphlets  or  articles,  has 
not  yet  found  its  historian;  J,  R.  M'Culloch 
attempted  the  work  in  his  Literature  of  Political 
Economy  (1845),  with  a  fair  measure  of  success. 

The    series   of  volumes   edited   by   M'Culloch 
(printed  for  the  Political  Economy  Club  and  Lord 
Overstone),  in  some  degree  supplement  his  work, 
at  least  for  the  early  part  of  the  period  above 
treated ;  their  titles  are :  A  Select  Collection  of  Scarce.^ 
and  Valuable  'Tracts  on  Money,  London,  printed] 
for  the  Political  Economy  Club,  1856.—^  SelecV 
Collection  of  Early  English  Tracts  on  Commerce, 
London,  printed  for  the  Political  Economy  Club. 
1856,—^  Select  Collection  of  Scarce  and  Valuable 


ENGROSSING— ENSENADA 


737 


Tracts  and  other  Pvblications  on  Paper  Currency 
and  Banking,  printed  by  Lord  Overstone,  London, 
1867. — A  Select  Collection  of  Scarce  and  Valuable 
Tracts  and  other  Publications  on  the  National  Debt 
and  the  Sinking  Fund,  printed  by  Lord  Overstone, 
London,  1857. — A  Select  Collection  of  Scarce  and 
Valuable  Tracts  on  Commerce,  printed  by  Lord 
Overstone,  London,  1859. — A  Select  Collection  of 
Scarce  arid  Valuable  Economical  Tracts,  printed 
by  Lord  Overstone,  London,  1859. — The  Evidence 
given  by  Lord  Overstone  before  the  Select  Committee 
of  the  House  of  Commons  of  1857  on  Bank  Acts, 
London,  Longman,  Brown  and  Co.  1857. —  Tracts 
and  other  Publications  on  Metallic  and  Paper 
Currency,  by  the  Right  Hon.  Lord  Overstone, 
London,  Longman,  Brown  and  Co.,  1858. 

[In  addition  to  M'Culloch's  Literature  there 
may  be  consulted  : — Prof.  Travers  Twiss,  View  of 
the  Progress  of  Political  Economy  in  Europe  since 
the  16th  century,  1847.— Prof.  Adolf  Held,  Zwei 
B'dcher  zur  socialen  Geschichte  Englands  (1881, 
especially  bk.  i. ,  Sociale  und  politische  lAt&ratwr 
von  1776  bis  18S2).—^xot  J.  K.  Ingram,  A  His- 
tory of  Political  Economy  (from  Encycl.  Britann. ), 
1887.— Prof.  H.  S.  Fox  well,  "  The  Economic  Move- 
ment in  England  "  {Harvard  Quarterly  Journal  of 
Economics,  vol.  ii.  1887). — L.  L.  Price,  A  short 
History  of  Political  Economy  in  England  from 
Adam  Smith  to  Toynbee,  1891. — Prof.  L.  Cossa, 
Introduzione  alio  studio  dell'  economia  politica, 
1892.  Eug.  trans.  (L.  Dyer),  1893.— W.  Cunning- 
ham, Growth  of  English  Industry  and  Commerce, 
and  List  of  Authorities,  2nd  ed.,  1892,  and  Christi- 
anity and  Economic  Science,  1914. — Bohm  Bawerk, 
Capital  and  Interest,  1890  ;  Positive  Theory  of 
Capital,  1891  ;  both  trans,  by  Smart. — W.  Smart, 
An  Introduction  to  the  Theory  of  Value,  1891. — 
Studies  in  Economics,  1895.  —  The  Return  to 
Protection,  190i.— Economic  Annals  of  the  19th 
century,  1910. — M.  Pantaleoni,  Pure  Economics, 
trans,  by  T.  B.  Bruce,  1898.-^.  S.  Nicholson, 
Principles  of  Political  Economy,  3  vols.,  1901. — 
Elements  of  Political  Economy,  1903. — A  Project 
of  Empire,  1909. — H.  Sidgwick,  Principles  of 
Political  Economy,  3rd  ed.,  1901. — N.  G.  Pierson, 
Principles  of  Economics,  2  vols.,  trans,  by  A.  A. 
Wotzel,  1902-12.— The  Right  Hon.  C.  Booth, 
lAfe  and  Labour  of  the  People  in  London,  2nd  ed. , 
1903. — J.  B.  Byles,  Sophisms  of  Free  Trade  and 
Popular  Political  Economy,  examined,  edited  by 
W.  S.  Lilly  and  C.  S.  Devas,  1903.— C.  F.  Dunbar, 
Economic  Essays,  1904. — F.  List,  The  National 
System  of  Political  Economy,  trans,  by  S.  S.  Lloyd, 
introd.  by  J,  S.  Nicholson,  1904. — Goschen, 
Essays  and  Addresses  on  Economic  Questions  {1866- 
1893),  1905. — A.  C.  Pigou,  Principles  and  Methods 
of  Industrial  Peace,  1905. — Protective  and  Pre- 
ferential Import  Duties,  1906. — S.  Leacock,  Ele- 
ments of  Political  Science,  1906. — Irving  Fisher, 
Nature  of  Capital  and  Income,  1906 — Rate  of 
Interest,  1907.  —  A.  Marshall,  Principles  of 
Economics,  5th  ed.  1907. — E.  R.  A.  Seligraan, 
Principles  of  Economics,  1907. — C.Gide,  Principles 
of  Political  Economy,  trans,  by  C.  W.  A.  Veditz, 
2nd  ed. — B.  S.  Rowntree,  Lafid  and  Labour, 
Lessons  from  Belgium,  1910. — Sir  Henry  Wood, 
Industrial  England  in  the  Middle  of  the  18th 
Century,  1910. — For  financial  history,   Prof.    C. 

VOL.  I. 


F.  Bastable,  Public  Finance,  190S,  —  TJieary  of 
International  Trade,  1903.— Prof.  E.  R,  A.  Selig- 
man.  Incidence  of  Taxation,  1892.  —  Anton 
Menger,  The  Right  to  the  Whole  Produce  of  Labour^ 
1899,  trans,  by  M.  E.  Tanner,  good  for  early  part 
of  the  century  and  history  of  English  socialism. — 
Karl  Marx,  Capital,  trans,  from  2nd  German 
edition,  1907,  good  for  history  of  factory  legislation 
and  for  references  to  the  minor  economic  literature. 
— The  Political  Economy  of  Dugald  Stewart  (2 
vols.,  ed.  SirWm.  Hamilton,  1855)  is  a  mine  of  refer- 
ences to  the  pamphlet  literature  of  the  end  of  the 
18tli  century. — E.  Cannan,  History  of  the  Theories 
of  Production  and  Distribution  in  English  Political 
Economy,  1776-1848,  8vo,  1893.— J.  Bonar,  Phil- 
osophy and  Political  Economy,  1893. — ^Schulze 
Gavernitz,  Zum  Socialen  Frleden,  1890.      j.  b. 

ENGROSSING.      See    Forestallers    and 

ENREGISTREMENT,  Fr.  One  of  the 
principal  divisions  of  the  French  finances,  con- 
sisting of  a  registration  duty  on  all  deeds  and 
documents,  inchiding  notarial  acts,  judgments, 
contracts,  sales,  leases,  indentures,  wills,  in- 
surance policies,  loans,  articles  of  association, 
successions,  transfers  of  property,  etc.  The 
registration  dues  have  been  frequently  criticised 
for  their  exaggeration.  M.  Leroy  Beaulieii 
describes  them  in  his  Traii6  de  la  Science  des 
FinavyCes,  as  a  fiscal  brigandage.  He  admits 
the  utility  of  registration  as  a  record  of  trans- 
actions in  case  of  loss  of  the  original  deeds,  but 
adds  that  the  tax  is  only  justifiable  provided 
that  it  is  of  moderate  amount,  whereas  as  it  is 
established  in  France  it  frequently  becomes  a 
confiscation  of  private  fortunes  by  the  state. 
The  effect  of  this  heavy  charge  is  to  restrict  the 
free  circulation  of  such  property.  T.  l. 

[^Oode  annote  de  V enregistrement  et  du  timbre, 
par  Dalloz  et  Verge,  Paris,  1878. — Annuaire  de 
V administration  de  V enregistrement,  P.  Dupont.] 

ENSENADA,  Zenon  de  Somodevilla  y 
Bengoechea,  Marquis  de  la  (1702-1782),  died 
in  Medina  del  Campo.  Belonging  to  a  noble 
but  poor  family,  through  his  personal  merit,  he 
rapidly  rose  to  the  highest  rank,  made  an 
immense  fortune,  and  received  the  title  of  marquis 
in  1736  from  the  Infante  Don  Carlos,  afterwards 
Charles  III.  of  Spain. 

Ensenada  was  one  of  the  most  efficient  finance 
ministers  of  Spain.  Under  his  administration, 
the  ordinary  revenue  rose  in  a  few  years  from 
211  to  360  millions  of  reales  (say  from  21  to 
36  millions  sterling),  although  he  contrived  to 
alleviate  the  pressure  of  the  enormous  and  vex- 
atious taxation  which  oppressed  the  lower  classes 
of  the  population.  He  put  an  end  to  the  scan- 
dalous exactions  of  the  farmers  of  the  rentas 
reales  (royal  taxes).  He  established  registros  or 
register  ships,  which  were  allowed  to  trade  with 
America  independently  of  the.^oteand  galleons. 
The  flota  was  the  annual  fleet  between  Spain  and 
her  American  colonies,  the  galleons  were  the 

3  B 


738 


ENTAIL,  LAW  OF 


trading  vessels  escorted  by  the  fleet.  He  formed 
the  design  of  doing  away  with  the  millones  or 
numerous  minor  excise  taxes  and  tolls  which 
weighed  on  every  transaction  of  daily  life,  and 
of  compensating  the  resulting  deficiency  by  a 
better  management  of  the  customs  and  of  the 
excise  on  salt  and  tobacco,  and  by  establishing 
in  Castile  the  tmica  contribucion  or  single  tax, 
which  was  to  be  of^  per  cent  on  every  species 
of  income  and  property.  It  had  been  suggested 
for  more  than  a  century  by  the  majority  of 
Spanish  economic  writers  and  introduced  into 
Catalonia  in  1729.  The  preliminary  survey 
or  catastro  was  begun  under  his  direction. 
Ensenada  also  abolished  the  internal  duties, 
which  interfered  with  the  transport  of  corn  from 
one  province  to  another,  and  improved  the 
means  of  internal  communication.  The  royal 
navy,  military  ports,  and  arsenals  were  the 
object  of  his  incessant  and  successful  exertions, 
which  were  extended  to  almost  every  branch  of 
government. 

Ensenada's  views  and  plans  are  explained  in 
clear  and  straightforward  language  in  the  Repre- 
scTdaciones,  which  he  submitted  to  King  Ferdi- 
nand VI.,  and  which  have  been  given  in  full  for 
the  first  time  in  Don  Antonio  Villa's  excellent 
biographical  essay  {El  Marques  de  Ensenada, 
Madrid,  1878).  One  of  them,  written  in  1751, 
will  be  found,  although  not  quite  complete,  in 
the  Semanario  Erudito  of  Valladares  (Madrid, 
1788,  vol.  xii.  p.  260),  and  in  French  in  the 
French  translation  of  Coxe's  Memoirs  of  Spain 
under  the  Bourbon  Kings,  published  by  Andres 
Muriel  in  Paris  in  1827  (L'Espagne  sous  les  rois 
de  la  Maison  de  Bourbon,  vol.  iv.  p.  282). 
Coxe  gives  a  very  favourable  account  of  the  in- 
ternal administration  of  Ensenada  (ch.  liv.)  ; 
which  will  be  discussed  in  a  special  notice  by 
Count  Feman  Nunez  in  his  Vida  de  Carlos  III., 
now  (1892)  in  the  press.  e.  ca. 

ENTAIL,  Law  of.  An  entail  is  de- 
fined by  Wliarton  (Law  Lexicon)  as  "an 
estate  settled  with  regard  to  the  rule  of  its 
descent."  The  object  of  legislators  in  recog- 
nising entails  has  been  to  preserve  estates 
undiminished  in  the  hands  of  successive 
generations  of  the  same  family.  This  fixity 
of  landed  property  was  essential  to  feudalism, 
which  based  the  political  rights  and  duties  as 
well  as  the  social  consideration  of  each  in- 
dividual on  his  relation  to  the  land.  Feudal 
law,  therefore,  regulated  the  disposition  and 
devolution  of  laud  less  with  reference  to  the 
wishes  of  the  owner  or  to  the  increase  of  the 
riches  of  the  community,  than  with  reference 
to  the  permanence  and  efficiency  of  the  feudal 
organisation.  Feelings  of  family  pride  deepened 
by  feudal  ideas  contributed  in  turn  to  per- 
petuate the  system  of  entails  which  had  fostered 
them.  But  in  the  main  the  system  of  entails 
is  a  political  institution. 

In  one  form  or  another  the  system  of  entails 


may  be  traced  in  every  country  where  feudalism 
established  itself.  In  many  of  those  countries 
it  disappeared  in  the  series  of  political  changes 
which  opened  with  the  French  Revolution.  In 
England,  however,  it  has  survived,  but  with 
many  modifications  which  have  almost  destroyed 
its  identity.  The  English  law  relating  to  entails 
may  be  considered  under  three  heads  : 

I.  The  doctrine  of  "  estates  "  in  land  ;  II.  the 
practice  of  making  settlements  of  land  ;  IIL 
the  modifications  recently  made  in  the  law 
relating  to  land. 

I.  The  unity  of  ownership,  so  prominent  in 
Roman  law,  is  almost  lost  in  the  feudal  land 
law.  In  England  land  is  not  technically  an 
object  of  private  ownership,  since  the  crown 
is  supreme  lord  of  all  the  land  of  England. 
Private  persons  can  only  have  estates,  i.e. 
interests  more  or  less  extensive  in  land.  Many 
different  persons  may  have  estates  or  interests 
in  the  same  piece  of  land.  In  freehold  land 
there  are  three  diflferent  estates :  (a)  estate  in 
fee  simple,  (6)  estate  tail,  (c)  estate  for  life. 
Estate  in  fee  simple  or  an  estate  to  a  man  and 
his  heirs  is  practically,  although  not  technically, 
the  same  thing  as  full  ownership.  The  tenant 
in  fee  simple  has  the  fullest  power  of  enjoying 
and  disposing  of  the  land.  An  estate  tail  is 
an  estate  to  a  man  and  the  heirs  of  his  body, 
i.e.  to  a  man  and  his  descendants.  It  may 
be  an  estate  in  tail  male,  i.e.  descending  only 
to  male  offspring,  or  an  estate  in  tail  female, 
i.e.  descending  only  to  female  offspring,  or  an 
estate  in  tail  special,  i.e.  descending  only  to 
offspring  by  a  particular  wife.  But  estates  in 
tail  special,  are,  in  practice,  very  uncommon. 
When  the  offspring  of  the  tenant  in  tail  are 
all  deceased,  the  estate  tail  is  at  an  end  and 
the  land  reverts  to  the  grantor  of  the  estate 
tail  or  to  his  representative.  Thus  an  estate 
tail  is  a  smaller  interest  in  the  land  carved  out 
of  the  fee  simple  estate.  "When  there  is  an 
estate  tail  in  one  party  there  must  be  a 
reversion  in  fee  in  another  party.  An  estate 
given  to  a  man  and  the  heirs  of  his  body  was 
at  first  regarded  as  a  fee  simple  estate  given 
conditionally  upon  the  birth  of  issue.  When 
the  tenant  had  issue  he  acquired  the  right 
of  alienating  so  as  to  defeat  the  rights  of  his 
heirs  and  also  of  the  reversioner.  By  the 
statute  De  Donis  Conditionalibus  (13  Ed.  I. 
c.  1),  the  power  of  alienation  was  entirely  taken 
away.  But  within  two  centuries  the  lawyers 
invented  methods  of  evading  the  statute, 
namely,  the  collusive  actions  known  as  Fines 
or  Recoveries,  whereby  the  tenant  in  tail 
could  once  more  alienate  his  land,  and  defeat 
the  rights  of  heirs  and  reversioners.  By  the 
Act  for  the  Abolition  of  Fines  and  Recoveries 
(3  &  4  Will.  IV.  c.  74),  these  actions  were 
superseded  and  the  tenant  in  tail  was  enabled 
to  attain  the  same  object  by  simply  executing 
a  deed  to  that  eflfect  and  having  it  enrolled  in 


ENTAIL,  LAW  OF 


739 


a  public  ofRce.  Thus  a  tenant  in  tail  can 
tui-n  Lis  estate  tail  into  an  estate  in  fee  simple, 
and  acquire  virtually  unrestricted  ownership. 
An  estate  for  life  does  not  descend  to  ofispring 
of  the  tenant,  and  cannot  be  enlarged  so  as  to 
extinguish  the  rights  of  the  reversioner.  The 
position  of  the  tenant  for  life  at  common  law, 
and  previously  to  certain  modern  statutes,  was 
that  of  a  usufructuary,  who  might  enjoy  the 
income,  but  might  not  change  the  character, 
much  less  impair  the  capital  value,  of  the 
property.  Thus  he  could  not  open  mines,  fell 
timber,  or  plough  up  old  meadow  land.  Nor 
could  he  dispose  of  the  land  by  way  of  gift, 
sale,  or  exchange,  or  lease  it  for  more  than  a 
very  limited  period.  He  has  been  recently 
invested  with  very  wide  powers  which  will 
be  explained  later  on. 

II.  The  settlements  of  real  estate  in  use 
date  from  the  1 7th  century.  When  a  landowner 
executes  a  settlement,  he  usually  reserves  a 
life  estate  to  himself  and  gives  an  estate  in 
tail  to  his  eldest  son  with  remainders  in  tail 
to  his  other  sons.  The  eldest  son,  when  born, 
acquires  an  estate  in  tail  to  take  effect  after 
his  father's  death.  Such  a  future  estate  in 
tail  cannot  be  banned  without  the  consent  of 
the  tenant  for  life,  who  is  called  the  protector. 

.  If  the  son  held  out  till  his  father's  death,  he 
would  become  tenant  in  tail  in  possession,  and 
then  could  bar  the  entail  and  get  an  estate  in 
fee  simple.  But  whilst  his  father  lives  he  has 
nothing.  Therefore,  when  he  wants  an  estab- 
lishment of  his  own,  he  has  every  reason  to 
join  with  his  father  in  making  a  new  settlement 
similar  to  the  old  one.  Thus  the  perpetuation 
of  an  estate  in  the  same  family  is  ensured. 
But  the  powers  of  a  tenant  for  life  at  common 
law  were  not  enough  even  for  the  proper 
management  of  an  estate.  In  every  well-drawn 
settlement  there  were  appointed  trustees,  in- 
vested with  powers  of  selling,  exchanging,  or 
leasing  parts  of  the  estate  and  of  executing 
permanent  improvements  and  charging  the 
estate  with  the  cost  thereof  These  powers 
the  trustees  were  to  exercise  only  with  the 
consent  of  the  tenant  for  life  and  with  a  view 
to  the  interest  of  all  persons  entitled  under  the 
settlement. 

III.  The  modifications  recently  made  in  the 
law  amount  to  bestowing  upon  the  tenant  for 
life  powers  similar  to  those  bestowed  upon  the 
trustees  by  the  settlement.  A  series  of  statutes 
of  the  present  reign  ending  with  the  Settled 
Land  Act  of  1882  has  annexed  to  the  char- 
acter of  tenant  for  life  the  fullest  powers  of 
alienating  the  whole  or  parts  of  the  estate,  and 
of  employing  the  proceeds  either  to  buy  other 
land  or  to  pay  off  encumbrances  on  the  fee 
simple,  or  to  make  permanent  improvements, 
or  to  invest  in  certain  specified  securities. 
The  tenant  for  life  now  combines  two  totally 
distinct   characters :    his   former  character   of 


usufructuary,  and  his  new  character  of  trustee 
for  all  parties  (himself  included)  who  have  an 
interest  under  the  settlement.  The  settled 
estate  is  now  to  be  regarded  not  so  much  as 
land,  but  as  capital  which  happens  to  be 
invested  in  land,  but  may  be  invested  other- 
wise at  the  discretion  of  the  tenant  for  life. 
It  remains  to  notice  the  objections  made  by 
economists  against  systems  of  entail  generally, 
and  to  consider  how  far  they  are  applicable 
to  the  system  of  entails  now  existing  in 
England.  These  objections  are  principally 
two  :  I.  entails  check  the  improvement  of 
land  ;  II.  entails  restrict  the  transfer  of  land. 

I.  Entails  check  the  improvement  of  land, 
and  so  lessen  the  wealth  of  the  community  ; 
because  the  limited  owner,  as  compared  with  the 
absolute  owner,  has  (a)  less  motive  to  improve 
and  (b)  less  power  of  improving,  (a)  The  limited 
owner  has  less  motive  to  improve  his  land, 
because  he  cannot  dispose  of  it  by  sale  or  testa- 
ment, and  because  the  property  will  all  go  to  one 
son,  without  affording  a  provision  for  the  other 
children.  Hence  the  limited  owner  is  exposed 
to  the  temptation  of  desiring  to  apply  the 
whole  income  of  the  land,  either  to  his  own 
purposes  or  to  making  a  provision  for  daughters 
and  younger  sons.  The  English  tenant  for  life 
cannot  now  be  deprived  of  the  power  of  selling 
his  land,  but  he  can  touch  only  the  income 
of  the  proceeds.  This  objection,  therefore,  is 
lessened  rather  than  removed  by  recent  legis- 
lation, (b)  The  limited  owner  lacks  power  to 
improve  the  land,  because  (i)  his  freedom  of 
action  has  been  narrowly  regulated  by  law. 
(ii)  His  land  may  have  been  encumbered  with 
charges  created  in  favour  of  other  members  of 
his  family,  which  lessen  the  net  income  ;  (iii) 
he  has  to  make  provision  for  children  other 
than  the  heir,  and  is  thus  further  straitened. 

(i)  The  English  tenant  for  life  (see  Settled 
Land  Act,  1882),  has  now  the  legal  right  to  do 
almost  anything  which  the  tenant  in  fee  simple 
could  do.  His  means  for  permanent  improve- 
ment are  now  much  greater  than  they  were 
formerly,  since  he  can  sell  part  of  his  land  in 
order  to  raise  capital  for  improving  the  rest. 
He  can  do  this  without  impoverishing  his 
younger  children,  as  the  land  which  he  sells 
would  under  the  settlement  have  gone  to  the 
eldest  son.  (ii)  The  charges  on  the  land  to  pro- 
vide a  jointure  for  the  widow  of  the  late  tenant 
for  life,  and  portions  for  the  younger  brothers 
and  the  sisters,  are  not  affected  by  recent  legisla- 
tion. They  form  deductions  from  the  gross 
income  of  the  tenant  for  life,  and  lessen  his 
means  of  improvement,  (iii)  The  tenant  for 
life  still  has  to  provide  for  his  younger  children, 
and  may  thus  be  tempted  to  set  apart  for  them 
money  which  might  with  advantage  be  spent 
on  improving  the  land.  Kecent  legislation, 
therefore,  whilst  much  enlarging  the  powers  of 
improvement  possessed  by  a  tenant  for  life,  has 


740 


ENTAIL,  LAW  OF— ENTAIL  (SCOTLAND) 


not  put  him  upon  an  equality  in  this  respect 
with  the  tenant  in  fee  simple. 

II.  It  is  said  that  a  system  of  entail  deprives 
landowners  of  (a)  the  power,  (b)  the  motive  to 
sell  their  land,  and  thus  produces  the  following 
evils:— (i)  the  retention  of  land  in  the  hands  of 
persons  who  may  be  .too  impoverished  to  im- 
prove it ;  (ii)  the  exclusion  of  capital  from 
being  employed  in  the  improvement  of  land 
which  under  a  system  of  free  sale  would  be 
purchased  by  capitalists  ;  (iii)  a  restriction  in 
the  number  of  landowners,  which  diminishes  the 
stability  of  society ;  and  (iv)  the  removal  of  a 
strong  motive  to  industry  and  economy  in  the 
labouring  class,  namely,  the  hope  of  becoming 
the  owner  of  a  piece  of  land. 

That  the  power  to  sell  is  wanting,  under  a 
complete  system  of  entail,  is  clear.  That  it  is 
not  wanting  under  the  modified  system  of 
entail  now  existing  in  England  is  also  clear. 
The  motive  to  sell  is  still  wanting  to  the 
tenant  for  life,  in  so  far  as  he  cannot  appro- 
priate the  capital  sum  paid  by  the  purchaser. 
But,  since  his  income  is  much  reduced  by  prior 
charges,  and  by  the  necessity  of  saving  for 
children  other  than  the  heir,  he  has  the 
strongest  inducement  to  exchange  an  invest- 
ment like  land,  which  at  the  present  day  rarely 
pays  more  than  2  per  cent,  for  investments  like 
railway  debentures,  which  pay  3  per  cent.  For 
the  increase  of  return  all  goes  to  swell  his 
income,  the  charges  upon  it  remaining  the  same. 

Under  the  Settled  Land  Act,  a  good  deal  of 
land  has  been  sold  in  England.  But  hitherto 
land  has  been  offered  for  sale  mostly  in  large 
masses.  For  this  there  are  several  reasons  : — 
(i)  the  influence  of  habit  upon  those  who  con- 
duct the  sale  of  land  ;  (ii)  the  extravagant 
expenses  connected  with  making  out  a  title, 
which  may  be  as  heavy  for  a  small  piece  of 
ground  as  for  a  large  estate,  and  so  act  as  a 
prohibitory  tax  on  sales  of  small  parcels  ;  (iii) 
the  present  condition  of  the  market  for  agiicul- 
tural  produce  which  represses  any  strong  desire, 
in  the  English  middle  or  lower  dass,  to  become 
freeholders.  Energetic  persons  engaged  in 
agriculture  prefer  to  employ  their  capital  in 
working  a  large  farm  rather  than  in  buying  a 
small  one.  Other  small  capitalists  dislike  so 
risky  and  unproductive  an  investment  as  land 
is  at  the  present  time.  For  all  these  reasons 
the  estates  which  have  come  into  the  market 
have  generally  been  bought  undivided  by 
wealthy  men  who  can  afford  to  place  great  sums 
in  a  sort  of  property  which  gives  social  con- 
sideration and  out-of-door  amusement,  but 
yields  only  a  paltry  return  in  money.  Thus 
the  sales  which  have  taken  place  in  England 
are  not  believed  to  have  much  increased  the 
number  of  landowners.  In  Wales,  the  tenants 
sometimes  buy  their  farms  when  offered  for 
sale.  In  Ireland  the  tenants  are  almost  the 
only  purchasers.    In  those  countries  the  number 


of  landowners  is  thus  increasing.  Moreover, 
as  small  owners  rarely  make  family  settle- 
ments, an  increasing  part  of  the  land  in  Wales 
and  Ireland  is  no  longer  subject  to  a  system  of 
entails,  but  is  Jield  by  tenants  in  fee  simple. 

[For  the  legal  learning  of  entails,  the  reader  may 
consult  Kenelm  Digby's  History  of  the  English 
Law  of  Real  Projser^y.— Williams'  Law  of  Real 
Property. — Goodeve,  Modern  Law  of  Real  Pro- 
perty.—The  Land  Laws,  by  Sir  Frederick  Pollock 
(English  Citizen  Series),  and  many  other  text-books, 
together  with  the  statutes  and  leading  cases  to 
which  they  make  reference.  Some  interesting  ^ 
observations  upon  the  rise  of  feudal  systems  of 
tenure,  upon  entails  and  primogeniture,  will  be 
found  in  Maine's  Ancient  Law,  ch.  vii.,  and 
Early  Law  and  Custom,  ch.  ix. 

Of  the  writers  who  have  considered  entails  in 
their  economic  aspect,  only  a  few  can  be  men- 
tioned here :  Adam  Smith,  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk. 
iii.  ch.  ii.,  who  dwells  on  the  injustice  to  younger 
children  caused  by  entails,  and  asserts  in  terms 
much  too  absolute  the  improbability  of  a 
great  proprietor  executing  great  improvements. — 
M  'Culloch,  Principles  of  Political  Economy,  who 
justifies  primogeniture  by  its  efi'ect  in  raising  the 
fashionable  standard  of  living,  and  so  giving  an 
impetus  to  the  pursuit  of  wealth. — Mill,  Principles 
of  Political  Economy,  bk.  v.  ch.  ix.,  who  condemns 
entails  partly  as  encouraging  idleness  and  ex- 
travagance, partly  on  the  grounds  above  explained 
at  length. — Boyd-Kinnear,  Principles  of  Property 
in  Land. — Cliff'e  Leslie,  Land  Systems  and  In- 
dustrial Economy.  — A  volume  of  the  Cobden  Club 
Essays,  entitled  Systems  of  Land  Tenure  in  various 
Countries. — George  Brodrick,  English  Land  and 
Landlords  (also  included  in  the  Cobden  Club 
Essaj's), — Shaw  Lefevre,  English  and  Irish  Land 
Questions. — Arthur  Arnold,  Free  Land. — Kay, 
Free  Trade  in  Land,  etc.  None  of  these  writers 
can  be  said  to  have  fully  considered  the  latest 
stage  of  the  English  law  relating  to  this  subject, 
and  therefore  many  of  their  criticisms  are  partially 
obsolete.]  F.  c.  M. 

[Refer  for  other  sides  of  the  question  to 
Bequest,  power  op  ;  Morcellbmbnt.  ] 

ENTAIL  (Scotland)  anciently  and  still 
sometimes  called  tailzie,  from  Lat.  talliaium, 
cut  off ;  any  deed  by  which  the  ordinary  legal 
course  of  succession  is  cut  off  and  a  fresh  one 
substituted.  The  power  to  create  an  entail, 
previously  doubtful  in  Scotland,  was  definitely 
given  by  the  act  1685  c.  22.  Every  proprietor 
in  fee  since  that  date  may  grant  a  simple  des- 
tination which  merely  names  a  succession  of 
heirs,  each  one  of  whom  may  dispose  of  the 
estate  as  he  pleases,  and  whose  successor  in  the 
destination  merely  takes  in  default  of  such  dis- 
position, or  he  may  protect  the  succession  he 
prescribes  by  restrictive  clauses  forbidding  any 
interference  with  the  succession  by  selling, 
alienating,  or  disposing  of  the  lands,  contracting 
debt,  or  doing  an}'  deed  whereby  the  succession 
might  be  frustrated.  These  clauses  must  be 
inserted  in  all  title-deeds,  and  the  entail  with 
the  judicial  authority  of  the  court  of  session 


ENTAIL  (SCOTLAND)— ENTREPRENEUR 


741 


must  be  recorded.  Every  act  or  deed  contra- 
vening these  restrictions  was  declared  null,  and 
the  real  heir  might,  on  contravention,  take  up 
the  estate.  In  1770  the  heir  in  possession  of 
entailed  lands  was  allowed  a  modified  power  of 
leasing,  and  of  charging  against  future  heirs  a 
proportion  of  the  expense  of  improvements  on 
the  property  by  the  Montgomery  Act,  10  Geo. 
III.  c.  51.  Further  relaxations  were  granted 
in  1824  by  the  Aberdeen  Act,  5  Geo.  IV.  c.  87, 
enabling  an  heir  of  entail  in  possession  to  make 
limited  provisions  in  favour  of  a  husband  or 
wife  or  children,  which  were  payable  by  the 
successors  out  of  the  yearly  rents  or  proceeds, 
but  did  not  affect  the  fee  of  the  entailed  estates ; 
by  the  Rutherfurd  Act  1848  the  fee  may 
now  be  charged  in  favour  of  younger  children. 
But  no  powers  either  under  the  Montgomery 
Act  or  the  Aberdeen  Act  could  be  exercised  so 
as  to  deprive  the  successors  of  more  than  two- 
thirds  of  the  free  yearly  rents.  In  1836  the 
Rosebery  Act,  6  &  7  Will.  IV.  c.  42,  gave 
the  heii'  in  possession  a  limited  power  to  sell 
parts  of  the  estate  for  the  entailer's  debts  under 
the  authority  of  the  court  of  session.  In  1848 
the  Rutherfurd  Act,  11  &  12  Vict.  c.  36,  first 
conferred  on  an  heir  of  entail  in  possession  the 
power  to  disentail.  Elaborate  and  intricate 
provisions  were  made  by  the  Rutherfurd  Act 
distinguishing  between  entails  made  before  and 
after  its  date,  and  heirs  in  possession  who  were 
born  before  or  after  that  date,  with  regard  to 
the  consents  required  to  disentail.  Broadly 
speaking,  if  the  heir  in  possession  was  born 
before  the  act  and  the  entail  was  made  before 
the  act,  he  requires  the  consent  of  all  the  heirs 
if  less  than  three,  or  of  the  next  three  heirs,  or 
of  the  heir  apparent  and  two  of  the  heirs  who 
would,  including  the  heir  apparent,  be  succes- 
sively heirs  apparent,  provided  the  nearest  heir 
be  twenty-one  years  old  ;  or  if  such  consents  be 
refused  by  any  heir,  even,  since  1882,  the  nearest 
heir  for  the  time,  the  court  may  assess  the  value 
of  the  heir's  interest  and  dispense  with  his  con- 
sent on  the  payment  to  him  of  the  value  of  his 
interest,  or  sufficient  security  for  such  payment. 
The  next  heir  in  succession  thus  receives  a  lump 
sum  for  his  expectancy  instead  of  getting,  as  in 
England,  the  interest  of  the  purchase  money  if 
and  when  he  succeeds  in  lieu  of  his  interest  in 
the  land.  The  distinction  between  old  and  new 
entails  is  now  removed.  Other  powers  now 
possessed  by  heirs  in  possession  of  entailed 
estates  are — to  sell  under  the  same  conditions 
as  those  of  disentailing,  to  excamb,  or  exchange, 
any  portion  of  the  entailed  estate  for  an  equiva- 
lent in  contiguous  lands,  without  any  consent, 
taking  or  giving  not  more  than  £200  for 
equality  of  exchange,  to  grant  feus  and  leases, 
to  charge  improvements,  and  to  charge  family 
provisions  in  favour  of  the  wives,  husbands,  or 
children  of  heirs  of  entail  in  possession. 

[Rankine,  Land  Ownership,  chap,  xxxiv. — Bell's 


Principles,  §  1716,  et  seq. — Duff  ou  Entails. — 
Duncan  on  Entail  Procedure.]  J.  w.  b.  i. 

ENTREpStS.  a  term  applied  in  France 
and  other  countries  to  places  of  deposit  for 
goods,  analogous  to  the  bonded  warehouses  in 
the  ports  and  trade  centres  of  the  British 
Empire.  In  them  artic!es  subject  to  custom 
or  excise  duties  may  be  placed,  until  time  of 
payment  of  the  imposts  to  which  they  are 
liable  on  delivery  for  consumption,  or  until 
removal  for  the  convenience  of  trade,  or  ex- 
portation to  foreign  countries.  In  the  latter 
case  the  importers  are  relieved  altogether  from 
the  necessity  of  the  revenue  payments,  and  in 
the  others  this  outlay  need  not  be  incurred 
until  such  time  as  the  consumers  are  ready  for 
their  use.  In  this  coimtry,  where  an  immense 
transit  trade  centralises,  where  the  operations 
are  often  of  great  magnitude,  and  the  few  duties 
retained  are  great  in  proportion  to  the  prime  cost 
of  the  articles,  the  facilities  afforded  by  this 
system  permit  of  much  trade  being  carried  on 
which  would  otherwise  be  cramped  or  altogether 
prevented.  The  use  of  capital  is  economised,  and 
excessive  fluctuations  in  price  are  checked  by 
the  large  stocks  it  is  possible  to  retain  on  hand, 
as  well  as  the  speed  with  which  supplies  may 
be  transferred  to  the  consumers,  at  a  lessened 
cost  for  time  and  money  expended.  On  the 
other  hand,  the  care  bestowed  upon  their  safe 
custody,  and  the  supervision  of  the  necessary 
operations,  such  as  sorting,  vatting,  and  other 
processes,  constitutes  a  charge  upon  the  revenue 
for  the  benefit  of  the  consumer  or  trader. 

These  observations  apply  with  much  greater 
force  to  the  "  entrepSts  "  established  in  France 
and  elsewhere,  because  of  the  multitude  of 
articles  which  have,  for  the  security  of  the 
revenue,  to  be  taken  in  charge,  at  a  considerable 
cost  if  the  supervision  be  eflectual,  or  of  risk  if 
it  be  insufficient.  There,  too,  it  is  not  only  the 
national  revenue  which,  as  here,  has  to  be  safe- 
guarded, but  also  the  municipal  tolls  in  the 
shape  of  octroi.  It  is  mainly  this  which  has 
led  to  the  division  of  these  entrepots  into  ^'reels'' 
where  the  goods  are  actually  kept  in  custody, 
and  '^fictifs,"  nominal  or  conventional,  where 
the  owner  has  them  in  his  own  charge,  but  is 
answerable  for  the  payment  of  the  duties  to 
which    they   are    liable.      See    also    Bonded 

WaREIK)USES. 

{Nouveau  Dictionnaire  d^ Economic  Politiqtie, 
1891,  vol.  1.  p.  898  ;  and  Dictionnaire  des  Finances, 
1889,  vol.  ii.  p.  118.]  s.  BO. 

ENTREPRENEUR.  An  alternative  name  for 
the  employer  (see  Employers  and  Employed). 
Adam  Smith  (  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  i.  ch.  vi. ) 
used  the  term  "undertaker,"  and  J.  S.  Mill 
{Political  Economy,  bk.  ii.  ch.  xv.  §  1  footnote), 
expresses  his  regret  that  "  this  word,  in  this 
sense,  is  not  familiar  to  an  English  ear." 
He  adds  that  "French  political  economists 
enjoy   a   great    advantage    in    being    able    ta 


742 


ENTRY,  BILL  OF— ENTRY,  RIGHT  OF 


speak  currently  of  'les  profits  de  Tentrepre- 
neur'";  and  it  seems  that,  partly  perhaps  in 
consequence  of  this,  political  economy  has  m 
Fran(S  avoided  the  mistake  committed  by  some 
of  the  older  EngUsh  economists  m  failing  to 
distinguish  the  functions  of  the  employer  and 
his  share  in  the  produce  of  industry  as  such 
from  the  functions  and  share  of  the  capitalist 
as  such.  General  F.  A.  Walker  (  Wages  Ques- 
tion, ch.  xiv.)  echoes  Mill's  regret  that  "we 
have  not  a  single  English  word  which  exactly 
fits  the  person  who  performs  "  the  office  of  the 
employer  in  modem  industry.  "The  word 
undertaker,"  he  remarks,  "at  one  time  had 
very  much  this  extent,"  and  so  had  the  word 
"adventurer."  But  they  have  since  acquired 
other  senses.  The  ' '  French  word  entrepreneur, " 
however,  he  adds,  "has  very  nearly  the  desired 
significance,  and  it  may  be  that  the  exigencies 
of  politico-economical  reasoning  will  yet  lead 
to  its  being  naturalised  among  us."     l.  l.  p. 

[See  also  French  School.] 

ENTRY,  Bill  of.  The  name  given  to  an 
office  within  the  custom  house  at  London,  and 
other  ports  of  the  United  Kingdom,  from  which 
there  issue  daily  lists  of  ships  arriving  and 
sailing,  with  accounts  of  their  cargoes,  de- 
liveries from  bonded  warehouses,  and  other 
particulars  of  considerable  interest  to  the 
mercantile  community.  In  addition  to  these 
printed  publications,  manuscript  accounts  are 
rendered  to  those  who  may  desire  such  special 
information  as  can  be  gleaned  from  the  customs 
records,  or  may  be  compiled  from  the  various 
documents  and  forms  supplied  for  customs 
purposes.  The  printed  lists  are  sold  to  sub- 
scribers, and  the  special  returns  are  paid  for  in 
proportion  to  their  length  or  the  trouble  in- 
volved in  their  preparation,  for  the  exclusive 
use  of  those  at  whose  expense  they  are  compiled. 

The  history  of  this  arrangement  is  somewhat 
peculiar  ;  it  is,  or  was  until  recently,  a  remnant 
of  the  old  times  when  special  privileges  were 
conferred  on  favoured  individuals  for  their 
pecuniary  advantage,  or  in  return  for  payments 
made  by  them.  One  of  these  acquired,  in  1660, 
by  letters  patent,  the  exclusive  right  of  access 
to  all  official  documents  connected  with  the 
customs  reports  and  entries,  and  of  obtaining 
and  publishing  any  portion  of  the  information 
they  furnished.  Ultimately,  in  1817,  this 
right  became  vested  in  the  Customs  Annuity 
and  Benevolent  Fund — a  mutual  insurance 
fund  supported  by  payments  of  the  officers 
themselves,  supplemented  by  the  profits  of  the 
bill  of  entry,  and  devoted  to  the  sole  benefit 
of  their  widows  and  orphans.  Through  the 
energy  and  wisdom  of  the  directors  this  had 
grown  to  be  a  valuable  business,  which,  at  the 
expiration  of  the  crown  patent,  in  1880,  the 
treasury  appropriated  to  its  own  benefit,  and  it 
is  now  profitably  carried  on  by  the  commis- 
sioners of  customs.      The  public   funds  thus 


became  possessors  of  a  private  property  created 
by  independent  exertions  on  behalf  of  a  charit- 
able purpose. 

The  existence  of  such  a  source  of  information 
is  of  great  advantage  to  merchants,  statisticians, 
traders,  and  shipowners,  by  enabling  them  to 
obtain  correct  knowledge  on  points  too  minute, 
too  varied,  and  too  numerous  to  be  set  forth  in 
the  periodical  returns  of  trade  and  navigation 
laid  before  parliament. 

[Rejxjrts  of  Commissioners  of  Customs. — Bill  oj 
Entry,  Journals  A  and  B. — Bourne,  Royal  Statis- 
tical Society  s  Journal,  vol.  xxxv.  pp.  214-215, 
1872.]  s.  Bo. 

ENTRY,  Right  of.  The  payment  of  the 
rent,  and  the  performance  of  the  covenants  in  a 
lease,  are  usually  secured  by  a  "condition  or 
proviso  for  re-entry,"  which  enables  the  land- 
lord on  non-payment  of  the  rent  or  non- 
performance of  the  covenants,  to  take  possession 
of  the  premises  let,  as  if  no  lease  had  been 
made.  The  courts  of  equity  and  the  legisla- 
ture have,  in  a  certain  measure,  succeeded  in 
preventing  landlords  from  making  any  oppres- 
sive use  of  this  power.  Thus  a  tenant  who  has 
been  ejected  in  consequence  of  the  non-payment 
of  rent  may  be  reinstated  if  he  pays  the  rent 
and  costs  within  six  months  after  the  execution 
of  the  judgment.  As  regards  the  non-perform- 
ance of  covenants,  not  relating  to  the  payment 
of  rent,  and  not  belonging  to  one  of  the  ex- 
cepted classes  referred  to  below,  a  right  of 
re-entry  or  forfeiture  is  not  enforceable  unless 
the  tenant  has  failed  to  comply  with  the  terms 
of  a  notice  specifying  the  breach  and  requiring 
him  to  remedy  it  and  to  pay  compensation  in 
money  in  respect  of  it  (Conveyancing  Act,  1881, 
§  14).  In  such  cases  forfeiture  is  therefore 
impossible,  except  when  the  breach  is  wilful 
and  persistent.  The  rule  just  mentioned  does 
not,  however,  extend  to  covenants  against 
assigning  and  underletting,  and  the  omission 
to  obtain  the  landlord's  consent  to  an  assign- 
ment or  underlease  of  the  premises  may  lead  to 
the  forfeiture  of  the  lease  although  it  was  due 
to  forgetfulness  on  the  part  of  the  tenant's 
solicitor,  and  although  the  landlord  would  not, 
under  the  circumstances,  have  withheld  his  con- 
sent if  asked  for  (Barrow  v.  Isaacs  [1891],  i.  ; 
Queen's  Bench,  417).  The  attempts  to  induce 
the  legislature  to  enact  some  provisions  more 
favourable  to  tenants  in  respect  of  such  cove- 
nants have  proved  abortive,  and  their  only  result 
has  been  §  3  of  the  Conveyancing  Act  of  1892, 
which  provides  that  in  the  absence  of  an  express 
agreement  to  the  contrary,  a  landlord  shall  not 
make  his  consent  to  an  assignment  or  under- 
letting dependent  on  the  payment  of  a  sum  of 
money  beyond  a  reasonable  amount  in  respect 
of  expenses.  Conditions  for  forfeiture  on  the 
bankruptcy  of  the  tenant,  or  on  the  taking 
in  execution  of  the  tenant's  interest,  were  also 
originally  excepted  from  the  rule  granting  relief 


ENUMERATED  COMMODITIES— l^PHjfeM^RIDES 


7  43 


as  stated  above  ;  but  it  is  now  provided  by  §§  2 
and  3  of  the  Conveyancing  Act  of  1892  that, 
subject  to  certain  exceptions,  a  lease  is  not  to 
be  forfeited  in  such  a  case,  unless  the  tenant's 
interest  remains  unsold  within  a  year  after  the 
date  of  the  bankruptcy  or  of  the  taking  in  (execu- 
tion. The  practical  importance  of  the  exception 
is  materially  reduced  by  this  alteration,   e.  s. 

ENUMERATED  COMMODITIES.  This 
term  has  two  distinct  meanings,  according  as  it 
is  applied  :  (1)  to  the  European  trade  of  Eng- 
land ;  (2)  to  the  colonial  trade  of  England. 
In  both  cases  it  refers  to  commodities  which 
were  originally  enumerated  in  the  Navigation 
Act  of  1660,  but  which  were  altered  from  time 
to  time  by  subsequent  legislation, 

(1)  With  regard  to  the  European  trade,  the 
first  Navigation  Act  in  1651  forbade  the 
importation  of  European  products  except  in 
British  ships,  or  ships  of  the  country  where  the 
goods  were  produced,  or  from  which  they  could 
only  be,  or  most  usually  were,  exported.  The 
second  Navigation  Act  in  1660,  while  adopting 
most  of  the  provisions  of  1651,  modified  this 
particular  article.  It  renewed  the  restriction 
about  importation  to  (1)  all  Russian  and 
Turkish  products,  and  (2)  certain  enumerated 
commodities :  viz.  timber,  salt,  pitch,  tar,  rosin, 
hemp  and  flax,  raisins,  figs,  prunes,  olive  oils, 
all  kinds  of  corn  or  grain,  sugar  or  potashes, 
wines,  vinegar  and  spirits  (12  Car.  II.  c.  18, 
§  8).  All  other  European  goods  could  be  im- 
ported in  any  vessel.  Two  years  later  a  further 
restriction  was  made,  and  it  was  provided  that 
certain  goods  should  not  be  imported  into  Eng- 
land in  any  ship  whatever  from  Germany, 
Holland,  and  the  Spanish  Netherlands.  This 
second  list  of  enumerated  commodities  included 
all  wines  other  than  Rhenish,  spices,  grocery, 
tobacco,  potashes,  pitch,  tar,  salt,  resin,  timber, 
and  olive  oil  (13  &  14  Car.  II.  c.  11,  §  23). 
Changes  in  the  enumeration  were  made  at 
intervals  in  obedience  to  momentary  pressure 
or  changing  interests.  But  no  great  relaxation 
of  the  system  of  1660  and  1662  was  made  till 
1822,  when  the  importation  of  enumerated 
goods  was  extended  to  ships  of  the  country  or 
place  from  which  they  were  imported  ;  and  at 
the  same  time  the  exceptional  restrictions  upon 
trade  with  Germany,  the  Netherlands,  Russia, 
and  Turkey,  were  abolished  (3  Geo.  IV.  c.  43, 
§  6).  The  distinction  between  enumerated  and 
non-enumerated  commodities  disappears  alto- 
gether after  the  repeal  of  the  Navigation  Act 
in  1849. 

(2)  As  applied  to  the  colonial  trade,  the 
term  enumerated  commodities  had  an  equally 
important  significance.  The  act  of  1660 
limited  all  trade,  both  of  export  and  import, 
with  British  plantations  in  Asia,  Africa,  or 
America  to  British  ships.  But  it  added  a  dis- 
tinction between  those  colonial  products  which 
could  only  be  carried  to  England  and  those 


which  might  be  carried,  still  in  British  ships, 
to  countries  other  than  England.  The  former, 
which  are  the  enumerated  commodities  ia  this 
connection,  naturally  included  all  those  com- 
modities which  England  did  not  produce  herself, 
or  did  not  produce  in  sufficient  quantity  for 
her  needs.  The  non- enumerated  commodities, 
which  included  all  those  goods  in  which  the 
home  producers  dreaded  colonial  rivalry,  were 
originally  allowed  to  choose  any  market  out- 
side England,  but  were  ultimately  limited  to 
countries  south  of  Cape  Finisterre.  The  motive 
for  this  restriction  was  to  prevent  the  manu- 
facturing rivals  of  England  from  obtaining  raw 
materials  from  our  colonies.  These  and  other 
oppressive  regulations  with  regard  to  colonial 
trade  were  undoubtedly  a  chief  cause  of  the 
revolt  in  1774  of  the  American  colonies,  whose 
success  dealt  a  fatal  blow  at  the  policy  of  the 
navigation  acts,  and  in  1796  the  United 
States  were  allowed  to  carry  their  goods  in  their 
own  ships  to  Great  Britain.  In  1822,  the 
distinction  of  enumerated  commodities  among 
colonial  products  became  obsolete,  and  the 
colonies  were  allowed  to  export  not  only  their 
own  produce,  but  their  imports  from  other 
countries,  to  any  place  in  Europe,  Africa,  or 
America,  either  in  British  ships  or  in  ships  of 
the  country  to  which  they  were  exported 
(3  Geo.  IV.  c.  44,  §  4,  and  c.  45,  §  2). 

[M'Culloch's  edition  of  Adam  Smith,  note  xi., 
and  Leone  Levi,  History  of  British  Commerce,  pt. 
iii.  eh.  ii.,  give  a  clear  account  of  the  enumerated 
commodities  in  European  trade.  For  the  term  as 
applied  to  colonial  products  see  Adam  Smith, 
Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  iv.  eh.  vii.  pt.  2.]      R.  L. 

]6pHEMERIDES.  About  the  middle  of  the 
18th  century  proposals  for  reform  both  in 
finance  and  agidculture  began  to  interest  the 
French  public.  In  1751  a  special  review,  the 
Journal  ceconomique  ou  Mdmoires,  Notes  et  Avis 
sur  I' agriculture,  les  arts,  et  le  commerce,  was 
established  in  order  to  deal  with  these  subjects. 
This  journal  contained  essays  both  on  practical 
and  theoretical  questions  ;  the  latter  presenting 
restrictive  as  well  as  liberal  views.  Recom- 
mendations of  free-trade  in  corn,  and  transla- 
tions of  works  of  English  economists,  as  Josiah 
Tucker  and  Hume,  strengthened  the  position 
of  the  French  school  of  free  trade  who  became 
afterwards  ,the  physiocrats.  The  Gazette  du 
Commerce,  established  in  April  1763,  admitted 
the  contributions  of  Le  Trosne  and  St.  Peravy 
as  well  as  those  of  their  opponents.  The  govern- 
ment, favouring  these  discussions  on  the  corn 
policy,  bought  up  this  newspaper  and  connected 
with  the  Gazette  du  Commerce  a  special  review, 
the  Journal  de  V Agriculture,  du  Commerce,  et 
des  Finances  (1764).  This  Journal  soon 
passed  into  the  sole  possession  of  the  physio- 
crats and  was  their  organ  from  September  1765 
to  November  1766.  It  ceased  to  appear  in 
1783. 


744 


fePH^M:6RIDES 


Among  the  periodicals  treating  on  subjects  akin 
to  those  dealt  with  by  the  Journal  de  V Agri- 
culture was  a  weekly  paper,  the  Eph6m6rides 
du  Gitoym  ou  chroniqiie  de  Vesprit  national 
(6  vols.  12mo),  established  in  December  1765, 
after  the  model  of  Addison's  Spectator,*  by 
the  Abbe  Baudeau.  He  intended  through  its 
means  to  defend  the  interests  of  "humanism" 
by  pleading  for  the  abolition  of  slavery  in  the 
colonies.  He,  however,  employed  his  organ 
to  attack  the  Economists,  professing  for  his 
own  part  mercantilist  views  and  a  detestation 
of  free- trade.  Le  Trosne  replied  in  the  Jowmal 
de  V Agriculture  of  March  1766  to  Baudeau  ;  the 
latter  answered,  but  soon  desisted,  for,  after 
reading  but  half  a  page  of  Le  Trosne's  private 
observations  on  the  futility  of  the  "balance  of 
trade,"  he  abandoned  his  intention  of  continu- 
ing these  polemics.  Shortly  after  this  the 
Marquis  of  Mirabeau  brought  Baudeau  fully  to 
agree  with  the  physiocratic  school.  This 
event,  le  saut  de  la  science,  proved  very  import- 
ant for  the  progress  of  the  Economists.  For  the 
tpMrrUrides  was  ready  to  receive  their  contri- 
butions just  at  the  time  that  the  editor  of  the 
Journal  de  V  Agriculture  put  difficulties  in  their 
way  (December  1766).  After  January  1767 
the  new  organ  appeared  as  a  monthly  review 
under  the  title  ijpMmdrides  du  Citoyen,  ou 
BihliotMque  raisonnie  des  Sciences  morales  et 
politiques.  Baudeau  remained  its  editor  till 
May  1768,  when  his  place  was  taken  by  Du 
Pont  de  Nemours.  The  most  eminent  writers 
of  the  physiocratic  school  contributed  to  this 
journal.  Among  the  most  interesting  articles 
are  the  following  : — Quesnay's  **  Essays  on  the 
Government  of  Peru  "  (1767,  t.  i.)  ;  he  declares 
that  the  system  of  tithes  in  Peru  proves  its  an- 
cient government  tohave  been  the  mostprosperous 
and  the  fairest  in  the  world. — On  "Despotism 
in  China"  signed  M.  A.  (1767,  t.  iii.,  iv.,  v.,  vi.), 
in  which  he  describes  Chinese  political  institu- 
tions as  exhibiting  "an  order  of  essential 
stability,"  besides  minor  articles  (1767,  t.  x., 
1768,  t.  ii.)  ;  cp.  Oncken's  edition  of  Quesnay's 
(Euvres,  pp.  660-692. — Mirabeau's  "Letters  on 
the  Legal  Order."  In  these  he  undertakes  to 
give  an  historical  account  of  the  causes  of  economic 
legislation,  and  the  study  of  the  "physical  "causes 
leading  towards  its  reform  (1767,  t.  ix.,  x.,  xi., 
xii.  ;  1768,  t.  i.  to  vi.,  viii.  to  xii.  ;  1769,  t.  1. 
to  iii., v.). — On  the  economic  education  of  girls  ; 
insisting  upon  the  necessity  of  instructing  them 
in  the  science  of  the  natural  social  order  (1768, 
t.  iii.).— Dialogues  between  a  child  and  its 
teacher,  on  the  use  of  science  to  princes  (1769, 
t.  vi.  to  ix.). — Historical  eulogies  on  Sully, 
whose  merits  as  statesman  and  as  a  predecessor 
of  the  physiocratic  school  are  dilated  on  (1770, 
t.  iii.  to  xii. ;  1771,  1. 1.  to  xi.).— Baudeau  wrote 
"Avis  au  peuple  sur  son  premier  besoin," 
treating  of  a  free  trade  in  corn,  the  best  manner 
of  baking  bread,  and  on  its  price  (1768,  t.  i.. 


ii. ,  iv. ,  V. ).  "  Avis  aux  honnStes  gens,  qui  veulent 
bien  faire,"  dealing  with  the  effects  of  the  bad 
harvest  of  1769,  and  the  methods  pursued  to 
cheapen  the  price  of  bread  (1768,  t.  x.,  xi. ; 

1769,  t.  X.).     An  Explanation  of  the  Tableau 

l^conomique    to    Madame    de ("political 

economy  made  easy")  (1767,  t.  xi.,  xii.  ;  1768, 
t.  viii.  ;  1770,  t.  ii.).  On  luxury,  its  destructive 
effects  on  agriculture  (1767,  t.  i.  to  iii.).  "  On 
the  actual  state  of  Poland,"  on  the  causes  leading 
to  its  destruction  by  the  Moscow  policy  (1770, 
t.  ii.  to  iv.,  xi.  ;  1771,  t.  i.,  iii.  to  v.). — There 
are  also  some  observations  by  Butre  respecting 
agriculture  on  a  large  and  a  small  scale,  illus- 
trated by  accounts  of  farms  and  estates  culti- 
vated on  the  Metayer  principle,  and  proving 
the  unprofitable  character  of  the  latter  (1767, 
t.  ix.,  xi.,  xii.). — Among  Du  Pont's  contribu- 
tions his  "Notice  abreg^e"  containing  the  first 
sketch  of  a  history  of  economics,  particularly 
deserves  mention  (1769,  t.  i.  to  iv.,  vi.,  ix. ; 

1770,  t.  i.  avertissement). — Among  the  latest 
important  articles  were  Turgot's  "Reflexions 
sur  la  formation  et  la  distribution  des  richesses  " 
(published  in  1769,  t.  xi.,  xii.,  and  1770,  t. 
i.,  but  written  in  November  1766)  and  the 
"  Abrege  de  I'^conomie  politique  "  by  the  Mar- 
grave of  Baden-Durlach  (1772,  t.  i.). — Minor 
articles  were  written  by  Roubaud,  St.  Peravy, 
Le  Trosne,  Morellet,  Franklin. — Criticisms  are 
also  included  directed  against  Linguet  (1767, 
t.  iii.  ;  1770,  t.  i.),  who,  in  his  TMorie  des  lois 
civiles,  1767,  had  taken  no  notice  of  the  physio- 
cratic conception  of  natural  law,  and  in  accord- 
ance with  Hobbeism  had  declared  that  "  1' esprit 
des  lois — c'est  la  propriete";  Forbonnais,  who 
is  censured  on  account  of  his  attacks  against  the 
physiocratic  theory  that  trade  was  a  simple 
exchange  and  not  affording  a  "produit  net" 
(1767,  t.  vi.,  ix.); — against  the  attempted  re- 
futation of  their  doctrine  by  Graslin,  the  author 
of  an  JSssai  sur  la  Richesse  et  sur  VImpdt  (1768, 
vol.  ii.,  iii.,  x.)  ; — against  the  Doutes  adress4s 
aux  philosophes  dconomistes  by  Mably,  who 
had  from  the  communistic  standpoint  attacked 
the  foundation  of  this  system,  the  right  of 
private  property  (1768,  t.  ii.,  iii.,  v.  to  viii. ; 
1769,  t.  v.). — The  J^lemenis  g6n6raux  de  Police 
of  Justi  (1769,  French  edition),  is  shown  to 
be  a  work  of  very  shallow  and  contradictory 
views,  which  maintains  the  wisdom  of  grand- 
motherly regulations  (1769,  t.  ii.,  iii.)  ;  Galiani's 
Dialogues  sur  le  Commerce  des  Bleds,  one  of  the 
wittiest  productions  of  economic  literature,  is 
described  as  "un  ouvrage  charmant,  qui 
renferme  les  plus  jolis  lazzis  du  monde"  (1769, 
t.  xi.,  xii.);  Baudeau  also  criticised  Bearde 
de  L'Abbaye's  JRecherches  sur  les  moyens  de 
supprim.er  les  impdts,  pricedies  de  Vexamen  de 
la  nx)uvelle  Science,  1770,  a  criticism  directed 
against  the  single-tax  theory  (1770,  t.  vii.); 
and  Pinto  the  mercantilist  "Pindar  of  the 
stock  exchange  "  (Trait4  de  la  circulation  et  du 


:6phem]6rides 


745 


cridit,  1 7  7 1 ),  (1 7  7 1 ,  t.  X. ).  Besides  these  articles 
the  review  contained  a  chronicle  of  public  events 
considered  to  be  symptoms  of  the  progress  of  the 
doctrine  of  the  physiocrats :  this  includes  the 
utterances  of  the  French  parlements  in  the  pro- 
vinces on  the  corn-trade  ;  the  emancipation  of 
serfs  in  Denmark ;  the  encouragement  given 
publicly  to  agiiculture  by  the  heir-apparent  of 
the  crown  (Louis  XV.  being  king),  the  Dauphin 
Louis,  who  on  the  15th  June  1768  himself  held 
the  plough  at  Versailles  (1768,  t.  vii.  ;  1769,  t. 
viii. ).  Louis  was  followed  in  this  by  the  Emperor 
Joseph  IL,  who  drove  a  peasant's  plough,  the 
19th  August  1769,  at  Slavikovitz  in  Moravia 
(1770,  t.  xii.).  These  events  have  been  com- 
mented on  by  Diderot  in  a  review  which  he 
wrote  about  the  £phemArides,  in  the  following 
words  :  ' '  Plough,  plough  as  much  as  you  will ; 
I  promise  you  that  as  long  as  matters  stand  on 
their  present  footing,  the  wheatsheaf  growing 
under  your  royal  hands  will  not  nourish  your 
peasants"  {OEuvres,  t.  iv.  p.  85).  An  account 
is  given  of  an  experiment  made  by  the  Llarquis 
of  Mirabeau  and  his  son  at  Aigueperce  in 
Limousin,  to  form  a  bureau  de  conciliation,  com- 
posed of  prud'hommes  elected  by  the  parishes, 
in  order  to  avoid  the  frequency  of  lawsuits. 
The  experiment  Avas  imitated  by  the  Marquis 
le  Serent  at  Malestroit  in  Bretagne;  it  was 
a  precui'sor  of  the  modern  boards  of  con- 
ciliation (1771,  t.  iii.  p.  110-194  ;  t.  vii.  p. 
183,  cp.  Lomenie,  Les  Mirabeau,  t.  ii.  p.  79 ; 
t.  iii.  p.  59).  This  part  of  the  l^phimerides 
contains  some  statements  about  financial  reforms 
in  foreign  countries,  especially  of  the  experi- 
ment of  a  **  single  tax  "  on  land  {impdt  unique) 
in  Baden  (1771,  t.  iv.,  v.,  vi.,  vii.),  with  the 
performance  of  which  Schlettwein  was  entrusted 
in  the  village  of  Dietlingen  (1770)  (see  Impot 
Unique). 

The  J^phemerides  was  suppressed  by  the 
Controller  -  General,  the  Abbe  Terray,  in 
November  1772  (t.  iii.  is  the  last  of  the  sixty- 
three  volumes  of  this  series).  The  editors 
sought  in  vain  to  connect  themselves  with 
other  journals.  It  is  characteristic  of  him  that, 
after  being  forbidden  to  publish  the  J^pMyndridcs 
in  1772,  Du  Pont  continued  to  work  in  their 
line  by  issuing  a  fortnightly  Correspondance  lit- 
Uraire  et  politique  in  MS.,  and  to  send  tran- 
scripts to  the  monarchs  interested  in  the^physio- 
cratic  doctrines  (cp.  Carl  Friedrichs  von  Baden 
briejlicher  Verkehr  mit  Mirabeau  und  Du  Pont, 
edited  by  Carl  Knies,  Heidelberg,  1892,  vol.  i. 
p.  151-152  ;  cp.  also  vol.  i.  pp.  21,  56,  57,  61 ; 
vol.  ii.  p.  109  seq.,  197).  After  a  three  years' 
silence  Turgot,  who  had  become  minister,  enabled 
the  Abbe  Baudeau  to  resuscitate  the  review. 
It  thus  became  almost  an  official  organ  in- 
tended to  explain  and  justify  Turgot's  politics. 
In  December  1774  appeared  the  first  part  of  these 
N'ouvelles  ^phem^rides  £conomiques,  ou  Bihlio- 
thequ^  raisonnee  de  VHistoire  et  dc  la  Politique 


(18  vols.,  12  in  1775,  6  in  1776).  The  Journal 
de  V Agriculture  too  became  again  an  organ  of 
the  physiocratic  school  under  the  direction  of 
Abbe  Roubaud.  Among  the  contents  of  the 
Nouvelles  l^pMmirides,  the  following  are  remark- 
able :  *'  Letters  and  Memoirs  written  to  a  Magis- 
trate of  the  Paris  Parliament  on  the  Arret  of 
September  13th,  1774,"  by  Baudeau  (1775,  t.  i.) 
This  is  an  historical  and  theoretical  interpreta- 
tion of  the  causes  which  lead  on  to  Turgot's 
celebrated  ordinance,  by  which  the  free  circula- 
tion of  corn  in  the  provinces  of  France  was 
established  and  its  free  exportation  abroad  was 
made  the  object  of  future  decisions  of  the 
government  (see  Turgot,  Q^uvres,  1844,  t.  ii. 
p.  169). — Bigot  de  Ste.  Croix's  posthumous 
Essay  on  the  Abuse  of  Exclusive  Privileges,  on 
the  Freedom  of  Trade  and  Industry  (1775, 
t.  i.  iii.),  is  a  literary  forerunner  of  the  abolition 
of  corporations  by  Turgot. — The  third  part  of 
vol.  i.  (1775)  opens  with  an  li^loge  furdbre  de 
M.  Frani^ois  Quesnay,  delivered  bf^  the  Marquis 
de  Mirabeau  four  days  after  the  master's  death, 
the  20th  December  1774.  T.  v.  of  the  same 
year  contains  an  historical  eulogium  of  Quesnay 
by  the  Count  d'Albon. — Baudeau  again  contri- 
butes inqiiiries  and  historical  memoirs  on  the 
finances  of  France  from  Louis  XII.  to  Louis 
XV.  (1775,  t.  ii.,  iii.),  and  a  refutation  of  an 
author  who  had  wi^itten  in  defence  of  the 
Corvee  system. — The  Marquis  de  Pezay  writes 
an  essay  on  The  Fortification  of  the  Military 
Frontiers  of  Alsace. — Freville  inserts  a  transla- 
tion of  extracts  from  A.  Young's  Eastern  Tour 
through  England  (1775,  t.  ii.  iii.),  and  On  the 
Present  State  of  British  Commerce  (1775,  t.  viii.) 
Turgot's  ordinance,  which  allows  again  leases  of 
twenty-nine  years'  duration  (January  2,  1775) 
is  published  as  a  memorable  event  (t.  ii.). — 
The  general  aspects  of  the  school  are  dealt  with 
in  a  Letter  on  the  Economists  (1775,  t.  iii.)  ;  in 
this  the  contrast  between  formal  liberty,  adhered 
to  by  the  economists,  is  contrasted  with  the 
postulate  of  economic  equality  and  the  latter 
declared  unnatural.  Still  the  fundamental 
principle  of  the  economists  is  declared  to  be  the 
truth,  that  "the  particular  happiness  of  in- 
dividuals can  only  be  reasonably  and  firmly 
established  upon  the  basis  of  the  general 
happiness  of  the  Avhole  race  "  (1775,  t.  iii.  p.  59). 
The  philosophical  and  political  ideas  of  the 
physiocratic  school  are  embodied  in  a  Memoir 
on  Public  Instruction  by  Mercier  de  la  Riviere 
(1775,  t.  ix.  X.),  and  in  Roubaud's  Political 
Peflections  on  America  (1776,  t.  iii.),  which  are 
full  of  sympathy  for  separation  of  the  colonies 
from  England. — Finances  are  dealt  with  in 
Reflections  oj  a  Citizen  on  the  financial  adminis- 
tration of  great  cities,  and  especially  of  the  City 
of  Ly OTIS  (t.  iv.),  written  to  oppose  indirect  local 
taxation ;  they  exhibit  the  destructive  tendency 
of  the  physiocratic  doctrine  for  local  life  by 
subjecting  it  to  central  goverimient.     An  essay 


746 


:^PH^MERIDES 


is  directed  against  the  heavy  taxation  of 
tanneries  after  1759  (1776,  t.  iv.,  also  1776,  t. 
iv.\  and  of  salt,  spirituous  liquors  and  tobacco  ; 
this  essay,  Le  Profit  du  Feuple  et  le  Profit  du 
Roi,  had  been  previously  written  in  1769  by 
Baudeau,  and  twelve  copies  only  printed,  1775, 
t.  iv.  ;  cp.  a  letter  to  Baudeau  on  that  subject 
in  1775,  t.  X.,  extracted  from  Nouvelles  de  la 
Ripuhlique  des  ic^^rcs  (Lausanne,  vol.  i.  1775)  ; 
cp.  also  the  criticisms  on  Bandeau's  essay  con- 
tained in  Nouv.  £ph.,  1776,  t.  ii.  p.  70,  taken 
from  the  Journal  Encyclop6dique  of  1775,  vol. 
viii.  Other  articles  deal  with  the  suppression 
of  the  duty  on  fish  coming  to  Paris  during 
Easter-time  (1776,  t.  iv.,  and  Turgot,  CEuvres, 
ed.  Daire,  vol.  ii.  p.  402),  and  the  suppression 
of  a  series  of  duties  in  Russia  by  Catherine  II. 
(17th  (28th)  March  1775,  t.  vii.).  Historical 
details  are  given  relative  to  duties  laid  on  eggs, 
butter,  cheese  (1776,  t.  i.),  on  wines  coming 
to  Paris  (1775,  t.  v.),  and  likewise  on  such 
imports  within  Champagne  (1776,  t.  iii.).  A 
new  method  of  levying  the  duty  on  brandy 
is  described,  and  the  weight  of  the  impost  of 
1771  on  the  manufacture  of  paper,  33  per  cent 
on  the  cheapest  sorts,  is  complained  of  (1776, 
t.  v.).  A  document,  proving  the  antiquity  of 
complaints  on  French  finances,  from  the  year 
1415,  is  published  in  1775,  t.  xi.  An  essay 
of  Baudeau,  written  in  1768  was  published  for 
the  first  time  in  1776,  t.  i.,  on  the  occasion  of 
the  abolition  of  the  "Caisse  de  Poissy"  on  the 
9th  February  1776  (see  Turgot,  CEuvres,  vol.  ii. 
p.  316);  this  institution  since  1743  had  farmed 
the  exclusive  market  right  of  meat  for  Paris  to 
a  company,  which  was  entitled  by  it  to  take  a 
duty  of  6  per  cent  upon  all  sales  of  meat  at 
Sceaux  and  at  Poissy.  Bandeau's  article  pro- 
duced great  irritation  among  the  partners  in  the 
company,  who  brought  an  action  against  its 
author ;  the  text  of  the  latter  is  inserted  in 
Nouv.  ItJph.,  1776,  t.  vi.  This  volume  also 
contains  a  "memoir  on  the  taxes  raised  in 
unforeseen  cases  ('affaires  extraordinaires ')  in 
France  duiing  the  war  of  1756-1763."  They 
amounted  to  no  less  than  1,105,227,761  livres. 

The  free-trade  movement  is  represented  by  a 
memoir  written  by  M.  Belly  on  the  decline  of 
the  trade  of  Leghorn  in  consequence  of  the 
number  of  charges  (1775,  t.  vi.)  ;  the  same 
author  contributes  an  essay  on  the  state  of 
commerce  and  manufactures  in  Italy  (t.  vii.) 
The  obstacles  to  the  shipping  trade  in  the 
Rhone  (1775,  t.  ix.,  t  xi.),  and  to  the  exporta- 
tion of  iron  (1776,  t.  iv.),  are  complained  of, 
and  a  petition  of  the  Guyenne  chamber  of 
commerce  for  free  trade  to  the  East  Indies  is 
published  (1776,  t.  iv.). 

Among  the  events  favourable  to  the  econom- 
ists the  following  are  worth  mention :— The 
correspondence  of  King  Gustavus  of  Sweden 
(when  a  youth)  with  Count  Tessein  and 
Scheflfer,    published   by   Col.    St.    Maurice  de 


St.  Leu  (1775,  t.  iv.,  1776,  t.  ii.) ;  the  founda- 
tion of  a  "Societe  d'emulation"  in  Paris  after 
the  model  of  the  London  "Society  for  encour- 
aging arts  and  manufactures,"  the  rules  of 
which  are  contained  in  1775,  t.  ix.  The 
economic  reforms  introduced  in  Tuscany  by 
the  Grand-duke  Leopold,  and  enumerated  in 
Saggi  di  Agricoltura ;  di  un  Paroco  Slam- 
miniatese,  Florence  1775,  are  favourably  re- 
ported on.  Among  these  the  erection  of  a  kind 
of  co-operative  store  at  Florence  for  the  sale  of 
all  sorts  of  goods  deserves  mention  ;  upon  the 
abolition  of  corporations  it  was  imitated  at 
Paris  by  the  Bureau  de  Correspondance 
Generale,  March  1776  (K  ^ph.  1776,  t.  iii. 
p.  177).  The  publication  of  Ephemeriden 
der  Menschheit  by  Isaac  Iselin  at  Basel 
chronicled  with  enthusiasm  by  Baudeau. 

The  literary  movement  is  represented  by  a^ 
lengthy  criticism  of  Necker's  book,  Sur  le 
Commerce  et  la  Legislation  des  Grains.  It 
marks  the  distinct  contrast  between  social 
protectionism  and  the  spirit  of  individual 
property ;  the  contrast  between  landed  and 
moneyed   "capitalism."     (Eclaircissemenis  de- 

mandis   cu  M.   N ,   au  nom   des  ProprU- 

taires  Fonciers  et  des  Cultivateurs  f^'an^ais 
1775,  t.v.  65-168,  t.  vii.  89-167,  t.  viii.  93-139, 
and  Bandeau's  letters  to  M.  N.  on  his  "  Eloge 
de  Colbert,"  held  at  the  French  academy  in 
1774,  t.  ix.  pp.  44-106).  A  letter  directed 
against  the  free-trade  theory  of  the  economists 
by  the  Count  de  Magnieres  (t.  xii.)  is  refuted 

by  M.  de  R (?)  in  1776,  t.  ii. — A  review 

of  the  book  of  Condillac,  Sur  le  Commerce  et  le 
Gouvernemeni  (1776,  t.  iv.  pp.  109-130,  t.  v. 
pp.  131-147),  written  by  Baudeau,  treats  this 
author  as  a  heretic  from  the  orthodox  school. 
"The  true  economists  are  easy  to  characterise 
by  one  feature  which  everybody  understands. 
They  recognise  one  master  (the  doctor  Quesnay), 
one  doctrine  (that  contained  in  the  Philosophic 
rurale  and  the  Analyse  l^conomique),  classical 
text -books  (the  Physiocratie),  and  technical 
terms  .  .  .  precisely  like  the  old  scholars  of" 
China"  (p.  iii.). 

The  Nouvelles  J^pMmArides  ceased  in 
June  1776,  on  the  dismissal  of  Turgot  from 
the  ministry  (12th  May  1776),  after  which 
date  the  only  organ  of  the  physiocrats  was  the 
Journal  de  V Agriculture,  which  Roubaud  had 
reconstituted  in  1775  ;  but  this  periodical  also 
came  to  an  end  in  1783.  Baudeau  made  a 
last  effort  to  re-establish  his  former  review, 
for  there  are  at  the  Bibliotheque  Rationale  at 
Paris  three  volumes  of  Nouvelles  J6ph6m4rides 
economiques  of  1788  (Paris,  Onfroi  et  Royer) 
extant.  These  contain  attacks  against  Colbert 
and  Necker,  historical  remarks  on  Sully ;  funda- 
mental questions  of  economics,  inquiries  into 
the  origin  of  taxation  among  the  Greeks  aud 
Romans,  and  on  the  influence  of  morals  en 
agriculture  by  the  Marquis  de  P (?). 


r 


Apices— EQUALISATION  or  international  demand        747 


In  1789  appeared  J^pMmerides  de  V Human- 
ity ou  bibliothdque  raisonnie  des  sciences  morales. 
Tome  premier  (and  last),  aux  depens  de  la 
Societe.  This  is  probably  the  last  utterance  of 
this  kind  made  by  the  Economistes,  and  is  en- 
tirely written  by  A.  F.  J.  Freville.  It  begins 
with  a  lengthy  exposition  of  their  doctrines  (pp. 
1-68),  contains  articles  on  the  principles  of 
taxation  (pp.  108-132),  and  their  application 
to  the  Austro-Belgian  provinces  (pp.  337-394); 
others  against  Keeker's  theory  of  the  circula- 
tion of  riches,  as  enunciated  in  his  book,  De 
V administrai/lon  des  finances  en  France,  t.  iii. 
eh.  xxi.  (pp.  284-336).  The  greater  part  of 
the  volume  deals,  however,  with  political 
questions  ;  it  is  filled  up  with  polemics  against 
the  champions  of  absolutism,  such  as  Count 
Windischgraetz  (pp.  68-108,  133-158,  265- 
284),  and  with  observations  on  the  convocation 
of  the  ]itats  g6neraux  (pp.  159-264).  It  closes 
with  a  philosophical  letter  on  Montesquieu's 
Esprit  des  lois  (pp.  395-400).  Constitutional 
questions  being  at  this  time  the  most  prominent 
ones,  and  economic  problems  standing  more  in 
the  backgi-ound,  this  publication  ceased  with 
its  first  volume.  The  Journal  d'  Economic  pub - 
lique,  de  Morale  et  de  Politique,  edited  by 
Roederer  and  Morellet  appeared  August  1796. 

The  £pMmerides  thus  played  an  important 
part  in  the  literary  life  of  economics  during 
the  18th  century.  As  an  example  it  may  be 
mentioned  that  Lavoisier,  in  his  introductory 
remarks  to  his  statistics  De  la  Richesse  terri- 
toriale  du  Royaume  de  France,  printed  by  order 
of  the  national  assembly  in  1791,  and  reprinted 
in  1797  in  the  Journal  d' Economic  publiqu^, 
edited  by  Roederer,  mentions  Quesnay  as  having 
reached  the  same  conclusions  as  himself,  and 
notes  the  fact  that  Quesnay's  statistics  were 
the  occasion  of  Voltaire's  X'^omwe  auxquarante 
dcus.  The  Ephemerides  formed  a  scientific  econ- 
omic review  AVTitten  with  a  distinct  practical 
tendency,  namely,  to  struggle  for  free  trade, 
free  enterprise,  and  equal  taxation  ;  to  combat 
the  crushing  burdens  imposed  by  commercial 
restraints,  industrial  monopoly,  arbitrary  assess- 
ment, and  lavish  public  expenditure.  Being  in 
the  exclusive  possession  of  a  "  school,"  they  pre- 
served, in  spite  of  the  variety  of  their  contents, 
a  systematic  uniformity  in  method  and  policy. 
Besides  exhibiting  the  first  example  of  journal- 
ism made  subservient  to  social  science,  they  are 
the  richest  source  for  the  history  of  contemporary 
economic  life,  and  the  growth  of  modern  ideas, 
not  only  in  France  but  even  in  eastern  Europe. 

Their  immediate  influence  in  France  was 
rather  short-lived,  and  after  the  outbreak  of 
the  Revolution  they  became  so  entirely  for- 
gotten as  to  enable  the  tale  to  be  spread  that 
they  had  been  written  in  order  to  help 
Voltaire,  Servan,  and  Bovier  to  establish  a 
democratic  revolution  (Abbe  Barruel,  Memoires 
pour  servir  d  Vhistoire  du  Jacobinisme,  Londres 


1797,  2nd  pt.  pp.  210-215).  The  interest,  how- 
ever, which  the  JiJphdmerides  excited  abroad 
was  a  far-reaching  one ;  and  by  inducing 
monarchs,  statesmen,  and  landlords  to  intro- 
duce agricultural  and  financial  reforms,  to 
alleviate  feudal  burdens  and  commercial 
restraints,  they  benefited  even  the  lower  classes 
in  Sweden,  Denmark,  Baden,  Austria,  and 
Tuscany.  Thus  they  helped  towards  trans- 
planting economic  progress  eastwards  both  in 
thought  and  practice. 

[An  account  of  the  origin  of  this  review  is  given 
in  the  Journal  de  V Agriculture,  March  1766  ;  in 
the  EpMmerides,  1769,  t.  iv.,  v.;  in  the  Diction- 
7iaire  de  I'Economie  Politique,  under  the  heading 
"Ephemerides  du  Citoyen"  ;  in  the  Nouveau  Dic- 
tionnaire  d'  Economic  Politique  the  information 
will  be  found  under  the  heading  "Baudeau."  See 
also  Lomenie,  Les  Mirabeait,  1879,  t.  ii.  p.  251. 
Levallois,  Rousseau,  ses  amis  et  ses  enneviis,  1865, 
t.  ii.  p.  385. — G.  Schelle,  Du  Pont  de  Nemours 
et  V ecole physiocratique,  1888,  pp.  43,  99, 125,  144, 
211,  408.  In  Germany  Mauvillon  complained 
in  1775  of  the  want  of  a  German  economic  review 
of  the  value  of  the  Ephemerides  ( Untersuchungen 
iiber  die  Natur  und  den  Ursprung  der  Reich- 
turner  und  Hirer  VertJicilung,  a  translation  of 
Turgot)  ;  only  the  next  year  they  were  imitated 
by  Isaac  Iseliu,  the  editor  of  Ephemeriden  der 
Menschheit  oder  Bibliothek  der  Sittenlehre  und  der 
Politik,  Leipzig,  1776-1782.  ^  The  only  known 
complete  set  of  tlie  Nouvelles  Ephemerides  belongs 
to  the  Giessen  University  Library  (pressmark  B. 
800), — the  use  of  it  was  most  liberally  allowed  to 
the  writer  of  this  article,  in  order  to  enable  him 
to  draw  \x])  the  above  statement.]  s.  B. 

(See  also  Baudeau,  Du  Pont  de  Nemours, 
Physiocrats,  Quesnay,  and  Turgot.) 

EPICES.  The  French  judges  down  to  the 
revolution  were  paid  partly  by  salaries  (gages), 
and  partly  by  the  payments  of  suitors  (epices) 
The  latter  were  originally  voluntary  presents  in 
kind,  and  several  of  the  early  kings  tried  to 
limit  their  amount.  But  in  the  15th  century 
the  4'^'ces  gradually  became  compulsory  and  were 
paid  in  money.  These  payments  for  justice 
constituted  a  considerable  indirect  tax  upon  the 
people,  and  gave  rise  to  many  abuses.  It  was 
the  interest  of  the  judges  to  si)in  out  cases  so 
as  to  increase  the  charges  upon  suitors,  and 
thus  justice  became  dilatory  as  well  as  expensive. 
On  several  occasions  the  states-general,  and 
even  the  parliament  itself,  petitioned  for  the 
increase  of  the  judges'  salaries,  in  order  that 
the  Apices  might  be  abolished  or  at  least  dimin- 
ished. But  the  French  treasury  was  never  in 
a  condition  to  adopt  this  very  simple  remedy, 
and  the  abuse  of  qnces  lasted  till  the  constituent 
assembly  abolished  the  old  parliaments,  and 
made  justice  gi-atuitous. 

[Adam  Smith,  Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  v.  eh.  ii. 
pt.  2.]  R.  L. 

EQUALISATION  OF  INTERNATIONAL 
DEMAND.  The  equation  of  international  de- 
mand is  a  particular  case  "  of  the  more  genera] 


748        EQUALISATION  OF  INTERNATIONAL  DEMAND— EQUALITY 


law  of  Value  (g.v.)  .  .  .  called  the  equation 
of  supply  and  demand,"  but  presents  some 
peculiarities  which  almost  justify  Mill  (Princi- 
ples of  FolUical  Bconomy,  bk.  iii.  ch.  18,  §  4), 
in  describing  it  as  "an  extension"  of  that  law. 
These  are  :  the  absence  of  (1)  a  single  market— 
which  allows  the  substitution  of  price  for  value 
in  discussing  domestic  trade,  and  (2)  of  the  re- 
gulator given  by  cost  of  production  (see  Intbe- 
NATIONAL  Trade).  An  analysis  of  the  forces 
tending  to  bring  about  equilibrium  of  supply  and 
demand,  always  important,  is  here  essential. 

On  the  simplest  supposition — that  of  two 
countries  trading  in  two  commodities — each 
article  is  necessarily  the  price  of  the  other,  and 
the  equation  of  reciprocal  demand  is  the  evident 
outcome  of  the  bargaining  on  each  side,  carried 
to  the  point  at  which  no  additional  advantage 
can  be  gained.  When  several  commodities 
enter  into  foreign  trade  the  equation  is  estab- 
lished in  substantially  the  same  way.  Values 
are  so  arranged  that  the  sum  of  exports  is 
equivalent  to  that  of  imports,  since,  were  it 
otherwise,  readjustment  of  quantities,  of  values, 
or  of  both,  would  be  necessary.  In  the  actual 
complications  of  foreign  trade  carried  on  be- 
tween many  countries  the  law  takes  a  somewhat 
different  foi-m.  "  It  may  be  concisely  stated  as 
follows.  The  produce  of  a  country  exchanges 
for  the  produce  of  other  countries  at  such 
values  as  are  required,  in  order  that  the  whole 
of  her  exports  may  exactly  pay  for  the  whole 
of  her  imports "  (Mill,  Principles,  bk.  iii.  ch. 
18,  §  4).  Though  each  country  must  export  to 
an  amount  equal  to  what  it  imports,  its  trade 
with  any  one  country  may  mainly  or  even  ex- 
clusively be  import  or  export,  an  excess  on 
either  side  being  compensated  by  a  corresponding 
deficit  in  the  trade  with  other  countries. 

The  statement  of  the  equation  of  inter- 
national demand  has  to  be  further  modified  so  as 
to  include  the  effect  of  the  various  elements  of 
indebtedness.  All  debts  due  to  a  country  act 
like  an  effectual  demand  created  by  the  same 
value  of  exports.  The  principal  heads  are  :  (1) 
interest  on  foreign  loans  or  on  capital  invested 
abroad  ;  (2)  freightage  for  shipping  services  ; 
(3)  such  items  as  (a)  tribute  due  by  foreign 
states  ;  (ft)  earnings  of  citizens  abroad  ;  (c)  ex- 
penditure of  foreigners  travelling  in  the  country. 
Accordingly,  the  final  result  is  that  *Hhe  state 
of  international  demand  which  results  in  com- 
mercial equilibrium  is  realised  when  the  recipro- 
cal demand  of  trading  countries  produces  such 
a  relation  of  imports  and  exports  amongst 
them  as  enables  each  country,  by  means  of  her 
exports,  to  discharge  all  her  foreign  liabilities  " 
(Cairnes,  Leading  Principles,  bk.  iii.  ch.  18,  § 
5).  In  the  most  complicated  as  in  the  simplest 
case,  the  force  producing  equilibrium  is  the 
action  of  self-interest,  causing  the  supply  of 
commodities  for  exchange  at  such  terms  as 
will  afford  the  maximum  advantage  to  the 


trading  countries  (see  Giffen,  Essays  in  Fin- 
ance). 

The  mechanism  of  Price  {q.v.)  enables  the 
complex  adjustments  of  value  which  are  requisite 
to  be  easily  carried  out  (see  International 
Trade). 

As  to  the  difficult  question  whether  the 
equation  of  international  demand  can  be  consci- 
ously altered  to  the  advantage  of  one  of  the 
parties,  see  Mill,  Principles,  v.  ch.  iv.  §  6  ; 
Cournot,  Principes  Mathdmatiques  de  la  TJieorie 
des  RicTiesses ;  TMorie  des  Richesses,  bk.  iii.  ch. 
iv.  ;  Sidgwick,  bk.  iii.  ch.  v.,  who  maintain 
that  it  can  ;  also  Torrens,  the  Budget.  See 
contra,  Jevons,  Theory,  pp.  157,  158. 

[See  references  under  International  Trade  and 
International  Value,  more  especially  those  to 
Mill,  Cairnes,  and  Mangoldt.]  c.  f.  b. 

EQUALITY.  The  claim  for  equality  may 
mean  in  politics  (1)  simply  a  claim  for  just 
and  impartial  administration  of  the  laws;  or 
(2)  a  claim  that  the  laws  themselves  should  not 
favour  one  class,  still  less  one  individual,  at  the 
expense  of  another  ;  or  (3)  a  claim  for  equal 
division  of  the  comforts  and  discomforts  of  life. 
In  the  economic  as  distinguished  from  political 
doctrine,  the  claim  of  equality  appears  as  the 
basis  of  the  theory  of  free  competition,  and 
takes  a  form  not  precisely  identical  with  any 
one  of  the  three  described.  Economic  reasoning, 
so  far  as  it  is  quantitative,  must  assume  a  simi- 
larity of  units.  There  might  be  a  "free  com- 
petition" within  certain  classes  of  the  com- 
munity only  ;  and  thus  only  the  fiLrst  kind  of 
equality  might  be  secured.  An  economic  theory 
of  the  probable  effects  of  such  a  competition 
would  be  perfectly  possible.  The  most  striking 
modem  instance  is  perhaps  the  industrial  system 
of  the  southern  states  of  America  before  the 
emancipation  of  the  slaves.  "Where  the  laws 
were  clearly  defined  and  fairly  carried  out,  the 
task  of  the  deductive  economist  would  be  com- 
paratively easy.  He  would  need  indeed  to 
postulate  that  they  were  so,  before  he  could 
draw  his  theoretical  conclusions  ;  and  he  would 
then  be  postulating  equality  in  the  first  sense, 
impartial  administration.  There  might  also  be 
a  state  of  things  in  which  legislation  was  pro- 
fessedly indifferent  to  the  privileges  of  particular 
classes,  and  all  men  were  left  free  so  far  as  legal 
hindrances  were  concerned,  to  seek  their  for- 
tunes in  the  same  ways.  Economic  theory 
would  assume  in  this  case  that  there  was  equality 
not  only  in  the  first  sense,  but  in  the  second ; 
and  this  has  been  perhaps  the  commonest  as- 
sumption of  modem  economists.  It  was  made 
by  Adam  Smith  with  full  consciousness  of  its 
Utopian  character ;  indeed  he  could  not  conceive 
the  possibility  of  so  close  an  approach  to  it  as 
has  now  been  made  by  free-trading  England. 
The  fuU  attainment  of  it  is,  however,  impossible 
in  a  community  of  human  beings,  so  long  as 
they  are  divided  by  physical,  social,  and  other 


EQUATION  OF  SUPPLY  AND  DEMAND— EQUITABLE  MORTGAGE       749 


causes,  into  classes  respectively  weaker  and 
stronger.  The  effort  of  legislation  has  been  to 
redress  such  inequality  by  means  of  special 
protection  and  assistance.  The  result,  though 
for  every  other  reason  desirable,  is  unfavourable 
to  economic  theory,  so  far  as  it  makes  the 
assumption  of  legal  equality,  in  the  second  as 
well  as  the  first  sense,  farther  removed  from 
the  reality.  It  is  no  doubt  possible  to  conceive 
the  patronage  of  the  laws  as  simply  an  attempt 
to  secure  to  every  one  that  equality  of  op'por- 
tunities,  of  which  the  reinforcement  by  the  laws 
of  the  inequaUties  of  wealth  would  deprive  the 
poorer  members  of  society.  From  this  point 
of  view  an  economic  theory  of  free  competition 
could  be  worked  out  for  competing  citizens, 
supposed  equally  strong  and  fit  for  the  race  for 
wealth.  But  the  inequalities  left  out  seem 
too  great  for  the  equality  assumed.  Even  if 
we  neglected  other  causes  of  difference,  oppor- 
tunities would  never  be  perfectly  equal  till 
human  beings  were  physically  and  intellectually 
identical  one  with  another. 

On  the  other  hand  the  effort  after  an  equality 
of  opportunities  seems  to  cany  society  a  step 
nearer  perfection  than  the  effort  after  justice 
and  legal  equality  in  the  senses  described.  The 
opportunities  may  be  conceived  to  be  not  of 
making  money  but  of  developing  the  faculties 
and  doing  the  best  work  for  which  a  man  has 
the  capacities.  In  all  the  noblest  of  the 
founders  of  socialistic  and  communistic  schemes, 
such  as  aimed  at  equality  in  the  distribution 
of  wealth,  equality  of  opportunities  for  the 
development  of  human  individuality  has  been 
the  real  aim,  more  or  less  clearly  understood. 
[See  also  Aristocracy,  Communism,  Taxa- 
tion (equality  of  burdens).] 

[Sir  Jas.  Fitzjames  Stephen,  Liberty,  Equality, 
Fraternity,  eh.  v.  "Equality"  (1873). — Bedolliere 
(ifimile),  in  Maurice  Block's  Dictionnaire  de  la 
politique,  art.  "Ilgalite." — A.  Wagner,  Lehrhuch; 
Gmndlegtong  (1879),  2nd  part,  §§  220  to  223,  pp. 
418-426. — F.  Y.  Edgeworth,  Mathematical  Psycliics 
(1881),  pp.  129,  seq. — J.  S.  Mackenzie,  Social 
Philosophy  (1890),  pp.  249,  seq.']  j.  b. 

EQUATION  OF  SUPPLY  AND  DEMA.ND. 
(See  Demand.) 

EQUILIBRIUM  is  discerned  by  Jevons 
{Theory  of  Political  Economy,  ch.  iv.)  to  be  a 
cardinal  conception  in  the  abstract  science 
which  he  elsewhere  calls  the  Mechanics  of 
Industry  {q.v.).  So  Professor  Marshall,  indi- 
cating in  the  preface  to  his  Principles  of  Eco- 
nomics the  leading  ideas  by  which  he  was 
inspired,  says,  "the  demand  for  a  thing  is  a 
continuous  function,  of  which  the  'marginal' 
increment  is  in  stable  equilibrium  balanced 
against  the  corresponding  increment  of  its  cost 
of  production."  Professor  Marshall  employs 
the  term  equilibrium  amount  as  the  amount  of 
any  commodity  produced  in  a  unit  of  time 
when  the  demand  for  and  supply  of  that  com- 


modity are  in  equilibrium,  and  when  there  is 
therefore  no  tendency  in  the  quantity  produced 
in  a  particular  time  to  increase  or  diminish. 
The  term  equilibrium  price  is  similarly  used  to 
denote  the  price  of  the  equilibrium  amount  in 
the  same  circumstances.  M.  G.  D. 

EQUITABLE  ASSETS.  Assets  that  could 
be  made  available  for  the  payment  of  debts 
only  through  a  decree  or  order  of  a  court  of 
equity.  Such  assets  were  always  treated  as  a 
trust  fund,  and  were  therefore  divided  amongst 
creditors  pari  passu  without  any  regard  to  the 
priority  of  one  debt  over  another.  The  chief 
equitable  assets  are  the  proceeds  arising  from  the 
sale  of  lands  devised  in  trust  to  pay  or  charged 
with  the  payment  of  debts. 

[Williams  on  Executors  and  Administrators, -pt. 
iv.  bk.  i.  ch.  i.,  London,  1879. — The  Administration 
of  Assets,  by  A.  S.  Eddis,  London,  1880.] 

J,  E.  C.  M. 

EQUITABLE  ESTATE.  An  estate  in  land 
that  formerly  was  recognised  in  a  court  of 
equity  only.  The  principal  equitable  estates 
are  the  estate  taken  by  a  person  entitled  to  the 
benefit  of  land  given  in  trust,  equities  of  redemp- 
tion (see  Equity  of  Redemption),  and  equitable 
charges. 

{^Principles  of  Equity ^  by  E.  H.  T.  Snell,  London, 
1892.]  J.  E.  c.  M. 

EQUITABLE  EXECUTION.  The  method 
by  which  a  judgment  creditor  obtains  payment 
by  the  appointment  of  a  receiver  of  the  rents 
and  profits  of  the  lands  of  the  debtor.  At 
common  law  certain  forms  of  property,  such  as 
the  interest  of  a  mortgagor  in  the  mortgaged 
premises,  or  the  right  to  an  unascertained  sum 
of  money,  could  not  be  reached  by  any  ordinary 
■writ.  When  the  creditor  had  exhausted  every 
method  of  obtaining  payment  he  could  resort 
to  the  Court  of  Chancery,  who  would  apj^oint  a 
receiver.  Now  the  High  Court  of  Justice  can 
appoint  a  receiver  in  all  cases  where  it  is  just 
and  convenient  that  such  appointment  should 
be  made. 

\_The  Law  of  Execution,  by  T.  K.  Anderson, 
London,  1889.]  J.  e.  c.  m. 

EQUITABLE  MORTGAGE.  A  contract  for 
a  mortgage  that  previous  to  the  Judicature 
Acts  could  be  enforced  only  in  a  court  of 
equity.  The  most  usual  case  in  which  it  arises 
is  where, a  person  deposits  the  title  deeds  of 
property  with  a  creditor  as  security  for  a  debt. 
But  a  mortgage  is  also  "equitable"  if  the 
subject  matter  is  trust  or  equitable  property, 
such  as  an  equity  of  redemption,  or  where  there 
is  a  written  agreement  to  make  a  mortgage. 
The  mortgagee  in  every  case  may  either  call  on 
the  mortgagor  to  make  a  legal  mortgage  or  may 
take  proceedings  to  enforce  a  foreclosure  or  a 
sale, 

\_The  Principles  of  Equity,  by  E.  H.  T.  Sneli, 
London,  1892.]  j.  e.  c.  m. 


750 


EQUITABLE  WASTE— EQUITY 


EQUITABLE  WASTE.  Waste  in  the  nature 
of  acts  of  spoliation,  that  a  court  will  restrain 
a  tenant  for  life  from  committing,  though  his 
estate  was  granted  to  him  with  liberty  to  com- 
mit waste,  such  as  pulling  down  the  family 
mansion  or  cutting  down  ornamental  timber. 

[Goodeve,  Law  of  Real  Property,  London, 
189L]  ^-  ^  c-  *^- 

EQUITY  is  the  name  applied  to  a  number 
of  legal  rules,  which  formerly  were  administered 
by  the  court  of  chancery.  The  chancellor 
was  originally  the  king's  secretary,  and  as  such 
he  had  to  advise  the  king  in  "  matters  of  grace 
and  favour "  ;  viz.  in  matters  in  which  the 
king's  intercession  was  invoked  for  the  sake  of 
mitigating  the  strict  rules  of  the  common  law. 
**When  early  in  the  reign  of  Edward  III. 
the  chancellor  ceased  to  be  a  part  of  the  king's 
personal  retinue,  and  to  follow  the  court,  his 
tribunal  acquired  a  more  distinct  and  sub- 
stantive character  .  .  .  ;  petitions  for  grace 
and  favour  began  to  be  addressed  primarily  to 
him,  instead  of  being  simply  referred  to  him 
by  the  king,  or  passed  on  through  his  hands. 
In  the  twenty-second  year  of  that  king  such 
transactions  were  recognised  as  the  proper  pro- 
vince of  the  chancellor,  and  from  that  time 
his  separate  and  independent  equitable  jurisdic- 
tion began  to  grow  into  the  possession  of  that 
powerful  and  complicated  machinery  which 
belongs  to  later  history"  (Stubbs's  Const. 
History,  ii.  269).  One  of  the  most  important 
stages  in  that  growth  was  reached  when,  in  the 
reign  of  Richard  II.,  the  "writ  of  subpoena" 
was  introduced,  which  enabled  the  chancellor 
to  enforce  obedience  to  his  decrees  by  the  threat 
of  imprisonment.  One  of  the  most  important 
matters  which  came  under  the  chancellor's 
jm-isdiction  was  the  protection  of  the  rights  of 
persons  possessed  of  "uses"  in  land.  For 
several  reasons  it  had  become  convenient  to 
sever  the  legal  ownership  of  land  from  the  bene- 
ficial ownership,  and  with  that  object  it  became 
customary  on  a  transfer  of  ownership  to  enfeofi" 
one  person  "  to  the  use  "  of  another.  The  first- 
named  person  was  called  the  "feofiee  to  the 
use,"  and  he  was  the  only  person  whom  the 
ordinary  courts  recognised  ;  but  as  he  was  in 
duty  and  conscience  bound  to  allow  the  rights 
of  beneficial  ownership  to  the  second-named 
person,  known  by  the  technical  name  of 
"cestui  que  use,"  the  chancellor  in  the  exer- 
cise of  his  equitable  jurisdiction  compelled 
him  to  do  so,  if  he  wished  to  take  advantage 
of  his  formal  right.  The  practice  in  matters 
of  this  nature  developed  into  a  regular  system 
called  "equity,"  to  distinguish  it  from  the 
"common  law"  administered  by  the  other 
courts.  That  system  was  characterised  — (1) 
by  the  recognition  of  rights  which  the  other 
courts  refused  to  enforce  (so-called  "  equitable 
riejhts");  (2)  by  legal  doctrines  differing  in 
substance  from  the  doctrines  of  common  law  : 


(3)  by  a   special    procedure  ;    (4)   by  special 
kinds  of  relief. 

(1)  The  most  conspicuous  among  equitable 
rights  are  the  rights  derived  from  trusts.  Trusts 
are  the  modern  successors  of  "uses,"  but  are 
used  on  a  much  larger  scale,  and  also  in  the 
case  of  personal  property  ;  the  most  familiar 
instances  being  the  trusts  created  by  wills  and 
settlements,  by  which  the  control  of  certain 
land  or  certain  funds  is  given  to  one  or  more 
persons  for  the  benefit  of  another  person  or 
other  persons.  Another  instance  of  an  equit- 
able right  is  the  right  of  the  mortgagor  to 
redeem  the  mortgaged  property,  the  legal  right 
to  which  is  vested  in  the  mortgagee. 

(2)  Amongst  doctrines  specially  belonging 
to  the  sphere  of  equity  may  be  mentioned  the 
rule  that  a  debt  may  be  assigned  ;  that,  in  the 
absence  of  an  express  stipulation  or  necessary 
implication,  time  is  not  considered  as  of  the 
essence  of  a  contract,  that  penalties  named  in 
contracts  cannot  be  enforced  unless  they  par- 
take of  the  nature  of  liquidated  damages,  etc. 

(3)  The  administration  of  trusts  and  of  the 
estates  of  deceased  persons  involves  protracted 
inquiries  and  the  taking  of  accounts,  etc.  ;  for 
this  purpose  a  special  procedure  and  a  special 
machinery  has  been  developed  in  the  courts  of 
equity,  which  were  the  only  courts  which  had  to 
deal  with  matters  of  this  nature. 

(4)  Among  the  special  kinds  of  relief  which 
could  be  obtained  with  the  assistance  of  the 
courts  of  equity,  the  right  to  claim  specific 
performance  of  contracts  for  the  sale  of  land, 
and  the  right  to  claim  injunctions,  i.e.  orders 
restraining  the  opposite  party  from  doing 
certain  acts  injuring  the  rights  of  the  plaintift', 
are  the  most  important.  The  courts  of  equity, 
in  granting  relief  of  this  kind,  were  supplying 
a  material  defect  in  the  administration  of  justice, 
as  in  the  courts  of  common  law  ;  the  only 
remedy  in  the  case  of  breach  of  contract  or 
injurious  acts  consisted  in  pecuniary  damages, 
which  in  many  cases  did  not  adequately  com- 
pensate the  injured  party.  The  power  of  the 
courts  of  equity  to  enforce  their  decrees  by  the 
imprisonment  of  disobedient  parties  materially 
helped  them  in  the  exercise  of  this  jurisdiction. 

The  Judicature  Act  of  1873  has  merged  the 
equity  courts  and  the  courts  of  common  law 
into  one  high  court,  and  the  rules  of  equity 
are  now  administered  in  all  courts  ;  but  as  they 
are  derived  from  a  different  source  from  the 
common  law  rules,  and  have  always  been  treated 
as  a  separate  system,  the  distinction  is  still 
kept  up,  though  it  has  no  longer  any  practical 
meaning.  The  matters  which  are  specially 
fitted  for  the  procedure  of  the  chancery  court, 
have,  however,  been  assigned  to  a  special 
chancery  division  which  is  organised  in  a 
manner  appropriate  to  the  proceedings  required 
with  regard  to  them. 

[Spence,  EquUaJble  Jurisdiction.— B..  A.  Smith, 


EQUITY  OF  EEDEMPTION— EREOK,  LAW  OF 


51 


Principles  of  Eqtiity.  For  the  place  of  equity 
in  systems  of  law  generally,  and  its  importance 
in  the  evolution  of  society,  see  Maine,  Ancient 
Law.]     ,  E.  s. 

EQUITY  OF  REDEMPTION.  The  right 
thart  a  mortgagor  has  to  recover,  on  payment  of 
principal,  interest,  and  costs,  a  mortgaged  estate 
which  has  under  the  mortgage  deed  become  the 
property  of  the  mortgagee  owing  to  the  failure 
of  the  mortgagor  to  pay  the  principal  and 
interest  at  the  time  agreed  on.  The  right 
resembles  real  estate  inasmuch  as  it  will 
descend  to  the  mortgagor's  heirs.  It  is  alien- 
able, and  may  itself  be  mortgaged. 

[The  Principles  of  Equity,  by  E.  H.  T.  Snell, 
London,  1892.]  j.  e,  C.  m. 

EQUITY  TO  A  SETTLEMENT.  When  a 
husband  had  to  resort  to  a  court  of  equity  in 
order  to  reduce  into  possession  property  of  his 
wife,  the  court  compelled  him  to  make  a  settle- 
ment of  a  portion,  usually  one  half,  of  such  pro- 
perty on  the  wife  and  children. 

[The  Principles  of  Equity,  by  E.  H.  T.  Snell, 
London,  1892.]  j.  e.  c.  m. 

ERROR  EXCEPTED.  These  words  are  fre- 
quently inserted  at  the  end  of  a  statement  of 
account,  and  are  intended  to  show  that  the 
accounting  party  wishes  to  reserve  the  right  to 
make  further  claims  in  case  any  error  should 
subsequently  be  discovered  in  the  account. 

E.  s. 
ERROR,  Law  of.  When  an  average  of  a 
set  of  statistics  is  taken,  the  deviation  of  any 
one  of  them  from  the  average  is  sometimes 
called  an  error ;  and  the  arrangement  of  the 
group  about  its  mean,  a  law  of  error.  A  parti- 
cular arrangement,  which  under  certain  fre- 
quently-realised conditions  arises,  is  designated 
as  the  law  of  error.  According  to  this  law  the 
figure  which  is  likely  to  occur  most  frequently 
is  the  one  which  forms  the  average  ;  the  others 
are  grouped  symmetrically  above  and  below  the 
average  ;  becoming  less  frequent  as  they  are 
more  distant  from  that  central  magnitude.  In 
the  exact  language  of  symbols,  if  x^,  x^,  etc.,  are 
the  quantities  averaged,  and  X  the  average,  the 
number  of  quantities  comprised  between  x  and 
a  neighbouring  value  a;  + Ace  is  approximately  = 
1     (X-x)2 

^  ^^  Zr^  ^  ^^  5  where  w  and  e  are  the  well- 
known  constants  3-1415  .  .  .,  2-718  .  .  .  • 
and  c  is  a  constant  proper  to  the  group  under 
consideration.     This  arrangement  is  represented 

^     _(X-^)2 
by  the  curve  Y=— ^-e  c2       ;  the  number 

VTrc 
of  observations  in  the  neighbourhood  of  any 
point  in  the  axis  of  x  being  proportioned  to  the 
ordinate  at  that  point ;  and  the  number  of 
observations  comprised  between  two  values  of 
X  being  equal  to  the  area  intercepted  by  the' 
ordinates  at  those  two  points,  the  curve,  and 


the  axis  x.  Two  illustrations  of  this  curve  are 
given  in  the  annexed  diagrams.  The  curve  is 
spread  out,  as  in  Fig.  1,  when  the  constant  c  is 


POP  Q 

large  ;  it  is  gathered  in,  as  in  Fig.  2,  when  the 


Fig.  2. 


Q' 


POP 


Q 


constant  c  is  small.  The  constant  c  being  ascer- 
tained for  any  group  of  statistics,  we  are  able  to 
predict  what  proportion  of  the  gi'oup  will  pro- 
bably be  comprised  between  limits  defined  in 
terms  of  that  constant.  Thus  half  of  the  group 
is  likely  to  be  comprised  between  the  limits 
X--4769  .  .  .  c  and  X+-4769  .  .  .  c  ;  or, 
in  other  words,  it  is  as  likely  as  not  that  an 
observation  taken  at  random  will  be  distant 
from  the  average  X  by  an  interval  gi-eater  than 
•4769  .  .  .  c  ;  which  multiple  of  c  is  accord- 
ingly called  the  pt^'ohahle  error.  Again  the 
greater  part  of  the  group  is  comprised  between 
the  limits  X  -  2c,  X  +  2c  ;  the  odds  are  more 
than  200  to  1  against  any  observation  being  at 
a  distance  greater  than  2c  from  the  average. 
The  odds  are  50,000  to  1  against  the  distance 
of  any  observation  from  the  average  being 
greater  than  3c.  The  points  P  and  Q  (P'  and  Q') 
in  the  figures  are  intended  to  represent  the 
"  probable  "  and  what  may  be  called  the  impro- 
hahle  error  (2c  or  more). 

The  condition  under  which  the  law  of  error 
is  fulfilled  is  that  each  of  the  things  averaged 
is  dependent  in  the  same  way  upon  (the  same 
function  of)  a  great  number  of  independently 
variable  elements.  For  example  add  together 
ten  or  more  digits  obtained  thus  :  the  first  is  the 
first  decimal  place  in  any  constant,  e.g.  v,  the 
second  addendum  is  the  first  digit  in  any  other 
constant,  e.g.  e,  and  the  remaining  eight  con- 
stituents of  the  sum  are  the^rs^  digits  in  almost 
any  other  unconnected  constants.    Form  another 


762 


ERROR,  LAW  OF 


Bum  of  ten  digits  by  taking  the  second  decimal 
place  in  each  of  the  ten  constants  ;  and  so  on. 
The  set  of  sums  thus  formed  will  group  them- 
selves according  to  the  law  of  error  ;  the  average 
being  45,  and  the  constant  c  being  \/165  =  13 
nearly.  About  half  the  group  will  be  found  be- 
tween  45-6  {i.e.  39)  and  45  +  6  {i.e.  51)  since 
.477  VieB  =  6  nearly.  A  very  small  proportion 
of  the  group— rless  than  a  two-hundredth  part-- 
raay  be  expected  to  occur  outside  the  limits 
45  ±26-  (26  =  2  X  Vl65  nearly).  If  the  number 
of  elements  entering  into  each  of  the  figures 
averaged  had  been  greater  than  ten,  e.g.  twenty, 
the  "probable"  and  the  "improbable"  error 
would  have  been  greater  absolutely,  namely  10 
and  36  respectively  ;  but  less  relatively  to  the 
average,  now  90.  Similar  consequences  would 
follow  if,  instead  of  a  simple  sum,  we  had  em- 
ployed almost  any  fwiction. 

There  is  reason  to  believe  that  the  condition 
which  has  been  indicated  is  frequently  fulfilled  ; 
and  the  law  of  error  has  been  observed  to  pre- 
vail in  extensive  classes  of  phenomena,  which 
may  thus  be  summarised  : — 

1.  Repeated  observations  of  one  and  the  same 
physical  quantity. 

2.  Shots  fired  at  the  same  object. 

3.  A  series  of  numbers  each  of  which  is  ob- 
tained by  taking  at  random  a  batch  of  say  n 
balls  out  of  a  bag  containing  white  and  black 
balls  mixed  up  in  a  certain  proportion,  and 
noting  the  number  of  whites  in  each  batch  of  n 
balls  ;  or  a  series  obtained  by  tossing  coins  or 
dies  and  noting  the  number  of  heads  or  aces  ; 
and  similar  series. 

4.  Measurements  of  the  organs  of  numerous 
specimens  of  a  natiu-al  species. 

5.  Statistics  of  social  phenomena  which  do 
not  present  a  progressive  character,  e.g.  the 
number  of  births,  deaths,  or  marriages  or 
the  rates  of  the  same,  or  the  ratios  between 
the  male  and  female  rates  ;  observed  at  places 
or  times  not  materially  distant  from  each 
other. 

Illustrations  of  the  third  and  fifth  classes 
are  given  in  the  accompanying  tables,  the 
materials  of  which  have  been  taken  from 
Professor  Westergaard's  Theorie  der  Statistik. 
In  Table  I.,  column  1,  was  obtained  from  100 
batches  of  balls  ;  each  batch  numbering  100 
balls,  which  were  taken  at  random  from  a  bag 
containing  black  and  white  balls  in  equal  pro- 
portions ;  the  number  of  white  balls  in  each 
batch  having  been  noted,  the  number  of  these 
numbers  comprised  between  two  limits,  which 
are  defined  by  a  multiple  of  the  constant  c, 
forms  an  entry  in  column  2.  The  correspond- 
ing limits  are  given  in  column  1.  Thus  twenty- 
five  of  the  observations  occurred  between  the 


limits  50 -.3-7^  and 

V2 


50 +  .3-7:^, 
V2 


or  47  and 


since  the  value  of  c  is  here  V2  x  10  ;  40 


of  the  errors  occurred  between  50  -  '^—p^  and 

V2 

50  +  •5—7^  or  45  and  55  ;  and  so  on.    Column  3 

V2, 
similarly  registers  the  arrangement  of  the  statis- 
tics obtained  from  750  batches  of  lottery  tickets 
— each  batch  numbering  100 — by  noting  the 
number  of  prizes  in  each  batch  (the  average 
being  16,  and  the  constant  c  being  5  nearly). 

Table  I. 

Table  showing  the  correspondence  between  fact 
and  theory  in  the  arrangement  of  the  num- 
bers of  white  balls  in  batches  of  100  balls 
each  drawn  at  random  from  a  bag ;  and  of 
prizes  in  batches  of  100  tickets  drawn  at  a 
lottery.^ 


Limits  above 

and  below  the 

average. 

Percentage  of  errors  within  limits. 

Observed, 

Calculated. 

Balls  drawn 
from  bag. 

Tickets 
drawn  at 
lotteiy. 

1 

2 

3 

4 

•^4 

25 

23 

23 

•5   ,, 

40 

36 

36    ,    ' 
49        \ 

•7  „ 

50 

48 

1-1  ,, 

70 

67 

69 

1-5  „ 

85 

83 

82       ' 

2-1  „ 

95 

95 

93       1 

These  results  of  observation  are  to  be  com- 
pared with  the  predictions  of  theory  which  are 
contained  in  column  4. 

Table  II. 

Table  showing  the  correspondence  between  fact 
and  theory  in  the  proportion  of  male  to  all 
births  for  nineteen  years  in  Italy. '-^ 


Limits  above 
and  below 
the  average. 

Number  of  errors  within  limits. 

Observed. 

Calculated. 

1 

2 

3 

•^4 

2 

5 

•5    „ 

7 

7 

•7    „ 

9 

9 

1-1         M 

12 

12 

1-5    „ 

16 

U 

2-1     „ 

17 

16 

1  Westergaard,  op.  cit.  p.  67. 

2  See  Westergaard,  op.  cit.  p,  39.  The  first  column 
differs  from  his  only  in  notation  ;  the  second  column  is 
the  same  as  his  ;  the  third  column  is  calculated  from  th'" 
second  column  of  his  table  at  p.  67. 


ERROR,  LAW  OF— ESCHEAT 


753 


In  Table  II.,  the  first  column  gives  limits 
defined  by  the  constant  c  as  before  ;  the  second 
column  gives  the  arrangement  of  errors  ob- 
tained' by  comparing  the  proportion  of  male 
births  to  all  births,  male  and  female,  in  Italy 
for  each  of  nineteen  years  with  the  average  pro- 
portion for  the  whole  period  ;  the  third  column 
gives  the  theoretical  arrangement. 

The  applications  of  the  law  of  error  with 
which  we  are  here  concerned  relate  partly  (I.) 
to  practice,  and  partly  (II.)  to  the  investigation 
of  causes. 

(I.)  It  is  useful,  when  employing  an  average 
obtained  from  statistics,  e.g.  a  death-rate,  or  an 
index-number,  to  have  the  means  of  estimating 
the  extent  to  which  the  figui'e  in  the  case  with 
which  we  are  dealing  is  likely  to  differ  from  the 
average  obtained  in  past  experience.  It  is  use- 
less to  calculate  the  average  to  a  number  of 
decimal  places  not  warranted  by  the  "  probable 
en'or  "  to  which  the  figure  is  liable. 

(II.)  Under  the  second  head  two  cases  may  be 
distinguished  :  (a)  where  the  analogy  of  simple 
games  of  chance  holds  good  ;  the  constant  c 
being  that  which  would  be  obtained  if  the 
statistics  were  of  the  sort  which  forms  our  third 
class  of  phenomena  above  ;  and  (b)  where  the 
constant  is  not  such. 

(a)  In  the  first  case  we  have  the  advantage 
of  knowing  that  the  given  group  cannot  be 
broken  up  into  two,  or  more,  with  widely  dif- 
ferent averages  ;  that  the  analysis  which  is  a 
principal  object  of  the  scientific  statistician  has 
been  already  pushed  almost  up  to  its  limit. 
Our  statistics  cannot  be  like  batches  of  balls 
taken  from  bags  in  which  the  proportion  of 
white  to  black  is  very  different ;  but  rather  are 
analogous  to  the  successive  numbers  of  white 
balls  occuiTing  in  batches  of  the  same  size  taken 
at  random  from  the  same  bag.  It  would  appear 
hopeless  therefore  to  trace  by  ordinary  induction 
the  causation  of  any  particular  event  of  this 
character.  It  is  only  crazy  gamblers  who  pre- 
tend to  predict  the  "runs"  in  games  of  pure 
chance.  But  we  are  not  precluded  from  apply- 
ing the  law  of  error  to  detect  delicate  differences, 
such  as  may  exist  between  a  perfect  and  a 
slightly-loaded  coin.  Take  for  example  the 
observation  that  the  percentage  of  male  com- 
pared with  female  births  for  more  than  a 
vcnWxon  plural  births  (of  twins  or  triplets)  in 
Prussia  during  a  certain  period  of  years  was 
104-447  (males  to  100  females)  ;  whereas  the 
corresponding  ratio  for  all  births  (single  as  well 
as  plural)  was  106-305  ;  the  observation  on 
which  this  average  is  based  numbering  several 
millions.  Given  these  numbers,  and  knowing 
as  we  do  that  the  phenomenon  belongs  to  class 
(a),  we  are  able  to  determine  the  constant  c  ; 
which  proves  to  be  nearly  -3.  Thus  the  dif- 
ference between  the  two  averages  compared,  viz. 
1-858,  is  about  six  times  the  constant,  and 
accordingly  (see  above  par.  1)  the  odds  against 
VOL.  I. 


the  observed  difference  in  the  averages  being 
due  to  accident  and  not  to  a  real  cause  which 
may  be  expected  to  continue  acting — are  many 
times  more  than  50,000  to  1  (Duesing).  "We 
have  obtained,  at  a  stroke,  a  degree  of  evidence 
in  favour  of  a  law  which  otherwise  could  only 
be  obtained  by  a  laborious  analysis  of  the 
returns.  By  parity  of  reasoning  it  is  found 
that  in  times  a.nd  places  where  the  absolute 
number  of  births  is  large  the  proportion  of 
males  is  small  (ibid.). 

(b)  This  summary  method  may  be  employed 
also  in  the  second  case  (Avhere  the  analogy  with 
games  of  chance  does  not  hold  good)  ;  but  not 
in  such  a  clear  light  of  foreknowledge  as  to  the 
character  of  the  causes  under  investigation. 

Besides  the  exact  and  direct  applications  of 
the  law  of  error,  it  also  affords  what  may  be 
called  "regulative  ideas"  to  the  statistician; 
supplying  the  rationale  of  many  received 
maxims  :  that  ceteris  paribus  an  average  is  more 
worth  the  greater  the  number,  and  the  less  the 
divergence,  of  the  returns  averaged  ;  that  a  few 
accurate  returns  may  be  better  than  many  loose 
ones. 

[For  a  general  exposition,  at  once  simple  and  accu- 
rate, of  the  law  of  error,  see  Venn,  Logic  of  Chance, 
third  ed.  1888,  chaps,  xviii.  and  xix.  See  also 
Jevons,  Principles  of  Science,  chap.  xvii. — Bertil- 
lon,  art.  " Moy euBQ,"  Dictionnaire  -EncyclopMique 
des  Sciences  Mcdicales. — Quetelet,  Physique  Sociale. 
For  the  conditions  under  which  the  fulfilment  of 
the  law  may  be  expected,  Glaisher,  Memoirs  of  the 
Astronomical  Society,  vol.  xl.  p.  104. — Galton, 
Philosophical  Magazine,  1875,  "Statistics  by 
inter-comparison." — Edgewoi'th,  liic?.  1892,  "The 
Law  of  Error." — For  the  a  posteriori  proof,  that  the 
law  is  fulfilled,  see  Galton,  Natural  Inheritance. — 
Westergaard,  Grundzuge  der  Theorie  der  Statistik, 
chap.  iii.  — Edgeworth,  '  *  Empirical  proof  of  thelaw 
of  Error,"  Phil.  Mag.,  1887. — For  the  application 
of  the  law  to  practice,  Dormoy,  Theorie  niathima- 
tique  des  assurances  sur  la  vie.  For  the  application 
of  the  law  to  induction,  (a)  where  the  analogy  of 
games  of  chance  holds  good,  Westergaard,  op.  cit. 
— Lexis,  Massenerscheinungen.  —  Duesing,  Das 
Geschlechtsverhdltniss  in  Preussen  ;  (6)  in  general, 
Edgeworth,  Journal  of  the  Statistical  Society. 
Jubilee  Volume,  1885,  "Methods  of  Statistics," 
ibid.  December  1885,  "  Methods  of  Determining 
Rates. "  Many  of  these  writers  throw  light  on  other 
parts  of  the  subject  besides  those  with  special 
reference  to  which  they  have  been  cited.  Several 
otherauthors  might  have  been  cited.  Merriman  has 
published  an  immense  list  of  writers  on  the  cognate 
subject  of  the  Method  of  Least  Squares,  many  of 
whom  have  touched  on  the  law  of  error,  and  some 
on  its  applications  to  social  phenomena  (see  Pro- 
babilities ;  Statistics).]  f.  y.  e. 

ESCHEAT  (historical)  was  a  feudal  term  in- 
troduced  by  the  Normans  into  England,  and 
applied  to  the  reversion  of  land  to  the  lord. 
The  ordinary  cause  of  such  reversion  was  the 
failure  of  heirs,  when  the  whole  estate  passed 
into  the  hands  of  the  lord.     If  the  heir  was  a 

3  c 


'84 


ESCHEAT— ESTATE 


minor,  the  phrase  was  escceta  cum  Tmrede,  when 
the  necessities  of  the  heir  and  other  children  were 
paid  for  out  of  the  estate  and  the  surplus  only 
went  to  the  lord,  until  the  heir,  on  reaching 
his  majority,  paid  a  relief  and  obtained  seisin. 
Escheat  also  took  place  in  cases  of  trea^n  or 
felony.  If  the  criminal  was  a  tenant-in-chief, 
the  whole  of  his  property  reverted  to  the  crown  ; 
but  if  he  was  a  sub-tenant,  his  movables  only 
fell  to  the  crown,  while  the  real  estate  passed 
to  the  immediate  lord. 

[Dialogusde  Scaccario,  ii.  x.]  b.  l. 

ESCHEAT  (MODERN  LAW),  takes  place 
where  a  person  dies  intestate  and  without  an  heir. 
The  lands  of  such  a  person  go  to  the  feuda,l  lord, 
but,  as  in  the  case  of  freehold  land  the  right  of 
mesne  lords  can  in  our  days  be  established  but 
rarely,  such  land  generally  goes  to  the  sovereign 
as  lord  paramount.  Copyhold  land  goes  to  the 
lord  of  the  manor,  and  §  4  of  the  Copyhold  Act 
provides  that  the  right  of  escheat  is  to  continue 
after  enfranchisement ;  enfranchised  copyhold 
land,  though  otherwise  of  the  nature  of  freehold 
land,  does  not  therefore  escheat  to  the  crown, 
but  goes  to  a  private  person.  Formerly  the 
lands  of  felons  were  subject  to  the  right  of 
escheat,  but  an  act  passed  in  1870  has  repealed 
this  rule.  On  the  other  hand  the  Intestate 
Estates  Act  of  1884  has  made  certain  rights  as 
to  real  property  subject  to  escheat,  which  were 
not  so  subject  before.  The  same  act  has 
enabled  the  crown  to  waive  its  right  in  certain 
cases.  The  procedure  which  takes  place  to 
inquire  as  to  the  right  of  the  crown  has  been 
simplified  by  the  Escheat  (Procedure)  Act  of 
1887. 

The  right  of  the  state  to  acquire  the  property 
of  a  person  dying  without  relations  or  a  will 
exists  in  most  countries  independently  of  feudal 
rules,  and  seems  justified  by  reason  and  con- 
venience. 

[Bentham,  J.  S.  Mill,  Godin,  and  other  reformers, 
have  proposed  to  narrow  the  rights  of  intestate 
succession  {i.e.  to  extend  escheat)  in  order  to 
correct,  to  some  extent,  the  unequal  distribution 
of  wealth.]  E.  s. 

ESCUDO.  The  name  of  the  Spanish  half 
dollar. 

Gold  and  Silver  Coins  as  follows: 


MeUl. 

Denomination 
of  Coin. 

Fine- 
ness. 

Weight. 

Value. 

In  gold 

916-6 

fine  at 

£3:l7:10J 

an  ounce. 

In  gold 

francs, 

900 

fine. 

add 

10  Escudos  (or 
Doubloon) 
4  Escudos 
2  Escudos  (or 
Dollar) 

900 

900 
900 

grains. 
129-44 

51-78 
25-89 

£   s.  d. 
1    0    7i 

0    8    3 
0    4    li 

francs. 
26-0 

10-4 
5-2 

Metal. 

Denomination 
of  Coin. 

Fine- 
ness. 

Weight. 

Value. 

In  silver 
925  fine 
at     5/6 
an  oz. 

In  sil- 1 

ver 
francs, 

900 

fine. 

Silver 

Bscudo  (or  i 
Duro  or 
Dollar) 

900 

grains. 
200-30 

s.    d. 
2    2| 

francs. 
2-6 

These  coins  have  not  been  struck  for  circula- 
tion in  Spain  since  1868,  when  the  system  of 
pesetas  (francs)  was  introduced-.  Similar  coins, 
including  a  doubloon  of  eight  escudos,  are  cur- 
rent in  the  Philippine  Islands  (see  Doubloon). 

F.  E.  A. 

ESCUSADO,  the  name  of  the  portion  of 
ecclesiastical  tithes  made  over  in  1567  by  the 
Pope  to  the  crown  of  Spain.  e.  ca. 

ESSART,  ExART,  sometimes  also  called 
Assart.  A  mediaeval  term  applied  to  a  portion 
of  forest  land  cleared  and  brought  into  cultiva- 
tion. To  make  essarts  was  technically  a  breach 
of  the  forest  law,  punishable  by  fine.  These 
fines,  with  the  yearly  rents  levied  on  the 
essarted  lands,  which  the  maker  of  the  essart 
was  usually  allowed  to  keep  under  cultivation, 
formed  a  considerable  item  in  the  revenues  of 
the  royal  and  other  lords  of  forests  in  mediaeval 
England.  These  rents  would  appear  to  have 
been  fixed  at  the  highest  rate  that  could  be 
maintained,  a  rate  which  will  be  found  to  be 
often  several  times  as  great  as  that  paid  by  free 
or  even  customary  tenants  for  other  land  in 
the  same  neighbourhood.  In  spite  of  these 
high  rates,  however,  fresh  essarts  were  made 
almost  every  year  in  England.  The  forest  of 
Wirrall  in  Cheshire,  for  instance,  was  entirely 
under  cultivation  before  the  death  of  the  Black 
Prince,  who,  in  his  capacity  of  Earl  of  Chester, 
by  a  formal  charter  of  disafforestment,  put  his 
seal  to  the  work  of  reclamation.  The  word 
essart  has  been  variously  derived  from  the  old 
French  assortir,  to  make  smooth,  or  one  of  the 
low  Latin  terms,  exertum,  rooted  up,  sarrire, 
to  weed,  or  exarare,  to  plough  up. 

[Manwood,  Forest  Law,  London,  1596,  etc.— 
Ducange,  Glossarium  Media!  et  Infimce  Latini- 
tatis,  ed.  nova  a  L.  Favre,  Paris,  1884. — Forest 
accounts  among  the  ancient  records  of  the  ex- 
chequer in  the  Public  Eecord  Office.]  a.  h. 

ESTATE.  A  so-called  owner  of  land  has, 
according  to  English  law,  no  absolute  right  of 
ownership ;  all  that  he  has  is  an  interest  varying 
in  extent  and  duration,  and  known  in  technical 
language  as  an  "estate"  in  the  land.  The 
largest  estate  known  to  the  law  is  an  **  estate 
in  fee  "  (fee  simple),  which  gives  the  owner  as 
complete  rights  of  enjoyment  and  alienation 
as  the  nature  of  the  property  will  admit ;  an 
estate  tail  (see  Entail),  being  convertible  into 
an  estate  in   fee — by  the  tenant  alone,  if  in 


ESTATE  DUTY— ESTIMO 


755 


I 


possession,  and  otherwise  by  him  jointly  with 
the  tenant  for  life — confers  rights  nearly  as 
complete.  An  estate  for  the  life  of  the  tenant, 
or  for  the  life  or  lives  of  another  person  or 
other  persons,  gives  the  tenant  the  privileges 
of  ownership  during  his  life  or  during  the  life 
or  lives  of  such  other  person  or  persons  ;  but 
a  tenant  for  life — unless  the  estate  is  conferred 
upon  him  "without  impeachment  of  waste" — 
is  not  allowed  to  pull  down  buildings,  cut 
timber,  or  open  mines.  An  estate  for  the  life 
of  another  person  is  called  an  *'  estate  pur  autre 
vie."  Estates  in  fee  or  in  tail,  and  estates  for 
life,  are  called  "freehold"  estates,  estates  for 
a  definite  number  of  years,  however  large  the 
number  may  be,  are  "leasehold,"  also  called 
"less  than  freehold"  (see  Leasehold  Piio- 
perty).  The  word  estate  is  also  used  as  a  com- 
prehensive name  for  the  assets  of  a  bankrupt  or 
of  a  deceased  person.  In  the  latter  case  a 
distinction  is  made  between  freehold  land  and 
houses  (real  estate)  and  other  property  (personal 
estate).  E.  S. 

ESTATE  DUTY.     See  Death  Duties. 

ESTCOURT,  Thomas  (end  of  18th  and  early 
1 9th  century).  Thomas  Estcourt  sat  in  parlia- 
ment as  member  for  Cricklade  from  1784  to 
1806.  In  1804  he  published  An  account  of  an 
Effort  to  Better  the  Condition  of  the  Poor  in  a 
Country  Village  {Long  Newton)  and  some 
Regulations  suggested  by  which  the  same  might 
be  extended  to  other  parishes  of  a  similar  descrip- 
tion. The  work  was  printed  by  the  board  of 
agriculture.  Estcourt  states  that  in  1800 
arrangements  were  made  for  letting  to  any 
cottager  a  small  quantity  of  land  at  a  rent  of 
£1  :  12s.  an  acre,  the  land  to  be  forfeited  if 
not  properly  cultivated,  or  on  the  receipt  of 
parish  relief  other  than  medical.  He  states 
that  the  offer  was  largely  accepted,  and  that 
the  scheme  greatly  decreased  the  poor-rate  in 
the  village.  c.  g.  c. 

ESTERNO,  Phil.,  Comte  d'  (1805-1883), 
born  at  Dijon,  died  at  Paris.  Esterno's  life 
was  mainly  devoted  to  agriculture  and  to 
political  economy.  The  first  work  of  his 
which  caused  him  to  be  known  as  an  economist 
was  entitled,  Des  banques  d^partementales  en 
France,  1  vol.  in  8vo,  1838.  In  this  Esterno 
argued  in  favour  of  departmental  banks,  to  be 
established  in  a  good  many  towns,  and  at  Dijon 
in  particular.  This  was  at  a  time  when  the 
government,  urged  on  by  a  spirit  of  centralisa- 
tion, were  hostile  to  institutions  of  this  descrip- 
tion 

In  1840  Esterno  took  part  in  a  discussion 
instituted  by  the  Academy  of  Moral  and  Politi- 
cal Sciences,  on  the  signs  and  causes  of  poverty 
in  different  countries.  Buret  (q.v.)  won  the 
prize.  Esterno's  paper  was  rejected  because, 
according  to  the  report,  "it  was  not  an  econo- 
mic essay  which  was  wanted."  This  work, 
printed  in  1842,  under  the  title  of  La  mishre ; 


de  ses  causes,  de  ses  effets,  in  8vo,  reflected  the 
ideas  of  Malthus,  while  Buret,  on  the  other 
hand,  had  allowed  sentiment  to  overpower 
reason. 

During  the  same  year  (1842)  Esterno  assisted 
as  secretary,  in  conjunction  with  P.  Rossi,  who 
was  president,  in  founding  at  Paris  a  society 
for  promoting  political  economy  (Society  d'econo- 
mie  politique),  an  association  which  only  lasted 
a  few  months,  but  was  a  forerunner  of  the 
society  now  known  under  the  same  name. 

In  1867-68  Esterno  published  another  work, 
Des  priviUgies  de  I'ancien  regime  en  France  et 
des  2orivilegies  du  nouveau,  2  vols,  in  8vo.  In 
this  work  the  author  argued,  in  a  brisk  and 
original  style,  in  favour  of  agriculture,  which 
was  put  too  much  on  one  side  by  the  privileged 
persons  under  the  new  regime,  the  moneyed 
classes,  as  distinguished  from  the  landed  pro- 
prietors, notwithstanding  the  untrustworthy 
titles  of  some  of  their  institutions,  Le  Credit 
agricole,  for  example.  Before  this  date  (1867- 
1868),  and  later  on,  Esterno  strove,  on  behalf  of 
the  agricultural  interest,  against  those  artificial 
monopolies  which,  even  to  this  day,  have 
arrested  the  development  of  agriculture  in 
France.  He  thus  became  deeply  interested 
in  works  of  irrigation,  and  it  is  to  him  and  to 
his  energy,  though  he  never  allowed  his  name 
to  appear,  that  the  adoption  of  the  regulations 
of  29th  April  1845  and  11th  July  1847  {lois 
d'Angeville)  is  due. 

Esterno's  mental  activity  led  him  to  occupy 
himself  with  other  subjects  with  which  we 
are  not  concerned  here.  His  intelligence,  his 
energy,  and  his  scientific  devotion  enabled  him 
to  render  them  interesting  to  others.  He  was 
a  vice-president  of  the  second  SociitS  d' economic 
politique.  A.  c.  f. 

ESTIMO.  The  revenue  of  Florence  in  the 
flourishing  days  of  the  republic  was  mainly 
derived  from  indirect  taxes,  which  produced 
some  300,000  florins  a  year.  But  in  times  of 
war,  which  became  frequent  in  the  14th  century, 
this  income  was  insufficient,  and  it  was  supple- 
mented either  by  direct  taxes  or  by  compulsory 
loans  (prestanze).  Both  taxes  and  loans  were 
supposed  to  be  based  upon  an  estimo,  or  govern- 
ment valuation  of  property,  and  hence  the  term 
estimo  comes  to  be  applied  to  the  exactions 
themselves.  The  earliest  estimo  was  formed  in 
1288,  and  seems  to  have  referred  only  to  real 
property.  Another  assessment  took  place  in 
1327,  when  a  foreign  judge  was  appointed  to 
determine  the  wealth  of  each  individual  by  the 
secret  testimony  of  seven  of  his  neighbours. 
But  the  attempt  to  provide  a  regular  basis  for 
direct  taxation  proved  a  failure  in  the  14th 
century.  An  estimo  soon  became  obsolete  as 
property  rapidly  changed  hands,  and  a  charge 
upon  real  property  alone  pressed  heavily  upon 
the  noble  families  and  the  peasants  of  the 
country,  while  the  wealthy  burghers  escaped. 


756 


ESTOPPEL— EVANS 


For  the  most  part  the  forced  loans  were  arbi- 
trarily assessed  by  the  existing  government,  and 
one  great  reason  for  the  Florentine  greed  for 
office,  which  introduced  the  system  of  lot,  was 
the  desire  to  escape  taxation.  When  the 
ClOMPi  {q.v.)  rose  in  revolt  in  1378,  ong  of 
their  demands  was  that  no  loan  should  be 
levied  without  an  estimo,  but  their  subsequent 
defeat  prevented  any  change  being  made.  The 
discontent  excited  by  arbitrary  and  ^nfair 
assessment  forced  the  government  in  1427  to 
introduce  the  Catasto  {q.v.),  which  was  only  a 
new  name  for  a  thorough  estiTno  of  real  and 
personal  property  including  income.  But  this 
great  reform  was  abandoned  by  Cosimo  de  Medici 
in  1441,  when  the  old  arbitrary  assessments, 
formerly  maintained  to  favour  the  wealthy 
burghers,  were  revived  to  relieve  and  conciliate 
the  poorer  classes.  The  Medici  from  this  time 
introduced  the  principle  of  progressive  taxation, 
and,  as  Guicciardini  says,  used  the  taxes  instead 
of  the  dagger  to  ruin  their  opponents. 

[Canestrini,  La  Sdenza  e  VArte  di  Stato  desunta 
dagli  A  tti  offidaZi  della  Repubblica  Fiorentina  e  dei 
Medici  (only  one  volume  of  this  great  work  was 
published), — Napier,  Florentine  History,  vol.  iii. 
p.  117. — Perrens,  Histoire  de  Florence.']      E.  L. 

ESTOPPEL.  A  term  used  in  connection 
with  the  rule  of  law,  according  to  which  a 
person  who,  by  statements  or  conduct,  causes 
another  person  to  believe  in  the  truth  of  a 
certain  matter  of  fact,  with  the  intention  of 
inducing  him  to  act  upon  it,  cannot,  in  any 
dispute  concerning  the  matter  in  question,  be 
allowed  to  assert  that  the  state  of  things  which 
he  represented  to  be  in  existence,  did  not,  in 
fact,  exist ;  thus,  for  instance,  a  person,  by 
accepting  a  bill  of  exchange,  induces  the  holders 
to  assume  that  the  drawer  was  of  full  age,  and 
otherwise  capable  to  draw  a  bill,  and  he  is 
therefore  "estopped"  from  denying  the  drawer's 
capacity  (Bill  of  Exchange  Act,  §  54  [2]). 
Estoppel  by  conduct  is  in  certain  cases  also 
called  "estoppel  by  negligence,"  e.g.  if  a 
person  by  the  careless  filling  in  of  a  cheque 
enables  a  fraudulent  holder  to  alter  the  amount, 
he  is  estopped  from  denying  that  he  drew 
the  cheque  for  the  full  amount,  as  by  his 
negligence  he  has  allowed  the  banker  to  think 
that  he  has  done  so.  Estoppel  by  state- 
ment or  conduct  is  in  the  older  law  books 
called  "estoppel  by  matter  in  pais,"  and 
distinguished  from  "estoppel  by  deed"  and 
"estoppel  by  record."  "Estoppel  by  deed" 
prevents  a  party  to  a  deed  from  denying  any 
fact  mentioned  in  the  same  by  way  of  recital 
or  otherwise.  "  Estoppel  by  record  "  precludes 
a  party  to  an  action,  or  his  successor  in  title, 
from  denying  any  fact  established  by  the 
decision  in  the  action.  The  fullest  statement 
on  the  law  of  estoppel  is  contained  in  the  notes 
to  the  Duchess  of  Kingston's  case  in  Smith's 
Leading  Cases,  vol.  ii.  E.  s. 


ESTOVERS  (derived  from  the  same  root  as 
the  old  French  word  estovoir  =  to  be  necessary), 
also  called  "Bote,"  is  the  right  of  a  tenant  for 
life,  unless  restrained  by  agreement,  to  take 
the  necessary  wood  from  the  estate  for  the  use 
or  furniture  of  a  house  or  farm.  "Common 
of  Estovers  "  is  the  right  of  a  commoner  to  cut 
wood  (see  Commons).  e.  s. 

l&TATS  GENfiRAUX,  The,  or  States  General 
of  France,  were,  under  the  old  monarchy,  the 
national  representative  assembly  of  the  kingdom, 
composed  of  elected  members  of  the  three 
orders,  the  noblesse,  the  clergy,  and  the  third 
order  or  state  (Tiers  J^tat  or  bourgeoisie),  but 
no  fixed  rule  was  ever  followed  for  their  election 
and  assembling.  Their  first  authentic  meeting 
was  summoned,  1302,  by  King  Philippe  le  Bel, 
to  assist  him  in  his  struggle  against  Pope 
Bonifacius  VIIL  ;  after  this  date  they  were 
convoked  at  irregular  and  often  very  protracted 
intervals,  whenever  the  royal  finances  were  in 
a  state  of  extreme  distress.  In  1357,  during 
the  captivity  of  King  John  in  England,  they 
vainly  tried  to  give  a  constitution  to  the 
kingdom.  The  Mats  OdnArai(jx,  which  must 
not  be  confounded  with  the  Assemblies  des 
Notables,  were  at  all  times  steady  and  consistent 
upholders  of  the  theory  that  no  tax  could  be 
valid  without  their  assent ;  the  monarchy  never 
contested  this  doctrine,  but  never  followed  it 
in  practice.  The  ^tats  GenSraiox  of  1614  were 
the  last  before  the  revolution  of  1789. 

[Toussaint  Quinet,  Recueil  des  ^tats  tenus  en 
France,  1651,  1  vol. — Paulin,  Qrandes  chroniques 
de  France  (vol.  vi.  1350-1382,  Paris,  1838).— Jean 
Masselin,  Journal  des  J^tats  G^neraux  de  14^4 
(in  Latin,  translated  into  French  by  Bernier  in 
1835). — Rathery,  Histoire  des  Mats  Gin&raux  en 
France  (1845).  —  Bouillee,  Histoire  compUte  des 
Mats  Generaux  et  autres  assemblees  reprisentatives ' 
de  1302  d  1626  (Paris,  1845,  2  vols.).— Augustin 
Thierry,  Histoire  du  Tiers  Mat. — The  most  recent 
works  are  M.  Jallifier's  Histoire  des  l^tatsG&niraux 
(1  vol.  Paris,  1888),  and  M.  Georges  Picot's  ex- 
haustive Histoire  des  Mats  G^niraux  considiris 
au  point  de  vue  de  leur  influence  sur  le  gouverne- 
ment  de  la  France  (1355-1614).]  e.  Ca. 

ETHEL.     See  Alod. 

EVANS,  David  Morier  (1819-1874),  wasi 
born  in  Wales.  He  treated  economic  subjects ; 
from  a  journalistic  point  of  view,  aiming  rather 
at  giving  an  accurate  narrative  of  the  successive 
phases  of  economic  crises  and  the  like  than  at 
tracing  their  hidden  causes.  In  his  own  words 
he  was  a  man  of  "  facts  and  figures." 

Besides  numerous  contributions  to  the  Bankers' 
Magazine,   which  he  edited  for  some  years,  the  , 
Bullionist,  and  the  Stock  Exchange  Gazette,  Evans 
wrote  The  Commercial  Crisis,  1S47-4S,  London, 
1848-49.  —  The    Annual    Coviviercial    Register^ 
London,  1850. — Fortunes  Epitome  of  the  Public [ 
Funds,  London,  1851-56. — Facts,  Failures,  and' 
Frauds,  London,  1859. — The  History  of  the  Com-  ■ 
merdal  Crisis.  1857-58,  and  of  the  Stock  Exchange 


EVANS— EVERETT 


757 


Panic,  1869,  London,  1869. — Notes  on  Specula- 
tion, London,  1864. 

[See  Dictionary  of  National  Biography,  London, 
1888,  Times  for  2nd  January  1874.]  a.  h. 

EVANS,  Thomas  (end  of  IStli  and  early 
19tli  century).  In  1798  Thomas  Evans  was 
acting  as  secretary  to  the  London  Correspond- 
ing Society,  and  was  imprisoned  for  nearly  three 
years  on  a  charge  of  treasonable  practices.  He 
afterwards  acted  as  librarian  to  the  Spencean 
Society,  and  published  the  work  whose  title  is 
given  below.  The  book  contains  the  usual 
Spencean  doctrines,  advocates  the  nationalisa- 
tion of  the  land  as  the  only  remedy  for  the 
prevailing  distress,  and  denounces  Malthus  as 
the  "  hireling  of  pagan  landlords." 

Christian  Policy,  tlie  Salvation  of  this  Empire, 
*'  being  a  clear  and  concise  examination  into  the 
causes  that  have  produced  the  impending 
national  bankruptcy,  and  the  effects  that  must 
ensue  unless  averted  by  the  adoption  of  the 
only  real  and  desirable  remedy  "  (2nd  ed.,  1816). 

c.  G.  c. 

EVELYN,  John,  F.K.S.  (1620-1706),  the 
author  of  the  famous  Diary,  published  several 
works  of  economic  interest.  Amongst  these 
may  be  mentioned  (1)  Sylva,  or  a  Discourse  of 
Forest  Trees  and  the  Propagation  of  Timber,  etc., 
London,  1664,  foL,  5th  ed.  1729.  A  new 
edition  with  notes  by  A.  Hunter  was  published 
in  1776  ;  4th  ed.  1812.  (2)  Navigation  and 
Commerce,  their  Origin  and  Progress.  Con- 
taining a  Succinct  Account  of  Trajficke  in 
General:  its  Benefits,  etc.,  London,  1674,  8vo. 
(3)  Terra :  A  Philosophical  Discourse  of  Earth, 
Relating  to  the  Culture  and  Improvement  of  it 
for  Vegetation,  and  the  Propagation  of  Plants, 
etc.,  London,  1676.  New  edition,  with  notes 
by  A.  Hunter,  1778.  (4)  Numismata:  A 
Discourse  of  Medals,  Ancient  and  Modern,  etc., 
London,  1697,  fol.  Evelyn  also  translated 
several  French  works  on  horticulture. 

[M'Culloch's  Literature  of  Pol.  Econ.,  146,  212. 
For  a  full  account  of  Evelyn's  life  and  writings 
see  Dictionary  of  National  Biography.  ] 

w.  A.  s.  H. 

EVELYN,  John  (/.  1830),  of  Edgbaston, 
Birmingham,  was  the  author  of  Co-operation: 
An  Address  to  the  Labouring  Classes  on  the  Plans 
to  he  pursued  in  Conducting  Trading  Unions, 
1830,  8vo.  By  "trading  unions"  Evelyn 
meant  co-operative  societies. 

[Brit.  Mus.  Cat.]  w.  a.  s.  h. 

EVERETT,  Alexander  Hill  (1792-1847), 
was  born  at  Boston,  Massachusetts.  He  gradu- 
ated with  the  highest  honours  at  Harvard  ; 
engaged  in  the  diplomatic  service,  and  from 
1825  to  1829  served  as  U.S.  minister  to  Spain  ; 
returned  to  Boston  and  became  editor  and  pro- 
prietor of  the  North  American  Review ;  from 
1830  to  1835  was  in  the  Massachusetts  Legisla- 
ture ;  in  1840  undertook  a  diplomatic  mission 
to  Cuba  ;  and  in  1847  was  engaged  in  a  similar 


errand  in  China,  when  he  died  at  Macao. 
His  writings  cover  a  wide  range  in  history  and 
literature.  Of  economic  interest  is  the  follow- 
ing :  New  Ideas  on  Population  ivith  Remarks 
upon  the  Theories  of  Malthus  and  Godwin, 
Boston,  1823,  pp.  125  (translated  into  French). 
In  opposition  to  the  Malthusian  theory  Everett 
argues  that  an  increase  of  population  is  a  cause 
of  abundance  and  not  of  scarcity,  since  it  de- 
velops the  new  elements  of  skill  by  which  the 
same  quantity  of  labour  is  applied  with  greater 
etfect.  Although  the  population  of  Great  Britain 
doubled  in  the  18th  century,  improvements  in 
the  mode  of  applying  labour  increased  its  produc- 
tiveness probably  a  thousand  times.  Everett, 
by  travel  and  intercourse  with  eminent  men 
in  Europe,  enjoyed  opportunities  possessed  by 
few  of  the  earlier  American  writers  on  economic 
subjects.  He  had  an  interview  with  Malthus, 
carefully  discussing  the  points  at  issue.  The 
latter  suggested  to  Everett  that  his  views  were 
similar  to  those  of  Mr.  S.  Gray  in  the  Happiness 
of  States  (1815).  The  Malthusian  theory  was 
also  discussed  in  a  correspondence  between 
Everett  and  Prof.  George  Tucker  in  the  Demo- 
cratic Review,  vol.  xvii.  pp.  297-310,  379-391, 
438-444,  and  vol.  xxi.  pp.  397-410. 

[For  a  summary  of  Everett's  views,  v.  Dem.  Rev., 
vol.  X.  p.  466,  where  there  is  a  sketch  of  his  life 
until  1840.  To  the  North  American  Pi.eview  he 
contributed  mauy  essays,  among  them  "  M'Culloch's 
Political  Economy  "  (1827),  xxv.,  112  ;  "Political 
Economy"  (1829),  xxviii.,  368  ;  " British  Opinions 
on  the  Protecting  System,"  xxx.,  160  ;  "  American 
System,"  xxxii.,  127  ;  "  Phillip's  Manual  of  Politi- 
cal Economy,"  xxxii.,  215  ;  "The  Laws  of  Popu- 
lation and  Wages,"  xxxix. ,  68  ;  "Rae's  Political 
Economy,"  xl.  122.  Everett  was  a  protectionist ; 
and  in  1833,  as  chairman  of  a  committee  at 
the  Tariff  Convention  in  New  York,  prepared  a 
memorial  to  Congress  in  reply  to  the  memorial 
prepared  by  Gallatin  for  the  Free  Trade  Conven- 
tion at  Philadelphia.  He  advocated  reforms  in 
the  banking  system  in  two  articles  on  "The 
Currency"  in  Boston  Quarterly  Review,  July 
1839  ;  January  1840.]  D.  r.  d. 

EVERETT,  George  {fl.  1693-1698),  Ship- 
wright, appears  to  have  occupied  some  position 
of  importance  in  the  government  dockyards. 
He  was  also  employed  by  the  commissioners  of 
customs  in  the  detection  of  smuggling.  He 
published  (1)  The  Pathway  to  Peace  and  Profit ; 
or,  Truth  in  its  Plain  Dress,  etc.,  London,  1694, 
8vo.  (2)  Encouragement  for  Seamen  and 
Mariners,  in  two  pants,  etc.,  London,  1695,  4to. 
The  first  of  these  pamphlets  embodies  certain 
proposals,  which  Everett  laid  before  the  lords 
of  the  admiralty  in  February  1694,  for  securing 
greater  economy  and  efficiency  in  the  dockyards. 
If  they  were  adopted  he  promised  an  annual 
saving  of  £100,000.  The  second  pamphlet  was 
directed  against  the  abuses  of  the  system  of 
impressment  for  the  sea  service.  His  object 
appears  to  have  been  to  devise  a  system  which 


768 


EVICTION— EXCHANGE 


3honld  at  tlie  same  time  secure  a  constant 
supply  of  sailors  for  the  royal  navy  and  get  rid 
of  the  expense  to  the  government,  and  "injury 
to  the  subject,"  of  the  system  then  in  vogue. 
Amongst  his  suggestions  may  be  noticed  the 
registration  of  all  seamen  and  mariners,  iTxed 
pay  days,  abolition  of  the  sale  of  all  offices  in 
the  navy,  and  a  strict  application  of  the  principle 
of  promotion  by  merit,  an  additional  allowance 
for  seamen  disabled  in  the  public  service,  the 
payment  to  the  family  of  the  sailor  of  six 
months'  wages  for  every  nine  months  he  should 
be  at  sea,  etc.  Everett's  ])amphlets  are  of  no 
theoretical  interest,  but  they  throw  much  light 
on  the  conditions  of  labour  in  the  dockyards 
and  the  sea  service  at  the  end  of  the  17th  cen- 
tury. 

[Watt's  BibL  Brit— Cat.  of  Treasury  Papers, 
xxxvi.  38  ;  liv.  29.]  w.  a.  s.  h. 

EVICTION.  The  recovery  of  possession  of 
land  whether  by  simple  re-entry  or  by  legal 
process  is  often  termed  eviction.  Eviction  is 
substantially  the  same  as  Ejectment.  The 
term  is  rather  popular  than  technical,    r.  c.  M. 

EVOLUTION.     See  Development. 

EX.  ALL.  A  well-known  phrase  on  the 
stock  exchange,  used  to  signify  that  a  security 
quoted  or  dealt  in  conveys  to  the  buyer  no 
rights  in  the  shape  of  dividends  or  drawings 
or  issue  of  new  stock  or  other  contingent 
advantages.  The  word  ex.  is  simply  short  for 
excluding  (see  Ex.  Dividend,  Ex.  Draw^ing, 
Ex.  New).  a.  e. 

EXAMPLES,  Examples  in  economics,  as 
elsewhere,  are  simply  cases,  real  or  fictitious, 
or  partly  both,  supposed  to  embody  a  general 
principle.  They  may  be  classified  as  follows  : 
(1)  Real  hut  general,  as  Ricardo's  huntera 
{Principles,  ch.  i.  §  i.),  and  Ad.  Smith's 
bricklayers,  carpenters,  and  men  of  letters 
{Wealth  of  Nations,  I.  x.).  The  examples  are 
taken  from  a  known  genus  but  not  from  known 
individuals.  Where  the  genus  is  perfectly  well 
known,  no  cavil  is  possible.  Ad.  Smith's  illus- 
tration of  division  of  labour  could  hardly  have 
been  improved  by  a  reference  to  a  particular 
pin-making  establishment  in  a  specified  place. 
But,  in  exposition,  the  more  concrete  the  genus 
the  more  telling  the  example ;  e.g.  'blacksmith' 
seems  nearer  life  than  'workman.'  (2)  Real 
and.  particular,  as  in  Cairnes's  illustration  of 
the  theory  of  international  trade  from  the 
Australian  gold  discoveries  (see  Cairnes). 
Adam  Smith,  where  he  does  not  use  the  real 
and  general,  uses  the  real  and  particular,  and 
falls  back  on  fiction  only  for  his  similes  (as 
"the  highway,"  "the  waggonway  through  the 
air,"  the  "wings,"  and  "the  pond  and  the 
buckets,"  W.  of  N.,  II.  ii.),  or  his  metaphors 
(J' wheel  of  circulation,"  "channel  of  circula- 
tion.") Ricardo  and  his  immediate  followers 
have  preferred,  as  a  rule,  (3)  Fictitims  examples. 
These  may  be  illustrations  of  which  the  com- 


ponent elements  are  generically  well  known,  as 
even  the  favourite  "man  on  the  desert  island," 
but  the  combining  of  the  elements  is  the  work  of 
the  writer,  and  is  more  or  less  arbitrary,  as  De 
Quincey's  "man  with  the  musical  box  on  Lake 
Superior,"  and  Bastiat's  "plank  and  plane." 
There  is  also  a  risk  that  the  construction 
of  the  example  may  involve  a  begging  of  the 
question  to  be  proved.  "  Suppose  that  there 
are  but  two  nations  in  the  world  living  side  by 
side,  with  a  population  of  one  million  souls  in 
each"  (Barbour,  Bimetallism).  "My  object 
was  to  elucidate  principles,  and  to  do  this  I 
imagined  strong  cases  that  I  might  show  the 
operation  of  those  principles"  (Ricardo,  Letters). 
There  is  no  necessary  fallacy  in  this  method 
of  exposition  any  more  than  in  illustrating  the 
law  of  gravitation  by  the  action  of  bodies  in 
vacuo.  Concrete  cases  must  necessarily  ex- 
emplify much  more  than  one  principle,  and, 
even  if  they  suggested  a  particular  generalisa- 
tion, they  may  perhaps  not  clearly  illustrate  it 
without  a  fictitious  simplification.  The  lawful- 
ness of  such  a  method  of  exposition  or,  it  may 
be,  of  proof  is  discussed  elsewhere  (see  Deduc- 
tive Method).  j.  b. 

EXCAMBION  is  the  technical  term  used  in 
Scotch  law  to  designate  the  contract  whereby 
one  piece  of  land  is  exchanged  for  anotlier. 
The  persons  effecting  the  exchange  are  known 
as  excambers.  Each  party  gives  the  other  such 
a  warranty  of  title  that,  if  evicted  from  the" 
land  which  he  has  received,  he  and  his  heirs 
can  recover  from  the  other  party  and  his  heirs 
the  land  which  he  originally  gave.  When 
lands  burdened  with  debt  are  disponed  in 
excambion,  they  are  freed  from  that  debt  and 
are  thenceforward  burdened  with  the  debts, 
if  any,  formerly  afiecting  the  land  given  in 
exchange.  Tenants  in  tail  have  a  statutory 
power  of  effecting  such  exchanges  which  now 
extends  to  one-fourth  of  the  total  value  of  the 
property  entailed  (see  Land). 

[Bell's  Dictionary  and  Digest  of  the  Law  oj 
Scotland,  edited  by  George  Watson,  Edinburgh, 
1882,  art.  "Excambion,"  and  the  authorities 
therein  cited.]  F.  c.  M. 

EXCHANGE. 

Exchange,  p.  758 ;  Exchange,  Value  in,  759  ;  Exchange, 
Value  in  (History  of  Theory),  p.  762  ;  Exchange,  Usury 
(see  Usury),  p.  767 ;  Exchange  (as  Bourse),  p.  767 : 
Exchange,  Stock,  p.  768  ;  Exchange,  Provincial  Stock, 
p.  770 ;  Exchange,  Foreign,  p.  770  ;  Exchange,  Foreign 
(Practical  Working  of),  p.  772 ;  Exchange  between 
Holland  and  Dutch  India,  p.  773  ;  Exchange  between 
Great  Britain  and  British  India,  p.  776 ;  Exchange, 
Internal,  p.  777  ;  Exchange  of  Notes  (Scotland),  p.  778 ; 
Exchange  Broker,  p.  778  ;  Exchangei;  Royal,  p.  778. 

Exchange,  the  voluntary  giving  of  one  com- 
modity or  service  on  condition  of  receiving  an- 
other, is  to  a  great  extent  the  basis  of  the  exist- 
ing system  of  Production  and  Distribution 
{q.v.).  If  there  were  no  exchanges,  each  article 
of  separate  property  could  be  used  only  by  its 
owner,  and,  excluding  gifts,  slaveholding,  and 


EXCHANGE— EXCHANGE,  VALUE  IN 


759 


communistic  arrangements,  each  man  would 
have  to  subsist  on  what  he  could  produce 
directly  for  himself,  using  his  own  and  no  one 
else's  instruments  of  production.  As  things 
are,  however,  separate  property  is  used  in  the 
main  by  those  who  are  most  capable  of  using  it, 
whether  they  are  its  owners  or  not,  and  no  one 
lives  only  on  what  he  has  himself  produced  but 
each  lives  on  what  has  been  produced  by  a  vast 
number  of  other  persons  (see  Adam  Smith, 
Wealth  of  Nations,  bk.  i.  ch.  i.  at  end).  This 
is  the  result  of  exchanges  ;  owners  of  property 
allow  others  to  use  it  because  they  can  get 
commodities  and  services  in  exchange  for  the 
use  of  it,  and  men  are  able  to  devote  themselves 
exclusively  to  one  occupation  because  the  pro- 
ducts of  that  occupation  can  be  exchanged  for 
the  products  of  other  occupations.  While  pro- 
duction is  thus  largely  dependent  on  exchanges, 
distribution,  as  the  word  is  commonly  under- 
stood, could  not  exist  at  all  without  them. 
The  use  of  the  word  implies  that  the  whole 
produce  of  all  the  workers  is  considered  to  be 
a  joint  or  common  produce  which,  after  being 
produced,  has  to  be  divided  or  "distributed." 
If  each  man  lived  on  his  own  patch  of  ground, 
using  his  own  instruments,  and  receiving  no 
help  from  any  one  either  in  commodities  or 
services,  each  man's  produce  or  income  would 
obviously  be  quite  distinct  from  that  of  every 
other  person,  and  the  conception  of  a  joint  pro- 
duce requiring  to  be  distributed  would  never 
have  been  formed.  Individuals'  incomes  would 
vary,  but  the  variations  would  be  questions  of 
production  only,  since  each  man's  income  would 
depend  enthely  on  the  amount  he  produced. 
Exchange  being  practised,  questions  of  "dis- 
tribution "  arise  because  each  man's  income  de- 
pends not  only  on  how  much  he  produces  but 
also  on  the  value  of  what  he  has  to  sell,  i.e. 
on  how  much  of  certain  other  things  he  can 
get  in  exchange  for  a  given  quantity  of  his 
work  or  of  the  use  of  his  property. 

Adam  Smith  showed  a  very  fair  appreciation 
of  the  importance  of  exchange  with  regard  both 
to  production  and  distribution.  He  rightly 
attributed  what  he  called  the  "  dirision  of 
labour,"  but  what  is  now  usually  called  the 
"division  of  employments,"  to  the  practice  of 
exchange,  and  he  did  not  treat  of  wages,  profits, 
and  rents,  till  he  had  discussed  "the  rules 
which  men  naturally  observe  in  exchanging" 
goods  {Wealth  of  Natiom,  bk.  i,  ch.  iv.) 
Unfortunately,  James  Mill,  to  whom  the  com- 
mon arrangement  of  English  works  on  political 
economy  is  chiefly  due,  seems  to  have  had  no 
adequate  conception  of  the  importance  of  ex- 
change. He  spoke  of  it  as  if  it  were  a  mere 
incident  which  occasionally  happens  to  com- 
modities after  they  have  been  produced  and 
distributed  {Elements  of  Political  Economy,  In- 
troduction), and  when  he  endeavoured  to  im- 
prove upon  J.  B.   Say's  division  of  political 


economy  into  Production,  Distribution,  and 
Consumption,  by  inserting  Exchange,  or  "Inter- 
change "  as  he  called  it,  he  placed  it  not  only 
after  production,  but  after  distribution  also. 
M'CuUoch  returned  to  Say's  arrangement,  but 
J.  S.  Mill  followed  in  his  father's  footsteps, 
treating  exchange  after  distribution,  and  declar- 
ing distinctly  that  "  exchange  and  money  make 
no  difference  in  the  law  of  wages,  in  the  law  of 
rent,  nor  in  the  law  of  profits  "  {Principles,  bk. 
iii.  ch.  xxvi..  Contents).  But  so  far  is  this 
from  being  the  case  that  the  very  existence  of 
wages,  rent,  and  profits,  including  interest,  is 
dependent  upon  exchange.  The  payment  of 
any  particular  sum  of  wages,  rent,  or  profits 
is  a  case  of  exchange,  and  every  variation 
in  wages,  rent,  and  profits  is  a  variation  of 
value,  wages  being  the  value  of  work  done, 
rent  the  value  of  the  use  of  land,  and  profits, 
the  value  of  the  use  of  capital  and  of  the 
capitalist's  services  (see  Sidgwick,  Principles  of 
Political  Economy,  bk.  ii.  ch.  i.  §  2).  Of 
wi'iters  since  J.  S.  Mill,  most  have  so  far  devi- 
ated from  his  arrangement  as  to  place  "ex- 
change" before  "distribution,"  e.g.  Walker, 
{Political  Economy),  or,  with  Prof's.  Sidgwick 
and  Marshall,  to  treat  exchange  and  distribu- 
tion as  too  intimately  connected  to  be  treated 
separately  (see  Distribution).  e.  c. 

Exchange,  Value  in.  Yalue  in  exchange, 
or  exchangeable  value,  denotes  a  ratio  of  ex- 
change—  "the  ratio  of  the  number  of  units 
of  one  commodity  to  the  number  of  units  of 
another  commodity  for  which  it  exchanges  "  ; 
as  Jevons  particularly  clearly  points  out  ( Theoiy 
of  Political  Economy,  ch.  iv.),  and  most  authori- 
ties admit.  The  unsettled  question  is  :  What 
are  the  circumstances  which  cause  the  ratio  to 
be  what  it  is  ?  "  Utility  and  difficulty  of  attain- 
ment," answers  Mill  (bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.),  and  similar 
terms  are  used  by  almost  all  economists,  but  in 
various  shades  of  meaning,  and  with  different 
emphasis  on  each  of  the  two  factors.  The 
confusion  is  aggravated  by  the  not  sufficiently 
noticed  circumstance  that  the  operation  of  the 
two  causes,  utility  and  difficulty,  is  different  in 
different  classes  of  transactions.  It  is  proposed 
here  to  discriminate  those  essentially  distinct 
cases  ;  mapping  out  and  partially  exploring 
the  ground,  which  may  be  more  fully  investi- 
gated under  the  head  Value. 

A  convenient  tripartite  division — Two-sided 
monopoly,  one-sided  monopoly  (or  one-sided 
competition),  two-sided  competition — is  based 
upon  the  degree  in  which  competition  is  present. 

I.  The  action  of  competition  is  at  a  minimiim 
where  the  dealers  in ,  two  articles  exchanged  are 
single  individuals,  or  bodies  of  persons  actuated 
by  one  will,  e.g.  two  governments  negotiating  a 
commercial  treaty,  or  a  trade -union  coming  to 
an  agreement  with  a  combination  of  masters 
about  the  rate  of  wages.  The  general  principle 
in  this  case  is  that  both  parties  will  be  gainers 


760 


EXCHANGE  VALUE,  IN 


by  the  bargain  ;  in  technical  language  the 
total  utility  (see  Consumer's  Rent,  Demand, 
DupuiT,  Final  Utility),  of  each  will  be 
greater  after  than  without  the  transaction. 
But  to  what  extent  each  party  will  be  gainers  is 
not  in  general  determinate  ;  there  is  a  scftt  of 
indefinite  tract,  a  "spielraum"  (Bohm-Bawerk), 
within  which  the  point  of  equilibrium  must  be 
determined  by  other  than  purely  economic  con- 
siderations. Jevons  well  says  :  "the  existence 
of  combinations  in  trade  disputes  usually  re- 
duces them  to  a  single  contract  bargain  of  the 
same  [this]  indeterminate  kind.  The  men,  for 
instance,  ask  for  15  per  cent  advance  of  wages 
all  round.  Rather  than  have  a  strike,  it  might 
be  for  the  interest  of  the  employers  to  give  the 
advance,  or  for  the  men  to  withdraw  their 
demand  ;  a  fortiori,  any  intermediate  arrange- 
ment, would  still  more  meet  their  views.  But 
there  may  be  absolutely  no  economic  principle 
on  which  to  decide  the  question.  Mathematic- 
ally speaking,  the  problem  is  an  indeterminate 
one  and  must  be  decided  by  importing  new 
conditions"  {State  in  Relation  to  Labour,  p. 
154). 

II.  Where  there  is  a  monopolist,  sole  or 
corporate,  on  the  one  side,  and  on  the  other  side 
an  indefinite  number  of  buyers,  or  sellers, 
competing  with  each  other,  the  most  general 
principle  is  that  the  monopolist  will  beat  down 
the  other  parties  to  the  point  at  which  each  of 
them  is  only  just  a  gainer  by  his  bargain  ;  the 
addition  to  the  total  utility  of  each  will  be  a 
minimum.  The  "law  of  indifference"  that 
there  should  be  one  price  in  a  market  is  not  in 
general  true  of  monopoly.  The  oppressiveness 
of  the  monopolist  is  modified  by  regard  for  his 
own  future  interests,  as  when  an  American 
railway  company  "builds  up"  a  customer  by 
giving  him  favourable  terms,  by  fear  of  com- 
petition and  of  public  opinion,  and  other  con- 
siderations not  here  relevant  (see  Monopoly). 

Mere  convenience  will  often  prompt  the 
monopolist,  instead  of  making  separate  terms  in 
each  transaction,  as  theoretically  conceivable, 
to  prescribe  rates  for  classes  of  persons  and  goods. 
These  charges  are  not  in  general  proportioned 
to  the  cost  incurred.  Thus  soldiers,  in  some 
foreign  theatres,  are  admitted  at  a  different  rate 
from  citizens  ;  though  the  accommodation  of  the 
former  may  be  as  good  as  that  of  the  latter. 
The  differences  between  first  and  third  class 
passenger  fares,  and  between  the  rates  for 
different  kinds  of  goods,  do  not  correspond  to  the 
outlay  of  the  company  in  each  case.  For  the 
object  of  the  monopolist  is  to  render  his  net 
profits  a  maximum  ;  and  this  result  wiU  not  in 
general  be  reached  by  apportioning  charge  to 
cost.  True,  if  the  cost  changes,  the  arrange- 
ment most  advantageous  to  the  monopolist  is  apt 
thereby  to  be  disturbed,  and  accordingly  the 
charge  will  be  in  general  altered,  but  not  pro- 
portionately to  the  cost.     Thus  a  tax  on  a  mono- 


polised article  will  in  general  increase  the  price, 
yet  not  equally  with  the  tax,  but,  as  it  happens, 
by  either  more  or  less  (Cournot,  ThAorie  MathA- 
matique,  ch.  vi.);  the  assertion  which  is  often 
made  that  the  charge  will  be  unaffected  by  the 
tax  is  true  only  where  the  tax  is  a  lump  sum, 
not  of  a  specific  or  an  ad  valorem  tax. 

In  the  case  of  monopoly  then  value  is  not 
measured  by  cost ;  but  it  is  measured  by  utility : 
by  total  utility  in  case  the  monopolist  takes  the 
full  advantage  of  his  position  ;  by  final  utility 
in  the  more  usual  case,  where  a  rate  is  fixed  for 
a  class  of  commodities.  In  that  case  each 
consumer  will  go  on  purchasing  up  to  the  point 
at  which  it  is  just  not  worth  his  while  to  pur- 
chase another  unit  of  commodity  at  the  prevail- 
ing price. 

III.  The  most  general,  or  at  least  the  most 
frequently  treated,  case  is  where  there  is  un- 
limited competition  on  both  sides  of  the  market. 
This  case  may  be  subdivided  into  two :  A,  where 
value  is  not  measured  by  cost  of  production, 
and  B,  where  it  is. 

A,  the  first  subdivision,  corresponds  to  what 
Mill  calls  the  "law  of  value  anterior  to  cost  of 
production,  and  more  fundamental,  the  law  of 
demand  and  supply  "  (see  Mill,  Political  Economy 
bk.  iii.  ch.  xvi.  §  1,  and  Prof.  Marshall's 
criticism  of  the  passage ;  Principles,  p.  544,  2nd 
edition).  This  case  may  be  subdivided  into 
two :  (1)  where  production,  or  at  least  repro- 
duction is  impossible,  or  may  be  left  out  of 
account ;  (2)  where  this  abstraction  is  not 
admissible. 

(Al).  To  this  head  belong  market  values — not 
only  commodities  which  cannot  be  multiplied 
rapidly,  but  also  those  of  which  the  quantity  in 
existence  cannot  be  diminished  rapidly,  namely 
the  precious  metals  in  circulation  (Mill,  bk.  iii. 
ch.  ii.  §  5).  Prof.  Marshall  gives  an  instruc- 
tive general  type  of  the  "temporary  equilibrium" 
of  market  value ;  unaffected  by  cost*  of  production 
which  requires  a  "long  period"  in  order  to 
influence  value  {Principles,  bk.  v.  ch.  ii.). 

Other  articles  referred  by  Mill  to  this  category 
are  "  ancient  sculptures,  pictures  by  old  masters, 
rare  books  or  coins,  or  other  articles  of  anti- 
quarian curiosity"  {Political  Economy,  bk.  iii. 
ch.  ii.  §  2).  Compare  Prof.  Marshall's  enumer- 
ation of  articles  in  the  case  of  which  "  there  is 
no  connection  between  cost  of  reproduction 
and  price"  (at  the  end  of  the  chapter  last 
referred  to). 

Mill  adds  to  his  list  of  such  articles  "building 
grounds  in  a  town  of  definite  extent  (such  as 
Venice),  the  most  desirable  sites  in  any  town 
whatever  .  .  .  potentially  all  land  whatever " 
{loc.  cit.).  It  should  seem  that  his  limitation 
of  the  statement  to  the  case  of  "  countries  fully 
occupied  and  cultivated,"  is  unnecessary.  But 
it  is  impossible  here  adequately  to  discuss 
all  the  difficulties  which  the  subject  presents. 

It  is  a  nice  question  whether  it  is  proper  tc 


EXCHANGE,  VALUE  IN 


761 


include  in  this  section  (Al)  the  exchange  of 
present  goods  for  future  (cp.  Bbhm-Bawerk, 
Positive  Theory),  the  settling  of  the  rate  of 
interest.  Mill  says  "this  is  evidently  a  question 
of  demand  and  supply  "  used  in  the  same  as  in 
the  preceding  cases  (Political  Economy,  iii. 
ch.  xxiii.  §  1).  It  is  usual,  however,  to  regard 
the  "sacrifice"  incuired  by  postponing  consump- 
tion as  a  mode  of  cost;  and  so  not  to  be  included 
in  this  section. 

(A2)  To  this  class  belong  "commodities  of 
which,  though  capable  of  being  increased  or 
diminished  to  a  great  extent,  the  value  never 
depends  upon  anything  but  demand  and  supply" 
in  a  sense  opposed  to  determination  by  cost  of 
production  (Mill,  bk.  iii.  ch.  ii. ,  last  paragraph). 
Perhaps  the  most  typical  case  under  this  head 
is  international  trade,  where  in  Cairnes's  phrase 
(Leading  Principles,  bk.  iii.  ch.  iv.  §  4),  cost 
"controls"  but  does  not  "determine"  value; 
in  the  terms  above  used  with  respect  to  mono- 
poly affects,  but  does  not  measure,  value.  Thus 
suppose  tea  produced  in  China  exchanges  for 
cutlery  made  in  England.  There  is  no  equation 
between  the  efforts  and  sacrifices  of  the  Chinese 
and  the  British  producer.  For  the  mobility 
tending  to  produce  that  equation  is  wanting. 
As  an  additional  verification  that  value  is  not 
proportioned  to  cost  in  this  case,  it  may  be 
observed  that  if  the  cost  of  production  be  altered, 
e.g.  by  an  improvement  or  a  tax,  the  value  in 
the  international  market  will  be  altered  indeed, 
but  not  in  proportion  to  the  alteration  of  the 
cost  (Mill,  bk.  iii.  ch.  xviii.  §  5,  and  bk.  v. 
ch.  iv.  §  6). 

The  cognate  case  of  "  non-competing  groups  " . 
(Cairnes)  is  amenable  to  the  same  law.  The 
labour-market  (cp.  Mill,  bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.  last 
par.)  forms  a  particularly  important  instance 
— so  far  as  it  is  legitimate  to  abstract  efforts 
and  sacrifices  incurred  with  a  view  to  prepara- 
tion for  that  market  (see  below,  p.  762,  col.  1, 
par.  3). 

Throughout  the  whole  class  of  transactions 
which  have  been  considered  (A)  there  is  wanting 
that  adjustment  between  remuneration  and  effort 
and  sacrifice  which  is  the  essence  of  the  classical 
doctrine  that'  cost  of  production  determines 
value.  Up  to  this  point  those  who  have 
impugned  or  ignored  that  doctrine  are  correct. 

(B)  A  transition  from  the  regime  of  "non- 
competing  groups, "  to  "industrial  competition" 
(Cairnes)  is  obtained  by  supposing  removed 
the  barriers  which  have  prevented  competition. 
There  ensues  with  the  mobility  of  industry  the 
equation  of  "net  advantages"  (Marshall)  in 
different  occupations.  It  will  be  convenient  to 
break  up  class  B  in  two :  (1)  where  abstraction 
is  made  of  division  of  labour  ;  (2)  more  concrete. 

(Bl)  Suppose  each  worker  free  to  apply  hia 
labour  in  doses,  or  increments,  to  any  industry^ 
— the  abstract  supposition  implicitly  made  by 
Jevons  in  his  analysis  of  labour  (7%<;(//7/,  ch.  vi.). 


No  one  will  work  in  any  branch  beyond  the 
point  at  which  the  trouble  attending  the  last 
increment  of  product  is  just  compensated  by  its 
remuneration.  In  this  case  then  it  becomes 
true  that  value  is  measured  by  the  final  disutility 
of  the  producer  ;  while  it  does  not  cease  to  be 
true  that,  as  in  former  cases,  value  is  measured 
by  the  final  utility  of  the  consumer.  There  is 
no  opposition  between  these  verities  ;  one  need 
not  be  subordinated  to  the  other. 

In  this  case  the  relation  between  the  two 
factors  of  value,  utility  and  disutility,  is  almost 
as  symmetrical  as  in  what  Prof  Marshall  calls 
"the  simplest  case  of  equilibrium  between  desire 
and  effort  when  a  person  satisfies  one  of  his 
wants  by  his  own  direct  action,  as  for  instance 
when  he  picks  blackberries.  .  .  .  After  he  has 
eaten  a  good  deal  the  desire  for  more  diminishes, 
while  the  task  of  picking  begins  to  cause 
weariness  which  at  last  counterbalances  the 
desire  for  eating,  and  equilibrium  is  reached." 
(Principles,  bk.  v.  ch.  iii.  §  1).  In  such  a  case 
the  question  whether  it  was  the  desire,  or  the 
weariness,  which  "determined,"  or  "regulated" 
the  equilibrium  would  be  insignificant. 

The  "fundamental  symmetry"  (Marshall) 
between  the  forces  of  demand  and  supply  is 
aptly  represented  by  mechanical  illustrations. 
"Justin  the  same  way,  when  several  balls  are 
lying  in  a  bowl,  they  mutually  determine  one 
another's  positions  ;  and  again,  when  a  heavy 
weight  is  suspended  by  several  elastic  strings  of 
different  strengths  and  lengths,  the  equilibrium 
positions  of  all  the  strings  and  the  weight 
mutually  determine  one  another "  (Marshall, 
Principles,  bk.  vi.  ch.  i.).  The  principle  that 
water  seeks  its  own  level  has  been  employed  by 
Dr.  Irving  Fisher  in  his  masterly  Investigations 
in  the  Theory  of  Value  and  Prices  (from  Trans- 
actions of  Connecticut  Academy,  vol.  ix.,  July 
1892)  to  construct  a  more  elaborate  illustration 
of  the  great  principle  thus  enounced  by  Cournot, 
"  Le  systeme  economique  est  un  ensemble  dont 
toutes  les  parties  se  tiennent  et  reagissent  les 
unes  sur  les  autres." 

What  has  been  said  of  the  relation  of  dis- 
utility to  value  applies  equally,  or  even  better, 
to  the  "sacrifice"  of  postponing  consumption. 
As  Prof.  J.  B.  Clark  well  says  (Yale  Review, 
No.  3),  "  the  final  act  of  abstinence  is  like  the 
last  act  of  labour,  the  costliest  of  all "... 
"the  cost  entailed  on  society  by  its  final  acts 
of  abstinence  is  a  second  possible  measure  of 
value."  It  may  be  observed  that  the  abstrac- 
tion proper  to  this  section  (Bl)  is  not  so  violent 
in  the  case  of  capital  as  labour.  The  idea  of  a 
capitalist  distributing  his  outlay  among  differ- 
ent enterprises,  from  each  of  which  ceteris  pari- 
bus he  will  expect  a  similar  return — is  one  that 
is  partially  realised  in  the  "share"  market. 
Compare  Cournot,  PriTwipes  de  la  Theorie  dea 
Michesses,  1863,  Art.  45. 

(B2)  The  "fundamental  symmetry"  between 


762 


EXCHANGE,  VALUE  IN  (HISTORY  OF  THEORY) 


utility  and  disutility  as  factors  of  value,  continues 
to  subsist  when  we  restore  the  concrete  circum- 
stance of  division  of  labour.  But  superficial 
differences  arise.  The  individual  may  be  con- 
ceived as  seeking  to  maximise  his  total  utility, 
per  saltum  by  a  change  of  occupations,  rather 
than  by  doses  distributed  at  different  points  of 
the  industrial  system.  The  equation  of  "net 
advantages"  in  different  occupations,  rather 
than  of  final  disutilities,  is  now  the  condition. 
But  the  analogy  of  physical  equilibrium  is  still 
appropriate.  ' '  The  normal  value  of  everything 
rests,  like  the  keystone  of  an  arch,  balanced 
between  the  contending  pressures  on  its  two 
opposing  sides.  The  forces  of  demand  press  on 
the  one  side,  those  of  supply  on  the  other" 
(Marshall).  We  must  regard  "the  various 
elements  of  an  economic  problem — not  as  deter- 
mining one  another  in  a  chain  of  causation — 
A  determining  B,  B  determining  C,  and  so  on 
— but  as  all  mutually  determining  one  another" 
{jMd.  preface  to  1st  ed.,  p.  xiv.). 

To  rightly  apprehend  the  relation  between 
value  and  cost  of  production  it  should  be  con- 
sidered that  one  occupation  may  comprise 
several  commodities.  The  production  of  dif- 
ferent articles  has  been  joined  together  by  nature 
or  custom.  It  would  be  idle  to  expect  the  value 
of  beef  and  hides  to  be  respectively  proportioned 
CO  the  quantity  of  labour  "worked  up"  (Ricardo) 
or  "  congealed  "  (Marx)  in  each.  A  person  who 
chooses  a  literary  or  academic  career  may  hope 
to  be,  on  the  whole,  as  well  off  in  that  as  in 
any  other  line  open  to  him  ;  but  he  must  not 
expect  the  pay  of  each  particular  task — e.g. 
writing  an  article,  or  giving  a  lecture — to  be 
proportioned  to  the  trouble  (cp.  Mill  on  Sub- 
sidiary Industries,  bk.  ii.  ch.  xiv.,  and  see 
Joint  Production). 

The  sense  in  which  value,  in  the  case  under 
consideration  (B2),  is  determined  by  cost  of 
production,  as  well  as  marginal  utility,  appears 
to  the  present  writer  to  have  been  best  stated 
by  Prof.  Marshall.  Besides  showing  the  inter- 
dependence of  the  two  factors,  as  above  men- 
tioned, he  also  makes  it  clear  that  time,  "  a 
long  period,"  is  required  in  order  that  the 
forces  of  supply  should  work  themselves  out. 
Thus  in  the  case  of  labour  the  adjustment  be- 
tween cost  and  value  must  be  dated  from  the 
time  when  parents  begin  to  make  efforts  and 
sacrifices  with  a  view  to  the  education  and 
advancement  of  their  children.  There  is  pre- 
sented the  vast  conception  of  trained  industry  put 
upon  a  future  labour-market,  by  parental  pro- 
vidence, for  vicarious  remuneration. 

But  perhaps  no  form  of  words  devised  by  one 
person  can  be  expected  to  recommend  itself  to 
all  others  as  the  best  adapted  to  express  the 
subtle  relations  of  utility  and  cost  to  value. 
As  in  higher  spheres  of  speculation,  it  may  be 
hoped  that  differences  of  doctrine  are  less 
important  than  at  first  sight  would  appear. 


[As  to  the  indeterminateness  of  the  bargain 
between  two  individual  or  corporate  units,  see 
Auspitz  and  Lieben,  Theorie  des  Preises,  p.  381. 
— Bdhm-Bawerk,  Positive  Theory  (translated  by 
W.  Smart),  bk.  iv.  ch.  ii. — Edgeworth,  Mathe- 
matical Psychics,  p.  21,  et  seg'.  —  Jevons,  Theory  oj 
Political  Economy,  pp.  130-137,  and  Marshall, 
Principles  of  Economics,  p.  715  ;  Mathematical 
Appendix,  Note  xii. — Menger,  Grundsatze,  pp.  176- 
178. — Price,  Industrial  Peace,  pp.  14  and  54. — 
Sidgwick,  Political  Economy,  bk.  ii.  ch.  x.  §  S 
(end),  also  p.  349. 

On  the  abstract  theory  of  monopoly,  see  Coumot, 
Principes  Mathhnatiques,  chs.  v.  and  vi.  et  passim. 
— Hadley,  Railway  Transportation,  a.nd  other  books 
and  reports  relating  to  railways. — Marshall,  Prin- 
ciples of  Economics,  bk.  v. 

The  authorities  on  the  more  general  case  of  value 
in  exchange  defy  quotation  by  their  number. 
Those  to  whom  the  present  writer  is  most  indebted 
have  been  mentioned  in  the  text.]  F.  T.  E. 

Exchange,  Value  in.  History  of 
Growth  of  Theory.  For  the  purpose  of  an 
elementary  survey  of  the  history  of  the  theory 
of  value  we  may  roughly  divide  the  various 
theorists  into  two  "schools"  —  the  "  cost -of - 
production"  school  and  the  "utility"  school. 
The  "cost"  school  is  the  older;  its  sway 
over  our  science  has  only  begun  to  be  broken 
in  the  last  few  decades  by  the  "  utility  "  school, 
the  earliest  quite  consistent  representatives  ol 
which  wrote  in  the  middle  of  this  century. 

The  "  cost -of -production"  school. — The  first 
step  towards  an  analysis  of  the  economic  pheno- 
menon of  value  consisted  in  a  discrimination 
between  value  in  use  and  value  in  exchange. 
Aristotle  makes  this  important  distinction : 
"To  take  e.g.  a  shoe,  there  is  its  use  as  a 
covering  of  the  foot,  and  also  its  use  as  an 
article  of  exchange"  {PoliL,  i.  9,  p.  22  of 
Welldon's  Transl.).  His  example  is  followed, 
among  English  economic  thinkers,  by  Locke 
("Considerations  of  the  lowering  of  interest 
and  raising  the  value  of  money,"  in  Works, 
ed.  1714,  ii.  p.  21)  in  the  end  of  the  17th, 
and  by  Hutcheson  (System  of  Moral  Philo- 
sophy, 1755,  ii.  p.  53)  in  the  middle  of  the 
18th  century.  Locke,  I.e.,  speaks  of  "the 
intrinsic  natural  worth  of  anything,"  as  separ- 
ate from  its  "value";  and  Hutcheson,  I.e.,  ob- 
serves that  "  the  prices  and  values  in  commerce 
do  not  at  all  follow  the  real  use  or  importance 
,  of  goods  for  the  support  .  .  .  of  life."  French 
physiocrats  (e.g.  Dupont  and  Quesnay),  speak 
of  valeur  usuelle  and  valeur  venale;  and  Turgot 
distinguishes  between  valeur  estimative  and 
valeur  commer^ahle  or  echangeable,  defining 
the  first  as  a  purely  individual,  the  second  as 
an  essentially  social  mode  of  weighing  the 
sacrifice,  necessary  in  order  to  get  possession  of 
the  commodity,  against  the  enjoyment  of 
possessing  it.  English  economic  treatises  of 
the  18th  century  sometimes  show  an  apprecia- 
tion of  the  diflerence  between  use  value  and 


EXCHANGE,  VALUE  IN  (HISTORY  OF  THEORY) 


763 


exchange  value  by  discriminating  between  the 
vords  "worth"  and  "value." 

When  Adam  Smith  wrote  his  Wealth  of 
nations,  he  made  this  old  primary  analysis  of 
value  the  basis  of  further  analysis.  He  first 
hints  that  "things"  must  have  some  "value 
in  use"  in  order  to  have  any  "value  in  ex- 
change,'' and  then  for  a  time  entirely  drops 
"value  in  use"  out  of  the  discussion,  proceed- 
ing to  investigate  "what  is  the  real  measure 
of  this  exchangeable  value  ;  or,  wherein  consists 
the  real  price  of  all  commodities, "  and  ' '  what 
are  the  different  parts  of  which  this  real  price 
is  composed  or  made  up  "  (bk.  i.  ch.  iv.  p.  42, 
ed.  1793).  He  does  not  explicitly  treat  the  pro- 
blem :  How  does  value  measure  men's  desires 
to  possess,  or  consume,  commodities  ?  This 
significant  feature  is,  however,  to  be  found 
among  the  French  physiocrats.  Turgot — 
("  Valeurs  et  Monnaies,"  in  (Euvres,  ed.  Daire, 
vol.  i.  p.  83)  says:  "For  an  isolated  individual, 
the  valeur  estimative  of  an  object  is  precisely 
that  portion  of  his  total  faculties  (la  portion  die 
total  de  ses  facultes),  which  corresponds  to  his 
desire  for  the  object,  or  which  he  is  willing  to 
employ  in  order  to  satisfy  this  desire."  Adam 
Smith  proceeds  (comp.  bk.  i.  ch.  iv.  and 
ch.  vii.)  to  discuss  "the  different  circumstances 
which  sometimes  raise  some  or  all  of  these 
different  parts  of  price  above,  and  sometimes 
sink  them  below  their  natural  and  ordinary 
rate,"  i.e.  their  cost  of  production  —  or  "the 
whole  value  of  the  rent,  labour,  and  profit,  which 
must  be  paid  in  order  to  bring  "  the  commodity 
to  market.  Here  he  looks  at  the  problem 
chiefly  from  the  point  of  view  of  the  seller,  as 
if  exchange  were  regulated  almost  exclusively 
by  estimates  of  labour  or  cost.  In  this  con- 
nection he  uses  "worth"  and  "cost"  as  iden- 
tical terms.  The  manner  in  which  Adam 
Smith  treated  this  question  gave  rise  to  that 
school  of  economic  thinking  which  (to  use  the 
phrase  of  Professor  Nicholson,  art.  "Value" 
in  Ihicy.  Brit.)  regards  utility  "simply  as  a 
kind  of  entrance  examination  which  every 
commodity  must  pass  to  enter  the  list  of 
valuables,  whilst  the  place  in  the  list  is  deter- 
mined by  variations  in  the  degree  of  the 
difficulty  of  attainment." 

Ricardo  states:  "Utility  then  is  not  the 
measure  of  exchangeable  value,  although  it  is 
absolutely  essential  to  it"  {Principles,  ed. 
Gonner,  p.  5).  Elsewhere  (pp.  7,  8),  Ricardo 
speaks  of  labour  as  the  "foundation  of  the 
exchangeable  value,"  and  of  "quantity  of  labour 
realised  in"  commodities  "  as  "regulating  their 
exchangeable  value." 

Mai  thus  {Principles,  ed.  1820,  p.  52)  sees 
that  value  in  exchange  "does  not  depend 
merely  upon  the  scarcity  in  which  commodities 
exist  .  .  .  but  upon  the  circumstance  of  their 
not  being  distributed  ...  in  such  quantities 
to  each  as  the  wills  and  powers  of  individuals 


will  enable  them  ultimately  to  effect  by  means 
of  exchanges."  He  does  not,  however,  search 
further  into  the  relation  between  "such 
quantities  "  and  their  value  in  use.  This  latter 
term  he  describes  in  his  Definitions  (ed.  1827, 
p.  234)  as  being  "synonymous  with  utility. 
It  rarely  occurs  in  political  economy,  and  is 
never  implied  by  the  word  value  when  used 
alone. " 

J.  S.  Mill  emphasises  more  strongly  than 
his  predecessors  the  importance  of  the  play  of 
supply  and  demand  in  determining  exchange 
value.  He,  however,  retains  Ricardo's  notion 
of  two  laws  of  value  :  one  for  commodities  that 
"are  susceptible  of  being  multiplied  at  pleasure," 
and  another  for  commodities  that  are  not. 
These  latter,  "no  doubt,  are  exceptions,"  and 
it  is  for  these  latter  that  he  conceives  his 
supply-and- demand  theory  of  value  {Principles, 
bk.  iii.  ch.  ii.). 

Karl  Marx,  the  founder  of  German  social 
democracy,  seeks,  on  the  lines  of  Hegelian 
dialectics,  to  separate  value  in  use  totally  from 
value  in  exchange.  The  latter  is  "something 
quite  independent "  of  value  in  use  ;  and  an  in- 
vestigation of  value  in  use  may  be  of  some  good 
in  commercial  education,  as  ' '  die  Disciplin  der 
Waarenkunde, "  but  does  not  belong  to  economic 
science,  though  ' '  nothing  can  have  exchange 
value  without  being  a  thing  of  utility  "  {Das 
Kapital,  ed.  1883,  pp.  2  and  8).  Exchange 
value,  Marx  continues,  is  a  ratio,  and  as  where 
there  is  a  ratio  there  must  be  homogeneity,  he 
arrives  at  the  conclusion  that  commodities  can 
only  be  homogeneous  as  products  of  human 
labour.  This,  therefore,  determines  value. 
Marx's  theories,  though  they  have  never  been 
accepted  by  any  economist  of  note,  are  worth 
consideration,  partly  because  of  their  enormous 
influence  on  socialistic  workmen  in  different 
parts  of  the  world ;  partly  because  they  un- 
doubtedly disi)lay  some  of  the  worst  conse- 
quences of  consistently  neglecting  to  analyse 
consumption  or  demand  as  carefully  as  pro- 
duction or  supply. 

Turning  to  the  French,  German,  and  other 
Continental  theorists  of  the  cost-of- production 
school,  we  find  that,  with  few  exceptions,  they 
have  been  far  more  disposed  to  devote  attention 
to  the  utility  element  of  value  in  exchange  than 
the  "classic"  English  school  from  Smith  to 
Fawcett.  Though  there  are  most  important 
scientific  divergences  between  the  majority  of 
19th  century  German  economists  and  the  new 
"Austrian  school,"  it  is  still  by  no  means 
difficult  to  look  upon  the  former  as  slowly  and 
laboriously  paving  the  way  for  the  latter. 

J.  B.  Say  indicated  {Traits,  ed.  1803,  ii.  p. 
58)  that  the  fundamental  elements  of  value  in 
exchange  were,  the  quantities  offered  and  de- 
manded, and  the  expense  of  production,  which 
latter  he  called  "  the  natm-al  value  "  of  the  com- 
modity.    He  set  the  example  for  later  French 


764 


EXCHANGE,  VALUE  IN  (HISTORY  OF  THEORY) 


economists  of  treating  the  value  problem  as 
essentially  dealing  with  the  laws  which  deter- 
mine when  and  how  ''utilities"  exchange 
against  one  another.  "No  doubt  what  deter- 
mines us  to  give  up  a  commodity  which  we 
possess  in  order  to  get  another  is  some  q»ality 
in  this  other  commodity  which  pleases  us,  and 
which  quality  is  not  to  be  found,  or  to  be 
found  only  in  less  amount  (a  moindre  dose) 
in  the  commodity  which  we  give  in  exchange  " 
(Coquelin  and  Guillaumin,  Did.  de  V^c.  Pol., 
1853,  vol.  ii.  p.  808) — this,  and  not  the  cost  of 
production,  is  the  starting  point  of  most  French 
discussions  of  value.  J.  Garnier's  definition 
{TraU6  d'J^e.  Pol,  ed.  1889,  p.  280)  :  "things 
have  value  in  exchange  when  they  are  useful 
and,  at  the  same  time,  transferable  and  scarce  ; 
that  is  to  say,  value  in  exchange  is  exchangeable 
utility,  corresponding  to  the  amount  of  labour 
which  the  thing  saves,  and,  in  most  cases, 
owing  its  existence  to  labour  and  other  ex- 
penses," is  characteristic  of  the  standpoint  of 
many  French  economists.  An  exception  from 
the  general  French  attitude  is  F.  Bastiat, 
notable  not  so  much  for  solid  scientific  merits 
as  for  a  widespread  popularity.  He  defines 
value  in  exchange  as  "the  proportion  (rapport) 
between  two  services  exchanged"  (Harmonies 
Ji!conomiqties,  ed.  1851,  p.  118). 

Among  most  German  economists  of  this  cen- 
tuiy  there  is  a  tendency  to  treat  utility  as  of 
at  least  equal  importance  with  cost  of  produc- 
tion in  the  determination  of  exchange  value, 
"The  value  in  exchange  of  a  commodity,  or  its 
suitableness  for  the  purpose  of  being  exchanged 
against  other  commodities,  depends  upon  that 
combination  between  use-value  and  cost-value 
which  has  its  rise  in  the  economic  relations 
of  men  one  with  another,"  writes  W.  Roscher 
in  his  System  der  VolJcswirthschaft,  ed.  1882,  i. 
p.  10.  And  Schaffle  defines  value  in  exchange  as 
"a  disguised  comparison  between  the  cost- values 
and  the  use- values  of  the  two  commodities  which 
are  to  be  exchanged  against  each  other"  (Kapital- 
ismus  und  Sodalismus,  p.  35).  In  his  Bau  und 
Leben  des  sodalen  Korpers,  ed.  1878,  iii.  p.  279, 
the  same  writer  shows  that  exchange  value  is 
at  the  same  time  an  individual  and  a  social 
phenomenon.  Adolph  Wagner  (Allgem.  od. 
theoret.  Volksw.,  Thl.  I.,  Grundlegung,  ed. 
1876,  p.  47)  says  that  "the  exchange  value 
of  a  commodity  depends,  for  the  individual 
who  demands  it,  upon  its  degree  of  concrete 
utility  for  him,  and  upon  the  difl&culty  of 
getting  it."  Wagner  is  careful  to  observe  that 
value  in  use  is  "the  foundation  of  aU  the 
estimates"  which  determine  exchange  value, 
and  that  difficulty  of  attainment  is  an  incident 
which,  though  in  most  cases  present,  can  by 
no  means  be  used  exclusively  for  the  definition 
of  exchange  value.  The  position  of  the  majority 
of  living  German  economists  is  also  well  repre- 
sented by  Professor  Neumann  in  Schonberg's 


Handh.  d.  Pol.  OeTc.,  ed.  1885,  vol.  i.  p.  156, 
etc.  He  proposes  to  abandon  the  phrasea 
"value  in  use"  and  "value  in  exchange"  as 
not  sufficiently  emphasising  the  all-important 
personal  element  in  value.  The  essential  thing 
in  all  the  varying  meanings  of  value  (  Werth)  is 
"the  estimate  (Beurtheilung)  of  the  usefulness 
or  fitness  of  a  thing  for  human  interests,  wants, 
or  aims."  Neumann,  however,  does  not  enter 
into  any  far-reaching  examination  of  the  rela- 
tions between  his  subjective  and  objective 
"  categories  of  value."  This  intermediate 
position  between  the  extreme  cost-of-production 
school  and  the  modern  utility  school  is,  how- 
ever, not  taken  by  Max  Wirth,  Prince  Smith, 
and  several  other  German  "free  traders." 
Their  value  theory  is  very  closely  related  to 
that  of  Bastiat  (5. v.)  and  to  that  of  the  classic 
English  school.  Another  notable  dissenter 
from  the  majority  of  German  economists  is 
Eugen  Diihring.  He  has  adopted  the  value 
theory  of  H.  0.  Carey,  according  to  whom  value 
"results  exclusively  from  labour."  Value  in 
exchange  is  "the  measure  of  the  resistance 
ofiered  by  nature,  to  the  possession  of  the  things 
desired,"  or  "the  measure  of  the  power  of 
nature  over  man  "  (Principles  of  Social  Science, 
ed.  1877,  ch.  vi.  §  88).  The  economic  writers 
among  the  German  social  democrats  continue 
to  follow  Karl  Marx. 

[In  the  following  works  are  to  be  found  refer- 
ences to  the  more  important  writers  of  the  cost-of- 
production  school  both  in  England  and  on  the 
Continent.  W.  Roscher,  System  der  Volksioirih- 
schaft,  ed.  1882,  vol.  i.  p.  10-12,  footnotes. — 
Adolph  Wagner,  Grundlegung,ed.  1876,  pp.  37-40, 
43,  footnotes. — Schdnberg,  Handbuch,  ed.  1885, 
vol.  i.  p.  156,  footnote  ;  also  footnotes  to  several 
of  the  following  fifteen  pages. — Coquelin  et  Guil- 
laumin, Bidionnaire  de  I' Ac.  Pol.,  1853,  article 
"Valeur."— J.  Garnier,  TraitS  d':Ec.  Pol.,  ed. 
1889,  pp.  275-280,  692-694.— J.  R.  M'Culloch, 
Literature  of  Pol.  Ec,  ch.  i. — J.  K.  Ingram, 
History  of  Pol.  Ec,  1888.— L.  L.  Price,  Histcmj 
of  Engl.  Pol.  Ec.  since  Adam  Smith,  1890.— K. 
Marx,  Das  Kapital,  vol.  i.,  footnotes  to  ch.  i. 
— E.  von  Bdhm-Bawerk's  KajpitaZ  und  Kapitalzins 
(Engl.  Transl.  by  W.  Smart),  contains  in  its 
historical  part,  vol.  i.,  a  great  number  of  biblio- 
graphical references,  which  are  very  useful  to  a 
student  of  the  history  of  the  general  theory  of 
value,  though  the  book  deals  only  with  the  history 
of  the  theory  of  interest. — Specially  for  ItaliaL 
theory  :  An  gusto  Graziani,  Storia  critica  delta 
Teoria  dd  Valore  in  Halia,  Milano,  1889. — Spe- 
cially for  early  German  theory  :  W.  Roscher, 
Geschichte  der  National-okonomik  in  Deutschland, 
1874.] 

The  ''Utility"  School. — Though  all  econo- 
mists insist  that  "utility  is  indispensable  to 
value,"  and  though  many  of  the  writers  who 
have  been  classed  as  belonging  to  the  cost-of- 
production  school  strongly  emphasised  the  gi'eat 
importance  of  utility  to  value  in  exchange,  they 
never  succeeded  in  working  out  a  consistent 


EXCHANGE,  VALUE  IN  (HISTORY  OF  THEORY) 


^65 


quantitative  theory  of  the  general  and  necessary 
connection  between  utility  and  value  in  ex- 
change. To  have  done  this  is  the  scientific 
characteristic  of  the  "utility  school."  The 
principal  achievemsnts  of  this  school,  as  far  as 
they  concern  the  general  theory  of  value,  consist 
(1)  in  the  discovery  of  the  connection  between 
the  variation  of  the  utility  to  an  individual  of 
a  unit  of  a  commodity  and  the  variation  of  the 
number  of  such  units  possessed  or  commanded 
by  him  ;  and  (2)  in  the  discovery  of  the  law 
of  the  marginal  determination  of  all  forms 
of  exchange  value  (see  Margin).  These  dis- 
coveries led  to  the  important  distinction  between 
total  utility  and  degree  of  utility,  and  to  the 
unravelling  of  the  complicated  connection  be- 
tween exchange  value  as  determined  in  a 
market,  under  the  influence  of  free  competition 
between  producers  and  consumers,  and  the  mar- 
ginal degree  of  utility  of  a  unit  of  the  commodity 
to  individual  dealers  in  the  market.  These 
deductions  have  led  to  the  general  theory  that 
valiie  in  exchange  is  a  relative  Tnarginal  degree 
of  utility  and  a  function  of  quantity  possessed. 
Hence  it  is  concluded  that  variations  in  cost  of 
production  or  difficulty  of  attainment  can  never 
directly  affect  or,  strictly  speaking,  determine 
value  in  exchange,  but  only  indirectly  affect  it, 
when  and  in  so  far  as  the  variations  in  cost  of 
production  affect  quantity  possessed  —  such 
conditions  as  time  and  Friction  {q.v.)  being 
taken  into  account.  What  directly  determines 
exchange  value  is  not  the  desire  to  avoid  work, 
the  root  idea  of  the  "cost"  school,  but  the 
desire  to  possess  the  commodity — not  the  pro- 
duction, the  past  history  of  the  commodity,  but 
the  consumption,  the  future  destiny  of  the 
commodity.  This  theory  is  the  result  of 
quantitative  analyses  of  Consumption  {q.v.). 
The  "cost"  school  had  in  a  very  conspicuous 
manner  neglected  the  theory  of  consumption — 
had  indeed  often  denied  that  there  could  be 
such  a  thing.  The  "  utility  "  school,  on  the 
contrary,  looks  upon  the  quantitative  theory  of 
consumption  as  the  only  sound  basis  of  economic 
theory  in  general. 

The  root  idea  of  the  "  utility  "  theory  is  to 
be  found  in  economic  treatises  from  the  earliest 
time,  e.g.  Aristotle.  "It  follows,"  he  wrote, 
"that  such  things  as  are  the  subjects  of  ex- 
change must,  in  some  sense,  be  comparable.  .  .  . 
Money  .  .  .  measures  everything,  and  conse- 
quently measures,  among  other  things,  excess 
or  defect,  e.g.  the  number  of  shoes  which  are 
equivalent  to  a  house  or  a  meal.  .  .  .  But  this 
will  be  impossible  unless  the  shoes  and  the 
house  or  meal  are  in  some  sense  equalised. 
Hence  arises  the  necessity  of  a  single  universal 
standard  of  measurement.  .  .  .  This  standard 
is  in  truth  the  demand  for  mutual  services, 
which  holds  society  together  ;  for  if  people  had 
no  wants,  or  their  wants  were  dissimilar,  there 
would  be  either  no  exchange,  or  it  would  not  be 


the  same  as  it  is  now"  {Nic.  Ethics,  v.  8,  p. 
152  of  Welldon's  transl.).  Condillac  {Le  Com- 
merce et  le  Gouvernement,  ed.  Daire,  1847,  p. 
250)  observes  :  "  We  say  that  a  thing  is  useful 
when  it  serves  one  of  our  wants.  .  .  .  Accord- 
ing to  this  utility  we  estimate  the  thing  more 
or  less.  .  .  .  Or,  it  is  this  estimate  which  we 
call  value.  .  .  .  The  value  of  things  is  then 
founded  upon  theii-  utility,  or,  what  amounts 
to  the  same,  upon  our  wants  for  them,  or,  what 
still  amounts  to  the  same,  upon  the  use  we  can 
make  of  them."  B.  Hildebrand  (National- 
okonomie  d.  Gegenwart  u.  Zukunft,  1848,  p. 
318)  foreshadows  the  theory  that  value  is 
determined  by  marginal  utility  and  is  a  func- 
tion of  quantity  wanted.  The  French  engineer 
Dupuit,  when  attempting  to  find  a  measure  for 
the  utility  of  public  works,  observed  that  the 
utility  of  a  commodity  is  often  not  only 
different  for  different  individuals,  but  that  it 
will  vary  enormously  for  the  same  individual 
when  the  quantity  possessed  or  commanded  by 
him  varies.  "The  utility  for  the  same  indi- 
vidual of  a  piece  of  bread  can  grow  from  zero 
to  the  amount  of  his  whole  fortune"  ("De 
I'influence  des  peages  sur  I'utilite  des  voies 
de  communication,"  in  Annates  des  jjonts  et 
chaussdes,  1849,  p.  185  ;  also  "De  la  mesure  de 
I'utilite  des  travaux  publics,"  in  Annates,  1844). 
Dupuit  states  (Annates,  1849,  p.  172)  that  his 
theory  is  an  elaboration  of  that  of  P.  L.  0.  Rossi, 
who  considered  the  theory  of  utility  as  the  true 
basis  of  economics.  Other  more  or  less  frag- 
mentary attempts  at  building  a  value -theory 
upon  an  analysis  of  utility  are  to  be  found  in 
writings  of  K.  H.  Rau,  von  Thiinen,  Fried- 
lander,  Knies,  Schaffle,  L.  von  Stein,  A.  Wakas, 
Th.  de  Quincey,  Samuel  Bailey,  R.  Jennings, 
and  others  (see  the  bibliographical  notes  by 
Menger  and  Jevons  referred  to  below). 

The  first  economists  who  succeeded  in  estab- 
lishing and  elaborating  a  consistent  theory 
of  value  by  a  thorough  analysis  of  consump- 
tion or  demand,  were  A.  Cournot  and  H.  H. 
Gossen.  In  his  Rechei'ches  sur  les  Frincipes 
mathdmatiques  de  la  Theorie  des  Richesses 
(Paris,  1838)  Cournot  observes  (p.  22) :  "What 
is  truly  important  is  to  know  the  laws  which 
govern  the  variations  of  values,  or,  otherwise 
expressed,  to  have  a  theory  of  wealth.  This 
theory  alone  will  allow  us  to  show  to  what 
absolute- variations  are  due  those  relative  varia- 
tions "  (in  values)  "which  fall  within  the  field 
of  observation."  In  the  chapter  on  "the  law 
of  demand  "  Cournot  writes  :  "  Let  us  then  as- 
sume that  the  annual  demand  D  for  each  com- 
modity is  a  special  function  F  (p)  of  the  price  p 
of  this  commodity.  To  know  the  forms  of  this 
function  would  be  to  know  what  we  call  the 
law  of  demand.  .  .  .  The  form  of  the  function 
would  evidently  depend  upon  the  nature  of  the 
utility  of  the  commodity,  upon  the  nature  of 
the  services  which  it  can  render,  or  upon  the 


766 


EXCHANGE,  VALUE  IN  (HISTORY  OF  THEORY) 


enjoyments  which  it  can  procure,  upon  the 
habits  and  the  customs  of  each  people,  upon 
the  average  wealth  and  upon  the  scale  accord- 
ing to  which  this  wealth  is  divided  "  (p.  50). 
Cournot  proceeds  to  argue  (p.  56)  that  "as  the 
ftinction  F  (jp)  is  continuous,  the  fiyiction 
pF  (p),  which  expresses  the  total  value  of  the 
quantity  annually  demanded,  must  also  be 
continuous."  Further,  it  is  possible  to  assign 
to  p  such  a  small  value  that  ^F  (p)  becomes 
zero,  and  also  to  assign  to  p  so  high  a  value  that 
the  same  happens.  It  is  easily  seen  that  these 
quantitative  relations  between  price  and  quantity 
demanded  at  that  price  have  their  exact  analogy 
in  the  subjective  fact,  not  treated  by  Coumot, 
that  the  value  in  exchange  of  a  commodity  is 
the  differential  coefficient  of  its  value  in  use. 

The  treatise  by  Gossen  entitled  JSntwicJcelung 
der  Gesctze  des  menschlichen  Verkehrs  und  der 
daraus  fliessenden  Eegeln  fur  Tnenschliches 
Handeln  (1st  ed.,  Braunschweig,  1854),  opens 
with  the  explicit  assumption  of  economics  being 
the  theory  of  pleasure  and  pain  —  economic 
activity  having  for  its  aim  the  realising  of  a 
maximum  of  pleasure  with  a  minimum  of  pain. 
He  proceeds  in  a  strictly  logical  sequence  to 
expound  the  theories  of  utility,  of  labour,  and  of 
exchange.  ' '  The  magnitude  of  the  same  desire, " 
writes  Gossen,  "diminishes  steadily,  when  we 
without  interruption  continue  to  administer  to 
it,  till  at  last  a  state  of  satiety  is  reached"  (p.  4). 
He  distinguishes  between  total  utility,  degree  of 
utility,  and  marginal  degree  of  utility. 

The  two  early  pioneers  of  the  utility  theory 
of  value,  Cournot  and  Gossen,  failed  to  gain 
recognition.  Their  suggestive  writings  were 
practically  unknown  at  the  time  when  W.  S. 
Jevons,  Karl  Menger,  and  Leon  Walras,  early 
in  the  seventies,  published  independently  of 
each  other  their  epoch-making  treatises. 

Jevons  as  early  as  1860  thought  out  the  out- 
line of  his  theory,  and  had  in  1862  published 
a  preliminary  notice  of  the  same.  His  well- 
known  Theory  of  Political  Economy  (1st  ed. 
1871,  3rd  ed.  1888)  has  exercised  a  great  re- 
forming influence.  Its  most  salient  and  en- 
during feature  is  the  profoundly  philosophical 
spirit  in  which  its  early  chapters  deal  with  the 
method  and  very  foundation  of  the  science. 
In  his  introduction  (ch.  i.)  Jevons  contends 
'*  that  economics,  if  it  is  to  be  a  science  at  all, 
must  be  a  mathematical  science  .  .  .  simply 
because  it  deals  with  quantities"  (pp.  3,  4 
2nd_  ed.,  1879).  Having  shown  the  mathe- 
matical connection  between  total  utility,  or  value 
in  use,  and  degrees  of  utility,  having  framed  the 
law  of  variation  of  final  or  marginal  degree  of 
utility,  and  having  shown  how  this  law  rules  the 
distribution  of  a  commodity  in  different  uses 
he  only  needs  to  define  Market  {q.v.)  and  to 
formulate  the  Law  of  Indifference  (q.v  )  to 
lay  the  foundation  of  his  theory  of  exchange 
(ch.  IV.).     This  is  expressed   in   the  words- 


"  The  ratio  of  exchange  of  any  two  commoditied 
will  be  the  reciprocal  of  the  ratio  of  the  final 
degrees  of  utility  of  the  quantities  of  commodity 
available  for  consumption  after  the  exchange 
is  completed  "  (p.  103).  Jevons  continues  : 
"There  are  two  steps  between  labour  and 
value.  Labour  affects  supply,  and  supply 
affects  the  degree  of  utility,  which  governs 
value,  or  the  ratio  of  exchange  "  (p.  179). 

Leon  Walras,  in  liJlSments  d' Economic  politique 
pure,  ou  TMorie  de  la  Mchesse  sociale  (1874), 
and  subsequent  works  supported  the  same 
theory  of  value  as  Jevons,  the  chief  point  of 
difference  being  one  of  terminology.  Walras, 
for  example,  often  using  the  highly  concentrated 
and  therefore  rather  ambiguous  term  rarity 
(rarete)  instead  of  final  or  marginal  degree  of 
utility.  Leon  Wabas  developed  the  mathe- 
matical utility  theory  of  value  expounded  by 
his  father  A.  Walras,  and  he  also  utilised  the 
work  of  A.  Cournot  above  referred  to. 

Karl  Menger  published  his  Grundsdtze  der 
Volkswirthschaftslehre  in  the  same  year  as 
Jevons  his  Theory  (1871).  In  the  preface  he 
announces  as  his  object  to  frame  so  general  a 
theory  of  price  that  it  accounts  not  only  for 
price  of  commodities  but  also  for  interest,  wages, 
rent,  etc.  (p.  x.).  He  approaches  his  subject 
by  way  of  an  elaborate  analysis  of  the  economic 
significance  of  goods  {Gilter  as  distinct  from 
Waaren  or  commodities),  and  he  establishes  in 
the  very  first  chapter  the  doctrine  of  the  different 
"orders"  of  goods — a  very  characteristic  part 
of  his  theory,  and  valuable  as  an  attempt  to 
broach  the  special  problems  of  the  value  of 
tools  or  of  goods  which  only  indirectly  serve 
our  life.  Menger's  theory  of  value  (pp.  98-99 
and  107-108)  is  in  substance  the  same  as  that 
of  Jevons  and  Walras  though  not  formulated 
with  the  same  amount  of  precision. 

[Between  the  years  1875  and  1890  there  grew 
up  in  England,  America,  Austria,  Germany,  Hol- 
land, Italy,  France,  and  Denmark,  a  "school" 
of  economists  engaged  in  developing  the  science 
on  the  lines  of  Jevons,  Walras,  or  Menger.  The 
well-known  treatises  of  such  Continental  econo- 
mists as  E.  von  Bohm-Bawerk,  Friedrich  von 
Wieser,  Wilhelm  Launhardt,  K,  Auspitz,  and 
R.  Lieben,  N.  G.  Pierson,  Emil  Sax,  Harald 
Westergaard,  are  all  founded  upon  the  utility 
theory  of  value.  The  new  theory  has,  besides, 
exercised  a  very  marked  influence  on  many  promi- 
nent economists  of  the  present  day  who,  like 
Professor  H.  Sidgwick  and  Professor  F.  A.  Walker, 
cannot  be  said  actually  to  belong  to  this  "  utility 
school." 

Among  English  treatises  distinctly  belonging  to 
the  "  utility  school,"  we  can  only  mention  a  few. 
P.  Y.  Edgeworth's  Mathematical  Psychics  (1881) 
is  interesting  as  an  attempt  at  utilising  the  new 
theory  for  establishing,  on  strictly  mathematical 
lines,  a  science  of  social  life.  Tl^e  Alphabet  of 
Economic  Science,  by  Ph.  H.  Wicksteed  (1888), 
takes  up  the  theory  of  vahie  of  Jevons,  and 
gives  a  popular  explanation  of  the  fundamental 


EXCHANGE  (USURY)— EXCHANGE  (BOURSE) 


767 


theorems  of  the  higher  mathematics  upon  which  it 
rests.  Professor  A.  Marshall,  in  his  Principles  of 
Economics,  vol.  i.  (1890),  shows  the  true  organic 
connection  between  the  modern  theory  and  the 
doctrines  of  the  leading  economists  of  the  past. 

The  most  complete  bibliography  to  the  value 
theory  of  the  utility  school  is  found  in  the  ap- 
pendix to  W.  S.  Jevons's  Theory  of  Political 
Economy,  ed.  1888.  See  also:  Carl  Menger, 
Grundsdtze  der  Volkswirthschaftslehre,  thl.  i.  1872 
(notes  to  pp.  78-80,  108-113,  215-216,  are  ex- 
cellent as  a  guide  to  German  writers  on  the  sub- 
ject) ;  Leon  Walras,  TMorie  de  la  Monnaie,  1886, 
pp.  vii.-ix. — Auspitz  and  Lieben,  Untersuchungen 
uber  die  Theorie  des  Preises,  1889  (preface). — 
Graziani,  Storia  critica  della  Teoria  del  Valore  in 
Italia. — R.  Zuckerkandl,  article  "Preis"  in  Con- 
rad's Handle,  h.  d.  Staatsio.,  also  same  writer's  Zur 
Theorie  des  Preises,  1889.— E.  Cannan,  History  of 
the  Theories  of  Production  and  Distribution  in 
English  Pol.  Ec.  Ill 6-18 J^,  8vo,  1893.]  g.  k.  s. 

Exchange  (Usury).     See  Usury. 

Exchange,  as  Bourse,  (a)  A  place  where 
merchants,  bankers,  brokers,  etc.,  assemble  at 
certain  hours  for  the  transaction  of  business  ; 
and  (6)  the  assemblage  itself.  In  both  senses 
the  word  is  commonly  contracted  into  'Change. 

"The  last  yere,  I  shewyd  your  goode  lorde- 
shipe  a  platte,  that  was  drawen  howte  for  to 
make  a  goodely  Bursse  in  Lombert  strette  for 
marchaunts  to  repayer  unto.  I  doo  suppose  yt 
wyll  coste  ii.  M.  li  (£2000)  and  more,  wyche 
shalbe  very  beautyfull  to  the  citti,  and  allsoo 
for  the  honor  of  our  soverayngne  lord  the  Kinge." 
Thus  wrote  Lord  Mayor  Sir  Richard  Gresham 
in  1538  to  Cromwell,  the  lord  privy  seal.  He 
had  recently  seen  and  admired  the  new  Burse 
at  Antwerp,  and  was  anxious  that  London 
merchants,  whose  custom  it  was  to  congregate 
twice  a  day  in  the  open  air  in  Lombard  Street, 
should  be  provided  with  a  similar  house,  or 
covered  walk,  to  shelter  them  from  the  inclem- 
ency of  the  weather.  But  powerfully  as  he 
advocated  the  scheme,  it  did  not  find  favour. 
Owners  of  property  were  difficult  to  treat  with  ; 
and,  as  the  merchants  themselves  appear  to 
have  been  completely  indifferent,  the  plan  was 
suffered  to  fall  through.  After  the  lapse  of  a 
quarter  of  a  century,  it  was  however  again 
brought  forward  by  his  public-spirited  son.  Sir 
Thomas  Gresham.  On  the  death  of  his  only 
child  in  1564,  Sir  Thomas  appears  to  have  con- 
ceived the  idea  of  making  his  country  his 
principal  heir ;  he  munificently  offered,  pro- 
vided the  city  would  furnish  a  suitable  site,  to 
erect  the  building  at  his  own  expense.  His 
fellow-citizens  gratefully  accepted  the  offer  ; 
they  raised  a  sufficient  sum  by  subscription, 
purchased  the  piece  of  land  on  which  the  Royal 
Exchange  now  stands,  and  conveyed  it  over  to 
him.  By  the  end  of  1568,  merchants  were 
able  to  hold  their  meetings  within  the  building. 
It  consisted  of  a  quadrangular  arcade,  enclosing 
an  open  court,  and  bore  a  general  resemblance 


to  the  Burse  at  Antwerp.  After  completion, 
it  was  inspected  and  formally  opened  (23rd 
January  1571)  by  Queen  Elizabeth,  who  "caused 
the  same  Burse  by  an  herralde  and  a  trompet 
to  be  proclaimed  the  Royal  Exchange,  and  so  to 
be  called  from  thenceforth,  and  not  otherwise." 
By  Gresham's  will  the  Royal  Exchange  was 
vested  in  the  Corporation  of  the  City  of  London 
and  the  Mercers'  Company,  conjointly.  And  to 
them  it  in  due  time  reverted.  Exactly  100 
years  after  the  laying  of  the  foundation  stone 
the  building  M-as  swept  away  in  the  great  fire 
of  1666  ;  and  its  successor,  the  second  exchange, 
was  also  destroyed  by  fire  in  1838.  The  pre- 
sent structure  dates  from  1844. 

To  the  stranger  who  visits  the  Royal  Ex- 
change, expecting  to  find  there  the  very  heart 
of  the  business  of  London,  the  deserted  appear- 
ance of  its  interior  is  a  source  of  wonderment  ; 
with  the  exception  of  a  short  interval  in  the 
afternoon,  when  it  is  resorted  to  by  dealers  in 
some  of  the  minor  branches  of  commerce  (paper, 
drugs,  etc.),  and  of  an  hour  or  so  on  Tuesdays 
and  Thursdays,  when  foreign  bills  are  dealt  in, 
it  appears  to  be  given  over  to  loungers.  It 
has  to  a  great  extent  outlived  its  object.  In 
Gresham's  time,  and  for  long  afterwards,  the 
space  afforded  by  the  quadrangle  and  ambula- 
tory was  sufficient  for  all  re(|uirements,  but 
to-day  the  building  would  hardly  give  standing- 
room  to  a  tithe  of  those  who  every  day  come 
together  in  the  city  to  discuss  and  transact 
affairs  ;  long  ago  it  became  apparent  either  that 
the  exchange  must  be  enlarged,  or  that  some  of 
those  who  frequented  it  must  go  elsewhere. 
One  after  another,  the  larger  and  wealthier 
traders  departed  and  built  homes  for  them- 
selves in  more  convenient  localities.  Dealers 
in  stocks  and  shares,  produce  merchants,  ship- 
owners, insurance  underwriters,  coal,  metal, 
corn,  hop,  wool-traders,  and  others,  now  possess 
their  own  separate  exchanges.  There  is  one 
small  but  important  group  which  transacts 
business  in  the  old  parent  centre,  and  which 
the  mind  more  particularly  associates  with  the 
word  "  'Change. "  On  Tuesdays  and  Thursdays, 
after  luncheon  time,  the  principals  of  the  great 
merchant-banking  houses  (Rothschild,  Baring, 
Huth,  Klein  wort,  etc.),  the  representatives  of 
a  few  of  the  more  enterprising  joint-stock  banks 
(London  County  and  Westminster,  London 
City  and  Midland,  Martins,  etc.),  and  the 
London  Branch  managers  of  all  the  foreign  and 
Anglo-foreign  banks  (Credit  Lyonnais,  Deutsche 
Bank,  Swiss  Bankverein,  Anglo-Austrian  Bank, 
etc.),  collect  at  the  eastern  end  of  the  courtyard 
to  discuss  matters  of  common  interest  and  to 
deal  in  foreign  bills.  The  attendance  is  never 
more,  perhaps,  including  the  brokers,  than  five 
or  six  score  ;  but  it  comprises  members  of  firms 
whose  names  are  "household  words"  on  every 
bourse  throughout  the  world,  and  is  eminently 
representative  of  the  financial  side  of  England's 


(68 


EXCHANGE,  STOCK 


Welthandel.  Hubbub  and  excitement,  ap- 
parently necessary  concomitants  of  the  dealings 
in  other  commercial  assemblies,  are  here  absent ; 
the  negotiations  are  conducted  in  a  quiet  under- 
tone, and  with  an  air  of  nonchalance  which  might 
almost  lead  the  onlooker  to  believe  that  thachief 
object  of  the  meeting  is  conversation,  and  that 
business  is  quite  a  secondary  consideration. 

Formerly  the  foreign  mails  were  despatched 
from  London  twice  a  week,  on  Tuesdays  and 
Fridays,  and  on  these  "  post  days  "  alone  were 
foreign  bills  negotiable  on  "'Cliange."  The 
custom  of  a  bi-weekly  meeting  (since  1879 
Tuesday  and  Thursday)  still  subsists,  as  it  is 
found  that  so  far  as  the  business  in  bills  of 
exchange  is  concerned,  two  exchange-days  are 
sufficient  for  all  practical  purposes,  and  are 
perhaps  more  advantageous  than  a  daily  market 
would  be,  inasmuch  as  they  collect  on  the  same 
spot  and  at  the  same  time  all  the  important 
buyers,  and  therefore  establish  a  genuine  quota- 
tion. The  business  in  cheques  and  telegraphic 
transfers,  which  has  now  attained  huge  propor- 
tions, is  of  too  urgent  a  nature  to  wait  for 
"post-day,"  and  is  effected  daily  and  hourly 
by  telephone. 

Owing  to  the  fact  that  the  settlement  by 
bill  of  our  mercantile  transactions  with  other 
couatries  is  usually  effected  by  means  of  drafts 
on  London  from  abroad — the  bills  drawn  on 
abroad  from  England  forming  only  a  very  small 
fraction  of  the  whole,  that  is  to  say,  our  ex- 
porters, instead  of  drawing  against  their  sales, 
mostly  arrange  to  have  remittances  sent  them  ; 
and  our  importers,  instead  of  remitting  against 
their  purchases,  mostly  arrange  to  accept, — the 
traffic  in  "London"  paper  on  the  Continental 
bourses  is  on  a  far  larger  scale  than  that  of  the 
dealings  in  foreign  bills  on  the  Royal  Exchange  ; 
and  the  buying  and  selling  of  long  or  short 
"London,"  either  for  the  portfolio — as  stock- 
in-trade,  investment,  or  speculation,  as  the  case 
may  be — or  in  execution  of  orders  received 
from  customers,  is  part  of  the  regular  round  of 
a  Continental  banker's  duties,  and  necessitates 
his  daily  attendance  at  the  bourse.  An  English 
banker,  on  the  contrary,  is  rarely  or  never  seen 
on  "  'Change,"  as  he  confines  his  bill-operations 
to  paper  payable  at  home,  and  immediately 
disposes  through  his  broker  of  whatever  foreign 
paper  may  be  sent  up  to  him  from  the  provinces 
for  negotiation.  A  notable  consequence  of  this 
predominance  of  foreign-drawn  over  English- 
drawn  paper  in  the  various  markets  is  that 
the  course  of  most  of  the  exchanges  is  con- 
trolled from  abroad,  and  that  the  fluctuations 
registered  here  are  mere  reflections  of  the  move- 
ments produced  by  forces  operating  on  the 
other  side.  G^  q^ 

Exchange,  Stock.  The  largest  stock  ex- 
change in  the  world  is  that  of  London,  in  which 
securities  to  the  nominal  value  of  not  less 
than  £10,000,000,000  are  marketable  (1914) 


These  securities  aie  officially  recognised,  and 
there  are  besides  numbers  which  have  no 
official  quotation,  but  are  yet  dealt  in  from 
time  to  time  according  to  the  speculative  rago 
of  the  moment.  There  are  also  in  the  United 
Kingdom  twenty  other  exchanges,  including 
Manchester,  Liverpool,  Leeds,  Sheffield,  New- 
castle, Birmingham,  Bristol,  Aberdeen,  Edin 
burgh,  Glasgow,  Dublin,  Belfast,  Cardiff,  Hali- 
fax, Huddersfield.  The  whole  of  these  do 
not  include  the  attendance  of  as  many  persons, 
or  turnover  of  so  much  money  and  securities,  as 
the  London  stock  exchange  alone.  Their 
business,  however,  presents  some  points  worthy 
of  notice  (see  Exchange,  Stock,  Provincial). 
The  London  stock  exchange  is  not  only  the  chief 
of  the  English  stock  markets  ;  it  is  also  linked 
internationally  with  nearly  all  the  financial 
centres  of  the  world,  and  it  would  be  difficult 
to  name  a  security  which  could  not  find  a 
market  in  London,  either  through  the  ordinary 
channels  provided  by  arbitrage  dealers  (see 
Arbitrage),  who  buy  in  the  cheaper  and  sell 
in  the  dearer  markets,  or  through  the  agency 
of  trusts  which,  by  the  aid  of  English  invest- 
ments, form  funds  applied  to  the  purchase  of 
a  vast  variety  of  securities  in  European,  Asiatic, 
American,  and  Australian  exchanges  as  well  as 
those  which  are  of  native  production.  There 
has  never  been  anything  in  history  like  the 
London  stock  exchange  for  magnitude  and  ex- 
tent of  financial  resources.  It  is  an  immense 
business  engine  with  certain  unavoidable  draw- 
backs which  give  it  also  the  nature  of  an 
extensive  gambling  centre.  On  the  whole, 
it  has  been  found  by  experience  that  the  advan- 
tages and  merits  of  such  an  organisation 
outweigh  altogether  the  drawbacks  imposed 
by  the  too -speculative  spirit  of  mankind. 
It  has  been  asserted,  and  even  by  members  of  the 
stock  exchange,  that  nine-tenths  of  the  opera- 
tions on  which  stockbrokers  live  by  commission 
are  gambling  operations.  And  though  no  doubt 
the  speculative  public  pay  annually  a  heavy  tax 
to  the  professional  stock  exchange  element — 
rough  estimates  are  made  that  in  prosperous  years 
the  annual  revenue  of  members  of  the  London 
stock  exchange  may  amount  to  £3,000,000  or 
£4,000,000, — yet  the  stock  exchange  provides 
a  useful  barometer ;  and  sometimes  by  its  extreme 
sensitiveness  to  events  which  have  yet  to  happen, 
eases  and  mitigates  the  effects  of  disasters  which 
would  otherwise  have  assumed  proportions  of  a 
national  calamity.  The  stock  exchange  is  alwaya 
running  ahead  of  anticipated  events,  and  the 
events  when  they  happen,  being  so  "dis- 
counted," have  the  less  effect  if  any  effect  at 
all.  This  is  by  no  means  the  only  publioj 
service  done  by  the  stock  exchange.  The! 
modern  fashion  of  turning  over  growing  private  ( 
undertakings  into  joint-stock  companies  makes ; 
the  stock  exchange  a  necessity.  It  is  also  a:j 
means  by  which  astute  men  of  business  cai 


EXCHANGE,  STOCK 


769 


insure,  or  hedge,  against  the  worst  results  of 
what  would  otherwise  be  a  hazardous  operation. 
Thus  the  stock  exchange  is  often  used  as  a  hedge 
against  commercial  contracts.  For  example,  if  a 
group  or  firm  of  contractors  have  undertaken  to 
supply  steel  rails  for  a  South  American  railway 
at  an  advantageous  rate,  the  chief  contingency 
to  be  guarded  against  is  default  or  discredit  on 
the  part  of  the  state.  "While  undertaking  to 
contract  on  the  one  hand,  they  find  it  advisable 
to  acquire  the  option  to  deliver  stock  at  fixed 
prices  on  the  stock  exchange  ;  so  that,  what- 
ever hapi)ens,  there  is  no  great  or  irreparable 
loss  to  be  feared.  There  has  also  scarcely  been 
a  boom  in  American  securities  in  recent  years 
without  the  life  of  Mr.  Pierpont  Morgan  being 
insured  by  both  London  and  Wall  Street  opera- 
tors. Commercial  operations  which  depend  on 
the  maintenance  of  peace  in  Europe  can  obvi- 
ously be  entered  into  with  some  sort  of  security 
when  it  is  possible  to  hedge  against  disaster  by 
recourse  to  the  stock  exchange.  On  the  occa- 
sion of  the  coronation,  both  of  King  Edward 
VII.  and  of  King  George  V.,  heavy  insurances 
were  effected  at  Lloyd's  by  stock  exchange 
operators  for  the  rise,  on  the  risk  of  the  death 
of  the  monarch.  It  is  a  two-edged  tool,  how- 
ever, and  can  only  be  used  safely  by  men  of 
the  greatest  discretion  and  experience.  We 
may  usefully  record  here  an  extract  from  the 
conclusions  of-  the  royal  commission  on  the 
London  stock  exchange,  which  reported  in  1878 
as  follows : 

"The  public  are  enabled  to  count  upon  a 
reasonable  speed  and  certainty  in  the  transac- 
tion of  business,  and  the  vast  amount  of  busi- 
ness done  secures  to  those  who  deal  in  the 
London  stock  exchange  as  small  a  difference 
between  the  buying  and  selling  prices  as  can 
be  obtained  in  any  other  mai'ket.  We  think, 
however,  that  if  it  were  possible,  it  would  be 
desirable  that  the  exchange  should  be  open  to 
the  public, — not  so  much  because  an  investor 
would  in  the  event  have  any  real  control  over 
the  bargain  which  his  broker  might  make  for 
him,  as  for  the  purpose  of  removing  a  certain 
amount  of  jealousy  and  suspicion  which  is 
created  in  some  minds  by  the  present  system." 
The  stock  exchange  has  not  found  it  practicable 
to  throw  open  its  doors  to  the  public,  and  it 
remains  what  it  was — a  strictly  regulated  club. 

The  report  of  the  royal  commissioners  also 
contained  these  words  :  *'  In  the  main  the  exist- 
ence of  such  an  association,  and  the  coercive 
action  of  the  rules  which  it  enforces  upon  the 
transaction  of  business  and  upon  the  conduct 
of  its  members,  has  been  salutary  to  the 
interests  of  the  public."  The  stock  exchange 
having,  or  rather  being,  a  valuable  monopoly, 
it  is  not  surprising  that  the  tone  of  its  govern-- 
ment  is  exclusive.  It  has  a  share  capital  of 
£240,000,  the  shares  being  reckoned  as  £12 
paid.     The  £12  shares  are  (in  the  year  1910) 

VOL,  I. 


worth  about  £190  each,  and  none  other  than  a 
member  of  the  stock  exchange  is  allowed  to 
be  a  proprietor.  For  the  year  1909-10,  the 
dividend  paid  was  £8  :  10s.  a  share,  or  70  per 
cent  of  the  share  capital,  and  the  net  revenue  of 
the  year  had  been  £211,810  :  2  :  3,  after  pay- 
ment of  interest  at  3  per  cent  on  £450,000 
debentures.  The  share  and  debenture  capital 
together  are  more  than  balanced  by  freehold 
and  leasehold  property,  which  stands  at 
£1,080,628  :  6  :  7  in  the  accounts,  and  may  be 
worth  more.  The  value  of  the  connection  of  the 
stock  exchange  may  then  be  reckoned  at  some- 
thing more  than  five  millions  sterling. 

The  management  of  the  stock  exchange  has 
thus  been  good  enough  to  stand  the  test  of 
public  opinion  during  the  fast-working  19th 
century.  About  the  year  1700,  dealers  in 
public  securities  found  the  accommodation  in 
the  Bank  of  England  too  small  and  migrated 
to  'Change  Alley  ;  thence  to  Sweetings  Alley 
in  1773,  where  a  room  was  engaged  and  kept 
up  by  subscription  ;  and  afterwards  to  Capel 
Court  where,  in  the  year  1802,  a  building  was 
opened,  but  the  public  were  excluded.  There 
were  at  that  time  about  500  subscribers,  and 
this  was  the  formal  beginning  of  the  stock  ex- 
change, as  it  is  now  known.  Seventy  years  ago 
the  number  of  members  was  about  350,  and 
now  (1910)  the  number  is  5019  besides  2344 
clerks,  who  are  admitted  at  reduced  rates.  The 
stock  exchange  included,  as  it  still  includes,  a 
responsible  body,  a  complete  organisation,  a 
local  habitation,  a  public  institution  privately 
managed.      Its  Benevolent  Fund  is  unique. 

Mr.  F.  Levien,  for  many  years  secretary  to  the 
committee  for  general  purposes,  in  his  evidence 
before  the  royal  commission  in  1877,  described 
the  internal  administration  of  the  stock  ex- 
change in  the  following  words  :  "  The  adminis- 
tration of  the  stock  exchange  is  vested  in  two 
bodies,  whose  functions  are  distinct.  First 
come  the  managers,  who  represent  the  pro- 
prietors or  shareholders  in  the  undertaking, 
under  the  deeds  of  1802  and  1876,  who  are  the 
executive  of  the  landlords  of  the  house  and 
premises,  have  control  over  all  monies  paid  for 
admission,  fix  annually  the  charge  for  admission 
of  members  for  the  year  ensuing,  appoint  all 
officials,  except  the  secretary  to  the  committee 
for  general  purposes  and  the  official  assignees, 
and  superintend  all  matters  connected  with  the 
building,  supplies,  etc."  He  goes  on  to  de- 
scribe the  functions  of  the  committee  for  general 
purposes,  who  are  the  executive  of  the  sub- 
scribers, and  ''have  control  over  the  business 
of  the  house  ;  make,  and  administer  the  rules 
and  regulations  for  the  conduct  of  the  business 
of  the  stock  exchange  ;  adjudicate  all  questions 
between  members  and  complaints  against  mem- 
bers by  non-members,  if  desired  to  do  so  by  the 
latter.  They  investigate  the  question  whether 
their  published  requirements  have  been  com- 

3  D 


770         EXCHANGE,  STOCK,  PROVINCIAL— EXCHANGE,  FOREIGN 


plied  with  by  governments  and  companies  asking 
for  settlements  or  official  quotations,  for  loans 
or  shares,  and  have  vested  in  their  hands  the 
election  by  ballot  of  those  who  seek  to  become 
members  of  the  stock  exchange."  This  com- 
mittee have  been  known  to  suspend  or  expel 
members  for  offences  against  the  body,  also  for 
those  against  the  public,  seeing  that  such  con- 
duct would  be  calculated  to  bring  the  stock 
exchange  into  disrepute.  On  the  whole,  the 
management  has  been  successful,  and,  again 
on  the  whole,  is  approved  by  public  opinion. 
New  members  are  elected  and  old  members  re- 
elected on  the  first  Monday  in  March  of  each 
year.  An  applicant  for  membership  must  be 
recommended  by  three  members  of  at  least 
four  years'  standing,  each  of  whom  must  pay 
£525  in  case  of  default  by  the  new  member 
within  four  years  of  his  admission.  The  full 
entrance  fee  is  £525  and  the  annual  subscription 
£42.    (See  Broker  ;  Dealer  ;  Jobber.)     a.  e. 

Exchange,  Stock,  Provincial,  in  Great 
Britain  and  Ireland.  The  best  known  of 
these  are  art; : — Aberdeen  with  14  members,  Bel- 
fast 32,  Birmingham  60,  Bradford  12,  Bristol 
32,  Cardiff  19,  Cork  23,  Dublin  87,  Dundee  18, 
Edinburgh  74,  Glasgow  266,  Greenock  12, 
Halifax  9,  Huddersfield  11,  Leeds  27,  Liver- 
pool 176,  Manchester  104,  Newcastle  16,  Shef- 
field 39,  and  Southport  6  ;  collectively  (about 
the  year  1910)  1037  members. 

All  are  organised  associations  managed  by 
committees,  and  the  aggregate  of  yearly  busi- 
ness transacted  is  very  great.  It  is  noted  that 
cases  of  dispute  and  litigation  between  pro- 
vincial brokers  and  clients  are  rare,  and  it  is 
claimed  on  behalf  of  these  institutions  that  no 
description  of  business  in  this  country  is  carried 
on  with  greater  rapidity  and  accuracy  than  that 
in  which  these  exchanges  are  engaged. 

Up  to  the  year  1890  the  provincial  exchanges 
had  no  common  understanding  or  organisation ; 
but  in  that  year  the  council  of  associated  stock 
exchanges — that  is  to  say  of  provincial  stock 
exchanges — was  established,  a  consultative  body 
composed  of  delegates,  generally  the  chairmen 
and  deputy  chairmen  of  the  various  exchanges. 
The  council  meets  annually,  or  more  frequently 
in  cases  of  emergency  ;  the  presidency  and  ad- 
ministration being  undertaken  by  the  larger 
exchanges  in  turn.  The  provincial  exchanges 
have  undertaken  the  revision  and  codification 
of  stock  exchange  rules  with  the  object  of  secur- 
ing identical  arrangements  in  carrying  on  the 
business  throughout  the  whole  body  of  associated 
exchanges.  Thus  the  notice  of  the  rule  of  the 
Manchester  stock  exchange  committee  {Econo- 
mist, January  7,  1911)  is  identical  with  that  of 
the  London  stock  exchange,  with  the  difference 
that  it  is  more  stringent  than  the  latter  through 
the  reference  to  the  Prevention  of  Corruption 
Act  1906,  and  the  rule  that  "no  member  of 
this  exchange  may  divide   commissions  with 


any  one."  The  first  public  action  of  this  body 
was  their  successful  attempt,  by  securing  the 
guarantee  of  share  titles,  to  avert  from  share- 
holders, in  future,  the  disastrous  possibilities 
opened  out  by  the  North  Western  Railway 
Company's  now  historical  denial  of  their  stock 
certificates.  The  London  stock  exchange  de- 
clined to  take  action  in  the  matter,  until  the 
principle  of  indefeasible  titles  to  securities  had 
been  accepted  by  public  bodies ;  the  Forged 
Transfers'  Acts,  and  the  benefits  resulting  from 
them,  will,  accordingly,  always  be  associated 
with  the  provincial  exchanges,  more  especially 
with  that  of  Liverpool,  a  member  of  which  in- 
stitution having  secured  the  passing  of  these 
acts  and  put  them  into  operation. 

The  business  of  the  provincial  stock  exchanges 
consists  largely  of: — Transactions  for  invest- 
ment in  British,  Canadian,  and  American  rail- 
way stocks  ;  dealings  in  shares  of  insurance, 
banking,  shipping,  commercial  and  industrial 
undertakings.  The  application  of  the  Limited 
Liabilities  Act  adds  largely  to  the  number  of 
these  undertakings.  Being  practically  brokers' 
markets,  investors  can  there  operate  free  from 
such  profits  as  are  absorbed  by  London  dealers. 
The  Association  of  Provincial  Stock  and  Share 
Brokers,  a  new  organisation  which  held  its  first 
annual  meeting,  June  27,  1914  {Times,  June 
29),  promises  to  be  useful. 

Exchange,  Foreigk.  The  term  foreign  ex- 
change denotes  the  value  at  which  an  amount 
quoted  in  the  currency  of  the  country  where 
the  transaction  originates  is  interchangeable 
with  that  of  a  foreign  country.  The  quotation 
of  foreign  exchange  fixes  the  market  value,  for 
the  time  being,  of  foreign  currency  in  the  place 
wherein  the  quotation  is  made.  For  instance, 
if  the  French  exchange  is  quoted  in  London 
to-day  at  25  frs.  20  c.  for  cheques  on  Paris, 
it  means  that  for  every  sovereign  a  London 
banker  would  buy  or  sell  25  frs.  20  c.  in  a 
cheque  on  Paris — one  must  say  buy  or  sell, 
because  it  is  most  unlikely  that  he  would  do 
both,  for  there  is  always  a  difference  between 
buying  and  selling,  therefore  the  quotation  is 
generally  twofold — for  instance  25  frs.  20  c.  to 
25  frs.  25  c,  meaning  that  the  London  banker 
would  give  the  public  an  order  on  Paris  for  25 
frs.  20  c.  for  each  sovereign  he  receives,  or  would 
give  a  sovereign  for  every  25  frs.  25  c.  offered 
to  him  in  the  shape  of  a  cheque  on  Paris. 

He  thus  leaves  a  margin  of  profit  of  2^ 
centimes  in  each  pound,  either  in  buying  or  sell- 
ing, the  actual  exchange  being  25  frs.  22|-  c. 
This  margin  of  profit  pays  for  the  trouble  and 
outlay  involved  in  the  transaction,  which  the 
banker  in  London  and  his  agent  in  Paris  have 
to  carry  out. 

It  is  necessary  to  point  out  that  these  quota- 
tions constantly  fluctuate  for  various  reasons,  the 
principal  cause  being  the  balance  of  trade  between 
different  countries ;  let  us  cite  an  instance : 


EXCHANGE,  FOREIGN 


771 


If  operators  in  France  sell  in  England  goods 
or  securities  of  a  greater  value  than  what 
English  operators  sell  in  France,  the  balance 
of  trade  is  said  to  be  against  England  ;  conse- 
quently the  quotation  in  Paris  for  pounds 
sterling  declines.  There  are,  however,  indirect 
influences  on  the  exchanges  between  different 
countries ;  for  example,  England  may  owe 
money  to  the  United  States  for  wheat,  cotton, 
or  other  commodities,  while  the  United  States 
may  owe  money  to  France  for  silk  or  wine. 
In  that  case  the  American  merchant  would 
probably  send  to  France  bills  drawn  on  England 
against  the  goods  which  English  merchants 
have  bought  from  him.  These  bills  being  sold 
in  Paris  would  tend  to  depress  the  quotation  of 
pounds  sterling  in  Paris,  just  as  if  England 
owed  the  money  to  France.  "We  thus  see  that 
foreign  exchanges  play  an  important  part  in 
facilitating  the  settlement  of  debts  due  by  one 
country  to  another,  thus  avoiding  the  cumbrous 
mode  of  paying  international  indebtedness  by 
the  transmission  of  specie. 

Another  cause  of  variation  in  foreign  ex- 
changes is  the  inequality  of  the  value  of  money 
in  different  commercial  centres  ;  money,  like 
water,  finds  its  level,  it  flows,  unless  some 
obstacle  intervenes,  to  those  countries  where  a 
better  rate  exists,  until  it  equalises  those  dif- 
ferences. Those  obstacles  are  the  question  of 
credit,  and  of  the  dissimilarity  in  the  respective 
currencies ;  where  these  things  are  equal,  a 
difference  in  discount  rates  will  attract  or  repel 
money  from  one  country  to  another.  For 
instance,  when  the  Baring  crisis  occurred  in 
November  1890,  the  Bank  of  England  raised 
its  rate  of  discount  to  7  per  cent. ,  which  rate 
was  maintained  for  some  time,  and  was  higher 
than  the  value  of  money  in  other  commercial 
centres.  The  effect  was  immediately  apparent ; 
all  foreign  merchants  and  bankers  who  had 
confidence  in  their  London  agents  remitted 
money  to  obtain  a  higher  rate  of  discount  than 
what  obtained  in  their  respective  countries. 
These  remittances  acted  on  the  foreign  ex- 
changes, causing  them  to  rise  to  the  gold  export 
point  (see  Gold  Points  in  Foreign  Exchanges), 
necessitating  the  shipment  of  gold  to  London. 

Another  effect  of  high  discount  rates  is  the 
depression  in  the  value  of  merchandise  and 
securities,  such  as  bonds  and  shares  held  on 
borrowed  money.  These  are  sent  to  markets 
abroad  where  money  is  cheaper,  and  naturally 
money  is  sent  to  London  in  payment  of  the 
goods  and  securities  received.  Another  cause 
of  fluctuations  in  foreign  exchange  is  internal 
disturbance,  either  social  or  financial,  creating 
alarm  and  inducing  the  transference  of  money 
from  one  country  to  another  for  safe  custody. 

We  have  seen  at  intervals  in  Paris  that  dis- 
turbances have  caused  the  exchange  on  London 
to  advance  very  rapidly  in  consequence  of  large 
Bums  being  sent  to  London  for  safe  keeping. 


The  season  when  English  people  migrate  to 
the  Continent  is  generally  marked  by  a  decline 
in  the  value  of  sovereigns  abroad,  and  the  ex- 
change is  then  said  to  move  against  this  country. 
The  quotation  of  exchange  between  countries 
using  gold  as  the  chief  circulating  medium  can 
however  only  fluctuate  between  well-defined 
limits  called  the  export  or  import  gold  points. 
Thus  the  exchange  on  London  cannot  for  any 
length  of  time  fall  below  25  frs.  10  c,  nor 
rise  above  25  frs.  40  c.  ;  because  in  the  former 
case  gold  would  be  sent  from  London  to  Paris 
to  purchase  pounds  sterling,  and  in  the  latter 
case  the  reverse  operation  would  take  place, 
and  gold  would  be  sent  from  Paris  to  London. 
The  difference  of  30  c.  or  3d.  per  sovereign 
covers  the  freight  and  insurance,  also  the  mint 
charges  involved  in  converting  the  gold  of  one 
country  into  that  of  the  other. 

There  is,  however,  considerable  difficulty  at 
times  in  fixing  the  exchange  between  this 
country  and  another  which  has  a  silver  or 
paper  currency.  Sometimes  the  variations  are 
great  and  rapid  ;  sometimes  it  is  difficult  to  fix 
a  close  ratio  between  buyers  and  sellers  of  ex- 
change on  countries  having  a  basis  of  circula- 
tion different  from  our  own.  Let  us  take  the 
exchange  between  this  country  and  India, 
which  is  the  largest  silver  using  country  in  the 
world.  The  exchange  in  London  on  India 
varies  materially  and  suddenly.  On  some  occa- 
sions there  has  been  no  reasonable  quotation  for 
bills  on  our  great  dependency,  because  of  the 
uncertain  value  of  silver.  The  rupee  declined 
from  the  rate  of  2s.  fd.  in  1864,  to  the  rate  o^ 
Is.  2-|d,  in  August  1892,  and  subsequentl} 
even  lower.  These  enormous  fluctuations  arose 
from  the  variations  in  the  gold  price  of  silver 
in  this  country,  but  the  fluctuations  in  the 
exchanges  between  India  and  other  silver-using 
countries  has  been  very  slight. 

Thus  the  exchange  between  Shanghai  and 
Calcutta  did  not  vary  so  much  during 
the  year  1891  as  the  quotation  between 
London  and  Paris  ;  in  fact,  the  fluctuations 
between  China  and  India  seldom  exceed  ^  per 
cent,  which  represents  the  cost  of  freight  and 
insurance  on  transmitting  silver  between  those 
countries. 

The  greatest  variations,  however,  arise  in 
the  exchanges  between  this  country  and  those 
where  there  has  been  a  suspension  of  specie 
payments.  The  most  notable  instances  are 
with  Russia,  Spain,  and  Portugal  in  Europe  ; 
and  with  Brazil,  Chili,  and  Argentine  in  America. 
There  is  hardly  a  limit  to  the  possible  deprecia- 
tion of  a  paper  currency.  We  have  noticed, 
with  regard  to  Argentine,  a  premium  on  gold 
of  300  per  cent,  or  a  reduction  in  the  value  of 
paper  to  one-fourth  of  its  former  gold  value. 

All  depends  in  these  cases  upon  the  quantity 
of  paper  money  issued,  relatively  to  demand 
and  to  the  absorbing  power  of  the  country  con 


772 


EXCHANGE,  FOREIGN 


cerned  and  upon  the  credit  of  the  government 
which  is  responsible  for  the  ultimate  redemp- 
tion of  the  paper  currency.  We  know  that 
almost  every  country  has  passed  through  this 
critical  financial  stage ;  even  in  this  country,  at 
the  beginning  of  the  19th  century,  gold  lias 
been  quoted  at  a  premium  of  over  50  per  cent, 
as  against  Bank  of  England  notes.  At  such  a 
time  the  foreign  exchanges  were  greatly  adverse 
to  this  country,  and  all  gold  was  exported. 
Fifty  years  ago  the  United  States  had  a 
similar  experience  of  a  forced  paper  currency 
with  foreign  exchanges  all  against  that  country, 
causing  the  exportation  of  gold  and  silver^  to 
pay  for  war  stores.  "We  thus  see  that  foreign 
exchange  acts  like  a  barometer  giving  indica- 
tions of  the  financial  aspect  in  every  country, 
acting  as  a  warning  when  a  financial  storm  is 
impending,  counselling  those  who  have  too 
many  engagements  afloat  to  take  in  sail ;  while 
in  fair  weather  it  gives  an  assurance  of  smooth 
water  ahead,  administering  a  well-founded  im- 
petus to  all  who  embark  in  legitimate  enterprises. 

[See  Goachen,  Foreign  Exchanges.']        s.  M. 

Exchange,  Foreign,  practical  working  of. 
If  it  be  sought  to  apply  the  theory  of  the 
foreign  exchanges  to  practical  ends,  or  to  draw 
trustworthy  conclusions  from  their  fluctuations, 
the  following  axioms  should  be  noted. 

Firstly y  the  current  rate  of  exchange  is  the 
price  of  a  bill  of  exchange  either  at  usance  or 
at  sight.  It  is  not  necessarily  the  ratio  at 
which  the  money  of  one  country  exchanges  for 
the  money  of  another.  At  a  time  when  e.g.  a 
cheque  on  Berlin  is  to  be  bought  at  20  '40  marks 
to  the  £,  it  may  be  necessary  to  pay  20*20  for 
German  gold  coin  (because  it  must  be  assumed 
that  the  seller  has  been  at  the  expense  of  im- 
porting it)  ;  but  20-40  would  be  called  the  rate 
of  exchange,  not  20-20. 

Secondly,  the  price  of  bills  is  governed  by 
the  ordinary  laws  of  supply  and  demand. 
When  they  grow  scarce  they  grow  dear,  when 
they  become  plentiful  they  become  cheap.  If 
they  become  very  dear,  the  would-be  purchasers 
look  round  to  see  whether  there  is  anything 
else  they  can  remit  to  better  advantage — pro- 
duce, let  us  say,  or  some  particular  stock 
exchange  security,  or  one  of  the  precious  metals 
— and,  as  soon  as  they  discover  such  an  article, 
they  cease  buying  bills,  and  the  price  stops 
rising  ;  if  they  become  very  cheap,  the  would-be 
sellers  consider  whether  it  might  not  pay  better 
to  employ  the  money  standing  at  their  credit 
abroad  in  the  purchase  of  something — gold,  say, 
or  a  foreign  bond— which  is  saleable  at  home' 
and  immediately  this  becomes  feasible  they  cease 
off'ering  bills,  and  the  price  stops  falling. 

Thirdly,  the  rate  of  exchange  at  A  for  cheques 
on  B  must  correspond,  or  tend  to  correspond, 
with  the  rate  of  exchange  at  B  for  cheques  on 
A,  assuming  that  credit  has  not  been  shaken 
on  either  side,  and   that   there   exists   a  free 


market  for  cheque  and  cable  transfer.  Other- 
wise exchange-dealers  would  secure  a  speedy 
and  easy  profit.  Thus  if  Paris  telephones 
"Cheque  London  25-26  "  while  here  it  stands 
at  26*24,  bankers  on  both  sides  would  instantly 
sell  as  much  as  possible,  the  result  being  as 
follows : — 

London  pays  say  £5000  (amount  of  the  Paris 
draft),  and  receives  £5000  (proceeds  of  its  draft 
on  Paris  for  fr.  126,200  at  25-24). 

Paris  pays  fr.  126, 200  (amount  of  the  London 
draft),  but  receives  fr.  126,100,  proceeds  of 
its  draft  on  London  for  £5000  at  25-26  ; 
showing  without  any  outlay  whatsoever,  a 
gain  of  100  francs.  This  is  called  arbitrage- 
business,  and  illustrates  the  manner  in  which 
the  exchanges  are  actually  regulated,  for  it  is 
of  course  obvious  that  under  the  influence  of 
such  transactions  the  rates  in  Paris  and  London 
will  very  speedily  be  brought  to  a  level. 

Fourthly,  as  it  is  the  custom  of  trade  to  give 
credit  to  the  buyer  who  buys  to  sell  again,  most 
bills  are  drawn  at  a  usance,  varying  from  thirty 
days  to  six  months,  according  to  custom,  and 
the  usual  exchange  quotation  applies  to  bills  at 
usance.  Between  the  exchange  for  a  bill  at 
sight  and  that  for  a  bill  at  usance,  the  differ- 
ence depends  on  the  rate  of  interest  prevailing 
in  the  place  upon  which  it  is  drawn.  The 
usance,  for  example,  of  bills  on  Italy  is  three 
months,  and  if  interest  in  Italy  rules  at  4  per 
cent,  a  bill  at  usance  should  cost  1  per  cent  less 
than  a  bill  at  sight. 

Fifthly,  as  the  bills  drawn  on  London  from 
abroad  vastly  outnumber  the  bills  drawn  on 
abroad  from  London,  the  demand  and  supply 
of  the  former  exercises  a  proportionately  greater 
influence  over  the  course  of  the  exchange  than  , 
that  of  the  latter.  In  other  words,  the  actual 
rise  or  fall  takes  place  on  the  foreign  market, 
and  London  in  most  instances  merely  adjusts 
its  rates  according  to  the  quotations  telegraphed 
from  abroad. 

Lastly,  in  those  countries  where  the  value  of 
the  currency  oscillates  in  relation  to  gold,  the 
exchange  is  subject  to  two  sets  of  fluctuations — 
to  fluctuations  of  limited  extent  caused  by 
changes  in  the  ratio  of  supply  to  demand,  and 
to  fluctuations  of  almost  unlimited  extent 
caused  by  changes  in  the  value  of  the  currency- 
medium.  Thus,  if  the  normal  exchange  with 
a  paper  currency  country  be  48d.  per  $  gold,  or 
$5  to  £1,  a  rise  in  the  gold  premium,  which  is 
illimitable,  from  200  per  cent  to  300  per  cent 
would  cause  the  exchange  to  move  from  16d. 
per  $  paper,  or  $15  per  £,  to  12d.  per  %  paper, 
or  $20  per  £. 

[S%e  Lord  Goschen,  Foreign  Exchanges  (Effing- 
ham Wilson,  1863) — the  classical  work  on  this 
subject.  For  the  calculations  needed  for  "the 
solution  of  the  problems  encountered  in  the 
merchant's  every-day  experience,"  see  especially 
the  works  of  George  Clare,  A  £  G  of  the  Foreign 


I 


EXCHANGE  BETWEEN  HOLLAND  AND  DUTCH  INDIA 


773 


Exchanges  (Macmillan,  1895), — A  Money  Market 
Primer  (Effingham  Wilson,  1893).— H.  Deutsch, 
Arbitrage  (EflF.  Wilson). —  Ottomar  Haupt,  Arbi- 
trages et  Parities,  1894.  Franklin  Escher,  special 
lecturer  on  Foreign  Exchange  at  New  York  Univer- 
sity, in  Elements  of  Foreign  Exclmnge  (Eff.  Wilson, 
1910),  gives  an  interesting  explanation  of  the  sub- 
ject from  the  point  of  view  of  the  United  States. — 
Hartley  Withers,  Money  Changing^  1913.]     g.  c. 

Exchange  betvj^een  Holland  and  Dutch 
India.  (The  guilder  converted  in  this  state- 
ment as  12  =  £1.)  To  explain  the  working 
of  the  exchange  between  Holland  and  Dutch 
India,  it  is  necessary  to  describe  the  diflFerent 
currency  systems  in  force  in  the  mother 
country  and  the  dependency.  To  begin  with 
that  of  Holland.  At  the  commencement  of 
the  19th  century  the  state  of  the  currency  in  the 
Netherlands  was  very  unsatisfactory.  From 
early  times  silver  had  been  the  only  standard 
of  value,  but  an  almost  unexampled  variety  of 
silver  coin  was  in  circulation,  owing  to  the 
fact  that,  during  the  existence  of  the  Republic 
of  the  United  Netherlands,  nearly  every  province 
had  a  separate  mint.  Gold  coin  had  also  been 
struck,  and  was  a  medium  of  exchange  at  rates 
officially  fixed  by  the  government ;  but  silver 
alone  was  legal  tender  until  the  year  1816, 
when  (Act  of  28th  September)  dual  legal 
tender  was  introduced  at  the  ratio  of  15 '87, 
between  the  then  current  silver  gilder  of  200 
aas  weighing  9-61  grammes  fine,  and  the  ten 
guilder  piece  weighing  6*056  grammes  fine  gold. 

Gold  being  thus  over -valued,  as  compared 
with  the  bimetallic  ratio  of  \^\  adopted  by 
France  in  1803,  all  the  full  weight  silver  coins 
were  driven  out  of  the  country,  and  gold 
coin,  struck  according  to  the  law  of  1816, 
together  with  all  the  worn  and  clipped  silver 
coin  of  earlier  date,  formed  the  only  circulat- 
ing medium. 

To  remedy  this  state  of  affairs  it  was  enacted 
in  1839  (Act  of  22nd  March)  that  the  historical 
guilder  of  the  weight  of  9  -61  grammes  fine  silver 
should  be  reduced  to  the  weight  of  9*45  gram 
fine,  thus  raising  the  ratio  from  15*87  to  15*60  ; 
but  the  clipping  of  the  old  coin  continued  on  a 
most  scandalous  scale,  so  that  often  a  premium 
of  5  to  1\  per  cent  had  to  be  paid  for  full 
weight  pieces.  A  thoroughly  efficient  reform 
of  the  currency  became  indispensable,  and  a 
general  recoinage  of  all  the  old  silrer  money, 
struck  before  1839,  was  accordingly  ordered  by 
the  Act  of  22nd  May  1845. 

Within  a  couple  of  years  a  nominal  amount  of 
85  millions  of  guilders  old  silver  (£7,083,000) 
was  withdrawn  from  circulation  and  converted 
into  new  coin,  at  a  cost  of  some  8  millions 
(£666,600),  the  operation  itself  being  to  a 
great  extent  facilitated  by  the  still  existing 
double  standard,  gold  coin  being  available  for 
the  use  of  the  public  in  adequate  quantities. 
At  the  same  time,  the  question  whether  the 


double  standard  system  could  be  continued, 
became  a  matter  of  ample  discussion  in  the 
press,  and  after  lengthened  debates  in  parlia- 
ment the  law  of  26th  September  1847  was 
enacted,  by  which  the  monetary  system  of  the 
Netherlands  was  based  on  the  silver  standard 
only,  with  the  silver  guilder  of  10  grammes  and 
iVoo  fi^6  ^^  ^^  unit,  all  the  gold  coins  in  the 
hands  of  the  public  being  withdrawn  from 
circulation  and  demonetised. 

This  decision  was  taken  when  nothing  yet  had 
transpired  about  the  Californian  and  Australian 
gold- fields.  That  only  became  known  to  the 
world  a  couple  of  years  later  ;  nothing,  there- 
fore, can  be  more  erroneous  than  the  assertion, 
often  made,  that  the  final  adoption  of  the  silver 
standard  as  basis  of  the  monetary  system  of  the 
Netherlands  originated  in  the  fear  of  a  probable 
fall  in  the  value  of  gold.  The  greater  con- 
venience of  silver  for  domestic  purposes  was 
the  principal  motive  for  a  reform  which  at  that 
time  perfectly  answered  the  purpose. 

The  recoinage  of  the  old  silver  coins  being 
completed  in  1849,  a  beginning  was  made  in 
the  following  year  by  withdrawing  the  gold 
ten  and  five  guilder  pieces  from  circulation. 
Of  these  g.  172  millions  (£14,333,300)  had 
been  coined  and  delivered  to  the  public,  but 
scarcely  one  -  third  of  that  amount,  say 
g.50  millions  (£4,166,600)  was  presented  for 
exchange  against  the  state  notes  munthiljctten). 
These  notes  were  intended  to  be  issued  as  a 
temporary  medium  of  exchange  only,  but  as 
the  public  became  accustomed  to  them  they 
proved  so  convenient  that  up  to  Oct.  1,  1904, 
they  formed  part  of  the  currency  of  the  country 
to  a  limited  extent — varying  between  10  mil- 
lions (£833,300)  originally  and  later  15  millions 
(£1,250,000). 

All  the  gold  coins  received  from  the  public 
were  sold  on  government  account  at  a  loss  of 
1  million  of  guilders  (£83,300),  and  altogether 
the  reform  of  the  currency,  including  the  re- 
coinage of  the  old  silver  money,  and  the 
demonetisation  of  the  former  gold  coin,  has 
been  effected  at  a  cost  of  about  10  millions 
(£833,300). 

Since  that  date,  1847,  the  state  of  the 
currency  became  most  satisfactory  in  every 
respect,  and  certainly  no  new  reform  would 
have  been  thought  of  if  the  monetary  policy 
of  the  neighbouring  countries  had  remained 
unaltered.  But  in  1872  the  rulers  of  Germany 
deemed  it  advisable  to  introduce  gold  as  the 
standard  of  the  newly-constituted  Empire,  and 
it  soon  became  evident  that  Holland  could  not 
remain  indifferent  to  the  intended  reform  of  the 
German  currency. 

In  October  1872,  therefore,  the  Dutch 
government  appointed  a  special  commission  to 
consider  the  subject  and  to  advise  as  to  the 
measures  necessary  in  the  interests  of  the 
country,  and  in  December  the  commission  ro- 


774 


EXCHANGE  BETWEEN  HOLLAND  AND  DUTCH  INDIA 


ported  that  it  would  be  impossible  for  Holland 
to  retain  the  silver  standard  established  by  the 
Act  of  November  1847,  were  all  her  neighbours 
to  adopt  gold  as  their  standard  of  value.  Accord- 
ing to  their  views  the  most  desirable  solution 
onhe  question  for  Europe  in  general  would  "be 
the  adoption  by  the  leading  monetary  powers 
of  the  double  standard— admitting  the  free 
coinage  of  both  gold  and  silver  as  legal  tender 
at  the  same  fixed  ratio  of  value.  They  con- 
sidered that  a  great  stability  of  value  for  both 
metals  would  be  the  result  of  the  compensatory 
action  of  that  system,  if  introduced  throughout 
the  whole  of  Europe  ;  that  Holland  alone  would 
be  powerless  in  the  matter,  and  therefore  that 
it  would  be  indispensable  for  Holland  to  adopt 
the  single  gold  standard  should  Germany  decide 
upon  that  line  of  action,  and  that,  in  the  mean- 
time, without  abrogating  the  law  of  1847,  the 
further  coinage  of  silver  on  private  account  should 
at  once  be  restricted  or  stopped  altogether. 

In  conformity  with  the  recommendation  of 
the  commission,  the  closing  of  the  Utrecht 
mint  for  private  coinage  of  silver  was  ordered 
by  the  law  of  21st  May  1873,  and  on  Germany 
establishing  the  gold  standard  by  the  law  of  9tli 
July  1873,  a  bill  was  submitted  to  the  states 
general,  proposing  the  introduction  of  a  legal 
tender  currency  of  ten  and  five  guilder  pieces  in 
gold,  and  the  withdrawal  from  circulation  of  the 
silver  standard  coins  issued  under  the  currency 
regulations  of  1847.  The  bill,  however,  was 
rejected  ;  matters  remained  as  they  were  until 
the  middle  of  the  year  1875,  when,  according 
to  the  law  of  6th  June,  the  mint  was  opened 
to  the  public  for  the  coinage  of  ten  guilder  pieces 
of  6*048  grammes  fine  gold,  to  be  legal  tender 
concurrently  with  the  silver  guilder,  the  further 
coinage  of  which  remained  prohibited. 

Thus  the  system  of  the  Stalon  boiteux  was 
introduced  in  the  Netherlands,  and,  though  it 
is  of  course  open  to  the  greatest  objections,  it 
must  be  acknowledged  that,  up  to  this  moment, 
it  has  caused  no  serious  inconvenience  or  mis- 
chief whatever.  As  a  rule,  the  balance  of  trade 
is  in  favour  of  Holland,  and  bullion  accordingly 
flows  in  freely.  But  occasionally  the  tide  turns, 
as  was  the  case  in  1882,  when  a  strong  demand 
for  export  set  in  and  the  bank's  stock  of  gold, 
which  about  the  middle  of  1880  had  amounted 
to  80,000,000  of  guilders  (£6,666,600),  de- 
creased to  below  5,000,000  (£416,600).  The 
defect  of  the  system  then  became  evident.  If 
once  the  gold  stock  of  the  country  were  ex- 
hausted, silver  would  become  the  regulator  of 
the  currency  without  any  other  limit  to  the 
depreciation  of  the  currency  and  a  correspond- 
ing rise  in  the  foreign  exchanges  than  the  price 
of  bar  silver  in  the  London  market. 

To  protect  the  general  interests  of  the 
country  against  the  serious  dangers  eventually 
certain  to  result  from  such  an  unsettled  state 
of  aliairs.  a  bill  was  passed  (Act  of  27th  April 


1884)  empowering  the  government,  as  soon  aa 
the  state  of  the  currency  should  render  it 
necessary,  to  withdraw  from  circulation,  and  to 
sell  in  the  open  market,  silver  coin  to  the 
amount  of  25,000,000  of  guilders  (£2,083,300, 
at  12  gs.  =£1)  and  to  buy  gold  with  the  pro- 
ceeds. Up  to  this  moment,  however  (February 
1911)  there  has  never  been  any  need  to  put  this 
measure — which  in  the  full  sense  of  the  term 
may  be  considered  as  the  safety  valve  of  the 
present  currency  system  of  Holland — into  force. 
The  law  of  1884  is  the  unequivocal  acknow- 
ledgment of  the  principle  that  the  state  is 
responsible  for  the  maintenance  of  the  gold  value 
of  the  silver  currency,  and  that  it  is  one  of  the 
first  duties  of  every  government  that  has  .imposed 
a  standard  of  value  upon  its  subjects  to  take 
every  reasonable  precaution  in  its  power  to  pre- 
vent that  standard  from  fluctuating. 

The  currency  system  which  has  now  beer 
in  force  in  Holland  for  about  forty  years, 
though  defective  in  principle,  has  fully  answered 
the  requirements  of  the  country,  and  it  may 
remain  unaltered  for  many  years  more  unless 
it  breaks  down  through  the  immense  profit  to 
be  made  by  unscrupulous  persons  in  manufac- 
turing illicit  coins  of  exactly  the  same  weight 
and  standard  as  the  legal  ones.  But  if  this 
becomes  the  case,  it  will  not  only  be  Holland 
but  nearly  the  whole  continent  that  will  have 
to  face  a  difficulty  of  the  greatest  magnitude, 
the  solution  of  which  may  make  an  international 
understanding  with  respect  to  money  matters 
more  urgent  than  ever. 

Having  thus  described  the  system  of  currency 
in  force  in  Holland,  we  will  now  turn  to  that 
of  her  Indian  possessions. 

In  Dutch  India  the  state  of  the  currency 
was  for  many  years  even  worse  than  it  was  in 
the  mother  country  before  the  reform  of  1847 
was  eflected,  and  even  the  government  itself 
was  instrumental  in  wilfully  perverting  the 
currency  of  the  colony. 

The  erroneous  idea  prevailed  that  the  wants 
of  the  native  population  were  on  too  limited 
a  scale  to  require  the  precious  metals  for  a 
general  medium  of  exchange,  and  that  it  was 
in  the  interest  of  "the  good  people  of  these 
countries  to  increase  the  circulation  of  copper 
coin  as  much  as  possible"  (Decree  of  the 
Governor -General  of  Dutch  India,  of  25th  June 
1818).  Hence  the  government  continued  for 
years  to  eff'ect  the  bulk  of  its  payments  in 
copper  money,  the  so-called  doits  (duiten), 
which  were  imported  in  large  quantities  frcan 
Holland  with  the  unavoidable  result  that  all 
the  good  money  formerly  issued  was  driven  out 
of  the  country.  Silver  was  still  the  legal 
standard,  and  the  silver  guilder  the  unit  of 
account,  but  virtually  only  copper  remained  as 
the  general  circulating  medium  for  the  whole 
community.  A  general  depreciation  of  the 
currency  was  the  natural  consequence  of  tliii 


EXCHANGE  BETWEEN  HOLLAND  AND  DUTCH  INDIA 


775 


state  of  affairs,  a  loss  of  25  to  SO  per  cent 
having  to  be  incurred  on  every  remittance  to 
Holland  or  elsewhere. 

The  colony  suffered  severely  for  many  years 
under  this  miserable  and  scandalous  condition 
of  the  currency.  At  last  the  government  be- 
came aware  that  measures  of  a  most  stringent 
character  ought  to  be  taken  to  resettle  currency 
matters  on  a  satisfactory  basis.  By  the  law  of 
1st  May  1854  the  monetary  system  of  the 
mother  country,  as  regulated  by  the  law  of 
1847,  was  introduced  in  Dutch  India,  and 
since  that  time  nothing  has  been  left  undone 
by  the  authorities  to  secure  the  colony  the 
benefit  of  a  thoroughly  efficient  currency.  For 
some  consecutive  years  large  shipments  of  silver 
coin  from  Holland  to  Java  were  made  on  govern- 
ment account,  between  1854  and  1860,  90 
millions  of  guilders  (£7,500,000).  Every- 
where an  opportunity  was  offered  to  exchange 
silver  for  the  circulating  copper  money,  and 
thus  a  long-wished-for  reform  was  effected  at  a 
cost  to  the  state  of  about  20  millions  of  guilders 
(£1,666,600). 

Ever  since  that  date  the  condition  of  the 
currency  in  Dutch  India  has  been  as  satis- 
factory, nay  as  perfect,  as  in  the  mother 
country  itself ;  even  the  late  silver  crisis  leav- 
ing it  altogether  unaffected  in  consequence  of 
the  measures  taken  by  the  government  to 
keep  the  currency  at  the  standard  value  by 
closing  the  Utrecht  mint,  not  only  for  the 
home,  but  also  for  the  colonial  coinage. 
Having  no  mint  of  its  own,  Dutch  India 
has  always  been  supplied  with  the  money 
required  for  circulation  by  specie  imports  from 
Holland,  the  standard  coin  being  exactly 
identical,  and  the  stock  of  silver  legal  tender 
money  available  in  Holland  has  till  now  been 
more  than  sufficient  to  meet  the  requirements 
of  the  circulation  of  the  colony. 

Thus  a  very  close  •  link  exists  between  the 
currency  of  Dutch  India  and  that  of  Hol- 
land. At  first  it  was  thought  that  silver 
might  remain  the  standard  in  the  eastern 
possessions  of  the  kingdom,  whatever  reform 
might  be  introduced  in  the  monetary  system  of 
the  mother  country  ;  but  gradually  the  convic- 
tion prevailed  that,  equally  with  the  people  of 
Holland,  the  Indian  subjects  were  entitled  to 
protection  from  the  difficulties  in  which  the 
action  of  a  depreciating  currency  must  necessarily 
involve  them,  and  to  remove  aU  uncertainty  as 
to  the  standard  of  value  in  the  colony  the  law 
of  28th  March  1877  decided  that  gold  ten 
guilder  pieces  should  from  that  date  be  legal 
tender  in  Dutch  India, — thus  establishing  the 
monetary  system  of  the  colony  on  exactly  the 
same  basis  as  in  Holland. 

Meanwhile  no  gold  whatever  is  to  be  found 
in  circulation  in  Dutch  India  ;  but  the  lack  of 
gold  has  never  caused  any  inconvenience,  and 
is  in  fact  of  no  consequence  so  long  as  the 


circulating  silver  money  fetches  the  full  value 
of  gold  for  payments  in  Holland.  More  than 
once  Dutch  India  has  had  to  face  an  unfavour- 
able balance  of  trade,  making  the  export  of 
specie  unavoidable  (Table  A),  but  the  rate  of  ex- 
Table  A. 

Imports  and  Exports  of  Silver  Coin 
from  and  to  Holland. 

(The  guilder  converted  as  12  =  £1.) 


Years. 

Government  account. 

Private  account. 

Imports. 

Exports. 

Imports. 

Exports. 

£ 

£ 

£ 

£ 

18S8 

1    724,166 

1889 

666,666 

1    792,500 

1890 

333,333 

1    210,166 

1891 

83,333 

804,166 

1892 

166,666 

345,667 

733,333 

1893 

83,333 

1894 

83,333 

332 

1895 

1896 

51,250 

4,542 

1897 

189» 

133,333 

300 

1899 

675,600 

1900 

198,750 

1901 

176,666 

750,154 

1902 

12,022 

250,000 

1903 

83,333 

1904 

91,667 

1905 

350,000 

1,479 

1906 

375,000 

83,333 

1907 

583,333 

4,167 

1908 

Table  B. 
Batavia  Rates  of  Exchange  for  Bank  Bills. 


Amsterdam 

London 

six  months'  date. 

six  months'  sight. 

Years. 

(Par  =  100) 

(Par=g.  12) 

1 

. 

-i^" 

1    -g 

bD 

^ 

gj 

^ 

bo 

i 

fo 

% 

<o 

^ 

s 

< 

w 

:i 

5 

1888 

103 

im 

102A 
10l| 

11-85 

11-675 

11-75 

1889 

102^ 

100 

11-975 

11-70 

11-825 

1890 

102 

99^ 

lOOi 

12-05 

11-80 

11-925 

1891 

101 

99; 

1001 
lOOf 

12-05 

11-925 

11-975 

1892 

lOli 

99; 

12-10 

11-90 

12- 

1893 

102i 

100 

lOli 

12-05 

11-825 

11-94 

1894 

lOlj 

100 

lOOf 

12-05 

11-90 

11-975 

1895 

loot 

100 

100x% 

12-125 

12-025 

12-075 

1896 

IOI7 

100 

12-15 

12-025 

12-09 

1897 

101 

lOOi 

101 

12-OG 

11-94 

12- 

1898 

101^ 

100^ 

101 

12- 

11-90 

11-95 

1899 

102^ 

lOlf 

im 

11-95 

11-80 

11-875 

1900 

102 

102tV 

11-86 

11-79 

11-825 

1901   , 

101 

lOOi 

lOiA 

12-04 

11-84 

11-94 

1902 

lOlJ 

100^ 

lOOfg 

12-075 

11-925 

12- 

1903 

101^ 

lOOi 

loiA 

ri- 

11-875 

11-94 

1904 

IOI5 

\m 

101 

ll -96 

11-91 

11-94 

1905 

101: 

101 

101? 

11-925 

11-85 

11-89 

1906 

1021 

lOlf 
102^ 

102^ 
102j 

11-90 

11-775 

11-84 

1907 

102, 

11-825 

11-675 

11-75 

1908 

102^ 

lOli 

102i 

11-94 

11-725 

11-83 

change  never  exceeded  the  bullion  point  of  gold 
(see  Gold  Points  in  Foreign  Exchanges), 
since  silver  could  always  be  used  as  a  remittance 
to  Holland  in  order  to  effect  payments  there, 
or  to  purchase  sterling  biUs  in  Amsterdam  foi 
payments  in  England. 


776     EXCHANGE  BETWEEN  GEEAT  BKITAIN  AND  BEITISH  INDIA 


In  consequence  rates  of  exchange  at  Batavia 
—the  financial  centre  of  Dutch  India— have 
maintained  a  most  remarkable  steadiness  during 
the  last  forty  years,  as  shown  in  table  B,  see 
page  775,  to  explain  which  it  may  be  added  that 
the  way  of  quoting  the  rate  of  bills  drawn  on 
Amsterdam  is  exactly  the  reverse  of  the  quota- 
tions for  sterling  paper.  For  the  latter  the 
Dutch  Indian  currency  is  the  fluctuating  term, 
the  quotation  consisting  of  a  varying  number 
of  guilders  and  cents  to  be  paid  for  the  pound 
sterling.  In  the  exchange  between  Batavia  and 
Amsterdam,  on  the  other  hand,  the  latter  place 
gives  the  "uncertain"  a  quotation  of  101, 
meaning  that  g.  100  Dutch  Indian  currency 
gives  claim  to  g.  101  Netherlands  currency. 
Thus  it  is  obvious  that  a  rise  in  the  quotation 
of  bills  on  Amsterdam  must  correspond  to  a 
decline  in  sterling  quotations.  [See  Exchange, 
Foreign,  practical  working  of.] 

During  the  last  forty  years  in  drawing  from 
Java  the  extreme  rates  for  Dutch  bills  have 
been  99^  and  104^,  and  for  English*"  bills 
g,  12-15  and  g.  11*375,  thus  showing  a  fluctua- 
tion of  only  5|-  per  cent  for  the  former,  and  7 
per  cent  for  the  latter  bills.  Since  1875,  when 
the  great  fall  in  the  price  of  bar  silver  set  in, 
idtes  have  not  fluctuated  more  than  2^  or  3  per 
cent.  Thus  Dutch  India  has  been  spared  the 
disturbance  in  money  and  exchange  matters 
which  has  caused  so  much  inconvenience  and 
loss  in  British  India. 

By  the  law  of  December  31,  1903,  renewing 
the  charter  of  the  Netherlands  bank,  power 
was  granted  it  to  issue  notes  of  10  guilders 
(16s.  8d.),  and  simultaneously  the  state  notes 
were  withdrawn  from  circulation.  Since  then 
the  regulation  of  the  fiduciary  currency  of  Hol- 
land has  remained  in  the  hands  of  the  bank 
under  the  regulations  ordered  by  law. 

[But  the  fact  is  not  to  be  overlooked  that  the 
whole  structure  of  the  currency  of  Dutch  India 
must  collapse  in  case  Holland  is  forced  by  circum- 
stances to  complete  its  monetary  reform  by  the 
demonetisation  of  the  silver  actually  circulating 
as  full  legal  tender  money.  Then  the  colony 
would  be  obliged  to  follow,  and  it  is  therefore  not 
at  all  impossible  that  at  some  future  period  even 
the  Eastern  Archipelago  may  appear  in  the  market 
for  the  sale  of  silver  and  the  purchase  of  gold, 
unless  it  may  still  be  practicable  to  arrive  at  an 
international  understanding  about  the  free  coinage 
of  silver  as  proposed  originally  in  the  report  of  the 
Dutch  currency  commission  of  1 87  2.  ]  n.  p.  v.  d.  b. 

[Ratio  of  silver  to  gold  in  Holland,  taking  mint 
charges  into  account,  15*625  to  1.] 

Exchange  between  Great  Britain  and 
British  India.— The  drop  in  the  value  of 
silver,  commencing  after  1867  (see  Latin 
Union),  compelled  the  government  of  British 
India  to  make  in  1893  an  arrangement  for  its 
remittances  between  India  and  London,  similar 
in  many  respects  to  that  in  existence  between 
Holland  and  the  Dutch  Indies  (see  Exchange 


between  Holland  and  Dutch  India),  The 
rate  at  which  council  bills  were  issued  in  London 
was  separated  from  the  price  of  silver.  In 
order  to  effect  this,  the  coinage  of  rupees  in 
India  on  private  account  was  suspended,  with 
a  view  to  the  introduction  of  a  gold  standard. 
The  Indian  government  had  been  anxious  that 
this  step  should  be  taken ;  but  the  home  govern- 
ment desired  that  a  thorough  examination  into 
the  whole  matter  should  be  previously  made. 
A  departmental  committee  was  appointed,  con- 
sisting of  Lord  Herschell,  afterwards  lord 
chancellor,  chairman,  other  members  being  Mr. 
Leonard,  now  Lord,  Courtney,  Sir  Thomas, 
afterwards  Lord,  Farrer,  Sir  Reginald,  now  Lord, 
Welby  of  the  treasury,  Mr.  Arthur  Godley, 
now  Lord  Kilbracken,  of  the  India  office,  Sir 
Richard  Strachey,  and  the  late  Mr.  B.  W. 
Ourrie,  who  was  a  member  of  the  council  of 
India  and  of  the  firm  of  Glyn  and  Co.  Thp 
committee  considered  the  proposals  of  the 
Indian  government,  which  aimed  at  fixing  the 
exchange  at  the  rate  of  Is.  6d.  per  rupee.  This 
rate  the  committee  did  not  adopt ;  the  market 
rate  being  at  the  time  (June  1893)  approximat- 
ing to  Is.  2d.  for  the  rupee.  The  general  con- 
clusions of  the  committee,  in  their  report  to  the 
secretary  of  state  for  India,  Lord  Kimberley, 
were  that  "while  conscious  of  the  gravity  of 
the  suggestion,  we  cannot,  in  view  of  the  serious 
evils  with  which  the  government  of  India  may 
at  any  time  be  confronted  if  matters  are  left  as 
they  are,  advise  your  lordship  to  over-rule  the 
proposal  for  the  closing  of  the  mints  and  the 
adoption  of  a  gold  standard,  which  that  govern- 
ment, with  their  responsibility  and  deep  interest 
in  the  success  of  the  measures  suggested,  have 
submitted  to  you.  But  we  consider  that  the 
following  modification  of  these  proposals  are 
advisable : — The  closing  of  the  mints  against 
the  free  coinage  of  silver  should  be  accompanied 
by  an  announcement  that  though  closed  to  the 
public,  they  will  be  used  by  the  government  for 
the  coinage  of  rupees  in  exchange  for  gold,  at 
a  ratio  to  be  then  fixed,  say  Is.  4d.  per  rupee  ; 
and  that  in  the  government  treasuries  gold  will 
be  received  in  satisfaction  of  public  dues  at  the 
same  ratio."  The  Indian  government  acted 
immediately  on  this  recommendation,  and  an 
act  was  passed  in  the  council  at  Calcutta  (June 
1893)  carrying  the  report  of  the  committee 
into  effect,  and  fixing  the  rate  at  Is.  4d. 

The  action  of  the  government  in  1893  was 
immediately  followed  by  a  rise  in  the  selling 
rate  of  India  council  bills  in  London  from  about 
Is.  2d.  to  Is.  4d.  for  the  rupee,  and  by  a  rather 
more  than  corresponding  fall  in  the  market 
price  of  silver.  Suggestions  have  been  made 
to  bring  the  rate  for  council  bills  upwards  to 
Is.  6d.,  and  ultimately  to  about  2s.  for  the 
rupee.  It  remains  to  be  seen  whether  the 
Indian  government  will  have  sufficient  control 
over  the  market  for  bills  to  enable  it  to  carry 


EXCHAKGE,  INTERNAL 


777 


this  into  effect.  Nor  can  the  influence  on  the 
coinage  legislation  of  other  countries — as  for 
example  on  the  United  States  of  America — or 
on  the  rate  of  exchange  in  the  trade  with  other 
silt^r-using  countries  be  stated  at  present,  or 
the  effect  which  may  be  produced  on  the  trade 
of  British  India,  or  on  the  condition  of  the 
people.  One  result,  if  the  measure  continues 
to  operate,  will  be  the  formation  of  the  largest 
"token"  circulation  of  coins  that  has  been 
known  in  modern  times,  as  the  rupee  will  cir- 
culate at  the  rate  which  the  government  fixes 
it  at  relatively  to  gold,  irrespective  of  the  gold 
price  of  uncoined  silver  ;  while  for  the  present, 
at  all  events,  there  is  no  gold  coin  current  to 
represent  the  rupee.  A  further  result  will  be 
the  entire  separation  of  the  rate  for  the  bills 
on  India  from  the  market  value  of  the  ordinary 
circulation  of  the  country.  The  council  bills 
are,  as  was  desired,  issued  at  the  rate  fixed 
for  the  time  by  the  Indian  government.  The 
arrangements,  in  so  far  as  they  are  based  on  an 
authoritative  rate  fixed  by  a  government  ibr 
monetary  transactions,  and  a  fixed  ratio  be- 
tween gold  and  silver  are  similar  in  some  points 
to  those  on  which  bi-metallic  systems  have  been 
founded  ;  but  while  this  is  the  case,  the  leading 
principle  of  bi-metallism.  namely,  the  power 
of  the  subject  to  have  his  bar  silver  or  bar 
gold  coined  into  money  and  to  be  able  to  pay 
his  debts  with  either  metal  so  coined,  is  entirely 
absent.  The  success  of  the  plan  depends  solely 
on  the  power  which  the  Indian  Council  may 
be  able  to  exert  over  the  London  market.  The 
Indian  Coinage  Acts  of  1899  and  1906  enacted 
that  "gold  coins,  whether  coined  at  Her 
Majesty's  Royal  Mint  in  England,  or  at  any 
mint  established  in  pursuance  of  a  procla- 
mation of  Her  Majesty  as  a  branch  of  Her 
Majesty's  Royal  Mint,  shall  be  a  legal  tender 
in  payment  or  on  account  at  the  rate  of 
fifteen  rupees  for  one  sovereign."  No  such 
gold  coins  have  yet  (1914)  been  struck  at  any 
mint  in  India. 

No  reference  has  been  made  in  this  state- 
ment to  other  points,  many  of  great  weight, 
connected  with  this  question,  such  as  the 
possibility  of  private  coinage  —  in  the  vast 
region  of  India,  touch  of  which  is  not  under 
the  control  of  our  government — of  spurious 
silver  rupees  equally  valuable  with  those  issued 
by  authority,  an  operation  which  would  be  very 
proiitable  to  the  coiner  (this,  however,  up  to 
the  present,  1914,  does  not  appear  to  have 
been  carried  on  to  any  very  large  extent) — of 
the  effect  on  the  Indian  cultivator  of  the  soil, 
who  will  now  be  deprived  of  the  resource  which 
silver,  in  the  form  of  ornaments,  has  been  to 
him  in  time  of  famine — or  of  the  result  on  the 
trade  of  other  silver-using  countries. 

The  measure  was  designed  to  prevent  the 
rate  from  dropping  lower,  but  it  will  have  the 
effect  of  stereotyping  the  loss  entailed  by  the 


fall  in  exchange  both  on  the  government  and 
on  private  individuals  at  the  point  at  present 
fixed. 

[See  Report  of  the  Committee  appointed  to  inquire 
into  the  Indian  Currency,  1893. — Cc/rrespondenct 
between  the  Government  of  India  and  the  Secretary 
of  State,  1893.    Comp.  Econ.  Journal,  Sept.  1893.] 

[Ratio  of  silver  to  gold  in  India,  with  rupee  at 
Is.  4d.,  takiug  mint  charge  into  acct.,  22*37  to  1.] 

Exchange,  Internal.  One  factor  in  the 
calculation  of  all  exchanges  is  the  cost  of  the 
transmission  of  bullion,  including  therein  the 
cost  of  actual  transport  and  the  risk  and  trouble 
involved.  In  the  foreign  exchanges  these 
charges  are  in  a  general  way  concealed  by  the 
fact  that  the  two  sides  are  in  terms  of  different 
currencies  ;  and  they  are  modified  by  the  com- 
petition of  bills  of  exchange,  according  to  the 
supply  and  demand  of  which  will  be  the  pro- 
portion of  such  charges  which  a  remitter  will 
have  to  bear.  The  same  expenses  attach  to  the 
settlement  of  transactions  between  different 
parts  of  the  same  country,  but  they  are  rendered 
more  apparent  by  being  expressed  in  the  form 
of  a  commission  or  premium.  They  are  also 
usually  more  imiform,  as  they  are  not  affected 
by  momentary  competition,  but  are  governed 
by  the  condition  of  the  banking  system,  tending 
gradually  to  diminish  in  proportion  to  the  com- 
pleteness of  its  development. 

In  this  country  the  facilities  for  intei-nal 
exchange  are  considerable,  and  its  cost  has  been 
brought  to  a  low  point.  The  post-office  system 
of  money  orders,  and  of  postal  notes  and  orders, 
furnishes  the  means  of  remitting  small  sums  to 
almost  every  village,  at  a  cost  that  has  continually 
decreased  as  the  facilities  offered  have  increased. 
In  the  first  quarter  of  the  present  century  re- 
mittances could  only  be  made  to  a  few  towns,  and 
at  a  cost  of  about  2^  per  cent.  At  the  present 
time  the  number  of  points  to,  or  from,  which  re- 
mittances may  be  made  has  risen  to  upwards  of 
10,000,  whilst  the  cost  may  not  much  exceed  one- 
half  per  cent.  For  larger  sums  remittances  were 
formerly  made  by  bankers'  drafts,  or  bank  post 
bills,  the  charges  on  which  were  defrayed  partly 
by  a  direct  commission,  and  partly  by  deferred 
payment.  At  the  jjresent  time,  by  means  of  the 
country  cheque  clearing  (see  Cleauing  Sys- 
tem), remittance  may  be  made  throughout  the 
whole  of , England  and  Wales  absolutely  without 
cost,  whilst  for  the  collection  of  drafts  other 
than  cheques,  and  for  all  collections  in  Scotland 
and  Ireland,  the  cost  has  been  brought  generally 
to  about  -^  of  1  per  cent.  This  result  is  greatly 
due  to  the  spread  of  branch  banking  (see  Banks, 
England  and  V/ales). 

In  the  United  States  the  development  of  the 
national  banking  system  (see  Banks,  National, 
U.S.A.)  has  led  to  remarkable  results  in  the 
same  direction.  This  system  was  established  in 
1865,  at  which  time  the  cost  of  southern  and 
western  exchange  on  New  York  was  from  X  to 


778 


EXCHANGE  OF  NOTES— EXCHANGER,  ROYAL 


1^  per  cent,  and  even  for  different  parts  of  the 
state  of  New  York  it  was  ^  per  cent.  The  diffi- 
culty of  obtaining  reliable  remittances  was  even 
more  serious  than  its  cost,  as  the  notes  or  drafts 
of  banks  in  any  state  were  frequently  quite  use- 
less but  a  few  miles  beyond  its  borders. '  By 
1890  the  rates  of  commission  or  premium,  on 
internal  exchange,  had  so  far  declined  that  they 
ranged  from  1  cent  per  $100  (t^^  of  1  per  cent) 
in  some  small  states,  as  Rhode  Island  and  New 
Hampshire,  up  to  21  cents  per  $100  (^  of  1 
per  cent),  in  Nevada,  Texas,  and  some  other 
states.  The  influence  of  the  Bank  Act  of  1913 
on  internal  exchange  remains  to  be  seen. 

In  France  the  Bank  of  France,  through  its 
numerous  branches,  has  long  afforded  consider- 
able facilities  for  internal  exchange,  which  have 
increased  in  recent  years  by  the  still  more 
numerous  branches  of  other  banks.      R.  w.  b. 

Exchange  of  Notes  (in  reference  to  the 
note  circulation  in  Scotland).  All  the  banks 
now  (1914)  carrying  on  .business  in  Scot- 
laud  are  banks  of  issue.  They  are  nine  in 
number,  and  there  is  a  stringent  system  main- 
tained of  exchange  of  notes  once  a  day  in  every 
town  in  which  there  are  two  or  more  banks. 
In  the  case  of  a  bank  holding  the  notes  of 
another  bank  not  represented  in  its  town,  these 
are  remitted  to  the  issuing  banks  at  short  in- 
tervals. On  Saturdays  there  is  an  afternoon 
as  well  as  a  morning  exchange,  so  that  the  re- 
turns of  circulation  made  at  the  close  of  business 
on  Saturdays,  as  required  by  the  terms  of  the 
Bank  Act  of  1845,  exhibit  the  amount  of  notes 
then  in  active  circulation,  i.e.  in  the  pockets 
and  tills  of  the  people.  No  bank  ever  issues 
the  notes  of  any  one  of  the  other  banks. 

The  notes  are,  by  the  system  described  above, 
"cleared"  to  a  gi-eat  extent  independently  of 
the  ordinary  settlement  of  drafts  and  bills 
between  the  banks.  The  system  is  a  very  con- 
venient one,  and  saves  the  banks  concerned  a 
great  deal  of  labour. 

All  clearing-house  balances,  other  than  those 
arising  at  the  Edinburgh  clearing-house,  are 
settled  by  drafts  on  Edinburgh,  which  pass 
through  the  clearing-house  there,  and  the 
balances  of  the  Edinburgh  clearing-house  are 
settled  bi-weekly  by  transfers  of  cash  made  in 
London  four  days  later.  Interest  at  3  per  cent 
is  paid  by  the  debtor  banks  on  balances  until 
the  date  of  final  settlement  in  London. 

Exchange  Broker.  Unlike  the  bill-broker 
(see  Bill-Broking),  who  in  most  cases  is  really 
a  dealer  in  bills,  which  he  buys  and  sells  for  his 
own  account,  the  exchange  or  foreign  bill  broker 
is  strictly  what  the  title  of  his  calling  implies, 
namely,  an  intermediary  or  negotiator  between 
the  buyers  and  sellers  of  bills  of  exchange  drawn 
on  foreign  countries. 

Such  bills  fall  into  two  classes  ;  those  drawn 
from  the  provincen,  and  those  drawn  from,  or 
held  in,  London.     As  regards  the  former,  all 


practically  pass  through  the  country  bankei 
into  the  hands  of  his  London  agent  for 
negotiation,  and,  as  the  latter  does  not  attend 
'Change,  they  are,  without  exception,  sold 
through  brokers.  In  the  case,  however,  of 
London-drawn  paper,  or  of  such  as  is  remitted  to 
London  houses,  the  seller  is  quite  at  liberty,  if 
he  so  chooses,  to  go  on  'Change  and  save  the 
brokerage  by  offering  the  bill  for  sale  himself ; 
but  he  usually  finds  it  to  his  advantage  to  em- 
ploy a  skilled  agent. 

The  exchange  broker  must  be  sufficiently 
familiar  with  foreign  law  and  custom  to  be  able 
to  point  out  and  explain  any  irregularity  of 
form,  stamp,  or  endorsement,  etc.,  in  the  bills 
that  pass  through  his  hands.  He  ought  also 
to  be  competent,  besides  knowing  the  present 
state  of  the  exchange,  to  form  an  opinion  as  to 
its  probable  course,  in  order  to  advise  his  client,  i 
if  need  be,  when  best  to  buy  or  sell.  He  is! 
also  expected,  when  executing  a  buying  order, 
to  protect  his  client's  interest  by  exercising  a 
due  regard  to  the  financial  and  moral  standing 
of  the  parties  to  the  bill. 

On  concluding  a  bargain,  the  broker  makes 
it  legally  binding  by  passing  a  contract  note  to 
both  parties,  giving  particulars  of  the  bill  andj 
specifying  the  rate  at  which  it  has  been  sold. 
In  the  buyer's  copy  he  also  fills  in  the  name  of 
the  party  who  has  to  deliver,  and  in  the  seller's 
that  of  the  party  who  has  to  receive  and  pay. 
Payment,  it  may  be  added,  is  not  effected 
through  the  broker,  as  in  stock  exchange  trans- 
actions, but  the  principals  settle  direct  on  the 
following  day.  The  charge  for  brokerage  is 
nominally  one  per  mille  (2s.  per  cent),  but  is 
subject  to  modification.  Brokerage  accounts 
are  rendered  once  a  year. 

The  growing  tendency  to  effect  settlements  by  ] 
bill  on  London,  instead  of  by  bills  drawn  from 
England  on  abroad,  is  strikingly  illustrated  by 
the  fact  that,  notwithstanding  the  enormous 
increase  in  our  foreign  trade  in  the  last  half- 
century,  the  number  of  exchange  brokers  has 
only  risen,  according  to  the  Post-Office  Directory, 
from  13  in  1841  to  15  in  1911,  as  against  an 
increase  during  that  period  in  the  number  of 
London  stock  brokers  from  343  to  upwards  of 
5000,  with  over  2300  clerks  besides.        G.  C. 

Exchanger,    Royal.     The  chief  functions] 
of    the    king's    or    royal    exchanger  were   as! 
follows :    to  buy  bullion  for  coin  save  where 
private  mints  existed,  to  exchange  current  coin 
of  one  metal  or  denomination  for  that  of  others, 
and  to  exchange  foreign  and  English  coins. 

In  the  reign  of  Henry  I.  we  find  this  office 
and  that  of  moneyer  united  and  vested  in  one 
person.      But   this   union   did   not   continue. 
Succeeding  kings  separated  the   office   of  ex-, 
changer  and  developed  its  constitution.     Thus  I 
Edward  I.  had  tables  of  Exchange  set  up  in  vari' ' 
ous  places,  as  York,  Dover,  Canterbuiy,   etc. 
In  addition  to  the  other  and  more  ordinary  ser- 


EXCHEQUER,  EAELY  HISTORY  OF 


779 


vices  which  he  performed,  the  exchanger  and  his 
subordinates  were  entrusted  with  the  important 
duty  of  so  discharging  his  office  that  the  export 
of  precious  metals  from  the  country  might  be 
prevented.  He  continued  a  royal  functionary 
and  in  discharge  of  his  duties  till  the  reign  of 
Henry  VI 1 1.  Then  the  complaints  of  the  gold- 
smiths and  the  advice  of  Sir  Thomas  Gresham 
were  listened  to,  and  in  1539  the  office  of  the 
royal  exchanger  was  abrogated  on  the  ground 
that  its  charges "  and  action  impeded  traffic. 
Despite  a  nominal  restoration  in  1546,  the 
previous  date  may  be  regarded  as  marking  the 
termination  of  this  restraint  on  the  exchange. 
Statesmen  and  theorists  were,  however,  very 
much  divided  as  to  the  expediency  of  this  action, 
and  the  protests  against  the  extinction  of  the 
office  proceed  from  well-known  men,  as  for  in- 
stance, Sir  Robert  Cotton. 

Its  reconstitution  was  mooted  at  the  very 
beginning  of  the  reign  of  Charles  I.  (in  1626). 
The  goldsmiths  were  heard  in  opposition  in  the 
privy  council,  but  did  not  prevail.  On  25th 
May  1627  the  revival  of  the  exchanger  was 
announced,  and  the  king  appointed  "Henry, 
Earl  of  Holland,  and  his  deputies,  to  have 
the  office  of  our  changes,  exchanges,  and  out- 
changes,  whatsoever,  in  England,  Wales,  and 
Ireland,"  for  a  period  of  thirty -one  years. 
The  goldsmiths  petitioned,  and  the  House  of 
Commons  protested  against  this  reconstituted 
office.  The  Earl  of  Holland  offering  to  submit 
his  office  to  the  judgment  of  the  latter  body,  a 
debate  took  place,  and  it  was  agreed  that  it  was 
a  "grievance."  No  steps  seem  to  have  been 
taken  to  exercise  any  jurisdiction,  and  no 
attempt  was  made  subsequently  to  revive  this 
ancient  office. 

[Kuding's  Annals  of  the  Coinage. — Macpherson, 
Anruds  of  Commerce. — Rymer,  Feeder  a;  and  MSS. 
authorities.]  e.  c.  k.  o. 


EXCHEQUER. 

Exchequer,  Early  History  of,  p.  779 ;  Exchequer,  present 
constitution  of,  p.  781 ;  Exchequer,  Scotland,  p.  784  ; 
Exchequer  Bill,  p.  784  ;  Exchequer  Bill,  History  of, 
p.  784 ;  Exchequer  Bond,  p.  785 ;  Exchequer  Bond, 
History  of,  p.  785 ;  Exchequer,  Closing  of,  1672,  p.  786. 

Exchequer,  Early  History  of.  The 
Exchequer,  i.e.  the  department  of  government 
which  superintended  and  managed  the  king's 
revenues,  and  into  which  all  dues  were  paid, 
appears  as  an  organised  part  of  the  state  system 
in  Norman  times.  In  Early  English  times 
there  seems  to  have  been  a  treasury,  sometimes 
at  Winchester,  sometimes  at  Westminster, 
while  a  hoard  was  kept  in  the  king's  chamber, 
and  local  treasuries  were  found  in  some  pro- 
vincial towns  (Hall,  Antiquities  of  the  Uaxhequer, 
p.  3),  but  there  are  no  traces  of  a  court  of 
account  so  early.  Richard,  Bishop  of  London, 
the  treasurer,  son  of  Bishop  Nigel  of  Ely,  and 


our  chief  authority  for  the  early  history  of  the 
exchequer,  writing  in  1178  (Liebermann,  p. 
11),  states  that  it  dates  from  the  Norman  Con- 
quest, the  arrangement  being  taken  from  the 
exchequer  across  the  seas  {Dialogus  de  Scaccario, 
i.  iv.).  Though  this  fact  of  a  Norman  origin 
for  the  English  exchequer  cannot  be  proved,  it 
is  probable  that  both  came  into  existence  about 
the  same  time  ;  even  if  entirely  independent, 
the  English  exchequer  is  certainly  not  much 
older  than  the  Norman  ;  while  on  the  other 
hand,  some  of  its  peculiarities,  such  as  the 
"  blanch  farm,"  show  that  the  system  was  not 
borrowed  in  its  entirety  from  Normandy. 

In  Henry  I.'s  time  it  is  found  as  a  distinctly 
organised  department  and  as  a  court  of  law 
under  the  name  "  scaccarium, "  a  name  derived 
from  the  chequered  cloth  which  covered  the 
table  at  which  the  accounts  were  made  up. 
All  the  financial  business  of  the  crown  was 
carried  on  at  the  exchequer,  and  as  in  early 
times  the  regulation  of  finance  and  the  adminis- 
tration of  justice  were  intimately  connected, 
much  judicial  work  fell  for  a  while  under  its 
contiol,  until,  with  the  elaboration  of  the 
judicial  system,  new  courts  arose,  and  until  its 
authority  was  restrained  by  Magna  Carta,  by 
the  statute  of  Rutland  (12  Edw.  I.)  and  by 
other  statutes,  to  cases  which  directly  affijcted 
the  revenue.  This  close  connection  between 
justice  and  finance  is  indicated  by  the  fact  that 
the  officials  who  sat  as  justitiarii  in  the  curia 
regis,  the  supreme  judicial  court,  sat  also  in  the 
exchequer  as  barones  scaccarii.  These  were  the 
great  officers  of  the  household  and  others 
specially  named  by  the  king,  presided  over  by 
the  king  or  by  his  representative,  the  chief 
justiciar,  until  the  final  disappearance  of  that 
official  in  Henry  III.'s  reign,  when  the  treasurer, 
always  an  important  functionary,  took  the 
foremost  place.  The  treasurer,  who  was  assisted 
in  the  performance  of  his  duties  by  the  chamber- 
lains, had  indeed  the  superintendence  of  every 
department,  and  was  responsible  for  the  com- 
pilation of  the  great  roll,  the  annual  record  of 
the  crown  dues,  while  he  also  gave  directions 
for  the  execution  of  the  royal  writs.  The 
chancellor,  the  representative  of  the  equitable 
jurisdiction,  acted  as  nominal  guardian  of  the 
great  seal,  and  also  as  a  check  upon  the 
treasurer,, whose  roll  was  copied  by  one  of  the 
chancellor's  clerks.  The  constable,  with  clerical 
assistance,  made  payments  to  the  royal  officers 
and  others  upon  receipt  of  the  king's  writ,  for 
without  such  a  warrant  the  issue  of  money  was 
strictly  forbidden.  To  cut  the  tallies  (see 
Tallies),  used  as  receipts,  a  cutter  of  the  tallicH 
was  employed.  Under  these  more  important 
dignitaries  were  a  large  body  of  officials,  sitting 
in  the  lower  chamber,  who  prepared  the 
summonses  and  other  business,  and  acted  as 
fiscal  experts.  Some  of  these  offices  were  held 
in  fee,  and  mention  is  found  of  a  woman  hold 


780 


EXCHEQUER 


ing  office  as  chamberlain  and  acting  by  deputy 
(HaU,  p.  82). 

Full  sessions  of  the  exchequer  were  held  at 
Easter  and  at  Michaelmas,  generally  at  West- 
minster, although  instances  of  its  session  else- 
where are  found  as  late  as  the  reign  of  Hdward 
II.  (Madox,  ii.  p.  7).  Other  sessions  were  held 
during  the  Hilary  and  Trinity  terms,  and  when- 
ever it  was  deemed  necessary,  not  excepting 
Sunday  (Thomas,  p.  7). 

Manifold  were  the  duties  of  the  officials  in 
connection  with  the  revenue  ;  not  only  did  they 
receive  payments  from  the  sheriffs  and  others 
responsible  for  debts  to  the  crown  after  careful 
examination  of  the  accounts,  but  they  also 
directed  payments  to  be  made  to  meet  the 
royal  requirements,  and  met  administrative 
expenses  of  all  kinds. 

Business  was  carried  on  in  two  departments. 

(1)  The  upper  chamber,  known  as  the  ex- 
chequer of  account  (scaccariumi  majus),  where 
the  reports  of  the  sheriffs  and  of  others  were 
received,  and  where  all  legal  negotiations  were 
carried  on. 

(2)  The  lower  chamber  or  exchequer  of  receipt 
{scaccariiim  inferius)  where  the  money  was  paid 
down,  weighed,  and  tested,  and  from  whence  it 
was  issued  when  necessary.  The  proceedings 
in  the  case  of  a  sheriff,  the  most  important  of 
all  accountants,  may  be  taken  as  typical  of  the 
method  adopted  in  transactions  with  the  cus- 
tomers, escheators,  bailiffs,  and  others  respon- 
sible for  the  collection  of  the  revenue. 

At  Easter  the  sheriff  having  received  a 
summons  and  a  statemeut  of  the  items  for 
which  he  had  to  account,  appeared  in  person  at 
the  exchequer,  unless  excused  for  special  reasons, 
when  an  attorney  of  suitable  rank  might  act  as 
his  representative.  The  view  of  his  account  was 
then  taken,  and  a  proffer  was  made  by  him, 
being  generally  an  instalment  of  half  the  total 
amount  for  which  he  was  responsible.  In 
return  he  received  a  receipt,  known  as  a  tally, 
the  counterfoil  of  which  was  retained  at  the 
exchequer.  When  summoned  to  the  Michaelmas 
session,  the  sheriff  was  required  to  answer  for 
the  full  annual  dues  "in  money  or  in  tallies "  ; 
he  then  presented  the  tally  or  the  voucher 
which  represented  such  payments  or  allowances 
as  might  already  have  been  made,  together  with 
the  remainder  still  due  in  cash,  and  received 
full  quittance  of  his  obligations.  A  simple 
expedient  for  balancing  the  liabilities  and  the 
actual  payments  of  the  sheriff  was  devised  by 
means  of  counters  placed  upon  the  squares  of 
the  chequered  table,  those  on  the  one  side  of 
the  table  representing  the  value  of  the  tallies, 
warrants,  and  specie  presented  by  the  sheriff, 
and  those  on  the  other  the  amount  for  which 
he  was  liable,  so  that  it  was  easy  at  a  glance 
to  see  whether  the  sheriff  had  met  his  obliga- 
tions or  not.  In  Tudor  times  "pen  and  ink 
doti  "  took  the  place  of  counters,  and  are  found 


in  use  for  the  last  time  in  1676  (Hall,  Anti- 
quities of  the  Exchequer,  p.  131). 

Depreciation  of  the  coinage  through  wear 
and  the  possibility  of  fraud  led  in  early  times 
to  the  adoption  of  precautionary  measures. 
Thus  when  money  was  paid  by  tale  a  payment 
of  sixpence  on  every  pound  was  added  to  make 
good  any  possible  deficiency  ;  this  was  found 
to  be  inadequate,  and  in  place  of  such  a  pay- 
ment ad  scalam,  a  payment  per  perisum  was 
demanded,  by  which  any  deficiency  in  the 
actual  weight  had  to  be  made  up,  or  a  com- 
position of  one  shilling  in  the  pound  was 
exacted.  In  some  cases  the  coin  was  submitted 
to  a  smelting  test ;  this  was  generally  done 
with  the  farm  of  the  county,  which  was  said  to 
be  blanched  or  dealbated,  when  such  a  test  or 
a  composition  in  lieu  of  it  had  been  accepted. 
A  regular  staff  of  officials  was  employed  in  the 
exchequer  of  receipt  to  see  that  real  combustion, 
i.e.  the  actual  testing  of  bullion,  or  nominal 
combustion,  i.e.  the  additional  payment  offered 
as  a  substitute,  was  not  evaded  by  the  king's 
debtors  (see  Assay). 

Among  the  important  records  bearing  on  the 
work  of  this  department,  and  carefully  guarded 
by  successive  generations  of  officials,  in  hampers 
and  chests,  were  the  Domesday  book,  the  most 
ancient  record  of  the  liabilities  of  crown  tenants, 
the  Red  and  Black  Books  of  the  exchequer,  and 
other  similar  compilations  ;  the  most  important 
for  centuries  was  the  great  roll  of  the  exchequer, 
commonly  known  as  the  Pipe  Roll  or  Rotulus 
Annalis,  the  official  register  of  all  debts  due  to 
the  crown  arranged  under  the  heads  of  counties, 
drawn  up  annually  under  the  superintendence 
of  the  treasurer,  and  which  served  as  the 
supreme  authority  by  which  the  sheriffs  and 
other  accountants  were  judged.  The  first  of 
these  rolls  still  extant  is  that  for  31  Henry  I. 
(1130),  but  from  the  second  year  of  Henry  II. 
the  series  is  complete.  A  duplicate  of  this  roll 
was  prepared  for  the  chancellor,  who  closely 
checked  any  error  on  the  part  of  the  treasurer, 
while  at  the  date  of  the  compilation  of  tlie 
dialogus  a  third  roll  was  transcribed  for  the 
king  {Dialogus,  I.  vi.).  In  later  times  with 
the  expansion  of  royal  revenue  a  number  of 
other  rolls  dealing  with  special  parts  of  it 
became  necessary  (Thomas,  Ancient  Exchequer, 
p.  68).  As  attendance  on  the  king  and  their 
duties  in  the  various  courts  prevented  the  great 
officials  from  regular  attendance  at  the  ex- 
chequer, and  as  the  sources  from  which  the 
revenue  was  derived  changed,  various  new 
officers  were  appointed  to  meet  the  demands  in 
different  directions.  Thus  as  the  chancellor 
and  his  subordinates  became  engrossed  by  the 
business  of  the  chancery,  theii*  places  were  taken 
by  the  comptroller  of  the  pipe  and  the  chancellor 
of  the  exchequer  (Thomas,  p.  100),  the  latter 
official  being  often  mentioned  from  the  roigu  of 
Henry  III.  onwards,  when  the  remembrance/ 


EXCHEQUER,  PRESENT  CONSTITUTION  OF 


781 


is  also  first  heard  of,  keeping  the  memoranda 
roll,  upon  which  were  entered  points  left  for 
consideration  until  the  close  of  the  audit,  and 
acting  in  the  capacity  of  solicitor  to  the 
treasury  (see  Pipe  Rolls).  Towards  the  end 
of  Elizabeth's  reign  the  number  of  oflBcials 
reached  its  highest  point,  and  it  is  also  notice- 
able as  the  time  when  the  lord  high  treasurer, 
as  he  was  now  called,  began  to  act  less  fre- 
quently in  person  at  the  exchequer  and  more 
by  means  of  written  instructions,  and  this 
gradually  led  to  a  new  system  for  the  conduct 
of  business  (Thomas,  p.  21).  Upon  the  death 
of  the  Earl  of  Salisbury  in  1612  the  treasmy 
was  for  the  first  time  put  in  commission,  and 
since  verbal  orders  could  not  be  accepted  at  the 
exchequer  from  several  persons,  written  in- 
structions became  a  necessity,  and  led  to  the 
use  of  treasury  warrants,  which  again  paved  the 
way  for  the  modern  department  of  the  treasury. 
There  is  evidence  that  the  lord  high  treasurer 
still  acted  in  person  until  the  removal  of  the 
exchequer  to  Oxford  in  1643.  Finance  under 
the  commonwealth  was  managed  by  committees 
of  revenue  until  Cromwell  revived  the  ex- 
chequer in  1654,  and  put  the  treasury  in  com- 
misijion,  which  has  been  its  normal  condition 
sinae  that  time.  During  the  Great  Fire  of  1666 
the  exchequer  was  moved  for  a  while  to  Non- 
such (Hall,  76).  In  the  course  of  George  III.'s 
reign  many  of  the  old  offices  were  gradually 
swept  away,  until  in  1833  the  ancient  account 
and  receipt  departments  of  the  exchequer  were 
entirely  abolished  (3  &  4  Will.  IV.  c.  99  ;  and 
4  Will.  IV.  c.  15),  the  office  of  king's  remem- 
brancer being  the  sole  relic  to-day  of  the  early 
system,  for  the  work  of  the  exchequer  is  now 
undertaken  by  the  modem  departments  of  the 
paymaster-general  and  the  treasury,  while  the 
Bank  of  England  has  taken  the  place  of  the 
old  exchequer  of  receipt.  See  Budget  ;  Ex- 
chequer, Present  Constitution  of  ;  Jews, 
Economic  Influence  of  (for  exchequer  of  the 
Jews)  ;  Pipe  Rolls  ;  Tallies  ;  Treasury. 

[Gneist,  R.,  History  of  the  English  Constitution, 
translated  by  P.  A.  Ashworth  (1886).— Hall,  H., 
Antiquities  and  Curiosities  of  the  Exchequer  (1891) 
and  Introduction  in  Pipe  Roll  Society's  Publica- 
tions, iii.  (1884)  ;  Court  Life  under  the  Planta- 
genets  (1890).  He  gives  a  valuable  list  of  manu- 
script and  printed  authorities  on  the  subject  of  the 
exchequer  in  Antiquities, -p.  224. — Henderson,  E., 
Historical  Documents  of  the  Middle  Ages  (1892), 
gives  a  translation  of  the  DiaZogus  de  Scaccario, 
the  Latin  text  of  which  is  given  by  Madox  and 
by  Bp.  Stubbs  in  his  Select  Charters  illustrative  of 
English  History. — Liebermann,  F.,  Einleitung  in 
den  Dialogus  de  5caccano.(  1875).  — Madox,  T.,  His- 
tory and  Antiquities  of  the  Exchequer. — Stubbs, 
W.,  Constitutional  History  of  England  (1875). — 
Thomas,  F.  S.,  The  Ancient  Exchequer  of  England 
(1«48).]  E.  A.  M. 

Exchequer,  Present  Constitution  of. 
The  Exchequer  is  the  national   purse  or  re- 


ceptacle into  which  (a)  all  the  public  revenues 
are  paid,  and  out  of  which  (6)  all  public  ex- 
penditure is  defrayed.  The  moneys  paid  into 
the  exchequer  constitute  in  the  aggregate  the 
consolidated  fund  of  the  United  Kingdom  (see 
Consolidated  Fund),  of  which  the  local  situa- 
tion or  receptacle  is  in  practice  at  the  Banks  of 
England  and  Ireland,  where  all  such  moneys  are 
carried  to  a  general  account,  operated  upon  by 
the  commissioners  of  the  ti'easury,  and  known 
as  the  "Consolidated  Fund  Account,"  or  Ex- 
chequer Account. 

a.  The  following  is  the  machinery  by  which 
the  exchequer  is  supplied,  viz. : 

In  the  fiscal  system  of  the  United  Kingdom 
the  financial  year  does  not  coincide  with  the 
calendar  year,  but  is  reckoned  from  the  1st  of 
April  to  the  31st  of  March.  Towards  the  close 
of  one  financial  year  or  beginning  of  the  next — 
that  is  to  say,  in  the  month  of  March  or  April 
— the  chancellor  of  the  exchequer  lays  before 
the  House  of  Commons  his  budget  (see  Budget), 
which  is  a  statement  of  the  revenue  and  ex- 
penditure of  the  outgoing,  and  the  estimated 
revenue  and  expenditure  of  the  incoming,  year. 
He  first  estimates  the  revenue  of  the  incoming 
year  on  the  assumption  that  the  existing  scheme 
of  taxation  will  be  continued  unaltered  by  par- 
liament. If  he  considers  that  on  this  basis  the 
revenue  of  the  year  will  exceed  the  expenditure, 
he  generally  proposes  to  abolish  or  reduce  cer- 
tain taxes  ;  if  the  contrary,  to  raise,  increase, 
or  extend  them.  It  is  not  necessary  that  the 
scheme  of  the  chancellor  of  the  exchequer,  so 
far  as  the  revenue  which  he  anticipates  is 
founded  upon  the  existing  basis  of  taxation, 
should  be  sanctioned  as  a  whole  by  parliament ; 
for,  in  the  absence  of  an  enactment  to  the  con- 
trary, all  taxes  and  imposts  go  on  from  year  to 
year  without  express  legislative  renewal,  except 
the  tea-duty  and  the  income-tax.  If,  there- 
fore, the  House  of  Commons  approves  of  the 
budget  proposals,  all  that  is  necessary,  in  the 
first  instance,  is  that  it  should,  by  resolutions 
passed  in  committee  of  ways  and  means,  sanction 
the  levy  of  tea-duty  and  income-tax  during  the 
financial  year,  at  the  old  rates,  or  at  new  rates 
proposed  by  the  chancellor  of  the  exchequer, 
as  the  case  may  be  ;  and  that  it  should  also 
sanction  by  similar  resolutions  any  changes 
which  he  proposes  in  other  duties  or  taxes. 
These  resolutions  are  subsequently  confirmed, 
as  soon  as  the  exigencies  of  parliamentary 
business  will  allow,  by  acts  of  parliament  pre- 
pared for  the  purpose,  which  are  now  called 
Finance  Acts.  At  this  stage  the  arrangements 
for  supplying  the  exchequer  with  the  necessary 
revenue  during  the  financial  year  are  formally 
complete.  The  commissioners  of  customs  and 
excise  and  of  inland  revenue,  acting  under 
the  directions  of  the  commissioners  of  tlie 
treasury,  levy  the  duties  and  taxes  prescribed 
by   statute ;    the    post  office   continues    from 


'82 


EXCHEQUER,  PRESENT  CONSTITUTION  OF 


year  to  year  its  profitable  labours  ;  and  the 
moneys  derived  from  these  several  sources  are, 
together  with  the  hereditary  revenues  of  the 
crown,  and  certain  other  miscellaneous  items, 
paid  in  by  their  collectors  as  they  accrue  to  the 
exchequer  account  at  the  Banks  of  England  and 
Ireland. 

b.  Such  is  the  manner  in  which  the  exchequer 
is  filled.  It  is  now  necessary  to  explain  the 
procedure  by  which  its  treasures  are  disbursed. 
From  the  foregoing  account  it  will  be  seen  that 
the  levying  of  the  national  revenue  is  com- 
pletely under  the  control  of  parliament.  The 
control  of  parliament  over  the  national  expendi- 
ture— or,  in  other  words,  over  the  disbursements 
of  the  exchequer — is  no  less,  in  fact  if  anything 
it  is  more  complete.  The  expenditure  of  any 
given  year  is  divided  into  two  classes.  1.  The 
first  consists  of  charges,  more  or  less  permanent 
in  their  nature,  which  are  authorised  by  act  of 
parliament  either  for  a  given  period  or  until 
the  act  authorising  them  has  been  repealed. 
These  charges  therefore  do  not  form  the  subject 
of  an  annual  vote  of  parliament,  but  are  paid 
as  they  fall  due  under  the  authority  of  the  act 
which  grants  them.  They  are  called  fixed 
charges  on  the  Consolidated  Fund  (q.v.),  and 
comprise  the  interest,  sinking  fund,  and  cost  of 
management  of  the  public  debt ;  the  civil  list, 
or  dotation  of  the  crown  ;  the  allowances  to 
members  of  the  royal  family  ;  certain  pensions 
granted  for  public  services  ;  the  salaries  of  the 
judges  ;  and  of  certain  high  officers  whose  inde- 
pendence is  thought  to  be  better  guaranteed  by 
permanent  grant  than  by  annual  vote.  In  the 
finance  accounts  of  the  United  Kingdom  for 
1912-13  the  sums  issued  from  the  exchequer 
for  fixed  charges  on  the  consolidated  fund 
amounted  to  £24,500,000,  or  rather  less  than 
one-seventh  of  the  total  expenditure.  In  addi- 
tion to  those  charges  there  were  payments  to 
local  taxation  accounts,  etc.,  amounting  to 
£9,653,000  assigned  by  various  acts  to  local 
purposes.  2.  The  ordinary  charges  of  the 
military,  naval,  and  civil  government,  and  of 
collecting  the  revenue,  form  the  second  class 
of  public  expenditure.  They  are  annually 
granted  by  parliament,  and  as  they  are  voted 
by  the  House  of  Commons  in  committee  of 
supply,  they  are  called  the  supply  services  (see 
Supply,  Parliamentary).  The  amount  issued 
from  the  exchequer  in  1912-13  on  account  of 
expenditure  on  the  supply  services  is  returned 
at  £151,604,000,  being  nearly  five-sixths  of 
the  total  expenditure  of  the  year. 

Money  to  defray  a  fixed  charge  on  the  consoli- 
dated fund  is  taken outoftheexchequerunder  the 
authority  of  the  special  act  of  parliament  which 
fixes  the  charges.  The  following  is  the  machinery 
by  which  money  for  supply  services  is  obtained. 

The  government  submits  to  the  House  of 
Commons  estimates  of  the  sums  which  it  re- 
quires, under  the  several  heads  or  denomina- 


tions of  service,  known  as  votes  (as  the  House 
of  Commons  votes  them).  Each  of  these  votes 
is  discussed  at  such  length  as  the  House 
thinks  proper,  and  any  item  in  a  vote  can  be 
rejected,  but  the  House  cannot  add  a  penny 
to  a  vote,  it  being  a  constitutional  maxim 
that  expenditure  can  only  be  voted  on  the 
recommendation  of  the  crown.  Nor  has  the 
House  of  Lords  any  share  in  the  matter.  It 
is  a  co-ordinate  branch  of  the  legislature  ;  but 
the  privilege  of  voting  the  money  of  the  sub- 
ject is  exclusively  reserved  to  the  represen- 
tative chamber. 

Suppose  now  that  the  House  of  Commons 
has  voted  the  proposed  expenditure.  This 
alone  would  not  enable  the  government  to  act ; 
for,  although  the  exchequer  is  being  daily  filled 
with  the  produce  of  taxes,  it  cannot  be  availed 
of  without  further  parliamentary  authority  for 
defraying  the  expenditure  which  the  House  of 
Commons  has  sanctioned. 

The  House  of  Commons  alone  criticises  and 
sanctions  the  proposed  expenditure,  but  the 
doors  of  the  exchequer  cannot  be  unlocked 
without  the  authority  of  an  act  of  parliament. 
Accordingly,  acts  are  passed  from  time  to  time, 
each  parliamentary  session,  authorising  certain 
sums  to  be  taken  out  of  the  exchequer  to  defray 
expenditure  sanctioned  up  to  date.  These  acte 
are  often  referred  to  as  ''  ways  and  means  acts." 
Their  parliamentary  title  is  "  consolidated  fund 
acts,"  and  the  language  in  which  they  are 
couched  is  instructive,  as  summarising  the  pro- 
cedure of  parliamentary  supply,  viz.  : — "Most 
Gracious  Sovereign. — We,  your  Majesty's  most 
dutiful  and  loyal  subjects,  the  Commons  of  the 
United  Kingdom  of  Great  Britain  and  Ireland, 
in  Parliament  assembled,  towards  making  good 
the  supply  which  we  have  cheerfully  granted  to 
your  Majesty  in  this  Session  of  Parliament, 
have  resolved  to  grant  unto  your  Majesty  the 
sums  hereinafter  mentioned,  and  do  therefore 
most  humbly  beseech  your  Majesty  that  it  may 
be  enacted,  and  be  it  enacted  by  the  King's 
Most  Excellent  Majesty,  etc.,  etc."  (Then 
follow,  after  the  usual  preamble  of  an  act  of 
parliament,  provisions  authorising  the  treasury 
to  issue  certain  sums  out  of  the  exchequer.) 
Thus  the  House  of  Commons  grants  the  money ; 
but  the  three  estates  of  the  realm  conjointly 
authorise,  by  statute,  the  taking  of  money  out 
of  the  exchequer.  In  the  parliamentary  session 
of  1910  three  such  Consolidated  Fund  Acts 
were  passed  (10  Edw.  7,  c.  4  ;  1  Geo.  5,  c.  9  ; 
10  Edw.  7  and  1  Geo.  5,  c.  14).  The  last  of 
these  acts  passed  each  session  is  called  the 
"  Appropriation  Act "  ;  it  sets  out  in  detail  all 
the  votes  which  the  House  of  Commons  haa 
sanctioned  in  supply,  and  applies  to  them,  and 
to  them  only,  the  required  sums  of  money  out  of 
the  exchequer,  thus  strengthening  parliamentary 
control  over  administration  by  making  it  illegal 
for  the  executive  to  expend  upon  one  service 


EXCHEQUER,  PRESENT  CONSTITUTION  OF 


783 


money  which  has  been  voted  for  another.  This 
practice  of  appropriating  the  supplies,  as  it  is 
called,  dates  from  the  Revolution  of  1688. 

Thus  it  wiU  be  seen  that  the  control  of 
parliament  over  the  exchequer  is  complete. 
A  fixed  charge  on  the  consolidated  fund  can 
only  be  paid  on  the  authority  of  a  special 
act  of  parliament,  and  a  supply  service  can 
only  be  paid  after  it  has  been  voted  by  the 
House  of  Commons  in  committee  of  supply, 
and  after  the  disbursement  of  the  necessary 
funds  has  been  authorised  by  a  consolidated 
fund  act  or  by  a  ways  and  means  act.  The 
practical  security  that  these  conditions  are  ob- 
served and  that  ministers  do  not  take  money 
from  the  exchequer  for  purposes  which  parlia- 
ment has  not  approved  is  that  money  is  only 
issued  out  of  the  exchequer  with  the  permission 
of  an  independent  officer  appointed  under  the 
Exchequer  and  Audit  Departments  Act,  1866 
(29  &  30  Vict.  c.  39),  and  styled  the  comptroller 
and  auditor-general,  over  whom  the  executive 
government  has  no  control,  and  who  guards 
the  exchequer  on  behalf  of  parliament.  Before 
any  money  can  be  issued  from  the  exchequer 
the  treasury  has  to  requisition  and  obtain  from 
tliat  officer  a  credit  or  credits  on  the  Exchequer 
accounts  at  the  Bank  of  England  and  Bank  of 
Ireland,  and  such  credits  are  only  gi-anted  if  he 
has  satisfied  himself  that  the  demand  is  for  a 
service  authorised  by  parliament.  Then  parlia- 
ment provides  against  ministers  obtaining  money 
from  the  exchequer  for  a  purpose  which  parlia- 
ment has  authorised,  but  spending  it  otherwise, 
by  the  fact  that  every  department  to  which  public 
money  is  issued  is  ol3liged,  under  the  Exchequer 
and  Audit  Act  (29  &  30  Vict.  c.  39),  to  render 
an  account  of  the  disposal  of  such  money  to 
the  officer  above  mentioned,  the  comptroller  of 
the  exchequer,  etc. 

It  will  here  be  proper  to  say  a  word  as  to  the 
difference  between  the  *'  committee  of  supply  " 
and  "  committee  of  ways  and  means  "  in  rela- 
tion to  public  finance.  In  committee  of  supply 
the  House  of  Commons  determine  how  nmch 
money  government  shall  be  allowed  to  spend  ; 
in  committee  of  ways  and  means  it  considers 
where  the  money  thus  authorised  to  spend  is 
to  come  from.  "The  committee  of  supply 
considers  what  specific  grants  of  money  shall 
be  voted  as  supplies  demanded  by  the  crown 
for  the  service  of  the  current  year,  and  ex- 
plained by  the  estimates  and  accounts  prepared 
by  the  executive  government,  and  referred  by 
the  House  to  the  committee.  The  committee 
of  ways  and  means  determines  in  what  manner 
the  necessary  funds  shall  be  raised  to  meet  the 
grants  which  are  voted  by  the  committee  of 
supply,  and  which  are  otherwise  required  for 
the  public  service.  The  former  committee  con- 
trols the  public  expenditure,  the  latter  provides 
the  public  income.  The  one  authorises  the 
payment  of  money,  the  other  sanctions  the  im- 


position of  taxes  and  the  application  of  public 
revenue  not  otherwise  applicable  to  the  service 
of  the  year"  (May's  Parlia/nentary  Practice, 
p.  616,  ed.  1879). 

The  grants  which  have  been  described  are 
made  by  parliament  to  the  crown,  and  the 
sovereign,  by  royal  order,  places  them  at  the 
disposal  of  his  finance  department,  the  treasury. 
The  treasury  from  time  to  time,  as  money  is 
wanted,  issues  out  of  the  exchequer  to  the 
accounts  of  the  paymaster -general  or  the 
Revenue  Departments,  as  the  case  ma,y  be,  such 
sums  as  may  be  required  to  meet  the  expendi- 
ture of  the  various  services. 

Careful  distinction  must  be  drawTi  between 
the  exchequer  and  the  treasury.  The  exchequer 
is  the  national  purse,  the  treasury  is  the  finance 
department  of  the  state,  which  controls  the 
exchequer,  on  behalf  of  the  executive  govern- 
ment, subject  to  the  check  and  audit  of  the 
comptroller  and  auditor-general  acting  on  be- 
half of  parliament.  The  treasury  is  governed 
by  a  board  of  commissioners,  of  whom  the  chan- 
cellor of  the  exchequer  is  one.  The  treasury, 
through  the  chancellor  of  the  exchequer, 
moves  parliament  at  the  commencement  of  the 
financial  year  to  provide  the  means  of  carrying 
on  the  government.  It  is  to  the  account  of  the 
treasury,  the  exchequer  account,  that  all  public 
moneys  are  paid  into  the  banks  of  England  and 
Ireland,  and  it  is  the  treasury  again  which 
Avhen  the  supplies  granted  to  the  crown  by 
parliament  have  been  placed  by  the  sovereign 
at  the  disposal  of  her  finance  department,  the 
treasury,  supervises  and  controls  the  expendi- 
ture of  such  supplies  throughout  every  branch 
of  the  public  service.  The  duties  of  the 
treasury,  as  the  department  responsible  for  the 
administration  of  the  exchequer,  are  thus  sum- 
marised by  Mr.  H.  D.  Traill  in  his  Central 
Government  (English  Citizen  Series,  1881), 
viz.  : — 

1.  To  provide  the  means  of  meeting  the 
necessary  yearly  expenditure  on  the  military, 
naval,  and  civil  services  of  the  nation. 

2.  To  exercise  a  general  control  and  super- 
vision over  the  amount  and  details  of  that  ex- 
penditure. 

3.  To  revise  and  regulate  the  internal  or 
domestic  expenditure  of  the  other  public  offices 
of  the  state,  and  generally  to  exercise  such  a 
superintendent  authority  over  the  financial 
management  of  such  offices  as  is  implied  in 
these  revisory  and  regulative  powers. 

4.  To  decide  upon  appeals  from  its  own  sub- 
ordinate departments  in  all  cases  arising  out  of 
the  receipt  of  revenue,  and 

5.  To  determine  as  to  the  remission  of  fines 
and  forfeitures  due  to  the  crown. 

The  board  of  treasury  consists  of  five  com- 
missioners, namely  :   the  first  commissioner  or 
first  lord  of  the  treasury,  an  office  which  is 
I  generally  held  by  the   prime  minister  ;    the 


784 


EXCHEQUER  (SCOTLAND)~EXCHEQUER  BILL 


chancellor  of  the  exchequer ;  and  three  other 
commissioners,  known  as  junior  lords  of  the 
treasury.  The  financial  powers  of  the  treasury 
are  in  effect  centred  in  the  chancellor  of  the 
exchequer,  who  may  therefore  be  described  as 
the  finance  minister  of  the  United  Kingdom. 

Exchequer  (Scotland)  ;  originally  a  de- 
partment or  committee  of  the  Scottish  parlia- 
ment, by  the  Treaty  of  Union,  Art.  19,  this 
court  was  to  continue  until  a  new  revenue 
court  should  be  established  in  Scotland.  By 
6  Anne  c.  26,  a  new  exchequer  court  was 
established  in  Scotland  on  the  English  model, 
the  judges  being  the  lord  high  treasurer  of 
Great  Britain,  the  lord  chief  baron,  and  four 
barons  of  exchequer.  It  was  an  attempt  to 
establish  a  common  judicatory  for  England 
and  Scotland,  and  aU  members  of  the  English 
or  Scottish  bars  were  entitled  to  plead  before 
it,  and  the  privileges  of  senators  of  the  Scottish 
college  of  justice  were  conferred  on  the  barons. 
It  had  exclusive  jurisdiction  over  customs,  ex- 
cise, and  other  revenues  of  the  crown,  and  all 
honours  and  estates  accruing  to  the  crown,  and 
the  gift  of  the  office  of  tutor  dative,  or  guardian 
appointed  by  the  court.  English  forms  of  pro- 
cedure were  to  be  used.  Other  powers  were  the 
passing  of  sheriffs'  accounts,  superintending 
the  administration  of  the  sovereign's  feudal 
superiorities,  dues,  and  fines  of  crown  vassals, 
etc.  By  3  Will.  IV.  c.  13,  all  powers  of  this 
court  bearing  on  revenue  were  transferred  to 
commissioners  of  the  treasury  in  London,  but 
its  legal  jurisdiction  was  preserved.  Other 
statutes  modified  and  altered  the  court.  Finally 
by  the  court  of  exchequer.  Art.  1856  (19  & 
20  Vict.  c.  56)  it  was  abolished  as  a  separate 
court  and  all  its  former  jurisdiction  was 
transferred  to  the  court  of  session,  becoming 
the  revenue  department  of  that  court.  The 
English  forms  and  terms  were  assimilated  to 
those  of  the  court  of  session,  and  one  of  the 
lords  ordinary  to  be  named  by  the  crown  was 
to  act  in  exchequer  causes. 

[Clerk  and  Scrope's  Historical  View  of  the  Court 
of  Exchequer  in  Scotland;  and  Mackay's  Prac- 
tice, vol.  1.  43,  192.]  J.  w,  B.  I. 

Exchequer  Bill.  This  is  one  of  the 
.securities  on  which  the  British  exchequer 
formerly  raised  money  for  tempoi-ary  purposes. 
(See  Exchequer  Bill,  History  of.)  The 
bills  bore  a  fixed  rate  of  interest,  not  above 
6^  or  below  2  per  cent,  and  were  a  favourite 
security  with  bankers,  merchants,  and  others, 
who  required  a  good  security  for  a  short  period. 

Exchequer  Bill,  History  of.  Exche^^uer 
bills  were  a  form  of  security  on  which  the 
government,  under  the  authority  of  parlia- 
ment, might  borrow  money  for  the  service  of 
the  state.  They  have  been  in  use  since  the 
year  1696,  and  had  their  origin  in  the 
scarcity  of  tlie  circulating  medium  during  the 
great  recoinage  at  that  time.      Their  inven- 


tion as  a  substitute  for  "money"  is  attributed 
to  Charles  Montague,  the  chancellor  of  the 
exchequer  in  William  the  Third's  reign,  and 
may  be  said  to  have  been  the  first  intro- 
duction of  a  paper  currency  organised  by  the 
state. 

The  first  exchequer  bills  were  issued  under 
the  authority  of  7  Will.  III.  c.  31,  and  were 
to  "pass  in  payments  from  any  person  or 
persons  to  any  other  person  or  persons  that 
shall  be  willing  to  accept  and  take  the  same." 
They  were  made  out  in  sums  as  low  as  £5  and 
£10,  and  were  to  bear  a  daily  interest  not  ex- 
ceeding 3d.  per  cent  per  diem.  The  object  of 
the  inventor  of  these  bills,  however,  was  not 
realised.  They  were  received  with  so  little 
favour  that,  out  of  £1,500,000  authorised  to 
be  issued,  only  about  £160,000  got  into  circu- 
lation ;  an  amount  too  limited  to  give  any 
relief  to  the  monetary  difficulties  of  the  time. 
In  1697,  under  Acts  8  and  9  Will.  III.  c.  8 
and  c.  20,  their  use  was  considerably  extended 
by  making  them  pass  in  payment  of  all  taxes, 
duties,  etc.,  and  "in  all  payments  at  the  ex- 
chequer due  to  the  king."  Originally  ex- 
chequer bills  were,  like  the  ordinary  loans  at 
the  exchequer,  charged  upon  the  produce  of 
certain  specified  duties  imposed  or  renewed  by 
the  act  authorising  the  issue  of  the  bills.  As, 
however,  it  frequently  happened  that  the  duties 
so  appropriated  proved  insufficient  to  pay  off 
the  loans  raised  thereon,  it  subsequently  be- 
came the  practice  to  make  the  bills  payable 
out  of  the  general  supplies  granted  by  parlia- 
ment year  by  year.  This  practice  did  not 
extend  to  the  bills  charged  on  the  annual  malt 
duty  and  land-tax,  which  duties  continued  to 
be  specially  appropriated,  although  they  often 
were  deficient  and  had  to  be  made  good  out  of 
the  supplies  of  the  following  year.  In  1763-64 
exchequer  bills  entirely  superseded  the  old  form 
of  loans  at  the  exchequer,  and  for  a  period  of 
ninety  years,  i.e.  until  1853,  continued  with 
cue  or  two  exceptions  to  be  the  only  form  of 
temporary  security  on  which  money  was  bor- 
rowed either  to  meet  the  ordinary  service  grants 
of  parliament  or  for  loans  granted  for  purposes 
of  a  local  character.  Amongst  the  latter  may 
be  mentioned  the  building  of  churches,  public 
works,  poor  relief,  Irish  tithes,  Shannon  naviga- 
tion, relief  of  West  India  proprietors,  etc.  Tha 
largest  amount  of  exchequer  bills  issued  in  anj- 
one  year  was  in  1813,  when  it  reached  the  total 
of  over  £54,000, 000.  The  amount  of  exchequei 
bills  in  circulation  has  at  various  times  been 
reduced  by  a  process  called  "funding,"  i.e.  by 
the  creation  of  "funded  debt"  in  lieu  thereof. 
The  usual  course  was  to  offer  government  stock 
to  the  public  at  a  given  price  to  be  subscribed 
for  either  in  exchequer  bills,  or  money,  or  both. 
The  bills  so  subscribed  were  cancelled,  and  the 
money  subscribed  was  applied  in  paying  off 
other  exchequer  bills  on  their  maturity.     In 


EXCHEQUER  BOND 


785 


eases  where  the  bills  required  to  be  funded  have 
been  held  entirely  by  the  Bank  of  England  or 
by  the  national  debt  commissioners,  the  ex- 
change of  bills  for  stock  has  been  effected  by 
arrangement,  but  always  under  statutory 
authority.  The  first  instance  of  funding  was 
in  1709,  Avhen  exchequer  bills  with  the  ac- 
crued interest  thereon,  together  amounting  to 
£1,775,000,  were  funded.  Until  1797  there 
were  only  two  further  fundings,  viz.  £2,000,000 
in  1717  and  £986,800  in  1746.  From  1797 
to  1858,  when  the  last  "  funding  "  of  exchequer 
bills  took  place,  no  less  a  sum  than  £143,000,000 
was  cancelled  by  the  creation  of  funded  debt, 
of  which  about  £105,000,000  was  cancelled 
during  the  period  of  twenty- five  years,  from 
1797  to  1821  inclusive.  The  largest  amount 
of  exchequer  bills  funded  at  one  time  was 
£27,262,000  in  ]  818-19.  In  1861,  under  the 
provisions  of  Act  24  Vict.  c.  5,  exchequer  bills 
ceased  to  be  issued  annually  and  to  bear  a  daily 
rate  of  interest.  The  issue  of  exchequer  bills 
at  the  present  time  is  regulated  by  the  Act  29 
Vict,  c,  25.  They  are  of  the  nominal  value  of 
£100,  £200,  £500,  or  £1000,  and  are  current 
for  a  period  of  five  years,  but  they  may  be  sent 
in  for  payment,  after  due  notice,  at  the  expira- 
tion of  each  twelve  months  from  the  date  of  the 
bills  during  their  legal  currency,  and  may  be 
paid  in  for  customs  or  inland  revenue  duties  at 
any  time  in  the  last  six  months  of  each  year 
of  their  currency.  The  rate  of  interest  is  fixed 
and  advertised  by  the  Treasury  every  half-year, 
and  varies  with  the  rate  of  interest  prevailing 
in  the  money  market  at  the  time.  The  bills  are 
prepared  and  issued  by  tlie  Bank  of  England  who 
receive  an  allowance  for  the  management  of  the 
same.  There  has  been  no  new  issue  of  exchequer 
bills,  beyond  the  periodical  renewals,  since  1861. 
They  have  been  gradually  superseded  by  Ex- 
chequer Bonds  and  Treasury  Bills  (q.v.), 
and  there  are  none  extant  at  the  present 
time.  G.  H.  H. 

Exchequer  Bond.  Unlike  exchequer  bills, 
these  securities  run  for  a  specific  period,  say, 
two  or  three  years  from  the  date  of  issue. 
The  bonds  bear  coupons,  but  may  be  registered 
or  inscribed  in  the  books  of  the  Bank  of 
England,  in  which  case  no  coupons  would  be 
available,  and  the  half-yearly  interest  Avould 
have  to  be  applied  for  personally.  a.  e. 

Exchequer  Bond,  History  of. — These 
are  securities  on  which  money  may  be  bor- 
rowed by  the  government  under  the  author- 
ity of  parliament.  They  are  regulated  by  the 
Exchequer  Bills  and  Bonds  Act  (29  Vict.  c.  25), 
but  they  differ  from  exchequer  bills  by  being 
issued  for  fixed  periods,  generally  for  one  to 
three  years,  and  bearing  a  fixed  rate  of  interest. 
In  the  absence  of  any  special  provision  in  an 
act  authorising  money  to  be  raised  by  this 
security,  the  principal  of  exchequer  bonds  is 
repayable  by  votes  of  parliament.  Formerly, 
VOL.  r. 


when  bonds  had  matured,  and  it  was  found 
necessary  to  replace  them  by  new  bonds,  special 
statutory  authority  had  to  be  obtained  in  each  ' 
case.  It  is  usual  now  to  take  power  in  the  act 
authorising  the  issue  of  bonds  to  replace  them 
on  maturity  by  new  bonds  or  other  securities. 
Exchequer  bonds  may,  under  treasury  warrant, 
be  delivered  up  to  be  registered  or  inscribed  in 
the  books  of  the  Bank  of  England,  and  trans- 
ferable certificates  issued  in  lieu  thereof.  This 
class  of  security  has  generally  been  made  use  of 
for  special  services  only. 

Exchequer  bonds  were  first  introduced  in 
1853  by  Mr.  Gladstone,  in  connection  with  his 
scheme  for  redeeming  or  commuting  certain 
three  per  cent  stocks  and  South  Seas  annuities. 
Under  16  Vict.  c.  23,  holders  of  these  stocks 
were  offered,  as  one  alternative,  the  option  of 
taking  exchequer  bonds  in  exchange  for  their 
stock.  The  bonds  were  to  be  payable  to  bearer, 
so  as  to  be  readily  transferable  ;  to  bear  interest 
at  2|  per  cent  per  annum  payable  half-yearly 
until  1864,  and  thenceforward  at  2^  per  cent 
per  annum  until  1894.  They  were  to  be 
ofiered  for  sale,  the  proceeds  to  be  applied  in 
paying  off  dissentient  holders  of  stock,  and 
they  could  be  issued  in  exchange  for  and  in 
cancellation  of  exchequer  bills  ;  only  £418,300, 
however,  were  issued,  of  which  £408,900  were 
in  cancellation  of  exchecjuer  bills.  Subsequent 
acts  made  these  bonds  repayable  out  of  moneys 
voted  by  parliament,  and  until  such  time  in- 
terest would  continue  to  be  paid  at  2^  per  cent. 
Power  was  also  taken  to  replace  them  in  1894 
by  new  bonds,  to  be  issued  for  any  term  not 
exceeding  six  years.  There  was  an  issue  in 
1854-55  of  £6,000,000,  for  periods  not  exceed- 
ing six  years,  to  defray  expenses  connected 
with  the  Russo-Turkish  and  South  African 
wars.  Between  1874-75  and  1879-80 
£7,750,000  was  borrowed  from  the  National 
Debt  Commissioners  on  Exchequer  bonds  with 
three  years'  currency,  for  the  purpose  of  grant- 
ing loans  to  local  authorities  for  public  works. 
By  44  &  45  Vict.  c.  55  they  were  converted 
into  permanent  funded  debt.  In  1876,  under 
39  Vict.  c.  1,  £4,000,000  was  borrowed  on 
exchequer  bonds,  also  from  the  National  Debt 
Commissioners,  for  the  purchase  of  176,602 
shares  in  the  Suez  Canal  Company  (the  value 
of  these  is  now,  1913,  over  £39,000,000).  An 
advance  of  £400,000  in  1885-86  to  the  govern- 
ment of  the  Cape  of  Good  Hope  for  the  con- 
struction of  a  railway  was  provided  by  the  issue 
of  exchequer  bonds  repayable  by  moneys  voted 
by  parliament.  The  colony  repaid  the  advance 
in  1890,  and  the  bonds  were  paid  off  as  provided. 
The  interest  on  the  bonds  was  paid  by  the 
colony.  Under  the  National  Debt  Redemption 
Act  1889  (52  Vict.  c.  4)  bonds  to  the  amount 
of  £18,100,000  were  issued  to  pay  off  holders 
of  three  per  cent  stocks  who  had  dissented  from 
Mr.  Goschen's  conversion  scheme  of  1888.     Of 

3b 


786 


EXCHEQUER,  CLOSING  OF  THE— EXCISE 


this  amount,  bonds  for  £12,800,000,  which 
were  held  by  the  national  debt  commissioners, 
were,  by  the  National  Debt  (Conversion  of 
Exchequer  Bonds)  Act  1892,  converted  into 
permanent  funded  debt.  Since  1890  the 
principal  issues  have  been  £24,000,000  for  the 
purposes  of  the  war  in  South  Africa;  £6,000,000 
for  capital  expenditure  authorised  by  Naval 
and  Military  Works  Acts  ;  £2,600,000  under 
the  Cunard  Agreement  (Money)  Act  1904 ; 
£10,000,000  under  the  Finance  Act  1905,  to 
redeem  Bonds  issued  for  the  South  African 
War;  and  £21,000,000  under  the  War  Loan 
(Redemption)  Act  1910.  In  1905  a  new 
feature  was  introduced  into  this  class  of  security. 
The  Bonds  issued  under  the  Finance  Act  of 
that  year  were  made  redeemable  in  ten  years 
from  the  date  of  issue  by  annual  drawings  of 
one-tenth  part  of  the  total  issue  in  each  year, 
and  special  provision  was  made  for  the  annual 
redemptions  by  the  appropriation  of  the 
requisite  sum  out  of  the  new  sinking  fund  of 
the  previous  financial  year.  The  total  amount 
of  Exchequer  Bonds  now  (1914)  outstanding  is 
£8,695,249.  G.  H.  H. 

Exchequer,  Closing  of  the  (1672).  The 
only  part  of  the  public  debt  which  was  in- 
curred before  the  revolution  of  1688  originated 
in  the  closing  of  the  exchequer  on  2nd  January 
1672-73.  Maladministration  of  the  finances, 
the  sale  of  Dunkirk,  and  the  disastrous  close  of 
the  first  Dutch  war,  undermined  the  credit  of 
Charles  II.,  which  had  been  good  for  some 
years  following  the  restoration.  In  1666  the 
Commons  proposed  to  appoint  commissioners 
to  examine  the  accounts  of  those  through  whose 
hands  the  money  granted  for  the  war  had  passed. 
The  bill  was  delayed  in  the  Lords  till  the 
prorogation.  Commissioners  were  appointed 
two  years  later,  and  in  consequence  of  their 
report  the  treasurer  of  the  navy  was  expelled 
the  House  of  Commons.  It  was  therefore  im- 
possible to  apply  to  the  Commons  for  further 
supplies  to  execute  the  secret  treaty  with  Louis 
XIV.  which  Charles  signed  at  Dover  in  May 
1670.  In  the  emergency  it  was  suggested 
that  the  sum  of  £1,328,526,  the  total  amount 
borrowed  from  the  bankers  and  others  on  the 
security  of  the  supplies,  should  be  appropriated 
with  a  view  to  overcoming  the  financial  diflS- 
culties  of  entering  on  the  Dutch  war.  In 
1667  Charles  had  published  a  declaration  to 
secure  inviolably  the  course  of  payments  at 
the  exchequer,  both  with  regard  to  principal 
and  interest.  But,  on  2nd  January  1672-73, 
he  issued  a  proclamation  to  the  efiect  that 
all  payments  upon  assignations  at  the  ex- 
chequer would  be  suspended  for  one  year. 
The  consternation  in  the  city  was  great ;  the 
bankers  were  unable  to  meet  their  engagements, 
and  many  people  were  ruined.  To  quiet  the 
public  mind,  the  king  promised  to  pay  6  per 
cent  while  the  money  was  detained,  and  in 


1676  letters  patent  were  issued,  charging  the 
king's  hereditary  revenue  with  the  interest, 
which  amounted  to  rather  more  than  £79,000 
per  annum.  This  engagement  was  regularly  kept 
until  the  year  before  Charles's  death,  when  pay- 
ment was  stopped.  The  creditors  tried  for 
twelve  years,  without  success,  to  get  legal 
redress,  until,  in  1697,  judgment  was  given 
against  the  government.  Somers,  the  chancellor, 
afterwards  set  aside  this  decision,  notwith- 
standing the  fact  that  ten  out  of  the  twelve 
judges  were  opposed  to  him.  The  chancellor's 
decree  was  afterwards  reversed  by  the  House  of 
Lords,  and  in  1699  it  was  enacted  that  after  25th 
December  1701  the  hereditary  excise  should 
be  charged  with  the  interest  of  the  principal 
sum,  at  3  per  cent,  redeemable  on  payment  of 
£664,263,  or  half  the  principal.  The  principal 
was  never  repaid,  and  in  1716  it  was  incorpor- 
ated with  other  public  debts  in  the  general  fund 
which  was  then  established.  It  may  therefore 
still  be  regarded  as  part  of  the  national  debt. 

[Grellier,  History  of  the  National  Debt,  p.  12 
seq.  —  Hamilton,  Inquiry  concerning  .  .  .  the 
National  Debt,  p.  &Q ;  State  Trials,  xiv.  pp.  1-114. 
— Hewins,  "Origin  and  Growth  of  the  National 
Debt,"  Co-operative  Annual  for  1889,  p.  228,  229. 
— Thorold  Rogers,  The  first  nine  years  of  the  Bank 
of  England,  8vo,  1887. — Defoe,  Comjpleat  English 
Tradesman,  3rd  ed.  i.  164,  188,  346,  347,  ii.  94. 
There  are  several  pamphlets  dealing  with  the 
subject ;  amongst  these  may  be  mentioned,  The 
Joyful  News  of  Opening  the  Exchequer  to  the 
Goldsmiths  {in  a  letter  by  the  Author  of  the 
Bankers'  Case,  Thos.  Twine),  1677.— The  Case  of 
the  Bankers  and  their  Creditors,  by  a  true  Lover 
of  his  King,  1674. — Considerations  on  the  Gold- 
smiths' Letters  Patent,  1678.  "His  Majesty's 
(Chas.  II, )  patent  to  the  goldsmiths  for  payment 
and  satisfaction  of  their  debt,"  1677  (patent 
granted  to  Sir  Robert  Vyner  for  £416,724,  and 
to  eleven  other  "persons  hereafter  named"  for 
sums  ranging  from  £295,994  down  to  £1784, 
the  interest  at  6  per  cent  to  be  paid  by  the 
quarter).  ]  w.  a.  s.  H. 

EXCISE,  The,  is  the  name  given  collectively 
to  those  duties  which  in  the  fiscal  system  of 
the  United  Kingdom  are  levied  upon  commodi- 
ties  produced  within   tho   kingdom  itself,   as 
distinguished  from  customs  duties  (see  Customs) 
which  are  levied  at  the  ports  upon  commodities 
imported  from  abroad.     The  word  excise  (Latin, 
excido)   signifies    etymologically  something   cut 
off;  as  an  excise  duty  may  in  effect  be  con- 
sidered something  cut  off  or  deducted,  for  the 
benefit  of  the  state,  from  the  price  of  the  article 
as  paid  by  the  consumer.    If  there  were  no  duty 
the  consumer  would  pay  a  lower  price  for  the 
article.     The  price,  therefore,  that  he  actually  . 
"pays  includes  the  duty  ;  whence  it  foUows  that  ■ 
the  duty  itself  is  something  deducted  or  sub-j 
tracted  from  the  actual  price  paid.     The  price  inJ 
fact  is  divided  into  two  parts,  one  part  being] 


EXCISE 


787 


subtracted  from  the  whole  for  the  benefit  of  the 
state,  and  the  remainder  going  to  the  vendor. 

Duties  of  this  character,  whether  levied  on 
articles  produced  at  home  or  imported  from 
abroad,  were  at  first  equally  known  as  excise 
duties,  but  in  revenue  parlance  the  word  has 
long  been  restricted  to  duties  on  native  com- 
modities, those  on  foreign  articles  being  known 
as  the  customs. 

An  excise  duty  properly  so-called  belongs  to 
the  category  of  indirect  taxes,  because  though 
levied  on  the  producer,  its  burden  really  falls 
on  the  consumer.  It  is,  however,  the  practice 
to  classify  under  the  general  head  of  excise  the 
railway  duty  on  passengers,  a  direct  tax  ;  of 
which  the  real  as  well  as  the  apparent  incidence 
generally  falls  on  the  railway  companies  ;  and  a 
large  group  of  assessed  taxes,  being  license  duties 
paid  to  the  state  in  return  for  permission  to  prac- 
tise or  follow  certain  sports,  trades,  or  occupa- 
tions ;  e.g.  the  dog,  game,  and  gun  licenses  and 
the  licenses  on  brewers,  auctioneers,  and  pawn- 
brokers. For  a  considerable  period  previous  to 
their  introduction  into  England  excise  duties 
formed  part  of  the  fiscal  system  of  Holland. 
They  were  first  imposed  in  this  country  in  1643 
by  the  Long  Parliament  in  order  to  raise  funds 
for  the  war  against  King  Charles  the  First. 
The  principal  articles  first  subjected  to  the 
duty  were  ale  and  beer,  cider,  perry,  and  strong 
waters,  to  which  was  soon  afterwards  added  a 
long  list  of  articles  of  food  and  clothing,  e.g. 
flesh,  victuals,  and  salt,  alum,  copperas,  hats, 
saflron,  starch,  and  all  manner  of  silks  and 
stuffs.  The  prime  necessaries  of  life — flesh  and 
salt — were  subsequently  struck  out  of  the  list, 
but,  nevertheless,  the  general  tendency  from 
the  Restoration  (1660)  to  the  administration  of 
Sir  Robert  Walpole  was  rather  to  extend  than 
to  restrict  the  operation  of  these  imports. 

Walpole,  to  whom  the  material  progress  of 
England  is  so  deeply  indebted,  applied  himself 
from  the  first  to  fiscal  reform.  His  biographer. 
Archdeacon  Coxe,  boasts  of  him  that  "he 
found  our  tariff  the  worst  in  the  world  and  left 
it  the  best."  By  economical  administration 
and  the  maintenance  of  a  strictly  pacific  policy 
in  foreign  affairs,  he  enabled  himself  to  help 
forward  the  growing  prosperity  of  the  country 
by  a  substantial  alleviation  of  the  burden  of 
taxation.  One  of  the  main  objects  to  which  he 
set  himself  was  to  make  the  exportation  of  our 
manufactures,  and  the  importation  of  the 
principal  articles  used  in  them,  as  free  as 
possible.  The  reforms  which  with  this  view 
he  carried  out  belong  rather  to  the  history  of 
customs  than  of  excise  ;  but  in  the  department 
of  excise  proper  his  beneficent  activity  made 
itself  felt  in  the  abolition  of  some  duties,  the 
reduction  of  others,  and  the  simplification  of 
many  more.  The  most  famous  and  the  greatest 
of  all  his  schemes,  though  it  ended  in  failure, 
was  the  bill  for  warehousing  wine  and  tobacco, 


generally  known  as  the  Excise  Scheme,  which 
occupies  so  important  a  place  in  our  fiscal  and 
parliamentary  history  that  it  deserves  a  separate 
notice  (see  Excise  Scheme). 

The  history  of  the  excise  since  the  administra- 
tion of  Walpole  cannot  here  be  written  in  extenso. 
It  contains  few  features  of  salient  interest,  nor 
does  it  record   any  convulsion   such   as   that 
which  was  excited  by  his  unlucky  Excise  Scheme. 
It  will  be  observed  on  reference  to  the  follow- 
ing list   that   the   greater  part  of  the   excise 
revenue   is   derived   from    taxes   on    alcoholic 
drinks.       This  is  no  new  fact  ;    more  than  a 
hundred  years  ago  Cowper  drew  attention  to  it 
in  some  indignant  lines  in  "  The  Task." 
"  The  Excise  is  fattened  by  the  rich  result 
Of  all  this  riot,  and  ten  thousand  casks 
For  ever  dribbling  out  their  base  contents 
Touched  by  the  Midas  finger  of  the  State 
Bleed  gold  for  ministers  to  sport  away." 
Such  indignation  is  perhaps  misplaced  ;  as  it  is 
obvious    that  taxation  should  be  imposed  on 
luxuries  rather  than  on  necessaries  ;  and  what- 
ever may  be  thought  of  the  wisdom  of  consum- 
ing alcoholic  drinks,  they  certainly  cannot  be 
classed    among   the    necessaries   of  life.      The 
tendency   of  modern   legislation    has    been    to 
throw   the   largest   possible    burden    of  excise 
taxation  on  alcoholic  drinks,  and  to  exempt,  as 
far  as  possible,  other  articles. 

Chief  Heads  of  Excise  Revenue,  from  the  4th  Report  re- 
lating  to  Customs  and  Excise,  1912-13  (net  receipts)— 

Beer  Duty £13,200,343 

Spirit  Duty 18,432,492 

Railway  Duty 283,929 

Patent  Medicine  Labels         ....  328,319 

Playing  Cards 32,033 

Miscellaneous 205,346 

License  Duties — 

A.  Liquor  Licenses — 

(a)  Manufacturers   .        .        .  £427,051 

(6)  Dealers       ....  126,714 

ic)  Retailers     ....  3,949,829 

{d)  Occasional  licenses,  etc.    .  16,737 

Total  Liquor  Licenses      .  .        .      4,520,334 

B.  Auctioneers,  etc.  .  .  .  87,332 
Hawkers  ....  25,336 
Pawnbrokers.  .  .  .  40,328 
Plate  Dealers  .  .  .  65,920 
Patent    Medicines    (Makers 

and  Dealers)       .        .        .  10,780 
Methylated  and  Motor  Spirit 

(Makers  and  Dealers)  .  14,693 
Tobacco  (Growers  and  Manu- 
facturers) ....  4,736 
Tobacco  (Dealers)  .  .  .  102,408 
Refreshment  Houses  .  .  9,486 
Miscellaneous        .        .        .  694 

Total         ....  ~.        7       861,713 

C.  Male  Servants  .  .  .  16,381 
Carriages  .  .  .  .  35,956 
Motorcars  ....  535,146 
Armorial  Bearings         .        .  6,096 

Total  ....     ~~.        T      592,579 

D.  Gun 20,776 

Game 34,562 

Total  ....      "^^        r~       55,338 

E.  Dog 48,775 

Fines  and  Penalties 2,487 

Total £38,063,688 


788 


EXCISE  SCHEME 


The  Finance  Act  of  1907  directed  that  the 
duties  on  Beer  and  Spirits  and  the  Excise 
Licenses  should  be  paid  into  the  Exchequer,  an 
equivalent  amount  being  issued  to  the  Local 
Taxation  Accounts  out  of  the  Consolidated  Fund. 
The  power  to  levy  the  duties  on  licenses  for  game, 
dogs,  guns,  carriages,  armorial  bearing^,  and  male 
servants  was,  from  1909,  transferred  in  England 
and  Wales  to  County  and  Borough  Councils.  The 
Finance  Act  of  1910  increased  the  Liquor  and 
Motor  Car  Licenses,  but  provided  that  the  pay- 
ments to  the  Local  Taxation  Accounts  arising 
from  these,  and  also  from  the  Beer  and  Spirit 
duties,  should  continue  on  the  scale  of  the  receipts 
from  these  duties  in  1908-9,  the  surplus  being 
retained  for  the  Imperial  Revenue.  This  applies 
to  carriage  licenses  in  Scotland  and  the  whole 
of  the  motor  car  licenses  in  Ireland.  The  fol- 
lowing are  some  of  the  duties  that  have  been 
repealed:  Cider,  1830;  Glass,  1845;  Bricks, 
1850;  Soap,  1852-53;  Paper,  1861;  Hops, 
1862. 

[Dowell,  Hist,  of  Taxation  and  Taxes  in  England 
(ed.  1888) ;  Highmore,  Excise  Laws  ;  Ann.  Rep. 
of  Commissioners  of  Inland  Revenue,  esp.  1870, 
1885,  and  of  Commiss.  of  Customs  and  Excise.] 

EXCISE  SCHEME,  The,  was  the  proposal 
introduced  into  parliament  by  Sir  Robert 
Walpole  in  1733  for  applying  wliat  is  now 
known  as  the  bonded  or  warehousing  system  to 
tobacco,  and  afterwards  to  wine.  Instead  of 
paying  duty,  or  giving  bonds,  the  merchant, 
on  landing  tobacco  from  Maryland  or  Virginia 
in  London  or  Bristol,  was  to  lodge  it  in  ware- 
houses under  the  control  of  excise  officers,  to 
pay  duty  only  as  he  took  it  out  for  home  con- 
sumption, and  if  taken  out  for  re-exportation 
abroad  no  duty  was  to  be  paid.  The  same 
system  was  to  be  extended  to  wine.  Various 
advantages  were  claimed  for  the  change.  First, 
it  would  put  an  end  to  sundry  frauds  on  the 
revenue,  from  smuggling  on  an  immense  scale 
down  to  abuses  which  dishonest  merchants,  prac- 
tising on  discounts,  allowances,  and  drawbacks, 
and  rapacious  lightermen  and  watermen,  carried 
out  at  every  port  in  the  island.  Second,  the 
prevention  of  these  frauds  and  the  decrease  of 
smuggling  would  be  a  great  gain  to  the  honest 
trader.  Third,  accompanied  as  it  was  by  a 
siipplification  of  rates,  this  cheaper  and  easier 
collection  would  be  a  great  advantage  to  the 
revenue.  Fourth,  and  much  the  most  im- 
portant of  all,  it  would  tend  to  make  London 
a  free  port,  and  by  consequence  the  market  of 
the  world.  Such  were  the  advantages  claimed 
for  the  change  at  the  time.  But  another,  and 
not  the  least  important,  may  be  added,  viz. 
that  it  anticipated  and  fulfilled  the  principle  of 
Adam  Smith's  fourth  canon  of  taxation,  by 
taking  as  little  as  possible  out  of  the  pockets 
of  tlie  people  beyond  what  it  yielded  to  the 
revenue.  The  merchant,  relieved  of  the  neces- 
sity of  paying  the  duty  on  the  importation  of 


the  article,  would  have  the  use  of  his  capital  foi 
a  longer  time,  and  would  therefore  be  able  to 
sell  at  a  lower  rate  to  the  consumer.  In  fact 
the  merchant  would  gain,  and  the  state  lose,  the 
interest  on  the  amount  of  the  duty  for  the  period 
between  the  importation  and  the  sale  of  the 
article.  The  merchant's,  and,  through  him, 
the  consumer's  gain  would  in  practice  be  greater 
than  the  state's  loss,  as  the  rate  of  interest 
which  he  would  require  on  his  capital,  in  order 
to  make  his  business  remunerative,  would  greatly 
exceed  the  rate  at  which  the  state  could  borrow ; 
and  moreover  the  loss  of  the  state  was  more 
than  counterbalanced  by  the  economy  of  the  cost 
of  collection,  and  the  prevention  of  fraud,  which 
the  scheme  involved. 

Such  was  the  famous  excise  scheme,  which 
alone  would  suffice  to  establish  Walpole's  repu- 
tation as  a  finance  minister  far  in  advance  of 
his  age.  But  the  public  mind  of  the  time  was 
not  sufficiently  instructed  to  receive  it ;  and 
the  design  had  no  sooner  been  bruited  abroad 
than  a  popular  outcry  arose,  one  of  the  loudest 
and  fiercest  of  which  history  makes  mention, 
which  shook  his  power  to  its  foundations,  and 
at  no  long  distance  of  time  compelled  him  to 
abandon  the  scheme.  The  parliamentary  Op- 
position, whose  motives  need  no  explanation, 
used  all  tueir  powers  of  misrepresentation  against 
Walpole's  plan,  the  object  of  which  was  to  turn 
the  customs  duty  on  the  importation  oi  tobacco 
into  an  excise  duty  on  its  consumption,  as  a 
scheme  for  levying  a  general  excise  over  the 
whole  range  of  commodities.  Food,  clothing, 
and  the  other  necessaries  of  life  were,  they  de- 
clared, to  be  loaded  with  a  crushing  tax.  Every 
man's  house  might  be  invaded  at  any  hour  by 
the  excise  officer.  Every  man's  goods  and  all 
his  dealings  would  be  exposed  to  minute  and 
ceaseless  inquisition.  A  great  standing  army 
of  revenue  officers  would  be  created,  which  would 
overturn  Magna  Charta,  —  even  undermine 
parliament.  Such  were  the  misrepresentations 
to  which  the  credulity  and  factious  spirit  of 
the  people,  and  the  general  unpopularity  of  the 
excise  as  a  whole,  made  them  an  easy  prey. 
The  whole  country  resounded  with  shouts  of 
"  no  slavery,  no  excise,  no  wooden  shoes."  The 
majority  in  the  House  of  Commons  in  favour  of 
the  measure  went  down  from  sixty-one  on  the 
first  resolution  to  seventeen  on  a  subsequent 
issue  ;  and  this  dwindling  of  his  supporters, 
combined  with  the  growing  frenzy  out  of  doors, 
determined  Walpole  to  abandon  a  measure  which 
in  the  inflamed  temper  of  the  nation  could 
hardly  be  put  into  execution  without  an  armed 
force.  "I  will  not,"  he  said,  in  announcing 
his  resolution  to  his  friends,  "  be  a  minister  to 
enforce  taxes  at  the  expense  of  blood." 

The  abandonment  of  the  scheme  was  cele- 
brated throughout  the  country  with  rejoicings 
as  for  a  national  victory  ;  the  crisis  was  long 
remembered  ;   and  it  is  noteworthy  that  the 


EX.  DIVIDEND— EXECUTOR 


789 


popular  feeling,  many  years  after  the  occasion 
had  passed  away,  found  an  exponent  in  the  tory 
prejudices  of  Dr.  Johnson,  who  in  his  dictionary 
defined  "excise"  as  a  "hateful  tax  levied  upon 
commodities,  and  adjudged  not  by  common  judges 
of  property,  but  by  wretches  hired  by  those  to 
whom  excise  is  paid." 

For  a  compact  and  trustworthy  account  of 
Walpole's  excise  scheme  the  reader  is  referred 
to  Lord  Morley's  Walpole  (series  of  English 
Statesmen,  Macmilkn  and  Co.),  from  which 
the  foregoing  description  is  mainly  taken. 

Writing  more  than  forty  years  after  Walpole's 
failure,  Adam  Smith  had  still  to  lament  that  so 
excellent  a  scheme  had  not  been  resumed  by 
subsequent  ministers  {The  Wealth  of  Nations, 
bk.  V.  ch.  ii.).  The  credit  of  resuming  it  was 
reserved  for  William  Pitt,  who  notwithstanding 
the  inevitable  parliamentary  opposition,  carried 
it  into  law  in  1789  (29  Geo.  III.  c.  68).  [See  E. 
Leser,  Ein  Accise-Streit  (Walpole's  Scheme),  1879.] 
The  amounts  raised  by  means  of  the  excise  have 
varied  much  since  the  first  imposition  of  the  tax 
levied  under  this  name.  As  the  articles  subjected 
-to  it  have  differed  very  greatly,  an  exact  comparison 
is  scarcely  possible.  In  the  earlier  periods  the 
excise  was  farmed  out,  and  "in  1657  an  ofter 
was  made  to  give,  for  the  farm  of  the  excise  and 
the  port  duties,  no  less  than  £1,100,000  per 
annum  "  (Dowell,  2nd  ed.  vol.  ii.  p.  13).  Up  to 
the  end  of  the  17th  century,  the  yield  scarcely 
altered.  Dowell  writes  (p.  62),  "the  revenue 
from  inland  duties  had  varied  considerably  in 
different  years.  In  1700  over  a  million,  it  was  in 
1702  nearly  £1,400,000."  During  the  later  half 
of  the  18th  century  great  additions  were  made 
to  the  tax,  though  Walpole's  proposals  were  not 
accepted  (see  Excise). 

The  gross  produce  of  the  tax  has  been  in  round 
figures  at  the  following  dates  : 

1835     .         .         .     £15,200,000 
1855     .         .         .     £15,300,000 
1875     .         .         .     £28,400,000 
1895    .         .         .     £30,500,000 
1905     .         .         .     £35,600,000 
1913    .         .         .     £38,000,000 
EX.  DIVIDEND.     A  stock  exchange  phrase, 
shortened,  as  usual,  to  signify  that  the  price  at 
which  a  given  security  can  be  bought  or  sold 
is  exclusive  of  dividend,  which  has  been,  or  is 
about  to  be  deducted.     Unless  so  specified,  the 
security  in  question  is  cum  dividend,  meaning 
that  the  dividend  or  interest  accrued  since  the 
previous  distribution  is  covered  by  the  purchase 
money.     Certain  securities,  including  corpora- 
tion  bonds,   exchequer   bills,   Indian   deferred 
paper,   English   mortgage   bonds,   never  carry 
interest  in  the  prices,  which  are  quoted  net, 
the  buyer  being  charged  interest  up  to  the  date 
of  the  completion  of  purchase  (see  Ex.  All  ; 
Ex.  New).  .  a.e. 

EX.  DRAWING.  This  phrase  simply  means 
that  in  case  of  the  Drawing  {q.v.)  of  bonds 
at  par,  the  bargain  is  not  to  be  affected  by  the 
price  obtained  by  the  hazard  of  drawing,  and 


the  buyer  gets  no  benefit.  Thus,  a  specific 
government  bond  might  have  been  bought  at 
90  a  week  or  two  before  the  periodical  drawing 
of  such  bonds,  and  the  buyer  would  get  £100 
if  his  bond  happens  to  be  among  the  lucky 
numbers,  unless  the  words  "ex.  drawing" 
formed  part  of  the  contract.  a.  e. 

EXECUTION  is  the  name  of  the  procedure 
by  which  the  judgment  or  order  of  a  court  of 
law  is  enforced.  This  is  generally  done  by 
"writs  of  execution,"  which,  in  the  case  of 
judgments  of  the  high  court,  are  issued  in  the 
central  office  or  a  district  registry,  and  directed 
to  the  sheriff  of  the  county  in  which  they  are 
to  operate.  The  usual  writs  issued  in  the  case 
of  money  claims  are  writs  of  fieri  facias  (cp. 
Fieri  Facias,  Writ  of),  commonly  called  fi.  fa. 
and  writs  of  elegit  (Elegit,  Wkits  of,  q.v.) ; 
claims  are  also  enforced  by  "garnishee  orders," 
viz.  orders  by  virtue  of  Avhich  the  judgment 
creditor  obtains  a  charge  on  debts  owing  to 
the  debtor,  or  "charging  orders"  which  affect 
stocks  or  shares  standing  in  the  debtor's  name, 
or,  if  the  debtor  has  an  equitable  interest  in 
the  property  out  of  which  the  judgment  creditor 
seeks  to  obtain  payment  of  his  debt,  by  the 
appointment  of  a  Receiver  {q.v.)  Judgments 
for  the  recovery  of  land  are  enfoiced  by  ' '  writ 
of  possession,"  and  judgments  for  the  recovery 
of  any  property  other  than  land  by  "writ  of 
delivery"  or  "writ  of  attachment " ;  in  the 
case  of  judgments  directing  a  person  to  do  any 
act,  other  than  the  payment  of  money,  the 
disobedient  jjarty  is  subject  to  imprisoimient 
through  the  instrumentality  of  a  "writ  of 
attachment"  or  through  "committal,"  which  two 
means  of  execution  difier  in  form  only.  Im- 
prisonment on  account  of  the  non-payment  of 
money  has  been  nearly  abolished,  and  where 
it  occurs  it  is  punitive  in  its  nature,  and  not 
merely  a  means  of  enforcing  payment  (see  Debt, 
Imprisonment  for).  e.  s. 

EXECUTOR  ;  the  legal  administrator  of  the 
personal  estate  of  a  deceased  person.  In  Scot- 
land if  appointed  by  written  nomination  of 
the  deceased  he  is  called  executor  nominate,  if 
by  decree  of  the  commissary  court  executor 
dative,  the  former  answering  to  the  English 
executor  the  latter  to  the  English  adminis- 
trator. His  title  in  either  case  is  completed 
by  confi^-mation  (see  Confirmation  of  Ex- 
ecutor) which  answers  to  the  English  taking 
out  probate  or  letters  of  administration.  A 
husband  has  in  Scotland  no  absolute  right  to 
administer  to  his  wife's  movable  or  personal 
estate.  In  default  of  an  executor  nominate,  a 
residuary  legatee  is  preferred,  then  the  next  of 
kin,  those  in  the  same  degree  being  entitled  to 
be  joined  if  they  please,  then  the  husband  or 
wife  of  the  deceased,  then  the  creditors,  and 
lastly  a  special  legatee.  An  executor  differs 
from  a  trustee  in  that  an  executor's  duty  is  to 
distribute  the  fund,  a  trustee's  to  hold  it. 


■s..— 


790 


EXECUTRY— EXPERIENCE 


[Currie  on  Confirmation  of  Executors.— M'L&ren 
on  Wills,  ii.  §  1657.— Dove  Wilson,  Sheriff  Court 
Prac^/ce,  4th  ed.,  546.]  j.w.b.i. 

EXECUTRY  (Scottish)  ;  the  subject  of  an 
executor's  administration  ;  the  whole  of,  the 
personal  estate  of  a  deceased  person,  equivalent 
both  to  legal  and  equitable  assets  in  England. 

J.  w.  B.  I. 

EXERCITOR  (Scottish)  ;  a  term  derived 
from  Roman  law  and  implying  one  who  employs 
a  ship  for  his  own  profit  in  trade,  and  to  whom 
the  profits  belong.  It  matters  not  whether  he 
is  the  actual  owner  or  only  the  freighter.  He 
is  liable  for  necessaries  ordered  by  the  master. 
His  obligations  properly  fall  in  the  first  instance 
under  the  jurisdiction  of  the  admiralty  court. 

[Bell's  Pr.,  §450.]  j.w.  B.i. 

EXHEREDITATIO  signifies,  in  Roman  law, 
a  testator's  declaration  in  his  will  that  he  ex- 
cludes from  being  his  Tieres  a  member  of  his 
family  belonging  to  the  class  of  relations  who 
cannot  be  passed  over  in  the  will  in  silence, 
but  must  either  be  appointed  heredes  or  thus 
declared  to  be  disinherited.  e.  a.  w. 

EX.  NEW.  This  refers  to  the  quotation  of 
prices  on  the  stock  exchange  for  shares  or 
other  security,  the  holders  of  which  are  about 
to  leceive  an  allotment  of  new  stock  at  what 
may  be  considered  an  advantageous  price  of 
issue.  When  these  words  form  part  of  the 
contract,  the  seller  retains  the  advantage,  if 
any,  and  the  buyer's  right  to  the  security  is 
exclusive  of  any  right  to  subscribe  to  the  new 
issue  (see  Ex.  All  ;  Ex,  Div.).  A.  e. 

EXPECTATION  OF  LIFE,  a  term  intro- 
duced by  De  Moivre,  denotes  the  number  of  years 
which  persons  of  a  certain  class,  e.g.  English 
males,  live  on  an  average  after  a  certain  age, 
e.g.  20  ;  the  average  being  obtained  as  follows. 
The  number  of  years  which  each  of  a  great 
many,  say  n,  specimens  of  the  class  under  ob- 
servation, lives  after  the  assigned  age  having  been 
observed,  the  sum  of  these  numbers  is  divided 
by  n.  The  Expectation  is  thus  the  arithmetic 
mean  of  the  n  observed  numbers  (see  Average). 
It  is  contrasted  with  another  average  of  the 
same  numbers,  viz.  the  Median  (see  Average), 
technically  termed  the  * '  equation  of  life. "  The 
term  "expectation"  is  objected  to  by  Dr.  Farr 
as  suggesting  the  latter  rather  than  the  former 
sort  of  average.  He  prefers  to  say  mean  after- 
lifetime.  Comparing  the  two  kinds  of  average, 
Neison  seems  to  think  that  the  expectation  of 
life  is  not  so  well  suited  "  for  medical  and  other 
purposes  in  which  it  is  required  to  determine 
the  relative  value  of  an  improvement  or  other 
change  which  may  have  taken  place  within  a 
given  period  of  life." 

(See  Death-rate;  De  Moivre;  Insur- 
ance ;  Mean  Afterlifetime  ;  Statistics.) 

[Walford's  Insurance  Cyclopcedia,  article  "  Ex- 
pectation. "—Parr,  Vital  Statistics,  pp.  279,  309. 


— Neison,  Contributions  to  Vital  Statistics,  p. 
100. — Report  of  the  Registrar-General  for  1885, 
Supplement. — Humphreys,  Journal  of  the  Stat- 
istical Society,  1883.]  f.  y.  e. 

EXPEDITATION.  By  the  Forest  Laws 
(q.v.)  all  mastiffs  or  other  large  dogs  kept  within 
a  forest  had  to  be  expeditated,  i.e.  maimed 
sufficiently  to  prevent  them  chasing  the  deer. 
According  to  the  laws  of  Canute  the  dog  was  to 
be  hamstrung,  but  by  a  charter  of  Henry  II. 
a  somewhat  milder  operation  was  allowed,  three 
toes  of  one  forefoot  being  cut  off  with  a  chisel, 
leaving  the  ball  of  the  foot  intact.  For  keep- 
ing an  unexpeditated  dog  within  a  forest  a  fine 
of  3s.,  called  **footgeld,"  was  imposed,  but 
before  the  end  of  the  15th  century  in  many  of 
the  English  forests  this  fine  had  become  a  cus- 
tomary payment,  sometimes  called  "hound- 
silver,"  collected  triennially,  which  formed  no 
small  item  in  the  revenues  of  the  forest  owner. 

[See  Ducange,  Glossarium  medice  et  infimce 
Latinitatis,  Editio  nova  a  L.  Favre,  Paris,  1884. — 
Manwood,  Forest  Laws,  London,  1615. — Cowell's 
Interpreter  of  Words  and  Phrases,  London, 
1701. — Forest  Accounts,  some  of  which  are 
quoted  by  Manwood.  ]  a.  h. 

EXPENDITURE  or  SPENDING  has  two 
distinct  meanings  which  are  often  confused. 

1.  Expenditure  may  mean  simply  the  pay- 
ment out  of  money,  that  is,  the  exchange  of 
money  for  other  goods.  In  this  sense  it  does 
not  imply  any  consumption  of  wealth  on  the 
part  of  any  one,  and  it  cannot  be  opposed  to 
"saving."  A  man  who  saves  £100  a  year 
ordinarily  expends  or  spends  those  £100,  i.e. 
exchanges  them  for  other  goods,  just  as  much 
as  if  he  did  not  save  anything.  The  things  on 
which  he  expends  them  will  be  different,  but 
the  expenditure,  unless  of  course  the  money  is 
hoarded,  will  be  the  same. 

2.  Expenditure  may  mean  payment  of  money 
for  personal  consumption  on  the  part  of  an 
individual,  and  consumption,  pure  and  simple, 
on  the  part  of  the  community.  In  this 
sense  it  is  rightly  opposed  to  "saving."  The 
£100  a  year  saved  by  an  individual  is  not 
in  this  sense  of  the  word  expended  or  spent 
either  by  himself  or  any  one  else.  It  is  simply 
the  value  in  money  of  a  part  of  the  community's 
income,  which,  instead  of  being  consumed,  has 
been  added  to  the  capital  of  the  country  (see 
Saving,  Productive  and  Unproductive). 

EXPENSES  OF  PRODUCTION  (see'pkc 

duction). 

EXPERIENCE.  Upon  the  value  of  experi- 
ence in  the  study  of  political  economy  the  most 
contradictory  opinions  have  found  adherents. 

Some  economists  have  expressed  themselves 
as  though  political  economy  were  a  science 
similar  in  type  to  astronomy — as  though  all 
economic  truths  could  be  derived  by  strict 
deduction    from   one   or   two   first   principles, 


EXPERIENCE— EXPERIMENTAL  METHODS  IN  ECONOMICS 


791 


such  as  "All  men  desire  wealth,"  or  "All 
men  are  averse  to  labour."  Other  economists 
have  denounced  general  reasoning,  and  have 
laid  exclusive  stress  on  the  accumulation  of 
facts.  They  would  apparently  reduce  political 
economy  to  the  task  of  observing  and  recording 
particulars  without  any  admixture  of  inference. 
These  opposite  opinions  have  rarely  been  held 
in  their  most  extreme  forms.  But  by  stating 
them  as  forcibly  as  possible  we  may  be  assisted 
to  detect  the  fallacies  which  they  involve. 

It  will  appear  upon  examination  that  neither 
of  these  principles  can  be  carried  out  in  its 
integrity.  The  attempt  to  carry  out  either 
would  result  in  intellectual  paralysis. 

There  has  never  yet  existed  an  economist  so 
rigorously  deductive  in  his  method  as  not  to 
draw  to  some  extent  upon  experience  of 
economic  phenomena.  Many  economists  have 
indeed  drawn  upon  a  field  of  experience  too 
restricted  to  justify  dogmatic  conclusions. 
Many  economists  have  been  too  much  influenced 
by  the  economic  experience  of  their  own  time, 
or  of  then-  own  country.  Even  this  narrow 
experience  they  may  not  have  studied  exhaust- 
ively. They  may  have  picked  up  their  know- 
ledge of  it  insensibly,  here  and  there,  bit  by 
bit.  It  is  thus  that  the  man  of  business,  as 
contrasted  with  the  student,  acquires  his 
knowledge  of  economic  phenomena.  Ricardo, 
the  greatest  of  those  economists  who  are  alleged 
to  have  been  rigorously  deductive  in  method, 
may  be  said  to  have  acquired  most  of  his 
knowledge  in  this  way.  Such  knowledge,  being 
very  partial,  may  sometimes  prove  misleading. 
But  even  such  knowledge  has  gi-eat  influence 
upon  the  development  of  theory.  Ricardo's 
economic  theories  would  certainly  have  been 
different  had  he  lived  in  another  age  than  the 
nineteenth  century,  or  in  another  country  than 
England. 

An  economist  strictly  deductive  in  method 
could  never  get  beyond  his  first  premisses.  The 
contrary  seems  possible  because  the  economist 
who  apparently  deduces  everything  from  first 
principles  in  reality  weaves  into  his  argument 
statements  of  fact  and  wide  generalisations 
which  have  become  so  familiar  that  he  and  his 
readers  forget  how  they  were  first  acquired. 

Nor  has  there  ever  yet  existed  an  economist 
who  merely  observed  and  recorded.  Those 
economists  who  aimed  at  this  ideal  have  never- 
theless written  history.  The  writing  of  history 
involves  processes  of  selection,  comparison,  and 
inference,  in  which  the  historian's  mind  is 
active.  No  two  persons  perform  these  processes 
in  quite  the  same  way,  and  it  is  extremely  easy 
to  make  mistakes  in  performing  them.  It  is 
not  merely  that  historians  often  infuse  their 
work  with  their  own  political  or  religious 
sentiments,  with  the  prejudices  of  their  own 
age  or  their  own  class.  It  is  rather  that  the 
historian  cannot  construct  a  narrative  out  of 


facts  without  interpreting  those  facts.  But  he 
cannot  interpret  the  facts  without  using  hia 
mind,  without  adding  to,  or  rather,  without 
transforming,  those  facts. 

The  object  of  all  science,  including  political 
economy,  is  not  merely  to  amass  facts  but  also 
to  explain  them.  Facts  are  explained  in  so  far 
as  they  are  successfully  brought  under  general 
laws.  The  general  laws  are  always  at  first 
hypotheses,  or  in  the  vulgar  tongue,  guesses — 
guesses  at  truth.  Hypot  heses  are  suggested  by 
facts,  and  facts  are  interpreted  by  hypotheses. 
He  who  forms  a  hypotliesis  with  hardly  any 
knowledge  of  the  facts  is  pretty  sure  to  throw 
away  his  trouble.  He  who  clings  to  a  hypo- 
thesis once  formed,  neglecting  or  rejecting  new 
facts,  does  worse,  for  he  is  trying  to  confirm 
liimself  in  error.  But  to  refrain  from  forming 
hypotheses  is  impossible  to  a  reasoning  creature, 
and,  if  it  were  possible,  would  bt'  suicidal.  The 
value  of  experience  is  not  absolute  but  varies 
directly  as  the  power  of  the  mind  which  has 
the  experience.  One  glance  at  the  field  of 
battle  will  suggest  a  decisive  movement  to  the 
great  general.  The  vicissitudes  of  a  short  and 
obscure  life  will  give  the  great  poet  a  key  to 
human  nature  in  its  infinite  variety.  The 
scientific  genius,  although  less  brilliant,  is  not 
essentially  diff'erent  from  theirs. 

Whether  in  physical  or  in  political  science 
the  master  mind  is  that  to  which  facts  suggest 
their  own  explanation.  F.  c.  M. 

[Cairnes,  Character  and  Logical  Method  of 
Political  Economy. — Bagehot,  Economic  Studies.'] 

EXPERIMENTAL  METHODS  IN  ECONO- 
j\nCS.  Experiment  in  the  scientific  sense  has 
been  well  described  as  "  putting  in  action  causes 
and  agents  over  which  we  have  control,  and 
purposely  varying  their  combinations  and  notic- 
ing what  effects  take  place  "  (Herschel,  Study 
of  Natural  Philosophy,  p.  76).  In  sciences 
such  as  physics  and  chemistry,  in  which  the 
phenomena  are  amenable  to  arrangement,  it  is 
by  far  the  most  potent  instrument  of  discovery. 
Where,  however,  there  is  not  the  same  facility 
for  easy  manipulation,  the  inquirer  is  com- 
pelled to  fall  back  on  the  less  effective  method 
of  simple  observation.  Instead  of  creating 
instances  for  himself,  he  has  to  find  them  in 
nature,  or  wait  till  they  are  presented  spontane- 
ously to  his  view. 

Economics,  in  common  with  the  other  social 
sciences,  clearly  belongs  to  the  latter  class.  The 
phenomena  of  wealth  are  closely  inter-connected, 
and  are  besides  affected  by  the  other  forms  of 
social  activity.  Hardly  any  economic  event 
can  be  said  to  be  the  result  of  a  single  cause, 
it  is  rather  the  product  of  several  contributory 
causes.  Nor  are  the  total  effects  of  any  one 
agency  easily  separable ;  they  are  combined 
with  those  of  others  in  a  whole  which  cannot 
be  analysed.  In  technical  language  "  plurality 
of  causes"  and  "  intermixture  of  effects,"  tho 


792 


EXPERIMENTAL  METHODS  IN  ECONOMICS— EXPERT 


two  great  hindrances  to  the  use  of  experiment 
(MiU,  Logic,  bk.  iii.  ch.  x.),  are  generally 
present  in  economic  facts.  To  secure  the 
requisite  isolation  of  any  phenomenon  selected 
for  study  is  rarely  possible.  The  most  rigprous 
form  of  inquiry,  known  as  the  "method  of 
difference,"  the  essence  of  which  "is  the  compari- 
son of  two  instances,  which  resemble  one  another 
in  all  material  respects,  except  that  in  one  a 
certain  cause  is  present,  while  in  the  other  it  is 
absent"  (Keynes,  Scope,  p.  170),  is  plainly  ex- 
cluded, since  we  cannot  introduce  a  single  cause 
that  will  have  only  a  measurable  effect,  nor  can 
we  be  sme  that  the  surrounding  conditions 
remain  unaltered.  The  ' '  method  of  agreement 
in  which  the  instances  compared  resemble  each 
other  in  only  one  particular  is  not  merely  inferior 
as  an  experimental  resource,  but  is  inapplicable 
to  social  phenomena.  Two  countries  or  periods 
that  had  one  common  feature  would  have  more 
than  one.  In  two  classes  of  cases,  however, 
experiment  may  be  sometimes  used,  viz.  (1)  in 
reference  to  the  premises  or  data  of  economic 
science,  thus  the  "  law  of  diminishing  returns  " 
admits  of  experimental  proof;  (2)  More  import- 
ant than  the  preceding  exception,  which  is 
rather  apparent  than  real,  are  those  cases  in 
which,  by  deductive  reasoning,  it  can  be  shown 
that  the  action  of  an  economic  force  is  limited, 
and  then  its  working  within  those  limits  can 
be  experimentally  ascertained. 

These  exceptions  notwithstanding,  it  may  be 
said  that  scientific  experiments  {experimenta 
Ivjcifera)  are  a  very  slight  resource  in  econo- 
mics. 

The  case  is  somewhat  different  with  regard  to 
practical  questions.  Legislative  measures  and 
individual  actions  are,  if  so  intended,  so  many 
experiments  on  the  social  system.  Thus  if 
several  countries,  widely  differing  in  other 
respects,  have  established  a  system  of  peasant 
proprietary  with  good  results,  while  several 
other  countries,  also  widely  differing  inter  sc, 
are  without  that  system  and  show  inferiority, 
we  may  argue  that  peasant  proprietary  is  experi- 
mentally justified.  The  same  reasoning  would 
be  applicable  to  commercial  policy,  and  has 
actually  been  used  in  reference  to  the  case  of 
Victoria  and  New  South  Wales,  but  illogically, 
as  a  number  of  cases  are  required  to  exclude 
other  influences. 

Again,  by  applying  special  legislation,  e.g.  a 
particular  kind  of  land  tenure,  to  one  part  of 
a  country,  we  can  ascribe  to  its  influence  the 
special  effects  noticed  in  that  district.  Practical 
experiments  {experimenta  fructifera)  may  also 
be  employed  by  means  of  (1)  permissive  legisla- 
tion, or  (2)  temporary  legislation. 

Private  persons  also  carry  out  practical 
economic  experiments,  as  in  the  cases  of  profit- 
sharing  (Leclaire),  and  the  recent  eight  hours 
day  experiment  at  Sunderland  (Economic  Jour- 
nal, ii.  pp.  755,  756).     A  large  accumulation 


of  instances  may  even  give  a  very  near  approach 
to  rigorous  scientific  proof. 

A  vaguer  use  of  the  term  "experimental 
method"  is  common  in  continental  and  especially 
in  French  writers.  J.  B.  Say,  for  example, 
declares  that  the  true  method  of  political 
economy  is  La  methode  exp^rimentale  qui  cotisiste 
esscntiellement  d  n'admettre  comme  vrais  que  les 
faits  dont  V  observation  et  experievAie  ont  ddmontrd 
la  r4alit6  (TraitS,  Discours  pr^l're,  p.  x.  5th  ed. 
1826).  Here  "  experiment "  is  used  as  synony- 
mous with  "  experience  "  ;  it  therefore  includes 
observation  and  experiment  in  the  strict  sense. 
[J.  N.  Keynes,  Scope  and  Method  of  Political 
Economy,  pp.  169-178. — J.  S.  Mill,  Logic,  bk.  iii. 
chs.viii.,  X.  ;  bk.  vi.  ch.  ix. — G-.  C.  Lewis,  Methods 
of  Observation  and  Reasoning  in  Politics,  ch.  vi. 
— Jevons,  Methods  of  Social  Reform,  pp.  253  seq. 
— Leon  Donuat,  La  Politique  Experimentale, 
2nd  ed.  Paris,  1891].  c.  f.  b. 

EXPERT.  An  expert  may  be  defined  as  a 
person  possessing  special  knowledge  of  any 
science  or  art.  Art  is  here  taken  in  its  most 
comprehensive  signification,  to  include  the  use- 
ful as  well  as  the  fine  arts,  cooking  or  carpentry 
as  well  as  music  or  painting.  The  opinion  of 
an  expert  on  matters  connected  with  his  own 
subject  is  more  likely  to  be  correct  than  the 
opinion  of  a  man  to  whom  that  subject  is 
almost  or  altogether  unknown.  But  the  degree 
in  which  an  expert's  opinion  outweighs  the 
opinion  of  the  ordinary  man  will  vary  according 
to  the  nature  of  the  subject. 

For,  first,  the  subject  may  be  one  with  which 
the  ordinary  man  has  no  acquaintance,  or  it 
may  be  one  with  which  he  is  acquainted, 
although  not  so  fully  as  the  expert.  Thus 
every  man  in  his  senses  knows  to  some  extent 
what  food  is  wholesome,  although  he  may  not 
know  so  much  on  this  point  as  a  qualified 
doctor.  Every  man  who  can  write  has  some 
power  of  comparing  hands,  although  not  so 
much  power  as  belongs  to  an  expert  in  hand- 
writing. But  only  an  expert  in  navigation  can 
determine  the  exact  position  of  a  ship  out  of 
sight  of  land.  Only  an  expert  in  astronomy 
can  determine  the  probable  distance  of  a  fixed  star 
from  our  planet.  In  such  matters  the  judgment 
of  the  ordinary  man  is  absolutely  worthless. 

Secondly,  the  subject  may  be  so  complex 
that  no  expert  has  more  than  a  very  imperfect 
knowledge  of  it.  Political  and  economic  science 
are  characterised  by  this  complexity.  Upon 
political  or  economic  questions  the  opinion  of  a 
man  who  knows  much  is  far  more  valuable  than 
the  opinion  of  a  "man  who  knows  little  or 
nothing  ;  but  even  the  opinion  of  the  man  who 
knows  much  affords  a  very  imperfect  security. 
Such  complex  questions  often  present  different 
aspects  to  different  classes  of  experts.  Let  us 
suppose  that  an  opinion  is  required  on  the 
expediency  of  a  law  to  regulate  the  hours  of 
labour.     At  least  five  different  classes  of  experts 


EXPERTISE— EXPLOIT 


793 


are  more  or  less  entitled  to  be  heard : — (a)  The 
economist  who  has  read  and  reflected  upon  the 
theory  of  economic  phenomena  ;  (6)  the  politi- 
cal philosopher  who  has  read  and  reflected  upon 
the  theory  of  the  state  and  of  legislation  ;  (c) 
the  statesman  who  is  familiar  with  the  practice 
of  government,  and  can  judge  what  kind  of 
laws  it  is  usually  expedient  to  make  and  possible 
to  enforce  ;  (d)  the  employer  who  has  had  the 
opportunity  and  the  will  if  not  the  wisdom  to 
discover  how  production  can  be  carried  on  to 
the  greatest  profit ;  (e)  the  workman  who  has 
had  the  opportunity  and  the  will,  if  not  the 
wisdom,  to  discover  what  are  the  best  conditions 
of  life  which  he  can  obtain  for  himself ;  all 
these  men  can  bring  to  the  determination  of 
the  problem  a  knowledge  which  other  men  do 
not  possess,  and  are  entitled  in  a  gi-eater  or  less 
degree  to  speak  with  the  authority  of  experts. 
One  person  might,  of  course,  combine  more  than 
one  of  these  characters,  and  might,  therefore, 
claim  a  higher  degree  of  authority. 

Thirdly,  the  subjects  of  knowledge  difl"er  in 
the  degree  in  which  they  excite  passions  such 
as  prevent  the  expert  from  employing  his  intel- 
lectual superiority  to  its  fullest  advantage.  On 
any  subject,  indeed,  were  it  astronomy  or  textual 
criticism,  the  judgment  of  an  expert  may  be 
disabled  by  vanity  or  love  of  contention.  But 
on  those  subjects  which  immediately  touch  the 
interests  of  mankind,  notably  theological,  politi- 
cal, and  economical  subjects,  the  judgment  of 
the  expert  is  more  likely  to  be  disturbed  by  his 
passions.  These  passions  are  at  least  as  un- 
governable in  ignorant  men.  But  wherever 
they  prevail  they  lessen  the  interval  between 
the  ignorant  man  and  the  expert.  For  the 
finer  the  intellectual  instrument  the  more  it  is 
disturbed  by  acute  emotion.  f.  c.  m. 

EXPERTISE  (French)  is  the  legal  process 
by  which  judges,  when  called  on  to  decide  special 
or  technical  cases,  may  appoint,  on  their  own 
authority,  or  on  the  demand  of  one  or  both  of 
the  litigants,  persons  possessing  the  necessary 
knowledge  or  experience,  called  experts,  to  ex- 
amine, and  report  on,  the  points  at  issue.  The 
conditions  under  which  those  operations  are 
conducted  are  laid  down  in  Arts.  303-323  of 
the  Code  of  Civil  Procedure.  One  of  the  most 
frequent  applications  of  the  law  is  in  the  settle- 
ment of  disputes  between  foreign  importers  and 
the  French  customs  authorities  relative  to  the 
class,  quality,  origin,  or  value  of  merchandise 
subject  to  duty.  The  first  supplementary  con- 
vention to  the  Anglo-French  treaty  of  commerce 
of  1860  confeiTcd  on  British  importers  in  France 
the  right  to  demand  an  expertise.  When  the 
Customs  propose  to  exercise  the  right  of  pre- 
emption, the  importer  and  the  customs  each 
nominates  one  of  the  experts.  In  case  of  dis- 
agreement the  two  experts  choose  an  umpire, 
and  if  they  cannot  agree  on  the  choice,  the 
umpire  is  appointed  by  the  president  of  the 


nearest  tribunal  of  commerce.  Objections 
were  frequently  made  that  the  persons  named 
as  erperts  did  not  possess  the  necessary  quali- 
fications, and  on  the  renewal  of  the  tai-eaty 
of  commerce,  in  1873,  a  protocol  was  signed^ 
stipulating  that  they  should  be  chosen  from  a 
list  of  merchants  or  manufacturers  drawn  up 
by  the  chambers  of  commerce  in  each  locality 
having  a  customs  bureau.  A  British  chamber 
of  commerce  had  just  been  founded  in  Paris, 
and  that  body  submitted  to  the  Paris  chamber 
(French)  the  names  of  tlie  principal  British 
merchants  in  Paris,  for  them  to  be  comprised 
in  the  list  of  experts  ;  but  the  French  chamber 
of  commerce  refused  to  nominate  them  on  the 
ground  of  their  foreign  nationality,  although 
British  traders  had  previously  been  accepted  as 
experts.  The  British  chamber  appealed  to  the 
Foreign  Ofiice,  and  on  the  intervention  of  the 
British  ambassador  the  French  minister  of 
foreign  affairs  considered  the  claim  a  just  one, 
and  some  of  the  names  proposed  were  added 
to  the  list  of  experts  in  Paris.  Those  names 
were,  however,  subsequently  removed  from  the 
list  on  the  expiration  of  the  treaty  of  commerce 
in  1881,  and  British  importers  who  now  have 
disputes  with  the  French  customs  can  only 
be  represented  in  an  expertise  by  a  French 
merchant  or  manufacturer,  who  is  naturally 
disposed  to  impede  rather  than  to  facilitate 
foreign  competition  in  his  own  trade.  There 
is  no  appeal  from  the  decision  of  the  experts 
in  commercial  affairs,  when  they  agi-ee,  but 
civil  expertises  arc  still  governed  by  Art.  323  of 
the  Code  of  Civil  Procedure,  nnder  which  judges 
are  not  bound  to  adopt  the  opinion  of  experts 
if  they  are  not  convinced  by  it.  t.  l. 

[Lois  du  27  JuUlet  1822  et  du  7  Mai  ISSl ; 
arrets  de  la  Cour  de  Cassation,  30  Avril  1838, 
et  30  Janvier  1839.] 

EXPLOIT.  The  French  verb  exploiter  pri- 
marily means  simply  to  use  in  such  a  way 
as  to  make  a  profit  out  of.  It  is  applied  to 
such  actions  as  working  a  mine  or  a  rail- 
way, cultivating  a  farm,  or  publishing  a  news- 
paper. There  are  some  things  which  it  is  ad- 
mittedly improper  to  use  in  such  a  way  as  to 
make  a  profit  out  of  them  ;  it  is  disgraceful, 
for  instance,  to  exploiter  any  one's  credulity, 
ignorance,  or  good  natiure.  Hence  the  word 
comes  to  have  sometimes  a  bad  sense.  The 
socialists  who  teach  that  the  capitalist  obtains 
an  illegitimate  gain  by  employing  men  for 
wages  have  applied  the  term  to  his  action  in 
this  bad  sense.  To  exploiter  men  or  labourers 
thus  means  to  use  them  in  such  a  way  as  to 
make  a  profit  out  of  them,  it  being  at  the  same 
time  implied  by  the  use  of  the  word  that  this, 
though  not  perhaps  disgraceful  to  an  individual 
who  does  it  under  present  circumstances,  is 
fundamentally  improper,  and  would  not  be 
allowed  in  an  improved  state  of  society. 

It  is  almost  exclusively  in  this  bad  sense  that 


794 


EXPORTS  AND  IMPORTS— EXPORTS,  DUTIES  ON 


the  word  "exploit "has  been  introduced  into 
English.  E-  c. 

EXPORTS  AND  IMPORTS,  see  Imports 
AND  Exports. 

EXPORTS,  Duties  on.  Duties  on  exports 
have  been  generally  condemned  by  modem 
economists,  but  they  survive  in  many  of  the 
British  possessions  as  well  as  in  some  foreign 
countries.  The  history  of  these  duties  in  Great 
Britain  is  merged  in  that  of  the  customs  revenue. 
The  original  customs  duties  were,  in  fact,  duties 
on  exportation.  They  appear  to  have  been 
levied  by  prerogative  of  the  crown  from  early 
times,  but  the  first  statute  which  imposed  them 
was  one  of  3  Edward  I. 

Two  somewhat  diverse  theories  have  been 
suggested  as  explanatory  of  the  origin  of  these 
duties  in  England.  One,  which  we  find  first 
indicated  by  Sir  W.  Petty,  is  adopted  by  Mr. 
Dowell  (History  of  Taxation).  It  holds  that 
the  sovereign  power  simply  levied  a  toll  on  all 
merchandise,  whether  inward  or  outward,  as  a 
reward  for  its  protection  of  the  merchant.  The 
duties  "were  in  the  nature  of  a  premium  paid 
to  the  king  for  insurance."  The  analogy  of 
the  customs  duties  levied  at  Athens  and  at 
Rome  (po)-to7-ia)  may  be  held  to  favour  this 
view.  The  other  theory  is  on  the  whole  the 
more  probable,  and  is  that  adopted  by  Mr. 
Hubert  Hall  (History  of  the  Customs)  ;  the 
king's  chief  concern  was  to  see  that  he  got 
as  much  revenue  as  he  could.  He  was  from 
ancient  times  entitled  to  a  purveyance  or  prise 
on  certain  classes  of  commodities — "if  then 
these  were  conveyed  beyond  the  kingdom  the 
crown  would  suffer  a  possible  loss  to  its  state 
or  dignity."  When  it  was  found  that  the  wools 
and  hides  on  which  the  king  was  entitled  to 
the  internal  toll  or  prise  were  being  exported 
and  escaping  taxation,  he  at  once  put  on  a 
countervailing  export  duty  in  order  to  secure 
his  revenue  (see  Prisage). 

It  seems  probable  that  these  duties  were  ad- 
justed at  the  discretion  of  the  crown  according 
to  its  necessities,  and  Mr.  Hall  thinks  that 
immediately  before  the  statute  3  Edw.  I.  "it 
is  probable  that  the  commuted  prise  on  staple 
exports,  such  as  wool,  hides,  and  minerals,  was 
taken  at  an  average  rate  of  half  a  mark  per 
sack  of  wool  or  an  equivalent  bulk  of  woolfells, 
a  mark  per  last  of  hides,  and  an  ad  valorem 
duty  of  3d.  on  every  librate  or  twenty  solidi  of 
lead  or  tin." 

The  Act  of  3  Edw.  I.  (1275),  which  is  the 
first  instance  of  levying  taxation  by  act  of 
parliament,  placed  the  export  duty  at 

^  mark  per  sack  (26  stone)  of  wool. 
„     „     per  300  woolfells. 
1     ,,     per  last  of  leather. 

These   are  the   custuma  atitiqua  sive  magna, 
and  the  chief  contributor  to  the  revenue  was 


the  wool.      In  the  thirty-second  year  of  this 

reign  the  produce  was  as  follows  : 

Wool  at  6s.  8d.        .         .     £1501     0     9j 
Woolfells  at  6s.  8d.  .  57  15     1 

Leather  at  13s.  4d.  .  0     8     71 


Total  of  the  great  customs    £1559     4     5| 

In  February  1303  an  agreement  was  made 
with  the  alien  merchants,  whereby  they  under- 
took, in  consideration  of  the  king's  protection, 
to  pay  50  per  cent  beyond  the  ancient  customs 
on  wool  and  leather,  and  certain  fresh  rates  on 
other  commodities  whether  exported  or  im- 
ported. Rates  were  specified  for  wax,  cloth, 
and  wine,  and  all  other  articles  were  to  be 
charged  3d.  in  the  pound  of  20  shillings. 
These  were  the  custuma  nova  sive  parva. 

The  next  development  of  the  exports  (as  part 
of  the  customs)  duties  was  by  the  statute  of 
49  Edw.  III.,  which  levied  the  due  of  tunnage 
and  poundage,  afterwards  known  technically  as 
a  subsidy.  The  poundage  was  a  duty  of  6d. 
on  the  pound-weight  of  all  articles  exported 
and  imported. 

With  variations  in  the  rate  these  two  forms 
of  export,  and  import,  duty  were  continued  on 
the  same  basis  down  to  the  Restoration  in  1660. 
They  were  granted  by  the  Commons  for  periods 
of  years  as  a  rule  ;  sometimes  for  the  life  of  the, 
reigning  sovereign.  After  Agincourt  in  1415, 
such  a  life  grant  was  made  to  Henry  V.,  and  the 
duties  had  gone  up  considerably,  as  follows : — 
From  denizens.  Prom  strangers. 
On  wool  per  sack  £2  3  4  £3  0  0 
On  woolfells  2     3     4         3     0     0 

On  leather  per  last      2     3     4          5     6     8 

and  in  the  following  reign  the  rate  for  wools, 
etc.,  was  raised  to  £5  for  strangers,  and  that 
for  leather  to  £5  for  natives.  The  subsidy 
of  poundage  had  already  been  raised  to  Is.  on 
the  pound -weight,  and  there  was  a  special 
duty  of  .double  that  amount  on  tin  exported 
by  strangers.  In  1421  the  yield  of  all  the 
customs  was  £40,687,  of  which  the  great 
custom  on  wools,  export  duty,  produced 
£26,036  ;  in  1431  the  total  was  £34,851,  of 
which  the  greater  proportion  was  derived  from 
export  duties.  But  the  revenue  appears  to 
have  been  a  falling  one  ;  the  customs  regulations 
were  anything  but  complete,  as  is  shown  by 
the  act  of  27  Hen.  VIII.  c.  14,  to  regulate  the 
exportation  of  leather  from  other  ports  besides 
Southampton  and  London ;  and  there  were 
constant  interferences  with  the  export  trade  by 
way  of  partial  or  complete  prohibition,  as 
late  as  Mary's  reign.  In  1570  the  value  of 
woollen  goods  and  cloth  exported  from  England 
amounted  to  £26,665,  and  from  this  was 
obtained  £2388  :  10  :  11,  viz.  customs  £1523, 
and  subsidy  £865  :  10  :  11  ;  gi-adually  the 
revenue  from  imports  was  becoming  the  more 
considerable. 


EXPORTS,  DUTIES  ON 


796 


The  Long  Parliament,  after  declaring  in 
1640  that  "no  subsidy,  custom,  etc.,  maybe 
imposed  upon  any  merchandise  exported  or 
imported  without  common  consent  in  parlia- 
ment," proceeded  to  levy  heavy  duties  on  the  old 
lines.  The  year  1660  marks  the  beginning  of 
a  transition  stage.  In  the  Book  of  Rates  for 
this  year,  212  articles  were  subject  to  export 
duty  "rated  for  duty  outwards."  The  duties 
gi'anted  to  Charles  II.  were  levied  with  some 
modifications  in  the  ninth  and  tenth  years  of 
William  III.  as  the  "new  subsidy"  and  con- 
tinued by  9  &  10  Anne,  c.  vi.  (1710)  by  the 
act  "  for  reviving,  continuing,  and  apportioning 
certain  duties  upon  several  commodities  to 
be  exported  and  certain  duties  on  coal,  etc., 
etc."  But  in  1721  the  export  duties  on  corn, 
woollen  fabrics,  linen  manufactures,  and  other 
staples  were  repealed  ;  the  mercantile  theory 
with  its  mania  for  exportation  had  found  these 
duties  obstructive.  Nevertheless  in  Saxby's 
manual  of  the  Customs  (dated  1757)  some 
twenty  -  five  pages  are  occupied  with  the 
enimieration  of  the  goods  rated  for  duty 
outwards,  and  the  directions  for  paying  the 
proper  duties,  and  in  Pitt's  consolidating 
Customs  Act  of  1787  there  are  fifty  articles 
subjected  to  export  duty,  many  of  them  being 
of  foreign  origin.  These  duties  were  increased 
during  the  great  war,  and  at  the  beginning  of 
the  century,  under  the  act  of  1809  (49  Geo. 
III.  c.  98)  Sched.  A  "Outwards,"  which  rated 
for  permanent  duty,  and  in  a  parallel  column 
for  temporary  or  war  duty  : — 

(a)  Foreign  commodities  to  the  number  of 
sixty-three  at  varying,  chiefly  specific  duties. 

(6)  British  goods,  of  which  coals,  skins,  and 
other  articles  were  subject  to  specific  duty  ;  all 
other  goods,  wares,  etc.,  to  an  ad  valorem  duty — 
excepting  cotton,  linen,  sugar,  woollen  goods, 
and  certain  special  exemptions  with  reference 
to  the  port  of  destination. 

By  an  act  of  1810  linen  goods  were  subjected 
to  an  ad  valorem  duty  of  1 5  per  cent  on  exports. 
But  with  the  close  of  the  war  and  the  progress 
of  the  new  economy  the  backward  policy  was 
reversed.  In  1815  the  export  duties  produced 
£365,598,  and  in  1826,  £102,255.  Under 
Mr.  Huskisson,  in  1826,  the  schedule  of  articles 
left  subject  to  export  duty  was  as  follows  : — 

Coals,  per  chald.  Is.  6d.  to  30s.  3d.  accord- 
ing to  destination,  etc. 

Culm,  per  ton,  Is.  to  10s.,  according  to 
destination,  etc. 

Skins,  per  100,  Is. 

Wool,  per  lb.,  Id. 

Woollen  manufacture,  per  lb.,  Id. 

Home  produce  with  certain  definite  exemp- 
tions, ad  valorem,  10s,  per  £100,  i.e.  ^%, 
and  with  Peel's  reformed  tariff"  of  1842  these 
disappeared  altogether.  In  1 9  0 1  an  export  duty 
of  Is.  a  ton  on  coal  was  levied,  producing  about 
£2, 0  0  0, 0  0  0  per  ann.  This  was  removed  in  1 9  0  6. 


One  of  the  few  accidental  gains  to  be  placed 
to  the  credit  of  the  old  mercantile  theory  was 
that  it  tended  to  discourage  duties  on  exporta- 
tion. Sir  W.  Petty  (1679)  shews  a  conscious- 
ness that  such  duties  required  careful  watching. 
Sir  John  Sinclair  (1790),  who  had  imbibed  the 
doctrines  of  Adam  Smith,  is  the  first  writer 
apparently  who  distinctly  expresses  a  doubt  as 
to  the  propriety  of  their  imposition.  Formerly, 
he  wiites,  almost  every  commodity  sent  out  of 
the  kingdom  was  subject  to  such  a  duty  ;  it  was 
supposed  that  the  duty  came  out  of  the  pockets 
of  foreigners,  but  "such  ideas  are  now  exploded." 
He  -referred  to  the  principal  export  duties  at 
that  time,  under  Pitt's  recent  act,  as  being 
those  on  coals  and  lead,  with  certain  duties  on 
raw  produce  intended  to  give  our  manufacturers 
"  an  advantage  over  rivals. "  McCulloch  {Taxa- 
tion and  the  Funding  System)  has  a  full  dis- 
cussion of  the  economic  propriety  of  export 
duties,  and  suggests  the  grounds  on  which 
they  have  generally  been  condemned.  His 
statement  of  the  arguments  for  and  against 
the  retention  of  such  a  duty  on  coals,  published 
just  at  the  time  when  that  duty  was  finally 
removed,  is  of  special  interest ;  it  embodies  the 
argument  in  which  economists  have  for  the 
most  part  summed  up  the  whole  discussion 
on  these  duties,  viz.  that  they  should  not 
be  levied  except  in  the  case  of  a  country 
which  has  a  monopoly  of  supply  of  the  com- 
modity taxed,  or  such  an  advantage  in  its 
production  as  to  approximate  to  a  monopoly. 

Turning  to  the  British  possessions  it  is 
natural  to  find  that  in  those  which  were  acquired 
during  the  17th  century,  when  export  duties 
Avere  an  unchallenged  feature  in  the  fiscal  system 
of  this  country,  the  export  duty  is,  so  to  speak, 
bred  in  the  grain  ;  in  the  colonies  established 
towards  the  close  of  the  18th  century  such  a 
duty  practically  had  no  place. 

The  notorious  4^  per  cent  ad  valorem  duty 
which  created  such  squabbles  between  the  crown 
and  the  West  Indian  islands  was  the  progenitor 
of  colonial  revenues.  At  the  time  of  the 
Restoration,  when  all  the  revenues  of  the 
crown  were  being  revised,  plantation  enterprise 
was  at  the  height  of  its  activity,  and  it  occurred 
to  the  crown  advisers  that  the  new  dominions 
beyond  the  seas  ought  to  contribute  their  share. 
Thus  the  origin  of  colonial  customs  was  pre- 
cisely the  same  as  that  of  the  English  customs. 
The  patent  of  1663,  constituting  the  office  of 
commissioners  of  customs,  empowered  them  to 
levy  and  collect  a  duty  of  4^  per  cent  ad  valorem 
on  all  dead  produce  exported  from  Barbados 
and  certain  other  sugar  colonies,  and  from  the 
plantations  in  America.  In  respect  of  the  latter 
no  such  duty  was  ever  actually  levied.  In  the 
West  Indies  it  was  the  cause  of  much  grumbling ; 
already,  in  1689,  it  was  urged  that  "moreover 
this  four  and  a  half  is  collected  in  such 
manner  that  in  the  judgment  of  aU  that  have 


796 


EXPORTS,  DUTIES  ON 


tryed  it,  the  attendance  and  slavery  is  a  greater 
bui'then  than  the  duty"  {Groans  of  the  Flawbers) ; 
it  was  found  to  be  "  the  same  thing  in  effect  as 
a  tax  on  lands."  It  was  the  subject  of  a  great 
action  in  1763  in  a  case  arising  on  the  island 
of  Grenada,  Campbell  v.  Hall,  where  payment 
of  the  duty  was  refused  on  the  ground  that  the 
island  was  ceded  by  France  on  the  condition 
that  the  privileges  of  the  former  regime  should 
be  secured  to  the  inhabitants.  This  led  to 
the  exception  of  "  the  Ceded  Islands,"  and 
Jamaica,  from  the  operation  of  the  duty.  It 
was  for  many  years  paid  in  kind,  and  in  1778 
the  right  so  to  pay  it  was  successfully  contested 
(Macpherson's  Annals,  iii.  625).  This  is  not 
remarkable  in  an  age  when  sugar  was  the 
current  money  of  account.  For  the  better 
collection  of  this  and  other  duties  the  customs 
department  had  branch  establishments  in  the 
colonies,  and  they  continued  to  levy  the  4^  per 
cent  till  it  was  abolished  with  slavery  in  1838. 

Of  the  other  colonies  the  only  ones  in  which 
duties  on  exports  were  levied  in  the  first  quarter 
of  this  century,  were  the  Mauritius  (certain  rates 
on  sugar,  coffee,  cotton,  indigo,  and  one  or  two 
other  articles),  the  Cape  (on  all  produce  shipped, 
half  the  amount  of  the  import  duties  on  similar 
articles),  and  Ceylon  (on  cinnamon,  etc.).  These 
were  roilics  from  foreign  rule  in  each  case,  and 
disappeared  gradually  under  British  rule.  The 
export  duty  on  cinnamon  from  Ceylon  had  an 
instructive  history,  as  it  was  exceedingly  pro- 
fitable when  Ceylon  had  almost  a  monopoly  of 
that  spice,  it  was  a  chief  element  in  driving 
other  tropical  countries  to  compete  with  Ceylon, 
and  was  dropped,  in  1833,  too  late  to  save  the 
colony's  pre-eminence  in  that  export. 

In  India  export  duties  were  a  relic  of  the  old 
system  :  when  the  imperial  government  took 
over  the  provinces  in  1857  there  were  export 
duties  levied  in  all  the  presidencies,  and  chiefly 
on  grain,  rice,  indigo,  lac,  opium,  silk,  tobacco, 
and  native  manufactures  of  all  sorts.  An  act  of 
1860  abolished  those  on  manufacture  of  wool, 
flax,  hemp,  jute,  etc.  At  the  present  day  those 
on  rice,  opium,  and  certain  other  commodities 
remain.  The  Indian  export  duty  on  rice  has 
been  quoted  by  Fawcett  and  others  as  an  instance 
where  the  duty  was  probably  justified  owing  to 
the  great  advantages  possessed  by  the  exporting 
country  in  the  production  of  the  commodity. 

The  most  striking  modern  recrudescence  of 
export  duties  was  in  connection  with  the  im- 
migration of  Indian  coolies  to  the  sugar-growing 
colonies.  One  of  the  conditions  of  government 
aid  in  importing  coolies  was  that  the  planters 
should  pay  their  fair  share  ;  and  after  much 
discussion  an  export  duty  on  sugar  and  the  other 
produce  of  the  plantations  was  settled  as  the 
best  method  of  obtaining  the  necessary  contribu- 
tions. Hardly  therefore  were  many  of  tlie  West 
Indian  colonies  freed  from  the  ancient  4^  per 
cen+i  duty  than  they  undertook  a  new  specific 


duty  on  exportation  of  sugar  and  other  produce. 
The  St.  Lucia  Schedule  was  a  fair  sample,  im- 
posing duties  on — 

Sugar  Charcoal  Hides 

Kum  Logwood  Cocoa 

Molasses  Firewood  Coffee 

From  a  return  given  to  parliament  in  1854 
it  would  appear  that  then  the  only  British 
colonies  which  levied  a  duty  on  exports  were 
the  West  Indian  islands  of  St.  Lucia,  St. 
Christopher,  Nevis,  Montserrat,  and  the  Virgin 
Islands,  and  the  Mauritius  which  exacted  9d. 
the  100  lbs.  on  sugar.  The  Turk's  Islands 
imposed  a  ^d.  per  bushel  on  salt.  But  it  was 
inevitable  that  a  principle  admitted  in  the  case 
of  a  special  service  should  sometimes  extend 
itself ;  and  in  later  years  there  has  been  an 
increased  tendency  to  levy  export  duties  in  the 
West  Indies  ;  while  in  New  Brunswick,  for  a 
time,  there  were  certain  export  duties  on  lumber, 
and  in  Prince  Edward  Island  in  1861  a  special 
duty  was  provisionally  authorised  to  be  collected 
for  a  special  purpose  on  all  agricultural  produce 
exported.  In  the  Bahamas  so  lately  as  1870 
and  1873  a  general  export  duty  on  aU  produce 
was  imposed  ;  but  that  has  now  been  dispensed 
with  ;  the  Virgin  Islands  being  now  the  only 
instance  of  the  survival  of  general  export  duties, 
which  are  almost  entirely  evaded,  upon  all 
the  commodities  which  nature  will  allow  those 
islands  to  produce.  Such  duties  were  distinctly 
condemned  by  the  royal  commission  which 
inquired  into  the  finances  of  various  West 
Indian  colonies  in  1883-84  (v.  their  report, 
pt.  iv.). 

At  the  present  time  export  duties  are  levied, 
usually  for  purposes  of  immigration,  in  many 
of  the  West  Indian  colonies,  but  not  British 
Guiana.  In  one  or  two  cases  they  are  levied 
under  a  delusive  name,  e.g.  "  statistical  tax," 
in  others  they  are  indirectly  increased  by  wharf- 
age duties  for  outward  goods.  In  Ti-inidad, 
besides  the  duties,  on  products  of  the  cane,  there 
is  an  export  duty  on  pitch.  In  Turk's  Islands 
that  on  salt  remains  a  chief  source  of  revenue. 
New  South  Wales,  Western  Australia,  and  Natal 
levy  one  on  gold.  The  Fiji  Islands,  for  pur- 
poses of  regulating  the  trade,  levied  one  in  1877 
on  sUver  coin  and  sandalwood,  and  in  1887  on 
Mche  de  m&r.  The  duties  on  pitch,  gold,  and 
salt  are  generally  looked  on  as  royalties  and  in 
the  nature  rather  of  a  rent  than  a  tax. 

The  plantations  on  the  mainland  of  America 
appear  never  to  have  paid  an  export  duty,  and 
the  United  States  maintained  the  tradition, 
which  also  fell  in  with  their  policy  of  encouraging 
exportation  as  much  as  possible.  One  feature 
in  the  recent  commercial  policy  of  the  United 
States  deserves  special  mention.  In  the  many 
treaties  or  agreements  which  they  have  been 
negotiating  with  the  Central  American  and 
other  states,  they  have  carefully  guarded  them- 
selves against  the  possibility  of  an  export  duty 


EXPROPRIATION 


797 


being  levied  in  the  contracting  state ;  apparently 
arguing  that  the  imposition  of  such  a  duty  is 
an  attempt  to  raise  the  price  to  the  United 
States  consumer,  and  must,  therefore,  be  treated 
as  an  unfriendly  act  to  be  punished  by  a  counter- 
yailing  duty. 

In  foreign  countries  duties  on  the  exportation 
of  commodities  are  still  prevalent,  levied  some- 
times on  the  chief  product  of  the  country,  as  on 
the  charcoal  and  olive  oil  of  Italy,  in  other  cases 
as  protective  of  home  manufactures,  as  in  the 
case  of  Swedish  iron. 

The  views  which  have  prevailed  as  to  the 
incidence  of  export  duties  have  been  indicated 
in  several  passages  above.  The  accepted  view 
that  the  duty  operates  as  a  restriction  to  ex- 
portation, except  where  the  exporting  country 
has  a  monopoly  of  production,  appears  to  be 
correct.  If  all  countries  levied  export  duties 
in  exporting  the  same  commodity  the  price  of 
the  commodity  would  be  raised  to  cover  the 
amount  of  the  duty,  and  the  foreign  consumer 
would  eventually  pay  the  duty  or  the  greater 
part  of  it.  But  as  the  facts  are  contrary  to 
this  hypothesis,  it  will  be  found  in  almost  all 
cases,  e.g.  sugar  exported  from  the  West  Indies 
— that  the  price  paid  by  the  foreign  consumer 
is  determined  by  stronger  considerations  :  the 
exporter  cannot  control  it ;  the  duty  falls  on 
him.  and  enhances  his  expenses  in  production, 
or  perhaps  more  accurately  it  lessens  his  profits. 
In  any  special  case  the  factors  which  determine 
price  are  important  in  deciding  the  incidence. 
The  case  of  monopoly  is  nowadays  hardly  of 
practical  importance. 

[Petty's  Treatise  of  Taxes  and  Contributions, 
1679,  chap.  vi. — Saxby's  British  Customs,  London, 
1757. — Sinclair's  Ristory  of  the  Public  Revenues^ 
London,  1804,  esp.  pt.  iii. — Jickling's  Digest  of 
the  Customs  Laws,  1815,  esp.  the  Pref. — McCulloch 
On  Taxation,  1845,  bk.  v. — McCullocli's  edition 
of  Adam  Smith's  Wealth  of  Nations,  vol.  iii.  p. 
460. — Tlie  First  Report  of  the  Commissioners  of 
Cicstoms,  1857. — Dowell's  ^is^on/  of  Taxation  and 
Taxes  in  England,  2nd  ed.,  1888,  bk.  i.  c.  5,  et 
passim. — Hall's  History  of  the  Customs,  1885.] 

o.  A.  H. 

EXPROPRIATION'.  Expropriation  may  be 
defined  as  the  compulsory  sale  of  private  pro- 
perty either  to  the  state  or  to  private  parties 
who  have  received  specific  authority  from  the 
state. 

That  such  compulsory  sale  is  sometimes  in- 
dispensable to  the  public  welfare  is  too  obvious 
to  need  demonstration.  The  necessity  for  ex- 
propriation can  rarely  arise  in  the  case  of 
movable  property.  Such  articles  can  almost 
always  be  obtained  by  a  voluntary  transaction, 
if  not  from  one  owner,  then  from  another. 
The  acquisition  of  a  particular  movable  can 
hardly  ever  be  matter  of  necessity  to  the  state. 
Even  a  unique  picture  or  statue  is  a  luxury 
which  it  is  not  advisable  for  the  state  to 
acquire   at  the   cost  of  infringing  upon    the 


general  freedom  of  an  owner  to  dispose  of  his 
property  at  his  pleasure.  In  come  coimtries 
the  finder  of  antiquities  is  obliged  to  transfer 
them  to  the  state  on  receiving  compensation. 
But  this  exceptional  rule  is  of  no  economic 
importance.  With  reference  to  immovable 
property  the  case  is  different.  Not  only  is 
land  necessary  as  the  basis  of  human  industry 
and  limited  in  extent,  but  the  land  suitable  for 
a  specific  public  purpose  is  often  very  nan*owly 
limited  indeed.  In  order  to  lay  out  a  street 
or  a  railway,  to  construct  a  public  building, 
a  fortress,  or  a  harbour,  particular  pieces  of  land 
must  be  obtained,  even  although  their  owners 
do  not  desire  to  part  Avith  them.  If  no  com- 
pulsion were  to  be  used  in  such  cases  the  state 
would  be  reduced  to  offer  a  preposterous  price 
or  to  forego  a  necessary  improvement. 

But  expropriation  is  allowable  only  in  order 
to  effect  an  appreciable  public  good.  All  com- 
pulsion is  painful,  and  pain  should  not  be 
inflicted  without  a  rational  object.  The 
presumption  is  in  favour  of  letting  every  man 
do  as  he  likes  with  his  own.  Therefore  the 
burden  of  proof  lies  upon  those  who  advocate 
expropriation  in  any  particular  instance. 

To  what  extent  expropriation  should  be 
carried  is  a  wider  question  than  that  to  which 
these  remarks  must  be  limited.  We  need  not 
inquire  whether  the  state  would  be  justified 
in  expropriating  certain  species  of  projierty  on 
the  ground  that  it  could  manage  them  more 
advantageously  to  the  whole  community  than 
private  owners  could  or  Avould  do.  Such  an 
inquiry  belongs  rather  to  the  head  of  State 
Interference  (q.v.).  Nor  need  we  inquire 
here  into  the  kindred  question  whether  it 
would  be  right  to  expropriate,  say,  la,rge  estates 
in  order  to  break  them  up  and  sell  the  land  in 
small  parcels  so  as  to  multiply  peasant  pro- 
prietors. Nor  need  we  determine  whether  the 
state  would  do  well  to  acquire  certain  sj)ecies 
of  property  on  the  ground  that  they  tend  to 
increase  in  value  merely  through  the  general 
progress  of  society,  and  that  this  increase  should 
go  to  enrich  the  community  rather  than  indi- 
viduals (see  Increment,  the  Unearned).  It  is 
enough  for  us  that  the  necessity  of  expropria- 
tion in  certain  cases  is  admitted  by  the  great 
majority  of  persons  who  have  considered  the 
subject.  We  have  only  to  consider  upon  what 
principles  expropriation,  when  necessary,  should 
be  conducted. 

In  case  of  expropriation  the  owner  should 
receive  at  least  the  price  which  he  could  obtain 
in  the  open  market,  if  he  were  disposed  to  sell. 
The  market  price  is  the  only  impartial  and  trust- 
worthy measure  of  the  value  of  property.  It 
represents  the  value  of  property  under  all  the 
actual  circumstances,  including  the  reasonable 
expectations  to  which  the  laws  and  policy  of 
the  state  have  given  rise.  It  is  unworthy  of 
a  civilised  government  to  pursue  a  certain  class 


798 


EXPROPRIATION— EYTON 


of  owners  with  covert  hostility,  to  burthen 
them  with  overwhelming  taxes,  or  to  deny 
them  ettectual  protection,  in  order  to  make 
their  property  worthless,  and  then  to  buy  it  at 
so  many  years'  purchase  of  zero.  Yet  these 
expedients  are  occasionally  recommended  in 
our  time  by  persons  who  profess  to  have  a 
special  sense  of  political  justice.  Even  in  the 
case  where  the  state  interferes  to  suppress  a  form 
of  property  distinctly  condemned  by  the  im- 
proved morality  of  the  general  public,  it  still 
owes  compensation  to  the  proprietors  affected. 
When  the  British  parliament  compensated  the 
West  Indian  slave-owners  it  acted  on  the  sound 
principle  that  the  state,  which  for  many  genera- 
tions had  recognised  and  maintained  the  law- 
fulness of  slavery,  was  particeps  criminis,  and 
ought  to  take  its  share  of  the  loss.  But  in  cases 
of  this  kind  the  right  amoiint  of  the  compensa- 
tion may  be  more  doubtful  than  in  others. 

Where  the  owner  of  property  expropriated 
has  increased  its  returns  by  a  violation  of  the 
law  the  case  is  different.  If  the  owner  of  a 
house  permits  it  to  be  over-crowded  with  lodgers, 
he  has  no  right  to  compensation  for  the  extra 
rent  which  he  has  thus  received.  If  he  lessens 
his  outgoings  by  allowing  the  house  to  fall 
out  of  repair,  the  cost  of  the  repairs  neces- 
sary to  make  it  habitable  should  be  deducted 
from  the  compensation  paid.  If  the  house  is 
so  ruinous  that  no  repair  can  make  it  habitable, 
he  is  entitled  to  compensation  only  for  the  site 
and  the  materials.  In  other  words  the  market 
value,  which  forms  the  basis  of  compensation, 
must  be  understood  as  the  market  value  obtain- 
able vyithxmt  a  breach  of  the  law.  It  would  be 
monstrous  that  a  man  should  obtain  compensa- 
tion for  relinquishing  a  profit  which  is  illegal. 

Subject  to  these  qualifications,  then,  the 
amount  of  the  compensation  should  not  be  less 
than  the  market  value.  But  it  may  justifiably 
be  somewhat  more.  Over  and  above  the  loss 
of  his  property,  he  who  sells  against  his  will 
suffers  the  pain  of  compulsion,  and  for  this  a 
reasonable  allowance  should  be  made.  Distinc- 
tion may  be  made  between  objects  which  have 
and  objects  which  have  not  "a  value  of 
affection."  Thus  one  acre  of  arable  land  differs 
from  another  acre  of  arable  land  only  in  its 
capacity  of  producing  wealth.  He  who  is  com- 
pelled to  seU  one  field  is  usually  able  to  buy 
another  field  which  wiU  do  just  as  well.  But  the 
house  where  a  man  has  lived  all  his  life  may 
be  much  more  to  him  than  any  other  house  of 
equal  value.  If  compelled  to  sell  it,  he  cannot 
buy  another  which  will  be  the  same  to  him. 
Prima  facie,  therefore,  the  indemnity  for  con- 
straint  put  upon  an  owner  to  sell  should  be 


more  liberal  in  this  case  than  in  the  other. 
Compensation,  however,  must  be  assessed  on 
general  rules,  and  fine  gradations  of  feeling 
cannot  always  be  taken  into  account. 

Yet  another  difficulty  remains.  The  owner 
who  is  compelled  to  sell  part  of  his  property 
may  have  the  value  of  the  remainder  greatly 
augmented  by  the  public  works  for  which  the 
land  was  taken.  Whether  this  prospective 
improvement  should  be  taken  into  account  in 
assessing  the  compensation  due  to  him  is  a 
much-disputed  question  (see  Betterment). 

The  principles  of  compensation  will  be  the 
same  whether  the  party  taking  by  compulsion 
be  the  national  government  or  a  municipal 
authority  or  a  private  joint-stock  company  or 
individual.  But,  when  the  state  confers  the 
power  of  expropriation  upon  its  subordinates  or 
upon  private  parties,  it  is  entitled  to  determine 
the  objects  for  which  this  power  shall  be  ex- 
ercised, the  extent  to  which  it  shall  be  exercised, 
and  the  service  which  shall  be  rendered  to  the 
public  by  those  who  are  invested  with  it. 
These,  however,  are  points  which  must  be 
determined  by  common  sense  in  each  case  as 
it  arises.  f.  c.  m. 

[See  also  Eminent  Domain.  ] 

EXTENSIVE  CULTIVATION  (see  In- 
tensive Cultivation). 

EXTENTS  (see  Court  Rolls,  Manorial 
Accounts,  and  Extents). 

EXTRANEUS.  A  freeman  by  birth  coming 
into  a  manor  from  outside,  and  so  opposed  to 
nativus,  but  holding  land  on  it  by  villein  tenure. 
He  could  not,  however,  be  ejected  as  long  as  he 
performed  the  services  due  from  his  holding, 
and  he  could  surrender  the  holding  at  will. 
Vinogradoff  shows  (Villainage  in  England, 
1891,  p.  63),  against  Britton's  theory,  that  the 
descendants  of  an  extraneus  might  lapse  into 
villainage  in  the  fifth  generation. 

[Vinogradoff,  pp.  77-82,  142.]  e.  g.  p. 

EYTON,  Robert  William  (1815-1881),  was 
born  at  Wellington  (Salop)  ;  graduated  from 
Christ  Church,  Oxford,  in  1839.  He  is  best 
known  as  an  antiquary,  but  his  works  are  of 
value  to  the  economist  for  the  information  they 
contain  on  the  economics  of  the  Middle  Ages, 
and  especially  on  the  fiscal  systems  of  the 
Anglo-Norman  kings. 

Such  of  his  works  are :  Domesday  Studies 
(Somerset),  London,  1881. — Domesday  Studies 
(Stafford),  London,  1881. — Key  to  Domesday, 
London,  1878. — Notes  on  Domesday,  London, 
1880.  — 27ie  Staffwdshire  Pipe  Rolls,  vol.  i., 
London,  1880. 

[See  life  in  Didionwry  of  National  Biography."] 


END  OF  VOL    r 


LIST   OF   CONTRIBUTORS. 


Initials.  Names. 

F.  E.  A.         F.  E.  Allum,  Royal  Mint,  Perth, 

Western  Australia. 
w.  J.  A.        W.  J.  Ashley,  M.A.,  Dean  of  tne 
Faculty  of  Commerce,  University 
of  Birmingham. 

A.  E.  B.  Sir  A.  E.  Bateman,  K.C.M.G., 
formerly  Comptroller  Genl.  of 
Commerce,  etc..  Board  of  Trade. 

c.  F.  B.  C.  F.  Bastable,  LL.D.,  Professor 
of  Political  Economy  in  Trinity 
College,  Dublin. 

J.  B.  J.  BoNAR,  M.A.,  LL.D.,  Deputy 

Master  of  the  Mint,  Ottawa, 
Canada. 

R.  w.  B.        R.  W.  Barnett. 

s,  B.  Stephan    Bauer,    Doctor    Juris, 

University,  Vienna  ;  Handels- 
kamraer,  Briinn,  Austria. 

N.  P.  V.  deB.  Dr.  N.  P.  Van  den  Berg,  Governor 
of  the  Bank  of  Holland,  Amster- 
dam. 

s.  BO.  Stephen  Bourne,  F.S.S. 

s.  c.  B.  The  Right  Hon.  Viscount  Buxton, 
formerly  President  of  the  Board 
of  Trade. 

A.  c.  Rev.  A.  Caldecott,  M.A.,  Fellow 

of  St.  John's  College,  Cambridge ; 
Professor  of  Mental  and  Moral 
Philosophy,  King's  College, 
London. 

A.  c.  f.  A.       Courtois,       fils,       formerly 

Secretaire  Perp^tuel  de  ia  Societe 
d'Economie  Politique  de  Paris. 

A.  K.  c.  A.  K.  Connell,  M.A.,  New 
College,  Oxford. 

0.  E.  c.  Clara  E.  Collet,  M.A.,  Board  of 
Trade. 

c.  G.  c.         C.  G.  Crump,  Public  Record  Office. 

E.  c.  Edwin    Cannan,    M.A.,    Balliol 

College,  Oxford ;  Professor  of 
Political  Economy  in  the  Uni- 
versity of  London. 

E.  ca.  E.  Castelot,  Correspondent  of  the 

British  Economic  Association, 
Paris. 

G.  c.  George  Clare. 

J.  B.  c.  J.  B.  Clark,  Ph.D.,  LL.D.  Col- 
umbia College,  New  York,  U.S.A. 


Initials.  Names. 

M.  D.  c.  Sir  M.  D.  Chalmers,  K.O.B., 
C.S.I.,  formerly  Permanent 
Under-Secretary,  Home  Office. 

p.  G.  c.  Major  P.  G.  Craig ie,  formerly 
Assistant  -  Secretary,  Board  of 
Agriculture  and  Fisheries. 

R.  c.  Sir  Robert   Chalmers,    K.C.B., 

Permanent  Secretary  and  Auditor 
of  the  Civil  List,  Treasury. 

w.  c.  The  Venerable  Archdeacon  W.  Cun- 

ningham, D.D.,  D.Sc,  Fellow 
of  Trinity  College,  Cambridge. 

w.  J.  c.  W.  J.  Corbett,  M.A.,  Fellow  of 
King's  College,  Cambridge. 

A.  D.  Dr.  A,  Daniell,  Advocate,  Edin- 

burgh, and  Barrister-at-Law. 

0.  F.  D.  C.  F.  Dunbar,  LL.D.,  formerly 
Professor  of  Political  Economy 
in  Harvard  University,  U.S.A. 

D.  R.  D.  D.  R.  Dewey,  Ph.L.D.,  Professor, 
Massachusetts  Institute  of  Tech- 
nology, Boston,  Mass.,  U.S.A. 

M.  G.  D.  Mark  G.  Davidson,  Advocate, 
Edinburgh. 

t.  w.  r.  d.  T.W.Rhys  Davids,  LL.D.,  Ph.D., 
Professor  of  Comparative  Re- 
ligion, Manchester,  Professor 
of  Pali  and  Buddhist  Literature 
in  University  College,  London. 


a.  e. 

F.  Y.   E. 


T.   H.   E. 


a.  de  F. 


A.  W.  F. 


W.  F. 


A.  Ellis. 

F.  Y.  Edgeworth,  M.A.,  D.C.L., 

Professor  of  Political  Economy 

in  the  University  of  Oxford. 
Sir  T.  H.  Elliot,  K.C.B.,  Deputy 

Master  and  Comptroller  of  the 

Mint. 

A.  de  Foville,  Conseiller-maitre 
a  la  Cour  des  Comptes,  Secretaire 
perpetuel  de  I'Academie  des 
Sciences,  ancien  Directeur  de 
I'Admn.  des  Monnaies  de  France, 
membre  de  I'lnstitut,  Paris. 

A.  W.  Flux,  M.A.,  Fellow  of  St. 
John's  College,  Cambridge — 
Director  of  the  Census  of  Pro- 
duction, Board  of  Trade. 

William  Fowler,  LL.B. 


800 


DICTIONAEY  OF  POLITICAL  ECONOMY 


Initials. 
C.  G. 


E.  0.  G. 


H. 

B. 

G. 

A. 

H. 

C. 

A. 

H. 

E. 

H. 

F. 

n. 

G. 

H. 

H. 

H. 

H. 

H.  iia. 

W.  H. 

W.  A.  S.   H. 

J.  K.    I. 

J.  W.  B.  I. 
E.  J. 
W.  E.  J. 

J.  N.  K. 


M. 

K. 

A. 

F.  V. 

L 

E. 

deL. 

G. 

B.  L. 

E. 

L. 

M.  L. 


T.  L. 
T.  J.  L. 


Names. 

C.  GiDE,  Professeur  d'Economie 
Politique  a  la  Faculty  de  Droit, 
Paris. 

Dr.  Chas.  Gross,  A.M.,  Inst,  in 
History  in  Harvard  University, 
Cambridge,  Mass.,  U.S.A. 

E.  C.  K.  GoNNER,  M.A.,  Professor 
of  Economic  Science  in  the  Uni- 
versity of  Liverpool. 

E.  0.  Greening,  Managing  Director 
of  the  Agricultural  and  Horticul- 
tural Association. 

H.  B.  Greven,  Professor  of  Poli- 
tical Economy  in  the  University 
of  Leyden,  Holland. 

A.  Hughes,  Public  Record  Office. 

C.  A.  Harris,  C.B.,  C.M.G., 
M.V.O.,  Chr.  College,  Cam- 
bridge— Colonial  Office. 

Elijah  Helm,  Manchester. 

F.  Hendriks,  F.S.S.,  F.LA. 

G.  H.  Hunt,  I.S.O.,  Treasury. 
Henry     Higgs,     LL.B.,     C.B., 

Treasury. 
Hubert  Hall,  F.S.A,,  Assistant 

Keeper  of  the  Records,    Public 

Record  Office. 
Wynnard   Hooper,   M.A.,   Clare 

College,  Cambridge. 
W.   A.  S.  He  WINS,  M.A.,  M.P., 

Pembroke  College,  Oxford. 

J.  K  Ingram,  LL.D.,  formerly 
Fellow  and  Vice  -  Provost  of 
Trinity  College,  Dublin. 

J.  W.  Brodie  Innes. 

E.  Johnstone. 

W.  E.  Johnson,  M.A.,  King's  Col- 
lege, Cambridge. 

J.  N.  Keynes,  M.A.,  D.Sc,  late 
Fellow  of  Pembroke  College, 
Cambridge. 

Rev.  M.  Kaufmann,  M.A. 

Dr.  A.  F.  V.  Leyden,  Doctor  of  Law, 
Holland. 

Professor  E.  de  Laveleye,  Liege. 

G.  B.  Longstaff,  M.A.,  M.D. 

R.  Lodge,  M.A.,  Professor  of 
History  in  the  University  of 
Edinburgh. 

Stanley  M.  Leathes,  C.B.,  M.A., 
Fellow  of  Trinity  College,  Cam- 
bridge, Civil  Service  Commis- 
sion. 

T.  LoNGHURST,  Hon.  Secy.,  British 
Chamber  of  Commerce,  Paris. 

Rev.  T.  J.  Lawrence,  M.A., 
LL.D.,  Lecturer  on  International 
Law  at  the  Royal  Naval  College, 
Greenwich,  and  at  the  Rdyal 
Naval  War  College,  Portsmouth. 


Initials. 
W.  L. 


Names. 
Walter  Lupton. 


A.  c.  M.  A.  C.  Miller,  M.A.,  Professor, 
University  of  Chicago. 

E.  M.  EWING  MaTHIESON. 

E.  A.  M.        Ellen     A,      M Arthur,     Head 

Lecturer  in  History  at  Girton 
College,  Cambridge. 

F.  c.  M.        F.  C.  Montague,  M.A.,lsometime 

Fellow  of  Oriel  College,  Oxford, 
Professor  of  History  in  Univer- 
sity College,  London. 

F.  w.  M.  F.  W.  Maitland,  LL.D.,  for- 
merly Professor  of  the  Laws  of 
England  in  the  University  of 
Cambridge. 

J.  M.  Professor  James  Mayor,  Professor 

of  Political  Economy,  University 
of  Toronto. 

J.  e.  0.  M.    J.  E.  C.  Munro,  LL.D. 

R.  M.-s,  Richmond  Mayo-Smith,  Ph.D., 
Professor,  Columbia  University, 
New  York  City,  U.S.A. 

s.  M.  Samuel  Montagu,  the  Right  Hon. 

Baron  Swaythling. 

J.  s.  N.  J.  S.  Nicholson,  M.A.,i  D.Sc, 
Professor  of  Commercial  and 
Political  Economy  and  Mercantile 
Law  in  the  University  of  Edin- 
burgh. 

V.  N.  Vaughan  Nash,  C.B.,  C.V.O. 

E.  B.  O.  E.  B.  OSBORN,  M.A. 


E.  G. 

F.  p. 


G.  II. 

J.  p. 

J.   R. 


L.  R. 
M.   P. 


R.   L. 
W.  P. 


Eleanor  G.  Powell,  Somemlle 
College,  Oxford. 

The  Right  Hon.  Sir  Frederick 
Pollock,  Bart.,  M.A.,  Professor 
of  Jurisprudence  in  the  Univer- 
sity of  Oxford. 

G.  H.  Pownall. 

J.  Peirson,  F.C.A. 

Sir  J.  R.  Paget,  Bart.,  R.C,  LL.B., 
M.A.,  Temple,  Gilbart  Lecturer 
on  Banking. 

L.  L.  Price,  M.A.,  Oriel  College, 
Reader  in  Economic  History  in 
the  University  of  Oxford. 

Rev.  L.  R.  Phelps,  M.A.,  Fellow 
of  Oriel  College,  Oxford. 

Signor  M.  Pantaleoni,  Professor 
of  Political  Economy  in  the 
University  of  Rome,  Co-editor  of 
the  Giornali  degli  Uconomisti. 

R.  E.  Prothero,  M.A.,  M.V.O., 
late  Fellow  of  All  Souls  College, 
Oxford,  M.P.  Univ.  of  Oxford. 

R.  L.  Poole,  M.A.,  Jesus  College, 
Oxford. 

Rev.  William  Patrick,  D.D., 
Principal  of  Manitoba  College, 
Winnipeg,  Canada. 


LIST  OF  CONTRIBUTORS 


801 


Initials.  Names. 

D.  G.  R.        D.    G.    Ritchie,    M.A.,    formerly 

Professor  of  Logic  and  Meta- 
physics, University  of  St. 
Andrews,  N.B. 

G.  B.  Professor  G.    Rossi,   Office  of  the 

Treasury,  Rome. 

J.  R.  John  Rae,  M.A. 

J.  E.  T.  R.  Professor  J.  E.  Thorold  Rogers, 
M.A.,  sometime  Professor  of 
Political  Economy  in  the  Uni- 
versity of  Oxford. 

T.  R.  The  Hon.  Sir  Thomas  Rai.eigh, 

M.A.,  K.C.S.I.,  K.C.,  Fellow 
of  All  Souls  College,  Oxford, 
Member  of  the  India  Council. 

w.  R.-A.  Professor  Sir  W.  Roberts- Austen, 
F.R.S.,  Royal  Mint,  Tower  Hill. 

E.  s.  E.  Schuster  (Doctor  Juris,  Uni- 

versity, Munich),  Lincoln's  Inn. 

F.  E.  s.         F.  E.  Steele. 

G.  F.  s.         GusTAV  F.  Steffen. 

H.  s.  Henry  Sidgw^ick,  Litt.D.,  some- 

time Professor  of  Moral  Phil- 
osophy in  the  University  of 
Cambridge. 


Initials.  Names. 

h.  m.  s.  H.  Morse  Stephens,  M.A.,  Pro- 
fessor of  History  and  Director  of 
University  Extension,  University 
of  California,  U.S.A.,  late  of 
Balliol  College,  Oxford. 
J.  s.  John  Smith,  C.B.,  Board  of  Trade. 

Professor  F.  W.  Taussig,  LL.B., 
Ph.D.,     Professor    of    Political 
Economy,  Harvard  University. 
H.  R.  Tedder. 

Sir    Edmund    AValker,    C.V.O., 
LL.D.,  D.C.L.,  President  of  the 
Canadian  Bank  of  Commerce. 
E.  Waterhouse,  B.A. 
E.  A.  Whittuck,  M.A.,  Oriel  Col- 
lege, Oxford. 
G.  w.  Graham  Wallas,  M.A.,  Lecturer 

at  the  London  School  of  Econo- 
mics, 
p.  w.  P.Waterhouse,M.A.,A.R.I.B.A., 

Balliol  College,  Oxford, 
p.  H.  w.       Rev.  P.  H.  Wicksteed,  M.A. 
s.  w.  Spenser       Wilkinson,       M.A., 

Chichele    Professor    of    Military 
History,  Oxford. 


F. 

w. 

t. 

II 

e. 
e. 

R. 
W. 

W. 

T. 

E. 

A. 

W. 

The  Editor  takes  the  responsibility  of  the  unsigned  Articles. 


Printed  by  R.  &  R.  Ct.ARK,  Limited,  Edinhtrgh, 


A 


In  Three  Volumes.     Medium  ^vo.     21 5.  net  each. 

Vol.  L— A  to  E.         Vol.  IL— F  to  M.         Vol  III— N  to  Z. 

Appendix  to  Vol.  III.,  Separately,  Sewed.     2s.  6d.  net. 

DICTIONARY 

OF 

POLITICAL    ECONOMY 

EDITED   BY 

Sir  R.  H.  INGLIS  PALGRAVE,  F.R.S. 

ECONOMIC  JOURNAL — "Its  value  is  manifest;  ample  and  trust- 
worthy information,  abundance  of  verified  documents,  bibliography  of 
inappreciable  value,  it  must  be  the  vade  mecum  of  him  who  wishes  more 
knowledge." 

STATIST. — "An  excellent  cyclopaedia  of  all  matters  pertainiug  to 
political  economy." 

STANDARD. — "  A  financial  work  of  more  than  ordinary  importance. 
.  .  .  The  information  has  been  well  brought  up  to  date.  .  .  .  Equally 
valuable  to  the  student  of  finance  or  political  economy  and  to  the  business 
community." 

OBSERVER.— ''Mx.  Palgrave's  extremely  valuable  work." 

SCOTSMAN. — "  Mr.  Palgrave  is  to  be  congratulated  on  having  brought 
together  a  vast  amount  of  valuable  material  and  arranged  it  in  a  fashion  in 
which  it  will  be  readily  accessible." 

MACMILLAN  AND  CO.,  Lm,  LONDON. 


WORKS  ON  POLITICAL  ECONOMY 

By  ALFRED  MARSHALL. 

PRINCIPLES    OF    ECONOMICS.     An  Introductory  Volume.     Sixth  Edition. 
8vo.     12s.  6d.  net. 

ELEMENTS  OF  ECONOMICS  OF  INDUSTRY.     Being  the  first  volume  of 

"Elements  of  Economics."     Third  Edition.     Crown  8vo.     3s.  6d. 

NATIONAL  INDUSTRIES  AND  INTERNATIONAL  TRADE.     8vo. 

[In  the  Press. 

By  Prof.  W.  SMART. 

THE  ECONOMIC  ANNALS   OF  THE  NINETEENTH  CENTURY.     Vol.  I. 

1801-1820.     8vo.     21s.net.     {Yo\.  II.  in  the  Press.) 

THE  DISTRIBUTION  OF  INCOME.      Second  Edition.      Extra    Crown   8vo. 
.3s.  6d.  net. 

THE  RETURN  TO  PROTECTION.    Second  Edition.    Crown  8vo.    3s.  6d.  net. 
AN  INTRODUCTION   TO  THE  THEORY  OF  VALUE  ON   THE   LINES 

OF  MENGER,  WIESER,  AND  BOHM-BAWERK.    Third  Edition.  Crown  8vo.   Is.  6d.  net. 
SECOND  THOUGHTS  OF  AN  ECONOMIST.     Crown  8vo.  [In  the  Press. 

By  Prof.  A.  C.  PIGOU. 

WEALTH  AND  WELFARE.     8vo.     10s.  net. 

PRINCIPLES   AND    METHODS    OF   INDUSTRIAL    PEACE.     Crown  8vo. 

3s.  6d.  net. 

PROTECTIVE    AND    PREFERENTIAL    IMPORT    DUTIES.      Crown  8vo. 

2s.  6d.  net. 

By  Prof.  C.  F.  BASTABLE. 

PUBLIC  FINANCE.     Third  Edition.     8vo.     12s.  6d.  net. 

THE   THEORY    OF   INTERNATIONAL    TRADE    WITH    SOME   OF    ITS 

APPLICATIONS  TO  ECONOMIC  POLICY.     Fourth  Edition.     Crown  8vo.     3s.  6d.  net. 

By  W.  S.  JEVONS. 

THE    THEORY    OF    POLITICAL    ECONOMY.      With   Notes,   etc.,    by   H. 
Stanley  Jevons,  M.A.     Fourth  Edition.     8vo.     10s.  net. 

PRINCIPLES   OF   ECONOMICS.     With  a  Preface  by   Henry  Higgs.     8vo. 

lOs.  net. 

INVESTIGATIONS    IN    CURRENCY   AND    FINANCE.      Edited   by   Prof. 
H.  S.  FoxvvELL.     Abridged  Edition.     8vo.     lOs.  net. 


PRINCIPLES   OF   ECONOMICS.      By  Dr.    N.  O.   Pierson.     Translated  by 
A.  A.  "VVoTZEL.     2  vols.     8vo.     lOs.  net  each. 

PRINCIPLES    OF    ECONOMICS.     By  Prof.  F.  W.  Taussig.     2  vols.     8vo. 

8s.  6d.  net  each. 

THE    PRINCIPLES    OF    POLITICAL    ECONOMY.      By   Professor   Henry 
SiDGWiCK.     8vo.     14s.  net. 


•/ 


MACMILLAN  AND  CO.,  Ltd.,  LONDON. 


Palgrave,  R. 
Dictionary. 


/HB 
61 
.P2  • 

T.l